View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Banks’ Responses to
Binding Regulatory
Capital Requirements

Larry D. Wall and Pamela P. Peterson

I
Wall is a research officer in
the Atlanta Fed’s research
department. Peterson is
a professor at Florida
State University.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

n recent years bank regulators have increased their focus on the adequacy of banking organizations’ capital ratios.1 The increased emphasis on capital regulation raises a number of interrelated questions. Is
focusing on capital an efficient way to regulate banks? What is the best
way to structure capital regulations? How do banks respond to different types of capital regulations? And what are the costs and benefits to banks
of different ways of meeting capital regulations? This article focuses on the
last two questions, examining banks’ responses, and the costs associated with
their responses, to capital regulations employed since the early 1980s.2
Understanding banks’ responses to capital regulations may be helpful in
designing regulations that meet regulators’ objectives. One objective of capital regulation has been to reduce the number of bank failures. Equity capital
provides a cushion to absorb losses that would otherwise cause a bank to fail.
Regulators have considered preventing failure an important goal at least in
part because of concern that one bank’s failure may adversely affect the stability of other financial institutions.3 Another objective has been to reduce the
losses to depositors and the deposit insurer when a bank fails. Both equity
and debt subordinated to depositors provide a cushion to reduce the losses to
depositors and the deposit insurer in the event of failure. Regulators are especially sensitive to deposit insurance losses because the government not only
provides insurance through formal programs such as the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) but also, in the absence of de jure coverage, has
historically been the insurer of last resort.
Economic Review

1

While U.S. bank regulators have been refining their
approach to capital regulation since the early 1980s
(see Table 1), this is not to say that they were previously uninterested in banks’ capital levels. During the
1970s regulators were concerned about capital, but
there were no regulations that specified minimum capital ratios. At the beginning of the 1980s regulators
became dissatisfied with many banks’ capital ratios, especially those of the larger banking organizations.4 As
a result, U.S. regulators specified minimum numerical
capital-to-asset ratios for almost all banks in 1981; the
remaining banks were required to raise their capital-toasset ratios and were brought under numerical standards in 1983.5
The banking industry increased its capital ratios in
the years after the 1981 guidelines were adopted.
However, the simplistic use of total assets as a risk
measure became questionable as banks adjusted their
portfolios. Given regulators’ concern with preventing
failure and protecting the deposit insurer, an appropriate measure of capital adequacy would measure a
bank’s ability to absorb losses from its portfolio with-

out failing or imposing substantial costs on the deposit
insurance agency. During the 1980s, however, banks
reduced their investment in high-liquidity, low-return
assets and increased their exposure in potentially risky
off-balance-sheet transactions, such as letters of credit
and over-the-counter derivatives. Thus, capital-to-totalasset ratios that may have been adequate in the early
1980s were likely becoming less adequate later in the
decade. As a consequence, the United States, along
with other industrialized countries, adopted risk-based
capital standards in 1988 that took full effect in 1992.6
These standards, often referred to as the Basle Agreement, established capital ratios that are dependent on
banks’ overall exposure to credit risk. Bank supervisors are engaged in on-going efforts to incorporate
other forms of risk—for example, standards for market
risk were recently adopted.
In response to concerns regarding the thrift bailouts
of the 1980s and the potential for a similar bailout
of banks, Congress passed the FDIC Improvement
Act (FDICIA) in 1991. FDICIA made a number of
changes that were intended to reduce taxpayers’ and

Table 1
Overview of Major Changes in Capital Regulation, 1981 to 1996
1981

The Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) sets numeric guidelines for all the banks it regulates.

1981

The Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC) and Federal Reserve divide banks into three categories: community, regional, and multinational (the seventeen largest banking organizations). Numeric
guidelines are set for the community and regional banks. No standards are set for the multinational banks,
but they are encouraged to raise their capital ratios.

1983

The OCC and Federal Reserve impose the regional bank numeric guidelines on multinational banks.

1985

The FDIC, OCC, and Federal Reserve establish a common set of capital guidelines that apply to all banking organizations.

1990

Interim risk-based capital guidelines take effect for all banking organizations. The risk-based guidelines
are supplemented with leverage guidelines.

1991

The FDIC Improvement Act, which establishes five capital categories, is passed. Regulators are given a
menu of mandatory and optional enforcement actions they may undertake as a bank’s capital ratios decline. Regulators ultimately define the categories both in terms of risk-based and leverage ratios.

1992

Final risk-based capital guidelines take effect for all banking organizations. The risk-based guidelines are
still supplemented with leverage guidelines.

Note: The table provides only a broad overview of bank capital regulation. Numerous refinements in the measures of both capital and risk
exposure occurred during this period. For more detailed discussions of the evolution of capital regulations, see Alfriend (1988 ), Gilbert,
Stone, and Trebing (1985), Keeton (1989), and Wall (1989, 1993).

2

Economic Review

March/April 1996

the government’s exposure to problem financial institutions. 7 Among these changes are provisions for
prompt corrective action that impose increasingly
strict limits on banks as their capital ratios decline.
The act provides a classification system with five tiers
based primarily on banks’ capital ratios, with the
lowest tier having a capital-to-assets ratio of less than
2 percent. Regulators are strongly encouraged to close
any bank falling into the lowest tier if the bank is unable to raise its capital ratio within ninety days of
falling below 2 percent.
The combined effect of the Basle Agreement and
FDICIA is to make capital ratios one of the primary
measures, for regulatory purposes, of U.S. banks’ financial condition. Banks may not respond to these
regulations if the regulations are not binding or if the
costs of meeting the regulations are greater than the
benefits. If banks do respond, they generally do so in
one of two ways. A bank may increase its capital ratios as measured under the regulatory standards without reducing either the probability that the bank will
fail or the losses to depositors and the deposit insurance agency if the bank fails. This first general category of response will be referred to hereafter as cosmetic
changes to the capital ratio. One way for a bank to
make cosmetic improvements in its capital ratios would
be to reduce its total assets to improve its capital-toassets ratio while increasing portfolio risk by increasing the proportion of risky assets, as appeared to be
happening in the early to mid-1980s. The other way of
making cosmetic changes is to exploit differences between capital as measured for regulatory purposes and
the bank’s true economic capital. A bank may exploit
these differences by (1) selling assets that have appreciated in value (but not those with reduced value) to
increase capital measured by regulatory accounting,
even if this action sometimes reduces the bank’s economic capital, and (2) refusing to recognize substantial reductions in the market value of assets.8
A second general response to capital regulations
would be to increase measured capital ratios in a way
that also reduces the probability of failure and the expected losses to depositors and the deposit insurer if
the bank should fail. Examples of this type of response
include reducing risk exposure and increasing the capital base without taking offsetting measures that increase risks.
Studies of the theoretical determinants of bank
capital levels suggest that taxes, deposit insurance,
bankruptcy costs, and managerial incentives may play
a significant role in determining the optimal level of
bank capital. Further, theory suggests that attempts to
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

raise new capital via stock issues could be costly to
shareholders because such efforts signal that management has adverse news about the bank.
Empirical evidence on the effectiveness of capital
regulation suggests that regulations have had a significant impact on most banks’ capital ratios in the period
since the 1981 numeric guidelines were imposed. Part
of the increase in capital for some banks during at
least part of this period appears to have been the result
of cosmetic changes. Some theories and empirical evidence suggest that certain banks respond to higher
capital ratios by increasing their risk exposure. However, none of the empirical evidence suggests that
banks increased their portfolio risk exposure by so
much that it more than offset the reduced risk from
higher capital. The evidence also suggests that banks
may have increased their regulatory capital by selling
appreciated assets and delaying the recognition of
losses.
Banks also have responded to the regulation by reducing their risk exposure and increasing their capital.
Banks reduced their risk exposure via loan sales and
perhaps by refusing to make new loans while allowing
existing loans to be repaid. Further, banks issued new
equity to help meet the regulatory guidelines even
though these issues often reduced the price of existing
shares, as predicted by some theories.
The next sections of this article review the theoretical determinants of changes in capital and the effectiveness of capital regulation. The article then considers the
literature on cosmetic changes to capital ratios and on
responses that increase the risk cushion.

Determinants of Capital Strategy
In evaluating its capital position, a bank must consider both the static costs associated with any given
capital ratio and the dynamic costs associated with adjusting it. The static costs, and possibly the dynamic
costs, depend in part on the penalties regulators impose for inadequate capital ratios. Banks are similar to
other corporations, however, in that they are subject to
a variety of nonregulatory costs associated with the
level and changes in their capital position.
Bank regulators have long considered the maintenance of adequate capital levels an important element
of maintaining banks’ safety and soundness. Banks
with inadequate levels have been subject to a variety
of penalties depending on the size of the deficiency,
including (1) more frequent and longer examinations,
Economic Review

3

(2) moral suasion aimed at senior management and the
board of directors, (3) denial of applications to acquire
banks, (4) formal agreements with their regulator to
raise capital and take other actions (such as suspending dividends until capital reaches acceptable levels),
and (5) effectively forcing closure by withdrawing the
bank’s charter or its deposit insurance.
In addition to these penalties, provisions in FDICIA
for prompt corrective action include a series of mandatory and optional penalties to be imposed on banks as
their capital level declines. In many ways these provisions are not a dramatic change because they do not
supply many new penalties and they continue to allow
regulators to exercise substantial discretion in imposing penalties. In another sense, however, prompt corrective action is a significant change in that it reduces
the potential for regulators to exercise forbearance for
undercapitalized banks. Regulators are now required
to specify a series of ranges of capital ratios and then
choose from a menu of potential penalties associated
with each range. Further, FDICIA mandates the development of risk-based insurance premiums, and a
bank’s capital level is currently one of the two determinants of the risk premium’s size.
The regulatory pressure on banks to maintain capital levels is one-sided; regulators will protest capital
ratios that are too low, but they virtually never complain about excessively high capital ratios. Market
forces, however, could potentially impose varying
costs based on both the level of a bank’s capital and
changes in the bank’s capital structure. The theoretical
starting point for analyzing market forces is Franco
Modigliani and Merton H. Miller’s (1958) demonstration that a firm’s capital structure (the choice of its
debt-to-equity ratio) does not affect its value in perfect
markets. An implication of this model is that securities
prices are an unbiased estimate of their intrinsic value
and, hence, the timing of a sale and the type of security sold by the firm do not affect the value of the firm.
Modigliani and Miller established not only the conditions under which capital structure is irrelevant but also conditions under which capital structure may be
relevant.9
Building on a variety of studies analyzing nonfinancial corporations’ optimal capital, Yair E. Orgler and
Robert A. Taggart Jr. (1983) developed a market model of optimal capital structure for banks.10 In their
model, lower capital ratios provide banks with more
favorable tax treatment and an increase in the value of
their deposit insurance. Offsetting these benefits of
lower capital ratios are the (eventual) diseconomies of
scale in producing deposit services and the dead4

Economic Review

weight costs of bankruptcy that are partially borne by
the banks’ owners.11 Mark J. Flannery (1994) argued
that agency costs also may be an important determinant of bank capital structures.12 Lower capital ratios
impose desirable limits on management and reduce the
need for shareholder monitoring. Conversely, lower ratios increase the incentives for bank shareholders to
have managers undertake riskier projects and to reject
some low-risk investments. These costs of reduced
capital may be mitigated, Flannery argued, by having
the bank issue deposits with very short maturities so
that debtholders may take effective action if the bank
adopts a high-risk investment strategy. Thus, Flannery
contended that banks should issue very short-term
debt and maintain low capital ratios (although they
would not necessarily be undercapitalized by regulatory standards).
Ronald E. Shrieves and Drew Dahl (1992) and
Joseph P. Hughes and Loretta J. Mester (1996) pointed
to another agency problem that may influence banks’
capital structure—managerial risk aversion. Most individuals are thought to be risk-averse, and there is no
good reason for thinking that bank managers are more
risk-averse than the average shareholder. However,
bank managers have proportionately far more of their
total wealth (including human capital) invested in their
bank than do most shareholders, and, as a consequence, managers have more to lose from the bank’s
failure. Thus, bank managers may choose higher capital levels, given their risk exposure, than would be optimal from a shareholder’s perspective. Hughes and
Mester estimated bank cost functions that allowed for
managerial risk aversion and found support for this
hypothesis.
An implicit assumption of the static trade-off models of capital structure is that the cost of adjusting a
bank’s capital structure is zero. Recent work that focuses on information asymmetries between managers
and investors has suggested, however, that the process
of adjusting the capital ratio may convey important information to shareholders. An important part of the
analyses of information asymmetries has focused on
the issuance of new securities by corporations. Stewart
C. Myers and Nicholas S. Majluf (1984) examined a
firm’s decision to issue debt or equity and concluded
that the announcement to issue equity conveys negative information to the market about the firm’s value.
That is, a firm issues stock when its stock price is
higher than management believes is the firm’s intrinsic
value and issues debt otherwise. Myers and Majluf’s
model suggests that firms generally prefer to issue
debt rather than equity. Their hypothesis, stated in
March/April 1996

general terms, is that actions implying that future earnings will be sufficient to generate adequate capital are
a positive signal to shareholders while actions that imply future earnings will be insufficient are a negative
sign. Their model approach has been extended to develop hypotheses about other methods of maintaining
or raising capital ratios such as recognizing gains on
appreciated assets—methods that do not include equity issuance.
Thus, theory suggests a variety of benefits and costs
to shareholders associated with higher capital ratios.
These benefits include a reduction in taxes, an increase
in the value of deposit insurance, and an increase in
bank managements’ incentive to operate efficiently.
The costs include increased dead-weight costs of
bankruptcy, diseconomies of scale in producing deposit services, and incentives to take on excessive risk.
Theory also suggests that the optimal level of capital
from the managers’ perspective may be higher than
that desired by shareholders if managers are riskaverse. In addition, banks may not always be at their
optimum level of capital if adjusting capital ratios is
costly. Announcements of new capital issues may be
viewed by the market as an adverse signal about the
issuing bank’s value and hence lead to a decline in the
price of the bank’s stock.

Do Banks Respond to
Capital Regulation?
The question of whether banks respond to capital
regulation hinges on two issues: Are regulatory capital requirements above those that the market would
require for at least some banks? And are the penalties for falling below the regulatory guidelines large
enough to induce banks to raise their capital ratios?
For the purposes of this analysis, the relevant market
requirement is not the standard that would be imposed
in the absence of any government intervention but,
rather, that which the market would require given the
regulatory safety net that has been extended to banks,
as noted by Allen N. Berger, Richard J. Herring, and
Giorgio P. Szegö (1995). Empirical analysis of this issue may be divided into three periods: prior to the
1981 numeric capital standards, from 1981 to the passage of FDICIA in 1991, and post-FDICIA.
Several studies—Sam Peltzman (1970), John J.
Mingo (1975), Alan J. Marcus (1983), and Dietrich J.
Kimball and Christopher James (1983)—examined the
effectiveness of capital regulations in the period before
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

numeric standards were adopted in 1981. Their results,
though mixed, tend to indicate that regulators were ineffective in influencing banks’ capital ratios. A problem with interpreting these studies’ results is that the
regulatory requirements for any given bank organization were set on a case-by-case basis and the factors
used to evaluate capital adequacy were likely to be
highly correlated with those used by the market. A
second problem is that the regulatory penalties associated with varying levels of capital inadequacy were
not transparent.
The numeric capital standards imposed on most
banks in 1981 gave outside observers (that is, anyone
lacking direct access to supervisory reports) a clearer
picture of regulatory expectations but failed to clarify
the penalty function.13 Dilip K. Shome, Stephen D.
Smith, and Arnold A. Heggestad (1986) raised doubts
about whether the 1981 standards were binding. For
their sample of ninety-nine bank holding companies,
the companies’ market value was significantly positively related to their book-equity-to-total-asset ratio
in 1981-82. However, this relationship became insignificant in 1983.
Michael C. Keeley’s (1988) analysis suggests that
the 1981 regulatory standards were effective in causing large bank holding companies with inadequate
capital to raise their capital ratios. Keeley divided his
sample into capital-sufficient banks (those that met the
1985 capital standards in 1981) and capital-deficient
banks (those not meeting the 1985 standards in 1981).
He showed that the capital-deficient banks raised their
ratios during the 1982-86 period so that almost all met
the standards by the end of the period.
A problem with analyzing Keeley’s results is that
the pressure for higher capital ratios could have come
from regulators, as Keeley suggests, but it could also
have come from market pressures, as Shome, Smith,
and Heggestad’s results imply. C. Sloan Swindle
(1995) attempted to separate the relative roles of the
market and regulators using the regulators’ private
capital adequacy ratings obtained from Thomas F.
Cargill’s (1989) study. Swindle’s results suggest that
banks with lower regulatory capital ratings have higher expected increases in their primary capital ratios.
How successful Swindle was in separating market and
regulatory effects depends on the degree to which the
regulatory ratings contain private information that is
not available to the market.14
In an attempt to sort out the relative importance of
regulators and the market, Larry D. Wall and David R.
Peterson (1987, 1988) estimated a pair of equations
that allow for separate market and regulatory influence.
Economic Review

5

They assumed that either the market or regulators exercise a binding influence on any individual banking
organization but that determining which influence is
binding is an empirical question for any given organization. The two equations assume that a change in the
capital ratio is a function of the difference between the
optimal and the existing capital ratio. The market and
regulatory equations were estimated simultaneously
using a disequilibrium estimation technique that provides estimates not only of the equation parameters
but also of the probability that capital changes at each
bank are best explained by the market model. Wall and
D. Peterson’s (1987) results for bank holding companies suggested that most of them came from the regulatory regime (that is, their capital changes are best
explained by the regulatory model) during the 1982-84
period. In their 1988 study, results for the lead banks
of large bank holding companies also suggested that
regulatory standards were binding for most banks between 1982 and 1984.15
The late 1980s and early 1990s saw several potentially important changes that may have increased both
regulatory and market pressure on banks to maintain
high capital ratios. The adoption of risk-based standards in 1988 saw increased regulatory interest in
banking organizations’ off-balance-sheet activities.
The passage of FDICIA in 1991 clarified the penalties
for banks with inadequate regulatory capital ratios.
However, other developments may have led to increased market pressure. The FDIC’s resolution of
some large failed banking organizations forced some
nondeposit creditors to absorb losses that led to increased risk premiums on their subordinated debt, according to Flannery and Sorin M. Sorescu (1996).
Further, FDICIA called for the least costly resolution
of failed banking organizations; that requirement has
been taken to imply that the FDIC should not extend
de facto deposit insurance to deposits over the de jure
coverage level of $100,000.
To help clarify the relative roles of the market and
regulators in the 1988-92 period, Wall and D. Peterson
(1995) updated their prior disequilibrium analysis of
changes in capital ratios, which assumed that the
leverage ratio was the binding constraint rather than
the risk-based capital ratios. Their results continued to
show that the regulatory standards are binding for the
majority of bank holding companies.
Thus, available evidence indicates that regulators
have had significant influence on the capital ratios of a
large proportion of banking organizations in the period
since 1981. The next two sections look at the evidence
on the extent to which these increases were merely
6

Economic Review

cosmetic and the different ways that banks could provide real increases in their capital cushion.

