View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Economic
Review Sffl
FEDERAL

ftBSÉ^&tìANK

MARCH/APRIL 1980

OF ATLANTA

BÄNRfWG ACT A New World
DISCOUNT RATE
HOUSING

The Crunch Arrives

F O O D PRICES

Slower Rise in 1980?

. UNDERGROUND

Iirfc



W

In Perspective

The Hidden Economy

A
Q

The purpose of the Economic Review is to inform the public about Federal Reserve
policies and the economic environment and, in particular, to narrow the gap between
specialists and concerned laymen. For more specialized readers, the Review also
summarizes our basic research projects, which are available in complete form in our
Research Paper and Working Paper series.

2




M A R C H / A P R I L 1980, E C O N O M I C REVIEW

page 4

page 6

page 12

The U S banking environment was substantially c h a n g e d

The Discount Rate Under The Federal
Reserve's New Operating Strategy

with the s i g n i n g of H R 4 9 8 6 by President Carter on M a r c h

H o w d o e s the Fed use the d i s c o u n t rate as a tool in

31. Some of the c h a n g e s will affect bankers, b u s i n e s s m e n ,

monetary policy? What d o e s a c h a n g e in the rate mean?

and consumers

Harry Brandt outlines a short history of the discount rate

Banking Act Makes Major Changes

i m m e d i a t e l y ; other c h a n g e s will

4

be

p h a s e d in gradually. A s u m m a r y of the Act's major points

6

a n d e x p l a i n s the rate's role in the Fed's new reserve control
strategy.

Home Building in the Early 1980s

12

Basic Questions on Food Prices

16

With b u i l d i n g in the throes of a s h a r p contraction, B. Frank

What h a p p e n s to food prices in a recession? H o w will the

King e x a m i n e s the factors w h i c h d e t e r m i n e d e m a n d for

Soviet grain e m b a r g o a n d current international tensions

n e w housing. What is t h e outlook for h o m e b u i l d i n g in the

affect U.S. prices? Gene D Sullivan r e s p o n d s to these a n d

early 1980s? H o w d e e p will the current s l u m p be, a n d

other guestions on the outlook for f o o d prices in 1980.

w h e n c a n w e e x p e c t a r e b o u n d to b e g i n ?

Thoughts on the
Underground Economy
E c o n o m i c Review, Vol. LXV, No. 2. Free subscription and additional copies available upon request to the Information Center,
Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Atlanta,
Georgia 30303. Material herein may be reprinted or abstracted,
provided this Review, the Bank, and the author are credited. Please
provide this Bank's Research Department with a copy of any
publication in which such material is reprinted.

23

Through two years of recession forecasts, the U.S. e c o n o m y has remained amazingly resilient. One reason, m a n y
economists believe, is the existence of an " u n d e r g r o u n d
economy." C o u l d this h i d d e n activity b e large e n o u g h to
distort e c o n o m i c m o d e l s and forecasts? In our new
mentary"

"Com-

section, Charles J. Haulk estimates the un-

m e a s u r e d activity's size a n d g r o w t h rate a n d reflects on
the implications for fiscal a n d monetary policy.

D i r e c t o r of R e s e a r c h : Harry Brandt
Associate D i r e c t o r : Bill Cox
B u s i n e s s E d i t o r : Gary W. Tapp
P r o d u c t i o n and G r a p h i c s :
Susan F. Taylor and Eddie W. Lee, Jr.

page 16

F E D E R A L RESERVE B A N K O F A T L A N T A 3




page 23

Banking Act Makes
Major Changes
On March 31, 1980, President Carter signed into law H.R. 4986, the "Depository Institutions
Deregulation and Monetary Control Act of 1980." Although the Act itself goes into effect six
months after signing, some of its provisions take effect at different times (noted below). Here is a
summary of the Act's major points.

Permits Nationwide
N O W Accounts

All depository institutions
(after December 31, 1980) may
offer N O W accounts (interestearning checking accounts) to
individuals and nonprofit organizations. The Act also allows
banks to provide automatic

transfer services from savings
to checking accounts, permits
S&Ls to use remote service
units, and authorizes all federally insured credit unions
to offer share draft accounts,
effective immediately.

Phases O u t Deposit
Interest Rate
Ceilings

Congress declares that interest rate ceilings on deposits
discourage saving and create
inequities for depositors,
especially those with modest

savings. The Act therefore sets
up machinery to phase out
interest rate ceilings on deposits over a six-year period.

Eliminates Usury
Ceilings

State usury ceilings on first
residential mortgage loans are
eliminated (as of March 31,
1980) unless a state adopts a
new ceiling before April 1,
1983. Credit unions may increase their loan rate ceiling
from 12 percent to 15 percent
and may raise the ceiling
higher for periods up to 18
months.

The Act also preempts state
usury ceilings on business and
agricultural loans above
$25,000 and permits an interest rate of not more than 5
percent above the Federal
Reserve discount rate, including any surcharge, on 90-day
commercial paper. This provision expires on April 1, 1983
or earlier if the state reinstitutes its ceiling.

Increases Level of
Federally Insured
Deposits

The Act increases Federal
deposit insurance at commercial banks, savings banks,

S&Ls, and credit unions from
$40,000 to $100,000, effective
immediately.

4




M A R C H / A P R I L 1980, E C O N O M I C REVIEW

The Act specifies that any
reserve requirement will now
be uniformly applied to all
transactions accounts at all
depository institutions. Transactions accounts include
demand deposits, N O W
accounts, telephone transfers, automatic transfers, and
share drafts. Specifically, all
banks, savings banks, S&Ls,
and credit unions will have to
maintain reserves in the ratio
of 3 percent for that portion
of their transactions accounts
below $25 million and 12 percent (the Board can vary this
between 8 and 14 percent)

for the portion above $25
million. They also must maintain reserves of 3 percent (or
within a range of 0 to 9 percent) against their non-personal time deposits and must
report (directly or indirectly)
their liabilities and assets to
the Federal Reserve.

The Act permits the Federal
Reserve Board, in "extraordinary circumstances," to impose
an additional reserve requirement on any depository

institution of up to 4 percent
of its transactions accounts.
If it were imposed, this supplemental reserve would earn
interest.

Any depository institution
issuing transactions accounts
or nonpersonal time deposits
will have the same discount

and borrowing privilege at the
Federal Reserve as member
banks, effective immediately.

Establishes Fees For
Fed Services

The Federal Reserve is
required to establish fees
for its services, such as currency and coin services, check
clearing and collection, wire
transfers, and automated

clearing house services. The
fees will take effect by
October 1, 1981, and the
Board must publish a proposed fee schedule by
October 1, 1980.

Expands Power O f
Thrift Institutions

The Act authorizes Federal
credit unions to make residential real estate loans. It
also gives S&Ls greater lending flexibility and higher loan

ceilings, expands their investing authority, permits them to
issue credit cards, and gives
them trust powers.

The Act reduces the number
of disclosures that must be
made under truth in lending
(TIL) requirements and eliminates agricultural credit from

TIL coverage. It also requires
the use of "simple English
phrases" to describe key
terms in such disclosures,
effective March 31, 1982. BE]

Requires Reserves
O n All Transactions
Accounts At
Depository
Institutions

Permits Board
T o Impose
Supplemental
Reserves

Provides Access
T o Discount Window

Simplifies Truth In
Lending Disclosures
A n d Financial
Regulations

FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F A T L A N T A




The Act provides for an
eight-year phase in of reserve
requirements for depository
institutions which are not
Federal Reserve members and
a four-year phase down of
previous reserve requirements
for member banks.

