View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Economic
j Review
FEDERAL R E S E R V E BANK O F A T L A N W ^ E R A L RLS, RVE BANK
I
OV PH1LAÜ LPHIA

MAY 1 9 8 1

ÏX990 S.E. Demographic Outlook

| G N P REVISIONS
* IIA M I

HOW

Important?

Foreign Deposit Profile

1 C H R Y S L E R Regional Repercussions
A G R I C U L T U R E Forces of Change




Economic m
Review Wm
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ATLANTA
President: William F. Ford
Sr. Vice President
and Director of Research:
Donald L. Koch
Vice President
and Associate Director of Research:
William N. Cox III
Financial Structure:
B. Frank King, Research Officer
David D. Whitehead
National Economics:
Robert E. Keleher
Regional and International Economics:
Gene D. Sullivan, Research Officer
Donald E. Baer, Research Officer
Charlie Carter
William J. Kahley
Database Management:
Delores W. Steinhauser
Editing: Gary W. Tapp
Graphics: Susan F. Taylor and
Eddie W. Lee, Jr.

Free subscription and additional copies
available u p o n request to t h e I n f o r m a t i o n
C e n t e r , Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta,
P.O. Box 1731, Atlanta, Georgia 30301. Material h e r e i n may be r e p r i n t e d or abstracted, p r o v i d e d this Review, the Bank,
and the author are credited. Please provide
this Bank's Research D e p a r t m e n t with a
copy of any publication in w h i c h such material is reprinted.

The purpose of the Economic Review is to inform the public about Federal Reserve policies and the
economic environment and, in particular, to narrow the gap between specialists and concerned laymen.

2




M A Y 1 9 8 1 , E C O N O M I C REVIEW

The Southeast in the 1980s

4

Now that the last of t h e b a b y b o o m has e n t e r e d the
labor force, w h a t will h a p p e n to e c o n o m i c g r o w t h in the
Southeast? H o w will the region's e m p l o y m e n t , income,
a n d p o p u l a t i o n in 1990 c o m p a r e with the rest of the
nation? W h a t is the d e m o g r a p h i c o u t l o o k for individual
states in the region?

Faulty Diagnosis: The GNP Revisions

..17

Southeastern Agriculture in the 80s . . . .

12

W h a t are the forces that will c h a n g e s o u t h e a s t e r n
agriculture d u r i n g the next 10 years? H o w will c o m p e t i tive positions shift? A l o n g - t e r m look at the region's
agricultural i n d u s t r y

Regional Repercussions
• of a Chrysler Failure

23

Recently, the C o m m e r c e D e p a r t m e n t , u s i n g u p d a t e d
s a m p l i n g information, r e v i s e d its G N P figures from
1946 to 1980. T h e n e w figures s h o w a stronger e c o n o m y over t h e past four years. W h y d i d the figures
c h a n g e for t h e better, h o w i m p o r t a n t are the revisions,
a n d w h a t are the i m p l i c a t i o n s for e c o n o m i c policy?

If Chrysler C o r p o r a t i o n s h o u l d eventually fail, how
w o u l d it affect i n c o m e a n d e m p l o y m e n t in the Southeast? W h i c h southeastern locations w o u l d b e a f f e c t e d
most?

The U.S. Economic Outlook:
No Instant Miracles

International Deposits in Miami —
A Profile

25

Robert F. Lanzillotti, D e a n of t h e G r a d u a t e S c h o o l of
Business, University of Florida, recently s p o k e to the
B o a r d of D i r e c t o r s of the A t l a n t a Federal Reserve Bank
on the R e a g a n e c o n o m i c p l a n a n d the short-run outlook. E x c e r p t s f r o m his remarks.

V O L U M E LXVI, N O . 3




28

A l m o s t $2.5 billion in international d e p o s i t s w a s held
by Miami b a n k i n g entities as of J u n e 1980. B a s e d o n
interviews with 14 Miami c o m m e r c i a l banks, E d g e Act
corporations, a n d foreign b a n k a g e n c i e s , this article
d e s c r i b e s these international d e p o s i t s a n d the reasons
w h y international b a n k i n g activity is s u r g i n g in Miami.

3

The Southeast
in the 1980s
T h e Southeast will see continued above-average economic growth in the 1980s,
but t h e level of regional income will remain below the national average for some
time. With t h e maturity of the baby boom generation, population growth will
slow in t h e region, b u t n o t as m u c h as nationwide. Migration will continue to
fuel t h e region's rising share of the U.S. population.

As the post-World War II baby boomers were
growing up and entering the labor force in the
1960s and 1970s, states of the Sixth District
were making great strides in attracting
population and businesses to the Southeast. 1
Well e n d o w e d w i t h sun, water, and other
natural resources, yet underpopulated,
underurbanized, and underindustrialized
relative to n o r t h e r n and midwestern states,
the Southeast has benefited from large inflows
of capital f o r investment in plant and
equipment in new or expanding industries
and from the in-migration of people from
outside the region. The inflows of capital and
people have simultaneously altered the

1

4




ln the remainder of this article, the terms, "Sixth District" and "Southeast," will
be used synonymously and will encompass the six states which comprise the
Sixth Federal Reserve District, including portions of these states located in other
Reserve Districts,

M A Y 1981, E C O N O M I C REVIEW

Table 1. Establishment Employment
Nation
% of total

District
% of total

Farm
Manufacturing
Durables
Nondurables
Mining
Construction
Trade
Government
Transportation,
Communications and
Public Utilities
Services
Finance, Insurance,
and Real Estate
Total N o n f a r m
Total (in 000,

1960

1980

1990

1960

1980

1990

17.3

4.0

3.0

11.5

3.9

3.2

21.6

21.9

21.5

19.5

20.8

27.4

6.8

9.0

10.4

15.4

12.9

13.5

10.4

12.0

8.6

8.4

1.1

1.2

1.1

1.0
4.8

12.9
1.3

10.4
1.2

5.5

6.1

5.8

4.8

4.7

18.6

22.7

23.0

18.6

21.8

22.2

13.6

17.0

16.0

14.9

18.5

17.2

6.1

5.8

5.6

6.5

5.5

5.2

10.9

17.2

17.5

12.0

18.8

19.8

3.9

5.1

6.0

4.3

5.5

5.9

82.7

96.0

97.0

88.5

96.1

96.8

6,361

11,628

13,690

61,246

94,231

108,422

1972 bench marks)
Sources: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis, State Departments of Labor, and Federal Reserve Bank — Atlanta.

region's industrial profile, causing it to more
closely resemble that of the nation as a whole
and enabled the region to grow more rapidly
than the nation as a whole. Population
movement has also caused the population
profile to diverge f r o m that of the nation.
Can w e continue to expect above-average
economic growth in the region now that the
last of the baby boomers have entered the
labor force? To answer this question, we will
first take a quick but careful look at how
employment, income, and population have
changed in the District while these boomers
were growing up. We will then age them 10
years (along w i t h everyone else) and explore
the major demographic and economic
changes which will occur in the 1980s if recent
and prospective economic and demographic
relationships are extended to 1990. H o w ,
under these circumstances, will 1990 compare
to 1980? Will the current decade's progress
match gains of the 1960s and 1970s? What are
the important relationships and issues which

FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F A T L A N T A




will emerge from economic-demographic
interactions d u r i n g the decade?

Changes in Employment, Income, and
Population, 1 9 6 0 - 8 0

Dramatic changes have occurred in the
Southeast's economy since 1960; it has
become more diversified, w i t h an
employment mix increasingly favorable to the
growth of personal income. Since 1960, for
example, farm payroll employment as a
percentage of total payroll employment in the
District is estimated to have fallen from 17
percent in 1960 t o 4 percent in 1980; during
the same period, farm employment in the U.S.
declined, but by less — from 111/2 percent of
the total to 4 percent (Table 1). This reduction
in farm jobs has occurred as farm operations
have become mechanized and as farmers have
switched f r o m crop production to less
labor-intensive livestock production.

5

The share of employment in manufacturing
also declined in this region and the nation in
the period 1960-80, but the relative decline
was sharper for the nation, which, in 1960,
employed a greater share of workers in
manufacturing than did the Southeast.
Convergence of the region's employment and
earnings mix to that of the nation has been
aided by the region's availability of low wage
and nonunionized labor. A generally favorable
business climate, including low taxes, also
helped attract capital to finance expansion of
the share of employment in higher paying
durable goods manufacture and a contraction
in the share of employment in such
nondurables as apparel, food, and textiles.
In the same period, the share of employment in trade, services, and government
expanded sharply, from 44 percent to about
58 percent of payroll employees, for both the
region and the nation — due, largely, to
general economic development. This growth
has offset the falling share of farm and
manufacturing employment.
The changing employment shares partly
explain why overall personal income per
capita in the region increased relative to that
in the nation. In 1960, per capita personal
income totaled only 74 percent of the national
average; by 1980, it rose to about $4,600 (1972
dollars) and represented 86 percent of the
national average. This convergence in per
capita personal income was also aided by the
fact that the labor force in the District,
excluding Florida, was growing more rapidly
than population relative to the nation. And, in
Florida, personal income per capita is
increased by the influx of retirees w i t h
above-average income and below-average
household size.
A marked increase in the region's economic
activity has accompanied the dramatic
structural changes in employment since 1960.
Total employment in the nation expanded
sharply to more than 94.2 million in 1980, up
54 percent from 1960; in that period,
Southeast employment rose by 83 percent,
reaching 11.6 million in 1980.
The remarkable employment change in this
region reflects, of course, the significant
migration to the region. Briefly, in the 20 years
after 1960, roughly the peak of the baby
boom, the District's population has increased

6




by 9.2 million — to a total of 30.4 million in
1980; for the nation, the increase was 48
million — to 226.5 million in 1980. Thus, the
region has accounted for almost one-fifth of
the total growth of the nation, much of it f r o m
foreign and domestic migration to the region.
The share of the nation's population
accounted for by the Southeast now stands at
13.4 percent, up from 11.9 percent in 1960.
Migration has also significantly affected the
region's population age structure compared to
the nation. The Southeast has gone from
having relatively more young in 1960
compared to the nation — 47 percent versus
45 percent in the age group 0-24 — to having
the same relative number of young, 41
percent, in 1980. Meanwhile, the relative
number of elderly has increased in the District
compared to the nation. In 1960, 9 percent of
both populations were age 65 and over, but in
1980, the District's percentage was 13 percent
while the nation's was 11 percent (in 1980, 44
percent of the estimated 3.8 million elderly of
the region resided in Florida). In both the
region and the nation, the population age
25-64 as a share of the total has increased in
this period due to the ending of the baby
boom.

National and Southeast Changes in
Employment, Income, and Population,
1980-90

If recent history serves as a useful guide, the
years of this decade will be marked by
continued growth of employment, income,
and population in the region at rates
exceeding the national average. 2 Furthermore,
all the region's states will benefit f r o m
better-than-average growth, although not all
states will benefit equally. Basically, the region
has developed considerable growth
m o m e n t u m over the past two decades, and,
given the region's existing advantages, that
m o m e n t u m is unlikely to be reversed in the
near future. It may slow, however, as flows of

P r o j e c t i o n s discussed in this article rely heavily on the projections developed by
the Bureau of Economic Analysis's Division of Regional Economic Analysis.
Those projections were modified to roughly take into account the results of the
1980 Census. Also, our employment projections refer to employment as
measured by the establishment survey rather than the more inclusive measure
of employment utilized by BEA.

M A Y 1981, E C O N O M I C REVIEW

capital and people cause wages and prices of
other resources to rise, thus eroding the
region's locational advantages. Further,
despite the prospect of continued
convergence of regional income toward the
national n o r m , the level will remain below the
national for some time. Economic and
demographic changes on the horizon will also
pose new or increased challenges which will
require our continuing attention, analysis, and
reaction.
Total employment in the Southeast is
projected to increase by 18 percent in this
decade, a slowdown from the 1960-80 period
when the baby boomers were swelling the
labor force; the increase for the nation,
meanwhile, is projected t o be 15 percent
(Table 1). Major relative employment gains are
likely for the manufacturing and finance,
insurance, and real estate industries, while
relative declines are expected in farm and
construction employment. In 1990, trade,
services, and government will employ 58
percent of payroll employees in both the
Southeast and the nation, as in 1980.
Manufacturing growth will be spurred by
the expansion of durables manufacturing,
especially the electronic equipment and
nonelectric machinery industries. Meanwhile,
due to slower demand growth and outside
competition, the growth of production of
apparel, textile, and f o o d products will slow;
diversification in the region will thus
continue. The relatively strong growth of
financial employment reflects the growing
strength of the Southeast economy and the
developing importance of the largest
metropolitan areas as financial centers.
Farm employment in the region, which
continues to decline absolutely and relative to
the nation, will account for a lesser share of
employment than it does in the nation by
1990. Construction's employment share also
falls significantly relative to the nation but
continues to be large relative to the nation,
the trends reflecting the slowdown of the
region's population growth and the region's
still rising share of the total population due to
natural increase and migration.
In part because of the continued
convergence of regional employment patterns
to the national profile, per capita personal

FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F A T L A N T A




Chart 1
Population a n d Age Structure
Baby boom moves

into 25-44

bracket.
Nation

District
Age
1980 —

" 7.3%
•7.8

1990—
15.5
14.8

15.3
14.7
18.7

15-24

14.2
15.7
16.3

m
16.3

25-34
11.1

10.0
9.7

11.6
15.0
10.2
10.4

45-54

9.5
8.0

9.5
5.6

55-64

12.7
14.9

9

16.8

35-44

14.2

18

•1990

5 to 14

18.2

%

-1980

7.2%

Under
5

11.2

6 5 or
over

0

0

9

18 %

Sources: U.S. Bureau of the Census, U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis and
Federal Reserve Bank-Atlanta.

income will also continue to converge to the
national average. Per capita personal income
is projected to increase from $4,600 currently
to $6,600 in 1990 (in 1972 dollars); as a
percentage of the national figure, the increase
is from 86 percent to 90 percent.
Demographically, continued convergence of
regional fertility to the national norm will also
contribute to continued per capita income
convergence.
Significant changes in the national and
regional population age structures are in the
o f f i n g in the 1980s (Chart 1). Regional and
national growth is projected to fall from 2.4
percent per year and 1.1 percent per year,
respectively, in the 1970s to 1.5 percent and .9
percent, respectively, in the 1980s. The relative
slowdown in population growth in the

7

I
Chart

2

1990 Age Dependency
Mississippi
rate

will

in

have

Ratios

highest

school

age

dependency

District.