Cosmetic Responses to
Capital Regulation
Cosmetic changes in bank capital ratios are possible
because the measures of both capital and risk are imperfect proxies for the economically relevant variables.
Regulators cannot construct perfect measures as long
as bank managers have private information about the
value or risk of their portfolios. However, even granting
the impossibility of perfect measures, the crudeness of
current measures offers substantial opportunities for
cosmetic improvements in capital ratios. Capital-to-totalasset measures (leverage standards) are easily defeated
by reducing low-risk, high-liquidity assets and substituting a smaller quantity of higher-risk, lower-liquidity
assets. The existing risk-based standards are slightly
more sophisticated, but numerous flaws remain: The
standards (1) require that most consumer and commercial loans carry the same risk weighting and do not allow for differing quality within asset classes, (2) do not
explicitly incorporate any charge for most noncredit
risks such as interest rate risk, and (3) do not explicitly
take account of diversification across different types of
risk or even across different credit risks. The opportunities for increasing regulatory capital arise because
capital is measured using accounting conventions
rather than accurate measures of true economic values.
Yet a bank’s economic capital will determine its longrun viability and the amount of losses to depositors
and deposit insurers in the event of failure. Banks can
exploit accounting conventions by accelerating the
recognition of gains on assets with market value
greater than book value while slowing the recognition
of losses on assets with market value less than book
value.
Changing Measured Risk. Banks may effectively
offset an increase in the capital ratios used by regulators by increasing their risk exposure as long as their
bank managers have private information that is unobservable to regulators about the riskiness of their
credit customers or any of their other risk exposures.
Whether bank shareholders would benefit from such
risk-increasing activities has been the subject of an ongoing debate.16
Yehuda Kahane (1977), Michael Koehn and Anthony
M. Santomero (1980), and Daesik Kim and Santomero
(1988) showed that an increase in the required equityMarch/April 1996

to-total-asset ratio by regulators may induce an increase or decrease in the portfolio risk taken by a bank.
The rise in portfolio risk exposure may only partially
offset an increase in capital or it may more than fully
offset the increase so that the bank becomes riskier.
In a pair of studies, Frederick T. Furlong and Keeley (1989) and Keeley and Furlong (1990) argued that
the framework used in prior studies is inappropriate.
The problem is that the prior studies took the expected
cost of deposits as a constant that is independent of the
bank’s capital position or risk. At first this assumption
might seem reasonable given that deposits are insured
and deposit insurance premiums could not be riskbased by law at that time. The assumption of independence is wrong, however, because it ignores the states
in which the bank fails and the FDIC pays for the deposits. When the model was adjusted so that the cost
of deposits is a decreasing function of the risk of failure (because the FDIC pays depositors when the bank
fails), then the results of prior studies did not hold.
Banks’ incentive to take more risk is greatest at low
capital levels, and the incentive decreases as capital increases. One important limitation of these two studies
is that banks continue to have an incentive to maximize risk in their models; an increase in capital merely
reduces the magnitude of the gains from risk-taking.
Gerard Gennotte and David Pyle (1991) incorporated an adjustment for the value of deposit insurance as
suggested by Keeley and Furlong but also allowed for
the expected return on an asset to decrease as a bank
increases its holdings. Gennotte and Pyle found that if
an interior optimum for size and risk exists, then a rise
in capital levels will lead to increased investment in
the risky asset and a greater probability of failure.
Robert B. Avery and Berger (1991) argued that, even
if Gennotte and Pyle’s results for increased risk of default hold, the expected losses to the deposit insurer
are decreasing in the absence of dead-weight liquidation costs of failure or extreme assumptions about the
distribution of asset returns.
Sarah B. Kendall (1991) pointed out that other models of banks’ incentive to take risk assume that only
two end-of-period states are possible: (1) the bank is
solvent and hence incurs no penalty or (2) the bank is
insolvent and is closed. She noted that a bank could
remain solvent but so undercapitalized that it incurs a
regulatory penalty. She found that an increase in regulatory capital requirements has an ambiguous impact
on its incentive to take more risk depending on its financial condition.
Paul S. Calem and Rafael Rob (1996) developed a
model of changes in banks’ asset choice and capital raFederal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

tios. They then simulated the model using parameters
estimated over the 1984-93 period. They first considered bank behavior given a constant deposit insurance
premium. In this case they found a U-shaped response of
bank risk-taking in response to higher capital requirements. Severely undercapitalized banks take more risk
in an attempt to return to adequate capital. Banks with
minimally adequate capital reduce their risk exposure
to reduce the risk that losses will cause them to be undercapitalized. Well-capitalized banks increase their
risk exposure to offset the increase in capital. The effect of higher risk-based capital requirements depends
on how strong the response of the requirements is to
risk (how stringent the requirements are in their terminology). If higher risk-based requirements are not too
stringent, they act like higher standards that are not
risk-adjusted. However, more stringent standards will
reduce portfolio risk. Finally, Calem and Rob considered an ex post penalty for taking losses in the form of
ex post risk-based insurance premiums. They found
that risk-related premiums had the effect of increasing
the range of capital values over which undercapitalized
banks took more risk. The risk-related premiums had
no impact on better-capitalized banks.
While the theoretical evidence is mixed, the empirical evidence generally suggests that higher capital
standards may be at most partially offset by increased
risk but do not increase the probability of failure.
Shrieves and Dahl (1992) found that, for commercial
banks with assets of more than $100 million during
the 1983-87 period, an increase in capital is associated
empirically with an increase in risk. Their evidence
suggests that this relationship is true even for banks
for which the regulatory capital ratios are not binding;
however, this finding suggests that bank managers
may be varying risk and leverage to hit some target for
variability of equity. Mark E. Levonian (1992) found
similar evidence that bank holding companies with
traded options in the late 1980s showed both increased
asset risk and capital, resulting in little change in the
FDIC’s expected losses.
Evidence against the hypothesis that higher capital
levels lead to an increase in risk comes from two types
of studies: studies of bank failures and studies of
banks’ involvement in off-balance-sheet activities.
Berger, Herring, and Szegö (1995) summarized the
findings of the bank failure literature concerning bank
capital: “Virtually every bank failure model finds that
a higher equity-to-asset ratio is associated with a lower
future probability of failure.”
Off-balance-sheet items are relevant to the issue of
how banks respond to higher capital levels because the
Economic Review

7

1981 capital standard did not incorporate off-balancesheet items. Banks seeking to offset the 1981 capital
requirements via higher risk could do so by substituting off-balance-sheet items for on-balance-sheet items.
Julapa Jagtiani, Anthony Saunders, and Gregory Udell
(1995) found that changes in the capital requirements
for banks have no consistent impact on the diffusion of
off-balance-sheet activities. One caveat in interpreting the analysis of off-balance-sheet activities is that
these activities may themselves create countervailing
pressure for better capitalization. That is, in almost all
cases, banks create a contingent liability to their customers that is valuable to the customers only if the
bank can meet any obligation that arises from the offbalance-sheet transaction. Given that off-balance-sheet

In evaluating its capital position, a bank
must consider both the static costs associated with any given capital ratio and the
dynamic costs associated with adjusting it.

items are not covered de jure by deposit insurance,
bank customers have an incentive to price their offbalance-sheet transactions in a way that reflects the
risk that the bank’s capital will ultimately be inadequate. G.D. Koppenhaver and Roger D. Stover (1991)
found that capital and stand-by letters of credit are
jointly determined, with higher levels of the former associated with higher levels of the latter. This result is
consistent with the hypotheses that banks offset higher
regulatory capital requirements by taking more risk
and that off-balance-sheet customers demand higher
capital ratios.
Recognizing Changes in the Market Value of Assets. At any given time, a bank is likely to have some
assets that have appreciated in value from their original acquisition cost and others that have declined in
value. Yet generally accepted accounting principles
(GAAP) and regulatory accounting generally record
assets at historic cost rather than at their current market value. Thus, regulatory capital may differ substantially from the economic capital available to support
8

Economic Review

the long-run viability of a bank and reduce losses
should it fail. A bank can boost its regulatory capital
by accelerating the recognition of gains or losses for
assets by selling them, achieving the effect of marking
these assets to market. Further, banks have some discretion in the timing of setting aside reserves for bad
loans. Thus, a seemingly low-cost way for a banking
organization to maintain or increase its regulatory capital ratios is to avoid recognizing losses on depreciated
assets and accelerate recognition of gains on assets
that have appreciated in value.17
Myron B. Slovin, Marie E. Sushka, and John
A. Polonchek (1991) recognized the potential for increasing regulatory capital through banks’ sale-andleaseback transactions (for example, selling their
headquarters building to outside investors and simultaneously leasing back the building) and divestitures.
They argued, however, that these transactions may also send a negative signal to the financial markets about
the value of existing assets and the bank’s future earnings prospect. Banks with favorable information about
their future prospects can, at least within certain
ranges of regulatory capital ratios, signal their good
news by not selling assets but rather waiting for future
earnings to boost their capital. Banks with unfavorable
information may find the do-nothing strategy too costly and be forced to engage in these transactions or take
other action to boost capital. Slovin, Sushka, and
Polonchek (1991) studied sale-and-leaseback transactions and divestitures for banking organizations during
the period from 1974 to 1988. Prior studies of nonbank
sale-and-leasebacks and divestitures had reported significantly positive abnormal returns to the sellers. In
contrast, Slovin, Sushka, and Polonchek found significant negative prediction errors for sale-and-leasebacks
and insignificantly positive prediction errors for divestitures. These results support their hypothesis that
asset sales represent unfavorable information to investors.
In terms of recognizing losses, evidence suggests
that banks manage their loan-loss allowance (reserves). If loan-loss reserves depend solely on expected future losses and they summarize all available
information, then they alone should be sufficient to
predict future loan charge-offs (the writing off of specific loans). Berger, Kathleen Kuester King, and
James M. O’Brien (1991) showed, however, that in
predicting the current value of charge-offs the information about lagged nonperforming loans adds significantly to that obtained from the loan-loss allowance.
Mary Brady Greenawalt and Joseph F. Sinkey Jr.
(1988) showed that loan-loss provisions are used for
March/April 1996

income smoothing but did not look at their use for
managing capital levels.
One potentially instructive case of banks deferring
recognition of reductions in asset values involves
banks’ loans to Latin America. During the early and
mid-1980s a number of large banks experienced a significant reduction in the value of their Latin American
loan portfolios, but many of the largest banks did not
fully recognize these losses until the late 1980s. Several studies examined the response of bank stock returns
to various announcements related to their Latin American loan portfolios. Although securities markets
quickly incorporated the implications of various moratoriums and reschedulings into stock returns, the
banks took longer to recognize the reduction in values
on their GAAP accounting statements.18 Thus, the purpose of the delay was unlikely to have been an attempt
to hide the losses from securities markets. Slovin and
Subbarao V. Jayanti (1993) provided evidence consistent with concern about capital exposure. They examined banks’ excess stock returns around the times of
the Mexican debt moratorium (August 19, 1982) and
the Bolivian debt moratorium (May 31, 1984). The set
of banks with exposure to each of these countries is
broken into two groups: (1) those with adequate regulatory capital ratios and (2) those with inadequate capital ratios. Slovin and Jayanti found that banks with
inadequate capital suffered significantly more adverse
stock return reactions than did banks with adequate
capital. Although loan-loss reserves were formally
counted as a part of regulatory capital at this time,
Slovin and Jayanti interpreted this fact as suggesting
that the market believed that banks with inadequate
capital would need to issue new capital, cut dividends,
or reduce their asset base. James J. Musumeci and
Sinkey (1990) reached a similar conclusion for the announcement of the Brazilian experience (February 20,
1987) using market value (but not book value) capital
ratios.
Analyzing the recognition of changes in securities
values may be especially interesting because securities
may have either gains or losses and trade in relatively
liquid markets.19 Myron S. Scholes, G. Peter Wilson,
and Mark A. Wolfson (1990) examined the recognition of securities gains and losses by a sample of mostly very large banks that are on Bank Compustat data
tapes. They found evidence that banks with lower capital ratios are likely to have smaller recognized losses
or larger recognized gains than banks with higher capital ratios. Mark Carey (1994) examined more than
6,000 commercial banks’ sales of securities from their
investment portfolios, or gains trading. He found that
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

most gains trading is done to boost current earnings or
to smooth earnings. Relatively few banks appear to engage in gains trading to boost their capital account, and
the magnitude of such trading appears to be small.
Carey also found little evidence that gains trading increases bank risk. Perhaps one important reason that
gains trading is not done to boost capital is revealed in
Carey (1992). He found that gains trading does not improve examiners’ evaluations of a bank. Indeed, gains
trading tends to reduce a bank’s CAMEL rating (see
note 14). Carey found that gains trading does not have
a favorable effect on the firm’s stock price. He suggested that gains trading may be motivated by managerial
compensation contracts that emphasize accounting
earnings, and he provided some weak evidence to support this hypothesis.
Summary of Cosmetic Changes. One type of cosmetic change that banks may make to their regulatory
capital ratios is to increase their capital but at the same
time increase their risk. Whether the increase in risk
will more than offset the rise in capital and increase
their probability of failure is unclear. The empirical
evidence provides some indication that increases in
capital are partially offset by greater risk-taking. However, none of the empirical studies indicate that higher
regulatory capital requirements actually increase
banks’ risk of failure or the likely losses to depositors
and deposit insurers in the event a bank failed. One
potentially useful area for empirical work is to test the
hypothesis in Calem and Rob (1996) that a bank’s response to higher capital requirements may depend in
part on their initial capital ratios.
Another type of cosmetic change involves raising
regulatory capital levels in ways that do not increase
the market value of capital. Examples of such actions
include accelerated recognition of gains (but not losses) via sale-and-leaseback transactions, gains trading
with securities, and deferring recognition of loan losses. These actions may sometimes circumvent the regulators. However, some empirical evidence suggests
that the market can see through these accounting gimmicks, interpreting them as signs of likely weakness in
future earnings and accordingly reducing the stock
price of the bank.
Regulators cannot prevent all cosmetic changes to
capital ratios, but they should be able to adjust regulatory requirements to offset banks from gaining material
improvements through cosmetic changes. In principal,
regulators could eliminate all cosmetic changes to equity by requiring mark-to-market accounting. However,
Berger, King, and O’Brien (1991) pointed out that
market value is an ambiguous concept and some of the
Economic Review

9

more relevant definitions of market value are not subject to perfect measurement. Nevertheless, they noted
substantial opportunities for regulators to adjust for
cosmetic changes to capital. Similarly, regulators
could, in principal, eliminate all incentives for banks
to increase their risk exposure by evaluating the riskiness of each bank’s total portfolio. Such measures do
not exist, however, and may not be attainable as long
as management has private information about the riskiness of its assets. However, regulators can identify
many of the strategies a bank can follow to increase its
risk, and their ability to identify material increases
should be enhanced by focusing more on banks’ risk
management procedures. Moreover, once regulators
identify cosmetic changes to capital ratios, they can, at
least in the United States, impose higher capital requirements to offset the cosmetic changes.

Effective Increases in the
Capital Cushion
A bank may provide an effective increase in its capital cushion when that is the cheapest alternative or
when regulators give the bank no choice. The increase
may stem from reducing the bank’s risk exposure or
increasing its capital levels.
Wayne Passmore and Steven A. Sharpe (1994) analyzed banks’ response to inadequate regulatory capital
levels in a model in which banks cannot avoid the regulations by making cosmetic changes to capital ratios.
Their analysis suggested that the reason a bank is undercapitalized influences the bank’s response and that
the time horizon under consideration is also important
in some cases. Loan levels decline in the short run (before equity capital levels can adjust) in response to a
variety of causes of undercapitalization, including an
increase in the risk weighting on loans, an increase in
the leverage requirement, or an exogenous capital
shock. However, some of these causes may spur a
short-term rise in securities holdings. The most striking short-run versus long-run difference relates to exogenous capital shocks, which in the long run has no
effect on the size or distribution of a bank’s portfolio.
Passmore and Sharpe also analyzed one other important case, that of a decline in loan demand. Ordinarily a decline in loan demand would be considered a
drop in the quantity of loans demanded at the going
contract rate of interest on loans. From the bank’s perspective, however, another equally valid interpretation
is that the quantity of loans demanded at the going
10

Economic Review

contract rate is unchanged but that the bank’s expected
rate of return at the going contract rate has dropped
because the bank anticipates a higher default rate. The
second interpretation is especially relevant when considering the impact of sudden declines in the capital
level given that the declines are often caused by an increase in default rates on outstanding loans. A decrease in loan demand by itself causes a short- and
long-run decrease in loans, a short-run increase in securities, but no long-run change in securities holdings.
Reducing Risk Exposure. Banks may reduce their
actual risk exposure in a variety of ways, including reducing the volume of risky financial activities and investing in financial instruments with low or negative
correlations with their existing portfolio (that is, engaging in diversification or hedging). In order to improve their regulatory capital ratios, however, banks
must reduce their volume of risky financial activities.
Risk reduction through greater diversification and
hedging is not explicitly incorporated into the capital
standards.
The literature on risk reduction to enhance regulatory capital ratios focuses on banks’ reducing the size
of their asset portfolios, especially their lending portfolios. Banks may reduce their portfolios either directly by selling off existing loans with other financial
intermediaries or indirectly by first converting loans
into securities (a process called securitization). Alternatively, banks may shrink their portfolios by refusing
to make new loans that have a positive net present value and allowing loan repayments to shrink the portfolios. From a social perspective, it is likely that some
type of loan sale is preferable to banks’ refusing to
make positive net present value loans.
Loan Sales. Loan sales have the potential for improving banks’ regulatory capital ratios.20 Potential
loan buyers must worry, however, that the selling bank
will sell loans that are of lower quality than the buyer
expects and will not adequately monitor the loan after
it has been sold. One way of alleviating buyers’ concerns is for the seller to retain the risk exposure via a
recourse agreement or by having the seller retain a junior claim on a fraction of the loan. The regulatory
capital requirements are structured, however, so that a
selling bank’s capital requirement is not reduced to the
extent that the sale of a loan does not reflect a reduction in the seller’s credit exposure. For example, if a
bank sells 80 percent of a loan but retains 99 percent
of the credit risk then the bank will get little or no reduction in its capital requirement.
Gary B. Gorton and George G. Pennacchi (1995)
suggested that the incentive for sellers to cheat loan
March/April 1996

buyers may be reduced if the seller retains a fractional
interest in the loan and desires to maintain a good reputation so that it can engage in future loan sales. Sellers will face reduced capital requirements if the credit
risk that is transferred is proportionate to the amount
of the loan; for example, if a bank sells 80 percent of a
loan with the buyer assuming 80 percent of each dollar
of credit losses, then the selling bank need only include the remaining 20 percent of the loan amount in
its regulatory capital ratio calculations.
Most of the theoretical analysis of the implications
of capital requirements for loan sales focuses on the
choice of retaining or selling newly originated loans.
Charles T. Carlstrom and Katherine A. Samolyk (1995)
suggested that bankers will sell loans even if they cannot precommit to good behavior if the gains from selling are large enough. Kathleene K. Donahoo and
Sherrill Shaffer (1991) showed that small changes in
capital requirements will not cause banks to start loan
sales programs but may increase the volume in existing programs. Large increases may cause banks to enter the market as loan sellers. Flannery (1989) argued
that the type of loan sold may depend in part on how
regulators treat it. His particular focus was the effect
of the supervisory evaluation of loan quality on the incentive to make and retain certain types of loans.
However, he noted that his argument also applies to
banks’ choice of which loans to sell.
Empirical evidence from Christine Pavel and David
Philis (1987) suggested that banks subject to binding
capital regulation are more likely to sell loans. Katerina Simons (1993) documented the effectiveness of alternative mechanisms in preventing sellers from taking
advantage of buyers. She found that the proportion of
the loans retained increases monotonically as the ex
post quality of the loan declines.
Reducing the Amount of New Loans. Most analyses
of reductions in bank lending have focused on the period in the late 1980s and early 1990s that is sometimes called the credit crunch. A major issue in the
credit crunch literature is whether binding capital constraints (induced by higher standards or weakened
capital bases) resulted in a reduction in bank lending,
especially to customers with limited nonbank alternatives. Early analysis identified, and in some cases
tested, a variety of possible explanations for the decline in lending, including a reduction in loan supply
due to (1) adverse shocks to capital combined with
binding regulatory requirements, (2) adverse shocks
to capital combined with market pressure for higher
capital, (3) an increase in regulatory capital requirements, and (4) less favorable treatment of loans for
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

the purpose of calculating regulatory capital requirements. Other explanations for the lending declines
might be reductions in loan demand due to (1) a perceived decrease in expected loan repayments, (2) a
weaker economy, (3) a secular decline in bank’s market share, and (4) banks’ higher capital levels.21
Determining which of the above factors contributed
to the credit decline is impossible a priori because all
of them can be supported by changes in the economic
environment in the early 1990s. One complication for
empirical analysis is that the explanations are not mutually exclusive, so the real question is not which explanations are true but rather what were their relative
contributions to the decline. Recent empirical work
has focused on multivariate, cross-sectional studies to
sort through the various explanations to the extent permitted by the data. Several studies document the
shocks to capital in the early 1990s. For example, Diana Hancock, Andrew J. Laing, and James A. Wilcox
(1995) showed that the capital shocks for their sample
of large banks were twice as large in the early 1990s.
Studies by Shrieves and Dahl (1995) and Hancock,
Laing, and Wilcox (1995) found that bank portfolios
were more sensitive to these shocks in the early 1990s
than in the late 1980s . Thus, capital shocks appear to
have played at least a partial role in the decline in
lending.
While loan losses appear to have contributed to the
decline in lending, the impact of the shocks may have
been increased if banks’ target capital levels rose because of regulatory or market pressure. One source of
possibly increased regulatory pressure was the imposition of risk-based capital guidelines in the late 1980s
in addition to a leverage (capital to total assets) standard. The risk-based capital standards focused on
credit risk, imposing full capital charges on most types
of lending to private firms and individuals but smaller
charges (in some cases no charge) for many types of
securities. Thus, these standards could have caused
banks to reallocate their portfolios from loans to securities. While the imposition of risk-based capital guidelines could provide a partial explanation, empirical
analysis by Berger and Udell (1991) found little support for a drop in lending related to risk-based capital.
While the imposition of risk-based capital standards
does not appear to be an important factor, an increase
in market or regulatory leverage targets appears to have
occurred in the early 1990s. Shrieves and Dahl (1995)
calculated mean target capital ratios for banks using
(1) parameters estimated using 1985-89 data and mean
values of the explanatory variables in 1990 to 1991
and (2) parameters and mean values of explanatory
Economic Review

11

variables from 1990 to 1991. They found that the capital targets were higher using the parameters estimated
from the 1990-91 data. Thus, the evidence suggests
that in 1990-91 banks had higher capital targets and
their loans adjusted more rapidly to capital shocks (including any reduction in lending demand).
However, Steven A. Sharpe’s (1995) critical review
raised a number of questions about what conclusions
may be drawn from this literature. One especially important issue he pointed to is that the capital shocks resulted from loan losses, and these loan losses in turn
may signal a decline in the profitability of lending.
Thus, Sharpe found it difficult to develop an unambiguous interpretation of the credit crunch papers he
surveyed. Consistent with this critique, one could ask,

Because banks may respond to binding
regulations in a variety of ways, regulators
need to consider what response they want
to elicit when formulating new regulations.