5

V

The Discount Rate Under
the Federal Reserve's New
Operating Strategy
by Harry

Brandt

The discount rate is one of three main
instruments the Federal Reserve uses to
implement monetary policy. T h e others
are open market operations (i.e., purchases and sales of U. S. Government securities in the open market) and changes
in reserve requirements. Under the
Federal Reserve Act, the directors of
each Reserve Bank establish the discount
rate, subject "to review and determination" of the Board of Governors.
Wide interdistrict interest rate differentials, however, are unrealistic in an
interdependent economy. Therefore, national considerations have long determined uniform discount rate setting,
although in the early history of the System each Reserve Bank set its discount
rate according to its District's banking
conditions. The usual practice, in recent
years, is for the Reserve Banks to initiate
a discount rate change, subject to the
Board of Governors' approval. 1 Sometimes, however, the Board of Governors
will inform the Banks, indicating its
readiness to approve a discount rate
change if a request is forwarded. This
chain of events typically takes place when

' E v e n if the rate is not c h a n g e d , R e s e r v e B a n k s m u s t e s t a b l i s h t h e d i s c o u n t
rate every 14 d a y s "or oftener if d e e m e d n e c e s s a r y by t h e B o a r d . " It
s h o u l d a l s o be noted that, w h i l e the d i s c u s s i o n is in terms of the d i s c o u n t rate, there are actually four different rates related to s p e c i a l provis i o n s in t h e Federal R e s e r v e A c t .

6




the Board of Governors wants to couple
a discount rate change with a reserve
requirement change or another significant monetary policy action.
O n c e a discount rate change anywhere
in the System goes into effect, the rate
soon becomes uniform for all Reserve
Banks—usually within a few days. T h e interval depends o n the various Boards of
Directors' meeting schedules or time to
set up telephone meetings.
The last time a split discount rate
was in force for an extended period was
in the spring and early summer of 1956.
San Francisco and Minneapolis raised
their discount rate from 2Vi to 3 percent,
while the other ten Banks went only to
23A percent. This split lasted four months,
after which the ten brought theirs to
Minneapolis and San Francisco's level.
The Board of Governors does not approve all the rate requests it receives.
In 1978 (the last full year for which p u b lished figures are available), the Board
of Governors approved 7 Systemwide discount rate increases and, on 14 separate
occasions, disapproved a total of 25 requests (including 4 from Atlanta).
Under what circumstances will the
discount rate be changed? T h e only policy directive in the Federal Reserve Act
is that discount rates should be established "with a view of accommodating
M A R C H / A P R I L 1980, E C O N O M I C REVIEW

*

k

*

Although the discount rate, once considered the Federal Reserve's only policy tool, has
gradually been surpassed as a policy instrument by open market operations and changes in
reserve requirements, it still serves an important function in making technical adjustments
and policy announcements. In the Fed's new operating procedure (announced on October 6,
1979), the Board indicated that the discount rate would be managed flexibly to discourage
excessive member bank borrowing.

commerce and business." W h e n the
Federal Reserve was first organized, some
Fed officials felt that, in order to discourage member bank borrowing for profit,
the System should follow the Bank of
England's policy of making the discount
rate a penalty rate; i.e., setting it higher
than what commercial banks charge their
customers. The Federal Reserve, however,
rejected the penalty notion, thinking that
a penalty rate would not be a real deterrent to member bank borrowing at the
discount window.
The guiding principle the Federal
Reserve followed in its early days was
to set the discount rate low enou gh to
permit member banks to meet legitimate
credit demands and high enou gh to
discourage borrowing for speculative
purposes. Fine in theory, this principle
broke down in practice. The Federal
Reserve concluded, especially during
the stock market speculation of the
Twenties, that a discount rate high
enough to curb speculation would hurt
legitimate business and agriculture.
Federal Reserve officials also learned—
as early as the 1921 recession—that during
recessions (when private credit demands
are weak) discount rate reductions do not
cause member banks to increase their
borrowing. This explains, starting in the
early Twenties, why the Federal Reserve
FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F A T L A N T A 7




turned increasingly to open market
operations, which—unlike discount borrowing—are at the initiative of the
Federal Reserve rather than the member
banks. 2 (Another motive was a desire
to boost Federal Reserve earnings.)
Therefore, while the discount rate was
initially considered the Federal Reserve's
only policy tool when the Federal Reserve
System was organized, open market operations surpassed it in importance by the
mid-Twenties. 3 Changes in reserve requirements were not available until the
Federal Reserve Act was amended in 1933
and 1935.
In recent years, the discount rate has
been changed for two principal reasons.
O n e is a technical adjustment; the second
is for its announcement or signal effect.
A technical adjustment is when the discount rate is changed to bring it into line
with short-term market interest rates,
especially the Federal funds rate (i.e., the
rate that commercial banks pay to borrow
short-term funds mainly from each other
and overnight). W h e n the Federal funds
2

O p e n market o p e r a t i o n s a n d d i s c o u n t i n g both i m p a c t o n the v o l u m e of
bank reserves. W h e n the F e d e r a l R e s e r v e b u y s s e c u r i t i e s in the market,
it creates bank reserves that b a n k s c a n u s e to lend or invest. W h e n the
F e d e r a l R e s e r v e lends at t h e d i s c o u n t w i n d o w , reserves are a l s o created.
However, these reserves h a v e to be repaid to the F e d by the b o r r o w i n g
b a n k s , but reserves created t h r o u g h o p e n market o p e r a t i o n s d o not.
^ D i s c o u n t i n g , w h i c h a c c o u n t e d tor three-fifths of R e s e r v e B a n k credit
between 1920 a n d 1927, a c c o u n t e d for l e s s than 2 percent between 1970
a n d 1978

rate moves up sharply but the discount
rate stays unchanged, member banks are
encouraged to borrow from Reserve
Banks. It then helps to increase the discount rate in order to encourage banks
to use alternative sources for covering
their temporary needs. 4 For example,
as the Federal funds rate moved up during most of 1978, the discount rate moved
up more or less in tandem, but with a
lag (see Chart 1).

TABLE 1
DISCOUNT RATE
Effective

New

Date

Rate %

CHANGES

Change

%

T y p e of
Change

1978
January 9

6V2

y2

Signal

M a y 11

7

V2

Technical
Technical

July 3

7%

%

A u g u s t 21

7%

y2

S e p t e m b e r 22

8

%

Signal
Mainly Technical

October 6

8V2

V2

Mainly Technical

November 1

91/2

1

Major Announcement

1979
J u l y 20

10

'/z

Mainly Technical

A u g u s t 17

10 Vz

V2

Signal

S e p t e m b e r 19
October 8

11

V2

12

1

Technical
Major A n n o u n c e m e n t

Chart 1

- 15
1980
F e b r u a r y 15
-

10

F R B D i s c o u n t Rate
- 5

1978

1979

D i s c o u n t rate f o l l o w e d f u n d s rate c l o s e l y in '78

The Board of Governors approved a
total of 13 discount rate changes since
1978 (see Table 1). One-half were for
technical or mainly technical reasons
(i.e., to adjust the discount rate to other
interest rates). Three rate changes involved major announcements: the 1percent increase in November 1978, the
1-percent increase in October 1979, and
the 3-percent surcharge on borrowings
by large banks in March 1980. The November 1978 discount rate change was
part of a broad Treasury-Federal Reserve

c o m e to the w i n d o w for two reasons. S o m e
i.e.. the c o s t of b o r r o w i n g at the w i n d o w v e r s u s
other m e a n s , others, by n e e d T h e b a n k i n g
c a n b e r e i n f o r c e d t h r o u g h o p e n market

8




13

Signal
Major A n n o u n c e m e n t

' T h r e e - p e r c e n t s u r c h a r g e to b o r r o w i n g s b y b a n k s of $ 5 0 0 million or more
for more than o n e w e e k or for m o r e than four w e e k s in a n y c a l e n d a r quarter
B a s i c rate w a s not c h a n g e d .

1980

" 3 % s u r c h a r g e on frequent b o r r o w i n g s by large b a n k s .

"Individual b a n k s actually
are motivated by profit—
the c o s t of b o r r o w i n g by
s y s t e m ' s need to b o r r o w
operations.

