View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Economic
Report of the
President
transmitted to congress
march 2024
together with the
annual report of the
council of economic advisers

economic
re p ort
of the

president

transmitted to congress | march 2024
together with the annual report
of the council of economic advisers

Contents
Economic Report of the President. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
The Annual Report of the Council of Economic Advisers. . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
Letter of Transmittal. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
Chapter 1: The Benefits of Full Employment. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
Chapter 2: The Year in Review and the Years Ahead. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61
Chapter 3: Population, Aging, and the Economy. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109
Chapter 4: Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing:
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 143
Chapter 5: International Trade and Investment Flows. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 173
Chapter 6: Accelerating the Clean Energy Transition.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 211
Chapter 7: An Economic Framework for Understanding
Artificial Intelligence. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 243
References.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 291
Appendix A: Report to the President on the Activities of
the Council of Economic Advisers during 2023. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 385
Appendix B: Statistical Tables Relating to Income, Employment,
and Production.........................................................................................401

____________
*For a detailed table of contents of the Council’s Report, see page 11.

iii

Economic Report
of the
President

Economic Report of the President
March 21, 2024
To the Congress of the United States:
When I was elected President, a pandemic was raging and our economy was
reeling, and trickle-down economics had undermined our nation’s growth
long-term. I was determined to rebuild from the middle out and bottom up,
not the top down, because when the middle class does well, we all do well.
We can give everyone a fair shot and leave no one behind. Our plan has
brought transformational progress.
In the near term, my Administration moved quickly to help hardworking families and businesses make it through the pandemic, with a historic rescue plan that vaccinated the nation, delivered immediate economic
relief to people in need, and sent funding to states and cities to keep essential
services going. We worked with the private sector and labor unions to ease
bottlenecks and shortages in our supply chains, getting goods flowing again
and making our economy more resilient for the future. Today, America is in
the midst of the strongest recovery of any advanced economy in the world.
Along the way, we’ve achieved one of the most successful legislative
records in generations, bringing new opportunities to communities of all
sizes nationwide. We’re tackling years of underinvestment in public infrastructure, clean energy, and advanced manufacturing, making sure the future
is made in America by American workers. We’re making the biggest investment in American infrastructure in generations, including over $400 billion
for 46,000 projects in 4,500 communities to date. These projects are rebuilding the nation’s roads, bridges, railroads, ports, airports, public transit, water
systems, high-speed internet, and more, in every part of the country. We’re
also making the most significant investment in fighting climate change in
history—advancing breakthroughs in clean technology, boosting energy
independence, lowering electricity costs for hardworking families, and revitalizing fence-line communities smothered by a legacy of pollution. At the
same time, we’re working with the private sector to strengthen America’s
semiconductor and advanced manufacturing industries as well, empowering
workers and small businesses to share in the benefits.
Already, my Investing in America agenda has attracted $650 billion
in private investment from companies that are building factories here in
America. We’ve ignited a manufacturing boom, a semiconductor boom, a
Economic Report of the President | 3

battery boom, an electric-vehicle boom, and more. My agenda is creating
hundreds of thousands of good-paying jobs, so folks never have to leave
their hometowns to find work they can raise a family on. Today, America
once again has the strongest economy in the world. A record 15 million
jobs have been created on my watch, giving 15 million more Americans the
dignity and peace of mind that comes with a steady paycheck. The unemployment rate has been below 4 percent for the longest stretch in over 50
years, and we’ve seen the lowest unemployment rate for Black Americans
on record. Economic growth is strong. Wages are rising faster than prices.
Inflation is down by two-thirds. We have more to do, but folks are starting
to feel the results. Real income and household wealth are higher now than
they were before the pandemic, and consumer sentiment has surged more in
recent months than any time in decades. Americans have filed a record 16
million new business applications since I took office, and each one of them
is an act of hope.
Importantly, we’re paying for many of these historic investments by
making our tax system fairer. We’ve cut the deficit by $1 trillion since I
took office, one of the biggest reductions in history, and I’ve signed legislation to cut it by $1 trillion more over the next 10 years, in part by raising
the corporate minimum tax to 15 percent and making the wealthy and big
corporations start paying their fair share.
It’s clear that we’re making tremendous progress for the American
people, but we have more to do to finish the job. My Administration is going
to keep fighting to lower costs for hardworking families, on everything
from prescription drugs, to housing, childcare, and student loans. Folks in
Washington have tried to reduce prescription drug costs for decades; our
historic Inflation Reduction Act is getting it done. It for example caps the
cost of insulin for seniors at $35 a month, down from as much as $400; and
starting next year, no senior on Medicare will pay more than $2,000 a year in
total out-of-pocket drug costs, even for expensive medications that can cost
many times more. It also protects and expands the Affordable Care Act; as a
result, more Americans have health insurance today than ever.
We’re also making real gains in expanding access to housing: More
families own homes today than did before the pandemic, rents are easing,
and a record of around 1.7 million housing units are under construction
nationwide. We’ll keep working to lower housing costs and boost supply,
by expanding rental assistance; speeding builders’ access to federal financing to build more affordable homes; and reducing mortgage payments for
first-time homebuyers. Meanwhile, we’re standing up for workers and
consumers, and cracking down on unfair hidden “junk fees” that companies
like airlines, banks, and insurers slip onto people’s bills.
At the same time, we’re working to get every child in America the
strong start they need to thrive. The American Rescue Plan expanded the
4 |

Economic Report of the President

Child Tax Credit, cutting child poverty nearly in half in 2021. We’ll keep
fighting to restore it, and to guarantee the vast majority of American families
access to high-quality childcare for no more than $10 a day. Our rescue plan
also made the biggest investment in public education in American history;
today, we’re pushing to further boost funding to schools in need, to expand
tutoring and afterschool programs, and to ease teacher shortages. I’m keeping my promise to ease the crushing burden of student debt as well. Despite
legal challenges, we’ve canceled $138 billion in student loans for nearly 3.9
million Americans, including more than 750,000 teachers, nurses, firefighters, social workers, and other public servants. Such widespread debt cancellation is freeing people to finally consider buying a home, having a child,
or starting the small business they always dreamed of. In all, our agenda is
making the promise of America real for many millions more Americans than
ever before.
The story of America is one of progress and resilience, of always moving forward and never giving up. It is a story unique among nations – we are
the only country that has emerged from every crisis stronger than we went
in. That is what’s happening across America today. There is still work to
do, but I’ve never been more optimistic about our future. We are the United
States of America, and there is nothing beyond our capacity when we do it
together.

Economic Report of the President | 5

The Annual Report
of the
Council of Economic Advisers

Letter of Transmittal
Council of Economic Advisers
Washington, March 21, 2024

Mr. President:
The Council of Economic Advisers herewith submits its 2024 Annual
Report in accordance with the Employment Act of 1946, as amended by the
Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978.
Sincerely yours,

Jared Bernstein
Chair

Heather Boushey
Member

C. Kirabo Jackson
Member

9

Contents
Economic Report of the President. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
The Annual Report of the Council of Economic Advisers. . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
Letter of Transmittal. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
Chapter 1: The Benefits of Full Employment. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
What Is Full Employment, and Why Does It Matter?.. . . . . . . . . . . 24
Estimates of the Natural Rate of Unemployment. . . . . . . . . . . . 27
A Monopsonistic Labor Market.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30
Evidence on the Benefits of Full Employment. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34
Long-Run Trends in Labor Market Outcomes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34
A Rising Tide Lifts Some Boats More Than Others: Cyclical
Variation Across Groups. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37
Full Employment’s Effect on Wages and Household Incomes.. 44
Getting to and Staying at Full Employment. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47
Conclusion. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54
Chapter 2: The Year in Review and the Years Ahead. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61
The Year in Review: The Continuing Recovery. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64
Output in 2023: A Return to Normal Growth. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64
The Gradual Rebalancing of Demand and Supply
in the Labor Market. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70
Inflation in 2023. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79
Financial Markets in 2023. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89
The Rise in Long-Term Rates. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Real Rates as the Driver of Higher Long-Term Rates. . . . . . . .
A Higher Expected Path for the Real Policy Rate. . . . . . . . . . .
The Term Premium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

90
94
95
97

11

Potential Risks for the Outlook. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98
The Forecast for the Years Ahead .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 101
The Near Term . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 103
The Long Term . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 104
Chapter 3: Population, Aging, and the Economy. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109
Declining Fertility in the 21st Century. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 110
U.S. Fertility Since the Global Financial Crisis.. . . . . . . . . . . 110
Low Fertility: A Global Trend.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113
Opportunity Cost. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114
Mortality: Uneven Progress in the 21st Century. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 120
Infectious Disease: The Importance of Vaccinations. . . . . . . . 121
External Causes: Setbacks in Midlife Mortality. . . . . . . . . . . . 125
Chronic Disease: Progress Through Innovation and Health
Care Access. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 127
Aging and the Economy.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 128
Confronting Sustained Low Fertility.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
A Role for Immigration in Filling Workforce Gaps. . . . . . . . .
The Old Age Dependency Ratio: A Race Between Aging
and Productivity Growth. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Aging and the Fiscal Outlook . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Planning for the Demographic Future. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

129
131
133
135
140

Chapter 4: Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing: Economic Insights
and Federal Policy Solutions. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 143
Magnitude and Trends. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 145
Unaffordable Housing. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 145
The Housing Supply Shortage. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 148
Causes of Housing Supply Shortages. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 150
The Wedge Between Price and Construction Cost: Land Value.....152
Zoning and Land-Use Regulations: Effects on
the Housing Supply. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 152
Additional Constraints. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 155
Housing Supply Shortages: Consequences for Welfare, Economic
Mobility, and Aggregate Output. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 159

12 |

Annual Report of the Council of Economic Advisers

Neighborhood Choice, Individual Welfare, and
Economic Mobility. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Wealth Accumulation.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Income Shocks, Housing Instability, and Homelessness.. . . . .
Implications for Inflation and Aggregate Growth.. . . . . . . . . .
Federal Policy’s Role . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Zoning Reforms: Expanding the Housing Supply
and Increasing Affordability. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Reducing Supply Constraints with Federal Taxes
and Other Subsidies. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Expanding Manufactured Home Delivery and Financing
to Address Rural Housing Constraints . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

159
160
161
162
163
163
167
171

Conclusion. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 172
Chapter 5: International Trade and Investment Flows. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 173
Long-Term Trends in Trade and Foreign Investment. . . . . . . . . . .
Global Integration Slowed After the Global Financial
Crisis, Following Earlier Decades of Rapid Growth. . . . . . . .
U.S. Trade Growth Tracks Global Trends: Signs of a
Recent Slowdown and Recovery. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
U.S. Trade Deficits Are Driven by Aggregate Saving and
Investment Patterns . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

175
176
181
184

The United States Leads in Global FDI Flows. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 188
The Rise of Global Value Chains and Early Signs of Reallocation.......195
Early Evidence of Supplier Reallocation in 2023.. . . . . . . . . . 197
The Costs and Benefits of Global Integration for Workers,
Consumers, and Communities. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 200
Global Integration and Inequality. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 201
Trading Firms and Job Creation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 204
Mitigating the Challenges of Global Integration. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 207
Conclusion. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 209

Contents

| 13

Chapter 6: Accelerating the Clean Energy Transition.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 211
The Economics of Structural Change. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 217
What Is Structural Change? .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 217
Determinants of Structural Change . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 218
Market Failures and Policy Implications . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 221
Structural Change and the Clean Energy Transition. . . . . . . . . . . . 222
The Costs of Fossil Fuels. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 222
Clean Energy Opportunities and Challenges. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 223
Financing the Speed and Scale of the Clean Energy Transition.....229
The Role of the Public Sector. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 231
Supply-Side Policies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 234
Demand-Side Policies. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 238
Coordinating Supply and Demand .. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 240
Conclusion. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 241
Chapter 7: An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial
Intelligence. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 243
Toward “Intelligent” Automation.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 244
Prediction Is Improving but Faces Constraints. . . . . . . . . . . . 247
Garbage In, Garbage Out. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 249
From the Technological Frontier to Reality.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Adoption Is Difficult and Invariably Lags the
Technological Frontier. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
AI Has the Potential to Be Even More Transformative
in the Future. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
When Will We Know the Future Has Arrived?. . . . . . . . . . . . .

252

AI and the Labor Market. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Modeling the Effect of Technological Change on
Labor Markets. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Occupation-Specific Effects of AI. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .
Evidence for AI’s Effects. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

260

252
255
257

262
266
271

Preparing Institutions for AI. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 273
Ownership, Liability, and Regulation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 274
Competition and Market Structure. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 278

14 |

Annual Report of the Council of Economic Advisers

Labor Market Institutions. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 282
Measuring AI and Its Effects.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 286
Conclusions and Open Questions. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 289
References.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 291
A.
B.

1-i
1-1
1-2
1-ii
1-iii
1-3
1-4
1-5
1-6
1-7
1-8
1-iv
1-9
1-10
1-11
1-12
1-13
1-14
1-15

Appendixes

Report to the President on the Activities of the Council
of Economic Advisers during 2023............................................ 385
Statistical Tables Relating to Income, Employment,
and Production............................................................................ 401

Figures

Measures of Labor Market Tightness............................................26
Estimates of the Natural Rate of Unemployment.........................28
The CBO’s Estimates of the Natural Rate of
Unemployment, 1996–2033..........................................................29
Share of Union Workers Involved in Work
Stoppages, 1949–2022...................................................................32
Change in the Labor Share and the Unemployment
Rate Gap, 1948–2023....................................................................33
Racial Gaps in the Unemployment Rate.......................................35
Racial Gaps in the Employment-Population Ratio.......................36
The Cyclicality of Unemployment versus Average
Unemployment..............................................................................38
The Cyclicality of the LFPR versus Average LFPR.....................39
The Cyclicality of Job-to-Job Rate Gaps, by Race
and Education................................................................................40
Monthly Transition Rate of the Disabled from
Nonparticipation to Employment..................................................41
Occupational Advancement Index.................................................43
Median Real Wages, by Race and Ethnicity.................................44
Hourly Wage Compression, Pre- and Post-COVID......................45
Effects of a Looser Labor Market on Household Income.............47
The Congressional Budget Office’s Estimate of the
Unemployment Rate Gap..............................................................48
Core PCE Price Inflation and Unemployment Rate Gap..............51
The Beveridge Curve, Pre- and Post-COVID...............................52
Phillips Curve, Pre- and Post-COVID, MSA-Level Data.............53

Contents

| 15

2-1
2-2
2-3
2-4
2-5
2-6
2-7
2-8
2-9
2-10
2-11
2-12
2-13
2-14
2-15
2-16
2-17
2-18
2-19
2-20
2-21
2-i
2-ii
2-22
2-23
2-24
2-iii
2-iv
2-v
2-25
2-26
2-27
2-28

16 |

Recession Probability Indicators, 2008–23...................................61
Selected U.S. Economic Measures, 2019–23................................62
Goods’ and Services’ Shares of Personal Consumption...............66
Share of U.S. Employees Working from Home............................66
Real Private Fixed Investment in Manufacturing
Structures, 1959–2023...................................................................67
Real Private Investment: Structures..............................................68
Ratio of Real Inventories to Sales: Merchant
Wholesale Trade, 2013–23............................................................69
Fiscal Impulse by Source..............................................................70
Real GDP Compared with Lagged Real GDP and PDFP.............71
Monthly Change in Nonfarm Employment...................................72
Quits, Hires, and Job Openings Rates...........................................73
Measures of Labor Market Tightness............................................74
Beveridge Curves..........................................................................75
Measures of Employment Separation...........................................76
Women’s Prime Age (25–54) Labor Force Participation..............77
Factors Affecting the Size of the Labor Force,
February 2020–October 2023........................................................77
Business Sector Productivity and Trend.......................................78
Private Sector Compensation Growth and Inflation.....................79
Contributions to Headline CPI Inflation.......................................80
Selected Measures of Rent Growth...............................................80
Contributions to GDP Growth, per the Federal Reserve’s
Financial Conditions Impulse on Growth (FCI-G).......................81
The Saving Rate............................................................................82
Wealth-to-Income Ratio versus Consumption Rate......................83
Indicators of Supply Chain Pressure.............................................84
Change in Core PCE Inflation.......................................................85
Actual and Expected Inflation, 2012–23.......................................85
Indicators of Consumer Attitudes..................................................86
University of Michigan Sentiment, Actual and Predicted.............87
University of Michigan Sentiment, Actual, Predicted,
and Augmented..............................................................................88
Selected Nominal U.S. Interest Rates...........................................90
Outstanding Loan Amounts Relative to GDP...............................91
Credit Conditions for Business Loans...........................................92
Bond Returns and Unrealized Gains/Losses.................................92

Annual Report of the Council of Economic Advisers

2-29
2-30
2-31
2-32
2-33
2-34
2-35
2-36
3-1
3-2
3-3
3-i
3-4
3-ii
3-5
3-6
3-7
3-8
3-9
3-10
3-iii
4-1
4-2
4-3
4-4
4-5
4-6
4-7
4-8
4-i
4-9

Treasury Volatility and Market Conditions...................................93
Nominal and TIPS Treasury Yield Curves....................................94
Components of Nominal Rates.....................................................95
Federal Funds Rate and Federal Funds Futures Rates..................96
U.S. Debt by Type and Holder......................................................98
Equity Risk Premium..................................................................100
Estimation of Potential Output Growth by
Okun’s Law, 2006–22..................................................................103
The Evolution of the U.S. Population’s Age Composition.........105
Fertility Rates by Race and Hispanic Origin, 2003–22..............111
Age-Specific Fertility Rates Over Time......................................112
Total Fertility Rate in the United States and Other
High-Income Countries and Regions, 1950–2021......................113
Changes in Travel Time to Nearest Provider, 2021–23..............118
Life Expectancy at Birth, 1900–2022.........................................121
U.S. Infant Mortality Rate, 1995–2022.......................................123
Selected Leading Causes of Death, 1950–2021..........................126
U.S. Age Distributions for Men and Women..............................130
Total Population through 2100....................................................132
U.S. Old Age Dependency Ratio through 2050..........................133
Annual Medicare Spending per Beneficiary...............................138
Global Prescription Drug Prices, U.S. Net Price
Adjustment, 2018........................................................................140
Savings Rates and Wealth in 2022, by Age Group.....................142
Housing Price Index versus Wage Index, 1975–2023................145
Renter Households That Spent More Than 30 Percent of
Family Income on Rent, 1960–2022...........................................146
Minimum Monthly Hours of Work Needed to Pay
for Median Monthly Rent............................................................147
Share of Households That Are Rent-Burdened by
Household Head Characteristics, 2022.......................................148
Share of Households That Are Rent-Burdened by
Geography, 2022..........................................................................149
U.S. Housing Production, 1963–2022.........................................150
Share of New Single-Family Homes under
1,400 Square Feet, 1973–2022....................................................150
Housing Prices and Construction Costs, 1980–2022..................152
Rent Comparisons Under Different Funding Scenarios..............158
Homeownership Rate and Median Net Family Worth, 2022......160
Contents

| 17

4-10
4-11
5-1
5-2
5-3
5-4
5-5
5-6
5-7
5-i
5-8
5-9
5-ii
5-10
5-11
5-12
5-13
5-14

5-15

5-16
6-1
6-2
6-3
18 |

Components of Year-on-Year Headline CPI
Inflation, 2013–23.......................................................................162
Financial Characteristics of LIHTC Unit Tenants, 2021............169
Trade in Goods as a Percent of GDP, 1995–2022.......................176
Total Foreign Direct Investment Flows as a
Percentage of GDP, 2006–22......................................................178
Indicators of Global Value Chain Participation..........................180
Real Quarterly Trade in Goods, Actual versus
Forecasted, 1992–2023................................................................181
Real Quarterly Trade in Services, Actual versus
Forecasted, 1992–2023................................................................182
U.S. Services Exports by Broad Product
Categories, 1999–2023................................................................183
U.S. Trade Balances and Real Growth, 1992–2023....................185
U.S.–China Trade Deficit, 2009–22............................................187
U.S. FDI Flows as a Percentage of GDP, 1990:Q1–2023:Q2.....189
Real FDI in U.S. Manufacturing New Establishments and
Expansions, 2014–22...................................................................191
Battery Investments as a Share of Total Actual
Manufacturing Investments, 2021–23.........................................192
U.S. Goods Imports by End Use, 1990–2023.............................197
Percentage Change in U.S. Import Share, by Country,
2017–23.......................................................................................199
Percentage Change in U.S. Import Share of Advanced
Technology Products, by Country, 2017–23...............................199
Pro-Poor Bias in Gains from Trade in the United States
(Percent Welfare Gain)................................................................203
FDI in Clean Energy Projects between 2021:Q1 and
2023:Q2, by Investor Headquarter Country, and Decline
in Manufacturing Employment between 1990 and 2007
(Percentage of Working-Age Population)...................................204
Correlations Between Historical Declines in Manufacturing
Employment between 1990 and 2007 and the Total Number
and Value of Recently Announced Clean Energy Projects
between 2021:Q1 and 2023:Q2...................................................205
Goods Trader and Employment by Firm Size,
1992–2021 Average.....................................................................206
U.S. Net Total Greenhouse Gas Emissions, with Emissions
Reduction Goals..........................................................................212
U.S. Emissions per Sector, 1990–2021.......................................214
U.S. Electricity Generation by Energy Source, 1990–2021.......214
Annual Report of the Council of Economic Advisers

6-4
6-5
6-i
7-1
7-2
7-3
7-4
7-5
7-6
7-7
7-8
7-9
7-10

1-1
1-2
1-3
2–1
2–2
2–3
5-i
5-ii
5-iii

Capital Cost Curves for PV Solar and Onshore
Wind, 2000–2020........................................................................226
Schematic: GHG Emissions with and without
Structural Change Dynamics.......................................................232
Projected and Target Global Manufacturing Capacity, 2030......236
A Stylized Diagram of How AI Extends Automation
with Prediction.............................................................................246
AI Capabilities Over Time and Across Tasks.............................248
Nonfarm Labor Productivity Growth, 1975–2010
(5-Year Moving Average)............................................................257
Employment-Population Ratio and Weekly
Work Hours, 1976–2022.............................................................261
Cumulative Changes in Real Weekly Earnings by
Education for Men and Women...................................................263
Smoothed Changes in Employment and Earnings Across
Occupational Wage Distribution.................................................264
Employment in High-AI-Exposed Occupations
by Earnings Decile......................................................................268
Share of Workers in High-AI-Exposure Occupations
by Demographic..........................................................................269
Industry AI Exposure versus Payroll Employment Growth
Relative to Long-Run Trends......................................................272
Average Population Density by Decile of Geographic
AI Exposure.................................................................................284

Tables

Wage Compression in the Pre- and Post-COVID
Labor Markets...............................................................................46
Predicted Changes in Real Household Incomes over
Selected Business Cycles..............................................................46
Inflation and Labor Market Outcomes Since Total PCE Peak.....50
Real GDP Growth and Its Components, 2023:Q4........................65
Economic Projections, 2022–34..................................................101
Supply-Side Components of Actual and Potential
Real Output Growth, 1953–2034................................................106
Percentage of Imports to the United States in the HighCapacity Battery Supply Chain by Top Partner Countries.........193
Percentage of Imports by Raw Materials and Lithium-Ion
Battery Parts by Top Sources, 2021–23......................................193
Ford Motor Company’s Investment Announcements in
High-Capacity Battery Materials, 2022–23................................193
Contents

| 19

1-1
1-2
1-3
1-4
2–1
2–2
3-1
3-2
3-3
3-4
3-5
3-6
3-7
4-1
4-2
4-3
4-4
5-1
5-2
6-1
6-2
6-3
6-4
7-1
7-2
7-3
7-4

20 |

Boxes

Alternative Measures of Labor Market Tightness.........................25
Workers’ Bargaining Power and Full Employment......................32
Occupational Upgrading................................................................42
Policies Targeting Structural Labor Market Slack........................55
Strong Balance Sheets Supported Household
Consumption in 2023....................................................................82
Consumer Attitudes and Economic Data......................................86
Climate and Population Growth..................................................115
Reproductive Autonomy and Labor Market Participation..........117
Abortion Access and Fertility After Dobbs v. Jackson
Women’s Health Organization.....................................................117
Infant and Maternal Mortality.....................................................123
Investing in Productivity through Human Capital......................136
Long-Term Care..........................................................................137
Consumption and Investment in an Aging Society.....................141
A Brief History of Exclusionary Zoning Laws
in the United States.....................................................................154
Penciling the Deal: The Math Behind Developing
Rental Housing with LIHTC.......................................................156
Assistance for Housing Demand.................................................164
State and Local Zoning: Recent Steps........................................166
Trade Balances and Capital Flows—Fundamental Drivers........186
The U.S. High-Capacity Battery Supply Chain and the
Complementary Role of Domestic and Trade Policies...............192
World War II and Technological Change....................................218
Fossil Fuel Subsidies...................................................................223
The Public Sector’s Role in Accelerating Structural
Change: The Case of South Korea..............................................233
The Need for Global Climate Collaboration...............................235
AI and Equity/Discrimination.....................................................251
Government Applications of AI..................................................258
What Can Voluntary AI Agreements Accomplish?.....................283
Should AI Be Taxed?...................................................................286

Annual Report of the Council of Economic Advisers

Chapter 1

The Benefits of Full Employment
This chapter is dedicated to Dr. William Spriggs and his lifelong efforts to
promote economic justice for all. It is hoped that the chapter reflects his
view: “Full employment should mean full employment for all; not some.”
(Spriggs 2015)
This chapter discusses the economic effects of tight labor markets—loosely
speaking, when jobs are plentiful relative to searchers—on working families
and the macroeconomy. This topic is of great consequence for working
Americans, and thus also for the worker-centered policies of the BidenHarris Administration. The chapter draws attention to three economic
periods characterized by tight labor markets: the late 1990s, the late 2010s,
and the most recent period, starting in the wake of the COVID-19 pandemic.
The chapter first describes the concept of “full employment,” and then
considers an economic framework rooted in firm market power, known
as monopsony power (Manning 2003). An immediate consequence of this
framework is the critical role of tight labor markets in improving workers’ bargaining position for higher wages and better jobs. The monopsony
framework also helps to lay the foundation for understanding the deep and
important benefits of full employment, particularly for groups often left
behind when labor markets are slack.
This chapter’s central findings also highlight the benefits of full employment
for labor market outcomes—such as unemployment, labor force participation, wages, and other measures—across demographic groups that are often
economically vulnerable. In particular, the CEA finds that demographic
groups (e.g., as determined by education, race, and sex) with higher average

21

unemployment rates relative to other groups see larger declines in unemployment rates during expansions. Relatedly, groups with lower average
labor force participation see relatively larger increases in their participation
rates during expansions than do those with higher participation rates. The
implication of these results is that strong labor markets lead to a convergence
in critical labor market outcomes across groups, a finding echoed by Cajner
and others (2017) and Aaronson and others (2019). The converse is also true:
economic downturns and slack labor markets are particularly harmful for
relatively less advantaged groups.
This chapter also highlights several striking findings related to tight labor
markets and traditionally disadvantaged demographic groups. First, racial
gaps in labor market outcomes shrink in tight labor markets. In the most
recent periods of full employment—just before the COVID-19 pandemic
and in the last two years—the unemployment and employment gaps between
Black and white men each fell to the lowest level on record. Second, economically vulnerable groups (e.g., the relatively less educated) are more
likely to switch jobs when the unemployment rate is low, enabling them
to climb the job ladder when jobs are plentiful. Third, workers who face a
work-limiting disability are more likely to obtain jobs in particularly strong
labor markets. Fourth, wages and earnings tend to be flat during periods of
weak or stagnant labor markets but grow when the economy experiences
a tight job market, such as in the late 1990s, the late 2010s, and the postCOVID years. Fifth, wages and annual earnings converge during tight labor
markets, as previously demonstrated with unemployment and participation
rate convergence; the effect appears in a remarkable narrowing of the ratio
of wages between the 90th and 10th percentiles and 90th and 50th percentiles since 2015.
Because of the depth of these benefits, the chapter next considers which
policy choices can help attain and maintain a full-employment labor market,
highlighting two crucial pillars of effective macroeconomic stabilization

22 |

Chapter 1

policy that can work toward this goal: (1) data-driven monetary policy and
(2) temporary fiscal policy. Both can be used to ameliorate negative shocks
to economic growth and output gaps. The chapter also considers a potential
cost of full employment: higher inflation than would otherwise occur. Here,
the CEA’s analysis finds little evidence to suggest that persistently tight
labor markets are necessarily costly in inflationary terms; indeed, the period
before COVID-19 featured historically low unemployment with quiescent
inflation. Many previous episodes of full employment did not clearly correlate with high inflation (though some early ones did, recent periods did
not). And though strong labor demand played a role in the excess inflation
of 2021–22, much of it was clearly due to nondemand, non–labor market
factors, including the pandemic and its impact on supply chains.
The chapter concludes with a review of the period since June 2022, when
total personal consumption expenditures price inflation peaked at 7.1
percent. From the perspective of the Phillips curve model, decreasing
inflation comes at the cost of increasing unemployment, a decrease in inflation expectations, or favorable supply shocks. Since June 2022, the U.S.
economy has experienced a substantial degree of disinflation, with relatively
little sacrifice in the form of labor market deterioration. This suggests
that recent inflation has largely been driven by factors other than the low
unemployment rate. The most likely explanation, since longer-term inflation
expectations remained anchored, is a resolution of supply disruptions—both
in production and labor supply—caused by COVID-19 and the recovery
from it. This explanation is supported by a recent CEA analysis showing that
supply-side variables, both alone and interacting with demand, explain most
of the disinflation over the past few years (CEA 2023a).
It is, of course, always possible that further disinflation will require more
declines in economic activity than have occurred thus far. But the disinflation that has occurred to date has very clearly not been accompanied by a

The Benefits of Full Employment | 23

sacrificing of the tight labor market conditions that deliver critical benefits
to American households.

What Is Full Employment, and Why Does It Matter?
Full employment is neither a new concept nor the sole purview of economists. Societal discussions of full employment predate economics as a discipline.1 In simple terms, full employment describes an economy in which
workers able and willing to work can obtain the jobs and hours they want.
Modern economics has generally defined full employment by citing the
theoretical concept of the lowest unemployment rate consistent with stable
inflation, which is referred to as u* (“u-star”), the natural rate of unemployment, or the nonaccelerating inflationary rate of unemployment (termed
NAIRU).2 (See box 1-1.)
Regardless of the specific model or definition, if unemployment is at
u*, the labor force is at full capacity, such that the number of workers needed
(labor demand) roughly matches the number willing to work at the wages
offered (labor supply). The value of u* is necessarily above zero, as, even at
full employment, so-called frictional unemployment exists, in which some
job seekers (i.e., the unemployed) are between jobs while others may have
wage demands that employers are unwilling to pay.
A separate and economically important way of conceptualizing u* is
to note that when unemployment is at its natural rate, additional demand
for workers is more likely to generate inflation than boost real incomes.
This conception of u* returns to the trade-off embodied in the Phillips
curve, as discussed above—specifically, the negative relationship between

See, for example, the British Historical Register (1731, 187): “The more distinct the Employment
is, the better, for many Inconveniencies have attended one Manufacture interfering with another;
besides, there will be an Intercourse of Trade created by one Part of the Kingdom supplying the
other with their distinct Manufactures; this will give full Employment to the whole Kingdom, and
a universal Cheerfulness to every Body: For the Poor are never happier, nor their Minds easier,
than when they have full Employment; and when they are employed, Riches are diffused over the
Nation.”
2
This definition replaces employment with unemployment, primarily because individuals have
many reasons for choosing to forgo work and attend school, retire, take care of family, etc. Full
employment is a case in which demand is sufficient to provide employment to those who want to
work. Of course, the unemployment rate itself may not be the only, or most inclusive, measure of
labor market tightness, as addressed in box 1-1. Further, the government could enact many policies
to boost incentives for individuals to join the labor force (some of which are highlighted in box 1-4
below), which might change the equilibrium rate of employment, although not necessarily the natural
rate of unemployment.
1

24 |

Chapter 1

Box 1-1. Alternative Measures of
Labor Market Tightness
One working definition of full employment is the unemployment rate
that is consistent with stable inflation. But the unemployment rate has
notable downsides as a yardstick of labor market slack when set against
the definition: it ignores workers who are out of the labor force, workers
who are underemployed, and job openings that are unfilled—among
other potential downsides.
While this chapter relies on the unemployment rate and the
Congressional Budget Office’s estimate of the natural rate of unemployment, this box considers four common alternative measures of labor
market slack: (1) the ratio of vacancies to unemployment (V/U); (2)
U-6, a broader measure of unemployment that incorporates some nonparticipants and some part-time workers; (3) the prime-age employmentto-population ratio; and (4) the quits rate.
A number of features make the ratio of vacancies to unemployment, V/U, appealing. First, in a large class of models of unemployment
(Pissarides 2000), the degree of tightness in the labor market is measured
via this ratio. Second, as a counterpart to the supply of workers who
want jobs, V/U directly accounts for vacancies, a measure of the unmet
demand for workers (Elsby, Michaels, and Ratner 2015). When there
are more job openings than unemployed, the labor market is considered
tight, since firms will have more difficulty recruiting and workers will
have an easier time finding a job. V/U is strongly correlated with the
unemployment rate, and researchers have found that it has a lower
forecast error than the unemployment gap when predicting core personal
consumption expenditures and wage inflation (Barnichon and Shapiro
2022). (Of course, there are critiques of vacancies as a measure of unmet
labor demand, as well. For example, Davis, Faberman, and Haltiwanger
2013 show that recruiting intensity by firms is itself cyclical.) Further,
Benigno and Eggertsson (2023) suggest that the unemployment-inflation
relationship becomes nonlinear after V/U goes above 1, leading to accelerating prices when the labor market gets tight.
Both U-6 and the prime-age employment-to-population ratio are
measures that expand the definition of job searchers beyond the unemployed. Focusing only on the unemployed assumes that those who are
outside the labor force have a negligible job finding rate. However, when
disaggregating into more granular groups, individuals who are out of the
labor force but want a job are just as likely to transition to employment
as the long-term unemployed. And even some nonparticipants who
say they do not want a job transition to employment (Kudlyak 2017).
Therefore, the unemployment rate could understate the true available
labor supply (Hornstein, Kudlyak, and Lange 2014).

The Benefits of Full Employment | 25

Figure 1-i. Measures of Labor Market Tightness
Z-score

6
5
4
3
2
1
0
–1
–2
–3
–4

–5
2001:Q1 2003:Q1 2005:Q1 2007:Q1 2009:Q1 2011:Q1 2013:Q1 2015:Q1 2017:Q1 2019:Q1 2021:Q1 2023:Q1
u*-u

V/U

Quits rate

U-6 (negated)

Prime-age EPOP

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Congressional Budget Office (CBO); CEA calculations.
Note: EPOP = employment-to-population ratio. u = unemployment rate. u* = CBO's natural rate of unemployment. U-6 rate
includes marginally attached individuals and those working part time for economic reasons. V/U= job openings divided by
unemployment. Z-scores were calculated using the sample mean and standard deviations of each measure from 2001 to 2019.
Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

U-6 starts with the standard unemployment rate as a base, but it
also includes so-called marginally attached individuals and workers
who are part time for economic reasons. Individuals are considered
marginally attached if they would accept a job if offered one and have
looked for work in the last year but not in the last four weeks. Workers
are considered part time for economic reasons if they report working less
than 35 hours per week due to slack work, unfavorable business conditions, an inability to find full-time work, seasonal declines in demand,
or other economic reasons.
The prime-age employment-to-population ratio (PAEPOP) further
includes all nonparticipants as potential job searchers. Focusing on those
who are prime age (i.e., 25–54) excludes the effects of population aging
and abstracts from school-going and retirement years. Researchers find
that, compared with unemployment, the PAEPOP is equally predictive
of core personal consumption expenditures inflation and is potentially a
better predictor of real wage growth (Furman and Powell 2021).
One additional measure of labor market tightness is the quits rate,
which counts the number of employed individuals who have voluntarily
left their job (excluding retirements and transfers) in a month as a
percentage of employment. The quits rate is a good indicator of the
strength of a labor market, as an elevated number of employed individuals voluntarily leave their jobs if they believe they can find a better job
(Gittleman 2022; Yellen 2014; CEA 2022). Researchers also find that
the quits rate and job-to-job switching behavior is a better predictor of

26 |

Chapter 1

wage growth and inflation than the unemployment rate (Karahan et al.
2017; Moscarini and Postel-Vinay 2017; Furman and Powell 2021).
Faccini and Melosi (2023) found that elevated quits were directly linked
to increases in the inflation rate in 2021.
Figure 1-i plots all four alternative measures, along with the unemployment gap, after normalizing each measure by its mean from 2001 to
2019 (inverting when necessary) and dividing by its standard deviation
to make them comparable. All five measures track each other relatively
well during the period before the COVID-19 pandemic, although the
V/U ratio did indicate a slightly tighter labor market before COVID-19.
Both during and after the pandemic, both V/U and the quits rate
diverge from the movements in the other three series. The two measures
have suggested a notably tighter labor market since 2021 than the
unemployment rate itself. The evolution of the two variables is precisely
why policymakers have become focused on movements in the Beveridge
curve and wage pressures in the labor market.

unemployment and inflation that has been at the center of macroeconomic
models for decades.3

Estimates of the Natural Rate of Unemployment
Although the historical record confirms a negative correlation between
unemployment and inflation in general (Crump et al. 2019), a number of
both theoretical and empirical problems render u* impractical for policy
purposes. First, u* is unobservable, meaning it must be estimated, which
can only be done in the context of a particular model, and typically with
wide margins of error (see chapter 1 of the 2016 Economic Report of the
President, CEA 2016a). Figures 1-1 and 1-2 offer two perspectives on the
issue. Figure 1-1 compares current estimates of the natural rate from multiple organizations—the Congressional Budget Office’s (CBO’s) reports,
various Federal Reserve System estimates, the CEA’s analyses, and those
of professional forecasters. Clearly, estimates of u* vary considerably over
time and across estimators; the range of estimates spanned nearly 2 percentage points at its maximum at the height of the global financial crisis and
exceeded 2 percentage points in the post-COVID period. However, even in
the relatively calm period before COVID-19, the estimates varied by nearly
a full percentage point.
For example, a very simple reduced-form Phillips curve implies a u* derived from this regression:
πt – π* = α + βut + ϵt, where πt is inflation and ut is the unemployment rate. Setting πt = π* (typically
2 percent) defines ut* as –α/β.

3

The Benefits of Full Employment | 27

Figure 1-1. Estimates of the Natural Rate of Unemployment

Percent
8.5
8.0
7.5
7.0
6.5
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5

3.0
1996

1999

2002

2005

Congressional Budget Office
Federal Open Market Committee
Fleischman and Roberts (2011)

Council of Economic Advisers

2008

2011

2014

2017

2020

2023

Survey of Professional Forecasters
Bok et al. (2023)
CEA supply-side model

Sources: Congressional Budget Office; Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia; Federal Reserve Board of Governors; Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco; Bok et al. (2023); Fleischman and Roberts (2011); CEA calculations.
Note: Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Second, the particular model underlying an estimate of the natural rate
of unemployment is crucial. For example, some estimates are considered
“long-run” estimates, which can be thought of as the unemployment rate
toward which the economy would tend in the absence of shocks. Short-run
shocks, such as those that impede matching workers and jobs in the labor
market or that temporarily raise unemployment (or inflation), can raise the
short-run natural rate, as they likely did after the global financial crisis and
COVID-19. In figure 1-1, the natural rates presented reflect a combination
of concepts. The CBO’s estimate is akin to a long-run rate, while the Survey
of Professional Forecasters’ estimate is likely a combination of concepts
across the different analysts who respond to the survey.4 Bok and others
(2023) present a number of measures, including one based on a Phillips
curve concept of the stable inflation rate of unemployment, making it akin
to a short-run approach.
Related to the distinction between the time horizon and model underlying any estimate of u*, figure 1-2 offers another perspective on the difficulty
of precisely estimating the value. The figure presents several vintages of
CBO forecasts of the natural rate starting in the mid-1990s. As is apparent,
the estimates are subject to large revisions over time. This is partly because
the CBO has itself changed the definition of the natural rate over time,

4

For a detailed discussion of the differences, see Bok et al. (2023).

28 |

Chapter 1

Figure 1-2. The CBO's Estimates of the Natural Rate of Unemployment, 1996–2033
CBO 10-year projections (percent)
6.1
5.8

February 2014

5.5

January 2012

January 2006

5.2

January 2010

4.9

January 2016

January 2008

4.6

April 2018
February 2023

4.3
4.0
1996

January 2020
2000

2004

2008

2012

2016

2020

2024

2028

2032

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Congressional Budget Office (CBO); CEA calculations.
Note: The natural unemployment rates shown are annual averages of quarterly projections by the Congressional Budget Office. Gray bars
indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

settling recently on a long-term concept, whereas previously the agency
distinguished short- and long-run rates.
Regardless of the reason, any entity’s estimate of u* in a given year
may change dramatically if unemployment surprisingly falls below the
estimated u* for a sustained period, as it did in the pre-COVID era of low
unemployment. The CBO’s estimate of u* for 2019, for example, fell when
it updated its estimates from 2016 to 2018 and then again in 2020. Finally,
as figures 1-1 and 1-2 show, u* is not a constant. Its movements are generated by changes in the macroeconomy, workers’ demographics, and fiscal
and monetary policy changes. For example, the CBO’s estimate of u* was
revised up at the onset of the global financial crisis (as were many other estimates); but as unemployment decreased in the latter stages of the recovery
from the crisis, the CBO’s estimate of u* repeatedly moved down. There is
good reason that the economist James Galbraith quipped, in a critique of u*,
“It’s not only invisible; it moves” (Galbraith 2001).
Another key limitation of using u* as a policy goal is that it embeds
variation in labor market outcomes across groups. This variation in structural labor market outcomes may be undesirable for society. As the CEA
explores in some detail, there is considerable structural variation in unemployment levels (and other labor market indicators) between demographic
groups in the labor market. Black male workers, for example, historically
(starting in 1976, when the data became available) have unemployment rates
averaging 7 percentage points above the rate white men face. The differences cannot be explained in full by other observable characteristics (e.g.,
differences in education), suggesting that discrimination may be a factor in
The Benefits of Full Employment | 29

the persistent differential. Therefore, were policymakers simply to aim for
historical estimates of u*, which have been consistent with large racial gaps,
they risk embedding permanent disadvantages in groups that have long been
left behind.
For all its shortcomings, the CEA still views u* as a useful concept,
as long as analysts understand that it cannot accurately be pinned down to
a specific rate, especially in real time, and that it leaves out critical dynamics at play in the U.S. economy and labor market. Today, most economists
would agree that 5 percent is above u*, at least over a long enough period
to allow acute short-run shocks to be worn away, and 3 percent is likely
below it. Indeed, before the pandemic, the jobless rate was in the range of
3.5 to 4 percent and did not create inflationary pressures. During the current
recovery, rates in this range have been maintained while inflation has fallen.
In other words, recent history shows that unemployment rates between 3.5
and 4 percent can be consistent with sustainable inflation in the long run and
allow the U.S. economy to enjoy the benefits of full employment.
The recent postpandemic period of tight labor markets and elevated
inflation raises two questions: (1) Has u* increased structurally, so that the
pursuit of maintaining tight labor markets engenders greater overheating
and inflationary risks than in prior cycles? Or (2) is pandemic economics a
special case, and thus, outside its unusual effects, can the U.S. labor market
still flourish with low unemployment not necessarily accompanied by high
inflation?
To explain the importance of engaging in this section’s u* target
practice, the next section gives a brief theoretical framework to delineate the
interaction of labor markets at full employment and the empirical findings
that the CEA presents in this chapter.

A Monopsonistic Labor Market
A brief summary of a basic labor market model helps ground an understanding of imperfect labor markets, in which employers wield some degree of
wage-setting power, and which economists typically call monopsony power.
In contrast, the textbook version of a perfect labor market envisions identical firms that are unable to set wages below the market level, lest they lose
all workers to other employers, a case in which employers face a perfectly
elastic labor supply curve. One implication of the perfect competition model
is that wage discrimination and worker exploitation do not persist because
competing firms can attract workers with better working conditions and pay.
Discriminating firms with poorer labor standards must either improve or go
out of business.
In reality, with monopsony power, firms are able to use their relative
strength in the hiring market to set wages to some degree. (For a summary

30 |

Chapter 1

of the empirical literature, see Ashenfelter et al. 2022.) Whereas a pure
monopsony would feature only one employer in a given market, the real
world is of course more complicated and closer to a model that features both
monopsony and competition (Manning 2003, 2021; Yeh, Macaluso, and
Hershbein 2022; CEA 2016b, 2022).
There are many plausible mechanisms that can lead to monopsonistic competition—for example, search frictions that delay job matching,
employer concentration, job heterogeneity, and institutional or legal
constraints like noncompete agreements (Burdett and Mortensen 1998;
Manning 2021; CEA 2016b; Card et al. 2018; Berger, Herkenhoff, and
Mongey 2022; U.S. Department of the Treasury 2022). The most commonly
proposed source of monopsony power is the presence of search frictions,
which impede the process whereby workers match with suitable employers. A canonical search model of monopsony power follows Burdett and
Mortensen (1998), in which firms post wages to attract workers. A critical
implication of the model is that the labor supply curve faced by the firms is
upward sloping: higher wages reduce attrition, improve the ability to hire,
and increase employment. This model is in stark contrast to the perfectly
competitive model, in which firms are wage takers and face perfectly elastic
labor supply curves.
Crucial for the analysis here is that the degree of labor market power
a firm can wield is intimately related to the relative prevalence of available
jobs and workers. In a tight labor market, monopsony power is reduced
because workers’ outside options improve as the likelihood of finding an
alternative or better job rises. The ability of workers to switch to new jobs,
or to quit and quickly find new jobs, allows them to raise their threat point
with firms in wage negotiations. Relatedly, firms face elevated attrition rates
and more difficulty recruiting workers. The improved bargaining position
of workers helps to raise labor’s share of income, as discussed in box 1-2.
One important implication of an economic setting in which employers
wield market power when competing for employees is that screening or
discriminating against workers based on gender, race, disabilities, or other
characteristics—for example, by changing hiring practices or weeding out
résumés based on workers’ characteristics—becomes a less economically
feasible option when the job market is very tight. To do so risks failing
to meet demand for the product or service that the employer sells, thereby
reducing potential profitability and falling behind (nondiscriminatory)
competitors. Informally, employer discrimination in tight labor markets
risks “leaving money on the table.” Thus, the economic framework of
monopsonistic competition suggests that—and CEA research documents
extensively—tighter labor markets are salutary for addressing persistent
racial, gender, and other labor market gaps between advantaged and less
advantaged groups.
The Benefits of Full Employment | 31

Box 1-2. Workers’ Bargaining Power
and Full Employment
One consequence of tight labor markets, where jobs are plentiful relative
to searchers, is that workers’ bargaining power improves. The reasoning
is intuitive: workers’ bargaining power is in part derived from the range
of options available in the labor market. In strong labor markets, it is
relatively easy to find jobs, and the job offers available are more likely
to include elevated wages or expanded opportunities. (See the evidence
given below on wages and occupational upgrading.) For a more detailed
discussion, see Stansbury and Summers (2020).
Another way that workers can exert bargaining power is through
unionization and union activity. Figure 1-ii shows that the share of union
members that engage in a work stoppage (y axis) increases when the gap
between the unemployment rate and the CBO’s natural rate decreases (x
axis). The figure is striking in light of the surge in union activity in recent
years. In the two years before the COVID-19 pandemic, about 450,000
workers engaged in work stoppages per year, highlighted by the educator
strikes in 2018–19 (BLS 2024). The strike activity in these years was
higher than had been registered since the mid-1980s. And in 2023, there
was once again a notable wave of strikes, the most prominent of which
occurred among workers who belong to the United Auto Workers union
at the Big 3 auto plants. Of course, work stoppages are only one example
of union activity, which is easy to measure and thus lends itself to this
analysis; other examples of union activity by workers include filing for

Figure 1-ii. Share of Union Workers Involved in Work Stoppages,
1949–2022
Percentage of union members

16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0

–3

–2

–1

0

1

2

3

Unemployment rate gap (percentage points)

Council of Economic Advisers

4

5

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Congressional Budget Office (CBO); Freeman (1998); Department of the Treasury (2023);
CEA calculations.
Note: Dotted line is the line of best fit for the graphed series. The unemployment rate gap indicates the gap between the
unemployment rate and the CBO's estimate of the natural rate of unemployment.
2024 Economic Report of the President

32 |

Chapter 1

6

Figure 1-iii. Change in the Labor Share and the Unemployment Rate
Gap, 1948–2023
Four-quarter log change in labor's share of income

2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
–0.5
–1.0
–1.5
–2.0
–2.5

–3

–2

–1

0

1

2

3

Unemployment rate gap (percentage points)

4

5

6

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Congressional Budget Office (CBO); CEA calculations.
Note: Dotted line is the line of best fit for the graphed series. The unemployment rate gap indicates the gap between the
unemployment rate and the CBO's estimate of the natural rate of unemployment. Labor's share is for the nonfinancial
corporate business sector.
2024 Economic Report of the President

union elections and negotiating for fair contracts, which have important
effects on the working conditions of those covered by union contracts.
The result of forces that raise bargaining power is that a larger
slice of the economic pie goes to workers (both union and nonunion)
as the economy achieves full employment. One measure of the size of
the slice is what economists call labor’s share of income, or, roughly
speaking, the share of total income that accrues to workers in the form
of compensation. Figure 1-iii shows that a higher labor’s share (y axis)
is associated with lower unemployment rate gaps (x axis).

Although the theoretical models provide a qualitative framework for
defining full employment, the CEA’s analysis shows that full employment
is clearly associated with labor market conditions that are tight enough to
provide workers with meaningful bargaining power. Such power is evident
in the empirical results presented in the next section on the benefits of full
employment.

The Benefits of Full Employment | 33

Evidence on the Benefits of Full Employment
This section provides a set of stylized facts on the benefits that strong labor
markets and full employment provide to workers, especially those who
belong to groups that are typically less attached to the labor market and are
less well compensated than other groups.

Long-Run Trends in Labor Market Outcomes
Long-run trends in unemployment and employment rates, disaggregated
by race and ethnic groups, paint a striking picture of the beneficial effect
of strong labor markets on these outcomes—a note highlighted by Spriggs
(2017). In this chapter, CEA researchers extend the methodology used by
Cajner and others (2017), who estimate gaps in the unemployment rate and
employment-to-population ratios across selected demographic groups that
are unexplained after controlling for age, geographic region, marital status,
and education.5 Figure 1-3 plots the unexplained portion of the unemployment rate for Black men minus white men and Black women minus white
women using a common decomposition method.6 Panel B of the figure
shows Hispanic men minus white men and Hispanic women minus white
women.7
There are several notable features of the differences in unemployment
rates across groups that cannot be explained by observable characteristics.
First, even after accounting for differences in explanatory variables, the
unemployment rates of Black men and women are considerably higher than
those of white men and women. However, the unexplained gaps have been
shrinking since the early 1980s. Second, weak labor markets are particularly
detrimental for economically vulnerable groups; during the global financial
crisis, the unexplained gap in unemployment rates between Black and white
men rose by about 2 percentage points, while the gap between Black and
white women increased by 1.5 percentage points. Further, the unexplained
unemployment rate gaps were persistently higher for the less advantaged
groups after the recession: it took nearly 10 years for the Black male
This work follows Cajner et al. (2017) in estimating Oaxaca-Blinder decompositions for each
year of data starting in 1976 and reporting the unexplained portion of the difference in labor market
outcomes (i.e., the portion not due to differences in the means of the explanatory variables). While
age and gender are obvious choices for exogenous factors that are important in shaping employment
and unemployment, Cajner et al. discuss the merits of controlling for variables that are outcomes
of choices, such as education. For example, if certain groups face structural barriers to education,
then controlling for education may understate the differences in labor market outcomes due to
discrimination faced by the group.
6
This chapter follows Cajner et al. (2017), who focus on the absolute difference in labor market
outcomes across groups rather than the ratios of labor market outcomes.
7
It is important to note that the demographic groups shown here are not meant to be exhaustive of
the groups that are economically vulnerable; indeed, within the relatively coarse groups presented,
there is substantial heterogeneity in labor market outcomes and general socioeconomic well-being.
5

34 |

Chapter 1

Figure 1-3. Racial Gaps in the Unemployment Rate
A. Black versus white

Percentage points of labor force

12
10
8
6
4
2
0

–2
1976

1981

1986

1991

1996

2001

Black/white male gap

2006

2011

2016

2021

2016

2021

Black/white female gap

B. Hispanic versus white
Percentage points of labor force

12
10
8
6
4
2
0

–2
1976

1981

1986

1991

1996

Hispanic/white male gap

2001

2006

2011

Hispanic/white female gap

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
Note: White and Black populations are non-Hispanic. Estimated using methodology from Cajner et al. (2017).
Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

unemployment rate to recover relative to the white male unemployment rate.
Nonetheless, it did recover, and when the labor market approached perhaps
the tightest periods covered by the CEA data, in 2018–19 and 2022–23, the
unemployment rate for Black men was as close to that for white men as has
been on record.
Figure 1-4 presents unexplained gaps in employment-population
ratios using the same controls and comparing the same demographic groups
as shown in figure 1-3. Employment-population ratios are determined by
the unemployment rate and labor force participation, which together help
summarize labor market outcomes across groups. While the cyclicality of
The Benefits of Full Employment | 35

Figure 1-4. Racial Gaps in the Employment-Population Ratio
A. Black versus white

Percentage points of population
5
3
1

–1
–3
–5
–7
–9

–11
–13

–15
1976

1980

1984

1988

1992

1996

2000

Black/white male gap

2004

2008

2012

2016

2020

2024

Black/white female gap

B. Hispanic versus white

Percentage points of population
5
3
1

–1
–3
–5
–7
–9

–11
–13

–15
1976

1980

1984

1988

1992

1996

Hispanic/white male gap

2000

2004

2008

2012

2016

2020

2024

Hispanic/white female gap

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
Note: White and Black populations are non-Hispanic. Estimated using methodology from Cajner et al. (2017). Gray
bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

employment-population ratios is less pronounced, in part due to long-running trend changes in labor force participation, the figures show that strong
labor markets are critical in closing the gaps in labor market outcomes
between groups. For example, the gap between Black and white women narrowed substantially in the full employment labor market of the late 1990s.
After the 2000 recession occurred, and the labor market remained weak
until well into recovery from the global financial crisis, there was a lack of
relative improvement for both Black men and women relative to white men
and women. When the labor market reached full employment in 2015–19,

36 |

Chapter 1

the gap closed substantially, and it continued to do so after the COVID-19
pandemic.
Because the analysis controls for characteristics that partially determine labor market outcomes, such as age, their interpretation hinges on
the source of the unexplained gaps shown in figure 1-4. One determinant
is clearly racial prejudice, which has long been a determinant of labor
market and other economic outcomes (Charles and Guryan 2008; Lang and
Lehmann 2012). Why would tight labor markets reduce racial discrimination in employment?8 First, it does so because workers can more easily find
alternative and better jobs, and they can leave for better opportunities when
they experience discrimination. Second, tight labor markets increase the cost
of discriminatory behavior, making it less economically feasible. If the subset of employers that discriminates by race can find, despite their prejudices,
the workers they need to maximize profitability, it is relatively costless to do
so, especially since they may not suffer the legal or reputational harm from
engaging in discriminatory behavior. But if the labor market is tight enough
that discrimination is costly and leads to lost profits, employers may be less
likely to discriminate and more likely to remove hiring barriers that exclude
qualified workers. This dynamic is at least part of the reason why strong
labor markets are salutary for narrowing racial gaps in the labor market.

A Rising Tide Lifts Some Boats More Than
Others: Cyclical Variation Across Groups
The CEA’s analysis shows that in the United States, economically vulnerable demographic groups—those that, on average, experience worse labor
market outcomes—are the same groups that benefit most from full employment. This examination starts by following a methodology similar to that
developed by Wolfers (2019) to estimate the relationship between lower
aggregate unemployment rates and the labor market outcomes of a broad
swath of demographic groups.
First, the CEA splits the prime-age population into 16 groups defined
by four race/ethnicity categories (Black non-Hispanic, white non-Hispanic,
other non-Hispanic groups, and Hispanic), sex, and two education groups (a
high school degree or less, and some college or more). Second, the CEA calculates the cyclical responsiveness of unemployment for each group across
all business cycles after 1976, when granular microdata became available.
Cyclical responsiveness is defined as the average increase (or decrease) in
While employment discrimination against protected classes is illegal, racial gaps in the labor
market persist. Strong antidiscrimination enforcement by agencies such as the Equal Employment
Opportunity Commission and Department of Labor’s Office of Federal Contract Compliance
Programs are important for creating the long-term structural changes in employment practices that
will prevent such discrimination.

8

The Benefits of Full Employment | 37

Figure 1-5. The Cyclicality of Unemployment versus Average Unemployment
Change in unemployent rate over expansions and recessions (percentage points)
9

Black male, high
school or less

8
7
6

Black female, high
school or less

White male, at least
some college

5
4
3

White female, at least
some college

2
1
0

0

2

4

6

8

10

Average unemployment rate, 1976–2023 (percent)
Council of Economic Advisers

12

14

Sources: Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
Note: Dotted line is the line of best fit for the graphed series. Sample restricted to prime age (25–54) individuals. White and
Black populations are non-Hispanic.
2024 Economic Report of the President

the unemployment rate from the peak (trough) of a business cycle to the
respective trough (peak), with dates defined by the business cycle minimum
and maximum of the aggregate unemployment rate gap. Third, the CEA
calculated the average unemployment rate for each group over the whole
period, 1976–2023.
Figure 1-5 shows the average group-specific unemployment rate on the
x axis and average cyclical responsiveness of the unemployment rate on the
y axis, along with the regression line relating the two.
This picture shows a remarkably strong relationship—and not a
mechanical one or one that need occur—between the group-average unemployment rate (higher x-axis value) and the degree to which the group’s
unemployment rate changes over the business cycle. For example, the topright point of figure 1-5 gives the cyclical sensitivity for prime-age Black
non-Hispanic men with an education of high school or less. The group’s
average unemployment rate is a staggering 12 percent, and this rate changes
by about 7 percentage points over the average business cycle. Further, the
regression line shows that if a group has a 1-percentage-point higher average
unemployment rate, its unemployment rate is expected to change by about
0.5 percentage point more over the business cycle.
Figure 1-6 replaces the unemployment rate with the labor force participation rate (LFPR), which also shows clearly that less advantaged groups

38 |

Chapter 1

Figure 1-6. The Cyclicality of the LFPR versus Average LFPR
Change in LFPR over expansions and recessions (percentage points)
4.5
4.0
3.5

Hispanic female, high
school or less

3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0

White male, at least
some college

0.5
0.0

50

55

60

Council of Economic Advisers

65

70

75

80

85

90

95

100

Average LFPR, 1976–2023 (percent)

Sources: Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
Note: LFPR = labor force participation rate. Dotted line is the line of best fit for the graphed series. Sample restricted to prime
age (25–54) individuals. White and Black populations are non-Hispanic.
2024 Economic Report of the President

benefit more from strong labor markets.9 The groups with a relatively low
average LFPR (moving to the left on the x axis in the figure) experience
relatively larger increases in the LFPR over the business cycle than other
groups.
In addition to unemployment rates falling, and LFPR rising, workers
from less advantaged groups have more success climbing the job ladder
than they otherwise would in a weaker job market. The ability to change
jobs, find better matches, and bargain for higher wages and benefits are
all crucial features of an economy that provides long-lasting opportunities
for workers (Topel and Ward 1992; Bjelland et al. 2011; Haltiwanger et al.
2018; Bosler and Petrosky-Nadeau 2016). Figure 1-7 shows that the ability
of economically vulnerable groups to reap the benefits of moving up the
job ladder is greater when the economy is at full employment than when it
is not. The analysis focuses on differences between demographic groups in
job-to-job switching rates—that is, the rate at which a worker takes a job at

There are likely two reasons why the relationship is not as precise for the LFPR. First, there are
persistent long-term trends in the LFPR that are not controlled for and that may make it difficult
to infer the cycle from the trend (CEA 2014; Aaronson et al. 2014). Second, the cyclicality of the
LFPR is typically more muted than for the unemployment rate and likely has more complicated lag
structures (Cajner, Coglianese, and Montes 2021).

9

The Benefits of Full Employment | 39

Figure 1-7. The Cyclicality of Job-to-Job Rate Gaps, by Race and Education
A. By Race (Black—white)

Job-to-job rate gap (percentage points)
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
–0.5
–1.0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

10

12

14

Unemployment rate (percent)

B. By Education (High School—Some College or More)
Job-to-job rate gap (percentage points)

2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0

–0.5

2

4

6

8

Unemployment rate (percent)

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Census Bureau; CEA calculations.
Note: Dotted line is the line of best fit for the graphed series. White and Black populations are non-Hispanic.
2024 Economic Report of the President

a different employer in a quarter—as produced by the Census’s Longitudinal
Employer-Household Data.10
Panel A of figure 1-7 represents the difference in job-to-job transition rates of Black workers relative to white workers. For example, from
2000:Q3 through 2022:Q3, the average job-to-job switching rate for Black
workers was 6.8 percent and was 4.7 percent for white workers, an average
The Census measure analyzed by the CEA is defined as, roughly, the number of workers whose
job is with one employer in quarter t and another employer in t + 1. Workers are included if they
spend one quarter or less unemployed between jobs at different employers. That number of job-tojob switches is divided by the average number of jobs in both quarters t and t + 1. For additional
information, see Census (2023).
10

40 |

Chapter 1

Figure 1-8. Monthly Transition Rate of the Disabled from Nonparticipation to
Employment
Percent
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

2022

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
Note: Graph shows the annual average share of prime age (25–54) individuals with self-reported disabilities who report
not being in the labor force in month t and employed in month t+1. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

gap of 2.1 percentage points. However, when the unemployment rate was
below 4 percent in 2019, that gap increased to 3.4 percentage points.
Meanwhile, when the unemployment rate was above 9 percent in 2010, the
gap shrank to 0.7 percentage point. This cyclical pattern manifests in the
downward-sloping regression line in panel A of figure 1-7.
Panel B of figure 1-7 echoes these findings for education groups, showing the difference in the job-to-job switching rate of those with only a high
school degree relative to those with a college degree or more. The regression
line is again downward sloping, indicating that strong labor markets benefit
the job ladder prospects of the less educated relative to the more educated.
Box 1-3 sheds additional light on the importance of cyclical upgrading for
average wages, and box 1-1 above further discusses a related measure—the
quits rate—as an alternative measure of labor market tightness.
Another important example of the kinds of workers who benefit
directly from full employment are those with work-limiting disabilities.
Figure 1-8 gives the rate at which prime-age workers who report a worklimiting disability move from nonparticipation to employment, calculated
from longitudinally matched Current Population Survey data; the rate rises
substantially when unemployment falls. Once such workers find jobs, they
accumulate experience and can switch to better jobs. This dynamic process
can lead to long-lasting benefits for these workers and their families, as well
as for the overall productive capacity of the economy (Yellen 2016).

The Benefits of Full Employment | 41

Box 1-3. Occupational Upgrading
Tight labor markets tend to boost average wage levels, and the CEA’s
analysis presented in this chapter shows that workers take advantage
of strong labor markets to switch jobs. This box shows that these two
dynamics are related: during tight labor markets, workers climb the
occupational job ladder and move into jobs associated with higher pay.
To evaluate occupational advancement, the CEA uses an occupational index that takes the median wage in 2018 and 2019 according
to detailed occupation and follows the share of the workforce in each
occupation both backward and forward in time. To measure the occupational wage level in 2018 and 2019, the CEA takes the median of the
hourly wage in the Current Population Survey Outgoing Rotation Group
by occupation (using IPUMS’s harmonized 2010 definitions). More formally, the index is calculated from parameters b0 and b1 in this ordinaryleast-squares regression: Wit = b0 + b1t + BXit + eit, where the sample
uses individual-level Current Population Survey data and includes each
individual in the labor force at time t in harmonized occupation i; Wit is
the median wage of occupation i as of 2018–19, while Xit is a vector of
demographic controls.
In panel A of figure 1-iv, the index is estimated with controls for
sex, age, and birth cohort. It shows that while occupational advancement is indeed cyclical, it has shown steady progress over the last four
decades. The index shown in panel B further controls for education.
An important interpretative distinction between education and the other
controls is that education is likely sensitive to economic conditions:
Educational attainment may in part be countercyclical if individuals
choose to enroll in educational programs when the labor market is weak.
Over the last 40 years, average educational attainment has risen
in the United States. In fact, the flatness of the line in panel B of figure
1-iv relative to the clear upward slope of the line in panel A suggests
that education has been a key driver of occupational advancement since
1980: As workers have become increasingly likely to graduate from
high school and earn a college degree, they have been able to move into
higher-paying occupations.
In addition, the results suggest that the recessions of the early 1980s,
and also in 2001 and 2008, represented a significant occupational decline
among American workers that did not immediately recover (again,
holding education constant). In contrast, during the tight labor markets
of the late 1990s and from 2014 to 2019, occupational advancement
began to accelerate again, then accelerated further during the COVID-19
pandemic. Over the roughly 10 years starting in 2014, workers made up
for the earlier 30 years of losses in occupational advancement. By 2023,
workers were on average in higher-paying jobs than at any point since
1980, even when controlling for education. This result suggests that

42 |

Chapter 1

Figure 1-iv. Occupational Advancement Index
A. Age–Sex Controls
Index: 2018–19 = 100

104
102
100
98
96
94
92

90
1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

2020

2000

2005

2010

2015

2020

B. Age–Sex–Education Controls

Index: 2018–19 = 100

102
101
100
99

98
1980

1985

1990

1995

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
Note: Both series include cohort controls. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

strong labor markets act through channels other than education and can
help workers catch up on the occupational ladder when prior recessions
have pushed them down.

The Benefits of Full Employment | 43

Figure 1-9. Median Real Wages, by Race and Ethnicity
2022 dollars

28
26
24
22
20
18
16
14
12

10
1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 2012 2015 2018 2021

Council of Economic Advisers

White

Black

Hispanic

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Economic Policy Institute’s State of Working America Data Library.
Note: White and Black populations are non-Hispanic. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Full Employment’s Effect on Wages and Household Incomes
The strong bargaining power afforded by tight labor markets raises not only
employment rates but also wages and incomes for less advantaged groups.
Figure 1-9 shows the median real wages of white non-Hispanic, Black
non-Hispanic, and Hispanic workers since 1973. In the figure, real wages
are stagnant over long stretches, aside from the periods of sustained growth
during the tight labor markets in the late 1990s, late 2010s, and the immediate period following the COVID-19 pandemic.11 Indeed, in the 23 years
from 1973 up to 1996, when the CBO estimates the labor market began the
prolonged period of full employment in the late 1990s, the unemployment
rate was only below the natural rate in about 27 percent of quarters; in those
years, white and Black median wages were roughly flat, whereas Hispanic
wages fell by about 10 percent. From 1996 through the end of the data in
2023, the unemployment rate was below the natural rate in 47 percent of
quarters, and wage growth performed better, rising 22, 23, and 29 percent at
the median for, respectively, white, Black, and Hispanic workers.

The composition of the workforce is known to have important implications for the dynamics of
wages, especially during business cycles when the lowest-paid workers typically lose jobs sooner
than more highly paid workers. This introduces an upward cyclical bias that can make the decline
in wages during recessions less pronounced than it otherwise might be (Solon, Barsky, and Parker
1994; Daly and Hobijn 2017). This composition effect had a large impact on the wage data shown in
figures 1-9 and 1-10, especially during the COVID recession, and is one reason why wages appeared
to rise sharply at the onset of that downturn (CEA 2021).
11

44 |

Chapter 1

Figure 1-10. Hourly Wage Compression, Pre- and Post-COVID
Index: 2015:Q1 = 100

123

120
117
114
111
108
105
102
99
96
93
2015:Q1

2016:Q1

2017:Q1

2018:Q1

2019:Q1

10th percentile

2020:Q1

2021:Q1

2022:Q1

2023:Q1

90th percentile

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
Note: Estimated using methodology from Autor, Dube, and McGrew (2023). Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Figure 1-10 also shows that real wages converged during the recent
tight labor markets, especially at the low end of the income distribution.
In figure 1-10, the CEA replicates the recent work of Autor, Dube, and
McGrew (2023), who estimate wage convergence in the periods before and
after COVID-19, adjusting for demographic differences due to age, labor
market experience, race and ethnicity, region, and nativity.12 Demographic
controls were especially important during the peak of the COVID-induced
recession due to the enormous shifts that occurred in the workforce.
Figure 1-10 shows the remarkable compression of wages in the labor
market both before and after the pandemic, which were both periods of full
employment. The 10th-percentile wage grew about 3 percentage points more
than that of the 90th percentile in the pre-COVID period, from 2015:Q1 to
2019:Q4; in the period after COVID, starting at the business cycle trough in
2020:Q2 and going through 2023:Q4, real wages grew by about 7 percentage points more at the bottom of the distribution than at the top. While there
are surely factors other than the strong labor market driving the post-COVID
wage compression—for example, the shift to remote work likely has held
down wage growth among higher-wage workers (Barrero et al. 2022)—the
Autor, Dube, and McGrew (2023) implement a Dinardo-Fortin-Lemieux (1996) reweighting
procedure, which allows for the comparison of wages at different points of the distribution under
the assumption that the distribution of individual characteristics is fixed at a base year—in this case,
immediately before the pandemic.
12

The Benefits of Full Employment | 45

Table 1-1. Wage Compression in the Pre- and Post-COVID Labor Markets

Percent change in ratio over period
Ratio
90th percentile / 10th percentile

2015:Q1–2019:Q4
–3

2020:Q2–2023:Q4
–8

50th percentile / 10th percentile

0

–5

–3

90th percentile / 50th percentile

–2

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
Note: This table shows the ratio of wages at the indicated percentiles. Estimated using methodology from Autor, Dube, and
McGrew (2023).
2024 Economic Report of the President

Table 1-2. Predicted Changes in Real Household Incomes over Selected
Business Cycles
1992–2000

2006–09

Expansion

Type of
Household

Percentile

-11

63

12

43

10th

7

41

-12

64

13

29

10th
25th

8
6

44
14

-13
-9

53
135

14
10

25th

Single mothers

Predicted
Percent of
Predicted
Percent of
Predicted
Percent of
Percent
Actual
Percent
Actual
Percent
Actual
Change in
Change in
Change in
Change in
Change in
Change in
Real Income Real Income Real Income Real Income Real Income Real Income
52

25th

Black

Expansion

7

10th

All

2009–19

Recession

4
6

27
14

-6

-10

47

146

7

11

28

45

-145
65

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Current Population Survey; Congressional Budget Office; CEA calculations.
Note: Estimated using methodology from Bernstein and Bentele (2019).
2024 Economic Report of the President

compression of wages occurred alongside the strongest stretch in the U.S.
labor market since the mid-1960s.
Table 1-1 records the changes in standard wage inequality ratios over
the two periods. The data reinforce the remarkable compression of wages,
especially between the top and bottom earners, as measured by the 90/10
wage ratio.
Following the methodology of Bernstein and Bentele (2019), figure
1-11 shows the effect on real annual earnings (equal to annual hours worked
times hourly wages) of a 1-point increase in the aggregate unemployment
rate relative to the CBO’s at five quantiles of the earnings distribution for
the overall population, Black households, and households headed by single
mothers.13 The relationship between labor market slack and incomes is
larger for low and middle earners than for high earners across all groups;
further, incomes respond more for low-income Black households, and those
headed by single mothers.
In particular, figure 1-11 plots the coefficients from group-specific regressions of the log real
annual earnings from the Annual Social and Economic Supplements to CPS data on the CBO
unemployment rate gap.
13

46 |

Chapter 1

Figure 1-11. Effects of a Looser Labor Market on Household Income
Change in annual earnings (percent)
0.0

–0.5
–1.0
–1.5
–2.0
–2.5

10th percentile

25th percentile
All households

Council of Economic Advisers

50th percentile
Black households

75th percentile

90th percentile

Single-mother households

Sources: Current Population Survey (CPS); Congressional Budget Office (CBO); CEA calculations.
Note: Estimated using methodology from Bernstein and Bentele (2019) with data from the 1977–2023 CPS Annual Social and
Economic Supplements. Each bar shows the expected change in household income associated with a 1-percentage-point
increase in the CBO's estimate of the unemployment rate gap.
2024 Economic Report of the President

The lighter blue bars in figure 1-11 show the coefficients for Black
households, which are larger in magnitude at each point of the distribution
than those of the overall population (navy bars); however, the biggest difference for Black households relative to the population is at the 25th percentile.
The same gradient is apparent among households headed by a single mother,
a group typically faced with lower wages and that is less attached to the
labor market than many other groups (Miller and Tedeschi 2019).
What do the coefficients mean in terms of real wage and income
growth? Table 1-2 shows, in the first column for each period, the predicted
percent change in real income based on the CEA’s simple model for various
groups during periods when the labor market tightened and slackened. The
second column of each period reports the predicted income change (from
the first column) as a share of the actual income changes experienced by
the relevant group. The results show that a large share of income gains and
losses are associated with aggregate labor market performance, reinforcing
the view that a strong economy is crucial to the well-being of economically
vulnerable groups.

Getting to and Staying at Full Employment
As the section above shows, the benefits of a persistently tight labor market,
especially for groups that are often left behind in periods of slack, are deep
and economically meaningful. But while recent U.S. economic history has
The Benefits of Full Employment | 47

Figure 1-12. The Congressional Budget Office’s Estimate of the
Unemployment Rate Gap
Percentage points

10
8
6
4

Above natural rate

2
0
–2
–4
1949

Below natural rate
1955

1961

1967

1973

1979

1985

1991

1997

2003

2009

2015

2021

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Congressional Budget Office; CEA calculations.
Note: Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

featured several periods at or near full employment, the longer sweep of
post–World War II history is less encouraging. Figure 1-12 shows the quarters when u > u* in dark blue and quarters when u < u* in light blue, using
the CBO’s measure of u*. The figure shows that over the first half of postwar history, from 1949 to 1981, the U.S. labor market spent 64 percent of
quarters with the unemployment rate below the natural rate; however, over
the second half of the period, starting in 1982, the United States achieved
full employment in 38 percent of quarters. Moreover, in the first half, when
the unemployment rate was below the CBO’s natural rate, the gap between
the unemployment rate and CBO’s natural rate averaged –1.2 percentage
points; in the second half, it averaged only –0.6 percentage point when it
was below the natural rate.
Aside from missing out on the benefits laid out in this chapter, another
cost of not being at full employment is what economists call hysteresis,
meaning lasting or structural damage to the economy’s supply side, which
lowers its potential growth rate (Yellen 2016). The economy’s growth rate
is broadly a function of the growth in the workforce’s size and the growth in
the productivity of this workforce (CEA 2023b). If, for example, potential
workers stay out of the workforce due to weak labor demand, they risk
sacrificing the productivity-enhancing experience and skills associated with
steady workforce attachment. One influential analysis by Reifschneider,
Wascher, and Wilcox (2013) frames the problem as the “endogeneity of
supply with respect to demand,” meaning that labor supply is influenced by
labor demand. One channel through which this operates is when weak labor
48 |

Chapter 1

demand reduces potential labor supply if workers who experience longterm unemployment spells lose skills and, therefore, become persistently
less employable. Another channel through which this operates is that less
employment requires less capital investment, which can, in turn, reduce the
supply of productive capital in the economy.
In the context of this chapter, the implication is that extended periods
of unemployment exceeding u* can generate persistently damaging hysteresis. While there is not much evidence for the notion that extended periods
of tight labor markets can lead to reverse hysteresis (i.e., improvements in
the economy’s potential growth rate), the dynamic is certainly plausible
(Yellen 2016). If, as this chapter has shown, full employment pulls workers
into the labor market who might otherwise be left behind, the positive effects
of reverse hysteresis might be realized. Full employment could also have
positive effects on other supply-side fundamentals, such as productivity.
The benefits of full employment raise the question of which policy
choices help lead to it and what trade-offs the choices involve. The inflation/unemployment trade-off embedded in the Phillips curve framework has
long dominated the policy discussion and, as Baker and Bernstein (2013)
show, was one reason for the long periods of slack shown in figure 1-12. In
recent years, however, more economists have recognized the measurement
challenges in u* (see the uncertainty embedded in figure 1-1), leading policymakers, including those with the Federal Reserve, to become more “data
driven” and rely less over time on point estimates of u* (Staiger, Stock, and
Watson 1997; Powell 2018).
More specifically, a data-driven argument surfaced that, because
analysts could not identify u* reliably enough to steer fiscal and monetary
policy, and the price Phillips curve was viewed as relatively flat, economic
policymakers could allow labor markets to tighten with a low risk of substantial inflationary consequences (Powell 2018). Findings like those shown
above regarding the equalizing benefits of tight labor markets, including
pulling in new workers from the sidelines (which also dampens inflationary
pressures), further strengthened the argument (Bernstein and Bentele 2019;
Cajner, Coglianese, and Montes 2021).
The full employment experiences of the late 1990s and the period
before the pandemic showed the logic of the position through data on critical
variables, such as jobs, the LFPR, wages, racial gaps in the labor market,
and more. During those periods, both unemployment and inflation remained
relatively low, representing a favorable trade-off on behalf of economically
vulnerable groups without salient inflationary risks. And indeed, as figure
1-2 shows, during the tight labor market before the pandemic, estimates
of the natural rate continued to be revised down over time, rewarding the
Federal Reserve’s data-dependent approach.

The Benefits of Full Employment | 49

Table 1-3. Inflation and Labor Market Outcomes Since Total PCE Peak
Total PCE, yearly

June 2022
(percent)
7.1

December 2023
(percent)
2.6

Change
(percentage points)
–4.5

Core PCE, yearly

5.2

2.9

–2.3

Outcome
Total PCE, three-month annualized
Core PCE, three-month annualized
Unemployment rate

Black unemployment rate
LFPR

Black LFPR

Nonfarm payrollsa

7.4
5.1
3.6

5.8

62.2

62.2

152,348

0.5
1.5
3.7

–6.9
–3.6
0.1

5.2

–0.6

63.4

1.2

62.5

157,347

0.3
3.3

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
Note: PCE = Personal Consumption Expenditures Price Index; LFPR = labor force participation rate. Unemployment rates and LFPRs
are adjusted for the 2023 population control revisions.

a Nonfarm payrolls are in thousands and nonfarm payroll change is in percent.
2024 Economic Report of the President

The past several years have challenged this pattern. When the pandemic began and the economy shut down, the unemployment rate soared
to almost 15 percent and inflation turned negative. Then, as the economy
reopened, lifted by historically strong fiscal and monetary support, unemployment fell sharply while inflation rose to a 40-year high in the summer
of 2022. Such movements are associated with a steep price Phillips curve,
rather than a flat one. As stated previously in this chapter, the period raises
two questions: (1) Has u* increased structurally, so that the pursuit of maintaining tight labor markets engenders greater overheating and inflationary
risks than in prior cycles? Or (2) is pandemic economics a special case, and
thus, outside its unusual effects, can the U.S. labor market still flourish with
low unemployment not necessarily accompanied by high inflation?
The CEA pursued the same question in the 2023 Economic Report
of the President, wherein, based on the evidence available, the researchers concluded that “the combination and interaction of numerous factors
exacerbated the elevated inflation. Although it is difficult to determine the
relative importance of each factor, the pandemic, and responses to it, had
substantial effects on both the supply and demand sides of the economy.
Specific factors of note include pandemic-induced supply disruptions, shifts
in consumer demand, the accumulation of excess savings, and stimulative
fiscal and monetary support throughout 2020 and 2021” (CEA 2023b, 52).
Given the developments over the year since the previous assessment,
the CEA has found more evidence that supply factors played a key role
in both inflation’s rise and its subsequent decline. Consider that if full
employment were the main cause of the increase in inflation, the subsequent
disinflation the economy has experienced should have brought about a substantial slackening of the labor market. However, the low magnitude of the
50 |

Chapter 1

Figure 1-13. Core PCE Price Inflation and Unemployment Rate Gap
Percent (core PCE), percentage points (unemployment rate gap)

10

8
6
4
2
0
–2
1985:Q1 1989:Q1 1993:Q1 1997:Q1 2001:Q1 2005:Q1 2009:Q1 2013:Q1 2017:Q1 2021:Q1
Core PCE inflation, year-over-year

Council of Economic Advisers

Unemployment rate gap

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Bureau of Economic Analysis; Congressional Budget Office (CBO); CEA calculations.
Note: PCE = Personal Consumption Expenditures. Core PCE inflation is year-over-year percentage change. The
unemployment rate gap indicates the gap between the unemployment rate and the CBO's estimate of the natural rate
of unemployment. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

so-called sacrifice ratio—the amount of increased unemployment or reduced
economic activity required to lower inflation—during the recent disinflation
since the peak in June 2022 suggests otherwise. Table 1-3 shows the decline
in personal consumption expenditures inflation—total and core, which
excludes volatile food and energy prices—along with the changes in various labor market variables (also see figure 1-13). Over the period covered,
which includes the most recent data available at publication time, the disinflation has required little sacrifice in terms of labor market slack or job loss.
This phenomenon is mirrored in the evolution of job openings and
unemployment, which have been analyzed via the Beveridge curve, as
shown in figure 1-14, with the job openings rate on the y axis and the
unemployment rate on the x axis. The Beveridge curve has become a common tool for analyzing shifts in the unemployment rate, allowing analysts
to parse changes in unemployment vis-à-vis job openings to determine if
changes in unemployment are more of a structural or cyclical nature (Daly
et al. 2011; Elsby, Michaels, and Ratner 2015; Barlevy et al. 2023). An
outward shift in the curve (i.e., a rise in unemployment for a given level of
job openings) indicates a likely deterioration in the ability of workers to find
available jobs, one of the factors economists use to infer u*.
Figure 1-14 shows three distinct periods, the first after the global
financial crisis up to the COVID-19 pandemic, the second in the pandemicinduced recession and recovery through June 2022 (the peak of personal

The Benefits of Full Employment | 51

Figure 1-14. The Beveridge Curve, Pre- and Post-COVID
Job openings rate (percent)

8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1

3

5

7

July 2009–February 2020

9

11

Unemployment rate (percent)
March 2020–June 2022

13

15

17

July 2022–December 2023

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; CEA calculations.
2024 Economic Report of the President

consumption expenditures inflation), and the third from July 2022 to
December 2023, coinciding with the start of the period of disinflation covered in table 1-3. Since June 2022, the job opening rate has fallen sharply, by
over 20 percent, while the unemployment rate has only edged up; this is in
sharp contrast to the typically close negative relationship between vacancies
and unemployment (Elsby, Michaels, and Ratner 2015; Figura and Waller
2022; Blanchard, Domash, and Summers 2022).
One interpretation of the recent decline in vacancies without a commensurate increase in unemployment is an improvement in what the economics
literature describes as the efficiency of the matching process between workers and available jobs, or “matching efficiency.” This interpretation would
imply a period of deteriorated matching efficiency—the blue locus of points
during the recovery from COVID through June 2022—potentially resulting from a rise in labor market churn, including a large increase in worker
quits, caused by disruptions resulting from COVID (Barlevy et al. 2023).
Thus, one possibility is that the recent improvement in matching efficiency,
which reduced job openings for a roughly constant unemployment rate,
may reflect post-COVID renormalization. Another potential explanation,
one put forth by Figura and Waller (2022), is that, in theory, the Beveridge
curve ought to be especially steep at high openings and low unemployment
rates. The reason is that as the number of vacancies rises relative to the
number unemployed—that is, moving to the upper left of the Beveridge
curve diagram—it becomes increasingly hard to fill open jobs; thus, firms
52 |

Chapter 1

Figure 1-15. Phillips Curve, Pre- and Post-COVID, MSA-Level Data
Year-over-year change in core CPI (percent)
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4

0

2

4

Council of Economic Advisers

6

8

Unemployment rate (percent)
2002–19

10

12

14

2020–23

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; CEA calculations.
Note: MSA = Metropolitan Statistical Area. CPI = Consumer Price Index. Core CPI includes all items less food and energy. Data
are semiannual and not seasonally adjusted. Fitted lines are predictions from log-log specification regressions. The lighter blue
fitted line is estimated over the pre-COVID period, and the dark navy line is estimated starting in 2020.
2024 Economic Report of the President

must post increasingly more vacancies to fill each open position, thereby
reducing unemployment only a small amount for all the additional vacancies. Consequently, Figura’s and Waller’s view was that the job openings
rate could fall without a large increase in job losses or unemployment as the
economy slid down a steep Beveridge curve.
Ultimately, the underlying reasons why job openings have come down
substantially with little sacrifice in terms of higher unemployment may not
be known for many years. This limits analysts’ ability to answer the crucial
question: Will matching efficiency continue to improve, or has the labor
market reached a flatter portion of the Beveridge curve and will any further
reduction in openings require an increase in unemployment? In other words,
it remains to be seen whether the labor market can benefit from further
normalization, putting reduced pressure on wages and prices, without a
substantial deterioration of job and income prospects for Americans.
While these economic conditions have supported low-sacrifice-ratio
dynamics thus far, the current inflationary episode is not over. The key question for staying at full employment then becomes: Can inflation continue
to decline without a large rise in unemployment? Figure 1-15 offers some
perspective, showing the price Phillips curve both before COVID and since
the pandemic, with year-over-year core Consumer Price Index inflation on
the y axis and the unemployment rate on the x axis for an available set of

The Benefits of Full Employment | 53

21 metropolitan statistical areas (or, roughly speaking, major cities).14 The
Phillips curve steepened considerably during the COVID era, as can be seen
by comparing the light blue pre-COVID line with the dark blue line. (See
also Barlevy et al. 2023.) The recent disinflation with little unemployment
sacrifice has likely been due in part to a movement back down the steeper
Phillips curve.
Because the normalization of inflation is a work in progress, analysts
cannot, at this time, conclude which sacrifice ratio the American economy
will ultimately face, though the evidence thus far supports a relatively low
one. Either way, the fact remains that, based on the benefits of full employment labor markets and costs of slack, especially to economically vulnerable groups, fiscal and monetary policymakers should use expansionary
macroeconomic policy to achieve and stay at full employment in periods of
slack, while maintaining a data-driven view in terms of reacting to inflationary pressures. Regarding fiscal policy, an appropriately timed and targeted
fiscal stimulus is a crucial pillar of economic policy to close the output
gap in periods of recession or in response to negative shocks to growth.
As demonstrated here, the other pillar is data-driven monetary policy that
takes into account both the numerous benefits attending a tight labor market
and the uncertainty surrounding u* in the context of fulfilling the Federal
Reserve’s dual mandate of full employment and stable prices. However,
while macroeconomic stabilization policy can help achieve full employment
for some groups, other groups will undoubtedly be left behind where these
policy remedies are ill suited to address structural disadvantages. Box 1-4
considers potential policy levers.

Conclusion
Analysts of the United States economy have learned many critical macroeconomic lessons in recent decades. One such lesson is that the difficulty
of estimating the lowest unemployment rate consistent with stable inflation makes it challenging for policymakers to bring about periods of full
employment. These lessons have, however, reinforced the importance of
policymakers following a data-driven approach to evaluating the supply
and demand forces that shape the tightness of the labor market. Further,
while analysts cannot reliably identify u*, the evidence does suggest that
(1) unemployment below 4 percent helps facilitate the many benefits of
full employment, and (2) outside large supply/demand shocks of the type
that occurred during the COVID-19 pandemic, low unemployment can be
consistent with low and stable inflation.
McLeay and Tenreyro (2019) and Hazell et al. (2022) show that regional variation in inflation and
unemployment can identify dynamics that national data fail to pick up.
14

54 |

Chapter 1

Box 1-4. Policies Targeting Structural
Labor Market Slack
This chapter focuses largely on cyclical labor market slack and urges the
use of fiscal and monetary policies to attain and maintain full employment in the labor market. But disaggregated labor market data focusing
on economically vulnerable populations reveal that many people suffer
not just from cyclical unemployment but also from structural unemployment. A simple way to understand this distinction is to note that
for workers facing structural barriers, even at full employment, their
unemployment rate will be elevated.
As the CEA’s analysis has shown, full employment helps less
advantaged groups in both absolute terms (e.g., reduced unemployment
and elevated real earnings) and relative terms (stronger gains compared
with others). However, other policies are needed to help some workers
overcome structural barriers that are somewhat invariant to labor market
cycles.
Affordable childcare. While the tight labor market in the current
cycle has facilitated historic workforce gains by women, including those
with children, the absence of affordable childcare is a structural barrier
that suppresses the ability of those with childcare responsibilities to fully
participate in strong labor markets. The link between affordable childcare, which is demonstrably underprovided in America (U.S. Department
of the Treasury 2021), and employment has been well researched; this
work is summarized in chapter 4 of the 2023 Economic Report of the
President (CEA 2023b, 132). This literature review finds the availability
of affordable care has “large, positive effects on maternal employment. .
. . Several studies of programs in other countries—specifically Canada,
Germany, and Norway—also confirm the responsiveness of mothers’
employment to [childcare] expansions.” Mothers most affected by the
enhanced availability of care tend to be “relatively disadvantaged (i.e.,
single mothers and those with lower levels of education).” Finally,
the research finds that “policies that expand access to [care] can boost
[working mothers’] productivity in the workplace by allowing them to
get additional education or job training and increasing the likelihood
they will work full time.” The Biden-Harris Administration’s commitment to affordable childcare takes seriously the distributional and
macroeconomic consequences of affordable childcare. A recent CEA
analysis shows that the American Rescue Plan’s historic investment in
the childcare industry succeeded in slowing cost growth for families,
stabilizing employment and increasing wages for childcare workers, and
increasing maternal labor force participation (CEA 2023c).
Antidiscrimination. As discussed in the text of this chapter, full
employment makes it more expensive for employers to racially discriminate; but history has clearly shown that tight labor markets are far from

The Benefits of Full Employment | 55

sufficient in preventing discrimination (Kline, Rose, and Walters 2022).
For example, even in periods when the overall unemployment rate is
below 4 percent, the unemployment rate for Black workers averaged 6.1
percent. Some argue that because highly educated groups have lower
unemployment, the differential is due to Black workers’ lower levels of
education, on average. But figure 1-3 shows that even after controlling
for education, Black workers face higher unemployment rates than white
workers.
The research evidence shows that at certain periods in U.S. history,
antidiscrimination policies have helped to partially overcome structural
barriers. In the 1960s, legislation was passed targeting gender and racial
labor market discrimination. Various studies show that these new laws
first exposed and then helped ameliorate extensive workplace discrimination, which partially blocked the cyclical benefits of full employment
for discriminated groups (Tomaskovic-Devey et al. 2006; Kurtulus
2016; Sanchez Cumming 2021). (The Equal Pay Act of 1963 prohibited
unequal pay based on gender for equal work, and the 1964 Civil Rights
Act—Title VII—prohibited workplace discrimination by race, gender,
and other protected classes, and the Age Discrimination in Employment
Act of 1967 prohibited employment discrimination against older workers. Notably, enforcement mechanisms were initially limited—e.g.,
employers accused of discriminatory practices could be investigated but
not sued; Sanchez Cumming 2021. Later, in 1990, the Americans with
Disabilities Act was passed, which extended the protections of Civil
Rights Act of 1964 to those with disabilities.)
It is, however, well documented that the track record of the
programs implementing these policies is uneven, and evidence shows
that their effectiveness waned beginning in the 1980s, in part due to a
lack of funding and commitment to their cause by government sponsors
and agencies. Sanchez Cumming (2021, 7) points out that the Reagan
Administration actively tried to repeal an Executive Order enforcing
equity in workplace practices by government contractors. Though the
administration failed in the repeal effort, Sanchez Cumming writes that
“there was a decline in the number of sanctions issued for noncompliance, fewer firms were required to adopt affirmative action plans, and
compliance reviews rarely found that women workers or workers of
color were unfairly underrepresented in contractors’ workforces.” Even
as antidiscrimination laws and U.S. institutions advocating for labor
market equity led to important progress toward fairer and more equitable
labor market outcomes, employment discrimination today continues to
be a pervasive feature of the U.S. economy. Insufficient funding and vulnerability to political whims often prevent a robust enforcement effort
from further ameliorating discrimination in the labor market. Indeed, the
relative lack of progress has led some racial justice advocates to call for

56 |

Chapter 1

more ambitious and direct programs to counter the effects of structural,
systemic racism, most notably guaranteed jobs programs. Paul, Darity,
and Hamilton (2018, 5), for example, argue on behalf of a “federal
job guarantee [that] would provide a job, at non-poverty wages, for all
citizens above the age of 18 that sought one.”
Affordable housing in robust economic areas. Chapter 4 of this
Report documents the lack of affordable housing in America, which, in
the context of full employment, serves to amplify the spatial mismatch
between where low-income households can afford to live and places
with robust labor demand. As an Urban Institute (2019) analysis puts
it, “This spatial mismatch between regional employment clusters and
potential worker populations limits access to jobs.” Important research
by Ganong and Shoag (2017) documents how the problem has worsened
over time as affordable housing in places with strong labor demand has
become increasingly scarce. Their work documents a sharp decline in
“income convergence” across places and ties it both to housing costs
and, as emphasized in chapter 4 of this Report, restrictions on land use.
Other structural barriers. While childcare, housing, and discrimination are among the most salient structural barriers to full employment,
other frictions also exist. Increased industrial concentration, whereby
powerful firms dominate single industries, can suppress job creation
and quality through anticompetitive effects, thereby reducing structural
demand even during strong cycles. Because unemployment and education levels are negatively correlated, individuals without access to higher
education face structural barriers to labor market opportunities. There
are also structural disincentives to elevated labor supply in the tax code,
including the “marriage tax penalty” (i.e., filing jointly means incurring
a larger tax bill than filing separately) and the phasing out of schedules
for government benefits that raise the marginal tax rate of an extra hour
of work.
Finally, two recent developments are worth noting. First, the
significant rise in working from home has the potential to reduce a
structural barrier to work for caretakers and others (e.g., those with long
commutes). Some recent evidence from Hansen and others (2023) suggests that more than 10 percent of jobs may allow for the option, though
it is too soon to tell whether the trend will persist.
Second, an important recent analysis by Hobijn and Șahin (2021)
of labor market flow data finds that it can take longer to return to full
employment after a labor market shock when the shock causes people to
leave the labor force. That is, the research finds that when workers leave
the labor force, it can lengthen the amount of time it takes to return to
full capacity in the labor market. This finding argues for policies, such as
those more common in European economies, that keep people connected
to work during a downturn, versus the emphasis in the United States on

The Benefits of Full Employment | 57

unemployment insurance for those separated from work due to layoffs.
In fact, the United States has a policy known as short-time compensation
(informally called “work sharing”), administered by the unemployment
insurance system, which can be used to help keep people at work during
periods of weak demand by reducing their hours and using the system’s
funds to partially make up the lost earnings. Of course, it is possible
that an economic shock could lead to structural changes such that a
fulsome recovery would be facilitated by workers moving to different
jobs in different sectors, so each downturn could require its own analysis
regarding the policy choice to encourage work sharing. To the extent that
work sharing can lessen the time it takes the job market to return to full
employment, its use is consistent with reaping the benefits documented
in this chapter.

In addition, the CEA’s research finds that tight labor markets provide
benefits across a large swath of the population. Groups with higher average unemployment rates see larger declines in unemployment during full
employment labor markets than groups with relatively low unemployment
rates. Groups with less attachment to the labor force on average also see
a relatively larger increase in participation rates when the unemployment
rate falls. Relatedly, racial gaps in labor market outcomes narrow in tight
labor markets. In the most recent period of full employment just before
COVID-19 and in the last year, the gaps between Black and white men in
unemployment and employment have fallen to the lowest rates on record.
Economically vulnerable groups—for example, the comparatively less
educated—are more able to switch jobs when the unemployment rate is
low and climb the job ladder when jobs are plentiful. Workers who face a
work-limiting disability are also brought in from the sidelines and obtain
jobs more often in particularly strong labor markets. As this chapter has
shown, these labor market benefits translate into higher wages and income,
particularly for workers who are more likely to be left behind in slack labor
markets.
While wages and earnings tend to be flat in periods of weak or stagnant
labor markets, they grow when the economy experiences a tight period, as
in the late 1990s, late 2010s, and after the COVD-19 pandemic. There is
also a wage convergence across groups and percentiles, just as there is in
unemployment and employment rates. Indeed, there has been a remarkable
decline in wage inequality since 2015, a time that has featured two periods
of full employment.

58 |

Chapter 1

Given the importance of full employment for racial equity, inequality,
workers’ empowerment, and the Biden-Harris Administration’s fundamental
goal of ensuring that workers have the bargaining power they need to claim
their fair share of the growing economy, it is clear that maintaining tight
labor markets must be an integral policy goal of American administrations.
Many economists have recognized that labor markets do not necessarily
settle into full employment and have reevaluated the importance of policies
that actively promote full employment conditions. And every time this has
occurred, the benefits of full employment have blossomed. Economists and
policymakers must therefore use the policy tools at their disposal to get to
and stay at full employment.

The Benefits of Full Employment | 59

60 | 

Chapter 2

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead
At the start of 2023, many macroeconomic forecasters expected the United
States’ economy to dip into a recession later that year (figure 2-1). They
also predicted that 2023 would be characterized by an anemic growth rate.
The economy was instead surprisingly resilient, as measured by indicators
including real gross domestic product (GDP), the unemployment rate, real
personal consumption expenditures, real disposable personal income, and
real private nonresidential investment (figure 2-2). This resilience was
especially notable for coinciding with slowing inflation.
Trends—including fiscal drag, rising interest rates, and mounting geopolitical risks—had been perceived as major economic headwinds, informing
these pessimistic forecasts. Additional fundamentals—such as a low saving rate and lackluster consumer sentiment—risked exacerbating reduced
Figure 2-1. Recession Probability Indicators, 2008–23
Percent probability or index: June 2022 = 100

100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10

0
Apr-2008

Dec-2009

Aug-2011

Apr-2013

Dec-2014

Aug-2016

Google Trends "Recession" search index
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia anxiety index

Apr-2018

Dec-2019

Aug-2021

Apr-2023

Wall Street Journal recession probability
Bloomberg recession probability

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia; Wall Street Journal; Google; Bloomberg; CEA calculations.
Note: Gray bars indicate recessions. Google Trends data are indexed relative to their peak month, June 2022, and are data from January 1,
2004, to December 31, 2023, downloaded on January 11, 2024. Data from the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia indicate Q2 of the
given year. Anxiety index represents the probability of a decline in real GDP for the subsequent quarter.
2024 Economic Report of the President

61

Figure 2-2. Selected U.S. Economic Measures, 2019–23
A. Real GDP

B. Unemployment Rate

23,000

14

22,000

12

Billions of 2017 dollars

Percent

10
9
8

10

21,000

7
6

8

20,000

5

6

19,000

4
3

4

18,000

2

17,000

0

2019

2020 2021 2022 2023
Blue Chip, Jan. 2023
Administration, Nov. 2022
Real GDP

D. Real Personal Consumption
cccExpenditures
Billions of 2017 dollars

C. Consumer Price Index

Four-quarter percent change

2
1
2019

2020
2021
2022
2023
Blue Chip, Jan. 2023
Administration, Nov. 2022
Unemployment Rate

E. Real Disposable Personal Income
Billions of 2017 dollars

0

2019

F. Real Private Nonresidential Fixed
ccInvestment

Billions of 2017 dollars

16,000

19,000

3,400

15,500

18,500

3,300

18,000

3,200

15,000

17,500

14,500

16,500

13,500

16,000

3,000
2,900
2,800

15,500

13,000

2,700

15,000

12,500
12,000

3,100

17,000

14,000

2,600

14,500
2019

2020

2021 2022 2023
Blue Chip, Jan. 2023
Real PCE

Council of Economic Advisers

14,000
2019

2020
2021
2022
2023
Blue Chip, Jan. 2023
Administration, Nov. 2022
CPI

2020

2021 2022 2023
Blue Chip, Jan. 2023
Personal income

2,500
2019

2020

2021
2022
2023
Blue Chip, Jan. 2023
Investment

Sources: Blue Chip Economic Indicators; Bureau of Economic Analysis; Bureau of Labor Statistics; CEA calculations.
Note: CPI = Consumer Price Index. All values are seasonally adjusted. Years indicate Q1 of the corresponding year. Administration forecast was finalized in
November 2022 but published in the 2023 Economic Report of the President and the Fiscal Year 2024 Budget. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

aggregate demand, rising unemployment, and cutbacks in consumer
spending.1 Meanwhile, the spring 2023 banking crisis raised concerns about
diminished credit availability and, in tandem with rising interest rates and
fading fiscal support, reinforced worries of a coming recession—the socalled hard-landing scenario. A yield curve inversion in late 2022 and early

A saving rate below the desired long-run rate may force consumers to curb spending if incomes do
not rise. The effects of net worth—otherwise neglected in this argument—are reviewed in box 2-1
later in this chapter.

1

62 |

Chapter 2

2023 was consistent with these forecasts, signaling that financial markets
may have also been anticipating a recession.2
The U.S. economy not only defied these 2023 forecasts but it even progressed
at a significant pace.3 In retrospect, the economy’s marked slowdown in
2022 appears to have reflected temporary supply constraints after the strong
rebound in 2021, rather than an impending recession. The level of real GDP
in 2023 even exceeded some forecasts from before the COVID-19 pandemic—including those of the Congressional Budget Office (CBO)—and
was boosted in part by strong continued consumer spending and a revival in
manufacturing structures investment (CBO n.d.). State and local purchases
also grew at a robust pace of 4.5 percent in 2023.4 Meanwhile, sound household balance sheets in recent years and a strong labor market have allowed
U.S. consumers to increase their spending at a pace closely resembling the
average pace in prior expansions.5 In 2023, the unemployment rate edged up
slightly from near-record lows, but remained below 4 percent for the entire
year. Labor force participation rates also increased from 2022 to 2023, both
in the aggregate and for men, women, and across most age and racial groups.
Meanwhile, progress in lowering inflation was substantial. From 2022
to 2023, headline Consumer Price Index (CPI) inflation decreased by 2
percentage points and core CPI inflation, which excludes the more volatile
categories of energy and food, decreased by 3 percentage points. Declining
inflation during a period of accelerating real activity reinforces the hypothesis that the resolution of supply issues—both supply chains and labor
supply—has played an important role in reshaping the economy away from
the perceived trends that influenced 2023 forecasts. These developments in

The yield curve is said to be “inverted” when shorter-term interest rates (e.g., the federal funds
rate) exceed longer-term rates (e.g., the 10-year Treasury rate). While these inversions are infrequent,
they often precede recessions.
3
See table 2-1 later in this chapter.
4
Unless otherwise stated, the yearly growth rate is calculated on a Q4/Q4 basis.
5
See box 2-1 later in this chapter.
2

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 63

2023—a resilient labor market and strong activity coupled with declining
inflation—are consistent with a “soft landing” scenario.
But challenges remain. Elevated real interest rates compared with earlier
during the pandemic—against the backdrop of a labor market that appears
to have rebalanced—could reduce investment in rate-sensitive sectors. In
addition, the impact of geopolitical conflicts on markets and supply chains
remains uncertain. To the extent that consumer attitudes respond to price
levels rather than, or in addition to, inflation, consumer sentiment could
remain weaker than economic data would predict, since prices are unlikely
to broadly decline outright. However, recent real wage gains could potentially help support both confidence and consumer spending.
This chapter begins with a review of the economy in 2023. It first examines
the acceleration in real GDP and its sources, and then surveys major labor
market developments, highlighting their consistency with the “soft landing”
scenario. Next, the chapter describes recent progress in disinflation. It then
describes developments in financial markets, exploring both potential upside
and downside risks. Finally, the chapter reviews the forecast underpinning
the President’s Fiscal Year 2025 Budget and summarizes the near-term and
long-term outlooks.

The Year in Review: The Continuing Recovery
This section describes the continued postpandemic recovery in 2023 and the
easing of supply chain bottlenecks, explores the state of demand and supply
rebalancing in the labor market, and provides updates on the progress of
disinflation over the past year.

Output in 2023: A Return to Normal Growth
Real GDP accelerated to a pace of 3.1 percent over the four quarters of 2023,
somewhat above the average growth of about 2.4 percent in the expansion
period before the COVID-19 pandemic, and higher than the anemic 0.7
percent pace in 2022:Q4. Table 2-1 disaggregates real GDP growth into its
major components.

64 |

Chapter 2

Table 2-1. Real GDP Growth and Its Components, 2023:Q4

Component

Q4/Q4 Growth
(percent)

Contribution to
Q4/Q4 GDP Growth
(percentage points)

Contribution to Q4/Q4
GDP Growth, Average
from 2010 to 2019
(percentage points)

(1)

(2)

(3)

Total

3.1

3.1

2.4

Consumer spending

2.6

1.8

1.6

6.1

0.5

0.4

Goods

Durables

Motor vehicles and parts

Nondurables

Services

Investment
Business fixed investment

Nonresidential investment
Structures

Equipment

Intellectual property

Residential investment

3.5

4.1

2.2

0.8

0.1
0.3

0.8

0.1
0.3

2.2

1.0

0.8

1.8
3.1

0.3
0.5

0.9
0.9

14.8

0.4

0.1

4.1

0.6

0.7

–0.1

0.0

0.4

–0.1

0.0

0.1

2.6

0.1

0.3

-

– 0.2

-

0.3

–0.1

Imports

–0.2

0.0

Government

4.3

0.7

0.4
– 0.6

Defense

3.3

0.1

Change in private inventories

Net exports
Exports

Federal

Nondefense

State and local

2.1

4.0
4.7

4.5

0.2

0.3
0.1

0.5

0.1

0.0
0.0
0.0
0.0
0.0

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
Note: GDP = gross domestic product. Column 2 lists the contribution of each component to the annual rate of growth of real
GDP. These may not precisely sum to totals because of approximations to the formulas used in the National Income and Product
Accounts. Column 3 lists the average GDP growth and contribution for the time period listed.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Consumer spending. Resilience in consumer spending (personal
consumption expenditures, or PCE) largely accounts for the increase in
real GDP growth over the past year. Spending growth increased across all
major subcategories of consumption. Goods PCE, which has run ahead of its
prepandemic trend since the third quarter of 2020, grew 3.5 percent in 2023
after declining in 2022. And while both durable and nondurable consumption grew, the former (including notable growth in motor vehicles) is responsible for the lion’s share of the growth in goods consumption. Real services
PCE also grew in 2023, at a rate similar to its growth in 2022. Figure 2-3
illustrates how the shares of services and goods consumption as a portion

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 65

Figure 2-3. Goods᾿ and Services᾿ Shares of Personal Consumption
Services as a share of nominal consumption

Goods as a share of nominal consumption

70

37

69

36

68

35

67

34

66

33

65

32

64

31

63

30

62
Jan-2019

Aug-2019

Mar-2020

Council of Economic Advisers

Oct-2020

May-2021

Services share (left axis)

Dec-2021

Jul-2022

Feb-2023

Sep-2023

Goods share (right axis)

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
Note: Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Figure 2-4. Share of U.S. Employees Working from Home
Percent

70
60
50
40
30
20
10

0
Jan-2018 Sep-2018 May-2019 Jan-2020 Sep-2020 May-2021 Jan-2022 Sep-2022 May-2023

Council of Economic Advisers

Source: Barrero, Bloom, and Davis (2023).
Note: Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President.

of total consumption have been sluggishly reverting to their prepandemic
trends. Future years’ data will indicate whether a structural, long-lasting
shift in consumer preferences is under way.
One factor that may help explain such a pattern is the sustained
increase in remote work since 2020 (figure 2-4). People working from home

66 |

Chapter 2

29

Figure 2-5. Real Private Fixed Investment in Manufacturing Structures, 1959–2023
Contribution to year-on-year real GDP growth (percentage points)
0.4

2023:Q4 contribution

Passage of IRA
and CHIPS

0.3
0.2
0.1
0.0
-0.1
-0.2
-0.3
1959 1963 1967 1971 1975 1979 1983 1987 1991 1995 1999 2003 2007 2011 2015 2019 2023

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
Note: IRA = Inflation Reduction Act; CHIPS = Creating Helpful Incentives to Produce Semiconductors—or the CHIPS and Science Act.
Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

may tend to spend more on goods (e.g., groceries and home improvement)
than on services (including restaurants and transportation).
Investment. Real private fixed investment increased 3.1 percent during
the four quarters of 2023, a growth rate slower than the norm for the period
before the COVID-19 pandemic. Residential investment continued to be a
drag on GDP, as high mortgage rates and the short supply of single-family
homes weighed on the housing market (see chapter 4 of this Report).
In contrast, investment in nonresidential structures boomed last year,
increasing 14.8 percent, the fastest clip seen since 2014. A combination
of factors likely drove this outcome. First, the shift to goods consumption
during the pandemic caused businesses to both rethink their supply chains
and consider expanding domestic production capacity. Meanwhile, the
Inflation Reduction Act (IRA) and the CHIPS and Science Act have strongly
incentivized domestic investment in clean energy manufacturing (White
House 2022, n.d.). Figure 2-5 demonstrates that the surge in nonresidential
investment is concentrated in manufacturing structures; manufacturing
structures’ contribution to GDP growth last year neared the highest level on
record. Investment in other nonresidential structures, especially in offices
and commercial structures (figure 2-6), has yet to recover to norms from
before the pandemic, and changes to working arrangements may yet prove
long-lasting, rebalancing the market more permanently (see figure 2-4).
And while investment in equipment and intellectual property decelerated in

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 67

Figure 2-6. Real Private Investment: Structures

Passage of
IRA and CHIPS

Year-on-year percent change

75
50
25

0
-25
-50
1995

1998

2001

2004

2007

Manufacturing structures

Council of Economic Advisers

2010

2013

2016

2019

2022

Commercial and health care structures

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.
Note: IRA = Inflation Reduction Act; CHIPS = Creating Helpful Incentives to Produce Semiconductors—or the CHIPS and
Science Act. All values are chained. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

2023, this slowdown may be attributable to firms redirecting their resources
toward manufacturing structures. Investment in equipment and intangibles
is likely to pick up over subsequent years, as newly built manufacturing
facilities require the installation of new equipment.
Finally, inventory investment continued to suppress GDP growth in
2023. In the pandemic’s immediate aftermath, inventory investment’s contribution to GDP growth climbed to highs not seen since the Korean War, as
firms scrambled to adapt to the shift of consumption from services to goods.
However, some sectors suffered from a bullwhip effect as consumption patterns rebalanced toward services in 2022. With inventory-sales ratios above
desired levels, pressures mounted to bring business inventories back in line
with demand. This phenomenon has been particularly acute in the merchant
wholesale trade sector, in which the inventory-sales ratio currently sits at
1.43 months’ supply, a historically high figure that is well above the 2019
average of 1.37 (figure 2-7). The rebalancing of inventories with sales still
appeared to be in progress last year.
Imports and exports. As the world economy abruptly closed in 2020,
the pandemic-induced recession injected turbulence into the contribution
of net exports to real GDP growth. However, large swings in this category
appear to be behind us, similar to the normalization of inventory investment.
In 2023, net exports contributed 0.3 percentage point to GDP growth on a
four-quarter basis; the large positive contributions in the first and last quarters were only partially offset by contributions moving closer to the normal
prepandemic rate of expansion in the middle of the year (see chapter 5).
68 |

Chapter 2

Figure 2-7. Ratio of Real Inventories to Sales: Merchant Wholesale
Trade, 2013–23
Monthsʼ supply

1.6

1.5

1.4

2019 average

1.3

1.2
2013

2014

2015

2016

Council of Economic Advisers

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
Note: Data are seasonally adjusted. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Government spending. The Federal Government’s real purchases in
2023 (expenditures and gross investment) contributed a quarter percentage
point more to GDP growth than they had in 2022. Defense and nondefense
expenditures each contributed about equally to GDP growth. Real State and
local government purchases accelerated in 2023, as these governments took
advantage of strong budget positions to increase employment (figure 2-8).
The Fiscal Impact Measure (FIM) index—which captures the overall effects
of Federal, State, and local fiscal policy on GDP growth—suggests that the
large fiscal drag, which had suppressed growth in recent years due primarily
to the roll-off of pandemic emergency aid, was no longer a drag on GDP
growth by the end of 2023 (figure 2-8).6
Private domestic final purchases. Private domestic final purchases
(PDFP) are a measure of GDP that includes only consumption and fixed
investment, removing more volatile components like inventory investment,
government purchases, and net exports. PDFP accelerated from a pace of
about 0.8 percent during the four quarters of 2022 to 2.7 percent in 2023.
Most of this boost in PDFP is due to consumer expenditures and nonresidential investment, whereas residential investment—among the sectors that is
most sensitive to higher interest rates—was a slight drag on growth. PDFP
growth can better summarize economic momentum and better predict future
GDP growth than GDP itself (CEA 2015), and this relationship may be even
more salient in today’s economic climate. The contributions to GDP from
The FIM measures the contributions of overall fiscal legislation to GDP growth. It considers
Federal, State, and local purchases, including taxes and transfers (Asdourian et al. 2024).

