Full text of Economic Report of the President : 1981
The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
Economic Report of the President Transmitted to the Congress January 1981 TOGETHER WITH THE ANNUAL REPORT OF THE COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS UNITED STATES GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE WASHINGTON : 1981 For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office Washington, D.C. 20402 CONTENTS Page ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT ANNUAL REPORT OF THE COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS* 3 21 CHAPTER 1. INFLATION AND GROWTH IN THE 1 9 8 0 S 29 CHAPTER 2. IMPROVING THE ADAPTABILITY OF THE ECONOMY 89 CHAPTER 3. T H E ECONOMY: REVIEW AND PROSPECTS 131 CHAPTER 4. T H E WORLD ECONOMY: COPING WITH TRANSITION ... 182 APPENDIX A. REPORT TO THE PRESIDENT ON THE ACTIVITIES OF THE COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS DURING 1980 APPENDIX B. 215 STATISTICAL TABLES RELATING TO INCOME, EM- PLOYMENT, AND PRODUCTION 227 *For a detailed table of contents of the Council's Report, see page 25. (in) ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT To the Congress of the United States: Over the next few years our country faces several economic challenges that will test the will of our people and the capability of our government. We must find ways to bring down a stubborn inflation without choking off economic growth; we must channel a much larger share of our national output to investment and reverse a decade-long decline in productivity growth; and we must continue to reduce the Nation's dangerous vulnerability to disruptive changes in the world supply and price of oil. In this Economic Report I set forth my views on how we can best meet those problems. The following Annual Report of the Council of Economic Advisers discusses the challenges and the policy responses in greater detail. It is useful to start by recognizing that in many respects we approach these challenges from a position of strength, with a record of significant economic progress, and the knowledge that over the past 4 years our people and our government have successfully resolved a number of difficult and potentially divisive economic issues. While it would be folly to close our minds to the stubbornness of the problems we face, it would serve the Nation equally ill to underrate our strengths and our proven ability to handle difficult issues. Strengths and Accomplishments During the economic turmoil that characterized the decade of the 1970s, and especially during the past 4 years, the American economy succeeded in providing additional jobs for its people on a scale unsurpassed in our history. Employment grew by almost 25 percent over the decade, and by more than 11 percent in the past 4 years alone. Not only were jobs provided for a sharply rising population reaching working age, but job opportunities were opened up by the millions for new second earners, principally women. Neither Europe nor Japan came even close to the job performance of the American economy. Along with employment, real per capita incomes grew during the past 4 years, despite the losses forced on the Nation by the huge increases in world oil prices and the effects of a slowing growth in productivity. As the year 1980 ended, per capita income, after taxes and adjusted for inflation, was some 8 percent higher than it was in 1976. We have heard much about American industry losing its competitive edge in international markets and about the "deindustrialization" of America. In fact, during the 3 years prior to the onset of the 1980 recession—and the effects of that recession will be transient-^the growth of industrial production in the United States was larger than it was in Germany, France, or the United Kingdom. The volume of American nonfarm exports rose by 35 percent between 1977 and the middle of 1980, and the share of U.S. exports among the total exports of the industrial countries rose by about 1 Vi percentage points, reversing a declining trend that had been underway since the 1950s. America's balance of payments is strong in large part because of its superior export performance. Despite a massive $40-billion annual drain of funds to pay for the oil-price increases of 1979 and 1980, our exports of goods and services now exceed our imports. Unlike the situation in most other oil-importing nations, our country's external balance is in surplus. The dollar is also strong. After a period of weakness in its value abroad, we took decisive action 2 years ago to stabilize the dollar. Since then, in a world of sharply changing circumstances and disruptions of oil supply, the dollar has remained strong, and has risen in value compared to most major currencies. While it is imperative that our country increase the share of its national output devoted to investment, the reason is not that investment has been weak in recent years. Between 1976 and 1980, real business investment grew almost 6 percent a year, substantially faster than GNP as a whole. Because of that rapid growth the share of business investment in GNP during the past 3 years exceeded that of any other 3-year period in the last three decades. There are other areas where the Nation has made more progress than we sometimes realize. While we are properly concerned to limit the growth in Federal spending and voice our impatience with the waste and inefficiency that often exist in government programs, we should not forget the good that has been accomplished with these programs. Examples abound. In the early 1960s, for instance, infant mortality in the United States was scandalously high compared to other countries, and most of that high mortality was concentrated among the poor. Due in large part to programs like Medicaid, infant mortality has fallen sharply. More generally, we have dramatically improved access to medical care for the poor and the aged. Through Federal grants we have strengthened the mass transit systems of our major cities and helped our municipalities install critically needed waste treatment plants. We have helped millions of young people, who could not otherwise have afforded it, get a college education. and we have provided job training for workers who needed new skills. Much attention is now focused on how to reduce the costs and ease the burden of Federal regulation to protect the environment, health, and safety. Concern about excessive regulatory costs is surely warranted, and my Administration has taken a number of specific steps to deal with the problem. In focusing attention on the burden of regulation, however, we should not lose sight of the substantial progress that has been made in enriching our lives, improving our health, and beautifying our country. Tackling Difficult Issues During the past 4 years the Nation has taken a series of important and in some cases painful steps to deal with its energy problems. Starting almost 2 years ago, we began to phase out controls on domestic oil and natural gas prices. We thus moved to end the dangerous practice of holding U.S. energy prices below the world market price, a practice which tended to subsidize wasteful consumption and perpetuate our excessive dependence on oil imports. Working with the Congress we also put in place the other principal elements of a comprehensive program to increase energy production and conserve energy use. We levied a windfall profits tax to divert the inevitable windfalls from oil decontrol to pay for the National Energy Program initiatives and to reduce the impact of decontrol on the poor. Partly as a result of these policies we have begun to see dramatic results in both the supply and conservation of energy. There are now 70 percent more drilling rigs in operation than when my Administration took office, and the number of oil and gas wells being drilled has reached a new record. By late 1980 the United States was importing almost 30 percent less oil than it did 2 years ago and our gasoline use had dropped by more than 10 percent over the same period. While some of the reduction in energy use was due to the recession, most of it reflects real energy conservation. What has happened in energy policy over the past 4 years augurs well for our country's future. Decontrolling domestic oil and gas was painful. It pushed up the prices each of us pay for driving and for heating our homes and added to our immediate inflation difficulties. But we showed that we were willing to take such painful steps when they were necessary in our Nation's longer-run interest. Because we are large-scale producers as well as consumers of energy, the energy problem was potentially a highly divisive issue in our country, involving the redistribution of hundreds of billions of dollars, pitting producer against consumer and one region of the Nation against another. But after prolonged and sometimes heated debate, we arrived at an approach that took account of the legitimate concerns of all groups and at the same time furthered the national interest. Dealing with the Nation's remaining economic problems will also require painful measures and the reconciliation of a number of different interests. Our handling of the energy problem should raise our confidence that we can be successful elsewhere. We have also had major successes in other fields. After decades of inaction, the past 4 years have seen the elimination of price-propping and competition-deadening regulations in a number of American industries. In these 4 years we witnessed more progress in economic deregulation than at any other time in the century. In the face of great skepticism and initial opposition, the executive branch, the Congress, and some of the independent regulatory agencies have deregulated or drastically reduced regulation in the airline, trucking, and railroad industries, and in banking and other financial institutions. We have also made a promising start in the communications industry. The transportation, communications, and finance industries comprise a triad that links the various