M a r c h 14

program announced at the White House
to strengthen the dollar in foreign exchange markets. It was one of several
measures, including Treasury actions, to
counter the decline in the dollar in the
foreign exchange markets. The October
1979 discount rate change was part of a
major Federal Reserve package to counter
the excessive money and credit growth,
while the surcharge imposed in March
was among many fiscal-monetary actions,
which included a wide ranging formal
restraint program on business and consumer credit. Four other discount rate
increases, classified as "signals," were
timed to coincide with a tightening in
open market policy.
What effect does a discount rate
change have? Some still interpret a discount rate increase to be tantamount to a
general increase in interest rates, and
vice versa. In principle, a technical,
market-following change in the discount
rate in itself should have little or no
M A R C H / A P R I L 1980, E C O N O M I C REVIEW

direct effect on other short-term interest
rates (such as Federal funds, Treasury
bills, the prime rate, etc.). However, if
market participants view the change as
signaling a shift in monetary policy, market rates may well increase or decrease
following a discount rate change, especially if the new discount rate is reinforced by other Federal Reserve tightening
or easing actions. 5 The direct result of a
discount rate change is to raise or lower
the cost of borrowing at the discount
window. But this affects relatively few
member banks, since there is still a fairly
strong tradition against borrowing—especially among smaller banks. Last year,
for example, only 22 percent of member
banks in the Sixth District borrowed from
this Bank (and much of this was for only
one or two weeks); nationally, the percentage was slightly higher.
In sum, much of the effect of a discount rate change is probably psychological. It puts the public, banks, and
foreigners on notice about monetary
policy intentions. Sometimes it is a signal
that the Federal Reserve is about to
tighten or ease credit through other
means. In many instances, however, the
change is merely an adjustment to market rates and has no policy implications.
The Federal Reserve's New Operating
Strategy and Its Relationship to Discount
Rate Setting
In the series of actions announced last
October 6, the one announcement that
received most of the attention and discussion was the adoption of a new open
market operating strategy. The October 6
Federal Reserve press release announced:
" . . . a change in the method used to
conduct monetary policy to support
the objective of containing
growth
in the monetary aggregates. . . . This
action involves placing greater emphasis in day-to-day operations on
T h e f i n a n c i a l c o m m u n i t y s o m e t i m e s interprets a d i s c o u n t rate c h a n g e
to m e a n it is the forerunner of other p o l i c y a c t i o n s , therefore, a d i s c o u n t
rate c h a n g e may b e f o l l o w e d by a c h a n g e in the p r i c e s a n d y i e l d s of
securities.

FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F A T L A N T A




the supply of bank reserves and less
emphasis on confining
short-term
fluctuations in the federal funds rate.
The press release went on to explain:
"Under the new procedures adopted . . .
for the conduct of open market
operations . . . wider day-to-day or
week-to-week
fluctuations in the
federal funds rate may occur . . .
Over recent years, the FOMC has
fixed a relatively narrow range for
the federal funds rate. To help
achieve better control over the
reserve base, it will now be
necessary—within
broad limits—to
permit wider fluctuations of that
rate if so determined by market
forces.'/
Remember that open market operations
involve the buying or selling of U. S.
Government securities in the open market by the New York Federal Reserve
Bank (through its Trading Desk). A n d in
simple terms, a purchase of securities increases the level of bank reserves, while
a sale of securities reduces bank reserves.
What the Federal O p e n Market C o m mittee ( F O M C ) , in effect, said on
October 6 was: T h e bottom line is money
growth. 6 We have been setting money
growth targets and telling the Trading
Desk to supply the reserves needed to
hit our money growth targets but to use
the Federal funds rate as its day-to-day
operational guide. 7 In a different setting
this technique might have kept monetary
growth within our targets. But in a period
of high interest rates and high inflation,
our operating technique may have contributed to excessive supplies of money
and credit. (Many had been saying all
along that the Federal Reserve could not
hit its monetary objectives under the

«The F e d e r a l O p e n Market C o m m i t t e e ( F O M C ) is the F e d e r a l R e s e r v e ' s
p r i n c i p a l m o n e t a r y p o l i c y m a k i n g g r o u p a n d c o n s i s t s of the s e v e n
m e m b e r s of t h e B o a r d of G o v e r n o r s a n d five F e d e r a l R e s e r v e B a n k
P r e s i d e n t s T h e other s e v e n B a n k P r e s i d e n t s a l s o attend the F O M C
m e e t i n g s regularly
B a n k reserves affect the ability of b a n k s to e x p a n d d e p o s i t s by e x p a n d i n g l o a n s a n d investments.

9

p r e - O c t o b e r procedure, noting that,
w h e n the two were in conflict, the Federal funds rate target w o n out over the
monetary objective.)
Chart 2 shows that this was basically
correct. For example, over the period
plotted (January 1978-October 6, 1979),
the weekly Federal funds rate almost
always stayed within the F O M C target
ranges, but M - 1 growth was often outside
their target ranges. In other words, the
funds target was met far more often than

Chart 2
While Federal funds rate stayed
regularly within target range . . . .

Percent

. . M t g r o w t h was frequently outside targets.

the monetary objective. U n d e r the old
(former) Federal funds targeting approach, the Desk (by buying securities
in the market) tried to hold the Federal
funds rate d o w n within a narrow target
range at a time w h e n the d e m a n d for
reserves, money, and credit increased
rapidly. In this way, the Federal Reserve
a c c o m m o d a t e d this demand by increasing
the supply of reserves. This technique,
therefore, has been held partly responsible for the excessive monetary growth
of the last several years. (It might have
10




been avoided if the Federal funds rate
had been allowed to increase faster than
it had.) Furthermore, because it was
widely watched for its policy significance,
the funds rate under this approach
acquired additional importance in the
market.
T h e Federal Reserve had reasons it
d e e m e d persuasive for sticking to a narrow Federal funds target for so many
years. It felt sharp fluctuations in the
Federal funds rate might disturb financial
markets. Furthermore, many in the Federal Reserve thought for a long time that
a g u i d e different from the funds rate
w o u l d not help achieve any better c o n trol of the money supply.
However, on O c t o b e r 6, 1979, the
F O M C instructed the Desk to use a
different method to conduct policy, aiming for a 4!/2-percent money (M-1) growth
for the final three months of 1979. A n d
here is the p u n c h line: It further advised
the Desk that, in supplying the reserves
consistent with this money growth, it
need not feel constrained by the Federal
funds rate as long as that rate from week
to week stayed within a wide 111/2- to
15 1 /2-percent range (previously, the range
had been a narrow 1114- to 11 3 A-percent,
shown in Table 2).
H o w does the new reserve control
strategy work? It is technical and still
experimental in some ways. 8 The essence
of the new p r o c e d u r e is that w h e n it
looks as if money will grow faster than
the C o m m i t t e e targeted, the Board staff
lowers the ( n o n b o r r o w e d ) reserve path,
so that the Desk supplies less reserves

' B a s i c a l l y , it starts with a c o n s t r u c t i o n of a reserve p a t h c o n s i s t e n t with
the F O M C ' s m o n e y g r o w t h objective. T o do this, the staff must first
c a l c u l a t e the v o l u m e of reserves n e e d e d to s u p p o r t the g r o w t h of M-1
a n d M - 2 d e s i r e d by the F O M C T h i s j o b of c o n s t r u c t i n g a reserve path
is c o m p l i c a t e d b y the fact that b a n k s are required to set a s i d e h i g h e r
p e r c e n t a g e s of reserves a g a i n s t certain t y p e s of d e p o s i t s than a g a i n s t
others; another is that different s i z e d b a n k s are required to set a s i d e
different p e r c e n t a g e s of reserves a g a i n s t the s a m e t y p e s of deposits.
It is further c o m p l i c a t e d by the fact that a l l o w a n c e s h a v e to b e m a d e
for reserves a g a i n s t M-1 a n d M - 2 deposit c a t e g o r i e s , s u c h a s reserve
requirements a g a i n s t l a r g e n e g o t i a b l e C D s , a n d c o m p l i c a t e d by the
bank's ability to get reserves at the d i s c o u n t w i n d o w S o m e o b s e r v e r s
view reserves o b t a i n e d at the w i n d o w a s an offset to reserves a b s o r b e d
t h r o u g h o p e n market s a l e s A n o t h e r view h o l d s that s i n c e m a n y b a n k s
borrow o n l y reluctantly, their c o m i n g to the w i n d o w b r i n g s them u n d e r
Federal R e s e r v e d i s c i p l i n e , f o r c e s them to a d j u s t their l o a n a n d investment portfolio, a n d in time l e a d s to a s l o w i n g in m o n e y g r o w t h

M A R C H / A P R I L 1980, E C O N O M I C REVIEW

TABLE 2
OPEN MARKET OPERATIONS

FOMC
Meetings

POLICY*

M, T a r g e t
(Or newly defined M1-A)

Fed Funds
Constraint

%

%

1979

Feb./Mar.
Mar./Apr.

