View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MONTHLY
REVIEW

IN THIS ISSUE:
• Incomes Policies: A Quick
Critique
• Measuring Monetary Policy
• Banking Nntes
• Index for the Year 1970
• District Business Conditions

FED ERA L R ESER V E



BAN K

OF A T L A N T A
DECEMBER 1970

In c o m e s P o lic ie s :

A Q u ic k C r it iq u e

A high and growing level of employment, low
unemployment, a stable price level, a high rate
of economic growth, and a reasonable balance
of international payments are five economic ob­
jectives that have top priority in almost all
countries. There are numerous economic policies
or tools available to any government for use in
achieving these goals. Indeed, they comprise a
broad spectrum of policy measures, ranging from
direct intervention in the economy to very
broad and general measures that affect the econ­
omy in a primarily indirect manner. Some rela­
tively new measures that have recently received
increasing attention in this country are the in­
comes policies.
This article focuses on incomes policies. To
provide background, however, it begins with a
brief discussion of more conventional policies
and notes some of their alleged deficiencies.
These problems have led to development of

M o n t h l y R e v i e w , V ol. L V , N o . 12. F re e su b scrip tio n

an d a d d itio n a l c o p ies a v a ila b le u p o n req u est to th e
R e se a rc h D e p a r tm e n t, F ed e r a l R e se rv e B a n k of
A tla n ta , A tla n ta , G eorgia 30303.
174




incomes policies in some nations and, more re­
cently, to calls for such a policy in the United
States. The article points out in general terms
what actions might comprise an incomes policy
and asks how well incomes policies have worked
in actual experience, especially with regard to
their generally accepted purposes.
M o re

C o n v e n t io n a l P o lic ie s

On one end of the spectrum of economic policies
are two general or aggregate tools—monetary and
fiscal policies. Essentially, both monetary and
fiscal policy actions indirectly affect the econ­
omy. They are designed to influence the eco­
nomic decisions of individuals, rather than ac­
tually dictate the decisions. These policies do
not determine directly the incomes most of us
earn or the prices we pay for our purchases.
There are exceptions, of course. Certainly, the
income of a person who entirely depends upon
Social Security would vary directly with govern­
ment action. Nevertheless, these policies usually
operate indirectly, rather than directly, on our
economic decision-making.
Monetary policy in the United States is deter­
mined and carried out by the Federal Reserve
M O N T H L Y R E V IE W

On one end of the spectrum of economic
policies are two general or aggregate tools—
m onetary and fiscal policies.

System. By adjusting the supply of reserves
available to banks, the Federal Reserve can af­
fect the supply of money and available credit
in the economy. This, in turn, affects the price of
credit, the investment decisions of investors, and
the purchasing power of consumers. Thus, total
spending in the economy can be spurred either
to absorb unused capacity or can be restrained to
relieve the pressure on an inflationary economy.
Fiscal policy operates primarily through the
budgetary activities of the Federal Government.
By increasing or decreasing its own expenditures,
the Government directly adds to or detracts from
total spending. By lowering or raising taxes, the
spending power of the private sector of the econ­
omy is increased or decreased.
C a lls fo r C o n tr o ls

Until recently, general monetary and fiscal poli­
cies have carried the burden of the fight against
inflation in the United States. They have not
been without opposition, however. Some critics
contend that, because of the complex and indirect
channels through which monetary policy operates,
it is effective in cooling an overheated economy
only after a long delay. Many observe that, for
various reasons, monetary policy discriminates
between various sectors of the economy. For ex­
ample, in a period of scarce credit, housing and
state and local governments are usually placed
under greater strain than are other sectors.
Fiscal policy is assailed because of the time
required to make policy adjustments. Even if
changes in expenditures and taxation are effec­
tive policy instruments, they usually require Con­
gressional action, which is not always rapid
and may be influenced by political considera­
tions.
Worse still, many critics argue that even if
restrictive monetary and fiscal policies were ef­
fective in curtailing excess demand, they would
still not be sufficient to stop the spiral of price
increases. Thus, we are told that the nation will
end up with the worst of all possible worlds—
inflation and high unemployment. The current
pressures on prices, according to critics, come
D ECEM BER

1970




from the cost or supply side of markets, and
monetary and fiscal policies are not effective in
fighting this “cost push” aspect of inflation. How
can this be?
There are several reasons why prices may not
respond immediately to reduced demand. First,
much of the economy is not characterized by
numerous, highly competitive small firms, a
necessary condition for what economists call
“perfect competition.” Instead, the economy con­
tains many firms which may have considerable
influence over the prices they charge. Once these
firms have set a price, they are reluctant to reduce
it. Cuts in production are preferred to price cuts
when output cannot be sold at existing prices.
Also, demand slowdowns are often accompanied
by rising costs. Despite production cuts, some
companies may be initially reluctant to lay off
trained personnel for fear of losing them to other
companies. As output falls, output per man-hour,
or productivity, tends to fall. At the same time,
workers attempt to catch up with past inflation
by demanding wage increases. With productivity
declining and wage rates rising, unit labor costs of
output rise. Thus, even in the face of declining
demand, there remain pressures to keep prices
from falling.
Eventually the decline in output and rising
costs lead to layoffs. Unemployment rises. Unit
labor costs begin to fall or rise more slowly.
Productivity increases. Companies undertake
other cost-cutting procedures. But with continued
pressure on wages, the results of these efforts
come slowly. Prices may continue to rise for a
time. Also, unemployment may continue to rise
until workers locate existing job vacancies or
until growth in the economy is sufficient to
provide new jobs for the unemployed.
Critics of restrictive policies found support for
their views in the economic development of the
past six or nine months. For a painfully long
time, prices seemed to have continued a relent­
less rise; unemployment has increased; and the
economy has behaved sluggishly. Despite recent
indications of better price performance, cries are
still heard for different policies, either to ob­
tain or to speed the necessary economic adjust­
ments. But what other policies are available?
Recall that monetary and fiscal policies lie
at one end of the spectrum of economic policies.
At the other end lie direct or compulsory con­
trols. These policies directly affect many of the
economic decisions of individuals. In general,
they are designed to fix specific prices, wages,
175

D espite recent indications of better price per­
formance, cries are heard for different policies,
either to obtain or to speed necessary econom­
ic adjustm ents.

profits, credit, or perhaps even types of produc­
tion, especially during periods of inflation. The
individual businessman would be prohibited from
charging more than a certain ceiling price for
his product. The individual worker could not
receive more than a ceiling wage for his labor
services. The individual consumer also might
be prohibited from purchasing an item for which
he does not have sufficient rationing points.
Clearly, such policies greatly interfere with
freedom of choice. In addition, they substantial­
ly distort the workings of a free enterprise econ­
omy. Usually, these policies require a large
bureaucracy merely to implement the controls.
Because they are fixed, prices cannot perform
their vital role as signals to producers and con­
sumers, and cannot direct productive resources
into areas of greatest demand. Consequently,
compulsory controls not only hinder individual
freedom but also undermine efficient produc­
tion processes. As a substitute for well-conceived,
responsible monetary and fiscal policies, direct
controls are not particularly attractive. Even
worse, historical experience has shown that they
do not eliminate, but only temporarily suppress,
the basic causes of inflation. For example, direct
controls could not offset ill-conceived, irrespon­
sible monetary or fiscal policies.
In c o m e s P o lic ie s

The undesirability of compulsory controls has
led most critics to seek milder measures. Most
often, they have urged that wage-price guide­
lines be established for the United States econ­
omy. This measure has been sought as a supple­
ment to, not a replacement for, corrective mone­
tary and fiscal policies. Critics maintain that
guidelines would assist the more general mea­
sures by shortening the time required for them
to slow the rise in prices and thus prevent at
least some of the rise in unemployment. Guide­
lines would assist in offsetting cost-push pres­
sures.
Wage-price guidelines are one variation of an­
other type of economic policy, incomes policies.
176



During the 1960’s, incomes policies of various
sorts were employed to help achieve the goals of
stabilization policy in numerous countries.
These policies vary from country to country in
both objectives and methods, and there is no
generally accepted definition of an incomes
policy. In the spectrum of economic policies,
they fall somewhere between the general or in­
direct monetary and fiscal policies and direct,
compulsory controls. Incomes policies seldom
involve actual direct controls but often restrain
the more or less free reins allowed by general
monetary and fiscal policies.
Most incomes policies are designed to reconcile
the economic goals of individuals (such as higher
profits by managers and businessmen) with the
economic goals of the nation as a whole (such as
stable prices). Usually an incomes policy is
primarily concerned with the advance of the
general price and wage levels, rather than with
wages and prices in particular industries.
In some countries, the government not only
defines acceptable limits for overall increases in
wages, prices, and profits but also sets a more
or less exact criterion for the distribution of in­
comes among the various categories of income
recipients. For example, the government might
decide that, in the aggregate, wage earners should
receive 65 percent of the national income.
One reason for the difficulty in defining an
incomes policy is the different emphasis given
to the various objectives of these measures in
several nations. Rather than attem pt a general
definition, let us look at three varieties of an in­
comes policy that have been used in the
Netherlands, the Scandinavian nations, and the
United States. This will highlight the variations
in the approaches and also permit us to draw
some conclusions about the effectiveness of
these policies.
Incomes Policy in the Netherlands
Among the Western nations, the Netherlands
has had one of the strongest incomes policies. The
dependence of the nation’s economy on foreign
trade has resulted in extraordinary cooperation
between trade unions, business, and the govern­
ment. All have realized the importance of main­
taining the country’s international competitive
position; all have been willing to accept an in­
comes policy.
After World War II, the Netherlands faced the
task of rebuilding its economy. To assist in ac­
M O N T H L Y R E V IE W

complishing the reconstruction without sacrific­
ing its international competitive position, a
strong incomes policy was adopted. Wage- and
price-fixing machinery was established. Although
controls were compulsory, they were greeted by
an exceptional spirit of cooperation between all
sectors of the economy. In 1945, the Labor Foun­
dation was established to formalize cooperation
between labor and management. In the same
year, an Extraordinary Decree on labor relations
set up a Board of Mediators with the power to
fix wages and determine rules governing wage
changes. The Board was also given the power
to administer penalties and sanctions. However,
the Board was required to seek the advice of
the Labor Foundation and, in practice, generally
followed its recommendations.
In 1950, another organization was established—
the Social and Economic Council. The Council
is comprised of equal representation from gov­
ernment, business, and labor. Whereas the Labor
Foundation is concerned primarily with wage
policy on the industry level, the Council focuses
on broader, national objectives (including the
distribution of income).

A m o n g th e W e s te r n n a tio n s , th e N e th e r la n d s
h a s h a d o n e o f th e s tr o n g e s t in c o m e s policies.