6

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 69

Figure 2-8. Fiscal Impulse by Source

Percentage-point contributions to quarterly SAAR of real GDP growth

17
15
13
11

9
7
5
3
1

-1
-3

-5
2016

Tailwinds to GDP growth
Headwinds to GDP growth
2017

2018

Federal spending
Taxes and benefits

Council of Economic Advisers

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

State and local spending
Four-quarter moving average

Source: Brookings Institution.
Note: GDP = gross domestic product; SAAR = seasonally adjusted annual rate. Fiscal policy includes Federal, State, and local
programs. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

those measures excluded from PDFP, such as inventory investment and net
exports, have proven especially volatile due to pandemic-induced shocks
and supply chain disruptions (figure 2-9). As a result, those components
of GDP growth have become noisier and provide a less meaningful signal
about the economy’s underlying momentum.

The Gradual Rebalancing of Demand and Supply in the Labor Market
The labor market gradually eased over the course of 2023. The unemployment rate averaged 3.6 percent for the year, close to the annual lows
observed just before the pandemic, and payroll employment grew 255,000
per month on average, well above the break-even pace needed to absorb
labor force growth while also maintaining the unemployment rate.7 The
average quarterly job growth pace slowed down a bit more at the end of the
year to a three-month pace of about 227,000 jobs per month, still a robust
pace but significantly lower than the average monthly pace of 377,000 jobs
created in 2022 (figure 2-10). This slowdown was expected; employment in
most sectors is now higher than it was in February 2020—the date of the last
prepandemic labor report—and in some sectors was even above the level
implied by extrapolating from prepandemic trends. In fact, employment
The CEA estimates the break-even pace to be between 80,000 and 100,000 jobs a month,
depending on immigration and the rate of the trend in labor force participation, among other factors.
Consistent with the robust and persistent pace of job growth, the unemployment rate in 2023 was the
lowest on record since 1969.

7

70 |

Chapter 2

Figure 2-9. Real GDP Compared with Lagged Real GDP and PDFP
A. Real GDP and Lagged Real GDP, 1995 to 2019

Percent change, annualized rate

10.0

8.0

R2 = 0.1

6.0
4.0
2.0
0.0

-2.0
-4.0
-6.0
-8.0

-10.0
-10.0

-8.0

-6.0

-4.0

-2.0

0.0

2.0

4.0

6.0

8.0

10.0

4.0

6.0

8.0

10.0

Percent change, annualized rate

B. Real GDP and Lagged Real PDFP, 1995 to 2019
Percent change, annualized rate

10.0
8.0
6.0
4.0
2.0
0.0
-2.0
-4.0
-6.0
-8.0
-10.0
-10.0

R2 = 0.4

-8.0

-6.0

-4.0

-2.0

0.0

2.0

Percent change, annualized rate
Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
Note: GDP = gross domestic product; PDFP = private domestic final purchases. Data are quarterly. Real GDP
is on the y axis. In panel A, one-quarter lagged real GDP is on the x axis. In panel B, one-quarter lagged real
PDFP is on the x axis.
2024 Economic Report of the President

growth in 2023 can be mostly attributed to a handful of sectors in which
the rebalancing of the labor market is still in progress. As of December
2023, the level of employment in the leisure and hospitality, education and
health services, and government sectors remain below February 2020 levels;
however, payroll gains in these sectors in 2023 were above their respective
2019 averages.
Several additional indicators suggest that the labor market has slowed
and that the gradual rebalancing between labor supply and labor demand
may be nearly complete. After peaking in 2022, both the hires rate and the

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 71

Figure 2-10. Monthly Change in Nonfarm Employment
Thousands

1,000
800
600
400
200

Payroll growth consistent with steady unemployment rate

0
Jan-2021

Jul-2021

Jan-2022

Jul-2022

Change in total nonfarm employment

Council of Economic Advisers

Jan-2023

Jul-2023

Three-month average

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; CEA calculations.
2024 Economic Report of the President

quits rate have declined to 2019 levels (figure 2-11).8 The quits rate is an
especially meaningful gauge of wage pressures and the scarcity of workers;
its decline suggests that workers are less confident than they were during the
pandemic recovery that higher-paying jobs await them elsewhere (Moscarini
and Postel-Vinay 2017).
The salary gap between those staying in one job and otherwise comparable workers who switch jobs decreased in 2023 after having increased
significantly during the pandemic-induced recession and its associated
recovery (Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta 2024). This metric is consistent
with the narrative suggested by the quits rate, that the labor market has
slowed, though the job openings rate remains well above 2019 levels (figure
2-11, panel B).
There are nevertheless reasons to doubt the job openings rate’s ability
to measure tightness, and the same can be said for measures that incorporate
job openings, such as the gap between available jobs and available workers
or the number of job openings per unemployed worker. As a comparison
of the two panels of figure 2-11 demonstrate, the job openings rate may be
While the Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey’s (JOLTS; BLS 2024) quits rate reached an
all-time high of 3 percent in the spring of 2022, the survey dates only to the early 2000s. To offer
some comparison with earlier job markets, particularly the robust labor markets of the 1970s, the
closest historical analog is the discontinued Manufacturing Labor Turnover Survey (MLTS), which
was conducted through the early 1980s, though it covered only the manufacturing sector. The
comparison suggests that the labor market in the manufacturing sector was as tight in 2022 as it
had been in the 1970s: Per JOLTS, the quits rate in the manufacturing sector reached 2.7 percent in
March 2022, similar to its peak of 2.8 percent in 1973 per the MLTS.

8

72 |

Chapter 2

Figure 2-11. Quits, Hires, and Job Openings Rates
A. Quits and Hires Rates
Percent
7
6
5
4

Hires rate (2019 average)

3
2

Quits rate (2019 average)

1
0
Jan-2019 Jul-2019 Jan-2020 Jul-2020 Jan-2021 Jul-2021 Jan-2022 Jul-2022 Jan-2023 Jul-2023
Quits rate

Hires rate

B. Quits and Job Openings Rates
Percent
8
7
6
5
4

Job openings rate (2019 average)

3
2

Quits rate (2019 average)

1

0
Jan-2019 Jul-2019 Jan-2020 Jul-2020 Jan-2021 Jul-2021 Jan-2022 Jul-2022 Jan-2023 Jul-2023

Council of Economic Advisers

Quits rate

Job openings rate

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics (Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey); CEA calculations.
Note: The quits rate is defined as the number of quits as a percentage of employment. The hires rate is defined as
hires as a percentage of employment. The job openings rate is defined as job openings as a percentage of
employment and job openings. Data are seasonally adjusted. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

generally more sensitive to business cycles than either the hires or the quits
rate—and that relationship has been especially strong since the pandemic.
For example, job openings may be nonlinear with regard to tightness;
firms may be more likely to post external vacancies for different jobs when
they are starved for labor than when labor markets are more normal. As
a consequence, elevated levels of job openings may (as shown in figure
2-12) exaggerate the true state of market tightness. If job openings soon
catch up with quits and hires, they may fall quite rapidly in the near future.
As shown in figure 2-13, panel B, the adjustment of job openings with the
implied common cyclical component from quits and hires or by alternative
methods (Mongey and Horwich 2023; Elsby et al. 2015; Cheremukhin and
Restrepo-Echavarria 2024) suggests that market tightness is back to normal
The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 73

Figure 2-12. Measures of Labor Market Tightness
A. Jobs versus Available Workers
Thousands

175,000
170,000
165,000
160,000
155,000
150,000
145,000
140,000
135,000

130,000
Jan-2020

Jul-2020

Jan-2021

Jul-2021

Available workers (labor force)

Jan-2022

Jul-2022

Jan-2023

Jul-2023

Available jobs (vacanies plus employment)

B. Job Openings per Unemployed Person
Ratio
2.5
2.0
1.5

2019 Average

1.0
0.5
0.0
Jan-2020

Jul-2020

Jan-2021

Council of Economic Advisers

Jul-2021

Jan-2022

Jul-2022

Jan-2023

Jul-2023

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics (Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey); CEA calculations.
Note: Unemployed persons are over age 16 years. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

prepandemic levels and that the current position of the labor market is back
on the prepandemic Beveridge curve (the relationship between job openings and the unemployment rate). These adjustments imply that standard
Beveridge curve calculations shown in figure 2-13, panel A, may overstate
the further progress to come in the labor market’s rebalancing (as implied,
e.g., by Figura and Waller 2022).
Meanwhile, both layoffs and the number of job losers who were laid
off have been essentially flat in 2023 (figure 2-14). These indicators tend to
rise rapidly at the onset of recessions, and their relative quiet supports the
view that the U.S. economy is returning to more normal, sustainable conditions while avoiding a recession. Initial claims for unemployment insurance,
another often-cited leading indicator of recessions, remained flat in 2023.
Finally, the labor supply appears to have firmed up: the labor force
participation rate of prime-age civilians—those between the age of 25 and

74 |

Chapter 2

Figure 2-13. Beveridge Curves
A. Standard Beveridge Curve
Job openings rate

8.0
7.0
6.0
5.0
4.0
3.0
2.0
1.0
0.0

0.0

2.0

4.0

6.0

8.0

10.0

Unemployment rate

January 2001-March 2020

12.0

14.0

16.0

14.0

16.0

April 2020-December 2023

B. Beveridge Curve with Adjusted Vacancies
Job openings rate

8.0
7.0
6.0
5.0
4.0

EDITS
Data was updated but plots were not‐‐fixed
Adjusted legend titles
Needed format adjusted
Fixed y‐axis labels

3.0
2.0
1.0
0.0

0.0

2.0

4.0

6.0

8.0

10.0

12.0

Unemployment rate
January 2001-March 2020

April 2020-December 2023

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics (Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey); CEA calculations.
Note: The job openings rate is defined as job openings as a percentage of employment and job openings. In panel B,
the modified Beveridge curve using vacancy rates is adjusted to reflect long-term labor market relationships. Data are
monthly and seasonally adjusted.
2024 Economic Report of the President

54 years—is close to a 20-year high, and the participation rate for primeage women exceeded its all-time high this year (figure 2-15). Employers’
allowances of more flexible work schedules during and since the COVID19 pandemic—including the rise in work-from-home arrangements—may
also have contributed to record labor force participation among prime-age

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 75

Figure 2-14. Measures of Employment Separation
A. Layoffs and Discharges

Thousands
14,000
12,000
10,000
8,000
6,000
4,000

2019 average

2,000
0
Jan-2020

Jul-2020

Jan-2021

Jul-2021

Jan-2022

Jul-2022

Jan-2023

Jul-2023

Jan-2022

Jul-2022

Jan-2023

Jul-2023

B. Job Losers on Permanent Layoffs
Thousands
4,000
3,500
3,000
2,500
2,000

2019 average

1,500
1,000
500
0
Jan-2020

Jul-2020

Jan-2021

Jul-2021

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics (Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey); Current Population Survey; CEA
calculations.
Note: Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

women.9 It is likely that increasing access to affordable childcare, a key
policy goal of the Biden-Harris Administration, would be associated with
further improvements in the labor supply (CEA 2023a).10
These positive developments in labor force participation rates are
especially remarkable given the backdrop of a downward, long-run trend
in the labor force as a result of the aging U.S. population. Labor force
Survey evidence suggests that, on average, women place a higher value on flexible work
arrangements relative to men. See Aksoy et al. (2022) and Mas and Pallais (2017).
10
Research by Francine Blau and her colleagues suggests that a meaningful portion of the growing
gap in the labor force participation rate of prime-age women between the United States and other
advanced nations can be explained by weak U.S. family policies (Blau and Kahn 2013).
9

76 |

Chapter 2

Figure 2-15. Womenʼs Prime Age (25–54) Labor Force Participation
Percentage of population

80

78

Previous peak (May 2000)

76

74

72

70
1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021 2023

Council of Economic Advisers

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Note: All values are seasonally adjusted. Data are monthly. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Figure 2-16. Factors Affecting the Size of the Labor Force, February
2020–October 2023
Thousands of workers

Total gap relative to Feb.TOTAL
2020*
Aging since Feb. 2020
Excess retirements
COVID-19 deaths

–2,695
–2,586
–865
–312

Foreign-born labor force**

+213

All other labor force participation

Potential status quo extra labor supply***

+855

–10

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
Note: * = Adjusted for annual population controls. ** = Relative to 2012–18 trend. *** = Sum of factors less aging,
immigration, and COVID-19 deaths.
2024 Economic Report of the President

participation for civilians age 65 years and above has steeply declined in the
postpandemic economy. While increased retirements have been expected
due to population aging, they have substantially exceeded expectations since
the onset of the pandemic. According to the CEA’s calculations, excess
retirements subtracted almost 900,000 workers from the labor market in
2023 (figure 2-16).

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 77

Figure 2-17. Business Sector Productivity and Trend

Percent, annual rate

25
20
15
10

5
0
-5
-10
2015

2016

2017

2018

Labor productivity

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

Trend

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Federal Reserve Board; CEA calculations.
Note: The trend is estimated with a modified version of the FRB/US supply-side component, which adds
demographic controls. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

The slowdown in labor markets and the acceleration of real GDP imply
that labor productivity (figure 2-17) rebounded in 2023 after a decline in
2022.11 Productivity has displayed its typical cyclicality in recent years,
and now closely approximates its prepandemic trend, a result of businesses
catching up to desired hiring levels. Despite this, the future path of productivity is uncertain. One potential upside risk to productivity growth is artificial intelligence; whether developments in artificial intelligence will ignite a
similar acceleration in productivity as the information technology revolution
induced in the late 1990s remains to be seen (see chapter 7).
All the available metrics of nominal wage inflation—such as the
Employment Cost Index, average hourly earnings, unit labor costs, and the
Atlanta Fed’s wage tracker—show that nominal wage growth has moderated over the last year (Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta 2024). A strong
labor market has nevertheless fostered progress on real labor compensation.
Compensation growth, as measured by the Employment Cost Index—which
includes both benefits and salaries and which controls for compositional
effects—has been outpacing inflation since 2022:Q4 (figure 2-18), implying
that workers’ purchasing power has improved over the last year. Moreover,
real average hourly earnings—an alternative, more timely measure of wages
and salaries, albeit one more susceptible to compositional effects—have
more than caught up with inflation and are now above prepandemic levels,
especially for the 80 percent of the workforce in production and nonsupervisory occupations. Moderate wage growth above the inflation rate is an
11

Labor productivity is measured as output per hour in the business sector.

78 |

Chapter 2

Figure 2-18. Private Sector Compensation Growth and Inflation
Year-on-year percent change
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
Mar-2019

Nov-2019

Jul-2020
CPI

Mar-2021

Nov-2021

Jul-2022

Mar-2023

Nov-2023

ECI for private sector compensation

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; CEA calculations.
Note: CPI = Consumer Price Index; ECI = Employment Cost Index. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

important factor in providing continued support for aggregate consumer
spending as excess savings are gradually depleted. Of particular importance
for overall purchasing power, the pace of wage growth among the lowest
quartile of the wage distribution exceeded inflation in 2023.12

Inflation in 2023
After peaking in the summer of 2022, inflation trended downward through
the end of 2023. Disinflation in the food, energy, and goods sectors is
largely responsible for this reversal (figure 2-19). Inflation in the services
sector—which is largely influenced by wages, the most important cost in
services production—has been retreating more slowly, in step with the
gradual moderation of wage inflation.
Housing inflation appears to have played an outsized role in keeping
inflation above target in 2023. Rental contracts are renewed only infrequently, and are therefore slower to adjust to rental price pressures (which
include building maintenance and labor costs, utilities, and general costs
of living). However, data on newly signed contracts, such as the Zillow
rent index and the Bureau of Labor Statistics’ New Tenant Rent Index, all
showed a decline in the last two quarters of 2023, suggesting that housing
inflation should lessen over the coming quarters (figure 2-20).
Outside forecasters expected that core inflation would recede more
quickly in 2023, an expectation consistent with their forecasts of weak real
Consumers in the lowest quartile of the wage distribution tend to have a higher marginal
propensity to consume.
12

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 79

Figure 2-19. Contributions to Headline CPI Inflation
Percentage-point contribution to 12-month change

10
8
6
4
2
0

-2
Jan-2018

Nov-2018

Sep-2019

Goods excluding energy & housing

Jul-2020

Housing

May-2021

Mar-2022

Jan-2023

Services excluding energy & housing

Nov-2023

Food

Energy

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; CEA calculations.
Note: CPI = Consumer Price Index. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Figure 2-20. Selected Measures of Rent Growth

Four-quarter percentage change
20
15
10
5
0
-5
-10
2004

2006

2008

2010

Zillow rent

2012

2014
CPI rent

2016

2018

2020

2022

BLS new tenant rent

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland; Zillow.
Note: CPI = Consumer Price Index. BLS = Bureau of Labor Statistics. Data are quarterly. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

economic activity and a high unemployment rate (see figure 2-2, panel B).13
But in contrast to these expectations—and to the economies of the 1970s and
1980s—progress on reestablishing price stability for the U.S. consumer has
Some commentators were skeptical that any progress in the fight against inflation would happen
without sharp increases in the unemployment rate. On this point, also see chapter 1 of this Report.
13

80 |

Chapter 2

Figure 2-21. Contributions to GDP Growth, per the Federal Reserveʼs Financial
Conditions Im
mpulse on Growth (FCI--G)
Percentage points
2.0
1.5

1.0

Tailwinds to GDP growth

0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0

Headwinds to GDP growth

-1.5
-2.0
Jan-2021

Jun-2021

Nov-2021

Federal funds rate
Equity

Apr-2022
10-year Treasury
Housing

Sep-2022

Feb-2023

Mortgage rate
Dollar value

Jul-2023

Dec-2023

BBB rate
FCI-G

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Federal Reserve Board; CEA calculations.
Note: BBB = Better Business Bureau. Data are from FCI-G (baseline), and inverted such that the figure is read as a fiscal impact measure.
2024 Economic Report of the President

thus far been achieved without substantial increases to unemployment rates
or a slowdown in growth. Several causes can be ascribed to the decline in
inflation, the most prominent of which are tighter monetary policy, progress
in the resolution of supply bottlenecks, and lower import prices.
The tightening of monetary policy restrains aggregate demand by
inducing higher interest rates, which typically cool the housing market and
demand for durable goods, both of which are sensitive to interest rates.
Higher interest rates may also cause a decline in the stock market, further
reducing consumption through a wealth effect. According to the Federal
Reserve Board’s Financial Conditions Index Impulse on Growth (FCIG)—a measure that captures the overall effects of financial markets on real
GDP growth—monetary policy and its effects on financial markets created
a headwind to economic growth in the middle months of 2022.14 However,
according to the FCI-G, neither housing prices nor the stock market curbed
GDP growth in 2023 (see figure 2-21 and box 2-1).
A second factor contributing to disinflation—one that accords more
closely with the acceleration in real GDP—is progress in the resolution
of supply bottlenecks. While supply bottlenecks are difficult to measure
precisely—a likely reason why some forecasters had downplayed the role
of their resolution in reducing inflation and instead forecasted weak real
The FCI-G measures how financial conditions, including asset prices, house prices, and interest
rates—all of which are also affected by monetary policy—have the potential to affect the real
economy (Ajello et al. 2023).
14

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 81

Box 2-1. Strong Balance Sheets Supported
Household Consumption in 2023
At the outset of 2023, forecasters anticipated that high mortgage rates,
a historically low saving rate, and lackluster consumer sentiment would
exert a notable deceleration in consumer spending. Moreover, lowerincome households’ excess savings—presumed to have fueled consumption early in the recovery from the COVID-19 pandemic—were thought
to be depleted by the end of 2022. Many observers have therefore been
surprised by consumer resilience in the face of such strong headwinds
(figure 2-i).
Figure 2-i. The Saving Rate
Percentage of disposable income
30

25
20
15
10

2010:Q1–2019:Q4 average

5
0
2012:Q4 2013:Q4 2014:Q4 2015:Q4 2016:Q4 2017:Q4 2018:Q4 2019:Q4 2020:Q4 2021:Q4 2022:Q4 2023:Q4

Council of Economic Advisers

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.
Note: Data are seasonally adjusted. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Several factors likely contributed to last year’s acceleration in
consumption, including low unemployment, strong job growth, and
rising real wages. But an especially important factor was the resilience
of household balance sheets. Household liquid assets, defined as the real
value held in currency and deposits—including money market funds
shares—stayed above its prepandemic trend in 2023. Net worth relative
to income—which includes all liquid, financial, and housing household
assets—also ended the year higher than its level before the pandemic
(figure 2-ii). In particular, housing wealth held up well in 2023. Despite
high mortgage rates, undersupply in the housing market has so far supported house prices. Traditionally, housing wealth supports middle-class
homeowners’ consumption. These consumers are able either to extract
resources from their homes in the form of home equity lines—a channel
likely dampened by the recent rise in interest rates—or to lower their
saving rate, capitalizing on the perceived high present discounted value
of their homes. Finally, high interest rates did not substantially dent the

82 |

Chapter 2

Figure 2-ii. Wealth-to-Income Ratio versus Consumption Rate
Years of income
9

Consumption as a percentage of income

110

8

100

7
90
6
80

5
4
1951 1956 1961 1966 1971 1976 1981 1986 1991 1996 2001 2006 2011 2016 2021
Wealth-to-income ratio (left axis)

Council of Economic Advisers

70

Consumption rate (right axis)

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis; Federal Reserve Board; CEA calculations.
Note: The 2023:Q4 value is estimated by the CEA. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

stock market’s performance in 2023, which appears to be relevant in
gauging the support of consumption from wealthy consumers.

economic activity—the few available measures suggest substantial progress. For instance, the share of manufacturing plants reporting insufficient
labor has decreased significantly from its peak in 2022, a pattern that likely
reflects the improvement in the labor supply, especially among primeage workers, as documented above.15 Meanwhile, the Institute for Supply
Management’s supplier delivery index and the New York Federal Reserve
Bank’s Global Supply Chain Pressure Index (GSCPI) each indicate a decline
in supply chain pressures over the past year (figure 2-22).16
Core import prices—another cost driver, and a third potential explanation for the recent decline in inflation—have also receded. Import prices
are themselves driven by many different factors, including foreign demand,
foreign inflation, global supply chain pressures, and the relative strength of
the dollar. Over the course of 2023, nonpetroleum import prices fell 1.6 percent, which put downward pressure on the cost of many inputs for domestic
production.
These data are from the Quarterly Survey of Plant Capacity (U.S. Census Bureau n.d.).
The Institute for Supply Management’s index gauges changes in supplier delivery times. A
measure below 50 implies that deliveries are moving faster, and that supply chain pressures are
easing. The GSCPI summarizes several supply chain indicators, including an index of supplier
deliveries.
15
16

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 83

Figure 2-22. Indicators of Supply Chain Pressure

Standard deviation points

Index: 50+ equals slower

6

80

4

70

2

60

0

50

-2

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

NYFRB Global Supply Chain Pressure Index (left axis)

Council of Economic Advisers

2020

2021

2022

2023

40

ISM Supplier Deliveries Index (right axis)

Sources: Federal Reserve Bank of New York (NYFRB); Institute for Supply Management (ISM).
Note: A value above 50 for the Supplier Deliveries Index indicates slower deliveries. The NYFRB Global Supply Chain Pressure
Index is normalized such that zero indicates the series average value with positive/negative showing how many standard
deviations above/below the average the point is. The data are not seasonally adjusted. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

The factors that contributed in 2023 to the diminishing effects of
inflation can also be evaluated within the framework of the Phillips curve.
Augmented with proxies for supply shocks and the interaction of demand
and supply bottlenecks, the Phillips curve succinctly captures inflation’s rise
in the COVID-19 pandemic years leading into 2023, as well as its subsequent decline, during which there was no labor market or aggregate demand
deterioration (CEA 2023b). Consider a Phillips curve that includes (1) relative import prices as a cost-push factor, (2) the New York Federal Reserve
Bank’s GSCPI as a measure of supply chain pressures, and (3) an interaction
term between the GSCPI with slack (proxied by the CBO’s unemployment
gap measure)—all of which are meant to capture the demand-induced
bottlenecks at a time of supply chain disruptions.17 Inflation expectations
are proxied by the Survey of Professional Forecasters’ long-run PCE inflation expectations. Figure 2-23 shows that the model ascribes the majority of
the increase in inflation from 2018 to 2022 to supply chain disruptions and
most of the subsequent decline to the unsnarling of supply chains and the
resolution of demand bottlenecks. Notably, the role of slack, in isolation, is
minimal in explaining the recent evolution of inflation.
Long-term inflation expectations had been steady for decades when
inflation began to rise in 2021, and these expectations remained low even
as inflation started its climb. Figure 2-24 plots two of the most commonly
tracked measures of inflation expectations: the median expected annual
price percent change over the next 12 months, and the median expected
17

The Phillips curve used in these calculations builds from Yellen (2015).

84 |

Chapter 2

Figure 2-23. Change in Core PCE Inflation

Percentage points, annual averages of quarterly annualized rate
2018–22

2022–23*

Expectations

+0.4

-0.1

Import prices

-0.1

-0.4

Slack

-0.0

+0.0

Slack–supply chain interaction

+0.9

-0.6

Supply chains

+1.6

-0.5

Residual

+0.3

+0.2

Total

+3.0

-1.4

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Yellen (2015); Bureau of Economic Analysis; Congressional Budget Office;
Bureau of Labor Statistics; CEA calculations.
Note: * = First three quarters of 2023 only. PCE = Personal Consumer Expenditures price index.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Figure 2-24. Actual and Expected Inflation, 2012–23

12-month percent change
10
9
7
6
5
4
3
1
0
-1
2012

2013

2014

2015

1-year expected inflation

Council of Economic Advisers

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

5–10 years expected inflation

2021

2022

2023

Actual CPI inflation

Sources: University of Michigan; Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
Note: CPI = Consumer Price Index. Data are monthly. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

average annual price percent change over the next 5 to 10 years, from the
University of Michigan’s monthly survey of households. Both measures
peaked during 2022 and declined through the end of 2023. Long-term
inflation expectations in particular were reassuringly stable, indicating that
although households expected elevated inflation in the short run, they did
not expect inflationary conditions to last (box 2-2).

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 85

Box 2-2. Consumer Attitudes and Economic Data
Consumer perceptions about the economy, as measured by surveys,
can be useful indicators of how the general public experiences macroeconomic developments. Two of the most prominent monthly indices
measuring consumer attitudes are “Consumer Confidence,” published
by the Conference Board, and “Consumer Sentiment,” published by the
University of Michigan. As figure 2-iii illustrates, these two measures
broadly co-move over time. Both plunged when the pandemic hit, and
both remain below their respective prepandemic levels.
Figure 2-iii. Indicators of Consumer Attitudes
Index: 2019 = 100

140
120
100
80
60
40
20

0
1978

1982

1986

1990

1994

1998

2002

University of Michigan, consumer sentiment

Council of Economic Advisers

2006

2010

2014

2018

2022

Conference Board, consumer confidence

Sources: University of Michigan; Conference Board; CEA calculations.
Note: Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Historically, consumer attitudes have closely tracked a handful of
key economic aggregates, especially the unemployment rate, income
growth, inflation, the stock market’s performance, and housing prices.
An ordinary-least-squares regression, estimated from 1978 through mid2022 and controlling for both population demographics and the spread of
COVID-19, suggests that changes in these five measures explained most
of the variation in consumer sentiment, even during the extraordinary
depths of the pandemic (figure 2-iv). However, since mid-2022—around
the time headline inflation peaked on a 12-month basis—a large gap has
opened between actual and predicted sentiment.
This gap—already a historic anomaly—is particularly notable
since sentiment has often been a leading indicator of economic health;
it may either be signaling future weakness unanticipated by other measures, or that the pandemic shifted the relationship between the economy
and consumer sentiment. (For example, the Conference Board includes
both consumer confidence and consumer sentiment in its composite

86 |

Chapter 2

Figure 2-iv. University of Michigan Sentiment, Actual and Predicted
Index: 1966:Q1 = 100

120
110
100
90
80
70
60
50

40
1978 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 2002 2005 2008 2011 2014 2017 2020 2023
Actual

Council of Economic Advisers

Predicted

Sources: University of Michigan; Bureau of Labor Statistics; Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
Note: Predicted ordinary least squares of University of Michigan microdata are estimates from January 1978 to June 2022
using year-over-year percent change in the Standard & Poor's 500; real disposable personal income per household (split
into wage and nonwage); housing prices; Personal Consumption Expenditures price indexes for food, energy, core goods,
and core services; and the year-over-year differences in the unemployment rate and log total COVID-19 cases. Estimates
also include fixed effects by sex, age, education, birth cohort, Census region, month in survey sample, and calendar
month. Data are as of November 2023. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

index of leading indicators for the United States; see Conference Board
2024.) This chapter already discusses the possible near-term upside and
downside risks to the economy. On the possibility that sui generis factors have altered the link between sentiment and the economy, several
hypotheses require further attention.
Price changes (inflation) versus price levels. Consumer attitudes
may be sensitive to both high price changes (inflation) and high price
levels—products whose prices remain higher than consumers expect,
even after prices stop rising. This hypothesis implies that simple models
that only include inflation could mechanically overstate the improvement
in sentiment attributable to disinflation. That is, after a period of high
inflation, consumers may have a lingering distaste for the resulting high
level of prices that an inflation-only model would struggle to capture.
A straightforward, though hardly dispositive, test of the price level
hypothesis is to allow explicit terms for changes in inflation to enter the
regression model asymmetrically, such that declines in inflation affect
sentiment differently than rises in inflation. (Simply adding price levels
to a regression presents a statistical challenge, because price levels are
almost always nonstationary and thus can lead to spurious regression
results. The change in the price level, inflation, is already included in the
base model.) If this hypothesis were true, one would expect disinflation
to affect sentiment positively to a lesser extent than rising inflation affects
sentiment negatively, since falling but still-positive inflation implies that
the price level remains high. Augmenting the simple regression model
with these terms, the CEA finds exactly that: for energy, food, and core

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 87

Figure 2-v. University of Michigan Sentiment: Actual, Predicted, and Augmented
Index: 1966:Q1 = 100

120
110
100

90
80
70
60
50
40
1978

1981

1984

1987

1990

Actual

Council of Economic Advisers

1993

1996

1999

2002

Predicted

2005

2008

2011

2014

2017

2020

2023

Augmented

Sources: University of Michigan; Bureau of Labor Statistics; Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
Note: Predicted ordinary least squares of University of Michigan microdata are estimates from January 1978 to June 2022 using yearover-year percent change in the Standard & Poor's 500; real disposable personal income per household (split into wage and
nonwage); housing prices; Personal Consumption Expenditures price indexes for food, energy, core goods, and core services; and the
year-over-year differences in the unemployment rate and log total COVID-19 cases. Estimates also include fixed effects by sex, age,
education, birth cohort, Census region, month in survey sample, and calendar month. Augmented model includes change in inflation
and an asymmetry term. Data are as of November 2023. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

goods, a decline in inflation has less of an initial effect on sentiment than
does a rise in inflation of the same magnitude. As figure 2-v shows, the
augmented model’s in-sample predictions are not substantially different
from those of the baseline model, but its out-of-sample predictions for
the period since June 2022 are far superior, suggesting that price levels
matter for sentiment.
Broader, COVID-19-related shifts. An analysis by the Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago (Herbstman and Brave 2023) finds that
relationships between economic variables and sentiment broadly pivoted
during the pandemic. This shift was especially true of labor market variables; growth in earnings and employment affected sentiment less positively during the pandemic than before. (Note that one key difference
between the Consumer Sentiment and Consumer Confidence estimates
is their sensitivity to labor market conditions; see Hirsch 2012. The
Conference Board’s Consumer Confidence index explicitly incorporates
labor market experiences and expectations into its composite, whereas
the University of Michigan’s Consumer Sentiment index does not use
specific labor market questions in its measure.)
One plausible hypothesis is that the pandemic experience, including the government’s fiscal responses to the virus’s impact on American
life, affected sentiment in ways not fully captured by conventional economic metrics. The government provided unusually strong fiscal support
to families in 2020 and 2021, when the pandemic’s effects were felt the
most, and the rise and fall in unemployment during the pandemic was
overwhelmingly and unprecedentedly driven by temporarily furloughed
workers, many of whom reclaimed their positions when lockdowns

88 |

Chapter 2

ended. Either mechanism might explain why pandemic-era rises in the
unemployment rate had less of a negative effect on sentiment than would
be expected from prior cycles.
Other factors. Observers have suggested various other candidates
to explain the gap between economic indicators and consumer sentiment. For instance, heightened political partisanship, and the evolving
tendency for consumers to base their survey responses on political
rather than economic factors, may be being factored into the indices at
a rate not previously seen (Hartman 2022). Meanwhile, social media
has become a far more common source of news, for younger Americans
especially, and has been shown to disproportionately elevate negative
and often false information—making a gap between reliable indicators
and sentiment more plausible (e.g., O’Kane 2023). The shortage of
affordable housing, the subject of chapter 4 of this Report, is another
potential factor generating negative sentiment, particularly among
younger families for which homeownership is often out of reach. And as
certain pandemic-era supports have expired, real disposable income has
fallen for families who had been beneficiaries of those transfers—a final
potential factor behind the large residual.

Financial Markets in 2023
Markets had an eventful 2023, highlighted by at least three consequential
developments. First, risk-free interest rates—especially those with long
horizons, such as the benchmark 10-year Treasury note—climbed to levels
not seen since leading up to the global financial crisis, before reversing most
of the increase toward the end of the year. Even with little net change over
the year, long-maturity, risk-free rates remained high relative to the past 10
years, a trend that has resulted in higher borrowing costs for businesses,
consumers, and the government. Second, and relatedly, the high-profile
failure of a few banks affected lenders’ willingness to extend credit and
exerted upward pressure on the cost of borrowing relative to the risk-free
rate of interest, further tightening credit conditions. However, most of these
effects were short-lived, due in part to a rapid and effective policy response.
Third, the component in interest rates that nets out inflation effects—the real
rate of interest—rose markedly in 2023. The real policy rate remained high,
though much of the increase in long-maturity real rates reversed toward the
end of the year, and rates across maturities remained high relative to the
post–financial crisis period. Understanding the drivers of real rate movements is important for assessing the durability of recent economic trends.

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 89

Figure 2-25. Selected Nominal U.S. Interest Rates
Percent

Start of 2023

9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0

-1
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023
Federal funds rate

Council of Economic Advisers

10-year Treasury yield

30-year fixed mortgage rate

Sources: Federal Reserve Board; Bloomberg.
Note: The 30-year fixed mortgage rate is the average U.S. 30-year fixed mortgage products rate from Bankrate.com via Bloomberg.
Federal funds rate corresponds to the midpoint of the federal funds target rate range. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

The Rise in Long-Term Rates
Key interest rates—including the federal funds rate, the 10-year Treasury
rate, and the 30-year fixed mortgage rate—all rose during most of 2023.
After peaking in October, long-maturity rates declined, reversing much of
the earlier rise; but the policy rate remained at its highest level since 2001
(figure 2-25). Long-maturity yields were atypically low in the sustained
period of zero-rate monetary policy from the end of 2008 through the end
of 2015, and then again from 2020 to 2022. The 10-year yield was below
2.2 percent when policy tightening began in March 2022; since then, the
overnight policy rate has risen over 5 percentage points, and long-maturity
Treasury yields have risen as high as 5 percent on an intraday basis—the
largest policy rate increase and the largest 10-year Treasury yield increase
per tightening cycle since the 1980s. By the end of the year, the 10-year
Treasury yield had fallen below 4 percent, while the overnight federal funds
target rate remained above 5 percent, with a cumulative 1-percentage-point
increase during 2023.
As a benchmark for riskier rates, long-maturity Treasury yields are the
basis for rates that are important for businesses and consumers, such as corporate bond yields and the 30-year fixed mortgage rate. The national average
30-year fixed rate for conforming mortgage loans rose more than the 10-year

90 |

Chapter 2

Figure 2-26. Outstanding Loan Amounts Relative to GDP
Percent

Start of 2023

16
14
12
10
8
6

4
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023
C&I loans / GDP

Council of Economic Advisers

Commercial real estate loans / GDP

Consumer loans / GDP

Source: Federal Reserve Board; Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
Note: C&I = commercial and industrial; GDP = gross domestic product. Loan amounts are for all commercial banks from
the Federal Reserve's H.8 release. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Treasury yield,18 as illustrated by the teal line in figure 2-25, peaking above
8 percent, before falling to about 7 percent at the end of 2023. Meanwhile,
the quantity of outstanding commercial loans declined relative to the rate
of GDP growth (figure 2-26). While banks tightened standards for loans to
businesses and households early in 2023, the decline in borrowing was also
partly driven by lower demand in a higher-rate environment (figure 2-27).
The effect of a higher-rate environment on asset prices can have large
implications for the broader economy. A sharp rise in rates produces steep
unrealized (or “mark-to-market”) losses for fixed-rate security holders.
From March 16, 2022—when the Federal Reserve began to hike its policy
rate—until March 8, 2023, the 10-year Treasury yield rose nearly 2 percentage points. As higher rates on newly issued securities drove down the price
of extant securities with lower fixed rates, the holders of securities with
lower fixed rates, including banks, experienced large mark-to-market losses,
as illustrated in figure 2-28. For example, consider a bank with 10-year
Treasury holdings originally worth $50 billion, purchased in March 2022,
when the 10-year rate was 2 percent. By March 2023, the value of the bank’s
Treasury securities would have fallen by about $8 billion. These dynamics
tipped various banks, including Silicon Valley Bank and Signature Bank,
into insolvency.
One of the main channels through which banking stress reaches the
real economy is constrained credit. Credit conditions initially tightened and
Conforming mortgage loans are insurable by the Federal housing agencies. In order to “conform,”
a loan must meet the quality terms and conditions (e.g., a minimum credit score for a borrower and a
maximum amount borrowed) set forth by the U.S. Federal Housing Finance Authority.
18

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 91

Figure 2-27. Credit Conditions for Business Loans

Net percentage of domestic banks

Start of 2023

100

80
60
40
20
0
-20
-40
-60
-80
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023
Tighter loan standards

Stronger loan demand

Council of Economic Advisers

Source: Federal Reserve Board.
Note: This figure shows the net percentage of domestic banks that are tightening standards for or are increasing demand for
business loans, weighted by banks’ outstanding loan balances from the Federal Reserve’s Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey
on Bank Lending Practices. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Figure 2-28. Bond Returns and Unrealized Gains/Losses
Billions of dollars

Start of 2023

150

Percent
3.0

50

1.0

-50

-1.0

-150

-3.0

-250

-5.0

-350

-7.0

-450

-9.0

-550

-11.0

-650

-13.0

-750
Sep-2013

Apr-2015

Nov-2016

Jun-2018

Losses on held-to-maturity securities (left axis)
S&P U.S. bond index returns (right axis)

Jan-2020

Aug-2021

Mar-2023

-15.0

Losses on available-for-sale assets (left axis)

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC); Standard & Poor's (S&P).
Note: Unrealized losses are from the FDIC 2023:Q3 quarterly banking profile, table 7. Data are quarterly.
2024 Economic Report of the President

asset volatility rose as bank shares—shown in blue in figure 2-29, panel
A—sharply underperformed the broader market. Amid the bank failures, the
10-year Treasury yield fell by more than half a percentage point as investors
fled to safety, and the MOVE index (the Merrill Lynch Option Volatility
Estimate index), a popular measure of expected future Treasury market
volatility, spiked to its highest point since the pandemic-induced financial
market turmoil in March 2020. The navy line in figure 2-29, panel A,

92 |

Chapter 2

Figure 2-29. Treasury Volatility and Market Conditions

A. MOVE Treasury Volatility Index and Bank Subindex
MOVE index

Start of 2023

500

Bank
subindex
300

450

250

400
350

200

300
250

150

200

100

150
100

50

50

0
2007

2009

2011

2013

2015

2017

S&P bank subindex (right axis)

2019

2021

0

2023

MOVE index (left axis)

B. Market Credit Conditions
VIX

Start of 2023

90

Percent

80

20

70
60

16

50

12

40
30

8

20

4

10
0
2007

24

2009

2011

2013

VIX (left axis)

Council of Economic Advisers

2015

2017

2019

2021

2023

0

High yield credit spread (right axis)

Sources: Bank of America; Bloomberg.
Note: The MOVE index is published by the Intercontinental Exchange. The index measures the implied yield volatility of a
basket of one-month options on 2-year, 5-year, 10-year, and 30-year Treasury securities. The bank share price subindex is
for the level 2 banks industry group of the Standard and Poor's (S&P) 500 index. The VIX is published by the Chicago
Board of Options Exchange. The index measures the implied volatility of a basket of one-month options on the S&P 500
equity market price index. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

illustrates the strong negative relationship between the measure of Treasury
yield volatility and bank share prices, underscoring the importance of interest rate movements for the health of banks’ balance sheets. The Federal
Reserve rapidly introduced a new lending facility in 2023—the Bank Term
Funding Program—which is aimed at alleviating pressure for banks to sell
high-quality, fixed-income securities at a loss, and the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation, the Federal Reserve, and Treasury—in consultation
with the President—stepped in with a comprehensive guarantee for customers’ deposits in Silicon Valley Bank and Signature Bank, an action that

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 93

Figure 2-30. Nominal and TIPS Treasury Yield Curves
Percent

Oct. 19, 2023

5.25

4.75

Nominal

4.25

Dec. 29, 2023

3.75

Jan. 2, 2023

3.25

Oct. 19, 2023

2.75
2.25

TIPS

1.75
1.25

Dec. 29, 2023
Jan. 2, 2023

2Y

3Y

4Y

Nominal (Jan. 2, 2023)
TIPS (Jan. 2, 2023)

Council of Economic Advisers

5Y

6Y

7Y

8Y

Nominal (Oct. 19, 2023)
TIPS (Oct. 19, 2023)

9Y

10Y

Nominal (Dec. 29, 2023)
TIPS (Dec. 29, 2023)

Source: Bloomberg.
Note: TIPS = Treasury Inflation-Protected Securities. The figure shows real and nominal yield curves and their changes over
the year.
2024 Economic Report of the President

stemmed financial contagion. By the year’s end, the tightening started to
reverse course. Credit spreads narrowed, and, as shown by the VIX, implied
volatility on equities declined (figure 2-29, panel B), which was also consistent with persistently robust data on economic activity.

Real Rates as the Driver of Higher Long-Term Rates
Long-maturity real yields, as proxied by Treasury Inflation-Protected
Securities (TIPS), rose and then declined, roughly in tandem with nominal
Treasury yields during 2023 (figure 2-30), indicating that inflation expectations likely changed little and that most of the nominal yield change was
attributable to the real component in rates.19
The causes behind changes in real rates are often uncertain, and 2023
proved to be no exception—with particular uncertainty about why rates
rose so sharply but then declined. Figure 2-31 illustrates real term rates as
a component of nominal rates. Suggested explanations for the initial, sharp
increase in real rates include tighter monetary policy; a higher expected
neutral real rate (the theoretical interest rate that neither stimulates nor
slows the economy); and the difference in return demanded by investors to
hold long-maturity securities relative to short-maturity ones, also referred
Strictly speaking, the nominal minus TIPS yield spread only measures the inflation compensation
to investors, which is also affected by differential liquidity of TIPS relative to nominal securities and
the risk premium that investors may price for inflation, and so is not a direct measure of inflation
expectations. Estimates of these effects from the model of D’Amico, Kim, and Wei (2018) show
that break-even rates underestimated expected inflation by about 10 basis points, on average, during
2023.
19

94 |

Chapter 2

Figure 2-31. Components of Nominal Rates
Expected inflation

← Observed nominal rate

Inflation risk premium
Real term premium
Short-run expected real policy rate
relative to neutral

Expected future path
of short real rates

Real rate

Long-run neutral real rate
Council of Economic Advisers

Source: CEA analysis.
2024 Economic Report of the President

to as the “term premium.” However, these factors fail to fully explain why
long-maturity, risk-free real rate increases largely reversed in the latter part
of the year, making it difficult to forecast how these rates will evolve in the
future. Identifying the drivers of rate movements is difficult because concepts such as the neutral rate and term premia are not directly observable in
asset prices. Surveys and term structure models can be used to estimate the
various components that constitute nominal and real interest rates (Kim and
Wright 2005; D’Amico, Kim, and Wei 2018).

A Higher Expected Path for the Real Policy Rate
As the Federal Reserve increased its target rate in 2022 and 2023, estimates
of the expected path of near-term policy unsurprisingly shifted from below
neutral—stimulative—to above neutral—restrictive. As the nominal policy
rate rose to its highest level since 2001, the estimated real policy rate
reached its highest level since the global financial crisis and also became
restrictive for the first time in the postcrisis period.
Expectations for increasingly tight monetary policy over most of
2023 (figure 2-32, panel A) resulted in part from a series of economic data
releases that showed marked labor market resilience and buoyant consumption, which surprised forecasters throughout the year. Figure 2-32, panel B,
shows the total and average changes in the 10-year Treasury yield, clustered
around major data releases: nonfarm payrolls, unemployment insurance
claims, consumer confidence, and core CPI inflation. It incorporates both
positive and negative changes in the 10-year yield, and it filters out days of
Federal Open Market Committee meetings or other major nondata events
with a market impact. Jobless claims, which are released weekly, showed
the largest cumulative contribution to rising 10-year Treasury yields in
2023—the dark green bar in the figure—while the monthly inflation data

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 95

Figure 2-32. Federal Funds Rate and Federal Funds Futures Rates
A. Realized Policy Rate and Shift in Expected Policy Rate
Percent

5.50
5.25
5.00
4.75
4.50
4.25
4.00
3.75

3.50
Jan-2023

May-2023

Sep-2023

Realized rate

Jan-2024

May-2024

1/3/2023 Contract curve

Sep-2024

Jan-2025

12/29/2023 Contract curve

B. Change in the 10-Year Yield Around Data Release Surprises
Basis points

Basis points

50

5

40

4

30

3

20

2

10

1

0

0

-10

Nonfarm payrolls

UI claims

Total impact in second half of 2023 (left axis)
Change per surprise (right axis)

Consumer sentiment

Core CPI inflation

-1

Total impact in 2023 (left axis)

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bloomberg; CEA calculations.
Note: UI = unemployment insurance; CPI = Consumer Price Index. In panel A, expectations are derived from federal
funds futures contracts as of 12/29/2023 and 1/3/2023. Realized rates are monthly averages of the daily federal funds
effective rate. In panel B, data release surprises are classified as any time the data differ from expectations. Change
per surprise is a predicted value, measured in standard deviations from the median of surveyed expectations.
2024 Economic Report of the President

demonstrated the largest impact per surprise.20 The difference between the
light and dark green bars gives the impact over the first half of the year
alone. The estimates show that the unexpected part of payroll releases had
The estimates given here are from an event study regression of the change in 10-year Treasury yields
in a 1-day window, as given in economic data releases on the surprise component of the news. The
1-day window starts with the closing price on the date before the announcement and ends with the
closing price on the announcement date. The surprise component is the difference between the realized
outcome and the median Bloomberg survey expectation, scaled by the standard deviation of submitted
survey expectations.
20

96 |

Chapter 2

a disproportionate impact on rising yields during the first half of the year,
whereas jobless claims contributed relatively more in the latter half of 2023,
even with the sharp drop in yields toward the end of the year.
In mid-December 2023, the Federal Open Market Committee released
a statement and forecast on markets that was widely interpreted as signaling
that, barring any data surprises, policy tightening had peaked and the next
move would be a policy rate cut (Federal Reserve 2023a; Federal Reserve,
Federal Open Market Committee 2023). Figure 2-32, panel A, provides a
snapshot of the market-implied, expected short-run path of the federal funds
rate, showing the upward trajectory of the target policy rate during 2023
(solid navy line in the figure) and the expected path of the target rate as captured at the end of the year (dashed navy line). Despite the end-of-year shift
to expected easing, the anticipated path of the policy rate remained higher
than it had been at the start of 2023 (dashed blue line).

The Term Premium
The rising Treasury term premium further drove term rates higher during
2023. Conceptually, the real term premium is the component of the longmaturity, risk-free real rate that is not explained by the expected future
path of short-maturity real rates (figure 2-31). The 10-year Treasury term
premium was largely negative from 2019 to 2021, according to most estimates, before rising to be occasionally positive amid the growing interest
rate environment, a pattern that persisted during 2023.
Several types of risks could have supported the term premium in
2023. As interest rates rise, bond prices fall, though the relationship is not
one-for-one. The pricing of duration risk recognizes that the longer the
maturity of the bond (all else remaining equal), the larger the price decline
per percentage-point increase in the interest rate. The risk of capital loss for
an investor needing to sell a bond before maturity motivates them to demand
a higher term premium. A possible contributor to a higher real term premium
is greater near-term uncertainty about medium- to long-maturity real rates,
which could stem from investor uncertainty about the Federal Reserve’s
future policy rate. Heightened expected rate volatility, as policy expectations
rapidly shift, could amplify the pricing of duration risk in bond term premia.
The MOVE index—as noted above, a measure of expected future Treasury
rate volatility (figure 2-29, panel A)—rose along with rates across maturities and term premium estimates starting in late 2021. In March 2023, the
MOVE index temporarily spiked to its highest level since the peak of the
financial crisis in 2008 amid interest rate risk-related banking stresses. The
index ended the year within the range it has been since 2021, which is still
relatively high compared with the post–financial crisis period.

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 97

Potential Risks for the Outlook
Before long-maturity, real risk-free rates later declined—particularly compared with the negative real rates for the 2 years before the start of policy
tightening—the dramatic shift to a real risk-free return above 2 percent
produced some expected outcomes and posed some challenges and potential
risks. Structural changes in markets and the economy may have changed
the ways that firms and individuals respond to higher rates since the
United States was last in a similar rate environment, about 15 years ago.
Additionally, the speed at which organizations can now adjust to shocks
adds an additional degree of uncertainty to the outlook.

Figure 2-33. U.S. Debt by Type and Holder

A. U.S. Debt Shares Outstanding Net of Federal Reserve Holdings
Percent of total debt

50
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5

0
2006

2008

2010

Treasury

2012

2014

MBS

2016

Corporate

2018

2020

Municipal

2022

B. Domestic Holders of Treasury and Corporate Debt as of 2023:Q3
Billions of dollars

5,000
4,500
4,000
3,500
3,000
2,500
2,000

Will
get udpated'
1,500
1,000

500
0

Households State/ Monetary
local
authority
government

Council of Economic Advisers

Banks
Treasury

Insurance Pensions

MMF

Other
funds

Brokers/
dealers

Corporate

Source: Federal Reserve Board.
Note: MBS = mortgage-backed securities. MMF = money market fund. Data are from the Federal Reserve's financial
accounts. Only large categories of U.S. holders are shown. The "other funds" category includes mutual funds, closed-end
funds and exchange-traded funds. Household category includes non-profit holdings. Corporate bond holdings include
foreign bonds. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

98 |

Chapter 2

Treasury debt has constituted the largest portion of U.S.-issued debt
since overtaking corporate debt in 2011, as illustrated in figure 2-33, panel
A. Pension funds, other investment funds, and insurers are among the top
holders of the two largest debt categories: Treasury and corporate securities,
as illustrated in figure 2-33, panel B. Depending on the structure of the fund,
the possibility of losses or rapid investor redemptions could subject some
of these entities to a quickly changing risk profile. Those with relatively
short-maturity holdings, such as money market funds holding primarily
Treasury bills, will be less exposed as the prices of longer-duration securities are more sensitive to changes in interest rates. Although banks are not
the top holders of Treasury securities, concentrated holdings could still pose
risks, especially for less-diversified financial institutions such as small and
regional banks.
Higher real interest rates increase the risk of adverse events for leveraged entities, whether public or private. According to the most recent data
filed with the Securities and Exchange Commission, hedge funds’ holdings
of debt securities reached a historic high, constituting more than one-third
of their total assets (Federal Reserve 2023b). Mark-to-market losses are
not realized losses, but market volatility or an interruption of income could
force asset liquidations at a loss that spirals into a credit event. The banking stresses of this past March served as a reminder of these risks—and the
importance of vigilance in periods of transition.
Higher real rates also increase the risk of adverse movements in future
stock prices, as share valuations adjust to higher competing real returns.
When real risk-free rates are negative, investors can earn a positive real
return only by investing in riskier assets than Treasury debt, such as stocks.
Over the past 10 years, the average real risk-free rate has been about 0.3
percent, providing a low hurdle rate for equities. By the end of 2023, the
real risk-free rate was above 1.5 percent (figure 2-34, panel B), substantially
increasing the minimum real return that investors would require from riskier
assets.
The Standard & Poor’s (S&P) 500 equity index rose about 25 percent
in 2023 (figure 2-34, panel A), and the average price-to-earnings ratio per
share for S&P 500 companies rose slightly more. Price gains were therefore
attributable to higher share valuations rather than improved earnings, on
average. The inverse of the price-to-earnings ratio, the earnings-to-price
ratio, is a common proxy for the expected equity return. The intuition is
that earnings will either be paid out to the investor in dividends or will be
reinvested to boost future growth (Campbell and Shiller 2001). The return
that remains after subtracting the real risk-free rate is called the equity risk
premium. The average equity risk premium for the S&P 500 index, using the
10-year TIPS yield as a proxy for the real rate, ended the year at about 2.65
percent, far below its 10-year average, much of which was attributable to the
The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 99

Figure 2-34. Equity Risk Premium

A. Equity Risk Premium and the S&P 500 Index

Percent

Start of 2023

9

Index

8

5,000

7
6

4,000

5

3,000

4
3

2,000

2

1,000

1
0
2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

Equity risk premium (left axis)

2018

2020

0

2022

S&P 500 (right axis)

B. Equity Risk Premium and 10-Year TIPS Yield
Percent

Percent

9

Start of 2023

8
7

3
2

6
5

1

4

0

3
2

-1

1
0
2006

6,000

2008

2010

2012

2014

Equity risk premium (left axis)

Council of Economic Advisers

2016

2018

2020

2022

-2

10-year TIPS yield (right axis)

Source: Bloomberg.
Note: S&P = Standard & Poor’s; TIPS = Treasury Inflation-Protected Securities. Equity risk premium is a measure of
the average equity yield minus the real risk-free rate. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

sharp rise in the real rate, as shown in figure 2-34, panel B. The figure also
illustrates how, in 2023, the estimated equity risk premium fell below its
level from just before the 2008 financial crisis. A sharp correction in equity
valuation, implying a higher earnings-to-price ratio, could dent consumption
and potentially destabilize markets. However, a more modest and gradual
decrease could bring the equity risk premium back in line with historic
values relatively seamlessly.
Higher rates naturally raise the Treasury’s debt-servicing costs for
new issuances, regardless of the component in yields that is responsible for
the increase. However, the implications of higher rates for future debt and
GDP, which can make higher debt-servicing costs more or less sustainable,
depends on the primary drivers of rising rates. For example, an expected
rise in the neutral real rate—perhaps prompted by faster trend productivity
100 |

Chapter 2

growth—could reflect factors that would also boost GDP, and thus potentially moderate the debt-to-GDP ratio, all else remaining equal. However, a
higher term premium—which weighs on investments without any expected
offsetting productivity gain—is an unambiguous net drag on economic
activity.

The Forecast for the Years Ahead
The Biden-Harris Administration finalized the latest version of its official
economic forecast on November 9, 2023, with data available through
November 3. The forecast provides the Administration’s projections of key
economic variables over the next 11 years, from 2024 to 2034, as illustrated
in table 2-2. Because more 2023 data have become available during the
interval between when this forecast was finalized and the publication of this
Report, the official forecast discussed in this chapter may differ from current
estimates for 2023. Indeed, since the forecast was finalized, inflation has
fallen slightly more than expected and interest rates have declined, while
employment and economic activity have remained robust—suggesting that,
if the forecast were finalized today, it would likely show lower interest
rates, with continued progress on inflation, growth, and employment. This
overall forecast is a critical input to the President’s Fiscal Year 2025 Budget,
Table 2-2. Economic Projections, 2022–34
Percent Change (Q4-to-Q4)
Year
Actual

Real
GDP

Inflation Measures

GDP Price
Index

Level (percent)
Unemployment Rate

Interest Rates

CPI

Annual

Q4

3-Month
T-Bills

10-Year
T-Notes

2022

0.7

6.4

7.1

3.6

3.6

2.0

3.0

2023

2.6

3.0

3.4

3.6

3.8

5.1

4.1

2025

2.0

2.1

2.3

4.0

4.0

4.0

4.0

2023
Forecast
2024
2026
2027
2028
2029
2030
2031
2032
2033
2034

3.1

1.3
2.0
2.0
2.0
2.1
2.2
2.2
2.2
2.2
2.2

2.6

2.3
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1

3.2

2.5
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3

3.6

4.0
3.9
3.9
3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8

3.8

4.1
3.9
3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8

5.1

5.1
3.3
3.1
2.9
2.8
2.8
2.7
2.7
2.7
2.7

4.0

4.4
3.9
3.8
3.8
3.7
3.7
3.7
3.7
3.7
3.7

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Bureau of Labor Statistics; Department of the Treasury; Office of Management and
Budget; CEA calculations.
Note: The forecast is based on data available as of November 3, 2023; actual data for 2023 arrived later. The interest rate on 3month (91-day) Treasury bills is measured on a secondary-market discount basis.
2024 Economic Report of the President

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 101

informing many Federal agencies’ budget projections and forecasted tax
revenues.
All economic forecasts are subject to considerable uncertainties that
affect the range of potential outcomes. As the forecast was finalized, prominent sources of uncertainty included supply chain disruptions, progress on
disinflation, rising interest rates, and geopolitical issues that risked spillover
effects on the global trade of essential commodities. In a change from recent
years’ forecasts, the COVID-19 pandemic is no longer expected to be a
major impediment to economic growth. Vaccinations, increasing immunity,
and new treatments have combined to stabilize fatalities, which averaged
206 per day during 2023, down from daily averages of 1,255 and 670 during
2021 and 2022, respectively (CDC n.d.).
In the first full forecast year, 2024, real GDP is expected to grow at
1.3 percent, lower than the potential rate, as interest rates remain high and
inflation recedes. Starting in 2025, the President’s policies on infrastructure,
care, human capital, and immigration reform are expected to increase the
growth rate of both potential and actual GDP. During the budget window’s
final five years, beginning in 2030, the forecast accounts for the decreasing
downward pull on the labor force participation rate stemming from the baby
boom generation’s retirements. Because of the boost from the President’s
policies, together with the diminishing downward demographic pull, potential GDP growth is expected to be stronger relative to the period 2006–23.
The inverse relationship between the change in the unemployment rate
and the growth rate is known as Okun’s Law.21 Figure 2-35 shows the fourquarter change in the unemployment rate against the five-quarter change in
real output. This relationship accounts for 83 percent of the variance in the
unemployment rate from 2006 through 2022.22 The rate of real potential
output growth is estimated as the rate of real GDP growth consistent with
a stable unemployment rate—represented where the regression line crosses
the x axis, at 1.73 percent, with a standard deviation of ±0.2 percentage
point.
The consensus view of potential real GDP growth during the next 11
years is similar to this backward-looking, Okun’s Law–based estimate (figure 2-35). Expected year over year growth averages 1.8 percent in the Blue
Chip panel’s latest survey of private professional forecasters’ long-term
expectations in October 2023. The Administration’s forecasted pace for
Former CEA Chairman Arthur Okun proposed what came to be known as Okun’s Law in 1962
(Okun 1962). When GDP grows faster than its potential rate, the unemployment rate falls, and when
real output grows more slowly than its potential rate, the unemployment rate rises. In its simple firstdifference specification, Okun’s Law takes the form ΔUR = β(y* – y), where ΔUR is the change in
the unemployment rate, and y* and y are the rates of potential real GDP growth and of actual real
GDP growth, respectively. β and y* are estimated coefficients, where β should be between 0 and 1,
and y* is the estimated rate of potential real GDP growth.
22
Complete data for 2023 were not available when this Report went to press.
21

102 |

Chapter 2

Figure 2-35. Estimation of Potential Output Growth by Okun's Law, 2006–22
Four-quarter change in the unemployment rate (percentage points)

4.00
3.00
2.00

ΔUR = 1.30 – 0.76 * (%GDO)

2020

R² = 0.83

2009

ΔUR = 0.76 * (1.73 – %GDO)
(0.09) (0.18)

2008

Potential GDO growth = 1.73%

1.00
2007

0.00

2016

2022
2011

-1.00

2015

2013

2019
2017
2012

2018

2006

2010
2014

-2.00
-3.00
-2.00

2021
-1.00

0.00

Council of Economic Advisers

1.00

2.00

3.00

4.00

5.00

6.00

Five-quarter change in real GDO (percent)

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
Note: GDP = gross domestic product; GDI = gross domestic income; GDO = gross domestic output. GDO is the average of
GDP and GDI. The x axis plots five-quarter average growth of GDO through Q4 of each year, with Q4 of year t and Q4 of year
t-1 each receiving 1/8 weights while Q1, Q2, and Q3 receive 1/4 weights.
2024 Economic Report of the President

long-term real GDP growth exceeds the consensus pace, largely because, as
is common practice in Administration forecasts, it anticipates the effects of
growth-inducing policies in the budget that have not yet been enacted, and
possibly because the Blue Chip forecast does not anticipate the diminishing
downward pull of baby boomers’ retirements.

The Near Term
The Biden-Harris Administration expects lower-than-potential output in
2024, reflecting ongoing fiscal consolidation and the legacy of tight monetary policy. Real GDP growth during the four quarters of 2024 is expected
to be 1.3 percent, slightly slower than the 1.7 percent potential estimate
extrapolated from Okun’s Law, and the unemployment rate is expected to
edge up to 4.1 percent by Q4. Compared with the October 2023 Blue Chip
consensus forecast (the latest available when the Administration finalized its
forecast) of 0.9 percent real GDP growth, and a 4.3 percent consensus unemployment rate by the year end, the Administration’s forecast was slightly
optimistic. In comparison, however, with the February 2024 Blue Chip forecast, the latest as this Report goes to press, in which real GDP was revised up
and the unemployment rate was revised down, the Administration’s forecast
is closer to the latest consensus.
CPI inflation is projected to fall further, from an expected 3.4 percent
during the four quarters of 2023 to 2.5 percent during 2024. CPI inflation
tends to run higher than PCE inflation; thus, a 2.5 percent CPI inflation
rate is roughly consistent with a 2.2 percent PCE inflation rate. Inflation, as
The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 103

measured by the price index for GDP, meanwhile, is expected to fall from a
forecasted 3.0 percent rate during 2023 to 2.3 percent during 2024.
As inflation descends back to the target, the unemployment rate drifts
up slightly, reaching a peak of 4.1 percent in 2024:Q4. The unemployment
rate is then expected to edge lower, eventually falling—by 2027:Q4—to
3.8 percent, the rate that the Administration considers to be consistent with
stable inflation in the long term.
Yields on 10-year Treasury notes rose about 1 percentage point from
May 2023—when the previous (Mid-Session Review) Administration
forecast was finalized—to early November 2023, when the fall forecast
was finalized—even though, as discussed above, long-term rates retraced
much of that increase by the end of 2023. The Administration has therefore
substantially increased its near-term (2024) forecast of two interest rates—
those for the 91-day Treasury bill (T-bill) and for the 10-year Treasury note.
These interest rates are expected to average 5.1 and 4.4 percent, respectively, in 2024, representing a decline from their October 2023 levels, a bit
less of a decline than that projected by the Blue Chip consensus panel in
October. The implicit forecast from the October futures market was similar
to the Administration’s forecast of T-bill rates in 2024, but the futures
market implicitly forecasted higher yields on 10-year Treasury notes. The
Administration expects these interest rates to slowly decline over the first
five forecast years, eventually plateauing at 2.7 percent for the T-bill and
3.7 percent for the 10-year Treasury note, rates that are slightly higher than
the Blue Chip consensus of 2.6 percent and 3.5 percent, respectively, but
are substantially lower than what was reflected in October 2023 values from
market futures.
Although the Administration has substantially increased its forecast
of output growth in 2023 relative to the Mid-Session Review, the effect on
real GDP is partly offset by downward revisions to expected growth in 2024
and 2025. After adjusting for the September 2023 benchmark revision to
the National Income and Product Accounts, the level of real GDP has been
upwardly revised (relative to the Mid-Session Review) by about 1 percent
from 2025 and thereafter.23

The Long Term
In contrast to the near-term outlook, the Biden-Harris Administration’s
long-term forecast for real GDP growth exceeds the Blue Chip consensus
forecast by an average of 0.3 percentage point a year during the 10 years
between 2025 and 2034. As is the common practice in the Administration’s
forecasts, the forecast assumes that the President’s proposed economic
Because the benchmark adjustment to real GDP has affected levels and growth rates since 2012,
the calculations here cumulate growth rates only since 2022:Q4.
23

104 |

Chapter 2

Figure 2-36. The Evolution of the U.S. Population’s Age Composition
Baby boom cohort

Millions of people
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0

0

5

10

15

20

25

2012

Council of Economic Advisers

30

35

40

45

50

55

Years of age
2023

60

65

70

75

80

85

90

95

2034

Source: Social Security Administration.
Note: The U.S. Social Security population differs slightly from the U.S. civilian noninstitutional population.
2024 Economic Report of the President

policies—including a range of programs to enhance human capital formation, provide childcare, and reform immigration policy—will be enacted,
modestly boosting the average annual rate of potential real GDP growth
during the period 2030–34.
Demographics affect the long-term forecast in several ways (figure
2-36). The Administration recognizes that the baby boom cohort’s retirements are likely to wane during the last seven years of the budget window
(2028–34), easing the downward pressure on labor force participation. This
pressure began in 2008, when the oldest baby boomers (those born in 1946)
first reached the Social Security early retirement age of 62, and this downward pressure for continued declines in the participation rate will have been
almost halved by 2028, when the youngest members of the cohort turn 66.
During the past five years, this demographic force has lowered the growth
of the labor force participation rate and potential real GDP growth by about
0.4 percentage point a year; but during the period 2029–34, the downward
force is expected to lessen to only about 0.2 percentage point a year—an
improvement of 0.2 percentage point (chapter 3 provides an in-depth analysis of these demographic trends).
The supply-side components of long-run growth are shown in table
2-3, over both history and forecast.24 The civilian, noninstitutional population age 16 years and above is expected to grow by an average annual rate
Because many components of these growth rates are erratic in the short run, table 2-3 documents
historical growth rates for long intervals from business-cycle peak to business-cycle peak. The
exception is column 5, the interval between the last business-cycle peak, for 2019:Q4 through
2023:Q3 (the last available quarter when this forecast was finalized).

24

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 105

Table 2-3. Supply-Side Components of Actual and Potential Real Output Growth, 1953–2034
Component

1953:Q2 to
2019:Q4

1990:Q3 to
2001:Q1

(1)

(2)

1

Civilian noninstitutional population, age 16+

1.4

1.2

3

Employed share of the labor force

0.0

0.1

2
4
5
6
7

Labor force participation rate

0.1

Growth Rate (percentage points)
2001:Q1 to
2007:Q4

2007:Q4 to
2019:Q4

2019:Q4 to
2023:Q3

2023:Q3 to
2034:Q4

1.1

1.0

0.6

0.7

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

0.1

–0.3

–0.3

–0.2

–0.1

0.1

0.1

0.0

0.0

Average weekly hours (nonfarm business)

–0.2

0.0

–0.2

–0.1

–0.2

0.0

Output per worker differential: GDO vs. nonfarm

–0.3

–0.3

–0.6

–0.4

0.4

–0.2

Output per hour (productivity, nonfarm business)
Sum: Actual real GDO

2.1

3.0

2.4

3.5

2.4

2.4

1.5

1.8

1.3

1.8

Council of Economic Advisers

1.7

2.0

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Bureau of Economic Analysis; Department of the Treasury; Office of Management and Budget; CEA calculations.
Note: GDP = gross domestic product. Gross domestic output (GDO) is the average of GDP and gross domestic income. Real GDO and real nonfarm business output are measured as the
average of income- and product-side measures. The output-per-worker differential (row 6) is the difference between output-per-worker growth in the economy as a whole (GDO divided
by household employment), and output-per-worker growth in the nonfarm business sector. All contributions are in percentage points at an annual rate. The forecast jumps off from data
available on November 3, 2023. The total may not add up due to rounding. The periods 1953:Q2, 1990:Q3, 2001:Q1, 2007:Q4, and 2019:Q4 are all quarterly business-cycle peaks.
Population, labor force, and household employment have been adjusted for discontinuities in the population series.
2024 Economic Report of the President

of 0.7 percent from 2023 to 2034, which is below the average 1.0 percent
annual growth rate from 2007 to 2019.25 Much of this expected growth is
likely to result from immigration.26
The demographic factors weighing on the labor force participation
rate’s continued decline will be largely offset over the projection period
by the Administration’s human capital and childcare policy proposals. The
workweek is, meanwhile, projected to stabilize after a long period of decline
driven by the entry of women into the workforce and the declining share of
manufacturing in total employment. These factors are less likely to dominate
the path of the workweek than in past years.
The employed share of the labor force is projected to remain close to
its current level, and therefore makes no net contribution over the forecast
horizon. Productivity growth (measured as output per hour) is projected to
grow at an average 1.7 percent a year over the 11-year forecast interval,
somewhat more slowly than its 2.1 percent long-term average but faster
than the 1.5 percent growth rate during the 2007–19 business cycle. Finally,
the output per worker differential—the difference between the output per
person for the economy as a whole and the output per person in the nonfarm
business sector—is expected to be negative, which largely is a consequence
of the national income accounting convention that productivity does not
grow in the government or household sectors. Although the differential is
therefore most often negative over long periods, it is projected here to be
less negative in the projection period than over the other long periods given
The civilian, noninstitutional population excludes individuals who are incarcerated or are
living in mental health facilities or homes for seniors, or who are on active duty in the Armed
Forces. Projected population growth rates are sourced from demographers at the Social Security
Administration (2023a).
26
See the forecast from the Office of the Social Security Actuary at the Social Security
Administration (2023b).
25

106 |

Chapter 2

in the table, because of the projected declining share of government in total
output.
The real GDP forecast represents the sum of three primary layers: (1)
a baseline projection, developed through an Okun’s Law analysis; (2) an
adjustment to this baseline to accommodate the labor force participation rate
differing during the forecast interval from its behavior during the estimation
interval; and (3) an increase to potential GDP growth to reflect the effects
of the Administration’s pro-growth policies. When the baseline projection
of 1.7 percent potential growth, the 0.2-percentage-point adjustment due to
the baby boom cohort’s retirements slowing, and the 0.3-percentage-point
increase attributable to pro-growth Administration policies are summed, this
results in the Administration’s projected 2.2 percent a year real GDP growth
rate during the budget window’s final five years.

The Year in Review and the Years Ahead

| 107

108 | 

Chapter 3

Population, Aging, and the Economy
Death rates in the United States have declined over the past century, leading Americans to live longer, healthier lives, on average, than ever before.
Birthrates have declined, as well, though less steadily and with a short-lived
increase in the mid-20th century.
Declining birthrates and death rates arose in the context of expansions in
educational and labor market opportunities, progress toward gender equity,
and technological advancements in medicine and public health. Today, they
imply a slowing of U.S. population growth that is unprecedented in the
country’s history.
The impact of this and the other demographic trends that are the subject of
this chapter will have important effects on our Nation and our economy.
They form the backdrop for how the subjects of other chapters in this
Report—such as the labor market, artificial intelligence, climate, and housing—will play out. How these changes affect Americans will depend on the
Nation’s institutions and policy environment. Some demographic trends call
for immediate responses. Increases in drug overdose deaths and worsening
maternal mortality are urgent issues that demand decisive action. Other
demographic patterns—like the decline in U.S. fertility to historically low
levels and the growth of seniors’ share of the population—are important to
understand to help the Nation anticipate, plan for, and manage the changes.
An aging population implies fiscal challenges for social safety net programs—like Medicare, Medicaid, and Social Security—as the working
share of the population declines. Low fertility also implies that immigration
policy will play an increasingly important role in shaping the growth and

109

composition of the U.S. population and labor force. Without positive net
migration, the U.S. population is projected to begin shrinking by about 2040
(U.N. DESA 2022a; CBO 2024).
This chapter begins by describing fertility and mortality trends and their
causes. Some trends, like the acute spike in deaths during the COVID-19
pandemic, are short-lived. Others, like the trend toward smaller families and
childlessness in American households, are likely to persist due to diffuse and
slow-moving social, political, and economic changes. The persistent trends
imply that the U.S. population will continue to age, and the chapter discusses
what the aging U.S. population will mean for the U.S. labor force, consumer
demand patterns, productivity, saving and borrowing, the care economy, and
the fiscal future.

Declining Fertility in the 21st Century
The United States has experienced a sharp decline in birthrates since 2009.
This decline mirrors trends among other advanced economies in recent
decades. A trend toward smaller families has been widespread among
Americans, with U.S. women from varied backgrounds and demographic
groups choosing to have fewer children and waiting until later in life to
have them than at any other time in the country’s history (Aragão et al.
2023; Smock and Schwartz 2020). This section describes these trends and
their economic causes in order to better anticipate whether these patterns
are temporary or likely to persist over the coming decades. A key theme of
this section is that the widespread, long-run declines in U.S. birthrates—and
birthrates worldwide—are rooted in improvements in living standards,
wages, and opportunities.

U.S. Fertility Since the Global Financial Crisis
Declining U.S. fertility is not new, but rather the continuation of a long-run
trend that accelerated after the global financial crisis (Bailey and Hershbein
2018).1 An intuitive summary measure of fertility is the total fertility rate
(TFR), which describes the number of children a woman would have if she
followed the age-specific childbearing patterns in her country at a given
point in time. For example, a TFR of 2.0 would indicate that over a lifetime,
“Fertility” in this chapter refers to measured birthrates. It is separate from the medical concept of
“infertility.”

1

110 |

Chapter 3

Figure 3-1. Fertility Rates by Race and Hispanic Origin, 2003–22
Annual births per 1,000 women

120
100
80
60
40
20

0
2003

2005

2007

Hispanic or Latino

2009

2011

Non-Hispanic white

2013

2015

2017

Non-Hispanic Black

2019

2021

Non-Hispanic Asian

Council of Economic Advisers

Source: Centers for Disease Control and Prevention WONDER.
Note: Annual births per 1,000 women age 15–44 years in the given year. Race and Hispanic origin refer to the
mother. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

a woman following the typical patterns of birth in her place and time would
have two children. Any TFR below 2.0 is known as “subreplacement,”
meaning that the population would eventually shrink in the absence of
migration.2
The U.S. TFR fell from 2.12 in 2007 to 1.67 in 2022 (Hamilton,
Martin, and Ventura 2009; Hamilton, Martin, and Osterman 2022). The
decrease after the global financial crisis was driven more by a decline in the
number of families with any children than by shrinking family sizes among
those with some children (Kearney, Levine, and Pardue 2022). The pattern
coincides with broad societal changes in marriage and childbearing norms
(Parker and Minkin 2023).
The decline in fertility has been across all groups defined by race,
ethnicity, and nativity. However, before the global financial crisis, some
demographic groups differed significantly in fertility rates. In 2007, fertility rates among Hispanic women were about 40 percent higher than those
of Black, non-Hispanic women and about 60 percent higher than those of
white, non-Hispanic women. By 2019, the rates had largely converged (see
figure 3-1).
Figure 3-2 shows that women today are more likely to delay childbearing than their predecessors. The figure plots age-specific fertility rates (i.e.,
“Replacement-level fertility” is slightly above 2.0 and varies across time and place. It accounts for
naturally occurring sex ratio imbalances at birth and the fact that not all people will survive through
their childbearing years. In all places and times, fertility below 2.0 is subreplacement.

2

Population, Aging, and the Economy | 111

Figure 3-2. Age-Specific Fertility Rates Over Time
Annual births per 1,000 women

120

90

60

30

0
10–14
years

15–19
years

20–24
years

Council of Economic Advisers

1980

25–29
years

30–34
years
2000

35–39
years

40–44
years

45–49
years

2020

Source: National Center for Health Statistics.
Note: National births per 1,000 women for each age group. In the periods plotted, all States are represented.
2024 Economic Report of the President

annual births per thousand women observed in each age group), indicating
how the childbearing age profile has shifted rightward over the past several
decades. As recently as 2006–11, age-specific fertility was highest in the
25–29 age group (Erbabian, Osorio, and Paulson 2022). As of the latest data
from 2022, the rates are highest among women age 30–34. Overall, figure
3-2 implies both fewer births and an older average maternal age when giving
birth in 2020, relative to past decades.
Figure 3-2 shows that fertility among women in their late 30s and
40s has been climbing for the past four decades. With improved access to
contraception and the growth of assisted reproductive technology (ART)—a
blanket term referring to medical procedures designed to help achieve a
pregnancy (CDC 2019a)—more women are having children at later ages.
The growth of and access to ART help women and families achieve their
desired number of children, including later in life. In 2020, more than 74,000
(2 percent) of the roughly 3.6 million infants born in the United States were
conceived with ART (CDC 2022). The number of healthy women who froze
their eggs, an approach to delaying childbearing, rose from roughly 7,000
in 2016 to about 12,000 in 2020, a more than 70 percent increase (Kolata
2022). Based on growing ART use in other advanced economies (Chambers
et al. 2021; Lazzari, Gray, and Chambers 2021), this technology is likely
to play an increasingly important role in the United States, enabling some
women to achieve their desired families at older ages and helping some

112 |

Chapter 3

Figure 3-3. Total Fertility Rate in the United States and Other HighIncome Countries and Regions, 1950–2021

Annual live births per woman

7
6
5
4
3
2

Replacement level (2.1)

1
0
1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020
United States
Canada
Japan
Eastern Asia
Europe

Council of Economic Advisers

Source: United Nations, World Population Prospects 2022.
Note: Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

young women delay childbearing with greater assurance of eventual successful pregnancies.

Low Fertility: A Global Trend
Though the recent downturn in birthrates since the global financial crisis has
attracted significant attention, U.S. fertility has declined over a much longer
span. Figure 3-3 plots TFR for the United States, Canada, Japan, Eastern
Asia, and Europe. The figure shows that the rate has decreased in the United
States, from roughly 3.6 in 1960, near the peak of the U.S. baby boom, to
about 1.7 in 2021 (U.N. DESA 2022a).
The U.S. trend is in line with global fertility rate declines. In the mid–
20th century, global TFR was 4.9. The global average has decreased to 2.3
children per woman in 2021 (U.N. DESA 2022a). Two-thirds of the global
population is estimated to now live in a country with below-replacement fertility (Spears 2023), and the world population is projected to begin shrinking
this century (Spears et al. 2023; U.N. DESA 2022a). The overall global fertility rate masks large variations across countries in both their current levels
and transition paths, with the advanced European and East Asian economies
displaying lower fertility than average.3
The social, political, and economic implications of China’s low fertility have garnered significant
attention, particularly in 2023, when its total population was surpassed by India’s (U.N. DESA
2023). But low fertility is a global phenomenon, and today even India’s fertility is below
replacement level (Spears 2023).

3

Population, Aging, and the Economy | 113

The experiences of other advanced economies offer clues to the
United States’ potential demographic future. In Europe, TFR declined
from 2.7 in 1950 to 1.5 in 2021 (U.N. DESA 2022a). Since late in the 20th
century, some of the world’s lowest fertility rates have been found in major
Asian economies. China, South Korea, and Japan—countries with diverse
economic, policy, and social environments—are all characterized by low
fertility rates today. Japan, with a TFR of 1.3, has been below replacement
level for decades, along with Brazil, Canada, Chile, Germany, Thailand, and
others.
Other countries’ historical experiences are evidence that low fertility
rates do not automatically rebound. The average fertility rate in Europe
slowly declined in the second half of the 20th century. More recent trends
suggest that the United States is also converging toward the general pattern
of subreplacement fertility typical in high-income countries. Although 2021
U.S. fertility rates remained above those of European and East Asian countries, the global demographic trend suggests that U.S. rates may continue to
decline in coming decades (PWI 2023).

Opportunity Cost
Decisions over whether and when to be a parent and what type of family to
build are deeply personal and complex. Among adults without children who
reported that they probably will not ever have children, survey evidence
from Pew reveals diverse, multilayered explanations for not wanting children, some based on difficulties or constraints. Respondents listed financial
reasons, medical reasons, concerns over the state of the world, and concerns
over climate change (Brown 2021). (See box 3-1 for a discussion of how
slowing U.S. population growth relates to current climate challenges.)
Respondents who were already parents offered similar reasons, along with
age, for not wanting more children. Yet the most common answer given in
both groups was that these adults simply did not want to have children (or
to have more children).
Economic analysis, even if it cannot capture the full texture of these
decisions, can be helpful in understanding some of the underlying forces
driving fertility trends. Decisions about having children are, after all, in part
economic. Research suggests that birthrates are mostly pro-cyclical, rising
in economic expansions and declining during downturns. But temporary
economic conditions like recessions primarily affect when women have
children, rather than how many they have over their lifetime or if they have
them at all (Sobotka, Skirbekk, and Philipov 2011). Similarly, although
media and popular sources suggest that children’s direct costs explain falling birthrates (e.g., Picchi 2022; Hill 2021), researchers have found that
rising costs for housing and childcare, while certainly having an impact on

114 |

Chapter 3

Box 3-1. Climate and Population Growth
The past century has been a period of rapid growth in productivity, living
standards, and population size in the United States and globally. It has also
been a period of unprecedented increases in greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions from fossil fuel combustion, agriculture, and land use changes. The
economics of reducing greenhouse gas emissions are more fully discussed
in chapter 6 of this Report. This box focuses narrowly on how policy can
decouple population size from environmental harm and explains why
slowing population growth is no reason to relent on policy efforts aimed at
reducing GHG emissions and climate harms.
The elasticity of emissions with respect to population size (i.e., how
much emissions increase for each additional person) has never been constant,
in part because it interacts critically with environmental policies, which are
continuously changing the relationship between population size, prosperity,
and environmental harm. For example, the Montreal Protocol, which was
joined by the United States and 45 other countries in 1987, has dramatically
reduced U.S. chlorofluorocarbon emissions that had been depleting the protective stratospheric ozone layer (EPA 2007). Similarly, the U.S. Acid Rain
Program—a part of the 1990 amendments to the Clean Air Act—reduced
U.S. sulfur dioxide emissions by 94 percent from 1990 to 2021. As of 2022,
the emissions, which had contributed to air pollution and acid rain, were at
their lowest point ever (EPA 2022). These successes demonstrate that when
the United States and other governments choose to confront environmental
challenges, a choice the Biden-Harris Administration has explicitly made,
policy can significantly reduce linkages between population and environmental degradation.
The slowing and eventual reversal of global population growth that
analysts forecast (Spears 2023) does not relieve the United States of the
urgent need for environmental policy actions. While slowing population
growth implies decreased emissions relative to a higher-fertility counterfactual, the demographic change is not large enough in magnitude to substitute
for decisive policy action on GHGs (Kuruc et al. 2023).
Because of policy action today, led by the Biden-Harris Administration,
the emissions elasticity with respect to population will continue to shrink in
coming decades. The Inflation Reduction Act, which was signed into law
by President Biden in 2022, is the most ambitious investment in combating
the climate crisis to date. Together with the Bipartisan Infrastructure Law of
2021 and other enacted policies, it will help to lower U.S. GHG emissions to
an estimated 40 percent below their 2005 level by 2030 (DOE 2022). These
and other climate-focused Administration initiatives will fundamentally
alter how Americans and U.S. economic activity affect the environment. A
child born today is expected to live through 2100. The carbon footprint of
that lifetime will be influenced by energy, transportation, agriculture, and
land-use policy choices made now.

Population, Aging, and the Economy | 115

families, cannot account for the decline in fertility rates in the United States
(Kearney, Levine, and Pardue 2022).
Researchers have long sought to understand the economic determinants
of fertility. Canonical work by Gary Becker (1960) understood individuals’
or families’ demand for children as weighing the personal satisfaction that
children bring parents against the time and monetary opportunity costs of
parenting. Becker’s insights remain relevant today, although the conceptual
framework of opportunity costs is not sufficiently precise to make quantitative predictions about how particular changes in educational opportunities
or wage rates will affect a country’s TFR. Nonetheless, this understanding
is consistent with birthrates falling over time in places where real income
has risen relatively quickly (PWI 2023). Rising real income makes the
cost of inputs like food and shelter more affordable in dollar terms (i.e., an
income effect), while making parenting overall less affordable in terms of
the opportunity cost of raising children (i.e., a substitution effect). The two
effects push fertility decisions in opposite directions. Desired and realized
family sizes declining over the last half century suggests that the substitution
effect has dominated.
In the United States, young women’s labor market expectations have
been transformed dramatically over the last 50 years as part of a revolution
in college and professional degree attainment, labor force participation, and
the rising age of first marriage (Goldin 2004). In concert with these significant social and economic improvements, desires and decisions on childbearing have evolved. Women in their 20s and mid-30s are frequently in crucial
career development periods, which drives up fertility’s opportunity cost
(Goldin and Mitchell 2017). Box 3-2 discusses the relationship between
reproductive autonomy and female labor force participation, and box 3-3
discusses abortion access.
The expansion of opportunities over the past 50 years, including
opportunities to combine and balance career and family, is a significant
social and economic achievement. The Biden-Harris Administration is committed to improving options for working parents. The Administration has
repeatedly called on Congress to create and fund a national comprehensive
paid family and medical leave program, which would support parents’ bonding with a new child by easing the financial pressure to immediately return
to work after a birth or adoption.
Enhancing access to high-quality, affordable childcare is another channel through which policymakers can support working parents and caregivers, particularly women (Herbst 2022; Morrissey 2017). The Biden-Harris
Administration’s efforts and investments in supporting childcare have been
comprehensive. During the COVID-19 pandemic, the Administration allocated a historic $24 billion to the childcare industry through the American
Rescue Plan. A previous analysis by the CEA documented that these
116 |

Chapter 3

Box 3-2. Reproductive Autonomy and
Labor Market Participation
In 1968, only about 30 percent of women age 20 to 21 years said they
expected to be working by age 35. By 1975, this share approximately
doubled, to about 65 percent (Goldin 2004). The ability to choose
whether and when to have a child is essential for women’s ability to
fully participate in the market economy. It is thus no coincidence that
the period of rapidly increasing female labor force participation a half
century ago corresponds to a period of rapidly improving reproductive
health care options, especially hormonal birth control and the constitutional right to choose under Roe v. Wade.
A large body of research finds access to reproductive health care
has benefits reaching into the labor market and beyond. These include
reduced teenage pregnancies, delayed marriage, and improved educational attainment (Goldin and Katz 2002; Bailey 2006; Guldi 2008;
Hock 2007; Bailey, Hershbein, and Miller 2012; Boonstra 2014; Myers
2017).
The Biden-Harris Administration believes reproductive rights are
critical to maintaining the social, political, and economic progress of
the past decades. The Affordable Care Act (ACA), by requiring most
plans to cover contraception with no patient cost sharing, significantly
advanced access to contraception (HHS 2022). The Administration has
built on the ACA’s foundation, including by introducing enhanced subsidies for purchasing marketplace coverage in the Inflation Reduction
Act and strengthening the contraception coverage provisions of the ACA
(White House 2023f).

Box 3-3. Abortion Access and Fertility After
Dobbs v. Jackson Women’s Health Organization
Access to reproductive health care is critical for women’s health
and has the potential to affect demographic change. In its 2022 decision
in Dobbs v. Jackson Women’s Health Organization, the U.S. Supreme
Court overturned the precedent of Roe v. Wade, which in 1973 had
recognized a constitutional right to choose. The Dobbs decision enabled
States to enact new restrictions on abortion and newly enforce existing
restrictions, including outright bans (Nash and Guarnieri 2022). Other
States passed legislation to protect and advance access to reproductive
health care, and voters in several States have voted in defense of reproductive rights through ballot initiatives.
More than one in three women of reproductive age (15–44) live
in a State with an abortion ban (Shepard, Roubein, and Kitchener

Population, Aging, and the Economy | 117

2022; Myers et al. 2023). Although these laws vary by State, millions
of women currently live in a State with a total ban; other States may
allow access to abortion in very limited circumstances, such as when a
woman’s health is at risk or when the pregnancy is a result of rape or
incest. In these and other States with abortion restrictions, health clinics
that provide contraception and other essential health services have shuttered, eliminating critical points of care, including for other forms of
reproductive health care (McCann and Walker 2023; Nash and Guarnieri
2022). State bans are also influencing medical professionals’ geographic
decisions over residency and practice plans (Edwards 2023; Woodcock
et al. 2023), adding to the potential for shortages in the obstetrics and
gynecology workforce in these States.
Because State abortion bans have eliminated or severely restricted
access to abortion in many States, many women have been forced to
travel across State lines to get the care they need. Figure 3-i shows the
average travel time faced by women seeking abortion care from certain
restrictive States, based on data from Myers and others (2023). The
figure compares access from March 2022, which was before the Dobbs
decision was issued, to September 2023. Because a large contiguous
block of southern States has abortion bans in effect, travel times to the
nearest provider have more than tripled in several southern States (this
figure does not account for any potential international travel).
Appreciating the historic linkage between access to reproductive
health care and economic opportunities, family formation, and fertility
patterns since the 1970s (Myers 2017; Goldin and Katz 2002), it is
Figure 3-i. Changes in Travel Time to Nearest Provider, 2021–23
Average travel time in driving hours
8
7
6
5
4
3

Change
to 2023

2
1
0

2021

Council of Economic Advisers

March 2021

2023

Sources: Abortion Access Dashboard; CEA calculations.
Note: Driving times have been weighted by the reproductive-age female population. This figure does not account for
potential international travel.
2024 Economic Report of the President

118 |

Chapter 3

important to understand what effects the Dobbs decision could have on
these outcomes. Research has shown that when women are denied an
abortion, that denial has serious consequences for their well-being and
results in adverse financial circumstances and family outcomes (Foster
et al. 2018; Foster 2021; Miller, Wherry, and Foster 2023). For women
who have been able to access abortion care since Dobbs, there may have
been added economic, social, and personal costs due to longer travel,
stress, delay, expense, and time away from work (Lindo and PinedaTorres 2020). Finally, abortion restrictions also pose significant risks for
maternal health, including the health of women who experience miscarriages, ectopic pregnancies, or other pregnancy complications and may
be denied or receive delayed care—ultimately threatening their health
and lives (Howard and Sneed 2023; Sellers and Nirappil 2022).
To address the devastating consequences that the Dobbs decision has had on women across the country, the President has called on
Congress to pass a Federal law restoring the protections of Roe v. Wade
(White House 2022c). In the meantime, the Biden-Harris Administration
has taken executive action to protect access to the full spectrum of
reproductive health care. In the wake of Dobbs, the President issued
two Executive Orders and a Presidential Memorandum directing
a comprehensive slate of actions to protect access to reproductive
health care services, including access to emergency medical care and
medication abortion. In June 2023, the President issued a third Executive
Order to strengthen access to high-quality, affordable contraception, a
critical aspect of reproductive health care (White House 2023g). The
Administration remains fully committed to implementing these directives and defending reproductive rights.
While the effects of the Dobbs decision on the health and wellbeing of women are clear, the loss of abortion access resulting from
the decision may ultimately have only a small effect on birthrates. The
Congressional Budget Office estimates a roughly 1 percent increase in
birthrates annually as a result of the new legal landscape (CBO 2023a).
The relatively small impact on aggregate birthrates is in part due to
anticipated changes in patterns of sexual behavior, contraception use,
and how people access abortion care. Early research analyzing the
effects of the Dobbs decision suggests that roughly three-fourths to
four-fifths of people seeking abortions in the first half of 2023 were able
to obtain them, despite bans (Dench, Pineda-Torres, and Myers 2023).
In the aggregate, early data suggest that U.S. abortions were above preDobbs levels one year after the decision (WeCount 2023), despite the
added hardships and barriers to care erected in States where abortions
are banned.

Population, Aging, and the Economy | 119

funds stabilized employment for childcare workers, reduced out-of-pocket
expenses for families paying for care, and helped hundreds of thousands
of mothers enter the workforce or return to work (CEA 2023a). In the
President’s Fiscal Year 2024 Budget, he called for $400 billion over 10
years to dramatically expand access to childcare for families with young
children, while increasing childcare workers’ pay. Under the President’s
plan, most families would pay no more than $10 per day for childcare. In
April 2023, the President also signed a historic Executive Order directing his
Administration to expand access to affordable, high-quality care and provide
increased support for care workers and family caregivers through existing
Federal programs (White House 2023a).

Mortality: Uneven Progress in the 21st Century
Mortality rates are critical determinants of the population’s age structure,
and thus have an impact on aggregate economic outcomes. But more
importantly, longevity is intrinsically valuable. To quote Cutler, Deaton, and
Lleras-Muney (2006, 97): “The pleasures of life are worth nothing if one is
not alive to experience them.”
U.S. life expectancy has increased by nearly 30 years since the turn
of the 20th century.4 The escape from premature death to longer, healthier
lives is an accomplishment built on improvements in knowledge, nutrition,
sanitation, and public health infrastructure (e.g., childhood vaccinations),
as well as advances in medical science targeting chronic disease (Deaton
2014). Senior Americans are living longer than in past decades, and infant
or childhood death, which was commonplace in the United States a century
ago, is now a rare tragedy. Figure 3-4 charts this progress.5
Although the long arc of progress is clear, longevity improvements have
stalled in recent years. Over the decade before the COVID-19 pandemic, life
expectancy was essentially flat, as shown in the figure 3-4 detail. The stall
does not reflect an upper biological limit on longevity. Life expectancies in
other advanced economies have continued to increase above the U.S. level
(Schwandt et al. 2021; Heuveline 2023). The patterns of U.S. mortality over
the past decade are nuanced. Young and middle-age U.S. adults have experienced mortality setbacks due to increases in deaths from external causes,
including guns, vehicle accidents, and drug overdoses. Gun deaths among
children have risen and are now the leading cause of death among children
For a given population, life expectancy captures how long members of a hypothetical cohort would
live on average if its members were exposed to the population’s mortality risks over their lifetimes.
5
Figure 3-4 shows that the annual variability in life expectancy declined after the 1940s. Reductions
in parasitic and infectious diseases, the introduction of commercially available penicillin, and the
distribution of the first civilian flu vaccines in the United States were all likely contributors. But a
change in how life expectancy data were calculated beginning in 1948 is responsible for some of the
declining variance and renders pre and post comparisons difficult (Smith and Bradshaw 2006).
4

120 |

Chapter 3

Figure 3-4. Life Expectancy at Birth, 1900–2022
Years
90

World War I, 1918 Flu

World War II

COVID-19

80
70
60

Detail: 2010–22

Years
82

50

77

40
30
1900

72
2010

1910

1920

1930

Council of Economic Advisers

1940

1950

Both sexes

1960
Male

1970

2013

1980

1990

2016

2019

2000

2022

2010

2020

Female

Source: National Center for Health Statistics.
Note: The data for 2022 are provisional.
2024 Economic Report of the President

and teenagers 1 to 19 years of age (CDC 2023a). Meanwhile, seniors and
infants have experienced continuing, gradual mortality improvements. The
net effect of these forces, among others, was essentially unchanged male and
female life expectancy for several years before the onset of the COVID-19
pandemic.
U.S. mortality trends are driven by three broad cause-of-death categories: infectious disease, external causes, and chronic illness.6 All three
categories are amenable to public interventions that can help improve longevity, though each requires different policy responses.

Infectious Disease: The Importance of Vaccinations
For much of the past century, deaths from infectious disease have declined.
Influenza and pneumonia deaths per capita have decreased nearly 80 percent
since 1950. Infant and child mortality rates from infectious disease have
been especially responsive to public policy, driven down by childhood vaccinations and other public health infrastructure improvements, including in
sanitation, water filtration and chlorination, and public education on infant
care and hygiene (Cutler and Miller 2005; Cutler, Deaton, and Lleras-Muney
2006; Bhatia, Krieger, and Subramanian 2019). (See box 3-4.)
COVID-19 caused a major setback in infectious disease mortality.
Total U.S. deaths increased by 19 percent from 2019 to 2020 when the
External causes of death, per the definition from the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention
(CDC), include unintentional injury, poisoning (including overdose), and complications of medical
or surgical care (CDC 2019b).

6

Population, Aging, and the Economy | 121

pandemic began, causing life expectancy to fall abruptly (Sabo and Johnson
2022). Life expectancy fell for a second year, from 77.0 in 2020 to 76.4 in
2021, before rebounding to 77.5 in 2022 (Xu et al. 2022; Arias et al. 2023).
The United States’ experience in responding to COVID-19 illustrates
the role policy and public health authorities play in controlling infectious
disease. Upon taking office, the Biden-Harris Administration immediately
accelerated and improved vaccine distribution planning, resulting in the
largest adult vaccination program in U.S. history and leading to 270 million
individuals receiving a COVID-19 vaccine by May 2023. Federal efforts
also helped distribute 750 million free COVID-19 tests by shipping them
directly to 80 million households (HHS 2023a).
After the Biden-Harris Administration’s successful vaccine and
booster rollout, COVID-19 deaths slowed dramatically. Today, the public
health emergency seems to be exiting its acute phase. COVID-19 hospitalizations were down 91 percent from January 2021 to May 2023, and
deaths were down 95 percent over the same period (HHS 2023a). At the
pandemic’s peak, weekly COVID-19-related deaths reached almost 26,000.
As of September 2023, this number was about 1,400 (CDC 2023b).
Progress has also continued against other sources of infectious disease
mortality. Respiratory syncytial virus (RSV) is a highly contagious virus
that causes illness and up to 10,000 deaths annually in the United States, primarily among infants and seniors (CDC 2023c). In May 2023, the Food and
Drug Administration approved the world’s first RSV vaccine. It approved
a second vaccine later the same month. These advances promise continued
mortality reductions for infants and senior citizens, including by protecting
infants with vaccines administered to mothers during the in-utero period
(Fleming-Dutra et al. 2023).
Unfortunately, vaccination, one of the most potent tools available to
combat infectious disease, has become politically polarized and surrounded
by misinformation. Vaccine skepticism is also a headwind to continued
improvement in infant and child well-being. Although 88 percent of
Americans maintain confidence in the net benefits of child vaccinations for
measles, mumps, and rubella (Funk et al. 2023), there are worrying signs.
In a poll assessing support for mandatory measles, mumps, and rubella
vaccinations among schoolchildren, the trend was essentially flat at high
levels in recent years for Democratic and Democratic-leaning respondents
but down from 79 to 57 percent between October 2019 and March 2023 for
Republican and Republican-leaning respondents (Funk et al. 2023).
Continuing long-run improvements in the health of American families will require maintaining public health priorities like the Biden-Harris
Administration’s emphasis on childhood and senior vaccinations. Today,
the Administration continues ongoing, cross-agency efforts to combat
misinformation, offering vaccine education and outreach efforts in rural
122 |

Chapter 3

Box 3-4. Infant and Maternal Mortality
The story of early life mortality in the United States is one of continual,
if uneven, progress. Infant mortality—the number of deaths in the first
12 months of life occurring for every 1,000 live births—has declined
since the late 19th century (Lee 2007). In the early 1900s, the infant mortality rate was 100 (CDC 1999), meaning that 1 out of 10 children died in
their first year of life. By 2021, the most recent year for which complete
data are available, the rate had declined nearly 95 percent, to 5.4 (Ely
and Driscoll 2023). Broadening the scope to early child mortality beyond
infancy reveals a similar pattern: At the turn of the 20th century, more
than 20 percent of U.S. children did not live to age 5, while today the
share is less than 1 percent (Gapminder 2022). Figure 3-ii charts infant
mortality since the mid-1990s, showing that the 2022 rate was 19 percent
lower than it was two decades earlier (Ely and Driscoll 2023).
U.S. infant mortality has demonstrated a steady decline over the
past decades and, despite a rise from 5.44 to 5.60 between 2021 and
2022, remains near its historic low. It is still unclear what role the
COVID-19 public health emergency has played in the recent uptick. Yet
the United States lags behind other advanced economies on this metric
(Bronstein, Wingate, and Brisendine 2018). The United States has the
sixth-highest infant mortality rate among countries that belong to the
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD
2021). In 2019, before the COVID-19 pandemic’s health care disruptions and social upheavals, the U.S. infant mortality rate was 5.58 (Ely
and Driscoll 2023). Other advanced economies had infant mortality rates
Figure 3-ii. U.S. Infant Mortality Rate, 1995–2022
Deaths per 1,000 births
8.0
7.5
7.0
6.5
6.0
5.5
5.0
1995

1998

2001

2004

2007

2010

2013

2016

2019

2022

Council of Economic Advisers

Source: Centers for Disease Control and Prevention.
Note: The death rate is deaths per 1,000 live births. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Population, Aging, and the Economy | 123

that were substantially lower; for example, 1.9 in Japan and 3.7 in the
United Kingdom (OECD 2021).
The United States performs similarly poorly in international
comparisons of maternal mortality (i.e., deaths of pregnant and postpartum women for every 100,000 births). Maternal mortality accounted
for about 1,200 U.S. deaths in 2021, compared with about 100,000
overdoses and 700,000 heart disease deaths during the same year. The
rate nearly doubled from 2018 to 2021, going from roughly 17 to 33
deaths per 100,000 live births, though the contribution of COVID-19 to
this trend is yet unclear (Hoyert and Miniño 2023). (Maternal mortality
statistics from earlier years are not directly comparable due to a data
coding change; see NVSR 2020. Previously reported increases in maternal mortality over the period 2002–18 were an artifact of new coding
practices that were slowly diffusing across States, rather than reflective
of an actual worsening of mortality in consistently applied calculations;
see Joseph et al. 2021.)
What explains the relatively poor outcomes for babies and mothers
in the United States? Researchers have noted that cross-country differences in birthweight and gestational age account for a significant share
of the infant mortality gap (Chen, Oster, and Williams 2016). Because
infant health indicators like birthweight are often indicative of mothers’ well-being during gestation, the results point to the importance of
maternal health.
Black women have alarmingly high rates of maternal mortality,
two to three times the rate of white women, and have experienced the
largest increase in the rate in the past several years (Hoyert and Miniño
2023). Poverty contributes to both infant and maternal mortality (Turner,
Danesh, and Moran 2020; Kennedy-Moulton et al. 2023), but, critically,
differences in infant and maternal health across racial and ethnic groups
cannot be explained simply by differential poverty incidence. Elevated
mortality among U.S. Black women and their infants is greater than can
be accounted for by income (Kennedy-Moulton et al. 2023). Research
suggests that a combination of higher likelihood of preexisting conditions, higher likelihood of adverse pregnancy outcomes, and racial bias/
discrimination all contribute to higher Black maternal mortality (Lister
et al. 2019).
Recognizing the importance of maternal health, and the gaps in
our understanding of women’s health more broadly, the Biden-Harris
Administration released a blueprint for addressing maternal mortality
and reducing these disparities in 2022 (White House 2022d).
Progress on maternal health and closing racial mortality gaps is
possible. Black Americans experienced significant mortality improvements across age, sex, and cause-of-death categories during the two
decades beginning in 1990, especially in low-income areas (Schwandt

124 |

Chapter 3

et al. 2021). This progress shrank the Black/white mortality gap even
as white mortality also improved. Improved access to health care is
critical, and the Biden-Harris Administration is committed to improving maternal health and expanding insurance coverage. The American
Rescue Plan, which was signed into law by President Biden, established
a new State option to extend Medicaid coverage for low-income postpartum women from 60 days after childbirth to one year (White House
2021). As of December 2023, 41 States and D.C. have implemented the
one-year postpartum coverage extension, and extensions are pending in
several other States (KFF 2024).

communities (HHS 2021; White House 2022a). The Administration has also
worked to reduce financial barriers to vaccines, including via the Inflation
Reduction Act’s provision to remove cost sharing among Medicare Part
D and Medicaid beneficiaries for all adult vaccines recommended by the
Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC).

External Causes: Setbacks in Midlife Mortality
Whereas infectious disease disproportionately affects the very young and
old, deaths from external causes disproportionately affect older children
and middle-aged adults. This contrast highlights the difficulty in telling a
simple, singular story of mortality trends in America. Today, rates of death
from external causes—which include motor vehicle accidents, homicides,
suicides, and drug overdoses—are rising for young and middle-aged people
in the United States. Drug overdose deaths have risen in recent years to
become the largest category within the external cause group (Lawrence et
al. 2023; CDC WONDER n.d.). In 2021, drug overdoses were the leading
cause of death for Americans between age 25 and 44 and the fourth leading
cause for those between 45 and 64, after cancer, heart disease, and COVID19 (CDC WONDER n.d.).
Figure 3-5 charts changes in mortality across all age groups due to
accidents and overdoses, along with other leading causes of death. External
causes, which have received significant attention due in part to pioneering
work by Case and Deaton (2015), are the largest category of deaths among
individuals between age 1 and 44. The rising trend in overdoses and accidental deaths apparent in figure 3-5 is a matter for serious public concern.
Research has found that the history of widespread legal opioid prescription is driving the present U.S. overdose epidemic (Cutler and Glaeser
2021). The increase in opioid deaths in the mid-1990s was linked to aggressive promotional targeting of OxyContin by pharmaceutical companies to
Population, Aging, and the Economy | 125

Figure 3-5. Selected Leading Causes of Death, 1950–2021
Annual deaths per 100,000 people, age-adjusted

700

Detail: Accidents, Including Overdoses

Annual deaths per 100,000 people, age-adjusted
60

600

50

500

40
30
2000

400

2005

2010

2015

2020

300
200
100
0
1950

1955

1960

Heart disease

1965

1970

Cancer

1975
Stroke

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

Influenza and Pneumonia

2005

2010

2015

2020

Accidents (including overdoses)

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: National Center for Health Statistics; Centers for Disease Control and Prevention WONDER.
Note: Accidents refer to all "unintentional injuries," which include accidental overdoses. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

States with less prescription oversight and more prescribers than their peers
(Alpert et al. 2022; Arteaga and Barone 2023). Researchers further found
that competition for patients among health care professionals led to looser
opioid prescriptions (Currie, Li, and Schnell 2023).7
Even as State and Federal policymakers began to recognize opioids’
harm and address their overprescription and abuse, demand for opioids
remained strong because of the group of people already suffering from
addiction. The demand fueled an increased supply of prescription opioid
substitutes—first heroine, and later fentanyl (Giltner et al. 2022; Alpert,
Powell, and Pacula 2018). And the shift in supply to more dangerous illegal
opioids accelerated fatal overdose rates (Lancet 2022).
The Biden-Harris Administration’s National Drug Control Strategy
makes saving lives the Administration’s “North Star” (White House 2022b).
Several medicines approved by the U.S. Food and Drug Administration are
effective in treating opioid use disorder. Seeking and receiving treatment,
including Medication Assisted Treatment, is associated with significantly
improved outcomes (Mancher and Leshner 2019). Promoting widespread
availability of treatment and helping individuals successfully navigate into
treatment is a critical component of the Administration’s strategy. Further,
in March 2023, the Food and Drug Administration approved the first
One paper finds that physicians with stricter prescribing standards become more careful about
prescribing opioids when diversion—the possibility of misuse either by a patient or a different
unintended user—is a risk (Schnell 2022). These findings suggest an important role of physicians
with more lax prescribing standards.

7

126 |

Chapter 3

over-the-counter naloxone nasal spray, which has been shown to be a critical
tool for preventing fatal opioid overdoses (HHS 2023b). In August 2023,
the Biden-Harris Administration announced $450 million in new funding to
tackle opioid-related overdose deaths (White House 2023b); more than $80
million will help rural communities respond to overdose risks (HHS 2023c).

Chronic Disease: Progress Through Innovation and Health Care
Access
Chronic disease still claims the most American lives each year. While external causes of death matter most before age 45, most deaths occur after 45,
when chronic disease dominates as the leading cause. Historically, progress
against chronic disease has depended on advances in medical innovation and
health insurance coverage that makes effective treatment accessible.
Heart disease deaths declined in the second half of the 20th century
(see figure 3-5). Health behavior trends, particularly reductions in smoking,
played an important role (Cutler, Glaeser, and Rosen 2009; CDC 2014;
DeCicca and McLeod 2008; Evans, Farrelly, and Montgomery 1996).
Innovation also led to new medicines to control hypertension and cholesterol
and new treatments like stents and bypass surgeries. Longer lives from fewer
heart disease deaths were initially accompanied by a slow rise in cancer
deaths. Cancer death rates peaked in 1991, both as a consequence of smoking trends (ACS 2023) and because declines in heart disease allowed people
to survive longer, exposing them to additional cancer risk (Honoré and
Lleras-Muney 2006). Since the 1990s, cancer deaths have declined. Still,
the disease remains the second leading cause of death for people age 65 and
above across all race and ethnicity groups and for both men and women.
Progress on chronic disease mortality has been positive, though slow
and uneven, in the past decade. Overall mortality and life expectancy
above age 65 improved from 2010 to 2019, before the COVID-19 public
health emergency. Further progress is possible, and the Biden-Harris
Administration has led several initiatives aimed at addressing chronic disease. President Biden’s Cancer Moonshot initiative affirms the critical work
of continuing progress against cancer, including expanding access to and
technology for screenings, building on the successful human papillomavirus
vaccine to prevent cancers before they start, and strategically allocating
Federal funds. The Cancer Moonshot also expands the U.S. Patent and
Trademark Office’s program to expedite patents for cancer treatment innovations (White House 2023c).
In November 2023, President Biden established the first-ever White
House Initiative on Women’s Health Research (White House 2023d) to
address the consequences of the historic underfunding of research on
women’s health, especially for communities that have been historically

Population, Aging, and the Economy | 127

excluded from research, including women of color and women with disabilities (White House 2023e). The initiative will address midlife health
and chronic conditions connected to aging, among other areas. Decades
of research based on men has led to significant research gaps in women’s
health compared with men’s, masking differences that can be critical for
women’s health outcomes—for example, because women and men experience different heart attack symptoms, traditional diagnostic tools geared
toward men can lead to misdiagnoses for women (Mehta et al. 2016).
Medical treatment can only benefit those who receive it, which
highlights the importance of health insurance coverage for progress on
morbidity and mortality. There is now a large body of research evidence
that health insurance expansions in general—and the specific health insurance expansions created by the Affordable Care Act (ACA) and supported
by the Biden-Harris Administration—have improved health and saved lives.
Earlier Medicaid expansions were found to reduce infant and child mortality (Currie and Gruber 1996; Goodman-Bacon 2018), and researchers have
shown that the ACA’s expansions of Medicaid and Marketplace coverage
have reduced adult mortality (Goldin, Lurie, and McCubbin 2021; Miller,
Johnson, and Wherry 2019). Further, a wider body of work has documented
improvements, resulting from the ACA, in health care access and utilization;
self-reported physical and mental health; chronic disease; and maternal and
neonatal health (Guth, Garfield, and Rudowitz 2020; Soni, Wherry, and
Simon 2020).
The Biden-Harris Administration is committed to ensuring health care
access through expanded insurance coverage. In early 2023, the share of
individuals with no health insurance coverage fell to an all-time low of 7.7
percent (HHS 2023d). Today, Insurance Marketplace enrollment is at an alltime high, thanks in part to the Inflation Reduction Act’s enhanced subsidies
for purchasing coverage.

