View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Monetary Policy
and Racial
Unemployment Rates
M A D E L I N E
TA O Z H A

Z A V O D N Y

A N D

Zavodny is a senior economist and policy adviser in the
regional section and Zha is an assistant vice president
in the macropolicy section of the Atlanta Fed’s research
department. They thank Tom Cunningham, Bob
Eisenbeis, and John Robertson for helpful comments.

D

URING THE COURSE OF THE CURRENT EXPANSION, THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE AMONG AFRICAN

AMERICANS HAS FALLEN TO THE LOWEST LEVELS SINCE THE GOVERNMENT BEGAN REPORTING
THE SERIES IN

1972. WHEN THE FEDERAL OPEN MARKET COMMITTEE (FOMC) BEGAN

RAISING INTEREST RATES IN JUNE

1999 TO FORESTALL INFLATIONARY PRESSURES, CONCERN

mounted that monetary policy moves might slow the
pace of economic growth, undoing the employment
gains minorities and other disadvantaged groups
made during the 1990s. Implicit in such concern is
the idea that these groups will be disproportionately
affected by an economic slowdown. Although it is
widely believed that tighter monetary policy leads to
slower economic growth and higher unemployment
rates in the short to medium run, it has not been
established that the effects of monetary policy differ
across racial groups or that changes in monetary
policy have a larger effect on the black unemployment rate than do changes in inflation or other
macroeconomic fluctuations.
Previous research suggests that monetary policy
changes may have different effects on blacks than
on whites. One study found that increases in the
money supply during the period from 1974 to 1987
led to larger declines in the unemployment rate of
white males than of black males and concluded that
monetary policy actions have results that tend to
favor white men (Abell 1991). However, the study

also concluded that the effects of monetary policy
on black women appear similar to the effects on
white men, perhaps because of educational gains by
black women. Another study found that the U.S.
Federal Reserve’s conduct of monetary policy during the 1970s—a period when the Fed focused on
slowing the growth rate of the money supply in
order to reduce inflation—significantly widened the
gap between the unemployment rates of blacks and
whites (Hull 1983).
This article assesses whether monetary policy
shifts have different effects on the black unemployment rate than on the overall unemployment rate.
The focus is on the unemployment rate among
African Americans because this minority group
tends to have relatively high unemployment rates.
Most of the analysis that follows compares the black
unemployment rate to the overall unemployment
rate instead of to the white unemployment rate
because the overall unemployment rate captures
labor market conditions for the entire labor force. In
addition, because whites make up about 85 percent

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

1

of the total labor force, movements in the white and
overall unemployment rates tend to mirror each
other. The monetary policy shifts examined are
“exogenous” monetary policy moves, or changes in
the federal funds rate not accounted for by movements in other macroeconomic series. This crucial
distinction between any change in monetary policy
and an exogenous change is explained further below.
This article also examines the effects of exogenous changes in inflation, output, and other macroeconomic factors on the overall and black
unemployment rates. Using econometric techniques,
structural relationships between the black and
overall unemployment rates and changes in various
macroeconomic factors, including monetary policy,
are estimated during the period from 1972 to 1999.
The analysis then focuses on the effect of monetary policy on unemployment rates during the
1980s and 1990s.
The next section briefly explores the trends in the
black and overall unemployment rates. A discussion
of how the Federal Reserve conducts monetary policy and why its actions may affect unemployment
rates follows. The econometric model used to estimate the relationship between unemployment rates,
monetary policy, economic growth, and other variables is then detailed, and the results are discussed.
Results from the econometric model used in this
analysis suggest that exogenous changes in monetary policy have different effects on the unemployment rate among blacks than on the overall
unemployment rate. The black unemployment rate
tends to be more sensitive to cyclical fluctuations
and slightly more responsive to exogenous monetary policy moves than the overall unemployment
rate is. However, the examination of the effect of
exogenous monetary policy shifts during the 1980s
and 1990s indicates that exogenous monetary policy moves caused the black unemployment rate to
increase by no more than the same percentage as
the overall unemployment rate during the recessions in the early part of the two decades and
caused black unemployment to fall relatively more
than the overall unemployment during the late
1990s. In other words, the results do not indicate
that the unpredictable component of monetary
policy had significantly more adverse effects on
blacks during the 1980s and 1990s than on the
total population and may even have had positive
net effects on blacks.

Trends in Unemployment Rates
t is well known that the unemployment rate, or
the ratio of unemployed, active job seekers to
employed plus unemployed persons, is higher

I
2

for blacks than for whites. Chart 1 shows the unemployment rates for blacks, whites, and the total labor
force aged sixteen and older during the period from
1972 to 1999. The ratio of blacks actively seeking
jobs to the black labor force is clearly well above the
comparable ratios for whites and the overall labor
force during the entire period. The declines in the
black unemployment rate during the 1980s and
1990s expansions appear steeper than the drops in
the other unemployment rates, suggesting that the
racial unemployment gap may have narrowed during
those periods.
Another stylized fact is that the unemployment
rate of blacks is more cyclical than the unemployment rate of whites. During the 1981–82 recession,
for example, the black unemployment rate rose by
more than 5 percentage points, and the white unemployment rate rose by slightly less than 3 percentage points. As economist Alan Blinder (1987) put it,
when the economy catches a cold, blacks get pneumonia. Chart 2 displays the difference between the
black unemployment rate and the white and overall
unemployment rates in percentage points. As the
chart indicates, the difference between the black
and white or overall unemployment rates tends to
expand during recessions and narrow during expansions. This cyclical pattern is particularly clear during
the recessions in the early 1980s, when the differences between the black and other unemployment
rates rose sharply.
Potential reasons for these differences in unemployment rates across racial groups include differences in average educational attainment and
experience as well as discrimination against minorities. Blacks tend to have fewer years of completed
education, on average, than whites, and less-educated
workers tend to have higher and more cyclical
unemployment rates than more-educated workers
do (Hoynes 2000; Stratton 1993; Thurow 1965).
Similarly, the number of average total years of work
experience and tenure at a given employer is lower
among blacks than among whites, and unemployment rates are higher and vary more over the business
cycle for less-experienced workers.
Blacks are both more likely to be laid off and to
experience longer periods of joblessness after being
laid off than whites (Kletzer 1991; Moore 1992).
These differences tend to hold at all points in the
business cycle but become exacerbated during recessions. An analysis of employment data from large corporations by the Wall Street Journal concluded that
employment of blacks fell during the 1990–91 recession while whites, Asians, and Hispanics made
employment gains at large companies during the same
period (Sharpe 1993). The U.S. General Accounting

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

C H A R T 1 Unemployment Rates by Race, 1972–99

20

Rate

Black Unemployment Rate

10

Overall Unemployment Rate

White Unemployment Rate
1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

Note: Shown are six-month moving averages of unemployment rates for ages sixteen and older. Shaded areas indicate recessions.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics

C H A R T 2 Difference between Black and Overall or White Unemployment Rates, 1972–99
12
Black – White
P e rc e n ta ge P o in ts

10

8

6

Black – Overall

4

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

Note: Shown are six-month moving averages of the difference in the unemployment rates for ages sixteen and older. Shaded areas indicate
recessions.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics

Office (1994) similarly found that blacks were significantly more likely than whites to lose their jobs during the last recession, and blacks also were
unemployed longer, on average, than workers in
other racial and ethnic groups. These two studies
suggested that such differences are not entirely
explained by observable characteristics, such as education, but may be partially attributable to discrimination. Analyses of racial differences in male
unemployment rates have found similar results
(Abowd and Killingsworth 1984; Stratton 1993).
The greater cyclical responsiveness of black
unemployment rates prompts concern that mone-

tary policy actions aimed at quelling inflationary
pressures may have more adverse short-run
effects among blacks than among other racial and
ethnic groups. This analysis therefore examines
whether the black unemployment rate responds
differently than the overall unemployment rate
does when output, inflation, or other macroeconomic factors, including monetary policy, change.
The discussion does not focus on reasons for the
racial unemployment gap but rather investigates
whether the gap fluctuates over the business cycle
and the contribution of monetary policy to any
such fluctuations.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

3

Conduct of Monetary Policy
he Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)
has several tools it can use to influence general economic conditions that may affect
unemployment rates. These tools include the discount rate (the interest rate at which banks can borrow funds from the Federal Reserve), reserve
requirements (which specify what proportion of
deposits banks can loan out), and the federal funds
target rate. Banks can loan out excess reserves
(reserves in excess of reserve requirements) to
other banks in the federal funds market. The federal
funds target is the equilibrium interest rate in this
market desired by the Federal Reserve, and the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York conducts open
market operations (the buying and selling of securities) to help ensure that this target is met.
Changes in any of these tools have myriad
effects on the economy, but the effects are diffuse
and can occur with a substantial lag. Changes in
the discount rate, the federal funds target, or
reserve requirements are believed to first affect
short-term and long-term interest rates and then
affect the amount of money in circulation, measured by M1 and M2. Effects on aggregate output,
as measured by the value of gross domestic product (GDP), usually become observable within
about six months of a policy change, and the
impact on inflation is generally believed to begin
appearing about one year after a policy move.
Effects on unemployment rates occur at about the
same time as effects on GDP but tend to be more
muted than GDP responses. Many economists
believe that any effects of monetary policy on output and unemployment are transitory, whereas
effects on inflation may persist. Some industries
will be affected fairly quickly by policy moves,
such as the interest rate–sensitive construction
and manufacturing industries, while the service
and government sectors may remain relatively
unaffected until the general level of economic
activity changes.
The unemployment rates of blacks and whites
may be affected differently by changes in monetary
policy for several reasons. First, differences in the
industry mix of employment may lead to a differential impact. Blacks are less likely to be employed in
goods-producing industries than whites and are
more likely to work in the government sector,
potentially making blacks less exposed to interest
rates changes.1 However, the lower average level of
tenure among blacks makes them more vulnerable
to losing their jobs when the economy slows if
employers follow a “last hired, first fired” policy.2 As
discussed above, the lower average educational

T

4

attainment of blacks may also make them more vulnerable to economic downturns if employers lay off
less-skilled workers before more-skilled workers.3
A primary goal of the FOMC is price stability,
which is generally believed to be necessary for maximum sustainable economic growth. The FOMC
does not use monetary policy to attempt to influence
race-specific unemployment rates. As FOMC Vice
Chairman Roger Ferguson (2000) said, monetary
policy is a blunt tool that cannot be calibrated to
exempt a particular segment of the economy, such
as the minority labor force.

Methods
his analysis uses Bayesian vector autoregressions (VARs) to examine the relationships
between race-specific unemployment rates,
monetary policy, and other economic variables.
VARs are an econometric technique useful for estimating how variables respond to changes in other
variables. The results of a VAR can be used to predict
how a given variable, such as the unemployment
rate, will change over time in response to a change
in another variable, such as the federal funds rate
target. In a typical VAR model that includes several
variables, the value of each variable is regressed on
previous values of that variable and several other
variables. The econometrician must decide which
variables to include in each equation and how many
lags of each variable to incorporate.
Identifying the relationship between variables in a
VAR requires assuming that some variables do not
help predict future values of other variables. For
example, the unemployment rate of blacks might
reasonably be believed to not affect the federal
funds rate target set by the FOMC because the
FOMC does not determine monetary policy based
on race-specific unemployment rates. Granger
causality tests are an econometric technique that
can be used to test whether a particular variable
helps forecast, or “Granger causes,” another variable.
If a variable does not help predict another variable,
the latter variable is said to be exogenous with
respect to the first variable. In the model developed
here, the federal funds rate and the other macroeconomic variables are exogenous with respect to
the black unemployment rate.
The VAR model estimated here involves seven
equations and is based on the dynamic multivariate
framework developed by Leeper and Zha (1999).
The model includes six variables that are frequently
included in VAR systems used to model macroeconomic fluctuations: a commodity price index (Pcom),
M2 (M), the federal funds rate (R), real (inflationadjusted) GDP (y), the consumer price index (P),

T

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

and the overall unemployment rate (U).4 Because
this analysis also focuses on racial differences in
unemployment rates, the model also includes the
black unemployment rate (Ub). The model can be
represented by the following equations, which are
explained below:
Pcom = α 1 M + α 2 R + α 3 y + α 4 P
+α 5U + α 6 X + e1,
M = β1 R + β 2 y + β 3 P + β 4 X + ε 2 ,

(1)

(2)

R = γ 1 M + γ 2 X + ε 3,

(3)

y = δ 1P + δ 2U + δ 3 X + ε 4 ,

(4)

P = φ1U + φ 2 X + ε 5 ,

(5)

U = χ 1X + ε 6 ,

(6)

and
U b = ϕ 1y + ϕ 2 P + ϕ 3U + ϕ 4 X + ϕ 5Z + ε 7 ,

(7)

where the vector X is a set of lagged variables of
Pcom, M, R, y, P, and U, and the vector Z includes
lags of Ub. The variable εi represents exogenous disturbances in equation (i), where i = 1,…, 7; these
disturbances are random noise.
Estimating this system of equations yields the
vectors of coefficients α, β, γ, δ, φ, χ, and ϕ, which
describe how the variables respond when another
variable changes. Many of these coefficients have
economic interpretations. For example, β1 in equation (2) represents the interest elasticity of money
demand, and γ1 is the money elasticity of monetary
policy as set via the federal funds rate.5
Each equation in the system is based on fundamental economic relationships, which Leeper and
Zha (forthcoming) explore in greater detail. These
fundamental relationships determine which variables

are included and which are excluded in each equation. Equation (1) posits that the commodity price
index is a function of M2, the federal funds rate, real
GDP, the consumer price index (CPI), the overall
unemployment rate, and lagged values of all of the
variables except the black unemployment rate.
Equation (2) is a standard money demand equation
in which the demand for money depends on output
and the interest rate; the equation is estimated in
nominal rather than real terms, as represented by
the inclusion of the CPI on the right-hand side.
Equation (3) describes monetary policy as conducted
using the federal funds rate; the contemporaneous
CPI and real GDP are excluded from this equation
because the FOMC learns the values of these variables with a lag.
Equations (4) through (6) describe the production sector, which is composed of real output,
prices, and the overall unemployment rate. Because
firms need time to change production and investment, the production sector responds sluggishly to
changes in financial factors, represented here by M,
Pcom , and R. Contemporaneous values of money,
commodities prices, and the federal funds rate are
therefore excluded from equations (4) through (6).
These three equations are also ordered recursively,
with contemporaneous values of P and U affecting
y, contemporaneous values of U affecting P, and
only lagged values of variables affecting U.
Equation (7) models the black unemployment
rate, Ub. The black unemployment rate is a function
of its own previous values (Z) and also depends on
current real output, prices, and the overall unemployment rate as well as lagged values of all other
variables. One of the exclusion restrictions imposed
on the system is that the black unemployment rate
does not affect the other variables in the model;
note that the variables Ub and Z do not appear in
equations (1) through (6). The black unemployment
rate is mechanically related to the overall unemployment rate, but changes in the black unemployment

1. In 1999, about 32 percent of whites were employed in mining, construction, manufacturing, transportation, or public utilities,
compared with 28 percent of blacks. Almost 7 percent of blacks were employed in government, compared with 4 percent of
whites (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics 2000).
2. In February 1998, 57.4 percent of blacks had worked for their current employer for less than five years, compared with 56
percent of whites (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics 1998).
3. As of March 1998, about 16 percent of whites aged twenty-five and older had not completed high school, compared to 24 percent of blacks. About 25 percent of whites had a bachelor’s degree, compared with about 15 percent of blacks (U.S. Bureau
of the Census 1998a). An increase in average educational attainment of blacks over the past few decades has narrowed the
racial gap; in 1962, more than 75 percent of blacks had not completed high school and only 4 percent had finished college,
compared with 51 percent and 10 percent of whites, respectively (U.S. Bureau of the Census 1998b).
4. All variables except the federal funds rate and the unemployment rates are in logs.
5. The relationship between the interest rate and money in equation (3) is a quasi elasticity, instead of an elasticity, because the
federal funds rate is in levels, not logs. The coefficient on the M2 variable captures the elasticity as a percentage point change
instead of the traditional percentage change.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

5

rate should not cause changes in the overall unemployment rate. These assumptions were strongly
supported by Granger causality tests.
The Bayesian econometric method detailed by
Sims and Zha (1998) was used to estimate the system
of equations with monthly data from January 1972 to
December 1999 (The box on page 15 gives the data
sources). The Bayesian method imposes two types of
priors (or initial assumptions). The first prior is
designed to dampen the influence of distant lags;
using this prior means that more recent data effectively “matter more” than older data. The second
prior is used to induce similar long-run trends in the
variables. Using these priors does not influence the
nature of the results, as demonstrated by Robertson
and Tallman (2000). Rather, the purpose of the prior
is to improve the forecast performance of the model.
These issues are discussed further by Sims and Zha
(1998) and Robertson and Tallman (1999).

Structural Relationships
he Bayesian VAR model explained above is
used to address how exogenous changes in
monetary policy and in the other variables in
the model affect the black and overall unemployment rates. These exogenous changes are movements in each of the variables not explained by
movements in the other variables in the model. For
example, the FOMC may change the federal funds
rate in response to a change in commodity prices;
such a movement is not exogenous but is an endogenous response to a fluctuation in another variable.
An exogenous movement in the federal funds rate
occurs when the FOMC decides to tighten or loosen
policy more or less than the change predicted by
movement in the other variables, based on average
comovements between variables during the period
from 1972 to 1999. Exogenous movements in variables are “shocks” or unpredictable movements. The
ε terms in equations (1) through (7) represent these
shocks, which are the focus of this analysis. This
analysis considers the error term in equation (3), the
federal funds rate equation, to be exogenous monetary policy shifts. These shifts cannot be predicted
by movements in the variables in the model.
This analysis examines shocks that are one standard
deviation of the average unpredictable monthly
change from 1972 to 1999 for each series. These
shocks illustrate the effect of the “typical” adverse
shock experienced in each series during this period.
The magnitudes of the shocks in this analysis are as
follows: a 2.0 percent increase in the commodity prices
index; a 43 basis point increase in the federal funds
rate; a 0.13 percent increase in money demand as measured by M2; a 0.41 percent decrease in real GDP; a

T

6

0.20 percentage point increase in the CPI; and a 0.15
percentage point increase in the overall unemployment rate. The effects are symmetric, so the effect of
a favorable shock in each series is the exact opposite of
the unfavorable shocks discussed next.6
Chart 3 plots the dynamic responses of the overall
unemployment rate and the black unemployment
rate to various macroeconomic shocks over a fortyeight-month forecast horizon. The figures describe
the underlying structural relationships in the data,
as estimated by the model. Two-thirds probability
bands (shaded) are attached to the overall unemployment rate. These error bands suggest whether
movements in the overall and black unemployment
rates are significantly different; if the black unemployment rate falls within the error bands on the
overall unemployment rate, the probability that the
movement in the black unemployment rate is not
different from the movement in the overall unemployment rate is about 68 percent.7 The vertical
scale in the figures in Chart 3 is the percentage
point change in the unemployment rates.
The black and overall unemployment rates generally have similar dynamic responses, but the movements in the black unemployment rate tend to be
larger in absolute terms. For example, both the
black and overall unemployment rates first fall and
then rise when an exogenous upward movement in
commodity prices occurs. The black unemployment
rate appears to have a significantly larger response
than the overall unemployment rate to shocks in
commodity prices after about thirty months, and the
difference between the changes in the two series
plateaus at about 0.75 percentage points.
The responses of the overall and black unemployment rates to shocks in monetary policy and output
differ slightly in the middle of the forecast horizon.
In the first few months after a monetary policy or
output shock, the black unemployment rate is virtually unaffected both relative to its initial level and
relative to the overall unemployment rate. The black
unemployment rate begins to rise significantly more
than the overall rate about six months after an
exogenous upward movement in the federal funds
rate or an exogenous downward movement in GDP
growth, and the differences in the changes remain
significant for several months.
Although these differences are statistically significant, they are not large in magnitude. The peak
difference between the changes in the black and
overall unemployment rates in response to a monetary policy shock is less than 0.05 percentage
points, and the difference is similar with regard to
shocks to GDP growth. Given that the black unemployment rate is about twice the overall unemploy-

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

CHART 3
Dynamic Responses of Unemployment Rates across Racial Groups
to Different Structural Shocks

U n e m p lo ym e n t R a t e
( Pe r c e n t )

Commodi t y Mar k et S hock

0.2

Mo n e ta r y P o lic y Sh o c k

0.2

Black

0.1

0.1

Overall

0

0

0

12

24

36

48

0

12

Un e mp lo ym e n t R a t e
(P e rc e n t )

M oney Demand S hock

0.2

0.1

0.1

0

0

12

24

36

48

0

Un e mp lo yme n t Ra te
(P e rc e n t)

CPI S hock

0.2

0.1

0.1

0

0

12

24
Mont hs

48

12

24

36

48

Ove ra ll Un e mp lo yme n t Ra te Sh o c k

0.2

0

36

GDP Sh o c k

0.2

0

24

36

48

0

12

24
Mo n th s

36

48

Note: The shaded areas are the two-thirds probability bands associated with the response of the overall unemployment rate.
Source: Authors’ calculations

ment rate during much of the period from 1972 to
1999, the movement in the black unemployment
rate is actually smaller relative to the underlying
values of the series than the movement in the overall unemployment rate is.
The responses of the overall and black unemployment rates to shocks in the overall unemployment
rate are also statistically different at the beginning
of the forecast horizon. The results shown in Chart 3
indicate that the black unemployment rate will
increase by about 0.2 percentage points if there is a
0.15 percentage point exogenous increase in the
overall unemployment rate, and the difference per-

sists for about two years. Combined with the slightly
larger responsiveness of black unemployment rate
to fluctuations in GDP output, this result supports
the perception that the black unemployment rate is
more cyclically sensitive than the overall unemployment rate. Shocks in the overall unemployment rate
clearly lead to larger responses by both the black
and overall unemployment rates than do the other
variables, particularly in the near term.
The black unemployment rate also responds differently than the overall unemployment rate to shocks
in money demand and inflation, but the differences
do not become significant until about thirty months