strands of our economy together. Better performance in these industries should have effects far beyond their own boundaries. The gains from deregulation will be substantial. For example, productivity and efficiency will be directly increased as transportation load factors are improved and empty backhauls reduced. One survey of studies estimates that reform in the trucking industry alone will lead to $5 billion in annual cost reductions. Even more important will be the longer-run spur to innovation and the increased flexibility that comes from opening up these industries to the fresh winds of competition. Population trends will be working to help the country deal with some of its economic problems in the 1980s, whereas in the late 1960s and 1970s these trends required some difficult adjustments. The generation of the postwar baby boom began entering the labor market in the 1960s and the influx of new workers continued during the 1970s. The percentage of the population aged 16 to 24 rose sharply. And as birth rates slowed, women entered the labor force in ever increasing numbers. On average, the labor force became less experienced, and average productivity per worker suffered. The increased proportion of women and young people in the labor force also contributed to an increase in the average unemployment rate because the transition from school or home to job takes time and because these new workers sometimes had periods of unemployment as they explored different career possibilities. Because of the slowdown in birth rates in the past 15 years, the 1980s will see about half as fast a growth in the labor force as in the 1970s. The proportion of experienced workers will rise, contributing to an increase in productivity, while the proportion of young people will fall, leading to a drop in unemployment. There are a number of reasons, therefore, to confront with hope the economic challenges that face us. We have a solid record of achievement. In the fields of energy and deregulation we have already laid the foundations on which the future can build. And there are some favorable trends underway that should help raise productivity and reduce unemployment in the years ahead. Unresolved Problems Despite much progress in recent years, we are faced with some serious problems. An inflation that was already bad became worse after the 1979 oil-price increase. Productivity growth, which had been declining sporadically for a decade, virtually ceased in the last several years. And although we have made substantial progress in adapting our economy to a world of higher oil prices, we remain dangerously vulnerable to serious supply disruptions originating abroad. These problems are closely related to each other. Our inflation stems in part from our oil vulnerability and our slowing productivity growth. High and rising inflation, in turn, tends to cause economic reactions that depress productivity. As we make progress in one of these areas, we will also make progress in the others. None of the problems is so intractable that we cannot overcome it. But all are so deep-seated that progress will come slowly, only with persistence, and at the cost of some sacrifice on the part of us all. Inflation In the first half of the 1960s inflation averaged about 1 percent a year, so low as to be virtually unnoticeable. In the past 15 years, however, the underlying rate of inflation has risen sporadically but inexorably and it is now running at about 10 percent a year. During those 15 years there have been three major episodes in which the rate of inflation surged upward. The first came in the late 1960s, when the Vietnam war and the Great Society programs were financed for a number of years without a tax increase. The consequent high budget deficits during a period of economic prosperity generated strong inflationary pressures as total spending became excessive relative to the Nation's productive capacity. The second inflationary surge, which came in the early 1970s, was associated with the first massive oil-price increase, a worldwide crop shortage which drove up food prices, and an economy which again became somewhat overheated in 1972 and 1973. The third inflationary episode came in 1979 and 1980. It was principally triggered by another massive oil-price increase, but part of the rise in inflation may also have been due to overall demand in the economy pressing on available supply. Throughout the past decade, the slowing growth in productivity has pushed up the increase in business costs, adding its bit to the rise of inflation. Late in each of the three inflationary episodes monetary and fiscal restraints were applied, and at the end of each a recession took place, with rising unemployment and idle capacity. Inflation did fall back somewhat, but at the end of each recession it had not declined to the level from which it started. And so the inflationary process has been characterized by ratchet-like behavior. A set of inflationary causes raises the rate of inflation; when the initiating factors disappear, inflation does not recede to its starting position despite the occurrence of recession; the wage-price spiral then tends to perpetuate itself at a new and higher level. Instead of an occasional 3 percentage point rise in inflation, which disappeared when the initial causes of the inflation were gone, our basic inflation rate rose first from 1 to 4 percent, then from 4 to 7 percent, and in this latest episode from 7 to 10 percent. It is this downward insensitivity of inflation in the face of economic slack that has given the last 15 years their inflationary bias. A number of facts that are important for economic policy can be drawn from this history. First, excessive demand in the economy, fed by an overly large Federal budget deficit or excess growth in the money supply, was the major factor in one of the three inflationary episodes and played a subsidiary role in the other two. Second, twice in the last decade the tendency for government to stimulate the economy somewhat too freely during the recovery from recession probably played a role in retarding the decline of inflation or renewing its acceleration. That is why I was so insistent that a tax cut designed for quick economic stimulus not be enacted last year. Third, because the rate of increase in wages and prices did not decline very readily in response to the discipline of budgetary and monetary restraint, that restraint resulted only partly in reduced inflation; it also tended to retard the growth of output and employment. Finally, massive increases in world oil prices have twice in the past 7 years helped trigger a major inflationary episode. While we cannot eliminate Our vulnerability to such shocks, a reduction in that vulnerability will improve our chances of avoiding new inflation in the future. These realities dictate the broad tasks that economic policy must accomplish over the years ahead: Our monetary and fiscal policies must apply steady anti-inflationary restraint to the economy. The restraint must be strong and persistent enough to convince those who set wages and prices that the government means to stand by its guns in the anti-inflation fight. But it must not be so severe or so restrictive as to prohibit even moderate economic growth and recovery, and thus collapse under its own political unreality. We must seek means to reduce inflation at a lower cost in lost output and employment These include measures to increase investment, the reform of regulation, and incomes policies. An increase in investment raises productivity growth which, in turn, tends to slow the rise in business costs and prices. Demand restraint will then produce more reduction of inflation and less reduction in output. Measures to lower regulatory costs and increase competition and flexibility in our economy will also directly lower inflationary pressures and let us have more economic growth without sacrificing our inflation goals. An improved set of voluntary incomes policies can directly influence wages and prices in the direction of moderation, and thereby bring inflation down faster and at lower costs. Finally, we must build upon the foundations already laid and hasten our progress toward energy conservation and increased domestic energy supplies. W e must also work to improve our capability of weathering a severe disruption in foreign oil supplies, since even a highly successful energy program will still leave our economy vulnerable to such disruptions over the coming decade. Last August I outlined an Economic Revitalization Program that would accomplish the tasks set forth above. The specific economic policies I am recommending to the Congress in my 1982 Budget Message and in this Economic Report incorporate the elements of that revitalization program. Budget and Tax Policies It is now estimated that the Federal budget for the current fiscal year 1981 will be in deficit by $55 billion, substantially more than I had hoped or planned. In part the size of that deficit reflects the loss of revenues induced by the recession from which our economy is now beginning to recover. Had the unemployment rate remained at the 6 percent level where it stood when I first submitted the 1981 budget last year, the deficit would now be less than $20 billion. The size of the 1981 deficit also reflects three major factors which have driven up the estimates of Federal spending in the past 12 months. First, higher interest rates since the budget was originally submitted have added about $9 billion. Second, payments under many Federal programs, such as social security, are indexed to the consumer price index, which has proven in recent years to overstate significantly the actual rise in the cost of living because of the way it treats housing and mortgage interest costs. And third, defense spending was increased above original estimates. As part of a program of anti-inflationary fiscal restraint I am recommending a number of steps that will help to cut the deficit in half, to $27.5 billion in the new budget for fiscal year 1982, and