Between 1945 and 1954, wages were controlled
in the Netherlands. No increases were allowed
without permission of the Board, and wage boosts
were allowed only for cost-of-living increases.
Some differences were allowed, however, where
job skills differed, in order to induce workers to
advance. Since economic recovery was underway,
wages as a share of Gross National Product fell
during this period.
In 1954, the Council developed a new policy.
Rather than merely maintaining the purchasing
power of wage earners, real wages would be al­
lowed to increase. Wages as a share of GNP
would remain constant. Overall wage increases
were negotiated on this basis, largely through col­
lective bargaining. Wage differentials between
jobs, however, were permitted to increase.
A new government in 1959 instituted yet an­
other new policy. Emphasis was shifted from
economy-wide wage adjustments to changes by
particular industries. Wage increases in each in­
D ECEM BER

1970




dustry were tied to productivity advances in
that industry, as estimated by the Board of
Mediators. Industries with higher-than-average
productivity advances had to pass on some of
the advances in the form of both lower prices and
higher wages. Falling prices in high productivity
industries meant that wage increases could be
granted in industries with slow productivity
growth and reflected in higher prices without af­
fecting overall prices.
The task proved too difficult for the Board of
Mediators, and dissatisfaction with the estimates
grew. Accurate estimates of productivity in­
creases by industry are difficult to estimate. Also,
rapidly rising wages in other nations put pressure
on the Board’s standards. Labor demand in the
Netherlands was high and wages actually paid
often exceeded approved levels.
By 1963, the program had to be changed again.
Responsibility for individual negotiations was
shifted to the individual firms and unions. Settle­
ments were submitted for approval to the Labor
Foundation, which in turn was influenced by the
Economic and Social Council's assessment of the
economic climate and acceptable wage increases.
The Board of Mediators entered the process only
if the Foundation disapproved specific settle­
ments, but the Board did retain formal powers to
control wages.
These new arrangements did not last; the same
demand pressures developed again. In 1967, the
entire system was dropped and free negotiations
were permitted. The government, however, still
retains the power to invalidate individual agree­
ments.
But what about prices? Throughout the post­
war period, the government also had extensive
legal control over prices. However, the threat of
control was sufficient in itself, and actual pricing
policies were based almost entirely on voluntary
cooperation between the government and busi­
ness.
Price policy was actually carried out by the
Ministry of Economic Affairs. The Ministry
received advance notice of price increases for all
goods and services, along with the justification
for these price hikes. If the Ministry did not ap­
prove, it usually requested that they be rescinded.
If this failed, legal powers were available to force
a rollback.
Throughout the postwar period, price and wage
policies were closely coordinated. For example,
in 1951, prices were raised by 10 percent, but
wages by only 5 percent, in order to restore ex177

tem al balance. A 5-percent wage increase in
1964 was passed on into a 5-percent price in­
crease. These close policy links provided the
Netherlands’ government with considerable in­
fluence over wage and profit incomes and the
uses to which income was put. Investment ex­
penditures were stimulated, while consumption
was minimized.
In summary, the Netherlands moved from a
policy of virtually direct controls to progressively
less restriction until 1969.1 There is reason to be­
lieve that the policy greatly aided the nation to
achieve a stable reconstruction without seriously
eroding its international competitive position. As
the recovery proceeded, the vital cooperation be­
tween economic sectors began to diminish, and
the government’s ability to rely on voluntary
restraint dissipated. Free market forces finally
dominated.

Throughout the postw ar period , price and
wage policies were closely coordinated in the
N etherlands.

The Scandinavian Experience
Among the Scandinavian nations, Norway’s in­
comes policy most closely resembles that of the
Netherlands. Both nations faced similar prob­
lems. Direct government regulation was relied on
to speed postwar recovery without damaging the
international competitive position. Price and
profits controls were extensively utilized in Nor­
way, but since then have been progressively
relaxed. Compulsory arbitration of labor disputes
was employed until 1952. However, the various
economic policies have not been so closely co­
ordinated as in the Netherlands. Wage negotia­
tions, conducted on a national level between un­
ion and management groups, usually set patterns
for industry- and firm-level negotiations. The
government does not enter directly into the

1Recently, this trend has been reversed. In 1969 and 1970, the
Netherlands’ government used price controls with varying de­
grees of effectiveness. These have now been extended in
the form of guidelines until March 1971. Also, the budget
proposal for 1971 provides for a temporary wage freeze.

178



Am ong the Scandinavian nations, N orw ay’s
incomes policy m ost closely resembles that
of the Netherlands. . . . Sw eden presents a
slightly different picture.

negotiations but, rather, merely announces what
it considers acceptable settlement limits. Through­
out most of the 1950’s, government influence
was used sparingly. But in 1968, compulsory
arbitration was reinstated to settle stalled
negotiations. On the whole, government interven­
tion in the economy was not quite as detailed as
in the Netherlands; however, it has remained
somewhat stronger.
Sweden presents a slightly different picture.
The government’s policy maneuvers in that
country have been intermittent. The manual
labor force and the white collar labor force are
organized into two separate unions, and conse­
quently, it has been more difficult for nationwide
bargaining to achieve settlements consistent with
national economic objectives. As in Norway,
Sweden’s formal administrative framework is not
as elaborate as in the Netherlands.
Beginning in 1948, the Swedish Government
urged unions and management to use a policy of
wage restraint in order to achieve price stability.
Dividend limitations and higher profits taxes
were coupled with the request. The policy worked
fairly well from 1949 to the Korean War boom,
but in 1952, both wages and prices rose more
than 29 percent, and the wage restraint policy
was dropped by the government and by the
unions. In 1953 and in 1954, the policy was reinsti­
tuted, but under the pressure of stronger demand
again failed in 1955. Moderate national settle­
ments characterized the second half of the 1950’s.
The reason was probably reduced demand for
labor and goods, rather than union restraint.
Prices remained reasonably stable.
The 1960’s policy saw little change in Sweden.
Central negotiations still set the national pattern
for wage settlements. However, strong demand
for labor and other factors resulted in local wage
payments which have exceeded centrally negoti­
ated settlements. In the latter part of the decade,
the government appointed an arbitration com­
mittee to aid in settling stalled central wage
negotiations.
In general, Sweden’s incomes policy has been
much milder and more intermittent than those
M O N T H L Y R E V IE W

of the Netherlands and Norway. Legal fixing of
prices, profits, or wages was not used. Price sta­
bility was sought by efforts to hold down wage in­
creases, but compulsory arbitration was not em­
ployed. However, this policy has probably been
less effective. Substantial wage and price in­
creases have occurred, and during periods of
strong demand the policy has been dropped. How­
ever, in the face of excess demand, a general price
freeze is now being employed.
The United States—Wage-Priee Guidelines
The problems and the policy in the United States
have been different. Postwar reconstruction was
not necessary, and the balance of payments, al­
though a matter of concern, is less important to
the total economy. There were, however, two
other problems. The 1950’s were characterized
by slow growth and persistently high unemploy­
ment, with the unemployment rate averaging a
staggering 6.8 percent in 1958 and 6.7 percent in
1961. Prices during the period remained relatively
stable, however.
The task in the early 1960’s was to stimulate
growth and employment without inducing infla­
tion. Expansionary fiscal and monetary policies
were used to spur the growth. To accompany these
policies, the 1962 Economic Report of the Presi­
dent announced a set of wage-price guideposts.
The statement noted the inflationary bias built
into the institutions of the economy, such as the
ability of large corporations to offset unionnegotiated wage increases by raising prices.
Many prices were not determined by competitive
market forces, but were “administered.” A vigor­
ous application of wage-price guideposts might
overcome this bias.
The Report noted that the change in produc­
tivity is the basic guide as to whether or not
an increase in wages or prices is inflationary.
Money wages can increase at the same rate as the
overall rate of increase in productivity in the
economy without raising the labor cost per unit
of output. Thus, the wage increases would not
be inflationary. If the rate of productivity in
a particular industry is greater (less) than the
overall rate, and if its money wages increase

The problems and the policy in the United
States have been different.

D ECEM BER

1 9 70




equaled the overall rate, the unit labor cost
would fall (rise) in that industry. In this case its
prices should be lowered (raised). There could
be exceptions. For example, rapidly expanding
industries might need to bid wages up in order
to attract workers, while contracting industries
would pay relatively less.
This policy was entirely voluntary. Direct
government control of prices and wages was never
threatened. However, the persuasive power of the
government can still be great. Unjustifiably large
wage settlements and price increases were called
to the public’s attention in order to mobilize
public opinion. Shifts in government contracts,
the possible freeing of government stockpiles, and
the ever-present possibility of antitrust action
were powerful incentives for business and labor
to accept the guideposts.
The policy worked reasonably well so long as
there was unemployment and excess capacity. As
demand increased, however, so did pressure on
wages and prices. By 1966, transportation and
automobile wage settlements, among others, ex­
ceeded the guideposts. In 1967, average hourly
compensation in the private sector of the econ­
omy rose by 6 percent and consumer prices by
about 3 percent. The guideposts began to crumble
under the weight of excess demand. The 1967
and 1968 Economic Reports of the President
recognized the collapse of the policy. Without
the threat of compulsory controls, the guideposts
could not be enforced. With the guideposts inef­
fective, the government fell back on conventional
monetary and fiscal policies to combat the in­
flation which resulted from the overheated econ­
omy.2
S u c c e s s or F a ilu r e ?

A review of the experience with incomes policies
suggests that they have not been an unqualified
success. Nevertheless, there have been instances
when inflation probably would have been more
severe if some form of incomes policy had not
been in effect. These experiences suggest that

2Recently, the President established a National Committee
on Productivity, with representatives from labor, business,
the public, and the government. The Council of Economic
Advisers now prepares reports that spotlight significant
areas of inflation. Government purchases and regulations
are under review for possible inflationary impact. It re­
mains to be seen whether or not these actions will reduce
inflation.

179

A n essential requirement is that an incomes
policy m ust be accompanied by appropriate
monetary and fiscal policies.

such a policy is more likely to succeed if certain
conditions are present.
An incomes policy seems more likely to hold
down wage and prioe advances in an economy
that is less than fully employed than in an
economy in which there are few unused resources.
Although there is an absence of general demand
pressures in an underemployed economy, there
may be cost-push pressures in some sectors. This
type of policy could be useful in discouraging
wage and price increases resulting from the con­
centration of economic power by either big labor
or big business in certain industries. In this case,
the incomes policy may hold down excessive ad­
ministered price and wage increases while mone­
tary and fiscal policies are adopted to help bring
the economy to full employment. This seems to
have been the case in the United States during
the early 1960’s.
On the other hand, experience suggests that
if the economy were more than fully employed,
an incomes policy would collapse. Such was the
situation in Sweden in 1952 and 1955. In the
United States, wage and price guidelines appar­
ently had some marginal success until 1965
when, with the economy almost fully employed,
the policy became ineffective.
Another essential requirement is that the policy
must be accompanied by appropriate monetary
and fiscal policies. It cannot be used as a substi­
tute for limiting excessive demand. This is espe­
cially true when the policy relies wholly on vol­
untary cooperation. If the government is stim­
ulating purchasing power through deficit finan­
cing during a period of full employment and the
monetary authorities are adding to purchasing
power by expanding the monetary base, no
amount of exhortation would prevent business­
men and wage earners from giving in to the temp­
tation to seek higher prices and wages.
An incomes policy would be more effective
when there is a well-designed organizational
framework of labor and business and when there
is a strong consensus by these organizations in
support of the policy. In the European countries
where it was apparently effective during certain
periods, there were strong labor and business
180



organizations. The Netherlands is an out­
standing example. Lacking such a well-designed
and well-defined framework, the wage-price
guidelines in the United States had to depend a
great deal upon rallying the support of the
American public on essentially moral grounds.
For example, certain price increases in the early
1960’s were said to be unjustified or contrary to
the public interest. The huge power and influence
of the Presidency was brought to bear on those
seeking to exceed the guidelines.
As a practical matter, an incomes policy is
more likely to be effective when productivity is
increasing than when it is not. Condi tions of ris­
ing productivity make possible an increase in
real wages over time without pinching the profits
of businesses. Under these circumstances, the
policy is more likely to receive support than
when productivity, real wages, and profits are
declining.