If the problem was due solely to capital constraints,
why did the banks not use the loan sales market to
fund the loans?
If regulatory capital requirements played an important role in the credit crunch, then an important question is whether the changes in capital targets were due
to changes in regulatory or market pressure, an issue
that is outside the scope of the above credit crunch papers. Evidence that regulatory pressure was the dominant factor for at least some banks comes from Joe
Peek and Eric S. Rosengren (1995), who focused on
lending by banks in New England that were subject to
a formal regulatory mandate to improve their capital
ratios. Their findings suggest that banks subject to formal orders sought to increase their capital ratios by reducing their loan portfolio significantly faster than
banks that were not under a formal order, even after allowing for differences in capital ratios. Two types of
additional evidence come from Wall and D. Peterson
(1995). First, as previously noted, they found that most
banks in their sample had a high probability of coming
12

Economic Review

from the regulatory regime. Further, they found evidence, consistent with Peek and Rosengren’s, that
banks subject to a formal regulatory order to improve
their capital adjusted toward their capital targets at a
faster rate than did banks not subject to an order.
Increasing Capital Levels. The other way that
banks may effectively increase their capital cushion is
by increasing their regulatory capital. Banks can do so
by increasing their retained earnings or issuing new
securities. An efficiently run bank is already maximizing its profits given its risk level, so the only way it
can increase its retained earnings is by taking more
risk (which would initially decrease its effective capital cushion) or reducing its dividends. The types of securities a bank can issue to satisfy its regulatory capital
requirements have varied over time. The capital standards have given full weight to common and preferred
stock issues, including them in their most limited definitions of capital (core capital). The 1981 standards also counted a type of debt security called mandatory
convertible debt (debt that had to be refunded with
common or preferred stock) as an element of core capital (called primary capital). More recent standards
consider mandatory convertible debt an element of total capital (tier one plus tier two capital), not as an equity issue in core capital. Subordinated debt has been
included as an element of total capital but not as an element of core capital in the various post-1981 standards.
An understanding of banks’ decision to increase regulatory capital comes from two types of studies: (1) those
that examine banks’ decision to increase their capital
and (2) those that focus on stock market reactions to
banks’ announcements of plans to issue new capital.
Connecting the results of these two types of studies is
difficult because the studies of decisions to issue new
capital focus on banks whereas the stock market reaction studies focus primarily on bank holding companies. Banks that issue capital directly to the market are
generally too small to have widely traded stock issues.
In contrast, larger banks typically issue capital to their
bank holding company parent, which may or may not
have issued a capital instrument to fund the purchase.
Dahl and Shrieves (1990) analyzed 753 equity capital issues occurring during 1986 and 1987. They divided their sample along two dimensions: (1) adequately
capitalized (a total capital ratio greater than 7 percent)
versus undercapitalized banks (a ratio below 7 percent) and (2) independent banks versus banks affiliated with one-bank holding companies versus banks
affiliated with multibank holding companies. The
sample of holding company banks was subdivided beMarch/April 1996

cause independent banks issue securities to the market
whereas affiliated banks often issue securities to their
parents as noted above, and holding company banks
may be managed as part of an integrated unit rather
than as stand-alone entities. Not surprisingly, Dahl and
Shrieves found that, by regulatory standards, undercapitalized banks are more likely than adequately capitalized banks to issue capital. Further, to gauge the
importance of regulatory pressure they calculated, using an equation estimated with only adequately capitalized banks, the probability that an undercapitalized
bank will issue capital. They found that undercapitalized banks issue equity more often than would be predicted for similar yet adequately capitalized banks.
Dahl and Michael F. Spivey (1995) examined banks
during the 1981-88 period that were undercapitalized
according to standards used to implement the prompt
corrective action provisions of FDICIA. Their goal
was to determine which actions were most likely to result in the bank reaching an adequate capital level by
the end of 1989. The study found that less than onequarter of undercapitalized banks, pre-FDICIA, paid
dividends and that dividend payments were not statistically significantly related to the probability of recovery. In contrast, a bank’s survival was significantly
related to capital injections into the bank, a decision
that is under the control of the firm’s managers. As
Dahl and Spivey pointed out, owners are unlikely to
inject capital into banks that will probably be closed
by the regulators. Dahl and Spivey’s results also suggest that expense control (salary and occupancy expense and interest expense) is significantly related to
whether, but not how quickly, a bank becomes adequately capitalized.
Analyzing stock market reactions to bank capital issuance decisions may provide more insight into the
private costs of raising new capital. Wall and Pamela
P. Peterson (1991) reviewed bank holding companies’
decisions to issue several types of new securities between 1982 and 1986. They found significantly negative abnormal returns for common stock but not for
preferred stock, convertible debt, mandatory convertible debt, and subordinated debt. They found that the
common stock returns were significantly lower than
those for mandatory convertible debt (at the 5 percent
level) and preferred stock (at the 10 percent level). After further analysis of the characteristics of the issuing
firms and the abnormal returns, Wall and Peterson
concluded that their results are best explained by a
Myers and Majluf-type (1984) model.
The hypothesis that common stock issues may signal adverse private information is supported by Slovin,
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

Sushka, and Polonchek (1992), who analyzed the effect of the issuance announcement on the stock returns
of the issuing bank holding companies’ competitors.
The researchers focused on the issuance decision by
money center banks in the United States during the period from 1975 to 1988 and analyzed three groups of
competitors: other money center banking organizations, a sample of regional banking organizations, and
a sample of investment banking firms. They found that
all three groups of competitors showed significantly
negative abnormal returns in the wake of the securities
issuance announcement. In contrast, similar analysis
of the stock returns of the competitors of industrial
firms revealed no significant market response on the
part of the competitors. These results suggest that the
decision to issue common stock may have signaled the
market that it overvalued the assets of large financial
firms.
Marcia Million Cornett and Hassan Tehranian
(1994) suggested another way to look for evidence
that bank holding companies’ common stock issues
signal adverse information. They compared the abnormal stock returns of issuing bank holding companies
that have capital ratios below regulatory requirements
with those of issuing bank holding companies that
have adequate regulatory capital ratios. Bank holding
companies with capital ratios above the regulatory requirements are likely to be voluntary issuers that could
avoid issuing new capital if their managers thought
their stock was undervalued. In contrast, bank holding
companies with capital levels below the regulatory requirements may have been involuntary issuers of capital in the sense that the regulatory costs of not issuing
new capital would exceed any losses from issuing
stock that management believed was undervalued.
Cornett and Tehranian’s results support the hypothesis
that voluntary common stock issues had significantly
lower abnormal returns than did involuntary issues.
The abnormal returns associated with other types of
capital issues are insignificant for both the voluntary
and involuntary samples.
Summary of Effective Increases in the Capital
Cushion. Banks can increase their regulatory capital
ratios and their true capital cushions by shrinking their
loan portfolio. One way to shrink the portfolio is to
sell loans to other financial intermediaries. A possible
problem with such sales is that the buyers will discount the loans to reflect the possibility that the seller
may be trying to unload its weaker loans. To offset this
concern, banks selling loans tend to sell more of their
higher-quality loans. Another way of shrinking the
portfolio is to refuse to make good new loans while
Economic Review

13

accepting repayment on outstanding loans. The extent
to which this practice has occurred is difficult to measure, however, because banks that have had adverse
shocks to their capital may also be in markets with few
good lending opportunities. Banks may also increase
their regulatory capital ratios by issuing new capital
instruments.
One theme that arises in both the discussion of cosmetic changes and the discussion of new capital instruments is that of the stock market’s reaction to
different ways of meeting the capital regulations. The
market rewards banks that can meet capital requirements through profits from ordinary operations without relying on cosmetic accounting changes. On the
other hand, banks that must resort to accounting gimmicks or new capital issues are viewed as signaling
weak future profitability, and their stock prices drop to
reflect that adverse signal.

Conclusion
Bank capital ratios have become a primary measure
of banks’ financial condition as a result of international efforts to achieve a degree of harmony in bank supervisory rules across countries and the inclusion of
prompt corrective action in FDICIA. If this focus on
bank capital is to continue, then a better understanding
of banks’ responses to binding capital regulation
would be valuable.

One question about which little is said in this article
is, What determines banks’ choices from the menu of
alternatives when they are confronted with binding
regulation? Given that banks are likely to choose the
option that has the lowest long-run costs, a better way
of stating the question is, What determines the relative
magnitudes of cost associated with each of the alternatives? More research on this topic would be desirable.
Because banks may respond to binding regulations
in a variety of ways, regulators need to consider what
response they want to elicit when formulating new
regulations. Presumably the regulations are being imposed to reduce the risk of a systemic problem and the
expected losses of the deposit insurance agency. If so,
then regulations that encourage cosmetic responses
are, by definition, unlikely to accomplish regulatory
goals. Whether regulators should care whether banks
meet the regulations by reducing the volume of their
risky activities or by increasing their capital is less obvious. On the one hand, one could easily imagine circumstances under which a reduction in bank lending
would be considered undesirable in the short run.
However, pressing banks to undertake the alternative
of increasing capital might be even more costly in the
long run. A third alternative, which is not feasible under the current guidelines, would be to allow banks to
reduce risk exposure by increased diversification or
hedging. This option could prove to be the least costly
to banks and society in many instances.

Notes
1. For a long-term perspective on bank capital levels, see
Kaufman (1992).
2. For a broader discussion of capital regulation see Berger,
Herring, and Szegö (1995).
3. For a survey of systemic risk issues both prior to and after
the passage of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
Improvement Act of 1991, see Wall (1993).
4. Marcus (1983) argued that regulators were successful in
preventing any one bank from reducing its capital ratios
substantially below the industry average yet were unable to
prevent the industry as a whole from ratcheting their capital
ratios downward.
5. For a review of the 1981 capital standards, see Wall (1989).
6. For a discussion of the 1988 risk-based standards, see Wall
(1989).
7. See Wall (1993) for a discussion of the act.
8. Selling an asset that has appreciated in value may reduce
the economic capital of a bank by accelerating the tax the
bank pays on its earnings from the asset.
14

Economic Review

9. See Miller (1995) for a discussion of the relevance of
Modigliani and Miller’s propositions to banking.
10. For example, see Modigliani and Miller (1963), DeAngelo
and Masulis (1980), and Masulis and Trueman (1988) on
income taxes and Baxter (1967) and Kraus and Litzenberger
(1973) on bankruptcy costs.
11. Diseconomies of scale exist if an increase in volume results
in an increase in average unit costs. Dead-weight losses of
bankruptcy are costs that arise solely because of the
bankruptcy and provide no social value. An example of a
dead-weight cost would be the legal costs arising from a
bank’s failure.
12. See Jensen and Meckling (1976), Barnea, Haugen, and Senbet (1981), and Jensen (1986) for a discussion of agency
costs in more general settings.
13. However, even with the setting of numeric targets, the regulatory requirements were not perfectly transparent because
supervisors could set higher requirements on a case-by-case
basis.
March/April 1996

14. Cargill (1989, 357) analyzed the contribution of CAMEL
ratings in explaining bank certificate of deposit (CD) rates.
(CAMEL [capital, assets, management, earnings, and liquidity] ratings are an index used by examiners to summarize
their evaluation of a commercial bank.) He concluded that
“confidential CAMEL ratings assigned to banks on the basis of on-site examination are largely proxies for market information.” However, CD rates cannot be used to determine
whether CAMEL ratings reflect the results of confidential,
on-site examinations because by definition this information
would not be known to the market. All that can be said is
that CAMEL ratings do not contain publicly available information that is not already incorporated in Cargill’s other explanatory variables.
15. Bank holding companies and banks are treated separately
because some of the factors influencing the two capital ratios may be different. For example, a bank holding company’s consolidated capital ratio is likely to influence the
firm’s tax liability, whereas a subsidiary bank’s capital ratio
may not influence the bank holding company’s overall tax
liability. For example, a bank holding company may issue
debt and pass it along to a subsidiary bank as equity or issue
equity and pass it along as debt.
16. Management may not choose riskier portfolios even if they
increase shareholder wealth if managers and shareholders
have divergent interests. Noe, Rebello, and Wall (1996)
showed how a combination of regulatory policies for bank

closure and management compensation may be used to discourage management from following higher risk strategies,
even when these strategies are optimal for shareholders.
17. Studies of troubled nonbank firms suggest that managers
may make judicious choice of accounting treatments either
to avoid violations of debt covenants or to win concessions
from unions or the government. Several studies indicate that
the closer a firm is to violating its debt covenant restriction,
the more likely that the firm’s management will select income-increasing accounting choices (Christie 1990, DeFond and Jiambalvo 1994, Skinner 1993, and Sweeney
1994). There is some evidence that firms in financial difficulty may make income-decreasing choices if the lower income increases the likelihood of winning concessions from
unions or the government (DeAngelo, DeAngelo, and Skinner 1994).
18. For example, see Smirlock and Kaufold (1987), Bruner and
Simms (1987), and Mansur, Cochran, and Seagers (1990).
19. A recent decision (FAS 115) by the Financial Accounting
Standards Board effectively requires banks to mark most of
their securities portfolio to market for the purposes of determining their capital as measured by generally accepted accounting principles.
20. See Berger and Udell (1991) for a more extensive review of
the securitization literature.
21. For a review of many of the issues associated with the credit
crunch see Federal Reserve Bank of New York (1994).

References
Alfriend, Malcolm C. “International Risk-based Capital Standard: History and Explanation.” Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond Economic Review (November/December 1988):
28-34.
Avery, Robert B., and Allen N. Berger. “Risk-based Capital
and Deposit Insurance Reform.” Journal of Banking and Finance 15 (September 1991): 847-74.
Barnea, Amir, Robert A. Haugen, and Lemma W. Senbet.
“Market Imperfections, Agency Problems, and Capital
Structure.” Financial Management 10 (Summer 1981):
7-22.
Baxter, Nevins. “Leverage, Risk of Ruin, and the Cost of Capital.” Journal of Finance 22 (September 1967): 395-403.
Berger, Allen N., Richard J. Herring, and Giorgio P. Szegö.
“The Role of Capital in Financial Institutions.” Journal of
Banking and Finance 19 (June 1995): 393-430.
Berger, Allen N., Kathleen Kuester King, and James M.
O’Brien. “The Limitations of Market Value Accounting and
a More Realistic Alternative.” Journal of Banking and Finance 15 (September 1991): 753-83.
Berger, Allen N., and Gregory F. Udell. “Securitization, Risk,
and the Liquidity Problem in Banking.” Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System, Finance and Economics Discussion Series, no. 181, 1991.
Bruner, Robert F., and John M. Simms Jr. “The International
Debt Crisis and Bank Security Returns in 1982.” Journal of
Money, Credit, and Banking 19 (February 1987): 46-55.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

Calem, Paul S., and Rafael Rob. “The Impact of Capital-based
Regulation on Bank Risk-taking: a Dynamic Model.” Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Finance and
Economics Discussion Series, 96-12, 1996.
Carey, Mark. “Why Do Banks Gains-Trade?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, unpublished paper,
1992.
——. “Snacking and Smoothing: Gains Trading of Investment
Account Securities by Commercial Banks.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, unpublished paper,
1994.
Cargill, Thomas F. “Ratings and the CD Market.” Journal of
Financial Services Research 3 (December 1989): 347-58.
Carlstrom, Charles T., and Katherine A. Samolyk. “Loan Sales
as a Response to Market-based Capital Constraints.” Journal of Banking and Finance 19 (June 1995): 627-46.
Christie, Andrew A. “Aggregation of Test Statistics: An Evaluation of the Evidence on Contracting and Size Hypotheses.”
Journal of Accounting and Economics 12 (1990): 15-16.
Cornett, Marcia Million, and Hassan Tehranian. “An Examination of Voluntary versus Involuntary Security Issuances by
Commercial Banks: The Impact of Capital Regulations on
Common Stock Returns.” Journal of Financial Economics
35 (February 1994): 99-122.
Dahl, Drew, and Ronald E. Shrieves. “The Impact of Regulation on Bank Equity Infusions.” Journal of Banking and Finance 14 (December 1990): 1209-28.

Economic Review

15

Dahl, Drew, and Michael F. Spivey. “Prompt Corrective Action
and Bank Efforts to Recover from Undercapitalization.”
Journal of Banking and Finance 19 (May 1995): 225-43.
DeAngelo, Harry, Linda DeAngelo, and Douglas J. Skinner.
“Accounting Choice in Troubled Companies.” Journal of
Accounting and Economics 17 (1994): 113-43.
DeAngelo, Harry, and Ronald W. Masulis. “Leverage and Dividend Irrelevancy under Corporate and Personal Taxation.”
Journal of Finance 35 (May 1980): 453-64.
DeFond, Mark L., and James Jiambalvo. “Debt Covenant Violation and Manipulation of Accruals.” Journal of Accounting and Economics 17 (1994): 145-76.
Donahoo, Kathleene K., and Sherrill Shaffer. “Capital Requirements and the Securitization Decision.” Quarterly Review of
Economics and Business 31 (Winter 1991): 12-23.
Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Studies on Causes and
Consequences of the 1989-92 Credit Slowdown. 1994.
Flannery, Mark J. “Capital Regulation and Insured Banks’
Choice of Individual Loan Default Risks.” Journal of Monetary Economics 24 (September 1989): 235-58.
——. “Debt Maturity and the Deadweight Cost of Leverage:
Optimally Financing Banking Firms.” American Economic
Review 84 (March 1994): 320-31.
Flannery, Mark J., and Sorin M. Sorescu. “Evidence of Bank
Market Discipline in Subordinated Debenture Yields: 19831991.” Journal of Finance 51 (September 1996): 1347-77.
Furlong, Frederick T., and Michael C. Keeley. “Capital Regulation and Bank Risk-taking: A Note.” Journal of Banking
and Finance 13 (December 1989): 883-91.
Gennotte, Gerard, and David Pyle. “Capital Controls and Bank
Risk.” Journal of Banking and Finance 15 (September
1991): 805-24.
Gilbert, R. Alton, Courtenay C. Stone, and Michael E. Trebing.
“The New Bank Capital Adequacy Standards.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Review 67 (May 1985):
12-35.
Gorton, Gary B., and George G. Pennacchi. “Banks and Loan
Sales: Marketing Nonmarketable Assets.” Journal of Monetary Economics 35 (August 1995): 389-411.
Greenawalt, Mary Brady, and Joseph F. Sinkey Jr. “Bank
Loan-Loss Provisions and the Income-smoothing Hypothesis: An Empirical Analysis, 1976-1984.” Journal of Financial Services Research 1 (December 1988): 303-18.
Hancock, Diana, Andrew J. Laing, and James A. Wilcox.
“Bank Capital Shocks: Dynamic Effects on Securities,
Loans, and Capital.” Journal of Banking and Finance 19
(June 1995): 661-77.
Hughes, Joseph P., and Loretta J. Mester. “Bank Capitalization
and Cost: Evidence of Scale Economies in Risk Management and Signaling.” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Working Paper 96-2, 1996.
Jagtiani, Julapa, Anthony Saunders, and Gregory Udell. “The
Effect of Bank Capital Requirements on Bank Off-BalanceSheet Financial Innovations.” Journal of Banking and Finance 19 (June 1995): 647-58.
Jensen, Michael C. “Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers.” American Economic Review
76 (May 1986): 323-29.