reduce it still further to $8 billion in 1983, despite the substantial increases in defense spending which I find it necessary to recommend for those years: • Beyond exerting strict control over requests for new appropriations for ongoing programs, my 1982 budget sets forth a detailed list of requests to the Congress for the legislation needed to pare some $9 billion in spending in both fiscal 1982 and fiscal 1983. If enacted, these savings would help make possible a reduction in the share of GNP taken by Federal spending from 23.3 percent in 1981 to 23.0 percent in 1982 and 22.6 percent in 1983. • The personal tax reductions which I am proposing should take effect on January 1, 1982, rather than at some earlier date in 1981. • I am renewing my request to the Congress for a modest increase in the tax on gasoline; there is no better way to provide additional revenues for reducing the budget deficit than a measure which simultaneously reduces our imports of foreign oil. • I still strongly support the national health insurance proposal that I earlier submitted to the Congress, but the need for budgetary restraint to control inflation requires that its introduction be delayed until more budgetary room is available and adequate cost containment is in place. In order to avoid repetition of the recent situation in which many Federal payments rose too rapidly because they are tied to an index which does not accurately reflect changes in the cost of living, I am recommending that the Congress authorize use of a more representative index. I am informed by the Commissioner that the Bureau of Labor Statistics is now producing an index of this type and that it can quickly be made available on a timely basis. Although my 1982 budget emphasizes the need for fiscal restraint, and for reduction of the deficit, it also takes the first major step in a long-term program of tax reductions aimed at increasing capital formation. The causes of the longer-term slowdown in productivity growth are many—and some of them are still unknown. But a major depressing factor has been the failure of the Nation's capital stock to increase relative to its rapidly growing labor force in the past 5 or 6 years. Unlike earlier periods, American workers have not been working with increasing amounts of capital. Improving the trend of productivity growth will require restoring the growth of capital per worker. Higher investment will also be critically required throughout America's energy-using industries to speed up the replacement of 10 older energy-inefficient plant and machinery with newer energysaving capital. In addition, a large expansion of energy-producing industries—both conventional and nonconventional—will add further to investment needs. According to estimates made by my Council of Economic Advisers, the combined tasks of restoring the earlier growth of capital per worker and meeting the Nation's energy needs call for an increase in the share of investment in GNP from its recent IOV2 percent to 12V2 or 13 percent during the 1980s. This would require an expansion in investment by about one-fifth above the level that might normally be expected. It will not occur without the introduction of policies to make it happen. To begin this task, my 1982 budget incorporates the two major changes in tax laws that I outlined last August in my Economic Revitalization Program to improve incentives and provide increased sources of financing for business investment. The first and most important proposal is a major liberalization of tax allowances for depreciation. Because tax depreciation is now based on the historic cost of an asset, inflation reduces allowable tax deductions relative to the cost of replacing an asset and thus lowers the profitability of investment. Inflation also distorts the tax treatment of assets with different useful lives. I am proposing a new approach to depreciation worked out "by the Department of the Treasury which substantially simplifies depreciation accounting and increases the allowable rates of depreciation by about 40 percent. This approach, unlike sorjne other depreciation liberalization proposals that have been introduced in the Congress, tends to avoid major distortions of economic incentives since it provides approximately equal percentage increases in allowable depreciation rates for each industry. I also propose that the Congress expand investment incentives by improving the investment tax credit. That credit is now only partially available for short-lived assets; it should be made fully available. Even more importantly, part of the investment tax credit should be made refundable. Firms should be able to claim 30 percent of the value of the credit even if they had no tax liabilities for the year. In this way firms with substantial investment needs but with no current earnings can be supported in their efforts to rejuvenate and expand capital assets. Among these are younger and smaller firms that are just beginning to grow, and larger industries undergoing transition, such as autos and steel. The latter may temporarily be experiencing depressed profitability but still have major investment needs for retooling or for new industrial facilities. These two proposals would reduce business tax liabilities by $9 billion in calendar year 1981, $15 billion in 1982, and by 1985 the re- 11 ductions would amount to over $27 billion. We estimate that with enactment of these new incentives business investment should increase 5-10 percent above its normally expected level in 1982, with additional gains thereafter. While providing additional incentives for business investment, we can also move on a carefully phased basis to reduce other taxes in a way that improves both economic efficiency and tax equity. The Congress should enact an income tax credit for both employers and employees that would approximately offset the scheduled rise in social security payroll taxes that occurred in January of this year. To make the benefits available to lower-income workers who have no tax liability, I also propose an increase in the earned income tax credit. But, as I pointed out earlier in this Report, the critical importance of reducing the budget deficit as part of the fight against inflation has led me to recommend that this reduction take effect at the beginning of 1982, by which time the growth of revenues will make such a reduction consistent with overall budgetary objectives. At the present time one of the major inequities in our tax system is the so-called marriage penalty. Under a wide range of circumstances a husband and wife, each working, will together pay a higher tax than if they were not married. I propose that this penalty be eased by making a tax credit available to the lesser-earning spouse. The credit should be introduced in two steps, half in 1982 and the other half in 1983. I also propose that the Congress enact several important tax reforms: income from interest and dividends should be put on an equal footing with wages and other incomes by withholding taxes at the source; the excessive issuance of several types of tax-exempt bonds should be curtailed; and the use of certain commodity futures transactions as a tax avoidance scheme should be prohibited. The central feature of the tax policies I am proposing is their emphasis on increasing investment. By 1985, an unusually high 45 percent of the tax reductions will be directed toward spurring investment. But even this will not itself be sufficient to raise investment to the levels our country will need in the decade ahead in order to improve its productivity growth and deal with its energy problems. Careful control of Federal spending, however, will create the leeway for additional investment-oriented tax reductions in later years, within the framework of the overall budgetary restraint required to fight inflation. I do not believe that we should now commit budgetary resources to large-scale personal tax cuts which will stimulate consumption far more than investment and thereby foreclose the possibility of meeting the Nation's critical investment requirements. 12 Monetary Policy Monetary policy is the responsibility of the Federal Reserve System, which is independent of the Executive. I respect that independence. But there are several broad aspects of monetary policy having to do with public perceptions that do fall within the purview of the President in his role as national leader. Sustained restraint in monetary policy is a prerequisite to lowering inflation. The Federal Reserve exercises this restraint principally by keeping a strict limit on the growth of the Nation's money supply. In October 1979 the Federal Reserve modified its earlier policies and operating procedures to increase sharply the emphasis it gives to controlling the money supply. The Federal Reserve each year sets targets for monetary growth and seeks to hold the growth of the money supply within the targets. Increasingly the public in general and the financial community in particular have come to associate the credibility of the Federal Reserve and its determination to fight inflation with its success in keeping money growth continuously within the preannounced targets. It is very important, however, that public opinion not hold the Federal Reserve to such a rigid form of monetary targeting as to deprive it of the flexibility it needs to conduct a responsible monetary policy. Temporary fluctuations in monetary conditions can sometimes cause the money supply to overrun or underrun the targets for a short period of time without any damage to anti-inflation objectives. Furthermore, economic developments occasionally occur that may make it appropriate for the Federal Reserve to modify the targets it had originally set, or to deviate from its announced aim of lowering the targets each year. If the public interprets occasional necessary changes in the longer-run monetary target ranges or short-run deviations of actual money growth from those targets as evidence that the Federal Reserve has lessened its determination to fight