W o u ld a n in c o m e s p o lic y be a p p ro p ria te a n d
e ffe c tiv e in th e c u r r e n t A m e r ic a n eco n o m ic
s e ttin g ?

Moreover, it is more likely to succeed if it ap­
plies to all sectors of the economy. The applica­
tion of the policy to wages but not to prices
would be ineffective. It must apply to both. For
example, in the Netherlands, wage and price
policies were closely coordinated.
An incomes policy is more likely to be success­
ful when there is a strong threat of foreign com­
petition than when a greater part of the economy
is insulated from economic developments in
other countries. This was important to the suc­
cess of such a policy in the Netherlands. Foreign
competition mobilized strong public support for
it and provided an environment in which prices
and wages were under external pressures not to
increase too rapidly. On the other hand, if a
country—at the same time it adopted an incomes
policy—set up barriers to imports, the likelihood
of success would be diminished. But it might also
increase the need for an incomes policy.
Another implication to be drawn, from expe­
rience is that success of this type of policy is
closely tied to its timing. It might be appropriate
at one time and not at another. For example, it
could be worthless if applied before other restric­
M O N T H L Y R E V IE W

tive measures begin to bite. If excessive demand
pressures have been eliminated and price in­
creases are stemming mostly from cost-push
pressures, the policy stands a better chance of
success.
A n In c o m e s P o lic y N o w ?

Would an incomes policy be appropriate and ef­
fective in the current American economic set­
ting? It is contended by many persons that ex­
cess demand has now been largely eliminated in
the American economy. The slowdown in the
rate of economic growth, the large amount of un­
used capacity, and the higher unemployment
rates are cited as evidence that total demand has
been brought under control. At the same time, the
continuing rise in prices in some sectors of the
economy suggests to these persons that most cur­
rent increases in prices stem from cost-push fac­
tors. This seems, then, to be an appropriate time
for applying some kind of an incomes policy.
On the other hand, there are persons who cite
the diminishing strength of inflationary forces as

D ECEM BER

1970




evidence that, given time for the economy to ad­
just, monetary and fiscal policies will turn out
effective. These persons argue that, even if the
results are not completely satisfactory, one could
not expect an incomes policy to do much better.
In rebuttal, proponents of an incomes policy,
however, argue that it would reduce the time re­
quired for monetary and fiscal policies to work,
and, at the same time, hold down the rise in
unemployment.
Just as it is extremely difficult—if not impos­
sible—to determine how much influence incomes
policies have had in the past, it is an open ques­
tion as to how effective au€h a policy would be
under present conditions in the United States. In
any case, too much should not be expected from
an incomes policy, should one be put into effect.
It would not be a panacea, and it would not work
without sacrifice. At best, it would be marginally
helpful and would not be harmful to other wellchosen policies.

R obert H. F loyd

181

M e a s u r in g M o n e t a r y P o lic y

T w o m e n t a l k in a T r e a s u r e r ’s o ffic e , d e e p in s id e t h e
h e a d q u a r t e r s o f a n A m e r ic a n

c o r p o r a tio n .

T h e ir

to p ic :

“ H a s m o n e t a r y p o lic y b e c o m e le s s r e s t r ic ti v e s in c e l a s t
m o n t h ? ” F i n a n c i a l s t a t i s t i c s lie s c a t t e r e d a r o u n d t h e ro o m .

“L o o k w h a t's h a p p e n e d to t h e T r e a s u r y b ill r a te : I t ’s
g o n e d o w n th r e e - e ig h ts o f a p o in t. T h e F e d ’s e a s in g u p .”
“B u t t h e F e d e r a l fu n d s r a te ( a n d t h e y p a y a l o t o f
a t t e n t i o n to t h a t b e c a u s e i t ’s w h a t b a n k s p a y to b o rro w
m o n e y o v e r n ig h t) h a s n ’t b u d g e d . I d o n ’t s e e h o w y o u
c a n s a y m o n e ta r y p o lic y h a s e a s e d a n y .”
“O k a y , b u t t h e m o n e y s u p p l y g r e w a t a 5 - p e r c e n t r a te
th is m o n t h , a n d t h a t ’s a c c o r d in g to t h e F e d ’s o w n p r e s s
r e le a se . L a s t m o n t h , i t o n ly g r e w a t 4 p e r c e n t. P o lic y
lo o k s e a s ie r t o m e .”
“B u t fr e e r e s e r v e s fe ll. I t h o u g h t t h a t m e a n t c o n d itio n s
w e r e t ig h t e r .”
“S o d id I . B u t to ta l r e s e r v e s w e n t u p . T h a t d o e s n ’t lo o k
l ik e t h e F e d is tig h te n in g a n y . H o w c a n c o n d itio n s b e
tig h te r if th e b a n k s h a v e m o re re se rv e s? ”
“I ’m c o n fu s e d .”

182



M O N T H L Y R E V IE W

The conversation is hypothetical, of course. But
the situation is not. A lot of people spend a lot
of time trying to measure the posture of monetary
policy. Often as not, they rely on published
financial statistics: Treasury bill rates, Federal
funds rates, money supply growth—all are socalled indicators of monetary policy. Often as
not, each indicator gives a different answer.
Often as not, the result is, “I’m confused.”
To most economists, all this may look like
nonsense. They know the economy is complicated
and that a single “right” indicator of monetary
policy may not exist. If there is one, it has not
been discovered yet. If economic research ever
discovers one, it may turn out to be something
our two businessmen have never seen.
“The best our businessmen can do,” most
economists might say, “would be to consider as
many relevant elements as they can when they
analyze the economy. It is probably naive to
expect a single indicator to summarize the in­
fluence of monetary policy on something as
complicated as the American economy.”
“All right,” says the businessman, “but what
do I do in the meantime? I recognize that mone­
tary policy has a strong influence on economic
behavior. I still want to measure what that in­
fluence is. Anyway, I hear all the time about
experts making comments on the economy, and
they cite indicators like the money supply or the
Treasury bill rate. You can be patient and wait
for the results of economic research. But I can’t.
M y boss wants a sales forecast next week.
“Even if it won’t do a perfect job, can’t I
just pick one indicator or two and use them
anyway? Won’t they measure monetary policy
well enough for my purposes? What difference
does it make which indicator I choose?”
The answer, unfortunately, is that it makes
a lot of difference. That we shall see in the next
section. In the concluding section, we shall see
why.
D iffe re n t In d ic a t o r s G ive
D iffe re n t A n s w e r s

A list of all the variables people have used to
measure monetary policy might be virtually end­
less. But only a small group of indicators are in
widespread use, either because they have been
suggested by the results of economic research or
because they have been publicized in the financial
press. Each of them has some appeal.
We picked eight financial variables that have
D ECEM BER

1 9 70




been widely cited as indicators of monetary
policy. Two of them are interest rates: the
Federal funds rate and the rate on three-month
Treasury bills. A third, the level of free reserves,
is denominated in dollars but is thought to be­
have like an interest rate. The other five indi­
cators we picked are so-called monetary aggre­
gates: the money supply excluding time de­
posits, the money supply including time deposits,
the bank credit proxy, total reserves, and the
monetary base.1 (Definitions and sources of these
variables are in the Appendix.)
There is no obvious way to characterize par­
ticular readings of these indicators absolutely,
as either restrictive or stimulative. If we wish to
use the Treasury bill rate as an indicator, for
instance, then any characterization of a 5.25percent bill rate as “restrictive” or “stimulative”
is arbitrary. What is clear, however, is that a
5.25-percent bill rate indicates less stimulation
(or more restriction) than a 5.00-percent rate
and more stimulation than a 5.50-percent rate.
More stimulation might also be “indicated” by a
decrease in the Federal funds rate, by an increase
in free reserves, or by an increase in the growth
rates for any of the five monetary aggregates we
selected.2
Recognizing this, we calculated the number of
months in which each pair of indicators gave
signals in the same policy direction—toward
more restriction or toward less restriction.3 The
results, covering the 12 months of 1969 and the
60 months of 1965-69, are in Table I.
From these results, it is easy to see why our
two businessmen were confused. Different in­
dicators do give different signals. In 1969, the
monetary base and total reserves came closest to
giving the same signals; yet, even this pair agreed
in only 9 out of 12 months. More typically,
agreement on whether policy was more or less

10n e of the reasons for including both interest rates and
monetary aggregates on our list of indicators is that these
two types correspond to the “prices” and “quantities” on
the supply-demand diagrams economists use in financial
analysis. The economist’s choice of which interest rate, or
which monetary aggregate, is determined by his definition of
the market he wants to analyze. We were curious to see
whether signals given by price-type (interest rates) indicators/quantity-type (monetary aggregate) indicators corre­
sponded more closely with signals given by other price-type/
quantity-type indicators.
2Our eight financial variables, in other words, are ordinal
measures of monetary policy.
3Since we used eight indicators, each indicator can be com­
pared pairwise with seven others. There are 1 + 2 + 3 +
4 + 5 + 6 + 7 = 28 different comparisons to be made.