(Persons 5-24 per 100 persons 25-64)
68.5

60.4

5?

Ala.

Florida

6T2 6Z6

Fla.

will

Ga.

have

La.

extremely

Ms.

high

Tn.

District

elderly

Nation

region is due to the region's growing
population base and the relative decline in the
national age pool of likely migrants w h o add
so much to the region's growth. 3
The national trend toward a more stable,
mature, and productive labor force as a
consequence of the aging of baby boomers
will be less pronounced in the Southeast
relative to the nation. Past and expected
migration and natural increase trends are
likely to cause significant differences in
southeastern growth rates by age f r o m the
nation; except for the age group 45-64, growth
rates by age are higher for the Southeast in
the decade of the 1980s. As a consequence,
the District will likely show an overall increase
in the age dependency ratio, with a
particularly sharp increase in the elderly
dependency ratio (Charts 2 & 3).4

dependency

Issues of Growing Importance in the 1980s

rate.
(Persons 65 a n d over per 100 persons 15-64)
72.0

Ala.

Fla.

Louisiana's
elderly)

Ga.

La.

overall
will

be

Ms.

dependency

lowest

in

Tn.

rate

District

(school

Nation

age

plus

International political and economic
developments will impact importantly on the
Southeast — on Florida, in particular. Market
and migration changes — of capital and
people — will significantly influence the
population and business of District states. Will
legal (and illegal) migration, on balance, add

District.

(Persons under 15 plus persons 65 a n d over
per 100 persons 25-64)
50

—

The broad strokes of economic and demographic changes outlined in the preceding
section should, of course, be viewed with
extreme caution. As baseline projections
dependent upon historical tendencies, they
are subject to change as the underlying
assumptions regarding fertility, mortality,
migration, labor force participation, marriage
and divorce rates undergo transformation
and as consumer and government preferences
change and interact w i t h constantly changing
technology — here and abroad. In fact, there
are many developing transformations which
could significantly affect the scenario
presented in addition to the already inherent
uncertainties of the projections.

46.6

25

3

Ala.

Fla.

Ga.

La.

Ms.

Tn.

District

Nation

Sources: U.S. Bureau of Census, U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis and
Federal Reserve Bank-Atlanta.




The improved 1980 Census enumertion of Blacks and Hispanics who live
disproportionately in the Southeast also has caused the 1970s growth rates to be
somewhat overstated.
4
The age dependency ratio takes into account joint changes in the proportions of
children, "workers," and elderly in the population. Age dependency ratios thus
summarize the age structure of a population.

MAY 1981, E C O N O M I C REVIEW

Chart 3
1990 District A g e D e p e n d e n c y Ratio
(District Relative to N a t i o n )
Southeast's
exceed

school

age and elderly

dependency

rates

will

nation's.

Age 5-24

Under 15
plus
65 and over

65 and
over

128.2

105.3

per 100
aged
25-64

per 100
aged
25-64

per 100
aged
15-64

to or subtract f r o m the region's stock of
human and financial capital? W i l l immigrants
be welcomed as potential labor shortages
arise due to expanding markets in Latin
America and declining labor force growth at
home, or will they add ethnic to already
apparent racial tensions?
Nationally, federal government tax,
spending, and regulatory policy changes will
have complex and conflicting effects on the
region's well-being. Will deregulation of
energy prices offset or diminish the region's
current energy advantage by improving the
comparative advantage of northern states
which have suffered f r o m governmentimposed rigidities vis-a-vis the Southeast?
What will be the effects of deregulation of
transportation and financial markets? Will the
end of subsidies to borrowers adversely affect
housing and plant and equipment
construction in the Southeast? How will

FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F ATLANTA




p e n d i n g reallocations of spending and
transfers (more defense, less welfare and
Social Security benefits) affect the region?
Typically, there are positive and negative
implications for the region for each of these
questions.
Interregional^, will the slowdown of
national population growth and the maturing
of the population cause savings and
productivity to rise, leading to more
investment and capital per worker, income,
and sales, especially of luxury goods, or will
stagnation in the North lead to internal
beggar-thy-neighbor policies? What, if
anything, will be the impact of a slowing and
aging population on the structure of demand
and flexibility in the flow of resources? What
will be the impact of increased southeastern
representation in the Congress? How quickly
will low wage rate, land, tax, and unionization
advantages in the Southeast erode?
W i t h i n the region and individual states of
the region, growing infrastructure needs are
apparent. More schools and other investment
in human capital are needed to prepare the
young for w o r k in an increasingly
sophisticated technological society, and an
aging population requires increased health
care facilities. Will continued growth provide
the needed funds, or will continued growth
induce resistance and a halt to further growth
due to growing potential environmental
threats, congestion, and pollution?
Ultimately, of course, the answers to these
and other questions depend upon the
individual and collective choices made by
baby boomers and their relatives. These
choices, while not known with precision
today, are perhaps sufficiently known to
permit a cautious optimism regarding the
future population and employment structure
of the Southeast. The Southeast should
continue to advance toward a rising national
level of well-being — and at an above-average
pace.

— William J. Kahley

9

INDIVIDUAL STATE EMPLOYMENT,
INCOME, AND POPULATION
C H A N G E S , 1980-90
Additional insight into the changing economic and population structure in the
Southeast in this decade can be gained by
examining movements within individual
states. In fact, the changes and structure
vary widely by state. Furthermore, important changes are projected for each of the
Sixth District states (Tables 2 and 3).

A L A B A M A — T h e p o p u l a t i o n of A l a b a m a ,
t w e n t y - s e c o n d l a r g e s t in t h e n a t i o n , g r e w by only
1 3 p e r c e n t in t h e 1 9 7 0 s . In t h e 1 9 8 0 s , g r o w t h will
s l o w to 6 . 9 p e r c e n t a s it b e c o m e s t h e o n l y state in
t h e District to g r o w m o r e s l o w l y t h a n t h e nation.
B y 1 9 9 0 , it will h a v e m o r e b u r d e n s o m e s c h o o l
a g e , elderly, a n d o v e r a l l d e p e n d e n c y ratios t h a n
the nation. Overall e m p l o y m e n t growth, projected
at 1 9 . 3 p e r c e n t in t h e 1 9 8 0 s , e x c e e d s District a n d
national growth rates." E m p l o y m e n t projections
s h o w m a r g i n a l d e c l i n e s in t h e s h a r e s of f a r m i n g
a n d g o v e r n m e n t , o f f s e t by i n c r e a s e s in m a n u f a c t u r i n g , l a r g e l y in t h e p r i m a r y a n d f a b r i c a t e d m e t a l s
i n d u s t r i e s . P e r c a p i t a p e r s o n a l i n c o m e will
i n c r e a s e f r o m 7 8 p e r c e n t of t h e n a t i o n a l a v e r a g e
c u r r e n t l y to 8 6 p e r c e n t in 1 9 9 0 .

G E O R G I A — Georgia, currently the thirteenth
m o s t p o p u l o u s s t a t e , h a d a p o p u l a t i o n g a i n of 19
p e r c e n t in t h e 1 9 7 0 s . In t h e 1 9 8 0 s , g r o w t h will
s l o w to 10.2 p e r c e n t . G e o r g i a h a s a y o u n g e r t h a n - a v e r a g e p o p u l a t i o n a n d in 1 9 9 0 will have,
higher-than-average school age and overall
d e p e n d e n c y r a t i o s but a l o w e r - t h a n - a v e r a g e
e l d e r l y d e p e n d e n c y ratio. E m p l o y m e n t g r o w t h is
p r o j e c t e d to b e t h e l o w e s t in t h e r e g i o n , a n d , at
1 1 . 7 p e r c e n t , it is t h e only r e g i o n a l s t a t e b e l o w t h e
n a t i o n a l a v e r a g e g r o w t h f i g u r e . F i n a n c e , insura n c e , a n d real e s t a t e a n d c o n s t r u c t i o n e m p l o y m e n t will b e t h e f a s t e s t g r o w i n g e m p l o y m e n t
i n d u s t r i e s d u e l a r g e l y to c o n t i n u e d g r o w t h of
A t l a n t a as t h e m a j o r r e g i o n a l b u s i n e s s center. Per
c a p i t a p e r s o n a l i n c o m e is p r o j e c t e d to rise f r o m 85
p e r c e n t of t h e n a t i o n a l l e v e l c u r r e n t l y to 8 9 perc e n t in 1 9 9 0 .

'Employment growth figures for the states in the 1980s are probably
somewhat distorted by the fact that 1980 is a recession year. Thus,
states such as Alabama, Mississippi, and Tennessee, which are
perhaps more vulnerable to recession than Florida, Georgia, or
Louisiana, start the decade from a temporarily low relative employment base.




F L O R I D A — W i t h a 4 3 - p e r c e n t p o p u l a t i o n g a i n in
t h e 1 9 7 0 s , F l o r i d a w a s t h e third f a s t e s t g r o w i n g
s t a t e in t h e n a t i o n a n d n o w r a n k s s e v e n t h in size.
D u e to t h e d i m i n i s h e d m i g r a t i o n pool, t h e g r o w t h
rate will d e c l i n e , b u t r e m a i n h i g h , at 2 3 . 9 p e r c e n t .
In 1 9 9 0 , it will h a v e a n a t i o n a l a v e r a g e s c h o o l a g e
d e p e n d e n c y ratio b u t e x t r e m e l y h i g h elderly a n d
overall d e p e n d e n c y ratios. The 16-percent
e m p l o y m e n t g r o w t h will b e g r e a t e s t in f i n a n c e ,
i n s u r a n c e , a n d real e s t a t e , reflecting Miami's
g r o w t h as a f i n a n c i a l center. T r a d e a n d s e r v i c e s
will c o n t i n u e a s t h e l a r g e s t i n d u s t r i e s d u e to Florida's a t t r a c t i v e n e s s to r e t i r e e s a n d t o u r i s t s a n d to
t r a d e w i t h Latin A m e r i c a . Per c a p i t a p e r s o n a l
i n c o m e , c u r r e n t l y t h e h i g h e s t in t h e r e g i o n at 95
p e r c e n t of t h e n a t i o n a l a v e r a g e , will rise m a r g i n ally to 9 6 p e r c e n t of t h e nation's in 1 9 9 0 .

L O U I S I A N A — Louisiana's population, ninet e e n t h largest in t h e n a t i o n , g r e w by 15 p e r c e n t in
t h e 1 9 7 0 s ; in t h e 1 9 8 0 s , it will g r o w by 11.9
p e r c e n t . L o u i s i a n a , like G e o r g i a , h a s a y o u n g e r t h a n - a v e r a g e p o p u l a t i o n profile, w i t h a h i g h e r t h a n - a v e r a g e s c h o o l a g e d e p e n d e n c y ratio
e x p e c t e d in 1 9 9 0 ; its o v e r a l l a n d elderly d e p e n d e n c y ratios a r e e x p e c t e d to b e l o w e r - t h a n a v e r a g e . Louisiana's o v e r a l l e m p l o y m e n t g r o w t h
in t h e d e c a d e is p r o j e c t e d at 18 p e r c e n t , e q u a l to
t h e District's a v e r a g e . T h e m a n u f a c t u r i n g , t r a d e ,
s e r v i c e s , a n d financial i n d u s t r i e s will e x p a n d their
s h a r e of e m p l o y m e n t in this d e c a d e . Per c a p i t a
p e r s o n a l i n c o m e will i n c r e a s e f r o m 8 8 p e r c e n t of
t h e nation's c u r r e n t l y to 91 p e r c e n t in 1990.

M I S S I S S I P P I — Mississippi, w h i c h r a n k s thirtyfirst in t h e n a t i o n in p o p u l a t i o n size, g r e w by 1 4
p e r c e n t in t h e 1 9 7 0 s ; in t h e 1 9 8 0 s , p o p u l a t i o n
g r o w t h will b e 10.4 p e r c e n t . M i s s i s s i p p i is p r o j e c t e d to h a v e a significantly h i g h e r s c h o o l a g e
d e p e n d e n c y ratio in 1 9 9 0 t h a n o t h e r s t a t e s in t h e
District a n d c o m p a r e d to t h e nation. A n d , w h i l e its
1 9 9 0 e l d e r l y d e p e n d e n c y ratio is v e r y low, it will
h a v e a relatively high overall d e p e n d e n c y ratio.
E m p l o y m e n t g r o w t h in the d e c a d e is a relatively
high 2 3 p e r c e n t . T h e bulk of t h e e m p l o y m e n t
g r o w t h will b e in d u r a b l e s m a n u f a c t u r e . Per c a p i t a
p e r s o n a l i n c o m e will rise f r o m 6 9 p e r c e n t of t h e
n a t i o n c u r r e n t l y to 7 6 p e r c e n t in 1990.