16

Economic Review

Jensen, Michael C., and William H. Meckling. “Theory of the
Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Ownership
Structure.” Journal of Financial Economics 3 (October
1976): 305-60.
Kahane, Yehuda. “Capital Adequacy and the Regulation of Financial Intermediaries.” Journal of Banking and Finance 1
(1977): 207-18.
Kaufman, George G. “Capital in Banking: Past, Present, and
Future.” Journal of Financial Services Research 5 (April
1992): 385-402.
Keeley, Michael C. “Bank Capital Regulation in the 1980s: Effective or Ineffective?” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Review 1 (Winter 1988): 3-20.
Keeley, Michael C., and Frederick T. Furlong. “A Reexamination of Mean-Variance Analysis of Bank Capital Regulation.”
Journal of Banking and Finance 14 (March 1990): 69-84.
Keeton, William R. “The New Risk-based Capital Plan for
Commercial Banks.” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City
Economic Review 74 (December 1989): 40-60.
Kendall, Sarah B. “Bank Regulation under Nonbinding Capital
Guidelines.” Journal of Financial Services Research 5
(February 1991): 275-86.
Kim, Daesik, and Anthony M. Santomero. “Risk in Banking
and Capital Regulation.” Journal of Finance 43 (December
1988): 1219-33.
Kimball, Dietrich J., and Christopher James. “Regulation and
the Determination of Bank Capital Changes: A Note.” Journal of Finance 38 (December 1983): 1651-58.
Koehn, Michael, and Anthony M. Santomero. “Regulation of
Bank Capital and Portfolio Risk.” Journal of Finance 35
(December 1980): 1235-44.
Koppenhaver, G.D., and Roger D. Stover. “Standby Letters of
Credit and Large Bank Capital: An Empirical Analysis.”
Journal of Banking and Finance 15 (April 1991): 315-27.
Kraus, Alan, and Robert Litzenberger. “A State-Preference
Model of Optimal Financial Leverage.” Journal of Finance
28 (September 1973): 911-22.
Levonian, Mark E. “Have Large Banks Become Riskier? Recent Evidence from Option Markets.” Federal Reserve Bank
of San Francisco Economic Review (Fall 1991): 3-17.
Mansur, Iqbal, Steven J. Cochran, and David K. Seagers. “The
Relationship between the Argentinean Debt Rescheduling
Announcement and Bank Equity Returns.” Financial Review 25 (May 1990): 321-34.
Marcus, Alan J. “The Bank Capital Decision: A Time SeriesCross Analysis.” Journal of Finance 38 (September 1983):
1217-32.
Masulis, Ronald. W., and Brett Trueman. “Corporate Investment and Dividend Decisions under Differential Personal
Taxation.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis
23 (December 1988): 369-83.
Miller, Merton H. “Do the M&M Propositions Apply to Banks?”
Journal of Banking and Finance 19 (June 1995): 483-89.
Mingo, John J. “Regulatory Influence on Bank Capital Investment.” Journal of Finance 30 (September 1975): 1111-21.
Modigliani, Franco, and Merton H. Miller. “The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance, and the Theory of Investment.”
American Economic Review 48 (June 1958): 261-97.

March/April 1996

——. “Corporate Income Taxes and the Cost of Capital.”
American Economic Review 53 (June 1963): 433-43.
Musumeci, James J., and Joseph F. Sinkey Jr. “The International Debt Crisis, Investor Contagion, and Bank Security
Returns in 1987: The Brazilian Experience.” Journal of
Money, Credit, and Banking 22 (May 1990): 209-20.
Myers, Stewart C., and Nicholas S. Majluf. “Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions When Firms Have Information That Investors Do Not Have.” Journal of Financial
Economics 13 (June 1984): 187-221.
Noe, Thomas H., Michael J. Rebello, and Larry D. Wall. “Managerial Rents and Regulatory Intervention in Troubled
Banks.” Journal of Banking and Finance 20 (March 1996):
331-50.
Orgler, Yair E., and Robert A. Taggart Jr. “Implications of Corporate Capital Structure Theory for Banking Institutions.”
Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 15 (May 1983):
212-21.
Passmore, Wayne, and Steven A. Sharpe. “Optimal Bank Portfolios and the Credit Crunch.” Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, Finance and Economics Discussion Series, 94-19, 1994.
Pavel, Christine, and David Philis. “Why Commercial Banks Sell
Loans: An Empirical Analysis.” Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago Economic Perspectives 11 (May/June 1987): 3-14.
Peek, Joe, and Eric S. Rosengren. “Bank Regulation and the
Credit Crunch.” Journal of Banking and Finance 19 (June
1995): 679-92.
Peltzman, Sam. “Capital Investment in Commercial Banking
and Its Relationship to Portfolio Regulation.” Journal of Political Economy 78 (January/February 1970): 1-26.
Scholes, Myron S., G. Peter Wilson, and Mark A. Wolfson.
“Tax Planning, Regulatory Capital Planning, and Financial
Reporting Strategy for Commercial Banks.” Review of Financial Studies 3, no. 4 (1990): 625-50.
Sharpe, Steven A. “Bank Capitalization, Regulation, and the
Credit Crunch: A Critical Review of the Research Findings.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
Finance and Economics Discussion Series, 95-20, 1995.
Shome, Dilip K., Stephen D. Smith, and Arnold A. Heggestad.
“Capital Adequacy and the Valuation of Large Commercial
Banking Organizations.” Journal of Financial Research 9
(Winter 1986): 331-41.
Shrieves, Ronald E., and Drew Dahl. “The Relationship between Risk and Capital in Commercial Banks.” Journal of
Banking and Finance 16 (April 1992): 439-57.
——. “Regulation, Recession, and Bank Lending Behavior:
The 1990 Credit Crunch.” Journal of Financial Services Research 9 (March 1995): 5-30.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

Simons, Katerina. “Why Do Banks Syndicate Loans?” Federal
Reserve Bank of Boston New England Economic Review
(January/February 1993): 45-52.
Skinner, Douglas. “The Investment Opportunity Set and Accounting Procedure Choice: Preliminary Evidence.” Journal
of Accounting and Economics 16 (1993): 407-46.
Slovin, Myron B., and Subbarao V. Jayanti. “Bank Capital
Regulation and the Valuation Effects of Latin American
Debt Moratoriums.” Journal of Banking and Finance 17
(February 1993): 159-74.
Slovin, Myron B., Marie E. Sushka, and John A. Polonchek.
“Restructuring Transactions by Bank Holding Companies:
The Valuation Effects of Sale-and-Leasebacks and Divestitures.” Journal of Banking and Finance 15 (April 1991):
237-55.
——. “Informational Externalities of Seasoned Equity Issues:
Differences between Banks and Industrial Firms.” Journal
of Financial Economics 32 (August 1992): 87-101.
Smirlock, Michael, and Howard Kaufold. “Bank Foreign Lending, Mandatory Disclosure Rules, and the Reaction of Bank
Stock Prices to the Mexican Debt Crisis.” Journal of Business 60 (July 1987): 347-64.
Sweeney, Amy P. “Debt-Covenant Violations and Managers’
Accounting Responses.” Journal of Accounting and Economics 17 (1994): 281-308.
Swindle, C. Sloan. “Using CAMEL Ratings to Evaluate Regulator Effectiveness at Commercial Banks.” Journal of Financial Services Research 9 (June 1995): 123-41.
Wall, Larry D. “Capital Requirements for Banks: A Look at the
1981 and 1988 Standards.” Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta
Economic Review 74 (March/April 1989): 14-29.
——. “Too-Big-to-Fail after FDICIA.” Federal Reserve Bank of
Atlanta Economic Review 78 (January/February 1993): 1-14.
Wall, Larry D., and David R. Peterson. “The Effect of Capital
Adequacy Guidelines on Large Bank Holding Companies.”
Journal of Banking and Finance 11 (December 1987): 581600.
——. “Capital Changes at Large Affiliated Banks.” Journal of
Financial Services Research 1 (June 1988): 253-75.
——. “Bank Holding Company Capital Targets in the Early
1990s: The Regulators versus the Markets.” Journal of
Banking and Finance 19 (June 1995): 563-74.
Wall, Larry D., and Pamela P. Peterson. “Valuation Effects of
New Capital Issues by Large Bank Holding Companies.”
Journal of Financial Services Research 5 (March 1991):
77-87.

Economic Review

17

Do State and
Local Taxes Affect
Relative State Growth?
Zsolt Becsi

T
The author is an economist
in the regional section of
the Atlanta Fed’s research
department. He thanks
Tom Cunningham, Andy
Krikelas, and Ric McHugh
for helpful comments.

18

Economic Review

he South has experienced a remarkable economic awakening over
the past thirty years, with southern states growing at phenomenal
rates. At the same time, these states have had, on average, low state
and local taxes, and it seems reasonable to infer that tax policies
may have contributed to their relative success. However, while policymakers may believe that taxes matter for growth, until recently economic
theory suggested otherwise. It was believed that much of long-term growth
is determined by automatic forces of convergence, which moved southern
states toward catching up with the rest of the nation. But as theoretical
growth models have grown more sophisticated, it has been increasingly recognized that the two explanations for the South’s strong showing may not be
mutually exclusive.
In brief, growth models once assumed that long-term growth was exogenous, or determined by demographic and technological factors but not subject to policy influence. In particular, under this assumption taxes could
have only short-term effects on growth rates.1 Given the same resources and
access to technology and mobile inputs of production for all states, the models implied that all should converge over time to a common long-run,
steady-state growth rate. More recent models of economic growth allow
growth rates to be endogenous, or, simply put, see shocks, including tax policy, as influencing demographic and technological variables. Under certain
conditions, taxes may have permanent effects on growth, and convergence is
not automatic. Because policies can affect long-term growth, economists are
again taking this research seriously. And since convergence need not be automatic, researchers are developing models that go beyond convergence to
explain the different growth experiences of regions.
March/April 1996

The empirical literature has tried to resolve the
question of whether growth is exogenous or endogenous. Much testing has focused on one particular implication of the simplest exogenous growth models,
namely, convergence. Within this framework, some
studies have examined the growth effects of taxation,
mostly across countries. Evidence that taxes have
long-term growth effects is sometimes thought to be
evidence against convergence. However, less work has
been devoted to determining whether state and local
taxes affect relative state growth in the United States
and, if so, how strong the effects are. So far the evidence for negative and significant tax effects on
growth across countries and across U.S. states has
been mixed.
To sort out the main issues, this article presents an
overview of relative state growth and relative state and
local taxation from 1960 to 1992.2 After a brief discussion of the theoretical issues, the article surveys simple—but revealing—correlations across states and
across time that characterize states’ experiences. The
correlations indicate convergence, but they also imply
that shocks matter for long-term growth. Tax rates are
negatively related to growth and are sufficiently variable over time to reasonably explain variations in
growth rates. This observation holds true when using
average tax rates (ATRs), which describe the relative
size of state and local revenues, and, more importantly,
for marginal tax rates (MTRs), which measure the effects of a tax system on individuals’ choices and ultimately on growth. Since aggregate marginal tax rates
for each state are difficult to obtain, they are estimated
using a method by Reinhard B. Koester and Roger C.
Kormendi (1989).
While the simple correlations are revealing, they
are not conclusive. Correlations do not separate out the
effects of other influences on growth rates and taxes.
For instance, while convergence affects growth rates it
may also have a separate effect on tax rates. Because
they control for the effects of other explanatory variables, multivariate regressions are useful for separating out, or identifying, the growth effects of taxes. A
survey of the empirical literature shows what researchers have done to isolate these effects.
This article argues that the evidence on the growth
effects of taxes has been mixed because empirical
models imperfectly separate the growth effects of other government policies that occur simultaneously with
tax policies. Thus, the estimated tax effects are impure. While a few researchers have grappled with this
problem, the solutions offered do not identify tax effects. One purpose of this article is to demonstrate a
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

simple way to get a more nearly accurate specification. Application of the new insights yields regressions
in which relatively higher tax rates are found to have a
significant negative effect on relative growth rates. At
the same time there is evidence for convergence. The
final section reviews the results of the regressions performed and summarizes the underlying theoretical
considerations.

Facts on Growth
Personal income is measured in nominal terms
(not adjusted for inflation), which may overstate real
(inflation-adjusted) differences if state prices and inflation rates differ. Unfortunately, while using a real
measure would be preferable, price indexes for individual states do not span a sufficient amount of time.3
Using a relative measure cancels the influence of inflation on nominal growth rates, assuming that state
and national inflation rates do not deviate systematically. Because more recent personal income data are
available, this article uses them to measure output
rather than using gross state product (GSP). Personal
income comprises labor and capital income received
by individuals, such as wages, salaries, rent, dividends,
interest payments, and transfer payments. Gross state
product, which includes personal income data, has a
more inclusive definition of capital income. Still, using personal income data should not obscure longterm growth trends because the two series tend to
move in tandem.
The first columns of Table 1 compare relative per
capita personal income in 1960, 1976, and 1992 and
states’ rankings in these years. Comparing relative per
capita personal income in 1960 with 1992 figures, the
correlation is 0.84 with the rank of the states having a
correlation of 0.86. Thus, states’ relative per capita
personal income tended to be persistent, suggesting a
lack of mobility. However, for some states dramatic
changes did occur, both up and down. For instance, in
1960 the poorest ten states were among the twelve
states in the southeastern region, and on average (unweighted), per capita personal income in those states
was 34 percent below the national average. (The two
exceptions were Virginia and Florida.) By 1992, only
seven of the lowest-ranking ten states came from the
Southeast, and the region as a whole stood just 17 percent below the nation. In the interim, Georgia, North
Carolina, and Tennessee had leapfrogged out of the
bottom ten. While there were these big upward movers
Economic Review

19

20

Table 1
Relative Incomes and Growth Rates by Statea
Economic Review

Average Annual Differential Growth Rates of
PCPI over Different Intervals (Percent)

Relative State Per Capita Personal Income (PCPI) (Percent)

March/April 1996

Regionb

States

1960

Rank

1976

Rank

1992

Rank

1961-92

Rank

1961-76

Rank

1977-92

Rank

Far West

AK
CA
HI
NV
OR
WA

22.1
21.1
4.1
23.4
0.6
7.2

3
5
14
2
18
10

56.0
14.1
11.8
11.9
1.7
6.1

1
3
7
6
16
11

10.0
7.0
11.0
8.7
–7.6
5.8

7
11
6
8
28
12

–0.38
–0.44
0.22
–0.46
–0.25
–0.04

46
47
16
49
41
33

2.12
–0.44
0.48
–0.72
0.07
–0.07

1
45
15
49
25
33

–2.87
–0.44
–0.05
–0.20
–0.58
–0.02

50
42
27
32
47
26

Great Lakes

IL
IN
MI
OH
WI

17.4
–2.6
5.2
4.8
–1.0

8
21
11
13
19

12.8
–3.4
5.0
–0.4
–2.6

5
23
13
18
21

7.9
–8.9
–2.2
–6.1
–5.3

10
31
19
25
23

–0.30
–0.20
–0.23
–0.34
–0.13

43
38
40
44
36

–0.29
–0.05
–0.01
–0.33
–0.10

41
30
28
43
35

–0.31
–0.34
–0.45
–0.35
–0.17

35
39
43
40
29

Mideast

DE
MD
NJ
NY
PA

21.3
5.0
19.6
19.9
1.0

4
12
7
6
17

8.0
9.4
13.9
10.9
0.8

10
9
4
8
17

5.2
14.1
26.0
18.1
2.3

13
5
2
3
15

–0.50
0.29
0.20
–0.06
0.04

50
12
18
34
26

–0.83
0.28
–0.36
–0.56
–0.01

50
20
44
47
29

–0.18
0.29
0.75
0.45
0.10

30
14
3
9
20

New England

CT
MA
ME
NH
RI
VT

25.4
10.0
–16.9
–2.9
–1.7
–16.5

1
9
36
22
20
34

15.6
5.3
–16.6
– 6.2
– 4.5
–15.6

2
12
38
29
25
36

30.6
15.8
–10.5
8.1
0.3
– 6.8

1
4
33
9
18
27

0.16
0.18
0.20
0.34
0.06
0.30

23
20
17
10
25
11

–0.61
–0.30
0.02
–0.20
–0.18
0.06

48
42
27
40
39
26

0.94
0.66
0.39
0.89
0.30
0.55

1
4
11
2
13
5

Plains

IA
KS
MN
MO
ND
NE
SD

–9.4
– 4.1
–5.4
–5.3
–21.7
– 6.0
–19.1

28
23
25
24
40
26
39

–3.3
–0.5
–0.9
– 6.4
–11.0
– 4.7
–21.4

22
19
20
30
33
26
46

–10.4
– 4.7
1.7
– 6.1
–16.4
– 4.8
–15.3

32
21
17
24
38
22
37

–0.03
–0.02
0.22
–0.02
0.17
0.04
0.12

31
28
15
29
21
27
24

0.38
0.23
0.28
–0.06
0.67
0.08
–0.14

17
22
19
32
12
24
38

–0.44
–0.27
0.16
0.02
–0.34
–0.01
0.38

41
33
18
22
38
25
12
continued

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

Table 1 (continued)

Average Annual Differential Growth Rates of
PCPI over Different Intervals (Percent)

Relative State Per Capita Personal Income (PCPI) (Percent)
Regionb

States

1960

Rank

1976

Rank

1992

Rank

1961-92

Rank

1961-76

Rank

1977-92

Rank

Rocky Mountains

CO
ID
MT
UT
WY

3.1
–17.7
–9.2
–11.5
1.9

15
37
27
31
16

2.3
–10.5
–10.7
–18.9
3.9

15
31
32
39
14

2.2
–18.8
–20.8
–26.2
– 6.4

16
39
43
49
26

–0.03
–0.04
–0.36
–0.46
–0.26

30
32
45
48
42

–0.05
0.45
–0.10
–0.46
0.12

31
16
34
46
23

–0.00
–0.52
–0.63
–0.45
–0.64

24
46
48
44
49

Southeast

AL
AR
FL
GA
KY
LA
MS
NC
SC
TN
VA
WV

–37.9
– 47.3
–11.4
–28.9
–33.0
–29.0
– 60.3
–33.0
– 45.7
–33.7
–16.2
–33.0

47
49
30
41
45
42
50
43
48
46
33
44

–24.5
–27.7
–5.5
–16.4
–21.2
–19.2
–35.8
–19.6
–26.1
–20.0
–3.9
–20.9

47
49
28
37
45
40
50
41
48
42
24
44

–19.8
–25.7
–2.4
– 8.5
–20.4
–23.8
–35.9
–12.2
–21.8
–13.2
3.9
–25.8

40
46
20
29
42
45
50
34
44
35
14
47

0.57
0.67
0.28
0.64
0.39
0.16
0.76
0.65
0.75
0.64
0.63
0.22

8
3
13
6
9
22
1
4
2
5
7
14

0.84
1.22
0.37
0.79
0.74
0.61
1.53
0.84
1.23
0.86
0.77
0.76

6
4
18
8
11
13
2
7
3
5
9
10

0.29
0.13
0.20
0.49
0.05
–0.29
–0.00
0.47
0.27
0.43
0.48
–0.31

15
19
17
6
21
34
23
8
16
10
7
36

Southwest

AZ
NM
OK
TX

–9.8
–19.1
–16.6
–14.6

29
38
35
32

–11.7
–20.9
–12.3
–5.5

34
43
35
27

–14.2
–25.9
–20.2
– 8.7

36
48
41
30

–0.14
–0.21
–0.11
0.18

37
39
35
19

–0.12
–0.11
0.27
0.57

37
36
21
14

–0.16
–0.32
–0.49
–0.20

28
37
45
31

United Statesc
Economic Review

a

6.84

States with highest PCPI or highest growth rates receive highest ranking.
States are grouped into eight standard regions defined by the Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Department of Commerce.
c
Average U.S. growth rate of Per Capita Personal Income.
Source: DRI/McGraw-Hill
b