inflation and as a reason to expect higher inflation in the future, the Federal Reserve is confronted with an untenable situation. If it fails to make the adjustment in the monetary targets that is called for by a major change in economic circumstances, monetary policy may produce unwanted results. But if the Federal Reserve does change the targets in the face of public misunderstanding, it risks an impairment of its credibility. The same dilemma exists with respect to allowing shortrun deviations in money growth from the target ranges. Only if the public understands the realities, and the complexities, of carrying out an anti-inflationary monetary policy can the Federal Reserve successfully apply the measured restraint necessary to wring out inflation at minimum cost in production and jobs. On the one hand, the country must face the fact that in a world with a stubborn 333-540 0 - 8 1 - 2 13 :QL 3 10 percent inflation rate, keeping a tight rein on the growth of the money supply inevitably leads to interest rates that average significantly higher than those we were accustomed to in earlier periods of lower inflation. On the other hand, the public and the financial community must not become so obsessed with the mechanics of monetary targeting that any change in targets or any short-run deviation of money growth from those targets is taken as a sign that monetary restraint has been weakened. Without reasoned and persistent monetary restraint, inflation cannot be licked. Perhaps more than in any other area of economic policy, however, achieving success in monetary policy depends on an informed public opinion. Incomes Policies For the past 2 years my Administration has urged business and labor to comply with a set of voluntary pay and price standards. Even though it was introduced at a very difficult time—just before the oilprice explosion of 1979—this voluntary program of wage and price restraint did moderate the pace of inflation. It significantly reduced— although it could not eliminate—the effect of the oil-price rise on the underlying inflation rate. After 2 years of operation there is general agreement that the current pay and price standards would not continue to be effective in their present form and without additional support. For this reason we have carefully examined the possibility of strengthening a voluntary incomes policy by using the tax system to provide incentives to firms and workers to slow the rate of inflation. This approach has been labeled a tax-based incomes policy (TIP). The detailed results of our review are contained in the accompanying Annual Report of the Council of Economic Advisers. Broadly, we have concluded that an approach which provided a tax reduction to workers in firms whose average pay increase did not exceed some standard, set as part of a voluntary incomes policy, would be feasible and effective in helping to lower inflation. Two major conditions apply, however. First, such a policy must be a supplement to, not a substitute for, fiscal and monetary restraint. Without such restraint an incomes policy will produce only fleeting reductions in inflation or none at all. Second, a TIP program is likely to be desirable only on a temporary basis. After several years, such a program might cease to be effective and could induce significant distortions into wage relationships throughout the economy. But as an interim device to hasten the reduction in inflation and so shorten the period of reduced output and employment growth, a TIP program could serve the Nation well. 14 If the growth of Federal spending is restrained, periodic tax reductions will be both feasible and necessary in the years ahead as inflation and economic growth push taxpayers into higher brackets and raise average effective tax rates. Tax-based incomes policies are novel, and most people are unfamiliar with either the opportunities they present or the difficulties they pose. It is therefore highly unlikely that a TIP program could take effect in 1981. But it would be useful for the public in general, and the Congress in particular, to begin now to evaluate the pros and cons of TIP programs so that when the time comes for the next round of Federal tax cuts a TIP program will be seriously considered. Energy I am once again proposing that the Congress increase the Federal excise tax on gasoline by 10 cents per gallon as an additional incentive to cut petroleum consumption. The need for this tax is, if anything, even greater than it was 7 months ago when the Congress overturned my action to impose a gasoline conservation fee administratively. We have once more seen a tightening of world oil supplies. The massive inventories built up in late 1979 and early 1980 have been drawn upon to make up for the loss of exports from Iran and Iraq. If that conflict should continue or if exports do not return to normal, the buffer which those record high inventories provided will be exhausted. Even in the last 2 months, we have seen significant escalation in prices charged by some OPEC members. National security requires us to put additional downward pressure on consumption of gasoline and other petroleum products. If we do not, OPEC may do it for us. Paradoxically, one of the reasons given earlier for rejecting my proposed tax was that it was too small—some would have preferred a tax of 50 cents or even a dollar per gallon. Whether, over time, this Nation should move toward gasoline taxes that are comparable with those of our Western European allies is not a question that has to be answered now. In any event, to do so overnight would shock the economy excessively. At current gasoline consumption levels, a 50cent per gallon tax would draw approximately $50 billion per year out of consumers' pockets and require excessive adjustments by consumers and industry. It is much more sensible to start with the level I have proposed. There is other important unfinished business to attend to in energy. The Congress failed to complete work on my proposed Energy Mobilization Board, but events since August of 1979 have only made the case for the Board's creation more persuasive. It is equally important that we move ahead with the production of substi- 15 tutes for petroleum. The Synthetic Fuels Corporation is established and operating. Its mission—to encourage commercial-scale production of synthetic fuels through risk-sharing with American industry— is vital. My program of phased decontrol of domestic crude oil, along with the revamping of natural gas pricing policy contained in the Natural Gas Policy Act, is paying rich dividends. Drilling and seismic exploration have reached near-record levels. The Natural Gas Policy Act should be reviewed, however, to ensure that progress toward decontrol of new natural gas is not jeopardized by the increasing gap between oil prices and their natural gas equivalent, since world oil prices are now about twice those assumed in the act. Our contingency planning to deal with a severe oil-supply disruption needs to be improved, since the authorities upon which many of the existing plans are based will expire at the end of September of this year. We have had underway for some time an examination of which, if any, of these authorities should be extended and what additional authorities might be required. This work should be completed as soon as possible. Filling of the Strategic Petroleum Reserve must continue. The rate of fill should be at least the 100,000 barrels per day required by the Energy Security Act, and should, beyond that, be as high as can be accommodated without disrupting world oil markets. Increasing the Flexibility of Our Economy Energy is not the only area where we must take additional steps to improve the ability of the economy to adjust to the changes that will be demanded of it in the years ahead. To the extent that we can reduce barriers to the flow of labor, capital, and other resources from inefficient to efficient uses, we can reduce inflationary pressures that arise from bottlenecks and economic rigidities and simultaneously speed up the pace of productivity growth. We should not lose the momentum that has developed over the past 4 years in reducing obsolete and costly economic regulations. The Congress should complete its deliberations and pass legislation similar to that which I suggested last year to complete the task of modernizing our system of telecommunications regulation. In the broad area of environmental, health and safety regulation, where deregulation is not an appropriate solution, we must expand on the successful beginning that has been made in providing greater flexibility and incentives for firms to meet environmental requirements in more cost-effective ways. We must also continue our efforts to assure that the Nation's regulatory priorities are sensible. Our Nation can afford a cleaner environment, safer products, and healthier workplaces, but it does not 16 have unlimited resources. Other national goals cry out for attention, and we cannot afford waste in attempting to achieve any of them. During the coming years, when many of our most important industries will be facing difficult adjustment pressures, we must avoid taking shortsighted actions which block rather than promote this adjustment. Federal policies should indeed cushion the blow when sharp external shocks force an industry, its workers, and the communities within which it is located to undergo massive change in a short period of time. The programs of economic development and trade assistance which exist to meet these needs should be humanely and effectively administered. But such aid must be aimed at facilitating adjustment to change, not preventing it. While we can and should demand that all nations abide by internationally agreed-upon rules of trade, we must avoid the temptation to use the discretion open to us to prop up weak industries. Summing Up: The Need for Balance In the years immediately ahead, our country will be wrestling with two central domestic issues. The first is economic in nature: How can we reduce inflation