Aging and the Economy
Birth, death, and net migration patterns determine a population’s age structure. Today, the U.S. population is aging; the age profile of the population
is shifting toward relatively fewer younger people and more seniors than
in past decades. Aging societies present challenges, including in terms of
funding social insurance systems, meeting seniors’ social and infrastructure needs, and adapting to a reduced labor force as a share of the overall
population.
The United States is not alone in facing these challenges. Societies
around the world are aging because of low fertility rates (World Economic
Forum 2022). During the rapid population growth characterizing most of
the 20th century, most advanced economies’ population age distributions
128 |

Chapter 3

were bottom heavy, featuring a large share of young people and tapering
at increasingly old ages. The demographic transition to low fertility and
mortality implies that the United States now faces an age distribution more
heavily tilted toward older ages. The result is an age “pillar,” rather than the
“pyramid” of the past. Figure 3-6 shows the near-term aging challenge the
United States faces. Whereas the over-65 population was 12 percent of the
total in 2000, it is expected to account for 21 percent in 2040.

Confronting Sustained Low Fertility
All forecasts contain uncertainty, which can compound for population projections extending several generations into the future.8 Yet, over time frames
of 10 to 20 years, population projections can be made relatively precisely.9
Unforeseen social and economic changes may affect long-term desired family sizes and mortality rates, but the most likely near future for the United
States is one of sustained low fertility and an aging population, similar to
what is shown in figure 3-6.
Population forecasters do not anticipate a significant rebound in
fertility rates, with the U.N. World Population Prospects’ medium projection estimating U.S. TFR holding at 1.71 by the end of the century (U.N.
DESA 2022b), about equal to the 2022 rate. Similarly, the Congressional
Budget Office (CBO) projects no substantial rebound to above-replacement
fertility. It projects that fertility rates through the middle of the century will
level off at 1.7 (CBO 2024). The Census projects fertility to decline further,
slowly converging to 1.52 over the next 100 years (Census 2023a). While
the United Nations, CBO, and Census differ in the details of their assumptions and methodologies, they all imply a 2040 population pillar like the one
shown in figure 3-6.
There are several convergent reasons to plan for the possibility of
sustained low fertility embodied in these projections. First, the phenomenon
of low fertility is partially rooted in social and economic progress, including
improved educational and labor market opportunities. The direct costs and
opportunity costs of childbearing and parenting are likely to persist. Second,
the projections for the U.S. to remain below replacement are consistent with
earlier fertility trends in Europe and East Asia. Finally, in recent years, U.S.
fertility projections have tended to be revised downward, not upward, over
For example, technological breakthroughs in geriatric medicine could extend longevity beyond
current projections and further invert the age pyramid.
9
Over time frames of 10 to 20 years, the already-existing population tends to determine population
forecast outcomes in predictable ways. For example, there is little room for error in projecting the
number of people 50 years of age a decade from now, based on the population of those 40 today,
given the already-low mortality rates in the relevant age interval. The U.N. population projections
used in this chapter have been shown to be relatively precise (Ritchie 2023) over these forecasting
time frames.
8

Population, Aging, and the Economy | 129

130 |

Chapter 3

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

5–9

5–9

Men

Women

Under 5

Sources: Census Bureau; Congressional Budget Office; CEA calculations.
Note: Data for 2040 are from long-term demographic projections.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Council of Economic Advisers

Under 5

10–14

10–14

15–19

15–19

20–24

20–24

25–29

25–29

30–34

30–34

35–39

35–39

40–44

40–44

45–49

45–49

50–54

50–54

55–59

55–59

60–64

60–64

65–69

70–74

70–74

65–69

Percentage of total men/women by age group

85+

80–84
75–79

-15

B. 2000

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

Men

Women

Percentage of total men/women by age group

-15

Age (years)

75–79

80–84

85+

Age (years)

A. 1960

Figure 3-6. U.S. Age Distributions for Men and Women

Under 5

5–9

10–14

15–19

20–24

25–29

30–34

35–39

40–44

45–49

50–54

55–59

60–64

65–69

70–74

75–79

80–84

85+

-15

C. 2040

-10

-5

Men

0

5

10

Women

Percentage of total men/women by age group

Age (years)

15

time. For example, in 2012 the United Nations projected that long-run U.S.
TFR would converge to 2.0, but updated this to 1.7 in 2022 (U.N. DESA
2012, 2022a). The CBO’s 2019 demographic outlook placed long-run TFR
at 1.9 but updated this to 1.7 in its 2024 outlook (CBO 2019, 2024). The
Census’s 2017 projection included a national convergence to a TFR of 2.0,
but updated this to 1.5 in 2023 (Census 2018, 2023a). For these reasons,
below-replacement fertility in the United States may persist, as it has in
most of the world’s advanced economies. Policy deliberations and decisions
should be made with these dynamics in mind.

A Role for Immigration in Filling Workforce Gaps
One immediate implication of the changing age distribution is a slowdown
in U.S. labor force growth. The size of the labor force is consequential
along a number of dimensions. Because labor force growth and productivity
growth are components of the economy’s capacity growth rate, a labor force
that is growing more slowly implies slower overall growth.10 The labor
force also constitutes a large part of the tax base supporting U.S. entitlement
programs. Between 2023 and 2052, the population age 25 to 54 is projected
to grow at an average annual rate of 0.2 percent, well below its 1 percent
growth between 1980 and 2021. This rate is also below the senior population’s projected 1.2 percent growth between 2023 and 2052 (CBO 2022).
Historically, immigration has contributed to smaller occupational and
geographic labor force gaps. The foreign-born population in the United
States is responsive to local employment shocks and differential employment growth across labor markets (Blau and Mackie 2017), driven by immigrants’ relatively high geographic mobility (Basso and Peri 2020). Since the
COVID-19 pandemic, foreign-born workers have been critical across industries, particularly food services and agriculture (CEA 2023b). They also
help fill essential positions that are often not filled by local workers due to
skill mismatch, among other issues (Hooper 2023), and they facilitate labor
market participation among high-skilled native U.S. women by starting new
companies, creating new jobs, and lowering the price of market-provided
household services (Azoulay et al. 2022; Cortés 2023).
Patterns of recent immigration and U.S. fertility have combined such
that recent labor force growth has been—and anticipated future growth will
be—substantially attributable to foreign-born workers. Between 2000 and
2017, 43 percent of U.S. labor force growth was attributable to immigrants
(Basso and Peri 2020). Immigrants contribute to the U.S. labor force beyond
the proportion of their total numbers because they are more likely to be of
For a fixed productivity growth path, a slower-growing labor force implies lower per capita GDP
growth if the labor force declines as a fraction of the population. In other words, what matters for
GDP per capita is the number of workers per capita, a metric that is declining in an aging population
(see figure 3-8).
10

Population, Aging, and the Economy | 131

Figure 3-7. Total Population through 2100
U.S. population, millions
450
400
350
300
250
200
150
100
1950

1965

1980

1995

2010

Total population

Council of Economic Advisers

2025

2040

2055

2070

2085

2100

Without immigration

Sources: United Nations World Population Projections (2022), medium variant.
Note: The medium variant estimation was used to compute immigration population projections.
2024 Economic Report of the President

working age and have full-time jobs than their U.S.-born peers. In 2016, 78
percent of immigrants were between 18 and 64 years of age; meanwhile,
59 percent of individuals born in the United States were in that age group
(Vespa, Medina, and Armstrong 2020).
Figure 3-7 shows the projected U.S. population with and without
net migration through the end of the century. The population would begin
shrinking within 14 to 16 years in the absence of immigration—in 2038,
based on U.N. projections (pictured); and in 2040, per CBO projections
(CBO 2024). If immigration follows the pattern of past decades, the U.S.
population would reach nearly 400 million at the end of the century.
Overall, immigration generates important net benefits for the U.S.
economy, including through positive effects on productivity, entrepreneurship, and scientific innovation (Hunt and Gauthier-Loiselle 2010; Peri
2012; Prato 2022; Azoulay et al. 2022). Nonetheless, immigration’s costs
and benefits can be distributed unequally among stakeholders and regions
(Hooper 2023). Although most studies have found that the wage effects of
immigrants on natives are small and on either side of zero, immigration may
place downward pressure on the wages of some low-paid workers (Butcher
and Card 1991; Borjas 2003; Card 2009; Peri and Sparber 2009; Ottaviano
and Peri 2012). While the country as a whole benefits from the economic
activity and productivity boost immigration provides, local areas with
recently arrived immigrants or immigrants with relatively lower educational
attainment are likely to face immediate fiscal costs due to lower tax revenue
generated per capita and additional draws on public services, especially

132 |

Chapter 3

Figure 3-8. U.S. Old Age Dependency Ratio through 2050
Number of seniors age 65+ for every 100 people age 20–64
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

2020

2025

2030

2035

2040

2045

2050

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Census Bureau; Congressional Budget Office; CEA calculations.
Note: The dependency ratio is calculated as the number of people age 65 years and over for every 100 people age 20–64.
2024 Economic Report of the President

K-12 education (Edelberg and Watson 2023; Blau and Mackie 2017). The
Biden-Harris Administration recently took steps to extend the Temporary
Protected Status of Venezuelan migrants and accelerate work authorization
processing. This policy ensures that migrants can build sustainable lives and
enter the formal work sector, where they can contribute to State and local
income tax bases.

The Old Age Dependency Ratio: A Race Between Aging and
Productivity Growth
An aging population increases pressure on Federal deficits and debts (Sheiner
2018). As people age and retire, they shift from contributing to government
revenue via taxes paid on labor income to receiving Social Security and
Medicare benefits. The lifecycle patterns and the country’s evolving age
structure complicate issues of fair resource allocation across generations. At
the birth-cohort level, Social Security retirement support pays out roughly
the amount each generation contributes, though progressive redistribution
occurs within generations (Steuerle, Carasso, and Cohen 2004; Steuerle and
Smith 2023). Through Medicare, individuals receive significantly more on
average over a lifetime than they pay in via taxes (Sabelhaus 2023; Steuerle
and Smith 2023), largely because medical technologies and treatments
improve rapidly over time, raising the standard of care and real spending.
Figure 3-8 depicts one of the central forces governing the relationship
between the population’s age structure and benefit program financing. The
old age dependency ratio, defined here as the number of individuals age
Population, Aging, and the Economy | 133

65 years and over for each 100 people age 20–64, has increased rapidly in
recent years with the baby boom generation’s ongoing retirement.11 Between
2024 and 2050, this ratio will increase by 30 percent. After that, it will likely
continue to increase, though more slowly, nearly doubling between 2024
and the end of the century.
The extent of the fiscal challenge posed by the old age dependency
ratio depends not only on the share of working age people in the labor force
but also on workers’ productivity. Labor productivity is measured by the
economic output generated for each hour worked. It grows over time with
human capital improvements, labor-augmenting physical capital, and technological progress, making society wealthier per capita.
How will changes in the U.S. old age dependency ratio likely compare
with changes in productivity growth? Many observers have noted a recent
slowdown in productivity growth (e.g., Syverson 2017; Dieppe 2020),
and some evidence suggests that an aging population decreases the pace
of productivity gains (Maestas, Mullen, and Powell 2016), including by
reducing startup activity (Karahan, Pugsley, and Şahin 2019). Yet even
modest productivity growth could outpace the dependency ratio’s growth.
For example, labor productivity in the nonfarm business sector in 2023 was
1.5 times its value in 2000 (BLS 2023a), meaning that an hour of labor
today produces 50 percent more output than an hour of labor in 2000. This
implies an annualized 1.8 percent rate of real growth over this period. The
Bureau of Labor Statistics projects that labor productivity growth will be
slightly lower, at 1.7 percent, from 2020 to 2030 (BLS 2021). Either growth
rate would dramatically outpace the 30 percent old age dependency ratio
increase expected by 2050, an annualized change of 0.8 percent. Thus, even
very modest labor productivity growth acts as an important countervailing
force to concerns about dependency ratios.12 Box 3-5 discusses the role of
human capital investments in productivity growth.
Economic growth theory suggests that unprecedented U.S. and global
population decline may also have important scale effects. The historical timing of global population growth (over humanity’s long history) corresponds
closely with per capita productivity growth. Growth theorists consider the
link important: “Virtually all theories of economic growth predict a positive
This standard definition of the old age dependency ratio uses available binned age data. It is
meant to proxy, rather than exactly describe, average working lifetimes. For example, it ignores that
the normal retirement age for persons born in 1960 and later is 67 and that age 20 is an imprecise
marker for when full-time labor force participation may begin.
12
Nonetheless, a doubling of labor productivity would not imply that the tax revenue associated with
a single worker could support twice as many seniors. That is in part because living standards and the
costs of maintaining seniors also increase over time. For example, initial Social Security benefits are
wage-indexed to reflect the general rise in the standard of living that occurred during an individual’s
lifetime (SSA 2023a). Thus, real initial Social Security benefits increase over time as productivity
rises.
11

134 |

Chapter 3

relationship between population size and productivity” (Peters 2022, 1).
Specialization, trade, and the nonrival nature of innovation and knowledge
all imply channels running from larger populations to higher per capita living standards (Jones and Romer 2010). A key concept linking larger populations and rising per capita living standards is the production of nonrival
goods (Romer 2018; Jones 2019), which are unique, in that one person’s use
of them does not deplete the amount available to others. Such goods include
knowledge, like germ theory and calculus, and practical inventions, such as
water chlorination, internet communication protocols, and modified RNA
vaccines (the first of which were approved and deployed in response to the
COVID-19 pandemic). The total stock of knowledge and ideas therefore
equals the per capita stock, and a world with a declining population may
miss out on some critical innovations that make everyone better off (Jones
2022).
Declining population numbers also affect the intrafamily burden of
care work. Aging populations need care, and the burden often falls on family members. Low fertility implies that a decreasing number of children
and grandchildren can participate in the intergenerational compact of family care. For example, if the United States held at its present TFR of 1.66
indefinitely, then an average of 0.7 grandchildren would be born for every
grandparent in the long run. This would be a different future of care than the
past generations of Americans have experienced, on average. Technological
advances, including artificial intelligence, may someday ease the strain, but
the human burden of care remains an unsolved problem today (see box 3-6).

Aging and the Fiscal Outlook
Social Security and Medicare are the two main Federal assistance programs
for seniors in the United States, though Medicaid plays an increasingly
important role in long-term care as the payer for 6 in 10 nursing home residents (CBPP 2020). Entitlement programs are projected to be an important
driver of long-term increases in fiscal outlays over the next three decades,
accounting for more than 40 percent of noninterest spending in 2053, up
from less than 30 percent in 2023 (CBO 2023b).
Today, Social Security provides income support to roughly one-fifth
of the population, or 67 million beneficiaries. By 2050, about one-quarter
of the population is expected to receive benefits, boosting Social Security
spending to 6 percent of gross domestic product (GDP), up from 5.2 percent
currently (SSA 2023b).
As a growing share of the population transitions from the labor force
to retirement, total Medicare costs will also rise. Roughly one-third of the
projected increase in health care program expenditures as a share of GDP
through 2053 will be attributable to the population’s aging (CBO 2023b).

Population, Aging, and the Economy | 135

Box 3-5. Investing in Productivity
through Human Capital
As the ratio of workers to the overall population declines due to age
structure changes in the United States, the Biden-Harris Administration
is committed to policies that accelerate productivity growth, facilitating
more real output despite fewer workers. Investing in human capital via
health and educational inputs during childhood is one of the clearest
paths to increased productivity.
Research documents that educational investments in children and
young people raise productivity and contribute to aggregate economic
growth (Valero 2021; Hanushek and Wößmann 2010). High-quality
childcare has also been shown to be important for outcomes such as
school readiness, cognitive skill development, and employment and
earnings in later life (Deming 2009; Duncan and Magnuson 2013;
Campbell et al. 2014; Gray-Lobe, Pathak, and Walters 2022). Similarly,
research has shown that providing health care to children through
Medicaid and the Children’s Health Insurance Program has a positive
impact on human capital and confers long-term benefits (Cohodes et
al. 2016; Brown, Kowalski, and Lurie 2020; Miller and Wherry 2019;
Goodman-Bacon 2021; Arenberg, Neller, and Stripling 2020). Early
investments in human capital tend to compound, meaning that individuals who benefit from early investments gain more from later investment
than they would have otherwise (Cunha and Heckman 2007; Johnson
and Jackson 2019).
Consistent with these findings, a comparative analysis of public
programs shows that policies directly investing in children at young
ages—including via childcare, K-12 education, health care, and housing—offer the highest return on public investment (Hendren and
Sprung-Keyser 2020). These policies tend to increase employment and
earnings later in life, increasing tax revenue and/or decreasing government transfers. For example, even setting aside the direct benefits of
Medicaid to its beneficiaries, Medicaid expansions to children often
more than pay for themselves, affecting beneficiary productivity enough
to net returns in excess of the initial program cost. Analysts estimate that
Medicaid generates up to $2 in discounted future tax revenue for each $1
spent expanding the program to more children (Ash et al. 2023).
Given the productivity returns, investments in children are often
a win-win. The Child Tax Credit is a critical direct investment. The
failure of Congress to respond to the President’s call to renew the
expanded Child Tax Credit for 2022 caused 3 million children to fall
into poverty in 2022 (CEA 2023c). As the United States increasingly
relies on improved labor productivity in the face of an aging population,
disinvestments in children are a costly policy error.

136 |

Chapter 3

Box 3-6. Long-Term Care
Demand for long-term care will be increasingly important as the U.S.
population ages. Today, a mix of paid caregivers in long-term facilities
and in-home and community-based services—as well as informal unpaid
caregivers, who are often family members, friends, and neighbors—provide the country’s senior care (Osterman 2017). The care workforce is
composed of more than 37.1 million unpaid (BLS 2023b) and 4.7 million
paid providers (PHI 2022), with women constituting the majority (BLS
2022). In 2021, family caregivers’ unpaid economic contributions were
valued at $600 billion (Reinhard et al. 2023).
Addressing the needs of the senior population and younger family
members supporting them requires providing better access to affordable
institutional care and continuing to expand home and community-based
services to best accommodate individual preferences.
As the primary payer for long-term care services, Medicaid has
an important role to play. Home- and community-based services have
grown from making up less than 20 percent of Medicaid’s long term
care spending in 1995 to more than 50 percent today (Grabowski 2021).
As of 2020, roughly 75 percent of the 5.6 million Medicaid long-term
care enrollees used services under the home- and community-based
services model (Chidambaram and Burns 2023). The Biden-Harris
Administration has championed expanding home-based options in proposed budgets and Executive Orders. The Administration has also made
historic investments in improving long-term care quality and standards
(White House 2023a).
Long-term care improvements matter not only for seniors and their
loved ones but also for the labor market. Increasing formal care access
and affordability either in an individual’s home or a nursing facility
helps alleviate the burden on unpaid caregivers and improves labor
market participation (AARP 2020; Schmitz and Westphal 2017). With
increased access to formal home-based care, adult children of parents in
need are less likely to drop out of the labor force and more likely to work
full time over longer periods than they otherwise would (Shen 2023;
Coe, Goda, and Van Houtven 2023). One study finds that for every
three daughters with a senior parent receiving formal home-based care
through Medicaid, the substitution to formal care causes one daughter to
work full time who would not have otherwise (Shen 2023). As long-term
care demand rises, the Federal Government must therefore continue
investing in caregiving to improve the senior population’s well-being
and maintain a strong overall labor force.

Population, Aging, and the Economy | 137

Figure 3-9. Annual Medicare Spending per Beneficiary
2021 dollars

20,000

Part D
begins

ACA
passed

15,000

10,000

5,000

0
1967

1972

1977

1982

Council of Economic Advisers

1987

1992

1997

2002

2007

2012

2017

2022

Sources: Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services 2023 Medicare Trustees Report; CEA calculations.
Note: ACA = Affordable Care Act. Per-beneficiary spending is calculated as total expenditures divided by total
enrollment, including Parts A, B, C, and D. Deflated using CPI-U.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Medicare, with 86 percent of its recipients being at least 65 years of age,
is projected to account for more than 60 percent of Federal health expenditures in 2053. Demographic changes will exacerbate budget deficits and
the projected depletion of the Medicare and combined Social Security Trust
Funds beginning 2031 and 2034, respectively (CMS 2023a; SSA 2023c).13
The trust fund calculations, however, rely on assumptions using current
laws. Outside observers have suggested altering program structures in terms
of revenues or benefits (e.g., Lee and Edwards 2002; Sheiner 2018). The
Affordable Care Act of 2010 made such an adjustment via the Additional
Medicare Tax on high earners, and the President’s 2024 budget proposed to
increase taxes on earned and unearned income above $400,000 as part of a
package to further extend Medicare’s solvency (IRS 2024; U.S. Department
of the Treasury 2023).
Against this backdrop, Medicare’s slower-than-expected spending
in the past decade has been a fiscal bright spot. The growth rate in real
Medicare spending per beneficiary declined from 6.6 percent between 1987
and 2005 to 2.2 percent between 2013 and 2019 (CBO 2023c). Figure 3-9
plots how Medicare spending per beneficiary has evolved over the past
several decades.
Several phenomena have contributed to the slowdown in Medicare
cost growth: lower-than-expected growth in prescription drug expenditures,
The combined Social Security Trust Fund refers to the Old-Age and Survivors Insurance Trust
Fund and the Disability Insurance Trust Fund.
13

138 |

Chapter 3

due to both generic drug entry after exclusivity expiration and the introduction of fewer new drugs (CBO 2023c); declines in hospitalizations for acute
cardiovascular events, due in part to more effective medications (Cutler et
al. 2019); a slowdown in the diffusion and adoption of expensive new health
care technologies (Smith, Newhouse, and Cuckler 2022); and the influence
of the ACA (Buntin et al. 2022). In particular, the ACA’s payment reforms
for Medicare providers and private Medicare Advantage insurers were an
important source of savings (White, Cubanski, and Neuman 2014; CEA
2016).
One way to understand the massive importance of this slowdown in
cost growth is to consider the difference in future outlays between a scenario in which per capita Medicare spending is held at a projected real GDP
per capita growth rate of 1.6 percent,14 and a scenario in which per capita
Medicare spending resumes its 1980–2005 growth trend (a 3.5 percent
annualized growth rate). The difference in trajectory, combined with the
Medicare-supported population growing to 87 million by 2050, would add
up to a difference of about $14 trillion (in 2021 dollars) between 2024 and
2050 (CMS 2023b).
Real per capita Medicare spending growth has stalled, but this is
unlikely to persist indefinitely. As medical technology advances, Americans
will expect Medicare to cover expensive new treatments and cures that
extend and improve life. Past growth in treatments and cures has been dramatic. For example, in 1960, when real per capita U.S. health care spending
was less than 10 percent of what it is today (NHEA 2023), no doctor had
ever performed an angioplasty to clear a blocked artery, administered combination chemotherapy to treat cancer, or been able to prescribe a biologic
drug or synthetic insulin. The improvements since then have reduced mortality and allowed people with serious chronic conditions to live flourishing
lives. The coming decades will likely bring similar breakthroughs, and
society must plan for ways to pay for them.
The Inflation Reduction Act is placing and will continue to place downward pressure on the drug component of Medicare spending. It requires drug
companies to pay back Medicare if they raise prices faster than inflation.
And beginning in 2026, Medicare will pay reduced negotiated prices for
some drugs for the first time in the program’s history. This is an important
advance, as the United States has historically paid twice as much as other
advanced economies for the same pharmaceutical products (Mulcahy et al.
2022).15 Figure 3-10 compares drug prices in the United States and other
The projected real GDP per capita growth rate is based on a longer-term projection of the real
GDP growth rate from CBO and population projections from the Census (CBO 2023b; Census
2023b).
15
The U.S. drug prices shown in figure 3-10 reflect estimates of net prices, subtracting estimated
average rebates.
14

Population, Aging, and the Economy | 139

Figure 3-10. Global Prescription Drug Prices, U.S. Net Price Adjustment, 2018

Country-specific prescription drug prices versus U.S. drug prices; index: United States = 100
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0

U.S.

Japan

Canada

Germany

Italy

France

U.K.

OECD

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Office of Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation, Department of Health and Human Services; IQVIA MIDAS;
CEA calculations.
Note: OECD = Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Here, “OECD” means 32 OECD comparison countries
combined. U.S. prices are set to 100. Only some prescriptions sold in each country contribute to bilateral comparisons. In this
figure, U.S. drug prices reflect estimates of net prices, subtracting estimated average rebates.
2024 Economic Report of the President

countries. The IRA-authorized negotiation process will use the United
States’ leverage as an important customer to get concessions on price—just
as other nations have long done, and as the Department of Veterans Affairs
and Department of Defense have done for years (GAO 2013). The list of
drugs subject to price negotiations will expand in the future, driving overall
Medicare drug spending down and narrowing the gap between U.S. drug
prices and those in other advanced economies.

Planning for the Demographic Future
Rates of birth, death, and migration will govern the demographic future of
the United States, with wide-ranging effects (see box 3-7). Acute mortality
crises, including the opioid epidemic and COVID-19, are amenable to policy
solutions, and life expectancy improvements overall will depend on public
health initiatives, medical innovation, and support for public and private
insurance coverage. Future improvements in health and longevity are likely
to move along two axes: (1) addressing the rise in deaths due to external
causes, particularly drug overdoses; and (2) investing in the fight against
chronic disease.
Policy has little direct relationship with birthrates (Brainerd 2014;
Sobotka, Matysiak and Brzozowska 2019). Because low fertility has its origins in improved opportunities, especially among women, it is likely to persist indefinitely. Readiness for the coming demographic changes will require
attention and planning—including realistic assessments of the likely speed
of these changes and of the potential role of immigration in dampening this
140 |

Chapter 3

new demographic transition. Now is the time for U.S. policymakers to seriously confront the implications of shifting population patterns and to plan
responsibly.

Box 3-7. Consumption and Investment
in an Aging Society
As the U.S. population skews older, aggregate consumption patterns
change. Nonhousing expenditures—such as transportation, clothing, and
food purchased away from home—largely follow a hump-shaped pattern over the life cycle; they are lowest during early entry into the labor
force (under 25 years of age), highest during peak working age (from
45 to 54), and decline upon retirement (over 65) (Foster 2015). Health
care consumption, including hospitalizations and prescription drug use,
increases dramatically with age (Hales et al. 2019).
Aging has upstream effects on the labor market, as employment
shifts across economic sectors to accommodate demand changes. The
Bureau of Labor Statistics projects the health care and social assistance
sector will add 2.1 million jobs over the next 10 years, growing faster
than any other sector (BLS 2023c). Health care support occupations are
projected to account for one out of every six new jobs during the coming
decade.
The shifting age distribution also affects aggregate spending, borrowing, and saving. The canonical life-cycle hypothesis model predicts
that people consider their expected income stream and desired onsumption and make informed decisions to smooth lifetime consumption
(Modigliani and Brumberg 1954). The smoothing choices are typically
characterized by demand for borrowing at young ages and saving for
retirement during middle age. These behaviors imply that as people
age, their wealth tends to increase, even excluding the equity of durable
goods like housing and vehicles. Wealth balances typically decline only
at the highest ages, suggesting that the overall aging of the U.S. population has likely increased the aggregate supply of loanable funds.
The cross-sectional expenditure data shown in figure 3-iii confirm
this expectation. In 2022, the rate of saving for consumers under 25 was
essentially zero, on average, according to the Consumer Expenditure
Survey. The rate was higher for middle-aged Americans, peaking at
17.4 percent for those age 45 to 54, and negative for older Americans,
reaching –12 percent for people 75 and above. Research suggests that the
movement of baby boomers into their prime saving years increased the
aggregate saving rate by about 2 percentage points in the period 1980–90
(Dynan, Edelberg, and Palumbo 2009).
Because of its impact on rates of saving and aggregate loanable
funds, demographic change can also influence real interest rates, putting
downward pressure on the natural interest rate as aging cohorts save for

Population, Aging, and the Economy | 141

Figure 3-iii. Savings Rates and Wealth in 2022, by Age Group
Savings ratea

Net worth less durablesb

20%

$140,000

15%

$120,000

10%

$100,000

5%

$80,000

0%

$60,000

-5%

$40,000

-10%

$20,000

-15%

<25

25–34

35–44

45–54

Savings rate (left axis)

Council of Economic Advisers

55–64

65–74

75+

$0

Net worth (right axis)

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
a The savings rate = 1 – Total Expenditures / After-Tax Income in the CEX.
b Median net worth of families with heads in each age range, less housing equity and net vehicle equity (total vehicle value less
total vehicle loan balances).
2024 Economic Report of the President

retirement. In a steady state, cohorts moving through their life cycles
would have no time-varying impact. However, the baby boom generation is disproportionately large, and the United States is transitioning to
increasingly low fertility rates and long lives after retirement, changes
that will affect aggregate outcomes. Carvalho, Ferrero, and Nechio
(2017) argue that life-expectancy increases leading to increased savings
have, in particular, driven down real interest rates. Gagnon, Johannsen,
and Lopez-Salido (2016) estimate that demographic factors are responsible for a 1.25-percentage-point decline in real interest rates in the
United States since 1980. An inflection point exists where the savings
rate declines and wealth begins shrinking, but as figure 3-iii shows,
the declines tend to occur well past age 65. Although the last of the
baby boomers will soon enter the negative-saving life-cycle period, the
process that places upward pressure on interest rates will unfold gradually. Retirees consume only a fraction of their total savings each year,
with the bulk carried forward and reinvested. This implies the current
downward pressure on natural interest rates may therefore persist for an
extended period.

142 | Chapter 3

Chapter 4

Increasing the Supply of Affordable
Housing: Economic Insights and
Federal Policy Solutions
The Biden-Harris Administration believes that every American should have
access to safe and affordable housing (White House 2023a). Where people
live determines their available housing quality and amenities, such as labor
market access, transportation options, schools, protection from crime, environmental quality, and social networks—all of which affect their quality of
life and intergenerational economic mobility (Chetty and Hendren 2018).
However, the housing supply has failed to keep up with demand over the
last several decades, leading to a nationwide shortage of 1.5 to 3.8 million
homes and driving up the cost of housing (Calanog, Metcalfe, and Fagan
2023; Khater, Kiefer, and Yanamandra 2021; Lee, Kemp, and Reina 2022).
As a result, 45 percent of renters are now cost-burdened, meaning that they
spend 30 percent or more of their family income on rent, more than twice the
share who were cost-burdened in 1960 (Ruggles et al. 2023).
Economic analyses of housing markets identify at least two frictions restricting supply: (1) land-use regulations and zoning restrictions that limit what
can be built, and (2) rising input costs associated with construction (Khater,
Keifer, and Yanamandra 2021). While some land-use regulations can be a
reasonable part of community planning—for example, keeping factories
away from schools or ensuring that parks are situated near residential
areas—many other building regulations—for example, limiting housing
density and building heights, or imposing minimum lot sizes or parking
requirements—can create artificial barriers that hinder growth and drive

143

up the cost of housing. These policies arise naturally from a local decisionmaking process that is influenced by homeowners, who prefer higher home
prices, and account for the local costs of increased housing, such as more
congestion, but they fail to account for any regional or national benefits.
This classic market failure negatively affects individuals in neighboring
communities and potential new residents.
The costs of these housing restrictions reach across neighborhoods. Housing
shortages can lead to inefficiently low levels of labor mobility and human
capital investment, affecting both individual well-being and the macroeconomy. Research shows that relaxing local land-use regulations increases
migration, allowing workers to relocate from low- to high-productivity
regions, and boosts aggregate output (Peri 2012; Moretti 2012). Moreover,
homeownership is a wealth-building tool with a long tradition in the United
States, and restrictive housing policies are an important factor explaining
class and racial gaps in wealth and economic outcomes (Rothstein 2017).
Increasing the housing supply, especially when combined with policies that
directly support the production of affordable rental and ownership units, can
increase access and equity for groups with few financial resources, increase
overall wealth, and reduce disparities across groups (Carroll and CohenKristiansen 2021).
This chapter focuses on the major causes and consequences of the United
States’ long-standing shortage of housing—and especially affordable housing—as well as Federal policy’s ability to alleviate these issues. While there
are policy levers at all levels of government, this chapter focuses on Federal
policy. For example, public funds could be tied to zoning reforms and used
to reduce financing constraints for affordable housing developments, and
workforce training could increase the supply of labor used to construct
housing. The first section illustrates the magnitude and trends in the housing
supply shortage over the last six decades. The second and third sections
discuss the causes and consequences of housing shortages. The fourth

144 | Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing:
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

section highlights several areas where Federal policy can equitably boost the
housing supply and alleviate rising housing unaffordability.

Magnitude and Trends
Housing costs are demanding a growing share of household budgets in the
United States. At the same time, the U.S. housing market faces a long-run
supply shortage.
Figure 4-1. Housing Price Index versus Wage Index, 1975–2023
Index: 2000:Q1 = 100

350
300
250
200
150
100
50

0
1975 1978 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 2002 2005 2008 2011 2014 2017 2020 2023
Weekly Wage Index

Council of Economic Advisers

Case-Schiller Housing Price Index

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics (Quarterly Census of Employment and Wages); CEA calculations.
Note: Weekly Wage Index has been smoothed using a 4-quarter moving average. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Unaffordable Housing
Figure 4-1 shows that housing price increases have outpaced wage growth in
the last 20 years. Between 2000 and the early 2020s, housing prices tripled
while household income doubled; in other words, the price of housing rose
by 50 percent more than household income in the last 20 years.1 Of course,
increased spending on housing could be a rational consumption choice.
Some people will choose to spend more on housing in exchange for lower
nonhousing consumption because they prefer better housing amenities, like
Figure 4-1 reports changes in the housing price index. To provide additional context for the level of
rental expenses during this period: the median rent in 1960, 1980, 2000, and 2020 was, respectively,
$544, $692, $867, and $1,086, measured in 2022 dollars; and the 25th percentile of rent in 1960,
1980, 2000, and 2020 was $445, $479, $595, and $735.

1

Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing: | 145
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

a nicer location or a newer structure. But the steadily rising financial burden
of housing over many decades suggests that for many families, expensive
housing is not a proactive choice but rather a trend they are increasingly
forced to accept.
The share of households burdened by housing expenses has risen
steadily over the last 60 years. A common benchmark for describing
rent-burdened households is the income share spent on housing (i.e., rent/
mortgage, utilities, and other housing needs) (Cromwell 2022).2 The U.S.
Department of Housing and Urban Development defines families as rentburdened if this share exceeds 30 percent;3 and severely rent-burdened if
households spend more than half their income on housing. Figure 4-2 shows
the share of renter households that spend more than 30 percent, 40 percent,
and 50 percent of their income on rent. For each measure, the share has
more than doubled since the 1960s. Today, nearly 45 percent of renters are
rent-burdened and nearly 24 percent of renters are severely rent-burdened.
Figure 4-2. Renter Households That Spent More Than 30 Percent of Family
Income on Rent, 1960–2022
Percent
50
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

More than 30 percent

Council of Economic Advisers

1985

1990

1995

2000

More than 40 percent

2005

2010

2015

More than 50 percent

Sources: Census Bureau (American Community Survey); CEA calculations.
Note: The data for years after 2000 are averaged in 5-year bins. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Owners are typically excluded from the cost-burdened analysis because monthly mortgage
payments that reduce the principal are a transfer to savings.
3
This benchmark is based on public housing rent limits, which originated with the Brooke
Amendment in 1969 and were last updated in the 1980s.
2

146 | Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing:
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

2020

The financial burden of housing can also be illustrated by the number
of work hours required to pay for housing. Figure 4-3 reports the minimum
monthly work hours required to pay for monthly median rental rate housing
in 2002, 2012, and 2022. Estimates are shown separately for households
earning the median wage, the Federal minimum wage, and the wages that
put someone at 100 percent of the Federal poverty level for single-adult
households with no children.4 Median wage earners had to work nearly 55
hours to pay for monthly housing costs in 2002, or more than one week per
month based on a 40-hour work week; this number grew to more than 70
hours in 2022, or slightly less than two weeks of work. Households earning the Federal minimum wage had to work 110 hours to pay for housing
in 2002, or nearly three quarters of the monthly hours worked by full-time
workers. This number increased to 180 hours in 2022, suggesting that more
than a full month of minimum-wage work is now required to pay for median
rental-rate housing. In other words, median rental-rate housing has become
increasingly out-of-reach for low-wage workers, and even median-wage
Figure 4-3. Minimum Monthly Hours of Work Needed to Pay for Median
Monthly Rent
Hours

200
180
160
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0

2002

Median wage

Council of Economic Advisers

2012

Federal minimum wage

2022

Federal poverty level

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Census Bureau; Department of Labor; CEA calculations.
Note: Real median rent in 2002, 2012, and 2022, respectively: $923, $914, and $1306. The Federal poverty level is the poverty
level for a single individual with no children. Effective July 2009, the Federal minimum wage was raised to $7.25. Unlike in 2002
or 2012, the Federal minimum wage led to income below the Federal poverty level in 2022.
2024 Economic Report of the President

The minimum number of hours of work required to pay for median monthly rent is calculated as
median monthly rent divided by hourly wage for workers that earn the median monthly earnings, the
Federal minimum wage, or 100 percent of the Federal poverty level. For workers earning the median
monthly earnings or 100 percent of the Federal poverty level, monthly earnings are converted to
hourly earnings by assuming a that an employee works 160 hours per month, a typical full-time
schedule.

4

Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing: | 147
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

Figure 4-4. Share of Households That Are Rent-Burdened by Household Head
Characteristics, 2022
Percent
75
65
55
45
35
25
15
5

Age

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Census Bureau (American Community Survey); CEA calculations.
Note: A household is defined as rent burdened if the share of family income spent on rent is more than 30 percent.
2024 Economic Report of the President

workers must devote a considerable share of their monthly earnings toward
housing expenses. Many households have little disposable income after
paying for housing.
Figure 4-4 reports the share of rent-burdened households by age, race
and ethnicity, marital status, and income in 2022. Younger households are
more likely to be rent-burdened than older households, Hispanic households are more likely to be rent-burdened than non-Hispanic households,
single households are almost twice as likely to be rent-burdened as married
households, and 74 percent of households in the bottom quintile of the
income distribution are rent burdened. Additionally, figure 4-5 reports the
share of rent-burdened households by geographic region and population
density, as well as for households in the largest U.S. cities. While some
variation emerges based on demographic and geographic characteristics,
a large fraction of households across the entire country are rent burdened.
Rent-burdened households are not just located in urban centers or in coastal
States: 45 percent of rural households are rent-burdened, as are 44 and 40
percent of households in the South and Midwest, respectively.

The Housing Supply Shortage
Years of insufficient new construction relative to household formation have
led to a housing supply shortage (Khater, Keifer, and Yanamandra 2021).
Estimates of the stock of the total housing shortage range from 1.5 million
(Calanog, Metcalfe, and Fagan 2023) to 3.8 million (Khater, Keifer, and

148 | Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing:
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

Figure 4-5. Share of Households That Are Rent-Burdened by Geography, 2022
Percent

75
65
55
45
35
25
15
5

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Census Bureau (American Community Survey); CEA calculations.
Note: A household is defined as rent-burdened if the share of family income spent on rent is more than 30 percent. The cities chosen for
the graph are among the largest six cities in the U.S. by population as of 2022. Houston is not shown here as it is not recorded in the
2022 American Community Survey data.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Yanamandra 2021), and the annual flow of the shortage of units under
construction is estimated to be 100,000 (Parrott and Zandi 2021).
Increased housing demand is driven by a growing economy and a
growing population. In recent decades, however, housing production has
fallen dramatically. As figure 4-6 shows, quarterly housing starts per 1,000
people (shown in navy blue) fell from 22–40 units between 1963 and 1980
to 15–21 units between 1990 and 2005. Figure 4-6 also shows quarterly
single-family housing starts in light blue. Single-family housing starts were
relatively flat between 1963 and 2005 (averaging 10–18 units per 1,000
people). All types of housing starts fell sharply after the global financial
crisis and have not yet recovered to pre-2007 levels.
A decline in new housing construction has been concurrent with the
reduced availability of relatively small “starter homes” and low-cost rental
units. As illustrated in figure 4-7, the fraction of all new single-family homes
under 1,400 square feet declined from nearly 40 percent in the early 1970s
to about 7 percent in the early 2020s. Moreover, the supply of low-cost
rental units, measured as the share of rental units with contract rent below
the maximum amount affordable for households in the lowest quintile of the
income distribution, fell from 26.7 percent in 2011 to 17.1 percent in 2021
after adjusting for inflation. This is equivalent to the loss of 3.9 million
affordable units in the last decade (Joint Center for Housing Studies 2023).

Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing: | 149
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

Figure 4-6. U.S. Housing Production, 1963–2022
Housing starts per 1,000 people
40
36
32
28
24
20
16
12
8
4
0
1963

1967

1971

1975

1979

1983

1987

1991

Single-family

1995

1999

2003

2007

2011

2015

2019

All housing types

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Census Bureau; CEA calculations.
Note: The quarterly data are smoothed using a 3-year moving average. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

are

Figure 4-7. Share of New Single--Family Homes under 1,400 Square
Feet,
1973–2022
45
Percent
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
1973

1979

1985

1991

1997

2003

2009

2015

2021

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Census Bureau; CEA calculations.
Note: The data shows the share of completed new single family homes that are under 1,400 square feet. Gray bars
indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Causes of Housing Supply Shortages
The incentives of several key stakeholders inform economic models of housing markets that predict a constrained housing supply. First, homeowners
typically seek to maximize their home’s value. Second, local governments
150 | Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing:
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

have an incentive to raise public funds to maximize the welfare of their
constituents—among other things—which is generally linked to land
value through property taxation. Third, developers and landowners seek to
maximize their profit from economic development of residential and commercial real estate. These incentives jointly determine land value within a
community through zoning and land-use regulations, which generally enrich
insiders (i.e., existing property owners) at the expense of outsiders (i.e.,
renters and would-be property owners) (Fischel 2001).
Economic models make several predictions about how stakeholder
incentives influence changes to land-use regulations, the housing supply,
and housing prices (Ortalo-Magne and Prat 2014; Hilber and Robert-Nicoud
2013; Glaeser, Gyourko, and Saks 2005). Locations with more homeowners
than renters have stricter housing supply regulations than their counterparts,
and the regulations tighten as homeowners’ political influence grows (Fang,
Stewart, and Tyndall 2023). Regulations reduce the price elasticity of the
housing supply; in other words, the supply of housing is less responsive to
market prices in markets with more regulation.
Research consistently finds that increasingly stringent zoning restrictions lead to lower housing construction and a lower price elasticity of the
housing supply, while decreasingly stringent zoning restrictions lead to
higher housing construction costs and a higher price elasticity of the housing
supply (Baum-Snow 2023; Gyourko and Molloy 2015; Stacy et al. 2023;
Landis and Reina 2021). The relationship between zoning restrictiveness
and housing prices is more nuanced: tighter zoning restrictions lead to more
expensive housing, often by requiring new homes to be larger and occupy
larger lots (Gyourko and McCulloch 2023). More relaxed zoning restrictions
lead to a higher supply of smaller, lower-cost housing, and, in at least some
instances, can lead to lower prices and rents or slower growth in rents among
existing housing (Crump et al. 2020; Been, Ellen, and O’Regan 2023;
Baum-Snow 2023; Greenaway-McGrevy 2023).
Broadly, local decision-making processes lead to at least two cascading housing market failures. The first is of negative externalities, which
predict too much land-use regulation relative to the social optimum because
homeowners, developers, and local governments do not account for the
welfare cost of these regulations for individuals in neighboring communities or would-be residents. The excessive regulations lead to an incomplete
housing market, where the private sector does not create enough supply to
meet demand. Corrective policy at the State or Federal level can help bridge
the gap between housing supply and demand.

Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing: | 151
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

Figure 4-8. Housing Prices and Construction Costs, 1980–2022
Inflation-adjusted index

7
6
5
4
3
2
1

0
1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 2013 2016 2019 2022
CoreLogic National House Price Index
Houses under Construction: Fixed-Weighted Price Index

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Census Bureau; CoreLogic; CEA calculations.
Note: Both price indices are adjusted for inflation using the Personal Consumption Expenditures price index (core
services excluding housing), reindexed to 1982 = 100. The data are not seasonally adjusted. Gray bars indicate
recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

The Wedge Between Price and Construction Cost: Land Value
The causes and consequences of housing supply shortages in the United
States can be understood within the context of the housing market’s pricing efficiency, or the relationship between price and cost. As shown in
figure 4-8, physical construction costs have quadrupled since the 1980s,
accelerated by an increase in labor and material costs (Khater, Keifer, and
Yanamandra 2021; CBRE 2022), while construction sector productivity
has fallen (Goolsbee and Syverson 2023). Also seen in figure 4-8, housing
prices have increased more quickly than construction costs. Between 1980
and the early 2020s, housing prices grew by over sixfold, or about 50 percent
more than the fourfold increase in construction costs. Economists attribute
the growing gap between housing prices and physical construction costs in
the U.S. housing market to land prices, which largely reflect the impact of
restrictive land-use regulations (Gyourko and Molloy 2015).

Zoning and Land-Use Regulations: Effects on the Housing Supply
Exclusionary zoning policies are a subset of local land-use regulations that
can constrain the housing supply and thus decrease affordability. Examples
include prohibitions on multifamily homes, height limits, minimum lot
sizes, square footage minimums, and parking requirements—each of which
functions to constrain housing and population density. Researchers estimate
that loosening land-use restrictions would lead to a small but significant
152 | Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing:
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

increase in the metropolitan housing supply over the next decade (Stacy et
al. 2023).
Some zoning laws date back to the late 1800s, when city planners were
concerned about fire hazards, access to light and outdoor air, or proximity to industry (Fischel 2004). While some zoning laws were intended to
improve the quality of life for poor and vulnerable families, others were
designed to discriminate against minority groups and raise property prices
in suburban and urban neighborhoods (Rigsby 2016; Mangin 2014). Some
of the first zoning laws appeared in about 1917, when the Supreme Court
banned explicit race-based segregation in zoning ordinances in Buchanan v.
Warley (Rothstein 2017). Scholars have shown that certain zoning practices
enabled cities to continue race-based segregation (Gray 2022; Kahlenberg
2023). Box 4-1 provides additional detail on the history of zoning laws and
their effects on racial and ethnic minorities.
Single-family zoning is imposed on most residentially zoned land
across the country and constitutes 70 percent of all U.S. residential zoning
(Frank 2021). Minimum lot size requirements force developers to build
homes on larger lots than the market would otherwise provide (Gyourko,
Hartley, and Krimmel 2019; Furth and Gray 2019). For example, 81 percent of Connecticut land requires a minimum of 1 acre lots (Bronin 2023).
Research finds that doubling minimum lot sizes increases sale prices by
14 percent and rents by 6 percent, while intensifying residential segregation (Song 2021). Recent zoning changes allowing multifamily housing
in Boston and Minneapolis–Saint Paul has led to increased housing supply, desegregation, and increased shares of Black and Hispanic residents
(Resseger 2022; Furth and Webster 2022).
Another important land-use regulation concerns minimum parking
requirements, which dictate a minimum number of off-street spaces per
housing unit or business. However, studies have shown the requirements
often exceed what is needed to meet demand, leading to large shares of
land devoted to parking lots. For example, 30 percent of downtown Detroit
is dedicated to parking, compared with 12 percent in Los Angeles and 4
percent in Chicago (Sorens 2023; Chester et al. 2015; Kaufmann 2023).
Parking requirements impose space requirements beyond lot sizes, reducing
the housing supply and increasing the cost of housing (WGI 2021). Research
has found that parking requirements in Los Angeles reduce the number of
units in apartment buildings by 13 percent (Shoup 2014). A Seattle reform
that reduced parking requirements was found to be associated with developers building 40 percent less parking than would have been required before
the reform, resulting in 18,000 fewer parking spaces and saving an estimated
$537 million in construction costs, ultimately leading to lower-priced housing (Gabbe, Pierce, and Clowers 2020).

Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing: | 153
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

Box 4-1. A Brief History of Exclusionary
Zoning Laws in the United States
Some of the earliest zoning ordinances were enacted in the mid to late
1800s to isolate nuisance land use, such as by slaughterhouses, from
residential areas. Under the guise of further resident protection, however, other ordinances were implemented that isolated racial and ethnic
minorities. For example, the historic “Chinese laundry” regulations
allowed many white proprietors to be licensed while excluding Chinese
business owners (Howells 2022).
In 1910, Baltimore enacted one of the first zoning laws that
explicitly segregated neighborhoods by suggesting that the ordinances
protected the public. The Supreme Court’s 1917 Buchanan v. Warley
decision struck down explicitly racist zoning laws (Howells 2022).
In the wake of Buchanan v. Warley, communities began implicitly
segregating by race with new forms of zoning. Single-family zoning in
Berkeley, California, in early 1910s attempted to prohibit “Negroes and
Asiatics” from living in certain areas, and the strategy began to spread
across the country (Barber 2019). Single-family zoning also prohibited
apartment buildings and other types of affordable housing, leading to
increased class segregation (Gray 2022). Saint Louis introduced zoning
designed to preserve homes in areas unaffordable to most Black families
in 1919, and the city often changed areas’ zoning designations from residential to industrial once numerous Black families moved in (Rothstein
2014). Similarly, Seattle’s 1923 zoning laws changed many areas with a
large number of Black or Chinese American families from residential to
commercial (Twinam 2018). The Supreme Court upheld various zoning
restrictions, including against multifamily housing, in Euclid v. Ambler
(Supreme Court 1926), furthering class-based discrimination. The new
zoning rules restricted new housing levels and made prices unaffordable
for low income and most nonwhite households (CEA 2021).
In the 1920s, the Secretary of Commerce, Herbert Hoover, published “A Zoning Primer,” which encouraged States to allow municipalities to adopt exclusionary zoning (Gries 1922). The 1923 Standard State
Zoning Enabling Act provided model legislation that States could pass
to give municipalities zoning power; eventually, all States gave municipalities the right to determine local zoning regulations (Flint 2022).
The number of cities with zoning rules increased by 1,246 additional
municipalities between 1916 and 1936 (Fischel 2004).
The 1970s saw a second wave of zoning in response to (1) the
1968 Fair Housing Act, which attempted to clamp down on discrimination by race and other factors, as communities responded by increasing
economically discriminatory zoning; and (2) the growing importance
of real estate within household financial portfolios. By the 2000s, more
than 30,000 local governments in the United States had their own zoning

154 | Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing:
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

rules (Kahlenberg 2023). In recent decades, America’s neighborhoods
have continued to be segregated by race and income (Loh, Coes, and
Buthe 2020).

One analysis found that 40 percent of Manhattan buildings could not
be built today because they do not conform to zoning codes (Bui, Chaban,
and White 2016). Dense city centers would be almost impossible to build
with modern minimum parking requirements, and many new developments
are only approved after receiving special permits or variances to circumvent
zoning rules (Bui, Chaban, and White 2016; Gray 2022). Other factors
restricting the housing supply include mandatory public hearings, fees
and exactions, environmental review, design standards, lot configuration
requirements, building size regulations, rising insurance costs, and occupancy rules (Bronin 2023). Each regulation restricts what developers can
build, increases time-to-construction and structure costs, and leads many
would-be housing projects to be financially infeasible.

Additional Constraints
New multifamily housing development, whether for renter- or owneroccupied units, is a complex, long-run capital investment process that is
highly sensitive to the macroeconomic environment. The projects involve
various development costs, including (1) physical construction (“hard”)
costs, (2) project design and development (“soft”) costs, and (3) land costs.
Developers draw project financing from a combination of debt and equity
that require different rates of return from completed projects, imposing
minimum profitability thresholds and tying private development to interest
rate fluctuations. At the same time, most revenue for multifamily rental
development comes from rent charged to tenants, which is related to local
land-use regulations. Box 4-2 describes the calculus behind financing
housing development projects—this calculus is sometimes referred to as
“penciling the deal.”
Demographic shifts in the American population affect both housing
supply and demand. For example, a sharp increase in life expectancy during
the last century—combined with the aging of the baby boom generation—
has increased the demand for housing among older Americans (Berkeley
Economic Review 2019). In addition, to the extent that homeowners choose
not to move as they age, this will tend to reduce the rate of repeat sales for
the current stock of homes, reducing the supply of available homes. Changes
in fertility and international immigration have also affected housing demand.

Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing: | 155
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

Box 4-2. Penciling the Deal: The Math Behind
Developing Rental Housing with LIHTC
New multifamily development projects are characterized by large
upfront costs and long-run investment returns. Most of the revenue
generated by housing developments comes from rent charged to tenants,
as determined by local market conditions. The Low-Income Housing
Tax Credit (LIHTC) enables developers to meet these upfront costs and
charge less rent, making units affordable for 30 years after construction.
Developers balance future revenue streams against development and financing costs to determine whether a property is worth
constructing; in other words, whether the deal “pencils out” (Garcia
2019). Development costs can be grouped into three categories: (1)
hard physical construction costs, including labor and materials; (2) soft
costs (e.g., fees, financing, consulting, taxes, title, and insurance); and
(3) land acquisition costs, including those associated with closing (e.g.,
environmental studies and resolving zoning issues). While local market
conditions vary across the United States, land costs generally comprise
10–20 percent of total costs, soft costs comprise 20–30 percent, and
hard costs comprise 60–70 percent. Local land-use regulations, such as
zoning restrictions, parking requirements, and density restrictions, can
all increase development costs (Urban Institute 2016; Hoyt and Schuetz
2020).
To finance projects, developers obtain funding from debt and
equity. Debt typically comprises most of the funding, with loan-to-cost
ratios of 50 to 75 percent (Urban Institute 2016; Garcia 2019; RCN
Capital n.d.). Historically, interest rates have fluctuated between 4 and
8 percent. Equity, mostly from private investors, fills the gap between
debt and project costs. Housing development equity is a relatively risky
investment class due to the time required for projects to generate revenue. At a high level, equity investors compare the return on cost—the
ratio of the project’s first year net operating income to its costs—with
local capitalization rates. Local capitalization rates capture the average rates of return on alternative housing projects and typically range
between 3 and 6 percent. According to one analysis, differences of 1
to 1.5 percent between the return on cost and capitalization rates would
incentivize private investment (Garcia 2019; JPMorgan Chase 2022).
For example, on a $20 million project, the building could be
financed with $13 million in loans—which require $780,000 in debt
service payments, assuming a 6 percent interest rate—and $7 million
in private equity, which require $455,000 in returns to be attractive
based on typical market capitalization rates. Assuming a per-unit rent
that equals the nationwide median, the structure can have, at most, 136
units; this structure could generate a 6.5 percent capitalization rate in
10 years. These units would be affordable for a tenant who earns the

156 | Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing:
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

median income in 2022 ($74,755), but they would be unaffordable for
low-income households. For example, households in the bottom 20th
percentile of the income distribution can spend, at most, $765 in monthly
rent in order to not be considered cost-burdened, about half the nationwide median monthly rent ($1,300). Developers can privately choose to
designate some units as affordable by charging below-market-rate rent,
but to maintain profitability, they must raise rent on the remaining units.
Affordable housing can reduce the net operating income of a housing development project and threaten its viability. The LIHTC offers an
incentive to construct affordable housing by providing tax credit equity
in exchange for affordable unit construction. Among other requirements,
projects must meet one of three income tests to be eligible:
A. At least 20 percent of the units are occupied by tenants with
an income of 50 percent or less of area median income (AMI),
adjusted for family size.
B. At least 40 percent of the units are occupied by tenants with an
income of 60 percent or less of AMI, adjusted for family size.
C. At least 40 percent of the units are occupied by tenants with
income averaging no more than 60 percent of AMI, and no units
are occupied by tenants with income greater than 80 percent of
AMI, adjusted for family size.
The LIHTC provides a 10-year stream of annual credits based on
a housing project’s construction costs equal to either 30 or 70 percent
of the present value of the qualified basis, depending on whether the
project was approved for the competitive or noncompetitive allocation
(Tax Policy Center n.d.). The LIHTC is one of the few tax programs
that allows for credits to be bought and sold on a secondary market.
In particular, developers can sell their tax credits to investors who are
better able to take advantage of the LIHTC and other project-related
tax benefits to reduce their tax liability. Credits are typically sold by
developers at a discount, which fluctuated between $0.85 and $0.90 on
the $1 as of 2021, to reflect the time-value of money (Kimura 2022). The
tax equity investors typically take a passive role, receiving the benefits
but not participating in day-to-day decision-making.
In the case of the $20 million building, if 20 percent of the units are
set aside for low-income tenants, as specified by income test A above,
and the LIHTC credits were awarded competitively, the LIHTC program
can provide $1.4 million in equity, assuming that investors are willing to
purchase credits at a discount of $0.85 on $1. With this tax equity, only
$5.6 million in private equity is needed, which will require 7 percent
fewer returns from rent to cover financing costs.
Figure 4-i compares the per-unit rent in the affordable and remaining units with and without the LIHTC and under two scenarios: (1)
20 percent of units affordable at 50 percent of the nationwide median

Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing: | 157
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

Figure 4-i. Rent Comparisons Under Different Funding Scenarios
Dollars
1,600
1,400
1,200
1,000
800
600
400
200
0

Fully private

LIHTC

Fully private

LIHTC

Scenario A: 20% of units affordable to tenants Scenario B: 40% of units affordable for tenants
with incomes at most 50% of AMI
with incomes at most 60% of AMI
Affordable rent

Council of Economic Advisers

Break-even rent

Nationwide median rent

Sources: Census Bureau (2022); CEA calculations.
Note: LIHTC = Low Income Housing Tax Credit; AMI = Area Median Income. The figure illustrates calculations for a
$20 million hypothetical building.
2024 Economic Report of the President

income; and (2) 40 percent of units affordable at 60 percent of the
nationwide median. As shown, the LIHTC program allows developers
to allocate units to low-income renters without cross-subsidizing via
increased rent on the remaining units. If developers instead choose
to fund affordable units privately, for example, in order to satisfy an
inclusionary zoning requirement, the building’s remaining units would
need to be rented at above the market rate, as characterized in figure
4-i, based on the nationwide median rent for illustrative purposes, for
the developer to break even on costs. This funding scenario, however,
introduces additional risk as the developer would have no guarantee of
demand for the above-market-rate units.

Researchers estimate that the combined effect of changes in life expectancy,
international immigration, urbanization, and fertility can account for 41 percent of the observed housing price increase from 1970 to 2010 and forecast
an additional increase of 5 to 19 percent in housing prices through 2050
(Gong and Yao 2022). Likewise, research finds that a 1-percentage-point
increase in the current birthrate would increase housing prices by 4 to 5
percent in 25 to 30 years (Francke and Korevaar 2022). Moreover, foreignborn household heads are projected to be the primary source of new housing
demand by 2040 (Nguyen 2015).

158 | Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing:
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

Housing Supply Shortages: Consequences for Welfare,
Economic Mobility, and Aggregate Output
Even in functional housing markets, income variation across households
implies that low-income households face higher housing cost burdens than
those with a higher income. When land-use restrictions drive supply constraints, growing housing demand in cities and neighborhoods leads to more
expensive housing, rather than new housing development (Baum-Snow
2023). The resulting housing shortages manifest as lower vacancy rates and
higher prices and rents relative to wage growth. As the gap widens between
market prices and production costs, more households experience housing
insecurity, which negatively affects individual welfare and economic mobility (Been et al. 2011; Taylor 2018).

Neighborhood Choice, Individual Welfare, and Economic Mobility
Prices affect not only the type of housing in which individuals choose to
live, but also where they live. The latter decision is tied to a bundle of local
amenities, including access to jobs and transportation, schools, exposure
to crime, environmental quality, health care access, and social networks.
Importantly, neighborhood choice shapes children’s long-run educational
and economic outcomes, and neighborhood environment affects adult health
and well-being (Chetty and Hendren 2018; Chyn and Katz 2021).
Property taxes typically fund public schools; the greater the tax base
per capita, the more funds are available for education. Children from highincome households tend to live in expensive neighborhoods and, therefore,
have access to higher quality schools. Housing near high-scoring public
schools costs on average 2.4 times more, or nearly $11,000 more per year,
than housing near low-scoring schools (Rothwell 2012). Few affordable
housing options exist near high-quality schools (DiSalvo and Yu 2023),
which reduces the number of low-income, as well as Black and Hispanic,
students attending them, and exacerbates intergenerational inequality
(Ihlanfeldt 2019). Black and Hispanic students attending more segregated
schools are less likely to graduate from high school and attend college than
their peers attending less segregated schools, and they are less likely to work
and more likely to have low earnings as adults (Gould Ellen, De la Roca,
and Steil 2015).
Economic models, such as that developed by Tiebout (1956), suggest
that beyond valuing neighborhoods for their schools, households “vote with
their feet” and choose neighborhoods that best match their preferences.
However, because housing markets are incomplete and affordable houses
are often not available in neighborhoods with high-quality amenities,

Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing: | 159
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

rising housing prices push low-income households toward areas with few
amenities.
Housing supply constraints can affect demographic shifts in the
American population. For instance, young adults primarily demand entrylevel and lower-priced housing. As a result, shortages in the entry-level
market sector are felt most by young adults. Research has shown household
formation rates decreased in recent years as a result of increased housing
prices: a 1 percent increase in housing prices decreases household formation by almost 5 percent for young adults (Kiefer, Atreya, and Yanamandra
2018). Consistent with this finding, homeownership rates have been declining over time for young adults (Goodman, Choi, and Zhu 2023).

Wealth Accumulation
Homeownership has long been a common path to wealth accumulation
in the United States, with returns being especially high for those who can
afford expensive homes (Wolff 2022). As a result, housing supply restrictions have implications for wealth accumulation (La Cava 2016). Figure 4-9
reports homeownership rates and median net family worth by income, age,
race and ethnicity, and geography. Generally, patterns in homeownership
rates according to these characteristics are correlated with wealth patterns.
Higher-income, older, and white non-Hispanic households are more likely
to own their homes and have accumulated more wealth than other groups.
Intergenerational wealth transfers interact with homeownership. For
example, individuals are about 8 percentage points more likely to become
Figure 4-9. Homeownership Rate and Median Net Family Worth, 2022
Percent

Thousands of 2022 dollars

2,000

100
90

1,800

80

1,600

70

1,400

60

1,200

50

1,000

40

800

30

600

20

400

10

200

0

0

Income quintile

Age

Homeownership rate (left axis)

Median family net worth (right axis)

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Survey of Consumer Finances; Census Bureau; CEA calculations.
Note: The values for the fifth income quintile are calculated by averaging over data reported for 80–89.9 and 90–100 income quintiles.
2024 Economic Report of the President

160 | Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing:
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

homeowners if their parents are homeowners rather than nonhomeowners
(Choi, Zhu, and Goodman 2018). Because housing is the main source of
wealth for most households, disparities in homeownership rates and valuations across groups are likely to lead to differences in wealth accumulation
(figure 4-9). In particular, generations of discrimination in the housing
market have created a substantial racial wealth gap in America; one paper
estimates that, on average, Black Americans had 17 cents for every $1 in
wealth white Americans had in 2019 (Derenoncourt et al. 2023). Many
researchers show that these trends are likely to be perpetuated into the future
(Derenoncourt et al. 2023; Aaronson, Hartley, and Mazumder 2023). Black
and Hispanic homeowners also face an assessment bias in the value of their
homes, creating further household wealth disparities by race and ethnicity
(Avenancio-Leon and Howard 2022).

Income Shocks, Housing Instability, and Homelessness
Homeownership and home values affect households’ ability to withstand
income shocks. Black and Hispanic households were disproportionately
affected by the foreclosure crisis after the global financial crisis and the
financial hardship related to the COVID-19 pandemic (Reid et al. 2016;
Bayer et al. 2016; Gerardi et al. 2021; Cornelissen and Pack 2023; Hermann
et al. 2023). Foreclosures cause sustained housing instability and make
future homeownership difficult, in addition to inflicting other forms of
financial distress (Diamond, Guren, and Tan 2020).
While homeowners benefit from rising housing costs in their own
neighborhood, the 35 percent of households who rent their home do not
(Ruggles et al. 2023), and low-income residents who do not own their home
face the threat of eviction. Eviction orders, which are increasingly likely
after earnings declines and employment losses, increase homelessness and
further reduce future earnings, durable consumption, and credit access
(Collinson et al. 2023). Children are at the greatest risk for eviction, and
extensive research suggests they are substantially and lastingly harmed by
housing instability (Graetz et al. 2023). Finally, housing stability, quality,
safety, and affordability are all associated with improved health outcomes
(Taylor 2018).
Evidence suggests that regional variation in housing costs and availability explains regional variation in homelessness (Aldern and Colburn
2022). Counter to intuition, poverty rates are lower in places with higher
rates of homelessness (Aldern and Colburn 2022). Homelessness is strongly
correlated with median rent at the city or county level; one study shows
that a $100 increase in median rent is associated with a 15 percent rise in
homelessness in metropolitan areas (Byrne et al. 2016). Moreover, evidence
suggests that higher homelessness rates are not associated with higher

Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing: | 161
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

Figure 4-10. Components of Year-on-Year Headline CPI Inflation, 2013–23
Percentage points

10

8
6
4
2
0
-2
Feb-2013 May-2014 Aug-2015 Nov-2016
Goods excluding food & energy

Council of Economic Advisers

Feb-2018 May-2019 Aug-2020 Nov-2021

Housing

Services excluding energy & housing

Feb-2023
Food

Energy

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; CEA calculations.
Note: Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

incidence of mental health issues, substance abuse, or generosity of the local
safety net (Aldern and Colburn 2022). A statewide California study finds
that 75 percent of homeless residents remain in the county where they last
had housing (Benioff Homelessness and Housing Initiative 2023).

Implications for Inflation and Aggregate Growth
A constricted housing supply across regions creates migration frictions that
can lead to a geographic labor misallocation (Ganong and Shoag 2017).
All else being equal, workers should migrate from low to high productivity cities until productivity, and therefore wages, equalizes across cities.
If high-productivity cities also have a constrained housing supply, fewer
workers can respond to productivity and wage incentives. Recent evidence
suggests that many workers might not move to places with higher wages
because higher housing costs completely offset any increase in wages (Card,
Rothstein, and Yi 2023).
Housing supply restrictions also exacerbate inflation. When measured
by the Consumer Price Index (CPI), inflation reflects changes over time in
the price paid for a market basket of consumer goods and services, including food, energy, and housing. Housing expenses—the single largest basket
component—have accounted for at least 25 percent of the CPI basket since
1993. Figure 4-10 depicts a decade of inflation trends, including a decomposition of the market basket’s core components. As the level of housing

162 | Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing:
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

prices has increased, the contribution of housing to CPI has increased simultaneously (CEA 2023a). High housing inflation partially reflects a shift in
housing demand—for example, increased working from home—paired with
an already-constrained housing supply (Mischke et al. 2023). Housing inflation has steadily declined since the spring 2023 peak, and as a result, annual
inflation declined to 3.4 percent at the end of 2023.

Federal Policy’s Role
The three prominent frictions related to long-run housing supply shortages
and affordability issues are (1) locally determined land-use regulations,
which lead to exclusionary zoning; (2) financing and other construction
costs that increase the cost of producing housing; and (3) the spatial mismatch of workers and jobs, which reduces aggregate output. These three
costs motivate multiple Federal policy solutions.
Although much of housing supply policy is local, the Federal
Government can affect national priorities through various mechanisms. For
example, the government can help address long-standing implicit and explicit
discriminatory zoning practices. To this end, the Federal Government can
align its agency resources and policy priorities to promote zoning reforms
that reduce barriers that limit what can be built. Likewise, the Federal purse
can be used to advance existing agency priorities and launch new initiatives
to alleviate housing supply constraints, increase the production of affordable
units, and address the Nation’s growing affordability challenges.
A central goal of the Biden-Harris Administration is an economy in
which every American has access to a safe and affordable home. On one
hand, demand-side policies, including direct subsidies to cost-burdened
households, can help address acute affordability issues. Box 4-3 describes
several important examples. On the other hand, supply-side policies that
directly boost housing construction are an integral part of the solution.

Zoning Reforms: Expanding the Housing Supply and Increasing
Affordability
Local zoning and land-use restrictions are a long-standing, fundamental
hurdle for increasing the housing supply. Under these restrictions, housing
supply shortages have become increasingly salient, with a growing share of
household budgets dedicated to housing. Reducing barriers to the housing
supply can lead to several benefits: increased housing production, economic
growth, job creation, reduced class and racial segregation, and increased climate resiliency through reduced sprawl and commuting times. Fortunately,
momentum is building for zoning reforms, and numerous policy changes
have been enacted at the State and local levels. Examples, detailed in box

Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing: | 163
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

Box 4-3. Assistance for Housing Demand
Even in a functioning housing market with abundant supply, many lowincome families still struggle to afford housing. Federal policies can
help families close the gap between housing expenditures and personal
financial resources. The Federal Government can provide financial
assistance to individuals directly and also enact policies to decrease the
price of housing.
The Federal Government uses several assistance programs to help
low-income families access affordable housing, including Project-Based
Rental Assistance, Public Housing, and housing vouchers. The Section
8 Housing Choice Voucher Program, administered by HUD in partnership with local public housing agencies, is one of the largest Federal
housing programs (Center on Budget and Policy Priorities 2017). The
program generally caps families’ housing costs at 30 percent of their
income, helping 2.3 million low-income households annually, while
also reducing evictions and homelessness (HUD 2023d, 2023i). Almost
three-quarters of families receiving housing vouchers have children
(Center on Budget and Policy Priorities 2017). Households using vouchers were once young relative to the general population but have steadily
become older (Reina and Aiken 2022). Many voucher households live in
high-poverty and low-opportunity areas, where vouchers are more often
accepted; however, only about one in four voucher-eligible households
actually receive and use a voucher, due to the lack of program funding
(Gould Ellen 2018). When families use vouchers to move to low poverty
neighborhoods, children’s long-run outcomes improve in the form of
higher college attendance rates and adult earnings (Chetty, Hendren,
and Katz 2016).
Recognizing that funding limitations constrain the number of
households able to receive rental assistance, President Biden’s Fiscal
Year 2024 Budget proposed expanding rental assistance to well over
200,000 additional households through $2.4 billion in additional funding
for the voucher program, as well as $22 billion in mandatory funding to
provide guaranteed housing to extremely low income veterans and youth
transitioning out of foster care (White House 2023c; HUD 2024b).
Federal financial assistance to families in the form of cash, tax
credits, and in-kind benefits like the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance
Program (known as SNAP) can help alleviate some of the financial
burden of housing. For instance, the temporarily expanded 2021 Child
Tax Credit (CTC) helped families maintain stable housing by alleviating other financial burdens (CEA 2023b; Pilkauskas, Michelmore, and
Kovski 2023).
The Rural Housing Service of the U.S. Department of Agriculture
(USDA) offers direct and guaranteed loans to help low-income rural
residents buy and maintain housing. In 2022, USDA’s Single Family

164 | Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing:
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

Housing Direct Loan Program obligated $1.3 billion to underwrite
and service mortgages for low-income families that often face credit
constraints. Additionally, USDA obligated $13.1 billion in mortgage
loan guarantees to help provide moderate- to low-income rural residents
an opportunity to realize the dream of homeownership (USDA 2024).
In a housing market with sufficient supply, demand-side assistance
can be very effective. However, in a housing market with a constrained
supply, these policies may lead to increased rent prices for some rental
units, possibly directing some of the benefits to landlords and property
owners rather than renters (Diamond, McQuade, and Qian 2018).

4-4, include initiatives allowing construction of multifamily housing in areas
previously zoned for single-family homes, expanding homeowners’ right to
construct and rent out accessory dwelling units, and abolishing minimum
parking requirements (Greene and González-Hermoso 2019; Parking
Reform Network n.d.). Federal policy could build on these successes to help
cities and States continue their reforms.
Federal dollars can create incentives for State and local policymakers to meet housing policy goals. For instance, the Pathways to Removing
Obstacles to Housing (PRO Housing) program sponsored by the Department
of Housing and Urban Development (HUD) will award $85 million in competitive grants to communities with plans to remove barriers to affordable
housing and production in 2024 (HUD 2023b). In addition, President Biden
has called for $20 billion to create a first-of-its-kind fund that will award
planning and housing capital grants to State and local jurisdictions to expand
the housing supply and lower housing costs for lower- and middle-income
households (as described in the forthcoming Fiscal Year 2025 Budget, per
the U.S. Department of the Treasury). Further, HUD’s 2023 publication
Policy & Practice collects and disseminates evidence-based insights drawn
from State and local housing policy initiatives. HUD also recently announced
$4 million in grant funding to support research studying zoning and land-use
reforms, and a $350,000 award through the Research Partnerships program
to support the development of the “National Zoning Atlas” to “close data
gaps that limit our understanding of the relationship between zoning and
segregation, affordability, and other outcomes of interest” (HUD 2023j,
2023g). HUD has further reinforced the 1968 Fair Housing Act’s goal of
“Affirmatively Furthering Fair Housing” with a rule that would require
recipients of HUD funding to work to overcome patterns of segregation, promote fair housing choice, eliminate disparities in opportunities, and foster
inclusive communities free from discrimination (HUD 2023a).

Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing: | 165
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

Box 4-4. State and Local Zoning: Recent Steps
Zoning is one of the most significant regulatory powers of local government, and research shows reform can unlock economic growth and
opportunity (Flint 2022). Zoning reforms that are likely to increase
housing supply include allowing more multifamily housing to be built
(especially near public transportation hubs), legalizing accessory dwelling units (ADUs), and eliminating minimum parking requirements,
minimum lot sizes, minimum square feet requirements, and density
restrictions. None of these reforms prevent new single-family home
construction; rather, the changes prevent municipalities from requiring
only single-family homes.
Some steps taken in recent years include:
• Buffalo became the first major U.S. city to abolish minimum
parking requirements in 2017 (Poon 2017). Recently, more
cities have followed suit, including Anchorage, San Jose, and
Gainesville. Other cities, such as San Diego, made incremental
steps in the same direction by eliminating parking requirements
near public transit (Wamsley 2024; Khouri 2022).
• Minneapolis banned single-family exclusive zoning in 2018,
and Charlotte enacted a similar policy in 2021 (Grabar 2018;
Brasuell 2021). At the State level, Oregon, California, and
Washington enacted such policies in 2018, 2021, and 2023,
respectively (Garcia et al. 2022; Gutman 2023).
• California has enacted multiple policies intended to grow
housing supply in recent years. The State has legalized ADUs
statewide, allowed duplexes and lot splits in single-family
zones, and allowed mixed-income, multifamily housing in all
residential areas (Skelton 2021; Gray 2022). At the same time,
California has eliminated minimum parking requirements at
transit stations statewide (Khouri 2022). California has also
set up a Regional Housing Needs Allocation process, whereby
local jurisdictions must produce housing and land use plans to
comply with State housing targets (California Department of
Housing and Community Development 2023).
• Connecticut has enacted significant policy changes, requiring its
cities and towns to “affirmatively further fair housing” in their
zoning, promote diverse housing options, legalize ADUs, and
cap minimum parking requirements (Flint 2022).
• Montana enacted several changes in 2023 aimed at making
housing more affordable and reducing sprawl into rural and
agricultural areas (State of Montana Governor’s Office 2023).
These pro-housing changes include allowing duplexes, ADUs,
and apartment-style housing, while also speeding up permitting
approvals (Dietrich 2023).

166 | Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing:
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

• In 2022, Maine passed legislation to allow ADUs and duplexes
in residential zones, and legalized quadplexes in “designated
growth areas” (SMPDC 2023).
• In Massachusetts, a program known as MBTA Communities,
signed in 2021, requires cities and towns to allow multifamily
housing near transit stations, with a minimum density of 15
units per acre (Commonwealth of Massachusetts 2023). Fairfax
County, Virginia, is taking similar steps, such as easing height
and density restrictions near transit stations (Merchant 2016).
• Vermont legalized duplexes in all residential neighborhoods, as
well as triplexes and quadruplexes in all areas served by municipal sewer and water infrastructure in 2023 (Brasuell 2023).

In addition to HUD’s efforts, the U.S. Department of Transportation
(DOT) manages several large grant programs that improve transportation
connections, including connections to affordable housing and funding
for land-use reform. For example, the Reconnecting Communities and
Neighborhoods Program offers grant funding for capital construction, community planning, and regional partnerships that prioritize disadvantaged
communities, improve access to daily needs, foster equitable development,
and reconnect communities (DOT 2023). The Areas of Persistent Poverty
Program awards competitive grants to finance projects including those that
improve transit facilities, technologies, and transit service in areas of persistent poverty or in historically disadvantaged communities (FTA 2023).
In addition, the Economic Development Administration has updated its
guidance to emphasize efficient land use as part of the agency’s grantmaking
authority (White House 2023a). Many of these efforts are connected with the
Administration’s Housing Supply Action Plan, which provides incentives
for local zoning reforms by tying these reforms to Federal grant process
scoring (White House 2022). Together, these policies prioritize and direct
Federal spending toward increasing the housing supply and affordability,
especially in locations close to public transportation.

Reducing Supply Constraints with Federal Taxes and Other Subsidies
Addressing home affordability requires both short-term and long-term
solutions. To unlock supply and increase access in the short run, the BidenHarris Administration has called for a series of new policies designed to
lower costs for homeowners and homebuyers. This includes a temporary
mortgage payment relief tax credit for first-time homebuyers, which can
increase access to homeownership during this period of historically high
Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing: | 167
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

mortgage interest rates (as described in the forthcoming Fiscal Year 2025
Budget, per the U.S. Department of the Treasury). It includes down payment
assistance to first-generation homebuyers, which can increase access for
families that have not benefited from the generational wealth accumulation
associated with homeownership (HUD 2024a). Further, it includes a temporary tax credit targeting low- and middle-income homeowners who sell their
starter homes, which can unlock inventory in the starter-home market that is
currently facing an acute supply shortage (as described in the forthcoming
Fiscal Year 2025 Budget, per the U.S. Department of the Treasury). Finally,
to reduce the value gap between rehabilitation costs and postconstruction home values for single-family homes in distressed neighborhoods, it
includes new funding to subsidize rehabilitation expenses (White House
2023d). These funds can increase the likelihood that homes are rehabilitated
before sale, making it easier to attract homebuyers and boosting revitalization efforts in these neighborhoods.
To address supply issues in the long run requires making progress on
both cost and access. However, these policies take time to show progress.
President Biden has called for a new Project-Based Rental Assistance
Program to fund long-term contracts with private owners to rent new affordable units to America’s neediest families (White House 2023c). The Federal
Government has also directly reduced the cost of building affordable housing by subsidizing construction expenses through the tax code.
The largest construction subsidy, the LIHTC, has funded one in five
of all new multifamily units since 1987 and has created more than 3.5 million affordable rental units (HUD 2023e). The LIHTC awards developers a
stream of Federal tax credits over a 10-year period after a project is placed
in service. In exchange, developers must designate a subset of units as rent
restricted for low-income households. Box 4-2 provides additional details on
the LIHTC, including how it helps close the gap between profitability and
the investment returns required for investors to fund the project.
Figure 4-11 shows the financial characteristics of LIHTC unit tenants
in 2021. LIHTC provides housing for households with very low incomes:
24 percent had an annual income below $10,000, and 56 percent had an
income below $20,000. The program benefits a diverse group of households:
roughly one-quarter are white, another quarter are Black, and one-tenth selfidentify as Hispanic/Latino. The statistics suggest that the LIHTC program
effectively targets vulnerable families.5 Still, nearly 40 percent of tenants
spend more than 30 percent of their income on rent (HUD 2021).
While HUD collects demographic information describing households residing in each LIHTC
property, these data are incomplete because a universal list of buildings placed in service that
received LIHTC is not publicly available. Improving the collection of these data would permit HUD
to more completely portray the scope of the LIHTC portfolio and its residents.

5

168 | Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing:
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

Figure 4-11. Financial Characteristics of LIHTC Unit Tenants, 2021

Percentage of households in LIHTC units
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0

൑30%
income

>30%
income

<$10,000 $10,000 to >$20,000
$20,000
per year
per year

Spending on rent

Council of Economic Advisers

per year

White

Black

Hispanic/ Other/
Latino multiracial

Income

Sources: U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development; CEA calculations.
Note: LIHTC = Low-Income Housing Tax Credit. The "other/multiracial category" includes those reporting race as
Asian, American Indian/Alaska Native, Native Hawaiian or Other Pacific Islander, other, and multiple races. The shares
within each category do not sum to 100 percent due to missing or unreported data.
2024 Economic Report of the President

LIHTC-funded developments make an impact on both families and
neighborhoods, according to multiple studies of the program’s benefits
(Baum-Snow and Marion 2009; Eriksen and Rosenthal 2010). Evidence
from Chicago demonstrates that LIHTC-assisted developments have positive spillover effects on local property values (Voith et al. 2022). Home
price appreciation contributes to wealth accumulation for neighborhood
residents and increases funding for public services, but it can also make
localities inaccessible for financially disadvantaged families. At the same
time, LIHTC-assisted developments are associated with reductions in
violent crime through neighborhood revitalization (Freedman and Owens
2011). One study estimates that the program’s aggregate welfare benefits
in low-income areas are $116 million via property value appreciation,
declines in crime, and the inflow of racially diverse individuals (Diamond
and McQuade 2019). Further, access to affordable housing via LIHTC units
gives families and their children the stability required for regular health care
access and is associated with decreased rates of child abuse and neglect
(Gensheimer et al. 2022; Shanahan et al. 2022).
However, there is also evidence that new LIHTC projects may increase
owner turnover rates and crowd out private rental construction (Baum-Snow
and Marion 2009; Eriksen and Rosenthal 2010). Still, the Administration
believes the program can help improve housing affordability and supply,

Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing: | 169
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

and President Biden’s Fiscal Year 2025 Budget calls for roughly $30 billion
to expand and enhance the program. The President’s 2022 Housing Supply
Action Plan called for LIHTC reforms, including a now-finalized Treasury
rule allowing developers to average incomes across some, rather than all,
households in a given property to incentivize more mixed-income developments (White House 2022; Internal Revenue Service 2022).
The Historic Tax Credit subsidizes the rehabilitation of historic properties, including those that result in a new or renovated housing supply.6
Since its inception in 1976, the program has rehabilitated more than 300,000
housing units and has created 343,000 new housing units, 192,000 of which
are low- and moderate-income units (U.S. Department of the Interior 2022).
In Fiscal Year 2021, the National Park Service certified 1,063 historic
rehabilitation projects to revitalize abandoned and underutilized buildings;
nearly 80 percent of them were located in economically distressed areas
(U.S. Department of the Interior 2021). The National Park Service has also
shown that Historic Tax Credit–related rehabilitation projects provide a better return on investment than equal investments in new construction (U.S.
Department of the Interior 2020).
Federal housing tax subsidies can help achieve long-term housing supply goals and affect the U.S. economy’s climate impact. Buildings account
for 29 percent of all U.S. greenhouse gas emissions (Leung 2018). Estimates
suggest that rehabilitated structures produce 50–75 percent fewer carbon
emissions than new construction (Gupta, Martinez, and Nieuwerburgh
2023). The Inflation Reduction Act has committed $9 billion in tax credits,
rebates, workforce training, and funding opportunities to transform existing
homes into green homes and construct new, environmentally friendly residential spaces (Martin 2022). Currently, the commercial real estate market,
with high office vacancy rates and rising loan delinquencies, is in a position
to be transformed into usable and financially prudent residential spaces
(Sorokin 2023; DBRS Morningstar 2023; White House 2023b).
In addition to tax subsidies, the Federal Government provides several
block grants to State and local jurisdictions to assist in affordable housing development. HUD’s Community Development Block Grant Program
(CDBG) can support the acquisition and rehabilitation of housing for lowand moderate-income individuals. In Fiscal Year 2022, the CDBG State
and local grantees allocated more than $920 million to housing activities,
including public housing modernization and single- and multifamily home
rehabilitation (HUD 2022). Recently, HUD issued additional guidance on
how to make use of CDBG funds to further develop “decent, accessible,
equitable, and affordable housing,” providing specific ways that grantees
can best make use of CDBG funds (HUD 2023h). HUD also administers the
The Historic Tax Credit is a colloquial name for the Rehabilitation Tax Credit, which was made
available under section 47 of the Internal Revenue Code.

6

170 | Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing:
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

HOME Investment Partnerships Program, the largest Federal block grant
program that provides funding exclusively to increase access to an adequate,
affordable housing supply for low-income households (CRS 2021). Since
1992, HOME appropriations have cumulatively totaled nearly $45 billion,
with annual appropriations ranging between about $1 billion and $2 billion.
The funds have supported completion of more than 1.3 million affordable
housing units (HUD 2023c).

Expanding Manufactured Home Delivery and Financing to Address
Rural Housing Constraints
Manufactured housing costs 45 percent less to build per square foot
than site-built housing due to efficient production technologies that take
advantage of economies of scale (Freddie Mac n.d.). Manufactured homes,
which are required to comply with HUD-promulgated Manufactured Home
Construction and Safety Standards, are energy efficient, safe, and designed
to withstand natural disasters, inclement weather, and fires (Freddie Mac
2022; Code of Federal Regulations 2023). As a result, they may help provide
affordable housing units and alleviate supply constraints, especially in rural
communities.
Manufactured housing has a higher share of total owner- and renteroccupied housing in rural communities than in more densely populated
areas (Layton 2023). However, efforts to expand the manufactured housing
supply face hurdles driven by land-use regulations. Although the HUDpromulgated manufactured housing building code preempts State and local
design and construction code, local land-use regulations often restrict the
placement of manufactured homes, either implicitly or explicitly (HUD
2023f). For example, some jurisdictions have zoning requirements that limit
manufactured housing to specific zoning districts, and other jurisdictions
may have minimum home size requirements that preclude manufactured
housing (Freddie Mac 2022). In addition, minimum lot size and parking
regulations increase land costs and price manufactured homeowners out of
the market. Federal efforts to encourage the adoption of improved State and
local zoning policies could serve as a financial incentive to promote these
kinds of reforms as well.
Barriers to manufactured home financing dampen demand. The traditional government-sponsored mortgage enterprises, specifically Fannie Mae
and Freddie Mac, cannot purchase and guarantee loans for manufactured
homes because their owners do not typically own the land on which they
sit. Instead, owners must take out a so-called chattel loan, which, relative to
a mortgage, has higher interest rates, shorter repayment periods, and fewer
consumer finance protections (CFPB 2021). These loans can be prohibitively costly for low-income families (Goodman and Ganesh 2018). In light

Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing: | 171
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

of this, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac have identified the financing of manufactured and rural housing among the activities targeted by their 2022–24
Duty to Serve Plans, including the plan to begin purchasing loans titled as
personal property in 2024 and to increase the purchase of loans titled as real
property (FHFA 2022).7

Conclusion
Housing shortages and unaffordability have risen over the last 60 years, in
large part because of local land-use policies that restrict housing density and
what can be built. These effects are felt most by low-income and vulnerable
families, which are increasingly priced out of the housing market. Because
many amenities are bundled with housing and neighborhoods, housing
supply shortages inhibit economic mobility for millions of Americans.
Investing in the housing supply and producing affordable units opens the
door for upward mobility and increases overall economic growth.
Persistent market failures in the housing market create a role for government. Demand-side assistance can help households facing affordability
constraints. In addition, the Federal Government has encouraged efforts to
increase supply-side policies that incentivize local zoning reform, reduce
exclusionary zoning via grants and other spending, and directly subsidize
affordable unit construction through programs like LIHTC. While the efforts
have made a difference, the housing market still faces an acute supply shortage and declining affordability. Ultimately, meaningful change will require
State and local governments to reevaluate the land-use regulations that
reduce the housing supply.
Fortunately, local, State, and Federal policies can boost the housing
supply through incentivized changes to zoning policies, tax credits that
subsidize construction costs for affordable units, and other block grants that
prioritize affordable unit construction. By taking further steps to address
the country’s housing supply shortage, the United States will be richer, our
citizens will be more financially stable, and our environment will be greener.

The Safety and Soundness Act provides that the “Government-Sponsored Entities” have a “duty to
serve underserved markets,” specifying that the enterprises “shall provide leadership to the market in
developing loan products and flexible underwriting guidelines” to improve access and equity in the
mortgage financing market.

7

172 | Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing:
Economic Insights and Federal Policy Solutions

Chapter 5

International Trade and Investment Flows
After a period of rapid globalization during the 1990s and early 2000s,
global goods trade and financial flows showed signs of plateauing in the
decade after the global financial crisis due to a combination of factors,
including sluggish recoveries after the crisis and diminished opportunities
to further disburse production across borders. Still, the global economy
remains inextricably linked—even in the face of large economic shocks and
rising geopolitical tensions—with the U.S. economy continuing to play a
leading role. The United States is the world’s second-largest trading country,
with more than $7 trillion in combined goods and services exports and
imports in 2022, and it remains both the largest source of and destination for
foreign direct investment (USTR 2022a; OECD 2023a).
There are well-documented gains from trade and cross-border investment
flows. The benefits of global integration include lower inflation, a greater
variety of goods and services, more innovation, higher productivity, good
jobs for American workers in exporting sectors, foreign direct investment
in U.S. industries, and a higher likelihood of achieving our climate goals
(Bernstein 2023). However, policymakers must continue to pay careful
attention to negative effects associated with global integration and some
trade policies. First and foremost, global integration can disproportionately
affect certain groups of workers and communities through employment and
earnings losses when facing rising import competition. These distributional
effects are further complicated by differing commercial standards and practices, with some countries using unfair labor practices (e.g., forced or child
labor) or environmentally-degrading manufacturing techniques that are not
fully captured in prices and create an unfair and uneven global production
173

landscape that can distort and stymie competition. To mitigate the negative
consequences of trade and investment flows for both workers and communities, international policies (e.g., trade agreements and economic frameworks) can seek to promote high-level standards (e.g., fair labor practices),
and domestic policies (e.g., social safety nets and education or reskilling
programs) can be adapted to focus needed resources on workers who are
adversely affected by global integration.
By reorienting trade and foreign investment policy to center on workers, the
Biden-Harris Administration’s policy agenda continues to define and elevate
the standards by which trade and foreign investment are conducted, and it
serves as a mechanism for achieving broader economic goals. These goals
include confronting unfair trade practices, elevating labor and environmental
standards (USTR 2022b), and building cooperative and beneficial economic
relationships with U.S. partner countries (CEA 2023a). For example, the
Indo-Pacific Economic Framework is an innovative economic framework
that promotes inclusive growth by advancing higher economic standards,
building supply chain resiliency, facilitating and capturing the economic
opportunities that relate to addressing climate change, fighting corruption,
supporting efficient tax administration, and promoting high-standard labor
commitments. Another example is the United States–Mexico–Canada
Agreement’s Rapid Response Labor Mechanism, which promotes the right
of free association and collective bargaining rights by workers (USTR
2023a). Since 2021, this mechanism has been used to protect labor rights at
multiple different facilities, and thus it has had an impact on thousands of
workers in Mexico (U.S. Department of Labor 2023; USTR 2023a).
While the longer-term outlook for U.S. trade and investment flows remains
uncertain, early signs of important shifts have begun materializing. Supply
chains are being rewired in patterns consistent with near-shoring and friendshoring. Trade in many services sectors has proved resilient to the effects of
the COVID-19 pandemic and is growing. Foreign investors are contributing

174 |

Chapter 5

to a historic ramping up of domestic manufacturing in critical sectors, including advanced technologies and clean energy. In particular, a disproportionate
number of announced foreign investments in clean energy projects are being
located in regions of the country that experienced more pronounced losses in
manufacturing employment in the 1990s and early 2000s.
After describing the evolution of global integration over the past three
decades, this chapter surveys signs that, though still robust, goods trade
integration has slowed for many economies since the global financial
crisis. It then explores how the U.S. trade and investment landscapes have
changed in recent years, and it investigates the centrality of global value
chains for understanding shifts in trade and investment that are consistent
with near-shoring and friend-shoring. Finally, it discusses trade and foreign
investment’s costs and benefits for U.S. workers, consumers, and communities—highlighting how the Biden-Harris Administration’s economic
and trade frameworks and partnerships harness global integration’s benefits
while mitigating its costs.

Long-Term Trends in Trade and Foreign Investment
The liberalization of goods trade and cross-border financial markets—a
trend sometimes characterized as “hyperglobalization” (Rodrik 2011)—was
a defining economic story of the 1990s and early 2000s.1 However, it largely
stagnated after the global financial crisis and, while 2021 and 2022 saw a
rebound, global goods trade integration remained below its 2008 peak and
may level off once again as goods consumption normalizes in the aftermath
of the COVID-19 pandemic. The cessation of hyperglobalization has given

Major liberalization episodes include the integration of former Soviet countries in the early 1990s
with the rest of the global economy, the creation of the World Trade Organization in 1995, and
China’s accession to the World Trade Organization in 2001 (Aiyar et al. 2023).

1

International Trade and Investment Flows | 175

Figure 5-1. Trade in Goods as a Percent of GDP, 1995–2022
Percentage of GDP

75
65
55
45
35
25

15
1995

1997

1999

2001

2003

World
China (Mainland)

Council of Economic Advisers

2005

2007

2009

2011

2013

Canada
EU (excl. intra-EU trade)

2015

2017

2019

United States

2021

Sources: International Monetary Fund; CEA calculations.
Note: Data were only available through 2022. EU trade excludes trade between EU countries, which includes all countries
that were members as of 2022. The data for 1995 and 1996 are from the former Belgium-Luxembourg Economic Union.
2024 Economic Report of the President

way to what some have termed “slowbalization” (Economist 2021; Nathan,
Galbraith, and Grimberg 2022).2

Global Integration Slowed After the Global Financial Crisis, Following
Earlier Decades of Rapid Growth
Global goods trade integration—the total value of goods exports and imports
as a share of gross domestic product (GDP)—rose steadily, from 33 to 51
percent, between 1995 and 2008 (figure 5-1).3 Figure 5-1 also shows that the
extent and timing of the slowdown in goods trade integration differs across
economies, and the future outlook remains considerably uncertain. China’s
decline in goods trade integration since 2006—an outsized 38-percentagepoint drop—is the primary driver for the observed slowing in global goods
trade integration, and reflects the country’s shift away from importing
intermediate inputs and in favor of domestic sources for its production
There is a notable exception—trade in commercial services excluding travel and transportation
(e.g., business services and telecommunications) grew much faster than goods between 1990 to 2023
and shows no sign of slowing (Baldwin 2022). This continuing rise in cross-border digital activity
has been associated with the idea of “newbalization,” indicating the changing nature of globalization
with a slowdown in flows of tangible goods while intangible flows (e.g., of digital services and
cross-border data) accelerate (Nathan, Galbraith, and Grimberg 2022). Meanwhile, measuring
trade incorporating information on both freight and distance traveled compared with value shows
an increasing trend in global trade, in part reflecting the growing importance of commodities like
critical minerals (which weigh more than comparable manufactured products like toys) and can only
be sourced from distant locations (Ganapati and Wong 2023; Zumbrun 2023).
3
The economics literature describes the share of trade relative to GDP as trade openness.
2

176 |

Chapter 5

processes (Constantinescu, Mattoo, and Ruta 2018). Canada’s peak goods
trade integration in 2000 likewise preceded many other economies’ turning
points. While the European Union (excluding intrabloc trade) also experienced a dip after the global financial crisis, unlike comparable economies,
the slowdown in its goods trade integration has not been as marked and has
not yet reached a discernible peak.4
The United States’ trend line of overall goods trade integration differs
from the other economies shown in figure 5-1 in two respects. First, during
the steady increase of goods trade integration in the 1990s and early 2000s,
U.S. trade integration remained well below the world average and that of
most other major economies. Second, the United States’ decline in goods
trade integration since the global financial crisis has been far smaller than
China’s decline. Given that U.S. goods trade integration remains below
global averages and that of peer economies, figure 5-1 suggests there may
be additional scope to increase America’s trade with the global economy.
As this chapter discusses, the United States’ goods trade integration has
generated benefits for American workers and consumers, as well as for U.S.
growth; however, it has also created important vulnerabilities. These tradeoffs underline the strong role for policy to minimize adverse distributional
consequences and maximize the benefits (e.g., supply chain resiliency and
lower prices) from greater trade openness, as discussed in more depth later
in this chapter.
The discussion above of trade in goods is just one dimension of global
integration. Cross-border financial flows—which include flows in securities
(e.g., stocks and bonds) and in foreign direct investment (FDI), referring to
a firm or individual’s investment in a commercial interest in another country—are another key mechanism of global integration (Loungani and Razin
2001; OECD 2024).5 Unlike cross-border securities flows, which tend to be
highly volatile, FDI typically signals longer-term and often more productive
investment, and it can take the form of expanding or acquiring an existing
foreign-owned company or starting a new enterprise in a foreign country.
Global FDI flows as a share of GDP have also exhibited signs of slowing across many economies since the global financial crisis (figure 5-2).6
Including intra-EU trade, the EU’s global goods integration is far higher, at roughly 85 percent of
GDP in 2022 (vs. 35 percent excluding intra-EU trade), given that almost 60 percent of total EU
cross-border trade on average is between countries within the bloc.
5
Another channel for global integration is immigration (the cross-border movement of people),
which is beyond the scope of this chapter. Other forms of cross-border financial flows include
remittances and financial transactions (e.g., development aid transfers).
6
FDI flows are reported based on the geographic location of the investor, meaning that a foreign
entity’s investment in a U.S. firm counts as an inflow to the United States even if (on net) the
entity removed more money from the country than it put into the country that year. In the event that
transactions that decrease a foreign entity’s investment in a U.S. firm outweigh transactions that
increase the entity’s investments, the FDI inflow would be recorded as negative to the United States.
4

International Trade and Investment Flows | 177

Figure 5-2. Total Foreign Direct Investment Flows as a Percentage of GDP, 2006–22
Percentage of GDP, economy-specific

Percentage of GDP, world

14

8
7

12

6

10

5

8

4

6

3

4

2

2
0
2006

1

2008

2010

Canada (left axis)
European Union (left axis)

Council of Economic Advisers

2012

2014

2016

United States (left axis)
World (right axis)

2018

2020

China (left axis)

2022

0

Sources: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development; CEA calculations.
Note: This figure shows the sum of inflows and outflows of foreign direct investment relative to gross domestic product (GDP) for selected
economies.
2024 Economic Report of the President

While the United States has experienced a muted recovery since 2018, total
FDI flows remain below levels seen immediately before the crisis. But as
the lynchpin of the global financial system, the United States is still highly
financially integrated with the global economy according to several metrics,
including FDI (Bertaut, von Beschwitz, and Curcuru 2023; OECD 2023b).
The slowing integration trends through 2020 have been widespread,
making an impact on countries at diverse stages of development and often
facing different economic shocks (figures 5-1 and 5-2). Both cyclical factors (high-frequency developments often associated with business cycles,
e.g., temporary declines in demand) and secular factors (structural, slowermoving phenomena, e.g., technological change) help to explain these trends.
Cyclical factors include sluggish recoveries since the global financial crisis in advanced economies that have weighed on global aggregate
demand, and the impact of the crisis on the financial and corporate sectors,
which were compelled to address vulnerabilities in their balance sheets by
deleveraging and rebuilding capital buffers (Aiyar et al. 2023). And just as
some economies reached their pre-2008 unemployment levels roughly a
decade later, a new set of cyclical shocks surfaced—including the COVID19 pandemic and Russia’s further invasion of Ukraine—each of which had
an adverse impact on global financial conditions and complicated trade
flows.
Secular factors include a slowdown in production fragmentation, or
the unbundling of tasks across borders, also known as global value chains

178 |

Chapter 5

(GVCs) (Timmer et al. 2016). Because multinationals play a central role
in both trade integration and FDI (Qiang, Liu, and Steenbergen 2021), a
reduction in the pace of GVC creation helps explain the stagnation shown by
both measures. Other secular factors include China’s slowdown in growth
and decline in share of trade relative to GDP; in the 21st century, China’s
annual GDP growth rate reached a high in 2007, roughly coinciding with
a peak in the country’s trade integration, and has since been persistently
lower. Ongoing geopolitical tensions and rising national security concerns
have also resulted in an increase in trade sanctions, with the highest share of
global trade affected by sanctions since at least 1950 (WTO 2023a).
The combination of factors described above are generating important
shifts in the extent and intensity of interlinkages with cross-border supply
chains—known as GVC participation—and sourcing. Two GVC participation measures signal these shifts, some of which began with the global
financial crisis and have accelerated in recent years (WTO 2021). First,
the extent of China’s and the United States’ use of imported inputs for the
production of their exports has declined since the global financial crisis (see
figure 5-3, panel A).7
Second, the United States’ and European Union’s shares of content
in other countries’ domestic final demand dropped across many of the
selected economies between 2009 and 2019; in contrast, China’s content
in these countries’ domestic final demand increased (figure 5-3, panel B).8
For example, the share of U.S. value added in Mexico’s domestic final
demand fell by 4 percentage points between 2009 and 2019, and in contrast,
China’s share increased by 7 percentage points. And while the share of U.S.
value added in India’s domestic final demand increased by 1 percentage
point between 2009 and 2019, China’s share of value added increased by 6
percentage points over the same period. The shares of U.S. and European
Union value added in China’s domestic final demand remained unchanged
over this period.
Putting the two sets of findings together suggests that U.S. exports had
a lower value share of foreign-produced components in 2019 compared with
2009, while other countries became more dependent on China as a source
of inputs in their domestic consumption. Lower cross-border connectedness
may risk reducing the gains from trade and FDI for the U.S. economy.
The measure of foreign value-added content of overall exports is also called “backward GVC
participation” (WTO 2022).
8
The share of foreign value added in countries’ domestic final demand reflects how much value
added in goods and services purchased in other countries’ domestic markets originates from abroad
and shows a “domestic economy’s relative connectedness to production in other countries and
regions—independent of whether or not there are direct imports from foreign (upstream) industries”
(OECD 2021). Indicators of forward GVC participation that measure domestic value added sent
to other countries as a share of overall exports paint a more sanguine picture but do not offset the
multitude of indicators pointing to a generalized slowdown in GVC participation (OECD 2023c).
7

International Trade and Investment Flows | 179

Figure 5-3. Indicators of Global Value Chain Participation

A. Foreign Content in Countries’ Exports as a Share of Total Exports, 1995–2020

Percent

30
25
20
15
10
5

0
1995

1997

1999

2001

Canada

2003

2005

2007

United States

2009

2011

China

2013
EU-27

2015

2017

2019

Japan

B. Change in Share of Foreign Value Added in Domestic Final Demand, 2009–19
Percentage points

12
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6

Council of Economic Advisers

United States

China

EU-27

Sources: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development; CEA calculations.
Note: In panel A, the underlying indicator represents the import content of a country's gross exports and is a measure of global
value chain integration. In panel B, the underlying indicator represents the amount of foreign value added (from the United
States, China, and the EU-27, respectively) reflected in domestic final goods or services demand in various countries as a share
of total foreign value added in countries' domestic final demand; the figure shows changes in the share from 2009 to 2019.
2024 Economic Report of the President

The complexity of the current international environment for global
trade and FDI flows points to considerable uncertainty for the future outlook. Despite supply chain pressures during the COVID-19 pandemic, U.S.
goods trade proved resilient and supply chains had begun to normalize (CEA
2023b); U.S. consumption also remained strong in 2023 (see chapter 2 of
this Report). Together with policy actions that are also promoting shifts in
supply chains, these factors may boost global integration. But at the same
time, the ongoing pandemic recovery may be masking the impact of secular
headwinds, and still-developing shifts in supply chains may introduce new
obstacles (e.g., higher costs) to greater integration.

180 |

Chapter 5

Figure 5-4. Real Quarterly Trade in Goods, Actual versus Forecasted,
1992–2023
Millions of real 2022 dollars

900,000

Forecasts based on
linear trend between
2002 and 2007

800,000
700,000

Forecasts based on
linear trend between
2009 and 2019

600,000
500,000
400,000
300,000
200,000
100,000
0
1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
Actual imports

Council of Economic Advisers

Actual exports

Forecasted imports

Forecasted exports

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
Note: Actuals were deflated to 2022 dollars using import/export price indexes. Post-2007:Q4 forecast based on linear
trend in each series from 2002:Q1 to 2007:Q4; post-2019:Q4 forecast based on linear trend in each series from 2009:Q3
to 2019:Q4. Trade data are on a balance of payments basis. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

U.S. Trade Growth Tracks Global Trends: Signs of a Recent Slowdown
and Recovery
U.S. trade growth has broadly tracked global trade growth over the past
three decades (WTO 2023b). Between 1993 and 2023, U.S. trade in goods
and services grew at an average annual rate of 4.4 percent, which was faster
than the average annual rate of 2.4 percent growth for the U.S. economy.9
As with broader economic activity, U.S. trade flows are often broken
out into two major categories: goods trade and services trade. Goods trade
includes the importing or exporting of tangible products (e.g., automobiles
and cell phones), while services trade includes the importing or exporting
of intangible products (e.g., tourism and insurance). Demand for goods and
services is driven by different forces, as exemplified by pandemic-induced
shutdowns and work-from-home mandates that led to increased demand for
household goods and a sharp decline in demand for such services as diningin restaurants and international travel (CEA 2023a). Historically, services
trade has been less sensitive than goods trade to macroeconomic shocks.
Real trade flows underscore this point. Figures 5-4 and 5-5 compare actual
trade flows (in goods and services, respectively) with alternative paths, forecasting continued growth at pre–global financial crisis linear trend rates after
the start of the crisis and at 2009–19 linear trend rates after the start of the
pandemic. The negative demand shock during and after the crisis depressed
The real GDP growth rate for 2023 was calculated as the simple average of the annualized real
growth rate over the period 2023:Q1–2023:Q3.

9

International Trade and Investment Flows | 181

Figure 5-5. Real Quarterly Trade in Services, Actual versus Forecasted,
1992–2023
Millions of real 2022 dollars

300,000

Forecasts based on
linear trend between
2002 and 2007

250,000

Forecasts based on
linear trend between
2009 and 2019

200,000
150,000
100,000
50,000
0
1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
Actual imports

Council of Economic Advisers

Actual exports

Forecasted imports

Forecasted exports

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
Note: Actuals were deflated to 2022 dollars using import/export price indexes. Post-2007:Q4 forecast based on linear trend
in each series from 2002:Q1 to 2007:Q4; post-2019:Q4 forecast based on linear trend in each series from 2009:Q3 to 2019:Q4.
Trade data are on a balance of payments basis. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

both goods and services trade flows; however, the impact was more muted
for services trade flows. The slowdown in U.S. goods trade growth (particularly in goods imports) was therefore a key driver of the plateauing in overall
U.S. trade flows after the crisis.
Unlike during the global financial crisis, trade in both goods and
services collapsed in 2020 due to mobility restrictions motivated by public
health precautions that drove supply chain disruptions and brought global
travel to a sudden halt (OECD 2022; IMF 2022). After the pandemic, goods
trade flows recovered rapidly, especially for U.S. imports, which soon rose
above the trend forecasted before the pandemic and returned to this trend
in late 2023. U.S. goods exports recovered more slowly, but are near their
forecasted trend. These recovery paths offer reason for cautious optimism
that in 2024, both goods exports and imports will remain in line with their
trends before the pandemic (figure 5-4).
The outlook for services—namely, services exports—is more uncertain (for a definition of services, see BEA 2023a). Services imports (including American travel abroad) recovered to their growth trend before the pandemic by early 2022 but slowed in the early part of 2023 and are near their
long-term trend (figure 5-5). Services exports have not yet returned to their
long-term trend. However, there are reasons for optimism. Services exports
exhibited positive growth throughout 2023 and, on a monthly basis, reached
a historic high in November 2023 (U.S. Census Bureau 2023). And services
export sectors—including the financial sector, telecommunications, computer and information services, and intellectual property (e.g., patent and
182 |

Chapter 5

Figure 5-6. U.S. Services Exports by Broad Product Categories, 1999–2023
Billions of real 2022 dollars

Billions of real 2022 dollars

1,200

300
250

1,000

200

800

150

600

100

400

50

200

0
1999
2001
2003
2005
Construction (left axis)
Intellectual property (left axis)
Other (left axis)
Travel (left axis)
Total services (right axis)

2007

2009

2011

0

2013
2015
2017
2019
2021
2023
Financial (left axis)
Telecommunication/computers/information (left axis)
Transportation (left axis)
Other business services (left axis)

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
Note: Dashed lines indicate types of services that did not experience declines during recessions. "Other" includes maintenance and
repairs, insurance, personal/cultural/recreational services, and government goods and services. Trade data are on a balance of
payments basis. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

trademark licensing), and other business services (including services related
to research and development, computer and data processing, engineering,
and services that cover management of construction projects)—were largely
unaffected by the pandemic (figure 5-6). This is important because these
collectively represent high-value-added activities in which the United States
continues to maintain a comparative advantage (Baccini, Osgood, and
Weymouth 2019).
Within services, telecommunications, computer and information services, and other business services have grown steadily and were especially
resilient during the three recessions between 1999 and 2023. Two factors
explain this resiliency. First, services trade is often governed by long-term
contracts that are not easily changed without long lag times. Second, services
trade represents an extreme form of highly agile, “just in time” production:
inventories do not present obstacles in the event of a shock, and resources
can be redirected quickly toward other goals (Miroudot 2022).
Travel (foreign spending on travel to the United States) and transportation (revenues from airplanes and ocean carriers for transporting freight and
passengers) exports accounted for most of the pandemic-era drop; travel has
yet to recover to its level before the pandemic. Travel advisories and health
restrictions exacerbated these weaknesses, suggesting that lifting these

International Trade and Investment Flows | 183

restrictions can play a role in helping travel exports recover at a faster pace.10
Transportation exports are closely linked to the exporting of merchandise
freight (BEA 2018), and goods exports recovered more slowly than goods
imports—dragging the recovery of transportation services exports after
the pandemic. Transportation services exports also include revenue from
transporting passengers and are, as a result, closely linked to commercial
and business travel. While both sectors are improving as travel restrictions
loosen, business travel has recovered more slowly, with large businesses
having to cut back on travel—motivated in part by an interest in reducing
carbon emissions (Georgiadis et al. 2023).
The United States’ sluggish trade growth in 2023 mirrors global developments. From a cyclical perspective, the slowdown in U.S. goods imports
may be partly attributable to the postpandemic normalization toward services consumption (including nontradable services like restaurants and tradable services like travel), away from goods consumption (U.S. Department
of the Treasury 2023; CEA 2023a, chap. 2). Higher U.S. interest rates and
associated borrowing costs are also likely to affect goods imports negatively, since durable goods such as cars, home furnishings, and capital goods
are often purchased using borrowed funds (Romei 2023). Both goods and
services exports are negatively affected by slower growth in foreign markets
like Europe and China and by higher interest rates, which together are leading to lower external demand for U.S. exports. From a secular perspective,
the slowdown in trade could also reflect longer-term factors, including compositional changes in GVCs. The near-term outlook for overall U.S. trade
growth remains uncertain, in light of the many factors at play.