6.73

6.94

21

in the region, most southern states saw only gradual
changes over time. Although most states lacked mobility, the fact that the range of relative per capita personal incomes narrowed over the period suggests
convergence. For instance, in order to eliminate outliers, compare the range of relative per capita personal
incomes from the fifth-ranked state with that of the
state ranked forty-fifth: this range narrowed from 54.1
percent in 1960 to 34 percent in 1976 and then to 26.3
percent in 1992.
Convergence. Before looking at the data more
closely for evidence of convergence, what does theory
have to say about convergence in exogenous or endogenous growth models?4 Factors of production are
usually classified into broad categories such as land,
labor, capital, and raw materials. Capital goods are inputs into production that are themselves produced
goods or reproducible. A narrow conception of capital
includes only physical capital while a broader definition includes human capital, intangible capital such as
knowledge, and other things that enhance the quality
of inputs. In exogenous growth models, no matter
what the source of reproducible capital is, output is increased with diminishing returns. In other words, output increases become successively smaller when the
amount of an input rises. Thus, investment-led sustained growth is not possible because as the stock of
capital rises over time, the returns to capital will fall
until investment is no longer profitable.
If only initial capital stocks differed across states,
diminishing returns to capital in the exogenous growth
model would cause convergence of outputs. The driving force for convergence is mobile inputs flowing to
areas in which they have the highest returns. States
with higher initial capital stocks and lower returns to
capital will have an outflow of capital toward capitalpoor states, raising returns in the low-return states and
lowering them in high-return states. Over time, return
differentials will equalize as states adjust to a common
long-run, steady-state growth rate. This rate of growth is
determined by technology and demographics, both of
which are assumed to be exogenous. However, access to
different resources or technology or barriers to factor
flows may prevent equalization of returns and lead to
different steady-state growth rates and nonconvergence.
In endogenous growth models, by contrast, there are
no diminishing returns to the expanded notion of capital although there may still be diminishing returns to
each individual capital input. Thus, as capital rises the
return to reproducible inputs will not fall to the point
where investment becomes unprofitable; rather, investment continues, and sustained growth is possible.
22

Economic Review

The endogenous growth literature has explored several forces that offset the propensity for diminishing
returns to reproducible inputs that causes returns to
fall. Explanations that have received recent attention
involve technology. One explanation considered is that
technology and capital broadly defined may have
spillover effects. Spillovers occur when one firm’s
investments unintentionally raise the productivity of
other firms’ capital, a classic example being that
knowledge gained from investing spills over to other
firms. Such spillovers may prevent private returns
from falling when investment rises. Another explanation is that imperfect competition induces firms to
produce innovative goods in order to capture abovenormal profits. The technological progress that comes
from innovations or quality improvements may keep
the productivity of capital high. High returns to investment in capital broadly defined in turn induce additional investments, causing sustained growth.
Because in endogenous growth models returns need
not fall to a point at which capital investment is unprofitable, nor will returns necessarily equalize, longterm growth rates need not equalize either. Also, the
equilibrating mechanism of factor flows is still possible in endogenous growth models (see Assaf Razin
and Chi-Wa Yuen 1995). Endogenous growth models
allow a tension between equilibrating transitional
forces for convergence and long-run forces for divergence that may or may not yield convergence over extended periods of time. In addition, shocks may occur
frequently and be large enough to put a state continually on an adjustment path to new steady-state growth
paths. It may therefore be hard to distinguish among
the models on empirical grounds.
But what can be inferred from the data about states’
growth experiences? Table 1 also shows long-term average growth rates of per capita personal income relative to national growth. For example, from 1961 to
1992, Alabama grew on average 0.57 percentage
points faster than the national average annual growth
rate of 6.84 percent. Over the period, it was the ninthfastest-growing state. In fact, most of the Southeast
grew faster than the nation. Some of this rapid growth
can be explained as a catching-up phenomenon given
southern states’ lower-than-average per capita personal incomes at the beginning. For instance, in 1960, Alabama had a per capita personal income that was
almost 38 percent below the national average and was
ranked forty-seventh. By 1992, this rank improved to
40 and per capita personal income improved to slightly less than 20 percent below that of the nation. Even
though Mississippi was ranked last in 1960 and 1992,
March/April 1996

it grew at the highest rate, or 0.76 percentage points
above the national average.
Chart 1 plots the relationship between initial relative
per capita personal incomes in 1960 and the average of
subsequent annual growth rates from 1961 to 1992. Almost all the fastest-growing states are in the upper lefthand quadrant. States from the Southeast with low
initial incomes grew faster and produced nine out of
the ten fastest-growing states over this period. In fact,
the correlation between initial incomes in 1960 and
growth rates is negative across all states, – 0.71.
Simple cross-section regressions of long-term state
growth rates on initial income generally find a negative relationship between the two variables.5 In other
words, the poorer the state is initially, the faster it
grows. Such regressions have been called Barro regressions and are seen as a test for convergence (or
“beta-convergence,” as popularized by Robert J. Barro
and Xavier Sala-i-Martin 1991). The result of betaconvergence is robust to inclusion of other explanatory
variables such as population growth rates and savings
rates and other, exogenous characteristics that theoretically affect growth rates. Tests of convergence after
controlling for other factors in cross-section regressions are called tests of conditional convergence. According to this definition, on balance the average
growth rate is greater for poor states that have lower

initial incomes than for rich states. Thus, Barro regressions can determine whether there exist states that are
catching up and others that are losing ground. But as
Andrew B. Bernard and Steven N. Durlauf (1994)
have noted, the regressions cannot determine whether
states are running the same race or racing to the same
point even after controlling for state characteristics. In
other words, the cross-section test cannot detect whether there are multiple long-run equilibria or multiple
growth paths. Nor can these regressions identify which
states are converging and which are not (Danny Quah
1995).
While Barro regressions do not necessarily distinguish between competing models of growth, they are
useful for capturing a particular type of convergence.
They are also useful because a large body of literature
has explored their pitfalls (see, for instance, Ross
Levine and David Renelt 1992).6 More relevant for
this discussion, however, is that Barro-type regressions
are well suited for finding the growth effects of taxes
because, as discussed below, there are good reasons
for controlling for initial income in regressions of
growth rates on tax rates.
Growth rates used in Barro regressions are usually
averaged over long time periods to smooth out shortterm variations and to reveal trend behavior. The period from 1960 to 1992 should be sufficiently long to

Chart 1
1960 State PCPI and 1961–92 Average State Growth
Average State Growth
0.008
MS
0.006

(Relative to National Average)
SC
AR
AL

NC
TN GA

0.004

KY

0.002

WV

VA

FL
LA

0
–0.002
–0.004
–0.006
–0.7

–0.6

–0.5

–0.4

–0.3

–0.2
–0.1
State PCPI

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

indicates nonsoutheastern states.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

Economic Review

23

smooth out the temporary effects of shocks and leave
only permanent effects. However, splitting the sample
into two intervals provides additional insights about
convergence dynamics as well as about other longerterm shocks to states’ economies. The first thing to
note is that the growth experiences of different states
have been far from uniform. Growth rates for all states
from 1961 to 1976 and from 1977 to 1992 had a negative correlation of –0.3. A negative correlation means
that on average growth involved setbacks or that states
reverted to the mean, and a small correlation suggests
that growth was not too persistent. Part of the reason
for differences in 1961-76 and 1977-92 relative growth
is the oil shocks of the 1970s, which created winners in
the 1970 and then losers in the 1980s when oil prices
declined. Not only does this lack of persistence suggest
that growth is affected by shocks but also that there
may be room for state-specific shocks, including taxes. In addition, the variability of growth rates explains
why the rankings of relative per capita personal incomes from 1961 to 1992 were so persistent. Growth
rates, both positive and negative, would have to be sustained over long periods for rank correlations of relative per capita personal incomes to be lower and for
states to show more mobility among rankings.
Convergence to long-run equilibrium in the exogenous growth model implies that initial incomes matter
less as time passes and states become more equal. The
data are consistent with this assumption. Growth rates
over the various subintervals have been less and less
correlated with incomes just prior to the start of the interval. For instance, dividing the sample in half shows
that, while growth over the 1961-76 period had a
–0.66 correlation with initial 1960 per capita personal
income, subsequent growth from 1977 to 1992 had only a –0.41 correlation with per capita personal income
in 1976. While a dampened relationship of growth
with initial per capita personal income is consistent
with convergence, it could also be due to large shocks
that overwhelm the effect of initial conditions.
In sum, simple correlations involving growth rates
and state incomes suggest convergence among the
states. But low persistence in growth rates is evidence
that shocks may have mattered, too. If shocks matter
for growth rates averaged over fifteen years, then it is
possible that taxes may have mattered for fifteen-year
periods or even longer. Before looking at this possibility in the next section, the following facts about
growth in the Southeast should be mentioned. Relative
per capita personal incomes in the Southeast are just
as persistent as in the nation when comparing 1960
and 1992. Also, because the correlation of initial in24

Economic Review

come in southeastern states in 1960 and the growth
rate from 1961 to 1992 is slightly lower than in the nation, convergence within the southeastern states appears to be less pronounced. Dividing the sample
period in half shows that among the southeastern
states growth rates over the two periods are virtually
uncorrelated. This finding is consistent with the correlation of initial incomes with subsequent growth, a
measure of convergence. From 1961 to 1976, convergence in the Southeast was faster than in the nation
as a whole. However, during the period from 1977 to
1992, the correlation between initial per capita personal
income and growth was positive, signaling divergence
within the Southeast. So, while all states converged
rapidly early on, later some states failed to sustain the
pace, and two groups formed that diverged.

Facts on State and Local Taxes
What does theory identify as the effects of taxes on
growth? Taxes raise the cost or lower the returns to a
taxed activity. Taxes therefore create incentives for individuals or businesses to seek out activities that
minimize their tax payments, substituting away from
activities taxed at a higher rate to those taxed at lower
rates. By inducing this substitution, taxes distort behavior in the economy. In turn, the distortionary effect
of taxes is that resources are allocated less efficiently
and growth may suffer. In particular, when taxes reduce the after-tax return to capital broadly defined, individuals have the incentive to substitute away from
investing in physical and human capital or in technical progress, causing growth to slow. In exogenous
growth models tax policies tend to have only temporary effects on growth along the adjustment path to
long-run steady-state, but in endogenous growth models the effect on growth can be permanent.7 With geographically mobile inputs to production, after-tax
returns tend to be equalized across regions in exogenous growth models in the long-run but need not be in
endogenous growth models.
When talking about the distortionary effects of
taxes, economists are really talking about marginal tax
rates. Marginal tax rates are here defined as the additional taxes paid when personal income rises by a
small amount. For example, for a personal income tax
the marginal tax rate describes a person’s tax bracket
and shows how much taxes are paid on the last dollar
earned from working and investing. Because they affect individuals’ and firms’ decisions on how to spend
March/April 1996

their last dollar, changes of marginal tax rates create
distortions of economic decisions and impose burdens
on society, including efficiency losses and lower
growth. But because information to construct average
state marginal tax rates is not easily available, average
tax rates are sometimes used to measure the effects of
taxation. While average tax rates describe the size of
government collections, they may not be a good measure of the burden imposed on society, which depends
on how much behavior is distorted.8
Average Tax Rates. The first column in Table 2
features average tax rates across states averaged over
the 1961-92 period. Average tax rates are defined as
the ratio of total state and local tax receipts to state
personal income. With the principal exception of
Louisiana, southeastern states tend to have much lower average tax rates than the nation. In fact, out of the
lowest ten over the sample period, five—Alabama,
Tennessee, Florida, Virginia, and Arkansas—are from
the Southeast. Also, the (unweighted) average tax rate
of the Southeast was 9.34 percent below the nation’s.
From 1961 to 1992, the average tax rate averaged
across all U.S. states increased over time.
How persistent are average tax rates averaged over
different time periods?9 When the sample is divided into two periods, the correlations of average tax rates

over the subintervals are positive but not very high. Average tax rates from 1961 to 1976 have a correlation of
around 0.3 with average tax rates over the years from
1977 to 1992. Since average tax rates are not too persistent, taxes may be good candidates for shocks that
cause growth rates to vary over the subintervals as well
as over the longer term, a point made by William Easterly and others (1993). However, the rank correlation
of states’ tax collections across time periods is more
than twice the autocorrelation of average tax rates. In
other words, average tax rates were too variable over
time to affect rank order significantly. This variability
of tax rates suggests that the reforms of the 1970s (or
lack thereof for states that did not reform) had little effect on states’ rankings when ranked by the relative
size of tax collections. In contrast to the nation as a
whole, average tax rates in the Southeast were much
more persistent or more strongly positively correlated.
Average tax rates in the Southeast grew more slowly
than in the rest of the nation, causing relative average
tax rates in the Southeast to fall.10
Chart 2 plots relative average tax rates along with
relative state growth rates over the 1961-92 period.
The two appear to be negatively related. In fact, the
overall correlation is –0.42, and for the Southeast it is
almost the same. At the same time, the correlation

Chart 2
Relative Average Tax Rates and State Growth Rates, 1961–92
Average State Growth
0.008
0.006

(Relative to National Average)
SC
AR
TNVA GANC
AL

0.004

MS

KY
FL

WV

0.002

LA

0
–0.002
–0.004
–0.006
–0.3

–0.2

–0.1

0
0.1
0.2
Average State and Local Tax Rates

0.3

0.4

0.5

indicates nonsoutheastern states.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

Economic Review

25

26

Table 2
Average and Marginal State and Local Tax Rates by Statea
Economic Review

Estimated State Marginal Tax Rates (Percent)b

State Average Tax Rates (Percent)

March/April 1996

Regionc

States

1961-92

Rank

1961-76

Rank

1977-92

Rank

1961-92

Rank

1961-76

Rank

1977-92

Rank

Far West

AK
CA
HI
NV
OR
WA

15.44
10.65
11.24
9.45
10.00
9.86

50
41
44
20
31
28

7.25
10.70
10.35
9.55
9.30
9.57

1
47
43
28
26
29

23.62
10.60
12.12
9.34
10.71
10.16

50
31
47
10
35
25

23.45*
10.32
12.93
9.18
11.32
10.76

50
21
47
7
38
30

13.40*
13.35
12.70
11.30
10.64
10.79

45
44
42
29
22
24

14.72*
10.68
13.68
9.35
11.97
11.68

49
18
47
6
39
33

Great Lakes

IL
IN
MI
OH
WI

9.27
8.90
10.43
8.58
11.53

17
10
37
8
47

8.58
8.71
9.67
7.78
11.08

16
20
31
2
48

9.97
9.09
11.20
9.39
11.98

24
7
41
11
45

10.35
9.68
11.53
10.54
12.24

22
11
42
26
45

12.26
10.21
12.36
9.72
13.97

35
18
39
10
47

10.58
11.08
11.50
11.90
12.80

16
24
31
38
46

Mideast

DE
MD
NJ
NY
PA

9.53
9.63
9.32
13.09
9.40

22
24
18
49
19

8.61
8.94
8.39
11.75
8.85

17
23
12
50
22

10.45
10.32
10.24
14.43
9.95

29
27
26
48
23

10.88
10.26
10.87
15.01
10.10

34
19
33
48
16

12.29
12.29
12.16
18.54
12.29

37
36
34
50
38

10.84
10.13
11.22
14.98
10.04

23
11
30
50
9

New England

CT
MA
ME
NH
RI
VT

9.08
10.66
10.50
7.94
9.96
11.30

13
42
38
1
30
45

8.42
10.09
9.94
7.94
9.25
11.17

13
38
37
4
25
49

9.74
11.23
11.05
7.93
10.66
11.43

16
42
39
1
33
43

10.47
10.45
11.70
8.28
10.82
11.52

25
23
44
1
32
41

12.40
15.31
13.27
9.77
12.52
14.77

40
49
43
11
41
48

11.17
9.62
12.52
8.96*
10.70
12.14

29
7
43
3
19
41

Plains

IA
KS
MN
MO
ND
NE
SD

10.34
9.81
11.33
8.28
10.28
9.57
10.14

34
27
46
2
33
23
32

9.92
9.70
10.67
8.14
9.85
8.80
10.50

36
32
46
7
34
21
45

10.76
9.92
11.99
8.42
10.70
10.33
9.79

36
22
46
2
34
28
19

11.33
10.20
12.27
8.60
10.79
10.65
8.94

39
17
46
3
31
28
5

10.92
9.60
13.47
10.15
8.69
11.07
9.92

25
9
46
17
2
26
13

12.76
11.13
12.57
9.29
11.14*
10.72
8.73

45
25
44
5
27
20
2
continued

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

Table 2 (continued)

Estimated State Marginal Tax Rates (Percent)b

State Average Tax Rates (Percent)
Regionc

States

1961-92

Rank

1961-76

Rank

1977-92

Rank

1961-92

Rank

1961-76

Rank

1977-92

Rank

Rocky Mountains

CO
ID
MT
UT
WY

9.72
9.47
10.88
10.36
12.73

25
21
43
35
48

9.63
9.44
10.28
9.85
10.11

30
27
42
33
40

9.81
9.50
11.47
10.87
15.35

20
13
44
37
49

9.85
9.97
11.36
11.28
16.24*

12
14
40
37
49

10.14
9.11
11.79
10.37
11.39

16
6
32
19
31

10.33
11.15
10.81
11.71
14.31*

14
28
21
35
48

Southeast

AL
AR
FL
GA
KY
LA
MS
NC
SC
TN
VA
WV

8.39
8.57
8.45
8.92
9.10
10.38
9.81
9.15
9.06
8.40
8.54
9.94

3
7
5
11
14
36
26
15
12
4
6
29

7.98
8.31
8.45
8.36
8.47
10.24
9.87
8.64
8.35
8.17
7.89
9.22

5
9
14
11
15
41
35
19
10
8
3
24

8.79
8.84
8.45
9.48
9.72
10.52
9.74
9.65
9.77
8.64
9.19
10.65

5
6
3
12
15
30
17
14
18
4
9
32

8.92
9.32
9.15
9.99
10.47
10.65
9.58
10.21
10.28
8.58
9.64
11.13

4
8
6
15
24
29
9
18
20
2
10
35

9.05
8.71
8.83
10.13
10.69
11.34
10.59
10.09
9.84
9.38
10.50
11.20

5
3
4
15
23
30
21
14
12
8
20
28

8.98
10.23
10.14
10.48
11.70
11.53
9.90
10.82
10.66
8.64
10.09
11.75

4
13
12
15
34
32
8
22
17
1
10
36

Southwest

AZ
NM
OK
TX

10.64
10.65
9.23
8.62

39
40
16
9

10.37
10.10
8.61
8.14

44
39
18
6

10.90
11.19
9.85
9.09

38
40
21
8

11.27
11.65
10.60
9.89

36
43
27
13

11.80
11.16
8.42
9.13

33
27
1
7

12.05
12.20
11.84
11.13

40
42
37
26

United States
Economic Review

a
b
c

9.92

9.40

10.44

10.75

States with highest tax rates are ranked lowest.
Bold numbers represent that the constant term in the regression was insignificant; asterisks represent that adjusted R2 was less than 0.95.
States are grouped into eight standard regions defined by the Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Department of Commerce.