183

restrictive came in 6 to 8 of the 12 months in
1969, which implies that blind substitution of
one indicator for another would have changed
the answer almost half the time: In 4 to 6
months, the indicators gave opposite signals. Two
indicators that would generally be expected to
show close correspondence—the Federal funds
rate and the Treasury bill rate—gave the same
signals only 3 times out of 12.4
Nor was 1969 an unusual period. Calculations
4Here is a case where a pair of price-type indicators agree
less well with each other than with some of the quantitytype indicators. In general, Table I shows no tendency for
indicators to agree more with other indicators of the same
(price or quantity) type.

for the 60-month period from 1965-69 gave similar
results. Most of the indicator pairs agreed in 35
to 45 of the 60 months or, again, only a little
more than half the time. Moreover, separate
calculations for each of the five years show that
the degree of agreement for each pair of indi­
cators varies considerably from year to year.5
Table II repeats the analysis. The approach
is slightly more sophisticated, but the results are
much the same. To get each coefficient at the top
of Table II, we took the 12 monthly readings in

■"'Annual data for 1965-68 are not shown but are available on
request from the Research Department, Federal Reserve
Bank of Atlanta.

table i

NUMBER OF MONTHS IN WHICH
INDICATORS MOVED IN THE SAME POLICY DIRECTION
1965-1969*
M,

M o n e y Supply
(Narrow)

60

M;

M o n e y Supply
(Broad)

45

60

BCP

B a n k Credit
Proxy

35

40

60

TR

Total R e s e r v e s

34

39

51

60

M B

Monetary

40

43

43

48

60

FR

Free Reserves

33

32

31

31

29

60

FF

Federal F u n d s
Rate

33

34

32

45

35

40

60

BR

Three-month
T r e a s u r y Bill
Rate

26

39

37

40

31

31

39

60

Mi

M 2

BCP

TR

M B

FR

FF

BR

Base

1969**
Mi

M o n e y Supply
(Narrow)

12

M;

M o n e y Supply
(Broad)

8

12

BCP

B a n k Credit
Proxy

6

6

TR

Total R e s e r v e s

4

6

8

12

M B

Monetary

7

7

7

9

12

Base

12

FR

Free Reserves

8

6

8

8

5

12

FF

Federal F u n d s
Rate

7

7

7

7

6

7

BR

Three-month
T r e a s u r y Bill
Rate

3

7

Mi

mu

5
­

BCP

12

7

6

3

6

12

TR

M B

FR

FF

BR

* 6 0 - m o n t h tot al
* * 1 2 - m o n t h total

184



M O N T H L Y R E V IE W

1969 for each variable and ranked the months
I, 2, . . . , 12, in order of increasing restrictiveness.
(For instance, the month with the highest Trea­
sury bill rate was assigned a rank of 12; the
month with the lowest rate was ranked as 1.)
For the entire 1965-69 period, rankings ranged
from one to 60. The ranked relationships for
each pair of indicators are summarized by the
Spearman rank correlation coefficients in Table
II.6 Here, as in Table I, a higher number shows
closer correspondence between two indicators:
1.000 would show perfect correspondence; .000
would show no correspondence.
Table II reinforces the results of Table I:

Different indicators do give different signals. In
1969, for instance, only seven pairs of indicators
produced coefficients which can be considered
significantly different from zero. (A zero coef-

(1Spearman coefficients are discussed in most standard statis­
tical texts; see, for example, J. E. Freund, Modern Elemen­
tary Statistics (3d Ed., 1967), p. 364. If the monthly ranks
assigned to each of a pair of indicators are identical (1-1,
2-2, etc.), their joint Spearman coefficient will be one. If the
orderings are opposite (1-12, 2-11, etc., in the 12-month
case), the Spearman coefficient will be minus one. The
Spearman analysis has two advantages over the more naive
procedure embodied in Table I: It weights large move­
ments in the indicators more heavily than small movements,
and it also permits us to make some inference about whether
the relationships are statistically significant.

TABLE II
SPEARMAN COEFFICIENTS OF RANK CORRELATION
1965-1969
Mi

M o n e y Supply
(Narrow)

1.000**

M

M o n e y Supply
(Broad)

.669**

'2

1.000**

BCP

B a n k Credit
Proxy

.332**

.779**

1.000**

TR

Total R e s e r v e s

.332**

.523**

.783**

1.000**

M B

Monetary

.373**

.386**

.539**

.753**

1.000**

Base

FR

Free Reserves

.289*

.672**

.659**

.454**

.269*

1.000**

FF

Federal F u n d s
Rate

.237*

.611**

.529**

.278*

.184

.850**

1.000**

BR

Three-month
T r e a s u r y Bill
Rate

.209

.639**

.509**

.220*

.138

.758**

.929**

Mi

M 2

BCP

TR

M B

FR

FF

1.000**
BR

1969
Mi

M o n e y Supply
(Narrow)

1.000**

M =

M o n e y Supply
(Broad)

.783**

BCP

B a n k Credit
Proxy

.025

TR

Total R e s e r v e s

M B

Monetary

Base

1.000* *
.504

1.000**

-.225

.210

.532*

1.000**

.144

.330

.356

.571*

1.000**

FR

Free Reserves

.387

.683*

.252

.126

- .032

FF

Federal F u n d s
Rate

.808**

.648*

.049

-.021

.144

.413

1.000**

BR

Three-month
T r e a s u r y Bill
Rate

.436

.228

-.193

- .168

.147

.014

.657*

Mi

Ma

M B

FR

BCP

TR

1.000**

FF

1.000**
BR

* D i f f e r e n c e f r o m z e r o s i g n i f i c a n t ( 9 5 % level)
* * D i f f e r e n c e f r o m z e r o h i g h l y s i g n i f i c a n t ( 9 9 % level)

D ECEM BER

1 9 70




185

ficient for a pair of indicators would say, in ef­
fect, that if we wanted to guess the rank of a
month according to one of the indicators, we
would probably come as close by guessing at
random as we would come by using the ranking
for the same month according to the other in­
dicator.) Most of the 1965-69 coefficients are
significantly nonzero, but in almost every case
they are low enough to reinforce our conclusion
that different indicators give different answers
about the posture of monetary policy.7
W hy?

Different indicators do give different measure­
ments of monetary policy. That much is clear.
Even in cases where we might expect a pair of
indicators to move together very closely, they
don’t.
Why don’t they?
For a couple of reasons: First, monetary policy
actions take longer to influence some indicators
than others. Second, each indicator is not in­
fluenced solely by monetary policy actions but
by a great many other things. Indeed, when these
considerations are recognized, it would be sur­
prising if any pair of indicators did give the same
signals month after month.
Let’s look at each of these reasons in a little
more detail. Before doing that, however, we
should ask what we mean when we talk about
an indicator of monetary policy. Few of us are
interested in Federal Reserve monetary policy
actions8 for their own sake. W hat we are really
interested in are the effects of those policy ac­
tions. People use indicators to describe, and to
predict, the effects of monetary policy actions.
Effects on what? Effects on a great many dif­
ferent markets. Most people, and certainly most
economists, would answer, “effects on the econo­
my.” (More precisely, perhaps, “on total income
and production in our economy.” ) But a build­
ing contractor might not agree; he might be more
interested in knowing about effects on housing
starts. A prospective borrower might say, in­
stead, “effects on interest rates.” Obviously, the
list could get pretty long. Different people are

interested in the effects on many different
markets.
Assume, however, that our basic concern is
with monetary policy’s effects on the whole econ­
omy. For most of us, that would be true. Like the
two businessmen whose dialogue began this arti­
cle, we might rely on financial statistics such as
the Treasury bill rate or the money supply
figures, hoping that what happens to these statis­
tics now will tell us what will happen to the
economy later. Even so, there is no reason to
expect the financial statistics to move in tandem.
Policy actions now may affect the Treasury bill
rate right away, for instance, but it may be two
or three months before we can observe the effects
of the same policy actions on the money supply.
Nevertheless, policy actions probably do affect
some indicators rather quickly: not only the
Treasury bill rate but also the Federal funds rate
and the level of free reserves. Why don’t the
signals given by indicators like these correspond
more closely?
The answer lies in our second reason, which is
probably more important: Each indicator re­
sponds to a great many things besides monetary
policy actions. The Treasury bill rate responds to
monetary policy actions, for instance, but it also
responds to the amount of funds people want to
invest. Then, too, the bill rate depends on the
volume of bills the Treasury decides to sell. If the
Treasury bill rate falls by a percentage point,
there is no way we can tell how much of that
drop resulted from last week’s (or last year’s)
monetary policy actions and how much resulted
from other happenings.1’
The same point could be made for all the indi­
cators we examined (and any other indicators,
for that m atter). The various indicators “indi­
cate” a lot besides monetary policy. It is hardly
surprising that they often give different signals.
S t i ll

C o n fu se d ?

We started off with a pair of confused business­
men. They were confused because different indi­
cators were giving different signals about mone­
tary policy. If they read this article, would they
still be confused? Perhaps. But in the process,
they may have learned a few lessons that are not

7As before, there is no systematic tendency for price- or
quantity-type indicators to correspond more closely with
indicators of the same type.
sExamples of such actions are purchases and sales of govern­
ment securities, changes in the discount rate, and in the
reserve requirement percentages required of member banks.

186



!'Economists try to answer questions like these with so-called
econometric models. The results are both complicated and
uncertain.
M O N T H L Y R E V IE W

always understood: that the workings of the
economy are complicated; that our knowledge of
the linkages between monetary and financial
measures is inexact; and that he who puts his

APPENDIX:

trust in (and his money on!) a single financial
variable does so at his own risk.
W illiam N. Cox, III

DESCRIPTION AND SOURCES OF DATA

D e s c rip tio n

S o u rce

M o n e y S u p p ly
(N a r ro w )

S e a so n a lly a d ju ste d m o n th ly a verages of
d a ily fig u res a t a ll co m m ercia l ban ks

F e d e r a l R e se r v e B u lle tin

M o n e y S u p p ly
(B roa d )

S e a so n a lly a d ju ste d m o n th ly a v era g es of
d a ily figu res. (T im e d e p o sits a t a ll
co m m ercia l ban ks ad d ed to M i)

F e d e r a l R e s e r v e B u lle tin

B a n k C red it P r o x y

S e a so n a lly a d ju ste d m o n th ly a verages of
d a ily fig u r es

M o n ey M a rk e t & R eserve
R e la ti o n s h ip s , B o a rd o f

T o ta l R e se rv e s

S e a so n a lly a d ju ste d m o n th ly a verages of
d a ily fig u res

M o n ey M a rk et & R eserve
R e la ti o n s h ip s , B oard o f

I n d ic a to r

B oard o f G overnors o f th e
F ed er a l R e se rv e S y s te m
B o a rd o f G overnors o f th e
F ed er a l R e se rv e S y s te m

G overnors

G overnors
M o n e ta ry B a se

S e a so n a lly a d ju ste d m o n th ly a verages of
d a ily fig u r es (a d ju ste d for reserve
r eq u irem en t c h a n g e s a n d sh ifts in d e p o s ­
its a m on g c la sse s o f b an ks)

F ed era l R eserve B an k of
S t . L o u is R e v i e w , A u g u st

F re e R ese rv e s

S e a so n a lly a d ju ste d m o n th ly a verages o f
d a ily fig u r es

F e d e r a l R e s e r v e B u lle tin

F ed er a l F u n d s R a te

M o n th ly avera g es o f d a ily fig u res

F e d e ra l R e se r v e B u lle tin

T h r e e -m o n th
T r e a s u r y B ill R a te

M o n th ly average o f e n d -o f-w ee k d isc o u n ts

F e d e r a l R e s e r v e B u lle tin

D ECEM B ER

1970




1968, V ol. 50, n u m b er 8,
a n d U . S . F in a n c ia l D a t a ,
F ed er a l R e se rv e B a n k o f
St. L ou is

187

BANKING STATISTICS
Billion $

DEPOSITS
—

y

—

-2 3 .5

- 2 2 .5

Total Deposits* /

—

- 2 1 .5
_
- 13.5

—
«ru

ILoans (net)**

/
__

Investments**

/

- 12.5
«A.
- 7.0
4.0

Savings*
i i i I i i i i i i i 1 i i i i i i i i i i i- 6 .0
J

D J

1969

J

i i i i i i i i i i i Ii i i i i i i i i i i

D

J

1970

J

D J

1969

J

D

1970

LATEST MONTH PLOTTED: OCTOBER

Note: All figures are seasonally adjusted and cover all Sixth District member banks.
♦Daily average figures. ** Figures are for the last Wednesday of each month.
S IX T H D IS T R IC T