T E N N E S S E E — T e n n e s s e e is t h e nation's s e v e n t e e n t h m o s t p o p u l o u s state. Its i n c r e a s e in p o p u lation in t h e 1 9 7 0 s w a s 17 p e r c e n t ; in t h e 1 9 8 0 s , it
is p r o j e c t e d to i n c r e a s e by 14.2 p e r c e n t . T e n n e s see's p o p u l a t i o n profile in 1 9 9 0 is e x p e c t e d to b e
v e r y similar to t h e nation's, a l t h o u g h t h e s c h o o l
a g e d e p e n d e n c y ratio is p r o j e c t e d to b e slightly
h i g h e r t h a n t h e nation's. O v e r a l l e m p l o y m e n t is
p r o j e c t e d to i n c r e a s e b y 2 4 p e r c e n t in this d e c a d e ,
with e m p l o y m e n t g a i n s c o n c e n t r a t e d in d u r a b l e s
m a n u f a c t u r e . Per c a p i t a p e r s o n a l i n c o m e , n o w 8 2
p e r c e n t of t h e nation's, is p r o j e c t e d to i n c r e a s e to
8 8 p e r c e n t by 1 9 9 0 .

10 M A Y 1 9 8 1 , E C O N O M I C R E V I E W

Table 2. Establishment Employment by State
Florida

Alabama
% of Total
1980
1990
Farm

5.0

3.8

Georgia

% of Total
1980
1990
2.6

2.2

% of Total
1980
1990
3.7

Louisiana
% of Total
1980
1990

Mississippi
% of Total
1980
1990

Tennessee
% of Total
1980
1990

2.9

3.3

2.2

7.6

5.5

5.4

3.8

15.8

24.7

28.8

27.5

28.2

Manufacturing

25.3

26.3

12.2

12.9

23.2

23.8

13.2

Durables

12.2

13.7

6.9

7.5

8.2

8.4

6.3

7.8

13.6

17.8

12.1

13.9

13.1

12.4

5.5

15.1

15.4

7.0

8.0

11.1

11.1

15.4

14.3

5.0

4.3

1.1

0.9

0.5

0.6

4.9

5.1

4.6

4.7

Nondurables
Mining
Construction
Trade
Government
Transportation,
Communication,
and Public Utilities
Services
Finance, Insurance,
and Real Estate
Total Nonfarm
Total (In '000,
1972 bench marks)

1.2

1.6

5.3
0.3

0.2

0.3

0.3

4.8

5.5

7.5

6.6

4.4

4.9

8.5

7.1

19.5

19.8

26.1

25.6

22.6

23.4

22.8

23.5

18.2

19.1

20.4

21.8

18.9

17.0

21.7

18.8

17.0

15.9

21.0

19.0

17.0

16.6

19.1

17.7

5.1

5.0

6.0

5.7

6.3

6.2

7.2

7.0

4.7

4.4

4.6

4.6

14.2

14.3

21.6

22.3

15.3

15.1

16.2

17.5

13.4

13.1

15.9

15.6

4.1

4.7

6.7

7.9

4.9

5.7

4.7

5.5

3.7

4.3

4.1

4.8

95.0

96.2

97.4

97.8

96.3

97.1

96.7

97.8

92.4

94.5

94.6

96.2

1,421

1,695

3,625

4,207

2,221

2,480

1,593

1,876

896

1,103

1,872

2,329

Sources: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis, State Departments of Labor, and Federal Reserve Bank — Atlanta.

Table 3. Population and Age Structure of District States
Florida

Alabama
% of Total
1980
1990

Louisiana

Georgia

% of Total
1980
1990

% of Total
1980
1990

% of Total
1980
1990

Mississippi
% of Total
1980
1990

Tennessee
% of Total
1980
1990

7.6

7.9

6.3

7.2

8.0

8.4

8.1

8.3

8.5

8.6

7.2

7.9

5 to 14

16.0

15.3

13.5

13.5

16.7

15.4

17.1

15.8

17.6

16.4

15.3

14.8

Under 5 years

15-24

18.4

14.6

16.9

12.6

19.0

15.0

19.7

15.5

19.1

15.7

18.0

14.4

25-34

16.1

16.5

14.2

15.2

17.1

16.5

16.3

17.5

15.2

16.6

16.3

16.9

35-44

11.3

14.6

10.4

13.4

12.0

14.9

11.0

14.8

10.5

13.6

12.0

15.0

45-54

10.1

10.1

10.4

8.9

9.7

10.4

9.6

9.8

9.2

9.2

10.4

10.4

55-64
65 or over

9.2

8.4

10.9

8.1

8.3

7.9

8.4

7.8

9.1

7.4

9.4

8.3

11.4

12.5

17.4

21.2

9.3

10.9

9.8

10.6

11.5

12.4

11.4

12.2

3,890

4,160

9,740

5,464

6,024

4,204

4,704

2,521

2,784

4,591

5,243

All Races
Both Sexes
'000)

12,068

(in

Sources: U.S. Bureau of Census, U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis and Federal Reserve Bank-Atlanta.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ATLANTA




11

Southeastern Agriculture
in the 80s
Changes in factors affecting t h e supply of farm products will be the dominant
forces in southeastern agriculture in the 80s. Since farmers in the region use
more energy-related products than their national counterparts, cropping
patterns in t h e Southeast may be changed by increasing energy costs. Farm
credit volume will grow, b u t business will shift away from traditional lenders.
The region is in good position to share in the growing agricultural export
markets.

Southeastern agriculture seems likely to
change dramatically d u r i n g the decade of the
1980s. A number of economic forces have
already set some of those changes in motion.
Undoubtedly, other factors, as yet unrecognized, will also have important impacts.
The changes that appear most prominent
from this vantage point are developments
that will influence the future supply of farm
products.
Energy
At the t o p of the list is the rapidly rising
cost of energy. Energy affects not only the
fuels required to operate machinery but also
the w h o l e complex of agricultural inputs of
chemical origin, including fertilizers, insecticides, fungicides, and herbicides.
In the spring of 1980 when farmers were
probably negotiating f o r most of their inputs
for the year's crops, diesel fuel prices were
nearly double the level of a year earlier.
Prices of fertilizers and agricultural chemicals
were also up substantially (20 percent or
more), but the rate of increase was lagging
behind that for fuels. Agricultural chemical
prices are likely to increase more rapidly as
accumulated inventories are w o r k e d off and
manufacturing capacities become more fully
utilized.
12



This escalation in energy prices will have a
proportionately greater impact on southeastern agriculture than in the country as a w h o l e
because agricultural production in the Southeast is more energy-intensive than in most
other parts of the country. Estimates of 1980
production costs show that in the Southeast
47 percent of variable production costs for
cotton are made up of energy-sensitive items
as opposed to an average of 28 percent for
the U. S. The numbers for corn are 58 percent versus 53 percent and f o r soybeans, 45
percent versus 30 percent. Thus, the Southeast's disadvantage is substantial when energy
costs are rising, largely because more fertilizer is required on relatively less fertile soils
and more insecticides, fungicides, and herbicides are required for most crops because
of the longer growing season. In addition,
frequent rainfall (in normal years) requires
repeated applications of chemicals t o control
insects, diseases, and competing vegetation.
The rapid rise in energy costs tends to
make crop production more costly in southeastern states than in the rest of the U. S.,
affecting producers' comparative advantage.
If energy costs should double from 1980 to
1982, comparative positions for producers of
cotton, corn, soybeans, and rice w o u l d significantly deteriorate. Although crop production will not cease, producers w o u l d have an
M A Y 1 9 8 1 , E C O N O M I C REVIEW

incentive to shift t o crops that use relatively
less energy and in which their comparative
disadvantage is least. Rice, soybeans, and
wheat appear to be crops that producers will
expand in the coming decade, while acreage
of feed grains and cotton w o u l d probably decline unless price relationships among these
crops undergo major changes.
Energy from Crops
Considerable experimentation is now under
way on the feasibility of producing ethanol
from agricultural products as a partial substitute for oil-based fuels. Should vegetable
sources of energy become economically
competitive, the Southeast is in good position
to produce large tonnages of vegetable products for alcohol production. The long
growing season, with relatively abundant
rainfall, gives this area massive potential for
increased forage production. Should specialty
crops, such as sweet potatoes and sweet sorghum, in fact become efficient crops for alcohol generation, commercial crop production w o u l d take on a new dimension in this
area. A livestock system to utilize the byproducts from alcohol production could significantly alter traditional animal production
patterns.

W i t h increased irrigation will come new
concerns involving water rights, allocations,
and governmental jurisdictions. Actions to
regulate and police water usage will result in
additional costs that are also likely to influence crop choices.
Pollution
Related to water regulation is the broad
area of environmental regulation. Agriculture
will unquestionably experience greater future
impacts from governmental regulations in this
area. The direct effects on farmers themselves
will involve cost-increasing practices that will
be required to abate environmental pollution
in all forms. The abundance of surface and
subsurface water makes southeastern farmers
more vulnerable to restrictive regulations on
a broad spectrum of farm operations. For
example, crops that require frequent applications of potent toxic materials are candidates
for sharp alterations in cost structures as a
result of additional restrictions nearly certain
to be forthcoming. Livestock farmers are
likely to be required to make substantial expenditures to adequately treat and dispose of
animal waste products.
Farm Structure

Irrigation
The drought in 1980 reminded southerners
of the value of our relatively abundant water
supply, both surface and subsurface. The
potential for irrigation could make a significant difference in crops grown in this area.
For example, w i t h adequate moisture, producers could have quickly started a crop of
soybeans following 1980's winter wheat harvest. W i t h o u t water, much acreage either did
not get planted or did not emerge to an even
stand following planting. Irrigation could
have made a difference between obtaining
two substantial crops from the same acreage
in 1980 or obtaining only one crop. As more
irrigation systems are installed and utilized
more intensively in the Southeast, double
and triple cropping (in the case of some
vegetables) may become the rule rather than
the exception in the years ahead. The effect
would be to substantially increase the revenue from an acre of land while spreading
production costs over a much larger output
volume.

FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F ATLANTA




The rapid growth in farm size has enabled
producers to reduce average production costs
by expanding their volume of o u t p u t . The
trend is likely to continue, resulting in fewer
farmers and farm workers, while at the same
time spurring the use of larger machines and
the adoption of output-increasing technology.
Growth in farm size has resulted in a renewed expansion of tenancy as part-owner
farm operators attempt to gain control of
larger acreages w i t h o u t buying land outright.
In most cases, land prices have escalated to
the point where purchasers can no longer
hope to generate sufficient cash flow from
agricultural production to service indebtedness for farmland. The result? Landownership
rests increasingly w i t h those looking t o farmland as an investment opportunity. They see
farmland as protection against inflation because it appreciates more rapidly than the
general price level. Since this environment
increases tenant farm operators' uncertainty,
they are likely to respond by reducing land
improvements that pay off over the long
13

t e r m . Eventually, the p r o d u c t i v i t y of farmland
is likely to decline as tenancy becomes m o r e
p r o m i n e n t . Absentee owners also w i l l have
d i f f e r e n t concerns f r o m farm operators,
w h i c h may affect the unity of s u p p o r t for future farm legislation.
A n o t h e r p r o d u c t of fewer farms and larger
operations is t h e organization of producers
into larger cooperatives or g r o w e r associations. This t r e n d is n o t h i n g new in itself. It
has n o w spread f r o m poultry and vegetable
p r o d u c t i o n to other enterprises, and some of
its consequences are new or not yet fully
recognized.
These enlarged organizations of producers,
w h e t h e r cooperatives, corporations, or just
c o m m o d i t y associations, affect t h e c o m p e t i tive e n v i r o n m e n t . In most cases, they reduce
c o m p e t i t i o n a m o n g m e m b e r s w h i l e enabling
the m e m b e r s h i p to bargain m o r e effectively
w i t h o p p o s i n g forces in t h e marketing syst e m . Large farmer cooperatives b e c o m e the
marketplace for b o t h farmers' products and
farm inputs. They p e r f o r m research and educational f u n c t i o n s for their m e m b e r s , and
they substitute for many services traditionally
p r o v i d e d by t h e Land Grant Colleges and the
U. S. D e p a r t m e n t of Agriculture.
Credit
Large farm units have large credit
d e m a n d s — d e m a n d s so large, in fact, they
o f t e n surpass t h e l e n d i n g expertise, if not the
l e n d i n g limits, of local credit institutions.
Many lenders w h o have not specialized in
agricultural finance f i n d themselves ille q u i p p e d to make and manage loans of t h e
size and complexity required by large f a r m i n g
operations. Farmers in the South have l o o k e d
m o r e and m o r e to the specialized financial
institutions for credit needs. In cases w h e r e
farmers are l i n k e d to other businesses
t h r o u g h integration, credit needs are often
s u p p l i e d t h r o u g h large urban financial institutions. In the f u t u r e , loans will increasingly f l o w t h r o u g h corporate headquarters to
t h e p r o d u c e r level and w i l l probably escape
detection as agricultural credit altogether.
New banking legislation enacted in 1980
seems likely to affect t h e cost and availability
of agricultural credit. It requires u n i f o r m reserve requirements on all banks after an initial adjustment p e r i o d . Reserve requirements
are, in an i m p o r t a n t sense, a cost of d o i n g
14