10

February 6

3-7

M a r c h 20

4-8

A p r i l 17

4-8

M a y 22

0-5

Apr./May
May/June

J u l y 11
A u g u s t 14

2V2-6V2

July/Aug.

4-8

S e p t e m b e r 18

3-8

Aug./Sept.
Sept./Oct.

October 6

Sept./Dec.

N o v e m b e r 20

4Vfe
5

111/4-113/4
11 '/2-15'/2

Nov./Dec.

11 V2-15'/2

1980
January 8-9

4-5

Dec./Mar.

11 Mr 15 V6

F e b r u a r y 4-5

41/2

Dec./Mar.

11 1/2-15'/2

9 3 /4-1OV2

93/4-10'/2
93/>-IOV2
92/4-10'/2
103/4-11'/4

' T h e F O M C also sets longer run monetary targets, not shown, and short-run
targets for M2 (and more recently M1-B)

than originally planned, and vice versa.
In other words, the idea is to supply just
enough reserves to support a volume of
deposits that will achieve whatever
money growth rate the F O M C wants. This
approach concentrates on controlling
bank reserves and reduces the previous
emphasis on the Federal funds rate by
allowing it to fluctuate within a much
wider range. 9
How does the new strategy relate to
discount rate setting? The answer, at this
point, is not clear-cut. The Federal Reserve's October 6 press release said:
"The Board indicated that, within the
general framework of existing
policies
regarding the administration of the
discount window, the discount rate
would be managed flexibly to discourage excessive member bank
borrowing."
«Under the new procedure, the funds rate has b e c o m e a by-product of
the s u p p l y i n g of reserves, a n d member bank reserve needs are no longer
automatically a c c o m m o d a t e d by the Desk within a narrow range of
Federal funds rate movements.

FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F A T L A N T A




This seemed to suggest the discount
rate would be changed frequently in the
future and raised to discourage excessive
borrowing. However, the discount rate
actually remained unchanged from
October 6 to February 15, although
member bank borrowing averaged at
higher levels since O c t o b e r 6 than last
summer and the spread between the discount rate and Federal funds rate
widened.
The Board of Governors, until midFebruary, felt no further rise in the discount rate was needed since the money
supply slowed substantially in November
and December and banks were making
adjustments such as tightening lending
terms. 10 M o n e y growth, however, picked
up slightly in January and accelerated in
February, while credit growth accelerated
in the first two months of 1980. So, on
February 15, the Board of Governors
raised the discount rate another full
percentage point to show Federal Reserve
resolve in the face of accelerating inflation figures. The Board of Governors in
its announcement indicated its special
concern that the latest oil price increases
"may lead to further destabilizing pricing
decisions" and that these developments
reinforced the need to keep money and
credit under firm control.
The most recent discount rate change
occurred on March 14. Although the basic
rate stayed at 13 percent, large banks
using the window frequently were subject
to a 3-percent surcharge on their borrowings. This first surcharge ever was
imposed after discount borrowings had
climbed above $3 billion and the Federal
funds rate, above 16 percent. The discount rate change took a back seat,
however, to the many new credit restraint
measures under the Credit Control Act of
1969. A study is now under way at the
Board of Governors to evaluate the relationship between the new open market
operating procedures and the discount
rate.
US
'"February 11, 1980, letter from C h a i r m a n Volcker to Senator Proxmire.

11

Home Building in
the Early 1980s
by B. Frank

King

Though we are well into 1980's second
quarter, we still await the "Recession of
1979." Many analysts have seen the unexpectedly strong residential construction
activity of 1979 as a partial explanation
for the unexpected strength in the overall
economy. After all, sharp declines in
residential building have foreshadowed
each recent recession and have accounted for substantial chunks of lost
real output during those recessions.
Lately, however, signs of weakness in
housing have dominated. Housing starts
have dropped sharply since last October.
Their fourth-quarter level of 1.6 million
(at an annual rate) was 15 percent below
the third-quarter rate and 30 percent
below the fourth-quarter 1978 rate. By
February, starts were d o w n another 12
percent from December to a 1.3 million
annual rate. Recent further increases in
mortgage rates have dramatically slowed
mortgage borrowing, and home sales are
down sharply. Will declines in this pivotal
sector continue, or will it snap back in
1980 for a good year? A n examination of
home building seems in order.
To begin, we can narrow our scope. A
major part of multifamily residential
building for the past couple of years has
been either government-subsidized, low
income apartments, or multi-unit condominiums. O n l y a small increase in the
government-subsidized units is presently
budgeted. T h e multi-unit condos are
subject to much the same set of influences as single-family home building
because both types of housing are
12




owner occupied. Other multifamily
building may fluctuate, but it makes up
a relatively small portion of residential
construction. So the search for forces
that lead to changes in residential c o n struction can be concentrated on singlefamily home building.
A n analogy may aid in examining home
building in detail. In looking at housing
demand, it helps to make a distinction
much like that generally made between
climate and weather. Climate generally
refers to more or less stable long-run
influences; weather changes rapidly
around the long-term trend. The climate
of Georgia, for example, is usually described as subtropical, but when a winter
storm comes down from the northern
plains, Georgia weather can be downright
arctic.
The climate for new home demand and
output is principally provided by four
elements: household formations; age distribution of additional households; loss
of housing units through destruction,
conversion, or dilapidation; and income
growth. These together determine the
number of separate households that need
separate housing units, the proportion of
these households that normally want
single-family units, the part of the housing stock that must be replaced in each
period, and the amount of income households have for acquiring these units. To
be complete, one would add the singlefamily vacancy rate to the list of factors
in the climate, but this rate is and is likely
to continue to be so low and stable that
M A R C H / A P R I L 1980, E C O N O M I C REVIEW

Home building activity was unexpectedly strong in 1979, but starts have fallen sharply since
last October. Household formations, the age distribution of new households, loss of units, and
income growth, the major factors which determine long-term demand for new homes,
promise healthy home building for the next several years. But short-term factors, such as
mortgage rates and sharply reduced income growth, are strong enough to temporarily halt the
long-term trend.

it has minimal significance. Those elements are not entirely independent of
one another or of weather fluctuations,
but they are very much under the influence of long-run demographic, social,
and economic trends.
A second group of factors make up
housing's weather. They vary fairly widely
over short periods. Similar to short-term
variations in weather, large variations in
these factors may overcome the long-run
climate and cause floods and droughts
in residential construction. In assessing
short-term housing variations, one generally looks first at credit flows or
mortgage rates. The latter is more relevant today because improvements in
financial markets allow anyone who is
willing and able to pay the market rate
to get housing credit without exceptional
trouble. Short-term variations in real
income, housing costs themselves, and
expected capital gains from housing assets
are also important short-term influences
on housing output.
As we enter the 1980s, what does the
housing climate look like? A m o n g the
long-term factors, household formations
should push housing demand strongly for
several years. Additional households are
likely to have greatest impact on singlefamily units. Lower destruction rates and
slower income growth should counteract
some of the strength provided by household formation.
Long-term factors are favorable. New
households have been forming at a high
rate for several years. The annual rate
FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F A T L A N T A




was around 1.2 million in the late 1960s
but jumped to over 1.7 million in the late
1970s. It is expected to stay there in the
early 1980s.1 A large jump in the number
of single-person households and the
A v e r a g e A n n u a l C h a n g e in H o u s e h o l d s
(millions)

1965-

1970-

1975-

1980-

1985-

1970

1975

1980*

1985*

1990*

'Projected

H o u s e h o l d f o r m a t i o n s are b o o m i n g

movement of baby boom members into
their 20s account for this household formation bulge. The bulge is not likely to
run its course for a while because both
basic factors behind it are continuing.
As members of the baby boom move
into their late 20s and 30s, they enter
' H o u s e h o l d formation projections used in this analysis are from projections
series B f o u n d in the U. S. Bureau of the C e n s u s , "Projections of the
N u m b e r of H o u s e h o l d s a n d Families, 1979 to 1995," Current Population
Reports, Series P-25, No. 805, W a s h i n g t o n , D. C . , M a y 1979.