6. The effects of favorable shocks would be a mirror image around 0 on the vertical axis in each plot in Chart 3.
7. This analysis implicitly views the response of the black unemployment rate given and compares it with the uncertain response
of the overall unemployment rate. Alternatively, one could attach error bands to the movement in the black unemployment
rate and compare the movement in the overall unemployment rate with those error bands, or one could take into account the
uncertainty associated with both series. Because the forecast errors for the black unemployment rate are larger than those
for the overall unemployment rate, the comparable error bands on the black unemployment rate are larger than those shown
here for the overall unemployment rate.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

7

CHART 4
Macroeconomic
Movements
in the Policy
1980s Shifts
versus
Absent Exogenous
Monetary
Movements Absent Exogenous Monetary Policy Shifts
Changes in Commodity Prices
40
Pe r c e n t

Absent Policy Shocks
20

Actual Data

0

1985

1980

1990

M2 Gr o wth

P e rce n t

14
10
6

1985

1980

1990

Fed e ra l F u n d s Ra te
20

P e rc e n t

16
12
8

1985

1980

1990

GDP Gr o wth

Pe rc e n t

10
6
2
–2
1980

after the shocks have occurred. The differential
effects of shocks in money demand and inflation
appear to persist in the long run but are again fairly
small in magnitude relative to the underlying values
of the series; for example, the difference between
the responses of the black and overall unemployment rates to a money demand shock after three
years is only about 0.75 percentage points.
These structural relationships indicate some differences in the responses of black and overall unemployment rates to exogenous monetary policy and
8

1985

1990

other macroeconomic fluctuations. The timing and
persistence of the differences vary across the shocks,
but all of the differences are quite trivial when compared with the underlying values of the series. Using
the structural relationships between the unemployment rates and shocks in monetary policy and other
macroeconomic variables during the period from
1972 to 1999 generated by the model, the next sections examine the net effect of the implementation of
monetary policy during the 1980s and 1990s on the
overall and black unemployment rates.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

C H A R T 4 (Continued)
CP I

Pe r c e n t

16
12
8
4

Absent Policy Shocks
Actual Data

1985

1980

1990

Ov er al l U n e mp lo yme n t Ra te

P e rc e n t

12
10
8
6

1985

1980

1990

Bl ack Un e mp lo yme n t Ra te

P e rc e n t

22
18
14

1985

1980

1990

Source: Authors’ calculations

Monetary Policy during the 1980s
t the beginning of the 1980s, the FOMC was
engaged in a battle against inflation that
resulted in a double-digit federal funds rate.
At the same time, output growth was sluggish as the
economy struggled out of the 1979–80 recession
before entering the 1981–82 recession. In the early
1980s, both the black and overall unemployment
rates were high relative to the 1970s. However, it is
not clear whether exogenous movements in monetary policy—movements that were not in response
to movements in inflation, output growth, or other
macroeconomic factors—caused these movements
in the black and overall unemployment rates.
The structural relationships from the VAR model
are used to examine what the black and overall

A

unemployment rates and the other variables in the
model would have been during the 1980s absent
exogenous movements in monetary policy. In Chart 4,
the thinner lines give the forecast generated by the
model for each variable if there had been no exogenous monetary policy changes, and the thicker lines
are the realized values of the series, including any
effects of monetary policy shocks.8 The difference
between the two lines represents the effects of
exogenous policy shifts during the 1980s.
The figure for the federal funds rate in Chart 4
indicates that monetary policy was relatively tight
during the period from 1980 to 1983 and then was
loose for most of the remainder of the decade. When
the actual federal funds rate was above the value
predicted by the model, as in 1980–83, monetary

8. It should be noted that Charts 4–9 use the maximum likelihood estimates of the parameters; error bands for the “absent policy
shocks” series in the charts are not shown. Small differences between the two lines in each figure in Chart 4 and Chart 7 (and
small differences between the lines and 0 in Charts 5, 6, 8, and 9) should not be regarded as statistically significant differences.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

9

policy was tight. Although the FOMC raised the funds
rate target several times during the period from
1983 to 1985 in response to macroeconomic trends,
the increases were smaller than those predicted by
the model, indicating that policy was relatively
loose, and policy remained slightly below the forecast for most of the period from 1985 to 1990.
The relatively tight monetary policy during the
first part of the 1980s manifested itself in lower
money growth, slower output growth, and lower
inflation than would otherwise have been the case.
As the panel for GDP growth in Chart 4 indicates,
for example, the increases in the federal funds rate
caused the 1982–83 recession to have been deeper
than it otherwise would have been. Correspondingly,
inflation in the early 1980s was lower than the forecast generated by the model.
The efforts of the FOMC to deal during the early
1980s with the high inflation of the late 1970s
caused the overall and black unemployment rates
to be higher than they otherwise would have been.
The unemployment rates still would have been
high absent exogenous monetary policy moves
designed to reduce inflation, but the actions of the
FOMC led to further increases in unemployment
rates. Chart 5 shows the difference between the
forecast and actual data for the two unemployment series; this chart displays the difference
between the lines in Chart 4. In 1983, for example,
the overall unemployment rate would have been
almost 1 percentage point lower absent exogenous
changes in monetary policy, and the black unemployment rate would have been slightly more than
1 percentage point lower. During the second half

of the 1980s, however, exogenous monetary policy
shocks caused the unemployment rates to be considerably lower than they otherwise would have
been. In 1989, for example, monetary policy
resulted in the overall unemployment rate’s being
almost 0.7 percentage points below its forecast
value, and more than 1 percentage point lower for
the black unemployment rate.
Comparing the lines in Chart 5 suggests that
exogenous changes in monetary policy had slightly
more adverse effects among blacks than among the
total labor force during the early part of the 1980s
and substantially more beneficial effects later in the
decade. The increases in the black unemployment
rate are slightly larger in magnitude than the
increases in the overall unemployment rate, and the
declines are also larger.
Another way to view these effects, however, is relative to the actual values of the series. Because the
black unemployment rate is always substantially
higher than the overall unemployment rate for reasons unrelated to monetary policy, a larger percentage point movement in the black unemployment
rate than in the overall unemployment may not be
larger as a fraction of the underlying values of the
series. Chart 6 therefore shows the percentage difference between the actual unemployment rates
and the forecast values absent monetary policy
shocks relative to the actual values of the series.
Chart 6 suggests that the adverse effects of monetary policy shocks during the 1980s were slightly
smaller for blacks than for the total labor force. The
magnitude of the relative movement of the black
unemployment rate is dampened compared with the

CHART 5
Changes in Unemployment Rates Attributable to Exogenous Monetary Policy Shifts in the 1980s

P er c e nt ag e P oi nt s

1.5

Black Unemployment Rate
0.5

Overall Unemployment Rate
–0.5

1980

1985

Note: Data show the difference between actual and forecast paths.
Source: Authors’ calculations

10

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

1990

movement of the overall unemployment rate during
the period from 1980 to 1985. In the second half of
the decade, the beneficial effects of exogenous
shifts in monetary policy were slightly smaller for
blacks than for the total labor force. Comparing the
two figures, the overall unemployment rate was over
12 percent lower than it otherwise would have been
in 1989, compared with a 10 percent decline in the
black unemployment rate. Monetary policy shocks
therefore do not appear to have had more adverse
effects among blacks than among the labor force as
a whole during the 1980s and were perhaps slightly
less advantageous for blacks during the expansion.

Monetary Policy during the 1990s
he U.S. economy entered a recession in
August 1990 that prompted the FOMC to
lower the federal funds rate by more than
500 basis points between 1990 and 1993. The economy emerged from the recession in March 1991 and
began a period of sluggish growth that slowly accelerated, leading to increases in the federal funds rate
in 1994. As the expansion continued through the
decade, both the overall and black unemployment
rates fell dramatically, as noted earlier.
Monetary policy was relatively tight from 1990 to
1993 and then was loose for the remainder of the
decade. As the monetary policy panel in Chart 7 indicates, the actual federal funds rate target was above
the value predicted by the model early in the decade
and then well below the forecast later in the 1990s.
Tight monetary policy led to lower rates of money
growth than otherwise would have occurred from
1990 to 1995, as the M2 figure in Chart 7 indicates.

T

The shocks in monetary policy affected GDP
growth and inflation in the expected manner. Real
output growth was below the forecast during the
early 1990s, reflecting the impact of tight monetary
policy. GDP growth tended to be slightly above the
forecast after 1996, reflecting the relatively loose
stance of monetary policy during this period. The
effect of tight monetary policy on inflation early in
the decade is apparent during 1992–98, when CPI
inflation was considerably lower than forecast
absent exogenous policy moves. In other words,
exogenous monetary policy moves in the early
1990s led to inflation that was lower than it otherwise would have been during most of the 1990s, but
the effect gradually peters out.
Exogenous movements in monetary policy also
affected unemployment rates. The contractionary
effect of the tight monetary policy during the beginning of the 1990s manifested itself in higher overall
and black unemployment rates for much of the first
half of the decade. However, the looser policy
enabled by the early tightening led to a decline in
the unemployment rate series in the late 1990s relative to the predicted values.
Chart 8 shows the difference between the actual
and forecast paths for the two unemployment rates
in levels. During the 1990s, the effect of exogenous
monetary policy moves was larger on the black unemployment rate than on the overall unemployment
rate, and the difference was particularly large during
the expansion. As in the 1980s, the adverse effects
of the tight monetary policy during the early part of
the 1990s were slightly larger for the black unemployment rate than for the overall unemployment

CHART 6
Percentage Changes in Unemployment Rates
Attributable to Exogenous Monetary Policy Shifts in the 1980s

10

5

Pe rc e n t ag e

Overall Unemployment Rate
0
Black Unemployment Rate
–5

–10

1980

1985

1990

Source: Authors’ calculations

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

11

CHART 7
Macroeconomic Movements in the 1990s versus
Movements absent Exogenous Monetary Policy Shifts
Chang es in Co mmo d ity P ric e s

Pe r c e n t

40
Absent Policy Shocks
20
Actual Data
0

1995

1990

2000

M2 Gr o wth
10

P e rc e n t

8
6
4
2

1995

1990

2000

Federa l F u n d s Ra te
9

P e rc e n t

7
5
3
1
1990

rate. During the later part of the 1990s, exogenous
monetary policy had notably more beneficial effects
on black unemployment than on total unemployment. This chart again suggests that black unemployment rates are more responsive to monetary
policy. Again, however, larger fluctuations in the
level do not necessarily translate into higher percentage changes.
Chart 9 shows the difference between the actual
and forecast paths relative to the actual value each
month. The chart indicates that the tight monetary
policy in the early 1990s had a smaller adverse
effect on the black unemployment rate than on the
overall unemployment rate relative to the values of
the series. In addition, the effects of exogenous
monetary policy were slightly more beneficial for
blacks than for the population as a whole during the
12

1995

2000

later part of the 1990s. Monetary policy appears to
have slightly mitigated the effects of the early 1990s
recession on blacks. In addition, monetary policy
appears to have boosted black employment during
the second half of the 1990s.

Conclusion
his analysis examines whether exogenous
shifts in monetary policy have different
effects on blacks than on the total labor
force. The model used indicates that the black
unemployment rate does respond slightly differently
than the overall unemployment rate to exogenous
changes in the federal funds rate and in other
macroeconomic variables. Although the timing and
persistence of the differences vary across variables,
few of these differences are large in magnitude,

T

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

CHART 7 (Continued)
G DP Gr o wth
6

Pe r c e n t

4
2

Absent Policy Shocks
Actual Data

0

1995

1990

2000

CP I

P e rc en t

7
5
3
1
1995

1990

2000

Ov er al l Une mp lo yme n t Ra te
8

P e rc e n t

7
6
5

1995

1990

2000

Bl ack Un e mp lo yme n t Ra te
16

Pe rc e n t

14
12
10
8

1995

1990

2000

Source: Authors’ calculations

particularly when viewed relative to the actual values of the two series.
The examination of the conduct of monetary policy during the 1980s and 1990s suggests that movements in monetary policy not explained by the
movement of other variables in the model had larger
effects on the black unemployment rate than on the

overall unemployment rate. When scaled by the
actual unemployment rates, however, adverse effects
on the black unemployment rate appear the same
size as or smaller than those on the overall unemployment rate, and beneficial effects appear larger
during the 1990s. The model used here thus suggests that the unpredictable component of monetary

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

13

CHART 8
Changes in Unemployment Rates Attributable to
Exogenous Monetary Policy Shifts in the 1990s (in Levels)

Pe r c e n t a g e Po in t s

1.5

.5

–0.5

Overall Unemployment Rate

Black Unemployment Rate

–1.5

1995

1990

2000

Note: Data show the difference between actual and forecast paths.
Source: Authors’ calculations

CHART 9
Percentage Changes in Unemployment Rates Attributable to
Exogenous Monetary Policy Shifts in the 1990s (Relative to Actual Data)
15

P e rc e n ta ge

5

Overall Unemployment Rate

–5
Black Unemployment Rate
–15

–25
1990

1995

2000

Note: Data show the difference between actual and forecast paths.
Source: Authors’ calculations

policy in the recent past may have mitigated the
effect of recessions on blacks while enlarging the
effect of expansions. In addition, the pattern of
responses to exogenous policy moves suggests that
short-run movements in volatile unemployment
rates series should not necessarily be regarded as
the result of policy moves because the effects of
monetary policy do not become evident for several
months, during which time other events may occur.
This study does not examine why the black and
overall unemployment rates respond differently to
exogenous monetary policy shifts and other macroeconomic fluctuations. Any effects of monetary policy
14

shocks on unemployment rates are likely to be transitory, not permanent. It should also be kept in mind
that exogenous monetary policy is not a primary
cause of the persistent difference between black and
overall unemployment rates, which is due to structural factors. The literature that compares unemployment patterns among blacks to the rest of the labor
force suggests that differences in educational attainment, experience, and racial discrimination may play
a role in the differences in the two series. Future
research should examine further why black unemployment rates appear to show different cyclical
responses than the overall unemployment rate.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

B O X

Data Description
he model uses monthly data from January 1972 to
December 1999 for the following variables:

T

CPI: consumer price index for urban consumers (CPI-U),
seasonally adjusted.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department
of Labor.
Commodity prices: spot commodity price index of
raw industrials.
Source: Commodity Research Bureau.
Federal funds rate: effective rate, monthly average.
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.

quarterly data using the procedure described by Leeper,
Sims, and Zha (1996).
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Department
of Commerce.
M2: M2 money stock, seasonally adjusted, billions of
dollars.
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.
Overall and black unemployment rates: Civilian
unemployment rates (ages sixteen and older), seasonally adjusted.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department
of Labor.

GDP: real GDP, seasonally adjusted, billions of chained
1996 dollars. Monthly real GDP is interpolated from

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

15

REFERENCES
ABELL, J.D. 1991. “Distributional Effects of Monetary
and Fiscal Policy: Impacts on Unemployment Rates
Disaggregated by Race and Gender.” American Journal
of Economics and Sociology 50 (July): 269–85.

ROBERTSON, JOHN C., AND ELLIS W. TALLMAN. 1999. “Vector
Autoregressions: Forecasting and Reality.” Federal
Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review 84 (First
Quarter): 4–18.

ABOWD, JOHN M., AND MARK R. KILLINGSWORTH. 1984. “Do
Minority/White Unemployment Differences Really Exist?”
Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 2
(January): 64–72.

———. 2000. “Improving Federal Funds Rate Forecasts
in VAR Models Used for Policy Analysis.” Federal Reserve
Bank of Atlanta. Photocopy.

BLINDER, ALAN S. 1987. Hard Heads, Soft Hearts.
Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley.
FERGUSON, ROGER W., JR. 2000. “Some Recent Findings
Regarding the Economic Condition of Minority Americans.” Speech presented at the Coalition of Black
Investors, Washington, D.C., September 15.
HOYNES, HILARY. 2000. “The Employment, Earnings, and
Income of Less-Skilled Workers over the Business Cycle.” In
Finding Jobs: Work and Welfare Reform, edited by David
E. Card and Rebecca M. Blank. New York: Russell Sage.
HULL, EVERSON. 1983. “Money Growth and the Employment Aspirations of Black Americans.” Review of
Black Political Economy 12 (Spring): 63–74.
KLETZER, LORI G. 1991. “Job Displacement, 1979–86:
How Blacks Fared Relative to Whites.” Monthly Labor
Review 114 (July): 17–25.
LEEPER, ERIC M., CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS, AND TAO ZHA. 1996.
“What Does Monetary Policy Do?” Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, no. 2:1–63.
LEEPER, ERIC M., AND TAO ZHA. 1999. “Modest Policy
Interventions.” Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Working
Paper 99-22, December.
———. Forthcoming. “Assessing Simple Monetary
Policy Rules: A View from a Complete Macro Model.”
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review for the 25th
Annual Economic Conference in Monetary Policy in
Theory and Practice.
MOORE, THOMAS S. 1992. “Racial Differences in Postdisplacement Joblessness.” Social Science Quarterly
73 (September): 674–88.

16

SHARPE, ROCHELLE. 1993. “Losing Ground: In the Last
Recession, Only Blacks Suffered Net Employment Loss.”
Wall Street Journal, September 14.
SIMS, CHRISTOPHER A., AND TAO ZHA. 1998. “Bayesian
Methods in Dynamic Multivariate Models.” International
Economic Review 39 (November): 949–68.
STRATTON, LESLIE S. 1993. “Racial Differences in Men’s
Unemployment.” Industrial and Labor Relations
Review 46 (April): 451–63.
THUROW, LESTER D. 1965. “The Changing Structure of
Unemployment: An Econometric Study.” Review of
Economics and Statistics 47 (May): 137–49.
U.S. BUREAU OF THE CENSUS. 1998a. Educational Attainment in the United States: March 1998 (Update).
Washington, D.C.: U.S. Bureau of the Census.
<http://www.census.gov/prod/3/98pubs/p20-513.pdf>.
———. 1998b. Percent of People 25 Years Old and
Over Who Have Completed High School or College, by
Race, Hispanic Origin, and Sex: Selected Years 1940
to 1998. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Bureau of the Census.
<http://www.census.gov/population/socdemo/education/
tablea-02.txt>.
U.S. BUREAU OF LABOR STATISTICS. 1998. Employee Tenure
in 1998. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Labor.
<http://www.bls.gov/news.release/tenure.nws.htm>.
———. 2000. Employment and Earnings. Washington,
D.C.: U.S. Department of Labor.
U.S. GENERAL ACCOUNTING OFFICE. 1994. Equal Employment Opportunity: Displacement Rates, Unemployment
Spells, and Reemployment Wages by Race. Report
HEHS-94-229FS. September.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

The Economics
of Check Float
J A M E S M c A N D R E W S
W I L L I A M R O B E R D S

A N D

McAndrews is an assistant vice president in the
research and market analysis group of the New York
Fed. Roberds is a vice president in the macropolicy
section of the Atlanta Fed’s research department. The
authors thank Larry Schulz, Steve Smith, and Larry
Wall for helpful comments on earlier drafts.