11.98

11.21

27

between average tax rates and relative per capita personal incomes in 1960 is 0.33. This positive correlation presents a potential problem because it is difficult
to distinguish the influence of convergence and taxes
on growth. For example, suppose the positive correlation occurred only because of convergence and that
taxes are passive without any independent growth effects.11 Because convergence implies a negative correlation between initial incomes and subsequent growth,
taxes and growth may—indirectly through convergence—be negatively correlated for completely spurious
reasons. Alternatively, suppose there is no convergence
but that taxes do have negative growth effects: the positive correlation between taxes and growth would imply convergence (again, spuriously) indirectly through
the tax effects. Any regression of growth rates on average tax rates would need to control for the correlation
of tax rates and initial incomes to isolate convergence
and tax effects on growth.
The observation on the relation between average
tax rates and growth rates also tends to hold true for
the subintervals. For all states, the average tax rate has
negative correlations with growth over the period from
1961 to 1976 and from 1977 to 1992 of –0.36 and
–0.62, respectively, and the numbers for the Southeast
are very similar. These data indicate that states with
high growth rates also have relatively low tax revenues. Stronger negative correlations over time suggest a smaller role for taxes as a revenue source for
such states and localities. Or, if there were a good reason to think that average tax rates were a sound measure of marginal tax rates, one could infer a larger
negative growth effect of taxes. This possibility will be
explored below.
Marginal Tax Rates. The above section surveyed
average tax rates across states mainly because they
have been popular for inferences about tax effects on
growth. This section turns to marginal tax rates, which
are the better theoretical measure of what influences
behavior and ultimately growth because changes of the
tax rate on the last taxable dollar create individual incentives to change behavior and lower tax burdens. In
contrast, the average tax rate does not create behavioral changes but reflects the changes of the marginal
tax rate and changes of the tax base induced by behavior changes. Before estimating marginal tax rates and
characterizing them across states and time, this section
will first show how marginal tax rates and average tax
rates are related.
To see the relationship between marginal tax rates
and average tax rates, consider a linear flat tax. Not
only has the concept received a lot of public attention,
28

Economic Review

but the flat tax is also a useful device for estimating
marginal tax rates, as seen below. With a linear flat
tax, tax revenues are the sum of revenues independent
of behavioral changes and revenues that depend on behavioral influences through changes of income (or another measure of the tax base). Such a tax takes the
following form:
Revenues = l + MTR • Incomes.

(1)

Here MTR • Income is revenues that respond to income
changes, and the coefficient on income, MTR, gives the
effect on tax revenues of a small change in income in
period s. In other words, MTR is the marginal tax rate
of the flat tax. The constant l designates tax revenues
that are not affected by behavioral changes; nor does
this “lump-sum tax” influence individual incentives.
For this reason lump-sum taxes are also nondistortionary. While lump-sum taxes are not collected in
practice, they are implicit in tax schedules that are either progressive or regressive. If the lump-sum tax is
positive, the tax function is said to be regressive. If the
lump-sum tax is negative—a lump-sum transfer—the
tax schedule is progressive. Only if the lump-sum tax
is zero is the tax schedule proportional. Finally, to see
how average tax rates, denoted ATR, and marginal tax
rates are related, divide both sides of equation (1) by
income:
l
(2)
+ MTR.
Incomes
Thus, for a regressive (progressive) flat tax, the average tax rate is greater (smaller) than the marginal tax
rate and the average tax rate falls (rises) when income
rises. A tax is proportional when the average tax rate
equals the marginal tax rate or the average tax rate is
the same for all income levels.12
Koester and Kormendi (1989) propose a simple
way of finding an average marginal tax rate that holds
as a linear approximation.13 Basically, the estimation
procedure is to estimate equation (1) by regressing total tax revenues on a constant, l, and income. Using
the sum of state and local tax revenues and state personal income in the regression provides an estimate of
the average marginal tax rate over all taxed units. The
estimated marginal tax rate is not any one individual’s
marginal tax rate, but with certain restrictions it could
be interpreted as a representative individual’s tax rate.
In addition, one must assume that the tax base is income or that any other tax base (such as property or
sales) is proportional with income in order for this
equation to be a measure of what affects behavior.
ATRs =

March/April 1996

Also, as Koester and Kormendi point out, the
method is robust as long as there are no structural
changes to the tax schedule during the sample period.
This premise may not be tenable, though. During the
1960s many states adopted new sales tax and income
tax systems. During the 1970s many big changes occurred such as the tax limitation movement, and during the 1980s there were major federal and state tax
reforms.14 Thus, it makes sense to investigate the stability of the marginal tax rate estimates over time by
splitting the sample in two and considering if and how
marginal tax rates differ.
Table 2 shows the results of the Koester and
Kormendi-type ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions that estimate the above equation for all states individually. These regressions use Halbert White’s
(1980) formula for correcting for the possibility that
the variances of the error terms change over the sample. All the estimated marginal tax rate coefficients are
significant at the 5 percent level. Most regressions are
estimated with high accuracy, with only seven of the
153 regressions having adjusted R2s lower than 0.95.
Regressions for Alaska and Wyoming tend to have low
measures of fit. For the estimated marginal tax rates in
Table 2 that are in bold type, the regression constant
was insignificant. An insignificant constant implies
that the tax system was not significantly different from
proportionality or that the difference between the average tax rate and the estimated marginal tax rate in the
table was insignificant.15
The aggregate average tax rate in Table 2 was less
than the aggregate marginal tax rate for all periods reviewed. However, the two displayed dissimilar behavior over time: while the aggregate average tax rate
tended to increase, marginal tax rates fell. In other
words, differences between the two tax rates suggest
that the progressivity of the state and local tax system
for the United States as a whole fell over time. Looking at disaggregate behavior of the states, one finds
that the marginal tax rates of individual states were
more persistent than the average tax rates across subsamples. The autocorrelation of marginal tax rates was
0.46 comparing 1961-76 with 1977-92 while for average tax rates it was 0.3. Still, marginal tax rates in the
sample are not highly persistent but vary over time, so
they may explain some of the low persistence of state
growth rates across time.
Average tax rates of the southeastern states declined
relative to the nation’s because they did not increase as
fast as the rest of the nation’s. Marginal tax rates in the
region started out much lower relative to those in the
rest of the nation than indicated by their average tax
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

rates. Southeastern marginal tax rates (unweighted averages) were 18.1 percent lower than the nation’s during the 1961-76 period. But from 1977 to 1992, when
marginal tax rates in the nation fell, southeastern
marginal tax rates rose and converged to the national
average.
If one were to plot state marginal tax rates and
growth rates for the nation, one would find a negative
relation that is reflected in a negative correlation of
–0.39. Just as for average tax rates, the negative relationship of the marginal tax rate and growth rates has
grown stronger over time, with correlations going
from –0.36 during 1961-76 to –0.47 during 1977-92.
For the Southeast, the numbers are again similar. This
finding suggests that taxes may have had a stronger influence over the latter half of the sample. As before,
these simple correlations do not control for other variables such as the initial per capita personal income and
convergence effects. Because marginal tax rates across
all states are positively related to initial per capita personal incomes, it is difficult to disentangle the influence of convergence and taxes on growth. Thus, the
separate effects will need to be isolated before anything definitive can be said about the growth effects of
taxes. Nonetheless, the low persistence of marginal tax
rates suggests that tax rates could well explain the
variability of growth rates over time. Also, the negative correlation between marginal tax rates and growth
rates supports that taxes have a negative growth effect.
The discussion below will explore whether this result
holds when common influences such as the effect of
convergence are controlled for.

Empirical Evidence
Before proceeding to the regressions used in this
study, this section reviews related empirical studies of
taxation and growth. This review shows how previous
studies have dealt with the problems pointed out above
and identifies some other relevant issues. While the
previous section argues that to isolate tax effects from
convergence effects on growth one has to control for
initial income and use the correct measure of taxes,
namely marginal tax rates, this section shows that
identifying tax effects also requires limiting the influence of other government variables. More specifically,
the issue is how the government’s budget, which
equates revenues to expenditures and transfers, is balanced after marginal tax rates change. The way the government’s budget is balanced may have independent
Economic Review

29

effects on the economy and growth. Unless these influences are properly controlled for, estimates of tax
effects may include the effects of other fiscal policies.
The presence of these effects may explain why few
studies have found significant and negative growth effects of marginal tax rates. While some studies have
grappled with these problems, they have fallen short in
some areas, as the discussion will make clear.
A number of cross-section studies have analyzed the
relationship of taxation and international growth differences. As Peter N. Ireland’s (1994) review of the literature concludes, while some of these studies find tax
rate effects on long-term growth and appear to support
endogenous growth theories, others find no significant
effects. He suggests that part of the problem may be

It appears that state and local taxes
have temporary growth effects that are
stronger over shorter intervals and a
permanent growth effect that does not
die out over time.

that few studies average growth rates over sufficiently
long time intervals (to smooth out short-run fluctuations) to be able to distinguish among theories.
Also important is that few measures used as tax
variables are robust determinants of growth after other
explanatory measures are considered. For instance,
Koester and Kormendi (1989) have argued that previous studies may have mistakenly found negative longrun growth effects of taxation, if both tax and growth
rates are related to the level of initial income. To control for this possibility, Koester and Kormendi add the
initial level of income to cross-country regressions of
growth that use different tax measures. While they
find that both the average tax rate and marginal tax
rates have negative effects on growth in separate regressions, the coefficients on the average tax rate and
marginal tax rates are not significant. More recently,
for a broad cross-section of countries, Easterly and Sergio Rebelo (1993) concluded that the evidence that tax
rates matter for growth is fragile. Only the marginal income tax rate estimated using Koester and Kormendi’s
30

Economic Review

method, and the ratio of income taxes to personal income, survive inclusion of other explanatory variables
(such as initial income, and government expenditures
and nontax revenues) in their cross-country regressions. Other tax variables used to measure the effective
rate of taxation obliterate the effect of initial income
so that it is difficult to isolate convergence effects from
the effects of tax policy.
There have been a few studies looking for evidence
on the growth effects of state and local tax policy. As
Alaeddin Mofidi and Joe A. Stone (1990) noted, the
empirical findings have been mixed with estimated effects ranging from positive to negative. Tax rates may
be significant in simple regressions, as in the international literature, but multivariate regressions that add
more explanatory variables can result in insignificant
coefficients on tax rates. For instance, L. Jay Helms
(1985) argued that higher taxes may stimulate economic activity if used to finance appropriate expenditures. Thus, a regression should consider all sources
and uses of government funds to be able to interpret
the coefficient on taxes. Helms estimated a pooled
time-series, cross-section regression using annual data
for the period from 1965 to 1975. After controlling for
all sources and uses of funds except transfers to individuals, Helms found a negative and significant
growth effect of taxes. Thus, controlling for nontax
items to balance the budget becomes doubly important. It helps interpret the sign of the tax rate coefficient, which may be positive if taxes primarily finance
the appropriate spending, or, in Helms’s case, negative
if taxes primarily finance welfare transfers. Also, judicious choice of explanatory nontax variables will affect the significance of the estimated tax coefficients.
By contrast, John K. Mullen and Martin Williams
(1994) took another approach suggested in Koester
and Kormendi. They excluded expenditure variables in
their growth regressions in order “to disentangle average from marginal tax effects.” Specifically, they tested whether increases in the marginal tax rate that are
revenue-neutral—with simultaneous reductions in
transfers to keep revenues unchanged and so keep the
budget balanced—reduce real GSP growth rates over
1969-86. To find revenue-neutral marginal tax rate effects, Mullen and Williams include both the average
tax rate and the marginal tax rate in their growth regression, and they find negative coefficients on both,
with only the marginal tax rate significant. However,
the regression has low explanatory power, with an R2
equal to 0.192. Also, while the coefficient for initial
income is negative, suggesting beta-convergence, it is
also insignificant.
March/April 1996

The theoretical literature typically analyzes the effects of balanced-budget marginal tax rate shocks.
Usually, nondistortionary lump-sum transfers are used
to balance the government’s budget. This practice isolates the distortionary effects of taxes because one
does not have to worry about the effects of other government policies. But sometimes expenditures are allowed to adjust. By including government expenditures
in the growth and tax regressions, researchers try to
control for expenditure effects and isolate pure distortionary effects. Helms (1985) controls for expenditures
but excludes welfare transfer payments from the regression. The interpretation of the estimates is that
taxes finance distortionary welfare transfers, not lumpsum transfers as would be required to uncover the distortionary effects of taxes. To correctly identify the
distortionary tax effects requires an empirical specification that controls for all nontax revenue sources and
all expenditures and welfare transfers. In this case, the
lump-sum tax implicit in the tax schedule adjusts to
keep revenues constant and the government’s budget
in balance.16
Mullen and Williams (1994) and Koester and Kormendi (1989) propose a short cut around including all
expenditure and nontax revenue items in growth regressions. By controlling for average tax revenues
when marginal tax rates change, they hoped to isolate
revenue-neutral tax policy. Revenue-neutral marginal
tax rate effects would isolate the distortionary effects
of taxes because the budget would be balanced without expenditures, distortionary transfers, or nontax
revenues changing. However, controlling for average
tax rates means neutrality of average revenue but does
not imply revenue neutrality. Thus, these studies do not
isolate the distortionary tax effects on growth. However, the marginal tax rate changes that are regressivityneutral might do so.
To see that holding average tax rates fixed does not
mean that revenues are unchanged, consider equation
(2) and totally differentiate it. The flat tax schedule can
be changed only by changing the intercept, l, or the
slope of the tax schedule, MTR. The combined total effects of such shocks on average revenue collections are
∆ ATR  MTR  ∆ MTR
=
 ATR  MTR
ATR

(3)

L
  ∆ L − ∆ Income  ,
+
 ATR • Income   L
Income 
where the implied changes in income are also included
and ∆ denotes change. Equation (3) says that the percentage change in average tax rates is equal to a weightFederal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

ed average of the percentage change of marginal tax
rates and the percentage change of the average lumpsum tax, which is the ratio of nondistortionary taxes implicit in the tax schedule to personal income. Notice that
the average lump-sum tax rises when income falls,
which might happen when marginal tax rates increase.
Differentiating the regressivity index, ATR/MTR, yields17
ATR  ATR ∆ ATR ∆ MTR
∆
=
−
.
 MTR  MTR  ATR
MTR 

(4)

This equation states that regressivity falls or progressivity increases when the percentage change of average tax rates is smaller than the percentage change of
marginal tax rates.
There are several natural tax experiments that one
can analyze with the last two equations. For instance,
Mullen and Williams (1994) and Koester and Kormendi (1989) consider an ATR-neutral change of marginal
tax rates. Average revenue neutrality requires that
∆ATR = 0, or no change of the average tax rate. To accomplish this condition and satisfy equation (3), there
must be offsetting lump-sum tax reductions when the
marginal tax rate increases. Such a policy also implies
a rise in progressivity because now ∆(ATR/MTR) =
–ATR/MTR • ∆MTR/MTR in equation (4). Since total
tax revenues are the product of the income tax base and
the average tax rate—or Revenues = ATR • Income—
and the average tax rate cannot change, revenues will
change only if income changes. Because an increase in
the marginal tax rate tends to lower income, an ATRneutral increase of marginal tax rates implies a negative effect on tax revenues. Thus, ATR-neutrality does
not imply revenue-neutrality. A problem results because something must be done to offset the resulting
budget deficit and keep the government’s budget in
balance. For instance, the deficit might be offset by reductions in expenditures. However, changes in expenditures have their own growth effects that must be kept
separate from the growth effects of taxes. The upshot
is that growth-and-marginal tax rate regressions that
control for average tax rates but not for expenditures
have not isolated the distortionary effects of taxes. The
effects estimated in such regressions are in fact a mixture of tax and spending effects.
Alternatively, a progressivity-neutral tax policy may
come closer to isolating the distortionary effects of taxation. Such a policy requires no change in progressivity,
or ∆(ATR/MTR) = 0 in equation (4), which implies
∆ATR/ATR = ∆MTR/MTR in equation (4). Thus, average
revenue collections increase. The increase of the average tax rate offsets the negative effect of a smaller tax
base on revenues. In other words, it offsets ∆Y/Y < 0 in
Economic Review

31

equation (3). Thus, a progressivity-neutral increase of
marginal tax rates has a smaller negative revenue effect
than an ATR-neutral tax increase. This result can be
seen by looking at the percentage change of revenues,
which equals the percentage change of income plus
the percentage change of the average tax rate, or
∆Revenues/Revenues = ∆Y/Y + ∆ATR/ATR. For any
marginal tax rate increase ∆Y/Y < 0, but ∆ATR/ATR >
0 for a progressivity-neutral shock while for an ATRneutral shock ∆ATR/ATR = 0. Thus, revenues fall by a
smaller amount for a progressivity-neutral tax increase than for an ATR-neutral tax increase, so the implied budget deficit is also smaller, requiring a smaller
expenditure offset. A regressivity-neutral tax change
therefore comes closer to isolating the distortionary effects of taxes in simple growth regressions where expenditures are not controlled for.18
Controlling for Progressivity. This section reports
the results of simple cross-section regressions that
control for progressivity in order to isolate the effect
on growth of the marginal tax rate changes. To find the
effects of relative tax rates on relative growth rates, dependent and explanatory variables in the regressions
are expressed as log differences from their national averages. The explanatory variables include relative initial average personal income, RPCPI, relative marginal
tax rates, RMTR, and relative regressivity, RR, where
regressivity is defined as ATR/MTR (and relative progressivity is the inverse of RR.) As argued above, controlling for regressivity adds precision to the estimate
of the distortionary effect of marginal tax rates and a
meaningful interpretation. Thus, the discussion focuses primarily on the coefficient for RMTR, which is expected to be negative. To get a sense of how large the
tax effects are, the coefficient for RMTR is compared
with the coefficient on RPCPI, which measures the effect of initial conditions (or convergence).
The first cross-section regression estimates growth
effects with OLS after White’s correction. This regression uses a sample of all fifty states, j, where data are
averaged for the 1961-92 period and initial income is
from 1960. Equation (R1) presents the results of the
regression where standard errors are in parentheses
and significance values in brackets:
RG6192j = –0.00003 – 0.0115 RPCPI60j
(0.0003) (0.0016)
[0.93]
[0.000]
–0.0054 RMTR6192j – 0.0067RR6192j + ej ,
(0.0027)
(0.0056)
[0.043]
[0.24]
32

Economic Review

(R1)

where R2 = 0.63, adjusted R2 = 0.573, the standard error of estimate (SEE) is 0.0022, and the number of observations, N, is equal to 50.
The regression shows a negative relation between
relative growth and both relative initial income and
relative marginal tax rates. Both coefficients are significant at the 5 percent level. The coefficient on RPCPI
implies that for a state with an initial per capita personal income that is 60.3 percent below the national
average, as Mississippi in 1960 is in Table 1, one
would expect growth from 1961 to 1992 to be 0.693
percentage points above the national average. Because
Mississippi’s marginal tax rate was 11.6 percent below
the nation in Table 2, one would expect this fact to increase the relative growth rate by 0.063 percentage
points. Combined, the regression predicts growth for
Mississippi to be 0.756 percentage points above the
nation. (Mississippi’s actual growth rate was in fact
0.763 percentage points higher.) The estimated effect
on growth of relative marginal tax rates is slightly less
than half that of initial per capita personal incomes. A
state’s marginal tax rate would have had to be roughly
21 percent below the national average marginal tax
rate of 10.75 percent during 1961-92 to offset the negative effects on growth of an initial per capita personal
income that was 10 percent above average.
Next, this section investigates whether there have
been changes over time in the responsiveness of relative growth to relative marginal tax rates. These same
OLS regressions (with White’s correction) are used
when the time period is split into two subsamples. For
1961-76
RG6176j = 0.0006 – 0.0223 RPCPI60j
(0.0008) (0.0024)
[0.49] [0.000]

(R2a)

– 0.0131 RMTR6176j – 0.0235 RR6176j + ej,
(0.007)
(0.014)
[0.064]
[0.084]
where R2 = 0.615, adjusted R2 = 0.539, SEE = 0.004,
and N = 50. For 1977-92
RG7792j = –0.0007 – 0.0032 RPCPI76j (R2b)
(0.0008) (0.0052)
[0.38] [0.53]
– 0.0196 RMTR7792j – 0.0194 RR7792j + ej,
(0.0068)
(0.0098)
[0.004]
[0.048]

March/April 1996

where R2 = 0.398, adjusted R2 = 0.354, SEE = 0.0046,
and N = 50. The results reveal that the marginal tax
rate has negative growth effects that are weakly significant during 1961-76 and strongly significant over
1977-92. The growth effects of the marginal tax rate
not only strengthened over time but increased relative
to the effect of the initial position of the states. The coefficient on initial per capita personal income is only
significant in the first equation, indicating that in
1977-92 catching up was less important for states’
growth than previously. In fact, this finding indicates
nonconvergence of growth rates. Also, equations (R2)
indicate that the medium-run growth effects of
marginal tax rates were larger than the long-run effects
in equation (R1), a result consistent with the exogenous growth model, which predicts smaller growth effects the longer the time horizon is.
There are many potential problems with the above
regressions that have not been addressed here. 19
Nonetheless, the regressions give a “first-pass” conclusion that regressivity-neutral marginal tax rate increases reduce growth. Since regressivity-neutral tax
changes are “almost” revenue-neutral tax changes,
one can infer that growth rates are reduced when tax
rates rise. But one must bear in mind that offsetting
changes in nondistortionary transfers are occurring in
the background, something that is not likely to happen in practice. Also, tax effects appear to be relatively stronger the shorter the sample period is. But even
as the sample period lengthens, and the tax effect diminishes, the tax effect still remains (economically
and statistically) significant. Thus, tax effects have a
temporary component that diminishes over time as
well as a permanent component that does not disappear. While this is evidence for a hybrid endogenous
growth model with the transitional dynamics of an exogenous growth model, it could also be that the sample period was still too short to elicit true long-term
effects. Also, even though the results are consistent
with economic theory, they are not necessarily exploitable. In other words, it is not clear that a given
change in tax rates will produce changes in growth
rates consistent with the regressions in this article.
Care must be taken to ensure that the regressions are
structural and robust to other specifications. Only
then could one say that the regressions indicate
causality and not just happy circumstance.20 Future
work will need to address these issues.
By contrast to the regressions above, proceeding as
Mullen and Williams (1994) did and controlling for
relative average tax rates rather than relative regressivity to determine the strength of ATR-neutral marginal
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

tax rate changes results in insignificant and positive
coefficients on the marginal tax rate and significant
and negative coefficients for the average tax rate. As
argued before, there is a simple economic answer that
suggests that this sort of regression is misspecified.
Controlling for average tax rates does not control for
expenditures and so does not isolate the distortionary
effects of taxes. When controlling for average tax
rates, the coefficient on the marginal tax rate encompasses both the purely distortionary effect of taxes as
well as the effects of other variables that must adjust to
maintain the government budget identity. ATR-neutral
tax changes therefore still require that other expenditures’ terms be controlled for in regressions that purport to identify the distortionary effects of taxes. Thus,
the method is a dubious shortcut and explains why estimating progressivity-neutral marginal tax rate effects
is preferable.