U.S. Trade Deficits Are Driven by Aggregate Saving and Investment
Patterns
A country’s overall trade balance is the difference in value between its
imports and exports. A country that imports more than it exports runs a
trade deficit, while a country that exports more than it imports runs a trade
surplus. The United States is a net exporter of services and a net importer of
goods. Because the magnitude of its goods deficit far outweighs that of its
services surplus, overall, the United States has run a trade deficit since the
early 1990s (figure 5-7). In 2022, the annual value of the U.S. goods trade
deficit reached an all-time high and expanded as a percentage of GDP, and
For example, while flights between the United States and China—a major source of U.S. tourist
arrivals—were slated to increase from 48 a week to 70 a week beginning in November 2023,
these figures remain well below the 340 flights a week that connected the countries before the
pandemic (Bloomberg 2023). Still, developments suggest continued expansion in services exports
as pandemic-era travel policies ease further; e.g., China lifted its ban on group travel to the United
States in August 2023, which will allow large-scale tour groups to once again visit the United States
(Cheng 2023).
10

184 |

Chapter 5

Figure 5-7. U.S. Trade Balances and Real Growth, 1992–2023

Percentage of GDP

Percent, year-over-year
14

14

12

12

10

10

8

8

6

6

4

4

2

2

0

0

-2

-2

-4

-4

-6

-6
-8

1992

1995
1998
2001
2004
Goods balance (left axis)
Trade balance (left axis)

2007

2010

2013

2016
2019
2022
Services balance (left axis)
Real GDP growth (right axis)

-8

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
Note: Trade data are on a balance of payments (BOP) basis. Real GDP is seasonally adjusted at an annualized rate.
Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

the U.S. services trade surplus contracted as a percentage of GDP. These
trends started to reverse more recently, with the 2023 U.S. annual trade
deficit contracting by nearly 19 percent compared with 2022.
Trade deficits can elicit negative attention if the presumption is that
the GDP accounting identity (where negative net exports—exports minus
imports—are subtracted from GDP) describes the totality of the relationship
between trade and growth. Trade deficits are also sometimes associated
with import competition, which has historically generated concentrated
employment losses for certain groups of workers. However, the connections
between trade deficits, economic growth, and employment are closely tied
to broader macroeconomic conditions. For example, when an economy is
operating at full employment, a rising trade deficit can be a pressure-release
valve, providing needed supplies of imported goods and services that help
prevent overheating (Baker 2014). Moreover, imports complement domestic
spending on American goods and services, so that their negative accounting
impact on GDP is partially offset by the domestic value added generated,

International Trade and Investment Flows | 185

Box 5-1. Trade Balances and Capital
Flows—Fundamental Drivers
Overall trade balances. The fundamental drivers of a country’s overall
trade balance are its relative saving and investment rates—both public
and private (Ghosh and Ramakrishnan 2024). Countries with lower
domestic saving than domestic investment (likely as a result of low
domestic saving rates, high domestic investment rates due to attractive
economic opportunities, or a combination of the two) tend to run trade
deficits and accompanying current account deficits (where the current
account balance is defined as the trade balance plus net foreign investment income plus net transfer payments from foreign income sources
like worker remittances and foreign aid). The trade balance typically
accounts for the bulk of the current account balance and is highly correlated with it, so, for expositional simplicity, we focus on the trade
balance. Trade deficits are necessarily matched by capital and financial
account surpluses (the net inflows of foreign lending necessary to
finance the trade deficit)—as is the case with the United States.
There are several schools of thought on what drives the United
States’ trade deficit. One emphasizes a supply-side view, where much of
the onus for the United States’ capital and financial account surplus and
trade deficit can be placed on other countries’ excess supply of savings
or foreign saving gluts (Bernanke 2005; Pettis 2017; Klein and Pettis
2020). Under this framing, the United States absorbs disproportionately
large inflows of capital from countries where saving rates are relatively
high. This can occur due to both government policies (e.g., large foreign
reserve acquisitions, exchange rate management to influence currency
values, and suppression of consumption to boost internal savings) and
myriad other factors (including weak social safety nets or demographics)
(Devadas and Loayza 2018). When saving is too high relative to investment, this can result in weak demand for imports and capital outflows to
other countries, potentially causing distortive financial bubbles in recipient countries (McBride and Chatzky 2019). By emphasizing foreign
influences on domestic trade balances, this view downplays the impact
of domestic saving and investment. Under this model, excess saving
flowing from one country to another would tend to lower the receiving
country’s interest rate and appreciate its currency, leading to lower saving, higher investment, and a larger trade deficit.
A second school of thought emphasizes a demand-side view (e.g.,
Knight and Scacciavillani 1998). According to this theory, countries
can have excess demand for saving due to their outsized productive
investment opportunities compared with available domestic saving.
Needed inflows are imported via net sales of assets to foreigners (e.g.,
sales of Treasuries and securities and FDI inflows). These large net
capital inflows allow for a level of consumption and investment that

186 |

Chapter 5

Figure 5-i. U.S.–China Trade Deficit, 2009–22

Trade balance as a percentage of GDP
0.5
0.0
-0.5
-1.0
-1.5
-2.0
-2.5

2009

2011

2013
ATP goods

2015

2017

Non-ATP goods

2019

2021

Services

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Census Bureau; CEA calculations.
Note: ATP = advanced technology products. Trade data are on a balance of payments basis.
2024 Economic Report of the President

could not otherwise occur; with access to these foreign countries’ excess
savings, domestic households, firms, and government all benefit by
incurring lower borrowing costs. Over time, such investments can yield
strong returns and higher productivity—allowing them to service their
accumulated debts and potentially generating trade surpluses (Obstfeld
and Rogoff 1996).
Of course, together with other explanations—for example,
Caballero, Farhi, and Gourinchas (2017) on safe asset shortages—the
excess savings and excess demand views may all play a role and interact
in ways that can be problematic in some cases, particularly if excess
foreign funding supports excess demand that fuels unproductive, distortionary investment. An oft-cited example is the U.S. housing bubble
of the early 2000s, when excess foreign saving helped inflate a real
estate bubble that crashed with devastating and lasting consequences
(Jørgensen 2023).
Bilateral trade balances. A country’s overall deficit is the sum of
its bilateral balances, of which some generally will be negative and some
positive. While the overall balance reflects the macroeconomic factors
that determine saving and investment, bilateral imbalances can reflect a
comparative advantage—with systematic heterogeneity across different
goods and services (IMF 2019). As an example, figure 5-i divides the
U.S.-China deficit into services and two broad product-group categories:
advanced technology product (ATP) goods and non-ATP goods. ATP
goods include products that embody advanced technologies in biotechnology, life science, opto-electronics, information and communications,

International Trade and Investment Flows | 187

electronics, flexible manufacturing, advanced materials, aerospace,
weapons, and nuclear technology (Abbott et al. 1989). Two-thirds of
the ratio between the goods trade deficit and GDP is driven by trade in
non-ATP goods, and the United States has a long-standing, albeit small,
surplus with China in services—highlighting the role of comparative
advantage in determining the U.S.-China bilateral deficit, with the
United States showing relative advantage in technology-intensive production technologies and services sectors compared with China. China
has a comparative advantage in non-ATP goods.

along with downward pressure on inflation.11 Trade, including via higher
imports, can also boost the productivity of importing firms and the broader
economy by supporting higher growth (CEA 2015a). Data support this view;
the U.S. trade deficit tends to be countercyclical and is largest during periods of strong GDP growth because the same drivers of increased domestic
demand (including savings and investment rates) also tend to fuel increased
import demand (CEA 2015b). Box 5-1 discusses these fundamental drivers and the trade-offs from running large deficits, including how excessive
foreign savings flowing into a country can fuel unproductive, distortionary
investments over time (Bernanke 2005).

The United States Leads in Global FDI Flows
The United States is the largest source of and destination for FDI flows
globally.12 Over 20 percent of both U.S. FDI inflows and outflows in 2022
were targeted at cross-border manufacturing investments (OECD 2023b;
BEA 2023b). In addition to providing another source of financing for
domestic investments, FDI tends to increase wages and productivity in
target firms (Hale and Xu 2016) and can also generate positive spillovers

The COVID-19 pandemic offers an instructive anecdote. Imports surged during lockdowns,
allowing consumption of goods to increase and help buoy the recovery (Higgins and Klitgaard
2021). A large share of final expenditures on imported goods is generated domestically, as shown
by Hale et al. (2019): “Nearly half of the amount we spend on imported goods stays in the United
States to pay for the local component of the retail price of these goods. . . . Almost half of the total
expenditures on imports is embedded in the production of U.S. goods and services that use imported
intermediate inputs. Taking all of these factors into account, import content in total [personal
consumption expenditures] was just over 10% in 2017. The high share of local content means that
imports generate a number of transportation and retail jobs that might or might not be as numerous if
these goods were produced in the United States.”
12
Global comparison based on data from the first half of 2023 (OECD 2023b).
11

188 |

Chapter 5

across U.S. firms within an industry (Keller and Yeaple 2009).13 Reflecting
long-standing trends, the large majority of U.S. FDI flows are either destined
for or originate from the country’s closest trading partners. For example, in
2022, Canada and countries in Europe accounted for 79 percent of inward
U.S. FDI flows and 65 percent of outward U.S. FDI flows (BEA 2023c).
FDI flows are less volatile across time than cross-border securities
flows, but they still tend to fluctuate (Lipsey 2000). In order to smooth
out some of the volatility, figure 5-8 shows the three-quarter moving average of quarterly U.S. FDI-to-GDP inflows and outflows, as well as linear
trend lines for each series before and after the global financial crisis. The
smoothed series still shows sizable fluctuations in FDI flows, often durFigure 5-8. U.S. FDI Flows as a Percentage of GDP, 1990:Q1–2023:Q2
Three-quarter moving average (percent)
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
FDI outflows as a percentage of GDP

Council of Economic Advisers

FDI inflows as a percentage of GDP

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
Note: FDI = foreign direct investment. The moving average is centered on each quarter. Gray bars indicate recessions.
Linear trend lines (dotted lines) are based on periods before and after the global financial crisis.
2024 Economic Report of the President

ing nonrecessionary periods, which reflect the acyclicity of FDI flows in
FDI often correlates with the arrival not only of technological advances but also other intangible
assets, including novel managerial approaches and production processes, technical know-how, and
lessons from learning-by-doing in a cross-border setting (Branstetter 2006). FDI can also promote
trade through creating new cross-border commercial connections, and FDI’s effects on productivity
can result in increased domestic and global competitiveness for a firm and its peers. But absorptive
capacity, including an educated workforce and sufficient research and development investment,
is needed for a country to reap the benefits of FDI (Blomström, Kokko, and Mucchielli 2003).
Evidence from the United States signals that horizontal productivity spillovers across firms in an
industry tend to be strongest in high-tech industries and for firms most distant from the productivity
frontier. These effects accounted for between 8 to 19 percent of U.S. manufacturing productivity
growth during the late 1980s and early 1990s (Keller and Yeaple 2009).

13

International Trade and Investment Flows | 189

advanced markets (BIS 2017). Explanations for such fluctuations are often
unique to each episode and flow type. For example, the decline in U.S. FDI
outflows in 2018 has been attributed to a dramatic reduction in reinvested
earnings (retained profits) abroad due to a regulatory change in the tax
treatment of offshore profits.14 During that same year, a large portion of the
decline in U.S. FDI inflows was attributed to the reincorporation of a single
technology solutions provider—Broadcom; changes to the ownership structure reclassified the firm’s U.S. affiliate as a U.S.-headquartered company,
making its associated transactions no longer cross-border (Tabova 2020).
Taking a longer view, U.S. FDI outflows have broadly been on a
downward path since the global financial crisis due to many of the same
cyclical and secular headwinds that have had an impact on trade flows
(see the linear trends shown in figure 5-8) (UNCTAD 2023). Since 2022,
they have largely leveled off as a share of GDP. FDI inflows as a share
of GDP fell 19 percent from 2021 to 2022—more than double the median
post–global financial crisis year-on-year declines but smaller than the large
declines in the early 2000s and mid-2010s.15 The 2022 drop was primarily
driven by a fall in cross-border mergers and acquisitions, as tighter global
financial conditions and uncertainty in financial markets caused borrowing
costs to increase (UNCTAD 2023).
Aggregate flows mask the different types of foreign investment
transactions, including those that expand an economy’s production capacity
through new facilities or expanded existing facilities. Capacity-expanding
FDI flows into manufacturing have, for instance, partially offset aggregate
weak FDI trends, both globally and in the United States.16
The United States was the largest destination for capacity-expanding
FDI in 2022 (UNCTAD 2023). FDI expenditures in new U.S. establishments
and expansions of existing facilities were concentrated in manufacturing,
which represented almost two-thirds of total new FDI first-year expenditures in 2022 (BEA 2023d).17 This concentration of new FDI investments in
As noted by Tabova (2020), “For most of the period prior to 2018, reinvested earnings accounted
for the majority of [flows of U.S. direct investment abroad, USDIA]. The drop in USDIA in 2018
is driven by the drop in reinvested earnings as a result of the 2017 [Tax Cuts and Jobs Act] that
eliminated the tax incentive to keep earnings abroad and led to U.S. companies repatriating a large
part of their accumulated earnings abroad.”
15
After the global financial crisis, and measuring year-on-year percentage changes at a quarterly
frequency, FDI outflows to GDP declined at a median rate of –2.3 percent and FDI inflows to GDP
declined at a rate of –7.9 percent.
16
According to UNCTAD (2023), capacity-expanding FDI announcements grew by 64 percent year
on year, to $1.2 trillion globally in 2022, rising by 37 percent in advanced markets and more than
doubling in developing countries.
17
The Bureau of Economic Analysis’s (2023d) survey of new FDI in the United States identifies
capacity-expanding transactions that create new U.S. establishments and the building of new
physical facilities by existing U.S. affiliates of foreign-owned firms, as well as other transactions
from foreign investors for new acquisitions of U.S. businesses.
14

190 |

Chapter 5

Figure 5-9. Real FDI in U.S. Manufacturing New Establishments and
Expansions, 2014–22
Billions of 2022 dollars

6
5
4
3
2
1

0
2014

2015

2016
Total

2017

2018

Businesses expanded

2019

2020

2021

2022

Businesses established

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis; Bureau of Labor Statistics; CEA calculations.
Note: Series were deflated using the Producer Price Index: Total Manufacturing (2022 = 100). New FDI refers to
transactions that create new U.S. establishments and the building of new facilities by existing U.S. affiliates of foreignowned firms. First-year expenditures include expenditures in the year in which the transaction occured.
2024 Economic Report of the President

manufacturing deviates from earlier years; the manufacturing sector’s average share of capacity-expanding FDI spending from 2014 to 2021 was less
than one-third. FDI flows in new U.S. manufacturing production capacity
increased 247 percent from 2021 to 2022, reaching $5.3 billion and reversing a multiyear downward trend that began in 2019 (figure 5-9).18
These new foreign investments in manufacturing projects in the
United States are concentrated in strategically important sectors, including
advanced technologies and clean energy; foreign investments in computer
and electronic products (including semiconductor manufacturing) were
among the largest, at $1.8 billion of capacity-expanding FDI flows in 2022
(BEA 2023d).19 There has also been a sizable number of announced FDI

In 2022, expenditures outperformed the average from before the pandemic (2014–19) by a factor
of 1.7.
19
Looking at more speculative planned investment expenditures, the increase in capacity-expanding
FDI in the computer and electronics sector is striking, rising from $17 million in 2021 to $54 billion
in 2022 in real terms and representing roughly two-thirds of 2022’s planned capacity-expanding
manufacturing FDI.
18

International Trade and Investment Flows | 191

Box 5-2. The U.S. High-Capacity Battery
Supply Chain and the Complementary
Role of Domestic and Trade Policies
Battery supply chains in the United States illustrate the importance of
international trade partnerships in complementing domestic legislation
to achieve clean energy goals. The high-capacity battery supply chain is
characterized by five main value chains: (1) raw material production, (2)
material refinement and processing, (3) material manufacturing and cell
fabrication, (4) battery pack and end-use product manufacturing, and (5)
battery end of life and recycling (White House 2021b).
The 2022 Inflation Reduction Act (IRA) offers critical support to
clean energy industries, particularly the high-capacity battery value chain
for electric vehicles and energy storage. The Advanced Manufacturing
Production Tax Credit (45X) and Advanced Energy Project Investment
Tax Credit (48C) can allay almost a third of capital investment faced by
battery manufacturers (Mehdi and Morenhout 2023). In 2023, under the
Bipartisan Infrastructure Law (BIL), the Department of Energy allocated
$1.9 billion to build and expand commercial-scale facilities to extract
and process battery materials (e.g., lithium and graphite) and produce
components (U.S. Department of Energy 2023).
Provision of tax credits under the IRA and public funding under
BIL are designed to “crowd in” private sector investments (Boushey
2023). Between July 1, 2022, and June 30, 2023, the U.S. economy
received a total of $213 billion in new investments in the clean energy
Figure 5-ii. Battery Investments as a Share of Total Actual
Manufacturing Investments, 2021–23
Investment level (billions of real 2022 dollars)

12

BIL

Percentage of total investments
80

IRA

70

10

60

8

50

6

40
30

4

20

2

10

0
2021:Q1 2021:Q2 2021:Q3 2021:Q4 2022:Q1 2022:Q2 2022:Q3 2022:Q4 2023:Q1 2023:Q2 2023:Q3
Battery value (left axis)

Council of Economic Advisers

Battery share (right axis)

Sources: Clean Investment Monitor; CEA calculations.
Note: BIL = Bipartisan Infastructure Law; IRA = Inflation Reduction Act.
2024 Economic Report of the President

192 |

Chapter 5

0

Table 5-i. Percentage of Imports to the United States in the HighCapacity Battery Supply Chain by Top Partner Countries
Year

2021

China (percent) South Korea (percent) Japan (percent)

2022

2023

25.3

11.6

16.1

33.9

14.7

14.2

37.4

17.8

Canada (percent)
18.6

12.4

13.6

10.2

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Trade Data Monitor; CEA calculations.
Note: This table displays the percentage share of imported products in the high-capacity battery supply
chain from the top four partner countries. The "battery supply chain" is defined by the set of 10-digit HS
codes identified as inputs and lithium-ion batteries and parts by the Department of Commerce (2023). The
top-four country ranking is based on 2022 import values.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Table 5-ii. Percentage of Imports by Raw Materials and Lithium-Ion Battery Parts by Top
Sources, 2021–23

Imports

Raw Materials

Lithium-Ion Batteries and Parts
Council of Economic Advisers

China (percent)
8.0%
92.0%

South Korea (percent)
33.8%
66.2%

Japan (percent)
47.1%
52.9%

Canada (percent)
98.1%
1.9%

Sources: Trade Data Monitor; CEA calculations.
Note: This table displays the percentage share of imported products in the high-capacity battery supply chain from the top four partner countries.
The "battery supply chain" is defined by the set of 10-digit HS codes identified as inputs and lithium-ion batteries and parts by the Department
of Commerce (2023). The top-four country ranking is based on 2022 import values.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Table 5-iii. Ford Motor Company’s Investment
Announcements in High-Capacity Battery Materials, 2022–23

Materials Being Supplied
Nickel

Lithium
Council of Economic Advisers

Material Supplier (Country)

Arrangement

BHP Nickel West (Australia)

Agreement

Ioneer (United States);
Lake Resources (Argentina)

Agreement
Agreement

Vale (Indonesia) and Zhejiang
Huayou Cobalt (China);

Joint venture

Source: Reuters.
2024 Economic Report of the President

sector, representing a 37 percent increase from the prior year (Bermel
et al. 2023). Within manufacturing, actual investments in batteries
accounted for the largest share—72 percent—of total manufacturing
investments in 2023:Q3 (figure 5-ii).
The most critical metals for producing lithium-ion batteries are
lithium, cobalt, nickel, manganese, and graphite (Tracy 2022). Access
to these metals and related battery materials is fundamental to building
a flourishing U.S. battery supply chain. Globally, China controls most
of the market for mining and processing of critical battery materials
(International Energy Agency 2022). China’s share of imports to the
United States of products in the battery supply chain has been steadily
increasing since 2021 (table 5-i).
Among the top source countries, most battery supply chain imports
from China and South Korea are of lithium-ion batteries and parts, most
battery supply chain imports from Canada are of raw materials, and

International Trade and Investment Flows | 193

battery supply chain imports from Japan are more evenly distributed
between battery components and raw materials (table 5-ii). Company
announcements also provide tangible insights into planned domestic
and international investments to secure battery raw materials from
miners and refiners (table 5-iii). For example, Ford Motor Company
has recently entered into various arrangements to secure battery raw
materials, as table 5-iii shows.
In the long run, a suite of bilateral agreements and frameworks to
promote climate goals between the United States and partner countries
are expected to pave the way to achieve diversification of sources for
critical minerals. The U.S.-Japan Critical Minerals Agreement enables
the countries to develop and strengthen critical minerals supply chains
using best practices in labor and environmental standards (USTR 2023f);
the Australia–United States Climate, Critical Minerals, and Clean
Energy Transformation Compact is designed to coordinate on several
issues vital to clean energy and critical minerals supply chains (White
House 2023a); and the Minerals Security Partnership, with 13 countries,
targets financial and diplomatic support for projects along the minerals
supply chain (U.S. Department of State n.d.)

investments in clean energy in recent years (Bermel et al. 2023).20 While
these projects are in earlier stages of planning or implementation than the
FDI projects discussed above, and therefore are more speculative, foreign
investors nevertheless account for one-third of all clean energy announcements. Of $154 billion in announcements over the period 2021:Q1–2023:Q2,
$51 billion in announcements stems from companies with headquarters
abroad. South Korean and Japanese firms account for some of the largest
announcements in clean energy (including electric vehicles and batteries),
while Canadian firms plan to invest in critical minerals projects. Box 5-2
highlights the complementary roles of international and domestic policies
in promoting a more resilient battery supply chain, including through FDI
investments.
This is based on the Clean Investment Monitor (2024), a joint project of Rhodium Group and the
Massachusetts Institute for Technology’s Center for Energy and Environmental Policy Research. The
data set includes detailed metadata for manufacturing, utility-scale energy, and industrial facilities.
All included facilities have investments during the time horizon 2021:Q1–2023:Q2. Investments
fall into one of four camps: announced (excluding announcements of “intent,” without specifying
a particular location and committing resources); under construction or postconstruction but not yet
operating; operating or offline but planned to return to operation; and canceled, retired, or offline,
with no plans to return to operation. Joint ventures, investments in utilities, and canceled investments
were dropped.

20

194 |

Chapter 5

The near-term outlook for FDI inflows remains uncertain. While
the Biden-Harris Administration’s industrial strategy is attracting foreign
investment in capacity-expanding manufacturing projects in strategic sectors like clean energy and advanced technology, inflationary pressures in
partner countries have led to higher interest rates and tightening global
financial conditions (IMF 2023). Global economic conditions will continue
shaping the flows of cross-border mergers and acquisitions—a major component of FDI flows.

The Rise of Global Value Chains and
Early Signs of Reallocation
Global value chains are essential for understanding several important trends:
How trade and FDI have changed since the 1990s, the recent attention on
promoting supply chain resilience through greater supplier diversification,
and multinational corporations’ central role in concentrating production.
GVCs allow for the production of a single good to take place across several
countries, and for firms to specialize in the assembly of specific intermediate goods according to their comparative advantage (World Bank 2020).
In 2009, for example, a Boeing plant in Everett, Washington, assembled
Boeing’s 787 Dreamliner from parts sourced from around the world: The
wings were sourced from Japan, the horizontal stabilizers from Italy, the
wingtips from South Korea, and the engines from the United Kingdom
(Shenhar et al. 2016). Each country added value to the production of the
aircraft along the chain.
Two key developments allowed GVCs to gain such prominence in
global trade: the wave of trade liberalization (including decreases in tariff
rates), which was led by the United States and other major economies in
the 1990s and early 2000s (Brainard 2001; Aiyar and Ilyina 2023); and the
reduced costs of coordinating across distant locations, which were driven by
the information and communications technology revolution (Baldwin 2016).
Lower communication costs also facilitated the transfer of knowledge both
within and across firm boundaries, and allowed firms to locate production
facilities away from their headquarters—even across national borders (Fort
2017). Firms have taken advantage of these changes—and also of advances
in transportation technologies—to unbundle their production processes into
tasks performed at different locations, leveraging varying factor costs to
achieve greater efficiencies.21
However, benefits of offshoring in lower production costs may be offset by higher coordination
costs (Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg 2008). For example, the Boeing Company cited complexities
coordinating across its global supply chain for delays in developing the 787 Dreamliner (Peterson
2011).
21

International Trade and Investment Flows | 195

Multinational firms—themselves fueled by the information and communications revolution—have been particularly adept at taking advantage
of cross-border input cost differentials. By establishing foreign affiliates
through FDI, these firms can mediate trade with both foreign subsidiaries
(within-firm trade) and unaffiliated firms (arm’s-length trade) within GVCs
(OECD 2018). Multinational firms accounted for, respectively, 65 percent
and 60 percent of U.S. goods exports and imports on average between 1997
and 2017 (Kamal, McCloskey, and Ouyang 2022).22 And within-firm trade
accounts for a large share of multinationals’ total trade flows: In 2022, onethird (33.7 percent) of U.S. exports and almost half (46.6 percent) of U.S.
imports by value were between multinational parent firms and their affiliates
or related parties (U.S. Census Bureau 2022).23 The growth of trade within
multinational firms (i.e., flows between parents and affiliates) underscores
the highly fragmented nature of production.24
Global supply chains’ prevalence in U.S. production can also be
observed in the high share of intermediate goods or imported input trade
in the United States (figure 5-10).25 Industrial supplies (e.g., lumber and
steelmaking materials) and capital goods (e.g., drilling equipment)—typically, inputs into final goods—are highly positively correlated with GVC
trade and accounted on average for over half of imports between 1992 and
2022 (Hummels, Ishii, and Yi 2001; Baldwin and López-González 2014).
The import share of industrial materials grew more than that of any other
product group between 1992 through the onset of the global financial crisis
in 2008, showcasing how multinationals’ FDI and the establishment of GVC
linkages can support greater trade flows.
Multinationals are major contributors to the U.S. economy, especially in the manufacturing sector,
accounting for 70 percent of all domestic manufacturing employment, more than 50 percent of
all nonresidential capital expenditures, and more than 80 percent of all the industrial research and
development performed in the United States that underpins innovative output (Foley, Hines, and
Wessel 2021, chap. 1).
23
“Exports: Title 15 of USC Chapter 9, Section 301” of the Foreign Trade Regulations defines a
related party transaction as one “involving trade between a U.S. principal party in interest and an
ultimate consignee where either party owns directly or indirectly 10 percent or more of the other
party.” “Imports: Title 19 of USC Chapter 4, Section 1401a (g)(1)” of the Tariff Act of 1930 defines
related persons as including “any person directly or indirectly owning, controlling, or holding with
power to vote, 5 percent or more of the outstanding voting stock or shares of any organization and
such organization.” (See https://www.ecfr.gov/current/title-19/chapter-I/part-152.)
24
Two-way, related-party trade—where the multinational parent or affiliate sends partially finished
goods for processing, after which they are shipped back—is one possible indication of production
fragmentation. Other arrangements, however, including those in which the affiliate ships finished
goods to the parent without any shipments from the parent—or vice versa—are also possible
(Ramondo, Rappoport, and Ruhl 2016).
25
End use is a commodity classification system that identifies merchandise based on principal use
rather than the physical characteristics of the merchandise (U.S. Census Bureau 2012). A complete
list is available at census.gov/foreign-trade/reference/codes/enduse/imeumstr.txt. The Bureau of
Economic Analysis developed the concept of end use demand for balance of payments purposes.
22

196 |

Chapter 5

Figure 5-10. U.S. Goods Imports by End Use, 1990–2023
Trillions of 2022 dollars
3.5

3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
Foods, feed, and beverages
Capital goods except automotives
Consumer goods (nonfood) excl. auto

Industrial supplies and materials
Automotive vehicles, parts, and engines
Other goods

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Census Bureau; Bureau of Economic Analysis; CEA calculations.
Note: Trade data are on a Census basis. Deflated using industry-specific import price indexes. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of the President

The fact that GVC participation appears to have slowed since the
global financial crisis is also reflected in the intermediate trade data. The
imported share of U.S. industrial supplies and materials declined from 43
percent in 2008 to 25 percent in 2022—a decline inextricably linked to stagnation in post–global financial crisis trade flows (figure 5-10). Decreased
cross-border investment, due to an extended deleveraging process, translated into less investment in establishing new GVC linkages. And while
the economics literature shows that higher FDI flows are associated with
stronger “backward,” or upstream, GVC linkages (Fernandes, Kee, and
Winkler 2020), there are still positive signs of the United States’ participation in downstream or forward value chains. According to the Organization
for Economic Cooperation and Development’s (OECD 2023c) measure of
U.S. domestic value added in foreign countries’ exports, the United States’
forward value-added contributions as a share of foreign countries’ gross
exports increased from 24 percent in 2008 to 27 percent in 2020. Together
with other indicators, these patterns indicate a slowdown in GVC participation but not a wholesale retreat.

Early Evidence of Supplier Reallocation in 2023
While GVCs offer many benefits, successive economic shocks in recent
years, including those caused by the COVID-19 pandemic and Russia’s
further invasion of Ukraine, illustrate their vulnerability. Supply chain
bottlenecks can generate substantial economic disruptions, especially when

International Trade and Investment Flows | 197

firms concentrate reliance on a single producer (Baldwin and Freeman
2022; CEA 2022, chap. 6). And in the past three decades, the manufacturing
of intermediate goods has become highly geographically concentrated. In
1995, China was the top industrial input supplier to about 5 percent of U.S.
manufacturing sectors; by 2018, that share had climbed to over 60 percent
(Baldwin, Freeman, and Theodorakopoulos 2023).
Concentration of suppliers can lead to effects that can be felt both
domestically and abroad. The recent global semiconductor shortage, for
instance, exacerbated a nearly 30 percent decline in U.S. motor vehicle
assemblies between January and September 2021, and the average American
auto worker lost more than 2 work hours per week as a result—tantamount
to a 6 percent weekly pay cut (Bernstein 2023). Meanwhile, pandemicrelated supply chain disruptions exacerbated higher prices in the United
States (Santacreu and LaBelle 2022) and had negative effects on real GDP
(Bonadio et al. 2020). Along with increased onshoring, diversification to
include multiple locations and suppliers, especially for critical nodes in supply chains, can increase the resilience of the production chain and minimize
exposure to economic and security risks (Iakovou and White 2020; Shih
2020; IMF 2022).26
Some early evidence suggests that this sort of supplier diversification is
already under way in the United States. While the European Union, Mexico,
Canada, and China remain the United States’ top trading partners for both
exports and imports, the composition of U.S. trade vis-à-vis each of these
partners has shifted (figure 5-11). Between 2017 and 2023, China’s share
of U.S. imports declined by almost 8 percentage points, from 21.6 percent
to 13.9 percent. By the beginning of 2023, Mexico had become the United
States’ top trading partner—having increased its share of U.S. imports by
2 percentage points since 2017—and U.S. import shares from South Korea,
Canada, Germany, and Vietnam have also increased.
With respect to advanced technology products (ATP)—which include
semiconductors—the share of U.S. imports from China has decreased by
almost 14 percentage points (figure 5-12).27 Vietnam experienced the largest
increase in ATP import shares, followed by Taiwan, Ireland, and Germany.
Diversification through onshoring should similarly guard against concentrated reliance on a small
set of domestic suppliers. For example, the United States relies almost exclusively on domestic
sources for its infant formula. When a domestic U.S. infant formula facility was temporarily closed
in 2022, domestic supply declined dramatically. Policymakers navigated this crisis by taking
various actions to facilitate formula imports by a factor of 17 (WTO 2023a). Nonetheless, supplier
diversification may not achieve supply chain resiliency if shocks are global and are correlated across
locations (Goldberg and Reed 2023).
27
ATP include products that embody advanced technologies in biotechnology, life science, optoelectronics, information and communications, electronics, flexible manufacturing, advanced
materials, aerospace, weapons, and nuclear technology (Abbott et al. 1989).
26

198 |

Chapter 5

Figure 5-11. Percentage Change in U.S. Import Share, by Country, 2017–23

Change in import share (percentage points)
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10

Mexico

Vietnam

Canada

South Korea

Germany

Japan

China

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Trade Data Monitor; CEA calculations.
Note: These changes were calculated using nominal import values between 2017 and 2023. These countries were selected
based on having the highest import shares in 2023 and largest changes in import shares between 2017 and 2023.
2024 Economic Report of the President

Figure 5-12. Percentage Change in U.S. Import Share of Advanced
Technology Products, by Country, 2017–23
Change in import share (percentage points)

10

5
0
-5
-10
-15
-20

Vietnam

Taiwan

Ireland

Germany

Japan

Mexico

China

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Trade Data Monitor; CEA calculations.
Note: Advanced Technology Products (ATP) definition from U.S. Census Bureau. Calculated using nominal ATP import values
between 2017 and 2023. These countries were selected based on having the highest ATP import shares in 2023 and largest
changes in ATP import shares between 2017 and 2023.
2024 Economic Report of the President

These compositional changes took place both in response to U.S.
trade policy and longer-term factors in China, including rising unit labor
costs (Yang, Zhu, and Ren 2023) and declining FDI (Bloomberg 2023).
Mexico’s and Canada’s gains in overall U.S. market share are consistent
with patterns of near-shoring, while the other countries gaining share are
also trusted partners—consistent with notions of friend-shoring. The marked
increase in Vietnam’s share of ATP imports, for instance, is consistent with
International Trade and Investment Flows | 199

the U.S.-Vietnam Comprehensive Strategic Partnership’s goals, including to
promote resiliency in semiconductor supply chains (White House 2023b).
These reallocations have also broadly been larger in industries that faced
higher U.S. import tariffs on goods sourced from China (Freund et al. 2023).
Recent shifts should however be interpreted with caution, for several
reasons. First, reallocation may result in increasing costs in the form of
higher import prices from alternative locations, at least in the short term.
Since 2017, U.S. import prices from Vietnam, Mexico, South Korea,
Taiwan, and Singapore have increased in sectors that faced a decline in the
U.S. share of imports from China (Alfaro and Chor 2023). Second, while
diversification in import sources is under way, U.S. supply chains still
remain closely, albeit indirectly, linked with China. Countries that have
gained the most U.S. market share between 2017 and 2022 are also deeply
engaged in supply chains with China (Freund et al. 2023).28 These ongoing
engagements suggest that global value chains have lengthened to include
several Asian economies, particularly when linking China and the United
States (Qiu, Shin, and Zhang 2023). Some of these dynamics may reflect
underlying fundamentals (including rising labor costs and policy uncertainty), but they may also reflect a higher likelihood of increased transshipments and circumvention of U.S. trade restrictions (Hancock 2023).

The Costs and Benefits of Global Integration
for Workers, Consumers, and Communities
Classical trade models highlight how trade can improve aggregate economic efficiency but also lead to a redistribution of income across factors
of production in a manner that can increase inequality. Aggregate welfare
gains arise from comparative advantage, specialization, and trade across
countries based on advantaged goods and services. In any given country,
increased specialization leads to a relative increase in labor demand and
wages for workers in advantaged sectors over those in less-advantaged
sectors.29 Foreign direct investment, including through multinationals,
can also shape wage inequality through higher relative demand for more
specialized labor—including demand for college-educated workers or labor
demand that evidences a skill bias (Feenstra and Hanson 1997; Hale and
Xu 2016). In short, the presence of unambiguous overall welfare gains from
The members of the Indo-Pacific Economic Framework received about one-third of their imports
from and sent about a fifth of their exports to China in 2021 (Dahlman and Lovely 2023). This
framework includes these countries: Australia, Brunei Darussalam, Fiji, India, Indonesia, Japan,
South Korea, Malaysia, New Zealand, the Philippines, Singapore, Thailand, and Vietnam.
29
The factor-based Heckscher-Ohlin model provides one example. However, other models, like
the Specific Factors model, also generate winners and losers among workers based on factors of
production that are specific (or fixed) to export or import sectors.
28

200 |

Chapter 5

global integration does not imply that everyone will benefit from these gains
equally—some workers will explicitly lose. Therefore, trade and investment
policies should facilitate maximizing the benefits of robust trade and foreign investment flows while concurrently mitigating integration’s negative
effects, in conjunction with domestic redistribution policies.

Global Integration and Inequality
The evidence for the impact of increased U.S. trade and foreign investment
flows on inequality reveals a complex set of patterns. Shifts in U.S. labor
demand based on increased specialization and the associated diversification
of production processes (e.g., via offshoring) have generated distributional consequences, particularly for domestic manufacturing employment.
Between 1993 and 2011, total nonfarm employment increased by roughly
21 million workers; however, manufacturing employment declined by
almost 30 percent, or 5 million workers (BLS 2023a, 2023b). To understand
the decline in manufacturing employment, two primary factors have been
examined empirically: The trade-based view identifies import competition
leading to labor-intensive industries moving abroad, while the technologybased view identifies innovations in production techniques—including automation—that reduced or changed the nature of labor demand (e.g., shifting
from demand for production workers to college-educated service workers).
Disentangling the potential explanations requires overcoming acute empirical challenges, since these forces are often complementary and reinforce one
another (Fort, Pierce, and Schott 2018). While the literature suggests that
both factors played a role (e.g., Galle and Lorentzen 2021), this subsection
highlights causal results from the trade-based explanation.
Part of the steep decline in U.S. manufacturing employment since
2000 has been linked to the sharp rise in Chinese import competition—a
dynamic referred to as the “China shock” (Autor, Dorn, and Hanson 2013).30
While there remains an active debate on the share of U.S. manufacturing job
losses that can be ascribed to increased Chinese imports, there is a broader

Close to a fifth (16 percent) of the decline in manufacturing employment between 2000 and
2007 has been attributed to the rise in import competition from China (Caliendo, Dvorkin, and
Parro 2019). Firms that reorganized activities away from the production of machinery, electronics,
or transportation equipment and toward wholesale, professional services (including research and
development), and management drove almost a third of the negative manufacturing employment
decline between 1990 and 2015 (Bloom et al. 2019). Several factors have been analyzed to
understand the surge in U.S. imports from China during this period, including the United States
granting China permanent normal trade relations in 2000, China’s accession to the World Trade
Organization in 2001, reduced trade and investment policy uncertainty associated with these policy
actions, and China’s own trade and domestic reforms (e.g., tariff reductions and privatizations)
(Lincicome and Anand 2023).
30

International Trade and Investment Flows | 201

consensus on its unequal distributional employment implications.31 The
shock grew during the 2000s and plateaued in 2010; however, its adverse
local employment effects persisted through the next decade (Autor, Dorn,
and Hanson 2021). Critically, the decline in manufacturing employment was
not evenly distributed across workers or space. On one hand, losses were
concentrated in geographic areas that were more reliant on import-competing industries and where workers had lower levels of formal educational
attainment—especially the South and Midwest (Autor, Dorn, and Hanson
2013). On the other hand, regions with higher levels of formal educational
attainment experienced employment gains during this period—largely
localized in services sectors (Bloom et al. 2019).32 These dynamics comport
with long-term shifts that occurred within U.S. manufacturing firms: greater
outsourcing via participation in GVCs and increased automation that led to a
reorientation away from physical production processes toward the provision
of intellectual services (e.g., research and development, design, and logistical services) (Fort, Pierce, and Schott 2018).
Import competition from China was also accompanied by a substantial
fall in U.S. consumer prices, with disproportionate benefits accruing to lowand middle-income households because they have higher shares of tradable
goods like food and apparel in their consumption baskets (Fajgelbaum and
Khandelwal 2016; Russ, Shambaugh, and Furman 2017). Causal estimates
suggest that a 1-percentage-point increase in Chinese import penetration led
to a decline in consumer price inflation of 1 to 2 percentage points—largely
reflecting indirect pro-competitive cost effects, where greater foreign competition induces domestic firms to lower markups and thus further drives
down prices (Jaravel and Sager 2019).33 Considering the modeled impact of
increased Chinese import penetration across U.S. geographic regions, Galle,
Rodríguez-Clare, and Yi (2023) find that almost 90 percent of the U.S.
population saw an increase in purchasing power, with those regions that saw

For examples of studies that find smaller effects of the China shock on U.S. manufacturing
employment than Autor, Dorn, and Hanson (2013), see Jakubik and Stolzenburg (2020) and De
Chaisemartin and Lei (2023). Studies that also incorporate downstream supply chain effects in
addition to direct competition effects have found positive local employment effects of the China
shock (Wang et al. 2018); Antràs, Fort, and Tintelnot (2017) find that firms that increased their use
of Chinese imported intermediates also simultaneously increased their sourcing of domestic inputs
and increased their production.
32
Formal educational attainment is defined as the percentage of the total population with a college
degree in 1990, using the Decennial Census. Manufacturing workers who transitioned to the
services sectors associated with lower educational attainment (e.g., retail) have been found to have
experienced nominal earnings declines (Pierce, Schott, and Tello-Trillo 2023).
33
These results have been corroborated in the broader trade literature (e.g., Bai and Stumpner 2019;
Amiti et al. 2020).
31

202 |

Chapter 5

Figure 5-13. Pro-Poor Bias in Gains from Trade in the United States
(Percent Welfare Gain)
Absolute welfare changes relative to autarky

80

69

70
60
50

37

40
30
20
10
0

8

Aggregate

4
10th percentile

50th percentile

90th percentile

Council of Economic Advisers

Source: Fajgelbaum and Khandelwal (2016, table V).
2024 Economic Report of the President

purchasing power losses being spatially correlated with regions that also saw
a loss in manufacturing employment from the China shock.34
The results, showing that trade with China has benefited most
Americans’ purchasing power, are consistent with a larger body of evidence
on the benefits from trade with all countries—again, with disproportionate
benefits accruing to lower-income households.35 For example, the average
U.S. household has been shown to gain 8 percent in purchasing power from
trade compared with a counterfactual autarky (Fajgelbaum and Khandelwal
2016).36 However, the lowest-income U.S. households gain the most, at 69
percent (figure 5-13).
Recent trends in foreign direct investment may contribute to boosting
manufacturing activity and reducing inequality, including for communities
disproportionately affected by the China shock. Figure 5-14 maps historical manufacturing employment changes across commuting zones over the
period 1990–2007. Areas that incurred higher job losses are indicated in
darker shades of gray. The bubbles are sized to correspond to the magnitude
of announced clean energy projects since 2021 and are colored to indicate
the investor’s headquarters country. Areas that experienced larger historical
The authors find that the worst-affected areas experienced average losses as large as four times the
average overall gain in purchasing power.
35
There is also a literature documenting welfare increases due to greater access to varieties of goods
through trade (e.g., Broda and Weinstein 2006; Melitz and Trefler 2012).
36
The authors develop a general equilibrium model that considers the distributional effects of
international trade on the cost of living (the expenditure channel). Distributional effects through
workers’ earnings (the earnings channel) are not explicitly modeled to enable a focus on unequal
gains through the expenditure channel only.
34

International Trade and Investment Flows | 203

Figure 5-14. FDI in Clean Energy Projects between 2021:Q1 and 2023:Q2, by
Investor Headquarter Country, and Decline in Manufacturing Employment
between 1990 and 2007 (Percentage of Working-Age Population)

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Clean Investment Monitor; Autor, Dorn, and Hanson (2013); CEA calculations.
Note: Darker gray regions represent areas that incurred higher historical job losses. Bubbles—representing announced clean
energy projects between 2021:Q1 to 2023:Q2—are sized according to the magnitude of the project and colored to indicate the
country in which investors’ headquarters are located. Regions are defined as commuting zones (USDA).
2024 Economic Report of the President

losses in manufacturing employment have attracted a higher concentration
(both in number and size) of announced clean energy FDI projects.
Figure 5-15 illustrates the statistically significant correlations between
commuting zones with larger historical manufacturing employment losses
and the number and value of clean energy FDI projects announced since
2021. These relationships hold when the data set is expanded to include
all announced clean energy projects, suggesting that domestic clean energy
projects are likewise disproportionately locating in vulnerable communities,
which is consistent with early evidence from Van Nostrand and Ashenfarb
(2023).37 The key drivers of location choice and whether these investments
will improve labor market and socioeconomic outcomes in these geographies remain high-priority topics for future research.

Trading Firms and Job Creation
GVCs have created strong interconnections between exporting and importing—which are often performed by the same firms. Among goods traders,
averaged over the period 1992–2021, firms that both export and import
goods account for a plurality of total U.S. private sector employment (36
percent), followed by firms that only export goods (8 percent) and firms that
only import goods (6 percent) (figure 5-16). The majority of employment
at goods traders is by large firms (defined as those employing 500 or more
For all projects (both FDI and domestic), the correlations between the number and value of
projects with historical manufacturing employment declines are both significant at the 1 percent
level.
37

204 |

Chapter 5

Figure 5-15. Correlations Between Historical Declines in Manufacturing
Employment between 1990 and 2007 and the Total Number and Value of
Recently Announced Clean Energy Projects between 2021:Q1 and 2023:Q2
A. Decline in Manufacturing Employment and Number of FDI Projects
Percentage-point decline

30
25

20

Correlation: 0.145***

15
10
5
0
-5
-10

0

1

Number of FDI projects

2

3

B. Decline in Manufacturing Employment and Total Value of FDI Projects
Percentage-point decline

30
25
20

Correlation: 0.087**

15
10
5
0
-5
-10

0

1,000

Council of Economic Advisers

2,000

3,000

4,000

5,000

6,000

Millions of 2022 dollars

Sources: Autor, Dorn, and Hanson (2013); Clean Investment Monitor; CEA calculations.
Note: The decline in manufacturing employment from 1990 to 2007 is calculated as a percentage of the working-age population
for 722 commuting zones. Projects are classified as foreign direct investment (FDI) if the associated company headquarters could
be traced to a foreign country. Only projects announced between 2021:Q1 and 2023:Q2 are included. Stars denote statistical
significance at the 5 percent (**) and 1 percent (***) levels or lower.
2024 Economic Report of the President

workers); in contrast, the majority of employment at nontraders is by small
firms (those employing fewer than 500 workers). Nevertheless, small firms
directly engaged in the goods trade account for almost 10 percent of national
employment.
About 1.3 million small firms were estimated to be exporting goods
in 2021—with the potential for almost an equal number of additional small

International Trade and Investment Flows | 205

Figure 5-16. Goods Trader and Employment by Firm Size, 1992–
2021 Average
Percentage of employment
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0

Exporter

Importer

Small firms (less than 500 employees)

Council of Economic Advisers

Importer and exporter

Nontrader

Large firms (500 or more employees)

Sources: Census Bureau; CEA calculations.
2024 Economic Report of the President

businesses to begin exporting based on the tradability of the industries in
which they operate (U.S. Small Business Administration 2023a, 2023b).
Increased opportunities to export may accrue disproportionately to smaller
regions in the United States. While large metropolitan areas (including New
York City and Los Angeles) account for large volumes of U.S. exports,
the most export-intensive regions (with the highest shares of exports to
regional GDP) include relatively less populous cities like Wichita, Detroit,
Youngstown, and Houston (Parilla and Muro 2017).
Goods traders’ contribution to net job creation has grown over recent
years: During the 2001–7 period, goods traders accounted for only 10 percent of total net job creation; but between 2008 and 2019, that figure rose
to 60 percent. Overall, goods traders were responsible for almost 40 percent
of net job creation in the U.S. economy between 1992 and 2019 (Handley,
Kamal, and Ouyang 2021).38 These statistics underscore the changing nature
of the U.S. production landscape, where both exports and imports support
domestic jobs.39

Handley, Kamal, and Ouyang (2021) document that vast majority of goods-traders’ contribution
to net job creation is driven by the opening of new establishments, particularly, in servicesproviding sectors like wholesale, retail, business and professional services. These patterns hint at the
complementarity between manufacturing and services activities as well as the sectoral diversity in
job creation tied to trade participation.
39
See Fort (2023) for an in-depth discussion of U.S. firms’ organization of goods production across
firm and country boundaries.
38

206 |

Chapter 5

Mitigating the Challenges of Global Integration
The classical Ricardian trade model—that the concept of comparative
advantage allows all countries to access goods produced by the most
efficient and lowest-cost producers, increase their aggregate consumption,
and ultimately benefit from trade, even if a single country produces all
goods more efficiently in absolute terms—is based on several assumptions
that may not hold in the real world (Ricardo 1817). One such assumption
is that workers are frictionlessly mobile between sectors. When the costs
of transitioning to sectors where a country has a relative cost advantage
are high, domestic producers in import-competing sectors lose out—as do
their workers—even if overall consumption rises. Meanwhile, the classical
Ricardian model conceives of comparative advantage only with respect to
monetary costs. American workers and consumers may place a high value
on the consumption of foreign goods that adhere to high environmental and
labor standards, but adherence to such standards is not well captured by cost
signals. To make trade fair and beneficial for all, trade and foreign investment policies need to explicitly consider distributional, environmental, and
labor rights in their design.
The Biden-Harris Administration’s approach to trade and investment partnerships centers on promoting middle-class prosperity, reducing
inequality, addressing climate risks, and advancing fair competition (USTR
2023b). It aims to raise labor standards, adopt sustainable environmental
practices, bolster supply chain resilience, and minimize national security
risks through more U.S.-based production in certain sectors while concurrently supporting ongoing robust trade and investment flows with U.S. partners. This approach encompasses a combination of economic frameworks
and regional partnerships:
• United States–Mexico–Canada Agreement (USMCA) Rapid Response
Labor Mechanism: The USMCA modernized the North American Free
Trade Agreement and includes new labor obligations, such as the innovative rapid response mechanism, which provides for expedited enforcement
of workers’ rights of free association and collective bargaining at the facility level (USTR 2023a). Since 2021, the United States has invoked the
mechanism 18 times to seek Mexico’s review at 17 different facilities.40 As
a result, the United States has achieved improved outcomes for thousands
of Mexican workers—millions of dollars have been paid to workers, more
workers are represented by independent unions, there have been more
free and fair union elections, and unions have successfully negotiated for
higher wages and improved policies at facilities.41 These developments are
We thank USTR colleagues for sharing the rapid response mechanism’s statistics that are current
through December 20, 2023.
41
Based on review of all USMCA cases (U.S. Department of Labor 2023).
40

International Trade and Investment Flows | 207

consistent with studies finding that labor-related cooperation provisions
specific to trade union rights in the context of preferential trade agreements
improve compliance with requirements for enforcing collective labor rights
(Sari, Raess, and Kucera 2016).
• Indo-Pacific Economic Framework (IPEF): This is an economic
framework between the United States and 13 member countries: Australia,
Brunei Darussalam, Fiji, India, Indonesia, Japan, South Korea, Malaysia,
New Zealand, the Philippines, Singapore, Thailand, and Vietnam (USTR
n.d.–a). IPEF comprises four pillars: trade, supply chains, a clean economy
(including clean energy, decarbonization, and infrastructure), and a fair
economy (including tax and anticorruption). The trade pillar aims to enhance
resilience, sustainability, and inclusivity through a variety of provisions,
including high-standard labor and environment commitments (USTR n.d.–
b). The supply chains pillar aims to build resilient supply chains through
multiple initiatives, including the development of criteria for critical sectors,
the promotion of supply chain diversification, and establishing channels
for information sharing and crisis response mechanisms (U.S. Department
of Commerce 2022). The clean economy pillar aims to further the climate
goals articulated under the Paris Agreement through a variety of cooperative actions, including sharing best practices on the commercialization and
deployment of clean energy technologies and mobilizing private sector
investment in emission-reducing projects (U.S. Department of Commerce
2023a). The fair economy pillar aims to strengthen domestic legal frameworks to accelerate progress on various international standards related to
reducing corruption and bribery and promoting efficient tax administration
(U.S. Department of Commerce 2023b). Collectively, these pillars promote
inclusive growth by advancing higher economic standards, building supply
chain resiliency, addressing climate change, fighting corruption, and promoting high-standard labor commitments.
• U.S.-Taiwan Initiative on 21st-Century Trade: The first agreement
under this trade initiative covers areas of customs administration and trade
facilitation aimed at reducing red tape for U.S. exporters. These include
good regulatory practices and domestic services regulation, such as streamlining licenses for firms seeking to operate abroad and promoting fair competition opportunities. Anticorruption provisions address issues including
money laundering, and denial of entry for foreign public officials who have
committed specified corruption offenses. They also promote cross-border
trade and investment, information sharing, and exchanging best practices
in finance and other areas for small and medium-sized enterprises (USTR
2023c). A second round of negotiations commenced in August 2023, focusing on agriculture, labor, and the environment (USTR 2023d).
• U.S.-Kenya Strategic Trade and Investment Partnership (STIP):
STIP is an initiative to pursue high-standard commitments in selected areas
208 |

Chapter 5

(including agriculture, anticorruption, digital trade, the environment and
climate change action, regulatory practices, endorsing workers’ rights and
protections, and trade facilitation and customs procedures, among other
focus areas) intended to increase investment; promote sustainable and inclusive economic growth; benefit workers, consumers, and businesses (including small and medium-sized enterprises); and promote African regional
economic integration (USTR 2022c, 2023e).
• Regional partnerships: The Administration has focused on building
closer partnerships with regions across continents. Two examples, spanning
Europe and Africa, are highlighted here:
—U.S.-EU Trade and Technology Council: This council includes two
working groups focused on securing supply chains and addressing global
trade challenges (White House 2021a). One group, which focuses on secure
supply chains, aims to advance resilience and security in supply chains and
create coordination mechanisms to avoid disruptions (U.S. Department of
Commerce 2023c). The other group, which focuses on global trade challenges, aims to address issues of nonmarket economic policies and practices,
promote the development of emerging technologies by avoiding new and
unnecessary product and service barriers, promote and protect labor rights,
and address other trade and environment issues (USTR 2021).
—African Growth and Opportunity Act (AGOA): AGOA is a unilateral U.S. trade preference program that provides duty-free access to the U.S.
market for certain exports from countries in Sub-Saharan Africa that meet
AGOA’s eligibility criteria. Thirty-two countries currently qualify in 2024
(USTR n.d.–c). Eligibility encourages countries to make continual progress
on economic benchmarks (e.g., having a market-based economy); political
benchmarks (e.g., the rule of law, political pluralism, and anticorruption
efforts); poverty reduction (e.g., via job creation in exporting sectors); and
the protection of labor rights (e.g., prohibitions against child labor and protections of the rights to organize and bargain collectively). Countries must
also not engage in gross violations of internationally recognized human
rights or activities that undermine U.S. national security or provide support
for acts of international terrorism (USTR 2022d).

Conclusion
The decades-long trend of steady increases in global trade and foreign
direct investment plateaued after the global financial crisis. Nonetheless, the
United States remains the world’s second-largest trader after China, and the
largest country with respect to FDI flows. U.S. trade and foreign investment
patterns in 2022 and 2023 reflect a combination of cyclical and secular factors, in addition to the Biden-Harris Administration’s policy agenda—all of
which are interacting in novel ways to show signs of positive developments
International Trade and Investment Flows | 209

(including an increase in U.S. supply chain resilience and increasing FDI
inflows into the U.S. manufacturing sector), along with reasons for caution
(including services exports remaining below trends before the pandemic).
While the future outlook for U.S. trade and investment flows remains
uncertain, the Administration is continuing to pursue a worker-centered
trade agenda by reviewing trade policies for their impact on, and consequences for, American workers. This policy approach also aims to harness
the benefits of trade while reversing the jobs and earnings displacements that
beset too many American communities for decades. These ongoing actions
are helping to rebuild these communities, not by walling off international
trade but by leveraging its benefits while managing its costs for American
workers.

210 |

Chapter 5

Chapter 6

Accelerating the Clean Energy Transition
The clean energy transition is under way. Its end goal is an innovative,
cutting-edge U.S. economy powered by cheap, reliable, and secure clean
energy sources and technologies. In this future, various aspects of the
economy—the electricity that powers it, the cars and planes that move
people and goods, the products and foods we consume—will be provided
without the harm of air pollution and climate change. The production of
clean energy will also create new sources of economic growth, employment,
and prosperity, furthering American competitiveness throughout the 21st
century to meet global demand for clean energy technologies.
Contrast this future with the Nation’s past reliance on fossil fuels, a dependence that has come at significant costs. The use of fossil fuels—responsible
for 68 percent of total historical human-induced carbon dioxide emissions—
has given rise to climate change (Friedlingstein et al. 2020). The global average temperature has already risen more than 1 degree Celsius (1.8 degrees
Fahrenheit) since the preindustrial period, and is projected to reach 2.4 to 5
degrees Celsius (4.3 to 9 degrees Fahrenheit) by 2100 if no further action is
taken (Kriegler et al. 2017; IEA 2023a).
The cost of inaction is high, with damage from climate change already
starting to mount. In 2023, the United States experienced an unprecedented
28 weather- and climate-related disasters with losses of at least $1 billion
each (NOAA 2024). Some insurers are starting to pull out of home insurance
markets due to the high costs of covering climate-related disasters (CEA
2023a). Additional warming is expected to further damage human health,
productivity, living standards, and food security, driving mass migration and

211

Figure 6-1. U.S. Net Total Greenhouse Gas Emissions, with Emissions
Reduction Goals
Millions of metric tons of CO2 equivalent
8,000

2050 goal

2030 goal

7,000
6,000
5,000
4,000
3,000
2,000
1,000
0
1990

1995

2000

2005

Council of Economic Advisers

2010

2015

2020

2025

2030

2035

2040

2045

2050

Sources: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency; CEA calculations.
Note: Dotted segments represent pathways to achieving 2030 and 2050 emissions reduction goals. The measure
"millions of metric tons of CO2 equivalent" scales each gas by its global warming potential relative to CO2.
2024 Economic Report of the President

worsening social and political instability, among other social and economic
outcomes, and inequities therein (Carleton et al. 2022; Burke, Hsiang, and
Miguel 2015; Schlenker and Roberts 2009; Hsiang et al. 2013, 2023; Marvel
et al. 2023). This is further compounded by the harmful health consequences
of local air pollution due to continued burning of fossil fuels (Lelieveld et
al. 2019). To avoid these costs, policymakers must induce a rapid energy
transition from fossil fuels to clean energy sources.
Decarbonizing the U.S. economy is an immense undertaking. A combination of private and public investments triggered by Federal, State, and local
climate policies are already moving in this direction (CEA 2023a; White
House 2022; OMB 2023; California Legislature 2023; NYC Department
of Buildings 2023). Between 2005 and 2021, U.S. greenhouse gas (GHG)
emissions fell by 17 percent, as shown in figure 6-1 (UNFCCC 2023), a
remarkable annualized rate for a major industrial economy during a period
of economic growth (OECD 2023).1 Yet this pace is still not fast enough
GHG emissions also fell across the European Union during this period, but under a regulated
declining cap on emissions (UNFCCC 2024b; European Environment Agency 2023).
1

212 |

Chapter 6

to meet Paris Agreement commitments seeking to limit global warming to
1.5 degrees Celsius (UNFCCC 2024a). To achieve the midway goal of a 50
percent emissions reduction relative to 2005, the United States must lower
its annual emissions by 6 percent on average between 2021 and 2030, and
must further accelerate emissions reductions after 2030.2
Achieving decarbonization rapidly enough to avoid growing physical damage from climate change will require deploying commercially available
clean energy technologies—like solar and wind power, electric vehicles,
and heat pumps—at even faster rates (IEA 2023b). To reach net zero emissions by 2050, the United States will need to act across all sectors of the
economy. For example, the United States may need to double its share of
electricity generated by non-carbon-emitting sources to roughly 75 percent
by 2030 (National Academies 2021). Furthermore, more than half of global
emissions reductions by 2050 will need to come from technologies that are
yet to be invented or commercialized (IEA 2023b).
Faster decarbonization can be achieved in part by accelerating two complementary recent developments. First, the electricity sector needs to shift
away from fossil fuels. Much of recent U.S. GHG reduction comes from
the electricity sector (dark teal line, figure 6-2). A large share of emissions
reductions in the electricity sector to date have been the result of displacing
coal-fired generation with clean energy and natural gas (figure 6-3). The
electricity sector must now accelerate its transition from using fossil fuels,
including natural gas, to clean energy. At the same time, given a cleaner
source of electricity, a shift toward electrification in other sectors—such as
the transportation, industrial, commercial, and residential sectors—would be
an effective way to help lower emissions across the economy. Both tasks are
long-term shifts in the type of energy that powers the U.S. economy.

This CEA calculation assumes a constant-percentage annual GHG emissions decline between
observed 2021 U.S. GHG emissions and the Administration’s 2030 U.S. GHG emissions target.

2

Accelerating the Clean Energy Transition | 213

Figure 6-2. U.S. Emissions per Sector, 1990–2021
Millions of metric tons of CO2 equivalent

2,500
2,000
1,500
1,000
500

0
1990

1995
Transportation
Agriculture

2000

Council of Economic Advisers

2005
2010
Electric power industry
Commercial

2015
Industrial
Residential

2020

Source: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (2023).
2024 Economic Report of the President

Figure 6-3. U.S. Electricity Generation by Energy Source, 1990–2021
Electric power generated (billion KWh)
4,500

Total emissions from electric power industry
(millions of metric tons of CO2 equivalent)
3,000

4,000

2,500

3,500

2,000

3,000
2,500

1,500

2,000

1,000

1,500
1,000

500

0

1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
2020
2021

500

Coal (left axis)
Nuclear (left axis)
Petroleum and other (left axis)

Council of Economic Advisers

Natural gas (left axis)
Renewable (left axis)
Total emissions (right axis)

Sources: U.S. Energy Information Administration; U.S. Environmental Protection Agency.
2024 Economic Report of the President

214 |

Chapter 6

0

Economists characterize such broad transitions as structural change: longterm evolutions in an economy’s composition, whether through inputs or
outputs, from an established set of economic activities to a set of emerging ones. Structural change underlies many major moments in economic
development; past examples include the transition from agriculture to
manufacturing during the Industrial Revolution and the more recent shift
from manufacturing to services in advanced economies. The clean energy
transition—moving an economy primarily based on fossil fuels to one
powered by clean energy sources and technologies—can also be viewed
through this lens.
The structural change perspective provides a foundation for understanding
the forces that will determine the direction, pace, and endpoint in the transition from one energy system to another. It also offers a lens for identifying
the specific investments needed for accelerating the transition from an
energy system based on fossil fuels to one based on clean energy. For
example, in the electricity sector, the decline in capital costs for clean energy
has increasingly made it competitive with fossil-based electricity, yet some
new electricity capacity still uses natural gas (Lazard 2023; EIA 2023a).
This is in part because some types of clean electricity, such as solar, require
complementary technologies, like batteries, to be available during all parts
of the day. A structural change perspective highlights how the transition can
be accelerated through complementary investments in battery storage, along
with lowering siting and transmission costs, enabling renewable energy to
better substitute for fossil fuels by supplying electricity throughout the day.
Also embedded in a structural change perspective is the notion of path
dependence. Fossil fuels dominate today’s market not only because they
have historically been cheaper, due in part to Federal policies and subsidies
implemented in the past, but also because they have accumulated historical
economic advantages that are difficult for emerging clean energy technologies to surmount. However, this path dependence cuts both ways. Policies

Accelerating the Clean Energy Transition | 215

that provide a sufficient push for clean energy technologies to overcome
fossil fuels’ historically accumulated advantage can alter the need for future
government intervention. That is, putting the economy on a clean energy
path will make it easier to achieve long-term decarbonization. As that
happens, policy interventions need not be permanent: Once an economy
has built up sufficient economic advantage in clean energy, private market
incentives can sustain the clean energy transition.
By considering a subset of clean energy sources and technologies—including
wind, solar, electric vehicles (EVs), and batteries—through the economics
of structural change, this chapter provides a framework for understanding
the clean energy transition and the policies that can accelerate it.3 However,
this framework, like any, is not comprehensive, and does not address
every element of the Biden-Harris Administration’s whole-of-government
approach to climate policy. It is also an incomplete account of the benefits
of the clean energy transition, such as avoiding climate damage, lowering
air pollution and energy prices, creating high-quality jobs, and fostering
economic competitiveness. Instead, the narrower task of this chapter is to
offer an economic lens for understanding the path toward the clean energy
transition and how it can be achieved.
The chapter’s first section provides an overview of structural change and
how economists have applied the framework to explain important moments
in economic development. It then provides a taxonomy of the various
factors that can push or pull against structural change and thus determine
the direction, rate, and end point of long-term transitions. The section then
discusses market failures and economic frictions under which government
intervention may be needed when the direction and pace of market-driven
structural change are not in line with society’s goals.

This framework also applies to nuclear, hydropower, and technologies such as carbon capture and
storage and direct air capture that lower net GHG emissions.

3

216 |

Chapter 6

The second section applies the structural change framework to the clean
energy transition, discussing various ways in which the transition represents
a distinct case of structural change—and the ensuing set of unique challenges and opportunities. The push-and-pull factors discussed in the first
section are then mapped onto specific issues in the clean energy transition.
The third section describes how specific policies enacted by the BidenHarris Administration are strategically targeting these push-and-pull factors
to accelerate the clean energy transition. These and other efforts can build a
U.S. clean energy economy that benefits workers and communities, avoiding
the worst economic consequences of climate inaction.

The Economics of Structural Change
This section introduces structural change as a broad economic concept and
delineates the various push-and-pull forces that determine the direction and
speed of structural change. Market failures and other economic frictions
may inhibit the socially optimal direction and rate of structural change, justifying government intervention. The structural change lens shows how policy
interventions, if successful, need not be permanent; once properly directed,
an economy has the momentum to carry forward that transition on its own.

What Is Structural Change?
The transition to a net zero economy requires structural change. Structural
change refers to long-term (as opposed to short-term, cyclical) changes in
the composition of an economy, from an established activity to an emerging
one. Of particular interest are the direction and the pace of this change, as
well as the final composition of the economy. Embedded in a structural
change perspective is the notion of path dependence: that historical economic dependence continues to exert influence today (Nelson and Winter
1985). Once the process of structural change begins, it can gather momentum on its own without much further impetus.
History is rich with examples of structural change, many of which
were considered important turning points in economic development. For
instance, structural change in the allocation of labor from agricultural to
industrial activity characterized the Industrial Revolution (Nurkse 1952; Rao
1952; Lewis 1954; Ranis and Fei 1961). Similarly, much attention has been
given to the shift in labor shares from industrial to service-oriented activities

Accelerating the Clean Energy Transition | 217

during the latter half of the 20th century (Autor, Levy, and Murnane 2003;
Acemoglu and Autor 2011).
Redirection of capital—both physical and financial—also characterizes major historical transitions. During World War II, economies around
the world redirected domestic production from consumer durables—such as
automobiles and home appliances—to tanks, airplanes, and artillery. From
February 1942 until the end of the war, U.S. commercial auto production
ceased, and auto assembly lines were repurposed to produce 80 percent of
U.S. tanks and more than half of all aircraft engines (Gropman 1996). From
1940 to 1943, U.S. national defense gross investment rose from $13.2 billion
to $517.9 billion (in 2022 dollars), representing an enormous financial reallocation.4 Such redirection of resources transformed the trajectory of U.S.
innovation for decades thereafter (see box 6-1).
These and other historical examples have led to a rich intellectual
tradition in economics examining the drivers and consequences of structural
change (Johnston 1970; McMillan and Rodrik 2011; Autor, Dorn, and
Hanson 2013; Herrendorf, Rogerson, and Valentinyi 2014). Unlike more
static frameworks, this literature focuses on transitional dynamics and their
drivers. In doing so, it builds on macroeconomic models, but with an added
focus on understanding the composition of an economy and how it changes.

Determinants of Structural Change
The structural change framework focuses on understanding the forces that
shape—or reshape—the composition of an economy, whether through
inputs, outputs, or both. These forces can push or pull against structural
change, the balance of which determines the direction, speed, and end point
of an economy’s transition from an established activity to an emerging one.
This section details such push-and-pull forces.
Productivity spillovers arise under many circumstances. Spillovers
within a sector can occur at the individual level in the form of learning-bydoing (Arrow 1962; Lucas 1988) or at the sectoral level through technological or knowledge spillovers (Romer 1990; Acemoglu 2002; Acemoglu et
al. 2012). Regardless of the mechanism, productivity spillovers within a
sector favor the established economic activity and allow that advantage to
strengthen over time, making the emerging economic activity increasingly
unlikely to replace the established activity. Spillovers across sectors can,
however, accelerate structural change, particularly when knowledge and
technologies developed for an established sector can be applied to an emerging sector (Bloom, Schankerman, and Van Reenen 2013). Governmentsupported research efforts during the World War II mobilization effort,
for example, had spillovers onto postwar innovation that enabled the
4

This is from CEA calculations using data from the Bureau of Economic Analysis.

218 |

Chapter 6

Box 6-1. World War II and Technological Change
The U.S. government has played a critical role in enabling past periods
of rapid technological change, including during World War II, when
the Federal Government established the Office of Scientific Research
and Development (OSRD), an expansion of the then–recently created
National Research Defense Committee and a predecessor to the National
Science Foundation. This new office would eventually invest more than
$9 billion (in 2022 dollars) in research and development (R&D) between
1940 and 1945 to develop innovations in radar technology, military
weapons, and pharmaceuticals, among other sectors. Unlike previous
models of public investment in R&D, the OSRD’s novel approach
channeled investments to hubs of applied research while facilitating
partnerships and collaborations between public, private, and academic
researchers (Gross and Sampat 2023a). Despite its brief existence, the
OSRD bent the path of U.S. technical innovation for decades to follow,
as a potential template for the clean energy transition.
Many of the technological advancements generated by OSRD
support had direct civilian applications despite originally being intended
for military use. For example, while penicillin cells were discovered
in 1928, neither industry nor government had pursued their use as an
antibiotic until the OSRD began investigating them for military applications in the early 1940s. After demonstrating its success in the military,
the government released penicillin for commercial use in 1945 (Quinn
2013).
Recent evidence on the large-scale shock to research activity during World War II from the OSRD program suggests that public investment can have a sustained, long-term impact on subsequent innovation.
Technology hubs that received the greatest R&D investment from the
program during World War II realized 40–50 percent more patent-based
innovation activity per year by 1970 (Gross and Sampat 2023a). World
War II–era Federal investment in industrial activity and the ensuing
mobilization also led to a sectoral shift in the composition of manufacturing activity toward industries like lumber, chemicals, rubber, stone,
metals, machinery, and transportation equipment (Jaworski 2017).
These effects on future innovation were primarily driven by
spillovers and agglomeration economies, in which co-located firms
mutually benefit from the sharing of ideas, infrastructure, and other
assets (Duranton and Puga 2004). Gross and Sampat (2023a) find that
these effects were approximately double in clusters centered on a highly
ranked university. That firms and other research institutions (including
government labs) later located in these hubs also suggests spillover
benefits from regionalized innovation activity. Roughly 40 years after
World War II, industrial clusters that received the OSRD’s R&D
investment saw 90 percent higher employment in those manufacturing

Accelerating the Clean Energy Transition | 219

industries as well as additional manufacturing business formation (Gross
and Sampat 2023a).
The research demands necessitated by World War II are similar
in scope to those required to address climate change. Gross and
Sampat (2023b) argue that unlike the Manhattan Project or the Apollo
Program—which were focused on singular technological goals for singular customers—World War II demanded a portfolio-based approach
to technological innovations for a variety of end users. In this regard,
the authors note a parallel between the R&D investment approach of the
OSRD and the scope of today’s energy transition needs. But while the
challenges are similar in scope, the broad-based structural transformation necessary to address climate change may require investment at an
even greater scale.

development of information technologies and biomedical advances (see box
6-1).
An economy’s composition may reflect relative input prices between
established and emerging inputs. These include both the price of the input
itself and any complementary capital, land, or other material inputs associated with the input of interest. Relative adoption tilts toward the input with
lower contemporaneous prices. But in the presence of within-sector productivity spillovers, that tilt may be muted. For a new input, technology, or
sector to become dominant, lower relative contemporaneous prices may not
fully overcome the productivity advantage the established activity has built
up over time. For example, high efficiencies in some forms of fossil fuel
use from decades of experience would lead to lower adoption of renewables
even if electricity from renewables were cheaper today than from fossil
fuels.
Factor mobility can also accelerate structural change. Factor mobility
refers to the ease with which factors of production—labor, capital equipment, or materials—can be allocated across different economic activities.
For example, when workers in established sectors have skills that are attractive in emerging sectors, these workers can switch jobs across sectors—and
relocate geographically if moving costs are low—without acquiring much
additional education or retraining. Likewise, capital that can be redeployed
readily across established and emerging sectors—for example, if a factory
can shift from being powered by fossil fuels to clean energy—can help
accelerate structural change. But when factors of production cannot be easily
reallocated, the rate of structural change may be slow.

220 |

Chapter 6

Structural change is often shaped by the degree of substitutability
between existing technologies and those replacing them. Emerging economic activity must compete for consumers with existing activity. When
an emerging sector’s output perfectly substitutes for that of an established
sector, consumers will more readily adopt goods from the new sector
(Acemoglu 2002). However, when the new product is not a direct substitute, complementary investments are necessary to ensure the new good has
similar—if not better—attributes than the established good. For example,
complementary investments in battery storage alongside clean energy
sources for electricity will enable electricity supplied from clean sources at
all hours of the day, as is currently provided by the established electricity
generation mix (IRENA 2019).
New goods can also offer quality or attribute improvements that
induce added demand. In many sectors, the adoption of new product categories is hastened in part by consumer demand for improved attributes, new
use cases, or simply novelty.

Market Failures and Policy Implications
Policymakers and the public may in some cases decide that structural change
is occurring in the wrong direction or too slowly. This is justified in the presence of canonical market failures. Externalities, for instance—whereby economic activity imposes costs and benefits onto others without consequences
for the actor generating the activity—can lead markets to underprovide a
public good (e.g., innovation) or overprovide a public bad (e.g., pollution
or GHG emissions). Sector-level economies of scale that require coordination across complementary inputs may also prevent emerging sectors from
overcoming the initial hurdle of competing with established sectors.
Policymakers can address these market failures with familiar economic
policy tools, including input and output taxes designed to “internalize” the
externality, along with subsidies and public research-and-development
(R&D) investments. But government interventions differ in one fundamental way when structural change dynamics are at play: They can create lasting
change via path dependence. As such, to the extent that these interventions
are successful, they need not be permanent. Provided that an intervention
is sufficiently large to redirect an economy toward a more socially desirable composition, the intervention may no longer be needed once enough
momentum has been built (Acemoglu 2002; Acemoglu et al. 2012, 2016;
Meng 2023).
Structural change’s key implication—the ability to use policy interventions to permanently alter the direction of change toward a different
composition of the economy—may be attractive from a political economy
perspective. But because path dependence cuts both ways, it also places

Accelerating the Clean Energy Transition | 221

added importance on well-targeted policy interventions that direct the economy toward an efficient use of cost-effective inputs. Policies that promote
costly technologies may lead to a locking in of those technologies, making a
future redirection toward more cost-effective alternatives harder to accomplish. The momentum inherent in economies undergoing structural change
amplifies the importance of correctly promoting cost-effective technologies.

Structural Change and the Clean Energy Transition
The structural change framework and the push-and-pull forces articulated in
the first section provide a lens to understand opportunities and challenges
for accelerating the clean energy transition. Energy is an essential input
for nearly every form of economic activity, and it has undergone various
transitions over the past few centuries. As society invents new technologies,
energy sources—and the form energy takes—change. Before the Industrial
Revolution, labor—both human and animal—was the primary energy
input for the production of goods and services. The Industrial Revolution
unleashed a new and disembodied source of energy: fossil fuels. And the
introduction of steam-powered, and then electricity-powered energy brought
a transition in how the economy utilized fossil fuels (Devine 1982).
To lay out how the clean energy transition can be viewed through
a structural change lens, this section examines the various push-and-pull
forces that can accelerate or delay the clean energy transition. While these
forces are explored in isolation, policies must target these economic forces
simultaneously to achieve the required speed and scale of an economy-wide
clean energy transition, as discussed in the third section.

The Costs of Fossil Fuels
Fossil fuels—coal, oil, and natural gas—provide energy through combustion, and in doing so release air pollutants, toxins, and climate-damaging
greenhouse gases such as carbon dioxide (CO2) and methane. In 2021, 92
percent of U.S. anthropogenic CO2 emissions could be attributed to the
combustion of fossil fuels (EIA 2023b).
Understanding the economic challenges of transitioning from fossil
fuels to clean energy sources begins with understanding how fossil fuels
came to be dominant and deeply embedded in the global and U.S. economies. Because energy is central to both national and economic security,
fossil fuel providers benefited from government subsidies to secure strategic
geopolitical alliances beginning in the late 19th century. U.S. government
support, itself the result of political lobbying, aided fossil fuels in becoming
the primary sources of American energy (Victor 2009) (see box 6-2). This
is not a uniquely American phenomenon: Fossil fuels became a relatively

222 |

Chapter 6

cheap source of energy globally in part because they have been heavily
subsidized.
In addition to government support, the technical characteristics of fossil fuels and their availability further shaped the energy system that emerged
in the global economy. Fossil fuels are abundant, energy-dense, and found
in many parts of the world. They are also transportable carriers of energy: A
piece of coal can be mined in one location and shipped elsewhere to readily
meet that location’s energy demand, leading to global markets for many
fossil fuels and associated infrastructure as well as competitive price pressures. Additional technical qualities aid fossil fuels’ competitiveness even
when they are not the final energy carrier. For instance, use of some fossil
fuels, like natural gas, can be readily ramped up and down for electricity
generation, helping balance aggregate electricity supply and demand nearly
instantaneously (EIA 2012).

Clean Energy Opportunities and Challenges
Fossil fuels are not the only energy source, and they are far from the most
abundant one; sunlight and wind are freely available around the planet.
Aside from their critical role in mitigating GHG emissions and air pollution,
clean energy technologies have many economic and national security benefits. Because they do not rely on costly fuel inputs, these technologies have

Box 6-2. Fossil Fuel Subsidies
A key challenge for the clean energy transition is the cost competitiveness of renewable energy sources compared with the fossil fuel sources
they are replacing—a challenge made particularly difficult because the
U.S. government has long subsidized fossil fuel production. These subsidies have largely been enacted through the tax code. Since the introduction of the modern Federal income tax in 1913, fossil fuel producers have
received unique deductions, effectively shifting risk and losses from oil
and gas producers to taxpayers.
The largest fossil fuel subsidies focus on defraying the risks of
investment for producers. One major provision involves the deduction
of intangible drilling costs—which include wages and preparatory work
conducted to drill an oil well—amounting to 60–80 percent of total
drilling costs, according to one estimate. Oil producers may deduct
70 percent of these costs immediately, rather than over the lifetime of
the well, as is common with standard business expenditures (CRFB
2013). Also subsidized are the costs to explore new wells, despite novel
technologies that significantly reduce the risks of drilling unprofitable
or nonproducing wells. As recently as 2004, the Federal Government

Accelerating the Clean Energy Transition | 223

introduced new tax instruments to support investment in drilling capacity (U.S. Congress 2004).
Production is also subsidized, for instance, in the form of a percentage depletion. Independent oil producers are permitted to write off 15
percent of gross income on the first 1,000 barrels they produce a day,
and this deduction rises to 25 percent for marginal wells during periods
of low prices. Because this deduction is based on gross income, its
value can exceed the total value of the producer’s investment in the well
(CRS 2021). While these provisions target independent producers (those
without integrated refining capacity), this represents over 80 percent of
U.S. crude oil production (Golding and Kilian 2022).
While estimates vary, one valuation assesses the total producer
benefit from the Federal Government’s fossil fuel subsidies at $62 billion, on average, annually (Kotchen 2021). This benefit substantially
incentivizes production and the entry of new fossil fuel producers at
the margin, particularly when oil prices are low, and the subsidies’ total
contributions to domestic production are estimated to be substantial
(Erickson et al. 2017). Over the past 20 years, these subsidies have
fueled the development of unconventional projects through the shale
boom, with potential benefits to oil producers of up to $4 a barrel
(Erickson and Achakulwisut 2021). One study estimates that at oil prices
of $50 per barrel, fossil fuel subsidies could be responsible for up to 20
percent of U.S. crude oil production through 2050, while contributing 6
billion metric tons of CO2 emissions (Erickson et al. 2017).
These subsidies to fossil fuels, both direct and indirect, have
greatly promoted domestic production of natural gas and oil for more
than a century. Their scope and longevity demonstrate both the Federal
Government’s ability to support energy production and the extent to
which the oil and gas sectors have benefited from such support. As the
country looks to accelerate the adoption of nonemitting energy sources,
fossil fuel subsidies are also an obstacle to a rapid clean energy transition. As such, President Biden has repeatedly urged Congress to remove
these subsidies, most recently in his 2024 budget proposal, in order to
recover billions for taxpayers while winding down policy interventions
that slow the clean energy transition (OMB 2023).

near-zero marginal costs of generation and can, in the long run with continued technological advances, lower energy prices. Due to its cost advantages,
solar is already the fastest growing source of energy in the United States
and in the world (EIA 2024a; IEA 2023c). Clean energy technologies can
also reduce volatility in energy markets and enhance energy security (Cox,
Beshilas, and Hotchkiss 2019). Studies have also shown clean energy to be

224 |

Chapter 6

more resilient than fossil fuels in the event of a natural disaster (Chang 2023;
Esposito 2021).
And yet, despite the benefits of clean energy and the need to transition
away from fossil fuels to address climate change, many parts of the world
have been slow in adopting clean energy technologies that produce energy
from these abundant and free resources—or have not adopted them at all
(IRENA 2023). In some cases, this may be because clean energy technologies require inputs that are costly or exhibit low mobility. In other settings,
complementary technologies are needed for clean energy to serve as a better
substitute for fossil fuels. To understand what may accelerate or delay the
clean energy transition, this section maps the push-and-pull forces—productivity spillovers, input prices, factor mobility, and substitutability—articulated abstractly in the chapter’s first section, onto specific features of the
clean energy transition.
Productivity spillovers and declining capital cost curves. Technologies
tend to become cheaper as experience with their production increases,
consistent with the presence of productivity spillovers. This dynamic likely
characterizes the clean energy sector. Despite high initial costs, increased
manufacturing capacity and deployment of clean energy technologies have
been associated with lowering costs as a result of learning and investments
in process innovation (Nemet 2019).
The role of path dependence in productivity spillovers and declining
capital cost curves can be illustrated through the history of clean energy
technologies over the past century. In a number of cases, despite having
near-zero marginal costs, high capital costs—alongside ongoing government subsidies for fossil fuels—made clean energy more expensive than
energy derived from fossil fuels. For example, while in the early 20th
century, electric wind turbines were common across rural America, in
the two decades after President Roosevelt’s rural electrification programs
brought cheaper fossil-fuel-based electricity to rural areas, every American
wind power company went out of business (Pasqualetti, Righter, and Gipe
2004). Solar photovoltaic (PV) panels, first developed in the 1950s to power
space satellites, were unable to compete commercially for decades, and
were restricted to niche applications such as calculators and solar-powered
radios (Nemet 2019). Electric vehicles enjoyed an early boom around the
turn of the 20th century, after the discovery of electromagnetism and the
invention of the rechargeable battery allowed them to capture 38 percent of
the (albeit very small) U.S. automotive market. However, advances in the
combustion engine and the growing cost-competitiveness of fossil fuels—a
result partially of public subsidies—quickly led to the dominance of internal
combustion engine vehicles (Guarnieri 2012).
In the future, as clean energy technologies develop and disseminate, costs are likely to decline as a result of economies of scale and
Accelerating the Clean Energy Transition | 225

Figure 6-4. Capital Cost Curves for PV Solar and Onshore Wind, 2000–2020

2020 dollars per megawatt-hour, logarithmic scale
800

2000

2005

2010

400
200

2015

100

2001

2005

25

2020

2010

50

2015
2020
1,000

10,000

100,000

Cumulative installed capacity in megawatts, logarithmic scale

Council of Economic Advisers

PV Solar

1,000,000

Onshore wind

Sources: International Renewable Energy Agency (2023); Nemet (2019).
Note: Logarithmic scale shows the relationship between a 50 percent drop in capital costs and a 1,000 percent increase
in installed capacity.
2024 Economic Report of the President

learning-by-doing. Economies of scale will move clean technologies down
the average cost curve while learning-by-doing will shift down the average
cost curve itself as productivity increases. Together, these forces should
lead to lower costs at higher levels of output. However, if new technologies
cannot compete with existing energy technologies, they will be unable to
advance to mass production and experience the cost declines associated
with scale economies and learning effects (Hart 2020). This could result
from a lack of policies to spur demand, the competitiveness of established
technologies, or some combination of both. Indeed, as shown in figure 6-4, it
was not until the start of this century that clean energy’s capital costs began
declining dramatically, coinciding with when many governments around the
world began supporting its deployment (Nemet 2019).
Land, transmission, and supply chain costs. Capital costs of clean
energy for electricity have fallen dramatically over recent decades and are
now often lower than those of fossil fuels (Lazard 2023). These cost advantages notwithstanding, there are other inputs incurred when changing from
a fossil-fuel-based to a clean-energy-based system. Electricity from renewable energy has different land use requirements, necessitates investments
in transmission infrastructure, and relies on different raw materials than
fossil-fuel-based electricity. This implies that the total input cost of clean
energy relative to fossil fuels may still not be low enough for markets on
their own to deliver a structural transition.

226 |

Chapter 6

Clean energy electricity generation can be more land-intensive than
fossil fuel generation, even after accounting for land used in fossil fuel
extraction and distribution (Gross 2020; Van Zalk and Behrens 2018).
Utility-scale solar and land-based wind power generation requires large
quantities of contiguous land. By one estimate, the capacity necessary to
complete the U.S. net zero transition with current technologies could take
over 250,000 square miles, roughly the area of Texas (Nature Conservancy
2023). While some of this renewable capacity can be installed on existing
land uses—as in the case of rooftop solar—replacing the fossil-fuel-based
energy system will likely require repurposing land specifically for clean
energy. Siting, the process of picking locations for projects, can also incur
political risks. Local interest groups have sued and taken political action
against renewable projects, with opposition rising rapidly in recent years,
raising the cost of installation (Bryce 2023; Brooks and Liscow 2023).
Siting clean energy installations on cheaper land away from population
centers can mitigate these concerns, but may prompt an additional cost: the
need to transmit renewable energy generation to load centers. Current transmission regulations also create an externality: The cost of adding a marginal
transmission line is often borne by the marginal generator connecting onto
the grid—even though the extra transmission line benefits all connected
generators (Sankaran, Parmar, and Collison 2021). One recent analysis
argues that inadequacies in the current U.S. transmission system—which in
some parts of the country fails to connect regions with high solar and wind
potential—may lower renewable energy adoption by 65 percent by 2030
(Jenkins et al. 2022). And for planned renewable generation that can connect
to existing transmission lines, the average wait time for grid connection is
currently 3.5 years (RMI 2022).
Clean energy technologies require different inputs than do fossil fuel
technologies, which may be less raw-material-intensive in the construction
of generation facilities but require ongoing fuel supplies (IEA 2023b). Wind
generation uses over 5 metric tons of zinc per new megawatt of generation
capacity, while solar PV uses about 4 metric tons of rare earth metals. By
contrast, a new megawatt of natural gas generation capacity uses only about
1 metric ton of metal. Similarly, EV production requires over six times the
critical minerals compared with what is needed for producing internal combustion engines, owing primarily to the large quantities of graphite, cobalt,
nickel, and lithium used in batteries, though that difference will narrow as
battery recycling programs ramp up (IEA 2023b; Riofrancos et al. 2023).
Global supply chains can drive down input costs for clean energy technologies, but that may require government intervention. While the United
States is currently developing domestic capacity in this area, mining these
materials and transporting them requires, in some cases, creating new supply
chains and forming new trade relationships (IEA 2023b).
Accelerating the Clean Energy Transition | 227

Labor mobility. The clean energy transition will require a shift in the
labor market, with workers leaving fossil fuel jobs and entering clean energy
jobs. The extent to which labor is mobile across locations and sectors will
play an important role in the clean energy transition. These frictions are not
unique to the clean energy transition; they affect any process of structural
change.
The clean energy sector will require more highly skilled workers (IEA
2022). Globally, about 45 percent of energy workers were in occupations
requiring tertiary education as of 2019, compared with only about onequarter across the U.S. economy. In 2022, more than 80 percent of U.S.
clean energy employers reported at least “some difficulty” finding qualified
workers (DOE 2023a), compared with about 75 percent of firms across
the economy (Manpower Group 2022). In an industry survey, 89 percent
of U.S. solar companies reported difficulties finding skilled labor, citing
competition, small applicant pools, and applicants’ lack of training, experience, and technical skills (IREC 2022). Demand for workers in clean energy
sectors continues to increase (DOE 2023a). Indeed, in some sectors, such as
transportation, manufacturing clean energy technologies may be more laborintensive than manufacturing fossil-fuel-based counterparts (Cotterman,
Fuchs, and Whitefoot 2022), but that may not apply in all cases.
Geographic immobility may also slow transitions from fossil fuel to
clean energy jobs (Lim, Aklin, and Frank 2023). While some fossil fuel and
clean energy skills overlap (IEA 2022), fossil fuel and clean energy jobs
are often not in the same places. For instance, approximately one-third of
recently laid-off coal miners in Appalachia—some of them third-generation
employees—have not moved since job displacement, despite the lack of
clean energy job opportunities nearby (Greenspon and Raimi 2022; Weber
2020).
This clean energy labor demand presents an economic opportunity,
but also requires overcoming skill mismatch with the current workforce.
Some of this demand may be met by workers currently employed in fossil fuel sectors. But so long as these workers are able to find employment
more generally in an economy as large as the United States’, a one-to-one
match between fossil and clean industries’ labor pools may not be needed
(Curtis, O’Kane, and Park 2023). The likelihood of working at a clean firm
conditional on having worked for a fossil fuel firm in the previous year was
extremely low as of 2019, suggesting an important potential role for workforce development programs and place-based incentives (Colmer, Lyubich,
and Voorheis 2023).
Finally, fossil fuel extraction also has local fiscal effects (Raimi et al.
2023). Excise and royalty taxes on fossil fuel extraction provide a major
source of local tax revenue, supporting employment in local schools, hospitals, and other public services. An important consideration is whether and
228 |

Chapter 6

how revenue from local fossil fuel taxes can be replaced by proceeds from
investments in clean energy or other industrial sectors.
Substitutability. Electricity from clean energy sources like wind and
solar is not available at all times of the day, unlike electricity from fossil
fuels. This variability of renewable energy can be solved through complementary investments in battery storage and other solutions—including
nuclear and hydropower—which makes electricity from clean energy a
better substitute for electricity from fossil fuels. For example, to make clean
energy dispatchable at all hours of the day, battery storage can be deployed
in a manner that incentivizes batteries to be charged when renewables are
abundant and discharged when they are not.
Likewise, electric vehicle range—though it is improving rapidly—can
present a barrier to EV adoption. To date, most EVs have a lesser range than
cars powered by internal combustion engines. Recent surveys show that the
majority of EV owners have a second, nonelectric vehicle—and drive that
second vehicle more (Davis 2023). As a result, actual EV usage is less than
half of what State regulators typically assume (Burlig et al. 2021). While
there remain challenges for the substitution of EVs for internal combustion engine vehicles, solutions already exist and more are emerging. These
include carmakers installing larger battery packs, improvements in battery
technology, and progress on the building out of a robust EV charging network, which is currently under way.
In the extreme case of no substitutability between energy technologies,
demand can fail to materialize. Solar PV cells present an early case study
of missing demand. When silicon solar cells were first developed by Bell
Labs in 1954, they were too expensive for many commercial applications.
The U.S. government long remained their main buyer for use in satellites
and defense applications (Nemet 2019). Today, hydrogen as an energy
feedstock faces similar challenges in industrial settings, where some existing
equipment and processes for using fossil fuels cannot be used for hydrogen.
Complementary capital investments will be needed to generate demand for
hydrogen as an energy feedstock (CEA 2023b).

Financing the Speed and Scale of the Clean Energy Transition
While past structural changes have tended to move on their own timelines,
the biggest challenges for the clean energy transition are the required speed
and scale. As noted above, global temperatures are already rising and the
economic damage is growing. The United States and other countries need to
decarbonize across their economies through the rapid deployment of existing
clean energy technologies and investments in new technological solutions.
The energy transition has significant financing needs that require
accelerating private sector investments. Private investments in clean energy

Accelerating the Clean Energy Transition | 229

technologies have grown in recent years (White House 2023). However, as
a result of impediments common to structural change, they can be riskier
and less profitable than alternative investments. Removing such obstacles to
rapid structural change in the energy sector can accelerate the pace at which
financial markets fund the energy transition on their own. Conceptually,
this financing issue is not distinct from other challenges for the clean energy
transition discussed above; rather, it is a consequence of many of these
impediments existing simultaneously.
On the supply side, novel clean energy technologies can have difficulty
accessing traditional capital markets relative to other industries because of
greater perceived credit risk (Armitage, Bakhtian, and Jaffe 2023). Novel
technologies may experience large cost uncertainties as a result of construction timing and delays, uncertainty about future revenue streams, and manufacturing cost overruns due to a lack of production experience. Traditional
financial institutions may also have less capacity to assess risk for nascent
technologies, making them reluctant to underwrite projects (IEA 2021c).
Clean energy projects confront an additional set of challenges: They
must demonstrate initial commercial viability before being widely adopted.
Early-stage financiers are often unable or unwilling to provide the substantial initial capital this demonstration requires (Ghosh and Nanda 2010).
Financing risks can further limit early-stage investment. Nanda, Younge,
and Fleming (2015) document how energy projects’ financing needs and
profiles are riskier and more capital-intensive than those in other highgrowth industries, such as software and information technology. Potential
early-stage investors may refrain from investing in clean energy companies
if they anticipate that the technology will likely not receive mid-stage
financing in the “valley of death,” whereby market demand is insufficient
for large-scale deployment (Nanda and Rhodes-Kropf 2016).
Demand-side factors can also slow financing for the energy transition.
For example, investors in venture-financed energy start-ups have historically realized fewer exit opportunities compared with those in industries like
biotechnology, semiconductors, and information technology, where established markets exist for start-up firms even before they have demonstrated
commercial viability for their products (Ghosh and Nanda 2010). Energy
companies and utilities have in the past often been reluctant to acquire
start-ups with unproven technologies (Nanda, Younge, and Fleming 2015).
Even as venture capital investment in clean energy has increased over time
(CTVC 2023), venture capital firms may remain hesitant to invest in capitalintensive energy projects when the exit opportunities are limited in the short
run, because such investments may require repeated capital injections over
long periods of time to see a product through to market (Van den Heuvel
and Popp 2022; Fontana and Nanda 2023). Creating a more favorable exit

230 |

Chapter 6

environment for start-ups can help mobilize private sector investment in
these sectors.
In the transition to a new energy system, uncertainty about the broader
market for clean energy can inhibit private sector investment, creating an
opportunity for the public sector to send a durable demand signal. Lerner
and Nanda (2020) argue that understanding market demand is an important
prerequisite for early-stage companies to succeed. According to the authors,
software and service-based businesses have shorter development timelines,
and technological advancements allow these types of companies to ascertain market demand faster. Compared with software- and service-based
businesses, clean energy companies may have more difficulty forecasting
or demonstrating the demand certainty that would make them attractive to
investors.
In summary, the balance of the economic push-and-pull forces affecting the clean energy transition today may limit private sector investment
from reaching the necessary scale required to meet decarbonization goals,
even as progress has been made. The next section turns to the role that government can play in catalyzing a faster transition to the net zero economy.

The Role of the Public Sector
Due to the market failures and economic frictions discussed in the first
section, government intervention is necessary to reach net zero emissions.
Governments have long made investments in developing clean energy
technologies, though not always with the intent of reducing GHG emissions.
In the 1970s, large-scale public investments in wind and solar R&D, which
came about primarily in reaction to shortages and high prices in the oil
market, were major forays into this space (Pirani 2018; CRS 2018; Nahm
2021). Since then, governments around the world have amplified support for
clean energy, increasingly to accelerate the transition to a net zero economy.
Government intervention is critical to solving classic market failures,
such as pollution and knowledge externalities. When it comes to structural
change, such interventions are fundamentally about changing the direction and pace of transitions. Because economic incentives do not yet fully
encourage replacing the existing, fossil-fuel-based energy system with one
based on clean energy, government intervention can alter such incentives.
But importantly, from a structural change lens, those interventions need not
be permanent; once sufficient momentum builds in favor of the clean energy
transition, the private sector could continue the transition, even without
continued government involvement (see box 6-3).
Figure 6-5 illustrates this argument. Emissions in the absence of a
policy intervention are shown as the dashed green line, declining—as in
the case of recent U.S. GHG emissions—albeit not fast enough to meet net
Accelerating the Clean Energy Transition | 231

Figure 6-5. Schematic: GHG Emissions with and without Structural Change
Dynamics
Greenhouse gas emissions

Baseline

No structural change

Structural change with poor targeting

Structural change with correct targeting

Council of Economic Advisers

Time

Source: CEA calculations.
Note: GHG = greenhouse gas. In the absence of structural change dynamics, a temporary policy intervention would lower GHG emissions
but not their growth rate (solid teal line) relative to the no-policy trajectory (dashed green baseline). In the presence of structural change,
a temporary policy would lower the growth rate of GHG emissions. The added decline in GHG emissions is faster when the policy correctly
targets technologies (solid dark navy line) than when targeting is poor (solid lighter blue line).
2024 Economic Report of the President

zero goals. Consider first an economy without structural change dynamics.
A temporary policy intervention lowers the level of GHG emissions over
time but not the growth rate, as illustrated by the solid teal line. As a consequence, emissions continue changing at the same pace as before the policy.
For such an economy, achieving net zero emissions requires permanent
policy intervention. This trajectory contrasts with an economy featuring
structural change dynamics, as shown by the solid blue lines in the figure. A
policy under this scenario can permanently lower emissions’ growth rate by
building path dependence into clean energy sources, generating momentum
that maintains the clean energy transition even after the policy is lifted. That
is, under structural change, long-term decarbonization can be achieved with
policy interventions that eventually allow private market incentives to sustain the clean energy transition without continued government intervention.
The rate at which emissions decline depends on how well the policy
targets cost-effective technologies and GHG reduction options that can compete with fossil-fuel-based technologies to become self-sustaining. Policies
that target poorly (the solid light blue line in the figure) may lead to lock-in
of more costly technologies, ultimately making the economy’s redirection
toward the adoption of clean energy technologies more difficult and expensive than with better targeting (solid navy line).
This path dependence can emerge from economic conditions, but
can also have political origins. A growing literature has documented that
climate policies can help strengthen economic and consumer interest groups
232 |

Chapter 6

Box 6-3. The Public Sector’s Role in Accelerating
Structural Change: The Case of South Korea
The transformation of South Korea’s heavy and chemical industries (HCI)
sector since the 1970s is an example of export-led structural change. After
the devastation of the Korean War of the early 1950s, South Korea turned
to a broad export-based economic strategy in the 1960s and early 1970s,
giving preferential trade policy treatment to any exporting firm. In 1973,
in response to defense concerns, the South Korean government restricted
this policy to HCI firms, providing extensive loan subsidies from domestic financial institutions. The state additionally instituted performance
standards for subsidy recipients, relying on export targets and eschewing
financial indicators of firm performance. Although this policy system was
short-lived, lasting only until 1979, it had a sharp effect on South Korean
industrial production in the decades that followed (Lane 2022).
This sector-specific public intervention resulted in a steep increase
in the productivity of HCI firms, both during the 1973–79 period of direct
industrial strategy and afterward (Lane 2022). The share of HCI exports
remained above pre-1973 levels well after 1979, and remains above those
levels today (Lane 2022; Choi and Levchenko 2021; OEC 2023). Major
present-day South Korean exports—such as Samsung semiconductors and
Hyundai cars—were first produced between 1973 and 1979, and production grew sharply through the 1980s.
Government policies during this period helped spur structural
change, which had previously stalled due to frictions and market failures.
Before the intervention, South Korea’s HCI sector suffered from a financing problem: Western financial institutions were reluctant to provide loans
to Korean plants (Amsden 1992). The South Korean government spurred
investment with subsidized loans that resemble the investment tax credits
underlying modern clean energy investment. And because local demand
was not sufficient to sustain growth in the targeted industries, the South
Korean government then supported exports, allowing cheaper capital and
privileged regulatory status for exporting firms. The government’s last
intervention was to build human capital—essential due to the complexity of HCI manufacturing—by developing and promoting an extensive
engineering education pipeline (Amsden 1992).
The success of South Korea’s HCI sector can be linked to the
country’s industrial strategy during this period. The government’s temporary intervention was sufficient to shift the direction of investment and
establish comparative advantage over the long term in a previously undistinguished industry. Today, many of the component industries of the HCI
drive, such as motor vehicles and shipbuilding, remain pillars of the South
Korean economy. The program’s success suggests that public intervention
can be critical to overcoming obstacles to rapid structural change.

Accelerating the Clean Energy Transition | 233

that make policies more difficult to reverse. For instance, policies that yield
widespread economic benefits, such as by creating new industrial sectors
and sources of employment, can be politically costly to reverse and therefore
are more likely to stay in place across administrations (Meckling and Nahm
2021; Meckling et al. 2015). Conversely, the absence of policy certainty will
lead to underinvestment if potential entrants become unsure of the subsidies
or taxes they may encounter years down the road (Noailly, Nowzohour, and
van den Heuvel 2022). Studies have documented that frequent expirations of
renewable energy production and investment tax credits—as well as shortterm extensions—have a negative impact on the development of a domestic
wind industry (Lewis and Wiser 2007; DOE 2022a).
Finally, public sector interventions work best when governments
directly support desired outcomes rather than require firms to adopt specific
processes or market behaviors (Rodrik 2014). For example, to increase
renewable energy adoption in the power sector, government interventions
would ideally either subsidize renewable energy or tax fossil fuel emissions—without mandating where, how, or what type of renewable energy is
built, as in the case of technology-neutral tax credits. Furthermore, to meet
research and development goals—which may otherwise face private financing challenges—governments could invest in well-diversified portfolios
covering large suites of potential new technologies rather than pick a handful
of firms and products, anticipating that some technologies may ultimately
fail while others succeed. These interventions can provide certainty to the
private sector while allowing flexibility for new innovations. They can help
mitigate the potential effects of incomplete information, particularly during
a transition to emerging technologies, and address the difficulty of acquiring
accurate information in the face of rent-seeking by firms.
In order to accelerate the clean energy transition, the supply- and
demand-side policies highlighted below take account of these considerations. These interventions must also be coordinated because they are part
of a broader, multipolicy approach that simultaneously enhances the push
forces and removes the pull forces behind the clean energy transition.

Supply-Side Policies
Enhancing productivity spillovers. Government can induce the creation of
new technologies. Basic research can lead to breakthrough technologies
that generate high economic returns (National Research Council 2001), but
because private returns are significantly smaller than public returns, private
investors tend to underinvest in basic research (Lucking, Bloom, and Van
Reenen 2020). This pattern is particularly pronounced in the energy sector,
where the private sector has historically underinvested in basic R&D (Nemet
and Kammen 2007).

234 |

Chapter 6

The U.S. government has therefore long supported basic research,
and remains the world’s largest funder of energy research (IEA 2023d;
Sandalow et al. 2022). The Bipartisan Infrastructure Law (BIL)—enacted as
the Infrastructure Investment and Jobs Act (Public Law 117-58), along with
the 2020 Energy Act (Public Law 116-260, div. Z)—more than triples the
Department of Energy’s annual funding for energy programs and includes a
significant expansion of funds for R&D (DOE 2022b). Such public investments in research will yield global knowledge and productivity spillovers
that can accelerate the energy transition (Berkes, Manysheva, and Mestieri
2022). Nonetheless, current public investments in energy R&D still fall
short of the levels required to meet climate targets, given that key technologies needed to reduce costs and decarbonize industrial sectors have yet to
become commercialized (see box 6-4). Current U.S. public energy R&D
spending remains below the amount spent in the aftermath of the oil crises
of the 1970s (Gallagher and Anadon 2022).
Lowering capital, land, and transmission costs. Certain clean energy
technologies, like solar PV cells, have already seen significant declines in
capital costs. However, newer technologies—such as grid-scale battery storage, hydrogen electrolyzers, carbon capture and storage, direct air capture,
and advanced modular nuclear reactors—still face high capital costs (DOE
2023c).
Public sector interventions, including loan guarantees, can lower
capital costs for clean energy technologies. The Department of Energy’s
Clean Energy Financing Program, which provides loan guarantees for innovative clean energy technologies—and which was recently scaled up under
the Inflation Reduction Act (IRA) of 2022 (Public Law 117-169)—is an
example of such a public sector intervention. Such programs can lower the
future cost of renewable technologies through learning-by-doing (Arkolakis
and Walsh 2023) and by encouraging complementary private investments
required to achieve the net zero economy (Heintz 2010; Juhász, Lane, and
Rodrik 2023). Loan guarantees can lower the risks inherent in financing
clean energy projects, thereby increasing the availability of capital (Bachas,
Kim, and Yannelis 2021; CRS 2012). They can also provide an information
signal to private financiers to further de-risk projects and “crowd in” private
capital—shortening the time frame by which clean energy technologies
become bankable (DOE 2023e). One analysis of the Department of Energy’s
early-stage grants to high-tech clean energy start-up firms finds a positive
effect on future financing from the private sector (Howell 2017). Another
study finds that young firms in Germany that received public investment
were more likely to access bank loans, and that this effect was particularly
pronounced in sectors that were “information-opaque” (Hottenrott, Lins, and
Lutz 2017).

Accelerating the Clean Energy Transition | 235

Box 6-4. The Need for Global Climate Collaboration
Solving climate change is an inherently global challenge, for which the
United States’ clean energy transition is only one part of the solution. The
world will avoid dangerous climate change only if other countries also
undertake similar structural transformations. In 2022, the United States
accounted for 14 percent of global GHG emissions; China’s share was 31
percent. Collectively, major powers have the potential to substantially curb
emissions: The United States, China, the EU-27, Brazil, Russia, and India
together accounted for more than 60 percent of global emissions in 2022
(Friedlingstein 2023).
U.S. investments in clean energy technologies could drive down
global production costs (Way et al. 2022; Larsen et al. 2023) and encourage
innovation worldwide (Berkes, Manysheva, and Mestieri 2022). But even
accounting for these investments and their global spillovers, the world
is projected to fall short of the manufacturing and deployment capacity
necessary to meet global climate goals. For example, while the world is
expected to develop sufficient or near-sufficient manufacturing capacity for
EV batteries and solar modules by 2030 to stay on track for global net zero
emissions by 2050 (IEA 2021a), global manufacturing capacity of wind
turbines, heat pumps, and other key technologies is likely lagging behind the
necessary pace to meet decarbonization goals (figure 6-i).
There is an urgent need for other governments to join the United States
in rapidly accelerating their clean energy transitions. In the United States
and elsewhere, strategic public sector intervention to remove impediments
to structural change in the energy transition can generate the necessary
buy-in from the private sector to yield clean energy technologies that will be
cheaper than their carbon-emitting counterparts.
Figure 6-i. Projected and Target Global Manufacturing Capacity, 2030
Percent

120

2030 target
for net zero
by 2050

100
80
60
40
20
0

Solar PV
Gap

Wind
Rest of world

Council of Economic Advisers

Hydrogen
electrolyzers
Europe

Heat pumps

North America

EV batteries Fuel cell trucks
Other Asia Pacific

China

Sources: International Energy Agency; CEA calculations.
Note: “Manufacturing capacity” refers to the maximum rated output of facilities for producing a given technology, as
distinguished from the capacity of the technologies themselves once deployed. Capacity is stated on an annual basis for the
final product.
2024 Economic Report of the President

236 |

Chapter 6

However, lowered capital costs for clean technologies may be insufficient if other input costs remain high. The land requirements of some clean
energy technologies imply added costs—and often this demand occurs in
agriculturally productive areas (van de Ven et al. 2021). Governments can
help navigate this trade-off, especially in the case of wind farms. Each turbine has a relatively small footprint (Denholm et al. 2009), and incentivizing
the use of arable space between wind turbines for agriculture dramatically
lessens a wind farm’s land requirements. Likewise, policies can encourage
solar co-location with agriculture. While growing crops under solar PV is
still a nascent practice, tax breaks and direct subsidies could scale it up
(Boyd 2023), potentially through the resources provided by the IRA for the
U.S. Department of Agriculture’s Rural Energy for America Program.
High land prices can also be mitigated by building renewable energy
generation away from agriculturally productive areas. But these locations
tend to be far from population centers where electricity demand is highest,
and new renewables projects are limited by the transmission capacity of the
section of the grid to which they are connected. Expanding transmission is
therefore an important complement to building new clean energy generation
capacity. New transmission is needed both within and across regions of the
country (DOE 2023d). The BIL allocates $2.5 billion to specific projects to
this end. Absent such investment in transmission as well as in distribution,
increased electrification will strain the existing grid.
Increasing labor mobility. Governments can play a central role in
removing labor market frictions that could otherwise impede the clean
energy transition (CEA 2021). Initiatives that address both skill needs and
mismatch in the labor market, along with geographic immobility, are particularly necessary to accelerate the energy transition.
Workforce development programs are needed to train the next generation of workers in the clean energy sector and to retrain workers transitioning from the fossil fuel industry. Government initiatives that standardize
education to include training on clean energy technologies are critically
important—particularly for multicraft work like rooftop solar installation,
which requires knowledge of carpentry, roofing, metal work, electrical,
and information technology (IREC 2023). Programs that create pathways
between education, training, entry-level jobs, and long-term careers are
necessary to ensure long-term job quality and retention. Recent Federal policies reflect the importance of establishing a pipeline from apprenticeships to
entry-level jobs. The IRA, for instance, introduced a bonus adder on top of
a wide range of tax credits in the power, manufacturing, and transportation
sectors for eligible firms that provide prevailing wages and employ qualified
apprentices for certain construction, alteration, and repair work. Moreover,
the creation of new apprenticeship programs provides an opportunity to
accelerate economic growth by ensuring that workers—and in particular
Accelerating the Clean Energy Transition | 237

women—who have been historically underrepresented in the energy sector
have access to the jobs of the future. Women represent less than 20 percent
of employed workers in both the clean and fossil fuel sectors (Colmer,
Lyubich, and Voorheis 2023).
Government interventions in retraining programs can support workers
currently in the fossil fuel sector, retraining them for either the clean energy
sector or other industries (Katz et al. 2022; Hanson 2023). Hyman (2022)
provides evidence that deliberately targeting labor immobility during market
disruptions can increase the likelihood that workers will switch industries—and improve workers’ outcomes. In the context of the clean energy
transition, estimates for the costs of retraining programs vary (Louie and
Pearce 2016), but may be minor relative to the overall costs of the transition
(Vanatta et al. 2022).
Government programs addressing geographic immobility can complement workforce development programs. Such programs can provide funding
to construct clean energy manufacturing facilities close to their fossil-fuelbased counterparts, or provide moving allowances to help workers relocate
(Vanatta et al. 2022; Pollin and Callaci 2016). The Department of Energy,
for instance, announced $15.5 billion in funding for the conversion of
existing automotive manufacturing facilities to support the EV supply
chain (DOE 2023b). Policies can also support communities where local tax
revenues have historically depended on fossil fuel industries (International
Renewable Energy Age 2023).