A

MERICANS COMMONLY THINK OF THEMSELVES AS LIVING IN A TECHNOLOGICALLY ADVANCED
NATION. ACCORDING TO STANDARD MEASURES SUCH AS COMPUTERS PER CAPITA OR INTERNET
USAGE, THE

UNITED STATES RANKS AT OR NEAR THE TOP OF THE LIST OF DEVELOPED COUN-

TRIES. IN SOME RESPECTS,

AMERICANS’ PENCHANT FOR TECHNOLOGY CARRIES OVER TO THE

area of payments. For example, the United States
ranks near the top among industrialized countries in
use of debit and credit cards. What is surprising to
many observers, however, is that cash and checks
still dominate the overall market for retail payments.
The popularity of cash is perhaps to be expected.
Despite advances in communications technology, cash
remains an economical means of payment for small
transactions and continues to be used widely throughout the world. Among developed countries, however,
only the United States remains dependent on the use
of checks. In 1997 (the last year for which statistics
are available), American consumers and businesses
wrote an estimated 66 billion checks. This figure
amounts to roughly 250 checks per capita annually, or
one check per business day per U.S. resident. The
aggregate value of these checks is estimated at $77.8
trillion, $1,177 per check on average. And despite the
rapidly expanding use of electronic payment media,
the market share of checks remains quite high at 73
percent, measured as a percentage of noncash retail
transaction volume.1 Chart 1 shows that comparable
market shares for Canada and the United Kingdom,
two countries which formerly saw wide use of checks,
amount to only 36 and 31 percent, respectively.2

Certainly the market for retail payments is an
evolving one, and recent years have seen dramatic
increases in the use of electronic modes of payment.
However, the extent to which electronic forms of
payment have substituted for checks is less than
what is often supposed. Chart 2 plots U.S. per capita
usage of checks, payment cards, and direct bank
transfers over the period from 1988 to 1997.
Comparable figures for Canada are also plotted.
Both countries have seen strong growth in the use
of noncheck forms of payment.3 Growth in the use
of direct transfers has been very similar in both
countries while growth in the use of payment cards
(particularly debit cards) has been somewhat faster
in Canada than in the United States. In Canada this
growth has involved extensive substitution away
from check payments, so check usage per capita is
actually falling. By contrast, per capita check usage
in the United States has actually trended upward
slightly over the same period.
The resource costs of maintaining a check-based
retail payment system are considerable. Wells (1996,
5) estimates that the cost of a check payment averages about $1.60 (in 1993 dollars) more than the
cost of a payment made electronically via the Fed’s

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

17

C H A R T 1 Percent of Total Retail Cashless Payments
United States

Checks
73%

Debit Cards
4%

Direct Transfers
(ACH Debits and Credits)
5%
Credit Cards
18%

Canada

United Kingdom
Checks
31%

Checks
36%
Debit Cards
18%

Direct Transfers
(Debits and Credits)
15%

Debit Cards
20%

Credit Cards
13%

Credit Cards
29%

Direct Transfers
(Debits and Credits)
38%

Source: Bank for International Settlements, 1998

Automated Clearinghouse (ACH) system, when the
costs to all parties are taken into account. While ACH
transactions are admittedly imperfect substitutes for
checks, it is instructive to contemplate the potential
resource savings of moving away from the use of
checks to an electronic instrument with the cost
characteristics of the ACH. Multiplying the $1.60 figure by 66 billion checks, an estimate of the savings
from moving all check payments to such an electronic payment instrument would be about $100 billion annually. Even if check usage in the United
States were to fall only to the same levels as in the
United Kingdom or Canada, the resulting annual savings would still be approximately $60 billion.4

The Check Float Hypothesis

W
18

hy do Americans continue to use such an
expensive means of payment? According
to an influential study by Humphrey and

Berger (1990), one reason is the existence of check
float. Check float can be defined as the income
earned by the writer of the check between the time
a check is received as payment and the time it is settled. Until the check clears and settles, the writer of
the check can earn interest on the funds in the
account on which the check is written. Given a large
enough check amount or a long enough delay in
clearing and settlement, the presence of float could
lead payors to prefer checks over less costly means
of payment that clear on a more timely basis. Using
1987 data, Humphrey and Berger estimate that the
average amount of float earned per check more than
compensates for the cost advantage of ACH.
On the basis of these results, Humphrey and
Berger argue that the continued use of checks constitutes an inefficient outcome or market failure in
the following sense. Other things being equal, an
increase (or decrease) in settlement times means

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

Payments Per Capita (Log Scale)

C H A R T 2 Retail Payment Usage in the United States and Canada, 1988–97

1000
Checks, US
Checks, Canada
100
Cards, US
Cards, Canada

10

Direct, US

Direct, Canada

1990

1995

Note: Payment cards include credit and debit cards. Direct bank transfers include automated clearinghouse credit and debit transfers
(United States), bill payments at ATMs (Canada), and direct debits (Canada).
Source: Bank for International Settlements (1993, 1998)

that interest income is simply transferred from a
payor to a payee (or vice versa). Hence, the net or
societal benefit of float is zero. On the other hand,
because people expend real resources (for example,
make use of checks as opposed to less costly means
of payment) in order to appropriate the value of
float for themselves, float can carry a societal cost.
This argument was restated by Lacker (1997), who
argues that the inefficiency associated with the continued use of checks results from a divergence
between private and societal benefits. Under the
current system for clearing and settling checks,
Lacker argues, costly attempts to manipulate check
clearing and settlement times may have a positive
value to private parties (that is, float may accrue to
payor or payee) but have essentially zero value to
society as a whole.
Other reasons have been offered to explain the
continued dominance of the use of checks. Mester
(2000) reviews some of these other explanations.
One possible reason lies in the large fixed cost necessary to implement an electronic payment instrument on a wide scale. Given the sunk costs of much
of the check infrastructure, a high fixed cost for
the electronic means of payment might delay its

adoption for a long time.5 Another potential explanation is the presence of “network effects” in the
use of different payment instruments. It may be,
for example, that no other means of remote payment is as widely accepted as the check, and this
convenience accounts for its continued use. A final
set of reasons points to the characteristics of check
payments that differentiate them from current
electronic methods. These include such characteristics as flexibility of payment initiation, legal
standing, user familiarity, and the automatic presence of a receipt (in the form of a canceled check).
It may be that people simply prefer the bundle of
characteristics offered by the check to other
means of payment.
Given that there is relatively little hard data on
check usage, it has been impossible to sort out the
validity of the competing explanations for the continued widespread use of checks. The check float
hypothesis, therefore, does not suggest that check
use would fall to zero without check float but only
that float continues to offer a key motive for the
continued use of checks. Since the publication of
Humphrey and Berger’s (1990) initial study, a number of research papers have explored the role of

1.
2.
3.
4.

Measured as a percentage of the value of noncash retail transactions, the market share of checks is even higher at 87 percent.
All figures in the paragraph above are from the Bank for International Settlements (1998, 1999).
See Weiner (1999) for an extensive survey of electronic payments in the United States.
These figures represent very approximate calculations and should be interpreted with caution. A more detailed estimate by
Humphrey, Pulley, and Vesala (2000) puts the cost savings from elimination of checks at about $91 billion.
5. Such costs are unlikely to be unique to the United States, however. The discussion below explains how the current system
for check clearing within the United States lessens incentives to undertake investments in electronic payment systems.
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

19

checks in the U.S. payment system. While some of
these studies disagree with Humphrey and Berger’s
conclusions, the issue of check float remains central
to their analyses. Below, the discussion reviews a
number of these studies and their treatments of the
float issue, using an analytical framework developed
by McAndrews and Roberds (1999). In addition,
many papers have discussed proposals for accelerating the movement away from the current, primarily check-based retail payment system to a more
electronics-based payment system. Some of these
proposals are analyzed in the discussion below, with
particular emphasis on their effects on check float.
While the framework of this discussion does not allow
identification of any
single “best” path to
increased efficiency
in the U.S. retail payment system, it does
Among developed countries,
illustrate some of the
only the United States
trade-offs that proremains dependent on the
posals for reform
must encounter.
use of checks. In 1997,

American consumers and
businesses wrote an estimated 66 billion checks.

How Does Check
Float Arise?

here are several
key features of
the U.S. check
payment system that
contribute to the creation of float. Essentially, these features define certain
property rights of the people and institutions
involved in the check payment process. A brief
description of these will be helpful before proceeding further.
The first feature is that the check payment system
is, like the U.S. banking system, highly decentralized.
There are approximately 10,000 banks and savings
institutions, as well as 10,000 credit unions (henceforth collectively called banks), in the United States.
Thus, it is likely that if person A (let’s call her
Andrea, the “payor”) pays person B (Bob, the
“payee”) by check, then Andrea will pay by a check
drawn on a different bank from Bob’s bank. If Andrea
and Bob had accounts at the same bank, then the
check could be settled as an “on-us” item. That is,
the bank would simply debit Andrea’s account and
credit Bob’s account in the amount of the check.
Since on-us checks remain the exception within
the United States, the allocation of property rights
within the check payment system is largely determined by the rules for interbank check settlement.6
There are a number of ways in which banks can clear
and settle checks among themselves. After Bob
20

T

deposits Andrea’s check at his bank (bank B or the
“depositary bank,” sometimes referred to in the literature as the collecting bank), bank B can return the
check to Andrea’s bank (bank A or the “paying bank”)
by mailing the check directly to bank A or by sending
it through a third party (a private clearinghouse, a
correspondent bank, or the Federal Reserve System).
No matter how the check is cleared, however, in the
vast majority of cases, Andrea’s check has to physically return to bank A before the bank must make
good on the check. This step is necessary because the
body of law that provides much of the legal framework for check payments, the Uniform Commercial
Code (UCC), allows a bank the right to inspect a
check before paying it. This “right to physical inspection” is the second key feature of the check payment
system. In practice, it means that checks must (usually) be transported to the banks on which they are
drawn before they will be settled. This process, as
illustrated in Chart 3, in turn means that check clearing can often be subject to travel delays.7
A third key feature of the check payment system
is the allocation of the costs of check collection.
Currently, a depositary bank (bank B in the example) bears the bulk of the costs associated with
clearing the check. In other words, a paying bank
(bank A) is under no legal obligation to share a
depositary bank’s costs of collecting checks drawn
by the paying bank’s depositors.
A final key feature of the check payment system
is the legal requirement that checks presented for
payment be paid at par, or full value. In the context
of the example, bank A would have to pay bank B
the full amount of Andrea’s check to Bob. In practice, such payments are made by transfer of banks’
account balances at the Federal Reserve. Note that
the requirement to pay at par does not vary with the
amount of time it takes to present a given check. As
Emmons (1996) notes, this feature of the check
payment system implicitly defines a zero interest
rate for check funds in the process of collection.
Thus, the greater the difference is between the market interest rate and this implicit rate, the greater
the incentive to “capture” check float will be.
The example illustrates how the key features of
the check payment system could interact so as to
influence the choice of payment medium. If bank A
and bank B are in the same city, then most likely
Andrea’s check will be settled within the same day.
If, however, Andrea’s bank is in a remote location,
then several days can pass before bank B can return
Andrea’s check to bank A. Since bank A pays the
same amount on Andrea’s check no matter when it
shows up, Andrea gains a day’s interest and Bob
loses a day’s interest for every additional day the

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

C H A R T 3 Check Clearing through the Federal Reserve System

Payment

Party A

Sends check to

Party B

Clearing

Party B
deposits check in
bank B.

Bank B magnetically encodes check with clearing
information and routes to Federal Reserve System.
Federal Reserve routes check to bank A.

Bank A
verifies funds
availability.

Settlement

Bank A debits
party A’s account.

Federal Reserve debits bank A’s reserve account.
Federal Reserve credits bank B’s reserve account.

Bank B credits
party B’s account.

Note: Checks are also cleared through the same institution (“on-us”) or through private third par ties such as clearinghouses and
correspondent banks.

check is delayed. (Check clearing may also be
delayed if Bob has a busy day and does not deposit
the check as soon as he receives it.)
Here, it may be useful to briefly contrast the clearing and settlement process for checks with that of
more automated forms of payment, such as payment
cards and ACH transactions. The crucial difference
is that clearing and settlement for these types of payments is completely electronic (and therefore to a
large extent automatic), making, in turn, the timing
of these processes very predictable. For example,
credit card transactions generally are cleared and
settled within a day. In the case of ACH transactions, the timing of settlement is flexible, but it is
also precisely controllable by the payor and payee.
The predictability of the clearing and settlement
process reduces the scope for people to undertake
actions in order to manipulate float since such actions
would immediately be observable to the other parties
involved in the transaction. Hence, float is generally
not an issue for these types of transactions.8
The payoff from the float on any single check is
usually inconsequential. When aggregated over a

large number of checks, however, float can have significant effects. Suppose, for example, that Andrea
owns a business (say, Andrea.com) that must pay
many suppliers such as Bob. If Andrea has a choice
between paying her suppliers electronically and
paying them by check, she may prefer to pay them
by check so as to have access to the float. This
approach is less efficient than electronic payment
from a societal point of view since extra costs are
incurred by the suppliers (or by the suppliers’
banks) in collecting Andrea’s checks. Since these
extra costs are borne by the suppliers and their
banks, they are of no immediate concern to Andrea.
In the meantime, Andrea’s suppliers may have
noticed that they are disadvantaged by this
arrangement. If they do a significant amount of
business with Andrea.com, they may end up negotiating more favorable payment terms. On the other
hand, if they only occasionally do business with
Andrea’s company, such negotiations may not be
practicable. Instead, the suppliers may, with the
help of their banks, make use of “accelerated presentment” techniques that speed the processing of

6. About 30 percent of checks written in the United States are on-us, according to Bank for International Settlements (1998)
estimates. Rules for interbank check settlement are governed by articles 3 and 4 of the Uniform Commercial Code and by
Federal Reserve Regulations J and CC.
7. According to Humphrey and Pulley (1998a, b), the right to physical inspection of a check before payment was originally
designed to guard against fraud. Nowadays, such inspection is rarely carried out except in the case of large-value checks.
8. See the U.S. General Accounting Office (1997) for detailed descriptions of the clearing and settlement processes for most
types of retail payments.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

21

checks. 9 While accelerated presentment may
improve the situation from the standpoint of the
creditors, it further diminishes economic efficiency
by incurring a societal cost for an activity (the capture of float) that has little societal benefit.10

Does Check Float Really Matter?
he foregoing discussion illustrates why check
float could cause people to prefer checks
over other, less costly means of payment. But
does check float have this effect in the real world? It
turns out that there are some plausible reasons to
suspect that it may not.
Wells (1996) observes that since the appearance
of the Humphrey and Berger study, reductions in
check-processing times have vastly reduced the
value of float for the average checkwriter. Wells calculates the value of float on an average check in
1993 to be about nine cents. For business checks,
the amount of float is apt to be higher, averaging
about twenty-one cents by Wells’s estimate. Since
this benefit is less than the difference in cost (to a
payor) between a payment by check and a payment
using the ACH, Wells argues that in most cases,
float cannot explain why checks are the preferred
means of payment.
Wells’s estimates of float value are for hypothetical “average” checks, which are assumed to clear in
one business day (as the vast majority of checks in
fact do). But for some payments, particularly those
with higher value or those with longer clearing
times, the potential value of float might actually be
large enough to overcome the cost differential
between checks and electronic payment media.
Wells argues that the terms of such payments are
often negotiable between payor and payee, however. If payment by check is costlier than electronic
alternatives, then both sides have an incentive to
share the benefits of using the less costly payment
medium. Hence checks probably would not be used
in these situations, at least on the basis of float-cost
considerations.
An earlier paper (McAndrews and Roberds 1999)
argues that such negotiation may not be necessary
to “even out” the effects of float. The study analyzes two model economies, one in which certain
people’s payments are subject to float and one in
which there is no float. In the first economy, some
people are nominally wealthier because they enjoy
float—that is, they can collect an extra day’s interest on their checks before they clear. However, this
income effect is undone by a price effect, as the
float beneficiaries bid up the prices of the goods
they would like to purchase.11 In general equilibrium
(taking movements of all prices into account), float

T

22

ends up having no impact. Such a neat cancellation
is unlikely in the real world, but one would still
expect price effects to undercut the real value of
any income effects associated with float transfers.
This dynamic would again work to diminish the
value of float and lessen the attractiveness of
checks as a payment medium.

A Coasian View
hile the preceding arguments illustrate
why float may be an unlikely explanation
for the continued use of checks, they do
not conclusively prove the case. Within the payment
industry, the business of playing the float “game”
(maximizing the float on one’s own checks while
minimizing the float on others’ checks) is still seen
as alive and well (see, for example, Humphrey and
Pulley 1998b).12
In understanding how check float could still be contributing to check use, the Coase theorem offers a
useful perspective. The Coase theorem states that
efficient outcomes can always be obtained through
bargaining among private parties, given an unambiguous initial assignment of property rights and sufficient
flexibility to bargain away the initial assignment of
rights.13 Given the apparent inefficiency of check payment (at least in terms of costs), its persistence thus
requires an explanation of why bargaining among private parties (payor, payee, and their banks) has not
produced an efficient outcome (greater use of electronics). McAndrews and Roberds offer two such
explanations, both of which focus on check float.
The first explanation involves transaction costs
and “unpriced float.” While bargaining over the
terms of payment may make sense for larger or
recurring transactions, such bargaining would be
too costly in the case of smaller-value or one-shot
transactions (and therefore in practice in many
transactions involving consumers or small businesses). In the latter case, payees may be willing to
simply accept the nominal value of a payment
regardless of float considerations. This willingness
creates an incentive for payors to try to capture the
benefits of float by delaying the clearing of their
checks. If only some people are successful at this
game, inefficiency results because “winners” overconsume while “losers” underconsume the goods for
which float is not priced (if everyone were successful, then prices would adjust in such a way as to
eliminate the net benefit of float).14 Since Wells’s
(1996) calculations imply that the aggregate
amount of check float is relatively small, “unpriced
float” cannot by itself carry large societal costs.
Unpriced float, or the threat of being on the losing end of the float game, can also lead to another

W

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

type of societal cost, however. This second cost
involves the notion of “reliance investments.”
Suppose a firm knows that it will receive many relatively small or nonrecurring payments from various customers and it is probably impractical to
bargain over float for these payments, given that
the firm cannot always identify such customers in
advance. In such cases, the firm’s best option may
be to undertake a reliance investment (an investment anticipating or “relying” on an initial assignment of property rights) in a technology that
allows the firm to accelerate presentment of its
customers’ checks.15 Once the firm has invested in
the technology (say, a lockbox service), the firm
can quickly process checks at a low incremental
cost, which lowers its incentives to employ electronic forms of payment. On the other hand, only
by undertaking such investments can the firm fully
exercise its property right to prompt payment at
par. If the firm does not make the investment, it
may end up subsidizing customers with access to
float. Inefficiency results because all parties would
be better off if they could first negotiate terms of
payment and thereby avoid the expense of the
reliance investment.
It seems likely that it is the decentralized nature of
the U.S. banking system that ultimately allows these
inefficiencies to persist. If the U.S. banking system
were dominated by a few large institutions, it would
be relatively easy for these banks to negotiate a set
of rules that would automatically determine the
allocation of float in interbank check clearing. Such
“Coasian bargaining” becomes more difficult, however,
when large numbers of institutions are involved.
To summarize, it is plausible that Humphrey and
Berger’s (1990) hypothesis concerning check float
can withstand both the weight of Wells’s (1996)

numerical evidence and the application of Coasian
logic. Certainly payoffs from playing the float game
have diminished since 1987. However, as long as
some people believe that they are winners at the
game, others will have an incentive to undertake
investments so as to avoid being the losers. Once
these investments have been made, incentives to
switch to lower-cost forms of payment are weakened.

Proposals for Change
ow should the United States change the
check payment system so as to encourage a
more rapid transition from a paper-based to
a more efficient and cost-effective electronics-based
retail payment system? While there have been many
proposed answers to this question, these proposals
fall into two broad categories. In the language of
Coasian analysis, the first category of proposals
would leave the property rights of participants in
the check payment system largely unchanged but
would seek to make lower-cost reliance investments
available to payees and their banks. The second category of proposals would substantially alter the current allocation of property rights with the idea that
the resulting modification in incentives would
increase the appeal of electronic payments.
The first set of proposals seeks to make greater
use of electronic technology in the check collection
process, particularly through electronic check presentment (ECP). The term ECP is used to describe
a collection process whereby the settlement of a
check is triggered using information from an electronic file instead of from the paper check itself.
Promoting greater use of ECP is an important facet
of Federal Reserve System policy in the retail payment area and has also been endorsed by several
payment industry groups.16

H

9. One such technique is to make use of so-called lockbox operations. These operations are designed to reduce the processing
time associated with mailed check payments.
10. Accelerated presentment provides some social benefit by reducing the scope for check fraud. Calculations by Lacker (1997,
15), however, suggest that the marginal benefit associated with fraud reduction is quite small in comparison with the marginal gain from the capture of float. Hence the discussion ignores this potential benefit.
11. In the model, all of the people who enjoy float are identical, so the “income effect” is the same for each.
12. Some support for this view can be obtained by a simple search of the Internet for the term “float management,” which yields
more than 200 hits. A search for the more euphemistic but essentially synonymous “controlled disbursement” turns up over
600 hits. The fact that many float management services remain economically viable suggests that the issue of float is far from
dead.
13. The theorem is attributed to Coase (1960), who, however, never wrote down a formal statement or proof. Various attempts
to formalize the theorem are described in Medema and Zerbe (forthcoming).
14. In practice, most of the winners at this game are likely to be firms since households generally lack the necessary resources
to be able to systematically manage float. Humphrey and Pulley (1998a) report that 90 percent of the benefits of float accrue
to businesses.
15. For a general discussion of the concept of reliance investments, see Kaplow and Shavell (1999).
16. For Federal Reserve policy, see, for example, Committee on the Federal Reserve in the Payments Mechanism (1998),
Greenspan (2000), and Ferguson (2000).