Conclusion
Thirty-five years ago the Southeast by and large
lagged behind the nation, but in the meantime strong
growth rates have propelled the region forward. Was
this progress due to convergence, or have state and local taxes affected relative state growth? To understand
the role of taxes for growth, this article reviews states’
growth experiences and the history of state and local
taxes in the United States from 1960 to 1992. That
states’ growth rates of per capita personal income are
negatively correlated with their initial levels reflects
convergence of incomes. At the same time, the rankings of states’ per capita personal incomes have been
fairly persistent because states’ growth rates tend to
fluctuate over time.
These fluctuations may have been caused by changing taxes. State and local tax rates fluctuated approximately as much as growth rates, making them good
candidates for explaining variable state growth rates.
This relationship holds true for both states’ average
and marginal tax rates. However, the two should not
be confused. Average tax rates only measure the size
of government collections, and marginal tax rates create distortions to individual behavior and the economy
as a whole. Distortions occur when households and
firms change their work, consumption, or investment
behavior to minimize tax payments. When households
substitute away from investment in physical or human
capital or technological progress, growth ultimately
suffers. However, marginal tax rates are difficult to
Economic Review

33

come by and must be estimated. Marginal tax rates,
estimated using a method of Koester and Kormendi
(1989), generally were higher than average tax rates,
but the gap narrowed as marginal rates fell and average tax rates rose when comparing 1961 with 1976
and 1977 with 1992. Thus, state and local taxes became less progressive for the United States overall and
more states had tax systems that were indistinguishable from proportionality.
While the simple correlations above suggest that a
relationship between taxes and growth exists, regressions can put the hypothesis to the test. The main
problem is isolating the tax effects on growth. First,
one needs to control for variables that affect both
growth rates and tax rates, such as initial incomes that
govern the rate of convergence but for independent
reasons may also influence taxes. One also needs to
keep separate changes in the marginal tax rate from
changes in other government policies while not violating the government’s budget constraint, which equates
revenues to government purchases and transfers. There
are two ways to accomplish this goal, namely, either
hold all spending and transfers constant or keep revenues fixed. In both cases, when marginal tax rates are
raised nondistortionary transfers implicit in the tax
schedule adjust to keep revenues the same.
Previous empirical work has attempted to isolate the
effects of marginal tax rates either by controlling for all
expenditure items except welfare transfers or by controlling for average tax revenues. Neither method correctly identifies the distortionary effects of taxation,
however. Real-world transfers are not distortionary because welfare alters incentives and creates distortions
that must be kept separate from those of taxes. Controlling for average tax revenues when marginal tax rates
increase implies a fall in revenues and a budget deficit.
To get around this problem, this study proposes controlling for progressivity when marginal tax rates change.
Progressivity-neutral tax increases cause smaller revenue reductions than if average tax rates do not change.
In other words, progressivity-neutral tax changes are
more likely to be revenue-neutral. In turn, the offsetting
policy changes that balance the budget in the background are smaller so that the estimates more accurately reflect the effect of taxes.
This article focuses on a specific question: Do state
and local taxes affect relative state growth? The study
finds that relative marginal tax rates have a statistically

34

Economic Review

significant negative relationship with relative state
growth averaged for the period from 1961 to 1992.
These results are economically significant because
controlling for progressivity with greater accuracy
than other specifications uncovers the effect of taxes.
Also, the growth effect of taxation appears sizable, especially when compared with the effect on growth of
initial state conditions, or the convergence effect. Aggregate marginal tax rates that are 20 percent below
the national average have the same positive effect on
state growth rates as initial incomes that are 10 percent
below average. Reestimating the regressions when the
sample period is split in half shows that the tax effects
grow even stronger when compared with the convergence effect, which is insignificant in the latter half of
the sample. Thus, it appears that state and local taxes
have temporary growth effects that are stronger over
shorter intervals and a permanent growth effect that
does not die out over time, at least for the sample considered. This finding also supports the inference that
part of growth is endogenous and susceptible to policy
influence.
Finally, while one can conclude that state and local
tax rates (relative to those of other states) affect relative state growth in both the short term and long term,
there is a caveat that should precede any policy recommendation. Specifically, to isolate the growth effect of
tax rates the regressions estimate the effect of a particular policy. Since a revenue-neutral change in aggregate state and local marginal tax rates is not likely to
occur in practice, one should not extrapolate to more
likely scenarios such as revenue-altering changes in
tax rates or other fiscal policies that may accompany
tax reform. Given this caveat, the results have the following policy implication. If growth is a policy objective, one should, at the very least, assess whether tax
policies are out of line with other states. If long-term
growth rates seem too low relative to other states, lowering aggregate state and local marginal tax rates is
likely to have a positive effect on long-term growth
rates. This likelihood is greater if the reduction in
marginal tax rates is sustained rather than temporary.
However, such a policy also reduces the progressivity
of the tax system. No matter what emphasis is placed
on growth, states should be aware of the potential
trade-offs as they make choices to encourage economic growth.

March/April 1996

Notes
1. For surveys of exogenous and endogenous growth models
see, for example, the Journal of Economic Perspectives
(Winter 1994), especially articles by Romer (1994), Grossman and Helpman (1994), and Pack (1994) and references
therein.
2. The perspective does not distinguish among the composition of state and local taxes across states, although it may be
very important for state growth. For instance, a plausible
explanation for the higher growth rates of southeastern
states may be their lower reliance on property taxes for revenues and greater reliance on nontax revenue sources. The
article also ignores the regional pattern of federal and state
and local government expenditures and transfers that is
thought to have particularly stimulated the Southeast and
may soon be reversed with federal government retrenchment.
3. The American Chamber of Commerce Researchers Association cost-of-living index of U.S. metropolitan areas is inappropriate for this study because it extends back only to
the mid-1980s. Similarly, statewide GSP price deflators can
be obtained only up to 1989 as of this writing.
4. See note 1 for references. For a comprehensive overview of
the convergence literature see Barro and Sala-i-Martin
(1991, 1992, 1995); Sala-i-Martin (1994) presents an
overview of cross-sectional regressions.
5. Initial income can be interpreted as a proxy for the initial
capital stock under broad or narrow definitions. Initial conditions such as whether initial capital is below or above its
long-run level determines the transition path to steady-state.
6. For other criticisms of Barro regressions see, for instance,
Quah (1993a, 1993b, 1995), Bernard and Durlauf (1994),
Pack (1994), Kocherlakota and Yi (1995), and Carlino and
Mills (1995).
7. See Ireland (1994) for a simple overview that contrasts the
effects of taxation in simple exogenous and endogenous
growth models. For more on tax effects in endogenous
growth models see, for instance, Stokey and Rebelo (1995)
and citations therein.
8. Average tax rates are perfect proxies for marginal tax rates
only when the tax system is proportional or when the two
are equal. Benson and Johnson (1986) have argued that nationwide the state and local tax system is close to proportionality: property taxes are roughly proportional, and sales
taxes are regressive and income taxes, progressive.
9. Unless otherwise stated, all correlations involving tax rates
use relative tax rates where relative is defined as logarithmic differences with the aggregate tax rate.
10. For more on this topic, see Bahl and Sjoquist (1990) as well
as Gold (1991).
11. Koester and Kormendi (1989) studied the effect of this positive correlation but offered little explanation for it. Easterly
and Rebelo (1993) explored the determinants of the correlation, suggesting that it could arise because of fiscal endogeneity such as scale effects in the costs of administering
fiscal programs or voting.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

12. Two simple ways of measuring the degree of progressivity
of a flat rate tax schedule in equations (1) and (2) are by the
ratio of the average tax rate to the marginal tax rate or by
their difference. Thus, a flat tax schedule is progressive (regressive) if ATR/MTR < (>) 1 or if ATR – MTR < (>) 0.
How progressive a tax system is tells how distortive the tax
is. More progressivity implies greater efficiency loss for society: marginal tax rates must be higher for a given level of
expenditures because as transfers increase, more revenues
must be raised.
13. Among more recent studies that use this method are Easterly and Rebelo (1993), Mullen and Williams (1994), and
Garrison and Lee (1995). More generally, one could include
exclusions, deductions, and exemptions, or one could have
multiple tax brackets or a nonlinear tax function. The virtue
of the approach is its simplicity, but there may be a significant bias in assuming linearity instead of a nonlinear specification.
14. Briefly, the relevant historical background can be summarized as follows. From 1961 to 1971, ten states adopted a
general sales tax, ten states adopted a broad-based personal
income tax, and nine adopted a corporate income tax (U.S.
Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations
1994). In the late 1970s and 1980s the tax limitation movement caused a number of legislative controls on taxes to be
enacted. During the 1980s two major federal income tax reforms lowered tax rates, broadened tax bases, and increased
the emphasis on economic development as opposed to equity. While state reforms echoed federal reform themes, the
cutback in the flow of federal grants caused rising state and
local taxes and user fees in the 1980s.
15. With a significant constant, comparing estimated marginal
tax rates and average tax rates gives an indication of how
progressive a tax system is. For the nation as a whole, state
and local taxes are progressive; the aggregate average tax
rate is less than the marginal tax rate for the United States.
Using any measures from note 12, overall progressivity fell
over time. However, the aggregate estimate may overstate
the case for progressivity. While most states appear to have
a progressive tax system, for a large number of states one
can reject progressivity or regressivity in favor of proportionality. Also, more states have become insignificantly different from proportionality from one subsample to the next.
Comparing average tax rates and marginal tax rates for the
Southeast, one sees that most states are progressive. However, the Southeast tended to be less progressive than the
nation, except for the 1977-92 period.
16. But the regression would also suffer from multicollinearity
because it would essentially be estimating a budget identity
that equates all sources and uses of government funds.
17. See note 12 for a discussion of this index. One common
measure of progressivity is the ratio MTR/ATR, where the
ratio is greater than one if taxes are progressive. A regressivity index can be thought of as the inverse of the progressivity measure, or ATR/MTR. Using these indexes,

Economic Review

35

regressivity and progressivity are referred to interchangeably.
18. The closer the state and local tax system is to proportionality, the more precise is the approximation of the distortionary
effect on growth for a regressivity-neutral tax policy. Of
course, as states move toward proportionality, average tax
rates become a better proxy for marginal tax rates.
19. Potential trouble spots are that the explanatory variables
may be endogenous, that there exist high correlations among
explanatory variables, or that some important variables were

omitted. These possibilities temper any policy inferences
one might want to make from the regression results.
20. Also, the level of aggregation in this study does not allow
specific conclusions about how the composition of a state’s
state and local taxes affects growth. Nor does the study allow inferences about how other nontax revenues enter the
mix. For the Southeast, it may be that the low tax rates (and
a tilt of the revenue mix toward nontax sources) spurred
growth, but the Southeast’s mix of relatively low property
and income taxes may also have been important.

References
Bahl, Roy, and David L. Sjoquist. “The State and Local Fiscal
Outlook: What Have We Learned and Where Are We Headed?” National Tax Journal 43 (September 1990): 321-42.
Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. “Convergence
across States and Regions.” Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity 1 (1991): 107-58.
——. “Convergence.” Journal of Political Economy 100 (April
1992): 223-51.
——. Economic Growth. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1995.
Benson, Bruce L., and Ronald N. Johnson. “The Lagged Impact
of State and Local Taxes on Economic Activity and Political Behavior.” Economic Inquiry 24 (July 1986): 389-401.
Bernard, Andrew B., and Steven N. Durlauf. “Interpreting Tests
of the Convergence Hypothesis.” National Bureau of Economic Research Technical Working Paper No. 159, June
1994.
Carlino, Gerald A., and Leonard O. Mills. “Convergence and
the U.S. States: A Time Series Analysis.” Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia Working Paper, August 1995.
Easterly, William, and Sergio Rebelo. “Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth.” Journal of Monetary Economics 32 (1993):
417-58.
Easterly, William, Sergio Rebelo, Michael Kremer, Lant Pritchett, and Lawrence H. Summers. “Good Policy or Good
Luck?” Journal of Monetary Economics 32 (1993): 459-83.
Garrison, Charles B., and Feng-Yao Lee. “The Effect of
Macroeconomic Variables on Economic Growth Rates: A
Cross-Country Study.” Journal of Macroeconomics 17
(Spring 1995): 303-17.
Gold, Steven D. “Changes in State Government Finances in the
1980s.” National Tax Journal 44 (March 1991): 1-19.
Grossman, Gene M., and Elhanan Helpman. “Endogenous Innovation in the Theory of Growth.” Journal of Economic
Perspectives 8 (Winter 1994): 23-44.
Helms, L. Jay. “The Effect of State and Local Taxes on Economic Growth: A Time Series Cross-Section Approach.” Review
of Economics and Statistics 67 (November 1985): 574-82.
Ireland, Peter N. “Two Perspectives on Growth and Taxes.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 80
(Winter 1994): 1-17.
Kocherlakota, Narayana R., and Kei-Ma Yi. “Can Convergence
Regressions Distinguish between Exogenous and Endogenous Growth Models?” Economics Letters 49 (1995): 211-15.

36

Economic Review

Koester, Reinhard B., and Roger C. Kormendi. “Taxation, Aggregate Activity, and Economic Growth: Cross-Country Evidence on Some Supply-Side Hypotheses.” Economic
Inquiry (July 1989): 367-86.
Levine, Ross, and David Renelt. “A Sensitivity Analysis of
Cross-Country Growth Regressions.” American Economic
Review 82 (September 1992): 942-63.
Mofidi, Alaeddin, and Joe A. Stone. “Do State and Local Taxes
Affect Economic Growth?” Review of Economics and
Statistics 72 (November 1990): 686-91.
Mullen, John K., and Martin Williams. “Marginal Tax Rates
and State Economic Growth.” Regional Science and Urban
Economics 24 (1994): 687-705.
Pack, Howard. “Endogenous Growth Theory: Intellectual Appeal and Empirical Shortcomings.” Journal of Economic
Perspectives 8 (Winter 1994): 55-72.
Quah, Danny. “Empirical Cross-Section Dynamics in Economic
Growth.” European Economic Review 37 (1993a): 426-34.
——. “Galton’s Fallacy and Tests of the Convergence Hypothesis.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics 95 (1993b):
427-43.
——. “Empirics for Economic Growth and Convergence.”
Centre for Economic Policy Research Paper No. 1140,
March 1995.
Razin, Assaf, and Chi-Wa Yuen. “Factor Mobility and Income
Growth: Two Convergence Hypotheses.” National Bureau
of Economic Research Working Paper No. 5135, 1995.
Romer, Paul M. “The Origins of Endogenous Growth.” Journal
of Economic Perspectives 8 (Winter 1994): 3-22.
Sala-i-Martin, Xavier. “Regional Cohesion: Evidence and Theories of Regional Growth and Convergence.” Yale University, Economic Growth Center Discussion Paper No. 716,
October 1994.
Stokey, Nancy L., and Sergio Rebelo. “Growth Effects of FlatRate Taxes.” Journal of Political Economy 103 (June 1995):
519-50.
U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations.
Budget Processes and Tax Systems. Significant Features of
Fiscal Federalism, vol. 1. Washington, D.C., December
1994.
White, Halbert. “A Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Covariance
Matrix Estimator and a Direct Test for Heteroskedasticity.”
Econometrica 48 (1980): 817-38.

March/April 1996

FYI
Tracking Manufacturing:
An Update on the
Survey of Southeastern
Manufacturing Conditions
R. Mark Rogers

A
The author is the forecast
coordinator in the macropolicy
section of the Atlanta Fed’s
research department. He
thanks Whitney Mancuso,
David Green, Chenyang Fend,
and Andrew Noble for
research assistance and
Frank King, Mary Rosenbaum,
Bobbie McCrackin, Whitney
Mancuso, and David Green
for helpful comments.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

t the end of 1991, the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta began a
survey of manufacturers in Sixth Federal Reserve District states.1
This Survey of Southeastern Manufacturing Conditions has been
valuable in helping gauge the strength of the southeastern economy over the past four years of recovery and expansion. In March
1995 the implementation of seasonal adjustment procedures substantially
improved the survey by making the data easier to interpret. The seasonally
adjusted data make time series comparisons much easier than they were
when only unadjusted data were available. As a result, the data provide a
clearer picture of the past four years as well as current conditions and manufacturers’ expectations.
Why does the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta conduct this survey? Like
the eleven other Reserve Banks across the nation, the Atlanta Fed monitors
economic conditions in its region. Its most important reason for doing so is
to contribute to the Federal Reserve System’s task of setting appropriate
monetary policy. The Atlanta Fed also releases the information in the survey
(at aggregate levels only) to the public so that interested citizens can have
additional current information on the region’s economy. In the Southeast,
one of the most important influences on the economy’s performance is manufacturing activity. It is more variable than most other sectors and is generally a higher-wage sector.
Consequently, to augment its analysis of economic conditions in the region, the Atlanta Fed’s research department in late 1991 launched the first
Economic Review

37

comprehensive survey to focus solely on changes in
indicators of manufacturing activity in the Southeast.
Because turnaround is rapid—less than three weeks
for gathering, compiling, and reporting the data—the
survey provides recent information on the southeastern
economy, information not available from other
sources.