business for a bank. Banks that have n o t
been m e m b e r s of the Federal Reserve System
have had lower r e q u i r e m e n t s than m e m b e r
banks. Thus, n o n m e m b e r banks w e r e able to
place a higher p r o p o r t i o n of their deposits in
earning assets and t o realize a higher return
(or a lower cost) f r o m their business operations.
A n o t h e r i m p o r t a n t legislative change is that
all banks can n o w pay interest on d e m a n d
deposits or c h e c k i n g accounts. If c o m p e t i t i o n
forces most banks to pay interest at somew h e r e near 5 percent on most checking deposits, the cost of funds to banks w i l l rise
sharply. Profits f r o m l e n d i n g those funds w i l l
be squeezed, unless average l e n d i n g charges
(interest on loans) m o v e up a comparable
a m o u n t . The latter is a very likely o u t c o m e
after an initial adjustment p e r i o d . Farmers
b o r r o w i n g f r o m such banks w i l l likely f i n d
that t h e interest they are asked to pay f o r
credit w i l l be at a p e r m a n e n t l y higher rate in
the f u t u r e . If o t h e r lenders, such as the Farm
Credit System agencies, d o not experience a
comparable rise in costs of funds acquired in
national m o n e y markets, their competitive
position vis-a-vis commercial banks w i l l be
enhanced.
To some extent, h o w e v e r , banks w i l l pass
along these higher interest rates to m o n e y
market rates and users of credit in general.
Bankers are i m p o r t a n t participants in national
m o n e y markets t h r o u g h their exchanges of
bonds, bills, and certificates of deposit.
Bankers w i l l not bid as eagerly for market instruments unless they offer returns high
e n o u g h to offset the rising costs of deposits.
The absence of bankers' participation in markets w h e n rates d r o p b e l o w acceptable levels
w i l l probably cause users of funds to have to
pay higher rates to attract investors back to
t h e market. Thus, costs of funds to farm
credit agencies w i l l probably rise also.
The end result w i l l be to tie interest rates
on agricultural loans m u c h m o r e closely to
national money market rates than they have
been in the past. The cost of credit seems
likely to rise in most localities, and interest
charges will display an increased volatility.
W i t h the large and g r o w i n g use of credit in
farm operations, f u t u r e success in farming
may d e p e n d as m u c h on the judicious acquisition and use of b o r r o w e d capital as on
technical agricultural expertise.
M A Y 1 9 8 1 , E C O N O M I C REVIEW

I

Input Costs

>

,

Inflation has not only occurred in land and
energy prices but has been running rampant
in practically all items farmers buy. As farmers
further expand o u t p u t , the brisk demand for
tractors, machinery, and other farm inputs
will continue to support rising price levels of
all major inputs. The rising general cost level
will probably keep farm operating margins
squeezed to the point that there will be little
room for income declines (such as we experienced in 1980) w i t h o u t threatening the
viability of many highly leveraged farming
operations.
Risks

I

»[

J

-j

Efforts to protect against these increased
economic risks will increase demands for insurance in a variety of forms. Lenders are
likely to play a major role in inducing farmers
to install irrigations systems, purchase crop
insurance, engage in some form of forward
pricing of products, and campaign for
strengthened government programs to provide price and income support to farmers.
However, serious efforts to combat inflation
at the national level will cause Congress to
press hard for reducing federal expenditures.
The dwindling rural population and the consequent reduced political strength of the agricultural sector will render agricultural
programs increasingly vulnerable to fiscal
budget-cutting efforts. Future farm sector
demands for price and income supports that
involve government-imposed restrictions on
output seem certain to be countered by
strong demands to expand rather than restrain supply. Pressures will grow to reduce
subsidies for crops such as tobacco and
peanuts that do not have strong nationwide
support.

Livestock Profits
f

'

,

Many factors affecting crop production will
also impact the Southeast's livestock sector.
Cattle and calf production, the largest single
income-earning enterprise across the Southeast, will continue to be pushed off land that
can be used for crops. The beef cattle enterprise is simply unable to provide a competitive return under existing levels of prices and
FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F ATLANTA




technology. Although some practices may increase the productivity of grazing land, considerable escalation in cattle prices will be
necessary to produce the future growth in
beef o u t p u t that once seemed likely for the
Southeast. It is clear that the increased returns to crop production in the Midwest have
all but stamped out the use of land for livestock grazing in most of that region. The
same trend has already been observed in the
more productive soil areas in the Southeast.
Feed Costs
Elevated energy costs further penalize the
importation of feed grains to the Southeast,
and the growing comparative disadvantage of
feed grain crops in this region will not allow
increased indigenous production. Livestockfeeding industries that depend heavily on
harvested grains are thus unlikely to experience much growth. The poultry industry,
however, w h i c h makes heavier use of soybean meal than do cattle or hogs, will receive
offsetting benefits from the increased local
supplies of soybeans and soybean meal. In
the Southeast, then, feed costs are not likely
to rise as much for poultry producers as for
cattle and hog producers. That, c o m b i n e d
w i t h the lower winter requirements for a u x i liary heat, may give southeastern poultry producers a considerable cost advantage over
colder regions.
Exports
O n the demand side, the biggest boost to
the region, as well as to the country as a
whole, has been the massive increase in export markets for agricultural commodities.
The growing demand for feed grains and
soybeans has been a particular b o o n for the
Southeast because of the relatively large area
of land in marginal uses that is adaptable to
soybean production. The superior returns
available from grain production in other regions have allowed a growing share of the
soybean market to be filled by southern
producers.
Part of the increase in export demand has
been attributable to a decline in the value of
the dollar against other currencies. This has
given U. S. agricultural products a price advantage in w o r l d markets. M o r e importantly,
rapidly growing purchasing power in other
15

countries has fueled the demand for f o o d
and feed products. Thus, even if the dollar
holds its own or regains some ground in
foreign exchange markets in the years ahead,
growth in export demand should continue
strong because purchasing power is now
strengthening in countries like Mexico with
its n e w f o u n d oil wealth. Another example is
the People's Republic of China where virtually unlimited needs set the stage for prospective rapid growth in demand for most
southeastern farm products.
The potential to respond to increased
foreign demand is large and growing. Agricultural producers have easy access to ports
all along the southern and eastern boundaries
of our region. Inland waterways t h r o u g h the
Southeast provide a transportation advantage
of growing consequence as fuel costs
continue to rise.
C r o w i n g demand and its impact on profitability will spur agronomic developments that
could easily double yields of crops like soybeans. The Southeast has an abundance of
land in marginal uses. Its producers have the
capability to utilize technological innovations
and expand production rapidly. The region is
also developing facilities for handling large
volumes of agricultural production. All these
features place the Southeast in a strong position to respond to the massive growth in export demand that seems highly likely to occur
in the 1980s.
Domestic Consumption
Although domestic population growth is
likely to be limited during the upcoming decade, changing tastes and preferences stemming f r o m rising incomes will enhance demand for superior f o o d products. Consumers
will demand more fruits, fresh vegetables,
and exotic f o o d preparations. Producers of
fruits and fresh vegetables, especially those
adjacent to large and growing population
centers, may encounter growing local demand that could offset rising shipping
charges that tend to shrink more distant markets. Producers of bulky products like melons, for example, are finding that a doubling

of fuel costs since 1978 has necessitated such
high prices in distant markets that the quantity demanded has declined.
O n ihe positive side, the maintenance of
f o o d assistance programs will assure southeastern food crop producers of more stable
demand than in the past. Specifically,
during economic hardships, eligible consumers need not curtail their food
purchases as long as the government's
food stamp program continues
to operate.
Highlights
Rapidly escalating farm input prices will
markedly raise production costs of southeastern farmers. Enterprises using large proportions of energy-related inputs will be particularly hurt, and most southeastern crop
producers use higher proportions of energy
than do their national counterparts. Shifts in
southeastern cropping patterns are likely to
occur as energy costs rise.
Credit use will expand dramatically, but
b o r r o w i n g costs will move up to a permanently higher plane, and business will shift
away from some traditional lenders.
Demand for f o o d products will expand
rapidly, with vigorous growth in effective
demand in foreign markets. Southeastern
producers have the advantage of a strategic
location to share in the growing export markets for agricultural products. The growth in
demand will raise prices sufficiently to offset
cost increases for major enterprises, so that
farmers will continue to bring marginal land
into production and hold d o w n their expansion of grazing livestock enterprises. O n
balance, total agricultural o u t p u t will expand
but shifts in competitive positions will cause
traditional enterprises to diminish in
importance.
The structure of southeastern agriculture
will continue to change rapidly in the decade
ahead. Commercial agriculture of the 1980s
will differ remarkably from its predecessor of
a short two decades ago.

—Gene D. Sullivan

16




M A Y 1 9 8 1 , E C O N O M I C REVIEW

Faulty Diagnosis:
The GNP Revisions
Revisions to t h e GNP figures announced in December depict a stronger
economy, especially for t h e last four years. Investment, productivity, saving, and
output were all higher t h a n previously reported. While some changes resulted
from redefinitions of categories, many of the revisions were substantial enough
to suggest that expansionist economic policies may have been overstimulative.

A patient being treated f o r severe anemia has
been t o l d that a new red cell counting
procedure adopted in his physician's clinic has
found him t o be only mildly anemic and was
so all along. The patient is immediately t o r n
between the emotions of joy at learning he
isn't terribly ill and of being irate over the side
effects he has developed f r o m his medication
that wasn't necessary.
All the w h i l e , the patient had been feeling
better than he was supposed t o , considering
his diagnosis. He couldn't convince the
physician of what good shape he was in, even
though he exercised and enjoyed life when he
wasn't being told by the doctor how sick he
was. Although recently the medication he was
taking was making him nervous and somewhat
hyperactive, the doctor had taken these
developments as unfortunate b u t necessary
consequences of trying to get the patient well.
N o w that the mistake has been f o u n d , what
will the correct course of action be? Unless
the patient has become addicted to the
medication, the obvious first step w o u l d be to
stop or reduce sharply the medication. Maybe
a valuable lesson was learned by the physician
— trust your judgment about the patient's

well-being if it runs counter to suspicious lab
results.
Of course, this episode of erroneous
diagnosis closely parallels governmental
policy and the economy. Official statistics
'regarding o u t p u t in the economy are the lab
results; the government, as the doctor,
prescribes economic remedies.
For several years, especially since 1975,
statistics portrayed an economy apparently
suffering from anemic growth, poor
productivity, a steeply declining saving rate,
and inadequate investment spending — and
therefore slowly growing potential. Because of
this supposed weak growth, fiscal and monetary policies were kept strongly stimulative.
Meanwhile, officials argued that o u t p u t was
far below potential and stimulus was
necessary to reduce unemployment and move
closer t o potential o u t p u t . Further, they
argued that all this could be achieved without
making inflation worse. These arguments held
sway despite evidence that noninflationary
potential had been reached, probably in
mid-1978. 1
' S e e Haulk and Goudreau, "Potential GNP," Economic Review, Federal Reserve
Bank of Atlanta, July/August 1979.

17
FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F A T L A N T A




CHART 1
Real o u t p u t r e v i s e d u p w a r d . . .
Bil. 1 9 7 2 $

a n d r e v i s i o n s increased s i n c e 1977.
Bil. 1 9 7 2 $

foreign subsidiaries of U.S. companies were
previously not counted as corporate earnings;
henceforth, they will be. In addition, errors
were found in the way nonmerchandise
international transactions were handled.
Foreign income on corporate tax returns had
previously been subtracted. Royalty payments
are now included in corporate profits. The
corrected procedure results in higher earnings
for U.S. firms. More recent tax return data
indicate profits were actually higher than
earlier data predicted. Finally, the timing of
depreciation of utility plants was changed to
coincide with plant start-up rather than
construction completion. All these changes
raised corporate profits (after inventory
valuation and capital consumption allowance
adjustments) by nearly 10 percent above levels
previously reported (see table). After adjusting
for inflation, profits were 25 to 30 percent
higher.
Interest Income Recalculated;
Saving Rate U p

1
1976

1
1977

1
1978

1
1979

o
1980

Recently, the Commerce Department
concluded what many suspected all along.
Revisions to the GNP figures announced in
December paint a much brighter picture than
did previously reported numbers, especially
for the last three or four years. For example,
f r o m first quarter 1978 to third quarter 1980,
real o u t p u t measured in 1972 dollars rose by
$69 billion as opposed to the earlier reported
$44 billion, a difference of over 50 percent.
There were other important differences as
well, including a higher saving rate, stronger
investment, and higher profits. What were the
changes that have so altered the nation's
economic vital statistics?

The 10-percent gain in net interest income
(a component of personal income) was also
the result of finding a sizable error in the way
interest paid to businesses was calculated:
businesses were being credited w i t h more
than they actually receive. In addition to the
interest income revisions, the last couple of
years saw a combination of changes in the
rental, proprietor, and employee
compensation components, totaling $10
billion.