while maintaining the economic growth that keeps our people employed? The second is even broader: What is the proper role of government in our society as spender of tax revenues and regulator of industry? I am confident we can successfully come to grips with both of these issues. We would make a costly mistake, however, if we approached these problems with the view that there is some single answer to the economic problem and a single criterion for determining the role of government. The resolution of both of these great issues demands a balancing of many approaches and many considerations. Indeed, the only helpful simple proposition is the one which states that any simple and quick answer is automatically the wrong one. The approach I have set forth in this Report will successfully meet the economic challenge. But it relies on not one but a number of essential elements. To reduce inflation we must be prepared for a period of sustained budgetary and monetary restraint. But since we know that this also tends to depress the growth of output and employment, we must not conclude that the greater the restraint the better. We want a degree of restraint that takes into account society's interest in employment and production as well as its concern to lower inflation. We can improve our prospects significantly by introducing investment-oriented tax cuts that increase supply and productivity. But the supply response will not be so quick or so great as to constitute an answer in and of itself. And, in particular, it would be very dangerous to make budgetary policy in the belief that the supply 17 response can be so large as to wipe out the need for fiscal prudence and budgetary restraint. We can improve our prospects still further by the use of voluntary incomes policies, strengthened when budgetary resources become available by tax incentives for wage moderation. But, again, incomes policies alone will not do the job. If we try to rely on them excessively, we will do more harm than good. Only with a balance among the various elements, and only with persistence in the realization that sure progress will come gradually, can we have both lower inflation and better growth. Sorting out the proper role of government also requires us to strike a balance. At times Federal spending has grown too rapidly. But in recent years its growth did not result from the introduction of a host of new government programs by spendthrift politicians or a surge of profligacy by wasteful bureaucrats. It stemmed mainly from two sources: first, increased military spending to meet national security goals that are overwhelmingly supported by the American people; and second, the growth of long established and broadly accepted social security and social insurance programs that are directly or indirectly indexed against inflation or automatically responsive to an increase in unemployment. There is some waste. There is some abuse. I have instituted a number of reforms to cut it back. I am sure my successors will continue this important effort. But waste and abuse are not the fundamental issues. The essence of the challenge that faces us is how to balance the various benefits that government programs confer on us against their costs in terms of higher taxes, higher deficits* and sometimes higher inflation. It is my view that we must strike the balance so as to restrict for some time the overall growth of Federal spending to less than the growth of our economy, despite the faster increase of the military component of the budget. As a consequence, in my 1982 budget I have proposed a series of program reductions. I have suggested a delay in the effective date of new programs I believe important. I have recommended improvements in the index we use to adjust Federal programs for inflation. I think we will do a better job in striking the right balance over the years ahead if we keep two principles in mind: The first is to recognize reality. The choices are in fact difficult, and we should not pretend that all we have to do is find wasteful programs with zero benefits. The second is to act with compassion. Some government programs provide special benefits for the poor and the disadvantaged; while these programs must not be immune from review and reform, they should not bear the brunt of the reductions. 18 The same general viewpoint is appropriate when we approach the problem of government as regulator, especially in protecting the environment, health, and safety. When we first awoke to the fact of generations of environmental neglect, we rushed to compensate for our mistake and paid too little attention to problems of cost and effectiveness. Sometimes the laws we passed and the deadlines we set took too little account of their economic impact. For 4 years my Administration has been engaged in a major program of finding ways to make regulations more cost-effective and to strike a reasonable balance between environmental concerns and economic costs. A strong foundation has been laid. Much remains to be done. But lasting progress will not come unless we realize that there is a balance to be struck. Those who believe that virtually all regulation is bad and that the best regulation is a dead regulation will come to grips with the real problem no more successfully than the enthusiasts who believe that concern with regulatory costs is synonymous with lack of concern for the environment. I believe that the government has indeed overregulated and that regulatory reform must continue to be a major objective of the Federal Government, as it has been during my Administration. But I also believe that true reform involves finding better ways to identify and to give proper consideration to gains as well as costs. My reading of the distant and the nearby past gives me confidence that the American people can meet the challenges ahead. There are no simple formulas. There will be no quick victories. But an understanding of the diverse concerns we have, a pragmatic willingness to bring to bear a varied array of weapons, arid persistence in the effort will bring success. January 17, 1981 19 THE ANNUAL REPORT OF THE COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS 21 LETTER OF TRANSMITTAL COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS, Washington, D.C.January 16, 1981. MR. PRESIDENT: The Council of Economic Advisers herewith submits its 1981 Annual Report in accordance with the provisions of the Employment Act of 1946 as amended by the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978. Cordially, Charles L. Schultze CHAIRMAN Stephen M. Goldfeld C O N T E N T S Pdge CHAPTER 1. INFLATION AND GROWTH IN THE 1 9 8 0 S Inflation Understanding Inflation The Sources of Inflation Managing Aggregate Demand Broad Principles The Role of Expectations and the Credibility of Demand Restraint Monetary Policy Incomes Policies The Pay and Price Standards Tax-Based Incomes Policies Price TIPs Conclusions Increasing Investment, Supply, and Productivity Productivity Investment Needs Investment Determinants and Inflation Tax Measures to Increase Investment The Impact of the Administration's Investment Incentives Saving The Integration of Demand-Side and Supply-Side Policies. Expected Productivity Gains Demand Versus Supply Responses to Tax Cuts The Supply-Side Response to Personal Tax Cuts Business Tax Cuts Conclusions Technical Appendix to Chapter 1: MEASURING PAY INCREASES UNDER A TIP 48 50 57 59 60 65 67 68 68 70 73 74 76 77 78 79 79 80 82 83 84 CHAPTER 2. IMPROVING THE ADAPTABILITY OF THE ECONOMY Adapting to Energy Uncertainty Adjusting to Higher Energy Prices Adjusting to Price and Supply Uncertainty Improving Regulatory Practices The Role of "Deregulation" 29 32 34 37 47 47 25 89 90 91 91 99 100 Page Efforts to Improve the Process of Social Regulation .... Efforts at "Smarter" Regulation Financial Markets Adapting to Change Adapting to Rising Interest Rates Adapting to Greater Rate Variability Pressures for Comprehensive Legislation The Financial Structure of the 1980s: Benefits, Risks, and Public Policy The Altered Role of Agriculture Expanding Agricultural Exports Future Causes of Rising Food Prices Policy Directions for the 1980s Trends in Industrial and Labor Markets Industrial Change Changing Labor Force Composition The Dilemma of Industrial Policy Preferred Policy Approaches CHAPTER 3. THE ECONOMY: REVIEW AND PROSPECTS A Review of 1980 An Overview of the Year The Major Sectors of Aggregate Demand Labor Market Developments Price Developments Wages, Productivity, and Income Shares Economic Policy The Prospects for 1981 and 1982 Fiscal Policy Monetary Policy World and Domestic Oil Markets The Economic Forecast The Goals of Economic Policy Supplement: National Income and Product Account Revisions 102 105 107 108 110 Ill 111 115 117 121 122 123 123 124 127 129 131 131 132 138 146 148 152 156 165 165 167 169 169 177 178 CHAPTER 4. THE WORLD ECONOMY: COPING WITH TRANSITION ... 182 The Industrial Economies: Trends and Prospects Economic Activity External Positions Inflation, Summary Assessment Risks in the Outlook The Global Oil Market Directions for Economic Policy: Needs and Challenges The Search for Solutions Monetary Policy and Exchange Rates 183 183 186 187 189 190 191 193 194 198 26 Page Challenges to the International Financial System Financing the Deficits of the Non-Oil Developing Countries Challenges to International Trade Relations Protection and Employment Export Subsidies Market Sharing Needed Responses 201 203 207 209 211 212 213 APPENDIXES: A. Report to the President on the Activities of the Council of Economic Advisers During 1980 B. Statistical Tables Relating to Income, Employment, and Production 215 227 List of Tables and Charts Tables 1. Changes in Employment in Major Industrial Countries, 1970-80 2. Changes in Industrial Production in Major Industrial Countries, 1970-80 3. Selected Indicators of Declining Demand Pressures 4. Governmental Surplus or Deficit and Gross National Product, 1958-80 5. International Comparison of Deficits and Inflation, 197779 rf.., 6. Monetary Growth Rates, 1975-80 7. Estimated Effects and Compliance Rates of Various Pay TIPs 8. Labor Productivity Growth, 1948-80 9. The Investment Share, and Growth in the Capital-Labor Ratio, 1949-79 10. Distribution of Workers by Percentage Change in Average Establishment Wage, Selected Manufacturing Industries, December 1978 to December 1979 11. Selected Financial Regulatory Changes, 1970-80 12. The Role of Agricultural Exports, 1930-80 13. Long-Term Unemployment as Percent of Labor Force, 1973-80 14. Growth in Major Components of Real Gross National Product, 1976-80 15. Changes in Real Business Fixed Investment, 1975-80 16. Real Output, Sales, and Inventories, Nonfarm Business Sector, 1974-75 and 1980 , 17. Labor Market Developments, 1976-80 27 30 30 39 41 42 53 65 69 71 86 110 117 127 138 142 144 147 List of Tables and Charts—Continued Pa %€ Tables 18. Measures of Price Change, 1976-80 19. Alternative Measures of Consumer Price Changes, 1980...... 