B

A

N

K

I N

G

N

O

T

E

S

BORROWINGS FROM FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ATLANTA
Million $

- 100

-5 0

188



M O N T H L Y R E V IE W

The significant decline in member bank borrow­
ings at the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta is
further evidence that easier monetary conditions
have prevailed during recent months. After
averaging $50 million during the first seven
months of this year (a decline from the level of
nearly $90 million in the fourth quarter of 1969),
the volume of borrowings eased to approximately
$15 million in August, September, and October.
In November, borrowings dropped to $4 million.
Banks that are members of the Federal Reserve
System are required to set aside a certain
proportion of their deposits in the form of re­
serves. If a bank anticipates a reserve deficit dur­
ing a given reserve week, exclusive of any carry­
over or “as of” adjustments, then it can attempt
to borrow or buy reserves to meet its reserve re­
quirements. Those banks with excess reserves
may try to lend or sell reserves.
Most commonly, banks adjust their reserve
position through the Federal funds market. In the
Sixth District, about 95 percent of the reserves
that banks have borrowed during 1970 have
come from this market.
For the individual bank, an inflow of deposits
or a shift from demand deposits to time deposits
results in a net addition to reserves. Banks can
also acquire reserves by selling loans or invest­
ments. Discounting with the Federal Reserve,
although infrequently used by banks in meeting
reserve deficiencies, is held in abeyance as an im­
portant alternative to the aforementioned meth­
ods. To illustrate: The number of banks making
use of the discount privilege in a given week
averaged less than ten in recent months, down
from over twenty a week in the first seven months
of the year.
The drop in discounting during the last sev­
eral months reflects conditions that have been
developing since spring. Total deposit inflows
have been strong throughout most of the year,
with nearly all gains coming from deposits that
carry low reserve requirements. Ever since Reg­
ulation Q was relaxed in June on large-denomina­
tion CD’s, banks have regained their ability to
adjust their reserves by controlling the inflow of
these deposits. Further easing occurred during
late September, when reserve requirements on
all time deposits in excess of $5 million at each
bank were reduced from 6 percent to 5 percent.
Other factors also help account for the reduced
level of discount activity. Recently, the growth
of bank credit in the Sixth District has been ex­
tremely moderate, with most of the gains centerD ECEM B ER

1 9 70




ALTERNATIVE BORROWING COSTS
P ercent

"\

- 9
\

Federal Funds Rate
V*V

N

\
\
”

V

- 6

Discount Rate
|
J

I
J

1
N

1970

LATEST PLOTTING: DECEMBER 1

ing around the acquisition of municipal obligations
by banks outside the larger cities. Furthermore,
the cost differences in borrowing from the dis­
count window and alternative sources have de­
clined sharply. The average cost of Federal funds
declined from about 9 percent at the first of this
year to 8 percent by early summer. However, for
the last several months, Federal funds have
traded below 6-^/2 percent. In June, many of the
larger banks were offering to pay over 7-V2 per­
cent for 30-to 89-day CD’s, whereas these same
banks currently are posting rates under 6 per­
cent. While rates on these alternative sources
were falling, the discount rate remained stable
at 6 percent until it was lowered one-quarter of
one percent in early November. Then another cut
took place on the first of December.
The bulk of reduction in the aggregate volume
of discounts has occurred at reserve city banks,
which have accounted for about four-fifths of
total member bank borrowing. Facing a weaker
loan demand, particularly for business loans, and
being able to attract short-term CD’s many of
these banks have used this opportunity to re­
build liquidity and to reduce their overall indebt­
edness.
Unless economic and credit conditions change
dramatically, discounting should remain below
the levels of late 1969 and early 1970. Banks
usually dislike borrowing at the discount window
if there are other means through which they
can acquire reserves at comparable borrowing
costs. As long as monetary conditions are mod­
erately easy, discounting will be less necessary as
a means of meeting reserve requirements.
J o h n

M.

G o d fr ey

189

R e p r in t s
I n c o m e s P o lic ie s : A Q u ic k C r itiq u e
R o b e r t H . F l o y d , D e c e m b e r 1970, p p . 174-181
M e a s u r in g M o n e t a r y P o lic y
W illia m

N .

C o x ,

I I I , D e c e m b e r 1970, p p . 182-187

R e v ie w s o f S ix th D is tr ic t S ta te E c o n o m ie s

Reprints of Monthly Review articles
(Single copies only)
A
A
A
A
A
A

R e v ie w
R e v ie w
R e v ie w
R e v ie w
R e v ie w
R e v ie w

of
of
of
of
of
of

A la b a m a ’s E c o n o m y , 1960-70, S e p te m b e r 1970, 35 p p .
F lo r id a ’s E c o n o m y , 1959-70, J u l y 1970, 35 p p .
G e o r g ia ’s E c o n o m y , 1960-70, A u g u s t 1970 , 35 p p .
L o u is ia n a ’s E c o n o m y , 1959-70, A u g u s t 1970, 32 p p .
M i s s is s ip p i’s E c o n o m y , 1960-69, F e b r u a r y 1970, 28 p p .
T e n n e s s e e ’s E c o n o m y , 1960-69, F e b r u a r y 1970, 27 p p .

S ta tis tic a l C o m p ila tio n s

(Single copies only)
S t a t i s t i c s o n t h e D e v e lo p in g S o u t h , 1970.
S t a t i s t i c a l t i m e s e r ie s fo r t r a c in g lo n g - r u n e c o n o m ic c h a n g e s in
t h e S o u t h e a s t a n d U n i te d S t a t e s .
S t a t i s t i c s o n C o m m e r c ia l B a n k s , S i x t h D is tr ic t, 1940-69, s e le c te d d a te s .
S t a t i s t i c a l ta b le s a n a ly z in g c h a n g e s in lo a n s , i n v e s tm e n ts , a n d d e p o s its
o f c o m m e r c ia l b a n k s in t h e S ix th D i s tr ic t.

These publications are now available upon request to
the Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of
Atlanta, Atlanta, Georgia 30303.

190



M O N T H L Y R E V IE W

B a n k A n n o u n c e m e n ts
On November 1, Coalmont Savings Bank, Coalmont,
Tennessee, a nonmember bank, agreed to remit at par
for checks drawn on it when received from the Federal
Reserve Bank.
A newly organized nonmember bank, The Citizens &
Merchants Bank, Bremen, Georgia, opened for business
on November 16. Officers are H. M. Wood, president;
W. Kenneth Jones, vice president; and Dennis Vanbrackle, cashier. Capital is $250,000; surplus and
other capital funds, $250,000.
On November 20, The Community Bank of Boca
Raton, Boca Raton, Florida, opened for business as a

D ECEM BER

1970




newly organized nonmember bank. Officers are Daniel
S. Goodrum, president; Jerry Thomas, chairman of the
Board; L. K. Orndorff, executive vice president and
cashier; and Fred Bayless, assistant cashier. Capital is
$700,000; surplus and other capital funds, $350,000.
Coosa Valley Bank, Gadsden, Alabama, another new­
ly organized nonmember bank, opened for business
and began to remit at par on November 21. Officers
are Tom Dawson, chairman of the board; Max L. Smith,
president; and Jerry T. Goss, vice president and
cashier. Capital is $250,000; surplus and other capital
funds, $250,000.

191

INDEX FOR THE YEAR 1
MONTH

PAGES

JANUARY

2-20

JULY

90-108

AUGUST

110-124

MARCH

38-48

SEPTEMBER

126-140

APRIL

50-60

OCTOBER

142-152

MAY

62-72

NOVEMBER

154-172

JUNE

74-88

DECEMBER

174-196

Loan Sales
by

G e n e D . S u l l i v a n , 12.

J o h n M . G odfrey , 104.

Profitability
by

J o h n M . G odfrey , 148.

G e n e D . S u l l i v a n , 126.

BANKING STRUCTURE

M ilk Flows Where Population Goes
by

PAGES

22-36

Growing Corner of the Nation's Egg Basket
by

MONTH

FEBRUARY

AGRICULTURE
Agriculture Shows M ixed Behavior
by

9 7 0

Gen

e

D . S u l l i v a n , 62.

A Decade of Holding Company Regulation
in Florida

BANK ANNOUNCEMENTS

by

C harles D . S a lley , 90.

11, 31, 45, 57, 66, 79, 103, 121, 131, 147, 166, 191.

BOARD OF DIRECTORS
BANK HOLDING COMPANIES
A Decade of Holding Company Regulation
in Florida
by

C harles D . S a lley , 90.

BANKING
Banking in a Developing Economy:
American Patterns
by

J

ohn

E. L

e im o n e ,

CHEMICAL INDUSTRY
Chemicals Bring Changes to the Southeast
Latin

154.

Banking Responds to Monetary Restraint
by

J o h n M . G odfrey , 7.

Term Lending: A Lagging Respondent to
Monetary Restraint
by

J o h n M . G o d f r e y , 80.

BANKING NOTES, Sixth District
Bank Liquidity
by

J o h n M . G odfrey , 118.

Business Loans
by

J o s e p h E . R o s s m a n , 168.

Certificates of Deposit
by

J o h n M . G odfrey , 136.

Deposit Inflows
by

J

ohn

by

R

o bert

E. W

il l a r d

, 161.

CONSTRUCTION
Construction Continues Strong
by

B oyd F. K in g , 15.

CREDIT FLOWS
Impairment in Credit Flows:
Fiction
by

Fact or

W illia m N . C o x , II I , 22.

DAIRY INDUSTRY
M ilk Flows Where Population Goes
by

G e n e D . S u l l i v a n , 62.

DEBITS TO DEMAND DEPOSIT ACCOUNTS
19, 35, 47, 59, 71, 87, 107, 123, 139, 151, 171, 195.

M . G o d f r e y , 84.

Reduced Discount Activity
by

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta and Branches,
Effective January 1 , 1970, 32.

J o h n M . G odfrey , 188.

192



DISTRICT BUSINESS CONDITIONS
20, 36, 48, 60, 72, 88, 108, 124, 140, 152, 172, 196.
M O N T H L Y R E V IE W

ECONOMIC CONDITIONS,

INTERNATIONAL FINANCE

G e n e ra l

Banking in a Developing Economy:
American Patterns

Getting Inflation Under Control
by

C h arles T . T aylor , 142.

The Southeast:
by

A t the Turn of the Decade

H arry B r andt , 2.

by

J o h n E . L e im o n e , 154.

International Lending Agencies:
for Economic Development
by

Alabama's Economy Moves in Step with the
Nation's

LATIN AMERICA

B oyd F . K in g , 100.

Area Diversity in Louisiana’s Growth
by

by

A r n o l d D i l l , 27.
E m e r s o n A t k in s o n , 55.
H a r r y B r a n d t , 2.