Demand-Side Policies
Boosting demand over longer horizons. Because private investors are reluctant to fund the commercialization of new energy technologies, government
interventions can create a long-term demand signal. Such interventions can
prevent novel clean energy technologies from being stranded in the “valley
of death” (Nemet 2019).
Production and investment tax credits for clean energy installations
can boost demand for these technologies. The United States has employed
some form of a production tax credit since 1992 to generate demand for a
wide variety of renewable energy technologies, all without favoring specific
firms (CRS 2020). Under the IRA, production and investment tax credits for
clean energy will be technology-neutral by 2025—production of any type
of energy with sufficiently low emissions will receive the same tax breaks.
Both subsidies are available without a total tax expenditure limit until 2032,
or when U.S. GHG emissions from electricity reach a certain threshold,
creating a durable market signal incentivizing the use of renewable energy
for electricity.

238 |

Chapter 6

Such policies have proven effective in mobilizing private sector financing in other contexts. One paper finds that such demand-side
policies shore up durable market demand and help mobilize private sector
investments—particularly venture capital—toward clean energy innovation (van den Heuvel and Popp 2022). And in the pharmaceutical industry,
demand-side policies (also known as “demand-pull” policies) have helped
to mobilize biomedical R&D when market incentives to do so are weak
(Glennerster and Kremer 2000; Global Trade Funding n.d.). Likewise,
advance market commitments have enabled greater production of pharmaceutical products—such as vaccines—in markets without mature market
demand (Kremer, Levin, and Snyder 2020; Berndt et al. 2006).
Improving substitutability. In the power sector, battery storage technologies provide one avenue for alleviating variability concerns and making
renewable energy a better substitute for fossil fuels. Grid-connected battery storage is rapidly increasing in the United States. In 2023, the United
States deployed 16 gigawatts (GW) of grid-connected battery capacity, with
another 15 GW planned for 2024 (EIA 2024b). To meet net zero goals, the
United States needs about 131 GW of grid-scale storage by 2050, according
to models (Narich et al. 2021). Policies encouraging additional deployment
are likely to lower costs further (NREL 2023). These policies include investment tax credits for battery adoption and production tax credits for battery
manufacturing—both of which are provided under the IRA.
Batteries installed on electricity grids should be charged when
wholesale electricity prices are low and discharged when these prices rise.
Assuming the marginal electricity generator uses renewable energy when
prices are low and fossil fuels when prices are high, tax incentives for batteries will result in reduced GHG emissions by replacing electricity from
fossil fuels with electricity from renewables. If low electricity prices instead
coincide with deriving marginal electricity from fossil fuels, battery incentives could lead to increased GHG emissions (Hittinger and Azevedo 2015;
Pimm et al. 2019; Beuse et al. 2021). Policies that tie investment tax credits
for batteries only to grids with a positive within-day correlation between
wholesale prices and marginal emissions would ensure that battery expansion coincides with GHG reductions.
Better substitutability between clean energy and fossil fuels also
ensures that clean energy subsidies deliver both lower electricity prices and
GHG reductions. This is because clean energy subsidies have composition
and scale effects (Baumol and Oates 1988). They make clean energy cheaper
relative to fossil fuels, tilting the composition of electricity toward clean
energy and lowering GHG emissions, all else remaining equal. Clean energy
subsidies also increase the overall scale of electricity consumption by making electricity cheaper, increasing all energy inputs, including fossil fuels,
and thus possibly GHG emissions, all else remaining equal (Casey, Jeon,
Accelerating the Clean Energy Transition | 239

and Traeger 2023). When clean energy and fossil fuels are better substitutes,
as with greater battery deployment, the composition effect dominates over
the scale effect and clean energy subsidies both reduce emissions and lower
electricity prices (Hassler et al. 2020; Casey, Jeon, and Traeger 2023).
Likewise, policies that make EVs more substitutable with internal
combustion engines—either by improving range or increasing charging convenience—can accelerate their adoption. The IRA’s production tax credit
for battery manufacturing is aimed at driving down the cost of production,
which can improve range. The investment tax credit for household adoption
of battery storage under the IRA and the $7.5 billion allocated for building
a national high-speed EV charger network under the BIL are designed to
increase charging convenience.

Coordinating Supply and Demand
The necessary scale and speed of the clean energy transition requires coordinating supply and demand policies. Demand for clean energy technologies
often requires complementary and simultaneous supply-side investments in
different technologies and supporting infrastructure. As noted above, EVs
are dependent on a charging infrastructure. Some consumers are reluctant
to invest in EVs before an adequately convenient supply of chargers is
installed, while investments in chargers are unprofitable before consumers
collectively purchase a sufficient fleet of EVs (Li et al. 2017). Prior research
has suggested that supply-side investments—such as subsidies for the EV
charging infrastructure—should be developed in tandem with direct EV
subsidies (Cole et al. 2023; Rapson and Muehlegger 2022; Dimanchev et
al. 2023).
Similar network effects and coordination problems exist in the switch
to new fuels, like clean hydrogen, which require investments in the technologies for both production and demand (Armitage, Bakhtian, and Jaffe
2023). In addition to retrofitting facilities to use hydrogen as a feedstock,
midstream infrastructure, including pipelines and storage, will be essential
for maturing the clean hydrogen industry—in addition to investments in
the technology used for hydrogen production (U.S. Department of Energy
2023c). The current short-term availability of infrastructure to transport,
store, and distribute hydrogen is often cited as a constraint on industry
growth, especially given the challenges of co-locating production and end
use (Zacarias and Nakano 2023).
The public sector can play a significant coordinating role, incentivizing demand while ensuring adequate supply to establish new markets.
When future demand is uncertain, firms may find investing in the necessary
production technology or infrastructure more challenging, in part because
financing is more difficult to obtain under such conditions. However, in the

240 |

Chapter 6

absence of adequate supply, investments in technologies and infrastructure
to create demand are often also difficult to justify. Policy interventions can
resolve such coordination challenges. For example, offtake contracts—to
purchase an agreed-upon quantity at a price often determined ahead of
production—are often a prerequisite for project financing. Loan underwriters therefore commonly ask to see offtake contracts before approving debt
financing (Global Trade Funding n.d.). The Department of Energy is currently establishing a demand-side support program that provides offtake
certainty—through contracts with, for instance, hydrogen producers and
buyers—for projects in the Regional Clean Hydrogen Hubs program funded
by the BIL (U.S. Department of Energy 2023).

Conclusion
Decarbonizing the global economy—in addition to mitigating the effects of
climate change—provides new economic opportunities. The shift to clean
energy can lower energy prices, offer greater energy security, reduce volatility in energy markets, mitigate local air pollution, and create new sources
of employment in emerging sectors. Switching to clean energy also offers
a generational opportunity for the United States to further its economic
competitiveness in the innovative sectors of the 21st century. This chapter
has explained in detail how to achieve these objectives through structural
change, presenting an economic framework for understanding the factors
that can accelerate the clean energy transition. It has further highlighted
specific government interventions that can remove obstacles to the transition
and create opportunities for the private sector to drive new sources of green
growth.
The Biden-Harris Administration is strategically targeting these highreturn investments. On the supply side, examples of this approach include
the Department of Energy’s expanded funding for energy programs and
R&D through the BIL, which serves to accelerate innovation spillovers and
drive down capital costs for emerging technologies where private sector
investments are still insufficient. Similarly, the IRA includes loan guarantees for innovative clean energy technologies to mitigate risk for clean
energy projects and to unlock new private financing. Both the BIL and the
IRA support the construction of new clean energy manufacturing facilities
in communities with preexisting fossil fuel industry presence, thereby reducing labor market frictions by helping workers transition to the clean energy
sector (U.S. Department of the Treasury 2023).
On the demand side, the IRA, among many other of its provisions,
employs tax credits for renewable energy installation and for household
adoption of electric vehicles, renewable energy generation, and heat
pumps. The duration of these tax credits boosts demand for clean energy
Accelerating the Clean Energy Transition | 241

technologies over longer time horizons sufficient for enabling scale economies and learning-by-doing. Battery incentives under the IRA can also
accelerate the clean energy transition in the power sector by making renewable energy sources less variable and thus a better substitute for fossil fuels.
By simultaneously pursuing these interventions, the clean energy agenda
of the Biden-Harris Administration is jointly addressing the supply- and
demand-side challenges needed to ensure a rapid clean energy transition.
Although the scale and urgency of the clean energy transition present
unique challenges, this transition ultimately shares many features with prior
government- and market-led transformations. In the process of reaching net
zero emissions, both governments and private actors will need to grapple
with how to transform an economy powered by fossil fuels to one powered
by clean energy. A structural change framework helps illuminate how to
achieve this shift, through targeted government investments that lower the
cost of clean energy and their complementary inputs and technologies, as
well as through programs that enable the transition to help both workers and
their communities. Such successful interventions could pay large dividends
for decades to come, putting the U.S. economy on a path toward a future
where energy is clean, cheap, reliable, and secure.

242 |

Chapter 6

Chapter 7

An Economic Framework for
Understanding Artificial Intelligence
Artificial intelligence (AI) systems touch the lives of virtually every
American. They range from simple systems like text autocorrect to complex
algorithms capable of setting prices, driving cars, and writing essays. In
recent years, AI systems have advanced rapidly as recent developments in
computing, data availability, and machine learning models have simultaneously come together to produce rapid improvements. Still, much remains
unknown. Agrawal, Gans, and Goldfarb (2022) suggest that AI is in “the
between times,” where society has begun to see the technology’s potential
but has not come close to fully realizing it. While AI’s capabilities will
depend in part on the technology itself, its effects will be shaped by economic, regulatory, and social pressures. How society deploys this technology and what technology-specific guardrails are implemented will be critical
factors in determining both the breadth and magnitude of its effects.
Economic incentives play a central role in how decisions are made. An economic framework, combined with a basic understanding of AI technology,
allows us to make predictions about when, how, and why AI may be adopted.
While such a framework can also tell us what broader effects AI adoption
may have, applying economic insights to an evolving and proliferating
technology like AI is especially challenging. However, it is also especially
valuable, because decisions made at the onset of a new technology have a
greater influence on its eventual impact. This chapter begins with a basic
discussion of the technology and then examines how the inputs to AI have
changed, with a particular focus on the concept of diminishing returns and
the key role of data in AI systems. Next, it examines the economic incentives
243

for AI development and adoption, including on macroeconomic outcomes
like productivity. The chapter’s third section adapts standard economic
models to explore AI’s potential effects on labor markets across the earnings
distribution, demographic groups, industries, and geographic areas, updating
previous work with new data and augmenting it with a novel analysis based
on not only exposure to AI but also the complexity of each task. Finally,
the fourth section examines important economic issues for upcoming policy
choices related to the law and regulations, competition issues, and social
outcomes (e.g., how technology interacts with existing inequalities like
racial discrimination).

Toward “Intelligent” Automation
Since Adam Smith’s first observations about how machinery allowed for
the division of labor, economists have studied the economic effects of
technology (Smith 1776). Many technologies—like Smith’s example of specialization by workers in a pin factory—enable more output from the same
inputs. Some technologies, however, enable an increase in capital to reduce
labor. Economists call this class of technologies automation (Brozen 1957;
Zeira 1998; Acemoglu and Restrepo 2018).1 This definition of automation
is broader than factory machines and computers, and includes technologies that have been in place for centuries. For example, according to this
definition, a windmill set up to grind wheat would be a kind of automation.
These kinds of technologies can have broad effects—including on prices,
wages, input usage, and output—which in turn may resonate throughout the
economy.2 As discussed later in the chapter, a wide range of potential uses of
AI entail this kind of capital-for-labor substitution, making it an automation
technology.
To understand the incentives for AI’s development and adoption, it
is necessary to have a basic common understanding of the technology. The
field of AI is broad and changing quickly. What follows is a stylized representation of basic concepts that may not be applicable to every circumstance.
In some cases, automation technologies simply replace existing labor. In most cases, however,
automation technologies allow for greater output than before, and in some cases, they may allow for
the creation of products that would never be economically viable to create by hand.
2
While this definition’s emphasis on the word “substitution” might suggest that automation
technologies invariably reduce employment, this need not be the case. Because automation
technologies make certain production steps faster and cheaper, they can increase overall demand for
both the product being made and related products. Additionally, labor is generally required to create
and maintain such technologies.
1

244 |

Chapter 7

Although definitions of AI vary across fields and purposes, AI systems
are generally understood to take in data and,3 through statistical or computational techniques, make predictions.4 Some have called them “prediction
machines” (Agrawal, Gans, and Goldfarb 2018). In many cases, predictions
are used to inform recommendations or determine how other components of
the system will act. For example, AI systems have been developed to solve
challenging scientific problems, and they are widely used to set prices and
rank job candidates. In other cases, as with some generative AI models,
these predictions themselves are simply aggregated to form an output.5 In
this context, predictions are far broader than forecasting the future, and can
indeed be about practically anything for which reliable data can be obtained.
The ability to make predictions often allows improved decision-making, even in the face of uncertainty. As a result, AI systems can automate
more tasks than prior technologies and improve the work quality of existing processes. For example, stamping machines automate the creation of
certain kinds of metal parts, but automated systems may have struggled to
handle situations where the production process had inherent variation, like
harvesting produce. Today, an AI-augmented system might use sensor data
to predict when fruit is ripe and how to detach it, allowing that production
process to be further automated (Zhou et al. 2022). Likewise, autocorrect
systems are an example of how AI increases the quality of work. Originally,
these systems relied on lists of often-mistyped words and their correct spelling. When the software detected misspellings, it suggested a correction.
Advanced autocorrect systems using AI employ dictionaries, information
about what all users tend to type, and data from individual users’ past typing activities to predict what they intend to type (Lewis-Kraus 2014). As
a result, the systems detect not only misspellings but also incorrect words.
Figure 7-1 portrays a stylized diagram of how AI systems interact
with traditional automation in order to emphasize key ideas relevant to
the economic discussion.6 During training, an algorithm is applied to data
In this context, data can refer to any machine-readable information and is not limited to the kinds
of datasets that economists might be most familiar with. It can potentially include digitally encoded
text, images, sound, video, information on real-time human input, simulation feedback, and many
other categories of information.
4
For example, Executive Order 14110 (2023) defines AI systems as those that “use machine- and
human-based inputs to perceive real and virtual environments; abstract such perceptions into
models through analysis in an automated manner; and use model inference to formulate options for
information or action.” It defines an AI model as something that “implements AI technology and
uses computational, statistical, or machine-learning techniques to produce outputs from a given set
of inputs.”
5
Executive Order 14110 (2023) defines generative AI as “the class of AI models that emulate the
structure and characteristics of input data in order to generate derived synthetic content. This can
include images, videos, audio, text, and other digital content.”
6
Of particular note, figure 7-1 emphasizes the role of data in AI, though in many cases it might be
more accurate to more generally refer to inputs.
3

An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 245

Figure 7-1. A Stylized Diagram of How AI Extends Automation with Prediction
Prediction process

Training
data

Algorithms

Runtime
inputs

Training

Computing
power

Model
usage

Traditional automation

Prediction

Action

Result

Model

Feedback

Council of Economic Advisers
2024 Economic Report of the President

using computing power.7 In some instances, this training process can be
quite complex and involve many iterations; often, it includes validation
and testing steps, which are not shown in the figure. The training process
produces a model, which is combined with data at the time it is used to create a prediction. Such predictions, however, are rarely useful until they are
applied in some way. In typical AI systems, one or more predictions are used
to take actions automatically. For example, a large language model might
make many predictions about individual words based upon a user’s request,
and then the system aggregates them into one output to display. The same
kind of model in a different context, such as customer service, might not
only respond to the user but also issue a refund. Finally, the results may be
evaluated to create feedback to help further refine the model in the future,
and some systems learn continuously to further improve performance and
prevent degradation.
As figure 7-1 illustrates, AI systems can integrate multiple sources of
data, often at different points and for different purposes. For example, in the
diagram, data may enter the system at the training, runtime, and feedback
stages. In some cases, human input can be an important part of development
as well (Amershi et al. 2014; Mosqueira-Rey et al. 2022; Ouyang et al.
2022).8 AI’s reliance on data raises unique economic issues, including ones
related to competition and transparency. These issues are discussed in more
detail later in the chapter.
Figure 7-1 also illustrates that having the requisite algorithm, data,
and computational power to make predictions is a necessary but not sufficient condition for AI-based automation. For example, even after a model
Some types of AI systems—for example, systems that rely on coded rules rather than machine
learning—may not make use of training data (e.g., Taddy 2019).
8
In some cases, a large amount of human input has been important in fine-tuning models to
ensure acceptable performance, and serious concerns have been raised about the pay and working
conditions of those workers (Perrigo 2023; Bartholomew 2023).
7

246 |

Chapter 7

is developed for self-driving cars, it may not be deployed in older cars that
lack the sophisticated sensors necessary to collect the requisite data while
being driven. Similarly, practical limitations on actions may limit the scope
of AI deployment. For example, many tasks involving flexible materials
have proven very difficult for robots to handle (Billard and Kragic 2019).
AI systems may ameliorate these problems, but such physical limitations
may continue to prevent the automation of tasks even where the system has
sufficient predictive power. Finally, in some cases, translating prediction
into action may require making decisions that we are unwilling or unable
to fully delegate to AI due to ethical or other concerns (Agrawal, Gans, and
Goldfarb 2018).

Prediction Is Improving but Faces Constraints
In general, prediction quality can be thought of as the output of an economic
production function. Developers choose an option from a variety of different algorithms, each of which can be optimized subject to the developer’s
constraints, such as development time, data availability, or budget for computational resources. Economists represent these kinds of situations where
agents are maximizing an objective subject to restrictions as constrained
optimization problems (Mas-Colell, Whinston, and Green 1995). Typically,
in a constrained optimization setting, not all constraints are equally binding,
and some may not be binding at all. As an extreme example, a complete
lack of data on a problem could render a lack of computational resources
irrelevant. Of course, these constraints are constantly changing as new
data become available, as computational resources become cheaper, and
as research develops more efficient algorithms and other innovations.9 The
relationship between design and development choices (e.g., algorithms,
data, and computational resources) and prediction quality is thus complex
and varies from situation to situation. In part because of the complex interactions of these constraints, predictions about AI’s future capabilities have
often been wrong (Armstrong, Sotala, and Ó hÉigeartaigh 2014).
It is potentially more informative to look at how AI performs various
tasks. Figure 7-2 shows the performance of the best available AI model in
each year on a number of benchmarks, rescaled to compare with human
performance on the same test. Comparing AI’s performance with human
performance in this way is potentially useful for understanding if and when
AI systems may be deployed as a substitute for labor, although researchers
have raised serious concerns about these kinds of benchmarks, both in the
way they aggregate performance (e.g., Burnell et al. 2023) and in the way
Research can also alter these constraints in other ways. For example, a great deal of work in both
machine learning and econometrics is done to find ways to compensate for data limitations, often at
the cost of increased computational requirements.

9

An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 247

Figure 7-2. AI Capabilities Over Time and Across Tasks
Test scores of AI relative to human performance
0.2
0.0

Human performance, as the benchmark, is set to zero

-0.2
-0.4
-0.6
-0.8
-1.0
1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

MNIST (handwriting recognition)
ImageNet (image recognition)
SQuAD 2.0 (reading comprehension)

Council of Economic Advisers

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

Switchboard (speech recognition)
SQuAD 1.1 (reading comprehension)
GLUE (language understanding)

2020

Sources: Adapted from Hutson (2022), based on Kiela et al. (2021); CEA calculations.
Note: MNIST = Modified National Institute of Standards and Technology; SQuAD = Stanford Question Answering Dataset;
GLUE = General Language Understanding Evaluation. Benchmark performance is scaled so that –1 is initial performance
and 0 is human performance.
2024 Economic Report of President

selected metrics may create the fictious appearance of sudden large performance improvements (Schaeffer, Miranda, and Koyejo 2023).
Figure 7-2 shows that AI systems have approached human performance at very different rates across the various benchmarks. In some cases,
the progress of AI was significantly influenced by data availability (e.g.,
Xiong et al. 2016; Sharifani and Amini 2023). Because of the way in which
they naturally produce and share digital information, the Internet and smartphones have been important data sources. Similarly, small, cheap sensors
have dramatically changed data availability in industrial and maintenance
operations. These complementary technologies have been especially important in creating the volume of data necessary to train modern AI systems,
and especially foundation models.
In most economic optimization problems, the marginal value of an
input (data, computational resources, etc.) tends to decrease as more of it is
used, as measured by the amount of output in quantity, quality, or otherwise.
In other words, adding more of something may help the situation, but it takes
more and more of that resource to generate the same increase in benefits as
before. As a simple example, hiring workers to work in an empty factory
may rapidly improve production, but over time the workers will begin to get
in each other’s way. This phenomenon is widely observed in economics,
including in returns to capital, income growth across countries, and even
research activity (Solow 1956; Mankiw, Romer, and Weil 1992; Kortum

248 |

Chapter 7

1997; Bloom et al. 2020). In extreme cases, more of an input can make the
problem worse. One such example, in software engineering, is given in The
Mythical Man-Month (Brooks 1975).
Many AI models have also exhibited evidence of diminishing returns
(Hestness et al. 2017; Kaplan et al. 2020; Zhai et al. 2022). While in some
cases it is possible to improve the performance effect of an input (e.g., via
new data-pruning methods; see Sorscher et al. 2022), these techniques typically do not change the underlying diminishing relationship (Muennighoff
et al. 2023).
Just because the marginal value of each additional input tends to fall
does not imply that performance is fundamentally limited. Adding more
of every input—if they are available—can continue to produce substantial
gains, as can finding new kinds of inputs (e.g., new kinds of data). And large
enough changes in inputs may shift which class of algorithms or models
perform best. For example, large language models became viable when sufficient data and computational resources became available, in turn spurring
researchers to develop further technical innovations like transformer-based
architecture or more specialized hardware (Vaswani et al. 2017; Bommasani
et al. 2021; Dally, Keckler, and Kirk 2021). But the speed of continued
progress is likely to be heavily dependent on the rate at which we continue
to produce new innovations rather than simply by virtue of ever-increasing
computational or data resources (Jones 2022; Philippon 2022).

Garbage In, Garbage Out
Data are key informational inputs into AI systems, and they are central to the
way AI performs. AI systems make informed predictions because they use
the correlations embedded in data. Many different changes have contributed
to improvements in AI systems, including improvements in algorithms and
increased availability of computational resources. Nonetheless, developers
of AI-based prediction models continue to grapple with many of the same
data-related challenges that statisticians and econometricians have faced for
decades.10 To understand AI technology as a whole, it is helpful to understand the unique role that data and data-related constraints play.
The scale and quality of available data directly affect the performance
of AI, but a large quantity of data alone is not sufficient. Prediction models
typically perform well in situations that look much like the data they are
trained on. In contrast, rare or novel circumstances where the past is a poor
guide to the future make prediction more challenging, as do data limitations
These fields are very much related. Economists borrowed a large number of techniques from
statisticians in the early days of econometrics; and in the late 1990s and early 2000s, many computer
scientists adopted statistics and econometric techniques like Bayesian updating. While it can be
challenging to collaborate because these different fields approach problems in different ways and
have very different jargon, past collaborations have yielded substantial improvements.
10

An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 249

that might not immediately be apparent. In situations with poor or incomplete data, models may be simultaneously highly confident and wrong in
their predictions (e.g., DeVries and Taylor 2018). For example, concerns
arise when input data are systematically biased. An AI system that is trained
without accounting for the bias is nearly certain to reproduce it. Many current facial recognition applications face this problem, and an overreliance
on AI facial recognition technology could exacerbate discrimination (e.g.,
Najibi 2020; Buolamwini and Gebru 2018; Raji et al. 2020a). (See box 7-1.)
Additionally, in some instances, people may intentionally feed an AI system
manipulated data so as to undermine its function (Shan et al. 2023). Such
attacks can be more difficult to detect and reverse than more traditional
methods of interference. After training is completed, isolating and removing
the impact of poor-quality data can prove challenging and expensive, and
may be only partially successful.11 For all these reasons, curation of data is
generally important for AI systems, just as it is for most technology firms.12
Data are unlike natural resources, such as iron or copper; they are often
drawn from users. User data include things such as the words they publish in
books or on social media, as well as records of the things they do, typically
captured by now ubiquitous electronic devices. AI enables predictions to be
individualized in ways that rules-based algorithmic approaches do not. Such
personalization can allow firms to create customized products or recommendations, and these tailored products can benefit consumers. However, AI can
also be used in ways that harm consumers through price discrimination, by
suggesting products or services sold by the AI company that may not best
meet a consumer’s needs, or through the exploitation of behavioral biases
(e.g., Gautier, Ittoo, and Cleynenbreugel 2020; Engler 2021). Many social
media companies, for example, design their products to maximize engagement rather than entertainment or education, even when such engagement
can be harmful (e.g., Luca 2015; Braghieri, Levy, and Makarin 2022). As
consumers learn about AI-related targeting, they may abandon products or
change their behavior, undermining the technology’s value (e.g., Garbarino
and Maxwell 2010; Nunan and Di Domenico 2022).

Researchers continue to make progress on so-called unlearning methods to address the issue of
unwanted data, though many approaches have been shown to have limited performance in practice
(Kuramanji et al. 2023; Zhang et al. 2024). The implications of successful unlearning are also
relevant for issues such as individual privacy protection (Neel and Chang 2023).
12
In many cases, data have scaled up more quickly than firms’ ability to curate them. While
AI-powered curation may improve the situation, AI systems may also make the situation worse. For
example, while some AI systems may help firms decide which content to publish, other AI systems
may increase the volume of proposed content requiring review (Edwards 2023).
11

250 |

Chapter 7

Box 7-1. AI and Equity/Discrimination
Many artificial intelligence applications use data generated by humans
to predict how individuals will behave. While these data can give AI
considerable power and utility, they also allow it to replicate many
of humanity’s worst biases. The capacity of AI to lead to discrimination—whether inadvertently or intentionally—poses new challenges for
enforcement of existing anti-discrimination policies.
Economists have shown that discriminatory behavior can have
many sources. Even in the absence of any intentional prejudgment (what
economists call prejudice), discrimination based on statistical inference can be harmful (e.g., Lang and Spitzer 2020). Users of predictive
algorithms have already faced this problem, including hiring managers
who found they were favoring male candidates (Dastin 2018), potential
employers who advertised job posts less heavily to women (Lambrecht
and Tucker 2019), and health care systems that favored white patients
over Black patients in predicting care needs (Obermeyer et al. 2019),
among many other examples. These effects may arise from the biases
of AI model developers, or inadvertently from previously unrecognized
patterns in the data. The lack of transparency in sophisticated AI algorithms may compound the issue (e.g., Chesterman 2021; Hutson 2021).
Even if AI providers remove obviously biased or prejudicial content
from their training data, discrimination based on subtle statistical patterns is still likely (Barocas and Selbst 2016).
An additional challenge is ill intent among the users of AI models.
AI’s opaque methods could provide cover for prejudiced entities to use
AI in numerous discriminatory ways, such as firms combining AI with
surveillance to predict, deter, and punish union organizing activity, or
landlords using AI to discriminate against potential tenants based on
their predicted demographics. Evidence suggests that illegal behavior
is already widespread in these contexts (McNicholas et al. 2019;
Christensen and Timmins 2023), and users will likely adopt AI tools to
continue their discriminatory practices and obfuscate their intent.
AI-abetted discrimination could harm individuals in the labor
market, in housing markets, in financial transactions, and anywhere
else predictive algorithms are used. Often, discrimination may only be
observable through sophisticated analysis of AI methods and outputs.
Regulatory measures to help identify discrimination in critical markets
are necessary. The Biden-Harris Administration’s Blueprint for an AI
Bill of Rights emphasizes the importance of protection from algorithmic discrimination, and its recent Executive Order has identified key
agencies within the Federal Government to develop the tools and issue
guidance or regulations needed to combat it (White House 2022, 2023a).
Nonetheless, widespread AI adoption means that identifying and
rooting out discrimination will remain an ongoing process. Researchers

An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 251

who study the auditing of AI algorithms generally conclude that a multifaceted approach is necessary, including a clear identification of objectives and metrics, transparency about the audit process, and a proactive
consideration of how auditability can be incorporated into AI models in
multiple stages (Guszcza et al. 2018; Raji et al. 2020b; Mökander et al.
2021; Costanza-Chock, Raji, and Buolamwini 2022). Explicit methods
to identify discriminatory capabilities and strengthen AI guardrails are
also likely to be a key component of a comprehensive antidiscrimination
strategy (e.g., Ganguli et al. 2022). Some of these methods may themselves use AI, since predictive algorithms may be useful in detection
of discrimination (e.g., Kleinberg et al. 2018). Reducing discrimination
may also involve encouraging some forms of AI adoption. For example,
algorithmic decision-making has been observed to reduce disparities in
some lending contexts (Bartlett et al. 2022).

From the Technological Frontier to Reality
There are a number of different ways to measure the economic impact of a
technology. How widely is it deployed? How does the production process
change for existing products and services? What new products and services
are created, and what old products and services decline or disappear? Of
particular interest to economists and policymakers is the idea of productivity, the notion that we can do more with the same resources. Recent evidence
suggests that large productivity increases driven by AI are possible in some
specific contexts (e.g., Brynjolfsson, Li, and Raymond 2023).13 And though
such forecasts are notoriously challenging, economic analysts have already
begun to update their forecasts to account for the potential of more rapid
growth brought about by AI (e.g., Goldman Sachs 2023; Chui et al. 2023). A
more fulsome answer to all these questions requires understanding not only
AI’s theoretical capabilities but also how AI systems might be used.

Adoption Is Difficult and Invariably Lags the Technological Frontier
Before a new technology can have real-world effects, it needs to be adopted
by individuals and businesses. This process is costly and difficult, and thus
the scale of adoption largely depends on weighing these costs against the
potential benefits. AI has been an active area of computational research
since the 1950s (Newell 1983), and many types of AI have been widely
deployed (e.g., Maslej et al. 2023). At the same time, in many industries AI
Precise measurement of productivity within firm environments can be challenging, but studies in
controlled settings also suggest the potential for sizable productivity improvements in other contexts
(e.g., Peng et al. 2023; Noy and Zhang 2023).
13

252 |

Chapter 7

adoption has been low and has skewed heavily toward large and young firms
(Acemoglu et al. 2022). In addition, some impressive advances in AI have
been very recent, and it takes time for firms to observe progress and adapt.
Furthermore, technologies are rarely adopted at an even rate. Instead,
early adoption is slow, as users and firms work through the challenges. It
then proceeds more quickly as these challenges are overcome and economies of scale drive down costs (Hall and Khan 2003). Adoption can lag
invention by decades, and differences in the surrounding circumstances can
substantially change adoption timelines. For example, more than 90 percent
of American households had microwaves within 30 years of their invention
(Roser, Ritchie, and Mathieu 2023). In contrast, it was more than 100 years
before flush toilets reached the same 90 percent threshold. Because the
devices depended on running water, adoption was delayed until people had
indoor plumbing.
Early adoptions of a technology often happen where it is least complicated to deploy. One of the earliest commercial AI success stories was in
identifying credit card fraud. In this case, data were widely available, the
key task clearly depended on prediction, the action to be taken was straightforward, and the costs and benefits of prediction quality could be readily
quantified (Ryman-Tubb, Krause, and Garn 2018; Agrawal, Gans, and
Goldfarb 2022). Similarly, in recent years, AI systems aimed at improving
customer service have developed rapidly because the data were previously
being collected, the functionality could easily be added to existing software,
and customer service involves many low-complexity tasks (Xu et al. 2020;
Brynjolfsson, Li, and Raymond 2023; Chui et al. 2023). These kinds of early
projects using a technology have positive spillover effects for the technology
as a whole, both because they are proof that the technology can be effective
in a real-world setting and because they create valuable human capital—in
the form of knowledge about how to adapt business practices to use the
technology. The markets for AI are already adapting, with investment
and start-up activity both increasing in recent years (Maslej et al. 2023).
Businesses specializing in cloud computing and AI deployment have also
since emerged, lowering costs and expanding adoption.
With AI, there are a variety of additional potential impediments to
adoption—consider five. First, even when data are available to train an AI
system, there may be additional data-related constraints on adoption. Many
firms may not yet collect the necessary data for certain AI implementations,
and they may face substantial challenges in beginning to do so. In other
cases, systems do not receive feedback sufficient to judge the quality of
their own predictions after they have been made. Finally, even when the data
exist, legal restrictions like copyright may prevent their use.14 Until these
14

Copyright and other related issues are discussed in more detail later in this chapter.

An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 253

data-related constraints on adoption are resolved, firms may have difficulty
implementing AI. This likely explains some of the uneven adoption across
industries and firms, as large firms are more able to invest in data collection
and incumbent firms may not yet have completed their digital transformation (Verhoef et al. 2021).
Second, because predictions can be wrong, AI systems introduce an
additional kind of risk. Risk is often a major factor in technology adoption;
when stakes are high, risk-averse firms may be less willing to make needed
investments or use inputs with uncertain returns (Roosen and Hennessy
2003; Whalley 2011).15 Often, the distribution of potential payoffs for business decisions is not just uncertain but also ambiguous, in that firms do
not know the potential set of outcomes and their probabilities. Ambiguity
makes prediction more difficult, and research has shown the condition has
a range of effects on firms’ willingness to develop or adopt new technologies (Knight 1921; Beauchêne 2019). Risk and ambiguity related to liability
assignment is a prominent example discussed later in the chapter.
Third, many potential AI applications exhibit network effects, in which
the use of the technology by one party increases its value to others. One way
in which these network effects can arise is by increasing the amount of feedback data from users, which in turn increases the quality of predictions for
everyone (Gregory et al. 2021). Adoption can also lead to network effects by
reducing coordination costs, such as vehicular communications systems that
simplify the set of predictions that autonomous cars would need to make if
they were widely adopted (Arena and Pau 2019).
Fourth, integrating AI systems with humans has unique challenges
related to incentives, job design, and communication. For example, some
processes may work best when AI systems handle routine decision-making,
like highway driving, and humans handle unusual situations, like construction zones. But without guardrails, the human may be tempted to leave too
much to the AI system or may accidentally fail to intervene (e.g., fall asleep
at the wheel) (Athey, Bryan, and Gans 2020; Herrmann and Pfeiffer 2023).
Fifth and finally, permanent or indefinite limits to AI’s adoption are
possible for many reasons, including those unrelated to the technology.
Institutional quality issues, coordination problems, and financial frictions
can all delay or halt technological adoption (e.g., Parente and Prescott 1994;
Foster and Rosenzweig 2010).

Some scholars have argued that the fields of AI and machine learning have a serious problem with
reproducibility because of the complexity and nuances of the problems, which may provide a further
incentive for firms to delay adoption (Kapoor and Narayanan 2023).
15

254 |

Chapter 7

AI Has the Potential to Be Even More Transformative in the Future
In the past, many innovations’ biggest effects came from enabling people to
structure entire productive processes differently and from spurring complementary inventions, not from performing individual tasks at a lower cost
(David 1990; Brynjolfsson, Hui, and Liu 2019; Agrawal, Gans, and Goldfarb
2022). Consider the migration of factories from steam power to electricity.
Steam power required vertical factories oriented around shafts used to power
machines. Even when electricity became less expensive than steam power,
adoption remained slow and unsteady because replacing the machines was
capital intensive for only a modest ongoing benefit. In the long run, the
largest gains from electricity were not from direct cost savings, but rather
arose because firms were no longer required to locate their factories next
to steam plants or design them vertically (Du Boff 1967). Realizing these
gains, however, required building entirely new factories and power plants,
and developing complementary technologies, all of which required even
more capital and time. Similarly, the widespread adoption of automobiles
and subsequent construction of the interstate highway system did not just
increase the number of car trips consumers took; it changed where people
lived (Biggs 1983; Eschner 2017).
AI is a general-purpose technology (GPT), like electricity and computers (Brynjolfsson, Rock, and Syverson 2021). Key hallmarks of these
technologies are that they improve over time and lead to complementary
inventions (Bresnahan and Trajtenberg 1995). Because of these similarities,
the effects of AI are also likely to be larger and more wide-reaching than the
initial use cases would suggest. While some services have been redesigned
on the basis of AI, and some new technologies have been built with AI from
the ground up, many systems and processes that could be redesigned to take
advantage of AI have not yet been updated (McElheran et al. 2023). Firms
that invest in AI are showing signs of increased product innovation, but they
do not yet show evidence of process innovations that might arise from a
more thorough restructuring of their operations (Babina et al. 2024).
In addition, AI technology continues to evolve in transformative
ways. For example, many recent developments in AI have come not from
increasingly specialized models but rather from foundation models, which
are trained on very large volumes of data and are adaptable to many different tasks (Bommasani et al. 2021). This stands in seeming contrast to
one of the earliest and best-known ideas in economics: that gains from
specialization are a fundamental force behind economic growth (Smith

An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 255

1776; Ricardo 1817).16 However, a further investigation suggests that the
rise of broad foundation models is consistent with the same forces that yield
specialization in other contexts. Gains from specialization are bounded not
only by the size of markets but also by training costs, transaction costs, the
need for workers to synchronize, and other frictional forces in the economy
(Becker and Murphy 1994; Bolton and Dewatripont 1994; Costinot 2009).
The degree of specialization ultimately depends on how these costs compare
with the potential benefits: if costs are high, then relatively little specialization is likely to occur. In the case of AI-induced automation, coordination
costs between computer systems are often low compared with coordination
costs between humans, especially as the scale increases. However, training
costs for foundational AI models are currently high, which likely limits
overall specialization. One way to reduce such costs is to train models on
targeted subsets of data (e.g., Kaddour et al. 2023), but many such applications may not yet make economic sense. Another approach is to fine-tune
models in specialized ways after their initial training (Min et al. 2023).
This approach is widely used, but research is ongoing as to how effective this method is compared with or in concert with specialization at the
training stage (e.g., Kumar et al. 2022). In addition, as discussed earlier in
the chapter, some systems continue fine-tuning after deployment, though
updating models over time may cause them to behave in unpredictable ways
(e.g., Chen et al. 2022; Chen, Zaharia, and Zou 2023). Finally, specialization may be integrated in more limited ways—for example, through multitiered production processes with generalized and specialized components
(Garicano 2000; Ling et al. 2023). The outcomes from ongoing AI research
in these areas may have large implications for future AI adoption, market
structure, and competition; later in this chapter, there is further discussion
of AI market structure and competition. Alternatively, decreases in computational costs or other methodological improvements may make specialized
generative models more economically viable over time (e.g., Leffer 2023).
Finally, AI may also drive changes outside the markets where it is
directly employed. In some areas, AI may allow automation of a wide
variety of tasks that might not have historically been regarded as predictioncentered. For example, farmers can make conditions more hospitable for
bees to increase plant pollination, and researchers are attempting to create
AI-powered robotic pollinators for this purpose (Cherney 2021). Conversely,
just as automobiles undermined the buggy whip industry (Levitt 2004) and
smartphones have decreased demand for printed maps, technology can make
Subsequent research has identified specific economic mechanisms that encourage specialization,
such as differences in inputs or skill endowments, gains from human capital deepening, and
consumer tastes for variety (Krugman 1981; Ohlin and Heckscher 1991; Becker and Murphy 1992).
Similarly, AI researchers have identified cross-country patterns of comparative advantage as one
reason AI might be specialized (Mishra et al. 2023).
16

256 |

Chapter 7

products obsolete. In this case, AI may partially or entirely eliminate the
need for products that exist primarily due to insufficient prediction capabilities. For example, many stores and warehouses carry substantial inventories
because they are unable to predict what customers will demand. If improved
prediction capabilities can substantially reduce the need for such storage,
there may be substantial reductions in the necessary land and infrastructure.
In short, AI may increase consumption of some products and decrease
consumption of others. This same dynamic, complementing in some places
while substituting in others, is also important in the labor market, and is
further explored later in the chapter.

When Will We Know the Future Has Arrived?
The scale and scope of AI’s effects on the economy will be influenced by the
development and adoption issues discussed earlier in the chapter. But even
after invention and adoption, there can be substantial delays before a technology’s effects are captured in macroeconomic statistics like productivity.
Thus, there is still considerable uncertainty—not only about when the future
effects of AI will be felt but also when economic statistics will reflect them.
In 1987, the Nobel Prize–winning economist Robert Solow said that
computers were everywhere except in the productivity statistics. As figure
7-3 shows, faster productivity growth actually did appear in the data, just
not until roughly two decades later, during a period of widespread Internet
adoption. Thus, it is uncertain whether the productivity increase was simply
delayed or whether the invention of a complementary technology was a
Figure 7-3. Nonfarm Labor Productivity Growth, 1975–2010 (5-year
moving average)
Percent
4.5
4.0

First mass
market PC

World Wide
Web invented

Widespread internet adoption

3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
1975 1978 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 2002 2005 2008 2011 2014 2017 2020

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics; CEA calculations.
Note: Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of President

An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 257

necessary prerequisite. Productivity also eventually returned to its earlier
trend, which suggests that it was more of a level shift than a structural
growth shift. Consistent with past experience, current productivity statistics
do not suggest an immediate uplift in productivity resulting from AI.
Some have argued that instead of a delayed effect, this pattern is the
result of a measurement issue common to general-purpose technologies
(Brynjolfsson, Rock, and Syverson 2021). These technologies initially
require large investments, particularly in intangible and thus unmeasurable
assets like new business practices and employee knowledge. Investments
in a new technology may also crowd out other productive work or other
potential productivity-increasing investments. As a result, there may be a
considerable period when expenditures are measured but benefits are not.
Ultimately, the evidence is inconclusive. It may be a while before the
full effects of AI are felt, and even longer before we can confidently observe
it in economic statistics. Moreover, a productivity boom is not guaranteed.
The current excitement over generative AI may fade if developers and users
discover that its drawbacks are insurmountable, if few new data are available
to power improvements, or if it turns out to be difficult to monetize the technology. Furthermore, how deeply AI becomes integrated into the economy
depends not only on technological progress but also on institutional and
regulatory issues. These topics are discussed more fully later in this chapter.
(See box 7-2.)

Box 7-2. Government Applications of AI
One way that AI can increase productivity and improve individuals’
well-being is by using it to improve the Federal Government. Numerous
administrative and regulatory processes could benefit from the adoption
of AI. The recent Executive Order directs agencies throughout the government to identify and implement beneficial uses (White House 2023a).
The order also encourages agencies to take steps to attract and retain the
AI talent necessary for adoption to take place.
Prediction, evaluation, and routine content generation are core
components of many government processes. Often, these tasks are
performed via labor-intensive methods, and AI could make these
operations more efficient by automating their most routine components.
Applications for government benefits are one such example. Most applications for benefits do not involve fraud, and many can be processed
with little human labor. However, application reviews must be thorough
enough to detect and disincentivize fraudulent activity, and so considerable human labor is used. Thoughtful application of AI could improve

258 |

Chapter 7

fraud detection in two ways, by detecting fraud directly, and by filtering
and processing clearly non-fraudulent applications so that employees can
more effectively target their fraud-detection efforts.
Government AI adoption will look different than private sector
adoption because of the unique challenges the government faces. For
example, private firms are often not required to protect privacy and
confidentiality to the same extent as the Federal government (e.g., GAO
2018). Performance standards that would be acceptable in a commercial
environment may be insufficient for sophisticated or sensitive government applications. In addition, many government activities simply
have no private sector analog. Commercial solutions and private sector
innovation will undoubtedly play a role in government AI adoption,
but the government may only realize the full benefits of AI by tailoring
applications to suit its unique needs.
Another reason to encourage government AI adoption is that
positive externalities are likely to result. Government innovations have a
long history of being repurposed to benefit other sectors of the economy.
Many current AI applications are only possible because of technologies
like GPS that arose from government research and development. Private
sector AI innovation has been rapid in recent years, but numerous
limitations remain. The government is well positioned to be a leader in
developing solutions to outstanding problems precisely because it faces
so many unique situations.
Institutions such as the Defense Advanced Research Projects
Agency (DARPA) have long embodied a model of mission-focused
innovation to considerable success (e.g., Bonvillian 2018). Similar
research agencies are found throughout the government and are already
engaged in targeted AI research. However, potential AI applications
are dispersed throughout many organizations, and spillovers between
agencies tackling similar problems are likely. New interagency councils
along with existing cross-government programs such as the U.S. Digital
Service are an initial step to ensuring that knowledge sharing within the
government remains a priority.
Government adoption of AI is not without risk. For example, automating too many processes too quickly could result in a lack of accountability and access to key services, in addition to public sector job losses.
But with these risks comes the opportunity for the government to lead
by example. Adoption that is done thoughtfully, with input from current
workers and other stakeholders, will lead to better outcomes and allow
the government to develop the key institutional knowledge necessary to
create good policy (Kochan et al. 2023).

An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 259

AI and the Labor Market
What does AI’s ability to undertake tasks previously performed by humans
mean for labor and the labor market? On net, will AI complement workers,
yielding increased jobs, productivity, and prosperity? Or will prediction
models substitute for human labor, yielding a world where fewer people are
needed to work, but also where fewer people can contribute to the economy
while also earning a living?
Although AI is a comparatively new technology, the notion of “technological unemployment” is hundreds of years old. Numerous 18th- and
19th-century economists hypothesized that technology would displace
workers by substituting for their labor (Mokyr, Vickers, and Ziebarth 2015).
During the Great Depression, John Maynard Keynes predicted that within a
century, individuals would work no more than 15 hours a week, and that the
innate desire to work would lead to many workers performing small tasks so
they could remain at least nominally employed (Keynes 1930).17
Figure 7-4 shows that so far, these predictions have not proven true.
Prime-age labor participation remains near long-term highs, matched only by
a brief period in the late 1990s. The average prime-age worker has worked
close to 40 hours a week for decades. Some have noted that increased life
spans have reduced overall time spent working over the life cycle, and
that working conditions have improved considerably (e.g., Zilibotti 2007).
Nonetheless, while Keynes accurately predicted massive average income
increases, he failed to recognize how ever-increasing demand for consumer
goods and other forces would keep people from working fewer hours.18
This historical evidence suggests that caution is warranted in making predictions about technology’s impact on the future of the labor
force. Moreover, mistaken predictions in this area have not been random:
They have overwhelmingly incorrectly predicted substitution instead of
complementarity (Autor 2015). To be fair, the adaptations of workers and
firms to technological change and increased wealth are difficult to foresee.
CEOs and Nobel laureates have recently made nearly identical predictions about AI shortening the
work week (Taub and Levitt 2023; Rees 2023).
18
Economists have highlighted many features of the economy that may discourage workers from
reducing their hours despite higher average incomes over time. Relative product quality or status
comparisons may lead consumer demand to track higher purchasing power (e.g., Frank 2008).
Increased wage inequality may be associated with an increase in the return to additional hours of
work (e.g., Freeman 2008). Performance-related compensation systems and increased competitive
pressures may make hours reductions more costly (Freeman 2008). Increasing income volatility
may lead individuals to increase their labor supply as insurance against future economic shocks
(Heathcote, Storesletten, and Violante 2010). Changes to work attributes may have made time spent
at work more pleasant, and individuals may value the social or intellectual components of work (e.g.,
Cowen 2017). Nonetheless, recent empirical evidence from inheritances and lottery winners in the
United States suggests that the work-reducing impact of greater wealth is substantial, and is stronger
among individuals with higher incomes (Brown, Coile, and Weisbenner 2010; Golosov et al. 2021).
17

260 |

Chapter 7

Figure 7-4. Employment-Population Ratio and Weekly Work Hours, 1976–2022

Hours worked per week

Percentage of working-age population employed
83

41.4

81
40.9

79
77

40.4

75
73

39.9

71
69
1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000 2003 2006 2009 2012 2015 2018 2021
Employment-population ratio (%)

Council of Economic Advisers

Hours (ASEC)

39.4

Hours (Monthly CPS)

Sources: Current Population Survey; Bureau of Labor Statistics; CEA calculations.
Note: CPS = Current Population Survey; ASEC = CPS Annual Social and Economic Supplements. Working-age population refers to the
population between the age of 25 and 54 years. The employment-population ratio is a 12-month moving average. ASEC hours are a
measure of hours worked in the last week. Monthly CPS hours are a measure of hours worked in the last week from the basic monthly
CPS. Gray bars indicate recessions.
2024 Economic Report of President

Still, technological change has greatly affected workers over time through
their occupations, the tasks they perform, and the payment they receive.
Economic frameworks characterize the forces behind these prior effects, and
in doing so they also provide suggestive evidence of the impact that AI may
have in the future.
In the next subsection, the CEA considers several leading frameworks
used by economists to study the impact of technological change in recent
decades. Although data limitations make it difficult to attribute this impact
to individual technologies, predictions from these frameworks align with
the observed patterns of economic change stemming from the widespread
adoption of general-purpose technologies like computers and the Internet.19
A common theme among these frameworks is that technologies make an
impact on different groups of workers differently, in large part because they
perform different tasks. The ability of AI to perform additional tasks may
mean that its effects will differ from the effects of automation in the past.
Technologies tend to be adopted in the circumstances where they are especially valuable, and
multiple technologies tend to be in use simultaneously; these features make isolating a single
technology’s effects difficult or impossible in most circumstances without further assumptions. In
one well-known example, researchers found that they could not empirically distinguish the purported
large effects of the computer from the effects of the pencil (DiNardo and Pischke 1997). In limited
cases, researchers can exploit exogenous variation in adoption brought about by other policies to
help isolate the impact of a specific technology. For example, this approach has been used to suggest
that broadband Internet adoption complements workers performing abstract tasks, and substitutes for
workers performing routine tasks (Akerman, Gaarder, and Mogstad 2015).
19

An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 261

In response to this concern, the CEA uses information about the current task content of occupations to provide suggestive evidence about the
occupations and workers that may be affected by AI in the future. As noted
throughout, the analysis presented has similarities to other analyses found
in the recent literature. The CEA’s measure of occupational AI exposure
is closely related to and extends the recent analysis by the Pew Research
Center (Kochhar 2023), and many of its conclusions are similar. However,
all predictions of the future are inherently speculative, because they are
based on the models and data that exist today. The assumptions that go into
this analysis may later prove to be erroneous. And many open questions
cannot yet be answered, or cannot be answered with the available data. The
particular concern of data limitations is discussed later in the chapter.

Modeling the Effect of Technological Change on Labor Markets
Though technological changes are often complex, a simple framework can
often explain their effects on employment and earnings. The model of skillbiased technological change (SBTC) is one influential example. This model
is based on the notion that technology increases the relative demand for
highly educated workers over time (generally proxied by a college education). The SBTC model conceives of “skill” very narrowly, and it abstracts
away from other features of labor markets such as unemployment. The
benefit of these simplifications is that they allow the model to succinctly
describe the relationship between technological change and wage patterns:
When the relative demand for highly educated labor grows more quickly
than the relative supply of labor from highly educated workers, the relative
wages of these workers rise compared with those of workers without college
degrees. This model suggests that the growing college wage premium over
the past several decades is a result of demand for educated workers increasing faster than their supply. Skill-biased technological change is sometimes
characterized as a race between education and technology; the more technological change outpaces the supply of educated workers, the more workers’
wages rise (Goldin and Katz 2007).
Figure 7-5 demonstrates this point; inflation-adjusted weekly earnings
for working-age men and women with graduate degrees have risen more
than 60 percent since 1964, while earnings for workers with less education have increased more slowly. In fact, 75 percent of the rise in earnings
inequality from 1980 to 2000, measured as the log of hourly wage variance, can be explained by the increase in the college wage premium alone
(Autor, Goldin, and Katz 2020). Figure 7-5 also shows that a model of
ever-increasing demand for highly educated labor is incomplete; the flatness
of the college premium over the last two decades, especially for men, and
the comparatively rapid wage growth among those who did not receive a

262 |

Chapter 7

Figure 7-5. Cumulative Changes in Real Weekly Earnings by Education for Men and Women

A. Men

B. Women

0.8

0.8

0.7

0.7

0.6

0.6

0.5

0.5

0.4

0.4

0.3

0.3

0.2

0.2

0.1

0.1

Cumulative change in real weekly earnings since 1964

Cumulative change in real weekly earnings since 1964

0.0

0.0

-0.1

-0.1

-0.2
1964 1969 1974 1979 1984 1989 1994 1999 2004 2009 2014 2019

-0.2
1964 1969 1974 1979 1984 1989 1994 1999 2004 2009 2014 2019

Less than high school
Some college
Bachelor's degree +

Council of Economic Advisers

High school graduate
Bachelor's degree

Less than high school
Some college
Bachelor's degree +

High school graduate
Bachelor's degree

Sources: Current Population Survey; CEA calculations.
Note: Data are cleaned and analyzed following Autor (2019). Full-time, full-year workers between the age of 18 and 64 are used and education categories
are harmonized using the procedures described by Autor, Katz, and Kearney (2008). All earnings are deflated by the chain-weighted (implicit) price deflator
for personal consumption expenditures.
2024 Economic Report of President

high school degree over the past decade, do not align with a purely demanddriven SBTC explanation.
The SBTC framework is hampered by two limitations: (1) it conceives
of “skill” as a one-dimensional attribute, typically proxied by education,
and (2) it does not explain why technological change increases the relative
demand for educated workers. As an example of the first limitation, the
SBTC framework would classify workers in occupations like stenographers,
typists, and paralegals similarly, based on their average level of educational
attainment. However, following personal computer adoption, paralegals
saw both earnings and employment rise (i.e., demand for the job increased),
while typists and stenographers saw their employment dwindle. In contrast,
many occupations that require manual labor (e.g., roofers) perform their
work much as they have for decades, with relatively stable employment and
modest real earnings growth in recent years. These distinctions are especially salient when considering AI’s predictive and generative capabilities;
jobs that rely on predictions or routine generation are more readily affected
by AI than others that do not involve these tasks.
To overcome the limitations of the SBTC model, researchers have
suggested an alternative framework that uses a richer notion of workers’
characteristics, categorizing workers by the task composition of their occupations (Autor, Levy, and Murnane 2003). Such models typically divide
tasks along two characteristic dimensions: whether they are routine or
nonroutine and whether they are manual or analytic. Technological change
has led to the automation of many routine tasks. Workers who performed
these tasks have seen their employment and earnings opportunities decline.
An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 263

Workers performing nonroutine manual tasks have been less affected by
recent technological changes, while those performing nonroutine analytic
tasks have been made more productive, as technology complements their
work. Because the workers performing nonroutine tasks are often at the
extremes of the earnings distribution, while workers performing routine
tasks are often in the middle, the model suggests that technology can cause
labor market polarization.
Research finds evidence of U-shaped job polarization in employment and earnings, particularly for the 1980–2005 period (Autor and Dorn
2013).20 Evidence also suggests that polarization happens inconsistently
over short periods, with employment and earnings growth often concentrated on one side or another of the occupational wage distribution (e.g.,
Mishel, Shierholz, and Schmitt 2013). Figure 7-6 shows that during the
period of peak productivity growth in the early 2000s, most employment
growth was near the bottom of the occupational wage distribution, even
as real earnings declined among that same group. In contrast, more recent
data from 2015 to 2019 show quite different growth patterns.21 Nearly all
growth in employment shares occurred in the top quintile of occupations,
and real earnings growth was broad based, though slightly stronger among
low-earning occupations than others.
Figure 7-6. Smoothed Changes in Employment and Earnings Across Occupational Wage Distribution
A. Smoothed Changes in Employment by Occupational
Wage Percentile

100x change in employment share
0.15

B. Smoothed Changes in Real Log Wages by
Occupational Wage Percentile

100x change in real hourly log wage
15

0.10

10

0.05

5

0.00

0

-0.05

1

10

19

28

37

46

55

64

73

Occupational wage percentile
2000–05

Council of Economic Advisers

2015–19

82

91

100

-5

1

10

19

28

37

46

55

64

73

Occupational wage percentile
2000–05

82

91

100

2015–19

Sources: American Community Survey; CEA calculations.
Note: Following Autor and Dorn (2013), occupations are ranked by initial mean wage and are grouped into percentiles weighted by aggregate hours.
Analysis uses full-time, full-year workers between the age of 18 and 64.
2024 Economic Report of the President

While this pattern is often attributed to computerization, other research has suggested that
the pattern may have begun even earlier, and that it could be linked to a broader shift from
manufacturing to services employment (Bárány and Siegel 2018).
21
The CEA ends its analysis of employment and earnings changes across the occupational
distribution in 2019 because of the lingering effects of the COVID-19 pandemic in more recent data.
20

264 |

Chapter 7

Both periods show employment share reductions at the middle of the
earnings distribution, aligning with a core task-based model prediction.
The patterns also suggest a nuanced interpretation of the SBTC model. The
rapid adoption of computers and information technology in the early 2000s
appears to have increased demand for workers in high-wage occupations
more rapidly than their available supply could adjust. The pattern of strong
demand for high-wage workers has continued; but in recent years, the supply
of workers to these occupations has also grown more rapidly. The proportion of the population age 25 years and above who have completed at least
four years of college increased by 12 percentage points from 2000 to 2022,
from 26 to 38 percent (Census 2023). Even as job polarization has pushed
workers into occupations at the earnings distribution extremes over some
periods, relative supply’s ability to catch up with relative demand in recent
years has enabled increasingly stable earnings growth across the earnings
distribution. The patterns also suggest that if AI continues or intensifies the
trend of strong demand growth for high-wage workers, then continued rapid
supply growth will be necessary to sustain broad-based earnings gains.22
Modification and additions to this task-based framework have recognized that occupations and tasks are not static. In 2018, more than 60 percent
of employment was in jobs that did not exist in 1940 (Autor et al. 2022).
New work tends to be concentrated in cities and in occupations with higher
average levels of education (Lin 2011; Autor et al. 2022). As new technologies emerge, workers begin performing entirely new tasks, gaining a
comparative advantage by complementing the technology. Some tasks cease
to be performed by humans, but the new tasks can keep people employed
even in the face of rapid technological change. Instead of a race between
education and technology, the “new task formation” framework characterizes the labor market as a race between human and machine (Acemoglu and
Restrepo 2018).
The new task formation framework is especially promising for
understanding AI and other recent technological shifts. For example, the
framework is robust enough to explain why few people now work as telephone operators, while data scientist and wind turbine service technician
are among the occupations projected to grow fastest in coming years (Price
2019; BLS 2023). It also explains why the share of total income going to
workers has declined in some recent periods of technological change but has

Conversely, AI could make training workers easier in ways that moderate this pattern. For
example, Brynjolfsson, Li, and Raymond (2023) find that the largest productivity gains in their
context came from improvements among novice or less skilled workers. It may be that in this
context, current AI systems are most useful for training such workers. Furthermore, it may be that an
AI system trained on data from existing workers is simply unable to do better than the best of those
existing workers.
22

An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 265

risen at others: Technology automates and creates new tasks simultaneously
(Acemoglu and Restrepo 2019).

Occupation-Specific Effects of AI
The technological change literature discussed above generally concludes
that technology affects workers through a mix of complementarity and
substitution. Some workers typically benefit from technological change,
either because the evolving technology provides new labor market opportunities for them or because it enhances their productivity in their current job.
Conversely, some are harmed, typically due to job displacement. Predicting
the impact on a given occupation requires identifying whether it is exposed
to AI via its particular mix of activities, and also whether, on net, AI complements or substitutes for human performance of those activities.
Researchers have made several attempts to identify and explore the
occupations AI is most likely to affect. Surveying individuals about what
they expect is one approach. A second approach is to classify occupations
by task or activity content (e.g., Frey and Osborne 2017; Felten, Raj, and
Seamans 2021; Brynjolfsson, Mitchell, and Rock 2018; Kochhar 2023;
Ellingrud et al. 2023). Other researchers have compared the results of this
approach to an AI system’s predictions of what its own impact will be
(Eloundou et al. 2023). Each approach is limited in its ability to measure
and predict AI’s impact on future economic activity. For example, the occupational content measures used by these papers are generally retrospective
and are not necessarily based on actual exposure to deployed AI. No single
measure should be considered definitive.
The CEA begins its analysis by considering the specific activities
performed in each occupation, and the importance of these activities for
the occupation. The Department of Labor’s Employment and Training
Administration collects this information as part of its O*NET (n.d.)
database. The CEA follows the Pew Research Center (Kochhar 2023) in
identifying 16 work activities with high exposure to AI. CEA researchers
then construct a measure of these activities’ relative importance compared
to all other work activities.23 The measure is then used to identify a subset
of occupations in which AI-exposed activities are particularly central to the
performance of the work. Workers in such occupations are plausibly the

Although the CEA identifies the same AI-exposed work activities as Pew, the relative importance
measure used by the CEA differs slightly. In particular, it relies on normalizing the importance
scales for each activity across occupations, then measuring relative importance as the difference
between the average normalized importance of AI-exposed activities and all other activities.
Following Pew, the top 25 percent of occupations according to the measure are identified as
AI-exposed. Among these occupations, AI-exposed work activities are at least 0.25 standard
deviation more important to the performance of the occupation than the average for other activities.
23

266 |

Chapter 7

ones most likely to be affected by AI, whether positively through complementarity, or negatively through substitution or displacement.24
To explore the potential for complementarity versus substitution,
the CEA also considers a key feature of automation: Labor-substitution is
easiest and cheapest in situations where complexity and difficulty are low.
Working with AI in a complementary fashion may be more effective in
complicated and challenging jobs.25 The CEA captures the distinction by
using responses to a separate O*NET question about the degree of difficulty
or complexity at which each work activity must be performed for each job.
Survey respondents are asked to indicate the level of activity performance
requirements for their job, and are provided reference anchors that characterize the difficulty and complexity associated with different levels.26 CEA
researchers then divide the set of AI-exposed occupations into two groups
based on whether their performance requirements for AI-exposed activities
are above or below the average across all occupations. Although this measure is coarse, it reflects the underlying relationship between the difficulty
of an activity and its ability to be fully automated.
These measures of occupation-level exposure and potential for substitution allow the CEA to study AI’s potential effects across the earnings
distribution, demographic groups, industries, and geographic regions. The
CEA’s analysis examines the occupations most likely to be exposed to AI
in comparison with all other occupations. However, there are important differences within high and low exposure and activity performance categories
from which this analysis abstracts, and the results are contingent on the
exposure threshold chosen.27 As such, while this approach provides some
important insights about who is more or less likely to be affected, it does not
tell us how widespread these effects will be on the labor market as a whole.
In addition to affecting levels of employment and earnings, AI could affect job quality in
numerous ways. The potential for occupations to experience these changes is also likely correlated
with the exposure measure presented here.
25
Task or activity complexity has been shown to complicate decision-making and increase its
information demands, which may determine automation possibilities (e.g., Byström and Järvelin
1995; Sintchenko and Coiera 2003). Recent research has also suggested that task complexity plays
a role in whether AI is adopted for activities such as customer service and medical decision-making
(Fan et al. 2020; Xu et al. 2020). Other recent research on AI exposure has suggested that potential
complementarity can be measured using other O*NET information on work contexts and job zones
(Pizzinelli et al. 2023).
26
The O*NET questionnaire asks respondents to report the activity performance level needed to
perform their job on a 7-point scale, with benchmarks at the low end, midpoint, and high end. For
example, in the AI-exposed activity “Evaluating Information to Determine Compliance,” “Review
forms for completeness” scores a 1, “Evaluate a complicated insurance claim for compliance with
policy terms” receives a 4, and “Make a ruling in court on a complicated motion” scores a 6. See
Peterson et al. (1995) for further details on the survey design.
27
The percentage of employees who are exposed to AI directly depends on the threshold chosen.
However, the CEA’s analysis suggests that the economic and demographic distribution of effects is
relatively insensitive to that choice.
24

An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 267

With this caveat in mind, figure 7-7 groups occupations into deciles
based on the average earnings of workers, and then reports the percentage
of workers within each decile who are employed in AI-exposed occupations.
Similar to the task-based model’s predictions, employment exposure is not
monotonic. The most significant AI exposure levels correspond to occupations in the lower-middle portion of the earnings distribution, in the third
and fourth deciles. However, more than a quarter of workers in the top two
deciles are employed in AI-exposed occupations as well.
The addition of information about the required level of activity performance adds additional context regarding possible complementarity or
substitution. Although AI-exposed activities are relatively central to each
examined job, individuals in high-earning occupations are more likely to
be required to perform AI-exposed activities at a higher level of complexity
or difficulty than those in low-earning jobs. Because implementing AI as a
human substitute is more costly and/or challenging for complex and difficult
tasks, the analysis implies that AI may more quickly be able to substitute for
employment in the lower-middle portion of the earnings distribution. To the
extent that workers in some occupations can work in conjunction with AI to
raise their productivity, the analysis provides suggestive evidence that such
occupations may already have higher-than-average wages.
In figure 7-8, CEA researchers examine AI exposure across demographic groups. Previous research has suggested that AI exposure increases
with education, that it is least concentrated among young workers, and that
Figure 7-7. Employment in High-AI-Exposed Occupations by Earnings Decile
Percentage of employment within decile

50
40
30
20
10

0

1

2

3

4

5

High performance requirements

Council of Economic Advisers

6

7

Occupational earnings decile

8

9

10

Low performance requirements

Sources: American Community Survey; Department of Labor; Pew Research Center; CEA calculations.
Note: Deciles are calculated using mean occupational earnings of workers who are full-time, full-year workers age 16 plus.
Performance requirements are captured using the O*NET data measuring degree of difficulty or complexity at which a
high-AI-exposed work activity is performed within an occupation. High (low) indicates an average degree of difficulty above
(below) the median.
2024 Economic Report of the President

268 |

Chapter 7

it is somewhat more prevalent among women, as well as among white and
Asian workers (Kochhar 2023). Using its own occupation-level exposure
metric, the CEA largely replicates these findings. As in figure 7-7, the CEA
considers how AI-exposed workers whose jobs have lower performance
requirements differ from AI-exposed workers as a whole. This analysis
suggests that the demographic characteristics of workers negatively affected
by AI may be somewhat different from those of individuals simply exposed
to AI. For example, many high school graduates lacking four-year degrees
have jobs that are highly AI exposed and that have relatively low performance requirements. A similar fraction of college graduates are exposed
to AI, but their performance requirements are higher on average, and so
they may be less at risk of displacement. Similarly, while women are only
slightly more exposed to AI than men, they are more likely to have high
exposure with low performance requirements, suggesting that women may
be at higher risk of displacement.
The findings shown in figures 7-7 and 7-8 suggest that AI may be
a skill-biased technology, increasing relative demand for workers with
high levels of education in high-earning occupations. They also suggest
that AI could exacerbate aggregate income inequality if it substitutes for
employment in lower-wage jobs and complements higher-wage jobs. The
possibility of increased inequality from AI has been widely discussed among
economists studying the topic (e.g., Korinek and Stiglitz 2018; Furman and
Seamans 2019; Acemoglu 2021). However, such an interpretation of the
Figure 7-8. Share of Workers in High-AI-Exposure Occupations by Demographic
Demographic

Total

20%

10%

Men

19%

9%

Women

20%

12%

White

20%

10%

Black

19%

12%

Hispanic

17%

11%

Asian

23%

7%

Native American

19%

12%

Other
Less than high school

9%

High school graduate

22%

11%
11%
14%

Some College

17%

14%

Bachelor's degree +

6%
High exposure

Council of Economic Advisers

22%
21%

High exposure with low performance requirements

Sources: American Community Survey; Department of Labor; Pew Research Center; CEA calculations.
Note: Analysis uses full-time, full-year workers age 16 plus. Performance requirements are captured using the O*NET data measuring
degree of difficulty or complexity at which a high-AI-exposed work activity is performed within an occupation. Low indicates an average
degree of difficulty below the median.
2024 Economic Report of the President

An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 269

evidence presented here should be made cautiously. As the historical analysis given earlier in the chapter demonstrates, supply-and-demand forces both
play a role in determining patterns of wages and employment. Nonetheless,
the possibility of increased inequality resulting from AI adoption may
inform policy responses.
More generally, the economic and demographic breakdowns of figures
7-7 and 7-8 suggest possible effects, but they simplify a complex reality. For
example, figure 7-8 does not imply that the 10 percent of workers who have
high AI exposure and low performance requirements will inevitably lose
their jobs. Rather, the measures shown identify the occupations and workers
who perform the tasks that are most likely to change as a result of AI. The
implications for jobs and workers may be quite nuanced.
For example, most jobs remain a collection of tasks of which only a
portion can be automated. AI may allow humans to focus on other tasks,
fundamentally changing their jobs without reducing the use of their labor.
For example, if AI eventually allows school buses to drive themselves, children may still need someone on the bus to watch them, ensure they behave,
and ensure they enter and exit safely. In other words, AI-led automation
might fundamentally change the school bus driver’s job, but it is unlikely
to eliminate the job. Similarly, airplanes still have pilots, despite autopilot
systems having automated some of their tasks for more than a century
(Chialastri 2012).
Additionally, even among workers within an occupation, the extent of
automation may be highly context dependent. Different AI models may be
deployed in different situations, tailored to unique goals in ways that allow
them to succeed at different tasks. An AI model that can replace human
performance of tasks in some contexts might require extensive human assistance in others, or it may not be economically viable to adopt (e.g., Svanberg
et al. 2024).
More broadly, there are reasons to believe that integrating humans and
AI may often prove more effective than using either alone. Having multiple
approaches to prediction and problem solving often produces better results
than any one approach on its own. Diversity of thought can improve human
decision-making (Post et al. 2015), and prediction techniques may benefit
by combining multiple different machine learning approaches (Webb and
Zheng 2004; Dong et al. 2020; Naik et al. 2023). Emerging research suggests
that this principle extends to the combination of human and AI approaches
as well (Zirar, Ali, and Islam 2023; Hitsuwari et al. 2023).
Finally, these measures of AI exposure are based on the tasks that
future AI systems are believed to be well suited to perform. As AI technology develops, it may change in ways that lead it to automate a different set
of tasks than existing measures foresee.

270 |

Chapter 7

A more precise understanding of how AI affects specific occupations,
industries, demographic groups, and geographic regions will be critical for
constructing appropriate policy responses. Researchers continue to develop
and refine their frameworks to predict the potential effects of AI. As evidence of AI’s effects emerges, these frameworks will evolve to incorporate
the new information. At the same time, the limitations of available data
and testable frameworks will continue to constrain researchers’ quest for
understanding.

Evidence for AI’s Effects
Economists have already begun measuring AI’s adoption, and they are
looking for signs of its impact on the labor market. Although uncertainty
remains, some patterns have emerged. First, AI adoption is driven by larger
and more productive firms. While the percentage of businesses adopting or
integrating AI directly is still small, these firms employ a sizable share of
workers (Acemoglu et al. 2022; Kochhar 2023). Note that survey measures
of technology usage are likely to provide an underestimate of AI’s ongoing
impact on firms; whether businesses adopt AI directly or not, many of the
products and services they purchase and use implement AI. For example,
online advertising platforms, navigation systems, and recommendation
systems all commonly implement AI and have been widely adopted.
Limited evidence also suggests AI’s impact on labor market decisionmaking. For example, commuting zones with greater industrial robot adoption in the 1990s and 2000s saw reduced employment and wage growth,
and these effects can be distinguished from the simultaneous impact of
import competition (Acemoglu and Restrepo 2020). Though robots are only
one form of automation, and not all robots use AI extensively, predicting a
robot’s surroundings and interactions with others is often critical to its use.
Businesses with task structures exposed to AI showed a rapid increase in
AI-related job vacancy postings through the 2010s, but they simultaneously
reduced hiring of non-AI-related positions, which could indicate the substitution of AI for human labor (Acemoglu et al. 2020). Evidence from Dutch
employers suggests that workers whose jobs are displaced by automation are
less likely to be working and more likely to retire than their peers (Bessen et
al. 2023). Collectively, these papers suggest that a mix of complementarity
to and substitution from AI is likely already happening.
Using the occupation-level exposure measure discussed earlier in this
chapter, the CEA is also able to identify what percentage of workers in each
industry are most likely to be exposed to AI, and whether these workers
have high or low performance requirements that could be associated with
complementarity or substitution. The two panels of figure 7-9 plot these
measures against recent changes in employment growth relative to the long

An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 271

Figure 7-9. Industry AI Exposure versus Payroll Employment Growth
Relative to Long-Run Trends
A. AI-Exposed Employment with High Performance Requirements

Difference in growth rate of payroll employment from 2023 to annualized rate between
2007 and 2019 (percentage points)

10
10

5

00
-5
-5
-10
-10

-5

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

55

60

Percentage of AI-exposed employment with high performance requirements

65

70

65

70

B. AI-Exposed Employment with Low Performance Requirements

Difference in growth rate of payroll employment from 2023 to annualized rate between
2007 and 2019 (percentage points)

1010

55

00

-5-5

-10
-10
-5

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

55

60

Percentage of AI-exposed employment with low performance requirements

Council of Economic Advisers

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics (Occupational Employment and Wage Statistics); Pew Research Center; CEA calculations.
Note: Occupations are matched to the most detailed industry data available in the Current Employment Statistics. Point
sizes are proportional to industry employment and linear predictions are weighted by industry employment. These outliers
are not shown: 213, support activities for mining; 313, textile mills; 3132, fabric mills; 3361, motor vehicle manufacturing;
and 3212, veneer, plywood and engineered wood product manufacturing.
2024 Economic Report of the President

run trend from 2007 to 2019. The figure demonstrates three things: (1) most
industries and most workers still have relatively low exposure; (2) employment in AI-exposed occupations is dispersed across industries, with only
a handful of small industries having most of their employment in highly
exposed occupations; and (3) relatively little evidence of heterogeneity

272 |

Chapter 7

by performance requirements has emerged. In particular, the similarity of
the relationship plotted in the two panels suggests that neither large-scale
complementarity to nor substitution from AI is taking place. Industries with
a high share of exposed employment saw slightly less rapid employment
growth in 2023 relative to long-run patterns, but thus far AI exposure has
little explanatory power.

Preparing Institutions for AI
Productivity gains make society richer by allowing it to do more with fewer
resources. The new economic activity permitted by AI can, in principle,
provide the potential for everyone to be better off than they were before.
However, a world where AI increases everyone’s living standards is not
guaranteed. Institutions and regulatory environments have important effects
on the ways that technologies are developed and deployed, and on how their
effects are felt. Just as strong but flexible institutions were necessary for the
Industrial Revolution (e.g., Mokyr 2008), and as poor institutions still limit
development in much of the world (e.g., Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson
2005), so too will details of the U.S. institutional environment dictate both
how widely AI is adopted and who benefits from it.
The Federal Government’s role goes beyond ensuring that the gains
brought about by AI are widely shared. It must also ensure that the costs
to harmed individuals are addressed. To the extent that AI may displace
some employees, evidence shows that workers are likely to experience
significant negative effects. These effects may be sizable even if the labor
market remains strong and despite the fact that most workers eventually
find new jobs (Davis and von Wachter 2011). However, AI’s potential harm
is broader than its impact on affected workers. Loss of consumer privacy,
reduced market competition, and increased inequality are all potential
consequences of AI that the government can help manage (e.g., Acemoglu
2021). The potential use of AI by malicious actors is also a concern—and
one reason the Biden-Harris Administration has begun taking specific steps
to develop best practices and secure the nation’s infrastructure (White House
2023a).
Many new technologies affect only a single market or a few products.
AI has applications touching most industries and markets, likely including
some that do not yet exist. Also, the inputs to many AI models include data
generated from vast swaths of economic activity. Outlining every way in
which the institutional environment affects AI is therefore impossible. Still,
it is worth considering the broad economic forces at issue and some of the
ways the economy’s institutions must be reexamined to ensure they can
manage an economy in which AI is a fundamental feature.

An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 273

Ownership, Liability, and Regulation
The usefulness of AI arises from its ability to make predictions, automate
tasks, or generate outputs that humans value. However, these same characteristics that make AI systems useful often raise important questions about
both intellectual property rights and liability. This has been true of AI
systems in the past, and the rapid rise of generative AI systems has expanded
the scope of issues. For example, a number of recent copyright infringement lawsuits have challenged AI companies’ argument that generative AI
systems can be trained on copyrighted materials under fair use provisions
(Appel, Neelbauer, and Schweidel 2023; CRS 2023a; Sag 2023; Setty 2023;
Oremus and Izadi 2024). Similarly, creators have contested the training of
AI systems on their creative works, and celebrities have contested the use
of AI to replicate their likenesses from their personal traits (Kadrey et al. v.
Meta Platforms 2023; Horton 2023; Kahveci 2023). Furthermore, scholars
have begun to weigh numerous AI-related challenges to the boundaries of
liability law, such as generative AI systems that could produce defamatory speech, self-driving cars that could harm pedestrians, or AI systems
that could be used to commit crimes (Brown 2023; Gless, Silverman, and
Weigend 2016; King et al. 2020). The way these issues are resolved will
alter incentives for content creators, platforms, and end users. Thus, the
decisions that regulators and the legal system make will be a critical element
in determining whether and how AI is adopted and deployed (e.g., Brodsky
2016; Sobel 2017), and may have an impact on competition as well (e.g.,
Tirole 2023; Volokh 2023). An economic framing of ownership and liability
provides key insights for regulators in adapting to the challenges presented
by AI.
In a strict legal sense, ownership of AI inputs and systems is generally not in question.28 However, the contemporary economic conception of
ownership is considerably broader. Rather than focusing on the absolute
rights of owners to possess an asset themselves, economists emphasize that
the value of ownership derives from the capabilities it provides: the ability to
select the use of an asset, to prohibit its use by others, and to form contracts
around this use (e.g., Alchian 1965; Barzel and Allen 2023).29 Regulations
and legal constraints place limits on ownership, either by limiting what owners can do or by limiting what owners can prevent others from doing. For the
Regarding AI outputs, courts have considered cases in which an individual applied for patent or
copyright protections for AI outputs, and have generally ruled that such ownership rights are not
available to outputs generated by AI without human involvement (e.g., Thaler v. Vidal 2022; Thaler
v. Perlmutter 2023).
29
Extensive legal scholarship has also considered the nature of ownership, and is characterized
by multiple competing approaches. Economic thought has played a role in outlining the benefits
and drawbacks to each approach, although many economically salient features of ownership
are not strictly dependent on the legal theory applied (e.g., Coase 1960; Honoré 1961; Bell and
Parchomovsky 2005; Merrill and Smith 2011; Smith 2012; and Medema 2020).
28

274 |

Chapter 7

same reason, ownership rights and liability assignments are only economically meaningful to the extent that they can be enforced (e.g., Calabresi and
Melamed 1972).
The incentives created by ownership rights have very broad economic
effects. For example, the incentives of ownership are fundamental to determining how and why firms form, and to how product markets and financial
markets are structured (e.g., Grossman and Hart 1986; Aghion and Bolton
1992). Similarly, the ability to profit from new technologies is critical not
only for their development but also for economic growth as a whole (e.g.,
Aghion and Howitt 1992). Even in cases where strict legal ownership is not
in question, regulatory choices that change the incentives around ownership
may have sizable effects on overall market competition, as well as on the
path of technology development itself. With AI in particular, the incentives
of ownership will shape developers’ decisions to invest in advancing AI’s
technological frontier, companies’ decisions to deploy or commercialize AI
applications, and many other consequential decisions.
A particularly economically important capability of owners is that they
can form contracts related to the assets they own. Through these contracts,
the owners of assets can assign many or most of their specific rights and
responsibilities to others to reduce economic inefficiencies. Consider, for
example, an out-of-town landlord who contracts with a local management
company to find tenants and fix things that break. In some cases, clear
assignment of property rights and contracts are sufficient for markets to
achieve economic efficiency (Coase 1960). However, transaction costs,
uncertainty, private information, and other common features of the economy
can cause contract mechanisms to break down (e.g., Medema 2020). Writing
contracts that efficiently address all situations may be too costly to be
practicable. Moreover, unexpected or unplanned situations may also arise
for which writing contracts is impossible. Because the owner remains the
residual claimant (Fama and Jensen 1983), they bear both the positive and
negative consequences that may result. In these circumstances, contracts are
said to be incomplete, and market mechanisms may fail to achieve efficient
outcomes. Owners adapt to some market failures by forming firms, or by
merging or otherwise integrating to mitigate the problem (Williamson 1971;
Grossman and Hart 1986). Integrations can be beneficial when they address
market failures, but they also have the potential to undermine competition
(e.g., Broussard 2009). In many other cases, only government regulations
are capable of alleviating market failures.
The potential for incomplete contracts and associated issues related to
AI is high, for several reasons. First, the technology is developing rapidly.
Many specific ways in which AI will be used are still uncertain, as are the
consequences of those uses. Moreover, many of the most useful AI applications must make predictions in novel environments with limited relevant
An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 275

training data. In such situations, even thoughtfully developed AI models are
prone to unanticipated behavior. The existence of this possibility can cause
potentially serious market failures (Hart 2009). Second, data inputs often
originate from user activity, so negotiating directly with each user could
lead to high transaction costs. A similar concern exists regarding AI models
that are trained on copyrighted works from many different authors (e.g.,
Samuelson 2023). Also, AI providers often have considerable private information about how their models operate, which can be used to tilt contracts
away from economic efficiency and in providers’ favor and can prevent
agreements from being reached at all (Kennan and Wilson 1993; McKelvey
and Page 1999). For these and other reasons, the markets for AI technology
are especially susceptible to failure, so laws or regulations that address those
failures are needed to strike an economically efficient balance between AI’s
benefits and costs.
A related incomplete contracts issue arises because AI-created work
may not be subject to copyright or other intellectual property protection
(e.g., Thaler v. Vidal 2022; Thaler v. Perlmutter 2023). Intellectual property
rights narrow the residual, and the lack of such rights means that restrictions
on the use of AI outputs will be largely driven by contract law. When laws
do not otherwise assign ownership of an asset, then the government becomes
the de facto residual claimant, setting rules that manage its use and bearing responsibility for the consequences. Efficient management of common
assets is often possible, although it poses unique challenges (Ostrom 1990;
Frischmann, Marciano, and Ramello 2019).
Another way in which laws and regulations create incentives is
through the assignment of liability. Often, liability is determined separately
from ownership. However, the two concepts are linked because ownership often conveys some forms of liability, because liability is commonly
transferred or constrained through contracts, and because the economic
incentives of liability assignments depend on their ability to be enforced.
A lengthy literature in law and economics considers the economic foundations of liability law (Calabresi 2008; Landes and Posner 1987; Shavell
2004). Major concepts from this literature—such as the economic benefit of
assigning liability to the “cheapest cost avoider” to disincentivize harm efficiently—have proven influential in recent legal decisions related to digital
technologies (e.g., Sharkey 2022).
When laws and regulations have an impact on ownership rights or
potential liability, they often strike a delicate balance between multiple
incentives. For example, when patent laws assign ownership rights, they
balance the incentive to create and benefit from one’s creation against the
incentive to adopt and benefit from previous creations (Scotchmer 1991).
Other intellectual property laws, like copyright and trademark laws, balance similar incentives. And libel laws balance the potential benefits of
276 |

Chapter 7

information dissemination against the costs of harmful misinformation
(Dalvi and Refalo 2008). As technology evolves, the nature of these incentive forces can change as well, so regulations may need to be updated to
establish a new balance.
Interpretations of laws have adapted substantially to accommodate the
extensive technological changes of the past. For example, interpretations of
the “fair use” doctrine in copyright law have depended on the technology
available at the time; in recent decades, this doctrine has been interpreted
to look at how transformative the new use is in order to accommodate new
technologies like Internet search (Gordon 1982; Netanel 2011; Authors
Guild v. Google 2015). Similarly, the interpretation of tort law has evolved
repeatedly to accommodate technological changes, such as the rise of
mechanized transportation and factory production (Gifford 2018). Although
such adaptations may be encouraging, the ways in which existing laws and
regulations can be adapted to AI is, in many cases, still an open question.
Even in cases where existing laws or regulations can adapt, there may
also be other economic benefits from a proactive approach. For example,
defining explicit liability rules before the situation arises can improve
economic efficiency by reducing uncertainty about how liability will be
assigned, narrowing the residual and creating incentives as it does so. One
such case may be the liability issues related to autonomous AI systems
whose actions unexpectedly harm someone (e.g., Gifford 2018; Diamantis,
Cochran, and Dam 2023). Likewise, enacting more specific regulations
about AI liability may also reduce the costliness of enforcement, which can
improve economic incentives (Mookherjee and Png 1992). Other regulations, such as regulations that encourage increased transparency in AI systems, could also ease enforcement of liability law and improve incentives
(e.g., Llorca et al. 2023).
Scholars have already identified a few specific policies as potential
targets for reform. For example, in recent years some researchers have suggested adjusting or limiting patent protection to incentivize innovation more
effectively (Boldrin and Levine 2013; Bloom, Van Reenen, and Williams
2019). Others have argued that the inability to patent AI-generated inventions will weaken innovation incentives (e.g., Dornis 2020). Recent empirical evidence has generally found that patenting does encourage start-up
success and later innovation, but not necessarily in all markets (Gaulé 2018;
Farre-Mensa, Hegde, and Ljungqvist 2019; Sampat and Williams 2019).
This suggests that the limits to patentability associated with AI could be a
substantial concern for innovation in some fields. Conversely, there is less
evidence of a problem with AI innovation itself. Although thousands of
AI-related patents are filed each year (Miric, Jia, and Huang 2022), private
companies have released the algorithms used by multiple popular largelanguage-model AI frameworks as freely distributed open source software.
An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 277

The companies’ competitive strategies are often multifaceted, but they frequently appear to rely more heavily on their access to data, their ability to
integrate AI into other products, or positive network effects from adoption
than on the exclusive rights patent protection can provide (Heaven 2023;
Boudreau, Jeppesen, and Miric 2022).
Additionally, existing regulation of Internet activity delineates between
the creators of content and the platforms and providers who serve that content to consumers. Under current law, providers are shielded from liability
in most circumstances for content they serve but do not create, while they
are also given latitude to moderate the content (e.g., CRS 2024). Online
generative AI services blur the conceptual distinctions underpinning this
law. When a generative AI summarizes an article and posts it online instead
of a human, is the AI a content creator? If so, are AI algorithm operators
themselves liable for harm like defamation that may originate in the initial
article? Holding operators liable for such uses of their technology could
greatly limit generative AI adoption, even in places where it is beneficial
(Perault 2023). Conversely, the link between AI data inputs and outputs is
often opaque; in such situations, if AI systems operators are not held liable,
then enforcement of liability against other parties may be impracticable
(Bambauer and Surdeanu 2023).
In summary, many of AI’s most profound potential effects are closely
linked to the ways in which it tests existing delineations of ownership rights
and liability. Economics has a long history of demonstrating just how important those choices about ownership rights and liability can be. As policymakers and courts consider their options for addressing AI-related issues, they
will benefit from taking these economic forces into account.

Competition and Market Structure
Competition creates incentives that increase economic welfare and, as
President Biden has stressed, lower costs. It pushes firms to lower prices,
raise wages, and create higher-quality products (the combination of lower
prices and higher wages suggests that competition can reduce economic
rents that occur amid insufficient competition). And although its relationship with innovation is complicated, competition generally encourages
innovation at the technological frontier (Aghion et al. 2005; Bloom, Van
Reenen, and Williams 2019). In markets without robust competition, firms
have the ability to increase their own profits or advance their other interests
at the expense of others by raising prices, reducing production, or strategically underinvesting in quality, customer service, or innovation. Because
lower competition is typically associated with higher profits, firms may be
incentivized to merge, to foreclose rivals, or to take other actions in order
to undermine competition. Mergers and some types of conduct that reduce

278 |

Chapter 7

competition are illegal under antitrust laws, but the government also shapes
markets and influences competition through regulation and its own conduct
as a market participant.
As last year’s Economic Report of the President discussed, the economics of competition are particularly complex in digital markets (CEA
2023). AI is widely used in many of these digital markets, including to
set prices in platform markets, to optimize content on social media, and to
optimize inventory levels. However, because of their widespread and growing adoption, AI systems are also present in many markets outside digital
platforms.
In all these cases, the addition of AI can have positive or negative
effects on competition. In many cases, it can create better products and
lower costs. In some cases, the adoption of AI systems can also increase
competition by making it easier for new firms to enter or by lowering
switching costs. For example, AI-powered machine translation can reduce
language barriers, allowing greater international competition (Brynjolfsson,
Hui, and Liu 2019). Similarly, AI can alleviate other barriers by making it
easier to convert computer code from one language to another, or enter into
software development (e.g., Roziere et al. 2020; Weisz et al. 2022; Peng et
al. 2023). Conversely, AI integrations might inappropriately reduce competition by increasing the barriers to switching providers and thus locking
in customers who use their services. Data or integration methods locked to
proprietary AI models, for example, can create such barriers.
AI can also be used as a tool for either tacit or explicit collusion that
can harm competition. AI systems may make it less costly for firms to
closely track and respond to the behavior of rivals or facilitate sharing competitively sensitive information to which competing firms otherwise would
not be privy, factors that make it easier to sustain collusion (Tirole 1988).
They may also make it simpler for firms to engage in complex multimarket interactions that also can facilitate collusion (Bernheim and Whinston
1990). Recent research suggests that these pricing algorithms may actually
learn collusion as the optimal outcome of their profit-maximizing algorithm
(Calvano et al. 2020; Johnson and Sokol 2020; Abada and Lambin 2023).
“Learning by doing” is an economically important process in many
markets (e.g., Arrow 1962; Thompson 2010), and it has particularly important implications for competition in many AI markets. On one hand, such
learning improves the product, creating positive network effects that can, in
turn, attract more users and lead to a virtuous cycle that benefits consumers (Gregory et al. 2021). On the other hand, the same network effects that
can create product improvements can also drive smaller firms out of the
market, leaving a market with only a handful of dominant players. And, in
the long run, such network effects may also dampen future innovation and
competition by raising barriers to entry. Even entrants that have better or
An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 279

more efficient underlying technology may struggle to attract users if they
lack the data to appropriately tailor their products (Werden 2001; Farrell and
Klemperer 2007). Finally, some AI systems automate feedback loops to continuously improve, in effect automating the learning-by-doing process. Such
automation likely strengthens network effects, in turn increasing potential
consequences, both positive and negative.
In addition to AI’s effects on other markets, competition between AI
providers will be important for AI’s deployment and ultimate impact. In
some markets, entry costs are relatively modest, data are widely available,
and network effects are not too strong. In such markets, competition may be
robust and involve many small providers. Similarly, some AI systems will
be developed internally by firms that do not specialize in the technology,
but who use it to support their overall business. Multitiered integrations are
also likely, such as for systems in which general-purpose models interface
with other, more specialized add-on tools.30 In other cases, however, some
combination of high entry costs, data availability, and network effects may
drive markets toward having only a small number of players. Markets for
generative AI products, which require huge amounts of data and computing
power to train, may be particularly prone to this issue, with some even suggesting that such markets may naturally trend toward monopoly (Narechania
2022). There is an inherent economic trade-off between the cost of entry and
the benefits of increased competition, but appropriate government policy
can help ensure that a monopoly outcome is not a foregone conclusion.
Competition inside a market is also affected by competition in adjacent markets. For example, even if there are many aluminum can suppliers,
competition may be weak if there is only one supplier of the aluminum itself.
In this way, supply chains are only as competitive as their least competitive
link, a so-called competitive bottleneck. Firms may also participate in multiple markets through vertical integration or exclusive contracting. In such
situations, firms may use a dominant position in one market to undermine
competition in another (Ordover, Saloner, and Salop 1990; Moresi and
Schwartz 2021). Furthermore, self-preferencing by vertically integrated
firms can result in inferior technologies being adopted even in the long run
(Katz and Shapiro 1986).
Scholars have suggested that all these concerns may be particularly
acute in digital platforms and AI markets (Athey and Scott Morton 2022;
Vipra and Korinek 2023). For example, many AI-related products have been
built by organizations with ties to existing large technology firms that themselves are increasingly vertically integrated across the AI stack. Similarly,
some inputs necessary to create AI systems are controlled by a small number
For example, several foundation model providers have released libraries that allow their services
to be easily integrated into other software, including other AI models (e.g., Anthropic 2024; OpenAI
2024).
30

280 |

Chapter 7

of companies, raising concerns about the potential for competitive bottlenecks. For example, the design, production, and equipment used to produce
the specialty chips needed to power AI computing are each controlled by a
handful of firms, as is the provision of cloud computing (Narechania and
Sitaraman 2023).
AI policy will have a large role in ensuring healthy and competitive
markets, protecting consumers of AI outputs, workers who use AI systems,
and other market participants. Competition-aware policy can avoid inadvertently increasing barriers to entry while ensuring that some providers are not
unduly favored over others. Antitrust enforcement will play a critical role,
but so too will other government policies.
Broadly, ex ante regulation or other policies can improve efficiency
relative to ex post antitrust enforcement by offering certainty to businesses
and avoiding costly ex-post remedies (Ottaviani and Wickelgren 2011).
At the same time, such ex ante policies could backfire if poorly conceived
or executed. Developing standards in an open and transparent manner can
avoid inadvertently favoring a market’s incumbents or making it difficult for
smaller firms to comply or enter.
Similarly, freely available and portable data may encourage a competitive landscape and ensure that gains from data are widely distributed. Market
participants often have an incentive to maintain proprietary data. Data can be
copied at low cost, and productive improvements from data may be easily
replicated, so firms are likely to compete away gains from publicly available sources. However, reliance on proprietary data could cause fragmented
AI markets to emerge. If each firm can access only a small portion of the
available data, AI systems may not function as well as they otherwise could.
This has been an ongoing problem in pharmaceutical research (Schneider et
al. 2020) and is increasingly an issue on the Internet, where content and user
data are often locked into proprietary tools and applications. Increased availability of public data, such as that produced by the Federal Government,
may encourage more competition. Restrictions on what data may remain
proprietary and appropriate regulations on how AI companies can use the
data collected from their users may do the same.
Additionally, policies that encourage portability and interoperability can reduce barriers to competition (Brown 2020). Market providers
generally have an incentive to reduce customer switching, and systems
that encourage locking in may be developed to gain an anticompetitive
advantage. Interoperability requirements make switching providers easier,
reducing firms’ ability to gain an advantage through lock-in. In labor markets, firm strategies—such as noncompete agreements, training repayment
agreements, and other methods—can tie workers to specific firms; however,
these tactics could also limit competition in markets for AI skills. The
sophisticated skills needed to develop and work with AI systems can only
An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 281

be put to best use throughout the economy if workers can transition freely in
competitive labor markets, and so policies that reduce labor market barriers
could improve competition in markets for AI itself.
Finally, sharing competitively sensitive information through AI
systems can undermine competition and pose risks to firms under existing
antitrust laws. Government efforts to educate firms about these risks and to
promote sound antitrust compliance policies can reduce the possibility that
AI technologies will be used to lessen competition.
In summary, the policies needed to encourage competition go
well beyond the traditional tools of merger or monopolization analysis.
Competition will be affected by the choices the Federal Government makes
to regulate AI and its markets. The correct approach requires consideration
of the sophisticated ways in which individual markets interact with the
technological landscape and learning lessons from past instances in which
new technologies were not regulated to promote competition at the outset.
The Biden-Harris Administration has released new competition guidance
encouraging the Federal Government’s agencies to consider these issues in
their analyses of regulations (OMB 2023a), and the Office of Management
and Budget (OMB 2023b) has encouraged agencies to consider competition in their use and procurement of AI tools. This holistic framing may be
particularly important as the role of AI in the economy grows. (See box 7-3.)

Labor Market Institutions
AI has real potential to transform the labor market. The empirical case for
permanent market displacement is limited, but the transition to an economy
that thoroughly incorporates AI could displace many workers from their
existing jobs, create many new types of jobs, and affect the work of others
dramatically. What labor market features will be most important to protecting workers in the transition, and what features will help ensure they are
prepared to use AI?
In part, policies that reduce AI’s disruptive effects on labor markets
are the same ones that encourage efficient and responsible AI investment.
Encouraging innovation, reducing regulatory uncertainty, and supporting
needed human capital investment are all important goals of AI policy.
Responsible stewardship of the economy as a whole is also important, as the
negative effects on workers of job displacement are considerably magnified
by weak economic conditions (Davis and von Wachter 2011).
In practice, the negative effects of technological and regulatory change
are often quite concentrated on specific industries, occupations, and geographic regions. The experience of trade liberalization has shown that negative effects of job displacement can persist for many years and spill over
to local economies (Autor, Dorn, and Hanson 2013, 2021). Many policy

282 |

Chapter 7

Box 7-3. What Can Voluntary AI
Agreements Accomplish?
The Biden-Harris Administration announced voluntary agreements covering cybersecurity, algorithmic discrimination, output watermarking, and
other issues with seven leading artificial intelligence companies in July
2023; the agreement now covers fifteen companies (White House 2023b).
The agreements were a step toward creating the first AI-specific guidelines
and guardrails at a critical time. They demonstrated not only the industry
participants’ interest and willingness to work toward the common good,
but also their belief that it is possible to make progress through open
dialogue, unilateral action, and social norms. Still, the agreements are
unlikely to be a long-term solution.
Meaningful voluntary commitments are rare in the private sector. If
taking an action is in a firm’s unilateral interest, no commitment is necessary. If the action is not in the firm’s unilateral best interest, the company
will have an incentive to avoid making such a commitment.
The features that make agreements meaningful can also provide the
incentive to change course later. For example, the existence of a voluntary
agreement can create opportunities for new entrants. These new firms
may decline to make the commitment and may use that flexibility to outcompete committed firms (Brau and Carraro 1999). Existing firms may
respond to competition by dropping out of an agreement or abandoning
its limiting principles.
The recent voluntary agreement covers major players in generative AI. These markets feature many barriers to entry (Federal Trade
Commission 2023), making them a relatively favorable environment for
voluntary agreements to form and be sustained. Other AI market segments
that lack similar barriers may be less amenable to voluntary cooperation.

options for addressing AI substitution are similar to those suggested in the
context of past economic shocks.
Recent trade shocks have predominantly affected people in areas that
became subject to new import competition. Analogously, AI’s effects are
likely to be felt most acutely in places where AI-exposed workers live. The
CEA has mapped its occupation-level measure of AI exposure to workers’
places of residence, showing where exposure is most likely to have localized
effects. As figure 7-10 indicates, in the most AI-exposed regions, the average worker’s neighborhood is more than three times as dense as it is in the
least exposed regions. However, the story is somewhat different for workers
whose jobs have low performance requirements. Both the most exposed and
least exposed areas to this type of work are relatively dense, and less dense
areas are often in the middle of the exposure distribution.
An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 283

The evidence suggests that AI’s effects are likely to be felt most
strongly in urban areas. This finding is consistent with other recent research
demonstrating that a preponderance of innovation, along with a large fraction of new work, occurs in cities (Lin 2011; Gruber, Johnson, and Moretti
2023). Conversely, to the extent that exposure with a low average level of
required activity performance captures the possibility of job substitution,
the evidence suggests that only a subset of urban areas may experience
negative effects from widespread job displacement. Prior research suggests
one likely reason for the pattern: Occupational segregation is high, and
overall economic residential segregation has increased over time (Florida
and Mellander 2015; Bischoff and Reardon 2013). While some workers in
urban areas may become more productive as a result of AI, others could be
displaced, and the two sets of workers may live in different neighborhoods,
with differing implications for policy. And although greater job access
in dense urban labor markets may make it relatively easy for workers to
weather economic disruptions, evidence also suggests that at the local level,
the effect of competing with many displaced individuals can outweigh the
effect of increased nearby opportunities (Haller and Heuermann 2020). In
short, although evidence about geographically concentrated AI exposure is
limited, there is reason to believe that targeted place-based policies could
play a useful role, much as they play a role in other contexts such as clean
energy transitions (CEA 2022).

Figure 7-10. Average Population Density by Decile of Geographic AI Exposure
Weighted average population per square mile
3,000
2,500
2,000
1,500
1,000
500
0

1

2

3
High exposure

Council of Economic Advisers

4

5

6

7

Decile of geographic AI exposure

8

9

10

High exposure with low performance requirements

Sources: American Community Survey; Department of Labor; Pew Research Center; CEA calculations.
Note: Average density is the population-weighted geometric mean density of each workers' census tract of residence. Geographic units
are public-use microdata areas. Average population per square mile is the population-weighted geometric mean density of Census tracts
in each unit. Analysis uses full-time, full-year workers age 16 plus. Performance requirements are captured using the O*NET data measuring
degree of difficulty or complexity at which a high AI-exposed work activity is performed within an occupation. Low indicates an average
degree of difficulty below the median.
2024 Economic Report of the President

284 |

Chapter 7

Individual firms will play a major role in training their employees to
work with AI, particularly in cases where firms use customized systems or
adopt foundation models in unique ways. However, government can help
ensure that the training benefits workers. Economists distinguish general
human capital, which can be put to broad productive use, and firm-specific
human capital, which is not portable. Because many AI models are purposebuilt for a particular firm’s needs, many of the skills workers need to use
the models will likely be firm-specific or learned on the job. Economic
theory has shown that firm-specific human capital gives employers labor
market power over their employees and can allow them to keep wages low
(Acemoglu and Pischke 1998). In contrast, because general human capital
is portable, it gives employers no additional market power, and firms have a
lower incentive to invest in it.
The Biden-Harris Administration has made record investments to
encourage general human capital training through registered apprenticeships—and recently proposed to further expand and modernize the National
Apprenticeship System (White House 2023c; DOL 2023b). Registered
apprenticeships provide firms with resources to invest in workers’ skills
and provide opportunities for workers to learn on the job with a mentor
while getting paid. They also establish standards to ensure the resulting
human capital is portable and of high quality. Firms propose and register an
apprenticeship program in an approved occupation; the set of apprenticeable
occupations already includes many that are likely to work with AI technologies. Through increased flexibility, improved processes, and better data
collection, the proposed improvements to the Registered Apprenticeship
System would help to ensure that workers can develop the skills they need
to work with AI.
Unions can also help develop workers’ skills and protect their livelihoods. Unions counteract the effects of employers’ labor market power and
have been shown to yield increased worker training (Booth and Chatterji
1998; Green, Machin, and Wilkinson 1999). More generally, giving workers a voice in how AI is used may help ensure that they benefit from its
use. Collective bargaining has empowered workers to secure protections
related to the use of AI, such as the protections for screenwriters and actors
secured in their respective union contracts (WGAW 2023; SAG-AFTRA
2023). The engagement of frontline workers on the development of AI could
also have beneficial effects on the successful deployment of these systems
(Kochan et al. 2023). Unions can also have many other economic effects,
including positive effects on compensation for workers, as well as effects
on firm incentives to substitute capital for labor and to engage in research
and development (e.g., Hirsch 2004; Knepper 2020; U.S. Department of the
Treasury 2023). The net effect of these incentives on AI adoption is unclear

An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 285

and is likely to depend on the particular structure of unionized industries
(Haucap and Wey 2004).
The Federal Government can help ensure workers displaced by AI are
prepared to take their next steps in the economy both indirectly and directly
through Federal investment and programs. One critical indirect mechanism
that exists to ensure smooth labor transitions is the unemployment insurance
program. Unemployment insurance keeps workers economically stable,
and it encourages them to find new employment rather than leave the labor
force. Finding new, high-quality jobs for displaced workers may take time,
and a flexible unemployment insurance system allows workers to search for
higher-paying and better jobs (Chetty 2008; Schmieder, von Wachter, and
Bender 2012; Nekoei and Weber 2017).
The government can also help workers transition to new careers
directly by combining unemployment insurance with explicit training
and reemployment services. This approach is currently embodied by the
Reemployment Services and Eligibility Assessment Grants program (DOL
2023c). It has also been used to assist workers losing their jobs to foreign
competition via the Trade Adjustment Assistance (TAA) Program, which
has expired for new beneficiaries.31 Recent research using worker-level
administrative data suggests that displaced workers who are approved for
TAA increase their cumulative earnings by tens of thousands of dollars in
the years following the program (Hyman 2022). This research also finds
suggestive evidence that the skills learned from TAA may depreciate over
time, an area of concern as AI technology rapidly evolves. Policymakers
could build upon lessons learned from TAA to revitalize and expand a program for displaced workers that accommodates AI-related displacement as
a way to ensure that workers remain in the labor force and are able to work
productively with AI. (See box 7-4.)

Measuring AI and Its Effects
A common thread among the various questions and policies outlined above
is that they require observability. If the government cannot observe the ways
and extents to which AI is being used, it may be difficult to enforce existing
laws and to target and implement new regulations. Similarly, the government is constrained in its ability to assist workers who are displaced by AI
if it cannot observe who these workers are. Policies that improve observability or increase data collection may have a high impact if they allow the
government to identify AI adoption when it occurs, distinguish AI-generated
outputs from human-generated ones, and measure more precisely the economic effects of AI.
See CRS (2023b). The TAA program’s termination provisions took effect in July 2022 after
Congress declined to renew funding for the program.
31

286 |

Chapter 7

Box 7-4. Should AI Be Taxed?
Artificial intelligence has the capacity to increase productivity, but it may
do so while displacing many workers from their current jobs or exacerbating inequality. Technology industry leaders, the European Parliament,
and others have therefore suggested taxing the use of AI and related
technologies. They argue that an AI tax could fund training for displaced
workers and potentially reduce overall inequality (Quartz 2017; European
Parliament Committee on Legal Affairs 2017; Abbott and Bogenschneider
2018).
Economists generally consider the proposed AI tax analogously
to other taxes on capital as a production factor. Because some capital
is durable, deciding whether to invest in it may impact productivity and
growth in the future. Correspondingly, a tax that disincentivizes capital
investment has the potential to be especially costly. The concern is especially salient for general purpose technologies like AI, as one of their
functions is to increase existing capital’s reusability (Aghion, Howitt,
and Violante 2002). A lengthy literature has considered the optimal rate
of capital taxation for balancing economic growth against other features
of the economy and of existing tax policy (e.g., Diamond and Saez 2011;
Saez and Stantcheva 2018). Rich frameworks that incorporate borrowing
constraints, uncertainty, and other real-world features typically find that
the optimal way to fund fiscal policy is through a mix of taxes, including
on capital.
Economists have recently considered how an additional tax on AI
adoption could affect both impacted workers and overall economic wellbeing. The effective U.S. capital taxation rate has declined in recent years,
which some have argued could encourage excessive negative employment
impacts through automation (Acemoglu, Manera, and Restrepo 2020).
However, these researchers also argue that setting appropriate capital and
labor tax rates may sufficiently ensure that excessive automation does
not occur, as increased AI-specific tax rates only serve a purpose if it is
infeasible to alter these broader capital tax rates. Other recent research
considers technology’s declining cost trend and its differential effect on
present versus future workers. These papers find that taxing AI in excess
of other capital can be beneficial in the short run but not in the long run
(Guerreiro, Rebelo, and Teles 2022; Thuemmel 2022).
How might taxation affect AI-related innovation itself? Evidence
from historical patent data suggests that inventors respond to taxationbased incentives, both in how much they innovate and in where they do so
(Akcigit et al. 2021). Software-related patents, including for AI technology, comprise roughly half of those issued today, and this patenting activity is particularly geographically clustered (Chattergoon and Kerr 2021).
Taxes on AI adoption and innovation may therefore have implications for
overall growth, place-based policies, and other initiatives.

An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 287

Observing AI adoption and measuring its effects is inherently challenging. This is in part because firms that adopt AI do so in many ways.
They may have service contracts with large technology providers, make use
of purchased or open source tools with proprietary data, engage in in-house
model development, or purchase inputs for which AI is only one component. AI models may be large, in the sense of containing many parameters
and being trained on large volumes of data, or they may be small. And,
the potential negative effects of AI may be closely linked to the model’s
actions, or they may be further afield in upstream or downstream markets.
Nonetheless, the Federal Government is taking and has taken steps to
improve observability of AI adoption.
To address certain risks to safety and security, the recent Executive
Order identifies reporting thresholds for very large AI models based on
the number of arithmetic operations used to train them (White House
2023a). These thresholds may be well suited to identify providers in certain
segments of the AI market in the future, such as large language models.
Identifying such providers may be sufficient to identify and address some
kinds of AI-related risks. At the same time, substantively all effects from AI
adoption so far—including negative effects, such as discrimination—have
been associated with models that did not meet these thresholds (e.g., Brown
et al. 2020). More generally, in many economic contexts, there is little
reason to believe that the potential for negative effects from an AI model
is proportional to its underlying scale. So, although arithmetic reporting
thresholds have value, and additional thresholds could be implemented in
the future, other approaches are also necessary to address the wide range of
AI-related risks.
The Executive Order also directs agencies to consider methods of
identifying AI-generated outputs such as watermarking and content detection. These approaches could help observe and measure some types of AI
usage. If watermarking requirements are sufficient to identify the origins of
an AI output, then harmful outputs can also be traced back to their creators.
However, the practical uses of watermarking are likely limited to generative
AI outputs that are widely distributed. Many other uses of AI in economic
activity are not directly observable outside the firms where they occur.
Also, enforcement of watermarking requirements may be difficult unless
the generative AI models used to produce these outputs have already been
identified, or an alternative method of content detection is successfully
implemented.
A complementary approach may be to identify the workers and other
parties who are most likely to be affected by AI. Surveys of firms already
collect some information about AI adoption (Zolas et al. 2020), and data
from administrative processes are used to produce many other economic
statistics that could be useful. However, current gaps in data collection
288 |

Chapter 7

significantly limit some uses of these data. For example, occupation is a
key dimension along which exposure to AI is likely to have a labor market
impact, so policies that target vulnerable or displaced workers based on
their occupation could play an important role in the overall policy responses
to AI.32 However, linking workers with their occupations consistently is
challenging. Surveys that include occupation are subject to substantial
measurement error, and programs such as unemployment insurance often
have difficulty collecting this information in a standardized way (Fisher
and Houseworth 2013; DOL 2023a). Furthermore, even the best sources of
administrative data on workers in the United States do not include information on their occupations. Additional administrative processes or enhanced
surveys may address gaps in government data collection, making it easier to
implement policies that effectively target and assist affected workers.

Conclusions and Open Questions
AI has the potential to increase economic well-being. Like many previous
technologies, it will do so by transforming the economy in both expected
and unexpected ways. Economic theory demonstrates that the changes have
the capacity to benefit everyone, but recent empirical evidence shows that
broad-based benefits are not guaranteed. Sensible policies to encourage
responsible innovation, protect consumers, empower workers, encourage
competition, and help affected workers adjust are critical.
Many open questions remain, and the Biden-Harris Administration is
working continuously to seek answers to these questions and incorporate the
lessons it learns into its regulatory and policy responses. In 2022, the White
House’s Office of Science and Technology Policy released its Blueprint
for an AI Bill of Rights, which highlights five principles covering many
of the most pressing concerns about AI (White House 2022). Agencies
throughout the Federal Government are taking steps to implement the blueprint’s recommendations. The National AI Advisory Committee, launched
in May 2022, has engaged leaders from industry and academia to consider
major policy questions and make recommendations (NAIAC 2023). The
National Institute of Standards and Technology has launched the U.S. AI
Safety Institute to enable collaboration on safety and security standards
(NIST 2023). And the President’s Executive Order 14110 has identified key
government agencies and bodies to oversee and advise on numerous other
AI-related issues. The order directs the identified organizations to study
AI-related needs and make recommendations for additional tools required
to address them (White House 2023a).
For example, policies that target specific occupations could in many cases reduce the
administrative burden and practical difficulty of demonstrating displacement.
32

An Economic Framework for Understanding Artificial Intelligence | 289

The future path of technological change is always uncertain, but the
Biden-Harris Administration is working to ensure that the Nation’s institutions and policies are prepared for the changes that AI will bring. As AI’s
role in the economy grows, the Federal Government will need to continually
evaluate its institutional framework. Only by thinking broadly about AI and
its effects can society balance the technology’s potential for harm against its
many possible benefits.