CHART 2
Interest i n c o m e r e v i s e d up $ 1 0 billion for last t w o
years.
Bil. $

Net Interest C h a n g e - R e v i s e d M i n u s O l d

25

Corporate Profits Redefined
The Commerce Department's upward revision
in corporate profits was largely due to a
definitional change. Reinvested earnings of
18




M A Y 1981, E C O N O M I C REVIEW

MAJOR REVISIONS IN GNP ACCOUNTS
(Differences and Percent Changes)

GNP
Billions
of Dollars

Saving
Rate

Real GNP
Percent
Increase

Billions of
1972
Dollars

Percent
Increase

Percent
Increase

Corporate
Profits
After-Tax and
IVA and CCA adj.
Billions
of Dollars

Percent
Increase

Net
Interest

Fixed

Nonresidential
Investment

Percent
Increase

Billions of
1972
Dollars

Percent
Increase
3.4

1970:1

7.8

0.8

7.8

0.7

13.1

2.7

7.9

11.3

3.8

1970:2

9.8

1.0

8.9

0.8

10.7

4.9

14.3

10.6

3.3

2.9

1970:3

11.0

1.1

11.3

1.0

9.0

3.8

11.2

10.0

3.9

3.5

1970:4

12.7

1.3

13.3

1.2

3.8

3.8

12.2

9.7

4.3

4.0

1971:1

15.3

1.5

16.2

1.5

5.0

6.6

17.9

8.9

3.0

2.8

1971:2

12.7

1.2

13.6

1.2

6.2

4.2

10.7

8.7

5.0

4.7

1971:3

14.2

1.3

14.7

1.3

6.6

6.6

16.6

8.8

4.8

4.5

1971:4

14.6

1.3

14.9

1.3

1.4

7.3

17.3

8.2

4.0

3.6

1972:1

15.4

1.4

16.0

1.4

1.5

5.7

12.0

7.6

5.8

5.1

1972:2

15.0

1.3

15.5

1.3

5.4

3.4

6.8

8.0

4.5

3.9

1972:3

14.7

1.2

15.1

1.3

5.1

4.4

8.6

9.4

3.9

3.3

1972:4

14.1

1.2

12.6

1.0

6.1

4.3

8.0

10.7

4.3

3.5

1973:1

18.2

1.4

17.3

1.4

11.8

9.9

19.0

13.5

4.3

3.3

1973:2

19.2

1.5

17.9

1.5

10.3

8.8

18.2

15.6

7.6

5.8

1973:3

20.2

1.5

20.5

1.7

11.4

7.9

15.7

16.2

8.0

6.0

1973:4

21.6

1.6

24.4

2.0

9.2

9.0

17.8

14.5

8.3

6.3

1974:1

18.7

1.4

24.5

2.0

15.6

11.5

28.2

12.8

6.3

4.7

1974:2

23.7

1.7

31.8

2.6

17.8

13.4

39.6

11.6

4.4

3.3

1974:3

21.5

1.5

31.7

2.6

19.4

12.1

52.8

8.7

4.6

3.5

1974:4

21.4

1.5

32.7

2.7

14.7

11.6

42.6

8.5

5.0

4.0

1975:1

25.1

1.7

34.7

3.0

12.5

12.3

36.6

8.4

3.0

2.5

1975:2

18.1

1.2

31.1

2.6

10.3

12.5

29.0

8.0

4.9

4.3

1975:3

14.5

0.9

28.4

2.3

10.7

11.4

21.0

7.0

7.2

6.4

1975:4

23.8

1.5

31.8

2.6

14.1

18.9

35.4

6.5

7.8

7.0

1976:1

18.3

1.1

27.7

2.2

20.3

11.4

17.2

6.5

6.7

5.8

1976:2

15.5

0.9

28.4

• 2.2

19.7

11.8

19.3

4.6

6.5

5.5

1976:3

13.2

0.8

26.2

2.1

23.2

10.6

16.8

2.3

6.7

5.6

1976:4

16.4

0.9

27.3

2.1

13.5

11.2

18.2

0.7

6.4

5.2

1977:1

18.9

1.0

30.2

2.3

16.7

14.1

20.8

6.5

8.2

6.5

1977:2

17.9

0.9

32.2

2.4

11.8

14.5

19.0

7.1

11.5

9.0

1977:3

19.9

1.0

31.9

2.4

14.8

15.4

17.7

8.1

10.8

8.3

1977:4

17.3

0.9

30.2

2.2

13.7

15.5

19.9

7.5

14.6

11.1

1978:1

21.1

1.0

34.5

2.5

15.1

22.0

31.3

5.7

12.6

9.5

1978:2

25.4

1.2

37.6

2.7

2.0

17.2

20.3

5.1

13.2

9.4

1978:3

31.3

1.4

39.4

2.8

0

17.7

20.2

5.3

13.4

9.5

1978:4

36.7

1.6

39.2

2.7

12.8

20.7

23.1

6.9

13.9

9.6

1979:1

48.5

2.1

49.3

3.4

6.0

25.7

29.3

8.8

14.2

9.6

1979:2

44.8

1.9

51.1

3.6

3.7

22.3

25.4

9.0

14.4

9.8

1979:3

47.6

2.0

54.9

3.8

25.6

24.3

28.0

11.6

15.7

10.4

1979:4

39.4

1.6

50.3

3.5

34.3

21.9

27.3

12.4

13.6

9.0

1980:1

50.9

2.0

57.2

4.0

32.4

33.4

46.0

11.7

13.8

9.1

1980:2

43.5

1.7

54.7

3.9

26.5

22.6

30.0

11.8

10.8

7.4

1980:3

50.8

2.0

60.2

4.3

29.8

26.4

36.1

12.1

12.0

8.4

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ATLANTA




19

Virtually all of the increase in disposable
personal income resulting f r o m these net
interest revisions was allocated to savings. For
example, in third quarter 1980, there was a
$30-billion revision in disposable income, and
savings were raised by $25 billion in that
quarter; the revisions in consumption
spending were insignificantly small. What this
has done is to raise the personal saving rate.

CHART 3
S a v i n g rate h e a l t h i e r t h a n originally r e p o r t e d .
Percent

_

Saving Rate

3 0

The table shows the saving rate changes
over the period 1970 to 1980. The largest
upward revisions in the saving rate were for
the five quarters 1979:3 through 1980:3,
although fairly large revisions were in
evidence from 1973 through 1978:2 when they
suddenly diminished, probably due to the
lower interest rate effect on net interest
income. During the last one and a half years
or so, the saving rate was about 25 to 30
percent higher than originally reported. The
long-term trend still declined during the
seventies, but for the last two years when w e
heard so much about our deplorably low
saving rate, it was actually just under its
post-World War II average.
Changes in G N P
O n the expenditure side, there were two
major changes. First, net exports were raised
by including net reinvested foreign earnings.
Second, rebenchmarking (revisions of

20




sampling using more recent information)
discovered that producers' durable equipment
was being underestimated. W i t h a newer
model in place, gross business investment
outlays were calculated to be about 8 percent
greater in real terms than previously reported.
Fixed Investment Figures
Revised U p w a r d
Since the revisions were concentrated in the
producer durables c o m p o n e n t , fixed
nonresidential investment was raised
substantially both nominally and in constant
dollars. Producer durables accounted for 60 to
70 percent of the revisions in nonresidential
investment in the early 1970s and 100 percent
by 1979. The size of the revisions in both
absolute and percentage terms jumped in late
1973, fell back in 1974, and grew again in late
1975. Then in 1977, the revisions really
swelled, going t o 11 percent higher than the
originally reported figure. After reaching as
high as 14 percent, they appear to have
leveled off. In addition to nonresidential
investment revisions, residential investment
was boosted by 2 billion 1972 dollars.
The share of nonresidential fixed
investment in total GNP was raised by 8 to 10
percent for the past three years, less for
earlier years. The share of GNP going to
domestic investment has been higher in
recent years than in any time in the post-WW
II period. Furthermore, the fact that part of
the increase in revised GNP was due to
inclusion of unrepatriated earnings means that
the share of gross domestic product going to
investment was much higher than the
post-WW II average.
To the extent that producer durables have a
shorter life than structures, the increase of
producer durables relative to structures could
slow the total growth of capital, since net
investment w o u l d be lower. This may or may
not be a p r o b l e m , depending on whether the
shift is a true reflection of rates of return on
the different capital stock components. The
Commerce Department's Bureau of Economic
Analysis says that the revisions raised net
g r o w t h of capital f r o m 3.5 t o 3.9 percent per
year for 1969-79.2 That is an 11 percent faster

2

Survey of Current Business, December 1980, p. 23.

MAY 1981, E C O N O M I C

REVIEW

CHART 4
Nonresidential F i x e d I n v e s t m e n t over ten percent higher
since 1977 . . .
Bil. 1 9 7 2 $

Nonresidential Fixed Investment
—

—

—

25

—

20

Revised M i n u s Old

1976

1977

1978

1979

1980

and at p o s t w a r high a s a s h a r e of GNP.
Percent

Revised

~~

12

-'

in constant dollars, consumption was found to
be about one percent higher than earlier
reports indicated. Almost all the revision was
accounted for by outlays on nondurable
goods. Service outlays in nominal terms were
lowered while constant dollar expenditures
remained level, meaning that the deflator for
services was revised downward. For durables,
there was no significant change in nominal or
real outlays.
Federal government spending was revised
upward both nominally and in real terms. The
largest revisions in real federal spending were
for 1979 and 1980. For the third quarter 1980,
the new figure is $3 billion, or 3 percent above
the originally reported number.
Nineteen-eighty state and local government
spending, while 4 percent higher in real terms
after revisions (lower in nominal terms),
reflected a downward change in the
government spending deflator.
Finally, alterations in the deflation
procedure for nonmerchandise exports and
imports plus a lowered estimate for the cost
of items purchased by the federal government
significantly reduced the growth rate of the
GNP deflator, particularly for the last two
years.
H o w Important Are the Revisions?

rate. As a matter of interest, the annual net
growth rate of capital was 3.4 percent from
1949 to 1959 and 3.8 percent f r o m 1959 to 1969.
Given the big changes for 1977-79, we
probably had a record rate of capital
accumulation. These results indicate that
much of the concern over the supposed
weakness of investment in the U.S. has been
unduly alarmist. It is important to remember
that these revisions to producer durables are
based in part on data already several years
old. Additional upward revisions may come
when later data are available.
O t h e r Changes
Total consumption spending was negligibly
affected by the revisions. However, measured

FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F A T L A N T A




Even t h o u g h the inflation rate for the past few
years has been revised downward, it is still
uncomfortably high. It is still a serious
problem because, as it persists, the economy
tries to cope by developing inflationprotection schemes w h i c h make it more
difficult t o control inflation. The GNP
revisions did not reduce the growing tax
burden felt by the middle-class, w h o must
struggle against both inflation and the
decreasing share of their gross income left in
their pay envelopes.
Revisions in productivity figures indicate
that productivity grew about 16 percent faster
over the period 1972-79 than was earlier
thought. That still leaves a very slow rate of
increase of 0.92 percent per year. The
productivity slowdown is a complex
phenomenon and could be overstated for
reasons discussed in the final section of this
article.
The revisions are particularly disturbing
because so much has been written to try to

21

explain the growing American capital shortage
and poor productivity performance of recent
years. The revisions are very generous to the
producer durables component of investment.
That makes sense in view of the upward
revisions in profits and personal savings. It
also makes sense in light of the very low, even
negative, real after-tax interest rates prevailing
for much of the period since the late 1960s,
even taking into account problems created by
the effect of historical cost depreciation on
cash flow.
Some leading economists, including Otto
Eckstein, have made light of the revisions,
arguing that they are not of great importance.
For example, the changes in definition to
include unrepatriated earnings are of no
consequence except to recognize the claims
on foreigners that these profits represent.
Likewise, the changing of depreciation for
utilities was not overly significant. However,
recalculating the GNP deflator, discovery that
corporate profits were higher than estimated
and finding substantial errors in investment
estimates, personal income, and the saving
rates cannot be waved off lightly as
unimportant.
The discovery that investment as a share of
GNP has been at a post-WW II high for the last
three years is very important. Finding that the
saving rate, while having fallen, is not
inordinately low relative to post-WW II levels
is quite a piece of news — especially in view
of all that has been written and said about our
lack of savings and investment.
M o r e importantly, these revisions, many of
them based on data several years old, should
caution against over dependence or reliance
on statistics based on extrapolations from
sample data w h e n the structure of the
economy is rapidly changing. The changes in
the economy over the last ten years (massive
increases in government transfer payments,
increasing tax burden, financial market
developments, inflation, changes in industrial
output mix, oil price hikes, and invasion of

22




the U.S. markets by imports) should cause
those w h o use national statistics derived from
samples and historical relationships to view
those statistics w i t h a jaundiced eye.
Beyond the measurable changes, at least
those which are in principle measurable, there
has been rapid growth in the " u n d e r g r o u n d
economy" which causes the officially reported
numbers to understate true output. Thus,
GNP figures do not accurately portray the
state of the economy, and inflation rates are of
necessity not totally reliable since it is not
always possible to know the actual price at
which a transaction takes place (as opposed to
the list price). Further, the unemployment rate
released each month is not truly indicative of
economic suffering. The opportunities to
supplement unemployment compensation
with other transfer payments and unreported
income undermine the government's attempts
to conduct anti-inflation policies. The
revisions in the accounts, and the strong
possibility of further upward revisions, along
with what we know from attempts to measure
unreported income, must cast serious doubt
on the inflationary, expansionist policies of
the past few years.
There are obviously some things
policy-makers can do to alleviate real
problems afflicting the economy. Lowering tax
rates, which are so high that they reduce
production incentives and encourage
tax-avoiding behavior, w o u l d be a first step.
Reducing the growth of government spending
to eliminate perpetual deficits and their
effects on interest rates and money creation
w o u l d be a welcome move. The policymaker,
like the wise physician, must act to produce
overall good health rather than try to
eradicate every ache and discomfort in the
patient whether real or imaginary. Too much
treatment could lead to a weakening of the
patient's ability to cope w i t h truly serious
ailments.
0R]

—Charles ].