13

the age group that normally goes to market for a single-family house. Patterns
observed in both 1960 and 1970 censuses
indicate that about 3 out of 10 households in the under 25 age group live in
single-family houses. But 6 of 10 in the
25-34 age group and 8 of 10 in the 35-44
group live in these units. 2 In these days,
it is not necessarily (indeed, not often) a
new house that younger families buy, but
their purchases of existing houses often
start the upgrading process that results
in older families' purchases of new
housing.
The movement of the baby boom generation into its late 20s and 30s partially

0

200

400

600

(thousands)

Net additional h o u s e h o l d s per year 1980-1985

Additional h o u s e h o l d s will boost single family

demand

accounts for the jump in the share of
single-unit houses from around 55 percent of newly built residential units in the
early 1970s to around 70 percent during
the past 3 years. This distribution will
most likely hold stable as more than 70
-'An analysis of these tendencies is f o u n d in T h o m a s C . M a r c i n , " T h e Effects
of D e c l i n i n g Population G r o w t h on the D e m a n d for H o u s i n g , " U. S. Forest
Service, G e n e r a l Technical Report N C - 1 1 , W a s h i n g t o n , D. C . , 1974.

14




percent of net change in households over
the next 5 years occurs in the 25-44 age
group.
The basic demographic push to housing
demand in the early 1980s seems likely to
get some resistance from a declining rate
of loss of housing units and from slow
income growth. The rate at which housing units were taken out of the housing
stock slowed in the 1970s. This rate seems
likely to slow further as remodeling and
rehabilitation become more widespread.
Travel cost increases put a premium on
close-in locations where housing already
exists. Many units in these places will
be refurbished rather than demolished
and replaced. Thus, a further reduction in
the loss rate and the need for replacement units seem likely. Further, typical
projections indicate slow growth in labor
force, in capital investment, and in productivity in the early 1980s. This adds up
to slow real income growth. Both of
these forces would somewhat retard but
not overcome the influence of high
household formations. The climate still
seems likely to be conducive to housing demand similar to that of 1977 and
1978, when housing starts were in the
neighborhood of 2 million units.
But the current weather is terrible.
Short-term influences appear, on balance,
to provide strong resistance to housing
output. Credit costs have climbed despite
the vastly improved channels for mortgage availability. Mortgage rates finally
climbed above the inflation rate in
October, after being lower through most
of 1979. They have continued to climb
this year. These phenomena can be expected to cut down the number of
housing units demanded.
Income growth has dropped below its
long-term trends, making it less likely
that people will feel that they can afford
to buy houses. Real disposable income
was down in each quarter of 1979 and
dropped sharply again in the early part of
this year. Slower income growth, combined with higher mortgage rates, makes
MARCH/APRIL

1980, E C O N O M I C

REVIEW

Percent C h a n g e
(Annual Rate)

1978

1979

1980

Real d i s p o s a b l e i n c o m e has g e n e r a l l y d e c l i n e d

it less likely that potential home buyers
can qualify for loans, even if they are
willing to take the plunge.
At the same time, however, the rates
of increase in prices of both new and
existing homes went negative in the
fourth quarter of 1979 before rebounding
somewhat in January. Ordinarily, one
would think that slower rates of increase
in the prices of homes would support
demand for new housing units. But in
today's economy, part of the motivation
for purchasing housing is expected capital gains. Lower rates of price increase
may also reduce expectations of capital
gains and work against new single-family
and c o n d o m i n i u m demand. All this leaves
the influence of recent slowing in the
inflation of housing prices in a fog, but
the opposing forces involved may come
close to cancelling each other. Recent
slowing in housing inflation probably will
have little impact on the number of new
homes or apartments built for a while.
Government programs are not currently
a depressant. O n the other hand, they
are not much of a stimulus in the singlefamily sector. The status of plans for
FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F A T L A N T A




housing support this year is in limbo.
Recent increases in mortgage rates have
brought many calls for massive support.
At the same time, the move of the
Congress and the Administration toward
a balanced budget limits enthusiasm for
more housing support spending on that
front. There are even recent indications
that some home building trade groups
are ready to support restrictive fiscal
policy at the expense of housing support.
Where does that leave housing production? A strong underlying demographic
push is likely to be only somewhat mitigated by slower-than-usual long-term income growth and reduced losses from
the housing stock. However, short-term
forces are now overwhelming this strong
push. When the short-term weather improves, when mortgage rates fall, and
income growth rebounds, the slowdown
we are now experiencing is likely to be
followed by a rebound to 1977 and 1978
levels of starts in real residential construction spending. Early this year, the
consensus forecast saw 1.4-1.5 million
starts in 1980, with a slow first half and
a rapid rebound in the second. These
forecasts generally assumed that interest
rates would reach their peak early in the
year and that income growth would increase late in the year.
We already know that the early interest rate peak has not taken place. Most
forecasters now see less strength late in
the year than they previously did. Housing production, in all probability, will
slow more than previously expected; the
slowdown will continue longer, and the
rebound may be less sharp than expected, particularly if efforts to balance
the Federal budget fail and advances in
defense spending induce larger deficits
and continued upward pressure on interest rates. It looks more and more as if
starts in 1980 will be below the earlier
consensus range, and the rebound that
is waiting in the wings will stay there
until very late in the year if it comes at
all during 1980.
SU
15

Basic Questions
on Food Prices
with

Q

Gene D.

Sullivan

What happened to food
prices last year?

In the first half of the year, food
prices were jumping at a 12- to
15-percent annual rate. That primarily reflected the rapid run-up in meat

prices that accompanied a reduction in
beef output. By midyear, however, other
meats had become more plentiful and
food price increases were held below 7
percent during the second half of 1979.
For the year as a whole, the rate averaged 10.7 percent.

How does our current diet
translate into actual
dollars spent?

A

Meats, poultry, and fish account
for the major portion of food

jexpenditures, and that portion
las increased in recent years. Soft drinks
and prepared desserts showed the
sharpest increase. Eggs, fats, and sugars
declined the most in percent of actual
expenditures, possibly reflecting consumer concern about the healthfulness
of these products.
16




P e r c e n t of T o t a l
Food Expenditures
1965

1977

Meat, p o u l t r y , a n d fish

32.7

34.3

Dairy products

12.3

Vegetables

12.6
12.2

Grain products

12.3

11.9
11.9

Fruits

7.4

7.7

Eggs, d r y l e g u m e s , a n d n u t s
Soft d r i n k s , p u n c h e s , d e s s e r t s

5.2

4.3

3.1

3.8

Alcoholic beverages

3.7

3.7

Fats a n d o i l s
Sugar, syrup, jelly, a n d c a n d y
Other foods

3.5

2.9

3.1
4.1

2.6
4.6

100.0

100.0

M A R C H / A P R I L 1980, E C O N O M I C REVIEW

After a 10.7 percent increase in 1979, food prices will probably rise more slowly this year. Beef
prices may continue to climb, with the breeding stock still in the rebuilding process. Supplies
of most foods should be plentiful, but escalating marketing costs (especially energy costs) will
likely prevent an actual downturn in retail prices.

Are there any signs that our diet is changing
and if so, how is the food industry adjusting?