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

23

Stavins (1997) conducts a detailed analysis of the
potential costs and benefits of a particular type of
ECP in which each check is “truncated” at the bank
where it is first deposited (each deposited check is
immediately converted to electronic form and does
not physically go any further). Truncation of a check
avoids the costs of physically transporting the check
to the paying bank. Stavins finds that a small cost
savings (2.59 cents per check) could be obtained if
the current check collection system were to be
replaced with a system of ECP with truncation.17
While this result may be seen as encouraging for the
use of ECP technology, there exist at least two factors
that may serve to limit the potential social benefit of
ECP. The first is that,
under the current allocation of rights in the
check payment sysBy continuing to rely on
tem, banks retain the
checks for the bulk of
right to insist on physical presentment, so
noncash retail payments,
any participation in
the United States may be
an ECP program is
paying as much as $60
purely voluntary. The
banking industry as a
billion to $100 billion
whole might experimore than it needs to for
ence lower processing
payment services.
costs if ECP were universally adopted, but
unilateral adoption of
ECP by an individual
bank could deny that bank’s customers the benefits
of float without any offsetting compensation. For
this reason as well as others, the pace of voluntary
adoption of ECP has been quite slow.18
Even if universal ECP proves achievable within a
fairly short period of time (say, within the next ten
years), its net social benefit would still be suspect
precisely for the reasons described in the original
Humphrey and Berger (1990) study. As Lacker (1997,
19–21) argues, seen from a pure cost perspective the
“electronification” of the check through universal ECP
would represent nothing more than a large-scale
investment in an accelerated presentment technology.
Expressed another way, the universal conversion of
check clearing to ECP would, according to this view,
amount to the costly construction of another electronic payment system that would compete with
already existing systems (such as ACH and payment
card technologies). However, if the perspective is that
checks offer features that provide some benefit
beyond what is available through purely electronic
forms of payment—for example, flexibility and familiarity—investment in ECP could perhaps be justified
to the extent that participants in the U.S. economy
24

place a high enough valuation on such features of
check payment.
The second set of reform proposals would substantially reallocate property rights within the check
payment system. One such reallocation, discussed
by Humphrey and Pulley (1998a, b) and Lacker
(1997), follows the design of the check clearing system in Canada. There, the dollar amount of interbank settlement of a check is generally backdated to
the day the check is deposited, thereby eliminating
any float advantage accruing to the paying bank or
its customers. While such a system would almost
certainly lower incentives to capture float, its implementation could be considerably more difficult in
the United States than in Canada because of the
more complex and decentralized nature of the U.S.
banking and legal systems.
Lacker (1997, 18) discusses a related proposal.
Under this proposal, par settlement would not be
required until five days after a check is deposited.
Checks presented before this date would be discounted at a prespecified rate of interest, lessening
incentives to undertake accelerated presentment.
As with the previous proposal, the underlying idea
would be to lessen incentives to capture check float
by bringing the implicit interest rate on check funds
in the process of collection into alignment with market interest rates.19
Humphrey and Pulley (1998a, b) consider another
type of property rights reallocation, which would
have the effect of compelling greater use of ECP
technology. Under this second type of reallocation, the
UCC would be altered so that paying banks would
either (a) cede the right to physically inspect checks
before payment and agree to pay checks presented via
ECP or (b) retain the right to inspection (most likely
in the case of large-value checks) but agree to compensate collecting banks for the ensuing float costs.
This approach would allow banks to retain the right to
physical inspection in the cases in which it most mattered (where serious fraud is suspected) but would also
give banks an incentive to minimize float costs when
losses from fraud would be unlikely or immaterial.
Another method for reallocating property rights
in check payments would be to introduce truncation
technologies that automatically convert a check into
another form of payment. Several industry groups
are beginning to implement such technologies,
which convert checks into electronic “debits” that
are cleared either through the ACH or through ATM
networks.20 These technologies are seen as most
applicable to point-of-sale (POS) transactions
between merchants and consumers. In this type of
transaction, a consumer writes a check and hands it
to the merchant, who scans in the necessary infor-

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

mation from the check. The check is then returned
to the consumer. Precisely speaking, such technologies do not reallocate property rights within the
realm of check payments because a POS-truncated
check payment no longer represents a check in a
legal sense. However, the result is much the same
since these technologies in effect offer consumers
an easy way to cede their bank’s right to physical
presentment of their check without sacrificing the
convenience or familiarity of writing a check.
All of these changes in the allocation of property
rights could be (to varying extents) subject to the
same criticism as simple voluntary adoption of ECP,
namely, that they could result in large investments
in payment technologies that would largely replicate
existing systems. In addition, reallocation of property
rights would almost certainly be disadvantageous to
some beneficiaries of float under the current system. That is, some parties paying by check and
enjoying a float benefit would lose while payees
would gain. Even if the resulting system were superior to the present one in terms of economic efficiency, the accompanying distribution of gains and
losses could make a reallocation of property rights
difficult to implement.
Nonetheless, a precedent does exist for the reallocation of property rights within the check payment
system. Prior to the 1920s, it was not customary for
banks to pay checks at full value unless they were
presented directly (that is, in person and not through
the mail) or presented through a clearinghouse or
correspondent. Instead, paying banks would often
deduct a presentment fee before payment. The traditional view of the pre-1920s check payment system is
that it led to circuitous and inefficient routing of
checks in an attempt to avoid such fees.21

Nonpar payment of “remotely presented” checks
largely came to an end with the Federal Reserve’s
entry into the business of check clearing. The Fed
enforced par clearing among the member banks in
the Federal Reserve System and used a variety of
methods to encourage nonmember banks to clear at
par. As documented by Gilbert (2000), the
changeover to par clearing allowed banks to clear
checks more quickly and to reduce cash balances
necessary for settlement. Lacker, Walker, and
Weinberg (1999) argue that while the Fed’s entry
may not have increased the overall economic efficiency of the check collection system, it almost certainly shifted property rights within the system.22 As
paying banks lost the right to deduct presentment
fees, costs were shifted away from collecting banks
and toward paying banks. The ultimate effect of various proposed changes of property rights within the
check collection system would constitute a further
reallocation of costs in much the same direction.

Conclusion
he U.S. retail payment system is in many
ways a remarkable structure, handling more
than 90 billion noncash transactions each
year with a low rate of error and fraud. However, by
continuing to rely on checks for the bulk of such
payments, the United States may be paying as much
as $60 billion to $100 billion more than it needs to
for payment services.
One reason people continue to use checks is that
the current allocation of property rights within the
check payment system allows some payors to benefit from delays in check clearing times. Although the
incentives to capture check float are less now than
at other times, the opportunity costs associated

T

17. Implementation of another version of ECP has been under way for some time under the auspices of the Electronic Check
Clearing House Organization (ECCHO). Begun in 1990, this version of ECP uses an approach called “Electronic with Paper
to Follow.” In other words, the paper check is still returned to the paying bank, and it is the delivery of the paper check, in
most instances, that constitutes presentment and triggers settlement of the check. The delivery of the check information
electronically allows paying banks to deduct funds from its customers’ accounts prior to the arrival of the paper check, which
“increases banks’ investable funds,” (ECCHO 2000, 4). In contrast to the proposal analyzed by Stavins (1997), this system
reduces the risks of check fraud and of payment being released against accounts with insufficient funds but does not offer
payees the inducement of earlier funds availability.
18. A recent Government Accounting Office report (U.S. General Accounting Office 1998) indicates that, in addition to loss of
float, adoption of ECP has been hindered by the following factors: loss of canceled checks, diversion of banks’ computer
resources to Y2K problems, and banks’ concerns about increased vulnerability to fraud.
19. If prices of goods bought with checks remained the same, this proposal could be seen as transferring income to check writers
and therefore encouraging check use. In practice, one would expect that payees would discount checks and that nominal prices
would adjust upwards, canceling this effect.
20. See, for example, Marjanovic (1998, 1999, 2000).
21. See Gilbert (2000) for a detailed analysis of the traditional view.
22. In particular, they note that no cost data has been produced showing that average (systemwide) check-processing costs fell
after the introduction of par clearing. Hence it is possible that the main effect of the changeover to par clearing was simply
to reallocate rents.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

25

with “playing the float game” likely still form a significant component of the overall costs of the retail
payment system.
Market forces have already led to considerable
substitution of electronic forms of retail payment
for checks over the last decade. However, the pace
of substitution has been noticeably slower in the
United States than in other countries, suggesting
that some intervention may be necessary to
encourage greater use of electronics. Proposals to
this effect have focused on either voluntary adoption of check electronification technologies or on

reassignments of property rights within the check
payment system. While both types of proposals
hold some promise, they are also subject to the criticism that they could result in duplicative and
potentially inefficient investment. In addition, some
proposals could redistribute rents across payment
system participants in a way that would make the
proposals difficult to implement politically. Over
the near future, policymakers will need to confront
the issue of whether these drawbacks outweigh the
potential benefits of a faster transition to a more
efficient payment system.

REFERENCES
BANK FOR INTERNATIONAL SETTLEMENTS COMMITTEE ON
PAYMENT AND SETTLEMENT SYSTEMS. 1993. Payment
Systems in the Group of Ten Countries. Basel: Bank
for International Settlements. <http://www.bis.org/publ/
index.htm>.
———. 1998. Statistics on Payment Systems in the
Group of Ten Countries. Basel: Bank for International
Settlements. <http://www.bis.org/ publ/index.htm>.
———. 1999. Retail Payments in Selected Countries:
A Comparative Study. Basel: Bank for International
Settlements. <http://www.bis.org/ publ/index.htm>.
COASE, RONALD. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost.”
Journal of Law and Economics 3 (October): 1–44.
COMMITTEE ON THE FEDERAL RESERVE IN THE PAYMENTS
MECHANISM. 1998. The Federal Reserve in the Payments
Mechanism. Washington, D.C.: Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System. <http://www.federalreserve.gov/
boarddocs/press/General/1998/19980105/19980105.pdf>.
ELECTRONIC CHECK CLEARING HOUSE ORGANIZATION (ECCHO).
2000. ECP 101: The Basics. <http://www.eccho.org>.
EMMONS, WILLIAM R. 1996. “Price Stability and the
Efficiency of the Retail Payments System.” Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 78 (September/
October): 49–68.
FERGUSON, ROGER W. JR. 2000. “Electronic Commerce,
Banking, and Payments.” Speech presented at the 36th
Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition,
Chicago, May 4. <http://www.federalreserve.gov/ boarddocs/
speeches/2000/200005042.htm>.
GILBERT, R. ANTON. 2000. “The Advent of the Federal
Reserve and the Efficiency of the Payments System:
The Collection of Checks, 1915–1930.” Explorations in
Economic History 37 (April): 121–48.
GREENSPAN, ALAN. 2000. “Retail Payment Systems.”
Speech presented at the National Automated Clearinghouse Association Annual Meeting, Los Angeles, April 10.
<http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/ speeches/2000/20000410.htm>.

26

HUMPHREY, DAVID B., AND ALAN N. BERGER. 1990. “Market
Failure and Resource Use: Economic Incentives to Use
Different Payment Instruments.” In The U.S. Payment
System: Efficiency, Risk, and the Role of the Federal
Reserve—Proceedings of a Symposium on the U.S.
Payment System Sponsored by the Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond, edited by David B. Humphrey.
Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
HUMPHREY, DAVID, AND LAWRENCE PULLEY. 1998a. “Retail
Payment Instruments: Costs, Barriers, and Future Use.”
In Payment Systems in the Global Economy: Risks
and Opportunities. Chicago: Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago.
———. 1998b. “Unleashing Electronic Payments.”
Banking Strategies 74 (November/December).
<http://www.bai.org/bankingstrategies/1998-nov-dec/
Articles/Unleashing_Electronic_Payments/index.html>.
HUMPHREY, DAVID, LAWRENCE PULLEY, AND JUKKA VESALA.
2000. “The Check’s in the Mail: Why the United States
Lags in the Adoption of Cost-Saving Electronic Payments.” Journal of Financial Services Research 17
(1): 17–39.
KAPLOW, LOUIS, AND STEVEN SHAVELL. 1999. “Economic
Analysis of Law.” National Bureau of Economic Research
Working Paper 6960, February. <http://www.nber.org/
papers/w6960>.
LACKER, JEFFREY M. 1997. “The Check Float Puzzle.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly
83 (Summer): 1–25.
LACKER, JEFFREY M., JEFFREY D. WALKER, AND JOHN A.
WEINBERG. 1999. “The Fed’s Entry into Check Clearing
Reconsidered.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Quarterly 85 (Spring): 1–32.
MARJANOVIC, STEVEN. 1998. “Big-Bank Project Takes Aim
at Paper Checks.” American Banker, July 21.
———. 1999. “Three More Big Banks to Begin Check
Conversion.” American Banker, August 11.
———. 2000. “Banks Tap ATM Systems to Banish 18B
Checks.” American Banker, June 14.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

MCANDREWS, JAMES, AND WILLIAM ROBERDS. 1999. “A
General Equilibrium Analysis of Check Float.” Journal of
Financial Intermediation 8 (October): 353–77.

U.S. GENERAL ACCOUNTING OFFICE. 1997. Payments,
Clearance, and Settlement: A Guide to the Systems,
Risk, and Issues. June. <http://www.gao.gov>.

MEDEMA, STEVEN G., AND RICHARD O. ZERBE JR., Forthcoming. “The Coase Theorem.” In The Encyclopedia of
Law and Economics.

———. 1998. Retail Payments Issues: Experience with
Electronic Check Presentment. July. <http://www.gao.gov>.

MESTER, LORETTA J. 2000. “The Changing Nature of the
Payments System: Should New Players Mean New
Rules?” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business
Review (March/April): 3–26.
STAVINS, JOANNA. 1997. “A Comparison of the Social Costs
and Benefits of Paper Check Presentment and ECP with
Truncation.” New England Economic Review (July/
August): 27–44.

WEINER, STUART E. 1999. “Electronic Payments in the U.S.
Economy: An Overview.” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City Economic Review (Fourth Quarter): 1–12.
WELLS, KIRSTEN E. 1996. “Are Checks Overused?” Federal
Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 20
(Fall): 2–12.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

27

Perspectives on a
Potential North American
Monetary Union
M I C H A E L

C H R I S Z T

Chriszt is director of the Latin America Research
Group in the Atlanta Fed’s research department. He
thanks John Robertson, Elizabeth McQuerry, Steve
Kay, Myriam Quispe-Agnoli, Will Roberds, and
George Benston for their comments and suggestions
for future research.

I

N

AUGUST 2000, PRESIDENT-ELECT VINCENTE FOX OF MEXICO VISITED THE UNITED STATES AND

CANADA. HE

FORWARDED SEVERAL IDEAS REGARDING THE FURTHER INTEGRATION OF THE THREE

ECONOMIES THAT CONSTITUTE THE

NORTH AMERICAN FREE TRADE AGREEMENT,

OR

NAFTA.

AMONG HIS PROPOSALS WAS AN EVENTUAL SINGLE CURRENCY FOR NAFTA MEMBERS.

The idea of a single currency for the United States,
Canada, and Mexico is not new and has usually
referred to one of two approaches. The first, and
most discussed, is the unilateral adoption of the U.S.
dollar by Canada and Mexico, otherwise known as
dollarization. Dollarization has been advocated for
not only Canada and Mexico but also many other
countries in the Western Hemisphere (Hausmann
1999; Schuler 1999). Some Latin American countries
are already dollarized: Ecuador unilaterally dollarized
its economy in September 2000, and Panama has
employed the U.S. dollar as its currency since 1904.
Monetary union is the other interpretation of the
single-currency idea; that is, rather than unilateral
adoption of the U.S. dollar, a joint currency could be
developed and managed by a number of countries.
This article examines the idea of monetary union in
North America. Specific criteria for a single currency
for North America are discussed, as are the pros and
cons of a monetary union and dollarization in the
North American context. On the basis of optimal currency area (OCA) criteria, the article concludes that

available evidence suggests that a single currency for
NAFTA countries is possible. Canada appears much
more suited for joining the United States in a singlecurrency arrangement than does Mexico. Mexico
appears to be moving closer to fulfilling OCA criteria,
however. The article also concludes that monetary
union appears to hold several advantages over dollarization from the perspective of both the United
States and its NAFTA partners. Although monetary
union in North America is not likely to be a near-term
development, it is an important idea that merits further study and consideration.

The Single-Currency Debate
he idea of a single currency—be it via dollarization or monetary union—gained support
following the Mexican crisis in 1995 and
more recently the 1998 Asian crisis and its spillover
to other emerging markets. However, many analysts
noted that recent international financial crises were
caused or exacerbated at least in part by the prevailing fixed or semifixed exchange rate regimes among

T

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

29

the affected countries and therefore forwarded the
idea that flexible exchange rates were perhaps a
better option (Espinosa and Russell 1996; Roubini,
Corsetti, and Pesenti 1998; Sachs and Larrain 1999;
Chang and Velasco 1998). Indeed, at a more fundamental level, Friedman (1988) found that a system
of flexible exchange rates is a fundamental prerequisite for economic integration.
Nevertheless, flexible exchange rate regimes have
come under increased criticism, especially as applied
to emerging economies. Emerging markets that apply
flexible exchange rate regimes are prone to instability
and wide fluctuations in exchange rate values that
inhibit long-term planning necessary for successful
economic development
(Hausmann 1999).
Recognizing, however,
that fixed or semi-fixed
Close economic links among
regimes are susceptible
the NAFTA countries can be
to the kind of breakdown witnessed in
seen in the growing trade
Asia, more formal links
relationships among the
with the world’s main
United States, Canada, and
currencies—the U.S.
dollar, euro, or yen—
Mexico and have helped
are often considered
give rise to the debate over
more preferable than a
a single currency.
flexible exchange rate
arrangement.
In the case of the
Western Hemisphere,
linking to the dollar via dollarization or monetary
union has recently gained more attention and, in
one instance, has become a reality. In Ecuador, a
financial crisis led to the collapse of the Ecuadorian
sucre, and the U.S. dollar is now the official currency.
Ecuadorian officials concluded that the best way to
restore confidence in the economy was to introduce
the dollar as the official currency.1
The recent crises in emerging markets are not the
only reason dollarization or monetary union has
gained attention. The advent of the European
Monetary Union and the euro, the single currency for
eleven of the fifteen European Union members, has
also focused attention on the possibility of such an
arrangement for other economically integrating
countries, namely, NAFTA countries.
Simply taking the European Monetary Union model
and applying it directly to NAFTA countries is not
appropriate, however, because of the dissimilar economic and political histories involved and because
the current level of economic and political integration
is much deeper in Europe than in North America
(McCallum 2000). Nonetheless, important lessons
can be gleaned from the European experience.
30

The European Monetary Union is an effort to create greater economic efficiencies among integrated
economies. Creating economic efficiency among
NAFTA countries is also an appropriate goal. The
use of a single currency eliminates some transaction
costs, increases economic and financial efficiency,
and leads to increased trade and investment within
the single-currency area. The close economic links
among the NAFTA countries can be seen in the
growing trade relationships among the United States,
Canada, and Mexico (Chart 1) and have helped give
rise to the debate over a single currency for the
NAFTA countries. In addition, recent studies show
that the potential gains from trade among countries
that choose to participate in a monetary union can
be significant (Frankel and Rose 2000).

A Single Currency for NAFTA?
ow that the idea of a single currency for
NAFTA is on the table, the next step is considering whether such an arrangement is
appropriate. The best way to determine its suitability
is to apply the literature on OCAs to Canada and
Mexico. OCAs are groups of regions with economies
closely linked by the trade of goods and services and
by some degree of financial and labor mobility. OCA
theory predicts that fixed exchange rates are the
most appropriate for areas closely integrated
through international trade and factor movements
(Krugman and Obstfeld 1997). In the classic text on
OCAs, Mundell (1961) first noted that factor mobility
was a leading requisite for an OCA to exist. Since
then, economists have added to the OCA literature
and have developed a basic set of criteria for measuring OCAs (Tower and Willet 1976).
A number of these criteria, including size of the
economy, openness as measured by total trade as a
percent of gross domestic product (GDP), trade
concentration by country, and similarity of shocks,
are applied by Williamson (2000). He finds that,
according to the criteria, Canada would be a good
candidate for a fixed-dollar arrangement whereas
Mexico may not yet be ready.
Canada’s economy is the world’s eighth largest,
although it equals only about 7 percent of total U.S.
GDP. Canada’s economy is open in terms of trade as a
percent of GDP (70 percent), and nearly 80 percent of
Canada’s trade is with the United States. Both countries respond similarly to economic shocks although
as a major exporter of raw materials Canada confronts
different challenges during periods of steep swings in
global commodity prices. The flow of capital is open,
and there are few barriers to labor mobility. Despite
these favorable OCA measurements, Canada’s deep
financial markets and the prevailing satisfaction with

N

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

C H A R T 1 Interregional Trade as a Percent of Total Trade, 1989–99
40

38
Mexico

94

36
Canada
90

34
United States

Pe r c e n t U n it e d St a t e s

Pe r c e n t C a n a d a a n d M e x ic o

98

32
86

1995

1990

1999

Note: Although the scales differ, it is clear that the trend toward increased interregional trade is positive for all three countries.
Source: International Monetary Fund Direction of Trade Statistics; U.S. Department of Commerce

its current floating exchange rate regime make support for a fixed-rate arrangement with the U.S. dollar
unlikely in Canada (McCallum 2000; Murray 2000).
On the other hand, some critics feel that Canada
should have a stronger currency than it does and that
the 30 percent depreciation of the Canadian dollar
against the U.S. dollar over the last thirty years has
contributed to a decline in Canada’s living standards
and the need to link with the U.S. dollar to arrest
these declines (Courchene and Harris 1999).
For Mexico, the case is less compelling. Mexico’s
economy is a bit smaller than Canada’s at just over
5 percent of U.S. GDP. It is also an open economy,
with total trade amounting to 58 percent of GDP,
and it also trades heavily with the United States
(81 percent of total trade). Mexico responds differently to shocks than the United States, however;
Mexico is a major oil-exporting nation and also
remains vulnerable to changes in international interest rates. Importantly, though, the growing integration
between the two countries may to some extent make
responses to shocks more similar, especially if Mexico
diversifies its economy and becomes less reliant on
oil-export revenue. More research is needed in this
area before definite conclusions can be reached.
The post-1995 banking crisis restructuring in
Mexico is under way, and increased financial integration with Canada and the United States should
deepen Mexico’s financial system and make it less
vulnerable to changes in international interest rates.
Capital flows relatively freely between the United

States and Mexico even though most of the Mexican
petroleum industry remains off-limits to foreign
investors. Labor mobility is also a point of contention
between the United States and Mexico, with many
Mexicans migrating illegally to the United States
every year in addition to legal migration. Although
Mexico may not yet be an ideal candidate for a fixed
exchange rate regime on the basis of OCA criteria, it
appears that it may be headed in that direction.

Dollarization versus Monetary Union
t is clear that the NAFTA countries are establishing a foundation suitable to an OCA. The
question then becomes whether dollarization or
monetary union would be a better fit.
Dollarization occurs when a country or countries
adopt the U.S. dollar as their official currency. The
United States does not have to be an active participant in the policy-making process because it relinquishes no management of monetary policy. The
recent episode in Ecuador’s unilateral dollarization
exemplifies this situation.
Monetary union, however, requires substantial
cooperation since two or more countries are involved
in building a new currency regime together. Monetary
union differs significantly from dollarization because
all national monetary policies are abandoned in favor
of a shared policy among participating countries.
Fiscal policy coordination is also necessary. The
European Monetary Union is an example of this type
of arrangement.