Haulk

M A Y 1 9 8 1 , E C O N O M I C REVIEW

Regional Repercussions
of a Chrysler Failure
If Chrysler Corporation should eventually fail, t h e effects on t h e region's
economy would be small. In specific locations, however, the effects could be
significant. Chrysler's m a n u f a c t u r i n g facilities, dealers, and parts suppliers
employ (directly or indirectly) over 14,400 workers in the Southeast.

The Chrysler Loan Guarantee
Board recently approved an additional $400 million in federal
loan guarantees t o the Chrysler
Corporation. The approval was
conditional u p o n : employees
agreeing to forego wage and
benefit concessions (for UAW
workers this amounted t o $622
million over the life of the current contract, w h i c h expires in
September 1982); banks and
other institutional lenders agreeing to convert some debt to
equity, and to forgive other
debt altogether in exchange for

FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F ATLANTA




partial cash p a y m e n t s ; a n d
suppliers agreeing t o p r i c e
freezes and rollbacks, and to
more
generous
credit
terms. Despite t h e approval,
Chrysler's future remains uncertain
W h e r e are t h e C h r y s l e r
facilities and their secondary
suppliers located in the Sixth
District? What w o u l d be the
likely repercussions on income
and employment in the Sixth
District if Chrysler were to fail?
The direct influence on income
and employment in the Sixth

District w o u l d be small. H o w ever, the indirect effects, w h i c h
take into account the effects on
area dealers and parts suppliers
in addition to Chrysler plants,
w o u l d be considerable. This
preliminary study is designed
only to provide a rough estimate, not an in-depth analysis.
Currently, the Chrysler Corp o r a t i o n has t h r e e p r i m a r y
facilities located in the Southeast, w i t h a total w o r k force of
about 1,700. The facilities are
located at Cape Canaveral,
Florida (a wire products plant);

23

Facility

Location

Employment*

Huntsville Electrical Division

Huntsville,
Alabama
Cape Canaveral,
Florida

1 , 4 6 0 — J a n u a r y 1981

Chrysler Corporation
W i r e Products Plant
Chrysler M i c h o u d
Defense-Space
( E n g i n e e r i n g Facility)
Dealership E m p l o y m e n t :

Slidell, Louisiana
Alabama
Florida
Georgia
Louisiana
Mississippi
Tennessee

of July 1,1980, there w e r e 4,006
Chrysler dealerships througho u t the U. S. By January 1,1981,
that n u m b e r had d e c l i n e d to
3,823. There are at least 11,930
w o r k e r s at C h r y s l e r dealerships, parts depots, and regional headquarters in the District. W h e n the direct and indirect e m p l o y m e n t effects of
Chrysler's
manufacturing
facilities are c o m b i n e d w i t h the
i n f l u e n c e on dealerships, the
total comes to at least 14,468
workers. 3 A l t h o u g h this estimate is small relative to the
overall level of e m p l o y m e n t
(11.2 million), it w o u l d have significant effects in some communities.

33, but will b e O b y
July 1981 or s o o n e r

About 200
1,250
3,130
2,230
1,510
1,340
2,120
11,580

Regional H e a d q u a r t e r s
a n d Parts Depots
Total Direct E m p l o y m e n t

Atlanta, Georgia, a n d
Orlando, Florida

350
13,623

"Estimates of workers are from officials at the area facilities; estimates of dealership workers are from Chrysler officials
at the Detroit headquarters.

in H u n t s v i l l e , A l a b a m a (an
e l e c t r i c a l d i v i s i o n ) ; a n d in
Slidell, Louisiana (a defense and
space facility). T h e r e f o r e , direct
e m p l o y m e n t loss w o u l d be
about 1,700— mainly
in
Huntsville. 1
The Economic Stabilization
S u b c o m m i t t e e of t h e House
B a n k i n g C o m m i t t e e uses a
m u l t i p l i e r of 1.7 to d e t e r m i n e
direct and indirect e m p l o y m e n t
effects. For each 100 Chrysler
manufacturing w o r k e r s laid o f f ,
another 70 w o r k e r s w o u l d be

1

Assuming that none of the plants would be purchased
and run by another company.

laid off at secondary suppliers.
T h e s e 70 e x c l u d e
those
employees affected by dealership closings. If w e assume that
all secondary suppliers to the
Cape Canaveral and Huntsville
facilities are localized, t h e multiplier effect suggests that about
2,500 2 District
manufacturing
w o r k e r s w o u l d lose their jobs or
be laid off in t h e event of a
Chrysler failure.

Income Loss
The i n c o m e loss w o u l d be
even less than the e m p l o y m e n t
loss. Since these facilities c o u l d
argue that they have been adversely affected by i m p o r t s ,
they m i g h t qualify for trade
assistance-up to 70 percent of
gross weekly wages. 4 M o r e o v e r ,
w h e n taxes are taken into consideration, net disposable i n c o m e
losses w o u l d be negligible. I ®

There are o b v i o u s l y many
Chrysler dealerships that w o u l d
also be affected by a failure. As

E s t i m a t e s exclude the Chrysler workers at Slidell, Louisiana's defense-space facility. These workers would
likely continue in the event of a Chrysler failure.

—Charlie

3

4

Carter

Assuming that none of these workers would be hired by
other dealers, repair shops, etc.
President Reagan has proposed the elimination of the
trade assistance program. Congressional approval is
uncertain at this time.

I




24 M A Y 1 9 8 1 , E C O N O M I C R E V I E W

The U.S.
Economic Outlook:
No Instant Miracles
by Robert

F.

Lanzillotti

Robert F. Lanzillotti, Professor of Economics and Dean, Graduate School of
Business, University of Florida, recently addressed the Board of Directors of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta on the current economic outlook. Dr.
Lanzillotti is optimistic about the Reagan policies and is convinced the American
public will accept t h e necessary austerity accompanying this transition period.

For some weeks f o l l o w i n g the November elections many commentators viewed Stockman
and Company's proposals for drastic budget
cuts and major tax reductions as more postelection bravado than serious economic argument. The President's February 5 general
economic message removed all doubt about his
economic program: He intends to bring the
country to terms w i t h the problems of chronic
high inflation, l o w productivity growth, slack
production, and vulnerability to supply disruptions and OPEC price shocks.
What kind of costs are likely to result from
the bold approach President Reagan is advocating? Put differently, how large are the costs our
country is willing to bear to guarantee the
benefits of lower inflation? Are there alternative
policies w h i c h can both lower these costs and
also reduce inflation as quickly?
Sources of Inflation
Since the mid-1960s, the U.S. has experienced a series of major economic shocks,
w h i c h have i n c r e a s e d t h e u n d e r l y i n g
( " e m b e d d e d " ) inflation rate by almost tenfold
(from about 1 percent per year in the first half of
the 1960s to 9-10 percent currently).
The most traumatic shocks were triggered by
the OPEC oil prices hikes, especially in 1973-74
and 1979. The 1973-74 hikes added about $18

FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F A T L A N T A




billion to o u r i m p o r t e d oil bill (about 1.5 percent of GNP,) but the 1979 hike (from $15 to $35
per barrel) added another $50 billion to the cost
of i m p o r t e d oil (roughly 2 percent of GNP).
The U.S. economy, indeed the w o r l d economy, was ill-prepared to meet these developments. What is truly remarkable is that the
various economies, including the U.S., withstood these shocks so well, which is a kind of
tribute to the resiliency of our economy.
But not all of the inflation shocks of the 1960s
and 1970s were exogenous in nature. Many of
o u r r e c e n t e c o n o m i c w o u n d s w e r e selfinflicted.
The military adventure in Vietnam and the
m o u n t i n g of the Great Society programs were
financed for several years w i t h o u t a tax increase, leading to a very large federal deficit
and a classic demand-pull j u m p in the underlying inflation rate by 4 or 5 percent. This was
f o l l o w e d by the economic adventure in price
and wage controls in 1971-73, producing various economic distortions and inequities.
At the same time, the 1970s gave birth to new
adventures in regulation (worker and product
safety, air and water standards, and other "mandated costs" to business). These new regulations were enacted in the face of extensive
economic analysis urging the wisdom of deregulation. It is now clear that these federal regul a t i o n s have f a i l e d t o r e f l e c t a sensible

25

b a l a n c i n g o f n a t i o n a l p r i o r i t i e s , and have
largely disregarded the costs, benefits and
least-cost solutions to p r o p o s e d regulations.
I am convinced w e will c o n t i n u e to give gove r n m e n t regulations a "fresh l o o k " to determine w h e t h e r they should be m o d i f i e d or
discarded altogether in the light of new economic and technical k n o w l e d g e or new conditions. I expect this process to extend beyond
railroads, trucking, airlines, energy, telecommunications, and banking to the new regulat o r y agencies (EPA, NHTSA, CEQ, OSHA, CPSC,
etc.), as well as other g o v e r n m e n t interventions, i n c l u d i n g unwarranted subsidies to business.
In short, w h i l e it is clear that business wants
to get the federal g o v e r n m e n t o f f its back, in
the course of events I suspect it will b e c o m e
clear that some businessmen mean "just the
g o v e r n m e n t , not its subsidies."
The United States faces the same e c o n o m i c
d i l e m m a in the 1980s as in the 1970s: that is, are
w e w i l l i n g to manage o u r e c o n o m i c affairs to
correct the devastating inflation that fosters a
kind of economic warfare a m o n g our citizens?
In forging a policy to correct the inflation, it is
essential to understand inflation's sources and
w h y it has increasingly developed a "ratchetl i k e " character. In addition to supply shocks,
the 1960s and 1970s suffered f r o m excess aggregate demand, d e c l i n i n g productivity g r o w t h ,
and a refusal of wages and prices to decline in
response to slack in the economy.
This d o w n w a r d insensitivity of both wages
and prices has some rather deepseated structural origins, i n c l u d i n g multiyear wage contracts w i t h c o s t - o f - l i v i n g clauses, noncompetitive influences in the operations of
various markets, and g o v e r n m e n t interventions
in individual markets to fix wages, prices, quality, and p r o d u c t i o n conditions.
Moreover, unions, business, and the public
have w e l c o m e d the periodic validation by the
Congress that e c o n o m i c policy will c o n t i n u e to
be expansionary, and that Congress w i l l continue to provide " s p e c i a l " relief and assistance
w h e n high prices and wages generate competitive difficulties.
Most of all, I believe the inflation of the past
15 years has been a monetary and financial
p h e n o m e n o n , created by excess liquidity, excessive credit expansion, and ultimately, excessive money-supply expansion.
There is ample empirical evidence that budget deficits have c o n t r i b u t e d to recent surges in
26




inflation both by c o n t r i b u t i n g to higher aggregate demand and by justifying expectations
about levels of future aggregate d e m a n d . As w e
all k n o w only too w e l l , fiscal policy o r i e n t e d
toward stimulating aggregate demand to drive
d o w n unemployment requires monetary
authorities to monetize the public debt.
The real challenge for e c o n o m i c policy is
w h e t h e r w e can arrest and reverse the inflation
w i t h o u t inflicting equally devastating side effects on o u t p u t and e m p l o y m e n t . A corollary to
this is w h e t h e r our e c o n o m i c t h e o r y and
econometric models are adequate to provide
guidance and support to the supply-side strategy as the centerpiece of the new e c o n o m i c
policy.