In general, we have been eating fewer sweets, fats, starches,
and eggs and more fruits, green
eafy vegetables, meats, nuts, and beverages.
At the same time, consumers have
included more ready-prepared and fast
food items in their diet. Most observers
associate this trend with smaller families
and more working housewives who have
less time for preparing traditional homecooked meals.
The food industry has responded to this
change by including more processing,
packaging, and convenience in items
sold at grocery stores. Fast food establishments, of course, have proliferated.
Since fast food restaurants generally
specialize in less expensive types of meat
(hamburger, chicken, pork), the consumption of higher priced meat (steak,
lamb) has declined. In fact, we may be
in the midst of a more permanent shift
in demand from steak to poultry, pork,
and lower priced beef.
FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F A T L A N T A




Food Consumption
Per Person
(in P e r c e n t )
1965

1977

A. Dairy p r o d u c t s

30.1

28.3

B. V e g e t a b l e s

18.4

18.2

C

15.8

17.0

12.8

14.1
7.7

F. A l c o h o l i c b e v e r a g e s

9.1
2.3

G. Eggs, d r y l e g u m e s ,
and nuts

3.8

3.2

H. S u g a r s , s y r u p ,
jelly, and c a n d y

3.9

3.0

2.9

2.5

0.9

1.2

100.0

100.0

M e a t , p o u l t r y , a n d fish

D. Fruits
E. G r a i n p r o d u c t s

I. Fats a n d o i l s

3.4

J. S o f t d r i n k s , p u n c h e s ,
and desserts

/A
/
i

/
/

N,
B\
\

L

I
ir
H\
cX

/ /

/ \

National Diet by
Food Groups,

C

/

1

1977

17

How much of what we pay
for food goes for the
raw product?

A

The supply of raw products
influences food prices most in

cases where marketing charges
are relatively low, as in eggs, meats, and
dairy products. So even though consumers spend only one-fourth as much
on eggs as on vegetables in the average
weekly food budget,an increase in egg
prices would have nearly as much impact on food prices as a comparable
increase in vegetable prices because of
the larger share of the farm value in the
retail price for eggs.
For the same reason, an increase in
wheat prices has far less direct impact
on retail food prices than a comparable
rise in meat prices. Grain products, of
course, also make up a much smaller
proportion of the total expenditures on
food. Grain supplies, however, exert
their greatest influence indirectly through
their impact on supplies of meats and

What makes up
the "marketing
spread" (the difference between the farm
value and the retail price
of food), and how does it
compare with farm product
prices in contributing to
total food price inflation?

Q

18




Farm Value as a Percent
of R e t a i l F o o d P r i c e , 1 9 7 8

Eggs
Meat p r o d u c t s
Dairy products
Fats a n d oils
Fruits a n d v e g e t a b l e s
Baking and
cereal p r o d u c t s
Average for market
b a s k e t of f a r m f o o d s

livestock products. A shortage of grains
can make feed costs so expensive that
livestock production is reduced, thereby
indirectly affecting a component of the
diet that accounts for nearly half of the
total food expenditure. The chart shows
the proportion of the "farm value" (raw
product price) in the retail price for
various foods.

Basically, marketing spread c o n sists of processing, packaging,
- - shipping, and various merchandising expenses. The largest component
in these expenses is labor cost. Marketing spread, on average, accounts for 60
percent of total food expenditures. These
costs range from as much as 80 percent
for cereals and bakery products to as
low as 35 percent for eggs. Since it comprises such a large portion of the total,
marketing spread clearly is the major
factor in determining food prices. The

A

M A R C H / A P R I L 1980, E C O N O M I C REVIEW

lf the price of the raw
product depends largely
on supply, what factors
influence how much farmers produce?

Q
A

Weather variations are a major
factor, but they are largely un-

I predictable and outside the
control of farmers. But farmers can influence the amount of land they plant
for crops and the numbers of livestock
available for meat production, and they
regularly do so in response to their o w n
assessments of potential for profit. For
c r o p producers, these decisions are made
o n c e for the w h o l e year, in most cases,
and cannot be quickly adjusted, even
t h o u g h prospects may c h a n g e markedly
d u r i n g a p r o d u c t i o n cycle. If the price
of corn drops sharply after the c r o p is
planted, for example, farmers are limited
in the adjustments they can make to

40 percent w h i c h consists of the farm
value is, of course, heavily influenced by
supply fluctuations. These fluctuations
tend to deliver scattered, cyclical jolts
to f o o d prices, as in early 1978, for
example, w h e n a severe freeze destroyed
a large portion of the vegetable crop,
and in 1974, w h e n a major drought
sharply r e d u c e d grain production. T h e
marketing sector, o n the other hand,
produces more widespread, continuous
changes that are keyed to costs of labor,
energy, and inventory financing.
FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F A T L A N T A




c h a n g e that particular crop. Similarly, if
prices rise abruptly, farmers must wait
until next year to increase their p r o d u c tion by planting more acres.
January surveys showed that farmers,
influenced by higher prices at year-end
planned to make the following changes
in 1980 plantings (compared to 1979):
Barley

+11%
+10%

Wheat
Sorghum
Corn

+ 5%
+ 4%

Rice

-

1%

S u g a r beets

-

3%

Oats

- 5%
-10%

Sunflowers

After e x p a n d i n g 11 percent in 1979,
planned acreage of soybeans, an important source of livestock feed, is unc h a n g e d , but total grain supplies will
increase this year if farmers carry out
their intentions.

•

Processing

•

Packaging

•

Shipping

•

Marketing

Marketing Spread:

Total
-4T

V
of
V aa ll uu ee of
Raw Farm
p r o d u c t
Product

.
—
—

,_
F o o d

Price

on average, a c c o u n t s for
60% of t o t a l f o o d e x p e n d i t u r e

19

The Soviet grain embargo was
expected to substantially
increase U.S. grain stocks and
push prices downward, thus possibly
discouraging production. Why, then,
have grain prices remained relatively
strong following the embargo?

Although the embargo interrupted the export of a large
quantity of grain, brisk international demand has supported grain prices.

l see that cattle
production is beginning to pick up,
but pork and poultry are
slowing down. Aren't they
all equally dependent on
grain prices? What factors
cause the difference in production rates?

Q

20




In spite of recent gains, the dollar's value
during January and February remained
below its year-earlier level against most
of the currencies of important customers
for U. S. grain. So in the world market,
U. S. grain continued to be relatively
cheap. Some international demand reflects rising income levels in developing
countries, and some is undoubtedly
attributable to overall uncertainty accompanying the current international tension.
If this tension escalates in the future, it
could threaten world access to grain
supplies.

The year-end inventory of cattle shows an increase in young
beef breeding stock, but it will
De another two years before the calf
crop grows. That means that cattle production will not increase in 1980, thereby
keeping upward pressure on meat prices.
Responding to this shortfall in beef
supplies, pork and broiler producers have
filled the void with all the product the
market will take at price levels that remain profitable. But the rise in grain
prices since mid-1979 will discourage
further expansion of pork and poultry
unless they also rise in price. Already
broiler production has slowed from the
12- to 15-percent growth in 1979 to a
2- to 6-percent increase.
Pork producers had planned to expand
output further in 1980, but increased

A

M A R C H / A P R I L 1980, E C O N O M I C REVIEW

í

And what about livestock
production? Is it just as
inflexible as crop output?

Q

Livestock producers have more
options for reducing output on
short notice, since all forms of
livestock have salvage value if slaughtered

A
A

marketings of breeding stock suggest
that recent hog prices as much as 30
percent below year-ago levels are causing
some producers to reconsider their
intentions for expansion. Producers will
be watching grain and pork prices carefully in the coming months to guide pork
production levels during the rest of 1980.
Increased grain prices generally affect
pork and poultry more than cattle. Even
though hogs and poultry are more efficient grain users than cattle, cattle can
consume forages that hogs and chickens
cannot. Beef of somewhat lower quality
can be produced without any grain at all.
Thus, some beef can and will continue
to be produced even if grain should become too expensive to use for animal
feed.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ATLANTA




at nearly any stage of the production
process. Options to expand output are
much more limited, however, since actual
expansion of animal numbers requires
periods ranging from several months for
poultry up to five or six years in the case
of cattle.

Beef:

Pork:

Broiler:

Y o u n g breeding
stock increasing,
but another 2
years before
calf crop grows
much

30% price drop
causes r e c o n sideration of
increased
marketing

Rate of increase
has slowed

Increased grain prices generally
affect pork and poultry more than
cattle.