I

1. Gustavo Oviedo, “Ecuador Government Defends Move to Adopt Dollar,” Reuters Newswire, January 10, 2000.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

31

Williamson (2000) lists criteria for choosing among
fixed exchange rate regimes, including dollarization
and monetary union. The criteria to consider when
deciding on which fixed rate regime to adopt include
seignorage, the interest premium, the lender of last
resort, and the decision role in developing monetary
policy. The next section discusses these criteria with
regard to NAFTA countries.
Seignorage. Seignorage is the revenue governments gain by issuing currency and is an important
benefit of issuing one’s own currency. Net seignorage
is the difference between the cost of putting money
into circulation and the value of goods the money
will buy. Hausmann (1999) estimates that seignorage accounts for
roughly 0.5 percent of
a country’s GDP, and
The idea of a single currency, Schmitt-Grohé and
Uribe (1999) note
be it via dollarization or
that most estimates of
seignorage are undermonetary union, gained
stated in that they do
support following the
not consider increases
Mexican crisis in 1995 and
in the monetary base
over time. Regardless
more recently the 1998
of the exact amounts
Asian crisis and its spillover
in question, governto other emerging markets.
ments have come to
rely on seignorage revenue to some extent,
and it should not be
dismissed as unimportant or insignificant (Chang
2000). A country that unilaterally dollarizes by
adopting the U.S. dollar forgoes seignorage revenue.
In a monetary union, countries would share seignorage based on a specified formula, either the size of
GDP or a predetermined measure of the existing
money stock. Therefore, from the Canadian and
Mexican viewpoints, monetary union would have an
advantage over dollarization because neither country
would forfeit seignorage revenue as it would in a
dollarization arrangement.
From the perspective of the United States, the
issue is more complicated. Under dollarization, the
U.S. government stands to gain from the increased
issuance of currency abroad. However, legislation
introduced in the U.S. Senate in 1999 advocates
returning 85 percent of this net seignorage gain to
countries that dollarize.2 This effort to share
seignorage revenue appears to indicate that U.S.
policymakers do not plan to encourage dollarization
as a means to enhance U.S. revenue. The net effect
of how current foreign holders of U.S. currency
would view a new North American currency must
also be considered.
32

The U.S. Interest Premium. The interest premium is the amount of interest a country must pay
above U.S. rates on the international market for issuing debt. The rate is generally higher because other
countries’ risks of default are considered higher.
Default can occur for many reasons, but as the
recent crisis in Asia shows, an exchange rate collapse can be a primary cause. Countries with high
interest premiums often borrow in dollars because
the interest rate is lower than in domestic markets.
In the event of a significant exchange rate devaluation, however, the borrowing country can find itself
short of funds with which to pay its short-term debts.
That is, the weakened value of their currency means
more domestic currency is needed to purchase the
necessary dollars with which to repay the debt.
Under dollarization or monetary union, the interest premium would presumably be much lower
since the risk of default is greatly reduced. There is
no risk of devaluation since independent currencies
no longer exist. In the case of dollarization, the only
way a devaluation, or currency risk, could still come
into play is if the country renounces the dollar and
reissues its own currency. In the case of monetary
union, currency risk can resurface if the union is dissolved and countries reissue individual national currencies. Given the staggering amount of chaos that
would probably ensue, these options are not likely.
Importantly, the move to dollarization may not
completely erase the interest premium. If a country
dollarizes as the result of a crisis, as Ecuador did,
investors are likely to demand an interest premium
that continues well past the dollarization event
because of that country’s poor recent track record.
Stated differently, dollarization all but eliminates
currency risk, but it does not eliminate sovereign risk.
Chart 2 shows that even after Ecuador announced
its dollarization plan in January 2000, and even after
it became fully dollarized in September 2000, a significant interest rate premium has remained. This
situation may indicate the elimination of currency
risk, but the remaining sovereign risk appears substantial. Chang and Velasco (forthcoming) also find
that dollarization may not reduce interest rates in
the dollarizing economy.
In a monetary union, sovereign risk could be
reduced further since it becomes a collective factor
spread out among the participating countries. In the
case of a monetary union of NAFTA countries, those
joining the United States would likely share its sovereign risk profile. This risk reduction would be even
more pronounced if the countries involved formally
developed joint fiscal policy guidelines as did the
members of the European Monetary Union. Yet, even
without a formal agreement, fiscal policy among

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

Ec u a d o r B r a d y B o n d Yie ld L e s s Yie ld o n
T e n -Ye a r U .S. T r e a s u r y Se c u r it y

C H A R T 2 Ecuador Interest Rate Spread
5,000
Dollarization Fully Implemented
4,000

3,000

2,000

Ecuador Announces Dollarization Plan

1,000

Jan. 4,
1999

July 4,
1999

Jan. 4,
2000

July 4,
2000

Source: Standard and Poors

C H A R T 3 Central Government Budget Balance
4

As a P e rc e n t o f GDP

Mexico
0

United States
–4
Canada

–8

1995

1990

1999

Source: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development

NAFTA members seems to be converging as countries
have been better able to control national government
income and spending levels. Chart 3 shows that
Canada, Mexico, and the United States have central
government budgets that are nearly balanced.
For developing countries like Mexico, the interest
premium can be significant depending on domestic
and international developments. At the beginning of
1994, Mexico’s interest premium was 225 basis
points, but it rose to more than 2,000 basis points by
March 1995, three months after the peso was devalued. In September 2000 Mexico’s interest rate premium averaged 350 basis points, but in January

1999 it had risen to over 1,000 basis points in the
wake of the Brazilian devaluation (see Chart 4).
This premium is a significant cost to Mexican borrowers and a major roadblock to sustained longterm planning and investment in the Mexican
economy. Reducing both the level and volatility of
the interest rate premium is a major policy goal of
the Mexican government.
The Canadian case is broadly similar to Mexico’s,
although Canadian currency and sovereign risks
are quite low in comparison, and its interest premium has been negligible recently. However, the
noted long-term decline in the value of the Canadian

2. In 2000, Senator Connie Mack of Florida introduced legislation that would, if certain criteria were met, share seignorage revenue with countries that dollarize. See <http://www.senate.gov/~jec/dollaract.htm> for an overview and explanation of the bill.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

33

C H A R T 4 Mexican Interest Rate Spread

M e x ic a n B r a d y B o n d Yie ld L e s s
T e n -Ye a r U .S. T r e a s u r y Se c u r it y

3,000

2,000

1,000

Jan. 3,
1994

Jan. 3,
1996

Jan. 3,
1998

Jan. 3,
2000

Source: Standard and Poors

dollar shows that there is a degree of currency risk
at play, and sovereign risk persists as well; the
possibility of Quebec’s succession from Canada
continues even after two referendums favoring
continued federation.
Dollarization would likely do little to eliminate the
political risk tied to the Quebec question, but it would
all but end the threat of devaluation. It is unclear
whether monetary union with the United States and
Mexico would help eliminate the sovereign risk
Canada faces. Therefore, from the Canadian perspective, the interest premium issue can be seen as neutral
with regard to dollarization or monetary union.
The Lender of Last Resort. For a country contemplating dollarization, consideration must be given
to the fact that it would forgo the lender-of-last-resort
facility of its central bank since it could no longer
issue currency, that role having been transferred to
the U.S. Federal Reserve. In a monetary union, however, the lender-of-last-resort function would survive
in all participating countries with the newly created,
common central bank fulfilling this role.
The potential loss of this safety mechanism is an
important consideration. In their traditional roles as
lenders of last resort, central banks provide funds to
financial institutions to keep them operating during
financial crises. Such a resource is generally recognized as essential during liquidity crises—when an
institution is solvent but lacks sufficient liquidity.
However, providing funds during a solvency crisis—
when the financial institution is insolvent, as
occurred in Thailand in 1997—can actually do the
overall economy a disservice by allowing insolvent
institutions to keep operating and move further into
34

debt (Calvo 2000). A lender of last resort can only
serve its purpose if it acts prudently, and Calvo shows
that the lender-of-last-resort function in emerging
economies has often made bad situations worse.
However, a well-functioning lender of last resort
with clear guidelines on when and how funds will be
dispersed to financial institutions facing liquidity
problems is an important component of a mature
financial system. Given the choice between no
lender of last resort under dollarization and a solid
lender of last resort under a North American monetary union, both Canada and Mexico would likely
favor the latter.
As noted above, the United States is not inclined
to serve as a lender of last resort for financial institutions in dollarized countries. This position is
understandable given the fact that U.S. regulators
would have no supervisory or regulatory authority in
the dollarizing economy. Without this authority, U.S.
regulators would not be in a position to accurately
ascertain the health of foreign banks. However, the
debate to date has concentrated on the question of
the lender-of-last-resort role under dollarization, with
little attention being paid to such an arrangement
under a monetary union. Under a monetary union,
the lender-of-last-resort function could be jointly
administered and financial systems could be jointly
supervised under a uniform set of guidelines. Such
an arrangement would allow U.S. regulators to coordinate with Canadian and Mexican officials in ensuring the safety and soundness of North American
banks. Having safe and sound financial institutions in
North America is clearly in the best interest of the
United States, Canada, and Mexico. Clearly, U.S. par-

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

ticipation in a lender-of-last-resort function in a
North American monetary union would require deep
financial and regulatory integration, something that
is unlikely to be a near-term development. The
lender-of-last-resort issue is clearly an area for future
work, especially in view of the possibility of private
sector participation in a lender-of-last-resort role.
Developing Monetary Policy. As part of a country’s overall economic policy regime, monetary policy
is tied to the issue of national sovereignty. A dollarizing country gives up its monetary policy along with
its currency, and the national central bank ceases to
function as the executor of monetary policy, that
role being transferred to the U.S. Federal Reserve.
One of the main arguments against dollarization is
that dollarizing countries give up too much when
they forgo independent monetary policy. An independent monetary policy is seen as an essential policy tool in implementing changes necessary for
successful national economic policy. Many countries
that might otherwise contemplate dollarization consider the sacrifice of the ability to make these
adjustments too costly.
This is the position of North American countries,
where the Bank of Canada and Banco de México are
considered to be well-run, responsible institutions
highly in tune with the role and function of monetary
policy in their respective country’s economic policy
regimes. It is difficult to see why Canada and Mexico
would want to forsake their independent monetary
policies through dollarization. To be sure, increased
economic and financial integration in North America
would theoretically weaken claims to a truly independent monetary policy for either country since the
dominant size of the U.S. economy would drive the
policy agendas of Canada and Mexico. Nevertheless,
both the Canadian and Mexican central banks have
excellent track records in recent years with regard
to inflation (see Chart 5) during a time when North
American economic integration deepened. It is not
likely that either would be inclined to unilaterally
give up their independent monetary policies.
The United States should also be wary of dollarization from the perspective of monetary policy.
While the U.S. Federal Reserve would not be legally
compelled to consider the economic and financial
conditions of dollarizing countries when developing
and implementing monetary policy, ignoring such
information would likely be difficult in practice,
especially for North American neighbors. Such a
development could potentially cause tension within
NAFTA, something that is clearly not desirable for
any of its members. Therefore, dollarization in
North America is not likely to be considered optimal
from the U.S. monetary policy perspective.

From both the Canadian and Mexican viewpoints,
monetary union seems preferable to dollarization in
terms of monetary policy development. From the
U.S. perspective, the monetary union issue is more
complicated. Monetary union with Canada and
Mexico would require sharing monetary policy
development and implementation with foreign
countries. The idea is anathema to many in the
United States, and most studies of a single currency
for NAFTA dismiss the possibility of the United
States sharing monetary policymaking with Canada
or Mexico as wholly unrealistic (McCallum 2000;
Vernengo and Rochon 2000). One study that goes
beyond this dismissal is by Courchene and Harris
(1999). It argues that
the United States
should pursue monetary union because
The advent of the European
the euro presents a
Monetary Union and the
theoretical threat to
the dollar’s role as the
euro has also focused
international reserve
attention on the possibility
currency. If more counof such an arrangement for
tries, especially those
in Europe, choose the
other economically inteeuro as their reserve
grating countries, namely,
currency, the United
NAFTA countries.
States could find it
more difficult to
finance its balance-ofpayments deficit.
Grubel (1999) notes that a monetary union would
deliver increased trade and investment opportunities to the United States. Accordingly, he notes that
the NAFTA monetary union could eventually spread
to include Central America and the Caribbean and
perhaps even South America. In addition to increasing trade and investment opportunities, such a
broadly encompassing monetary union would bring
economic stability to what has historically been an
unstable region. Stability would be in the interest of
the United States since it would greatly diminish the
need for possible future bailouts of countries experiencing severe economic crises by promoting economic growth.
Moreover, there are precedents for U.S. participation in supranational organizations. Participation in
the World Trade Organization, the International
Monetary Fund, the World Bank, and even NAFTA
itself are seen as examples of the United States’ having surrendered a degree of pure sovereignty when
the economic benefits outweighed the supposed costs
of diminished narrowly defined national sovereignty.
Grubel (1999) notes that there are escape clauses
in these agreements that can be invoked if the

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

35

C H A R T 5 Consumer Price Inflation

Ye a r -o ve r -Ye a r Pe r c e n t C h a n g e

30

Mexico
20

10
United States

Jan. 1997

Canada

Jan. 1998

Jan. 1999

Jan. 2000

Source: International Monetary Fund

national interest is significantly threatened.
However, such a passage is not likely to be written
into a North American monetary union treaty
because an escape clause would likely be interpreted
as showing that the constituents were not fully committed to the union.
Similarly, Buiter (1999) notes that the development of a North American central bank would lack
legitimacy if it were not accompanied with appropriate political institutions since some policymakers
would be from foreign countries and would therefore lack any democratic accountability to U.S. citizens. Pastor (2000) also makes this point in his call
for the development of political institutions as a
means to deepen NAFTA.
The lack of multinational institutions is troubling to
many observers. Vernengo and Rochon (2000) also
note that if a North American central bank were to be
created, some sort of supranational political authority
would have to be developed as well. In their opinion,
the costs of establishing such institutions outweigh
the benefits of monetary union for the United States
and therefore are not likely to be pursued.
Including Canadians and Mexicans in monetary
decisions affecting the United States should not
necessarily be seen as threatening from a U.S. perspective. Such a stance presumes that Canadian and
Mexican monetary authorities would be predisposed
to work against the goals of low inflation and high
employment in North America, and there is no evidence to support this argument. Furthermore, policymakers at a North American central bank would
be instructed to develop and implement policy for
all of North America and not for individual countries, just as the members of the new European
36

Central Bank commit to consider the entire euro
area and not their home countries in making policy
decisions (Treaty on European Monetary Union
1992, Article 8 of the Statute on the European Monetary Institute).
A further cost-benefit analysis of the application of
monetary policy in a North American monetary union
is needed, but it seems clear that there are potential
benefits to monetary union for the United States that
should be closely examined on a systematic basis.

Conclusion: Is NAFTA Ready for a
Monetary Union?
he evidence presented in this article suggests
that Canada and perhaps even Mexico are candidates for forming a single-currency area with
the United States at some stage. A comparison of the
two most likely avenues to a single currency, dollarization and monetary union, suggests that monetary
union is preferable to dollarization. An important
question remains to be answered: Are the NAFTA
countries currently ready for a monetary union? The
answer involves both economic and political variables
as well as some practical implications. It seems
unlikely that the United States, Canada, and Mexico
will pursue this goal in the near future.
On the economic front, most policymakers and
opinion leaders in Canada favor the country’s current
flexible exchange rate regime. The same can be said
for Mexico, but the conviction that a free-floating
Mexican currency is the best exchange rate regime
for that country appears less certain. Furthermore,
NAFTA is still in its infancy, having been in effect for
only seven years. Economic integration is still developing, and financial integration has hardly begun.

T

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

While it is true that capital and trade flows have risen
significantly since 1994, there are still three very distinct financial and banking systems in place. In addition, the lender-of-last-resort issue would need to be
resolved before monetary union could proceed.
Finally, deeper investigation into the potential economic benefits of a single currency for all NAFTA
countries is needed before the idea of monetary
union is seriously considered.
On the political front, the obstacles are even more
daunting. Yielding their respective independent
monetary policies to form an international central

bank does not appear to be favored by the United
States, Canada, or Mexico at present. In the United
States in particular, the idea of sharing monetary
sovereignty is unlikely to gain support any time
soon. Furthermore, some sort of institutional development would be required giving a North American
central bank the democratic legitimacy it would
need to operate credibly (Buiter 1999; Vernengo
and Rochon 2000; Pastor 2000). Many technical
issues such as what a North American currency
would look like and how seignorage would be divided
also would have to be worked out.3

3. Grubel (1999) and Courchene and Harris (1999) offer interesting ideas about what a North American currency could look
like. Grubel calls the new North American currency the “Amero,” which would be an entirely new currency. Courchene and
Harris suggest that the United States would continue to use the U.S. dollar as is and Canada and Mexico could issue new currencies that would bear national symbols but would carry a North American Central Bank mark rather than a Bank of Canada
or Banco de México inscription.

REFERENCES
BUITER, WILLEM. 1999. “The EMU and NAMU: What is the
Case for North American Monetary Union?” Speech presented at the Douglas Purvis Memorial Lecture, Canadian
Economic Association, May.

GRUBEL, HERBERT. 1999. “The Case for the Amero: The
Economics and Politics of a North American Monetary
Union.” The Simon Fraser Institute Critical Issues
Bulletin, September.

CALVO, GUILLERMO. 2000. “The Case for Hard Pegs.” Speech
presented at the North-South Institute Conference on
Dollarization in the Western Hemisphere, October.

HAUSMANN, RICARDO. 1999. “Should There Be Five
Currencies or One Hundred and Five? Foreign Policy
116 (Fall): 65–79.

CHANG, ROBERTO. 2000. “Dollarization: A Scorecard.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review 85
(Third Quarter): 1–11.

KRUGMAN, PAUL, AND MAURICE OBSTFELD. 1997. International Economics: Theory and Policy. 4th ed.
Reading, Mass.: Addison Wesley Longman, Inc.

CHANG, ROBERTO, AND ANDRES VELASCO. 1998. “The Asian
Liquidity Crisis.” National Bureau of Economic Research
Working Paper 6796, November.

MCCALLUM, JOHN. 2000. “Engaging the Debate: Costs and
Benefits of a North American Common Currency.” Royal
Bank of Canada Current Analysis, April.

———. Forthcoming. “Dollarization: Analytical Issues.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Working Paper.

MUNDELL, ROBERT. 1961. “A Theory of Optimum Currency
Areas.” American Economic Review 51:657–65.

COURCHENE, THOMAS J., AND RICHARD G. HARRIS. 1999.
“From Fixing to Monetary Union: Options for North
American Currency Integration.” C.D. Howe Institute
Commentary 127, June.

MURRAY, JOHN. 2000. “Revisiting the Case for a Flexible
Exchange Rate in Canada.” Speech presented at the
North-South Institute Conference on Dollarization in the
Western Hemisphere, October.

ESPINOSA, MARCO, AND STEPHEN RUSSELL. 1996. “The
Mexican Crisis: Alternative Views,” Federal Reserve Bank
of Atlanta Economic Review 81 (January/February):
21–43.

PASTOR, ROBERT A. 2000. “Lessons from the Old World for
the New: The European Union and a Deeper, Wider
American Community.” Speech presented at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Atlanta Latin America Research Group
Seminar Series. September.

FRANKEL, JEFFERY, AND ANDREW ROSE. 2000. “Estimating
the Effect of Currency Unions on Trade and Output.”
National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper
7857, August.
FRIEDMAN, MILTON. 1988. “The Case for Flexible Exchange
Rates.” In The Merits of Flexible Exchange Rates, edited
by Leo Melamed. Fairfax, Va.: George Mason University
Press.

ROUBINI, NOURIEL, GIANCARLO CORSETTI, AND PAOLO PESENTI.
1998. “What Caused the Asian Currency and Financial
Crisis? Part I: A Macroeconomic Overview.” Nouriel
Roubini Global Macroeconomic and Financial Policy Site
at the Stern School of Business, New York University,
September. <http://www.stern.nyu.edu/globalmacro>.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

37

SACHS, JEFFERY, AND FELIPE LARRAIN. 1999. “Why Dollarization Is More Straitjacket Than Salvation. Foreign
Policy 116 (Fall): 80–92
SCHMITT-GROHÉ, STEPHANIE, AND MARTIN URIBE. 1999.
“Dollarization and Seignorage: How Much Is at Stake?”
University of Pennsylvania Research Paper, July.
<http://www.econ.upenn.edu/~uribe/seignorage.pdf>.
SCHULER, KURT. 1999. “Encouraging Official Dollarization in
Emerging Markets.” Staff Report, Joint Economic Committee (Office of the Chairman), U.S. Congress, April.
TOWER, EDWARD, AND THOMAS D. WILLETT. 1976. “The
Theory of Optimum Currency Areas and Exchange Rate
Flexibility.” Princeton University Department of Economics, International Finance Section, Special Paper in
International Economics 11, May.

38

TREATY ON EUROPEAN UNION. 1992. Council of the European Communities and Commission of the European
Communities. Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Community.
VERNENGO, MATIAS, AND LOUIS-PHILIPPE ROCHON. 2000.
“Does NAFTA Need a Common Currency? A Skeptical
View on NAMU.” Paper presented at the University of
Ottawa Conference “The Political Economy of Dollarization: Lessons from Europe for Canada,” October.
WILLIAMSON, JOHN. 2000. “The Case for Flexibility (in
Deciding Whether to Dollarize).” Speech made at the
North-South Institute Conference on Dollarization in
the Western Hemisphere, October.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

Is Commercial
Banking a Distinct
Line of Commerce?
LY N N W. W O O S L E Y,
B . F R A N K K I N G , A N D
M I C H A E L S . PA D H I
Woosley is an examiner in the policy and supervisory
studies section of the Atlanta Fed; King is a former vice
president and associate director of the Atlanta Fed’s
research department; and Padhi is a senior economic
analyst in the department’s financial section. They
would like to thank Larry Wall, Tom Cunningham,
and Tony Cyrnak for helpful comments.