The Way O u t : Tax Cuts, Monetary Restraint
M a n y things fall under t h e rubric of "supplyside e c o n o m i c s . " Essentially, it deals w i t h the
e c o n o m i c s of p r o d u c t i o n (as contrasted w i t h
t h e e c o n o m i c s of c o n s u m p t i o n and aggregate
d e m a n d ) . It includes anything that influences
cost, efficiency, productivity, and the level and
c o m p o s i t i o n of GNP.
Principal a t t e n t i o n is focused on incentives,
and w h e t h e r sharp tax cuts w i l l "generate m o r e
supply than d e m a n d , " by creating incentives to
w o r k , save, invest, and p r o d u c e .
In this c o n n e c t i o n , it is argued that tax cuts
can pay for themselves in 1982 and 1983. The
answer d e p e n d s , of course, on the type of tax
cuts a d o p t e d .
Personal tax cuts w i l l tend to increase aggregate d e m a n d by m o r e than the tax cut, by virtue
of t h e m u l t i p l i e r process. Hence, to the extent
the supply response to such actions is less than
t h e additional aggregate d e m a n d created, any
such tax r e d u c t i o n s are likely to add to inflationary pressures f r o m the d e m a n d side, at least in
t h e s h o r t run.
Recent studies demonstrate conclusively that
o n e of t h e principal causes of the decline in
p r o d u c t i v i t y g r o w t h d u r i n g the 1970s was the
decline in t h e g r o w t h of capital stock relative to
t h e labor force. In o r d e r to restore the g r o w t h
of o u r capital stock per w o r k e r to the g r o w t h
rate of t h e 1960s, real business fixed investment
as a percentage of real GNP must rise by at least
o n e - t o - t w o percentage points (above the recent average of a r o u n d 10 percent).
Hence, tax cuts in the f o r m of accelerated
depreciation allowances, larger investment tax
M A Y 1 9 8 1 , E C O N O M I C REVIEW

credit, o r lower corporate i n c o m e tax rates are
likely to generate the r e q u i r e d increases in
business fixed investment, a significant increase in o u r capital stock and a significant
increase in t h e level of productivity.
It goes w i t h o u t saying that demand-side and
supply-side e c o n o m i c policies must be harm o n i z e d in a f r a m e w o r k of fiscal restraint if w e
are to realize additional saving, investment,
faster p r o d u c t i v i t y g r o w t h , and r e d u c t i o n in the
inflation rate.
M y analysis of t h e p r o b a b l e macro-economic
effects of alternative tax reductions leads me to
the c o n c l u s i o n
that
investment-and
p r o d u c t i v i t y - o r i e n t e d tax cuts for business are
likely to increase saving, investment, and productivity by m u c h m o r e than cuts in personal
income taxes. M o r e o v e r , since t h e supply response requires t i m e to p r o d u c e the intended
effects, any personal tax cuts should be t i m e d
to be consistent w i t h t h e degree of d e m a n d
restraint needed to reduce inflation.
Tax reductions accompanied by reductions in
federal s p e n d i n g of roughly t h e same magnitude w i l l not change aggregate demand. But a
very large tax cut not linked to s p e n d i n g cuts
probably w o u l d lead to b o t h an increase in
inflation and a sharp rise in interest rates. M o r e over, s o m e of t h e s t i m u l u s to investment
spending f r o m t h e targeted tax cuts thus might
be w e a k e n e d by higher interest rates, generating new uncertainties.
In my o p i n i o n , t h e desired policy-mix is one
emphasizing tax cuts f o r business, c o u p l e d
w i t h m o n e t a r y restraint. If personal tax cuts are
also i n c l u d e d , it w o u l d be p r u d e n t to delay the
effective date to July 1, or preferably O c t o b e r 1,
1981. This strategy offers t h e best prospect for
significant r e d u c t i o n in the inflation rate w i t h i n
a span of t w o - t o - t h r e e years.
I am o p t i m i s t i c about t h e e c o n o m i c policies
of t h e Reagan administration because it is clear
they w i l l be t i l t e d in t h e direction of measures
oriented t o w a r d l o n g - t e r m policy goals, rather
than s h o r t - r u n e c o n o m i c crises.
Accepting the Costs
This will mean accepting slower e c o n o m i c
growth in order to stimulate investment in plant
and e q u i p m e n t , new technology, and higher
productivity, even if it means in the short run
there will c o n t i n u e to be some relatively high
levels of u n e m p l o y m e n t , lower profits and
slower rates of g r o w t h in total personal i n c o m e .
FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F ATLANTA




I am convinced that the American public as
well as the American business c o m m u n i t y is
prepared to accept the necessary austerity that
must accompany this period of transition f r o m
" a n e c o n o m y in distress" to an e c o n o m y capable of maintaining viable g r o w t h and stability.
The prospects f o r the U.S. e c o n o m y f o r 1981
and beyond thus d e p e n d principally u p o n o u r
success in b r i n g i n g d o w n the rate of inflation.
At this juncture, even t h o u g h I am strongly
supportive of the approach President Reagan is
planning, I am not optimistic that the inflation
rate will fall much in 1981. This j u d g m e n t is
based on my earlier c o m m e n t s about the pervasive institutionalizing of the inflation t h r o u g h
wage escalators, indexed transfer and pension
payments, and other contractual arrangements
w h i c h are not likely to be altered in the short
run. Accordingly, wage costs w i l l accelerate in
1981 for both "catch u p " and " k e e p u p " reasons
in the face of rather d i m prospects f o r productivity gains.
W h i l e there still are no clear indicators of t h e
widely predicted recession for early 1981, the
o u t l o o k is not strong for much real g r o w t h in
GNP. The w i d e swings w e witnessed in 1980 are
not likely to recur this year.
It is i m p o r t a n t also to ensure that t h e high
volatility of interest rates in 1980 is not repeated. I look for some reduction in t h e g r o w t h
of monetary aggregates and shall be b o t h surprised and disappointed if the Fed's recently
a n n o u n c e d reductions in target g r o w t h rates
for 1981 are not i m p l e m e n t e d .
W h a t does all this signify w i t h respect to t h e
e c o n o m i c o u t l o o k f o r the U.S.? The President's
program is bold, and the p r o p o s e d changes in
e c o n o m i c policy should p r o d u c e a q u a n t u m
i m p r o v e m e n t in the long-run e c o n o m i c outl o o k . The character of the p r o g r a m und o u b t e d l y already has f a v o r a b l y a f f e c t e d
producer and consumer expectations.
The real test, however, must be measured in
terms of the actual effects on e c o n o m i c performance, particularly the rate of inflation, national i n c o m e , o u t p u t , and p r o d u c t i v i t y .
Economic processes are complex and o f t e n
slow; hence, several years w i l l be required to
correct cumulative errors in e c o n o m i c policy
and to u n w i n d the tangles and imbalances
generated. In short, even assuming the program, w i t h all of its strengths, is adoped intact
by the Congress, history and p r u d e n c e caution
us that in the economic w o r l d there are " n o
instant miracles."
BE]
27

International Deposits
In Miami
A Profile
T h e surge in international banking activity in Miami is led by deposits from
Latin American individuals and nonfinancial firms. Interviews with Miami
commercial banks, Edge Act corporations and foreign bank agencies suggest
that foreign depositors come to Miami primarily for portfolio diversification,
political stability, and personal, bilingual service.

International banking transacted by Miami
commercial banks, Edge Act corporations, and
foreign bank agencies is surging. Four years
ago, Miami had no foreign bank agencies and
only 10 Edge Act corporations. As of late
March, 1981, 27 foreign bank agencies or
representative offices and 36 Edge Act
corporations have Miami banking offices open
or pending. These include 25 of the world's
largest 100 banks. 1 Additionally, Miami has
over 20 commercial banks w i t h active
international departments — that's over 75
banking entities in Miami w i t h an active
international orientation. 2
A significant f l o w of international deposits is
placed in these Miami international banking
institutions. As of June 1980, aggregated
international liabilities of Miami banking

'American Banker, July 25, 1980.
2

For a detailed list of the international banking participants in Miami, see
"Behind Miami's Surge in International Banking" in the Economic Review,
April 1981.

28



entities (commercial banks, Edges, and
foreign agencies), excluding liabilities to the
banks' o w n foreign offices, approached $2.5
billion. By far, the bulk of these international
deposits (90 percent) was placed in Miami by
individuals and nonfinancial firms. A large
part of these accounts are in time deposits;
most (over 90 percent) are from Latin America.
O n top of those deposits directly placed on
Miami books is a significant Miami-generated
deposit base (perhaps another third) placed
directly on a bank's Eurocurrency branch in
the Bahamas, Cayman Islands, and London.
In order to provide a profile of the character
of international deposits placed in Miami, this
author carried on a series of interviews during
February 1981 w i t h 14 Miami commercial
banks, Edge Act corporations, and foreign
bank agencies, w h i c h account for four-fifths of
Miami's foreign liability base. The interviews
concentrated on those factors affecting
individual and nonfinancial international
deposits in Miami.
M A Y 1981, E C O N O M I C REVIEW

Table 1. Miami Banking Entities' International
Deposits* ( J u n e 1 9 8 0 )
To
Foreign official institutions
Unaffiliated foreign b a n k s
All o t h e r f o r e i g n e r s
Total

Percent
of
Total
2.8
6.7

Percent
in Time
Deposits

Percent
Latin
American

13.3

99.0

0.5

88.6

90.5

80.4

93.5

100.0

73.2

93.3

"Excludes foreign liabilities to own branches and affiliates.
Source: U.S. Treasury.

The average international deposit account is
large compared to its domestic counterpart.
Some Edge Act corporations and foreign bank
agencies have a strictly wholesale orientation
and are hesitant to accept retail international
deposit accounts. An average time account in
these entities surpasses $100,000, and the

»
I

W H Y ARE INTERNATIONAL DEPOSITS
PLACED I N M I A M I ?
Are Interest Rates a Major Factor? — Yes, but.

:
j

I
b

Question 1. How responsive are foreigners'
Miami bank deposits to interest
rate differentials between the
U.S. and the foreigners' home
country?
Responses

a. very responsive
b. moderately responsive
c. not very responsive

3
7
4

Question 2. How significant is interest rate
competition on CDs in the Miami
banking market?
Responses

a. significantly competitive
b. moderately competitive
c. very limited competition

9
3
2

Nearly three-quarters of the interviewed
bankers perceive Miami international deposits
as somewhat to very responsive to rate
differentials between U.S. and Eurodollar
rates and what a large depositor could earn in
his home country. But none of the bankers
perceived interest rate differentials as the
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ATLANTA




number of international deposit accounts may
be 500 or less. Other edges and foreign bank
agencies, as well as the Miami-based
commercial banks, accept smaller accounts —
still, an average time account ranges from
$50,000-$100,000 or more.
Time deposits are the principal deposit
instrument, although most international
depositors (and the banks themselves) prefer
that the depositor also open a demand
deposit account; this facilitates the banking
relationship. The Miami banking entities are
principally interested in these full banking
relationships. Most request bank references
and prefer depositors referred to them rather
than relying on walk-in business. Some Miami
banking entities travel abroad selling their
personal deposit services; others d o not travel
at all and only passively accept international
deposits w h i c h may be generated by the
bank's Miami or w o r l d reputation. Few of the
Edges and agencies advertise locally for
international deposits.
prime explanation for Miami's international
deposit growth. They view international
depositors as increasingly sophisticated and
aware of the differences between home
country and international deposit interest
rates.
In response, an increasing number of Latin
American economies are allowing their
domestic time deposit rates to fluctuate w i t h
international rates — sometimes with a
marginally favorable difference in favor of the
home country. Mexico has been particularly
alert to maintaining its deposit rates
marginally above comparable U.S. and
Eurodollar rates. Costa Rica and Venezuela
also have permitted their rates to vary w i t h
international rates, although sometimes w i t h a
lag. In contrast, Guatemalan maximum
deposit rates, for instance, remained constant
throughout the extremely volatile 1980
international interest rate scenario and likely
induced a deposit outflow.
Several bankers mentioned the fact that
though some deposits do enter the Miami and
Eurodollar international deposit place due to
favorable interest rates, once placed abroad, a
significant proportion of these deposits stay,
even if the favorable rate differential
disappears. Therefore, it is likely that
international deposits are placed in Miami also
for portfolio diversification and political
stability purposes.
29

Table 2. Typical Interest Rates on Large Time Deposits

(percent)

1980

Rica1

Guatemala2

Mexico3

Venezuela4

United
States5

Eurodollar
Deposits6

January

15.0

9.0

17.35

15.00

13.39

14.33

18.15

15.00

14.30

15.33

20.71

17.00

17.57

18.72

22.03

17.00

16.14

17.81

21.11

13.00

9.79

11.20

19.13

12.00

8.49

9.41

18.20

12.00

8.65

9.33

9.91

10.82

February
March
April
May
June
July

17.5
16.1
10.8
10.9
11.8
12.2

9.0
9.0
9.0
9.0
9.0
9.0

August

13.3

9.0

18.98

12.00

September

13.7

9.0

20.74

12.00

11.29

12.07

21.74

12.00

12.94

13.55

23.25

16.00

15.36

16.46

October
November

15.4
17.9

9.0
9.0

'Six-month foreign currency deposit.
2

M a x i m u m interest rate permissible on deposit liabilities.

3

Large three-month certificates of deposit.

"Large six-month certificates of deposit.
5

Three-month certificates of deposit, secondary markets (average of five dealers).

6

Three-month rate.

Most of the bankers interviewed regarded
Miami as a moderate to significantly
competitive banking market for large
international deposits — significantly more
competitive than it was even a few years ago
due to the influx of the new internationally
oriented banks. Still, Miami rates are typically
below New York levels because of demand
factors — the bankers simply do not have New
York's loan demand. But competitive factors in
Miami's banking market are closing the gap
between Miami and New York rates.
The sensitivity of large CD deposits to a
particular bank's rates has been heightened by
the 1980 volatile rate scene. Large depositors
earned over 17 percent on three-month
certificates of deposit in March 1980, but the
renewal rate in June 1980 was at half that level.
This induced a greater number of depositors
to " s h o p a r o u n d " for rates. It also may have
induced greater deposit placements in
Eurodollar markets, since banks can quote
marginally higher Eurocurrency rates to such
interest-sensitive large depositors.
Some Miami banking entities resisted
paying the peak March/April 1980 CD rates,
assuming that the cost of funds w o u l d soon
fall and that the bulk of their depositors w o u l d
stay due to longstanding banking relationships
and personal attention given to their clientele.
Some banks, then, differentiate their product
30




(deposit services) t h r o u g h such personal
service.
Large depositors are dealt w i t h personally
by the bilingual senior official staff of Miami's
banking entities — this is often in contrast to
treatment afforded the same depositor in the
same bank's head office in money centers.
The smaller scale operations out of Miami
make such treatment possible. These accounts
also get significant attention because the
personal international accounts are the bulk
of Miami's international deposit base. It is this
service and personal attention — so important
to Latin American clients — that permit Miami
banking entities to compete against New York
and Eurodollar rates. The competition is in
nonprice (noninterest rate) factors.
Is Economic and Political Stability a Factor? —
Yes!
Question 3. How responsive are foreign
deposits in Miami to fears of
home country devaluation or
exchange control establishment?
a. very responsive
b. moderately responsive
c. unresponsive

8
6
0

M A Y 1981, E C O N O M I C REVIEW

Question 4. How important a role does the
political stability of the U.S. play
in attracting foreign deposits in
Miami?