21

lf we finally have a recession,
what will happen to food
prices? How do they usually
)ehave during contractions and
expansions of the economy?

Q

Traditionally, recessions have
caused consumers to conserve
on food expenditures by shifting to lower priced foods (from beef to
potatoes and beans, for example, or at
least to pork and chicken). Currently,

Some early forecasts called for
lower food prices in 1980. Why?
Does this still seem likely?
A lower rate of increase is most
likely. At the outset of 1979, it
_ was evident that beef produc- •
tion would decline sharply as herd liquidation ceased and as some young animals
were withheld from markets for herd
rebuilding. At that time, pork production had not yet expanded much, and it
was questionable if the poultry production capability could be expanded fast
enough to avert an overall meat shortage.
A year later, the numbers of hogs and
chickens have been expanded sufficiently
to provide an ample supply for foreseeable demand. Farmers harvested a
bumper grain crop in 1979, and indications are that they will expand plantings
of most grains in 1980. Supply prospects
are considerably brighter than in 1979.
If this situation continues, then, we can
expect to see some lowering, at least in

A

22




however, pork and chicken consumption
is already high as a result of the beef
shortage. Also, the government assistance
programs now available to the poor and
unemployed effectively buffer the shifts
that these groups were forced to make
before these programs. If a person receives a fixed food stamp allotment each
month, for instance, he need not curtail
beef or meat consumption during a recession. Hence, the swings in food consumption are not nearly as erratic during
recent business cycles as they have been
in the past.

prices of raw food products. However,
the rapid escalation in energy costs (a
large component of the marketing
spread) could prevent most of that downturn from reaching the retail level.
The major unknown in this equation is
the extent of increased food demand
U n a n s w e r e d E q u a t i o n for 1980:

Good

Energy

Supply
(but)

Costs
(

rising)

International
Conditions
(uncertain)

_

F o

•
•

° d Price
slowdown?
acceleration?

that may result from unsettled international conditions. As I mentioned earlier, uncertainty created by international
tensions and threats of military actions
tends to support commodity prices, especially grains. The threat of an outbreak
of military hostilities between major
world powers could so escalate the demand for food and fiber commodities
that prices would really soar.
M A R C H / A P R I L 1980, E C O N O M I C REVIEW

Commentary
• • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • H i

Thoughts on the
Underground Economy
by Charles

J.

Haulk

Unmeasured, untaxed economic activity may be growing faster than the "regular" economy. If
so, and if it was as large as 15 percent of national GNP by 1978, this "underground economy"
could be significantly distorting the economic models used for forecasting. As a result, fiscal
and monetary policy makers run the risk of thinking they are restricting the economy when
they may actually be overstimulating it.

Because of the fascination and infatuation
of the public and the economics profession with official statistics about the
economy, we have had our heads set
spinning with the numbers released over
the past several months. Productivity
growth has c o m e to a halt, consumers
have virtually stopped saving, and we
are faced with horrendous inflation at a
time when the unemployment rate is high
by historical standards. Real growth
creeps along, and our potential for
growth seems increasingly limited. A n d
yet despite all the negative news and the
predictions of recession, the economy
shows amazing resilience in the face of
lower real incomes, high debt burdens,
and rising taxes.
Why have so many highly skilled, wellintentioned students of the economy
decided to modify their recession forecasts? Primarily because it is becoming
increasingly obvious that the official
statistics used in the economic analysis
understate growth levels of output and
income and overstate the degree of
FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F A T L A N T A




hardship due to unemployment. The
reason for the distortion, many economists believe, is the existence of a large
and evidently growing underground
economy.
What is the Underground Economy?
The " u n d e r g r o u n d e c o n o m y " is economic activity that avoids official detection or measurement. Income from this
activity is unreported, unmeasured, and
U n d e r g r o u n d Economic Activity Includes:

•

Gambling
•

Smuggling
•

Prostitution
•

Drugs

•

Unreported
C a s h - O n l y Sales
•

Unreported Tips

•

Barter

23

untaxed. Persons engaged in producing
illegal goods or services, such as bookmaking, smuggling, prostitution, illegal
drugs, etc., earn incomes which must be
hidden in order to prevent detection of
the illegal activity. Crimes, such as
robbery, fraud, or embezzlement, are
essentially redistributive and do not add
to total output.
Persons engaged in otherwise legal
production of goods and services but
who can in some way cover up part or all
of their income and thereby reduce
their taxes are also part of the underground economy. Restaurant owners who
don't ring up cash sales, the friends
who help each other remodel their
homes, the painter who paints for cash
only and reports whatever income he
thinks fit, and the mechanic who fixes
his neighbor's car for cash are all examples of underground economic
activities.
The underground economy which is
accounted for by illegal activity is, by
admission of law enforcement officials, a
growing sector. Whether the sector is
growing faster than the measured economy is not provable. However, much of
the activity provided by this sector is
services whose demands increase as
incomes rise. In that regard, it seems
reasonable to argue that income earned
from these illicit activities is growing
faster than the overall economy.
The underground economy which is
accounted for by production of legal
goods and services but is d o n e so that
income is hidden is probably due to the
desire to increase after-tax income.
There may be instances of a person hiding income so that a spouse or other
interested party would not know the full
extent of that person's income.
The income and product in the underground economy generated in the
tax-avoiding sector are arguably growing
faster than the overall economy. In the
simplest e c o n o m i c terms, a person's
willingness to participate in the underground economy and thereby engage in
24




the illegal act of under-reporting income
is based on his perceptions of the benefits and costs of such an act. W h e n the
benefits in terms of after-tax income
gained from not reporting income are
greater than the costs, then the temptation to underreport income becomes
stronger.
The Benefits and Costs of Participating
The benefits are obvious—a higher
standard of living with no increase in
work effort or considerable gains in
wealth can be achieved by more work
effort when the tax rate is zero on the
income thus earned. The benefits of
underpaying taxes will grow relative to
income as the tax rate increases. The cost
of underpaying taxes is the probability of
being caught and convicted multiplied by
the punishment for violating the tax
laws. Since much of the cost of being
caught is the shame and embarrassment
of the arrest and trial, that cost is virtually independent of the amount of tax
underpayment. As a result, an increase in
tax rates as income rises will increase
benefits much faster than costs.
Another element that has contributed
to an increase in the benefits of underpaying taxes relative to the costs has
been a lowering of the public's assessment of the benefits it derives from
government spending. This is particularly
true in the area of transfer payments
(subsidies, aid to the needy, etc.).
Government spending for national
security, public safety, public health,
and, to a lesser degree, education is almost universally accepted. When a large
share of tax dollars is used for transfer
payments, the degree of taxpayer support
dwindles. Because individuals perceive a
smaller benefit from growing government
spending, their willingness to pay taxes
is further reduced.
Evidence of the growing incentive to
cheat the tax collector is abundant. In
1950, 25 percent of personal income
minus transfer payments went to pay income taxes, sales taxes, etc. By 1960,
M A R C H / A P R I L 1980, E C O N O M I C REVIEW

that figure was 33 percent; in 1970, 41
percent. As of 1979, taxes paid by individuals amounted to 45 percent of
personal income minus transfer payments.
Granted transfer payments recipients do
pay some taxes, however, the rise from
25 to 45 percent has been borne mainly
by persons who receive no financial assistance from the government. Although
not as much as in Great Britain or
Sweden, the U. S. taxpayer is increasingly
saddled with higher tax rates.
Because it is nearly impossible to avoid
property taxes and because not all citizens are property owners, most people
who avoid taxes do so primarily by not
reporting income. Sales taxes can be
avoided, but probably to a much lesser
extent, in terms of the total dollars involved than income taxes.
How D o We Know It's There?
Economic theory very clearly suggests
the existence of a growing underground
economy. What evidence do we have to
support the contention? The fact that
participants in the underground are trying to escape detection means that measuring income and product will be
extremely difficult and frustrating. Nonetheless, several attempts have been made
and other work continues toward that
end.
The IRS has made a "direct" estimation
of unreported income in 1976 through
the use of results obtained on the Taxpayer Compliance Audits, which are far
more thorough than the normal audit. 1
Their results indicate that unreported
income in 1976 was between $100 and
$135 billion, or about 10 percent of measured personal income that year.
The IRS admits, however, that their
more rigorous audit cannot track down
income for which there are no records
kept. Nor is there any good way to estimate the income of nonfilers. Their