290 |

Chapter 7

References
Chapter 1
Aaronson, S., M. Daly, W. Wascher, and D. Wilcox. 2019. Okun Revisited: Who Benefits
Most from a Strong Economy? Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2019072. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. https://
doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2019.072.
Aaronson, S., F. Galbis-Reig, T. Cajner, C. Smith, B. Fallick, and W. Wascher. 2014.
“Labor Force Participation: Recent Developments and Future Prospects.”
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 197–275. https://muse.jhu.edu/
pub/11/article/577366/pdf.
Ashenfelter, O., Card, D., Farber, H., and Ransom, M. 2022. “Monopsony in the Labor
Market: New Empirical Results and New Public Policies.” Journal of Human
Resources 57. https://doi.org/10.3368/jhr.monopsony.
special-issue-2022-introduction.
Autor, D., A. Dube, and A. McGrew. 2023. The Unexpected Compression: Competition at
Work in the Low Wage Labor Market. NBER Working Paper 31010.
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau for Economic Research. https://www.nber.
org/papers/w31010.
Baker, D., and J. Bernstein. 2013. Getting Back to Full Employment: A Better Bargain for
Working People. Washington: Center for Economic Policy Research. https://
cepr.net/documents/Getting-Back-to-Full-Employment_20131118.pdf.
Barlevy, G. J. Faberman, B. Hobijn, and A. Şahin. 2023. The Shifting Reasons for
Beveridge-Curve Shifts. NBER Working Paper 31783. Cambridge, MA:
National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w31783.
Barnichon, R., and A. Shapiro. 2022. “What’s the Best Measure of Economic Slack?”
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Letter, no. 4. https://www.
frbsf.org/wp-content/uploads/sites/4/el2022-04.pdf.
Barrero, J., N. Bloom, S. Davis, B. Meyer, and E. Mihaylov. 2022. The Shift to Remote
Work Lessens Wage-Growth Pressures. NBER Working Paper 30197.
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://www.nber.org/
papers/w30197.
Benigno, P., and G. Eggertsson. 2023. It’s Baaack: The Surge in Inflation in the 2020s
and the Return of the Non-Linear Phillips Curve. NBER Working Paper 31197.

291

Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://www.nber.org/
papers/w31197.
Berger, D., K. Herkenhoff, and S. Mongey. 2022. “Labor Market Power.” American
Economic Review 112, no. 4: 1147–93. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20191521.
Bernstein, J. 2012. “Raise the Economy’s Speed Limit.” New York Times, December 5.
https://www.nytimes.com/2012/12/06/opinion/a-slow-growth-rate-is-the-realthreat.html?_r=0.
Bernstein, J., and K. Bentele. 2019. “The Increasing Benefits and Diminished Costs of
Running a High-Pressure Labor Market.” Center on Budget and Policy Priorities. https://www.cbpp.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/5-15-19fe.pdf.
Bjelland, M., B. Fallick, J. Haltiwanger, and E. McEntarfer. 2011. “Employer-toEmployer Flows in the United States: Estimates Using Linked
Employer-Employee Data.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 29,
no. 4: 493–505. https://ideas.repec.org/a/bes/jnlbes/v29i4y2011p493-505.html.
Blanchard, O., A. Domash, and L. Summers. 2022. “Bad News for the Fed from the
Beveridge Space.” Peterson Institute for International Economics, Policy Brief
22–7. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.4174601.
BLS (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics). 2024. “Annual Work Stoppages Involving 1,000
or More Workers, 1947–Present.” https://www.bls.gov/web/wkstp/annuallisting.htm.
Bok, B., C. Nekarda, N. Petrosky-Nadeau, and R. Crump. 2023. Estimating Natural Rates
of Unemployment: A Primer. Working Paper 2023–25. San Francisco: Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco. https://doi.org/10.24148/wp2023-25.
Bosler, C., and N. Petrosky-Nadeau. 2016. “Job-to-Job Transitions in an Evolving Labor
Market.” Federal Reserve Board of San Francisco Economic Letter, no. 34.
https://www.frbsf.org/wp-content/uploads/el2016-34.pdf.
Burdett, K., and D. Mortensen. 1998. “Wage Differentials, Employer Size, and Unemployment.” International Economic Review 39, no. 2: 257–73. https://www.
jstor.org/stable/2527292.
Cajner, T., J. Coglianese, and J. Montes. 2021. The Long-Lived Cyclicality of the Labor
Force Participation Rate. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2017-047.
Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. https://doi.
org/10.17016/FEDS.2021.047.
Cajner, T., T. Radler, D. Ratner, and I. Vidangos. 2017. Racial Gaps in Labor Market
Outcomes in the Last Four Decades and over the Business Cycle. Finance and
Economics Discussion Series 2017-01. Washington: Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System. https://doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2017.071.
Card, D., A. Cardoso, J. Heining, and P. Kline. 2018. “Firms and Labor Market
Inequality: Evidence and Some Theory.” Journal of Labor Economics 36, no.
S1. https://doi.org/10.1086/694153.

292 |

References

CEA (Council of Economic Advisers). 2014. ‘The Labor Force Participation Rate Since
2007: Causes and Policy Implications.” https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/
sites/default/files/docs/labor_force_participation_report.pdf.
———. 2016a. Economic Report of the President. Washington: U.S. Government
Publishing Office. https://www.whitehouse.gov/wp-content/
uploads/2021/07/2016-ERP.pdf.
———. 2016b. “Labor Market Monopsony: Trends, Consequences, and Policy
Responses.” https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/sites/default/files/page/
files/20161025_monopsony_labor_mrkt_cea.pdf.
———. 2021. “The Pandemic’s Effect on Measured Wage Growth.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/cea/written-materials/2021/04/19/
the-pandemics-effect-on-measured-wage-growth/.
———. 2022. Economic Report of the President. Washington: U.S. Government
Publishing Office. https://www.whitehouse.gov/wp-content/uploads/2022/04/
ERP-2022.pdf.
———. 2023a. “Disinflation Explanation: Supply, Demand, and Their Interaction.”
https://www.whitehouse.gov/cea/written-materials/2023/11/30/
disinflation-explanation-supply-demand-and-their-interaction.
———. 2023b. Economic Report of the President. Washington: U.S. Government
Publishing Office. https://www.whitehouse.gov/wp-content/uploads/2023/03/
ERP-2023.pdf.
———. 2023c. “Did Stabilization Funds Help Mothers Get Back to Work After the
COVID-19 Recession?” Working Paper. https://www.whitehouse.gov/
wp-content/uploads/2023/11/Child-Care-Stabilization.pdf.
Charles, K., and J. Guryan. 2008. “Prejudice and Wages: An Empirical Assessment of
Becker’s The Economics of Discrimination.” Journal of Political Economy 116,
no. 5: 773–809. https://doi.org/10.1086/593073.
Crump, R., S. Eusepi, M. Giannoni, and A. Şahin. 2019. A Unified Approach to
Measuring U*. NBER Working Paper 25930. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau
of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w25930.
Crump, R., C. Nekarda, and N. Petrosky-Nadeau. 2020. Unemployment Rate Benchmarks. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2020-072. Washington: Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. https://doi.org/10.17016/
FEDS.2020.072.
Cumming, C. 2021. “The Importance of Anti-Discrimination Enforcement for a Fair and
Equitable U.S. Labor Market and Broadly Shared Economic Growth.” Washington Center for Equitable Growth. https://equitablegrowth.org/wp-content/
uploads/2022/01/122121-anti-discrimination-enf-ib.pdf.
Daly, M., and B. Hobijn. 2017. “Composition and Aggregate Real Wage Growth.” American Economic Review 107, no. 5: 349–52. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.
p20171075.

References | 293

Daly, M., B. Hobijn, A. Şahin, and R. Valletta. 2011. “A Rising Natural Rate of Unemployment: Permanent or Transitory?” Working Paper, Tinbergen Institute.
https://www.frbsf.org/wp-content/uploads/wp11-05bk.pdf.
Davis, S., J. Faberman, and J. Haltiwanger. 2013. “The Establishment-Level Behavior of
Vacancies and Hiring.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 128, no. 2: 581–622.
https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjt002.
DiNardo, J., N. Fortin, and T. Lemieux. 1996. “Labor Market Institutions and the Distribution of Wages, 1973–1992: A Semiparametric Approach.” Econometrica 64,
no.5: 1001–44. https://doi.org/10.2307/2171954.
Elsby, M., R. Michaels, and D. Ratner. 2015. “The Beveridge Curve: A Survey.” Journal
of Economic Literature 53, no. 3: 571–630. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.53.3.571.
Faccini, R., and L. Melosi. 2023. Job-to-Job Mobility and Inflation. Chicago Fed
Working Paper 2023-03. Chicago: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. https://
www.chicagofed.org/publications/working-papers/2023/2023-03.
Figura, A., and C. Waller. 2022. “What Does the Beveridge Curve Tell Us About the
Likelihood of a Soft Landing?” FEDS Notes. Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System. https://doi.org/10.17016/2380-7172.3190.
Fleischman, C., and J. Roberts. 2011. “From Many Series, One Cycle: Improved Estimates of the Business Cycle from a Multivariate Unobserved Components
Model.” FEDS Working Paper 2011-46. Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1957379.
Furman, J., and W. Powell. 2021. “What Is the Best Measure of Labor Market Tightness?” Peterson Institute for International Economics, Realtime Economics.
https://www.piie.com/blogs/realtime-economic-issues-watch/
what-best-measure-labor-market-tightness.
Galbraith, J. 2001. “The Surrender of Economic Policy.” American Prospect, December
19. https://prospect.org/economy/surrender-economic-policy/.
Ganong, P., and D. Shoag. 2017. “Why Has Regional Income Convergence in the U.S.
Declined?” Journal of Urban Economics 102: 76–90. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
jue.2017.07.002.
Gittleman, M. 2022. “The ‘Great Resignation’ in Perspective.” U.S. Bureau of Labor
Statistics, Monthly Labor Review. https://doi.org/10.21916/mlr.2022.20.
Haltiwanger, J., H. Hyatt, L. Khan, and E. McEntarfer. 2018. “Cyclical Job Ladders by
Firm Size and Firm Wage.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 10,
no. 2. 52–85. https://doi.org/10.1257/mac.20150245.
Hansen, S., P. Lambert, N. Bloom, S. Davis, R. Sadun, and B. Taska. 2023. Remote Work
Across Jobs, Companies, and Space. NBER Working Paper 31007. Cambridge,
MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w31007.
Hazell, J., J. Herreño, E. Nakamura, and J. Steinsson. 2022. “The Slope of the Phillips
Curve: Evidence from U.S. States.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 137, no. 3:
1299–344. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjac010.

294 |

References

Historical Register: Containing and Impartial Relation of All Transactions, Foreign and
Domestick 16. 1731. London: Sun Fire Office.
Hobjin, B., and A. Şahin. 2021. Maximum Employment and the Participation Cycle.
NBER Working Paper 29222. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w29222.
Hornstein, A., M. Kudlyak, and F. Lange. 2014. “Measuring Resource Utilization in the
Labor Market.” Economic Quarterly 100, no. 1: 1–21. https://www.richmondfed.org/-/media/RichmondFedOrg/publications/research/
economic_quarterly/2014/q1/pdf/hornstein.pdf.
Karahan, F., R. Michaels, B. Pugsley, A. Şahin, and R. Schuh. 2017. “Do Job-to-Job
Transitions Drive Wage Fluctuations over the Business Cycle?” American
Economic Review 107, no. 5: 353–57. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.p20171076.
Kline, P., E. Rose, and C. Walters. 2022. “Systemic Discrimination Among Large U.S.
Employers.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 137, no. 4: 1963–2036. https://
doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjac024.
Kudlyak, M. 2017. “Measuring Labor Utilization: The Non-Employment Index.” Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Economic Letter, no. 8. https://www.frbsf.org/
wp-content/uploads/sites/4/el2017-08.pdf.
Kurtulus, F. 2015. “The Impact of Affirmative Action on the Employment of Minorities
and Women: A Longitudinal Analysis Using Three Decades of EEO-1 Filings.”
Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 35, no. 1: 34–66. https://doi.
org/10.1002/pam.21881.
Lang, K., and J. Lehmann. 2012. “Racial Discrimination in the Labor Market: Theory and
Empirics.” Journal of Economic Literature 50, no. 4: 959–1006. https://doi.
org/10.1257/jel.50.4.959.
Manning, A. 2003. Monopsony in Motion: Imperfect Competition in Labor Markets.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. https://press.princeton.edu/books/
paperback/9780691123288/monopsony-in-motion.
———. 2021. “Monopsony in Labor Markets: A Review.” ILR Review 74, no. 1: 3–26.
https://doi.org/10.1177/0019793920922499.
McLeay, M., and S. Tenreyro. 2019. Optimal Inflation and the Identification of the Phillips Curve. NBER Working Paper 25892. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of
Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w25892.
Miller, C., and E. Tedeschi. 2019. “Single Mothers Are Surging Into the Work Force.”
New York Times, May 29. https://www.nytimes.com/2019/05/29/upshot/singlemothers-surge-employment.html.
Moscarini, G., and F. Postel-Vinay. 2017. “The Relative Power of Employment-toEmployment Reallocation and Unemployment Exits in Predicting Wage
Growth.” American Economic Review 107, no. 5: 364–68. https://doi.
org/10.1257/aer.p20171078.

References | 295

Mukoyama, T. 2014. “The Cyclicality of Job-To-Job Transitions and Its Implications for
Aggregate Productivity.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 39: 1–17.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2013.12.004.
Paul, M., W. Darity, and D. Hamilton. 2018. “The Federal Job Guarantee: A Policy to
Achieve Permanent Full Employment.” Center on Budget and Policy Priorities,
Policy Futures. https://www.cbpp.org/research/
the-federal-job-guarantee-a-policy-to-achieve-permanent-full-employment.
Pissarides, C. 2000. Equilibrium Unemployment Theory, 2nd ed. Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press. https://mitpress.mit.edu/9780262533980/
equilibrium-unemployment-theory/.
Powell, J. 2018. “Speech by Chairman Powell on Monetary Policy in a Changing
Economy.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. https://www.
federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/powell20180824a.htm.
Reifschneider, D., W. Wascher, and D. Wilcox. 2015. Aggregate Supply in the United
States: Recent Developments and Implications for the Conduct of Monetary
Policy. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2013-77. Washington: Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. https://doi.org/10.17016/
FEDS.2013.77.
Sanchez Cumming, C. 2021. “The Importance of Anti-Discrimination Enforcement for a
Fair and Equitable U.S. Labor Market and Broadly Shared Economic Growth.”
Washington Center for Equitable Growth. https://equitablegrowth.org/
wp-content/uploads/2022/01/122121-anti-discrimination-enf-ib.pdf.
Shroyer, A., and V. Gaitán. 2019. “Four Reasons Why Employers Should Care About
Housing.” Urban Institute, Housing Matters. https://housingmatters.urban.org/
articles/four-reasons-why-employers-should-care-about-housing.
Solon, G., R. Barsky, and J. Parker. 1994. “Measuring the Cyclicality of Real Wages:
How Important is Composition Bias.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 109, no.
1: 1–25. https://doi.org/10.2307/2118426.
Spriggs, W. 2015. “The Case of Women: Why the Fed Isn’t Close to Achieving Full
Employment and Shouldn’t Be Discussing Raising Interest Rates.” Seattle
Medium. https://seattlemedium.com/
the-case-of-women-why-the-fed-isnt-close-to-achieving-full-employment-andshouldnt-be-discussing-raising-interest-rates.
———. 2017. “Testimony Prepared for U.S. House of Representatives on a Mandate for
Full Employment.” 115th Congress, First Session. https://www.congress.
gov/115/meeting/house/105846/witnesses/HHRG-115-BA20-WstateSpriggsW-20170404.pdf.
Staiger, D., J. Stock, and M. Watson. 1997. “The NAIRU, Unemployment and Monetary
Policy.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 11, no. 1: 33–49. https://www.
aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/jep.11.1.33.
Stansbury, A., and L. Summers. 2020. The Declining Worker Power Hypothesis: An
Explanation for the Recent Evolution of the American Economy. NBER

296 |

References

Working Paper 27193. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w27193.
Tomaskovic-Devey, D., C. Zimmer, K. Stainback, C. Robinson, T. Taylor, and T.
McTague. 2006. “Documenting Desegregation: Segregation in American Workplaces by Race, Ethnicity, and Sex, 1966–2023.” American Sociological Review
71, no. 4: 565–88. https://doi.org/10.1177/000312240607100403.
Topel, R., and M. Ward. 1992. “Job Mobility and the Careers of Young Men.” Quarterly
Journal of Economics 107, no. 2: 439–79. https://www.jstor.org/stable/2118478.
U.S. Census Bureau. 2017. “Job-to-Job (J2J) Flows 101.” https://lehd.ces.census.gov/doc/
j2j_101.pdf.
U.S. Department of the Treasury. 2022. “The State of Labor Market Competition.”
https://home.treasury.gov/system/files/136/State-of-Labor-Market-Competition-2022.pdf.
Wolfers, J. 2019. “Okun Revisited: Who Benefits Most from a Strong Economy?
Comment.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring, 385–97. https://
par.nsf.gov/servlets/purl/10440910.
Yeh, C., C. Macaluso, and B. Hershbein. 2022. “Monopsony in the U.S. Labor Market.”
American Economic Review 112, no. 7: 2099–138. https://doi.org/10.1257/
aer.20200025.
Yellen, J. 2014. “Speech by Chair Yellen on Labor Market Dynamics and Monetary
Policy.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20140822a.htm.
———. 2016. “Speech by Chair Yellen on Macroeconomic Research After the Crisis.”
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. https://www.federalreserve.
gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20161014a.htm.

Chapter 2
Ajello, A., M. Cavallo, G. Favara, W. Peterman, J. Schindler, and N. Sinha. 2023. “A
New Index to Measure U.S. Financial Conditions.” Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, FEDS Notes. https://www.federalreserve.gov/econres/
notes/feds-notes/a-new-index-to-measure-us-financial-conditions-20230630.
html.
Aksoy, C., J. Barrero, N. Bloom, S. Davis, M. Dolls, and P. Zarate. 2022. Working from
Home Around the World. NBER Working Paper 30466. https://doi.org/10.3386/
w30446.
Asdourian, E., G. Nabors, L. Stojanovic, and L. Sheiner. 2024. “Hutchins Center Fiscal
Impact Measure.” https://www.brookings.edu/articles/
hutchins-center-fiscal-impact-measure/.
Barrero, J., N. Bloom, and S. Davis. 2023. “The Evolution of Work from Home.” Journal
of Economic Perspectives, September 3. https://www.aeaweb.org/
articles?id=10.1257/jep.37.4.23.
References | 297

Blau, F., and L. Kahn. 2013. Female Labor Supply: Why Is the U.S. Falling Behind?
NBER Working Paper 18702. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w18702.
BLS (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics). 2024. “Job Openings and Labor Turnover
Survey.” https://www.bls.gov/jlt/.
Campbell, J., and R. Shiller. 2001. Valuation Ratios and the Long-Run Stock Market
Outlook: An Update. NBER Working Paper 8221. Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w8221.
CDC (U.S. Centers for Disease Control and Prevention). No date. “COVID-19 Update
for the United States.” https://covid.cdc.gov/covid-data-tracker/.
CEA (Council of Economic Advisers). 2015. Economic Report of the President. Washington: U.S. Government Publishing Office. https://www.whitehouse.gov/
wp-content/uploads/2021/07/2015-ERP.pdf.
———. 2023a. Did Stabilization Funds Help Mothers Get Back to Work After the
COVID-19 Recession? Working Paper. https://www.whitehouse.gov/wp-content/
uploads/2023/11/Child-Care-Stabilization.pdf.
———. 2023b. “Disinflation Explanation: Supply, Demand, and their Interaction.”
https://www.whitehouse.gov/cea/written-materials/2023/11/30/
disinflation-explanation-supply-demand-and-their-interaction/.
Cheremukhin, A., and P. Restrepo-Echavarria. 2024. The Dual Beveridge Curve. Federal
Reserve Bank of Saint Louis, Working Paper 2022-021. https://www.dallasfed.
org/research/papers/2022/wp2221.
Conference Board. 2024. “U.S. Leading Indicators.” https://www.conference-board.org/
topics/us-leading-indicators.
Congressional Budget Office. No date. “Budget and Economic Data.” https://www.cbo.
gov/data/budget-economic-data.
D’Amico, S., D. Kim, and M. Wei. 2018. “Tips from TIPS: The Informational Content of
Treasury Inflation-Protected Security Prices.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 53, no. 1: 395–436. https://www.jstor.org/stable/26591911.
Elsby, M., R. Michaels, and D. Ratner. 2015. “The Beveridge Curve: A Survey.” Journal
of Economic Literature 53, no. 3: 571–630. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.53.3.571.
Federal Reserve. 2023a. “Federal Reserve Issues: FOMC Statement.” Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System. https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/
fomcpresconf20231213.htm.
———. 2023b. “Enhanced Financial Accounts.” Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System. https://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/efa/efa-hedge-funds.
htm.
Federal Reserve, Federal Open Market Committee. 2023. “Summary of Economic Projections.” December 13. https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/
fomcprojtabl20231213.pdf.

298 |

References

Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta. 2024. “Wage Growth Tracker.” Center for Human
Capital Studies, Data & Tools. https://www.atlantafed.org/chcs/
wage-growth-tracker.
Figura, A., and C. Waller. 2022. “What Does the Beveridge Curve Tell Us About the
Likelihood of a Soft Landing?” FEDS Notes. https://doi.
org/10.17016/2380-7172.3190.
Hartman, M. 2022. “Why Republican Consumers Are Glum and Democrats Upbeat.”
Marketplace. https://www.marketplace.org/2022/08/31/
why-republican-consumers-are-glum-and-democrats-upbeat/.
Herbstman, J., and S. Brave. 2023. “Persistently Pessimistic: Consumer and Small Business Sentiment After the Covid Recession.” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
Chicago Fed Letter 490. https://www.chicagofed.org/publications/
chicago-fed-letter/2023/490.
Hirsch, P. 2012. “Consumer Confidence vs. Consumer Sentiment.” Marketplace. https://
www.marketplace.org/2012/08/28/
consumer-confidence-vs-consumer-sentiment/.
Kim, D., and J. Wright. 2005. An Arbitrage-Free Three-Factor Term Structure Model and
the Recent Behavior of Long-Term Yields and Distant-Horizon Forward Rates.
Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2005-33. Washington: Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.813267.
Mas, A., and A. Pallais. 2017. “Valuing Alternative Work Arrangements.” American
Economic Review 107, no. 12: 3722–59. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20161500.
Mongey, S., and J. Horwich. 2023. “Are Job Vacancies Still as Plentiful as They Appear?
Implications for the ‘Soft Landing.’” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.
https://www.minneapolisfed.org/article/2023/
are-job-vacancies-still-as-plentiful-as-they-appear-implications-for-the-softlanding.
Moscarini, G., and F. Postel-Vinay. 2017. “The Relative Power of Employment-toEmployment Reallocation and Unemployment Exits in Predicting Wage
Growth.” American Economic Review 107, no. 5: 364–68. https://doi.
org/10.1257/aer.p20171078.
Okun, A. 1962. “Potential GNP: Its Measurement and Significance.” American Statistical
Association, Proceedings of the Business and Economic Statistics Section,
89–104.
O’Kane, C. 2023. “Photo of Connecticut McDonald’s $18 Big Mac Meal Sparks Debate
Online.” CBS News. https://www.cbsnews.com/news/
mcdonalds-prices-big-mac-sparks-expensive-menu-darien-connecticut-debateonline/.
Social Security Administration. 2023a. “Social Security Program Data.” https://www.ssa.
gov/OACT/HistEst/Population/2023/Population2023.html.
———. 2023b. “Table V.A2: Immigration Assumptions, Calendar Years 1940–2100.”
2023 OASDI Trustees Report. https://www.ssa.gov/OACT/TR/2023/lr5a2.html.
References | 299

U.S. Census Bureau. No date. “Quarterly Survey of Plant Capacity Utilization (QPC).”
https://www.census.gov/programs-surveys/qpc.html.
White House. 2022. “Fact Sheet: CHIPS and Science Act Will Lower Costs, Create Jobs,
Strengthen Supply Chains, and Counter China.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/
briefing-room/statements-releases/2022/08/09/
fact-sheet-chips-and-science-act-will-lower-costs-create-jobs-strengthen-supplychains-and-counter-china/.
———. No date. “Investing in America: cleanenergy.gov.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/
cleanenergy/.
Yellen, J. 2015. “Inflation Dynamics and Monetary Policy.” Transcript of Philip Gamble
Memorial Lecture, University of Massachusetts Amherst. https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20150924a.htm.

Chapter 3
AARP. 2020. “Caregiving in the United States.” https://www.aarp.org/content/dam/aarp/
ppi/2020/05/full-report-caregiving-in-the-united-states.doi.10.264192Fppi.00103.001.pdf.
ACS (American Cancer Society). 2023. “Cancer Facts & Figures 2023.” https://www.
cancer.org/content/dam/cancer-org/research/cancer-facts-and-statistics/annualcancer-facts-and-figures/2023/2023-cancer-facts-and-figures.pdf.
Alpert, A., W. Evans, E. Lieber, and D. Powell. 2022. Origins of the Opioid Crisis and Its
Enduring Impacts. NBER Working Paper 26500. Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau for Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w26500.
Alpert, A., D. Powell, and R. Pacula. 2018. “Supply-Side Drug Policy in the Presence of
Substitutes: Evidence from the Introduction of Abuse-Deterrent Opioids.”
American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 10, no. 4: 1–35. https://doi.
org/10.1257/pol.20170082.
Alvarez, P. 2022. “What Does the Global Decline of the Fertility Rate Look Like?” World
Economic Forum. https://www.weforum.org/agenda/2022/06/
global-decline-of-fertility-rates-visualised/.
Aragão, C., K. Parker, S. Greenwood, C. Baronavski, and J. Mandapat. 2023. “The
Modern American Family.” Pew Research Center. https://www.pewresearch.
org/social-trends/2023/09/14/the-modern-american-family/.
Arenberg, S., S. Neller, and S. Stripling. 2020. “The Impact of Youth Medicaid Eligibility
on Adult Incarceration.” Forthcoming, American Economic Journal: Applied
Economics. https://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/app.20200785.
Arias, E., K. Kochanek, J. Xu, and B. Tejada-Vera. 2023. “Provisional Life Expectancy
Estimates for 2022.” Centers for Disease Control and Prevention: National Vital
Statistics System. https://www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/vsrr/vsrr031.pdf.

300 |

References

Arteaga, C., and V. Barone. 2023. “A Manufactured Tragedy: The Origins and Deep
Ripples of the Opioid Epidemic.” Working paper. https://viquibarone.github.io/
baronevictoria/Opioids_ArteagaBarone.pdf.
Ash, E., W. Carrington, R. Heller, and G. Hwang. 2023. “Exploring the Effects of
Medicaid During Childhood on the Economy and the Budget.” Working paper,
Congressional Budget Office. https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/202310/59231-Medicaid.pdf.
Azoulay, P., B. Jones, J. Kim, and J. Miranda. 2022. “Immigration and Entrepreneurship
in the United States.” American Economic Review 4, no. 1: 71–88. https://doi.
org/10.1257/aeri.20200588.
Bailey, M. 2006. “More Power to the Pill: The Impact of Contraceptive Freedom on
Women’s Life Cycle Labor Supply.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. https://
doi.org/10.1093/qje/121.1.289.
Bailey, M., and B. Hershbein. 2018. “U.S. Fertility Rates and Childbearing in American
Economic History, 1800–2010.” In The Oxford Handbook of American
Economic History, 1: 75–100, ed. L. Cain, P. Fishback, and P. Rhode. New
York: Oxford University Press. https://doi.org/10.1093/
oxfordhb/9780190882617.013.21.
Bailey, M., B. Hershbein, and A. Miller. 2012. “The Opt-In Revolution? Contraception
and the Gender Gap in Wages.” American Economic Journal: Applied
Economics 4, no. 3: 225–54. https://doi.org/10.1257/app.4.3.225.
Basso, G., and G. Peri. 2020. “Internal Mobility: The Greater Responsiveness of ForeignBorn to Economic Conditions.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 34, no. 3:
77–98. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.34.3.77.
Becker, G. 1960. “An Economic Analysis of Fertility.” In Demographics and Economic
Change in Developed Countries, 209–40. New York: Columbia University
Press. http://www.nber.org/chapters/c2387.
Bhatia, A., N. Krieger, and S. Subramanian. 2019. “Learning from History About
Reducing Infant Mortality: Contrasting the Centrality of Structural Interventions to Early-20th-Century Successes in the United States to Their Neglect in
Current Global Initiatives.” Milbank Quarterly 97, no. 1: 285–345. https://doi.
org/10.1111/1468-0009.12376.
Blau, F., and C. Mackie. 2017. The Economic and Fiscal Consequences of Immigration.
Washington: National Academies Press. https://doi.org/10.17226/23550.
BLS (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics). 2021. “Employment Projections: 2020–2030.”
https://www.bls.gov/news.release/archives/ecopro_09082021.pdf.
———.2022. “Over 16 Million Worked in Health Care and Social Assistance in 2021.”
https://www.bls.gov/opub/ted/2022/over-16-million-women-worked-in-healthcare-and-social-assistance-in-2021.htm.
———.2023a. “Nonfarm Business Sector: Labor Productivity (Output per Hour) for All
Workers [OPHNFB].” https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/ophnfb.

References | 301

———. 2023b. “Unpaid Eldercare in the United States: News Release.” https://www.bls.
gov/news.release/elcare.htm.
———.2023c. “Employment Projections: 2022–2032 Summary.” https://www.bls.gov/
news.release/ecopro.nr0.htm.
Boonstra, H. 2014. “What Is Behind the Declines in Teen Pregnancy Rates?” Guttmacher
Policy Review 17, no. 3. https://www.guttmacher.org/gpr/2014/09/
what-behind-declines-teen-pregnancy-rates.
Borjas, G. 2003. “The Labor Demand Curve Is Downward Sloping: Reexamining the
Impact of Immigration on the Labor Market.” Quarterly Journal of Economics
118, no. 4: 1335–74. http://www.jstor.org/stable/25053941.
Brainerd, E. 2014. “Can Government Policies Reverse Undesirable Declines in Fertility?”
IZA World of Labor 23. https://doi.org/10.15185/izawol.23.
Bronstein, J., M. Wingate, and A. Brisendine. 2018. “Why Is the U.S. Preterm Birth Rate
So Much Higher Than the Rates in Canada, Great Britain, and Western
Europe?” International Journal of Health Services 48, no. 40: 622–40. https://
doi.org/10.1177/0020731418786360.
Brown, A. 2021. “Growing Share of Childless Adults in U.S. Don’t Expect to Ever Have
Children.” Pew Research Center. https://www.pewresearch.org/shortreads/2021/11/19/
growing-share-of-childless-adults-in-u-s-dont-expect-to-ever-have-children/.
Brown, D., A. Kowalski, and I. Lurie. 2020. “Long-Term Impacts of Childhood Medicaid
Expansions on Outcomes in Adulthood.” Review of Economic Studies 87, no. 2:
792–821. https://doi.org/10.1093/restud/rdz039.
Buntin, M., S. Freed, P. Lai, K. Lou, and L. Keohane. 2022. “Trends in and Factors
Contributing to the Slowdown in Medicare Spending Growth, 2007–2018.”
JAMA Health Forum 3, no. 12. https://doi.org/10.1001/
jamahealthforum.2022.4475.
Butcher, K., and D. Card. 1991. “Immigration and Wages: Evidence from the 1980’s.”
American Economic Review 81, no. 2: 292–96. http://www.jstor.org/
stable/2006872.
Campbell, F., G. Conti, J. Heckman, S. Moon, R. Pinto, E. Pungello, and Y. Pan. 2014.
“Early Childhood Investments Substantially Boost Adult Health.” Science
28:1478–85. https://doi.org/ 10.1126/science.1248429.
Card, D. 2009. “Immigration and Inequality.” American Economic Review 99, no. 2:
1–21. https://pubs.aeaweb.org/doi/pdf/10.1257/aer.99.2.1.
Carvalho, C., A. Ferrero, and F. Nechio. 2017. “Demographic Transition and Low U.S.
Interest Rates.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, FRBSF Economic
Letter 2017-27. https://www.frbsf.org/wp-content/uploads/sites/4/el2017-27.pdf.
Case, A., and A. Deaton. 2015. “Rising Morbidity and Mortality in Midlife Among White
Non-Hispanic Americans in the 21st Century.” Proceedings of the National

302 |

References

Academy of Sciences 112, no. 49: 15078–83. https://doi.org/10.1073/
pnas.1518393112.
CBO (Congressional Budget Office). 2019. “CBO’s Projections of Demographic and
Economic Trends.” In The 2019 Long-Term Budget Outlook. https://www.cbo.
gov/system/files?file=2019-06/55331-Appendix_A.pdf.
———. 2022. “The Demographic Outlook: 2022 to 2052.” https://www.cbo.gov/
publication/57975.
———. 2023a. “The Demographic Outlook: 2023 to 2053.” https://www.cbo.gov/
publication/58612.
———. 2023b. “The 2023 Long-Term Budget Outlook.” https://www.cbo.gov/
publication/59331.
———. 2023c. “CBO’s Projections of Federal Health Care Spending.” https://www.cbo.
gov/system/files/2023-03/58997-Whitehouse.pdf.
———. 2024. “The Demographic Outlook: 2024 to 2054.” https://www.cbo.gov/
publication/59697.
CBPP (Center on Budget and Policy Priorities). 2020. “Policy Basics: Introduction to
Medicaid.” https://www.cbpp.org/research/
policy-basics-introduction-to-medicaid.
CDC (Centers for Disease Control and Prevention). 1999. “Achievements in Public
Health, 1900–1999: Healthier Mothers and Babies.” https://www.cdc.gov/
mmwr/preview/mmwrhtml/mm4838a2.htm.
———. 2014. “Smoking and Cardiovascular Disease.” https://www.cdc.gov/tobacco/
sgr/50th-anniversary/pdfs/fs_smoking_cvd_508.pdf.
———. 2019a. “What Is Assisted Reproductive Technology?” https://www.cdc.gov/art/
whatis.html.
———. 2019b. “QuickStats: Percentage of Deaths from External Causes, by Age
Group—United States, 2017.” Morbidity Mortal Weekly Report 68: 710. http://
dx.doi.org/10.15585/mmwr.mm6832a7.
———. 2022. “State-Specific Assisted Reproductive Technology Surveillance.” https://
www.cdc.gov/art/state-specific-surveillance/2020/index.html.
———. 2023a. “Summary of Initial Findings from CDC-Funded Firearm Injury Prevention Research.” https://www.cdc.gov/violenceprevention/firearms/
firearm-research-findings.html.
———. 2023b. “COVID Data Tracker: Trends in United States COVID-19 Hospitalizations, Deaths, Emergency Department (ED) Visits, and Test Positivity by
Geographic Area.” https://stacks.cdc.gov/view/cdc/137422.
———. 2023c. “Respiratory Syncytial Virus Infection (RSV): RSV Surveillance &
Research.” https://www.cdc.gov/rsv/research/index.html.
———. No date. “CDC WONDER.” https://wonder.cdc.gov.

References | 303

CEA (Council of Economic Advisers). 2016. “The Economic Record of the Obama
Administration: Reforming the Health Care System.” https://obamawhitehouse.
archives.gov/sites/default/files/page/files/20161213_cea_record_healh_care_
reform.pdf.
———. 2023a. “Did Stabilization Funds Help Mothers Get Back to Work After the
COVID-19 Recession?” Working Paper. https://www.whitehouse.gov/
wp-content/uploads/2023/11/Child-Care-Stabilization.pdf.
———. 2023b. “The Labor Supply Rebound from the Pandemic.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/cea/written-materials/2023/04/17/
the-labor-supply-rebound-from-the-pandemic/.
———. 2023c. “The Anti-Poverty and Income-Boosting Impacts of the Enhanced CTC.”
https://www.whitehouse.gov/cea/written-materials/2023/11/20/
the-anti-poverty-and-income-boosting-impacts-of-the-enhanced-ctc/.
Census (U.S Census Bureau). 2018. “Methodology, Assumptions, and Inputs for the 2017
National Population Projections.” https://www2.census.gov/programs-surveys/
popproj/technical-documentation/methodology/methodstatement17.pdf.
———. 2023a. “Methodology, Assumptions, and Inputs for the 2023 National Population
Projections.” https://www2.census.gov/programs-surveys/popproj/technicaldocumentation/methodology/methodstatement23.pdf.
———. 2023b. “2023 National Population Projections.” https://www.census.gov/data/
tables/2023/demo/popproj/2023-summary-tables.html.
Chambers, G., S. Dyer, F. Zegers-Hochschild, J. de Mouzon, O. Ishihara, M. Banker, R.
Mansour, M. Kupka, and G. Adamson. 2021. “International Committee for
Monitoring Assisted Reproductive Technologies World Report: Assisted Reproductive Technology, 2014.” Human Reproduction 36, no. 11: 2921–34. https://
doi.org/10.1093/humrep/deab198.
Chen, A., E. Oster, and H. Williams. 2016. “Why Is Infant Mortality Higher in the United
States Than in Europe?” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 9,
no.2: 89–124. https://doi.org/10.1257/pol.20140224.
Chidambaram, P., and A. Burns. 2023. “How Many People Use Medicaid Long-Term
Services and Supports and How Much Does Medicaid Spend on Those
People?” KFF. https://www.kff.org/medicaid/issue-brief/
how-many-people-use-medicaid-long-term-services-and-supports-and-howmuch-does-medicaid-spend-on-those-people/.
CMS (Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services). 2023a. “National Health Expenditure
Data.” https://www.cms.gov/oact/tr/2023.
———. 2023b. “2023 Medicare Trustee Report.” https://www.cms.gov/
research-statistics-data-and-systemsstatistics-trends-and-reportsreportstrustfundstrusteesreports/2021-2022.
Coe, N., G. Goda, and C. Van Houtven. 2023. “Family Spillovers and Long-Term Care
Insurance.” Journal of Health Economics 90: 102781. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
jhealeco.2023.102781.
304 |

References

Cohodes, S., D. Grossman, S. Kleiner, and M. Lovenheim. 2016. “The Effect of Child
Health Insurance Access on Schooling: Evidence from Public Insurance Expansions.” Journal of Human Resources 51, no. 3: 727–59. https://doi.org/10.3368/
jhr.51.3.1014-6688r1.
Cortés, P. 2023. Immigration, Household Production, and Native Women’s Labor Market
Outcomes: A Survey of a Global Phenomenon. NBER Working Paper 31234.
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau for Economic Research. https://doi.
org/10.3386/w31234.
Cunha, F., and J. Heckman. 2007. “The Technology of Skill Formation.” American
Economic Review 97, no. 2: 31–47. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.97.2.31.
Currie, J., and J. Gruber. 1996. “Health Insurance Eligibility, Utilization of Medical Care,
and Child Health.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 111, no. 2: 431-66. https://
doi.org/10.2307/2946684.
Currie, J., A. Li, and M. Schnell. 2023. “The Effects of Competition on Physician
Prescribing.” Working paper. https://static1.squarespace.com/
static/572372e7c2ea51b309e9991a/t/64aeceef4539e40f84b
240d3/1689177840601/CLS_062123.pdf.
Cutler, D., A. Deaton, and A. Lleras-Muney. 2006. “The Determinants of Mortality.”
Journal of Economic Perspectives 20, no. 3: 97–120. https://doi.org/10.1257/
jep.20.3.97.
Cutler, D., K. Ghosh, K. Messer, T. Raghunathan, S. Stewart, and A. Rosen. 2019.
“Explaining the Slowdown in Medical Spending Growth among the Elderly,
1999–2012.” Health Affairs 38, no. 2: 222–29. https://doi.org/10.1377/
hlthaff.2018.05372.
Cutler, D., and E. Glaeser. 2021. “When Innovation Goes Wrong: Technological Regress
and the Opioid Epidemic.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 35, no. 4:
171–96. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.35.4.171.
Cutler, D., E. Glaeser, and A. Rosen. 2009. “Is the U.S. Population Behaving Healthier?”
In Social Security Policy in a Changing Environment, 423–42, ed. J. Brown, J.
Liebman, and D. Wise. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. https://doi.
org/10.7208/chicago/9780226076508.003.0013.
Cutler, D., and G. Miller. 2005. “The Role of Public Health Improvements in Health
Advances: The Twentieth-Century United States.” Demography 42, no. 1: 1–22.
https://www.jstor.org/stable/1515174.
Deaton, A. 2014. The Great Escape: Health, Wealth, and the Origins of Inequality. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. https://press.princeton.edu/books/
hardcover/9780691153544/the-great-escape.
DeCicca, P., and L. McLeod. 2008. “Cigarette Taxes and Older Adult Smoking: Evidence
from Recent Large Tax Increases.” Journal of Health Economics 27, no. 4:
918–29. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jhealeco.2007.11.005.

References | 305

Deming, D. 2009. “Early Childhood Intervention and Life-Cycle Skill Development:
Evidence from Head Start.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics
1: 111–34. https://doi.org/10.1257/app.1.3.111.
Dench, D., M. Pineda-Torres, and C. Myers. 2023. The Effects of the Dobbs Decision on
Fertility. IZA Discussion Paper 16608. Bonn: Institute of Labor Economics.
https://docs.iza.org/dp16608.pdf.
Dieppe, A. 2020. “The Broad-Based Productivity Slowdown, in Seven Charts.” World
Bank Blogs. https://blogs.worldbank.org/developmenttalk/
broad-based-productivity-slowdown-seven-charts.
DOE (U.S. Department of Energy). 2022. “The Inflation Reduction Act Drives Significant Emissions Reductions and Positions America to Reach Our Climate
Goals.” https://www.energy.gov/sites/default/files/2022-08/8.18%20InflationReductionAct_Factsheet_Final.pdf.
Duncan, G., and K. Magnuson. 2013. “Investing in Preschool Programs.” Journal of
Economic Perspectives 27: 109–32. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.27.2.109.
Dynan, K., W. Edelberg, and M. Palumbo. 2009. “The Effects of Population Aging on the
Relationship among Aggregate Consumption, Saving, and Income.” American
Economic Review 99, no. 2: 380–86. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.99.2.380.
Edelberg, W., and T. Watson. 2023. “Immigration Impact Index.” Brookings Institution.
https://www.brookings.edu/articles/immigration-impact-index/.
Edwards, E. 2023. “Abortion Bans Could Drive Away Young Doctors, New Survey
Finds.” NBC News. https://www.nbcnews.com/health/health-news/
states-abortion-bans-young-doctors-survey-rcna84899.
Ely, M., and A. Driscoll. 2023. “Infant Mortality in the United States, 2021: Data from
the Period Linked Birth/Infant Death File.” Centers for Disease Control and
Prevention, National Vital Statistics System. https://www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/
nvsr/nvsr72/nvsr72-11.pdf.
EPA (U.S. Environmental Protection Agency) 2007. “Achievements in Stratospheric
Ozone Protection Progress Report.” https://www.epa.gov/sites/default/
files/2015-07/documents/achievements_in_stratospheric_ozone_protection.pdf.
———. 2022. “Sulfur Dioxide Trends.” https://www.epa.gov/air-trends/
sulfur-dioxide-trends.
Erbabian, M., V. Osorio, and M. Paulson. 2022. “Measuring Fertility in the United
States.” Penn Wharton Budget Model. https://budgetmodel.wharton.upenn.edu/
issues/2022/7/8/measuring-fertility-in-the-united-states.
Evans, W., M. Farrelly, and E. Montgomery. 1996. Do Workplace Smoking Bans Reduce
Smoking? NBER Working Paper 5567. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau for
Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w5567.
Fleming-Dutra, K., J. Jones, L. Roper, M. Prill, I. Ortega-Sanchez, D. Moulia, M.
Wallace, M. Godfrey, K. Broder, N. Tepper, O. Brooks, P. Sánchez, C. Kotton,
B. Mahon, S. Long, and M. McMorrow. 2023. “Use of the Pfizer Respiratory

306 |

References

Syncytial Virus Vaccine During Pregnancy for the Prevention of Respiratory
Syncytial Virus–Associated Lower Respiratory Tract Disease in Infants:
Recommendations of the Advisory Committee on Immunization Practices—
United States, 2023.” Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, MMWR
Morbidly Mortality Weekly Report 72: 1115–22. https://www.cdc.gov/mmwr/
volumes/72/wr/mm7241e1.htm.
Foster, A. 2015. “Consumer Expenditures Vary by Age.” Bureau of Labor Statistics:
Beyond the Numbers. https://www.bls.gov/opub/btn/volume-4/consumer-expenditures-vary-by-age.htm.
Foster, D. 2021. The Turnaway Study: Ten Years, a Thousand Women, and the Consequences of Having—or Being Denied—an Abortion. New York: Simon &
Schuster. https://www.simonandschuster.com/books/The-Turnaway-Study/
Diana-Greene-Foster/9781982141578.
Foster, D., M. Biggs, L. Ralph, C. Gerdts, S. Roberts, and M. Glymour. 2018. “Socioeconomic Outcomes of Women Who Receive and Women Who Are Denied
Wanted Abortions in the United States.” American Journal of Public Health
112, no. 9: 1290–96. https://doi.org/10.2105/ajph.2017.304247.
Funk, C., A. Tyson, B. Kennedy, and G. Pasquini. 2023. “Americans’ Largely Positive
Views of Childhood Vaccines Hold Steady.” Pew Research Center. https://www.
pewresearch.org/science/wp-content/uploads/sites/16/2023/05/PS_2023.05.16_
vaccines_REPORT.pdf.
Gagnon, E., B. Johannsen, and J. López-Salido. 2021. “Understanding the New Normal:
The Role of Demographics.” IMF Economic Review 69, no. 2: 357–90. https://
doi.org/10.1057/s41308-021-00138-4.
GAO (U.S. Government Accountability Office). 2013. “Prescription Drugs Comparison
of DOD and VA Direct Purchase Prices.” https://www.gao.gov/assets/gao-13358.pdf.
Gapminder. 2022. “Child Mortality Rate, Under Age 5.” https://www.gapminder.org/data/
documentation/gd005/.
Giltner, A., A. Evans, C. Cicco, S. Leach, and W. Rowe. 2022. “Fentanyl Analog Trends
in Washington, D.C., Observed in Needle-Exchange Syringes.” Forensic
Science International 338: 111393. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
forsciint.2022.111393.
Goldin, C. 2004. From the Valley to the Summit: The Quiet Revolution That Transformed
Women’s Work. NBER Working Paper 10335. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau
for Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w10335.
Goldin, C., and L. Katz. 2002. “The Power of the Pill: Oral Contraceptives and Women’s
Career and Marriage Decisions.” Journal of Political Economy 110, no. 4:
730–70. https://doi.org/10.1086/340778.
Goldin, J., I. Lurie, and J. McCubbin. 2021. “Health Insurance and Mortality: Experimental Evidence from Taxpayer Outreach.” Quarterly Journal of Economics
136, no. 1: 1–49. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjaa029.

References | 307

Goldin, C., and J. Mitchell. 2017. “The New Life Cycle of Women’s Employment: Disappearing Humps, Sagging Middles, Expanding Tops.” Journal of Economic
Perspectives 31, no. 1: 161–82. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.31.1.161.
Goodman-Bacon, A. 2018. “Public Insurance and Mortality: Evidence from Medicaid
Implementation.” Journal of Political Economy 126, no. 1: 216–62. https://doi.
org/10.1086/695528.
———. 2021. “The Long-Run Effects of Childhood Insurance Coverage: Medicaid
Implementation, Adult Health, and Labor Market Outcomes.” American
Economic Review 111, no. 8: 2550–93. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20171671.
Grabowski, D. 2021. “The Future of Long-Term Care Requires Investment in Both
Facility- and Home-Based Services.” Nature Aging 1: 10–11. https://doi.
org/10.1038/s43587-020-00018-y.
Gray-Lobe, G., P. Pathak, C.R. Walters. “The Long-Term Effects of Universal Preschool
in Boston.” 2022. Quarterly Journal of Economics 138, no. 1: 363–411. https://
doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjac036.
Guldi, M. 2008. “Fertility Effects of Abortion and Birth Control Pill Access for Minors.”
Demography 45, no. 4: 817–27. https://www.jstor.org/stable/25651477.
Guth, M., R. Garfield, and R. Rudowitz. 2020. “The Effects of Medicaid Expansion
Under the ACA: Studies from January 2014 to January 2020.” Kaiser Family
Foundation. https://www.kff.org/report-section/
the-effects-of-medicaid-expansion-under-the-aca-updated-findings-from-a-literature-review-report/.
Hales, C., J. Servais, C. Martin, and D. Kohen. 2019. “Prescription Drug Use Among
Adults Aged 40–79 in the United States and Canada.” NCHS Daily Brief 347.
https://www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/databriefs/db347-h.pdf.
Hamilton, B., J. Martin, and E. Osterman. 2023. “VSRR 028: Births: Provisional Data for
2022.” https://doi.org/10.15620/cdc:127052.
Hamilton, B., J. Martin, and S. Ventura. 2009. “Births: Preliminary Data for 2007.”
National Vital Statistics Reports 57, no 12. https://www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/nvsr/
nvsr57/nvsr57_12.pdf.
Hanushek, E., and L. Wößmann. 2010. “Education and Economic Growth.” In Economics
of Education, 60–67, ed. D. Brewer and P. McEwan. New York: Academic
Press. https://shop.elsevier.com/books/economics-of-education/
brewer/978-0-08-096530-7.
Hendren, N., and B. Sprung-Keyser. 2020. “A Unified Welfare Analysis of Government
Policies*.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 135, no. 3: 1209–1318. https://doi.
org/10.1093/qje/qjaa006.
Herbst, C. 2022. “Child Care in the United States: Markets, Policy, and Evidence.”
Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 42, no. 1: 255–304. https://doi.
org/10.1002/pam.22436.

308 |

References

Heuveline, P. 2023. “The COVID-19 Pandemic and the Expansion of the Mortality Gap
between the United States and Its European Peers.” Plos One 18, no. 3. https://
doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0283153.
HHS (U.S. Department of Health and Human Services). 2021. “Confronting Health
Misinformation.” https://www.hhs.gov/sites/default/files/surgeon-general-misinformation-advisory.pdf.
———. 2022. “New HHS Report Shows National Uninsured Rate Reached All-Time
Low in 2022.” https://www.hhs.gov/about/news/2022/08/02/new-hhs-reportshows-national-uninsured-rate-reached-all-time-low-in-2022.html.
———. 2023a. “Fact Sheet: End of the COVID-19 Public Health Emergency.” https://
www.hhs.gov/about/news/2023/05/09/fact-sheet-end-of-the-covid-19-publichealth-emergency.html.
———. 2023b. “The Biden-Harris Administration Takes Critical Action to Make
Naloxone More Accessible and Prevent Fatal Overdoses from Opioids Like
Fentanyl.” https://www.hhs.gov/about/news/2023/03/29/biden-harris-administration-takes-critical-action-make-naloxone-more-accessible-prevent-fatal-overdoses-opioids-fentanyl.html.
———. 2023c. “Biden Harris Administration Invests More Than $80 Million to Help
Rural Communities Respond to Fentanyl and Other Opioid Overdose Risks.”
Health Resources and Services Administration. https://www.hrsa.gov/about/
news/press-releases/rcorps-2023-awards.
———. 2023d. “National Uninsured Rate Reaches an All-Time Low in Early 2023.”
https://www.aspe.hhs.gov/reports/
national-uninsured-rate-reaches-all-time-low-early-2023.
Hill, A. 2021. “‘I Had Second Thoughts’: The Gen Z-ers Choosing Not to Have Children.” Guardian, April 23. https://www.theguardian.com/society/2021/
apr/23/i-had-second-thoughts-the-gen-z-ers-choosing-not-to-have-children.
Hock, H. 2007. “The Pill and the College Attainment of American Women and Men.”
Working paper, Florida State University. https://coss.fsu.edu/econpapers/
wpaper/wp2007_10_01.pdf.
Honoré, B., and A. Lleras-Muney. 2006. “Bounds in Competing Risks Models and the
War on Cancer.” Econometrica 74, no. 6: 1675–98. https://doi.
org/10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00722.x.
Hooper, K. 2023. “What Role Can Immigration Play in Addressing Current and Future
Labor?” Migration Policy Institute. https://www.migrationpolicy.org/research/
immigration-addressing-labor-shortages.
Howard, J., and T. Sneed. 2023. “Texas Woman Denied an Abortion tells Senators She
‘Nearly Died on their Watch.’” CNN. https://www.cnn.com/2023/04/26/health/
abortion-hearing-texas-senators-amanda-zurawski/index.html.
Hoyert, D., and A. Miniño. 2023. “Maternal Mortality Rates in the United States, 2021.”
Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, National Center for Health

References | 309

Statistics. https://www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/hestat/maternal-mortality/2021/
maternal-mortality-rates-2021.pdf.
Hunt, J., and M. Gauthier-Loiselle. 2010. ‘How Much Does Immigration Boost Innovation?” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2, no. 2: 31–56. https://
doi.org/10.1257/mac.2.2.31.
IRS (U.S. Internal Revenue Service). 2024. “Affordable Care Act Tax Provisions.”
https://www.irs.gov/affordable-care-act/affordable-care-act-tax-provisions.
Johnson, R., and C. Jackson. 2019. “Reducing Inequality through Dynamic Complementarity: Evidence from Head Start and Public School Spending.” American
Economic Journal: Economic Policy 11, no. 4: 310–49. https://doi.org/10.1257/
pol.20180510.
Jones, C. 2019. “Paul Romer: Ideas, Nonrivalry, and Endogenous Growth.” Scandinavian
Journal of Economics 121, no. 3: 859–83. https://doi.org/10.1111/sjoe.12370.
———. 2022. “The End of Economic Growth? Unintended Consequences of a Declining
Population.” American Economic Review 112, no. 11: 3489–527. https://doi.
org/10.1257/aer.20201605.
Jones, C., and P. Romer. 2010. “The New Kaldor Facts: Ideas, Institutions, Population,
and Human Capital.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2, no. 1:
224–45. https://doi.org/10.1257/mac.2.1.224.
Joseph, K., A. Boutin, S. Lisonkova, G. Muraca, N. Razaz, S. John, A. Mehrabadi, Y.
Sabr, C. Ananth, and E. Schisterman. 2021. “Maternal Mortality in the United
States: Recent Trends, Current Status, and Future Considerations.” Obstetrics
Gynecology 137, no.5: 763–71. https://doi.org/10.1097/
AOG.0000000000004361.
Karahan, F., B. Pugsley, and A. Şahin. 2019. Demographic Origins of the Startup Deficit.
NBER Working Paper 25874. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau for Economic
Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w25874.
Kearney, M., P. Levine, and L. Pardue. 2022. “The Puzzle of Falling U.S. Birth Rates
since the Great Recession.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 36, no. 1:
151–76. https://www.econ.umd.edu/sites/www.econ.umd.edu/files/pubs/
jep.36.1.151.pdf.
Kennedy-Moulton, K., S. Miller, P. Persson, M. Rossin-Slater, L. Wherry, and G. Aldana.
2023. Maternal and Infant Health Inequality: New Evidence from Linked
Administrative Data. NBER Working Paper 30693. Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau for Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w30693.
KFF (Kaiser Family Foundation). 2024. “Medicaid Postpartum Coverage Extension
Tracker.” https://www.kff.org/medicaid/issue-brief/
medicaid-postpartum-coverage-extension-tracker/.
Kolata, G. 2022. “‘Sobering’ Study Shows Challenges of Egg Freezing.” New York Times.
https://www.nytimes.com/2022/09/23/health/egg-freezing-age-pregnancy.html.

310 |

References

Kuruc, K., S. Vyas, M. Budolfson, M. Geruso, and D. Spears. 2023. “Population Decline:
Too Slow for the Urgency of Climate Solutions.” University of Texas at Austin,
Population Wellbeing Initiative. https://sites.utexas.edu/pwi/files/2023/11/
Vienna_authors.pdf.
Lancet. 2022. “Managing the Opioid Crisis in North America and Beyond.” Vol. 399, no.
10324: 495. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0140-6736(22)00200-8.
Lawrence, W., N. Freedman, J. McGee-Avila, A. González, Y. Chen, M. Emerson, G.
Gee, E. Haozous, A. Haque, M. Inoue-Choi, S. Jackson, B. Lord, A. Nápoles,
E. Pérez-Stable, J. Vo, F. Williams, and M. Shiels. 2023. “Trends in Mortality
from Poisonings, Firearms, and All Other Injuries by Intent in the U.S., 1999–
2020.” JAMA Internal Medicine 183, no. 8: 849–56. https://doi.org/10.1001/
jamainternmed.2023.2509.
Lazzari, E., E. Gray, and G. Chambers. 2021. “The Contribution of Assisted Reproductive
Technology to Fertility Rates and Parity Transition: An Analysis of Australian
Data.” Demographic Research 45: 1081–96. https://doi.org/10.4054/
demres.2021.45.35.
Lee, K. 2007. “Infant Mortality Decline in the Late 19th and Early 20th Centuries: The
Role of Market Milk.” Perspectives in Biology and Medicine 50, no. 4:
585–602. https://doi.org/10.1353/pbm.2007.0051.
Lee, R., and R. Edwards. 2002. “The Fiscal Effects of Population Aging in the U.S.:
Assessing the Uncertainties.” Tax Policy and the Economy 16: 141–80. https://
www.nber.org/books-and-chapters/tax-policy-and-economy-volume-16/
fiscal-effects-population-aging-us-assessing-uncertainties.
Lindo, J., and M. Pineda-Torres. 2020. New Evidence on the Effects of Mandatory
Waiting Periods for Abortion. NBER Working Paper 26228. Cambridge, MA:
National Bureau for Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w26228.
Lister, R., W. Drake, B. Scott, and C. Graves. 2019. “Black Maternal Mortality: The
Elephant in the Room.” World Journal of Gynecology & Women’s Health 3, no.
1. https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC7384760/.
Livingston, G., and D. Cohn. 2010. “The New Demography of American Motherhood.”
Pew Research Center, Social & Demographic Trends Project. https://www.
pewresearch.org/social-trends/2010/05/06/
the-new-demography-of-american-motherhood/.
Maestas, N., K. Mullen, and D. Powell. 2016. “The Effect of Population Aging on
Economic Growth, The Labor Force and Productivity.” Working Paper, RAND
Labor & Population. https://www.rand.org/content/dam/rand/pubs/working_
papers/WR1000/WR1063-1/RAND_WR1063-1.pdf.
Mancher, M., and A. Leshner. 2019. “The Effectiveness of Medication-Based Treatment
for Opioid Use Disorder.” In Medications for Opioid Use Disorder Save Lives,
ed. M. Mancher and A. Leshner. Washington: National Academies Press.
https://doi.org/10.17226/25310.

References | 311

McCann, A., and A. Walker. 2023. “Dozens of Abortion Clinics Have Closed Since Roe v.
Wade Was Overturned.” New York Times. https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2023/06/22/us/abortion-clinics-dobbs-roe-wade.html.
Mehta, L., T. Beckie, H. DeVon, C. Grines, H. Krumholz, M. Johnson, K. Lindley, V.
Vaccarino, T. Wang, K. Watson, and N. Wenger. 2016. “Acute Myocardial
Infarction in Women.” Circulation, vol. 133, no. 9. https://www.ahajournals.
org/doi/10.1161/CIR.0000000000000351.
Miller, S., N. Johnson, and L. Wherry. 2019. Medicaid and Mortality: New Evidence from
Linked Survey and Administrative Data. NBER Working Paper 26081.
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau for Economic Research. https://doi.
org/10.3386/w26081.
Miller, S., and L. Wherry. 2019. “The Long-Term Effects of Early Life Medicaid
Coverage.” Journal of Human Resources 54, no. 3: 785–824. https://doi.
org/10.3368/jhr.54.3.0816.8173r1.
Miller, S., L. Wherry, and D. Foster. 2023. “The Economic Consequences of Being
Denied an Abortion.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 15, no. 1:
394–437. https://doi.org/10.1257/pol.20210159.
Modigliani, F., and R. Brumberg. 1954. “Utility Analysis and the Consumption Function.” In The Collected Papers of Franco Modigliani, ed. F. Modigliani.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. https://doi.org/10.7551/mitpress/1923.001.0001.
Morrissey, T. 2017. “Child Care and Parent Labor Force Participation: A Review of the
Research Literature.” Review of Economics of the Household 15, no. 1: 1–24.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-016-9331-3.
Mulcahy, A., C. Whaley, M. Gizaw, D. Schwam, N. Edenfield, and A. Becerra-Ornelas.
2022. “International Prescription Drug Price Comparisons: Current Empirical
Estimates and Comparisons with Previous Studies.” Health and Human
Services Department, Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation. https://aspe.hhs.gov/reports/
international-prescription-drug-price-comparisons.
Myers, C. 2017. “The Power of Abortion Policy: Reexamining the Effects of Young
Women’s Access to Reproductive Control.” Journal of Political Economy 125,
no. 6: 2178–2224. https://doi.org/10.1086/694293.
Myers, C., L. Bennett, F. Vale, and A. Nieto. 2023. “Abortion Access Dashboard.” https://
experience.arcgis.com/experience/6e360741bfd84db79d5db774a1147815.
Nash, E., and I. Guarnieri. 2022. “13 States Have Abortion Trigger Bans—Here’s What
Happens When Roe Is Overturned.” Guttmacher Institute. https://www.guttmacher.org/
article/2022/06/13-states-have-abortion-trigger-bans-heres-what-happens-whenroe-overturned.
NHEA (National Health Expenditure Data). 2023. “National Health Expenditure Data.”
https://www.cms.gov/data-research/statistics-trends-and-reports/
national-health-expenditure-data.

312 |

References

OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development). 2021. “Health at a
Glance 2021: OECD Indicators.” https://doi.org/10.1787/7a7afb35-en.
Osterman, P. 2017. Who Will Care for Us? Long-Term Care and the Long-Term Workforce. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. https://www.russellsage.org/
publications/who-will-care-us-0.
Ottaviano, G., and G. Peri. 2012. “Rethinking the Effect of Immigration on Wages.”
Journal of the European Economic Association 10, no 1:152–97. https://doi.
org/10.1111/j.1542-4774.2011.01052.x.
Parker, K., and R. Minkin. 2023. “Public Has Mixed Views on the Modern American
Family.” Pew Research Center. https://www.pewresearch.org/socialtrends/2023/09/14/public-has-mixed-views-on-the-modern-american-family/.
Peri, G. 2012. “The Effect of Immigration on Productivity: Evidence from U.S. States.”
Review of Economics and Statistics 94, no. 1: 348–58. https://doi.org/10.1162/
REST_a_00137.
Peri, G., and C. Sparber. 2009. “Task Specialization, Immigration, and Wages.” American
Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 1 no. 3: 135–69. https://doi.
org/10.1257/app.1.3.135.
Peters, M. 2022. “Market Size and Spatial Growth—Evidence from Germany’s Post-War
Population Expulsions.” Econometrica 90, no. 5: 2357–96. https://doi.
org/10.3982/ecta18002.
PHI (Paraprofessional Healthcare Institute). 2022. “Direct Care Workers in the United
States.” https://www.phinational.org/wp-content/uploads/2022/08/DCW-in-theUnited-States-2022-PHI.pdf.
Picchi, A. 2022. “It Now Costs $310,000 to Raise a Child: ‘Something Has to Give.’”
CBS News. https://www.cbsnews.com/news/raising-a-child-costs-310000/.
Prato, M. 2022. “The Global Race for Talent: Brain Drain, Knowledge, Transfer, and
Growth.” Working Paper, World Bank. https://thedocs.worldbank.org/en/doc/35
e299dda0bce4645403a3418356b405-0050022023/original/prato-global-racetalent-november2022.pdf.
PWI (Population Wellbeing Initiative, University of Texas at Austin). 2023. “Projections
of Long-Term Population Decline for the United States: Causes, Consequences,
and Responses to Sustained Low Birth Rates.” PWI Policy Discussion Paper.
https://sites.utexas.edu/pwi/us_long-term_population_decline/.
Reinhard, S., S. Caldera, A. Houser, and R. Choula. 2023. “Valuing the Invaluable: 2023
Update.” AARP Public Policy Initiative. https://doi.org/10.26419/
ppi.00082.006.
Ritchie, H. 2023. “The U.N. Has Made Population Projections for More Than 50 Years—
How Accurate Have They Been?” OurWorldInData.org. https://ourworldindata.
org/population-projections.

References | 313

Romer, P. 2018. “Prize Lecture: On the Possibility of Progress.” Nobel Prize in
Economics. https://www.nobelprize.org/prizes/economic-sciences/2018/romer/
lecture/.
Sabelhaus, J. 2023. “Will Population Aging Push Us Over a Fiscal Cliff?” Aspen Institute
Economic Strategy Group. https://www.economicstrategygroup.org/publication/
population-aging-fiscal-cliff/.
Sabo, S., and S. Johnson. 2022. “Pandemic Disrupted Historical Mortality Patterns,
Caused Largest Jump in Deaths in 100 Years.” U.S. Census Bureau. https://
www.census.gov/library/stories/2022/03/united-states-deaths-spiked-as-covid19-continued.html.
Schmitz, H., and M. Westphal. 2017. “Informal Care and Long-Term Labor Market
Outcomes.” Journal of Health Economics 56: 1–18. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
jhealeco.2017.09.002.
Schnell, M. 2022. “Physician Behavior in the Presence of a Secondary Market: The Case
of Prescription Opioids.” Working paper. https://static1.squarespace.com/
static/572372e7c2ea51b309e9991a/t/62a361101fa2
c47a22943335/1654874393320/Schnell_06102022.pdf.
Schwandt, H., J. Currie, M. Bär, J. Banks, P. Bertoli, A. Bütikofer, S. Cattan, B. Chao, C.
Costa, L. González, V. Grembi, K. Huttunen, R. Karadakic, L. Kraftman, S.
Krutikova, S. Lombardi, P. Redler, C. Riumallo-Herl, A. Rodríguez-González,
K. Salvanes, P. Santana, J. Thuilliez, E. Doorslaer, T. Ourti, J. Winter, B. Wouterse, and A. Wuppermann. 2021. “Inequality in Mortality between Black and
White Americans by Age, Place, and Cause and in Comparison to Europe, 1990
to 2018.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States
of America 118, no. 40. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.2104684118.
Sellers, F., and F. Nirappil. 2022. “Confusion Post-Roe Spurs Deals, Denials for Some
Lifesaving Pregnancy Care.” Washington Post. https://www.washingtonpost.
com/health/2022/07/16/abortion-miscarriage-ectopic-pregnancy-care/.
Sheiner, L. 2018. The Long-Term Impact of Aging on the Federal Budget. Hutchins
Center Working Paper 40. Washington: Brookings Institution. https://www.
brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2018/01/wp405.pdf.
Shen, K. 2023. “Who Benefits from Public Financing of Home-Based Long Term Care?
Evidence from Medicaid.” Working Paper, SSRN. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/
ssrn.4523279.
Shepard, K., R. Roubein, and C. Kitchener. 2022. “1 in 3 American Women Have Already
Lost Abortion Access; More Restrictive Laws Are Coming.” Washington Post.
https://www.washingtonpost.com/nation/2022/08/22/
more-trigger-bans-loom-1-3-women-lose-most-abortion-access-post-roe/.
Smith, D., and B. Bradshaw. 2006. “Variation in Life Expectancy During the Twentieth
Century in the United States.” Demography 43: 647–57. https://doi.
org/10.1353/dem.2006.0039.

314 |

References

Smith, S., J. Newhouse, and G. Cuckler. 2022. Health Care Spending Growth Has
Slowed: Will the Bend in the Curve Continue? NBER Working Paper 30782.
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau for Economic Research. https://doi.
org/10.3386/w30782.
Smock, P., and C. Schwartz. 2020. “The Demography of Families: A Review of Patterns
and Change.” Journal of Marriage and Family 82, no. 1: 9–34. https://doi.
org/10.1111/jomf.12612.
Sobotka, T., V. Skirbekk, and D. Philipov. 2011. “Economic Recession and Fertility in the
Developed World.” Population and Development Review 37, no. 2: 267–306.
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1728-4457.2011.00411.x.
Soni, A., L. Wherry, and K. Simon. 2020. “How Have ACA Insurance Expansions
Affected Health Outcomes? Findings from the Literature.” Health Affairs 39,
no. 3: 371–78. https://doi.org/10.1377/hlthaff.2019.01436.
Spears, D. 2023. “The World’s Population May Peak in Your Lifetime; What Happens
Next?” New York Times. https://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2023/09/18/
opinion/human-population-global-growth.html.
Spears. D., S. Vyas, G. Weston, and M. Geruso. 2023. “Long-Term Population Projections: Scenarios of Low or Rebounding Fertility.” Working Paper, SSRN.
https://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.4534047.
SSA (U.S. Social Security Administration). 2023a. “National Average Wage Index.”
https://www.ssa.gov/oact/cola/AWI.html.
———. 2023b. “2023 OASDI Trustees Report.” https://www.ssa.gov/OACT/TR/2023/
VI_G2_OASDHI_GDP.html.
———. 2023c. “The 2023 Annual Report of the Board of Trustees of the Federal
Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Federal Disability Insurance Trust
Funds.” https://www.ssa.gov/oact/TR/2023/tr2023.pdf.
Steuerle, C., A. Carasso, and L. Cohen. 2004. “How Progressive Is Social Security and
Why?” Urban Institute. 2004. https://www.urban.org/sites/default/files/
publication/57666/311016-how-progressive-is-social-security-and-why-.pdf.
Steuerle, C., and K. Smith. 2023. “Social Security & Medicare Lifetime Benefits and
Taxes: 2022.” Urban Institute and Brookings Institution, Tax Policy Center.
https://www.taxpolicycenter.org/publications/social-security-medicare-lifetimebenefits-and-taxes-2022/full.
Syverson, C. 2017. “Challenges to Mismeasurement Explanations for the U.S. Productivity Slowdown.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 31, no. 2: 165–86. https://
doi.org/10.1257/jep.31.2.165.
Turner, N., K. Danesh, and K. Moran. 2020. “The Evolution of Infant Mortality
Inequality in the United States, 1960–2016.” Science Advances 6, no. 29.
https://doi.org/10.1126/sciadv.aba5908.

References | 315

U.N. DESA (United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population
Division). 2012. “2012 Revision.” https://population.un.org/wpp/Download/
Archive/Standard/.
———. 2022a. World Population Prospects 2022. https://population.un.org/wpp/.
———. 2022b. Methodology Report: World Population Prospects 2022. https://population.un.org/wpp/Publications/Files/WPP2022_Methodology.pdf.
———. 2023. “India Overtakes China as the World’s Most Populous Country.” Policy
Brief 153. https://www.un.org/development/desa/dpad/publication/
un-desa-policy-brief-no-153-india-overtakes-china-as-the-worlds-most-populous-country.
U.S. Department of the Treasury. 2023. “General Explanations of the Administration’s
Fiscal Year 2024 Revenue Proposals.” https://home.treasury.gov/system/
files/131/General-Explanations-FY2024.pdf.
Valero, A. 2021. Education and Economic Growth. CEP Discussion Paper 1764. London:
Centre for Economic Performance. https://files.eric.ed.gov/fulltext/ED614082.
pdf.
Vespa, J., L. Medina, and D. Armstrong. 2020. “Demographic Turning Points for the
United States: Population Projections for 2020 to 2060.” U.S. Census Bureau.
https://www.census.gov/content/dam/Census/library/publications/2020/demo/
p25-1144.pdf.
WeCount. 2023. “#WeCount Report April 2022 to June 2023.” Society of Family Planning. https://societyfp.org/wp-content/uploads/2023/10/
WeCountReport_10.16.23.pdf.
White, C., J. Cubanski, and T. Neuman. 2014. “How Much of the Medicare Spending
Slowdown Can be Explained? Insights and Analysis from 2014.” Issue Brief,
Kaiser Family Foundation. https://files.kff.org/attachment/
issue-brief-how-much-of-the-medicare-spending-slowdown-can-be-explainedinsights-and-analysis-from-2014.
White House. 2021. “Fact Sheet: Vice President Kamala Harris Announces Call to Action
to Reduce Maternal Mortality and Morbidity.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/
briefing-room/statements-releases/2021/12/07/
fact-sheet-vice-president-kamala-harris-announces-call-to-action-to-reducematernal-mortality-and-morbidity/.
———. 2022a. “Fact Sheet: The Biden Administration’s Historic Investments to Create
Opportunity and Build Wealth in Rural America.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/
briefing-room/statements-releases/2022/03/01/
fact-sheet-the-biden-administrations-historic-investments-to-create-opportunityand-build-wealth-in-rural-america/.
———. 2022b. “National Drug Control Strategy.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/
wp-content/uploads/2022/04/National-Drug-Control-2022Strategy.pdf.
———. 2022c. “Fact Sheet: President Biden to Sign Executive Order Protecting Access
to Reproductive Health Care Services.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/
316 |

References

briefing-room/statements-releases/2022/07/08/
fact-sheet-president-biden-to-sign-executive-order-protecting-access-to-reproductive-health-care-services/.
———. 2022d. “White House Blueprint for Addressing the Maternal Health Crisis.”
https://www.whitehouse.gov/wp-content/uploads/2022/06/Maternal-HealthBlueprint.pdf.
———. 2023a. “Fact Sheet: Biden-Harris Administration Announces Most Sweeping Set
of Executive Actions to Improve Care in History.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/
briefing-room/statements-releases/2023/04/18/
fact-sheet-biden-harris-administration-announces-most-sweeping-set-of-executive-actions-to-improve-care-in-history/.
———. 2023b. “ICYMI: Biden-Harris Administration Announces $450M to Support
President Biden’s Unity Agenda Efforts to Beat the Overdose Epidemic & Save
Lives.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/ondcp/briefing-room/2023/09/01/
icymi-biden-%E2%81%A0harris-administration-announces-450m-to-supportpresident-bidens-unity-agenda-efforts-to-beat-the-overdose-epidemic-save-lives.
———. 2023c. “The President and First Lady’s Cancer Moonshot.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/cancermoonshot/.
———. 2023d. “Fact Sheet: President Joe Biden to Announce First-Ever White House
Initiative on Women’s Health Research, an Effort led by First Lady Jill Biden
and the White House Gender Policy Council.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/
briefing-room/statements-releases/2023/11/13/
fact-sheet-president-joe-biden-to-announce-first-ever-white-house-initiativeon-womens-health-research-an-effort-led-by-first-lady-jill-biden-and-the-whitehouse-gender-policy-council/.
———. 2023e. “Remarks as Prepared for Delivery by First Lady Jill Biden on a Press
Call Announcing White House Initiative on Women’s Health Research.” https://
www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/speeches-remarks/2023/11/13/
remarks-as-prepared-for-delivery-by-first-lady-jill-biden-on-a-press-callannouncing-white-house-initiative-on-womens-health-research/.
———. 2023f. “Fact Sheet: One Year In, President Biden’s Inflation Reduction Act Is
Driving Historic Climate Action and Investing in America to Create Good
Paying Jobs and Reduce Costs.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/
statements-releases/2023/08/16/
fact-sheet-one-year-in-president-bidens-inflation-reduction-act-is-drivinghistoric-climate-action-and-investing-in-america-to-create-good-paying-jobs-and-reduce-costs/.
———. 2023g. “Fact Sheet: President Biden Issues Executive Order on Strengthening
Access to Contraception.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/statements-releases/2023/06/23/
fact-sheet-president-biden-issues-executive-order-on-strengthening-access-tocontraception/.

References | 317

Woodcock, A., G. Carter, J. Baayd, D. Turok, J. Turk, J. Sanders, M. Pangasa, L. Gawron,
and J. Kaiser. 2023. “Effects of the Dobbs v Jackson Women’s Health Organization Decision on Obstetrics and Gynecology Graduating Residents’ Practice
Plans.” Obstetrics & Gynecology 142, no. 5: 1105–11. https://doi.org/10.1097/
AOG.0000000000005383.
Xu, J., S. Murphy, K. Kochanek, and E. Arias. 2022. “Mortality in the United States,
2021.” Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, National Center for Health
Statistics. https://www.cdc.gov/nchs/products/databriefs/db456.htm.

Chapter 4
Aaronson, D., D. Hartley, and B. Mazumder. 2021. “The Effects of the 1930s HOLC
‘Redlining’ Maps.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 13, no. 4:
355–92. https://doi.org/10.1257/pol.20190414.
Aldern, C. and G. Colburn. 2022. Homelessness Is a Housing Problem: How Structural
Factors Explain U.S. Patterns. Berkeley: University of California Press. https://
homelessnesshousingproblem.com/.
Avenancio-Leon, C., and T. Howard. 2022. “The Assessment Gap: Racial Inequalities in
Properly Taxation.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 137, no. 3: 1383–1434.
https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjac009.
Barber, J. 2019. “Berkeley Zoning Has Served for Many Decades to Separate the Poor
from the Rich and Whites from People of Color.” Berkeleyside. https://www.
berkeleyside.org/2019/03/12/
berkeley-zoning-has-served-for-many-decades-to-separate-the-poor-from-therich-and-whites-from-people-of-color.
Baum-Snow, N. 2023. “Constraints on City and Neighborhood Growth: The Central Role
of Housing Supply.” Journal of Economic Perspective 37, no. 2: 53–74. https://
doi.org/10.1257/jep.37.2.53.
Baum-Snow, N., and J. Marion. 2009. “The Effects of Low-Income Housing Tax Credit
Developments on Neighborhoods.” Journal of Public Economics 93: nos. 5–6:
654–66. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2009.01.001.
Bayer, P., F. Ferreira, and S. Ross. 2016. “The Vulnerability of Minority Homeowners in
the Housing Boom and Bust.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy
8, no. 1: 1–27. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/pol.20140074.
Been, V., I. Ellen, and K. O’Regan. 2023. “Supply Skepticism Revisited.” NYU Law and
Economics Research Paper. https://ssrn.com/abstract=4629628.
Been, V., I. Ellen, A. Schwartz, L. Stiefel, and M. Weinstein. 2011. “Does Losing Your
Home Mean Losing Your School? Effects of Foreclosures on the School
Mobility of Children.” Regional Science and Urban Economics 41: 407–14.
https://nyuscholars.nyu.edu/en/publications/
does-losing-your-home-mean-losing-your-school-effects-of-foreclos.

318 |

References

Benioff Homelessness and Housing Initiative. 2023. “Executive Summary of the California Statewide Study of People Experiencing Homelessness.” University of
California, San Francisco. https://homelessness.ucsf.edu/sites/default/
files/2023-06/CASPEH_Executive_Summary_62023.pdf.
Berkeley Economic Review. 2019. “Baby Boomers and the Future of Homeownership in
the United States.” https://econreview.berkeley.edu/
baby-boomers-and-the-future-of-homeownership-in-the-united-states/.
Brasuell, J. 2021. “Charlotte’s New, Controversial Comprehensive Plan to End SingleFamily Zoning.” Planetizen. https://www.planetizen.com/
news/2021/06/113893-charlottes-new-controversial-comprehensive-plan-end-single-family-zoning.
———. 2023. “Vermont Latest State to Preempt Single-Family Zoning.” Planetizen.
https://www.planetizen.com/
news/2023/06/123767-vermont-latest-state-preempt-single-family-zoning.
Bronin, S. 2023. “Zoning by a Thousand Cuts.” 50 Pepperdine Law Review 719. https://
dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3792544.
Bui, Q., M. Chaban, and J. White. 2016. “40 Percent of the Buildings in Manhattan
Could Not Be Built Today.” New York Times, May 20. https://www.nytimes.
com/interactive/2016/05/19/upshot/forty-percent-of-manhattans-buildingscould-not-be-built-today.html.
Byrne, T., E. Munley, J. Fargo, A. Montgomery, and D. Culhane. 2016. “New Perspectives on Community-Level Determinants of Homelessness.” Journal of Urban
Affairs 35, no. 5: 607–25. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9906.2012.00643.
Calanog, V., T. Metcalfe, and K. Fagan. 2023. “The Outlook for the Housing Market.”
Moody’s Analytics, Quarterly Analysis. https://cre.moodysanalytics.com/
insights/research/q42022-the-outlook-for-the-housing-market/.
California Department of Housing and Community Development. 2023. “Regional
Housing Needs Allocation (RHNA).” https://www.hcd.ca.gov/planning-andcommunity-development/regional-housing-needs-allocation.
Card, D., J. Rothstein, and M. Yi. 2023. Location, Location, Location. NBER Working
Paper 31587. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://
doi.org/10.3386/w31587.
Carroll, D., and R. Cohen-Kristiansen. 2021. “Evaluating Homeownership as the Solution
to Wealth Inequality.” Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, “Economic
Commentary.” https://www.clevelandfed.org/publications/economic-commentary/2021/
ec-202122-evaluating-homeownership-as-the-solution-to-wealth-inequality.
CBRE (Coldwell Banker Richard Ellis). 2022. “2022 U.S. Construction Cost Trends.”
https://www.cbre.com/insights/books/2022-us-construction-costtrends#:~:text=CBRE%27s%20new%20Construction%20Cost%20
Index,material%20costs%20continue%20to%20rise.

References | 319

CEA (Council of Economic Advisers). 2021. “Exclusionary Zoning: Its Effect on Racial
Discrimination in the Housing Market.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/cea/
written-materials/2021/06/17/
exclusionary-zoning-its-effect-on-racial-discrimination-in-the-housing-market/.
———. 2023a. “An Update on Housing Inflation in the Consumer Price Index.” https://
www.whitehouse.gov/cea/written-materials/2023/04/27/
update-on-housing-inflation-in-cpi/.
———. 2023b. “The Anti-Poverty and Income-Boosting Impacts of the Enhanced CTC.”
https://www.whitehouse.gov/cea/written-materials/2023/11/20/
the-anti-poverty-and-income-boosting-impacts-of-the-enhanced-ctc/.
CFPB (Consumer Financial Protection Bureau). 2021. “Manufactured Housing Finance:
New Insights from the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act Data.” https://files.
consumerfinance.gov/f/documents/cfpb_manufactured-housing-finance-newinsights-hmda_report_2021-05.pdf.
Chester, M., et al. 2015. “Parking Infrastructure: A Constraint on or Opportunity for
Urban Redevelopment? A Study of Los Angeles County Parking Supply and
Growth.” https://www.tandfonline.com/doi/full/10.1080/01944363.2015.10928
79.
Chetty, R., and N. Hendren. 2018. “The Impacts of Neighborhoods on Intergenerational
Mobility I: Childhood Exposure Effects.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 133,
no. 3: 1107–62. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjy007.
Chetty, R., N. Hendren, and L. Katz. 2016. “The Effects of Exposure to Better Neighborhoods on Children: New Evidence from the Moving to Opportunity
Experiment.” American Economic Review 106, no. 4: 855–902. https://doi.
org/10.1257/aer.20150572.
Choi, J., J. Zhu, and L. Goodman. 2018. “Is Homeownership Inherited? A Tale of Three
Millennials.” Urban Institute. https://www.urban.org/urban-wire/
homeownership-inherited-tale-three-millennials.
Chyn, E., and L. Katz. 2021. “Neighborhoods Matter: Assessing the Evidence for Place
Effects.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 35, no. 4: 197–222. https://doi.
org/10.1257/jep.35.4.197.
Code of Federal Regulations. 2023. “Title 24: Housing and Urban Development.” https://
www.ecfr.gov/current/title-24/subtitle-B/chapter-XX.
Collinson, R., J. Humphries, N. Mader, D. Reed, D. Tannenbaum, and W. Dijk. 2023.
Eviction and Poverty in American Cities. NBER Working Paper 30382.
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://www.nber.org/
papers/w30382.
Commonwealth of Massachusetts. 2023. “Multi-Family Zoning Requirement for MBTA
Communities.” Executive Office of Housing and Livable Communities. https://
www.mass.gov/info-details/
multi-family-zoning-requirement-for-mbta-communities.

320 |

References

Center on Budget and Policy Priorities. 2017. “United States Housing Choice Vouchers
Fact Sheet.” https://www.cbpp.org/sites/default/files/atoms/
files/3-10-14hous-factsheets_us.pdf.
Cornelissen, S., and L. Pack. 2023. “Immigrants’ Access to Homeownership in the United
States: A Review of Barriers, Discrimination, and Opportunities.” Joint Center
for Housing Studies at Harvard University. https://www.jchs.harvard.edu/sites/
default/files/research/files/harvard_jchs_immigrant_homeownership_cornelissen_pack_2023.pdf.
Cromwell, M. 2022. “Housing Costs a Big Burden on Renters in Largest U.S. Counties.”
U.S. Census Bureau, America Counts. https://www.census.gov/library/
stories/2022/12/housing-costs-burden.html.
CRS (Congressional Research Service). 2021. “An Overview of the HOME Investment
Partnerships Program.” https://sgp.fas.org/crs/misc/R40118.pdf.
Crump, S., T. Mattos, J. Schuetz, and L. Schuster. 2020. “Fixing Greater Boston’s
Housing Crisis Starts with Legalizing Apartments Near Transit.” Brookings
Institution. https://www.brookings.edu/articles/
fixing-greater-bostons-housing-crisis-starts-with-legalizing-apartments-neartransit/.
DBRS Morningstar. 2023. “DBRS Morningstar CMBS Monthly Highlights—June Remittance: Delinquency and Special Servicing Rates Move Higher on Continued
Office Underperformance.” https://www.dbrsmorningstar.com/research/417134.
Derenoncourt, E., C. Kim, M. Kuhn, and M. Schularick. 2023. “Wealth of Two Nations:
The U.S. Racial Wealth Gap, 1860–2020.” Quarterly Journal of Economics.
https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjad044.
Desegregate Connecticut. No date. “FAQS.” https://www.desegregatect.org/faqs.
Diamond, R., A. Guren, and R. Tan. 2020. The Effect of Foreclosures on Homeowners,
Tenants, and Landlords. NBER Working Paper 27358. Cambridge, MA:
National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w27358.
Diamond, R., and T. McQuade. 2019. “Who Wants Affordable Housing in Their Backyard? An Equilibrium Analysis of Low-Income Property Development.”
Journal of Political Economy 3: 1063–1117. https://doi.org/10.1086/701354.
Diamond, R., T. McQuade, and F. Qian. 2018. The Effects of Rent Control Expansion on
Tenants, Landlords, and Inequality: Evidence from San Francisco. NBER
Working Paper 24181. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
Research. https://www.nber.org/system/files/working_papers/w24181/w24181.
pdf.
Dietrich, E. 2023. “Homeowner Group Files Court Challenge Against Pro-Construction
Housing Laws.” Montana Free Press. https://montanafreepress.org/2023/12/15/
homeowner-group-files-court-challenge-against-pro-construction-housing-laws/.
DiSalvo, R., and J. Yu. 2023. “Housing Affordability and School Quality in the United
States.” Journal of Housing Economics 60. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
jhe.2023.101933.
References | 321

DOT (U.S. Department of Transportation). 2023. “Reconnecting Communities and
Neighborhoods Grant Program.” https://www.transportation.gov/grants/
rcnprogram.
Eriksen, M., and S. Rosenthal. 2010. “Crowd Out Effects of Place-Based Subsidized
Rental Housing: New Evidence from the LIHTC Program.” Journal of Public
Economics 94, nos. 11–12: 953–66. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
jpubeco.2010.07.002.
Fang, L., N. Stewart, and J. Tyndall. 2023. “Homeowner Politics and Housing Supply.”
Journal of Urban Economics 138. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jue.2023.103608.
FHFA (Federal Housing Finance Agency). 2022. “Duty to Serve Underserved Markets
Plan.” https://sf.freddiemac.com/docs/pdf/marketing-materials/freddie-macunderserved-markets-plan.pdf.
Fischel, W. 2001. The Homevoter Hypothesis: How Home Values Influence Local
Government Taxation, School Finance, and Land-Use Policies. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press. https://www.hup.harvard.edu/catalog.
php?isbn=9780674015951.
———. 2004. “An Economic History of Zoning and a Cure for Its Exclusionary Effects.”
Urban Studies 41. https://doi.org/10.1080/0042098032000165271.
Flint, A. 2022, “The State of Local Zoning: Reforming a Century-Old Approach to Land
Use.” Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. https://www.lincolninst.edu/publications/articles/2022-12-state-local-zoning-reform.
Frank, T. 2021. “End to Single-Family Zoning in Berkeley Forces Us to Reflect on Our
Past.” Sierra Club, San Francisco Bay, blog. https://www.sierraclub.org/sanfrancisco-bay/blog/2021/06/
end-single-family-zoning-berkeley-forces-us-reflect-our-past.
Francke, M., and M. Korevaar. 2022. “Baby Booms and Asset Booms: Demographic
Change and the Housing Market.” Working paper, SSRN. https://dx.doi.
org/10.2139/ssrn.3368036.
Freddie Mac. 2022. “Could More Inclusive Zoning for Manufactured Homes Help
Address the Current Housing Supply Gap?” Single-Family Division. https://
sf.freddiemac.com/articles/insights/
could-more-inclusive-zoning-for-manufactured-homes-help-address-the-currenthousing-supply-gap.
———. No date. “Manufactured Housing.” Single-Family Division. https://sf.freddiemac.
com/working-with-us/affordable-lending/duty-to-serve/manufactured-housing.
Freedman, M., and E. Owens. 2011. “Low-Income Housing Development and Crime.”
Journal of Urban Economics 70, nos. 2–3: 115–31. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
jue.2011.04.001.
FTA (Federal Transit Administration). 2023. “Areas of Persistent Poverty Program.”
https://www.transit.dot.gov/grant-programs/areas-persistent-poverty-program.

322 |

References

Furth, S., and N. Gray. 2019. “Do Minimum-Lot-Size Regulation Limit Housing Supply
in Texas?’ Mercatus Center at George Mason University. https://www.mercatus.
org/publications/urban-economics/
do-minimum-lot-size-regulations-limit-housing-supply-texas.
Furth, S., and M. Webster. 2022. “Single-Family Zoning and Race: Evidence from the
Twin Cities.” Working paper, Mercatus Center at George Mason University.
https://www.mercatus.org/research/working-papers/
single-family-zoning-and-race-evidence-twin-cities.
Gabbe, C., G. Pierce, and G. Clowers. 2020. “Parking Policy: The Effects of Residential
Minimum Parking Requirements in Seattle.” Land Use Policy 91: 104053.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2019.104053.
Ganong, P., and D. Shoag. 2017. “Why Has Regional Income Convergence in the U.S.
Declined?” Journal of Urban Economics 102: 76–90. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
jue.2017.07.002.
Garcia, D. 2019. “Making It Pencil: The Math Behind Housing Development.” UC
Berkeley Terner Center for Housing Innovation. https://ternercenter.berkeley.
edu/wp-content/uploads/pdfs/Making_It_Pencil_The_Math_Behind_Housing_
Development.pdf.
Garcia, D., et al. 2022. “Unlocking the Potential of Missing Middle Housing.” Terner
Center at UC Berkeley. https://ternercenter.berkeley.edu/wp-content/
uploads/2022/12/Missing-Middle-Brief-December-2022.pdf.
Gensheimer, S., M. Eisenberg, D. Hindman, A. Wu, and C. Pollack. 2022. “Examining
Health Care Access and Health of Children Living in Homes Subsidized by the
Low-Income Housing Tax Credit.” Health Affairs 41, no. 6: 883–92. https://doi.
org/10.1377/hlthaff.2021.01806.
Gerardi, K., L. Lambie-Hanson, and P. Willien. 2021. “Racial Differences in Mortgage
Refinancing, Distress, and Housing Wealth Accumulation during COVID-19.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, “Current Policy Perspectives.” https://www.
bostonfed.org/publications/current-policy-perspectives/2021/racial-differencesin-mortgage-refinancing-distress-and-housing-wealth-accumulation-duringcovid-19.aspx.
Glaeser, E., J. Gyourko, and R. Saks. 2005. “Why Have Housing Prices Gone Up?”
American Economic Review 95, no. 2: 329–33. https://doi.
org/10.1257/000282805774669961.
Gong, Y., and Y. Yao. 2022. “Demographic Changes and the Housing Market.” Regional
Science and Urban Economics 95. https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/
article/abs/pii/S0166046221000946
Goodman, L., J. Choi, and J. Zhu. 2023. “The ‘Real’ Homeownership Gap between
Today’s Young Adults and Past Generations Is Much Larger Thank You Think.”
Urban Institute, Urban Wire. https://www.urban.org/urban-wire/
real-homeownership-gap-between-todays-young-adults-and-past-generationsmuch-larger-you.

References | 323

Goodman, L., and B. Ganesh. 2018. “Challenges to Obtaining Manufactured Home
Financing.” Urban Institute. https://www.urban.org/sites/default/files/publication/98687/challenges_to_obtaining_manufactured_home_financing_0.pdf.
Goolsbee, A., and C. Syverson. The Strange and Awful Path of Productivity in the U.S.
Construction Sector. NBER Working Paper 30845. Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w30845.
Gould Ellen, I. 2018. “What Do We Know About Housing Choice Vouchers?” NYU
Furman Center. https://furmancenter.org/files/fact-sheets/HousingChoiceVouchers_ige.pdf.
Gould Ellen, I., J. De la Roca, and J. Steil. 2015. “Black and Latino Segregation and
Socioeconomic Outcomes.” NYU Furman Center Research Brief. https://
furmancenter.org/research/publication/
black-and-latino-segregation-and-socioeconomic-outcomes.
Grabar, H. 2018. “Minneapolis Confronts Its History of Housing Segregation.” Slate,
December 7. https://slate.com/business/2018/12/minneapolis-single-familyzoning-housing-racism.html.
Graetz, N., C. Gershenson, P. Hepburn, S. Porter, D. Sandler, and M. Desmond. 2023. “A
Comprehensive Demographic Profile of the U.S. Evicted Population.” 2023.
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 120, no. 41: e2305860120.
https://www.pnas.org/doi/10.1073/pnas.2305860120.
Gray, M. 2022. Arbitrary Lines: How Zoning Broke the American City and How to Fix It.
Washington: Island Press. https://www.theatlantic.com/ideas/archive/2022/10/
california-accessory-dwelling-units-legalization-yimby/671648/.
Greenaway-McGrevy, R. 2023. Can Zoning Reform Reduce Housing Costs? Evidence
from Rents in Auckland. Economic Policy Centre Working Paper 016. Auckland: University of Aukland Business School. https://cdn.auckland.ac.nz/assets/
business/about/our-research/research-institutes-and-centres/Economic-PolicyCentre--EPC-/WP016.pdf.
Greene, S., and J. González-Hermoso. 2019. “How Communities Are Rethinking Zoning
to Improve Housing Affordability and Access to Opportunity.” Urban Institute,
Urban Wire. https://www.urban.org/urban-wire/how-communities-arerethinking-z.oning-improve-housing-affordability-and-access-opportunity.
Gries, J. 1922. “A Zoning Primer by the Advisory Committee on Zoning.” U.S. Department of Commerce. https://www.govinfo.gov/content/pkg/
GOVPUB-C13-cf208d8ed0dda43ed677acd6cad8be81/pdf/GOVPUBC13-cf208d8ed0dda43ed677acd6cad8be81.pdf.
Gupta, A., C. Martinez, and S. Van Nieuwerburgh. 2023. Converting Brown Offices to
Green Apartments. NBER Working Paper 31530. Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau of Economic Research. http://www.nber.org/papers/w31530.
Gutman, A. 2023. “WA House Passes Bill Banning Single-Family Zoning.” Seattle Times,
March 7. https://www.seattletimes.com/seattle-news/politics/
wa-house-passes-bill-banning-single-family-zoning/.

324 |

References

Gyourko, J., J. Hartley, and J. Krimmel. 2019. The Local Residential Land Use Regulatory Environment Across U.S. Housing Markets: Evidence from a New Wharton
Index. NBER Working Paper 26573. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of
Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w26573.
Gyourko, J., and S. McCulloch. 2023. Minimum Lot Size Restrictions: Impacts on Urban
Form and House Price at the Border. NBER Working Paper 31710. Cambridge,
MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://www.nber.org/papers/
w31710.
Gyourko, J., and R. Molloy. 2015. “Regulation and Housing Supply.” In Handbook of
Regional and Urban Economics, ed. G. Duranton, J. Vernon Henderson, and W.
Strange. Oxford: Elsevier. https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/abs/pii/
B9780444595317000193.
Hermann, A., S. Wedeen, W. Airgood-Obrycki, and C. Herbert. 2023. “The Geography of
Renter Financial Distress and Housing Insecurity During the Pandemic.” Joint
Center for Housing Studies of Harvard University. https://www.jchs.harvard.
edu/research-areas/working-papers/
geography-renter-financial-distress-and-housing-insecurity-during.
Hilber, C., and F. Robert-Nicoud. 2014. “On the Origins of Land Use Regulations:
Theory and Evidence from U.S. Metro Areas.” Journal of Urban Economics
75, no. 1. https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/abs/pii/
S0094119012000666.
Howells, R. 2022. “The History of Zoning Laws in America.” Politically Speaking,
February 8. https://medium.com/politically-speaking/
the-history-of-zoning-laws-in-america-9babd157bc29.
Hoyt, H., and J. Schuetz. 2020. “Flexible Zoning and Streamlined Procedures Can Make
Housing More Affordable.” https://www.jchs.harvard.edu/blog/
flexible-zoning-and-streamlined-procedures-can-make-housing-more-affordable.
Hsieh, C., and E. Moretti. 2019. “Housing Constraints and Spatial Misallocation.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 11, no. 2: 1–39. https://doi.
org/10.1257/mac.20170388.
HUD (U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development). 2021. “Tenants in LIHTC
Units as of December 31, 2021.” https://www.huduser.gov/portal/Datasets/
lihtc/2021-LIHTC-Tenant-Tables.pdf.
———. 2022. “CDBG Activity Expenditure Reports.” Community Development Block
Grant Programs. https://view.officeapps.live.com/op/view.
aspx?src=https%3A%2F%2Ffiles.hudexchange.info%2Fresources%2Fdocumen
ts%2FCDBG_Expend_NatlAll.xlsx&wdOrigin=BROWSELINK.
———. 2023a. “HUD Announces New Proposed ‘Affirmatively Furthering Fair
Housing’ Rule, Taking a Major Step Towards Rooting Out Long-Standing Inequities in Housing and Fostering Inclusive Communities.” https://www.hud.gov/
press/press_releases_media_advisories/HUD_No_23_013.

References | 325

———. 2023b. “Pathways to Removing Obstacles to Housing (PRO Housing).” https://
www.hud.gov/program_offices/comm_planning/pro_housing.
———. 2023c. “HOME Program Funding, Commitments, and Disbursements.” Office of
Community Planning and Development. https://files.hudexchange.info/reports/
published/HOME_Prod_Natl_20230831.pdf.
———. 2023d. “Housing Choice Vouchers Fact Sheet.” https://www.hud.gov/topics/
housing_choice_voucher_program_section_8.
———. 2023e. “Low-Income Housing Tax Credit (LIHTC): Property-Level Data.”
Office of Policy Development and Research. https://www.huduser.gov/portal/
datasets/lihtc/property.html.
———. 2023f. “The Office of Manufactured Housing Programs.” https://www.hud.gov/
program_offices/housing/mhs.
———. 2023g. “HUD Takes Action to Highlight and Research Land Use and Zoning
Reforms.” https://www.hud.gov/press/press_releases_media_advisories/
hud_no_23_072.
———. 2023h. “Notice CPD-2023-10.” https://www.hud.gov/sites/dfiles/OCHCO/
documents/2023-10cpdn.pdf.
———. 2023i. “Tenant-Based Rental Assistance.” https://www.hud.gov/sites/dfiles/CFO/
documents/2024_CJ_Program_Template_-_TBRA.pdf.
———. 2023j. “FY 2023 Increasing the Supply of Affordable Housing through Off-Site
Construction and Pro-Housing Reforms Research Grant Program Pre and Full
Application NOFO.” https://www.hud.gov/program_offices/spm/gmomgmt/
grantsinfo/fundingopps/fy2023_increasing.
———. 2024a. “HUD 2024 Congressional Justifications.” https://www.hud.gov/sites/
dfiles/CFO/documents/2024-HUD-Congressional-Justifications.pdf.
———. 2024b. “Mandatory Affordable Housing Programs.” https://www.hud.gov/sites/
dfiles/CFO/documents/2024_Mandatory_Affordable_Housing_Programs.pdf
Ihlanfeldt, K. 2019. “The Deconcentration of Minority Students Attending Bad Schools:
The Role of Housing Affordability within School Attendance Zones Containing
Good Schools.” Journal of Housing Economics 43: 83–101. https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/abs/pii/S1051137718300718.
Internal Revenue Service. 2022. “Section 42, Low-Income Housing Credit Average
Income Test Regulations.” 87 FR 61489. https://www.federalregister.gov/documents/2022/10/12/2022-22070/
section-42-low-income-housing-credit-average-income-test-regulations.
Joint Center for Housing Studies. 2023. “The State of the Nation’s Housing 2023.”
https://www.jchs.harvard.edu/sites/default/files/reports/files/Harvard_JCHS_
The_State_of_the_Nations_Housing_2023.pdf.
JPMorgan Chase. 2022. “Cap Rates, Explained.” https://www.jpmorgan.com/insights/
real-estate/commercial-term-lending/cap-rates-explained.

326 |

References

Kahlenberg, R. 2023. Excluded: How Snob Zoning, NIMBYism, and Class Bias Build the
Walls We Don’t See. New York: PublicAffairs. https://www.hachettebookgroup.
com/titles/richard-d-kahlenberg/excluded/9781541701465/?lens=publicaffairs.
Kaufmann, J. 2023. “Downtown Chicago Is a Downer for Drivers.” Axios Chicago.
https://www.axios.com/local/chicago/2023/04/21/chicago-downtown-parking.
Khater, S., L. Kiefer, and V. Yanamandra. 2021.“Housing Supply: A Growing Deficit.”
2021. Freddie Mac, Research Note. https://www.freddiemac.com/research/
insight/20210507-housing-supply.
Khouri, A. 2022. “California Bans Mandated Parking Near Transit to Fight High Housing
Prices, Climate Change.” Los Angeles Times, September 23. https://www.
latimes.com/california/story/2022-09-23/
newsom-bill-banning-parking-requirement-transit-housing-climate-change.
Kiefer, L., A. Atreya, and V. Yanamandra. 2018. “Why Is Adulting Getting Harder?
Young Adults and Household Formation.” Freddie Mac, Insight. https://www.
freddiemac.com/research/insight/20180316-adulting.
Kimura, D. 2022. “Steady LIHTC Pricing Expected for First Half of 2022.” Affordable
Housing Finance, March 7. https://www.housingfinance.com/finance/
steady-lihtc-pricing-expected-for-first-half-of-2022_o.
La Cava, G. 2016. “Housing Prices, Mortgage Interest Rates and the Rising Share of
Capital Income in the United States.” BIS Working Paper 572. Bank for International Settlements. https://ssrn.com/abstract=2814142.
Landis, J., and V. Reina. 2021. “Do Restrictive Land Use Regulations Make Housing
More Expensive Everywhere?” Economic Development Quarterly 35, no. 4:
305–24. https://doi.org/10.1177/08912424211043500.
Layton, D. 2023. “Manufactured Housing Is a Good Source of Unsubsidized Affordable
Housing—Except When It’s Not: High-Level and Specific Policy Recommendations (Part 3).” NYU Furman Center, The Stoop. https://furmancenter.org/
thestoop/entry/
manufactured-housing-is-a-good-source-of-unsubsidized-affordable-housingexcept-when-its-not-high-level-and-specific-policy-recommendations-part-3.
Lee, Y., P. Kemp, and V. Reina. 2022. “Divers of Housing (Un)affordability in the
Advanced Economies: A Review and New Evidence.” Housing Studies 37, no.
10: 1739–52. https://doi.org/10.1080/02673037.2022.2123623.
Leung, J. 2018. “Decarbonizing U.S. Buildings.” Center for Climate and Energy Solutions. https://www.c2es.org/wp-content/uploads/2018/06/
innovation-buildings-background-brief-07-18.pdf.
Loh, T., C. Coes, and B. Buthe. 2020. “Separate and Unequal: Persistent Residential
Segregation Is Sustaining Racial and Economic Injustice in the U.S.” Brookings. https://www.brookings.edu/articles/
trend-1-separate-and-unequal-neighborhoods-are-sustaining-racial-andeconomic-injustice-in-the-us/.

References | 327

Mangin, J. 2014. “The New Exclusionary Zoning.” Stanford Law & Policy Review 25.
https://law.stanford.edu/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/mangin_25_stan._l._poly_
rev_91.pdf.
Martin, C. 2022. “The Inflation Reduction Act Will Reduce Household Energy Insecurity—but It Could Do More.” Metropolitan Policy Program at Brookings.
https://www.brookings.edu/articles/
the-inflation-reduction-act-will-reduce-household-energy-insecurity-but-itcould-do-more/.
Merchant, C. 2016. “A Zoning Change in Fairfax Will Allow More Density.” Greater
Greater Washington, June 29. https://ggwash.org/
view/41968/a-zoning-change-in-fairfax-will-allow-more-density.
Mischke, J., et al. 2023. “Empty Spaces and Hybrid Places: The Pandemic’s Lasting
Impact on Real Estate.” McKinsey Global Institute. https://www.mckinsey.com/
mgi/our-research/empty-spaces-and-hybrid-places/.
Moretti, E. 2012. The New Geography of Jobs. New York: Liveright / Houghton Mifflin
Harcourt. https://books.google.com/books/about/The_New_Geography_of_
Jobs.html?id=br0S54w0u_sC.
Nguyen, M. 2015. “The Intersection of Immigration and Housing Policies: Implications
for the U.S. Housing Market and Economy,” Housing Policy Debate 25:
796–98. https://doi.org/10.1080/10511482.2015.1043084.
Office of Policy Development and Research. 2023. Policy & Practice. U.S. Department
of Housing and Urban Development. https://www.huduser.gov/Portal/Policyand-Practice.html.
Ortalo-Magne, F., and A. Prat. 2014. “On the Political Economy of Urban Growth:
Homeownership versus Affordability.” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 6, no. 1: 410–42. https://www.jstor.org/stable/43189657.
Parking Reform Network. No date. “Mandates Map.” https://parkingreform.org/resources/
mandates-map/.
Parrott, J., and M. Zandi. 2021. “Overcoming the Nation’s Daunting Housing Supply
Shortage.” Urban Institute. https://www.urban.org/sites/default/files/publication/103940/overcoming-the-nations-daunting-housing-supply-shortage_0.pdf.
Peri, G. 2012. “The Effect of Immigration on Productivity: Evidence from U.S. States.”
Review of Economics and Statistics 94, no. 1: 348–58. http://www.jstor.org/
stable/41349180.
Pilkauskas, N., K. Michelmore, and N. Kovski. 2023. The 2021 Child Tax Credit, the
Living Arrangements and Housing Affordability of Families with Low Incomes.
NBER Working Paper 31339. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w31339.
Poon, L. 2017. ‘Buffalo Becomes First City to Bid Minimum Parking Goodbye.” Bloomberg. https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2017-01-09/
buffalo-is-the-first-to-abandon-minimum-parking-requirements-citywide.

328 |

References

RCN Capital. No date. “Multifamily and Commercial Real Estate Loan Ratios.” https://
rcncapital.com/blog/multifamily-and-commercial-real-estate-loan-ratios.
Reid, C., D. Bocian, W. Li, and R. Quercia. 2016. “Revisiting the Subprime Crisis: The
Dual Mortgage Market and Mortgage Defaults by Race and Ethnicity.” Journal
of Urban Affairs. https://www.tandfonline.com/doi/full/10.1080/07352166.2016
.1255529?scroll=top&needAccess=true.
Reina, V., and C. Aiken. 2022. “Moving to Opportunity, or Aging in Place? The Changing
Profile of Low-Income and Subsidized Households and Where They Live.”
Urban Affairs Review 58, no. 2: 454–92. https://doi.
org/10.1177/1078087420969895.
Resseger, M. 2022. “The Impact of Land Use Regulation on Racial Segregation:
Evidence from Massachusetts Zoning Borders.” Working paper, Mercatus
Center at George Mason University. https://www.mercatus.org/research/
working-papers/
impact-land-use-regulation-racial-segregation-evidence-massachusetts-zoning.
Rigsby, E. 2016. “Understanding Exclusionary Zoning and Its Impact on Concentrated
Poverty.” Century Foundation. https://tcf.org/content/facts/
understanding-exclusionary-zoning-impact-concentrated-poverty/?agreed=1.
Rothstein, R. 2014. “The Making of Ferguson: Public Policies at the Root of its Troubles.” Economic Policy Institute. https://files.epi.org/2014/
making-of-ferguson-final.pdf.
———. 2017. The Color of Law: A Forgotten History of How Our Government Segregated America. New York: Liveright. https://www.epi.org/publication/
the-color-of-law-a-forgotten-history-of-how-our-government-segregatedamerica/.
Rothwell, J. 2012. “Housing Costs, Zoning, and Access to High Scoring School.” Metropolitan Policy Program at Brookings. https://www.brookings.edu/articles/
housing-costs-zoning-and-access-to-high-scoring-schools/.
Ruggles, S., S. Flood, S. Sobek, D. Backman, A. Chen, G. Cooper, S. Richards, R.
Rogers, and M. Schouweiler. 2023. IPUMS USA: Version 14.0. Data set,
Minneapolis. https://doi.org/10.18128/D010.V14.0.
Shanahan, M., A. Austin, C. Durrance, S. Martin, J. Mercer, D. Runyan, and C. Runyan.
2022. “The Association of Low-Income Housing Tax Credit Units and Reports
of Child Abuse and Neglect.” American Journal of Preventive Medicine 62, no.
5: 727–34. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.amepre.2021.11.020.
Shoup, D. 2014. “The High Cost of Minimum Parking Requirements.” Parking Issues
and Policies 5: 87–113. https://www.emerald.com/insight/content/doi/10.1108/
S2044-994120140000005011./full/html.
Skelton, G. 2021. “Don’t Be Fooled: California’s New Housing Laws Make Significant
Changes to Zoning.” Los Angeles Times. https://www.latimes.com/california/
story/2021-09-22/skelton-sb9-housing-single-family-zoning.