What’s in the Survey?
The Atlanta Fed’s manufacturing survey covers
manufacturing plants in all or parts of the six states in
the Sixth Federal Reserve District. This monthly mailin survey is distributed to about 230 selected firms with
plants located in these states. The survey’s panel of
manufacturers is patterned on the distribution of industries according to the two-digit standard industrial classification (SIC) for shipment values from the Census
Bureau’s quinquennial Census of Manufactures in
1992. Table 1 shows the current distribution of survey
respondents according to the two-digit SIC classification; the table also gives 1992 Census of Manufactures
shipment values for Sixth District states and the United
States. Tabulated responses are not weighted by firm
size, nor are adjustments made for variances in response rates by industry from an “ideal” distribution.
For the most part, the survey design and operation
is little changed from when reports were first released
to the public in November 1992.2 The survey asks for
information about a broad range of activities: production, shipments, new orders, order backlogs, materials
inventories, inventories of finished goods, number of
employees, average employee workweek, prices received for finished products, prices paid for inputs
(nonlabor), capital expenditures, new orders for exports, and supplier delivery time. Responses to the survey are qualitative—not for specific levels such as
dollar amounts. For each question respondents are
asked to report activity as being an “increase” or a
“decrease” or as showing “no change” (a) from the
previous month, (b) from the same month a year ago,
and (c) in terms of expected levels of activity six
months from the current month. In addition to the
questions specific to the manufacturer’s own plant,
each respondent is asked for an evaluation of the
firm’s industry activity at the national level.
Data for each question are aggregated into percentages reporting each of the three responses—increase,
decrease, and no change.3 A diffusion index is also calculated for each question. This index is merely the dif38

Economic Review

ference between the positive response share (the percentage reporting increases) and the negative response
share (the percentage reporting decreases). Numerical
values of the diffusion indexes range from minus 100 to
positive 100. At the zero value, the percentage reporting
increases equals the percentage reporting decreases.
While the diffusion indexes are not calculated from specific dollar levels of activity for each respondent, there
is a statistical relationship that higher index values are
associated with higher growth rates.
Survey questionnaires are mailed out on or near the
twenty-fourth of each month. The timing of the mailing allows respondents to provide data that reflect
known activity for the reference month, for the most
part, rather than estimates based largely on data from
the previous month. For the initial release of data for a
given reference month, the sample size averages between 115 and 125 respondents; the data received late
boost the subsequent month’s tally to between 125 and
140 replies. Summary data are released to the public
on the second business day after the tenth of the month
after the reference month.

Why Seasonally Adjust the Data?
For the past four years, the Survey of Southeastern
Manufacturing Conditions has provided useful information and has played a role in the bank’s consideration of the proper monetary policy. However, during
the first two years of the survey, it became apparent
that the data about current activity and expectations
have some significant seasonal movements that, at
times, overwhelm cyclical movement and add uncertainty to interpretation. For example, each July the
share of respondents reporting decreased production
output jumps sharply—apparently because of vacation
shutdowns and slowdowns. Similarly, output numbers
are weakest around December as Christmas production
is completed for the most part and there are vacationrelated cutbacks in hours of production. Related to the
pre-Christmas boost in production and the December
slump, data about manufacturers’ expectations are
generally strongest in December and weakest in June.
June expectations data reflect the anticipation of production cutbacks in December (six months after June).
See Chart 1 comparing seasonally adjusted and not
seasonally adjusted production diffusion indexes.
With these volatile monthly patterns in the data,
cyclical movement was often overwhelmed. The
question then became, After taking into account these
March/April 1996

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

Table 1
States’ Value-Added Manufactures by Industry
As a Percentage of States’ Total Value Added by Manufactures

Economic Review

SIC
Code

Description

AL

FL

GA

LA

MS

TN

DIST.

U.S.

Survey
Distribution
By Units1

20
22
23
24

Food and kindred products
Textile mill products
Apparel and other textile products
Lumber and wood products

7.3
7.4
7.1
4.3

14.4
D2
3.5
2.5

15.7
D
6.4
3.2

7.9
D
0.6
2.3

11.5
D
8.0
8.3

14.0
2.5
5.2
1.5

12.3
1.6
4.9
3.1

11.2
2.1
2.6
2.4

8.51
2.84
4.12
3.09

25
26
27
28
29

Furniture and fixtures
Paper and allied products
Printing and publishing
Chemicals and allied products
Petroleum and coal products

2.5
13.3
3.5
11.8
D

1.4
4.2
11.6
9.3
0.4

1.5
11.6
5.8
10.3
D

—
7.9
2.0
40.5
18.2

8.1
9.5
D
8.9
D

2.9
5.5
6.4
16.5
D

2.2
8.3
5.7
16.1
2.8

1.6
4.3
8.1
11.8
1.7

2.06
8.76
4.90
13.14
—

30
31
32
33
34

Rubber and misc. plastic products
Leather and leather products
Stone, clay, and glass products
Primary metal industries
Fabricated metal products

6.1
D
2.2
7.3
6.3

3.2
D
3.3
0.7
4.8

3.9
D
3.5
2.9
3.5

0.9
D
1.1
0.9
3.5

5.6
D
2.6
2.7
5.9

5.8
1.0
2.3
4.4
5.8

4.2
0.2
2.6
3.1
4.9

4.2
0.3
2.5
3.7
6.0

4.12
—
4.64
3.09
10.57

35
36
37
38
39

Machinery, except electrical
Electric and electronic equipment
Transportation equipment
Instruments and related products
Miscellaneous manufacturing

6.8
5.7
5.6
1.4
1.4

4.7
15.7
8.3
10.7
1.3

4.9
8.1
14.9
2.6
1.1

2.7
1.9
8.8
0.4
0.3

7.4
10.4
10.3
0.8
D

7.3
5.7
8.9
2.4
2.0

5.5
8.0
9.7
3.5
1.2

9.4
8.7
11.5
6.4
1.6

6.70
9.02
9.79
2.58
2.06

100.0

100.0

100.0

100.0

100.0

100.0

100.0

100.0

100.0

Total
1

Average for October-December 1995
“D” indicates that census disclosure rules prevent the release of data when there are too few firms in a geographic location for a particular industry.
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Census of Manufactures, 1992
2

39

normal seasonal fluctuations, is southeastern manufacturing improving or not? Seasonal adjustment procedures indeed do a relatively good, although not
perfect, job of taking these seasonal fluctuations into
account. Statistical programs adjust the data for seasonally weak months by raising the data for these
months by a typical difference between the unadjusted
months’ value and an average yearly value such as a
thirteen-month centered average.4 Similarly, data for
seasonally strong months are lowered by the typical
difference between it and a broader average. As a result, a user can discount normal seasonal influences on
the data and focus more closely on data that may suggest changes in underlying economic strength.

The Seasonal Adjustment Process
To seasonally adjust the data, the Atlanta Fed used
a standard seasonal adjustment program—the Census
Bureau’s X11 program. However, before seasonally

adjusting the data, standard procedures were implemented to determine whether seasonal adjustment was
appropriate. In the preliminary stage of the seasonal
adjustment process, the X11 program conducts a statistical test (an F-test) to determine whether the seasonality is “stable”—that is, whether the movement in
a data series has a regular intrayear pattern.
Data can be processed through seasonal adjustment
programs regardless of whether seasonality is stable.
However, doing so for data that do not show a stable
seasonal pattern does not improve the user’s ability to
discern true cyclical movements and may instead distort
cyclical patterns. Seasonal adjustment programs compare unadjusted monthly numbers to a yearly moving
average and then apply seasonal factors to unadjusted
data. If the pattern of the differences from the moving
average is not regular (that is, stable), then the seasonal
factors that are calculated are simply “averages” of random movements. Under these circumstances seasonally
adjusted data merely reflect the addition of random
factors (the seasonal factors based on unstable data) to
unadjusted data. In short, data series that reveal no sea-

Chart 1
Survey of Southeastern Manufacturing Conditions
Production Diffusion Indexes, Seasonally and Not Seasonally Adjusted
Diffusion
Index

40

Seasonally Adjusted

20

0

Not Seasonally Adjusted
–20

1992

1993

1994

1995

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

40

Economic Review

March/April 1996

sonal patterns should not be run through a seasonal adjustment procedure. Some examples of national data series without clear seasonality are from the U.S.
consumer price index report, including the price series
for household insurance, household maintenance and
repairs, and public transportation costs.
Seasonality Tests. For the Atlanta Fed survey, unstable series are monitored on an ongoing basis so that, if
they do begin to exhibit a more stable seasonal pattern,
they may be seasonally adjusted in the future. Beginning with the initial release of January 1996 data, only
three series are not being reported in seasonally adjusted form: (1) prices received for the current month versus
the previous month, (2) supplier delivery time for the
current month versus the previous month, and (3) new
orders for exports for six months from November.
These series did not pass a statistical test for stable seasonality.5 A list of the F-test results for seasonal stability
can be found in Table 2 with the top panel indicating the
test results for responses in the “this month versus last
month” category and the bottom one providing test results for responses in the “six months from now” category.
After F-test results determined which series should
be seasonally adjusted, data for each question in the
survey were seasonally adjusted by components—that
is, the response categories “decrease,” “no change,”
and “increase.” A seasonally adjusted diffusion index
was created using the seasonally adjusted components.6
After the data have been seasonally adjusted but
before the survey is published, one final process is
necessary. For each month the seasonally adjusted
components (decrease, no change, increase) for a given question do not always sum exactly to 100 because
of the nature of the seasonal adjustment statistical procedure. The unadjusted responses’ percentage shares
of course sum to 100. So that the sum of the parts
equals the whole, seasonally adjusted components are
statistically constrained to sum to 100. As a result, the
seasonal factors implied by the difference of published
(constrained) adjusted and unadjusted data for a given
component are not the same as the factors generated
by the unconstrained data. The published seasonally
adjusted diffusion indexes are the difference of these
constrained seasonally adjusted components.
It is important to note that only four years of data are
used to derive the seasonal factors and that revisions
could be significant with the inclusion of more data.
This past year, seasonal factors were revised from those
based on only three years of data, and modest changes
were seen in the factors as well as in the test statistics
for seasonal stability.
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

Southeastern Manufacturing: Trends,
Current Conditions, and Expectations
Several trends in the southeastern manufacturing data have emerged during the past four years from
the responses given by participating manufacturers.
Trends have become evident in the proportions reporting increases, decreases, or no change for the various
survey questions—such as for production, shipments,
and new orders. Changes over the business cycle can
also be seen by looking at the diffusion index for a
given survey question. While in many situations as the
proportion of respondents reporting increases moves
up, the share with decreases declines, and vice versa,
there are instances when both shares move together
with the impact showing up in the no-change category.
In these instances, the diffusion index is particularly
useful because it reveals the difference between the
proportion reporting higher levels of activity and the
share reporting lower levels of activity.
During the last four years, the various survey series
have shown a manufacturing sector largely in a postrecovery phase of economic expansion. Reports have
reflected varying magnitudes of strength for manufacturing output with corroborating data in other series,
such as orders and employment. Similarly, price data
have followed the strength in output.
The diffusion index for output portrays an almost
continually expanding southeastern manufacturing sector from early 1992 until the end of 1995. There were
mild softenings in mid-1993 and early 1995. A moderate weakening in output, possibly related to a temporary inventory adjustment, began in December 1995.
By early 1995 somewhat more firms than not reported
higher inventories for finished goods while series for
new orders and backlogs remained soft. In May 1995,
for the first time, more plants reported decreases in output than reported increases, beginning an extended period of softness that continued into early 1996.
The survey’s employment data suggest that management has been cautious in adding to the manufacturing
work force in the Southeast. By February 1992 more
manufacturers were adding to the work force than were
laying off workers, but the net positive hiring trend
took a brief detour in mid-1993, as indicated by the
employment diffusion index, which turned negative
from May 1993 through August 1993. Thereafter, manufacturers were more inclined to add to their labor
force until April 1995, when the employment index again
turned negative. Despite mostly favorable hiring trends
over the first three years of the survey, the underlying
Economic Review

41

Table 2
Test for Stable Seasonality
This Month versus Last Month Series
Series

Decrease

No Change

Increase

Diffusion Index

Production

7.114

3.136

8.497

9.645

Shipments

5.701

2.818

5.917

6.346

New orders

2.853

0.547*

3.719

3.308

Backlog of orders

2.978

0.689*

5.562

4.698

Materials inventories

3.156

1.756*

2.835

4.267

Finished goods inventories

3.534

1.120*

4.203

4.674

Number of employees

2.856

5.050

5.027

2.096

Employee workweek

3.187

2.680

5.138

5.899

Prices received

1.972*

3.189

2.399

1.711*

Prices paid for raw materials

0.606*

3.739

3.160

2.026

New orders for exports

0.601*

2.793

3.597

2.358

Supplier delivery time

1.143*

1.718*

1.552*

1.049*

Industry activity nationwide

2.745

1.568*

3.737

2.751

Six Months from Now Series
Series

Decrease

No Change

Increase

Diffusion Index

Production

11.099

2.504

7.891

9.198

Shipments

10.113

2.709

8.064

9.509

New orders

9.175

2.112

8.318

8.986

Backlog of orders

6.962

1.626*

7.633

10.691

Materials inventories

2.877

0.605*

2.037

3.608

Finished goods inventories

3.752

1.374*

2.936

4.810

Number of employees

7.242

1.002*

5.558

7.769

Employee workweek

8.419

0.593*

6.871

14.525

Prices received

4.449

7.202

8.446

6.331

Prices paid for raw materials

0.767*

6.474

5.708

3.434

Capital expenditures

1.556*

1.951

2.910

2.388

New orders for exports

0.687*

1.995

1.869

1.355*

Supplier delivery time

1.563*

1.104*

1.915

2.075

3.563

6.544

9.247

Industry activity nationwide

11.160

Note: The table shows the values of the X-11 F-test for stable seasonality. Seasonal adjustment is done using RATS386-EZ-X11 with graduated extremes. Critical value for the 99 percent level is 2.36. Critical value for the 95 percent level is 1.83. An * indicates those series for
which seasonality is not significant at the 95 percent level. The tested series consist of data spanning the period January 1992–December
1995, except for supplier delivery time, which is tested over the March 1992–December 1995 period.

42

Economic Review

March/April 1996

caution of manufacturers should not be overlooked.
The percentage of plants reporting no change in their
number of employees remained high—never dropping
below 55 percent—throughout this period.
The data for the average workweek show a pattern
similar to that for the number of employees. Workweek figures have been positive on balance for the
1992-94 period, with the exception of a mildly negative five-month period in mid-1993. Since February
1995 the trend clearly has been for the index to remain
mildly negative. Comments from manufacturers give
several possible explanations for the fact that only a
small portion of plants have boosted either employment
or average work hours during the current expansion.
These explanations include management’s expectation
that output gains would be only moderately healthy
rather than robust during the expansion, firms’ cost of
labor being driven up by benefit costs, and foreign and
domestic competition’s forcing manufacturers to boost
productivity and reduce labor costs.
As the string of positive reports on production, shipments, and orders continued into the third year of this
expansion, the issue of price pressures became increasingly important. In both 1992 and 1993 the share of
respondents reporting an increase in prices for raw materials remained at a relatively constant 20 percent each
month. However, by the end of 1994 this figure had
surged to over 50 percent, peaking at 59 percent in January 1995. Such figures raised concern that inflation
pressure might be building at the manufacturing level
and could be passed on to consumers. The share of respondents reporting raising prices for their finished
product also rose, although much more slowly. The
share reporting increases rose from the 10 percent to
the 15 percent range in 1993 to a peak of 34 percent in
January 1995. The share reporting increases for either
series eased in early 1995 and remained soft into early
1996.
In analyzing the relationship of these numbers, particularly for input prices, to overall inflation trends,
several points should be considered. First, the figures
do not indicate the size of price increases, merely the
proportion of firms reporting those increases. Second,
for most firms the number of different raw materials
used in their production process exceeds the number
of finished products. Hence, reports typically show input prices increasing more often than do finished product prices. Finally, raw materials may be only a small
portion of total costs, and manufacturers may temporarily absorb that cost. To some degree, all these
factors likely have played a role in constraining reported increases in output prices in 1994 despite the fact
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

that figures for the raw materials price series have
been higher.

The Outlook Data
The data respondents report on outlook are difficult
to interpret for the Southeast because the survey has
not yet been in existence for even a full business cycle.
Yet thus far the outlook responses for a number of activities have been consistent with current-month data,
but only in a broad cyclical sense. The six-months-out
data tend to miss some of the more volatile oscillations
in the current-month figures. For example, the outlook
data for production peaked early during this expansion,
in December 1992, when two-thirds of the respondents
anticipated future output gains. This peak was consistent with the later maturing manufacturing sector in the
Southeast when output grew more slowly. On the other
hand, the noticeable deceleration in mid-1993 was not
foreseen by southeastern manufacturers.
In the prices-received and prices-paid series, the
six-months anticipation data appear to have been more
accurate for peaks and troughs for two or three months
ahead than for six months. Also, for the first two years
of the survey, manufacturers were significantly more
optimistic in terms of expectations of prices received
than later data bore out. Only in the spring of 1995 did
expectations data for prices, both received and paid,
approach the current-month diffusion index levels.
During the past four years, only a small percentage of
southeastern manufacturers were able to report increases in prices for their own finished products despite significant percentages of respondents indicating
higher input prices over the first three years of the survey, especially in 1994.

Summary
In March 1995 the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta
began publishing data for the Survey of Southeastern
Manufacturing Conditions in seasonally adjusted
form, thereby significantly improving the data’s usefulness in portraying the current status of southeastern
manufacturing. Seasonally adjusted data are now available historically back through 1992 for most month-ago
and six-months-ahead expectations series. Historical
data are available through the Commerce Department’s Economic Bulletin Board, on the Internet at
Economic Review

43

http://www.frbatlanta.org, or through the Atlanta Fed’s
public affairs department.
The new, seasonally adjusted data portrayed a robust manufacturing sector in the Southeast from 1992
through 1994 with gradually rising price pressures
peaking at the first of 1995. The fourth year of the survey, 1995, showed southeastern manufacturing activity

rebounding with modest growth following a mild inventory adjustment in the spring of the year. Output in
early 1996 weakened after an extended period of declines in backlogs. At the end of 1995, price indexes
for prices paid and for prices received were soft compared with 1994.

Notes
1. The Sixth Federal Reserve District encompasses Alabama,
Florida, Georgia, and parts of Louisiana, Mississippi, and
Tennessee.
2. See R. Mark Rogers, “Tracking Manufacturing: The Survey
of Southeastern Manufacturing Conditions,” Federal Reserve
Bank of Atlanta Economic Review 77 (September/October
1992): 26-33.
3. For supplier delivery time the question format was changed
in March 1992. The choice of responses was changed from
“decrease,” “no change,” and “increase” to “faster,” “no
change,” and “slower” to clarify intended responses. There
had been some doubt as to how respondents were interpreting these questions when the survey first began. For supplier
deliveries, “slower” is a positive response because slower deliveries generally indicate a strong economy with increasing
shortages of supplies. The diffusion index for supplier delivery time is the percentage of “slower” responses minus the
percentage of “faster” responses.
4. Using thirteen months to determine an average gives an
equal number of months before and after the “center” of the
average.
5. If the results of the F-test do not indicate stable seasonality at
the 95 percent confidence level or higher, that particular series is not seasonally adjusted. The 95 percent figure is a typical, high standard for acceptance of the hypothesis (that
stable seasonality is present). For a number of types of activity (that is, production, new orders, and so on), one or more of
the components of the diffusion indexes did not pass the 95
percent hurdle for stable seasonality. For example, for material goods inventories, the “no change” response has an Fstatistic that is well below the 95 percent critical value even
though the “decrease” and “increase” components had Fstatistics exceeding this value. In these cases, all of the components are seasonally adjusted if one component passed
(including, for this test purpose, “no change” as well as the
diffusion index [in a test directly on the unadjusted index]).

44

Economic Review

The seasonally adjusted diffusion index is still calculated indirectly from these seasonally adjusted components. For the
category “prices received this month versus last month, only
the “no change” component series is stable, likely reflecting
the fact that most responses fell in that category. The “increase” and “decrease” categories had a high ratio of noise
(monthly volatility) to any seasonal movement and did not
pass the test for stable seasonality.
When the survey data were first released in seasonally adjusted form in March 1995, the list of series not available in
seasonally adjusted form differed slightly. At that time the
series available only in unadjusted form were “prices received for this month versus last month” and “supplier delivery time” (for both time frames). For both the “supplier
delivery time” series there were an insufficient number of
observations for seasonal adjustment because the format for
these series changed in March 1992 (see note 3). A minimum
of three years of data is required for the X11 procedure.
6. Direct seasonal adjustment of the diffusion index was also
considered. The directly adjusted diffusion indexes were
practically identical to those computed using seasonally adjusted components. The directly adjusted indexes usually had
marginally less monthly volatility than the indirectly adjusted
indexes. The deciding factor in using an indirect seasonal adjustment process for the diffusion indexes was that the seasonally adjusted components are consistent with the indirectly
adjusted indexes. In other words, indirectly adjusted diffusion
indexes exactly (except for rounding) equal the difference
between percentages for positive and negative seasonally adjusted component responses. Directly adjusted indexes do
not always equal the difference between positive and negative response shares. Another concern was that with directly
adjusted indexes using additive factors it is possible for some
seasonally adjusted monthly indexes to take on values greater
than 100 or less than –100—possibilities that are not aesthetically or theoretically pleasing.

March/April 1996