FARM INCOME

R obert E . W illard , 132.

MONETARY POLICY
Banking Responds to Monetary Restraint
by

J o h n M . G odfrey , 7.

Impairment in Credit Flows:
Fiction

Agriculture Shows M ixed Behavior
by

J o h n E . L e im o n e , 154.

Lumber on the Rebound
by

The Southeast: A t the Turn of the Decade
by

by

G e n e D . S u l l i v a n , 12.
by

International Lending Agencies:
for Economic Development
J

o h n

E.

L

e im o n e

,

Instruments

38.

by

A Boost to the Southeastern

Measuring Monetary Policy
by

W illia m N . C o x , II I , 182.

Minutes 1962-65. Available for
Reference, 31.
PRODUCTION INDEX

R obert H . F loyd , 110.

Revenue Sharing:
by

What It Might Mean

R obert H . F loyd , 50.

A New Measure of Industrial Activity:
Manufacturing Production Index
by

PUBLIC FINANCE

Incomes Policies: A Quick Critique

Revenue Sharing:

R

obert

H.

F

loyd

,

174.

by

INDUSTRIAL ACTIVITY
A New Measure of Industrial Activity:
Manufacturing Production Index
by

C. S. P y u n , 74.

Industrial Pace Slows
by

R obert E . W illard , 4.

W hat’s Happening in Textiles?
by

R o b e r t E . W illa r d , 67.

W hat It Might Mean

R obert H . F loyd , 50.

SIXTH DISTRICT STATISTICS
District

18, 34, 46, 58, 70, 86, 122, 138, 150, 170, 194.

STABILIZATION POLICIES
Incomes Policies:
by

A Quick Critique

R obert H . F loyd , 174.

Measuring Monetary Policy
by

W illia m N . C o x , II I, 182.

INFLATION

TEXTILE INDUSTRY

Getting Inflation Under Control

What’s Happening in Textiles?

by

C harles T . T aylor , 142.

D ECEM B ER

1 9 70




District

C. S. P y u n , 74.

INCOMES POLICIES
by

A Quick Critique

R obert H . F loy d , 174.

OPEN MARKET OPERATIONS

GRANTS-IN-AID
Federal Aid:
Economy

Fact or

W illia m N . C o x , II I , 22.

Incomes Policies:
FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS

by

Latin

LUMBER INDUSTRY

Georgia’s Economy Jogs Along
by

Banking in a Developing Economy:
American Patterns

J o h n E . L e im o n e , 42.

Florida’s Torrid Growth Cools a Bit
by

Instruments

J o h n E . L e im o n e , 38.

ECONOMIC CONDITIONS, Sixth District States

by

Latin

by

R obert E . W illard , 67.
193

S ix t h

D is t r ic t S t a t is t ic s
S e a so n ally A djusted

(All d a ta are indexes, 1957-59 = IOO, u n less in d icated otherw ise.)
L a te s t M onth
1970

One
Month
Ago

Two
M onths
Ago

One
Ye ar
Ago

Tw o
M onths
Ago

One
Y e ar
Ago

348
198

362
154

361

326
196

181
173
182
130
93

181
173
182
129r
89

179
175
180
130
93

177
178
176
137

3 .9
40.7

3.7
4 0 .8r

3.5
40.5

2.7
41.2

402
286

401
288

398
276

373
260
293

252
172

255r
136

267
207

269
156

FLO R ID A

S IX T H D IS T R IC T

IN C O M E

IN CO M E AND SP E N D IN G
Oct.
Sep t.
Sept.
Sep t.

261
142
102
179

262
167
149
169

262
210
228
197

257
143
99
186

In stalm e n t C red it at B a n k s* (M il. $)
Oct.
Oct.

338
311

341
304

348
307

330
298

Oct.
Oct.
Oct.
Oct.
Oct.
Oct.
Oct.
Oct.
Oct.
Oct.
Oct.
Oct.
Oct.
Oct.

152
145
174
142
174
118
106
123
131
112
179
154
130
53

152
145
174
141r
175r
118
106
124r
127r
113r
192
154
128
55

151
145
174
141
173
118
106
125
126
112
195
153
130
55

152
150
176
144
181
115
111
130
137
117
210
152
141
56

Oct.

4.7

4.6

4.5

3.6

Oct.
Oct.
Oct.
Oct.
Oct.
Sep t.
Sep t.
‘ Oct.
Sep t.
Sep t.
Sep t.
Sep t.
Sep t.
Sept.
Sept.
Sept.
Sept.
Sept.
Sept.
Sept.
Sept.
Sept.
Sept.
Sept.
Sept.

3.1
40.1
201
233
174
168
102
311
244
208
167
235
261
195
165
268
288
168
184
171
202
241
370
593
378

3.3
4 0 .Or
246
216
271
165
96r
310
244
207
166
236
262
194
165r
262r
288
168r
182r
167r
199
238
361r
605
382r

3.0
40 .4
220
263
183
168
108
294
245
208
166
236
261
193
167
261
291
168
182
166
198
239
379
616
382

1.9
40 .9
211
249
179
161
103
269
239
203
159
231
254
200
169
261
283
168
194
168
194
240
384
589
353

. Oct.
. Oct.

360
300

358
302

356
298

334
281

. Oct.
. Oct.
. Oct.

247
203
287

249
206
282r

242
200
287

227
189
275

E M P LO Y M E N T AND PR O D U C TIO N
M anu factu ring

F o o d .............................................................
Lb r., Wood Prod ., F u rn . & F ix .
P ap er
.......................................................
P rim a ry M e t a l s ...............................
T e x tile s
.................................................
Tra n sp o rta tio n Equ ip m ent
N o n m a n u f a c t u r in g f .........................
C o n s t r u c t i o n .....................................
Farm E m p lo y m e n t ...............................
U nem p loym en t Rate
(P e rce n t of W ork F o rce Jt • •
Insured U nem p loym en t
(P e rce n t of Cov. E m p .) . . .
Avg. W eekly H rs. in Mfg. (H rs.)
C o nstru ctio n C o n tra cts* . . .

E le c tric Pow er P ro d u ctio n*
Cotton C o n su m p tio n ** . .

P ap er
..........................................
P rin tin g and P u b lish in g

N o n e le ctrica l M achine ry
E le c tric a l M a ch in e ry . . .
Tra n sp o rta tio n E qu ip m ent
F IN A N C E AND B A N KIN G
Lo ans*
A ll M em ber B a n k s ........................
Larg e B a n k s .....................................
D eposits*

One
M onth
Ago

La te s t Month
1970

A LABA M A

M a n u fa ctu rin g P a y ro lls
...............................Oct.
Farm C ash R e c e i p t s ...........................................Sep t.

220

E M P LO Y M E N T
...............................Oct.
N onfarm E m p lo y m e n tt
M anu factu ring
.................................................Oct.
N o n m a n u fa c tu rin g ...........................................Oct.
C o n s t r u c t i o n .................................................Oct.
Farm E m p lo y m e n t ................................................. Oct.
U ne m p loym ent R ate
(P e rce n t of Work F o r c e J t .........................Oct.
Avg. W eekly H rs. in Mfg. (H rs.) . . . Oct.

88

F IN A N C E AND B A N KIN G
M em ber B an k L o a n s ...........................................Oct.
M em ber B an k D e p o s it s .....................................Oct.
B an k D e b it s * * .............................................................Oct.
G EO RG IA
IN CO M E
M anu factu ring P a y ro lls
...............................Oct.
Farm C ash R e c e i p t s ...........................................Sept.
E M P LO Y M EN T
N onfarm E m p lo y m e n tt
...............................Oct.
M anu factu ring
.................................................Oct.
N o n m a n u fa c tu rin g ...........................................Oct.
C o n s t r u c t i o n .................................................Oct.
Farm E m p lo y m e n t .................................................Oct.
U ne m p loym ent Rate
(P e rce n t of W ork F o r c e J t .........................Oct.
Avg. W e ekly H rs. in Mfg. (H rs.) . . . Oct.

152
136
159
140
48

151
138
158
129r
49

151
139
157
127
47

153
146
157
152
52

4.1
39.0

4 .0
3 9 .Or

3.7
40.1

3.1
40.7

FIN A N C E AND B A N KIN G
M em ber B a n k L o a n s ...........................................Oct.
M ember B an k D e p o s it s .....................................Oct.
Ban k D e b it s * * .............................................................Oct.

358
246
331

355
247
326r

355
240
333

343
236
327

225
116

230r
269

227
234

116

131
119
134
116
43

131
120
134
119
43

131
120
134
117
44

133

6.5
42.0

6.6
4 1 .8r

6.4
42.5

5 .0
41 .8

295
195
213

296
198
209

295
194
222

274
178
204

291
78

287r
173

280
239

101

152
159
149
160
43

152
159
148
163
46

151
158
148
162
46

151
161
146
168
42

5.1
40.1

5.0
4 0 .4r

5.2
40.1

4.3
40.5

449
298
297

436
295
290

433
300
294

403
268
283

L O U IS IA N A
IN C O M F.
M a n u f a c t u r in g P a y r o lls
.................................. O c t.
F a r m C a s h R e c e i p t s .........................................S e p t.
EM PLO YM EN T
N o n fa rm
E m p l o y m e n t t .........................................O ct.
M a n u f a c t u r in g
...................................................... O ct.
N o n m a n u fa c t u r in g
.........................................O c t.
C o n s t r u c t i o n ...................................................... O c t.
F a r m E m p l o y m e n t ...................................................... O c t.
U n e m p lo y m e n t R a t e
(P e r c e n t o f W o rk F o r c e J t ........................... O c t.
A vg . W e e k ly H r s . in M fg . ( H r s .) . . . O c t.
F IN A N C E A N D

212
122
135
129
51

B A N K IN G

M e m b e r B a n k L o a n s * .........................................O c t.
M e m b e r B a n k D e p o s i t s * ..................................O c t.
B a n k D e b i t s * / * * .............................................................O ct.
M IS S IS S IP P I

INCO M E
M a n u fa ctu rin g P a y ro lls
.............................. Oct.
Farm C ash R e c e i p t s ...........................................Sept.

IN C O M E

224
133

231
153

225
194

225
131

Oct.
Oct.
Oct.
Oct.
Oct.

132
133
131
101
49

131
133
131r
103r
52

133
133
132
121
57

134
137
132
124
60

Oct.
Oct.

5.1
40.3

5.1
4 0 .l r

5.0
40.4

3.8
41.4

M em ber B a n k L o a n s ...........................................Oct,
. Oct.
M em ber B an k D e p o s i t s ............................... Oct
Oct.
. Oct.
B a n k D e b i t s * * ..............................