N ANALYZING THE COMPETITIVE IMPACTS OF BANK CONSOLIDATIONS, BANKING AGENCIES AND THE

I

U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE HAVE TENDED TO RELY ON THREE BASIC NOTIONS: THE MARKET FOR

BANK PRODUCTS IS PREDOMINANTLY LOCAL. IT IS DEFINED BY A GROUP OF PRODUCTS RATHER THAN
BY INDIVIDUAL ONES.

AND

IT IS SERVED PRIMARILY BY COMMERCIAL BANKS.

these propositions assume that the market for all bank
services is local and that the market is for services
offered only by banks. This approach allows analysts
to merge all products and services into a single “cluster of services” for analysis of competition.1
The concept of such a cluster of services, and the
underlying ideas about the market for such services,
is facing serious challenges, however. Since 1984
the U.S. Federal Reserve has taken a somewhat
broader view by acknowledging savings and thrift
institutions as local suppliers of banking services
and including them in their competitive analysis;
typically, though, these institutions are assigned a
lesser weight than commercial banks in order to
reflect their lower levels of expertise in providing
some components of the cluster (Woosley 1995). In
addition, some perceive that as bank services have
evolved toward electronic distribution, as in the

AT

THEIR SIMPLEST,

case of mortgages, and remote distribution—
through credit cards, for example—the set of services distributed locally is smaller (Ausubel 1991;
Jackson 1992; Hymel 1994). Indeed, increases in
types and locations of competitors have cast doubt
on whether a cluster of services exists at all.2 These
changes have induced the U.S. Department of
Justice to do separate analyses of small business
lending in the consolidations that it analyzes (Board
of Governors and U.S. Department of Justice 1995;
U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade
Commission 1997; Kramer 1999).3
Other evidence seems to support the conclusion
that the demand for small business loans is largely
confined to local financial institutions and that
lenders serve only areas fairly close to their physical location (Cole, Wolken, and Woodburn 1996;
Kwast, Starr-McClure, and Wolken 1997; Cole 1998;

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

39

Kwast 1999). As traditionally practiced, lending to
small businesses involves diverse borrowers that
have fewer of the standard measures of creditworthiness and require close monitoring of condition
and collateral. The borrowers are not generally
rated by national rating agencies and may lack
audited financial statements, and the character and
reputation of their owners/managers bears an
important weight in the firms’ performance and
thus in the lender’s analysis of the risks of their
debts (Petersen and Rajah 1994; Frame 1995; Berger
and Udell 1996).
Considerable anecdotal evidence also supports
local origins for small business borrowers from
banks. In addition,
surveys have found
that small businesses,
Community Reinvestment
like households, obtain
Act small business loan
credit from local instidata give a broader picture
tutions far more frequently than from
of the out-of-market parother sources (Elliticipation in a local small
hausen and Wolken
business lending market
1990, 1992; Kennickell
a
nd Kwast 1997;
and therefore an indication
Kwast, Starr-McClure,
of the degree of competiand Wolken 1997).
tive pressure applied by
Indeed, a recent analysis of the National
these institutions.
Survey of Small Business Finances indicated only a slight shift in business dependence on
local bank sources (Kwast, Starr-McClure, and
Wolken 1997).
Antitrust analysis by the Federal Reserve and the
Department of Justice often implies that small business lending markets deserve special attention. The
Federal Reserve basically holds to the cluster of
products and services approach (Frame 1995).4 The
Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice often
considers lending to small businesses as a separate
local market in its analysis of bank consolidations
(Board of Governors and U.S. Depart-ment of Justice
1995; Frame 1995; Cyrnak 1998; Kramer 1999).
The reasoning, anecdotes, and survey evidence
have not, however, convinced all observers that
small business lending is either a local market, a
market in which financial services are marketed in a
tight cluster, or a market served primarily by depository institutions (Jackson and Eisenbeis 1997;
Radecki 1998; Samolyk 1998; Grant Thornton LLC
2000).5 The increasing use of credit scoring in
underwriting small business loans suggests that
larger institutions believe high-powered scoring
models can substitute at least to some extent for the
40

banking relationships and on-site monitoring that
have typically characterized local banking (Frame,
Srinivasan, and Woosley forthcoming). Reliability of
surveys, particularly market-specific surveys conducted for purposes of antitrust analysis, is another
issue, with existing surveys having unavoidable
problems associated with missing or inaccurate
responses to potentially sensitive questions. And
while there is no evidence of bias in data collection
by the surveys, it is also true that there is no cost
associated with errors and omissions.
The surveys also have other kinds of problems.
They historically deal with static conditions, and
they generally reflect stable banking relationships.
The surveys provide no evidence on the impact of
marginal price changes or interest rate changes by
lenders chosen by small businesses. If these
changes would move customers to lenders located
in another area to a significant extent, then one
would have to extend the geographic market area.
In the extreme, if there were a national market in
small business loans with the same price for the
same type of loan at every supplier, one would
expect small business borrowers to choose the
most convenient (that is, local) bank from which
to borrow. The survey data are therefore subject
to at least two interpretations—either the market
is local or, under current market conditions, local
convenience outweighs any price or availability
advantages offered by out-of-market lenders.
Consequently, the surveys do not conclusively show
that small business lending markets are local.
New data collected on bank small business lending by location now allow analysis of the number and
size of lenders to small businesses in local markets.
By identifying the borrower location of small business loans, the number of each reporting bank’s
loans and their sizes can be assigned a local area.
This information allows comparing the number of
lenders originating loans in a specific local area with
the number of lenders physically located in that area.
Since loan number and dollar volume are also now
reported, market concentration can be calculated
and compared. If the data show significant numbers
of nonlocal small business loan originators, there
would be reason to doubt the assertion that small
business lending markets are local. Comparisons of
market concentration would give evidence on the
impact of nonlocal lenders on market concentration
and potentially on competition.
In addition, the data make it possible to compare
local loan-market concentration measures with measures of market concentration on the basis of
deposits in local institutions to determine whether
the deposit-based measures are useful approxima-

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

tions of loan-market concentration. Although, like
surveys, the new data reveal static conditions, the
additional information available in the Community
Reinvestment Act (CRA) small business loan data
gives a broader picture of the out-of-market participation in a local small business lending market and
therefore an indication of the degree of competitive
pressure applied by these institutions. Although the
Supreme Court said in United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, “In banking, as in most service industries, convenience of location is essential
to effective competition,” the presence of out-ofmarket lenders indicates that the convenience of
local offices can be overcome, at least to some
extent, by distant lenders offering, for example,
better rates, greater access to credit, or more flexible products and hours of service. It may be that as
time pressures increase for individuals, banking convenience is becoming more a matter of banking at a
convenient time than at a convenient location.
The issues of whether banking markets are local
and whether deposits are an appropriate proxy for
the cluster are crucial for antitrust analysis, particularly in small markets. Finding a source of reliable
information is important given that anecdotes are
generally insufficient and surveys provide only
inconclusive evidence.
This article compares measures of local market
concentration across deposit and small business
loan products to answer two questions: Are small
business lending markets local, and is deposit concentration an adequate proxy for small business
loan concentration?

New CRA Data
iven the apparent shift in banking patterns
and practices, it is desirable to measure both
the local orientation of lending markets and
the degree to which deposits are a sufficient proxy
for other parts of the cluster. The new CRA small
business loan data permit assigning small business
loans to the census tract of the borrower. The data
were collected by bank and thrift regulatory agencies beginning in 1996 pursuant to the revision of
federal regulations implementing the CRA. The data
help bankers, bank examiners, and community
groups monitor the extent to which commercial
banks and thrift institutions serve small businesses
in low- and moderate-income parts of their service
areas.6 Because the data are collected in the process
of judging institutions’ compliance with the
Community Reinvestment Act, they are referred to
as CRA data.
Each bank and thrift meeting or exceeding a certain size criterion (jointly, “large lenders”) is required
to report.7 Because of these criteria, a number of
smaller banks are excluded, particularly from rural
areas. Nevertheless, data on number and concentration of reporters give evidence on the nonlocal competitors and the structure of local small business
lending markets when large nonlocal bank and thrift
competitors are included. A reasonable extension of
the banking data is used to estimate the importance
of a portion of the nonreporters.
The CRA data are a welcome alternative and supplement to Call Report and survey data for two reasons.8 First, unlike Call Report lending data, CRA

G

1. United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, 374 U.S. 321 (1963); United States v. Phillipsburg National Bank, 399 U.S.
350 (1969); United States v. Marine Bancorporation, Inc., 418 U.S. 602 (1974); United States v. Connecticut National
Bank, 418 U.S. 656 (1974); United States v. Central State Bank, 621 F. Supp. 1276, 1292 (W.D. Mich., 1985), Aff’d. 817 F.
2d, 22 (6th Cir., 1987).
2. For example, in United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, Sup. Ct. page 1737, the court noted that “Some commercial
banking products or services are so distinctive that they are entirely free of effective competition from products or services
of other financial institutions; the checking account is in this category.” Today, bank checking accounts face competition from
thrift checking accounts, credit union share draft accounts, and money market accounts. For a more complete discussion of
this reasoning, see the section below on “The Cluster of Services and Local Deposits as a Proxy for Market Structure.”
3. Some, rather than questioning the existence of the cluster, question the use of deposits as a proxy (Dillon 1997).
4. See, for example, “First Security Corporation,” Federal Reserve Bulletin 86 (2000): 123–24 <http://www.bog.frb.fed.us/
boarddocs/press/bhc/1999/19991213/19991213.pdf> (October 17, 2000); and “Chemical Banking Corporation,” Federal
Reserve Bulletin 82 (1996): 239.
5. Although this latter issue deserves to be carefully analyzed, this paper does not attempt to do so because the new data analyzed
here are reported only by commercial banks and thrifts lending to small businesses.
6. Data on the location of loans to farms were also collected under the same mandate. These data are not analyzed in this study.
Farm loan data were excluded primarily because of the lack of location-specific data on significant sources of farm credit,
such as the Farm Credit System and trade credit granted by suppliers.
7. The criteria require reports of all depository institutions with assets greater than $250 million as well as all deposit-taking subsidiaries of bank holding companies with consolidated assets exceeding $1 billion, regardless of subsidiary size. This study is
based on 1998 data, reported by 1,714 institutions. (In 1997 there were 1,727 reporters, and in 1996 there were 1,844.)
8. “Call Report” is the common name for the Report of Condition and the Report of Income, which are financial statements
required by federal banking regulators.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

41

B O X

Measuring Market Structure: The HHI

I

n this study, the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index measures banking market concentration. Both the
Department of Justice and the Federal Reserve use
this index as a first step in analyzing the likely competitive impact of mergers. Many articles that deal
with market structure in any industry employ the HHI.
The HHI includes all the competitors that an analyst
chooses in a particular market. To compute the index
one squares each competitor’s market share and sums
these squared shares. If there is only one competitor, its
share would be 100 percent and the market HHI would
be 100 squared or 10,000. Two equally large competitors
would each have market shares of 50 percent and the

market would have an HHI of 5,000. Greater numbers of
competitors and more widely spread market shares
result in smaller indexes. A market with ten firms with
equal shares has an HHI of 1,000.
The HHI has two other useful characteristics.
Because of the squaring of shares, the HHI gives heavier
weight to firms with larger shares. In addition, 10,000
divided by the HHI equals the number of competitors
of equal size that would result in the given HHI value.
This latter characteristic gives another perspective on
market concentration.
To learn more about the HHI and its use, see Rhoades
(1993) and Holder (1993a).

lending data is location-specific. Second, while small
businesses responding to surveys may be reluctant
to respond to queries regarding their banking practices, lenders submitting small business loan data
for CRA purposes are subject to regulatory pressure
to file complete and accurate reports. Although the
resulting data may be neither perfectly suited to
competitive analysis nor perfectly accurate, it is a
significant addition to the data available for analysis.
Cyrnak (1998) analyzed 1996 CRA small business loan data to determine the extent and impact
of loan originations by out-of-market lenders on
urban and rural small business loan markets of varying sizes. For all but the largest markets, Cyrnak
found that the average number of out-of-market
lenders exceeded the average number of in-market
institutions, with the ratio of out-of-market competitors to in-market competitors inversely related to
market population. At the same time, out-of-market
institutions were responsible for fewer loans (both
number and dollar volume) than in-market institutions. The average size of small business loans was
smaller for out-of-market competitors than in-market
lenders. In rural markets, out-of-market CRA
reporters accounted for a higher proportion of loan
dollar volume and a lower portion of small business
loan originations by number of loans than in urban
markets. Cyrnak concluded that the higher proportion of dollar lending by out-of-market banks was
indicative of the greater importance of outside institutions in rural small business lending than in urban
small business lending. For rural markets, Cyrnak
found that out-of-market institutions accounted for

63 percent of institutions extending small business
loans—17 percent of business loans by number and
14 percent by volume.
The potential significance of out-of-market lending in rural markets is clear. Limiting competitive
analysis to local sources of credit is more often critical to antitrust analysis in small markets, in which
consolidations are likely to remove a significant
competitor. Markets outside of metropolitan areas
(rural markets) typically have fewer commercial
banks and thrift institutions than urban ones; by any
local measure they are more concentrated (Cyrnak
1998; Woosley 1998). Mergers of banks in rural markets are, thus, more likely to breach guidelines that
bank regulators and the Department of Justice use
to identify mergers with potential for serious
adverse effects on competition. For these reasons,
this article focuses on measuring competition in
rural counties.
This article extends Cyrnak’s study by examining
rural markets in greater detail. For the fifty states’
rural counties, three separate market concentration
measures are calculated and compared across four
possible product markets, using 1998 data.
(Concentration measures and product markets are
discussed below in detail.) These metrics are
reported by state and for the United States as a
whole, allowing interested readers to compare a
market’s competition to the norms for the state.
In general, Cyrnak concluded that CRA data
demonstrate that in some cases there is significant
out-of-market competition. The potential implications of the research presented here are broader. If

42

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

market concentration measures differ significantly
across the four product measures chosen, it may
indicate either that the cluster theory no longer
holds or that deposits are not the most appropriate
proxy for the ability to provide banking products
and services to a given locale.
Even if market concentration metrics are not
significantly different, or if they differ only in
degrees of extreme concentration, additional
analysis will shed light on the use of these out-ofmarket competitors as a mitigating factor or anticompetitive factor. In one tabulation of mergers
acted upon by the Federal Reserve Board, the most
frequently cited mitigating factor was strong
remaining competition, due either to thrift competition, numerous remaining competition, or nonbank
and out-of-market competitors (Holder 1993b). If
using deposit-based measures of concentration routinely understates the number and importance of
remaining out-of-market competitors, then further
consideration of potential mitigating factors is necessary. Furthermore, if Herfindahl-Hirschman Indexes
(HHIs) and other concentration measures differ
only insignificantly across product markets, the
Department of Justice practice of considering local
small business lending as a separate market may be
overly strict or redundant.9
Finally, using 1998 data will permit users to make
comparisons across time regarding the relative
importance of out-of-market lenders in a changing
competitive environment. It is possible that the
increasing prevalence of interstate or nationwide
branching and the continuing reduction in the number of commercial banks and thrifts has changed
competitive patterns since 1996. Incidentally, one
can assume that as reporting institutions have
become more familiar with the reporting requirements, the CRA data have become more accurate.

What Do the New Data Reveal?
ural markets analyzed here are counties that
are not in metropolitan areas and that have
at least one CRA reporter or banking office.10
In 1998 there were 2,356 of these markets in the
United States. Within the rural counties, concentration is measured in three different ways—number of
competitors, HHI, and the three-firm ratio—across
four different combinations of products and competitors, or markets.11
The first product market is the local deposit
base, including total deposits of each bank and thrift
with offices in the county.12 Banks and thrifts annually report deposits held in each office to the
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) as
part of the Summary of Deposits report. Bank regulators and the Department of Justice typically use
such deposit-based HHIs in the first step of analyzing
competitive effects of mergers.
The second market is small business loans based
on Call Report loan data for depository institutions
with physical locations within the market. Since Call
Report data do not identify local markets in which
an institution made small business loans, loans for
each given market are estimated. The estimation
method assumes that each institution’s loans and
deposits are distributed identically—that is, if bank A
has 15 percent of its deposits in county Z, then
15 percent of bank A’s small business loans are
attributed to county Z.13 This estimation is the one
that has traditionally been used to examine small
business lending for antitrust purposes when such
lending has been separated from the cluster of
banking products and services.
The third market is small business loans based
on CRA data for the market.14 A HHI table is constructed using only the CRA reporters that originated at least one loan in the county. This approach

R

9. The HHI is the primary measure of concentration used by federal regulators to assess the effect of mergers and acquisitions.
For an explanation of the HHI, see the box on page 42.
10. For the summary statistics presently in Tables 1, 2, and 3, all rural counties that had either a depository office or an out-ofmarket CRA lender are included. For Tables 4 through 7, only rural counties that had both a depository office and an outof-market lender are included. There are 2,237 rural counties that meet these criteria.
11. The three-firm ratio is the sum of the market shares of the three largest competitors.
12. The article follows the Federal Reserve’s policy of computing a market HHI counting all deposits held in branches of banks
and thrifts affiliated with banks, and half the deposits of other thrift offices. The partial consideration of thrifts recognizes
their limited offering of some bank products, such as business loans. All loans of banks or thrifts are given full weight for the
purposes of calculating concentration metrics for the three small business loan product markets. However, since thrifts
report small business lending differently than commercial banks, estimates based on Thrift Financial Reports may not accurately represent thrift small business loans in a locale.
13. In all three HHI tables based on small business loans, all banks and thrifts are given equal weight.
14. Cyrnak (1998) has reported 1996 HHI data excluding business credit card loans. Credit card loans are included here for
three reasons. First, credit card debt is a prevalent means of small business finance. Second, a line of credit accessed by a
credit card has few functional differences from other small business credit lines. Finally, for lenders that issue both credit
card loans and other small business loans, the CRA data do not identify the type of loan made.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

43

indicates market concentration among lenders
large enough to meet CRA reporting size criteria,
based on their CRA small business loan originations for the market.
The fourth market, referred to as combined measure, contains the most comprehensive set of competitors. It includes small business loans made by
both in-market and out-of-market firms, with
reporters’ CRA data combined with in-market nonreporters’ Call Report data to arrive at a more comprehensive set of market measures. Because of
reporting criteria, the CRA data omit many smaller
banks’ business lending. In order to partially adjust
for this omission, a set of market data is computed
that adds nonreporting business lenders with at least
one office in the county. This adjustment assumes
that banks with offices in a county are likely to make
small business loans in that county. Since these
banks are too small to be captured by the CRA criteria, this assumption is at least somewhat defensible.
The estimation methodology described above for the
Call Report data is used to estimate the in-market
loans of nonreporters. The inclusion of both small
and large financial institutions is likely to give the
most accurate portrayal of small business lending in
each area, given the limited availability of small business loan data.
For CRA purposes lenders report loan originations while for Call Report purposes lenders report
outstanding loans. Unless the CRA data are adjusted
to approximate outstanding loans, a comparison of
Call Report and CRA data will generally understate
the impact of lending by CRA reporters. Typically,
the small business loans reported for CRA purposes
were approximately 60 percent of the outstanding
small business loans noted on the Call Report.
Accordingly, in calculating the combined small business loan product market, the loan originations
reported for CRA purposes in a given market are
assumed to be 60 percent of outstanding loans in
that market.
The combined small business loan data for 1998
show much greater numbers of small business
lenders when out-of-market CRA reporters are
included.15 Table 1 compares the number of competitors across the four product markets. The mean
number of institutions more than doubles, from five
to thirteen, when combined small business lenders
are compared with deposit takers with local branches;
on average, more than 60 percent of small business
lenders do not have a physical presence in the market. For example, in the average rural county in
Alabama, 4.98 depository institutions have offices,
but 14.04 originated small business loans. Out-ofmarket banks are more important in smaller markets.
44

Since market concentration guidelines tend to be
breached more often in smaller markets, the greater
importance of out-of-market lenders implies that
antitrust authorities should be more attentive to
identifying outside lenders in these areas.
The HHI-based combined market structure measure did not differ as dramatically from Call Report
or deposit measures as one might expect, given the
substantial addition in the number of out-of-market
lenders shown by the CRA and combined data. Table 2
shows that combined business loan concentration
including both in- and out-of-market lenders is, on
average, 5.71 percent (240 points) lower than the
Call Report–based small business loan HHI with only
in-market lenders counted and only 1.67 percent
(65 points) higher than the deposit-based HHI. In
other words, including out-of-market lenders reveals
that the levels of lending concentration are lower than
apparent from the Call Report lending data. Again
using Alabama as an example, the average rural
county has a deposit-based HHI of 3,572 points and an
average small business loan HHI (based on Call
Report data) of 4,080. The average rural Alabama HHI
on the combined CRA and Call Report small business
loan data is 3,479. Although the Call Report loan data
generally indicate significantly higher concentration
levels than deposit data, the combined small business
loan data reveal average concentration levels that are
closer to those of the deposit data. With all measures,
rural markets typically exceed the HHI minimum set
out in the Department of Justice guidelines for banks
with mean HHIs of 3,901 (deposits), 4,206 (Call
Report small business loans), and 3,966 (combined)
(see Table 2).
Similarly, the three-firm ratios also differed less
dramatically when comparing deposit market tables
and combined small business loan market tables
than might be expected in light of the greater total
number of competitors. Table 3 compares the threefirm ratios across the various product and competitor
combinations. As with the HHI, the variation in
three-firm ratios generally indicates that omitting
out-of-market small business lenders makes small
difference in market concentration. The average
three-firm ratio for the combined small business
loan markets was 84.8 percent, compared with 85.4
percent and 87.7 percent for the deposit and Call
Report small business loan markets, respectively.
Smaller relative differences in HHIs and threefirm ratios than in number of lenders when out-ofmarket lenders are included arise from the character
of out-of-market loans. Many of the institutions with
widespread lending outside their geographic footprint
issue credit cards or signature loans with relatively
small loan amounts. Including estimates of small

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

T A B L E 1 Average Number of Competitors in Rural Markets

Alabama
Alaska
Arizona
Arkansas
California
Colorado
Delaware
Florida
Georgia
Hawaii
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Hampshire
New Mexico
New York
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
Oregon
Pennsylvania
Rhode Island
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Utah
Vermont
Virginia
Washington
West Virginia
Wisconsin
Wyoming
United States

Deposit

Call Reports

CRA

Combined

4.98
2.70
5.89
4.23
5.42
3.71
11.00
4.17
3.57
7.67
4.20
7.90
5.54
6.88
5.52
3.56
4.45
7.92
7.44
4.33
5.02
7.47
4.05
5.63
3.50
5.08
4.00
9.86
4.19
7.17
5.72
4.23
7.32
5.46
5.63
6.97
5.00
5.64
3.66
4.49
4.03
3.57
6.45
4.66
6.07
3.82
8.22
4.33
5.08

4.98
2.50
5.67
4.23
5.35
3.67
9.00
4.11
3.56
7.67
4.10
7.87
5.46
6.88
5.51
3.54
4.43
7.92
7.44
4.33
5.00
7.40
4.05
5.44
3.50
5.00
3.83
9.86
4.19
7.17
5.70
4.21
7.18
5.46
5.56
6.94
5.00
5.52
3.66
4.46
4.02
3.48
6.36
4.65
5.89
3.77
8.20
4.33
5.04

11.02
6.44
13.78
9.25
15.00
9.02
25.00
11.36
8.33
18.00
9.41
11.19
14.84
8.75
6.43
8.79
9.08
15.00
14.56
15.38
13.93
9.77
10.60
8.89
6.49
6.62
8.77
20.60
9.11
18.21
14.05
5.37
15.55
8.63
11.07
16.65
10.00
13.87
5.52
10.71
8.38
8.92
16.14
10.16
11.93
9.33
13.33
9.19
10.09

14.04
6.69
14.89
12.06
16.54
11.02
28.00
13.21
10.78
18.33
10.22
16.55
16.93
13.74
10.98
11.30
12.13
17.88
17.44
16.25
15.88
15.97
12.28
12.73
8.64
9.95
9.38
23.90
11.74
20.75
15.20
8.18
18.68
12.20
12.70
19.62
10.50
15.25
8.11
13.04
11.19
9.83
17.86
11.79
13.81
10.71
17.69
11.48
12.84

Note for Tables 1, 2, and 3: “Deposit” data are for local deposit bases, including total deposits of banks and thrifts. Call Report data are
small business loans based on Call Report loan data for depository institutions with physical locations within the market. CRA data are for
small business loan originations for the market. “Combined” data include small business loans made by both in-market and out-of-market
firms, as reported in CRA data and Call Reports. For all charts: Connecticut, New Jersey, and Washington, D.C., are omitted because they
have no completely rural counties.
Source for all tables and charts: Deposit data are from the FDIC Summary of Deposits. Call Report data are from the Federal Financial
Institutions Examination Council (FFIEC) Call Reports accessed via the Federal Reserve System’s National Information Center. CRA data are
from small business loan data as reported to the FFIEC for CRA purposes.