20. Measures of Compensation and Employment Costs, 197780 21. Alternative Measures of Changes in Real Earnings per Hour, 1978-80 22. Shares of National Income, 1976-80 23. Actual and High-Employment Federal Receipts and Expenditures, National Income and Product Accounts, Calendar Years, 1973-80 24. Growth in Monetary and Bank Credit Aggregates, 1979-81 25. Economic Outlook for 1981 26. Economic Projections, 1981-86 27. Revised Potential GNP, 1973-80 28. Real GNP Growth in Major Industrial Countries, 1976-82.. 29. Current-Account Balances in Major Industrial Countries, 1978-81 30. Inflation in Major Industrial Countries, 1976-82 31. Global Oil Balances, 1973-80 32. Global Current-Account Balances, Exclusive of Official Transfers, 1978-81 33. Non-Oil Developing Countries: Current-Account Financing, 1973-79 149 150 153 154 155 157 158 170 178 181 183 187 189 191 202 204 Charts 1. Standard Unit Labor Costs 2. Price Index for Personal Consumption Expenditures Excluding Food and Energy 3. Changes in Consumer Prices Since 1913 4. Productivity Adjusted for Cyclical Variation 5. Prices Received by Farmers 6. Relative Food Prices 7. Selected Interest Rates and Bond Yields 8. Personal Saving Rate 9. Real Inventory-Final Sales Ratio, Nonfarm Business 10. Labor Costs, Value-Added Deflators, and Labor Share in Six Major Foreign Countries 11. Wage and Price Changes in Seven Major Countries 28 35 35 38 70 116 116 135 139 143 185 188 CHAPTER 1 Inflation and Growth in the 1980s IN THE 1980s THE UNITED STATES will confront a variety of stubborn problems that have developed during the past 15 years. Chief among these problems is one that is shared by most other industrial countries—the persistence of large wage and price increases, even in the face of high unemployment and slack production. This problem poses the single most important challenge to U.S. economic policy—reducing inflation while maintaining a reasonably prosperous and growing economy. Many other problems are themselves closely related to inflation, either as cause or as consequence. Our Nation's productivity growth has virtually halted in recent years. The era of cheap energy has ended, the world has grown vulnerable to supply disruptions, and the course of domestic inflation and unemployment has become closely dependent on economic and political developments in the oil-rich but politically unstable Middle East. Meanwhile, the struggle to find a proper balance between a clean, healthy, and safe environment, on the one hand, and satisfactory economic growth with lower inflation, on the other, will continue. All of these developments, together with the growing interdependence of the world economy, have set in motion major changes in economic structure, occupational skill requirements, and industrial location that will continue to pose sizable adjustment problems to many industries, communities, and workers. While the magnitude of these economic challenges is cause for serious concern, it does not warrant pessimism. During the 1970s the U.S. economy performed quite well in many important respects. Over that decade our country outperformed most other major countries in providing jobs for its people (Table 1). Employment grew almost 25 percent as the American economy created jobs not only for millions of youths entering the labor market for the first time but also for millions of women, who found job opportunities in growing numbers. This performance continued through the last years of the decade at an increased pace. While the growth in the number of employed persons was temporarily interrupted by the recession of 1980, the basic performance was virtually unparalleled. 3 3 3 - 5 4 0 0 - 81 - 3 29 :QL 3 TABLE 1.—Changes in employment in major industrial countries, 1970-80 [Percent change] To 1980 first quarter from Country Germany France United Kingdom. Japan United States Note.—Data are for civilian employment. Sources: Department of Labor (Bureau of Labor Statistics) and Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Some of the rapid job creation was associated with the low rate of productivity growth, but production also increased rapidly. As shown in Table 2, the growth of industrial production in the United States, both during the decade as a whole and in the last years of the decade, compared favorably with that of other large industrial countries. TABLE 2.—Changes in industrial production in major industrial countries, 1970-80 [Percent change] To 1980 first quarter from Country Germany. France United Kingdom. Japan.... United States. Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Whatever the problems of the American economy, they do not arise from an inability to generate large increases in jobs and production. But if the challenges raised by chronic high inflation, energy and environmental problems, ebbing productivity growth, and structural readjustment are not faced, the potential for further growth will not be realized. In recent years the United States has successfully begun to tackle some of its most difficult problems. After years of inaction followed by several years of vigorous debate, and with some painful sacrifices, we have put into place the major elements of an energy program which is already paying dividends in the form of greater energy conservation and improved supply prospects. After decades in which the documented evidence about the greater productivity and efficiency to be gained from economic deregulation had been ignored, this Nation finally acted during the past 4 years to deregulate its airline, trucking, and railroad industries, and major elements of its financial industry. And during the 1980 recession the executive branch and the Congress showed their willingness to maintain the restraint and discipline 30 needed to control inflation by resisting strong pressures for a hasty and potentially inflationary fiscal stimulus. As this Report will have several occasions to point out, there are no simple and clear-cut answers to the complex economic problems confronting our country. Many of them will yield only gradually to persistent efforts pursued on many fronts. In some cases where our knowledge is particularly uncertain, we may have to try several approaches before finding an effective solution. Nevertheless, the willingness to tackle difficult problems which this country has shown in the last several years provides a reason to temper concern about the seriousness of our economic problems with a belief that they can be met successfully. The first two chapters of this Report examine the major economic challenges identified above and discuss appropriate policies to deal with them. In most instances the Administration has already made specific policy recommendations, and these are reflected here. But in some cases the chapters identify and evaluate additional policy options on which decisions would have been made had this Administration continued in office. The third chapter of this Report examines the Nation's general economic performance in 1980 and the outlook for 1981 and 1982, while the fourth chapter turns to issues pertaining to the international economy. Chapter 1 addresses the broad problem of reducing inflation while achieving satisfactory growth in employment, output, and productivity. It considers selected aspects of both demand-side and supply-side measures. After discussing the history and causes of inflation, the chapter outlines the role and the limitations of demand management policies, examines the special problems of setting and carrying out anti-inflationary monetary policies in a world of high inflation and frequent economic disturbances, and evaluates the potential usefulness of a tax-based incomes policy as a method for reducing inflation. The remainder of the chapter is devoted to supply-side policies and pays particular attention to two subjects: first, the importance of increasing the share of the Nation's output devoted to capital formation and the macroeconomic policies necessary to achieve that goal; and second, the integration of supply-oriented tax reductions with overall policies of demand restraint. Chapter 2 deals with major problems in particular sectors or markets. Specifically, it covers six major topics: energy, regulation, banking, agriculture, the labor market, and the generic problems of structural adjustment among industries confronting economic change. Broadly speaking, the policy measures discussed in Chapter 2 are aimed at increasing supply and productivity by improving the efficiency with which particular markets work and adjust to change. Like 31 the macroeconomic policies examined in Chapter 1, these too are a means of reducing inflation and speeding economic growth. INFLATION The Nation has for some time now experienced inflation that would have been unimaginable in earlier days. Although people's lives and the course of business may not, at first glance, appear radically different from what they were in 1960 before the recent inflation began, inflation has taken a very real toll. The uncertainty it has brought with it cannot be measured, but the