327
230
246

323
231
240r

326
230
249

299
209
227

E M P LO Y M E N T
N onfarm Em p lo y m en tt . . . .
M an u fa ctu rin g
..............................
N on m a n ufa ctu rin g
. . . .
C o n s t r u c t i o n ..............................
F arm E m p lo y m e n t ...............................
U nem p loym en t R ate
(P e rce n t of W ork F o rc e Jt . .
Avg. W eekly H rs. in Mfg. (H rs.)
FIN A N C E AND BA N KIN G

194



M a n u f a c t u r in g P a y r o lls
..................................O ct.
F a rm C a s h R e c e i p t s ................................................S e p t.
EM PLO YM EN T
N o n fa rm E m p l o y m e n t t .........................................O ct.
M a n u f a c t u r in g
...................................................... O ct.
N o n m a n u f a c t u r i n g ............................................... O c t.
C o n s t r u c t i o n ...................................................... O c t.
F a rm E m p l o y m e n t ......................................................O c t.
U n e m p lo y m e n t R a te
( P e r c e n t of W o rk F o r c e J t ........................... O c t.
A vg . W e e k ly H r s . in M fg . ( H r s .) . . . O c t.
F IN A N C E

AND

277

B A N K IN G

M e m b e r B a n k L o a n s * .........................................O c t.
M e m b e r B a n k D e p o s i t s * ..................................O ct.
B a n k D e b i t s * / * * .............................................................O ct.

M O N TH LY

R E V IE W

L a te st M o n th
1970

O ne
M on th
Ago

Tw o
M o n th s
Ago

O ne
Year
Ago

N o n m a n u f a c t u r i n g ........................... O ct.
C o n s t r u c t i o n ............................... O ct.
F a r m E m p l o y m e n t ............................... O ct.
U n e m p l o y m e n t R a te
( P e r c e n t o f W o r k F o r c e J t ................O ct.
A v g . W e e k ly H o u r s in M fg . (H rs.) . . O ct.

TEN N ESSEE
IN C O M E

258
116

M a n u fa c tu rin g P a y ro lls
................................O c t .
F a r m C a s h R e c e i p t s .............................................S e p t .

247
159

247
126

245
164

F IN A N C E A N D
EM PLO Y M EN T

148
156

N o n fa rm
E m p l o y m e n t t ...................................... O c t .
M a n u fa c tu rin g
...................................................O c t .

148
153

* D a ily a v e ra g e

* F o r S ix th D is tr ic t a r e a o n ly ; o t h e r t o t a l s f o r e n t i r e s ix s t a t e s

Tw o
M on th s
Ago

O ne
Year
Ago

144
154
57

145
149
60

144
143
58

144
159
58

5.0
3 9 .8

4 .8
3 9 .4 r

4 .8
3 9 .8

3.7
4 0 .2

355
226
284

354r
230
285

343
223
280

319
206
273

B A N K IN G

M e m b e r B a n k L o a n s * ....................... O ct.
M e m b e r B a n k D e p o s i t s * ................... O ct.
B a n k D e b i t s * / * * ...................................O ct.

149
157

146
151

O ne
M onth
Ago

L a te st M o n th
1970

b a s is

t P r e li m i n a r y d a t a

r -R e v is e d

N .A .

N o t a v a il a b l e

S o u r c e s : M a n u f a c t u r i n g p r o d u c t io n e s t im a t e d b y t h i s B a n k ; n o n fa r m , m fg . a n d n o n m f g . em p ., m fg . p a y r o l ls a n d h o u r s , a n d u n e m p ., U .S . D e p t, o f L a b o r a n d c o o p e r a t in g
s t a t e a g e n c i e s ; c o t t o n c o n s u m p t i o n , U . S . B u r e a u o f C e n s u s ; c o n s t r u c t io n c o n t r a c t s , F. W . D o d g e D iv., M c G r a w - H ill In f o r m a t io n S y s t e m s C o.; p etrol, prod ., U .S . B u r e a u of
M i n e s ; i n d u s t r i a l u s e o f e l e c . p o w e r , F e d . P o w e r C o m m . ; fa r m c a s h r e c e ip t s a n d f a r m e m p ., U .S .D .A . O t h e r i n d e x e s b a s e d o n d a t a c o lle c t e d b y t h i s B a n k . A ll i n d e x e s
c a lc u la te d

by th is B an k .

D e b it s t o D e m a n d

D e p o s it A c c o u n t s

Insured C om m ercial B anks in th e Sixth D istrict
(In T h o u sa n d s of Dollars)
Perc e n t C h a n g e

P e rc e n t C h a n g e
Year
to
d ate
1 0 m o s.

Oct.
1970

F ro m

1970

Oct.

Se p t.

O ct.

Se p t. O ct.

fro m

1970

1970

1969

1970

1969

1969

O c t.
1970

S T A N D A R D M E T R O P O L IT A N
S T A T IS T IC A L A R E A S t
B irm in g h a m
G ad sd en

. .

.

.

..........................

H u n ts v ille

. . . .

M o b ile

..........................

M o n tg o m e ry

.

T u s c a lo o s a

.

.

. . . .

2 ,0 8 7 ,0 5 2

2 ,0 0 0 ,9 9 0

1 ,9 1 9 ,1 6 6

7 4 ,2 0 7

7 5 ,1 7 3

7 2 ,5 0 5

2 2 6 ,0 1 2

2 0 4 ,8 1 9

2 2 4 ,8 9 6

+
-

4

+

9

+

1

+

2

+

6

+

0

+

8

-

4

6 4 0 ,6 1 9

6 3 8 ,5 7 0

-

+ 15

4 4 0 ,1 2 5

3 8 3 ,6 5 9

3 9 5 ,0 6 6

+15

+ 11

+

7

1 2 2 ,3 5 5

1 3 7 ,6 8 1

1 3 4 ,7 6 9

-1 1

-

+

3

9

.

.

1 ,1 4 9 ,3 2 4

1 ,0 2 8 ,6 4 9

1 ,1 2 0 ,0 0 2

+ 12

+

3

+

9

J a c k s o n v ille

.

.

1 ,9 5 2 ,5 1 3

2 ,0 5 1 ,4 5 5

2 ,0 2 1 ,6 5 9

-

-

3

+

5

M i a m i ................................

3 ,7 1 5 ,6 0 5

3 ,5 5 6 ,0 1 2

3 ,7 0 7 ,0 1 9

+

4

+

0

+

O r l a n d o ..........................

7 9 6 ,2 3 4

7 9 1 ,3 5 0

7 7 7 ,7 3 9

+

1

+

2

+ 14

.

5

1 1 7 ,8 1 9

1 1 5 ,4 2 5

+

6

+

1 5 1 ,7 5 4

1 7 8 ,1 2 2

+

5

-1 1

+

8

+

8

O

4 2 ,6 8 5

4 0 ,4 3 6

3 9 ,5 5 0

+

6

+

c a l a ................................

9 9 ,2 1 9

8 7 ,3 6 5

+

2

+15

+19

S t. A u g u s tin e

9

5 9 ,2 9 6

5 4 ,3 4 3

5 4 ,1 3 1

+

9

+10

+10

1 2 4 ,3 0 7

1 2 5 ,5 1 6

1 2 9 ,7 6 7

-

1

-

4

-

E l b e r t o n ..........................

1 8 ,0 7 5

2 0 ,8 8 5

1 6 ,9 5 4

+

7

+10

G a in e s v ille

. . . .

4

+ 13

+ 10

+ 10

1 3 2 ,6 1 1

1 3 3 ,6 6 8

1 1 8 ,0 6 5

-

1

+ 12

+ 15

.........................

8 ,0 4 3 ,2 6 3

7 ,6 8 5 ,6 7 9

7 ,6 2 3 ,7 4 2

+

5

+

6

+ 14

A u g u s t a ..........................

3 1 9 ,0 9 4

3 1 0 ,6 4 8

3 3 5 ,9 5 3

+

3

-

5

+

4

C o lu m b u s

. . . .

3 0 4 ,5 1 5

3 0 4 ,4 2 2

3 0 1 ,1 1 7

+

0

+

1

+

3

..........................

3 4 9 ,2 0 4

3 4 4 ,9 7 6

3 2 9 ,1 3 0

+

1

+

6

+

4

3 4 3 ,0 8 0

3 2 3 ,9 0 3

3 5 7 ,8 0 8

+

6

-

4

-

0

7 5 4 ,2 5 0

7 8 4 ,3 8 0

7 2 0 ,7 7 9

-

4

+

5

+21

P la q u e m in e

G riffin

..........................

L aG ran g e

. . . .

N ew nan

..........................

-1 3

4

9 7 ,8 7 4

9 1 ,7 9 1

9 1 ,8 4 5

+

7

+

7

+16

4 7 ,3 7 8

4 6 ,3 7 4

4 2 ,3 4 4

+

2

+ 12

+15
-

7

7

2 5 ,1 8 1

2 2 ,9 3 1

2 3 ,6 2 9

+10

+

3 3 ,9 0 5

3 1 ,6 6 2

2 5 ,0 3 9

+

7

+35

+23

e ................................

9 6 ,4 8 8

9 3 ,8 3 4

9 8 ,7 7 9

+

3

-

2

+

V a l d o s t a ..........................

7 1 ,6 3 0

7 1 ,0 1 4

6 4 ,2 4 7

+

1

+11

+

8

A b b e v ille

. . . .

1 3 ,3 8 5

1 4 ,2 6 9

1 4 ,0 9 2

-

6

-

5

-

0

. . . .

1 7 3 ,4 1 9

1 5 6 ,6 4 0

1 7 3 ,1 4 9

+11

+

0

-

6

8 ,0 3 0

7 ,4 9 3

9 ,7 4 9

+

-1 8

-

5 1 ,5 7 6

4 4 ,2 1 4

4 6 ,0 3 0

R o m

. . .

+15

+20

.

. . . .

+

.

+

3

D a l t o n ................................

+ 13

L a fa y e tte

9

+

+12

+ 11

.

-

+12

1 8 5 ,2 1 4

5

6 1 6 ,7 8 8

.

6

1 ,1 9 2 ,4 1 0

+28

2 ,1 9 9 ,8 1 1

.

1 5 9 ,0 1 7
l,0 9 8 ,5 9 8 r

+

6 0 0 ,6 5 1

R ouge

+

1 6 8 ,9 8 7
1 ,2 2 9 ,2 0 3

8

9

2 ,0 5 2 ,4 5 1

B a to n

+13

+

6 7 9 ,6 6 3

. . .

8

+11

2 ,2 7 9 ,0 5 8

.

-

+

7 7 ,2 9 3

+ 14

Savannah

-1 1

8

1 0 3 ,6 2 0

+ 12

M acon

6

+

7 3 ,1 3 1

7

A tla n ta

-

4 8 0 ,6 3 0

1 2 1 ,9 1 3

+

A l b a n y ................................

2 4 ,0 4 5

4 7 9 ,0 3 4

8 1 ,4 8 7

+ 15

.

2 2 ,7 4 3

5 1 8 ,9 4 7

1 3 2 ,7 0 9

1

.

2 1 ,3 6 6

.

.

7

P e te

.

.

..........................

H aven

A th e n s

8

.

..........................

+

B each

.

S a r a s o t a ..........................
T am pa

-

W. P a l m

.

P e te rs b u rg

1 8 7 ,4 9 7

T a m p a —S t.

8

1 0 0 ,8 7 5

2 6 1 ,7 9 7

.