15. Cyrnak (1998) shows similar changes for the 1996 data.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

45

T A B L E 2 Average Rural Market HHI

Alabama
Alaska
Arizona
Arkansas
California
Colorado
Delaware
Florida
Georgia
Hawaii
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Hampshire
New Mexico
New York
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
Oregon
Pennsylvania
Rhode Island
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Utah
Vermont
Virginia
Washington
West Virginia
Wisconsin
Wyoming
United States

46

Deposit

Call Report

CRA

Combined

3,572
6,107
3,714
4,060
3,762
5,180
7,382
4,410
4,779
3,114
4,405
2,733
3,398
2,758
3,510
4,700
3,951
2,355
2,831
3,633
3,905
2,649
4,080
3,209
5,508
4,225
4,396
3,012
4,714
2,617
3,476
4,060
2,719
3,486
3,637
3,116
2,412
3,192
5,085
3,972
4,612
5,267
3,178
3,843
3,276
4,451
2,626
3,647
3,901

4,080
6,336
3,806
4,292
4,298
5,434
2,033
4,642
5,274
3,005
4,268
3,180
3,769
3,033
3,751
4,914
4,076
2,692
3,651
4,563
4,073
2,936
4,160
3,571
5,720
4,427
5,201
2,338
4,987
3,053
3,601
4,536
3,241
3,681
4,454
3,311
4,196
3,521
5,191
4,210
4,962
5,380
3,236
4,268
4,244
4,809
3,091
3,913
4,206

4,063
5,967
2,404
4,959
2,944
4,072
1,726
3,817
5,382
2,472
4,036
4,559
3,417
4,699
5,194
4,687
4,410
3,333
4,103
2,411
3,413
4,746
4,494
4,795
4,947
5,548
3,381
2,216
4,703
2,965
3,173
6,164
3,218
4,251
3,978
3,258
6,059
2,898
6,156
4,218
4,673
4,717
3,027
4,092
2,898
4,579
4,167
5,022
4,447

3,479
6,164
3,689
4,172
3,427
4,519
1,315
4,794
4,584
2,410
3,835
3,285
3,282
3,172
3,672
4,643
3,799
2,883
3,016
3,164
3,633
2,727
4,134
3,355
5,781
4,131
4,506
2,372
4,771
2,713
2,993
4,518
3,089
3,773
4,603
2,658
6,312
3,728
4,838
3,955
4,535
4,612
3,789
4,328
3,858
4,880
3,060
4,232
3,966

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

C H A R T 1 Distribution of Rural HHI Levels
2,000

Deposit

Call Report

1,869

Combined

1,789
1,699

N u m b e r o f C o u n t ie s

1,600

1,200

800

400

279

251
145
8

1

204

222 234

10

HHI < 1,000

1,000 ≤ HHI ≤ 1,800

business loans made by nonreporters improves the
competitive picture significantly when concentration
is measured by number of competitors, but the
changes are less dramatic when the HHI or the
three-firm ratio measures concentration. Combined
small business loan HHIs and three-firm ratios were
similar or lower, on average, than the corresponding
measures of concentration using different sets of
products and competitors. Some markets that were
highly concentrated when only in-market competitors were considered become only moderately concentrated when measured by the HHI based on
combined small business loans. Overall, however,
with concentration measured by combined small
business loans instead of deposits, 2.22 percent
more markets exceeded Department of Justice
guidelines.16 Conversely, 3.25 percent fewer markets
exceeded Department of Justice guidelines if concentration is measured by combined small business
loans instead of Call Report data.
To give some idea of whether individual market
concentration differs significantly when out-ofmarket CRA lenders are included in concentration
measures, all markets with HHIs over 2,200 based
on in-market deposit takers and lenders were identified.17 Percentage differences in their HHIs when
out-of-market lenders were included were measured.

1,800 < HHI ≤ 2,200

HHI > 2,200

Tables 4 and 5 and Chart 1 show the results. Approximately 52 percent of the 1,699 markets in which
the deposit HHI exceeded 2,200 had lower HHIs
based on combined small business loans. In addition, in 8.7 percent of markets in which the deposit
HHI is extremely high, the combined small business
loan HHI is less than 2,200. On average, the combined HHI was fifty points lower than the deposit HHI
in very concentrated markets.
Similarly, in the markets in which the in-market
Call Report small business loan measures exceeded
2,200, 63.6 percent showed lower HHIs when out-ofmarket lenders were included, and 9.5 percent of
combined small business loan HHIs were less than
2,200. On average, the combined HHI based on small
business loans was 302 points lower than the HHI
based on Call Report data for these highly concentrated markets.
These results indicate that a market that is highly
concentrated when measured by deposits or Call
Report data is not likely to become unconcentrated
when measured by combined CRA and Call Report
data. On the other hand, it is possible that the market
will appear only moderately concentrated, or at least
less highly concentrated, when combined small business loans are used to measure concentration instead
of when deposits or Call Report data are used.

16. The HHI exceeded 1,800 in 1,978 markets when the product market is deposits, in 2,091 markets when the product market
is Call Report small business loans, and in 2,023 markets when the product market is combined small business loans.
17. Based on Call Report small business loan HHIs, there were 1,869 counties where the HHI exceeded 2,200. There were 1,699
counties where the deposit-based HHI exceeded 2,200 and 1,789 where the combined HHI based on small business loans
was greater than 2,200. The upper limit of 2,200 for HHI was chosen to reflect precedent for mergers receiving approval
without divestiture.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

47

T A B L E 3 Average Three-Firm Ratios

Alabama
Alaska
Arizona
Arkansas
California
Colorado
Delaware
Florida
Georgia
Hawaii
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Hampshire
New Mexico
New York
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
Oregon
Pennsylvania
Rhode Island
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Utah
Vermont
Virginia
Washington
West Virginia
Wisconsin
Wyoming
United States

48

Deposit

Call Reports

CRA

Combined

84.19
97.06
82.94
89.92
80.04
90.21
94.03
90.10
92.21
87.35
91.53
73.08
83.37
74.69
83.12
93.28
90.71
73.25
75.32
86.54
86.53
73.58
91.44
81.98
94.14
84.75
87.72
70.99
90.57
75.07
82.51
91.73
74.67
81.62
83.30
80.46
76.93
81.24
92.43
86.79
89.26
94.10
77.73
87.74
81.07
93.25
72.92
89.23
85.42

87.90
97.28
81.23
91.05
87.57
91.83
67.54
90.86
93.84
85.66
90.82
78.37
85.82
78.87
86.46
94.65
91.75
76.59
84.45
87.78
87.73
78.08
91.83
85.00
94.43
86.94
91.83
70.03
92.34
79.78
82.91
93.24
79.81
85.54
87.98
82.73
88.08
82.73
93.57
88.71
90.71
94.35
77.93
89.26
87.09
93.43
78.07
90.90
87.72

86.56
96.85
69.02
89.85
73.73
84.18
62.77
81.81
91.66
77.04
87.03
87.27
82.25
89.19
91.91
89.10
87.51
81.61
85.36
70.82
81.49
88.33
89.27
90.07
90.81
93.40
80.50
67.44
88.50
78.35
81.88
92.86
79.36
89.89
81.82
78.96
82.62
77.53
96.27
88.21
86.26
91.72
77.52
86.14
76.96
88.96
85.59
91.38
87.11

81.93
95.27
77.01
89.45
79.96
87.27
54.07
88.58
90.53
75.92
85.15
76.67
79.31
78.05
85.58
91.25
88.45
75.44
83.84
77.40
82.28
74.52
88.70
83.56
92.85
85.39
84.50
70.08
89.84
75.40
78.35
92.36
75.63
84.41
87.81
74.23
87.36
81.24
92.52
85.92
88.28
90.13
80.10
88.10
80.01
88.76
75.59
89.58
84.79

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

T A B L E 4 Highly Concentrated Deposit Markets

Number of Counties with
Deposit HHI > 2,200
Alabama
Alaska
Arizona
Arkansas
California
Colorado
Delaware
Florida
Georgia
Hawaii
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Hampshire
New Mexico
New York
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
Oregon
Pennsylvania
Rhode Island
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Utah
Vermont
Virginia
Washington
West Virginia
Wisconsin
Wyoming
United States

35
17
5
56
13
41
1
28
106
3
37
33
41
41
69
94
36
6
5
2
47
34
66
64
46
58
10
3
23
13
48
41
27
42
19
20
1
18
56
55
151
22
5
56
18
41
25
21
1,699

Percentage of Highly
Concentrated Counties
with Combined
HHI < 2,200
5.71
5.88
20.00
3.57
30.77
4.88
100.00
7.14
4.72
0.00
16.22
6.06
19.51
7.32
7.25
4.26
8.33
0.00
0.00
0.00
14.89
11.76
7.58
14.06
0.00
5.17
10.00
66.67
0.00
15.38
25.00
0.00
25.93
11.90
5.26
30.00
0.00
11.11
5.36
9.09
5.30
4.55
20.00
5.36
22.22
7.32
8.00
4.76
8.71

Percentage of Highly
Concentrated Counties
with Combined
HHI < Deposit HHI

Percentage of Highly
Concentrated Counties
with Combined
HHI > Deposit HHI

54.29
58.82
60.00
41.07
61.54
63.41
100.00
46.43
57.55
100.00
64.86
33.33
60.98
39.02
49.28
50.00
52.78
16.67
60.00
50.00
68.09
58.82
45.45
43.75
43.48
58.62
40.00
66.67
43.48
53.85
60.42
41.46
40.74
50.00
47.37
70.00
0.00
44.44
62.50
54.55
57.62
72.73
60.00
44.64
33.33
56.10
32.00
42.86
52.09

45.71
41.18
40.00
58.93
38.46
36.59
0.00
53.57
42.45
0.00
37.84
66.67
39.02
60.98
50.72
50.00
47.22
83.33
40.00
50.00
31.91
41.18
54.55
56.25
56.52
41.38
60.00
33.33
56.52
46.15
39.58
58.54
59.26
50.00
52.63
30.00
100.00
55.56
37.50
45.45
42.38
27.27
40.00
55.36
66.67
43.90
68.00
57.14
47.91

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

49

T A B L E 5 Highly Concentrated Call Report Markets

Number of Counties with
Call Report HHI > 2,200
Alabama
Alaska
Arizona
Arkansas
California
Colorado
Delaware
Florida
Georgia
Hawaii
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
Nebraska
Nevada
New Hampshire
New Mexico
New York
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
Oregon
Pennsylvania
Rhode Island
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Utah
Vermont
Virginia
Washington
West Virginia
Wisconsin
Wyoming
United States

50

38
18
6
57
22
43
1
29
109
3
35
47
46
56
73
95
39
10
8
2
50
40
66
77
49
62
11
4
25
16
50
43
34
47
25
23
1
22
59
60
165
23
7
60
24
40
31
19
1,869

Percentage of Highly
Concentrated Counties
with Combined
HHI < 2,200

Percentage of Highly
Concentrated Counties
with Combined
HHI < Call Report HHI

Percentage of Highly
Concentrated Counties
with Combined
HHI > Call Report HHI

10.53
5.56
16.67
1.75
27.27
4.65
100.00
3.45
5.50
0.00
11.43
14.89
21.74
14.29
5.48
6.32
7.69
10.00
0.00
0.00
14.00
12.50
6.06
10.39
0.00
3.23
9.09
50.00
4.00
25.00
24.00
0.00
29.41
10.64
4.00
30.43
0.00
18.18
5.08
8.33
6.67
4.35
14.29
6.67
25.00
7.50
16.13
0.00
9.47

84.21
61.11
33.33
54.39
50.00
76.74
100.00
44.83
77.06
100.00
57.14
55.32
65.22
58.93
73.97
69.47
66.67
30.00
62.50
100.00
62.00
85.00
50.00
54.55
57.14
72.58
45.45
50.00
48.00
75.00
64.00
60.47
61.76
65.96
40.00
69.57
100.00
50.00
64.41
61.67
76.97
65.22
42.86
50.00
58.33
62.50
58.06
26.32
63.62

15.79
38.89
66.67
45.61
50.00
23.26
0.00
55.17
22.94
0.00
42.86
44.68
34.78
41.07
26.03
30.53
33.33
70.00
37.50
0.00
38.00
15.00
50.00
45.45
42.86
27.42
54.55
50.00
52.00
25.00
36.00
39.53
38.24
34.04
60.00
30.43
0.00
50.00
35.59
38.33
23.03
34.78
57.14
50.00
41.67
37.50
41.94
73.68
36.38

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

TABLE 6
Percentage Distribution of Southeastern Rural Markets by Degree of Concentration, 1998

Unconcentrated
(HHI < 1,000)

Moderately
Concentrated
(1,000 ≤ HHI ≤ 1,800)

Deposits
Call Report
Combined

0.00
0.00
2.17

15.22
10.87
10.87

Deposits
Call Report
Combined

0.00
0.00
0.00

6.06
6.06
9.09

Deposits
Call Report
Combined

0.00
0.00
0.00

3.48
1.74
2.61

Deposits
Call SBL
Combined

0.00
0.00
0.00

Deposits
Call Report
Combined

0.00
0.00
0.00

Deposits
Call Report
Combined

0.00
0.00
1.47

Deposits
Call Report
Combined

0.00
0.00
0.53

4.81
3.74
4.01

Deposits
Call Report
Combined

0.36
0.04
0.45

11.22
6.48
9.12

Basis for
Calculating HHI

Highly Concentrated
(1,800 < HHI ≤ 2,200)

Extremely
Highly Concentrated
(HHI > 2,200)

8.70
6.52
8.70

76.09
82.61
78.26

9.09
6.06
0.00

84.85
87.88
90.91

4.35
3.48
7.83

92.17
94.78
89.57

7.50
0.00
7.50

90.00
97.50
90.00

8.33
6.94
11.11

91.67
91.67
87.50

13.24
7.35
10.29

80.88
88.24
85.29

8.02
5.08
8.29

87.17
91.18
87.17

12.47
9.92
10.46

75.95
83.55
79.97

Alabama

Florida

Georgia

Louisiana
2.50
2.50
2.50
Mississippi
0.00
1.39
1.39
Tennessee
5.88
4.41
2.94
Southeast

Nation

Sixth District Results
n the six states that are completely or partially
included in the Sixth Federal Reserve District,
there are 374 rural counties that have at least one
banking office and one out-of-market lender.18 The
vast majority of these markets is considered highly
concentrated by any of the product market measures
used in this analysis, with less than 5 percent considered unconcentrated or moderately concentrated.
In fact, no rural markets are unconcentrated when
measured by deposit HHI or Call Reports based on

I

HHI, and only 0.53 percent of markets is unconcentrated when measured by combined small business
loan HHI (see Table 6 and Chart 2).
For the Southeast overall, the combined small
business loans reveal an average of 12.42 competitors,
nearly three times the number of deposit and Call
Report competitors (4.20 and 4.18, respectively).
Similarly, the southeastern combined small business
loan three-firm ratio is 2.1 percent lower than the
deposit three-firm ratio and 3.9 percent lower
than the Call Report three-firm ratio.19 The average

18. The terms Sixth District, Sixth District states, and Southeast are used interchangeably in this article. The Sixth District
includes Alabama, Florida, Georgia, and parts of Louisiana, Mississippi, and Tennessee. The entire states of Louisiana,
Mississippi, and Tennessee were included in this study.
19. The regional combined small business loan three-firm ratio is 87.7 percent while the deposit and Call Report small business
loan three-firm ratios are 89.6 percent and 91.2 percent, respectively.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

51

C H A R T 2 Distribution of Rural HHIs in the Southeast

400
Deposit

Call Report

Combined

341

N u m b e r o f C o u n t ie s

326

326

300

200

100
18
0

0

2

HHI < 1,000

14

1,000 ≤ HHI ≤ 1,800

combined HHI of 4,123 is 8.2 percent lower than the
HHI based on Call Reports (4,460) for the region but
only 0.5 percent lower than the deposit HHI (4,143).
Some southeastern states benefit more than
others from out-of-market lending competition.
Georgia, for example, has the highest average rural
deposit-based HHI in the region, at least partly as a
relic of its previously restrictive branching laws. The
combined HHI is 195 points (4.3 percent) lower
than the deposit HHI and 690 points (15.1 percent)
lower than the Call Report HHI. In Alabama, which
has the lowest average rural deposit HHI in the
southeast, the combined HHI is only 106 points
(2.7 percent) lower than the deposit HHI but is
601 points (17.3 percent) lower than the Call
Report HHI. Florida’s average deposit HHI and Call
Report HHI are both lower than the combined HHI,
by 8.0 percent and 3.2 percent, respectively. In
Florida, some of the largest banking organizations
with widespread branching networks do not focus
on small business lending in the state. As a result,
the CRA data indicate fewer small business loans
than estimated by Call Report data. The resulting
average combined loan HHI is higher then the average deposit and Call Report–based HHI(s). Even so,
the mean combined three-firm ratio is 1.7 percent
lower than the deposit three-firm ratio and 2.6 percent
lower than the Call Report three-firm ratio.
Although most markets remain highly concentrated regardless of the measurement used, the variations in results illustrate the benefits of using the
combined small business loan HHI in addition to the
deposit measurements of concentration. The use of
multiple measures reveals additional information
about the specific markets in question that may be
helpful in analyzing the county’s competitive profile
52

30

15

19

31

1,800 < HHI ≤ 2,200

HHI > 2,200

and any potential mitigating factors in apparently
anticompetitive mergers.