References | 329

SMPDC (Southern Maine Planning and Development Commission). 2023. “Housing
Legislation LD 2003.” https://smpdc.org/ld2003.
Song, J. 2021. “The Effects of Residential Zoning in U.S. Housing Markets.” SSRN.
https://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3996483.
Sorens, J. 2023. “Abolish Parking Minimums. Yes, All of Them.” American Institute for
Economic Research, Daily Economy. http://www.aier.org/article/
abolish-parking-minimums-yes-all-of-them/.
Sorokin, O. 2023. “Office Vacancy Rates in 2022.” National Association of Realtors,
Economists’ Outlook. https://www.nar.realtor/blogs/economists-outlook/
office-vacancy-rates-in-2022.
Stacy, C., C. Davis, Y. Freemark, L. Lo, G. MacDonald, V. Zheng, and R. Pendall. 2023.
“Land-Use Reforms and Housing Costs: Does Allowing for Increased Density
Lead to Greater Affordability?” Urban Institute. https://www.urban.org/
research/publication/land-use-reforms-and-housing-costs.
State of Montana Governor’s Office. 2023. “Governor Gianforte Announces Bold, Transformational Pro-Housing Zoning Reform.” https://news.mt.gov/
Governors-Office/
Governor_Gianforte_Announces_Bold_Transformational_Pro-Housing_
Zoning_Reform.
Supreme Court of the United States. 1926. Village of Euclid v. Ambler Realty Co., 272
U.S. 365. https://supreme.justia.com/cases/federal/us/272/365/.
Tax Policy Center. No date. “Briefing Book.” https://www.taxpolicycenter.org/briefingbook/what-low-income-housing-tax-credit-and-how-does-it-work.
Taylor, L. 2018. “Housing and Health: An Overview of the Literature.” Health Affairs.
https://www.healthaffairs.org/do/10.1377/hpb20180313.396577/.
Tiebout, C. 1956. “A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures.” Journal of Political Economy
64. https://www.journals.uchicago.edu/doi/10.1086/257839.
Twinam, T. 2018. “The Long-Run Impact of Zoning: Institutional Hysteresis and Durable
Capital in Seattle, 1920–2015.” Regional Science and Urban Economics 73:
155–69. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.regsciurbeco.2018.08.004.
Urban Institute. 2016. “The Cost of Affordable Housing: Does It Pencil Out?” https://
apps.urban.org/features/cost-of-affordable-housing/.
U.S. Census Bureau. 2023. “Homeownership Rate in the United States
[RHORUSQ156N].” FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of Saint Louis. https://fred.
stlouisfed.org/series/RHORUSQ156N.
USDA (U.S. Department of Agriculture). 2024. “2024 USDA Explanatory Notes, Rural
Housing Service.” https://www.usda.gov/sites/default/files/documents/322024-RHS.pdf.
U.S. Department of the Interior. 2020. “Annual Report on the Economic Impact of the
Federal Historic Tax Credits for Fiscal Year 2020.” National Park Service,

330 |

References

Technical Preservation Services. https://www.nps.gov/subjects/taxincentives/
upload/report-2020-economic-impact.pdf.
———. 2021. “Annual Report on the Economic Impact of the Federal Historic Tax
Credits for Fiscal Year 2021.” National Park Service, Technical Preservation
Services. https://www.nps.gov/subjects/taxincentives/upload/report-2021-economic-impact.pdf.
———. 2022. “Federal Tax Incentives for Rehabilitating Historic Buildings: Annual
Report for Fiscal Year 2022.” National Park Service, Technical Preservation
Services. https://www.nps.gov/subjects/taxincentives/upload/report-2022annual.pdf.
U.S. Department of the Treasury. 2023a. “General Explanations of the Administration’s
Fiscal Year 2024 Revenue Proposals.” https://home.treasury.gov/system/
files/131/General-Explanations-FY2024.pdf.
———. 2023b. “Tax Expenditures FY2024 Update.” https://home.treasury.gov/system/
files/131/Tax-Expenditures-FY2024-update.pdf.
Voith, R., J. Liu, S. Zielenbach, A. Jakabovics, B. An, S. Rodnyansky, A. Orlando, and R.
Bostic. 2022. “Effects of Concentrated LIHTC Development on Surrounding
House Prices.” Journal of Housing Economics 56: 101838. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.jhe.2022.101838.
Wamsley, L. 2024. “From Austin to Anchorage, U.S. Cities Opt to Ditch Their Off-Street
Parking Minimums.” NPR. https://www.npr.
org/2024/01/02/1221366173/u-s-cities-drop-parking-space-minimums-development.
WGI. 2021. “Parking Structure Cost Outlook for 2021.” https://publications.wginc.com/
parking-structure-construction-cost-outlook-2021.
White House. 2022. “President Biden Announces New Actions to Ease the Burden of
Housing Costs.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/statementsreleases/2022/05/16/
president-biden-announces-new-actions-to-ease-the-burden-of-housing-costs/.
———. 2023a. “Biden-Harris Administration Announces Actions to Lower Housing
Costs and Boost Supply.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/statements-releases/2023/07/27/
biden-harris-administration-announces-actions-to-lower-housing-costs-andboost-supply/.
———. 2023b. “Fact Sheet: Biden-Harris Administration Takes Action to Create More
Affordable Housing by Converting Commercial Properties to Residential Use.”
https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/statements-releases/2023/10/27/
fact-sheet-biden-harris-administration-takes-action-to-create-more-affordablehousing-by-converting-commercial-properties-to-residential-use/.
———. 2023c. “Fact Sheet: President Biden’s Budget Lowers Housing Costs and
Expands Access to Affordable Rent and Home Ownership.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/briefing-room/2023/03/09/

References | 331

fact-sheet-president-bidens-budget-lowers-housing-costs-and-expands-accessto-affordable-rent-and-home-ownership/.
———. 2023d. “White House Announces New Actions on Homeownership.” https://
www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/statements-releases/2023/10/16/
white-house-announces-new-actions-on-homeownership/.
Wolff, E. 2022. Heterogenous Rates of Return on Homes and Other Real Estate: Do the
Rich Do Better? Do Black Households Do Worse? NBER Working Paper
30543. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.
org/10.3386/w30543.

Chapter 5
Abbott, T., R. McGuckin, P. Herrick, and L. Norfolk. 1989. “Measuring the Trade
Balance in Advanced Technology Products.” Working paper, Center for
Economic Studies. https://www2.census.gov/ces/wp/1989/CES-WP-89-01.pdf.
Aiyar, S., J. Chen, C. Ebeke, R. Garcia-Saltos, T. Gudmundsson, A. Ilyina, A. Kangur, T.
Kunaratskul, S. Rodriguez, M. Ruta, T. Schulze, G. Soderberg, and J. Trevino.
2023. “Geoeconomic Fragmentation and the Future of Multilateralism.” https://
www.imf.org/en/Publications/Staff-Discussion-Notes/Issues/2023/01/11/
Geo-Economic-Fragmentation-and-the-Future-of-Multilateralism-527266.
Aiyar, S., and A. Ilyina. 2023. “Charting Globalization’s Turn to Slowbalization After
Financial Crisis.” https://www.imf.org/en/Blogs/Articles/2023/02/08/
charting-globalizations-turn-to-slowbalization-after-global-financial-crisis.
Alfaro, L., and D. Chor. 2023. Global Supply Chains: The Looming “Great Reallocation.” NBER Working Paper 31661. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of
Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w31661.
Amiti, M., M. Dai, R. Feenstra, and J. Romalis. 2020. “How Did China’s WTO Entry
Affect U.S. Prices?” Journal of International Economics 126. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2020.103339.
Antràs, P., T. Fort, and F. Tintelnot. 2017. “The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and
Evidence from U.S. Firms.” American Economic Review 107, no. 9: 2514–64.
https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20141685.
Autor, D., D. Dorn, and G. Hanson. 2013. “The China Syndrome: Local Labor Market
Effects of Import Competition in the United States.” American Economic
Review 103, no. 6: 2121–68. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.103.6.2121.
———. 2021. On the Persistence of the China Shock. NBER Working Paper 29401.
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau for Economic Research. https://doi.
org/10.3386/w29401.
Baccini, L., I. Osgood, and S. Weymouth. 2019. “The Service Economy: U.S. Trade
Coalitions in an Era of Deindustrialization.” Review of International Organizations 14: 261–96. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-019-09349-x.

332 |

References

Bai, L., and S. Stumpner. 2019. “Estimating U.S. Consumer Gains from Chinese
Imports.” American Economic Review: Insights 1, no. 2: 209–24. https://doi.
org/10.1257/aeri.20180358.
Baker, D. 2014. “The Trade Deficit: The Biggest Obstacle to Full Employment.” Center
on Budget and Policy Priorities. https://www.cbpp.org/sites/default/files/atoms/
files/4-2-14fe-baker.pdf.
Baldwin, R. 2016. The Great Convergence: Information Technology and the New Globalization. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. https://doi.org/10.2307/j.
ctv24w655w.
———. 2022. “The Peak Globalization Myth, Part 4: Services Trade Did Not Peak.”
CEPR-VoxEU. https://cepr.org/voxeu/columns/
peak-globalisation-myth-part-4-services-trade-did-not-peak.
Baldwin, R., and R. Freeman. 2022. “Risks and Global Supply Chains: What We Know
and What We Need to Know.” Annual Review of Economics 14: 153–80.
https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-051420-113737.
Baldwin, R., R. Freeman, and A. Theodorakopoulos. 2023. “Hidden Exposure: Measuring
U.S. Supply Chain Reliance.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall.
https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2023/09/2_Baldwin-et-al_
unembargoed.pdf.
Baldwin, R., and J. López-González. 2014. “Supply-Chain Trade: A Portrait of Global
Patterns and Several Testable Hypotheses.” World Economy 38, no. 11: 1682–
721. https://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12189.
BEA (U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis). 2018. “A Guide to BEA’s Services Surveys.”
https://www.bea.gov/system/files/2018-04/surveysu.pdf.
———. 2023a. “U.S. International Economic Accounts: Concepts and Methods.” https://
www.bea.gov/system/files/2023-06/iea-concepts-methods-2023.pdf.
———. 2023b. “Table 6.1. U.S. International Financial Transactions for Direct Investment.” https://www.bea.gov/data/intl-trade-investment/
international-transactions.
———. 2023c. “Table 6.2: U.S. International Financial Transactions for Direct Investment by Country and Industry.” https://www.bea.gov/data/intl-trade-investment/
international-transactions.
———. 2023d. “New Foreign Direct Investment in the United States, 2022.” News
release. https://www.bea.gov/news/2023/
new-foreign-direct-investment-united-states-2022.
Bermel, L., J. Chen, B. Deese, M. Delgado, L. English, Y. Garcia, T. Houser, A. Khan, J.
Larsen, N. Stewart, and H. Tavarez. 2023. “The Clean Investment Monitor:
Tracking Decarbonization Technology in the United States.” Rhodium Group.
https://assets-global.website-files.com/64e31ae6c5fd44b10ff405a7/6500f1718b
8bc3b49a69d333_The%20Clean%20Investment%20Monitor_Tracking%20
Decarbonization%20in%20the%20US.pdf.

References | 333

Bernanke, B. 2005. “Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke at the Sandridge Lecture,
Virginia Association of Economists, Richmond, Virginia, on the Global Saving
Glut and the U.S. Current Account Deficit.” https://www.federalreserve.gov/
boarddocs/speeches/2005/200503102/.
Bernstein, J. 2023. “Remarks by Chair Jared Bernstein at the Economic Policy Institute.”
Transcript of speech at Economic Policy Institute, Washington, September 28.
https://www.whitehouse.gov/cea/written-materials/2023/09/28/
remarks-by-chair-jared-bernstein-at-the-economic-policy-institute-washington-d-c/.
Bertaut, C., B. von Beschwitz, and S. Curcuru. 2023. “‘The International Role of the U.S.
Dollar,’ Post-COVID Edition.” https://www.federalreserve.gov/econres/notes/
feds-notes/the-international-role-of-the-us-dollar-post-covid-edition-20230623.
html.
BIS (Bank for International Settlements). 2017. “BIS 87th Annual Report.” https://www.
bis.org/publ/arpdf/ar2017e_ec.pdf.
Blomström, M., A. Kokko, and J. Mucchielli. 2003. “The Economics of Foreign Direct
Investment Incentives.” In Foreign Direct Investment on the Real and Financial
Sector of Industrial Counties, 37–60. https://doi.
org/10.1007/978-3-540-24736-4_3.
Bloom, N., K. Handley, A. Kurmann, and P. Luck. 2019. “The Impact of Chinese Trade
on U.S. Employment: The Good, The Bad, and The Debatable.” Meeting
Papers 1433. Society for Economic Dynamics. https://red-files-public.
s3.amazonaws.com/meetpapers/2019/paper_1433.pdf.
Bloomberg. 2023. “China Is Having a Hard Time Wooing Foreign Investors Back.”
November 7. https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2023-11-08/
china-is-having-a-hard-time-wooing-foreign-investors-back.
BLS (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics). 2023a. “All Employees, Manufacturing
[MANEMP].” https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/MANEMP.
———. 2023b. “All Employees, Total Nonfarm [PAYEMS].” https://fred.stlouisfed.org/
series/PAYEMS.
Bonadio, B., Z. Huo, A. Levchenko, and N. Pandalai-Nayar. 2020. Global Supply Chains
in the Pandemic. NBER Working Paper 27224. Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau for Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w27224.
Boushey, H. 2023. “The Economics of Public Investment Crowding in Private Investment.” White House Briefing Room Blog. https://www.whitehouse.gov/
briefing-room/blog/2023/08/16/
the-economics-of-public-investment-crowding-in-private-investment/.
Brainard, L. 2001. “Trade Policy in the 1990s.” Brookings Institution. https://www.brookings.edu/articles/trade-policy-in-the-1990s/.
Branstetter, L. 2006. “Is Foreign Direct Investment a Channel of Knowledge Spillovers?
Evidence from Japan’s FDI in the United States.” Journal of International
Economics 68, no. 2: 325–44. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2005.06.006.
334 |

References

Broda, C., and D. Weinstein. 2006. “Globalization and the Gains from Variety.” Quarterly
Journal of Economics 121, no. 2: 541–85. https://doi.org/10.1162/
qjec.2006.121.2.541.
Caballero, R., E. Farhi, and P. Gourinchas. 2017. “The Safe Assets Shortage Conundrum.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 31, no 3: 29–46. https://doi.
org/10.1257/jep.31.3.29.
Caliendo, L., M. Dvorkin, and F. Parro. 2019. “Trade and Labor Market Dynamics:
General Equilibrium Analysis of the China Trade Shock.” Econometrica 87, no.
3: 741–835. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA13758.
CEA (Council of Economic Advisers). 2015a. “The Economic Benefits of U.S. Trade.”
https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/sites/default/files/docs/
cea_trade_report_final_non-embargoed_v2.pdf.
———. 2015b. Economic Report of the President. Washington: U.S. Government
Publishing Office. https://www.whitehouse.gov/wp-content/
uploads/2021/07/2015-ERP.pdf.
———. 2022. Economic Report of the President. Washington: U.S. Government
Publishing Office. https://www.whitehouse.gov/wp-content/uploads/2022/04/
ERP-2022.pdf.
———. 2023a. Economic Report of the President. Washington: U.S. Government
Publishing Office. https://www.whitehouse.gov/wp-content/uploads/2023/03/
erp-2023.pdf.
———. 2023b. “Issue Brief: Supply Chain Resilience.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/cea/
written-materials/2023/11/30/issue-brief-supply-chain-resilience/.
Cheng, S. 2023. “China Lifts Ban on Group Tours to U.S. and Other Countries, in Boost
to Global Travel Industry.” Wall Street Journal, August 10. https://www.wsj.
com/articles/
china-lifts-ban-on-group-tours-to-u-s-and-other-countries-in-boost-to-globaltravel-industry-1b467c78.
Clean Investment Monitor. 2024. Rhodium Group & MIT’s Center for Energy and Environmental Policy Research. https://www.cleaninvestmentmonitor.org/.
Constantinescu, C., A. Mattoo, and M. Ruta. 2018. “The Global Trade Slowdown:
Cyclical or Structural?” World Bank Economic Review 34, no. 1: 121–42.
https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/lhx027.
Dahlman, A., and M. Lovely. 2023. “U.S.-Led Effort to Diversify Indo-Pacific Supply
Chains Away from China Runs Counter to Trends.” Peterson Institute for International Economics, Realtime Economics. https://www.piie.com/blogs/
realtime-economics/
us-led-effort-diversify-indo-pacific-supply-chains-away-china-runs-counter.
De Chaisemartin, C., and Z. Lei. 2023. “More Robust Estimators for Instrumental-Variable Panel Designs, with an Application to the Effect of Imports from China on
U.S. Employment.” Working paper, Social Science Research Network. https://
dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3802200.
References | 335

Devadas, S., and N. Loayza. 2018. “When Is a Current Account Deficit Bad?” Research
and Policy Briefs, World Bank. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/server/
api/core/bitstreams/8edf9fe5-f97b-55d9-aa21-2a52c8d513bc/content.
Economist. 2021. “Globalisation Has Faltered.” January 29. https://www.economist.com/
briefing/2019/01/24/globalisation-has-faltered.
Fajgelbaum, P., and A. Khandelwal. 2016. “Measuring the Unequal Gains from Trade.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 131: no. 3: 1113–80. https://doi.org/10.1093/
qje/qjw013.
Feenstra, R., and G. Hanson. 1997. “Foreign Direct Investment and Relative Wages:
Evidence from Mexico’s Maquiladoras.” Journal of International Economics
42, nos. 3–4: 371–93. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0022-1996(96)01475-4.
Fernandes, A., H. Kee, and D. Winkler. 2020. “Determinants of Global Value Chain
Participation: Cross-Country Evidence.” World Bank Economic Review 36, no.
2: 329–60. https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/lhab017.
Foley, C., J. Hines, and D. Wessel. 2021. “Multinational Activity in the Modern World.”
In Global Goliaths: Multinational Corporations in the 21st Century Economy,
ed. C. Foley, J. Hines, and D. Wessel, 1–32. Washington: Brookings Institution
Press. https://repository.law.umich.edu/cgi/viewcontent.
cgi?article=1427&context=book_chapters.
Fort, T. 2017. “Technology and Production Fragmentation: Domestic versus Foreign
Sourcing.” Review of Economic Studies 84, no. 2: 650–87. https://doi.
org/10.1093/restud/rdw057.
———. 2023. “The Changing Firm and Country Boundaries of U.S. Manufacturers in
Global Value Chains.” American Economic Association 37, no. 3: 31–58.
https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.37.3.31.
Fort, T., J. Pierce, and P. Schott. 2018. “New Perspectives on the Decline of U.S. Manufacturing Employment.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 32, no. 2: 47–72.
https://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/jep.32.2.47.
Freund, C., A. Mattoo, A. Mulabdic, and M. Ruta. 2023. “Natural Disasters and the
Reshaping of Global Value Chains.” IMF Economic Review 70, no. 3: 590–623.
https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-022-00164-w.
Galle, S., A. Rodríguez-Clare, and M. Yi. 2023. “Slicing the Pie: Quantifying the Aggregate and Distributional Effects of Trade.” Review of Economic Studies 90, no.
1: 331–75. https://doi.org/10.1093/restud/rdac020.
Galle, S., and L. Lorentzen. 2021. “The Unequal Effects of Trade and Automation across
Local Labor Markets.” SSRN. https://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3800962.
Ganapati, S., and W. Wong. 2023. How Far Goods Travel: Global Transport and Supply
Chains from 1965–2020. NBER Working Paper 31167. Cambridge, MA:
National Bureau for Economic Research. https://www.nber.org/papers/w31167.

336 |

References

Georgiadis, P., M. O’Dwyer, I. Smith, S. Morris. 2023. “Business Travel Recovery Stalls
as Companies Seek to Cut Costs and Emissions.” Financial Times. https://www.
ft.com/content/ea564d48-6dfd-4c7f-b28b-c2028bbc2fe8.
Ghosh, A., and U. Ramakrishnan. 2024. “Current Account Deficits.” International Monetary Fund, Back to Basics. https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/fandd/issues/
Series/Back-to-Basics/Current-Account-Deficits.
Goldberg, P., and T. Reed. 2023. Is the Global Economy Deglobalizing? And If So, Why?
And What Is Next? NBER Working Paper 31115. Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau for Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w31115.
Grossman, G., and E. Rossi-Hansberg. 2008. “Trading Tasks: A Simple Theory of
Offshoring.” American Economic Review 98, no. 5: 1978–97. https://doi.
org/10.1257/aer.98.5.1978.
Hale, G., B. Hobijn, F. Nechio, and D. Wilson. 2019. “How Much Do We Spend on
Imports?” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Economic Letters. https://
www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/2019/january/
how-much-do-we-spend-on-imports/.
Hale, G., and M. Xu. 2016. FDI Effects on the Labor Markets of Host Countries. Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Working Paper 2016-25. https://doi.
org/10.24148/wp2016-25.
Hancock, T. 2023. “U.S. Trade Data Overstates Decoupling from China, Report Says.”
Bloomberg, October 12. https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2023-10-12/
us-trade-data-overstates-decoupling-from-china-gavekal-says.
Handley, K., F. Kamal, and W. Ouyang. 2021. “A Long View of Employment Growth and
Firm Dynamics in the United States: Importers vs. Exporters vs. Non-Traders.”
Working Paper, Center for Economic Studies. https://www2.census.gov/ces/
wp/2021/CES-WP-21-38.pdf.
Higgins, M., and T. Klitgaard. 2021. “How Much Have Consumers Spent on Imports
During the Pandemic?” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Liberty Street
Economics. https://libertystreeteconomics.newyorkfed.org/2021/10/
how-much-have-consumers-spent-on-imports-during-the-pandemic/.
Hummels, D., J. Ishii, and K. Yi. 2001. “The Nature and Growth of Vertical Specialization in World Trade.” Journal of International Economics 54, no. 1: 75–96.
https://doi.org/10.1016/s0022-1996(00)00093-3.
Iakovou, E., and C. White. 2020. “How to Build More Secure, Resilient, Next-Gen U.S.
Supply Chains.” Brookings Institution. https://www.brookings.edu/articles/
how-to-build-more-secure-resilient-next-gen-u-s-supply-chains/.
IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2019. “The Drivers of Bilateral Trade and the Spillovers from Tariffs.” In World Economic Outlook, April. https://www.elibrary.
imf.org/display/book/9781484397480/ch004.xml.
———. 2022. “Global Trade and Value Chains during the Pandemic.” In World
Economic Outlook, April. https://www.elibrary.imf.org/display/
book/9781616359423/CH004.xml.
References | 337

———. 2023. “Global Financial Stability Report.” https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/
GFSR/Issues/2023/10/10/
global-financial-stability-report-october-2023?cid=pr-com-AM2023-GFSREA2023002.
International Energy Agency. 2022. “Global Supply Chains of EV Batteries.” https://iea.
blob.core.windows.net/assets/4eb8c252-76b1-4710-8f5e-867e751c8dda/GlobalSupplyChainsofEVBatteries.pdf.
Jakubik, A., and V. Stolzenburg. 2020. “The ‘China Shock’ Revisited: Insights from Value
Added Trade Flows.” Journal of Economic Geography 21, no. 1: 67–95. https://
doi.org/10.1093/jeg/lbaa029.
Jaravel, X., and E. Sager. 2019. What Are the Price Effects of Trade? Evidence from the
U.S. and Implications for Quantitative Trade Models. CEP Discussion Paper
1642. London: Centre for Economic Performance. https://cep.lse.ac.uk/pubs/
download/dp1642.pdf.
Jørgensen, P. 2023. “The Global Savings Glut and the Housing Boom.” Journal of
Economic Dynamics and Control 146. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
jedc.2022.104563.
Kamal, F., J. McCloskey, W. Ouyang. 2022. “Multinational Firms in the U.S. Economy:
Insights from Newly Integrated Microdata.” Working Paper, U.S. Census
Bureau. https://www2.census.gov/ces/wp/2022/CES-WP-22-39.pdf.
Keller, W., and S. Yeaple. 2009. “Multinational Enterprises, International Trade, and
Productivity Growth: Firm Level Evidence from the United States.” Review of
Economics and Statistics 91, no. 4: 821–31. https://doi.org/10.1162/
rest.91.4.821.
Klein, M., and M. Pettis. 2020. Trade Wars Are Class Wars: How Rising Inequality
Distorts the Global Economy and Threatens International Peace. New Haven,
CT: Yale University Press. https://www.jstor.org/stable/j.ctv10sm96m.
Knight, M., and F. Scacciavillani. 1998. “Current Accounts: What Is Their Relevance for
Economic Policymaking?” Working Paper, International Monetary Fund.
https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/wp9871.pdf.
Lincicome, S., and A. Anand. 2023. “The ‘China Shock’ Demystified: Its Origins,
Effects, and Lessons for Today.” CATO Institute, Defending Globalization:
Economics. https://www.cato.org/publications/china-shock.
Lipsey, R. 2000. “Foreign Direct Investment and the Operations of Multinational Firms.”
National Bureau of Economic Research, Reporter. https://www.nber.org/
reporter/winter-2000/1/
foreign-direct-investment-and-operations-multinational-firms.
Loungani, P., and A. Razin. 2001. “How Beneficial Is Foreign Direct Investment for
Developing Countries?” Finance and Development 38, no. 2. https://www.imf.
org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2001/06/loungani.htm.

338 |

References

McBride, J., and A. Chatzky. 2019. “The U.S. Trade Deficit: How Much Does It Matter?”
Council on Foreign Relations. https://www.cfr.org/backgrounder/
us-trade-deficit-how-much-does-it-matter.
Mehdi, A., and T. Moorenhout. 2023. “The IRA and the U.S. Battery Supply Chain: One
Year On.” Center on Global Energy Policy at Columbia University School of
International and Public Affairs. https://www.energypolicy.columbia.edu/publications/the-ira-and-the-us-battery-supply-chain-one-year-on/.
Melitz, M., and D. Trefler. 2012. “Gains from Trade When Firms Matter.” Journal of
Economic Perspectives 26, no. 2: 91–118. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jep.26.2.91.
Miroudot, S. 2022. “Resilience in Services Value Chains.” Council on Economic Policies
Blog. https://www.cepweb.org/resilience-in-services-value-chains/.
Nathan, A., G. Galbraith, and J. Grimberg. 2022. “(De)Globalization Ahead?” Goldman
Sachs Global Macro Research Newsletter. https://www.goldmansachs.com/
intelligence/pages/top-of-mind/de-globalization-ahead/report.pdf.
Obstfeld, M., and K. Rogoff. 1996. Foundations of International Macroeconomics.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. https://mitpress.mit.edu/9780262150477/
foundations-of-international-macroeconomics/.
OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development). 2018. “Multinational
Enterprises and Global Value Chains.” https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/industryand-services/multinational-enterprises-and-global-value-chains_194ddb63-en;js
essionid=YO7EGol9Lb2iPwdAAYF_-ZXVzkslnGe1ksbgX1AF.
ip-10-240-5-163.
———. 2021. “Guide to OECD’s Trade in Value Added Indicators.” https://www.oecdilibrary.org/docserver/58aa22b1-en.pdf?expires=1707515380&id=id&accname=
ocid49017102b&checksum=FA3625888B88ACB19AB5EBDB5E292537.
———. 2022. “International Trade During the COVID-19 Pandemic: Big Shifts and
Uncertainty.” https://www.oecd.org/coronavirus/policy-responses/
international-trade-during-the-covid-19-pandemic-big-shifts-and-uncertainty-d1131663/.
———. 2023a. “Foreign Direct Investment Statistics: Data, Analysis and Forecasts.”
https://www.oecd.org/investment/statistics.htm.
———. 2023b. “FDI in Figures.” https://www.oecd.org/daf/inv/FDI-in-FiguresOctober-2023.pdf.
———. 2023c. “Trade in Value Added.” https://www.oecd.org/sti/ind/measuring-trade-invalue-added.htm.
———. 2024. “Foreign Direct Investment (FDI).” https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/financeand-investment/foreign-direct-investment-fdi/indicator-group/
english_9a523b18-en.
Parilla, J., and M. Muro. 2017. “U.S. Metros Most Exposed to a Trump Trade Shock.”
Brookings Institution. https://www.brookings.edu/
articles/u-s-metros-most-dependent-on-trade/.

References | 339

Peterson, K. 2011. “Boeing Says Learned from Outsourcing Issues with 787.” Reuters,
January 20. https://www.reuters.com/article/boeing-idUSN1916381720110120/.
Pettis, M. 2017. “Why a Savings Glut Does Not Increase Savings.” Carnegie Endowment
for International Peace. https://carnegieendowment.org/
chinafinancialmarkets/69838.
Pierce, J., P. Schott, and C. Tello-Trillo. 2023. Trade Liberalization and Labor-Market
Gains: Evidence from U.S. Matched Employer-Employee Data. Working Paper
CES-22-42. Suitland, MD: Center for Economic Studies. https://sompks4.
github.io/public/newlehd_114.pdf.
Qiang, C., Y. Liu, and V. Steenbergen. 2021. “Multinational Corporations Shape Global
Value Chain Development.” In An Investment Perspective on Global Value
Chains, ed. C. Qiang, Y. Liu, and V. Steenbergen, 62–107. Washington: World
Bank. https://elibrary.worldbank.org/doi/abs/10.1596/978-1-4648-1683-3_ch2.
Qiu, H., H. Shin, and L. Zhang. 2023. “Mapping the Realignment of Global Value
Chains.” Working Paper, Bank for International Settlements. https://www.bis.
org/publ/bisbull78.pdf.
Ramondo, N., V. Rappoport, and K. Ruhl. 2016. “Intrafirm Trade and Vertical Fragmentation in U.S. Multinational Corporations.” Journal of International Economics
98: 51–59. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2015.08.002.
Ricardo, D. 1817. On the Principles of Political Economy, and Taxation. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press. https://www.cambridge.org/core/books/on-theprinciples-of-political-economy-and-taxation/5C17BF2152379956950601EFE0
5AE14F.
Rodrik, D. 2011. The Globalization Paradox: Democracy and the Future of the World
Economy. New York: W. W. Norton. https://drodrik.scholar.harvard.edu/publications/globalization-paradox-democracy-and-future-world-economy.
Romei, V. 2023. “Global Trade Falls at Fastest Pace Since Pandemic.” Financial Times.
https://www.ft.com/
content/36982601-b799-4166-9e6b-39533efbdfdf?emailId=7ca6f95a-051d4797-bfd5-6a835f9a1c1d&segmentId=2785c52b-1c00-edaa-29be7452cf90b5a2.
Russ, K., J. Shambaugh, and J. Furman. 2017. “U.S. Tariffs Are an Arbitrary and Regressive Tax.” Centre for Economic Policy Research, VoxEU Column. https://cepr.
org/voxeu/columns/us-tariffs-are-arbitrary-and-regressive-tax.
Santacreu, A., and J. LaBelle. 2022. “Global Supply Chain Disruptions and Inflation
during the COVID-19 Pandemic.” Federal Reserve Bank of Saint Louis Review
104, no. 2: 78–91. https://doi.org/10.20955/r.104.78-91.
Sari, D., D. Raess, and D. Kucera. 2016. “Do PTAs Including Labor Provisions Reduce
Collective Labor Rights Violations? The Role of Labor Cooperation Provisions.” Working paper, Swiss Network for International Studies. https://www.
peio.me/wp-content/uploads/2016/12/PEIO10_paper_63.pdf.

340 |

References

Shenhar, A., V. Holzmann, B. Melamed, and Y. Zhao. 2016. “The Challenge of Innovation in Highly Complex Projects: What Can We Learn from Boeing’s
Dreamliner Experience?” Project Management Journal 47: 62–78. https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/10.1002/pmj.21579.
Shih, W. 2020. “Global Supply Chains in a Post-Pandemic World.” Harvard Business
Review. https://hbr.org/2020/09/global-supply-chains-in-a-post-pandemic-world.
Tabova, A. 2020. “What Happened to Foreign Direct Investment in the United States?”
Federal Reserve Board, FEDS Notes. https://www.federalreserve.gov/econres/
notes/feds-notes/what-happened-to-foreign-direct-investment-in-the-unitedstates-20200213.html.
Timmer, M., B. Los, R. Stehrer, and G. de Vries. 2016. An Anatomy of the Global Trade
Slowdown Based on the WIOD 2016 Release. GGDC Research Memorandum
GD-162. Groningen, Netherlands: Groningen Growth and Development Center.
https://ideas.repec.org/p/gro/rugggd/gd-162.html.
Tracy, B. 2022. “Critical Minerals in Electric Vehicle Batteries.” Congressional Research
Service. https://crsreports.congress.gov/product/pdf/R/R47227.
UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development). 2023. “World Investment Report 2023.” https://unctad.org/system/files/official-document/
wir2023_en.pdf.
U.S. Census Bureau. 2012. “Trade Term: End-Use.” https://www.census.gov/newsroom/
blogs/global-reach/2012/03/end-use-trade-term-of-the-month-2.html.
———. 2022. “U.S. Goods Trade: Imports and Exports by Related-Parties, 2022.”
https://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/Press-Release/related_party/rp22.pdf.
———. 2023. “Monthly U.S. International Trade in Goods and Services, December
2023.” https://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/current/index.html.
U.S. Department of Commerce. 2022. “Ministerial Statement for Pillar III of the IndoPacific Economic Framework for Prosperity.” https://www.commerce.gov/sites/
default/files/2022-09/Pillar-III-Ministerial-Statement.pdf.
———. 2023a. “Fact Sheet: Substantial Conclusion of Negotiations on Groundbreaking
IPEF Clean Economy Agreement.” https://www.commerce.gov/sites/default/
files/2023-11/US-Factsheet-SF-Pillar-III.pdf.
———. 2023b. “Fact Sheet: Substantial Conclusion of Negotiations of an Innovative
IPEF Fair Economy Agreement.” https://www.commerce.gov/sites/default/
files/2023-11/US-Factsheet-SF-Pillar-IV.pdf.
———. 2023c. “U.S.-EU Joint Statement of the Trade and Technology Council.” https://
www.commerce.gov/news/press-releases/2023/05/
us-eu-joint-statement-trade-and-technology-council.
U.S. Department of Energy. 2023. “Department of Energy Celebrates Two Years of President Biden’s Historic Investment in America’s Clean Energy Future.” https://
www.energy.gov/articles/

References | 341

department-energy-celebrates-two-years-president-bidens-historic-investmentamericas-clean.
U.S. Department of Labor. 2023. “USMCA Cases.” https://www.dol.gov/agencies/ilab/
our-work/trade/labor-rights-usmca-cases.
U.S. Department of State. No date. “Minerals Security Partnership.” https://www.state.
gov/minerals-security-partnership/.
U.S. Department of the Treasury. 2023. “Economy Statement by Eric Van Nostrand,
Acting Assistant Secretary for Economic Policy, for the Treasury Borrowing
Advisory Committee July 31, 2023.” https://home.treasury.gov/news/pressreleases/jy1661.
U.S. Small Business Administration. 2023a. “Report with Eight Deliverables for Project
to Support Small Business Administration (SBA) to Identify the Total Addressable Market of Small Business Exporters.” https://www.sba.gov/sites/default/
files/2023-02/SBA%20Total%20Addressable%20Market%20Study%20
FINAL-508%20%281%29.pdf.
———. 2023b. “SBA Research Sheds Light on Small Business Exporters.” https://www.
sba.gov/article/2023/mar/14/
sba-research-sheds-new-light-small-business-exporters.
USTR (Office of the U.S. Trade Representative). 2021. “U.S.-EU Trade and Technology
Council Inaugural Joint Statement.” https://ustr.gov/about-us/policy-offices/
press-office/press-releases/2021/september/
us-eu-trade-and-technology-council-inaugural-joint-statement.
———. 2022a. “Countries & Regions.” https://ustr.gov/countries-regions.
———. 2022b. “Fact Sheet: 2021 President’s Trade Agenda and 2020 Annual Report.”
https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/files/reports/2021/2021%20Trade%20
Agenda/2021%20Trade%20Report%20Fact%20Sheet.pdf.
———. 2022c. “United States and Kenya Announce the Launch of the U.S.-Kenya Strategic Trade and Investment Partnership.” https://ustr.gov/about-us/
policy-offices/press-office/press-releases/2022/july/
united-states-and-kenya-announce-launch-us-kenya-strategic-trade-and-investment-partnership.
———. 2022d. “2022 Biennial Report on the Implementation of the African Growth and
Opportunity Act.” https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/files/reports/2022/2022AG
OAImplementationReport.pdf.
———. 2023a. “Chapter 31, Annex A: Facility-Specific Rapid-Response Labor Mechanism.” https://ustr.gov/issue-areas/enforcement/dispute-settlement-proceedings/
fta-dispute-settlement/usmca/
chapter-31-annex-facility-specific-rapid-response-labor-mechanism.
———. 2023b. “2023 Trade Policy Agenda and 2022 Annual Report of the President of
the United States on the Trade Agreements Program.” https://ustr.gov/sites/
default/files/2023-02/2023%20Trade%20Policy%20Agenda%20and%20
2022%20Annual%20Report%20FINAL%20(1).pdf.
342 |

References

———. 2023c. “Agreement Between the American Institute in Taiwan and the Taipei
Economic and Cultural Representative Office in the United States Regarding
Trade Between the United States of America and Taiwan.” https://ustr.gov/sites/
default/files/2023-05/AIT-TECRO%20Trade%20Agreement%20May%202023.
pdf.
———. 2023d. “United States and Taiwan Hold Second Negotiating Round for the U.S.Taiwan Initiative on 21st-Century Trade.” https://ustr.gov/about-us/
policy-offices/press-office/press-releases/2023/august/
united-states-and-taiwan-hold-second-negotiating-round-us-taiwan-initiative21st-century-trade-1.
———. 2023e. “U.S.-Kenya Strategic Trade and Investment Partnership Summary of
Texts Proposed by the U.S. Side.” https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/2023-05/
U.S.-Kenya%20STIP%20Chapter%20Summaries%20May%202023.pdf.
———. 2023f. “United States and Japan Sign Critical Minerals Agreement.” https://ustr.
gov/about-us/policy-offices/press-office/press-releases/2023/march/
united-states-and-japan-sign-critical-minerals-agreement.
———. No date–a. “Indo-Pacific Economic Framework for Prosperity.” https://ustr.gov/
ipef.
———. No date–b. “Ministerial Text for Trade Pillar of the Indo-Pacific Economic
Framework for Prosperity.” https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/2022-09/IPEF%20
Pillar%201%20Ministerial%20Text%20(Trade%20Pillar)_FOR%20
PUBLIC%20RELEASE%20(1).pdf.
———. No date–c. “African Growth and Opportunity Act (AGOA).” https://ustr.gov/
issue-areas/trade-development/preference-programs/
african-growth-and-opportunity-act-agoa.
Van Nostrand, E., and M. Ashenfarb. 2023. “The Inflation Reduction Act: A Place-Based
Analysis.” https://home.treasury.gov/news/featured-stories/
the-inflation-reduction-act-a-place-based-analysis.
Wang, Z., S. Wei, X. Yu, and K. Zhu. 2018. Re-examining the Effects of Trading with
China on Local Labor Markets: A Supply Chain Perspective. NBER Working
Paper 24886. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://
doi.org/10.3386/w24886.
White House. 2021a. “U.S.-EU Trade and Technology Council Inaugural Joint Statement.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/
statements-releases/2021/09/29/u-s-eu-trade-and-technology-council-inauguraljoint-statement/.
———. 2021b. “Building Resilient Supply Chains, Revitalizing American Manufacturing, and Fostering Broad-Based Growth.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/
wp-content/uploads/2021/06/100-day-supply-chain-review-report.pdf.
———. 2023a. “Australia–United States Climate, Critical Minerals and Clean Energy
Transformation Compact.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/statements-releases/2023/05/20/

References | 343

australia-united-states-climate-critical-minerals-and-clean-energy-transformation-compact/.
———. 2023b. “Fact Sheet: President Joseph R. Biden and General Secretary Nguyen
Phu Trong Announce the U.S.-Vietnam Comprehensive Strategic Partnership.”
https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/statements-releases/2023/09/10/
fact-sheet-president-joseph-r-biden-and-general-secretary-nguyen-phu-trongannounce-the-u-s-vietnam-comprehensive-strategic-partnership/.
World Bank. 2020. World Development Report 2020: Trading for Development in the Age
of Global Value Chains. Washington: World Bank. https://doi.
org/10.1596/978-1-4648-1457-0.
WTO (World Trade Organization). 2021. “Global Value Chain Development Report
2021.” https://www.wto.org/english/res_e/booksp_e/00_gvc_dev_
report_2021_e.pdf.
———. 2022. “Trade in Value Added and Global Value Chains: Country Profiles Explanatory Notes.” https://www.wto.org/english/res_e/statis_e/miwi_e/
Explanatory_Notes_e.pdf.
———. 2023a. “World Trade Report.” https://www.wto.org/english/res_e/booksp_e/
wtr23_e/wtr23_e.pdf.
———. 2023b. “Evolution of Trade Under the WTO: Handy Statistics.” https://www.wto.
org/english/res_e/statis_e/trade_evolution_e/evolution_trade_wto_e.htm.
Yang, L., Y. Zhu, and F. Ren. 2023. “Does Government Investment Push up Manufacturing Labor Costs? Evidence from China.” Humanities and Social Sciences
Communications 10, no. 1. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41599-023-02180-1.
Zumbrun, J. 2023. “Is Globalization in Decline? A New Number Contradicts the
Consensus.” Wall Street Journal, November 3. https://www.wsj.com/economy/
global/
is-globalization-in-decline-a-new-number-contradicts-the-consensus60df8ecf?mod=djemRTE_h.

Chapter 6
Acemoglu, D. 2002. “Directed Technical Change.” Review of Economic Studies 69, no. 4:
781–809. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-937X.00226.
Acemoglu, D., P, Aghion, L. Bursztyn, and D. Hemous. 2012. “The Environment and
Directed Technical Change.” American Economic Review 102, no. 1: 131–66.
https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.102.1.131.
Acemoglu, D., U. Akcigit, D. Hanley, and W. Kerr. 2016. “Transition to Clean Technology.” Journal of Political Economy 124, no. 1: 52–104. https://doi.
org/10.1086/684511.
Acemoglu, D., and D. Autor. 2011. “Chapter 12: Skills, Tasks and Technologies—Implications for Employment and Earnings.” In Handbook of Labor Economics, 4B,

344 |

References

ed. O. Ashenfelter and D. Card. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science. https://www.
sciencedirect.com/science/article/abs/pii/S0169721811024105.
Amsden, A. 1992. Asia’s Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization. Oxford:
Oxford University Press. https://doi.org/10.1093/0195076036.001.0001.
Arkolakis, C, and C. Walsh. 2023. Clean Growth. NBER Working Paper 31615.
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau for Economic Research. https://doi.
org/10.3386/w31615.
Armitage, S., N. Bakhtian, and A. Jaffe. 2023. Innovation Market Failures and the
Design of New Climate Policy Instruments. NBER Working Paper 31622.
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau for Economic Research. https://doi.
org/10.3386/w31622.
Arrow, K. 1962. “The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing.” Review of
Economic Studies 29, no. 3: 155–73. https://doi.org/10.2307/2295952.
Autor, D., D. Dorn, and G. Hanson. 2013. “The China Syndrome: Local Labor Market
Effects of Import Competition in the United States.” American Economic
Review 103, no. 6: 2121–68. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.103.6.2121.
Autor, D., F. Levy, and R. Murnane. 2003. “The Skill Content of Recent Technological
Change: An Empirical Exploration.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, no.
4: 1279–333. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355303322552801.
Bachas, N., O. Kim, and C. Yannelis. 2021. “Loan Guarantees and Credit Supply.”
Journal of Financial Economics 139: 872–94. https://www.sciencedirect.com/
science/article/abs/pii/S0304405X20302361.
Baumol, W., and W. Oates. 1988. The Theory of Environmental Policy. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press. https://books.google.com/
books?hl=en&lr=&id=32-r0N8l9BgC&oi=fnd&pg=PR7&dq=baumol+and+oate
s+1988&ots=P3N0jyJZwI&sig=sZmDlJUPsVMTaFFUm6PqZVRqKHA.
Berkes, E., K. Manysheva, and M. Mestieri. 2022. “Global Innovation Spillovers and
Productivity: Evidence from 100 Years of World Patent Data.” Working paper,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. https://rhg.com/research/
emerging-climate-technology-ira/.
Berndt, E., R. Glennerster, M. Kremer, J. Lee, R. Levine, G. Weizsäcker, and H.
Williams. 2006. “Advance Market Commitments for Vaccines against
Neglected Diseases: Estimating Costs and Effectiveness.” Health Economics
16, no. 5: 491–511. https://doi.org/10.1002/hec.1176.
Beuse, M., B. Steffen, M. Dirksmeier, and T. Schmidt. 2021. “Comparing CO2 Emissions
Impacts of Electricity Storage Across Applications and Energy Systems.” Joule
5, no. 6: 1501–20. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joule.2021.04.010.
Bloom, N., M. Schankerman, and J. Van Reenen. 2013. “Identifying Technology Spillovers and Product Market Rivalry.” Econometrica 81, no. 4: 1347–93. https://
doi.org/10.3982/ECTA9466.

References | 345

Boushey, H. 2023. “The Economics of Public Investment Crowding in Private Investment.” White House Blog. https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/
blog/2023/08/16/
the-economics-of-public-investment-crowding-in-private-investment/
Boyd, M. 2023. “The Potential of Agrivoltaics for the U.S. Solar Industry, Farmers, and
Communities.” U.S. Department of Energy Solar Energy Technologies Office
Blog. https://www.energy.gov/eere/solar/articles/
potential-agrivoltaics-us-solar-industry-farmers-and-communities.
Brooks, L., and Z. Liscow. 2023. “Infrastructure Costs.” American Economic Journal:
Applied Economics 15, no. 2: 1–30. https://doi.org/10.1257/app.20200398.
Burke, M., S. Hsiang, and E. Miguel. 2015. “Global Non-Linear Effect of Temperature
on Economic Production.” Nature 527, no. 7577: 235–39. https://doi.
org/10.1038/nature15725.
Burlig, F., J. Bushnell, D. Rapson, and C. Wolfram. 2021. “Low Energy: Estimating Electric Vehicle Electricity Use.” AEA Papers and Proceedings 111: 430–35. https://
doi.org/10.1257/pandp.20211088.
Bryce, R. 2023. “Renewable Rejection Database.” https://robertbryce.com/
renewable-rejection-database/.
California Legislature. 2023. “An Act Making Appropriations for the Support of the
Government of the State of California and for Several Public Purposes in
Accordance with the Provisions of Section 12 of Article IV of the Constitution
of the State of California, Relating to the State Budget, to Take Effect Immediately, Budget Bill, Senate Bill No. 101, 2023.” https://leginfo.legislature.ca.gov/
faces/billTextClient.xhtml?bill_id=202320240SB101.
Carleton, T., A. Jina, M. Delgado, M. Greenstone, T. Houser, S. Hsiang, A. Hultgren, R.
Kopp, K. McCusker, I. Nath, J. Rising, A. Rode, H. Kwon Seo, A. Viaene, J.
Yuan, and A. Zhang. 2022. “Valuing the Global Mortality Consequences of
Climate Change Accounting for Adaptation Costs and Benefits.” Quarterly
Journal of Economics 137, no. 4: 2037–105. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/
qjac020.
Casey, G., W. Jeon, and C. Traeger. 2023. The Macroeconomics of Clean Energy Subsidies. CESifo Working Paper 10828. https://www.cesifo.org/en/
publications/2023/working-paper/macroeconomics-clean-energy-subsidies.
CEA (Council of Economic Advisers). 2021. “Innovation, Investment, and Inclusion:
Accelerating the Energy Transition and Creating Good Jobs.” https://www.
whitehouse.gov/wp-content/uploads/2021/04/Innovation-Investment-and-Inclusion-CEA-April-23-2021-1.pdf.
______. 2023a. “Chapter 9: Opportunities for Better Managing Weather Risk in the
Changing Climate.” In Economic Report of the President. Washington: U.S.
Government Publishing Office. https://www.whitehouse.gov/wp-content/
uploads/2023/03/erp-2023.pdf.

346 |

References

———. 2023b. “The Economics of Demand-Side Support for the Department of Energy’s Clean Hydrogen Hubs.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/cea/
written-materials/2023/07/05/
the-economics-of-demand-side-support-for-the-department-of-energys-cleanhydrogen-hubs/.
Chang, R. 2023. “Renewable Energy Is the Key to Building a More Resilient and Reliable Electricity Grid.” Center for American Progress. https://www.
americanprogress.org/article/
renewable-energy-is-the-key-to-building-a-more-resilient-and-reliable-electricity-grid/.
Choi, J., and A. Levchenko. 2021. The Long-Term Effects of Industrial Policy. NBER
Working Paper 29263. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w29263.
Cole, C., M. Droste, C. Knittel, S. Li, and J. Stock. 2023. “Policies for Electrifying the
Light-Duty Vehicle Fleet in the United States.” AEA Papers and Proceedings
113: 316–22. https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.20231063.
Colmer, J., E. Lyubich, and J. Voorheis. 2023. “Nice Work If You Can Get It? The Distribution of Employment and Earnings During the Early Years of the Clean
Energy Transition.” Working paper. https://drive.google.com/file/d/1gBN7KjQpvVObMasULONRs_xsl-ISBd4/view?usp=sharing.
Cotterman, T., E. Fuchs, and K. Whitefoot. 2022. “The Transition to Electrified Vehicles:
Evaluating the Labor Demand of Manufacturing Conventional versus Battery
Electric Vehicle Powertrains.” Working paper, Carnegie Mellon University.
https://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.4128130.
Cox, S., L. Beshilas, and E. Hotchkiss. 2019. “Renewable Energy to Support Energy
Security.” National Renewable Energy Lab. https://www.nrel.gov/docs/
fy20osti/74617.pdf.
CRFB (Committee for a Responsible Federal Budget). 2013. “The Tax Break-Down:
Intangible Drilling Costs” https://www.crfb.org/blogs/
tax-break-down-intangible-drilling-costs.
CRS (Congressional Research Service). 2012. “Loan Guarantees for Clean Energy Technologies: Goals, Concerns, and Policy Options.” https://crsreports.congress.gov/
product/pdf/R/R42152.
———. 2018. “Renewable Energy R&D Funding History: A Comparison with Funding
for Nuclear Energy, Fossil Energy, Energy Efficiency, and Electric Systems
R&D.” https://crsreports.congress.gov/product/pdf/RS/RS22858/17.
———. 2020. “The Renewable Electricity Production Tax Credit: In Brief.” https://sgp.
fas.org/crs/misc/R43453.pdf.
______. 2021. “Oil and Gas Tax Preferences: In Brief.” https://crsreports.congress.gov/
product/pdf/IF/IF11528.
CTVC. 2023. “Insights: CTVC by Sightline Climate.” https://www.ctvc.co/tag/insights/.

References | 347

Curtis, E., L. O’Kane, and R. Park. 2023. Workers and the Green-Energy Transition:
Evidence from 300 Million Job Transitions. NBER Working Paper 31539.
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/
10.3386/w31539.
Davis, L. 2023. “Electric Vehicles in Multi-Vehicle Households.” Applied Economics
Letters 30, no. 14: 1909–12. https://doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2022.2083563.
Denholm, P., M. Hand, M. Jackson, and S. Ong. 2009. “Land Use Requirements of
Modern Wind Power Plants in the United States.” National Renewable Energy
Lab, Technical Report TP-6A2-45834. https://www.nrel.gov/docs/
fy09osti/45834.pdf.
Devine, W. 1982. An Historical Perspective on the Value of Electricity in American
Manufacturing. Technical Report ORAU/IEA-82-8(M). Oak Ridge: Institute for
Energy Analysis, Oak Ridge Associated Universities. https://doi.
org/10.2172/6774921.
Dimanchev, E., S. Fleten, D. MacKenzie, and M. Korpås. 2023. “Accelerating Electric
Vehicle Charging Investments: A Real Options Approach to Policy Design.”
Energy Policy 181. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2023.113703.
DOE (U.S. Department of Energy). 2022a. “Wind Energy: Supply Chain Deep Dive
Assessment.” https://www.energy.gov/sites/default/files/2022-02/Wind%20
Supply%20Chain%20Report%20-%20Final%202.25.22.pdf.
———. 2022b. “DOE Optimizes Structure to Implement $62 Billion in Clean Energy
Investments from Bipartisan Infrastructure Law.” https://www.energy.gov/articles/
doe-optimizes-structure-implement-62-billion-clean-energy-investments-bipartisan.
———. 2023a. “United States Energy and Employment Report 2023.” https://www.
energy.gov/sites/default/files/2023-06/2023%20USEER%20REPORT-v2.pdf.
———. 2023b. “Biden-Harris Administration Announces $15.5 Billion to Support a
Strong and Just Transition to Electric Vehicles, Retooling Existing Plants, and
Rehiring Existing Workers.” Press release.
———. 2023c. “Pathways to Commercial Liftoff: Clean Hydrogen.” https://liftoff.energy.
gov/.
———. 2023d. “National Transmission Needs Study.”
———. 2023e. “Building a Bridge to Bankability.” https://www.energy.gov/sites/default/
files/2023-05/DOE-LPO22-PPTv03_LPO-Overview_May2023.pdf.
Duranton, G., and D. Puga. 2004. “Chapter 48: Micro-Foundations of Urban Agglomeration Economies.” In Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics, no. 4:
2063–2117. https://doi.org/10.1016/s1574-0080(04)80005-1.
EIA (U.S. Energy Information Administration). 2012. “Today in Energy.” https://www.
eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.php?id=7590.

348 |

References

———. 2023a. “Electricity Monthly Update: December 2022.” https://www.eia.gov/electricity/monthly/update/archive/february2023/.
———. 2023b. “Energy and the Environment Explained Where Greenhouse Gases Come
From.” https://www.eia.gov/energyexplained/energy-and-the-environment/
where-greenhouse-gases-come-from.php.
———. 2024a. “Solar and Wind to Lead Growth of U.S. Power Generation for the Next
Two Years.” https://www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.php?id=61242.
———. 2024b. “U.S. Battery Storage Capacity Expected to Nearly Double in 2024.”
https://www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.php?id=61202.
Erickson, P., and P. Achakulwisut. 2021. “How Subsidies Aided the U.S. Shale Oil and
Gas Boom.” Stockholm Environmental Institute. https://www.sei.org/publications/subsidies-shale-oil-and-gas/.
Erickson, P., A. Down, M. Lazarus, and D. Koplow. 2017. “Effect of Subsidies to Fossil
Fuel Companies on United States Crude Oil Production.” Nature Energy 2, no.
11: 891–98.
Esposito, D. 2021. “Meta-Analysis of Clean Energy Policy Models.” Energy Innovation
Policy & Technology LLC. https://energyinnovation.org/wp-content/
uploads/2021/09/Studies-Agree-80-Percent-Clean-Electricity-by-2030-WouldSave-Lives-and-Create-Jobs-at-Minimal-Cost.pdf.
European Environment Agency. 2023. “Total Net Greenhouse Gas Emission Trends and
Projections in Europe.” https://www.eea.europa.eu/en/analysis/indicators/
total-greenhouse-gas-emission-trends?activeAccordion=546a7c35-9188-4d2394ee-005d97c26f2b.
Fontana, S., and R. Nanda. 2023. “Innovating to Net Zero: Can Venture Capital and StartUps Play a Meaningful Role?” In Entrepreneurship and Innovation Policy and
the Economy, Volume 2, ed. B. Jones, and J. Lerner. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press. https://doi.org/10.1086/723236.
Friedlingstein, P., M. O’Sullivan, M. Jones, R. Andrew, J. Hauck, A. Olsen, G. Peters, et
al. 2020. “Global Carbon Budget 2020.” Earth System Science Data 12, no. 4:
3269–340. https://doi.org/10.5194/essd-12-3269-2020.
Friedlingstein, P., M. O’Sullivan, M. Jones, R. Andrew, D. Bakker, J. Hauck, P. Landschützer, et al. 2023. “Global Carbon Budget 2023.” Earth System Science Data
15: 5301–69. https://doi.org/10.5194/essd-15-5301-2023.
Gallagher, K., and L. Anadon. 2022. “Database on U.S. Department of Energy (DOE)
Budgets for Energy Research, Development, & Demonstration (1978-2023R).”
Harvard Kennedy School. https://www.belfercenter.org/publication/
database-us-department-energy-doe-budgets-energy-research-developmentdemonstration-1.
Ghosh, S., and R. Nanda. 2010. Venture Capital Investment in the Clean Energy Sector.
Working Paper 11-020, Harvard Business School. https://www.hbs.edu/ris/
Publication%20Files/11-020_0a1b5d16-c966-4403-888f-96d03bbab461.pdf.

References | 349

Glennerster, R., and M. Kremer. 2000. “A Better Way to Spur Medical Research and
Development.” Regulation 23: 34. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.
cfm?abstract_id=235870.
Global Trade Funding. No date. “Offtake Agreements, Project Finance Document Critical
for Loan Approval.” https://globaltradefunding.com/project-finance/projectfinance-documents/offtake-agreements/.
Golding, G., and L. Kilian. 2022. “Don’t Look to Oil Companies to Lower High Retail
Gasoline Prices.” Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. https://www.dallasfed.org/
research/economics/2022/0510.
Greenspon, J., and D. Raimi. 2022. Matching Geographies and Job Skills in the Energy
Transition. RFF WP 22-25. Washington: Resources for the Future. https://
media.rff.org/documents/WP_22-25_PnkcURf.pdf.
Gropman, A. 1996. “Mobilizing U.S. Industry in World War II: Myth and Reality.” Institute for National Strategic Studies. https://apps.dtic.mil/sti/tr/pdf/ADA316780.
pdf.
Gross, D., and B. Sampat. 2023a. “America, Jump-Started: World War II R&D and the
Takeoff of the US Innovation System.” American Economic Review 113, no.
12: 3323–56. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20221365.
———.2023b. “The World War II Crisis Innovation Model: What Was It, and Where
Does It Apply?” Research Policy 52, no. 9: 104845. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
respol.2023.104845.
Gross, S. 2020. “Renewables, Land Use, and Local Opposition in the United States.”
Brookings Institution. https://www.brookings.edu/articles/
renewables-land-use-and-local-opposition-in-the-united-states/.
Guarnieri, M. 2012. “Looking Back to Electric Cars.” https://ieeexplore.ieee.org/xpl/
conhome/6480931/proceeding.
Hanson, G. 2023. “Local Labor Market Impacts of the Energy Transition: Prospects and
Policies.” In Economic Policy in a More Uncertain World, 155–99. Washington: Aspen Economic Strategy Group. https://www.economicstrategygroup.
org/wp-content/uploads/2022/12/Hanson-chapter.pdf.
Hart, D. 2020. “The Impact of China’s Production Surge on Innovation in the Global
Solar Photovoltaics Industry.” Information Technology & Innovation Foundation. https://itif.org/publications/2020/10/05/
impact-chinas-production-surge-innovation-global-solar-photovoltaics/.
Hassler, J., P. Krusell, C. Olovsson, and M. Reiter. 2020. “On the Effectiveness of
Climate Policies.” Working paper, Institute for International Economic Studies
at Stockholm University.
Heintz, J. 2010. “The Impact of Public Capital on the US Private Economy: New
Evidence and Analysis.” International Review of Applied Economics 24, no. 5:
619–32. https://doi.org/10.1080/02692170903426104.

350 |

References

Herrendorf, B., R. Rogerson, and A. Valentinyi. 2014. “Chapter 6: Growth and Structural
Transformation.” In Handbook of Economic Growth, ed. P. Aghion and S.
Durlauf, 855–941. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science. https://www.sciencedirect.
com/science/article/abs/pii/B9780444535405000069.
Hittinger, E., and I. Azevedo. 2015. “Bulk Energy Storage Increases United States Electricity System Emissions.” Environmental Science & Technology 49, no. 5:
3203–10. https://doi.org/10.1021/es505027p.
Hottenrott, H., E. Lins, and E. Lutz. 2018. “Public Subsidies and New Ventures’ Use of
Bank Loans.” Economics of Innovation and New Technology 27, no. 8:
786–808. https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599.2017.1408200.
Howell, S. 2017. “Financing Innovation: Evidence from R&D Grants.” American
Economic Review 107, no. 4: 1136–64. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20150808.
Hsiang, S., M. Burke, and E. Miguel. 2013. “Quantifying the Influence of Climate on
Human Conflict.” Science 341, no. 6151: 1235367. https://doi.org/10.1126/
science.1235367.
Hsiang, S., S. Greenhill, J. Martinich, M. Grasso, R. Schuster, L. Barrage, D. Diaz, et al.
2023. “Ch. 19: Economics.” In Fifth National Climate Assessment, ed. A. Crimmins, C. Avery, D. Easterling, K. Kunkel, B. Stewart, and T. Maycock.
Washington: U.S. Global Change Research Program. https://doi.org/10.7930/
NCA5.2023.CH19.
Hyman, B. 2022. “Can Displaced Labor Be Retrained? Evidence from Quasi-Random
Assignment to Trade Adjustment Assistance.” Working Paper, U.S. Census
Bureau, Center for Economic Studies. https://www2.census.gov/ces/wp/2022/
CES-WP-22-05.pdf.
IEA (International Energy Agency). 2021a. “Net Zero by 2050: A Roadmap for the
Global Energy Sector.” https://iea.blob.core.windows.net/assets/deebef5d-0c344539-9d0c-10b13d840027/
NetZeroby2050-ARoadmapfortheGlobalEnergySector_CORR.pdf.
———.2021b. “The Role of Critical Minerals in Clean Energy Transitions.” In World
Energy Outlook. https://www.iea.org/reports/
the-role-of-critical-minerals-in-clean-energy-transitions.
———. 2021c. “The Cost of Capital in Clean Energy Transitions.” https://www.iea.org/
articles/the-cost-of-capital-in-clean-energy-transitions.
———. 2022. “World Energy Employment.” https://iea.blob.core.windows.net/assets/
a0432c97-14af-4fc7-b3bf-c409fb7e4ab8/WorldEnergyEmployment.pdf.
———. 2023a. World Energy Outlook. Paris: IEA. https://www.iea.org/reports/
world-energy-outlook-2023.
———. 2023b. “A Renewed Pathway to Net Zero Emissions.” https://www.iea.org/
reports/
net-zero-roadmap-a-global-pathway-to-keep-the-15-0c-goal-in-reach/arenewed-pathway-to-net-zero-emissions.

References | 351

———. 2023c. “Solar PV: Overview.” https://www.iea.org/energy-system/renewables/
solar-pv.
———. 2023d. “Energy Technology RD&D Budgets Data Explorer.” https://www.iea.
org/data-and-statistics/data-tools/energy-technology-rdd-budgets-data-explorer.
Interagency Working Group on Coal and Power Plant Communities and Economic Revitalization. 2023. “Revitalizing Energy Communities: Two-Year Report to the
President.” https://energycommunities.gov/wp-content/uploads/2023/04/IWGTwo-Year-Report-to-the-President.pdf.
International Renewable Energy Agency. 2023. “Renewable Power Generation Costs in
2022.” Report. https://energycommunities.gov/wp-content/uploads/2023/04/
IWG-Two-Year-Report-to-the-President.pdf.
IREC (Interstate Renewable Energy Council). 2022. “National Solar Jobs Census 2021.”
https://irecusa.org/wp-content/uploads/2022/07/National-Solar-JobsCensus-2021.pdf.
———. 2023. “Cultivating a Diverse and Skilled Talent Pipeline for the Equitable Transition.” https://irecusa.org/wp-content/uploads/2023/02/
Alliance-Report-2.23-Interactive-compressed.pdf.
IRENA (International Renewable Energy Agency). 2019. “Utility-Scale Batteries: Innovation Landscape Brief.” https://www.irena.org/-/media/Files/IRENA/Agency/
Publication/2019/Sep/IRENA_Utility-scale-batteries_2019.pdf.
———. 2023. “Renewable Capacity Statistics 2023.” https://mc-cd8320d4-36a1-40ac83cc-3389-cdn-endpoint.azureedge.net/-/media/Files/IRENA/Agency/
Publication/2023/Mar/IRENA_RE_Capacity_Statistics_2023.pdf?rev=d294915
1ee6a4625b65c82881403c2a7.
Jaworski, T. 2017. “World War II and the Industrialization of the American South.”
Journal of Economic History 77, no. 4: 1048–82. https://doi.org/10.1017/
S0022050717000791.
Jenkins, J., J. Farbes, R. Jones, N. Patankar, and G. Schivley. 2022. “Electricity Transmission Is Key to Unlock the Full Potential of the Inflation Reduction Act.” Rapid
Energy Policy Evaluation and Analysis Toolkit Project, PowerPoint presentation. https://repeatproject.org/docs/REPEAT_IRA_Transmission_2022-09-22.
pdf.
Johnston, B. 1970. “Agriculture and Structural Transformation in Developing Countries:
A Survey of Research.” Journal of Economic Literature 8, no. 2: 369–404.
https://www.jstor.org/stable/2720471.
Juhász, R., N. Lane, and D. Rodrik. 2023. “The New Economics of Industrial Policy.”
National Bureau of Economic Research. https://drodrik.scholar.harvard.edu/
sites/scholar.harvard.edu/files/dani-rodrik/files/the_new_economics_of_
ip_080123.pdf.
Katz, L., J. Roth, R. Hendra, and K. Schaberg. 2022. “Why Do Sectoral Employment
Programs Work? Lessons from WorkAdvance.” Journal of Labor Economics
40, no. S1: S249–91. https://doi.org/10.1086/717932.
352 |

References

Kotchen, M. 2021. “The Producer Benefits of Implicit Fossil Fuel Subsidies in the United
States.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 118, no. 14:
e20119691 https://www.pnas.org/doi/10.1073/pnas.2011969118.
Kremer, M., J. Levin, and C. Snyder. 2020. “Advance Market Commitments: Insights
from Theory and Experience.” AEA Papers and Proceedings 110: 269–73.
https://pubs.aeaweb.org/doi/pdfplus/10.1257/pandp.20201017.
Kriegler, E., N. Bauer, A. Popp, F. Humpenöder, M. Leimbach, J. Strefler, L. Baumstark,
et al. 2017. “Fossil-Fueled Development (SSP5): An Energy and ResourceIntensive Scenario for the 21st Century.” Global Environmental Change 42:
297–315. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2016.05.015.
Lane, N. 2022. “Manufacturing Revolutions: Industrial Policy and Industrialization in
South Korea.” University of Oxford, Department of Economics. http://dx.doi.
org/10.2139/ssrn.3890311.
Larsen, K., H. Pitt, M. Mobir, S. Movalia, A. Rivera, E. Rutkowski, and T. Houser. 2023.
“Global Emerging Climate Technology Diffusion and the Inflation Reduction
Act.” Rhodium Group. https://rhg.com/research/
emerging-climate-technology-ira/.
Lazard. 2023. “Levelized Cost of Energy Analysis +.” PowerPoint presentation. https://
www.lazard.com/media/2ozoovyg/lazards-lcoeplus-april-2023.pdf.
Lelieveld, J., K. Klingmüller, A. Pozzer, R. Burnett, A. Haines, and V. Ramanathan. 2019.
“Effects of Fossil Fuel and Total Anthropogenic Emission Removal on Public
Health and Climate.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 116, no.
15: 7192–97. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1819989116.
Lerner, J., and R. Nanda. 2020. “Venture Capital’s Role in Financing Innovation: What
We Know and How Much We Still Need to Learn.” Journal of Economic
Perspectives 34, no. 3: 237–61. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.34.3.237.
Lewis, J., and R. Wiser. 2007. “Fostering a Renewable Energy Technology Industry: An
International Comparison of Wind Industry Policy Support Mechanisms.”
Energy Policy 35, no. 3: 1844–57. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2006.06.005.
Lewis, W. 1954. “Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour.”
Manchester School 22, no. 2: 139–91. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9957.1954.
tb00021.x.
Li, S., L. Tong, J. Xing, and Y. Zhou. 2017. “The Market for Electric Vehicles: Indirect
Network Effects and Policy Design.” Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 4, no. 1: 89–133. http://dx.doi.
org/10.1086/689702.
Lim, J., M. Aklin, and M. Frank. 2023. “Location Is a Major Barrier for Transferring U.S.
Fossil Fuel Employment to Green Jobs.” Nature Communications 14: 5711.
https://doi.org/10.1038/s41467-023-41133-9.
Louie, E., and J. Pearce. 2016. “Retraining Investment for U.S. Transition from Coal to
Solar Photovoltaic Employment.” Energy Economics 57: 295–302. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.eneco.2016.05.016.
References | 353

Lucas, R. 1988. “On the Mechanics of Economic Development.” Journal of Monetary
Economics 22, no. 1: 3–42. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(88)90168-7.
Lucking, B., N. Bloom, and J. Van Reenen. 2020. “Have R&D Spillovers Declined in the
21st Century?” Fiscal Studies 40, no. 4: 561–90. https://doi.
org/10.1111/1475-5890.12195.
Manpower Group. 2022. “The United States’ 2022 Talent Shortage.” https://
go.manpowergroup.com/hubfs/Talent%20Shortage%202022/MPG_2022_TS_
Infographic-US.pdf.
Marvel, K., W. Su, R. Delgado, S. Aarons, A. Chatterjee, M. Garcia, Z. Hausfather, et al.
2023. “Ch. 2: Climate Trends.” In Fifth National Climate Assessment, ed. A.
Crimmins, C. Avery, D. Easterling, K. Kunkel, B. Stewart, and T. Maycock.
Washington: U.S. Global Change Research Program. https://doi.org/10.7930/
NCA5.2023.CH2.
McMillan, M., and D. Rodrik. 2011. Globalization, Structural Change and Productivity
Growth. NBER Working Paper 17143. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of
Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w17143.
Meckling, J., N. Kelsey, E. Biber, and J. Zysman. 2015. “Winning Coalitions for Climate
Policy.” Science 349, no. 6253: 1170–71. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.
aab1336.
Meckling, J., and J. Nahm. 2021. “Strategic State Capacity: How States Counter Opposition to Climate Policy.” Comparative Political Studies 55, no. 3: 493–523.
https://doi.org/10.1177/00104140211024308.
Mendell, R., M. Einberger, and K. Siegner. 2022. “FERC Could Slash Inflation and
Double Renewables with These Grid Upgrades.” Rocky Mountain Institute.
https://rmi.org/ferc-could-slash-inflation-and-double-renewables-grid-upgrades/.
Meng, K. 2023. Estimating Path Dependence in Energy Transitions. NBER Working
Paper 22536. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://
doi.org/10.3386/w22536.
Nahm, J. 2021. Collaborative Advantage: Forging Green Industries in the New Global
Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press. https://global.oup.com/academic/
product/collaborative-advantage-9780197555361.
Nanda, R., and M. Rhodes-Kropf. 2016. “Financing Risk and Innovation.” Management
Science 63, no. 4: 901–18. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2015.2350.
Nanda, R., K. Younge, and L. Fleming. 2015. “Innovation and Entrepreneurship in
Renewable Energy.” In The Changing Frontier: Rethinking Science and Innovation Policy, ed. A. Jaffe and B. Jones, 199–232. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press. https://www.nber.org/system/files/chapters/c13048/c13048.pdf.
Narich, C., M. Kammen, T. Stark, B. Powers, J. Budiman, P. Szinai, and X. HidalgoGonzalez. 2021. “The Role of Storage in the Path to Net Zero.” Accenture and
University of California-Berkeley Renewable and Appropriate Energies Lab.
https://www.accenture.com/content/dam/accenture/final/a-com-migration/r3-3/
pdf/pdf-144/accenture-path-to-net-zero-pov.pdf.
354 |

References

National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine. 2021. Accelerating Decarbonization of the U.S. Energy System. Washington: National Academies Press.
https://doi.org/10.17226/25932.
National Renewable Energy Lab. 2023. “Annual Technology Baseline: Utility-Scale
Battery Storage.” https://atb.nrel.gov/electricity/2023/
utility-scale_battery_storage.
National Research Council. 2001. Energy Research at DOE: Was It Worth It? Energy
Efficiency and Fossil Energy Research 1978 to 2000. Washington: National
Academies Press. https://doi.org/10.17226/10165.
Nature Conservancy. 2023. “Power of Place National Executive Summary.” https://www.
nature.org/content/dam/tnc/nature/en/documents/FINAL_TNC_Power_of_
Place_National_Executive_Summary_5_2_2023.
pdf?itid=lk_inline_enhanced-template.
NCEI (National Centers for Environmental Information). 2024. “Billion-Dollar Weather
and Climate Disasters.” https://www.ncei.noaa.gov/access/billions/overview/.
Nelson, R., and S. Winter. 1985. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. https://www.hup.harvard.edu/
books/9780674272286.
Nemet, G. 2019. How Solar Energy Became Cheap: A Model for Low-Carbon Innovation. Oxford: Routledge. https://www.routledge.com/
How-Solar-Energy-Became-Cheap-A-Model-for-Low-Carbon-Innovation/
Nemet/p/book/9780367136598?utm_source=cjaffiliates&utm_medium=affiliate
s&cjevent=ced8fe67678411ee8168008b0a82b82a.
Nemet, G., and D. Kammen. 2007. “U.S. Energy Research and Development: Declining
Investment, Increasing Need, and the Feasibility of Expansion.” Energy Policy
35, no. 1: 746–55. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2005.12.012.
Nemet, G., V. Zipperer, and M. Kraus. 2018. “The Valley of Death, the Technology Pork
Barrel, and Public Support for Large Demonstration Projects.” Energy Policy
119: 154–67. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2018.04.008.
NOAA (National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration). 2024. “Billion-Dollar
Weather and Climate Disasters.” https://www.ncei.noaa.gov/access/billions/
overview.
Noailly, J., L. Nowzohour, and M. van den Heuvel. 2022. Does Environmental Policy
Uncertainty Hinder Investments Towards a Low-Carbon Economy? NBER
Working Paper 30361. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w30361.
NREL (National Renewable Energy Laboratory). 2023. “Utility-Scale Battery Storage.”
https://atb.nrel.gov/electricity/2023/utility-scale_battery_storage.
Nurkse, R. 1952. “Some International Aspects of the Problem of Economic Development.” American Economic Review 42, no. 2: 571–83. https://www.jstor.org/
stable/1910629.

References | 355

NYC Department of Buildings. 2023. “Solar Electric Generating Systems Tax Abatement
Program.” https://nyc-business.nyc.gov/nycbusiness/description/
solar-electric-generating-systems-tax-abatement-program.
OEC (Observatory of Economic Complexity). 2021. “South Korea.” https://oec.world/en/
profile/country/kor.
OCED (Office of Clean Energy Demonstrations). 2023. “OCED Funding Opportunity
Announcements.” https://oced-exchange.energy.gov/Default.
aspx#FoaId3c3d8e7f-1839-45fc-8735-c0caf87408ef.
OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development). 2023. “Greenhouse
Gas Emissions.” https://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=air_ghg.
OMB (U.S. Office of Management and Budget). 2023. “Budget Exposure to Increased
Costs and Lost Revenue Due to Climate Change: A Preliminary Assessment
and Proposed Framework for Future Assessments.” White Paper. https://www.
whitehouse.gov/wp-content/uploads/2023/03/climate_budget_exposure_fy2024.
pdf.
Pasqualetti, M., R. Righter, and P. Gipe. 2004. “History of Wind Energy.” In Encyclopedia of Energy, ed. C. Cleveland, 419–33. Cambridge: Academic Press.
https://www.researchgate.net/publication/265594973_History_of_Wind_Energy.
Pimm, A., E. Barbour, T. Cockerill, and J. Palczewski. 2019. “Evaluating the Regional
Potential for Emissions Reduction Using Energy Storage.” In Proceedings of
2019 Offshore Energy and Storage Summit, 1–6. https://ieeexplore.ieee.org/
document/8867357.
Pirani, S. 2018. Burning Up: A Global History of Fossil Fuel Consumption. London:
Pluto Press. https://www.jstor.org/stable/j.ctv4ncp7q.14?typeAccessWorkflow=l
ogin&seq=10.
Pollin, R., and B. Callaci. 2016. “The Economics of Just Transition: A Framework for
Supporting Fossil-Fuel-Dependent Workers and Communities in the United
States.” Working paper, Labor Studies Journal. https://peri.umass.edu/publication/
item/762-the-economics-of-just-transition-a-framework-forsupporting-fossil-fuel-dependent-workers-and-communities-in-the-united-states.
Quinn, R. 2013. “Rethinking Antibiotic Research and Development: World War II and the
Penicillin Collaborative.” American Journal of Public Health 103, no. 3:
426–34. https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC3673487/.
Raimi, D., E. Grubert, J. Higdon, G. Metcalf, S. Pesek, and D. Singh. 2023. “The Fiscal
Implications of the U.S. Transition Away from Fossil Fuels.” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 17, no. 2: 295–315. https://doi.
org/10.1086/725250.
Ranis, G., and J. Fei. 1961. “A Theory of Economic Development.” American Economic
Review 51, no. 4: 533–65. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1812785.

356 |

References

Rao, V. 1952. “Investment, Income and the Multiplier in an Under-Developed Economy.”
Indian Economic Review 1, no. 1: 55–67. https://doi.
org/10.1177/0019466220080205.
Rapson, D., and E. Muehlegger. 2023. The Economics of Electric Vehicles. NBER
Working Paper 29093. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w29093.
Riofrancos, T., A. Kendall, K. Dayemo, M. Haugen, K. McDonald, B. Hassan, M. Slattery, and X. Lillehei. 2023. “Achieving Zero Emissions with More Mobility and
Less Mining.” Climate and Community Project. https://www.climateandcommunity.org/more-mobility-less-mining.
RMI. 2022. “FERC Could Slash Inflation and Double Renewables with These Grid
Upgrades.” https://rmi.org/
ferc-could-slash-inflation-and-double-renewables-grid-upgrades/.
Rodrik, D. 2014. “Green Industrial Policy.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 30, no. 3:
469–91. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxrep/gru025.
Romer, P. 1990. “Endogenous Technological Change.” Journal of Political Economy 98,
no. 5: S71–102. https://www.jstor.org/stable/2937632.
Sandalow, D., M. Meidan, P. Andrews-Speed, A. Hove, S. Qiu, and E. Downie. 2022.
“Guide to Chinese Climate Policy 2022.” Oxford Institute of Energy Studies,
chap. 21: “Clean Energy R&D.” https://chineseclimatepolicy.oxfordenergy.org/
book-content/domestic-policies/clean-energy-rd/.
Sankaran, V., H. Parmar, and K. Collison. 2021. “Just & Reasonable? Transmission
Upgrades Charged to Interconnecting Generators Are Delivering System-Wide
Benefits.” American Council on Renewable Energy. https://acore.org/
wp-content/uploads/2021/10/Just_and_Reasonable.pdf.
Schlenker, W., and M. Roberts. 2009. “Nonlinear Temperature Effects Indicate Severe
Damages to U.S. Crop Yields under Climate Change.” Proceedings of the
National Academy of Sciences 106, no. 37: 15594–98. https://doi.org/10.1073/
pnas.0906865106.
UNFCCC (United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change). 2023. “2023
Voluntary Supplement to the U.S. Fifth Biennial Report.” https://unfccc.int/
sites/default/files/resource/US_BR_Voluntary_Suplement_2023.pdf.
———. 2024a. “The Paris Agreement.” https://unfccc.int/process-and-meetings/
the-paris-agreement.
———. 2024b. “What Is the Kyoto Protocol?” https://unfccc.int/kyoto_protocol.
U.S. Congress. 2004. “H.R.4520: American Jobs Creation Act of 2004.” https://www.
congress.gov/bill/108th-congress/house-bill/4520.
U.S. Department of the Treasury. 2023. “New U.S. Department of the Treasury Analysis:
Inflation Reduction Act Driving Clean Energy Investment to Underserved
Communities, Communities at the Forefront of Fossil Fuel Production.” https://
home.treasury.gov/news/press-releases/jy1931.

References | 357

Van den Heuvel, M., and D. Popp. 2022. The Role of Venture Capital and Governments
in Clean Energy: Lessons from the First Cleantech Bubble. NBER Working
Paper 29919. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://
doi.org/10.3386/w29919.
Van de Ven, D., I. Capellan-Peréz, I. Arto, I. Cazcarro, C. de Castro, P. Patel, and M.
Gonzalez-Eguino. 2021. “The Potential Land Requirements and Related Land
Use Change Emissions of Solar Energy.” Scientific Reports 11. https://doi.
org/10.1038/s41598-021-82042-5.
Vanatta, M., M. Craig, B. Rathod, J. Florez, I. Bromley-Dulfano, and D. Smith. 2022.
“The Costs of Replacing Coal Plant Jobs with Local Instead of Distant Wind
and Solar Jobs across the United States.” iScience 25, no. 8. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.isci.2022.104817.
Van Zalk, J., and P. Behrens. 2018. “The Spatial Extent of Renewable and Non-Renewable Power Generation: A Review and Meta-Analysis of Power Densities and
Their Application in the U.S.” Energy Policy 123: 83–91. https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0301421518305512.
Victor, D. 2009. “The Politics of Fossil-Fuel Subsidies.” Working paper, Global Studies
Initiative. https://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1520984.
Way, R., M. Ives, P. Mealy, and J. Farmer. 2022. “Empirically Grounded Technology
Forecasts and the Energy Transition.” Joule 6, no. 9: 2057–82. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.joule.2022.08.009.
Weber, J. 2020. “How Should We Think about Environmental Policy and Jobs? An
Analogy with Trade Policy and an Illustration from U.S. Coal Mining.” Review
of Environmental Economics and Policy 14. no. 1. https://doi.org/10.1093/reep/
rez016.
White House. 2022. “Federal Budget Exposure to Climate Risk.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/wp-content/uploads/2022/04/ap_21_climate_risk_fy2023.pdf.
Zacarias, M., and J. Nakano. 2023. “Exploring the Hydrogen Midstream: Distribution and
Delivery.” Center for Strategic and International Studies. https://www.csis.org/
analysis/exploring-hydrogen-midstream-distribution-and-delivery.

Chapter 7
Abada, I., and X. Lambin. 2023. “Artificial Intelligence: Can Seemingly Collusive
Outcomes Be Avoided?” Management Science 69, no. 9: 5042–65. https://doi.
org/10.1287/mnsc.2022.4623.
Abbott, R., and B. Bogenschneider. 2018. “Should Robots Pay Taxes? Tax Policy in the
Age of Automation.” Harvard Law & Policy Review 12. https://heinonline.org/
HOL/Page?handle=hein.journals/
harlpolrv12&div=10&g_sent=1&casa_token=&collection=journals.
Acemoglu, D. 2021. Harms of AI. NBER Working Paper 29247. Cambridge, MA:
National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w29247.

358 |

References

Acemoglu, D., G. Anderson, D. Beede, C. Buffington, E. Childress, E. Dinlersoz, L.
Foster, N. Goldschlag, J. Haltiwanger, Z. Kroff, P. Restrepo, and N. Zolas.
2022. Automation and the Workforce: A Firm-Level View from the 2019 Annual
Business Survey. NBER Working Paper 30659. Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau of Economic Research. https://www.nber.org/system/files/working_
papers/w30659/w30659.pdf.
Acemoglu, D., D. Autor, J. Hazell, and P. Restrepo. 2020. AI and Jobs: Evidence from
Online Vacancies. NBER Working Paper 28257. Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w28257.
Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. Robinson, 2005. “Chapter 6: Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth.” In Handbook of Economic Growth 1:
385–472. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1574-0684(05)01006-3.
Acemoglu, D., A. Manera, and P. Restrepo. 2020. Does the U.S. Tax Code Favor Automation? NBER Working Paper 27052. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of
Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w27052.
Acemoglu, D. and Pischke, J. 1998. “Why Do Firms Train? Theory and Evidence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, no. 1: 79–119. https://doi.
org/10.1162/003355398555531.
Acemoglu, D., and P. Restrepo. 2018. “The Race between Man and Machine: Implications of Technology for Growth, Factor Shares, and Employment.” American
Economic Review 108, no. 6: 1488–542. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20160696.
———. 2019. “Automation and New Tasks: How Technology Displaces and Reinstates
Labor.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 33, no. 2: 3–30. https://doi.
org/10.1257/jep.33.2.3.
———. 2020. “Robots and Jobs: Evidence from U.S. Labor Markets.” Journal of Political Economy 128, no. 6: 2188–244. https://doi.org/10.1086/705716.
Aghion, P., N. Bloom, R. Blundell, R. Griffith, and P. Howitt. 2005. “Competition and
Innovation: An Inverted-U Relationship.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 120,
no. 2: 701–28. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/120.2.701.
Aghion, P., and P. Bolton. 1992. “An Incomplete Contracts Approach to Financial
Contracting.” Review of Economic Studies 59, no. 3: 473–94. https://doi.
org/10.2307/2297860.
Aghion, P., and P. Howitt. 1992. “A Model of Growth Through Creative Destruction.”
Econometrica 60, no. 2: 323–51. https://doi.org/10.2307/2951599.
Aghion, P., P. Howitt, and G. Violante. 2002. “General Purpose Technology and Wage
Inequality.” Journal of Economic Growth 7, no. 4: 315–45. https://doi.
org/10.1023/A:1020875717066.
Agrawal, A., J. Gans, and A. Goldfarb. 2018. Prediction Machines: The Simple
Economics of Artificial Intelligence. Brighton, MA: Harvard Business Review
Press. https://www.predictionmachines.ai/pre-order.

References | 359

———. 2022. Power and Prediction: The Disruptive Economics of Artificial Intelligence.
Brighton, MA: Harvard Business Review Press. https://www.predictionmachines.ai/power-prediction.
Akcigit, U., J. Grigsby, T. Nicholas, and S. Stantcheva. 2021. “Taxation and Innovation in
the Twentieth Century.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 137, no. 1: 329–85.
https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjab022.
Akerman, A., I. Gaarder, and M. Mogstad. 2015. “The Skill Complementarity of Broadband Internet.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 130, no. 4: 1781-1824. https://
doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjv028.
Alchian, A. 1965. “Some Economics of Property Rights.” Il Politico 30, no. 4: 816–29.
https://www.jstor.org/stable/43206327.
Amershi, S., M. Cakmak, W. Knox, and T. Kulesza. 2014. “Power to the People: The
Role of Humans in Interactive Machine Learning.” AI Magazine 35, no. 4:
105–20. https://doi.org/10.1609/aimag.v35i4.2513.
Anthropic. 2024. “Anthropic-SDK-Python.” Code commit. https://github.com/anthropics/
anthropic-sdk-python.
Appel, G., J. Neelbauer, and D. Schweidel. 2023. “Generative AI Has an Intellectual
Problem.” Harvard Business Review. https://hbr.org/2023/04/
generative-ai-has-an-intellectual-property-problem.
Arena F., and G. Pau. 2019. “An Overview of Vehicular Communications.” Future
Internet 11, no. 2: 27. https://doi.org/10.3390/fi11020027.
Armstrong, S., K. Sotala, and S. Ó hÉigeartaigh. 2014. “The Errors, Insights and Lessons
of Famous AI Predictions—and What They Mean for the Future.” Journal of
Experimental & Theoretical Artificial Intelligence 26, no. 3: 317–42. https://
doi.org/10.1080/0952813X.2014.895105.
Arrow, K. 1962. “The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing.” Review of
Economic Studies 29, no. 3: 155–73. https://doi.org/10.2307/2295952.
Athey, S., K. Bryan, and J. Gans. 2020. “The Allocation of Decision Authority to Human
and Artificial Intelligence.” AEA Papers and Proceedings 110: 80–84. https://
doi.org/10.1257/pandp.20201034.
Athey, S., and F. Scott Morton. 2022. “Platform Annexation.” Antitrust Law Journal 84,
no. 3. https://www.americanbar.org/content/dam/aba/publications/antitrust/
journal/84/3/platform-annexation.pdf.
Authors Guild v. Google, Inc. 2015. U.S. Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit, No.
13-4829-cv. https://law.justia.com/cases/federal/appellate-courts/ca2/134829/13-4829-2015-10-16.html.
Autor, D. 2015. “Why Are There So Many Jobs? The History and Future of Workplace
Automation.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 29, no. 3: 3–30. https://doi.
org/10.1257/jep.29.3.3.
Autor, D., C. Chin, A. M. Salomons, and B. Seegmiller. 2022. New Frontiers: The
Origins and Content of New Work, 1940–2018. NBER Working Paper 30389.

360 |

References

Cambridge, MA: National Bureau for Economic Research. https://doi.
org/10.3386/w30389.
Autor, D., and D. Dorn. 2013. “The Growth of Low-Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market.” American Economic Review 103, no. 5:
1553–97. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.103.5.1553.
Autor, D., D. Dorn, and G. Hanson. 2013. “The China Syndrome: Local Labor Market
Effects of Import Competition in the United States.” American Economic
Review 103, no. 6: 2121–68. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.103.6.2121.
———. 2021. On the Persistence of the China Shock. NBER Working Paper 29401.
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.
org/10.3386/w29401.
Autor, D., C. Goldin, and L. Katz. 2020. Extending the Race Between Education and
Technology. NBER Working Paper 26705. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau
for Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w26705.
Autor, D., F. Levy, and R. Murnane. 2003. “The Skill Content of Recent Technological
Change: An Empirical Exploration.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, no.
4: 1279–1333. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355303322552801.
Babina, T., A. Fedyk, A. He, and J. Hodson. 2024. “Artificial Intelligence, Firm Growth,
and Product Innovation.” Journal of Financial Economics 151, no. 103745.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2023.103745.
Bambauer, D., and M. Surdeanu. 2023. Authorbots. Arizona Legal Studies Discussion
Paper 23-13. Tucson: Arizona Legal Studies Research Paper Series. https://ssrn.
com/abstract=4443714.
Bárány, Z., and C. Siegel. 2018. “Job Polarization and Structural Change.” American
Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 10, no. 1: 57–89. https://www.aeaweb.org/
articles?id=10.1257/mac.20150258.
Barocas, S., and A. Selbst. 2016. “Big Data’s Disparate Impact.” California Law Review
104, no. 3: 671–732. https://www.jstor.org/stable/24758720.
Bartholomew, J. 2023. “Q&A: Uncovering the Labor Exploitation That Powers AI.”
Columbia Journalism Review, Tow Center. https://www.cjr.org/tow_center/
qa-uncovering-the-labor-exploitation-that-powers-ai.php.
Bartlett, R., A. Morse, R. Stanton, and N. Wallace. 2022. “Consumer-Lending Discrimination in the FinTech Era.” Journal of Financial Economics 143, no. 1: 30–56.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2021.05.047.
Barzel, Y., and D. Allen. 2023. Economic Analysis of Property Rights. New York:
Cambridge University Press. https://www.cambridge.org/core/books/economicanalysis-of-property-rights/6D5E9A3AA67284FD9A12379CA3028D50.
Beauchêne, D. 2019. “Is Ambiguity Aversion Bad for Innovation?” Journal of Economic
Theory 183: 1154–76. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jet.2019.07.015.
Becker, G., and K. Murphy. 1994. “Chapter XI: The Division of Labor, Coordination
Costs, and Knowledge.” In Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical

References | 361

Analysis with Special Reference to Education, 3rd Edition. Chicago: University
of Chicago Press. https://www.nber.org/books-and-chapters/
human-capital-theoretical-and-empirical-analysis-special-reference-educationthird-edition.
Bell, A., and G. Parchomovsky. 2005. “A Theory of Property.” Cornell Law Review 90,
no. 3: 531–616. https://scholarship.law.cornell.edu/clr/vol90/iss3/1.
Bernheim, B., and M. Whinston. 1990. “Multimarket Contact and Collusive Behavior.”
RAND Journal of Economics 21, no. 1: 1–26. https://www.jstor.org/
stable/2555490.
Bessen, J., M. Goos, A. Salomons, and W. van den Berge. 2023. “What Happens to
Workers at Firms That Automate?” Review of Economics and Statistics, 1–45.
https://doi.org/10.1162/rest_a_01284.
Biggs, R. 1983. “The Impact of the Interstate Highway System on Nonmetropolitan
Development, 1950–75.” In Beyond the Urban Fringe: Land Use Issues in
Nonmetropolitan America, ed. R. Platt and G. Macinko, 83–105. Minneapolis:
University of Minnesota Press. https://books.google.com/books?hl=en&lr=&id=
Nm0I8ogefv0C&oi=fnd&pg=PA83&dq=interstate+highway+system+migration
&ots=jTrCdS1jud&sig=KpyxVj-EBIhO4MGC9XppYQ2nEew.
Bischoff, K., and S. Reardon. 2013. “Residential Segregation by Income, 1970–2009.”
Working paper, US2010 Project. https://cepa.stanford.edu/content/
residential-segregation-income-1970-2009.
Billard, A., and D. Kragic. 2019. “Trends and Challenges in Robot Manipulation.”
Science. https://www.science.org/doi/full/10.1126/science.aat8414.
Bloom, N., C. Jones, J. Van Reenen, and M. Webb. 2020. “Are Ideas Getting Harder to
Find?” American Economic Review 110, no. 4: 1104–44. https://doi.
org/10.1257/aer.20180338.
Bloom, N., J. Van Reenen, and H. Williams. 2019. “A Toolkit of Policies to Promote
Innovation.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 33, no. 3: 163–84. https://doi.
org/10.1257/jep.33.3.163.
BLS (U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics). 2023. “Fastest Growing Occupations: Occupational Outlook Handbook.” https://www.bls.gov/ooh/fastest-growing.htm.
Boldrin, M., and D. Levine. 2013. “The Case Against Patents.” Journal of Economic
Perspectives 27, no. 1: 3–22. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.27.1.3.
Bolton, P., and M. Dewatripont. 1994. “The Firm as a Communication Network.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 109, no. 4: 809–39. https://doi.
org/10.2307/2118349.
Bommasani, R., D. Hudson, E. Adeli, R. Altman, S. Arora, S. von Arx, M. Bernstein, J.
Bohg, A. Bosselut, E. Brunskill, E. Brynjolfsson, S. Buch, D. Card, R.
Castellon, N. Chatterji, A. Chen, K. Creel, J. Quincy Davis, D. Demszky, C.
Donahue, M. Doumbouya, E. Durmus, S. Ermon, J. Etchemendy, K.
Ethayarajh, L. Fei-Fei, C. Finn, T. Gale, L. Gillespie, K. Goel. N. Goodman, S.
Grossman, N. Guha, T. Hashimoto, P. Henderson, J. Hewitt, D. Ho, J. Hong, K.
362 |

References

Hsu, J. Huang, T. Icard, S. Jain, D. Jurafsky, P. Kalluri, S. Karamcheti, G.
Keeling, F. Khani, O. Khattab, P. Wei Koh, M. Krass. R. Krishna, R. Kuditipudi, A. Kumar, F. Ladhak, M. Lee, T. Lee, J. Leskovec, I. Levent, X.L. Li, X.
Li, T. Ma, A. Malik, C. Manning, S. Mirchandani, E. Mitchell, Z. Munyikwa, S.
Nair, A. Narayan, D. Narayanan, B. Newman, A. Nie, J. Niebles, H. Nilforoshan, J. Nyarko, G. Ogut, L. Orr, I. Papadimitriou, J. Sung Park, C. Piech, E.
Portelance, C. Potts, A. Raghunathan, R. Reich, H. Ren, F. Rong, Y. Roohani,
C. Ruiz, J. Ryan, C. Ré, D. Sadigh, S. Sagawa, K. Santhanam, A. Shih, K.
Srinivasan, A. Tamkin, R. Taori, A. Thomas, F. Tramèr, R. Wang, W. Wang, B.
Wu, J. Wu, Y. Wu, S. Xie, M. Yasunaga, J. You, M. Zaharia, M. Zhang, T.
Zhang, X. Zhang, Y. Zhang, L. Zheng, K. Zhou, and P. Liang. 2021. On the
Opportunities and Risks of Foundation Models. ArXiv Preprint
ArXiv:1802.04865. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University. https://doi.org/10.48550/
arXiv.2108.07258.
Bonvillian, W. 2018. “DARPA and Its ARPA-E and IARPA Clones: A Unique Innovation
Organization Model.” Industrial and Corporate Change 27, no. 5: 897–914.
https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/dty026.
Booth, A., and M. Chatterji. 1998. “Unions and Efficient Training.” Economic Journal
108, no. 447: 328–43. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0297.00290.
Boudreau, K., L. Jeppesen, and M. Miric. 2022. “Profiting from Digital Innovation:
Patents, Copyright and Performance.” Research Policy 51, no. 5. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.respol.2022.104477.
Braghieri, L., R. Levy, and A. Makarin. 2022. “Social Media and Mental Health.” American Economic Review 112, no. 11: 3660–93. https://doi.org/10.1257/
aer.20211218.
Brau, R., and C. Carraro. 1999. “Voluntary Approaches, Market Structure and Competition.” Fondazione eni Enrico Mattei. FEEM Working Paper 53–99 https://doi.
org/10.2139/ssrn.200614.
Bresnahan, T., and M. Trajtenberg. 1995. “General Purpose Technologies ‘Engines of
Growth’?” Journal of Econometrics 65, no. 1: 83–108. https://doi.
org/10.1016/0304-4076(94)01598-T.
Brodsky, J. 2016. “Autonomous Vehicle Regulation.” Berkeley Technology Law Journal
21, no. 2: 851–78. https://www.jstor.org/stable/26377774.
Brooks, F. 1996. The Mythical Man-Month. Boston: Addison-Wesley Professional. https://
web.eecs.umich.edu/~weimerw/2018-481/readings/mythical-man-month.pdf.
Broussard, W. 2009. “The Promise and Peril of Collective Licensing.” Journal of Intellectual Property Law 17, no. 1: 21–34. https://heinonline.org/HOL/P?h=hein.
journals/intpl17&i=23.
Brown, N. 2023. “Bots Behaving Badly: A Products Liability Approach to the ChatbotGenerated Defamation.” Journal of Free Speech 3, no. 2: 389–424. https://
heinonline.org/HOL/P?h=hein.journals/jfspl3&i=389.

References | 363

Brown, I. 2020. “Interoperability as a Tool for Competition Regulation.” https://econpapers.repec.org/paper/osflawarx/fbvxd.htm.
Brown, J., C. Coile, and S. Weisbenner. 2010. “The Effects of Inheritance Receipt on
Retirement.” Review of Economics and Statistics 92, no. 2: 425–34. https://doi.
org/10.1162/rest.2010.11182.
Brown, T., B. Mann, N. Ryder, M. Subbiah, J. Kaplan, P. Dhariwal, A. Neelakantan, P.
Shyam, G. Sastry, A. Askell, S. Agarwal, A. Herbert-Voss, G. Krueger, T.
Henighan, R. Child, A. Ramesh, D. Ziegler, J. Wu, C. Winter, C. Hesse, M.
Chen, E. Sigler, M. Litwin, S. Gray, B. Chess, J. Clark, C. Berner, S. McClandish, A. Radford, I. Sutskever, and D. Amodei. 2020. “Language Models Are
Few-Shot Learners.” In Proceedings of the 34th International Conference on
Neural Information Processing Systems, 1877–1901. NIPS’20. Red Hook, NY:
Curran Associates. https://dl.acm.org/doi/abs/10.5555/3495724.3495883.
Brozen, Y. 1957. “The Economics of Automation.” American Economic Review 47, no. 2:
339–50. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1831605.
Brynjolfsson, E., X. Hui, and M. Liu. 2019. “Does Machine Translation Affect International Trade? Evidence from a Large Digital Platform.” Management Science
65, no. 12: 5449–60. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2019.3388.
Brynjolfsson, E., D. Li, and L. Raymond. 2023. Generative AI at Work. NBER Working
Paper 31161. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau for Economic Research. https://
doi.org/10.3386/w31161.
Brynjolfsson, E., T. Mitchell, and D. Rock. 2018. “What Can Machines Learn and What
Does It Mean for Occupations and the Economy?” AEA Papers and Proceedings 108: 43–47. https://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/pandp.20181019.
Brynjolfsson, E., D. Rock, and C. Syverson. 2021. “The Productivity J-Curve: How
Intangibles Complement General Purpose Technologies.” American Economic
Journal: Macroeconomics 13, no. 1: 333–72. https://doi.org/10.1257/
mac.20180386.
Burnell, R., W. Schellaert, J. Burden, T. Ullman, F. Martínez-Plumed, J. Tenenbaum, D.
Rutar, L. Cheke, J. Sohl-Dickstein, M. Mitchell, D. Kiela, M. Shanahan, E.
Voorhees, A. Cohn, J. Leibo, and J. Hernández-Orallo. 2023. “Rethink
Reporting of Evaluation Results in AI.” Science 380, no. 6641: 136–38. https://
doi.org/10.1126/science.adf6369.
Buolamwini, J., and T. Gebru. 2018. “Gender Shades: Intersectional Accuracy Disparities
in Commercial Gender Classification.” Proceedings of the First Conference on
Fairness, Accountability, and Transparency, PMLR 81: 77–91. https://proceedings.mlr.press/v81/buolamwini18a.html.
Byström, K., and K. Järvelin. 1995. “Task Complexity Affects Information Seeking and
Use.” Information Processing & Management 31, no. 2: 191–213. https://doi.
org/10.1016/0306-4573(95)80035-R.
Calabresi, G., and A. Melamed. 1972. “Property Rights, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral.” Harvard Law Review 85, no. 6: 1130–303.

364 |

References

https://heinonline.org/HOL/Page?handle=hein.journals/
hlr85&div=8&g_sent=1&casa_token=&collection=journals.
Calvano, E., G. Calzolari, V. Denicolò, and S. Pastorello. 2020. “Artificial Intelligence,
Algorithmic Pricing, and Collusion.” American Economic Review 110, no. 10:
3267–97. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20190623.
Census (U.S. Bureau of the Census). 2023. “CPS Historical Time Series Tables: Table
A-1. Years of School Completed by People 25 Years and Over, by Age and Sex:
Selected Years 1940–2022.” https://www.census.gov/data/tables/time-series/
demo/educational-attainment/cps-historical-time-series.html.
Chattergoon, B., and W. Kerr. 2021. Winner Takes All? Tech Clusters, Population
Centers, and the Spatial Transformation of U.S. Invention. NBER Working
Paper 29456. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://
doi.org/10.3386/w29456.
Chen, L., M. Zaharia, and J. Zou. 2023. How Is ChatGPT’s Behavior Changing Over
Time? ArXiv Preprint ArXiv: 2307.09009. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University.
https://doi.org/10.48550/arXiv.2307.09009.
Chen, L., Z. Jin, S. Eyuboglu, C. Ré, M. Zaharia, and J. Zou. 2022. “HAPI: A LargeScale Longitudinal Dataset of Commercial ML API Predictions.” Advances in
Neural Information Processing Systems 35. https://proceedings.neurips.cc/
paper_files/paper/2022/hash/9bcd0bdb2777fe8c729b682f07e993f1-AbstractDatasets_and_Benchmarks.html.
Cherney, M. 2021. “Buzz Off, Bees. Pollination Robots Are Here.” Wall Street Journal,
July 7. https://www.wsj.com/articles/buzz-off-bees-pollination-robots-are-here11625673660?reflink=desktopwebshare_permalink.
Chetty, R. 2008. “Moral Hazard versus Liquidity and Optimal Unemployment Insurance.”
Journal of Political Economy 116, no. 2: 173–234. https://doi.
org/10.1086/588585.
Chesterman, S. 2021. “Through a Glass, Darkly: Artificial Intelligence and the Problem
of Opacity.” American Journal of Comparative Law 69, no. 2: 271–94. https://
doi.org/10.1093/ajcl/avab012.
Chialastri, A. 2012. “Automation in Aviation.” INTECH Open Access. https://pdfs.semanticscholar.org/8232/21400579c2d309f84b33667cf3a7b4772d04.pdf.
Christensen, P., and C. Timmins. 2023. “The Damages and Distortions from Discrimination in the Rental Housing Market.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 138, no.
4: 2505–57. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjad029.
Chui, M., E. Hazan, R. Roberts, A. Singla, K. Smaje, A. Sukharevsky, L. Yee, and R.
Zemmel. 2023. “The Economic Potential of Generative AI: The Next Productivity Frontier.” McKinsey & Company. https://www.mckinsey.com/capabilities/
mckinsey-digital/our-insights/
the-economic-potential-of-generative-ai-the-next-productivity-frontier.
Coase, R. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law and Economics 56, no. 4:
837–77. https://doi.org/10.1086/674872.
References | 365

CEA (Council of Economic Advisers). 2022. Economic Report of the President. Washington: U.S. Government Publishing Office. https://www.whitehouse.gov/
wp-content/uploads/2022/04/ERP-2022.pdf.
———. 2023. Economic Report of the President. Washington: U.S. Government
Publishing Office. https://www.whitehouse.gov/wp-content/uploads/2023/03/
ERP-2023.pdf.
Costanza-Chock, S., I. Raji, and J. Buolamwini. 2022. “Who Audits the Auditors?
Recommendations from a Field Scan of the Algorithmic Auditing Ecosystem.”
In Proceedings of the 2022 ACM Conference on Fairness, Accountability, and
Transparency, 1571–83. New York: Association for Computing Machinery.
https://doi.org/10.1145/3531146.3533213.
Costinot, A. 2009. “On the Origins of Comparative Advantage.” Journal of International
Economics 77, no. 2: 255–64. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2009.01.007.
Cowen, T. 2017. “Why Hasn’t Economic Progress Lowered Work Hours More?” Social
Philosophy & Policy 34, no. 2: 190–212. https://doi.org/10.1017/
S0265052517000267.
CRS (Congressional Research Service). 2023a. “Generative Artificial Intelligence and
Copyright Law.” https://crsreports.congress.gov/product/pdf/LSB/LSB10922.
———. 2023b. “Trade Adjustment Assistance for Workers: Background and Current
Status.” https://crsreports.congress.gov/product/pdf/R/R47200.
———. 2024. “Section 230: An Overview.” https://crsreports.congress.gov/product/
pdf/R/R46751.
Dally, W., S. Keckler, and D. Kirk. 2021. “Evolution of the Graphics Processing Unit
(GPU)”. IEEE Micro 41, no. 6: 42–51. https://doi.org/10.1109/
MM.2021.3113475.
Dalvi, M., and J. Refalo. 2008. “An Economic Analysis of Libel Law.” Eastern Economic
Journal 34, no. 1: 74–91. http://www.jstor.org/stable/20642394.
Dastin, J. 2018. “Insight: Amazon Scraps Secret AI Recruiting Tool That Showed Bias
against Women.” Reuters. https://www.reuters.com/article/amazoncom-jobsautomation/
rpt-insight-amazon-scraps-secret-ai-recruiting-tool-that-showed-biasagainst-women-idINL2N1WP1RO/.
David, P. 1990. “The Dynamo and the Computer: An Historical Perspective on the
Modern Productivity Paradox.” American Economic Review 80, no. 2: 355–61.
https://www.jstor.org/stable/2006600.
Davis, S., and T. von Wachter. 2011. Recessions and the Cost of Job Loss. NBER
Working Paper 17638. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w17638.
DeVries, T., and G. Taylor. 2018. Learning Confidence for Out-of-Distribution Detection
in Neural Networks. ArXiv Preprint ArXiv:1802.04865. Ithaca, NY: Cornell
University. https://doi.org/10.48550/arXiv.1802.04865.

366 |

References

Diamantis, M., R. Cochran, and M. Dam. 2023. “AI and the Law.” In Technology Ethics,
edited by G. Robson, and J. Tsou., 242–49. New York: Routledge. https://doi.
org/10.4324/9781003189466.
Diamond, P., and E. Saez. 2011. “The Case for a Progressive Tax: From Basic Research
to Policy Recommendations.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 25, no. 4:
165–90. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.25.4.165.
DiNardo, J., and J. Pischke. 1997. “The Returns to Computer Use Revisited: Have
Pencils Changed the Wage Structure Too?” Quarterly Journal of Economics
112, no. 1: 291–303. http://www.jstor.org/stable/2951283.
DOL (U.S. Department of Labor). 2023a. “Employer and Occupation Sections.” https://
www.dol.gov/agencies/eta/ui-modernization/improve-applications/
employer-occupation.
———. 2023b. “U.S. Department of Labor Announces Proposed Rulemaking to
Modernize Registered Apprenticeship Regulations.” https://www.dol.gov/newsroom/releases/eta/eta20231214-0.
———. 2023c. “Reemployment Services and Eligibility Assessment Grants.” https://
www.dol.gov/agencies/eta/american-job-centers/RESEA.
Dong, X., Z. Yu, W. Cao, Y. Shi and Q. Ma, 2020. “A Survey on Ensemble Learning.”
Frontiers of Computer Science 14: 241–58. https://doi.org/10.1007/
s11704-019-8208-z.
Dornis, T. 2020. “Artificial Intelligence and Innovation: The End of Patent Law as We
Know It.” Yale Journal of Law & Technology 23: 97–159. https://dx.doi.
org/10.2139/ssrn.3668137.
Du Boff, R. 1967. “The Introduction of Electric Power in American Manufacturing.”
Economic History Review 20, no. 3: 509–18. https://doi.org/10.2307/2593069.
Eschner, K. 2017. “Three Ways the Interstate System Changed America.” Smithsonian
Magazine, June. https://www.smithsonianmag.com/smart-news/
three-ways-interstate-system-changed-america-180963815/.
Edwards, B. 2023. “AI-Generated Books Force Amazon to Cap E-Book Publications to 3
Per Day.” Ars Technica. https://arstechnica.com/information-technology/2023/09/
ai-generated-books-force-amazon-to-cap-ebook-publications-to-3-per-day/.
Ellingrud, K., S. Sanghvi, G. Dandona, A. Madgavkar, M. Chui, O. White, and P. Hasebe.
2023. “Generative AI and the Future of Work in America.” McKinsey Global
Institute. https://www.mckinsey.com/mgi/our-research/
generative-ai-and-the-future-of-work-in-america.
Eloundou, T., S. Manning, P. Mishkin, and D. Rock. 2023. GPTs Are GPTs: An Early
Look at the Labor Market Impact Potential of Large Language Models. ArXiv
Preprint ArXiv:2303.10130. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University. https://doi.
org/10.48550/arXiv.2303.10130.

References | 367

Engler, A. 2021. “Enrollment Algorithms Are Contributing to the Crises of Higher Education.” Brookings Institution, AI Governance. https://www.brookings.edu/
articles/
enrollment-algorithms-are-contributing-to-the-crises-of-higher-education/.
European Parliament Committee on Legal Affairs. 2017. “Draft Report with Recommendations to the Commission on Civil Law Rules on Robotics.” https://www.
europarl.europa.eu/doceo/document/JURI-PR-582443_EN.pdf.
Fama, E., and M. Jensen. 1983. “Separation of Ownership and Control.” Journal of Law
& Economics 26, no. 2: 301–25. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.94034.
Fan, W., J. Liu, S. Zhu, and P. Pardalos. 2020. “Investigating the Impacting Factors for
the Healthcare Professionals to Adopt Artificial Intelligence-Based Medical
Diagnosis Support System (AIMDSS).” Annals of Operations Research 294,
no. 2: 567–92. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-018-2818-y.
Farre-Mensa, J., D. Hegde, and A. Ljungqvist. 2019. “What Is a Patent Worth? Evidence
from the U.S. Patent ‘Lottery’?” Journal of Finance 75, no. 2: 639–82. https://
doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12867.
Farrell, J., and P. Klemperer. 2007. “Chapter 31 Coordination and Lock-In: Competition
with Switching Costs and Network Effects.” Handbook of Industrial Organization 3: 1967–2072. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1573-448X(06)03031-7.
Felten, E., M. Raj, and R. Seamans. 2021. “Occupational, Industry, and Geographic
Exposure to Artificial Intelligence: A Novel Dataset and Its Potential Uses.”
Strategic Management Journal 42, no. 12: 2195–2217. https://doi.org/10.1002/
smj.3286.
Fisher, J., and C. Houseworth. 2013. “Occupation Inflation in the Current Population
Survey.” Journal of Economic and Social Measurement 38, no. 3: 243–61.
https://content.iospress.com/articles/journal-of-economic-and-social-measurement/jem00377.
Florida, R., and C. Mellander. 2015. “Segregated City: The Geography of Economic
Segregation in America’s Metros.” Martin Prosperity Institute. https://urn.kb.se/
resolve?urn=urn:nbn:se:hj:diva-28303.
Foster, A., and M. Rosenzweig. 2010. “Microeconomics of Technology Adoption.”
Annual Review of Economics 2, no. 1: 395–424. https://doi.org/10.1146/
annurev.economics.102308.124433.
Frank, R. 2008. “Context Is More Important Than Keynes Realized.” In Revisiting
Keynes: Economic Possibilities for Our Grandchildren, ed. L. Pecchi, and G.
Piga, 143–50. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. https://andrewmbailey.com/money/
readings/pecchi.pdf.
Freeman, R. 2008. “Why Do We Work More Than Keynes Expected?” In Revisiting
Keynes: Economic Possibilities for Our Grandchildren, ed. L. Pecchi and G.
Piga, 135–42. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. https://dash.harvard.edu/bitstream/
handle/1/34310002/Why-Do-We-Work-More-Keynes-Expected_MS-for-PecchiPiga-VOL-4-07_0.pdf.