limited data also did not permit any
strong conclusions about trends in
noncompliance.
Several writers have tried to estimate
the size of the underground economy
through indirect means. The first widely
publicized attempt by Peter Gutmann 2
was based on certain assumptions about
the growth in the use of currency.
Gutmann argues that the rapid increase
in the amount of currency in circulation
relative to the amount of money in
checking accounts is indicative of increased use of underground transactions.
Gutmann's estimate for 1976 put unmeasured output and income close to 11
percent of measured output.
Continued rapid growth of currency
relative to demand deposits since 1976
would make the 1980 underground larger
than 11 percent of the measured economy under Gutmann's assumptions.
Edgar Feige 3 obtains estimates of total
currency and checking account transactions in the economy and, by making
certain assumptions regarding the growth
in checking account transactions for
purely financial purposes, estimates the
size of the underground economy. Feige
asserts that the unmeasured output in
1976 was as high as 19 percent of total
output and, by 1978, was up to 27 percent
of total output. His procedure would
predict further growth in 1979.
Using a more conservative procedure
than Feige, we have estimated that the
underground economy grew from 9
percent of reported G N P in 1970 to at
least 15 percent of G N P in 1978 (see
Appendix). Our procedure assumes that
all underground activities are done with
cash; Feige does not. None of the estimates mentioned attempts to estimate
the role of increased use of barter.
If the underground economy were an
unchanging proportion of G N P , we

2

'Estimates of I n c o m e U n r e p o r t e d o n Individual Tax Returns.Department of
the Treasury, Internal R e v e n u e Service, Publication 1104(9-79).

FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F ATLANTA




Peter G u t m a n n , " T h e Subterranean E c o n o m y , " Financial Analyst Journal,
N o v e m b e r / D e c e m b e r 1977.
'Edgar Feige, " T h e Irregular E c o n o m y : Its Size a n d M a c r o e c o n o m i c Implications," W o r k i n g Paper 7916. Social Systems Research Institute.

25

391.1 bil.$

Estimated

88.4

unreported
1970

0

+442%

1978

Estimated unreported activity grew
m u c h faster t h a n r e p o r t e d G N P .
2446.7 bil.$

+227%

Reported
1970

1978

would not need to be terribly concerned
with it because it would not distort relationships between important aggregate
e c o n o m i c variables (output, income,
spending, etc.) over time.
Because our estimates and others show
the underground economy to be growing
relative to the regular or measured
economy, we would expect changes in
the measured variables (GNP, income,
and employment) to be smaller than the
true changes. The effects of the unmeasured forces, then, are expanding.
Effects of the Underground Economy
on the Regular Economy
What important effects does the underground economy have on the regular
economy, and what are the implications
for e c o n o m i c policy?
First, a large and rapidly growing
underground economy means that actual
income and employment are larger than
official statistics show and that resources
are more fully utilized than unemployment rates indicate.
Second, because tax is avoided in the
underground economy, initially, a lower
price will be established for goods and
services produced in the underground
economy, drawing activity away from the
regular economy, a shift unintended by
policymakers and perhaps detrimental
to long-run economic growth.
26




Third, those who produce in both the
regular and underground economy are
likely to be relatively more efficient in
their underground pursuit because the
after-tax reward is higher per hour of
work effort. This would imply that productivity might be higher in an underg r o u n d industry than in the same field
in the regular economy.
Fourth, the fact that a much larger
volume of final transactions is being carried out than the G N P figures show
means that the estimates of money velocity and velocity increases are too
low. 4
Fifth, a disproportionate share of the
tax burden is borne by those who are not
engaged in the underground economy.
Sixth, if the share of unmeasured income going to investment or net exports
is increasing, it would mean a rise in the
savings rate in the unmeasured economy.
In turn, this would be consistent with a
decline in the measured savings rate
while the true overall savings rate was
unchanged or fell less than the published figure.
Seventh, because there is no price
index for unmeasured activity, we cannot
be sure what the inflation rate is in that
sector. If the inflation rate is lower in the
underground economy, then the rates of
inflation reported for the measured
economy would substantially overstate
real earnings losses.
Finally, all of this suggests that the
e c o n o m i c models used for forecasting
may well be technically and theoretically
deficient.
Policy Implications
These developments clearly have substantial implications for e c o n o m i c policy.
To the extent that fiscal and monetary
policy is expected to reduce unemployment and raise living standards in the
long run, those policies could be massively overstimulative if measured income
•'Because money velocity (the average n u m b e r of times a given monetary unit
is spent d u r i n g a given time period) is based partly o n the total a m o u n t of
s p e n d i n g activity.

M A R C H / A P R I L 1980, E C O N O M I C REVIEW

and employment are understating the
true levels. If growth is measured low,
in other words, e c o n o m i c policies are
likely to be aimed too high—in pursuit
of growth which is thought to be missing
but is merely unmeasured. Stimulation of
aggregate demand would then worsen
inflation at a time when resources are,
for all practical purposes, fully employed.
Monetary policy might also be deluded
into maintaining an overstimulative
stance. The setting of money growth rate
targets is based on certain assumptions
about the way money growth and nominal G N P growth are related. These
assumptions are based largely on past
performance. A rapid growth in the
underground economy would mean that
a given rate of money growth is supporting a much larger growth in activity than
the monetary policymakers believe. In
other words, money growth which policymakers would view as slow enough to

APPENDIX
In order to estimate the underground
e c o n o m i c activity, we start with the assumption that all underground activity
uses c a s h . We then obtain turnover rates
for currency, using the Feige assumption
that each unit of c u r r e n c y is used, on
average, 125 times before it has to be
destroyed because it is unfit for circulation. T h e annual turnover rate is estimated
by dividing the average length of the life
of c u r r e n c y into 125 to get the number of
transactions per bill annually. We then
multiply the turnover rate by the outstanding c u r r e n c y in each denomination to
obtain the value of total c u r r e n c y transactions.
From 1950 to 1965, the ratio of currency to G N P fell at a rate of 2.9 percent
per year. After 1965, the rate of decline
was 0.9 percent per year. T h e decline in
c u r r e n c y per dollar of G N P in the 1950s
was due to several factors, including
FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K O F A T L A N T A




G O V ' T . P O L I C I E S c o u l d be
aimed too high because . . .
A C T U A L G R O W T H (including
u n m e a s u r e d a c t i v i t y ) is
higher than . . .
MEASURED GROWTH, thus
overstimulating the
economy and increasing
inflation.

restrain growth could, in fact, not be
restrictive at all.
What can be done? In the absence of
hard data for the underground economy,
it would be difficult to try to take it into
account precisely in policy formulation. It
may be that monetary and fiscal policy
will have to focus more on prices and
interest rates directly, since data on income, output, and spending have become less reliable.

growth in the use of demand deposits by
c o n s u m e r s . However, with the massive
growth in c h a r g e cards and other technological advancements, one would expect that the need for currency would
continue to decline relative to G N P , at
least at the 1950-65 rate.
T o estimate illicit transactions involving currency, we calculate the e x c e s s of
c u r r e n c y in years after 1965 by a s s u m i n g
that without illicit d e m a n d s for currency,
the ratio of currency to G N P would have
continued to fall at 2.9 percent annually.
T h e transactions carried out through the
use of the e x c e s s currency are a s s u m e d
to be underground activity.
T h i s procedure is very conservative in
that it puts underground activities at zero
in 1965, which is very doubtful. But our
purpose in this article is to show the trend
of underground e c o n o m i c growth, so we
are not c o n c e r n e d with the absolute
levels per se. Using more liberal a s s u m p tions, we would get higher levels and
faster growth rates.
27

i

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta
Federal Reserve Station
Atlanta, Georgia 3 0 3 0 3
Address Correction Requested

<




Bulk Rate
U.S. Postage
PAID

Atlanta, Ga.
Permit 292