The Cluster of Services and Local Deposits
as a Proxy for Market Structure
n United States v. Philadelphia National Bank,
the Supreme Court noted that “some commercial
banking products or services are so distinctive
that they are entirely free of effective competition
from products or services of other financial institutions; the checking account is in this category.” 20
With the rise of thrift checking accounts, credit
union draft accounts, and money market accounts
offered by investment companies, this distinction no
longer holds. The Supreme Court also noted, “Others
enjoy such cost advantages as to be insulated within
a broad range from substitutes furnished by other
institutions. For example, commercial banks compete with small-loan companies in the personal-loan
market; but the small-loan companies’ rates are
invariably much higher than the banks’, in part, it
seems, because the companies’ working capital consists in substantial part of bank loans.” These conditions also no longer hold. Specialty lenders are not
dependent on commercial banks for working capital,
relying instead on access to capital markets and
securitization to provide needed funds. The Court
also held that “there are banking facilities which,
although in terms of cost and price they are freely
competitive with the facilities provided by other
financial institutions, nevertheless enjoy a settled
consumer preference, insulating them, to a marked
degree, from competition; this seems to be the case
with savings deposits.” In today’s marketplace, savings
deposits are subject to competition from thrifts,
credit unions, annuities, mutual funds, and other

I

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

T A B L E 7 Paired T-tests of Differences in Means a
Variable 1

Variable 2

Mean
Variable 1

Mean
Variable 2

T

Degrees
of Freedom

Prob. > |T|

3,880

4,081

–4.78

4,472

<0.0001

5.18

5.14

0.47

4,472

0.6378

Deposit HHI

Call SBL HHI

Deposit Number
of Competitors

Call Report Number
of Competitors

Deposit
Three-Firm Ratio

Call Report
Three-Firm Ratio

85.07

87.43

–5.44

4,472

<0.0001

Deposit HHI

Combined HHI

3,770

3,846

1.21

4,472

0.2244

Deposit Number
of Competitors

Combined Number
of Competitors

5.18

13.15

54.49

4,472

<0.0001

Deposit
Three-Firm Ratio

Combined
Three-Firm Ratio

85.07

84.47

–1.39

4,472

0.1653

Call Report HHI

Combined HHI

4,081

3,846

–3.78

4,472

0.0002

Call Report Number
of Competitors

Combined Number
of Competitors

5.14

13.15

54.87

4,472

<0.0001

a

These results assume unequal variances. Assuming equal variances yielded similar results.

securities and insurance products. With the rise of
alternative delivery systems, competing products
from nonbank institutions, and greater price competition among financial institutions, it may no longer be
accurate to assume this settled consumer preference.
As noted previously, deposits held by banks located
within the local market area typically are used to
measure market concentration (Woosley 1995).
These deposit-based HHIs are said to approximate
market structure of the cluster of banking services.21
The availability of CRA data gives an opportunity to
partially test this assertion and indeed provides evi-

dence about whether the concept of a cluster of services is appropriate in today’s financial environment.22 A series of paired T-tests indicated that some
of the differences in the means of the various HHIs
were not statistically equal to zero (Table 7).23
Similar results were found for the differences in the
means of the three-firm ratios and number of competitors. It appears that the deposit concentration
measures are not a consistently reliable proxy for
concentration in small business loans, whether measured by the traditional Call Report data or by the
combined Call Report and CRA data. The debatable

20. Similarly, United States v. Connecticut National Bank stated, “Commercial banks in the State offer credit-card plans, loans
for securities purchases, trust services, investment services, computer and account services, and letters of credit. Savings
banks do not.” Today, all of these products are offered by at least one type of nonbank financial institution.
21. Although deposits are routinely used as a proxy for the cluster by the federal banking agencies, case law does not require
such usage. Indeed, in United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, deposits, loans, and assets were used to measure
concentration. Similarly, in United States v. Phillipsburg National Bank and United States v. Marine Bancorporation,
Inc., demand deposits, loans, assets, and number of banking offices were used. Until recently, only deposits could be easily
identified by locale, encouraging regulators to use this readily available data for antitrust purposes. The advent of CRA small
business loan and small farm loan data and Home Mortgage Disclosure Act of 1975 data has increased the amount of available
data regarding banking products and services sold by location.
22. Antitrust review in the federal banking agencies still utilizes the cluster of products and services concept in the face of much
change in the nation’s financial system. Sometimes this adherence is supported as adherence to a concept stated by the
Supreme Court. The court, however, has changed its concepts when contrary evidence was presented. See, for example,
Brown v. Board of Education of Topeka, Kansas, 349 U.S. 294 (1955). Furthermore, the banking agencies have also
ceased to adhere to some of the dictates of previous Supreme Court decisions. For example, United States v. Philadelphia
National Bank included only commercial banks with their head offices in the local market as competition. Federal banking
regulators include all banks with offices in the local market. United States v. Connecticut National Bank specifically
excluded savings banks, but the banking regulators give local thrifts at least half weight in antitrust analysis, and the Federal
Reserve cited thrift competition as a mitigating factor in more than 53 percent of cases reviewed by Holder (1993b). United
States v. Philadelphia National Bank rejected “countervailing power,” or the market share of the dominant firm, as a
potential mitigating factor. Holder found that the Federal Reserve cited this factor as mitigating potential anticompetitive
effects in some markets affected by merger activity.
23. A T-test is a statistical measurement of the probability that the difference observed in the means is due to chance. Paired T-tests
are used when, as in this instance, the observed measurements are drawn from related, rather than independent, samples.
Pearson correlation coefficients indicated modest correlations between concentration measures based on the various products.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

53

reliability of deposits as a proxy for the cluster is consistent with the changing role of deposits in modern
banking. Banks today rely less on deposits and more
on wholesale, noncore funding, such as federal funds,
Federal Home Loan Bank advances, notes, and commercial paper. Given the greater access to national
and global capital and funding markets, even for
regional banks, deposits are becoming less relevant
as a measure of the capacity to provide banking products and services. Smaller banks may have fewer
wholesale funding options, but they are also relying
less on deposits and more on Federal Home Loan
Bank advances and similar funding sources.

Conclusions and
Policy Considerations
se of the data
first reported
for 1996 CRA
analysis sheds new
light on sources of
and the importance
of competition in
rural markets for
small business loans.
Analysis shows that
the number of lenders
in these markets is
seriously underestimated when only
lenders located in
the market are counted as competitors. Including
out-of-market lenders more than doubles the
number of total reporting loan originators on average, and the importance of out-of-market lenders
increases with markets of smaller size.
Out-of-market lenders typically make fewer and
smaller loans than in-market lenders, however. Thus,
out-of-market lenders have much less influence on
traditional measures of market concentration than
they do on the number of competitors in a market.
Even so, in markets in which the deposit-based HHI
exceeds the level typically approved in merger transactions, using the combined HHI reduces the HHI
enough for it to fall below that level in 12.7 percent
of markets. Similarly, when the deposit HHI exceeds
1,800, the combined HHI falls within the parameters
of the Department of Justice guidelines 7.8 percent
of the time.24 Including both CRA reporters and nonreporters with local offices reduces both mean concentration in highly concentrated markets and the
number of markets in which concentration exceeds
Department of Justice guidelines.
Using the four concentration measures above to
analyze variation of HHIs indicates that markets vary

As credit scoring, disintermediation, and electronic
distribution of banking
services increase, out-ofmarket providers are likely
to increase in importance.
At the same time, local
institutions are likely to
remain significant.

54

U

widely. No single measure approximates any other
precisely. Hannan (1991) concludes that variations in
deposit and loan concentration in banking markets
will introduce considerable noise into tests of the
relationship between deposit concentration and market performance. Consequently, a single concentration measure is a poor approximation of market
concentration as a structure measure in the structureconduct-performance approach to antitrust analysis.
Although using multiple measures of concentration
might increase the uncertainty connected with receiving regulatory approval of mergers, it appears that, for
at least some markets, deposits are not an adequate
proxy for small business lending.
Furthermore, the use of multiple measures is not
inconsistent with the reasoning or evidence used in
precedent. For example, in United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, Justice Brennan wrote,
“There is no evidence of the amount of business
done in the area by banks with offices outside the
area; it may be such figures are unobtainable.” One
could infer from this statement that such evidence
should be presented, if available. In addition,
United States v. Philadelphia National Bank,
United States v. Phillipsburg National Bank, and
United States v. Marine Bancorporation, Inc., all
used multiple market share indicators. Finally, the
consideration of business loans has received at least
some support from the high court. In dissenting
from the majority opinion in United States v.
Marine Bancorporation, Inc., Justices White,
Brennan, and Marshall opined, “A main component
of that cluster, and one which determines profits, is
the ability to provide loans, and it seems to me that
a prospect of competition for loans, whether based
on deposits garnered in Spokane or elsewhere, has
a substantial possibility of effecting deconcentration
in at least one segment of the banking business.”
The considerable variation in concentration measures across product markets also casts doubt on two
of the practices carried on in government antitrust
circles since United States v. Philadelphia National
Bank. Specifically, for small businesses it is unclear
whether commercial loans are provided as part of a
cluster of banking products and services (since outof-market lenders are not likely to be providing all
other parts of the cluster to these businesses) by
local institutions and whether deposit concentration
is an appropriate proxy for small business loan concentration. Although the Court has held that out-ofmarket banks are not important, at least to small
businesses (United States v. Philadelphia National
Bank) and that, as a result of relationship banking,
“the cluster has economic significance well beyond
the various products and services involved” (United

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

States v. Phillipsburg National Bank), the financial
services sector, its technology, and its customers’
preferences may have changed enough that these
findings are no longer valid. As credit scoring, disintermediation, and electronic distribution of banking
services increase, out-of-market providers are likely
to increase in importance. At the same time, local
institutions are likely to remain significant, particularly for businesses that have need of coin and currency services. Further research into the effect of
out-of-market lenders is needed to determine
whether such lenders influence prevailing local loan
rates, lend to a broad customer base within a given
market, are more likely to garner local customers for
nonloan products and services, or are more likely to
establish a branch office than outside banks with no
local loans.
Despite the need for additional research, using
multiple measures of market concentration is likely
to give a truer picture of market concentration,
especially in marginal cases. Furthermore, if addi-

tional research indicates that the changes in structure due to out-of-market competitors result in
changes in pricing or behavior, the Federal Reserve
should consider subjecting the acquisition of an inmarket institution by an out-of-market lender active
in the local market to competitive review similar to
that given to a merger of two in-market firms.25
Finally, the CRA data suggest that the traditional
use of mitigating factors may understate remaining
competition. Because of changes in the business of
banking since United States v. Philadelphia
National Bank, the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System has exhibited flexibility in
its approach to antitrust matters by considering the
particular factors of a case market-by-market. In
some cases, the Board has considered mitigating
factors such as remaining competition. The results
of this study support the approach of giving close
scrutiny beyond local-deposit-based concentration
measures to markets that would be affected by a
merger application.

24. In 9.7 percent of the rural markets examined, the combined small business loan HHI is less than 1,800 when the Call Report
small business loan HHI exceeds 1,800.
25. Cyrnak and Hannan (1999) compared deposit and combined small business loan HHIs in 98 metropolitan statistical areas
and found a relatively low correlation (a Pearson correlation coefficient of 0.56) between them. Their results indicated that
deposit-based HHIs performed as well, or better than, loan-based HHIs in determining business loan pricing. However, it is
uncertain whether their results using urban data are applicable to rural markets. First, there is generally much greater overlap
between the competitors with offices in a market and the competitors with loan originations in that market for urban markets
than for rural markets. Second, rural markets tend to be less competitive than urban markets (when competitiveness is
measured by market structure), so the price response to out-of-market competitors may be different. In addition, Cyrnak
and Hannan did not control for individual borrower characteristics.

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

55

A P P E N D I X

A

Structure-Conduct-Performance:
The Reigning Antitrust Paradigm and Alternatives
ntitrust analysis by both the federal bank regulators and the Department of Justice has its base in
what is called the structure-conduct-performance
approach. This approach, introduced and well explicated by Caves (1964), begins with theoretically based
and empirically verified assertions that the number
and market share of competitors in a product market
influence the prices offered and other competitive
behavior of the firms offering the product. Each will
charge a profit-maximizing price, but that price will
vary with the market’s structure. At one extreme, a
single provider will maximize its profit by selling at a
price that extracts monopoly rents. At the other, in a
market with many competitors, price will tend to equal
the marginal cost of producing the product. In structures other than those at the ends of the monopolycompetitive continuum, pricing will become closer to
monopoly pricing as the number of competitors
becomes fewer and the market becomes more concentrated. Hannan (1991) formally models this paradigm
specifically for markets with banking firms that offer
multiple types of loans and deposits. His results follow
those of many other descriptive applications; however,
his findings are more detailed and offer guidelines for
identifying variables to be controlled for in empirical
work when the model is applied to banking markets.
Thus, in the structure-conduct-performance model,
market structure influences the pricing conduct of
sellers of a product as well as many other kinds of competitive conduct. When structure is concentrated, it is
more likely that prices will be higher than marginal
costs of producing a product and that predatory conduct of other sorts will occur.
This pricing and other anticompetitive conduct
affects the way the market performs in bringing about
prices and quantities of products sold in the market.
As concentration increases toward monopoly, as prices
increase, and as quantities of the product decline,
other sellers and new products are deterred so that
the users of the product are less well served by the
producers. The market moves farther away from an
optimum solution provided in a market with many sellers of similar size—that is, its performance declines.
Out of this comes the concentration of antitrust

A

56

authorities on market structure and seller conduct as
keys to market performance.
There are other approaches to market performance
that provide alternative forms of analysis and, at times,
opposite conclusions. These tend to emphasize the
dynamics of market development. While the structureconduct-performance approach essentially takes
structure as a given, these approaches go deeper to
assess how the basic physical dimensions of production and their changes influence structure-conductperformance and, again, structure.
The two most often presented take different paths.
The contestable markets approach, developed by
Baumol (1982), deals with the influence of possible
competitors not currently operating in a local or product market but able to do so in the future at higher
costs than current competitors. The approach thus
focuses on the opportunities of out-of-market or fringe
sellers who might sell in a market if, for example,
prices were somewhat higher. The approach concludes
that it is realistically possible for out-of-market fringe
sellers to influence market conduct and performance
because the threat of their entry limits the conduct of
in-market sellers. Current structure may still be important, but more than static structural analysis is
required to generate valid conclusions about likely
market performance. If the contestable markets
hypothesis holds for local banking markets, the out-ofmarket lenders could play the role of fringe sellers as
depicted by this theory.
Another alternative, called the variable efficiency
approach, is associated with Demsetz (1973). It turns
the structure-conduct-performance approach on its
head. In this approach, production and marketing efficiency play a major role in determining market structure. The more efficient firms gain the higher market
shares and earn the higher profits. They do not, however, charge the higher prices. Their ability to produce
more efficiently allows them to charge lower prices and
gain market share. In the extreme, if economies of scale
will allow a single seller to supply the full market at a
cost lower than any number of other sellers, the market
will both tend to be a monopoly market and have the
lowest possible production costs for its output. In this

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

model, methods of production and marketing determine
optimal market structure; moves away from this structure may reduce production efficiency and raise prices.
If this theory best explains competition in local banking
markets, the out-of-market competitors are the efficient
producers of small business loans. Their lower cost
structures in originating, underwriting, or monitoring

loans, which may be due to better use of banking technologies such as credit scoring or electronic delivery,
would allow them to enter the market and gain market
share by charging lower prices. Additional research into
the pricing practices of out-of-market lenders and the
effect on local prices is necessary to determine whether
this theory of competition holds.

A P P E N D I X

B

Department of Justice Merger Guidelines
n order to identify mergers that deserve special
analysis, the Antitrust Division of the Department of
Justice has issued “guidelines” for consolidations
(Board of Regents and U.S. Department of Justice
1995; U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade
Commission 1997). These guidelines are stated in terms
of the HHI explained in the box on page 42. The guidelines call for using a market’s HHI and the change in the

I

HHI caused by a proposed merger to decide whether the
consolidation might have anticompetitive impacts.
For most industries, addition of more than 50 points
resulting in an HHI of 1000 or greater sends a warning.
For banking, the guidelines recognize that local banks
are not the only providers of bank services by using different benchmarks—an addition of 200 or more points
resulting in a market HHI of 1800 or more signals danger.

REFERENCES
AUSUBEL, LAWRENCE M. 1991. “The Failure of Competition
in the Credit Card Market.” American Economic
Review 81 (March): 50–81.

CAVES, RICHARD E. 1964. American Industry: Structure,
Conduct, Performance. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: PrenticeHall, Inc.

BAUMOL, WILLIAM J. 1982. “Contestable Markets: An Uprising in the Theory of Industry Structure.” American
Economic Review 72 (March): 1–15.

COLE, REBEL. 1998. “The Importance of Relationships to
the Availability of Credit.” Journal of Banking and
Finance 22 (August): 959–77.

BERGER, ALLEN N., AND GREGORY F. UDELL. 1996. “Universal Banking and the Future of Small Business Lending.”
In Universal Banking: Financial System Design
Reconsidered, edited by A. Saunders and I. Walters,
558–67. Chicago: Irwin.

COLE, REBEL, JOHN WOLKEN, AND R. LOUISE WOODBURN.
1996. “Bank and Nonbank Competition for Small
Business Credit: Evidence from the 1987 and 1993
Surveys of Small Business Finances.” Federal Reserve
Bulletin 82 (November): 983–95.

BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM AND
THE U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE. 1995. “Bank Merger
Competitive Review: Introduction and Overview.”

CYRNAK, ANTHONY W. 1998. “Bank Merger Policy and the
New CRA Data.” Federal Reserve Bulletin 84 (September): 703–15. <http://www.bog.frb.fed.us/pubs/bulletin/
1998/998lead.pdf> (October 17, 2000).

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000

57

CYRNAK, ANTHONY W., and TIMOTHY H. HANNAN. 1999.
“Is the Cluster Still Valid in Defining Banking Markets?
Evidence from a New Data Source.” Antitrust Bulletin
44 (Summer): 313–36.
DEMSETZ, HAROLD. 1973. “Industry Structure, Market
Rivalry, and Public Policy.” Journal of Law and
Economics 16 (April): 1–9.
DILLON, ED. 1997. “Are Deposits the Best Antitrust
Measure?” Bank Mergers and Acquisitions 12, no. 16:1–4.
ELLIHAUSEN, GREGORY E., AND JOHN D. WOLKEN. 1990.
“Banking Markets and the Use of Financial Services by
Small and Medium-Sized Businesses.” Federal Reserve
Bulletin 76 (October): 801–17.
———. 1992. Banking Markets and the Use of Financial
Services by Households.” Federal Reserve Bulletin 78
(March): 169–81.
FRAME, W. SCOTT. 1995. “Examining Small Business Lending
in Bank Antitrust Analysis.” Federal Reserve Bank of
Atlanta Economic Review 80 (March/April): 31–40.
FRAME, W. SCOTT, ARUNA SRINIVASAN, AND LYNN W.
WOOSLEY. Forthcoming. “The Effect of Credit Scoring
on Small Business Lending.” Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking.
GRANT THORNTON LLC. 2000. The Changing Community
of Banking. <http://www.grantthornton.com/resources/
finance/banksurvey2000/survey00_4print.html> (November 30, 2000).
HANNAN, TIMOTHY H. 1991. “The Functional Relationship
between Prices and Market Concentration: The Case of
the Banking Industry.” Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System Finance and Economics Discussion
Series Paper No. 169.
HOLDER, CHRISTOPHER L. 1993a. “Competitive Considerations in Bank Mergers and Acquisitions: Economic
Theory, Legal Foundations, and the Fed.” Federal
Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review 78
(January/February): 23–36.
———. 1993b. “The Use of Mitigating Factors in Bank
Mergers and Acquisitions: A Decade of Antitrust at the
Fed.” Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic
Review 78 (March/April): 32–44.
HYMEL, MICHAEL. 1994. “The Retail Bank CD Market.”
Growth and Change 25 (Fall): 427–44.
JACKSON, WILLIAM E., III. 1992. “Is the Market Well
Defined in Bank Merger and Acquisition Analysis?”
Review of Economics and Statistics 74, no. 4:655–61.

58

JACKSON, WILLIAM E., III, AND ROBERT A. EISENBEIS. 1997.
“Geographic Integration of Bank Deposit Markets and
Restrictions on Interstate Banking: A Cointegration
Approach.” Journal of Economics and Business 49
(July/August): 335–46.
KENNICKELL, ARTHUR B., AND MYRON L. KWAST. 1997. “Who
Uses Electronic Banking?” Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System Finance and Economics Discussion
Series Paper No. 1997-35. <http://www.bog. frb.fed.us/pubs/
feds/1997/199735/199735pap.pdf> (October 17, 2000).
KRAMER, ROBERT. 1999. “Mega-Mergers in the Banking
Industry.” Speech made at the American Bar Association
Meeting, Antitrust Section, April.
KWAST, MYRON L. 1999. “Bank Mergers: What Should
Policymakers Do?” Journal of Banking and Finance
23 (February): 629–36.
KWAST, MYRON L., MARTHA STARR-MCCLURE, AND JOHN D.
WOLKEN. 1997. “Market Definition and the Analysis of
Antitrust in Banking.” Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System Finance and Economics Discussion
Series Paper No. 1997-52. <http://www.bog.frb.fed.us/pubs/
feds/1997/199752/199752pap.pdf> (October 17, 2000).
PETERSEN, MITCHELL A., AND RAGHURAM G. RAJAH. 1994.
“The Benefits of Lending Relationships: Evidence from
Small Business Data.” Journal of Finance 49, no. 1:3–37.
RADECKI, LAWRENCE J. 1998. “The Expanding Reach of
Geographic Banking Markets.” Federal Reserve Bank of
New York Economic Policy Review 4 (June): 15–34.
<http://www.ny.frb.org/rmaghome/econ_pol/698rad.htm>
(October 17, 2000).
RHOADES, STEPHEN A. 1993. “The Herfindahl-Hirschman
Index.” Federal Reserve Bulletin 79 (March): 188–89.
SAMOLYK, KATHERINE. 1998. “Small Business Credit
Markets: Why Do We Know So Little about Them?” FDIC
Banking Review 10, no. 2:14–32. <http://www.fdic.gov/
bank/analytical/banking/1998mar/small.pdf>
(October 18, 2000).
U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE AND FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION. 1997. “Horizontal Merger Guidelines.” <http://www.
usdoj.gov:80/atr/public/guidelines/horiz_book/hmg1.html>
(October 11, 2000).
WOOSLEY, LYNN W. 1995. “Agencies Explain Screening of
Bank Acquisitions.” Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta
Financial Update 8 (January–March): 1–3.
———. 1998. “Bank Consolidation Affects Lending in
Southeastern Rural Markets.” Federal Reserve Bank of
Atlanta Financial Update 11 (July–September): 4–5.
<http://www.frbatlanta.org/publica/finan_update/v11n3/
fu_v11n3_4.html> (October 11, 2000).

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta E C O N O M I C R E V I E W Fourth Quarter 2000