consequent anxiety has torn at the fabric of our society. People feel less able to mark their progress and fear that the next round of inflation will leave them poorer. In a number of ways—such as introducing cost-of-living adjustments into wage contracts and indexing the benefits of social welfare programs—institutions have evolved to compensate for some of the uncertainty. But these institutions may sometimes only heighten the arbitrary redistribution of income brought on by inflation—redistribution that society often finds undesirable and unfair. In addition to these painful effects, moreover, inflation reduces the Nation's prospects for growth. The reduction may not appear dramatic, but it impairs the efficiency of the free-enterprise system and discourages capital investment, innovation, and risk-taking. Rising prices, it should be remembered, are not in the aggregate synonymous with a reduction in real income. When prices rise, someone receives the additional revenues. And for the economy as a whole, rising prices have gone together with rising money incomes. But a wage or salary increase comes infrequently and in a large lump, while prices tend to increase all the time. Furthermore, a pay increase may be viewed as uncertain and as a reward for effort, but price increases seem entirely beyond a consumer's control. As a result, a recent wage increase may be forgotten when the grocery bill rises. Thus rising prices are often treated as something that directly lower real incomes, even when in fact for the Nation as a whole they do not. Of course, the resulting anxiety is no less real. But when the country pays sharply higher prices to foreign oil producers, that does indeed lower its real income. We are poorer because we receive less oil than we did previously for the same amount of money. That would be true whether or not general inflation followed increases in the price of oil. The induced inflation, in the form of generally higher wages, salaries, and prices, is not the cause of the real income decline—the Nation's higher oil bill is. A similar phenomenon occurs when growth in productivity slows. Slower productivity growth leads to a slower rise in real incomes. A 32 decline in productivity growth may be accompanied by an unchanged pace of wage and salary increases, in which case inflation will rise. But a slackening of productivity growth may also result in lower wage increases and an unchanged inflation rate. In either case the same slowdown in the growth of real income would have occurred. It was not caused by inflation. Although some of the simpler notions that associate inflation with real income loss are wrong, high and rising rates of inflation do indeed weaken the Nation's macroeconomic performance. Inflation can contribute to slower growth in productivity by discouraging investment in two ways. First, some evidence suggests that when inflation increases, not only do people's expectations of future inflation rise, but their expectations tend to become much more uncertain. In this climate, expectations depend less on fact and more on opinion, rumor, and subjective perceptions. Innovative investments and other higher-risk economic activities, the seedbeds of future productivity growth, seem even riskier and are less likely to be undertaken. Meanwhile, businesses and households devote increasing effort to shielding themselves from the effects of inflation, often by speculating in nonproductive assets. Second, as discussed later in this chapter, the interaction between inflation and the tax system can indirectly discourage business investment and also affect the types of assets chosen, thereby distorting investment decisions and resulting in a less productive capital stock. In a market economy the structure of relative prices and costs, and the yardstick of business profits, provide signals to businesses about what to produce, what inputs to buy, and when to buy them. The system responds to changes in those signals—changes in the price of aluminum relative to copper, of glass relative to tin, and in wages relative to prices. But in a period of high inflation, with a consequent increase in uncertainty, it is much more difficult to distinguish signals from random events. It is hard to know to what extent particular wage and price increases simply represent general inflation or are conveying a "real" message. As a consequence, it is easier to make wrong decisions. Inefficiencies grow, and productivity falls. The uncertainty created by inflation also obstructs the conduct of economic policy. To the extent that high and rising inflation unhinges expectations from reality, the connection between economic policies and their results is attenuated, and the difficulties of policymaking are increased. Inflation itself is then more difficult to control. There is a temptation for macroeconomic policy to make announcements and take measures to impress the markets, but the intangible gains so purchased tend to evaporate rapidly. Uncertainty is in large part to blame for the damage done by inflation. In addition to causing serious worry among individuals planning their economic futures, uncertainty interferes with the efficient operation of markets and thereby lowers the productive potential of the economy. Although measures to cure inflation may themselves be painful, over the longer term a reduction in inflation will yield rewards in terms of increased productivity growth and real income. UNDERSTANDING INFLATION To understand our persistent inflation, it is necessary to look beyond the commonly cited price statistics. Such statistics as the consumer price index (CPI), the various producer price indexes, and the national income account deflators are specialized measures of inflation, each with its own idiosyncrasies. They may be sharply influenced by fluctuations in food and energy prices or in mortgage interest rates and therefore sometimes exaggerate and sometimes understate the fundamental trend of inflation. As an example, in July 1980 the consumer price index showed inflation at zero while the producer price index (PPI) for finished goods showed inflation at an annual rate of almost 20 percent. It is therefore useful to construct measures which better reveal the true course of inflation. Charts 1 and 2 present two different statistical series which together approximate the basic trend, or "underlying rate," of inflation. The underlying rate is the rate of inflation which today's economy would tend to perpetuate if supply and demand remained roughly in balance and no special factors came into play, such as a large rise in oil or food prices. Since payments to labor are estimated to account for almost twothirds of total production costs, prices over the longer term tend to move in conjunction with changes in unit labor costs. Chart 1 shows a special measure of that change—the rate at which wages and fringe benefits are increasing minus the trend of growth in productivity. Chart 2 is a version of the price index for personal consumption expenditures calculated by the Department of Commerce. It excludes the volatile components of food and energy. Each series tells basically the same story. 34 Chart 1 Standard Unit Labor Costs PERCENT CHANGE FROM 4 QUARTERS EARLIER^ -2 1...1...1...I...I...I...I...I...I...I...I...I...I..I1...I...I...I...1...I...1...I... 1960 62 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 ^PERCENT CHANGE IN RATIO OF COMPENSATION PER HOUR TO CYCLICALLY ADJUSTED PRODUCTIVITY, PRIVATE NONFARM BUSINESS, ALL PERSONS, UNREVISED. SOURCES: DEPARTMENT OF LABOR AND COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS. Chart 2 Price Index for Personal Consumption Expenditures Excluding Food and Energy PERCENT CHANGE FROM 4 QUARTERS EARLIER-!/ 10 ...I,..I..,!,..I,,.I...I...I..,!,..I.,,I...I.,.I...I...I...!.,,I...huh.. In.I 1960 62 66 68 70 72 74 78 J/PERCENT CHANGE IN FIXED-WEIGHT PRICE INDEX. DATA ARE PRELIMINARY AND SUBJECT TO REVISION. SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE. 35 80 Over the past 15 years the underlying rate of inflation has risen from about 1 percent in the first half of the 1960s to 9 or 10 percent now. The increase has not been steady. Instead, there have been three major episodes. Each period began with a sharp increase in the underlying rate and ended with the rate falling only part way to its original level. Thus, each new inflationary period has started from a higher underlying level than its predecessor. The first jump in the underlying inflation rate came during the Vietnam war, when a large rise in both military expenditures and outlays for Great Society programs was financed for several years without a tax increase. This led to a very large Federal budget deficit superimposed on an economy already operating at a high level. The result was a classic example of an excess of demand over supply. The underlying inflation rate rose from about 1 percent in the 1961-65 period to 4 or 5 percent by 1969. By the end of the decade the forces pushing up the inflation rate receded as taxes were belatedly raised and Vietnam war outlays declined. Although the economy entered a recession in 1970, the underlying rate of inflation continued at about 4 to 5 percent until wage and price controls were introduced in August 1971. For a short period the controls held down inflation in prices but did not reduce the growth in costs. Another inflationary episode began in late 1973 as the result of two major developments. A poor crop year worldwide caused a sharp surge in food prices, and the Arab oil embargo at the end of 1973 was followed by a threefold increase in world oil prices. Although the full impact of the increase in world oil prices was muted in the United States by price controls on domestically produced oil, energy prices and the prices of energy-using products increased sharply. Aggregate demand grew sharply in 1972 and early in 1973. A worldwide boom led to a major inventory buildup and a widely based acceleration of raw materials prices in 1973-74. Finally, the distortions