.
.

2 8 4 ,0 5 0

.

.

C o u n ty

2 0 1 ,7 7 6

.

+10

1 2 4 ,4 0 5

2 8 0 ,8 4 1

. . . .

10 m o s.
1970
fro m
1969

1 5 8 ,8 3 1

2 1 6 ,0 4 7

P e n s a c o la
T a lla h a s s e e

S e p t. O c t.
1970
1969

. .

B ru n s w ic k
9

O c t.
1969

. . . .

W in te r
F t. L a u d e r d a le —
H o lly w o o d
.

S e p t.
1970

L a k e la n d

S t.

6 1 1 ,1 7 7

to
d a te

G a in e s v ille

M o n ro e

6

+10
5

Y ear
O c t.
1970
F ro m

A le x a n d r ia
B u n k ie

..........................

H am m ond
N ew

. . . .

Ib e ria

1 7 4 ,9 8 6

1 6 9 ,6 2 4

1 7 2 ,2 5 0

+

3

+

2

+

5

T h ib o d a u x

.

.

.

. . . .

6

+ 17

+ 12

+

7

2

+

4
4

4 4 ,5 7 8

+

3

-

1 3 ,7 8 4

1 2 ,9 4 1

1 4 ,8 7 8

+

7

-

7

-

2 4 ,6 4 4

2 4 ,1 6 0

2 4 ,9 9 6

+

2

-

1

+

0

+

4

-

8

-

1

4 3 ,7 3 7

. . . .

7

6

4 2 ,2 8 5

L ak e C h a rle s

.

.

.

1 7 5 ,0 3 4

1 6 6 ,1 5 1

1 7 8 ,3 0 2

+

5

-

2

-

2

H a ttie s b u rg

.

8 6 ,2 0 4

7 7 ,1 0 7

8 2 ,8 2 8

+12

N ew

.

.

.

2 ,8 1 2 ,7 4 5

2 ,7 0 7 ,7 8 2

2 ,8 7 2 ,7 9 5

+

4

-

2

+

4

L a u r e l ................................

5 5 ,7 4 4

5 5 ,4 5 0

5 6 ,2 6 8

+

+

9

8 1 ,1 2 6

7 2 ,7 2 6

9 5 ,4 9 8

+ 12

-1 5

-

8

.

2 5 1 ,8 2 5

1 7 8 ,1 5 6

1 7 9 ,8 7 6

+41

+40

+27

M e r i d i a n ..........................

.

-

8

-1 2

-

5

8 3 8 ,7 6 5

8 4 4 ,0 6 4

9 3 4 ,4 9 2

-

+

N a t c h e z ..........................

4 5 ,0 8 5

4 6 ,9 9 7

-1 0

4 1 ,5 8 7

9 0 0 ,5 0 6

8 7 4 ,3 6 0

8 3 6 ,0 9 6

+

3

+

8

+ 11

P a s c a g o u la —
M o ss P o in t

9 1 ,1 9 4

-

+

6

6 5 7 ,8 4 0

5 8 0 ,6 6 5

6 2 1 ,0 9 6

+ 13

+

6

+

O rle a n s

B ilo x i—G u lf p o r t
Jack so n

..........................

C h a tta n o o g a
K n o x v ille
N a s h v ille
OTHER

.
.

.

.

. . .

1 ,9 0 7 ,2 8 1

. . . .

1 ,8 6 6 ,3 3 5

2 ,0 1 9 ,1 1 7

+

1

2

-

6

+

8

3
6

V ic k s b u rg
Y azoo

C ity

B ris to l

CENTERS

Jo hnson
8 2 ,3 1 6

7 9 ,0 9 7

8 4 ,6 0 6

+

4

-

3

+

..........................

1 0 0 ,7 3 3

1 0 3 ,1 4 5

9 3 ,2 2 6

-

2

+

8

+ 13

S e l m a ................................

5 6 ,6 0 9

5 1 ,7 7 6

5 7 ,4 8 5

+

9

-

2

+

A n n i s t o n .........................
D o th a n

B a rto w

..........................

B ra d e n to n

. . . .

+

5

5 5 ,0 0 7

5 1 ,4 4 6

+

7

+ 15

+ 14

. . . .

3 6 ,4 4 8

2 8 ,7 2 3

-1 1

+ 13

+

4

9 9 ,0 4 9

9 6 ,3 7 2

9 8 ,7 7 3

+

3

+

0

+

5

1 0 1 ,9 3 9

1 0 1 ,0 9 1

1 0 8 ,6 2 5

+

1

-

6

+

8

1 7 9 ,5 1 4

1 7 7 ,4 7 6

1 8 8 ,9 4 9

+

1

-

5

-

2

.

.

C ity

.

.

.

. . . .

D IS T R IC T ,

T o ta l

4 1 ,7 1 1 ,4 0 9 r

4 3 ,5 0 8 ,1 5 2

+

4

-

0

+

8

5 ,2 5 4 ,9 8 1

5 ,0 6 4 ,4 1 7 r

5 ,0 5 5 ,9 5 2

+

4

+

4

+

7

+

3 5 ,5 5 9

+

1

-

1

-

4

9 5 ,3 2 3

9 8 ,2 8 0

+

5

+

2

+

4

F l o r i d a ^ ..........................

1 3 ,9 1 9 ,5 9 6

1 3 ,3 6 0 ,4 1 4

1 3 ,8 1 0 ,9 7 8

+

4

+

2

2 2 3 ,5 9 9

-

0

-

7

-

3

G e o r g i a ! ..........................

1 1 ,8 8 9 ,7 4 3

ll,4 5 4 ,3 4 4 r

2 0 8 ,8 4 6

2 0 8 ,5 1 5

D a y to n a

B each

.

.

1 0 4 ,7 3 6
1 3 7 ,5 9 5

9 6 ,6 3 9
1 3 1 ,5 4 4

1 1 0 ,8 7 8
1 2 8 ,1 3 2

Includes only banks in the Sixth District portion of the state

1 9 70




+
+

8
5

+

6
7

+
+

3
4

tPartially estimated

. . . .

4 3 ,4 1 9 ,0 1 8

3 4 ,6 7 2

.

D ECEM BER

8 4 ,9 7 5

5 8 ,9 7 5
3 2 ,4 8 8

.

3 5 ,0 3 4

.

.

S IX T H

3

8 8 ,8 5 6

. . . .

.........................

K in g s p o r t

1

1 0 0 ,0 3 3

C o u n ty

.

1

.

A la b a m a !

B re v ard

F t. M y e rs —
N . F t. M y e rs

4

.

9

1 2 ,2 5 7 ,3 4 4

+

4

-

3

+ 11

4 ,7 9 9 ,4 4 9

4 ,9 6 8 ,3 6 0

+

3

-

0

+

6

L o u is ia n a !*

.

-

.

4 ,9 5 5 ,1 8 7

M is s is s ip p i*

•

•

•

2 ,0 4 5 ,2 9 8

1 ,8 9 1 ,1 7 2

2 ,0 3 4 ,5 4 2

+

8

+

1

+

7

T e n n e s s e e t*

.

.

•

5 ,3 5 4 ,2 1 3

5 ,1 4 1 ,6 1 3

5 ,3 8 0 ,9 7 6

+

4

-

0

+

6

t Estimated

195

D is t r ic t B u s in e s s C o n d it io n s

E c o n o m ic a c t iv it y r e m a in s la c k lu s te r in th e S o u th e a s t , a c c o r d in g to la te s t a v a ila b le d a ta . A lt h o u g h n o n fa rm e m p lo y m e n t ro se a g a in in O c to b e r, the rise w a s o n ly slig h t. C o n s t r u c t io n c o n tr a c t a w a r d s d ro p p e d
s u b s t a n t ia lly . C o n s u m e r s r e m a in e d

r e lu c ta n t p u r c h a s e r s a n d

re s p o n s e to b o u n t ifu l p ro d u c tio n , b u t e x c e ssiv e

bo rro w e rs. A g r ic u lt u r a l

p r ic e s s a g g e d

in

r a in fa ll h a s d im m e d p r o s p e c t s fo r a b u m p e r so y b e a n

crop. L o a n d e m a n d c o n tin u e d w e a k, a n d the p rim e le n d in g rate w a s m a r k e d d o w n tw ic e in N o v e m b e r.
O v e rall, n o n fa r m e m p lo y m e n t e d g e d u p w a rd for

Preliminary esti­
mates indicate, however, that October’s unemploy­
ment rate edged up to 4.7 percent. Strike ac­
tivity was primarily responsible for employment
changes. Settlement of the construction strike in
Atlanta boosted nonmanufacturing employment,
but transportation e q u ip m e n t e m p lo y m e n t
dropped sharply because of the GM strike. Sec­
ondary layoffs from the GM strike appear
minimal in the District. Primary metals, in par­
ticular have fared better than nationally, with
employment actually showing gains in October.

th e s e c o n d c o n s e c u tiv e m o n th .

T o ta l c o n s tr u c t io n

c o n tr a c t a w a r d s fe ll to the

The decline
was centered in the nonresidential sector. A re­
surgence of multi-family residential awards in
Florida helped to boost total residential volume
so that September’s decline was reversed. Sav­
ings flows to District savings and loan associa­
tions continued strong in October, and mortgage
credit was more readily available in a growing
number of markets.

Hence, total consumer credit outstanding in­
creased only moderately. The continued sluggish­
ness in auto sales and retail trade contributed
to reduce expansion in new loan volume.
In O c to b e r, a g r ic u lt u r a l p r ic e s d e c lin e d to the

The weakness was shared
by both the crop and livestock sectors. The pro­
spective bountiful citrus crop was the main price
depressor among crops, and heavy pork supplies
were responsible for triggering price declines for
all livestock items except milk. Excessive rain­
fall damaged unharvested crops throughout the
District and has dimmed the prospects for the
once excellent soybean crop.
low p o in t o f the year.

lo w e st le vel for a n y m o n th in 1 9 7 0 .

T h e v o lu m e o f n ew c o n s u m e r in s ta lm e n t lo a n s
m a d e by c o m m e r c ia l b a n k s in O c to b e r d e c r e a s e d
s o m e w h a t b u t r e m a in e d h ig h e r th a n r e p a y m e n ts.
NOTE:

The

p rim e

rate

w as

cut

tw ic e

in

N o v e m b e r,

u n d e r s c o r in g s l a c k lo a n d e m a n d a n d a r a p id d e ­

The number of
banks borrowing at the discount window de­
clined because bank reserve positions were under
less pressure. The discount rate of this Bank was
lowered from 6 percent to 5% percent, effective
November 11, and from 5% percent to 5V2 per­
cent, effective December 1. According to pre»
liminary data, demand deposit inflows were
strong in November, but interest-bearing deposits
declined modestly.

c lin e in sh o rt-te rm in te re st rate s.

D a t a o n w h i c h s t a t e m e n t s are b a s e d h a v e b e e n a d j u s t e d w h e n e v e r possible to e l i m i n a t e s e a s o n a l influences.

196



M ON TH LY REVIEW
D E C E M B E R 1970