368 |

References

Frey, C., and M. Osborne. 2017. “The Future of Employment: How Susceptible Are Jobs
to Computerisation?” Technological Forecasting and Social Change 114:
254–80. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.techfore.2016.08.019.
Frischmann, B, A. Marciano, and G. Ramello. 2019. “Retrospectives: Tragedy of the
Commons after 50 Years.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 33, no. 4: 211–28.
https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.33.4.211.
FTC (U.S. Federal Trade Commission). 2023. “Generative AI Raises Competition
Concerns.” https://www.ftc.gov/policy/advocacy-research/tech-at-ftc/2023/06/
generative-ai-raises-competition-concerns.
Furman, J., and R. Seamans. 2019. “AI and the Economy.” Innovation Policy and the
Economy 19: 161–91. https://doi.org/10.1086/699936.
GAO (U.S. Government Accountability Office). 2018. “Personal Information, Private
Companies.” https://www.gao.gov/blog/2018/05/01/
personal-information-private-companies.
Ganguli, D., L. Lovitt, J. Kernion, A. Askell, Y. Bai, S. Kadavath, B. Mann, E. Perez, N.
Schiefer, K. Ndousse, A. Jones, S. Bowman, A. Chen, T. Conerly, N. DasSarma,
D. Drain, N. Elhage, S. El-Showk, S. Fort, Z. Hatfield-Dodds, T. Henighan, D.
Hernandez, T. Hume, J. Jacobson, S. Johnston, S. Kravec, C. Olsson, S. Ringer,
E. Tran-Johnson, D. Amodei, T. Brown, N. Joseph, S. McCandlish, C. Olah, J.
Kaplan, and J. Clark. 2022. Red Teaming Language Models to Reduce Harms:
Methods, Scaling Behaviors, and Lessons Learned. ArXiv Preprint
ArXiv:2209.07858. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University. https://doi.org/10.48550/
arXiv.2209.07858.
Garbarino, E., and S. Maxwell. 2010. “Consumer Response to Norm-Breaking Pricing
Events in E-Commerce.” Journal of Business Research 63, nos. 9–10: 1066–72.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2008.12.010.
Garicano, L. 2000. “Hierarchies and the Organization of Knowledge in Production.”
Journal of Political Economy 108, no. 5: 874–904. https://doi.
org/10.1086/317671.
Gaulé, P. 2018. “Patents and the Success of Venture-Capital-Backed Startups: Using
Examiner Assignment to Estimate Causal Effects.” Journal of Industrial
Economics 66, no. 2: 350–76. https://doi.org/10.1111/joie.12168.
Gautier, A., A. Ittoo, and P. Van Cleynenbreugel. 2020. “AI Algorithms, Price Discrimination and Collusion: A Technological, Economic, and Legal Perspective.”
European Journal of Law and Economics 50: 405–35. https://link.springer.com/
article/10.1007/s10657-020-09662-6.
Gifford, D. 2018. “Technological Triggers to Tort Revolutions: Steam Locomotives,
Autonomous Vehicles, and Accident Compensation.” Journal of Tort Law 11,
no. 1: 71–143. https://doi.org/10.1515/jtl-2017-0029.
Gless, S., E. Silverman, and T. Weigend. 2016. “If Robots Cause Harm, Who Is to
Blame? Self-Driving Cars and Criminal Liability.” New Criminal Law Review
19, no. 3: 412–36. https://doi.org/10.1525/nclr.2016.19.3.412.

References | 369

Goldin, C., and L. Katz. 2007. The Race Between Education and Technology: The Evolution of U.S. Educational Wage Differentials, 1890 to 2005. NBER Working
Paper 12984. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau for Economic Research. https://
doi.org/10.3386/w12984.
Goldman Sachs. 2023. “AI May Start to Boost U.S. GDP in 2027.” https://www.goldmansachs.com/intelligence/pages/ai-may-start-to-boost-us-gdp-in-2027.html.
Golosov, M., M. Graber, M. Mogstad, and D. Novgorodsky. 2021. How Americans
Respond to Idiosyncratic and Exogenous Changes in Household Wealth and
Unearned Income. NBER Working Paper 29000. Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w29000.
Gordon, W. 1982. “Fair Use as Market Failure: A Structural and Economic Analysis of
the Betamax Case and Its Predecessors.” J. Copyright Society USA 30: 253.
https://www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/1122296.pdf.
Green, F., S. Machin, and D. Wilkinson. 1999. “Trade Unions and Training Practices in
British Workplaces.” ILR Review 52, no. 2. https://journals.sagepub.com/
doi/10.1177/001979399905200202.
Gregory, R., O. Henfridsson, E. Kaganer, and H. Kyriakou. 2021. “The Role of Artificial
Intelligence and Data Network Effects for Creating User Value.” Academy of
Management Review 46, no. 3: 534–51. https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.2019.0178.
Grossman, S., and O. Hart. 1986. “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of
Vertical and Lateral Integration.” Journal of Political Economy 94, no. 4:
691–719. https://doi.org/10.1086/261404.
Gruber, J., S. Johnson, and E. Moretti. 2023. “Place-Based Productivity and Costs in
Science.” Entrepreneurship and Innovation Policy and the Economy 2, no. 1.
https://doi.org/10.1086/723239.
Guerreiro, J., S. Rebelo, and P. Teles. 2022. “Should Robots Be Taxed?” Review of
Economic Studies 89, no. 1: 279–311. https://doi.org/10.1093/restud/rdab019.
Guszcza, J., I. Rahwan, W. Bible, M. Cebrian, and V. Katyal. 2018. “Why We Need to
Audit Algorithms.” Harvard Business Review. https://hbr.org/2018/11/
why-we-need-to-audit-algorithms.
Hall, B., and B. Khan. 2003. Adoption of New Technology. NBER Working Paper 9730.
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.
org/10.3386/w9730.
Haller, P., and D. Heuermann. 2020. “Opportunities and Competition in Thick Labor
Markets: Evidence from Plant Closures.” Journal of Regional Science 60, no. 2:
273–95. https://doi.org/10.1111/jors.12460.
Hart, O. 2009. “Hold-Up, Asset Ownership, and Reference Points.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 124, no. 1: 267–300. https://www.jstor.org/stable/40506229.
Haucap, J., and C. Wey. 2004. “Unionisation Structures and Innovation Incentives.”
Economic Journal 114, no. 494: C149–65. https://doi.
org/10.1111/j.0013-0133.2004.00203.x.

370 |

References

Heathcote, J., K. Storesletten, and G. Violante. 2010. “The Macroeconomic Implications
of Rising Wage Inequality in the United States.” Journal of Political Economy
118, no. 4: 681–722. https://doi.org/10.1086/656632.
Heaven, W. 2023. “The Open-Source AI Boom Is Built on Big Tech’s Handouts; How
Long Will It Last?” MIT Technology Review. https://www.technologyreview.
com/2023/05/12/1072950/open-source-ai-google-openai-eleuther-meta/.
Herrmann, T., and S. Pfeiffer. 2023. “Keeping the Organization in the Loop: A SocioTechnical Extension of Human-Centered Artificial Intelligence.” AI & Society
38: 1523–42. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00146-022-01391-5.
Hestness, J., S. Narang, N. Aredalani, G. Diamos, H. Jun, H. Kianinejad, M. Patwary, Y.
Yang, and Y. Zhou. 2017. Deep Learning Scaling Is Predictable, Empirically.
ArXiv Preprint ArXiv:1712.00409. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University. https://doi.
org/10.48550/arXiv.1712.00409.
Hirsch, B. 2004. What Do Unions Do for Economic Performance. IZA Discussion Paper
892. Bonn: IZA Institute of Labor Economics. https://dx.doi.org/10.2139/
ssrn.459581.
Hitsuwari, J., Y. Ueda, W. Yun, and M. Nomura, 2023. “Does Human–AI Collaboration
Lead to More Creative Art? Aesthetic Evaluation of Human-Made and
AI-Generated Haiku Poetry.” Computers in Human Behavior 139: 107502.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2022.107502.
Honoré, A. 1961. “Ownership.” In Oxford Essays in Jurisprudence, ed. A. Guest, 106–46.
Oxford: Oxford University Press. http://fs2.american.edu/dfagel/www/OwnershipSmaller.pdf.
Horton, A. 2023. “Scarlett Johansson Takes Legal Action Against Use of Image for AI.”
Guardian. https://www.theguardian.com/film/2023/nov/01/
scarlett-johansson-artificial-intelligence-ad.
Hutson, M. 2021. “The Opacity of Artificial Intelligence Makes it Hard to Tell when
Decision-Making is Biased.” IEEE Spectrum 58, no. 2: 40–45. https://ieeexplore.ieee.org/abstract/document/9340114.
Hyman, B. 2022. “Can Displaced Labor Be Retrained? Evidence from Quasi-Random
Assignment to Trade Adjustment Assistance.” Discussion Paper, U.S. Census
Bureau, Center for Economic Studies. https://www2.census.gov/ces/wp/2022/
CES-WP-22-05.pdf.
Johnson, J., and D. Sokol. 2020. “Understanding AI Collusion and Compliance.” Working
paper, Cambridge Handbook of Compliance. https://ssrn.com/abstract=3413882.
Jones, C. 2022. “The Past and Future of Economic Growth: A Semi-Endogenous Perspective.” Annual Review of Economics 14: 125–-52. https://doi.org/10.1146/
annurev-economics-080521-012458.
Kaddour, J., J. Harris, M. Mozes, H. Bradley, R. Raileanu, and R. McHardy. 2023. Challenges and Applications of Large Language Models. ArXiv Preprint
ArXiv:2307.10169. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University. https://doi.org/10.48550/
arXiv.2307.10169.
References | 371

Kadrey et al. v. Meta Platforms, Inc. 2023. U.S. District Court for the Northern District of
California. https://dockets.justia.com/docket/california/
candce/3:2023cv03417/415175.
Kahveci, Z. 2023. “Attribution Problem of Generative AI: A View from U.S. Copyright
Law.” Journal of Intellectual Property Law & Practice 18, no. 11: 796–807.
https://doi.org/10.1093/jiplp/jpad076.
Kaplan, J., S. McCandlish, T. Henighan, T. Brown, B. Chess, R. Child, S. Gray, A.
Radford, J. Wu, and D. Amodei. 2020. Scaling Laws for Neural Language
Models. ArXiv Preprint ArXiv:2001.08361. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University.
https://doi.org/10.48550/arXiv.2001.08361.
Kapoor, S., and A. Narayanan. 2023. “Leakage and the Reproducibility Crisis in
Machine-Learning-Based Science.” Patterns 4, no. 9: 100804. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.patter.2023.100804.
Katz, M., and C. Shapiro. 1986. “Technology Adoption in the Presence of Network Externalities.” Journal of Political Economy 94, no. 4. https://www.journals.
uchicago.edu/doi/abs/10.1086/261409.
Kennan, J., and R. Wilson. 1993. “Bargaining with Private Information.” Journal of
Economic Literature 31, no. 1: 45–104. https://www.jstor.org/stable/2728150.
Keynes, J. 1930. “Economic Possibilities for Our Grandchildren.” In Essays in Persuasion, 321–32. New York: Harcourt Brace. https://doi.
org/10.1007/978-1-349-59072-8_25.
King, T., N. Aggarwal, M. Taddeo, and L. Floridi. 2020. “Artificial Intelligence Crime:
An Interdisciplinary Analysis of Foreseeable Threats and Solutions.” Science
and Engineering Ethics 26: 89–120. https://doi.org/10.1007/
s11948-018-00081-0.
Kleinberg, J., J. Ludwig, S. Mullainathan, and C. Sunstein. 2018. “Discrimination in the
Age of Algorithms.” Journal of Legal Analysis 10: 113–74. https://doi.
org/10.1093/jla/laz001.
Knepper, M. 2020. “From the Fringe to the Fore: Labor Unions and Employee Compensation.” Review of Economics and Statistics 102, no. 1: 98–112. https://doi.
org/10.1162/rest_a_00803.
Knight, F. 1921. Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. Cambridge, MA: Riverside Press
Cambridge. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org/files/docs/publications/books/risk/
riskuncertaintyprofit.pdf.
Kochan, T., B. Armstrong, J. Shah, E. Castilla, B. Likis, and M. Mangelsdorf. 2023.
“Bringing Worker Voice into Generative AI.” IWER Research. https://mitsloan.
mit.edu/centers-initiatives/institute-work-and-employment-research/
bringing-worker-voice-generative-ai.
Kochhar, R. 2023. “Which U.S. Workers Are Exposed to AI in Their Jobs?” Pew
Research Center, Social and Demographic Trends Project. https://www.pewresearch.org/social-trends/2023/07/26/
which-u-s-workers-are-more-exposed-to-ai-on-their-jobs/.
372 |

References

Korinek, A., and J. Stiglitz. 2019. “Artificial Intelligence and Its Implications for Income
Distribution and Unemployment.” In The Economics of Artificial Intelligence:
An Agenda, 349–90. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. https://www.nber.
org/system/files/chapters/c14018/c14018.pdf.
Kortum, S. 1997. “Research, Patenting, and Technological Change.” Econometrica 65,
no. 6: 1389–1419. https://doi.org/10.2307/2171741.
Krugman, P. 1981. “Intraindustry Specialization and the Gains from Trade.” Journal of
Political Economy 89, no. 5: 959–73. https://www.journals.uchicago.edu/doi/
abs/10.1086/261015.
Kumar, A., A. Raghunathan, R. Jones, T. Ma, and P. Liang. 2022. Fine-Tuning can
Distort Pretrained Features and Underperform Out-of-Distribution. ArXiv
Preprint ArXiv:2202.10054. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University. https://doi.
org/10.48550/arXiv.2202.10054.
Kuramanji, M., P. Triantafillou, J. Hayes, and E. Triantafillou. 2023. Towards Unbounded
Machine Unlearning. ArXiv Preprint ArXiv:2302.09880. Ithaca, NY: Cornell
University. https://doi.org/10.48550/arXiv.2302.09880.
Lambrecht, A., and C. Tucker. 2019. “Algorithmic Bias? An Empirical Study of Apparent
Gender-Based Discrimination in the Display of STEM Career Ads.” Management Science 65, no. 7: 2966–81. https://pubsonline.informs.org/doi/10.1287/
mnsc.2018.3093.
Landes, W., and R. Posner. 1987. The Economic Structure of Tort Law. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press. https://chicagounbound.uchicago.edu/books/226/.
Lang, K., and A. Spitzer. 2020. “Race Discrimination: An Economic Perspective.”
Journal of Economic Perspectives 34, no. 2: 68–89. https://doi.org/10.1257/
jep.34.2.68.
Leffer, L. 2023. “When It Comes to AI Models, Bigger Isn’t Always Better.” Scientific
American. https://www.scientificamerican.com/article/
when-it-comes-to-ai-models-bigger-isnt-always-better/.
Lewis-Kraus, G. 2014. “The Fasinatng . . . Fascinating History of Autocorrect.” Wired,
July 22. https://www.wired.com/2014/07/history-of-autocorrect/.
Levitt, T. 2004. “Marketing Myopia.” Harvard Business Review. https://hbr.org/2004/07/
marketing-myopia.
Lin, J. 2011. “Technological Adaptation, Cities, and New Work.” Review of Economics
and Statistics 93, no. 2: 554–74. https://doi.org/10.1162/REST_a_00079.
Ling, C., X. Zhao, J. Lu, C. Deng, C. Zheng, J. Wang, T. Chowdhury, Y. Li, H. Cui, X.
Zhang, T. Zhao, A. Panalkar, W. Cheng, H. Wang, Y. Liu, Z. Chen, H. Chen, C.
White, Q. Gu, J. Pei, and L. Zhao. 2023. Domain Specialization as the Key to
Make Large Language Models Disruptive: A Comprehensive Survey. ArXiv
Preprint ArXiv:2305.18703. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University. https://doi.
org/10.48550/arXiv.2305.18703.

References | 373

Llorca, D., V. Charisi, R. Hamon, I. Sánchez, and E. Gómez. 2023. “Liability Regimes in
the Age of AI: A Use-Case-Driven Analysis of the Burden of Proof.” Journal of
Artificial Intelligence Research 76: 613–44. https://doi.org/10.1613/jair.1.14565.
Luca, M. 2015. “Chapter 12: User-Generated Content and Social Media.” In Handbook of
Media Economics 1: 563–92. https://doi.org/10.1016/
B978-0-444-63685-0.00012-7.
Mankiw, N., D. Romer, and D. Weil. 1992. “A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic
Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107: 407–37. https://doi.
org/10.2307/2118477.
Mas-Colell, A., M. Whinston, and J. Green. 1995. Microeconomic Theory. Oxford:
Oxford University Press. https://global.oup.com/academic/product/
microeconomic-theory-9780195073409?cc=us&lang=en&.
Maslej, N., L. Fattorini, E. Brynjolfsson, J. Etchemendy, K. Ligett, T. Lyons, J. Manyika,
H. Ngo, J. Niebles, V. Parli, Y. Shoham, R. Wald, J. Clark, and R. Perrault.
2023. The AI Index 2023 Annual Report. AI Index Steering Committee, Institute
for Human-Centered AI. Stanford, CA: Stanford University. https://aiindex.
stanford.edu/wp-content/uploads/2023/04/HAI_AI-Index-Report_2023.pdf.
McElheran, K., J. Li, E. Brynjolfsson, Z. Kroff, E. Dinlersoz, L. Foster, and N. Zolas.
2023. AI Adoption in America: Who, What, and Where. NBER Working Paper
31788. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.
org/10.3386/w31788.
McKelvey, R., and T. Page. 1999. “Taking the Coase Theorem Seriously.” Economics and
Philosophy 15, no. 2: 235–47. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0266267100003990.
McNicholas, C., M. Poydock, J. Wolfe, B. Zipperer, G. Lafer, and L. Loustaunau. 2019.
“Unlawful: U.S. Employers Are Charged with Violating Federal Law in 41.5%
of All Union Election Campaigns.” Economic Policy Institute. https://www.epi.
org/publication/unlawful-employer-opposition-to-union-election-campaigns/.
Medema, S. 2020. “The Coase Theorem at Sixty.” Journal of Economic Literature 58, no.
4: 1045–128. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.20191060.
Merrill, T., and H. Smith. 2011. “Making Coasean Property More Coasean.” Journal of
Law and Economics 54, no. S4: S77–S104. https://doi.org/10.1086/661946.
Min, B., H. Ross, E. Sulem, A. Veyseh, T. Nguyen, O. Sainz, E. Agirre, I. Heintz, and D.
Roth. 2023. “Recent Advances in Natural Language Processing via Large Pretrained Language Models: A Survey.” ACM Computing Surveys 56, no. 2: 1–40.
https://doi.org/10.1145/3605943.
Miric, M., N. Jia, and K. Huang. 2022. “Using Supervised Machine Learning for LargeScale Classification in Management Research: The Case for Identifying
Artificial Intelligence Patents.” Strategic Management Journal 44, no. 2:
491–519. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.3441.
Mishel, L., H. Shierholz, and J. Schmitt. 2013. “Don’t Blame the Robots: Assessing the
Job Polarization Explanation of Growing Wage Inequality.” Working paper,

374 |

References

Economic Policy Institute, Center for Economic and Policy Research. https://
files.epi.org/2013/technology-inequality-dont-blame-the-robots.pdf.
Mishra, S., R. Koopman, G. De Prato, A. Rao, I. Osorio-Rodarte, J. Kim, N. Spatafora,
K. Strier, and A. Zaccaria. 2023. “AI Specialization for Pathways of Economic
Diversification.” Scientific Reports 13: 19475. https://doi.org/10.1038/
s41598-023-45723-x.
Mökander, J., J. Morley, M. Taddeo, and L. Floridi. 2021. “Ethics-Based Auditing of
Automated Decision-Making Systems: Nature, Scope, and Limitations.”
Science and Engineering Ethics 27, no. 44. https://doi.org/10.1007/
s11948-021-00319-4.
Mookherjee, D., and I. Png, 1992. “Monitoring vis-a-vis Investigation in Enforcement of
Law.” American Economic Review, 556–65. https://www.jstor.org/
stable/2117321.
Mokyr, J. 2008. “The Institutional Origins of the Industrial Revolution.” Working paper,
Northwestern University. https://faculty.wcas.northwestern.edu/jmokyr/Institutional-Origins-4.PDF.
Mokyr, J., C. Vickers, and N. Ziebarth. 2015. “The History of Technological Anxiety and
the Future of Economic Growth: Is This Time Different?” Journal of Economic
Perspectives 29, no. 3: 31–50. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.29.3.31.
Moresi, S., and M. Schwartz. 2021. “Vertical Mergers with Input Substitution: Double
Marginalization, Foreclosure, and Welfare.” Economic Letters 202. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.econlet.2021.109818.
Mosqueira-Rey, E., E. Hernández-Pereira, D. Alonso-Ríos, J. Bobes-Bascarán, and A.
Fernández-Leal. 2022. “Human-in-the-Loop Machine Learning: A State of the
Art.” Artificial Intelligence Review 56: 3005–54. https://doi.org/10.1007/
s10462-022-10246-w.
Muennighoff, N., A. Rush, B. Barak, T. Le Scao, A. Piktus, N. Tazi, S. Pyysalo, T. Wolf,
and C. Raffel. 2023. Scaling Data-Constrained Language Models. ArXiv
Preprint ArXiv:2305.16264. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University. https://doi.
org/10.48550/arXiv.2305.16264.
NAIAC (National Artificial Intelligence Advisory Committee). 2023. “National AI Advisory Committee.” https://ai.gov/naiac/.
Naik, R., V. Chandrasekaran, M. Yuksekgonul, H. Palangi, and B. Nushi, 2023. “Diversity of Thought Improves Reasoning Abilities of Large Language Models.”
https://doi.org/10.48550/arXiv.2310.07088.
Najibi, A. 2020. “Racial Discrimination in Face Recognition Technology.” Harvard
University, Science in the News. https://sitn.hms.harvard.edu/flash/2020/
racial-discrimination-in-face-recognition-technology/.
Narechania, T. 2022. “Machine Learning as Natural Monopoly.” Iowa Law Review 7, no.
4: 1543–1614. https://ilr.law.uiowa.edu/sites/ilr.law.uiowa.edu/files/2023-02/
A4_Narechania.pdf.

References | 375

Narechania, T., and G. Sitaraman. 2023. “An Antimonopoly Approach to Governing Artificial Intelligence.” Vanderbilt Policy Accelerator for Political Economy &
Regulation. https://cdn.vanderbilt.edu/vu-URL/wp-content/uploads/
sites/412/2023/10/06212048/Narechania-Sitaraman-Antimonopoly-AI2023.10.6.pdf.pdf.
Neel, S., and P. Chang. 2023. Privacy Issues in Large Language Models: A Survey. ArXiv
Preprint ArXiv:2312.06717. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University. https://doi.
org/10.48550/arXiv.2312.06717.
Nekoei, A., and A. Weber. 2017. “Does Extending Unemployment Benefits Improve Job
Quality?” American Economic Review 107, no. 2: 527–61. https://doi.
org/10.1257/aer.20150528.
Netanel, N. 2011. “Making Sense of Fair Use.” Lewis & Clark Law Review 15, no. 3:
715–71. https://heinonline.org/HOL/P?h=hein.journals/lewclr15&i=731.
Newell, A. 1983. “Chapter 1: Intellectual Issues in the History of Artificial Intelligence.”
In Artificial Intelligence: Critical Concepts, Volume 1, ed. R. Chrisley and S.
Begeer, 25–70. Abingdon, U.K.: Taylor & Francis. apps.dtic.mil/sti/citations/
ADA125318.
Noy, S., and W. Zhang. 2023. “Experimental Evidence on the Productivity Effects of
Generative Artificial Intelligence.” Working paper, Social Science Research
Network. https://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.4375283.
Nunan, D., and M. Di Domenico. 2022. “Value Creation in an Algorithmic World:
Towards an Ethics of Dynamic Pricing.” Journal of Business Research 150:
451–60. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2022.06.032.
NIST (National Institute of Standards and Technology). 2023. “NIST Seeks Collaborators
for Consortium Supporting Artificial Intelligence Safety.” https://www.nist.gov/
news-events/news/2023/11/
nist-seeks-collaborators-consortium-supporting-artificial-intelligence.
Obermeyer, Z., B. Powers, C. Vogeli, and S. Mullainathan. 2019. “Dissecting Racial Bias
in an Algorithm Used to Manage the Health of Populations.” Science 366, no.
6464: 447–53. https://www.science.org/doi/10.1126/science.aax2342.
Ohlin, B., and E. Heckscher. 1991. Heckscher-Olin Trade Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press. https://mitpress.mit.edu/9780262082013/heckscher-ohlin-trade-theory/.
OMB (U.S. Office and Management and Budget). 2023a. “Guidance on Accounting for
Competition Effects When Developing and Analyzing Regulatory Actions.”
https://www.whitehouse.gov/wp-content/uploads/2023/10/RegulatoryCompetitionGuidance.pdf.
———. 2023b. “OMB Releases Implementation Guidance Following President Biden’s
Executive Order on Artificial Intelligence.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/
briefing-room/2023/11/01/
omb-releases-implementation-guidance-following-president-bidens-executive-order-on-artificial-intelligence/.

376 |

References

O*NET Online. No date. Database sponsored by U.S. Department of Labor. https://www.
onetonline.org/.
OpenAI. 2024. “OpenAI-Python.” Code commit. https://github.com/openai/
openai-python.
Ordover, J., G. Saloner, and S. Salop. 1990. “Equilibrium Vertical Foreclosure.” American Economic Review 80, no. 1: 127–42. https://www.jstor.org/stable/2006738.
Oremus, W., and E. Izadi. 2024. “AI’s Future Could Hinge on One Thorny Legal Question.” Washington Post. https://www.washingtonpost.com/
technology/2024/01/04/nyt-ai-copyright-lawsuit-fair-use/.
Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective
Action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. https://www.cambridge.org/
core/books/governing-the-commons/
A8BB63BC4A1433A50A3FB92EDBBB97D5.
Ottaviani, M., and A. Wickelgren. 2011. “Ex Ante or Ex Post Competition Policy? A
Progress Report.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 29, no. 3:
356–59. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2011.02.004.
Ouyang, L., J. Wu, X. Jiang, D. Almeida, C. Wainwright, P. Mishkin, C. Zhang, S.
Agarwal, K. Slama, A. Ray, J. Schulman, J. Hilton, F. Kelton, L. Miller, M.
Simens, A. Askell, P. Welinder, P. Christiano, J. Leike, and R. Lowe. 2022.
“Training Language Models to Follow Instructions with Human Feedback.”
Advances in Neural Informational Processing Systems 35: 27730–44. https://
proceedings.neurips.cc/paper_files/paper/2022/hash/b1efde53be364a73914f58805a001731-Abstract-Conference.html.
Parente, S., and E. Prescott. 1994. “Barriers to Technology Adoption and Development.”
Journal of Political Economy 102, no. 2: 298–321. https://doi.
org/10.1086/261933.
Peng, S., E. Kalliamvakou, P. Cihon, and M. Demirer. 2023. The Impact of AI on Developer Productivity: Evidence from GitHub Copilot. ArXiv Preprint
ArXiv:2302.06590. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University. https://doi.org/10.48550/
arXiv.2302.06590.
Perrigo, B. 2023. “Exclusive: OpenAI Used Kenyan Workers on Less Than $2 Per Hour
to Make ChatGPT Less Toxic.” Time, January 18. https://time.com/6247678/
openai-chatgpt-kenya-workers/.
Perault, M. 2023. “Section 230 Won’t Protect ChatGPT.” Journal of Free Speech Law 3:
363–73. https://heinonline.org/HOL/P?h=hein.journals/jfspl3&i=363.
Peterson, N., M. Mumford, W. Borman, P. Jeanneret, and E. Fleishman. 1995. “Development of Prototype Occupational Information Network (0*NET) Content
Model.” O*Net: Occupational Information Network. https://www.onetcenter.
org/dl_files/Prototype_Vol1.pdf.
Philippon, T. 2022. Additive Growth. NBER Working Paper 29950. Cambridge, MA:
National Bureau for Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w29950.

References | 377

Pizzinelli, C., A. Panton, M. Mendes Tavares, M. Cazzaniga, and L. Li. 2023. “Labor
Market Exposure to AI: Cross-Country Differences and Distributional Implications.” https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=4612697.
Post, C., E. De Lia, N. DiTomaso, T. Tirpak, and R. Borwankar, 2009. “Capitalizing on
Thought Diversity for Innovation.” Research-Technology Management 52:
14–25. https://doi.org/10.1080/08956308.2009.11657596.
Price, D. 2019. “Goodbye, Operator.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Econ Focus.
https://www.richmondfed.org/publications/research/econ_focus/2019/q4/
economic_history.
Quartz. 2017. “Bill Gates: The Robot That Takes Your Job Should Pay Taxes.” https://
qz.com/911968/bill-gates-the-robot-that-takes-your-job-should-pay-taxes.
Raji, I., T. Gebru, M. Mitchell, J. Buolamwini, J. Lee, and E. Denton. 2020a. “Saving
Face: Investigating the Ethical Concerns of Facial Recognition Auditing.”
Proceedings of the AAAI/ACM Conference on AI, Ethics, and Society: 145-51.
https://doi.org/10.1145/3375627.3375820.
Raji, I., A. Smart, R. White, M. Mitchell, T. Gebru, B. Hutchinson, J. Smith-Loud, D.
Theron, and P. Barnes. 2020b. “Closing the AI Accountability Gap: Defining an
End-to-End Framework for Internal Algorithmic Auditing.” In Proceedings of
the 2020 Conference on Fairness, Accountability, and Transparency, 33–44.
FAT* ’20. New York: Association for Computing Machinery. https://doi.
org/10.1145/3351095.3372873.
Rees, T. 2023. “AI Could Enable Humans to Work 4 Days a Week, Says Nobel PrizeWinning Economist.” Time. https://time.com/6268804/
artificial-intelligence-pissarides-productivity/.
Ricardo, D. 1817. On The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. Kitchener,
Canada: Batoche Books. https://socialsciences.mcmaster.ca/econ/ugcm/3ll3/
ricardo/Principles.pdf.
Roosen, J., and D. Hennessy. 2003. “Tests for the Role of Risk Aversion on Input Use.”
American Journal of Agricultural Economics 85, no. 1: 30–43. https://doi.
org/10.1111/1467-8276.00101.
Roser, M., H. Richie, and E. Mathieu. 2023. “Technological Change.” Our World in
Data. https://ourworldindata.org/technological-change?ref=bitcoinalpha.nl.
Roziere, B., M. Lachaux, L. Chanussot, and G. Lample. 2020. “Unsupervised Translation
of Programming Languages.” Advances in Neural Information Processing
Systems 33: 20601–11. https://proceedings.neurips.cc/paper/2020/hash/ed23fbf18c2cd35f8c7f8de44f85c08d-Abstract.html.
Ryman-Tubb, N., P. Krause, and W. Garn. 2018. “How Artificial Intelligence and
Machine Learning Research Impacts Payment Card Fraud Detection: A Survey
and Industry Benchmark.” Engineering Applications of Artificial Intelligence
76: 130–57. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.engappai.2018.07.008.

378 |

References

Saez, E., and S. Stantcheva. 2018. “A Simpler Theory of Optimal Capital Taxation.”
Journal of Public Economics 162: 120–42. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
jpubeco.2017.10.004.
Sag, M. 2023. “Fairness and Fair Use in Generative AI.” Fordham Law Review. https://
ssrn.com/abstract=4654875.
SAG-AFTRA (Screen Actors Guild–American Federation of Television and Radio
Artists). 2023. “TV/Theatrical Contracts 2023: Summary of Tentative Agreement.” https://www.sagaftra.org/files/sa_documents/
TV-Theatrical_23_Summary_Agreement_Final.pdf.
Sampat, B., and H. Williams. 2019. “How Do Patents Affect Follow-On Innovation?
Evidence from the Human Genome.” American Economic Review 109, no. 1:
203–36. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20151398.
Samuelson, P. 2023. “Generative AI Meets Copyright.” Science 381, no. 6654: 158–61.
https://doi.org/10.1126/science.adi0656.
Schaeffer, R., B. Miranda, and S. Koyejo. 2023. “Are Emergent Abilities of Large
Language Models a Mirage?” Advances in Neural Information Processing
Systems 36. https://proceedings.neurips.cc/paper_files/paper/2023/hash/
adc98a266f45005c403b8311ca7e8bd7-Abstract-Conference.html.
Schmieder, J., T. von Wachter, and S. Bender. 2012. “The Effects of Extended Unemployment Insurance Over the Business Cycle: Evidence from Regression
Discontinuity Estimates Over 20 Years.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 127,
no. 2: 701–52. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjs010.
Schneider, P., W. Walters, A. Plowright, N. Sieroka, J. Listgarten, R. Goodnow Jr., J.
Fisher, J. Jansen, J. Duca, T. Rush, M. Zentgraf, J. Hill, E. Krutoholow, M.
Kohler, J. Blaney, K. Funatsu, C. Luebkemann, and G. Schneider. 2020.
“Rethinking Drug Design in the Artificial Intelligence Era.” Nature Reviews
Drug Discovery 19: 353–64. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41573-019-0050-3.
Scotchmer, S. 1991. “Standing on the Shoulders of Giants: Cumulative Research and the
Patent Law.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 5, no. 1: 29–41. https://doi.
org/10.1257/jep.5.1.29.
Setty, R. 2023. “Getty Images Sues Stability AI Over Art Generator IP Violations.”
Bloomberg Law. https://news.bloomberglaw.com/ip-law/
getty-images-sues-stability-ai-over-art-generator-ip-violations.
Shan, S., W. Ding, J. Passananti, S. Wu, H. Zheng, and B. Zhao. 2023. Prompt-Specific
Poisoning Attacks on Text-to-Image Generative Models. ArXiv Preprint
ArXiv:2310.13828. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University. https://doi.org/10.48550/
arXiv.2310.13828.
Sharifani, K., and M. Amini. 2023. “Machine Learning and Deep Learning: A Review of
Methods and Applications.” World Information Technology and Engineering
Journal 10, no. 7: 3897–904. https://ssrn.com/abstract=4458723.

References | 379

Sharkey, C. 2022. “Products Liability in the Digital Age: Online Platforms as ‘Cheapest
Cost Avoiders.’” Hastings Law Journal 73: 1327–51. https://heinonline.org/
HOL/P?h=hein.journals/hastlj73&i=1329.
Shavell, S. 2004. Foundations of Economic Analysis of Law. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press. https://www.jstor.org/stable/j.ctv1m0kjr4.
Sintchenko, V., and E. Coiera. 2003. “Which Clinical Decisions Benefit from Automation? A Task Complexity Approach.” International Journal of Medical
Informatics 70, nos. 2–3: 309–16. https://doi.org/10.1016/
S1386-5056(03)00040-6.
Smith, A. 1776. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Oxford:
Oxford University Press. https://doi.org/10.1093/oseo/instance.00043218.
Smith, H. 2012. “Property as the Law of Things.” Harvard Law Review 125, no. 7: 1691–
1726. https://www.jstor.org/stable/23214445.
Sobel, B. 2017. “Artificial Intelligence’s Fair Use Crisis.” Columbia Journal of Law &
the Arts 41, no. 1: 45–98. https://doi.org/10.7916/jla.v41i1.2036.
Solow, R. 1956. “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal
of Economics 70, no. 1: 65–94. https://doi.org/10.2307/1884513.
Sorscher, B., R. Geirhos, S. Shekhar, S. Ganguli, and A. Morcos. 2022. “Beyond Neural
Scaling Laws: Beating Power Law Scaling via Data Pruning.” Advances in
Neural Information Processing Systems 35: 19523–36. https://proceedings.
neurips.cc/paper_files/paper/2022/file/7b75da9b61eda40fa35453ee5d077df6-P
aper-Conference.pdf.
Svanberg, M., W. Li, M. Fleming, B. Goehring, and N. Thompson, 2024. “Beyond AI
Exposure: Which Tasks Are Cost-Effective to Automate with Computer
Vision?” SSRN 4700751. https://futuretech-site.s3.us-east-2.amazonaws.
com/2024-01-18+Beyond_AI_Exposure.pdf.
Taddy, M. 2019. “The Technological Elements of Artificial Intelligence.” In The
Economics of Artificial Intelligence: An Agenda, ed. A. Agrawal, J. Gans, and
A. Goldfarb, 61–89. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. https://www.nber.
org/papers/w24301.
Taub, D., and H. Levitt. 2023. “JPMorgan’s Dimon Predicts 3.5-Day Work Week for Next
Generation Thanks to AI.” Bloomberg. https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2023-10-02/
dimon-sees-ai-giving-a-3-1-2-day-workweek-to-the-next-generation.
Thaler v. Perlmutter. 2023. U.S. District Court for the District of Columbia. https://ecf.
dcd.uscourts.gov/cgi-bin/show_public_doc?2022cv1564-24.
Thaler v. Vidal. 2022. U.S. District Court for the Eastern District of Virginia. https://cafc.
uscourts.gov/opinions-orders/21-2347.OPINION.8-5-2022_1988142.pdf.
Thompson, P. 2010. “Chapter 10: Learning by Doing.” In Handbook of the Economics of
Innovation 1, ed. B. Hall and N. Rosenberg, 429–76. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
https://doi.org/10.1016/S0169-7218(10)01010-5.

380 |

References

Thuemmel, U. 2022. “Optimal Taxation of Robots.” Journal of the European Economic
Association 21, no. 3: 1154–90. https://doi.org/10.1093/jeea/jvac062.
Tirole, J. 1988. The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
https://mitpress.mit.edu/9780262200714/the-theory-of-industrial-organization/.
———. 2023. “Competition and the Industrial Challenge for the Digital Age.” Annual
Review of Economics 15: 573–605. https://www.annualreviews.org/doi/10.1146/
annurev-economics-090622-024222.
U.S. Department of the Treasury. 2023. “Labor Unions and the Middle Class.” https://
home.treasury.gov/system/files/136/Labor-Unions-And-The-Middle-Class.pdf.
Vaswani, A., N. Shazeer, N. Parmar, J. Uszkoreit, L. Jones, A. Gomez, L. Kaiser, and I.
Polosukhin, 2017. “Attention Is All You Need.” Advances in Neural Information Processing Systems. https://doi.org/10.48550/arXiv.1706.03762.
Verhoef, P., T. Broekhuizen, Y. Bart, A. Bhattacharya, J. Dong, N. Fabian, and M.
Haenlein. 2021. “Digital Transformation: A Multidisciplinary Reflection and
Research Agenda.” Journal of Business Research 122: 889–901. https://doi.
org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2019.09.022.
Vipra, J., and A. Korinek. 2023. “Market Concentration Implications of Foundation
Models: The Invisible Hand of ChatGPT.” Working paper, Brookings Center on
Regulation and Markets. https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/
uploads/2023/09/Market-concentration-implications-of-foundation-modelsFINAL-1.pdf.
Volokh, E. 2023. “Large Libel Models? Liability for AI Output.” Journal of Free Speech
3: 489–558. https://heinonline.org/HOL/P?h=hein.journals/jfspl3&i=489.
Webb, G., and Z. Zheng. 2004. “Multistrategy Ensemble Learning: Reducing Error by
Combining Ensemble Learning Techniques.” IEEE Transactions on Knowledge
and Data Engineering 16: 980–91. https://ieeexplore.ieee.org/abstract/
document/1318582.
Weisz, J., M. Muller, S. Ross, F. Martinez, S. Houde, M. Agarwal, K. Talamadupula, and
J. Richards. 2022. Better Together? An Evaluation of AI-Supported Code Translation. 27th International Conference on Intelligent User Interfaces, 369–91.
New York: Association for Computing Machinery. https://doi.
org/10.1145/3490099.3511157.
Werden, G. 2001. “Network Effects and Conditions of Entry: Lessons from the Microsoft
Case.” Antitrust Law Journal 69, no. 1: 87–112. https://heinonline.org/HOL/
Page?collection=journals&handle=hein.journals/
antil69&id=99&men_tab=srchresults.
WGAW (Writers Guild of America West). 2023. “Summary of the 2023 WGA MBA.”
https://www.wga.org/contracts/contracts/mba/summary-of-the-2023-wga-mba.
Whalley, A. 2011. “Optimal R&D Investment for a Risk-Averse Entrepreneur.” Journal of
Economic Dynamics and Control 35, no. 4: 413–29. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.
jedc.2009.11.009.

References | 381

White House. 2022. “Blueprint for an AI Bill of Rights: Making Automated Systems
Work for the American People.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/wp-content/
uploads/2022/10/Blueprint-for-an-AI-Bill-of-Rights.pdf.
———. 2023a. “Executive Order on the Safe, Secure, and Trustworthy Development and
Use of Artificial Intelligence.” https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/presidential-actions/2023/10/30/
executive-order-on-the-safe-secure-and-trustworthy-development-and-use-ofartificial-intelligence/.
———. 2023b. “Biden-Harris Administration Secures Voluntary Commitments from
Eight Additional Intelligence Companies to Manage the Risks Posed by AI.”
https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/statements-releases/2023/09/12/
fact-sheet-biden-harris-administration-secures-voluntary-commitments-fromeight-additional-artificial-intelligence-companies-to-manage-the-risks-posed-by-ai.
———. 2023c. “Biden-Harris Administration Roadmap to Support Good Jobs.” https://
www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/statements-releases/2023/05/16/
biden-harris-administration-roadmap-to-support-good-jobs/.
Williamson, O. 1971. “The Vertical Integration of Production: Market Failure Considerations.” American Economic Review 61, no. 2: 112–23. http://dx.doi.
org/10.1179/102452907X166845.
Xiong, W., J. Droppo, X. Huang, F. Seide, M. Seltzer, A. Stolcke, D. Yu, and G, Zweig.
2016. Achieving Human Parity in Conversational Speech Recognition. Microsoft Research Technical Report MSR-TR-2016-71. Redmond, WA: Microsoft
Research. https://doi.org/10.48550/arXiv.1610.05256.
Xu, Y., C. Shieh, P. van Esch, and I. Ling. 2020. “AI Customer Service: Task Complexity,
Problem-Solving Ability, and Usage Intention.” Australian Marketing Journal
28, no. 4: 189–99. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ausmj.2020.03.005.
Zeira, J. 1998. “Workers, Machines, and Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 113, no. 4: 1091–117. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355398555847.
Zhai, X., A. Kolesnikov, N. Houlsby, and L. Beyer. 2022. “Scaling Vision Transformers.”
Proceedings of the IEEE/CVF Conference on Computer Vision and Pattern
Recognition (CVPR): 12104–113. https://doi.org/10.48550/arXiv.2106.04560.
Zhang, N., Y. Yao, B. Tian, P. Wang, S. Deng, M. Wang, Z. Xi, S. Mao, J. Zhang, Y. Ni,
S. Cheng, Z. Xu, X. Xu, J. Gu, Y. Jiang, P. Xie, F. Huang, L. Liang, Z. Zhang,
X. Zhu, J. Zhou, and H. Chen. 2024. A Comprehensive Study of Knowledge
Editing for Large Language Models. ArXiv Preprint ArXiv:2401.01286. Ithaca,
NY: Cornell University. https://doi.org/10.48550/arXiv.2401.01286.
Zhou, H., X. Wang, W. Au, H. Kang, and C. Chen. 2022. “Intelligent Robots for Fruit
Harvesting: Recent Developments and Future Challenges.” Precision Agriculture 23: 1856–907. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11119-022-09913-3.
Zilibotti, F. 2007. “Economic Possibilities for Our Grandchildren 75 Years After: A
Global Perspective.” In Revisiting Keynes: Economic Possibilities for Our

382 |

References

Grandchildren, ed. L. Pecchi, and G. Piga, 27–39. Scholarship Online.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. https://doi.org/10.7551/mitp
ress/9780262162494.003.0003.
Zirar, A., S. Ali, and N. Islam, 2023. “Worker and Workplace Artificial Intelligence (AI)
Coexistence: Emerging Themes and Research Agenda.” Technovation 124:
102747. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2023.102747.
Zolas, N., Z. Kroff, E. Brynjolfsson, K. McElheran, D. Beede, C. Buffington, N. Goldschlag, L. Foster, and E. Dinlersoz. 2020. “Advanced Technologies Adoption
and Use by U.S. Firms: Evidence from the Annual Business Survey.” NBER
Working Paper 28290. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau for Economic
Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w28290.

References | 383

384 |

References

Appendix A

Report to the President
on the Activities of the
Council of Economic Advisers
during 2023

385

Letter of Transmittal
Council of Economic Advisers
Washington, December 31, 2023
Mr. President:
The Council of Economic Advisers submits this report on its activities
during calendar year 2023 in accordance with the requirements of Congress,
as set forth by Section 10(d) of the Employment Act of 1946, as amended
by the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978.
Sincerely yours,

Jared Bernstein
Chair

Heather Boushey
Member

C. Kirabo Jackson
Member

Activities of the Council of Economic Advisers during 2023 | 387

Council Members and Their Dates of Service
Name

Position

Oath of office date

Separation date

Edwin G. Nourse
Leon H. Keyserling

Chairman
Vice Chairman
Acting Chairman
Chairman
Member
Vice Chairman
Member
Member
Chairman
Member
Member
Member
Chairman
Member
Member
Member
Member
Chairman
Member
Member
Member
Chairman
Member
Member
Member
Chairman
Member
Member
Member
Chairman
Member
Member
Chairman
Member
Member
Member
Member
Chairman
Member
Member
Chairman
Member
Member
Member
Member
Chairman
Member
Member

August 9, 1946
August 9, 1946
November 2, 1949
May 10, 1950
August 9, 1946
May 10, 1950
June 29, 1950
September 8, 1952
March 19, 1953
September 15, 1953
December 2, 1953
April 4, 1955
December 3, 1956
May 2, 1955
December 3, 1956
November 1, 1958
May 7, 1959
January 29, 1961
January 29, 1961
January 29, 1961
August 3, 1962
November 16, 1964
May 17, 1963
September 2, 1964
November 16, 1964
February 15, 1968
February 2, 1966
February 15, 1968
July 1, 1968
February 4, 1969
February 4, 1969
February 4, 1969
January 1, 1972
September 9, 1971
March 13, 1972
July 23, 1973
October 31, 1973
September 4, 1974
June 13, 1975
July 22, 1975
January 22, 1977
March 18, 1977
March 18, 1977
June 6, 1979
August 20, 1980
February 27, 1981
June 12, 1981
July 14, 1981

November 1, 1949

John D. Clark
Roy Blough
Robert C. Turner
Arthur F. Burns
Neil H. Jacoby
Walter W. Stewart
Raymond J. Saulnier
Joseph S. Davis
Paul W. McCracken
Karl Brandt
Henry C. Wallich
Walter W. Heller
James Tobin
Kermit Gordon
Gardner Ackley
John P. Lewis
Otto Eckstein
Arthur M. Okun
James S. Duesenberry
Merton J. Peck
Warren L. Smith
Paul W. McCracken
Hendrik S. Houthakker
Herbert Stein
Ezra Solomon
Marina v.N. Whitman
Gary L. Seevers
William J. Fellner
Alan Greenspan
Paul W. MacAvoy
Burton G. Malkiel
Charles L. Schultze
William D. Nordhaus
Lyle E. Gramley
George C. Eads
Stephen M. Goldfeld
Murray L. Weidenbaum
William A. Niskanen
Jerry L. Jordan

388 |

Appendix A

January 20, 1953
February 11, 1953
August 20, 1952
January 20, 1953
December 1, 1956
February 9, 1955
April 29, 1955
January 20, 1961
October 31, 1958
January 31, 1959
January 20, 1961
January 20, 1961
November 15, 1964
July 31, 1962
December 27, 1962
February 15, 1968
August 31, 1964
February 1, 1966
January 20, 1969
June 30, 1968
January 20, 1969
January 20, 1969
December 31, 1971
July 15, 1971
August 31, 1974
March 26, 1973
August 15, 1973
April 15, 1975
February 25, 1975
January 20, 1977
November 15, 1976
January 20, 1977
January 20, 1981
February 4, 1979
May 27, 1980
January 20, 1981
January 20, 1981
August 25, 1982
March 30, 1985
July 31, 1982

Council Members and Their Dates of Service
Name

Position

Oath of office date

Separation date

Martin Feldstein
William Poole
Beryl W. Sprinkel
Thomas Gale Moore
Michael L. Mussa
Michael J. Boskin
John B. Taylor
Richard L. Schmalensee
David F. Bradford
Paul Wonnacott
Laura D’Andrea Tyson
Alan S. Blinder
Joseph E. Stiglitz

Chairman
Member
Chairman
Member
Member
Chairman
Member
Member
Member
Member
Chair
Member
Member
Chairman
Member
Member
Chair
Member
Member
Chairman
Member
Member
Chairman
Member
Member
Chairman
Member
Member
Chairman
Chairman
Member
Member
Chairman
Member
Chair
Member
Chairman
Member
Member
Member
Chairman
Member
Chairman
Member
Member
Member
Member

October 14, 1982
December 10, 1982
April 18, 1985
July 1, 1985
August 18, 1986
February 2, 1989
June 9, 1989
October 3, 1989
November 13, 1991
November 13, 1991
February 5, 1993
July 27, 1993
July 27, 1993
June 28, 1995
June 30, 1995
January 29, 1996
February 18, 1997
April 23, 1997
October 22, 1998
August 12, 1999
August 12, 1999
May 31, 2000
May 11, 2001
July 25, 2001
November 30, 2001
May 29, 2003
November 21, 2003
November 21, 2003
February 23, 2005
June 21, 2005
November 18, 2005
November 18, 2005
February 27, 2006
July 17, 2008
January 29, 2009
March 11, 2009
September 10, 2010
March 11, 2009
April 19, 2011
April 19, 2011
November 7, 2011
February 7, 2013
August 4, 2013
August 6, 2013
July 21, 2014
August 10, 2015
August 31, 2015

July 10, 1984
January 20, 1985
January 20, 1989
May 1, 1989
September 19, 1988
January 12, 1993
August 2, 1991
June 21, 1991
January 20, 1993
January 20, 1993
April 22, 1995
June 26, 1994

Martin N. Baily
Alicia H. Munnell
Janet L. Yellen
Jeffrey A. Frankel
Rebecca M. Blank
Martin N. Baily
Robert Z. Lawrence
Kathryn L. Shaw
R. Glenn Hubbard
Mark B. McClellan
Randall S. Kroszner
N. Gregory Mankiw
Kristin J. Forbes
Harvey S. Rosen
Ben S. Bernanke
Katherine Baicker
Matthew J. Slaughter
Edward P. Lazear
Donald B. Marron
Christina D. Romer
Austan D. Goolsbee
Cecilia Elena Rouse
Katharine G. Abraham
Carl Shapiro
Alan B. Krueger
James H. Stock
Jason Furman
Betsey Stevenson
Maurice Obstfeld
Sandra E. Black
Jay C. Shambaugh

February 10, 1997
August 30, 1996
August 1, 1997
August 3, 1999
March 2, 1999
July 9, 1999
January 19, 2001
January 12, 2001
January 19, 2001
February 28, 2003
November 13, 2002
July 1, 2003
February 18, 2005
June 3, 2005
June 10, 2005
January 31, 2006
July 11, 2007
March 1, 2007
January 20, 2009
January 20, 2009
September 3, 2010
August 5, 2011
February 28, 2011
April 19, 2013
May 4, 2012
August 2, 2013
May 19, 2014
January 20, 2017
August 7, 2015
August 28, 2015
January 20, 2017
January 20, 2017

Activities of the Council of Economic Advisers during 2023 | 389

Council Members and Their Dates of Service
Name

Position

Oath of office date

Separation date

Kevin A. Hassett
Richard V. Burkhauser
Tomas J. Philipson

Chairman
Member
Member
Acting Chairman
Vice Chairman
Member
Acting Chairman
Vice Chairman
Chair
Member
Chair
Member
Member

September 13, 2017
September 28, 2017
August 31, 2017
July 1, 2019
July 24, 2019
May 22, 2019
June 23, 2020
June 23, 2020
March 2, 2021
January 20, 2021
June 13, 2023
January 20, 2021
August 28, 2023

June 30, 2019
May 18, 2019

Tyler B. Goodspeed
Cecilia Elena Rouse
Jared Bernstein
Heather Boushey
C. Kirabo Jackson

390 |

Appendix A

June 22, 2020
January 6, 2021
April 1, 2023

Report to the President on the
Activities of the Council of
Economic Advisers during 2023
Established by the Employment Act of 1946, the Council of Economic
Advisers is charged with advising the President on economic policy based
on data, research, and evidence. The Council is composed of three members:
a Chair, who is appointed by the President with the advice and consent of the
Senate; and two members, who are appointed by the President. Along with a
team of economists, they analyze and interpret economic developments and
formulate and recommend economic policies that advance the interests of
the American people.

The Chair of the Council
Jared Bernstein was confirmed by the Senate on June 13, 2023, as the
31st Chair of the Council of Economic Advisers. In this role, he serves as
President Biden’s Chief Economist and as a Member of the Cabinet. Before
his appointment as Chair, Dr. Bernstein served as a CEA Member from the
beginning of the Biden-Harris Administration.
Chair Bernstein has held a variety of posts in economic policy and
research. In policy, he was Chief Economist and Economic Adviser to
then–Vice President Biden from 2009 to 2011 and served as Deputy Chief
Economist at the Department of Labor during the Clinton Administration.
In research, Dr. Bernstein was a Senior Fellow at the Center on Budget and
Policy Priorities from 2011 to 2020 and spent 16 years in senior roles at
the Economic Policy Institute. An expert on labor markets and macroeconomics, Dr. Bernstein’s research focuses on income inequality, mobility,
employment and earnings, international trade, and the living standards of
the middle class. He received a BA from the Manhattan School of Music;
an MA from the Hunter School of Social Work; and an MA and PhD from
Columbia University.

The Members of the Council
Heather Boushey was appointed to the Council by the President on January
20, 2021. Before assuming this position, Dr. Boushey cofounded the
Washington Center for Equitable Growth, where she was President and CEO
Activities of the Council of Economic Advisers during 2023 | 391

from 2013 to 2020. She previously served as Chief Economist for Secretary
of State Hillary Clinton’s 2016 transition team and as an economist at the
Center for American Progress, the Joint Economic Committee of the U.S.
Congress, the Center for Economic and Policy Research, and the Economic
Policy Institute. She received a BA from Hampshire College and a PhD in
economics from The New School for Social Research.
C. Kirabo Jackson was appointed to the Council by the President on
August 28, 2023. Dr. Jackson is on leave from Northwestern University,
where he is the Abraham Harris Professor of Education and Social Policy,
a Professor of Economics, and a Faculty Fellow at the Institute for Policy
Research. Dr. Jackson is also on leave as editor-in-chief for the American
Economic Journal: Economic Policy. Dr. Jackson’s research focuses on
the economics of education, labor economics, and social policy issues. He
received a BA from Yale University, an MA from Harvard University, and
a PhD in economics from Harvard University.

Areas of Activity
A central function of the Council is to advise the President on all economic
issues and developments, including preparing frequent memos for the
President, the Vice President, and White House senior staff on key economic
data releases and policy issues. The Council works closely with officials at
various government entities—including the National Economic Council,
the Domestic Policy Council, the Office of Management and Budget, and
administrative agencies—to engage in discussions on numerous policy
matters. The Council, the Department of the Treasury, and the Office of
Management and Budget are responsible for producing the economic
forecasts that underlie the Administration’s Budget proposals. Finally,
the Council is a leading participant in the Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development (OECD), historically chairing the Economic
Policy Committee and participating in OECD working meetings. The
Council produces economic analysis that is presented in blog posts, issue
briefs, white papers, and public speeches. Under Chair Bernstein’s leadership, the CEA has increased the frequency of its blog posts, with a particular
focus on the analysis and interpretation of economic data releases.

Blog Posts
•

392 |

“A New Wage Measure for Core Non-Housing Services,” a blog
presenting a CEA-constructed wage measure specific to NHS industries that can address limitations of other prominent wage measures
(February 2023).

Appendix A

•

“The Employment Situation in [Month]” a series of blogs analyzing
the monthly Employment Report from the Bureau of Labor Statistics
(February, March, June, July, August, September, October 2023).

•

“How Junk Fees Distort Competition,” a blog identifying specific
junk fees and the challenges they pose to consumers and competition
broadly (March 2023).

•

“The Labor Supply Rebound from the Pandemic,” a blog on the return
of “missing workers” to the labor market following the pandemic and
the rebound in immigration flows (April 2023).

• “An Update on Housing Inflation in the Consumer Price Index,” a blog
analyzing the rise in housing inflation and its contribution to CPI inflation (April 2023).
•

“Investing in America Means Investing in America’s Small Businesses,”
a blog on how the Administration’s policies support small businesses
(May 2023).

•

“The DAME Tax: Making Cryptominers Pay for Costs They Impose on
Others,” a blog on how the proposed DAME tax can make cryptominers pay for costs imposed on local communities and the environment
(May 2023).

•

“The Potential Economic Impacts of Various Debt Ceiling Scenarios,”
a blog outlining the potential economic consequences if the U.S. government were to default on its obligations (May 2023).

•

“The Signal and the Noise: Trend Job Gains Reveal Transition to
Steady Growth,” a blog highlighting robust but decelerating job gains
and a normalization of labor supply back to prepandemic levels (May
2023).

•

“The Signal and the Noise, Part II: CPI Inflation,” a blog analyzing
total and core CPI inflation based on 3-month annualized changes
(May 2023).

•

“This Mother’s Day, More Moms Back at Work, but Care Challenges
Remain,” a blog on postpandemic maternal employment recovery and
how the Administration’s policies supporting parents and caregivers
can boost mothers’ labor supply (May 2023).

•

“Wage Sensitivity in Non-Housing Services Inflation,” a blog presenting a more disaggregated analysis of wage sensitivity in NHS inflation
(May 2023).

Activities of the Council of Economic Advisers during 2023 | 393

•

“Unsnarled Supply Chains Appear to Help Ease Goods Inflation,” a
blog analyzing the normalization of supply chains and cooling of core
goods inflation (June 2023).

• “Comments on the May 2023 Consumer Price Index Report,” a blog
analyzing total and core CPI inflation in May 2023 (June 2023).
• “Grocery Inflation is Finally Showing Signs of Cooling,” a blog outlining facts about grocery prices and inflation (June 2023).
•

“On Anniversary of Equal Pay Act, Signs of Progress and Remaining
Challenges for Women in the Labor Market,” a blog on the progress
in educational attainment, employment, and pay since the enactment
of the Equal Pay Act and remaining gender gaps in employment (June
2023).

•

“Apples to Äpfel: Recent Inflation Trends in the G7,” a blog analyzing
harmonized inflation data for G7 countries (June 2023).

•

“The June Consumer Price Index: Disinflation, Deflation, and Buying
Power in the U.S. Economy,” a blog on how the U.S. economy experienced falling inflation and real wage growth in June 2023 (July 2023).

•

“Improving Access, Affordability, and Quality in the Early Care and
Education (ECE) Market,” a blog on the lack of affordable quality care
for young children and policy solutions that can expand the availability
and affordability of high-quality early childhood education (July 2023).

•

“Labor Market Indicators Are Historically Strong After Adjusting for
Population Aging,” a blog outlining facts about the strength of labor
supply and demand after accounting for the effects of aging (July
2023).

•

“The Advance Estimate of Second Quarter Real GDP,” a blog analyzing the advance estimate of second-quarter real GDP (July 2023).

• “The July Consumer Price Index: It’s All About That Base (Effect),”
a blog about measuring CPI inflation over various timespans (August
2023).
•

“Chain Reaction: ‘Immaculate’ Disinflation and the Role of Easing
Supply Chains,” a blog on how supply chain normalization contributed
to falling inflation despite low unemployment (August 2023).

•

“New Student Loan Repayment Plan Benefits Borrowers Beyond
Lower Monthly Payments,” a blog on the benefits of SAVE over previous income-driven repayment plans for Federal student loan borrowers
(August 2023).

394 |

Appendix A

•

“Early Signs That Bidenomics is Attracting New Foreign Investment in
U.S. Manufacturing,” a blog on increases in foreign direct investment
in U.S. manufacturing (August 2023).

•

“What to Expect: The 2022 Census Poverty, Income, and Health
Insurance Reports,” a blog outlining the CEA’s expectations and
important context for the Census Bureau’s release of the 2022 income,
poverty, and health insurance reports (September 2023).

•

“The 2022 Income, Poverty, and Health Insurance Reports,” a blog on
key findings from the Census Bureau’s reports on poverty, income, and
health insurance for 2022 (September 2023).

•

“Chronic Absenteeism and Disrupted Learning Require an All-Handson-Deck Approach,” a blog on the importance of improving student
engagement and addressing chronic absenteeism exacerbated by the
COVID-19 pandemic (September 2023).

•

“The August 2023 Consumer Price Index,” a blog analyzing CPI inflation in August 2023 (September 2023).

•

“Crosswalk Talk: What’s the difference between the PCE and the
CPI?,” a blog on how and why the PCE and CPI differ (September
2023).

•

“An Update on Non-Housing Services Inflation: Progress in WageSensitive Prices,” a blog on easing in the wage-sensitive part of NHS
inflation and an update on housing inflation (September 2023).

•

“Federal Revenues After the 2017 Tax Cuts,” a blog on the effect of
lower tax revenues on the 2023 deficit and deficits dating back to the
enactment of the 2017 Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (October 2023).

•

“Union Deterrence and Recent NLRB Action,” a blog on the NLRB’s
decision in Cemex Construction Materials Pacific, LLC, and its relation to economic forces influencing unionization (October 2023).

•

“Four Facts About Hispanic Achievements in the U.S. Economy,” a
blog highlighting recent economic achievements of the Hispanic community in the United States in celebration of Hispanic Heritage Month
(October 2023).

•

“Commercial-to-residential Conversion: Addressing Office Vacancies,”
a blog assessing the benefits and challenges of transforming excess
office space into housing in high-demand markets (October 2023).

•

“As the U.S. Consumer Goes, So Goes the U.S. Economy,” a blog
highlighting the importance of consumption and the strong labor market for economic growth (October 2023).
Activities of the Council of Economic Advisers during 2023 | 395

•

“The Retirement Security Rule—Strengthening Protections for
Americans Saving for Retirement,” a blog outlining a new rule proposed by the Department of Labor to close loopholes and ensure the
financial advice Americans get for retirement is in their best interest
(October 2023).

•

“The Power of Empowering Workers: Reducing Racial Employment
and Unemployment Gaps,” a blog on the role of tight labor markets in
reducing racial labor market inequality (November 2023).

•

“American Rescue Plan’s Child Care Stabilization Funds Stabilized the
Industry While Helping Mothers Return to Work,” a blog outlining the
effect of the ARP stabilization funds on child care prices, child care
worker employment and wages, and maternal labor force participation
(November 2023).

• “The Anti-Poverty and Income-Boosting Impacts of the Enhanced
CTC,” a blog on the effects of the 2021 expansion of the Child Tax
Credit and subsequent expiration (November 2023).
•

“The Global Clean Energy Manufacturing Gap,” a blog on how the
Bipartisan Infrastructure Law and Inflation Reduction Act will support
global manufacturing of clean energy technologies (November 2023).

• “Disinflation Explanation: Supply, Demand, and their Interaction,” a
blog decomposing inflation to highlight the central role of unsnarled
supply chains (November 2023).
• “Go with the Flow: Getting Beneath the Surface of the Jobs Report,” a
blog about some of the dynamics underlying the topline numbers of the
November jobs report (December 2023).
•

“Disinflation Explanation, Part 2: Contribution Analysis,” a blog
decomposing core inflation into goods, housing, and non-housing
services (December 2023).

•

“Ten Charts That Explain the U.S. Economy in 2023,” a blog on how
the performance of the U.S. economy exceeded expectations in 2023
(December 2023).

•

“A Progress Report on Climate-Energy-Macro Modeling,” a blog on
how the CEA has worked with other Federal agencies to make progress
on quantifying climate risk within the President’s Budget (December
2023).

396 |

Appendix A

Issue Briefs, Speeches, and White Papers
•

“The U.S. Economy: Where It’s Been and Where It’s Going,” a speech
given by Chair Jared Bernstein at the Brookings Institution (February
8, 2023).

•

“Methodologies and Considerations for Integrating the Physical and
Transition Risks of Climate Change into Macroeconomic Forecasting
for the President’s Budget,” a white paper, cowritten with OMB,
outlining considerations for quantifying the macroeconomic effects
of climate change and more fully integrating them into future Budget
forecasts (March 2023).

•

“How President Biden’s Invest in America Agenda Has Laid the
Foundation for Decades of Strong, Stable, and Sustained, Equitable
Growth,” a speech given by CEA Member Heather Boushey at the
Peterson Institute for International Economics (May 31, 2023).

•

“The Economics of Demand-Side Support for the Department of
Energy’s Clean Hydrogen Hubs,” an issue brief on the importance
of demand-side support for expanding clean hydrogen capacity (July
2023).

•

“Protecting Competition Through Updated Merger Guidelines,” an
issue brief on how the draft of the updated Merger Guidelines from the
United States’ primary antitrust enforcement authorities reflects the
current economic evidence and the realities of the market (July 2023).

•

“Remarks by Chair Jared Bernstein at the Economic Policy Institute,”
a speech about the Biden-Harris Administration’s approach to international trade (September 28, 2023), a white paper.

•

“Did Stabilization Funds Help Mothers Get Back to Work After the
COVID-19 Recession?” a white paper on the effect of the American
Rescue Plan child care funding on maternal labor supply, cost growth
for families, and wages for child care workers (November 2023).

•

“Supply Chain Resilience,” an issue brief on progress making supply
chains more resilient and ongoing efforts to prepare for future economic shocks (November 2023).

•

“‘Weathering the Storm’: Federal Efforts Helped Bolster U.S. Education
Standing Among Peer Nations,” an issue brief on the Federal government’s policy response to test score declines due to COVID-19, successful interventions, and remaining challenges (December 2023).

Activities of the Council of Economic Advisers during 2023 | 397

Public Information
The Economic Report of the President, together with the Annual Report of
the Council of Economic Advisers, is an important vehicle for presenting
the Administration’s domestic and international economic policies. It is
available for purchase through the Government Publishing Office, and is
viewable at no cost at www.gpo.gov/erp. All the Council’s written materials
noted above, including this Report, can be found at www.whitehouse.gov/
cea. All links provided in this Report are active as of the date of publication.

The Staff of the Council of Economic Advisers
Front Office
Amy Ganz 	����������������������������������������Chief of Staff
Ernie Tedeschi 	����������������������������������Chief Economist
Molly Opinsky 	����������������������������������Special Assistant to the Chair
Kaleb Snider 	������������������������������������Special Assistant to a Member
Reid Fauble	����������������������������������������Special Adviser to a Member
Senior Economists
Alessandro Barbarino	������������������������Macroeconomics, Labor,
Econometrics
Jacob Bastian 	������������������������������������Public Finance, Social Insurance
Steven Braun 	������������������������������������Director of Macroeconomic
Forecasting
Evan Gee	��������������������������������������������Technology, Industrial Organization
Michael Geruso	����������������������������������Health and Demography, Public
Finance
Sandile Hlatshwayo 	��������������������������International Trade
Fariha Kamal 	������������������������������������International Trade
Kyle Meng 	����������������������������������������Climate, Energy, Environment
Jonas Nahm	����������������������������������������Industrial Strategy
Elena Patel 	����������������������������������������Public Finance and Tax, Housing
David Ratner	��������������������������������������Labor, Macroeconomics
Krista Schwarz	����������������������������������Finance
Elizabeth Tucker	��������������������������������Senior Adviser for National Security
Lee Tucker 	����������������������������������������Labor
Staff Economists
Will Nober 	����������������������������������������Industrial Organization, Climate
Chinemelu Okafor	������������������������������International
Aastha Rajan	��������������������������������������Labor, Public Finance
Lea Rendell	����������������������������������������Labor
Sam Slocum 	��������������������������������������Finance, Macroeconomics, Energy
398 |

Appendix A

Julia Turner	����������������������������������������Labor, Education, Care

Research Assistants
Erin Deal 	������������������������������������������Macroeconomics
Aiden Lee	������������������������������������������Industrial Strategy
Shawdi Mehrvarzan 	��������������������������Labor, International, OECD
Asha Reddy Patt 	������������������������������Education, Health, International
Naomi Shimberg	��������������������������������Climate, Energy, Environment
Natalie Tomeh	������������������������������������Housing, Public Finance
Special Adviser
Anna Katherine Pasnau	����������������������Clean Energy, Infrastructure, Labor
Statistical Office
Brian Amorosi 	����������������������������������Director of the Statistical Office
Madison Fox 	������������������������������������Statistical Office Associate
Administrative Office
Megan Packer	������������������������������������Manager of Finance and
Administration
Interns
Ayumi Akiyama, Karthick Arunachalam, Katherine Ashby, Steven Berit,
Atreya Bhamidi, Nissi Cantu, Andrew Gasparini, Cameron Greene, Simon
Hodson, Aarjav Joshi, Devansh Jotsinghani, Victoria Kidder, Margaret
Lin, Nour Ben Ltaifa, Rebecca Mann, Andrew Morin, Julian Ching Wang,
Griffin Young.
ERP Production
Alfred Imhoff 	������������������������������������Editor
Shea Gibbs 	����������������������������������������Editor
Michael Sarinsky 	������������������������������Editor

Activities of the Council of Economic Advisers during 2023 | 399

400 |

Appendix A

Appendix B

Statistical Tables Relating to Income,
Employment, and Production

401

Contents
National Income or Expenditure
B–1.

Percent changes in real gross domestic product, 1973–2023��������������

408

B–2.

Contributions to percent change in real gross domestic product,
1973–2023�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������

410

B–3.

Gross domestic product, 2008–2023���������������������������������������������������

412

B–4.

Percentage shares of gross domestic product, 1973–2023������������������

414

B–5.

Chain-type price indexes for gross domestic product, 1973–2023�����

416

B–6.

Gross value added by sector, 1973–2023��������������������������������������������

418

B–7.

Real gross value added by sector, 1973–2023�������������������������������������

419

B–8.

Gross domestic product (GDP) by industry, value added, in current
dollars and as a percentage of GDP, 2017–2023���������������������������������

420

B–9.

Real gross domestic product by industry, value added, and
percent changes, 2017–2023��������������������������������������������������������������

422

B–10. Personal consumption expenditures, 1973–2023��������������������������������

424

B–11. Real personal consumption expenditures, 2007–2023������������������������

425

B–12. Private fixed investment by type, 1973–2023�������������������������������������

426

B–13. Real private fixed investment by type, 2007–2023�����������������������������

427

B–14. Foreign transactions in the national income and product accounts,
1973–2023�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������

428

B–15. Real exports and imports of goods and services, 2007–2023�������������

429

B–16. Sources of personal income, 1973–2023���������������������������������������������

430

B–17. Disposition of personal income, 1973–2023���������������������������������������

432

B–18. Total and per capita disposable personal income and personal
consumption expenditures, and per capita gross domestic
product, in current and real dollars, 1973–2023����������������������������������

433

B–19. Gross saving and investment, 1973–2023�������������������������������������������

434

B–20. Median money income (in 2022 dollars) and poverty status of
families and people, by race, 2014–2022��������������������������������������������

436

B–21. Real farm income, 1957–2024������������������������������������������������������������

437

Contents

| 403

Labor Market Indicators
B–22. Civilian labor force, 1929–2023����������������������������������������������������������

438

B–23. Civilian employment by sex, age, and demographic characteristic,
1978–2023�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������

440

B–24. Unemployment by sex, age, and demographic characteristic,
1978–2023�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������

441

B–25. Civilian labor force participation rate, 1978–2023�����������������������������

442

B–26. Civilian employment/population ratio, 1978–2023����������������������������

443

B–27. Civilian unemployment rate, 1978–2023��������������������������������������������

444

B–28. Unemployment by duration and reason, 1978–2023��������������������������

445

B–29. Employees on nonagricultural payrolls, by major industry,
1978–2023�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������

446

B–30. Hours and earnings in private nonagricultural industries,
1978–2023�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������

448

B–31. Employment cost index, private industry, 2006–2023������������������������

449

B–32. Productivity and related data, business and nonfarm business
sectors, 1973–2023������������������������������������������������������������������������������

450

B–33. Changes in productivity and related data, business and nonfarm
business sectors, 1973–2023���������������������������������������������������������������

451

Production and Business Activity
B–34. Industrial production indexes, major industry divisions,
1978–2023�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������

452

B–35. Capacity utilization rates, 1978–2023�������������������������������������������������

453

B–36. New private housing units started, authorized, and completed
and houses sold, 1978–2023����������������������������������������������������������������

454

B–37. Manufacturing and trade sales and inventories, 1981–2023���������������

455

Prices
B–38. Changes in consumer price indexes, 1981–2023��������������������������������

456

B–39. Price indexes for personal consumption expenditures, and
percent changes, 1973–2023��������������������������������������������������������������

457

404 |

Appendix B

Money Stock, Credit, and Finance
B–40. Money stock and debt measures, 1986–2023��������������������������������������

458

B–41. Consumer credit outstanding, 1973–2023�������������������������������������������

459

B–42. Bond yields and interest rates, 1953–2023������������������������������������������

460

B–43. Mortgage debt outstanding by type of property and of financing,
1963–2023�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������

462

B–44. Mortgage debt outstanding by holder, 1963–2023������������������������������

463

Government Finance
B–45. Federal receipts, outlays, surplus or deficit, and debt, fiscal years
1959–2025�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������

464

B–46. Federal receipts, outlays, surplus or deficit, and debt, as percent
of gross domestic product, fiscal years 1954–2025�����������������������������

465

B–47. Federal receipts and outlays, by major category, and surplus or
deficit, fiscal years 1959–2025������������������������������������������������������������

466

B–48. Federal receipts, outlays, surplus or deficit, and debt, fiscal years
2020–2025�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������

467

B–49. Federal and State and local government current receipts and
expenditures, national income and product accounts (NIPA) basis,
1973–2023�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������

468

B–50. State and local government revenues and expenditures,
fiscal years 1958–2021������������������������������������������������������������������������

469

B–51. U.S. Treasury securities outstanding by kind of obligation,
1983–2023�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������

470

B–52. Estimated ownership of U.S. Treasury securities, 2009–2023������������

471

Corporate Profits and Finance
B–53. Corporate profits with inventory valuation and capital
consumption adjustments, 1973–2023������������������������������������������������

472

B–54. Corporate profits by industry, 1973–2023�������������������������������������������

473

B–55. Historical stock prices and yields, 1949–2003������������������������������������

474

B–56. Common stock prices and yields, 2000–2023�������������������������������������

475

Contents

| 405

International Statistics
B–57. U.S. international transactions, 1973–2023����������������������������������������

476

B–58. U.S. international trade in goods on balance of payments (BOP)
and Census basis, and trade in services on BOP basis, 1994–2023����

478

B–59. U.S. international trade in goods and services by area and country,
2000–2022�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������

479

B–60. Foreign exchange rates, 2003–2023����������������������������������������������������

480

B–61. Growth rates in real gross domestic product by area and country,
2005–2024�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������

481

406 |

Appendix B

General Notes
Detail in these tables may not add to totals due to rounding.
Because of the formula used for calculating real gross domestic product (GDP),
the chained (2017) dollar estimates for the detailed components do not add to the
chained-dollar value of GDP or to any intermediate aggregate. The Department
of Commerce (Bureau of Economic Analysis) no longer publishes chained-dollar
estimates prior to 2007, except for selected series.
Because of the method used for seasonal adjustment, the sum or average of seasonally adjusted monthly values generally will not equal annual totals based on
unadjusted values.
Unless otherwise noted, all dollar figures are in current dollars.
Symbols used:
p Preliminary.
... Not available (also, not applicable).
NSA Not seasonally adjusted.
Data in these tables reflect revisions made by source agencies through
February 8, 2024.
Excel versions of these tables are available at www.gpo.gov/erp.

General Notes

| 407

National Income or Expenditure
Table B–1. Percent changes in real gross domestic product, 1973–2023
[Percent change, fourth quarter over fourth quarter; quarterly changes at seasonally adjusted annual rates]
Personal consumption
expenditures

Year or quarter

1973 ����������������������
1974 ����������������������
1975 ����������������������
1976 ����������������������
1977 ����������������������
1978 ����������������������
1979 ����������������������
1980 ����������������������
1981 ����������������������
1982 ����������������������
1983 ����������������������
1984 ����������������������
1985 ����������������������
1986 ����������������������
1987 ����������������������
1988 ����������������������
1989 ����������������������
1990 ����������������������
1991 ����������������������
1992 ����������������������
1993 ����������������������
1994 ����������������������
1995 ����������������������
1996 ����������������������
1997 ����������������������
1998 ����������������������
1999 ����������������������
2000 ����������������������
2001 ����������������������
2002 ����������������������
2003 ����������������������
2004 ����������������������
2005 ����������������������
2006 ����������������������
2007 ����������������������
2008 ����������������������
2009 ����������������������
2010 ����������������������
2011 ����������������������
2012 ����������������������
2013 ����������������������
2014 ����������������������
2015 ����������������������
2016 ����������������������
2017 ����������������������
2018 ����������������������
2019 ����������������������
2020 ����������������������
2021 ����������������������
2022 ����������������������
2023 p ��������������������
2020: I ������������������
      II �����������������
      III ����������������
      IV ����������������
2021: I ������������������
      II �����������������
      III ����������������
      IV ����������������
2022: I ������������������
      II �����������������
      III ����������������
      IV ����������������
2023: I ������������������
      II �����������������
      III ����������������
      IV p �������������

Gross
domestic
product

4.0
–1.9
2.6
4.3
5.0
6.7
1.3
.0
1.3
–1.4
7.9
5.6
4.2
2.9
4.5
3.8
2.7
.6
1.2
4.4
2.6
4.1
2.2
4.4
4.5
4.9
4.8
2.9
.2
2.0
4.3
3.4
3.0
2.6
2.1
–2.5
.1
2.8
1.5
1.6
3.0
2.7
2.1
2.2
3.0
2.1
3.2
–1.1
5.4
.7
3.1
–5.3
–28.0
34.8
4.2
5.2
6.2
3.3
7.0
–2.0
–.6
2.7
2.6
2.2
2.1
4.9
3.3

Fixed investment
Nonresidential
Total

1.8
–1.6
5.1
5.4
4.2
4.0
1.7
.0
.1
3.5
6.6
4.3
4.8
4.4
2.8
4.6
2.4
.8
.9
4.9
3.3
3.8
2.8
3.4
4.5
5.6
5.2
4.3
2.5
2.0
3.8
3.8
2.8
3.2
2.0
–1.5
–.2
2.8
1.0
1.5
2.2
3.5
2.6
2.5
3.1
2.0
2.6
–.8
7.2
1.2
2.6
–6.4
–30.2
40.5
5.6
8.9
13.6
2.8
4.0
.0
2.0
1.6
1.2
3.8
.8
3.1
2.8

See next page for continuation of table.

408 |

Appendix B

Gross private domestic investment

Goods

0.4
–5.6
6.1
6.4
4.9
3.5
.3
–2.5
–.2
3.6
8.3
5.3
4.6
6.5
.4
4.5
1.8
–1.6
–.8
5.3
4.4
5.5
2.3
4.8
5.3
8.1
6.6
4.0
4.9
1.7
6.6
4.3
3.0
4.6
1.8
–6.8
.6
4.3
.9
2.4
3.9
5.3
4.0
3.7
5.4
2.1
3.8
8.8
6.6
–.6
3.5
–2.1
–8.6
51.7
3.2
16.5
14.7
–8.5
5.6
–1.2
–.3
–.7
.0
5.1
.5
4.9
3.8

Services

3.2
2.4
4.1
4.5
3.7
4.4
2.9
2.2
.3
3.4
5.3
3.6
5.0
3.0
4.5
4.7
2.7
2.3
2.0
4.7
2.7
2.8
3.0
2.7
4.0
4.3
4.5
4.5
1.3
2.1
2.3
3.6
2.7
2.5
2.0
1.2
–.6
2.1
1.0
1.1
1.4
2.6
1.9
1.9
2.0
2.0
2.0
–5.1
7.6
2.1
2.2
–8.4
–38.7
35.1
6.8
5.1
13.0
9.3
3.2
.6
3.2
2.8
1.8
3.1
1.0
2.2
2.4

Total

10.2
–10.4
–9.8
15.2
14.9
14.3
–3.4
–7.2
6.7
–17.3
31.3
14.2
1.9
–4.1
9.8
–.5
.7
–6.5
2.1
7.7
7.6
11.5
.8
11.2
11.4
9.7
8.5
4.4
–11.1
4.4
8.7
8.0
6.1
–1.4
–2.0
–15.3
–9.0
12.0
10.5
3.9
10.6
5.8
3.5
2.3
4.9
4.7
1.3
2.1
7.9
–2.4
1.8
–9.9
–46.4
98.9
13.2
–3.3
–5.4
16.1
27.9
6.2
–10.6
–7.6
3.4
–9.0
5.2
10.0
2.1

Total

3.5
–9.9
–2.6
12.1
12.1
13.1
1.1
–4.8
1.5
–8.0
18.3
11.3
3.7
.6
1.5
3.7
1.5
–4.2
–1.9
8.7
8.4
6.6
5.5
9.9
8.3
11.5
7.2
5.9
–4.7
–1.5
8.6
6.5
5.8
.0
–1.1
–11.1
–10.5
6.2
9.2
7.3
6.6
7.8
2.6
3.5
5.5
3.3
2.9
.7
3.8
–.8
3.1
–3.3
–28.2
28.3
15.2
9.3
5.9
–1.6
1.9
7.2
–.2
–4.3
–5.4
3.1
5.2
2.6
1.7

Total
10.6
–3.9
–5.9
7.8
11.9
16.0
5.5
–.9
9.0
–9.5
10.4
13.9
3.2
–3.2
2.2
5.1
4.5
–.9
–3.4
7.1
7.6
8.5
7.4
11.3
9.7
11.6
8.4
8.5
–6.8
–5.1
6.8
6.5
6.1
8.1
7.3
–7.0
–10.3
9.0
10.1
5.7
6.4
7.7
.9
3.3
5.6
5.6
3.1
–3.7
4.9
5.6
4.1
–7.7
–28.6
18.3
10.5
8.9
9.7
–1.3
2.7
10.7
5.3
4.7
1.7
5.7
7.4
1.4
1.9

Structures
7.9
–6.4
–8.1
3.8
5.7
21.7
8.8
2.7
14.1
–13.5
–3.9
15.7
3.3
–14.3
4.9
–3.3
3.3
–3.2
–12.8
1.0
.2
1.6
4.7
10.9
4.4
4.3
–.1
10.8
–10.6
–15.7
1.9
.3
1.5
9.0
17.7
–.9
–27.1
–3.4
9.0
4.1
6.4
9.6
–5.6
3.7
–.4
3.5
6.4
–14.9
–.9
.8
14.8
–5.2
–40.0
–8.9
1.5
7.8
1.0
–4.1
–7.7
–1.2
–.5
–1.3
6.5
30.3
16.1
11.2
3.2

Equipment
13.5
–3.7
–6.7
9.0
17.2
14.5
2.7
–4.4
4.6
–10.0
19.9
13.4
1.7
.8
.1
8.2
2.5
–2.7
–3.2
11.3
13.1
12.5
8.1
11.1
10.7
14.8
9.5
8.5
–7.7
–3.7
9.6
9.8
8.7
7.1
3.9
–15.9
–8.4
22.6
12.7
7.8
6.7
6.4
2.0
–.9
7.5
3.3
–2.1
–3.7
1.4
5.3
–.1
–20.5
–38.0
50.8
15.6
2.0
10.5
–8.0
1.9
16.8
4.9
5.6
–5.0
–4.1
7.7
–4.4
1.0

Intellectual
property
products
5.1
1.6
2.8
11.8
4.8
10.3
9.4
4.7
12.1
3.4
13.0
12.6
7.7
5.4
4.2
9.8
11.3
6.2
7.2
4.8
2.9
5.8
8.3
12.1
12.4
11.5
13.3
6.6
–2.1
.9
5.8
5.7
5.1
9.3
4.0
.9
3.8
1.6
7.2
3.7
6.1
8.2
4.3
9.0
7.2
9.9
7.3
3.4
11.6
8.3
2.6
6.2
–9.5
7.9
10.4
16.9
13.6
7.1
9.1
11.4
8.7
7.1
6.1
3.8
2.7
1.8
2.1

Residential

–10.5
–24.6
7.8
23.8
12.6
6.8
–9.1
–15.3
–22.0
–1.7
49.7
3.7
5.2
11.8
–.5
.1
–6.5
–13.6
2.9
13.6
10.6
1.6
.1
5.6
4.0
11.3
3.5
–1.5
2.0
8.1
12.7
6.6
5.2
–15.2
–21.2
–24.7
–11.5
–5.7
5.3
15.4
7.5
8.1
9.7
4.5
5.1
–4.1
2.2
15.9
.4
–17.4
.0
14.1
–26.7
66.1
30.1
9.8
–4.4
–2.7
–.5
–1.8
–14.1
–26.4
–24.9
–5.3
–2.2
6.7
1.1

Change
in
private
inventories
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������
����������������

Table B–1. Percent changes in real gross domestic product, 1973–2023—Continued
[Percent change, fourth quarter over fourth quarter; quarterly changes at seasonally adjusted annual rates]
Net exports of
goods and services
Year or quarter

1973 ����������������������
1974 ����������������������
1975 ����������������������
1976 ����������������������
1977 ����������������������
1978 ����������������������
1979 ����������������������
1980 ����������������������
1981 ����������������������
1982 ����������������������
1983 ����������������������
1984 ����������������������
1985 ����������������������
1986 ����������������������
1987 ����������������������
1988 ����������������������
1989 ����������������������
1990 ����������������������
1991 ����������������������
1992 ����������������������
1993 ����������������������
1994 ����������������������
1995 ����������������������
1996 ����������������������
1997 ����������������������
1998 ����������������������
1999 ����������������������
2000 ����������������������
2001 ����������������������
2002 ����������������������
2003 ����������������������
2004 ����������������������
2005 ����������������������
2006 ����������������������
2007 ����������������������
2008 ����������������������
2009 ����������������������
2010 ����������������������
2011 ����������������������
2012 ����������������������
2013 ����������������������
2014 ����������������������
2015 ����������������������
2016 ����������������������
2017 ����������������������
2018 ����������������������
2019 ����������������������
2020 ����������������������
2021 ����������������������
2022 ����������������������
2023 p ��������������������
2020: I ������������������
      II �����������������
      III ����������������
      IV ����������������
2021: I ������������������
      II �����������������
      III ����������������
      IV ����������������
2022: I ������������������
      II �����������������
      III ����������������
      IV ����������������
2023: I ������������������
      II �����������������
      III ����������������
      IV p �������������

Government consumption expenditures
and gross investment
Federal

Net
exports

Exports

Imports

�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������
�������������

18.4
3.1
1.5
4.3
–1.4
18.8
10.5
3.9
.7
–12.2
5.5
9.1
1.5
10.6
12.8
14.0
10.2
7.4
9.2
4.5
4.4
10.8
9.4
10.1
8.3
2.6
6.2
6.0
–12.2
4.0
7.2
7.2
7.4
9.9
9.2
–2.0
1.3
10.4
4.8
2.9
5.2
2.4
–1.5
1.4
6.1
.3
.8
–9.7
6.7
4.3
2.1
–15.4
–61.5
62.0
25.8
.9
2.0
1.5
24.2
–4.6
10.6
16.2
–3.5
6.8
–9.3
5.4
6.3

–0.5
–1.0
–5.6
19.2
5.7
9.9
.9
–9.3
6.2
–3.9
24.6
18.9
5.6
7.9
6.3
3.8
2.6
–.2
5.7
6.5
9.9
12.2
4.8
11.1
14.2
11.0
12.4
11.1
–7.6
9.6
5.9
10.9
6.1
4.0
1.6
–5.4
–5.2
11.3
3.3
.5
2.9
6.5
3.3
2.2
5.8
3.0
–1.9
.1
11.1
2.1
–.2
–13.0
–53.6
88.6
32.0
8.0
7.7
8.5
20.6
14.7
4.1
–4.8
–4.3
1.3
–7.6
4.2
1.9

Total
–0.3
3.0
3.0
–1.3
1.9
4.4
.9
.3
2.5
2.6
1.9
6.3
6.1
4.7
3.0
1.4
2.5
2.6
.0
1.3
–.7
.0
–.6
2.6
1.7
2.8
3.9
.5
4.9
3.8
1.8
.8
.8
1.9
2.3
2.6
3.1
–1.5
–3.4
–2.1
–2.3
.3
2.6
1.5
1.0
1.9
4.7
1.1
–.2
.8
4.3
4.4
8.6
–6.1
–1.9
5.7
–4.3
–1.5
–.3
–2.9
–1.9
2.9
5.3
4.8
3.3
5.8
3.3

Total
–3.6
3.7
.8
–1.0
2.3
3.5
1.2
4.0
6.0
4.5
2.7
7.1
6.7
5.3
3.6
–1.4
.5
1.5
–2.3
1.6
–4.5
–4.2
–4.8
1.1
.2
–.3
3.3
–1.9
5.5
8.1
6.6
2.6
1.8
2.4
3.6
6.4
6.2
1.8
–3.6
–2.6
–6.0
–1.0
1.4
.2
1.4
3.5
3.9
4.5
.6
–.1
4.0
5.2
31.8
–12.3
–1.9
18.1
–8.9
–6.8
2.1
–6.9
–3.9
1.2
9.8
5.2
1.1
7.1
2.5

National Nondefense defense
–5.0
1.2
.5
–2.1
.1
2.9
2.4
3.7
7.9
7.3
6.5
5.6
8.2
4.7
5.3
–.8
–1.3
.0
–4.9
–.4
–5.4
–6.7
–5.0
.3
–.8
–2.4
3.8
–3.3
4.7
8.1
9.0
2.8
1.8
3.1
3.9
7.4
4.9
1.3
–3.6
–4.7
–6.4
–3.4
–.2
–.5
2.1
4.5
4.3
3.2
–5.0
.2
3.3
3.9
.9
–.4
8.7
–7.1
–4.7
–3.2
–4.8
–6.9
.9
–.3
7.7
1.9
2.3
8.4
.9

–0.3
9.5
1.4
1.3
6.8
4.8
–1.1
4.6
2.0
–1.6
–6.6
11.5
2.8
6.8
–1.0
–3.0
5.8
5.4
4.3
6.2
–2.5
1.1
–4.3
2.6
1.9
3.3
2.4
.4
6.8
8.2
2.6
2.3
1.9
1.3
3.1
4.5
8.9
2.7
–3.5
1.2
–5.4
2.8
3.8
1.2
.4
2.1
3.2
6.4
8.6
–.6
4.7
7.1
90.1
–25.8
–15.1
63.4
–13.9
–11.4
11.8
–6.9
–9.8
3.3
12.6
9.5
–.4
5.5
4.6

State
and
local
2.9
2.4
4.9
–1.6
1.7
5.2
.7
–2.9
–.7
.8
1.1
5.4
5.5
4.1
2.4
4.1
4.3
3.6
1.9
1.1
2.2
3.1
2.2
3.6
2.7
4.6
4.2
1.8
4.6
1.5
–.8
–.2
.2
1.6
1.5
.3
1.0
–3.7
–3.2
–1.7
.2
1.1
3.3
2.2
.8
.9
5.2
–.9
–.6
1.3
4.5
4.0
–3.6
–2.0
–1.9
–1.3
–1.4
2.0
–1.6
–.4
–.8
3.8
2.8
4.6
4.7
5.0
3.7

Final
Final
Gross sales to Gross
sales of domestic private domestic Average
of GDP
domestic pur- domestic income and
GDI
pur(GDI) 3
product chases 1
chasers 2
2.8
–1.7
3.9
3.8
4.5
6.4
2.2
.5
.3
.4
6.0
5.0
4.6
3.9
3.0
4.6
2.9
1.0
.5
4.5
2.7
3.3
3.0
4.2
3.9
5.2
4.6
3.2
1.5
.9
4.3
3.1
2.9
2.9
2.3
–1.8
–.2
2.0
1.3
2.0
2.4
3.0
2.0
2.4
3.1
1.9
3.5
–1.3
4.7
1.0
3.4
–4.2
–24.4
25.1
4.5
7.6
8.3
.3
2.6
–1.9
1.5
3.4
1.0
4.6
2.1
3.6
3.2

2.9
–2.3
2.0
5.4
5.6
6.0
.5
–1.4
1.8
–.7
9.5
6.5
4.5
2.9
4.1
3.0
2.1
–.1
.9
4.6
3.2
4.3
1.8
4.6
5.2
5.9
5.6
3.7
.4
2.7
4.2
4.0
3.0
2.1
1.3
–3.1
–.8
3.1
1.4
1.2
2.7
3.3
2.7
2.3
3.0
2.5
2.7
.0
6.1
.5
2.8
–5.2
–27.5
38.1
5.5
6.1
6.9
4.2
7.1
.6
–1.1
.1
2.2
1.6
2.0
4.7
2.8

2.2
3.8
3.9
–3.5
–2.9
–2.4
3.4
2.7
2.6
6.7
3.8
4.1
5.9
6.0
5.5
6.1
5.4
6.0
1.5
.8
1.0
–1.2
1.3
.6
.4
1.2
1.2
.8
–1.2
–1.3
9.1
6.6
7.3
5.9
6.7
6.1
4.6
3.4
3.8
3.5
2.7
2.8
2.5
5.5
5.0
4.4
4.7
4.2
2.2
1.0
1.9
–.3
1.0
.8
.3
.7
.9
5.6
3.9
4.1
4.3
3.0
2.8
4.4
4.3
4.2
3.3
2.9
2.6
4.8
4.8
4.6
5.3
5.5
5.0
6.9
4.9
4.9
5.7
4.4
4.6
4.7
3.6
3.3
.9
–.4
–.1
1.3
3.2
2.6
4.8
2.7
3.5
4.4
3.8
3.6
3.4
4.1
3.6
2.5
2.6
2.6
1.3
–.3
.9
–3.5
–2.6
–2.6
–2.1
.6
.4
3.4
3.3
3.0
2.4
2.0
1.8
2.6
2.8
2.2
3.1
1.3
2.1
4.3
4.1
3.4
2.6
1.4
1.8
2.7
1.3
1.7
3.6
3.0
3.0
2.3
2.8
2.4
2.7
2.6
2.9
–.5
.2
–.4
6.5
4.4
4.9
.8
.0
.3
2.7 ������������� ���������������
–5.8
–2.4
–3.9
–29.8
–30.5
–29.3
37.9
28.9
31.8
7.5
15.3
9.6
8.9
3.1
4.2
11.9
4.6
5.4
1.9
3.6
3.4
3.6
6.2
6.6
1.5
.5
–.8
1.5
.0
–.3
.3
2.7
2.7
–.2
–3.0
–.3
3.6
.5
1.4
1.7
.5
1.3
3.0
1.5
3.2
2.6 ������������� ���������������

1 Gross domestic product (GDP) less exports of goods and services plus imports of goods and services.
2 Personal consumption expenditures plus gross private fixed investment.
3 Gross domestic income is deflated by the implicit price deflator for GDP.

Note: Percent changes based on unrounded GDP quantity indexes.
Source: Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic Analysis).

National Income or Expenditure | 409

Table B–2. Contributions to percent change in real gross domestic product, 1973–2023
[Percentage points, except as noted; annual average to annual average, quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates]
Personal consumption
expenditures

Year or quarter

1973 ����������������������
1974 ����������������������
1975 ����������������������
1976 ����������������������
1977 ����������������������
1978 ����������������������
1979 ����������������������
1980 ����������������������
1981 ����������������������
1982 ����������������������
1983 ����������������������
1984 ����������������������
1985 ����������������������
1986 ����������������������
1987 ����������������������
1988 ����������������������
1989 ����������������������
1990 ����������������������
1991 ����������������������
1992 ����������������������
1993 ����������������������
1994 ����������������������
1995 ����������������������
1996 ����������������������
1997 ����������������������
1998 ����������������������
1999 ����������������������
2000 ����������������������
2001 ����������������������
2002 ����������������������
2003 ����������������������
2004 ����������������������
2005 ����������������������
2006 ����������������������
2007 ����������������������
2008 ����������������������
2009 ����������������������
2010 ����������������������
2011 ����������������������
2012 ����������������������
2013 ����������������������
2014 ����������������������
2015 ����������������������
2016 ����������������������
2017 ����������������������
2018 ����������������������
2019 ����������������������
2020 ����������������������
2021 ����������������������
2022 ����������������������
2023 p ��������������������
2020: I ������������������
      II �����������������
      III ����������������
      IV ����������������
2021: I ������������������
      II �����������������
      III ����������������
      IV ����������������
2022: I ������������������
      II �����������������
      III ����������������
      IV ����������������
2023: I ������������������
      II �����������������
      III ����������������
      IV p �������������

Gross
domestic
product
(percent
change)

5.6
–.5
–.2
5.4
4.6
5.5
3.2
–.3
2.5
–1.8
4.6
7.2
4.2
3.5
3.5
4.2
3.7
1.9
–.1
3.5
2.7
4.0
2.7
3.8
4.4
4.5
4.8
4.1
1.0
1.7
2.8
3.8
3.5
2.8
2.0
.1
–2.6
2.7
1.6
2.3
2.1
2.5
2.9
1.8
2.5
3.0
2.5
–2.2
5.8
1.9
2.5
–5.3
–28.0
34.8
4.2
5.2
6.2
3.3
7.0
–2.0
–.6
2.7
2.6
2.2
2.1
4.9
3.3

Fixed investment
Nonresidential
Total

2.97
–.50
1.36
3.41
2.59
2.68
1.44
–.19
.85
.88
3.51
3.30
3.20
2.58
2.14
2.65
1.86
1.28
.12
2.36
2.24
2.51
1.91
2.26
2.45
3.42
3.49
3.29
1.63
1.70
2.13
2.54
2.38
1.95
1.63
.10
–.88
1.31
1.16
.94
1.18
1.91
2.27
1.65
1.79
1.86
1.35
–1.69
5.59
1.72
1.49
–4.34
–21.51
24.93
3.63
5.70
8.73
1.89
2.71
–.03
1.32
1.05
.79
2.54
.55
2.11
1.91

See next page for continuation of table.

410 |

Appendix B

Gross private domestic investment

Goods

1.52
–1.08
.20
2.03
1.26
1.19
.45
–.72
.33
.19
1.69
1.91
1.38
1.45
.47
.96
.64
.16
–.49
.76
.99
1.26
.71
1.06
1.12
1.54
1.83
1.23
.72
.92
1.15
1.21
.98
.87
.65
–.71
–.70
.62
.49
.48
.76
.96
1.08
.78
.88
.84
.63
1.02
2.51
.07
.47
–.44
–1.59
10.23
.71
3.52
3.24
–2.10
1.26
–.30
–.09
–.18
–.01
1.14
.11
1.09
.85

Services

1.45
.58
1.16
1.38
1.33
1.49
.99
.53
.52
.69
1.82
1.39
1.83
1.13
1.67
1.69
1.21
1.12
.61
1.60
1.26
1.26
1.20
1.20
1.33
1.88
1.66
2.06
.92
.78
.98
1.34
1.40
1.08
.98
.81
–.18
.68
.68
.46
.42
.95
1.19
.87
.90
1.01
.71
–2.70
3.08
1.65
1.02
–3.90
–19.92
14.70
2.92
2.18
5.49
3.99
1.45
.27
1.41
1.23
.80
1.40
.44
1.02
1.06

Total

1.95
–1.24
–2.91
2.91
2.47
2.22
.72
–2.07
1.64
–2.46
1.60
4.73
–.01
.03
.53
.45
.72
–.45
–1.09
1.11
1.24
1.90
.55
1.49
2.01
1.76
1.62
1.31
–1.11
–.16
.76
1.64
1.26
.60
–.49
–1.52
–3.49
1.84
.95
1.65
1.19
1.09
1.08
–.02
.77
1.02
.55
–.85
1.52
.86
–.21
–1.87
–9.29
13.52
2.36
–.46
–.84
2.71
4.63
1.16
–2.10
–1.45
.62
–1.69
.90
1.74
.38

Total

1.47
–.98
–1.68
1.54
2.23
2.10
1.11
–1.18
.50
–1.16
1.32
2.83
1.02
.34
.11
.59
.55
–.25
–.84
.83
1.17
1.29
.99
1.48
1.49
1.82
1.65
1.34
–.27
–.64
.77
1.23
1.33
.50
–.24
–1.05
–2.69
.44
1.00
1.48
.96
1.20
.78
.50
.77
.90
.48
–.37
1.25
.24
.09
–.57
–5.28
5.04
2.55
1.63
1.05
–.28
.35
1.23
–.05
–.79
–.99
.53
.90
.46
.31

Total
1.51
.10
–1.13
.66
1.26
1.72
1.34
.00
.87
–.43
–.06
2.18
.91
–.24
.01
.63
.71
.14
–.48
.33
.84
.91
1.15
1.13
1.38
1.44
1.36
1.31
–.31
–.94
.30
.67
.92
1.00
.89
.08
–1.95
.52
1.00
1.16
.61
1.07
.44
.25
.61
.93
.51
–.66
.78
.68
.58
–1.09
–4.12
2.69
1.35
1.18
1.27
–.15
.37
1.32
.68
.62
.24
.76
.98
.21
.26

Structures
0.30
–.08
–.42
.09
.15
.52
.51
.26
.39
–.09
–.56
.58
.31
–.49
–.11
.02
.07
.05
–.38
–.18
–.01
.05
.16
.15
.21
.16
.01
.24
–.04
–.56
–.09
.00
.06
.22
.42
.23
–.71
–.50
.08
.35
.03
.33
.01
–.10
.08
.17
.08
–.30
–.09
–.06
.36
–.16
–1.47
–.27
.03
.19
.02
–.12
–.21
–.03
–.01
–.03
.17
.77
.46
.33
.10

Equipment
1.12
.14
–.73
.39
1.01
1.08
.62
–.35
.28
–.47
.32
1.29
.39
.08
.03
.43
.35
–.14
–.28
.34
.73
.75
.78
.65
.76
.91
.89
.71
–.31
–.35
.26
.49
.60
.57
.25
–.29
–1.21
.91
.69
.62
.33
.48
.24
–.05
.22
.35
.06
–.58
.33
.26
–.01
–1.23
–2.16
2.50
.79
.15
.55
–.40
.11
.77
.25
.28
–.26
–.21
.38
–.22
.05

Intellectual
property
products
0.08
.05
.01
.18
.11
.12
.20
.09
.21
.12
.17
.30
.21
.17
.10
.18
.29
.22
.18
.17
.12
.11
.20
.33
.41
.37
.45
.36
.04
–.03
.14
.18
.26
.21
.23
.14
–.02
.11
.24
.20
.25
.26
.20
.40
.31
.41
.37
.22
.54
.48
.23
.31
–.49
.46
.53
.85
.70
.37
.47
.58
.45
.37
.32
.20
.15
.10
.11

Residential

–0.04
–1.08
–.54
.88
.97
.38
–.22
–1.19
–.37
–.72
1.38
.65
.11
.58
.10
–.05
–.16
–.38
–.35
.49
.32
.38
–.15
.35
.11
.38
.29
.03
.04
.29
.47
.57
.41
–.50
–1.13
–1.14
–.74
–.08
.00
.31
.34
.13
.34
.25
.16
–.03
–.04
.28
.47
–.44
–.49
.52
–1.16
2.35
1.20
.44
–.22
–.13
–.02
–.09
–.73
–1.41
–1.23
–.22
–.09
.26
.04

Change
in
private
inventories
0.48
–.26
–1.24
1.37
.24
.12
–.40
–.89
1.13
–1.31
.28
1.90
–1.03
–.31
.41
–.13
.17
–.21
–.26
.28
.07
.61
–.44
.02
.52
–.07
–.03
–.03
–.84
.49
–.02
.40
–.07
.10
–.25
–.47
–.80
1.40
–.05
.17
.24
–.11
.30
–.52
.00
.12
.08
–.48
.26
.62
–.31
–1.30
–4.01
8.48
–.18
–2.08
–1.89
2.99
4.28
–.07
–2.05
–.66
1.61
–2.22
.00
1.27
.07

Table B–2. Contributions to percent change in real gross domestic product,
1973–2023—Continued
[Percentage points, except as noted; annual average to annual average, quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates]
Government consumption expenditures
and gross investment

Net exports of goods and services
Year or quarter

1973 ����������������������
1974 ����������������������
1975 ����������������������
1976 ����������������������
1977 ����������������������
1978 ����������������������
1979 ����������������������
1980 ����������������������
1981 ����������������������
1982 ����������������������
1983 ����������������������
1984 ����������������������
1985 ����������������������
1986 ����������������������
1987 ����������������������
1988 ����������������������
1989 ����������������������
1990 ����������������������
1991 ����������������������
1992 ����������������������
1993 ����������������������
1994 ����������������������
1995 ����������������������
1996 ����������������������
1997 ����������������������
1998 ����������������������
1999 ����������������������
2000 ����������������������
2001 ����������������������
2002 ����������������������
2003 ����������������������
2004 ����������������������
2005 ����������������������
2006 ����������������������
2007 ����������������������
2008 ����������������������
2009 ����������������������
2010 ����������������������
2011 ����������������������
2012 ����������������������
2013 ����������������������
2014 ����������������������
2015 ����������������������
2016 ����������������������
2017 ����������������������
2018 ����������������������
2019 ����������������������
2020 ����������������������
2021 ����������������������
2022 ����������������������
2023 p ��������������������
2020: I ������������������
      II �����������������
      III ����������������
      IV ����������������
2021: I ������������������
      II �����������������
      III ����������������
      IV ����������������
2022: I ������������������
      II �����������������
      III ����������������
      IV ����������������
2023: I ������������������
      II �����������������
      III ����������������
      IV p �������������

Net
exports
0.80
.73
.86
–1.05
–.70
.05
.64
1.64
–.15
–.59
–1.32
–1.54
–.39
–.29
.17
.81
.51
.40
.62
–.04
–.56
–.41
.12
–.15
–.31
–1.14
–.90
–.85
–.24
–.67
–.49
–.63
–.30
–.06
.52
1.04
1.07
–.43
.12
.12
.20
–.31
–.77
–.16
–.20
–.26
–.12
–.24
–1.25
–.48
.58
.09
1.00
–2.58
–1.44
–1.04
–.87
–1.03
–.34
–2.59
.56
2.58
.26
.58
.04
.03
.43

Exports
Total
1.08
.56
–.05
.36
.19
.80
.80
.95
.12
–.71
–.22
.61
.24
.53
.77
1.23
.97
.78
.61
.66
.31
.84
1.02
.86
1.26
.26
.52
.86
–.59
–.19
.19
.88
.67
.95
.94
.67
–1.00
1.40
.90
.54
.41
.52
.04
.06
.49
.35
.06
–1.52
.66
.76
.32
–1.81
–8.78
5.06
2.31
.06
.20
.16
2.42
–.50
1.19
1.80
–.41
.76
–1.09
.59
.68

Goods
1.05
.49
–.14
.34
.12
.64
.69
.88
–.05
–.63
–.21
.41
.20
.27
.62
.99
.72
.56
.45
.52
.22
.65
.83
.68
1.10
.17
.32
.72
–.49
–.24
.19
.58
.52
.71
.53
.48
–1.00
1.13
.65
.37
.27
.41
–.03
.05
.32
.34
.01
–.75
.53
.44
.21
–.27
–6.58
4.90
1.65
–.02
–.03
–.13
1.83
–.69
.73
1.63
–.52
.89
–1.31
.55
.34

Imports
Services
0.02
.08
.09
.02
.07
.17
.11
.07
.17
–.08
.00
.20
.05
.25
.15
.24
.26
.22
.16
.14
.09
.19
.19
.18
.16
.08
.20
.13
–.10
.05
.01
.30
.15
.24
.41
.19
.00
.28
.26
.17
.13
.12
.07
.01
.17
.01
.05
–.77
.13
.33
.11
–1.53
–2.20
.16
.65
.08
.24
.29
.59
.18
.46
.17
.11
–.13
.22
.04
.34

Total
–0.28
.17
.91
–1.41
–.89
–.76
–.16
.69
–.26
.12
–1.10
–2.16
–.63
–.82
–.60
–.41
–.46
–.37
.01
–.70
–.87
–1.25
–.90
–1.01
–1.57
–1.39
–1.42
–1.71
.35
–.48
–.68
–1.51
–.98
–1.01
–.42
.37
2.07
–1.83
–.79
–.42
–.20
–.84
–.81
–.22
–.69
–.60
–.18
1.28
–1.91
–1.24
.26
1.89
9.78
–7.65
–3.74
–1.10
–1.07
–1.19
–2.76
–2.08
–.63
.77
.66
–.18
1.13
–.56
–.25

Goods
–0.33
.17
.85
–1.31
–.82
–.66
–.13
.66
–.18
.20
–.98
–1.78
–.50
–.80
–.39
–.35
–.37
–.25
–.04
–.76
–.82
–1.15
–.84
–.91
–1.40
–1.18
–1.31
–1.45
.39
–.41
–.67
–1.28
–.88
–.81
–.27
.47
2.10
–1.73
–.74
–.38
–.28
–.75
–.74
–.14
–.53
–.62
–.07
.67
–1.60
–.82
.21
1.10
7.07
–7.21
–3.06
–1.02
–.51
–.20
–2.38
–1.72
–.28
.98
.55
–.22
.78
–.64
–.08

Federal
Services
0.05
.00
.06
–.10
–.07
–.10
–.02
.03
–.09
–.08
–.12
–.38
–.13
–.02
–.21
–.07
–.09
–.13
.05
.05
–.05
–.10
–.06
–.10
–.17
–.21
–.11
–.26
–.04
–.07
–.01
–.22
–.09
–.20
–.15
–.10
–.03
–.10
–.05
–.04
.07
–.09
–.07
–.08
–.16
.02
–.11
.61
–.31
–.42
.05
.79
2.71
–.44
–.68
–.08
–.56
–.99
–.38
–.36
–.35
–.21
.11
.04
.35
.08
–.17

Total
–0.07
.47
.49
.12
.26
.60
.36
.36
.20
.37
.79
.74
1.37
1.14
.62
.26
.58
.65
.25
.10
–.17
.02
.10
.18
.30
.44
.59
.33
.67
.83
.40
.30
.14
.30
.34
.49
.72
–.02
–.67
–.42
–.46
–.16
.37
.35
.10
.35
.68
.56
–.05
–.16
.68
.78
1.78
–1.03
–.35
1.04
–.80
–.26
–.04
–.52
–.34
.49
.90
.82
.57
.99
.56

Total
–0.39
.06
.05
.01
.21
.23
.20
.38
.43
.35
.65
.33
.78
.61
.38
–.15
.15
.20
.01
–.15
–.32
–.31
–.21
–.09
–.06
–.06
.12
.02
.24
.47
.45
.31
.15
.17
.14
.46
.48
.34
–.23
–.16
–.43
–.18
.00
.04
.03
.22
.25
.40
.10
–.19
.27
.34
2.07
–.89
–.13
1.19
–.65
–.48
.13
–.47
–.26
.07
.59
.33
.07
.45
.16

National Nondefense defense
–0.40
–.07
–.07
–.04
.06
.04
.15
.22
.40
.47
.51
.38
.62
.52
.38
–.04
–.02
.02
–.06
–.31
–.32