*\

a. very important
b. moderately important
c. relatively unimportant

13
1

0

> Question 5. H o w responsive are foreign
deposits in Miami to political
instability in the foreign
depositor's home country?
a. very responsive
b. moderately responsive
c. unresponsive

13
1

political factors alone. The U.S. has
commercial and cultural ties w i t h Latin
America. A large part of Latin American trade
is conducted with the U.S.; many Latin
Americans travel to the U.S. for business
purposes. Further, a significiant number of
Latin Americans study in U.S. colleges, spend
their vacations in the U.S., and purchase retail
goods here.
All of these factors have induced the
placement of dollar deposits in the U.S. Miami
is in an especially good position for housing
such deposits — it is the U.S. arrival and
departure point for a third of international air
passengers destined to or arriving f r o m Latin
America. For many, Miami is increasingly the
final U.S. destination point also, since
business, banking, and tourism can be
combined there.

0

Political and economic stability is important
to the placement of international deposits in
the U.S. Miami international bankers see this
factor, along with portfolio diversification, as
the basic rationale behind international
deposit placement by individuals and
nonfinancial firms.
International depositors react to real and
perceived factors. In countries which
habitually have large current account deficits
combined with high inflation and stable
exchange rates, large depositors react to
rumors of devaluation and exchange control
implementation or tightening of existing
controls. This occurred, for instance, in
Mexico prior to the dramatic 1976 peso
devaluation which caused a Mexican deposit
overflow into dollar-denominated accounts in
Mexico and abroad. In those countries w h i c h
periodically adjust exchange rates, the deposit
outflow due to anticipated changes is
lessened. Where exchange controls are
already in effect, the deposit outflow is likely
reduced but not by any means eliminated.
Not surprisingly, bankers also agreed that
political instability in the depositor's home
country (or in a neighboring country) also
caused deposit inflows into Miami. This factor,
combined with the political and economic
stability of the U.S., has been a prime element
in attracting deposits.
Still, as one banker noted, other economies
offer political stability. The reasons w h y
deposits are placed in the U.S. go beyond

Are Euromarkets and International Banking
Facilities Important in Miami's International
Deposit Base? — Yes.

Question 6. What proportion of your bank's
Miami international deposit base
is actually booked on your
Eurocurrency branch?
a. less than 10 percent
b. 10 to 35 percent
c. over 35 percent

Question 7. How will the proposed IBFs affect
Miami's international banking
activities (assuming a $500,000
m i n i m u m transaction)?
a. very significant, positive
effect
b. moderate, positive effect
c. no effect
d. detrimental effect
Banks are able to offer Eurocurrency deposit
rates t h r o u g h placing international deposits
on Eurocurrency branch books. The Edge Act
corporations and foreign banks in Miami have
Eurocurrency branches, as do several Miami
commercial banks. Generally, bankers are not
anxious to offer Eurocurrency rates on small
transactions due to the paper w o r k involved in
matching maturities of the deposit liability
31

FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F ATLANTA




w i t h a similarly maturing income earning
asset. Still, competition in Miami is reducing
the m i n i m u m in w h i c h bankers will quote
Eurocurrency rates. Some Miami banking
entities apparently quote Eurocurrency rates
on deposits as low as $25,000, although most
require a $100,000 or higher deposit
minimum.
The Eurocurrency markets typically offer
higher deposit interest rates than comparable
U.S. rates. For instance, for the week ending
January 2,1981, U.S. three-month certificates
of deposit yielded, on average, 16.99 percent 3
while comparable Eurodollar deposits yielded
17.79 percent. Such Eurocurrency deposits
operate w i t h o u t reserve requirements, so long
as the funds are not transferred back to the
U.S. — this enables the yield differential
compared to U.S. booked deposits. Still,
many international depositors prefer to have
their deposits placed on U.S. rather than
Eurocurrency books, since the "safekeeping"
aspect of placing deposits in the U.S. is
foremost in mind.
The p r o p o r t i o n of international deposits
generated by banking entities in Miami but
actually placed on Eurocurency branch books
is difficult to estimate. The p r o p o r t i o n ,
however, has been growing because more
Miami-based commercial banks have
Eurocurrency branches and because the 1980
interest rate volatility caused international
depositors to be more rate conscious.
Five of the 14 interviewed banks responded
that less than 10 percent of their international
deposit base is placed in Eurocurrency
markets — partly because some of these
banks d o not have direct Eurocurrency
facilities. O n the other hand, another five of
the interviewed banks estimated that over 35
percent of their Miami deposits were actually
placed on Eurocurrency branches. A rough
estimate is that approximately one-third of
deposits generated by Miami banking entities
are actually booked in Euromarkets.
A recent Board of Governors' proposal
w o u l d permit banks operating in the U.S. to
offer International Banking Facilities (IBFs).
This proposal w o u l d eliminate reserve
requirements and interest rate ceilings on

3

Five-day average of rate quotes by five dealers for three-month certificates of
deposit in secondary markets. Source of interest rate quotes: Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Federal Fieserve Bulletin,
Washington, D.C., January 1981.

32




international deposits placed in such IBFs by
non-U.S. residents. In 1978 New York state
passed legislation that w o u l d exempt IBFs, if
approved by the Board of Governors, from
state and local taxes. Other states are now
considering accompanying legislation to
exempt IBFs f r o m state and local taxes. Florida
has already largely exempted foreign source
income f r o m state and local taxes, although
some relatively minor alterations to fully
exempt IBFs are being presented to the
Florida legislature this spring.
The Board of Governors' proposal permits
IBF establishment by all U.S. depository
institutions, by Edge Act corporations, and by
branches and agencies of foreign banks in this
country. Only non-U.S. residents, other IBFs,
and the parent institutions of IBFs w o u l d be
eligible to place funds with IBFs. IBF deposits
of foreign nonbank customers w o u l d be
subject to a two-day minimum maturity to
minimize use of such deposits for transaction
purposes. To maintain a wholesale
orientation, the Board proposed a $500,000
m i n i m u m transaction but at the same time
requested comment on an alternative
proposal that would require a $500,000 daily
average balance for the reserve computation
period, with a minimum amount of $100,000
for deposit or withdrawal transactions.
The proposal w o u l d , therefore, permit
banks to offer Eurocurrency-type large time
deposits through an IBF instead of resorting to
booking the deposit on a Eurocurrency
branch. This issue is important to Miami's
international banking development. It offers a
Eurocurrency dimension to Miami commercial
banks without offshore branches. It may
induce formation of Miami Edge Act
corporations by regional banks anxious to
offer IBFs but operating in states which have
not exempted such IBFs from state and local
taxation. At the same time, however, it may
induce placement of some funds into IBFs
which otherwise would have been placed on a
Miami banking entity's o w n books and made
available for local lending. Generally, IBF
funds would be destined abroad or to other
IBFs, since the only domestic lending
permitted is to U.S. offices of the IBF's parent
depository institution — and these latter
transactions are to be subjected to the
Eurocurrency reserve requirement (3 percent).
Twelve of the 14 interviewed Miami
international banking entities perceived the
M A Y 1 9 8 1 , E C O N O M I C REVIEW

IBF proposal as having positive effects on
Miami's international banking, although only
three perceived the facilities, as proposed, as
having very significant effects. Many felt that
the $500,000 m i n i m u m transaction (or
^ m i n i m u m $500,000 daily average balance f o r
the reserve c o m p u t a t i o n period) was too
i high; average certificate of deposit accounts,
although large, were well below these
I minimums. Still, all banks had some accounts
t which w o u l d be eligible for IBF placement.
Several of t h e bankers perceived the need for
Florida to offer fully tax-exempted IBFs for
defensive purposes, since N e w York —
Miami's principal U.S. c o m p e t i t o r for
international deposits — has already
exempted IBFs f r o m state and local taxation.
?
»

International Deposits in M i a m i — A
Perspective
Miami's international deposit base is primarily
generated f r o m nonfinancial firms and
individuals. O n l y a limited a m o u n t of official
and unaffiliated bank-to-bank foreign liability
activity is c o n d u c t e d f r o m M i a m i . The

J
*

potential for expansion of these latter foreign
liability f u n c t i o n s pends d e v e l o p m e n t in
M i a m i of an efficient bank clearings system
w h i c h can rival o t h e r c o m p e t i n g banking
centers.
International deposits — principally time
deposit accounts — are in M i a m i to take
advantage of asset diversification, e c o n o m i c
and political stability, and favorable deposit
returns d u e to interest rate differentials
b e t w e e n the U.S. and Euromarkets and the
depositor's h o m e c o u n t r y - c o n t r o l l e d rates.
A significant p r o p o r t i o n of M i a m i
international deposits are actually b o o k e d in
Euromarkets d u e to t h e marginally higher
deposit interest rates available there. The
p r o p o s e d IBFs, even w i t h $500,000 m i n i m u m
balances, w i l l b r i n g Eurocurrency deposits
o n t o M i a m i books. IBFs w i l l also induce
additional Edge Act corporations into M i a m i to
take advantage of Florida's anticipated full
e x e m p t i o n of IBF activity f r o m state and local
taxation. At the same t i m e , however, IBFs may
affect t h e a m o u n t of international deposits
available for local and U.S. lending.

—Donald E. Baer
33
t

I
I

1
V

•JM
i

-I

)
*

i>
•

•

FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F A T L A N T A




ALSO
AVAILABLE
WORKING PAPER SERIES:
Estimating Sixth District Consumer Spending
by Brian D. Dittenhafer
Changes in Seller Concentration in Banking Markets
by B. Frank King
Regional Impacts of Monetary and Fiscal Policies In the Postwar Period: Some Initial Tests
by William D. Toal
A Framework for Examining the Small, Open Regional Economy: An Application of the
Macroeconomics of Open Systems
by Robert E. Keleher
V

Southern Banks and the Confederate Monetary Expansion
by John M. Godfrey
An Empirical Test of the Linked Oligopoly Theory: An Analysis of Florida Holding Companies
by David D. Whitehead
Regional Credit Market Integration: A Survey and Empirical Examination
by Robert E. Keleher
Entry, Exit, and Market Structure Change in Banking
by B. Frank King
Future Holding Company Lead Banks: Federal Reserve Standards and Record
by B. Frank King
Money-Income Causality at the State-Regional Level
by Robert E. Keleher and Charles J. Haulk

'

*;' j i

The Influence of Selected Factors on the Slowdown in Southeastern Manufacturing Productivity!
by Charlie Carter
1919-1939 Reassessed: Unemployment and Nominal Wage Rigidity in the U.K.
by Barbara Henneberry, Robert E. Keleher, and James G. Witte
Home Office Pricing: The Evidence from Florida
by David D. Whitehead

'

Supply-Side Effects of Fiscal Policy: Some Historical Perspectives
by Robert E. Keleher and William R Orzechowski

I
- " *«

I
34




v

M A Y 1 9 8 1 , E C O N O M I C REVIEW

Copies of these publications are available upon request from: Research
Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, P.O. Box 1731, Atlanta,
Georgia 30301. Please include a complete mailing address with ZIP
Code to ensure delivery. Interested parties may also have their names
placed on a subscription list for future studies.

RESEARCH PAPER SERIES:
No.

1

Impact of Holding Company Affiliation on Bank Performance: A Case Study of Two
Florida Multibank Holding Companies
by Stuart G. Hoffman

No.

2

No.

3

Convenience and Needs: Holding Company Claims and Actions
by Joseph E. Rossman and B. Frank King
Small Banks and Monetary Control: Is Fed Membership Important?
by William N. Cox, III

No.

4

Component Ratio Estimation of the Money Multiplier
by Stuart G. Hoffman

No.

5

Holding Company Power and Market Performance: A New Index of Market
Concentration
by David D. Whitehead

No.

6

Fundamental Determinants of Credit Volume: A Survey and Regional Application
by Robert E. Keleher

No.

7

State Usury Laws: A Survey and Application to the Tennessee Experience
by Robert E. Keleher

No.

9

Supply—Side Effects of Fiscal Policy: Some Preliminary Hypotheses
by Robert E. Keleher

No. 10

An Empirical Analysis of Sectoral Money Demand in the Southeast
by Stuart G. Hoffman

FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F ATLANTA




35

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta
P.O. Box 1731
Atlanta, Georgia 30301

B u l k Rate
U.S. Postage

Address Correction Requested

A t l a n t a , Ga.
Permit 292




PAID