and inequities brought on by wage and price controls created irresistible pressures for easing the controls in 1973 and eliminating them in 1974. When this occurred, there was a burst of price and wage increases. When this burst receded, the U.S. economy entered its worst recession in 40 years. While the underlying rate of inflation fell back from its late 1974 peak, it did not fall to its starting point. Aside from brief fluctuations, it settled down in the 6 to 7 percent range from 1976 through 1978. The most recent inflationary episode was triggered when the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) raised oil prices in 1979 and early 1980. Relative to the size of the U.S. economy, the recent price increase was larger than the 1973-74 increase. By the 36 end of 1974 the world price of oil had tripled from about $4 to about $12 per barrel, thereby adding about $18 billion to our bill for imported oil, or roughly 1.4 percent of gross national product (GNP). Since the price of domestically produced petroleum (which at that time accounted for about two-thirds of the petroleum used in the United States) was restrained by controls, the average U.S. price remained lower than prices throughout the rest of the world. Still, domestic oil prices almost doubled, so that the total increase in consumer costs was almost 3 percent of GNP. During the most recent shock the price of imported oil rose from about $15 per barrel at the end of 1978 to $35 at the close of 1980. This added about $50 billion to the cost of the oil we now import into the United States, or about 2 percent of GNP. Since domestic crude oil prices were in the process of being decontrolled during this period, the price of domestic oil increased by about $15 per barrel, adding another $60 billion to the oil costs paid by consumers. The forces of inflation during this period were also strengthened to some extent by the behavior of aggregate demand. There was some acceleration of wages in 1978 as unemployment fell sharply. And for a time in late 1978 and early 1979, there appeared to be some excess demand in product markets. Spurred by these developments, inflation surged in 1979 and early 1980. As measured by the CPI—which was also heavily influenced by sharp increases in mortgage interest rates—inflation reached annual rates of 15 to 20 percent in the first quarter of 1980. By the spring of 1980 the forces that had given rise to this inflationary episode subsided, and the economy entered a brief recession. The measured inflation rate receded from its peak, but the underlying rate appears to have leveled off in the 9 to 10 percent range, up several notches from the 6 to 7 percent level at which the period had started. THE SOURCES OF INFLATION The chief problem with respect to inflation is not the sporadic developments that generate inflationary impulses. Instead, it is the ratchet-like nature of the inflationary process which makes it resistant to downward pressures. Chart 3, which shows year-to-year changes in the consumer price index since 1913, captures the essence of the inflation problem of the past two decades. The size of the inflationary bursts of recent years has not been out of line with those which occurred earlier in the century, but recent inflation has had an upward bias and has fluctuated around a rising trend line. An understanding of the "causes" of inflation must therefore encompass not only the various factors that give rise to particular inflationary episodes but also the reasons why inflation has developed a ratchet-like character. 37 Chart 3 Changes in Consumer Prices Since 1913 PERCENT CHANGE 25 -5 -10 " -15 1 1 i 1910 i 1 1 1 11 I i i 11 I i i 11 11 11 i 11 i 11 I i i 11 11 11 i E i 11 i 1 1 1 i i 11 i 11 1 1 1 1 i I i 11 i I i i i 11 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 NOTE: PERCENT CHANGE FOR 1980 IS FROM DECEMBER 1979 TO NOVEMBER 1980 A T A SEASONALLY ADJUSTED ANNUAL RATE. SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF LABOR. The Role of Aggregate Demand in Creating Inflation The inflation rate which occurs in any given year is a composite of the individual wage and price decisions made by millions of businesses, unions, and workers. Those decisions are influenced by the strength of demand relative to supply. As demand (or spending)—on the part of consumers, business, and government—declines relative to supply, there is pressure on workers to moderate their wage demands lest employment fall, and on producers to restrain prices for fear of losing sales. The converse also holds true: the smaller the number of unemployed people and the lower the amount of unused industrial capacity, the greater the upward pressure on wages and prices. Some evidence also suggests that a rapid rise in demand can generate upward pressure on both wages and prices, even if the level of demand is not excessive. In general, if demand is in rough balance with supply, the underlying rate of inflation for the economy as a whole will remain basically unchanged, even though prices and wages in individual sectors may fluctuate in response to conditions in particular markets. If excess demand exists, or if the rate of increase in demand is very large, the underlying rate of inflation will tend to rise. If aggregate demand falls below supply, some downward pressure will be exerted on inflation. Expectations about the future state of aggregate demand are also an important determinant of inflation. Wage decisions and many 38 price decisions cannot easily be reversed. Wages are often set for at least a year, and under most major union contracts they are set for 3 years. There are also many advantages to both buyers and sellers in avoiding frequent product price changes. As a consequence, decisionmakers have to think not only about market conditions at present but also about what they are likely to be in the future. Thus, both current and expected,aggregate demand influence the rate of inflation. Moreover, a firm's decisions today about what wages to offer or what prices to set for any future period will be conditioned by its expectations about the wages its competitors will pay and the prices its competitors will charge, and by the incomes that will be earned by its customers. In short, today's inflation rate is strongly influenced by what people expect it to be tomorrow. It was excess aggregate demand during the Vietnam war that drove up the underlying rate of inflation from 1 percent to 4 or 5 percent by the end of the 1960s. Although increases in oil and food prices were the principal causes of the next two inflationary surges, pressures from aggregate demand again played an identifiable role. The most troublesome feature of the inflation of the past 15 years, however, has been the fact that after each of the three inflationary episodes the underlying rate of inflation did not fall back to its earlier level. To what extent was this outcome a demand-related phenomenon? TABLE 3.—Selected indicators of declining demand pressures [Percent, except as noted] Item 1969 peak ys 1970 recession 1973 peak ys 1975 recession 1980 peak ys 1980 recession 1968 1 1970 1 to to 1969 IV 1971 IV 1973 I to 1974 (I 1974 HI to 1976 IV 1979 \ to 1980 I 1980 II to 1980 IV * Average level: Manufacturing weekly overtime (hours) 3.6 2.9 3.7 2.9 3.3 2.7 Unemployment rate: Total 3.5 2.1 5.5 3.9 4.9 3.3 7.7 5.9 5.9 4.2 7.5 6.4 59 49 86 43 60 88.1 85.9 82.6 76.9 91.9 84.2 79.3 76.3 87.5 83.9 4.3 1.6 37.0 2.7 26.1 11.8 — .3 2.4 -.2 2.6 .3 1.3 Males 20 years and over 2 38 Vendors reporting slower delivery Manufacturing capacity utilization: Primary processing industries Advanced processing industries Change during period: 3 Producer prices for crude materials excluding food and fuel4..... * Unemployment rate (percentage points).. 1 2 3 4 2 2 76.1 78.3 Preliminary. fourth quarter 1980 not available; November used as fourth quarter average. Change from quarter preceding start of period shown. Annual rates. Data prior to 1973 from series seasonally adjusted by Council of Economic Advisers. Note.—Based on seasonally adjusted data, except vendor performance. Sources: Department of Labor (Bureau of Labor Statistics), Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Purchasing Management Association of Chicago, and Council of Economic Advisers. 39 At the end of each inflationary episode the economy entered a recession—in 1970-71, in 1974-75, and in 1980. Unemployment rose steeply, and substantial amounts of idle capacity appeared (Table 3). The failure of inflation to fall back to earlier levels is therefore not attributable to excess demand. On the other hand, there clearly would have been some level of demand low enough to have caused business and labor to moderate the increase in wages and prices substantially so as to return to the earlier level of inflation. But for reasons discussed later, the rate of wage and price increase has become relatively insensitive to a moderate degree of economic slack. As a consequence, the cost of the necessary restraint—in terms of additional unemployment, idle capacity, and lost income, production, and investment—would have been extremely high. Federal Budget Deficits as a Cause of Inflation The Federal budget balance at any given time is an important factor in determining the level of current aggregate demand in the economy. If the Federal budget is in deficit, total spending—private and public—will be higher than it would be if taxes had been raised or spending had been cut to produce a balanced Federal budget. Any tax or spending measure that turned a budget deficit into a balanced budget would tend to reduce demand relative to supply and put downward pressure on the inflation rate. Furthermore, since businesses make wage and price decisions at least partly in the light of what they expect market conditions to be, announcements of future budget policies have a strong effect on current economic conditions and on the rate of inflation. Thus budget deficits can contribute to inflation both by being a part of current aggregate demand and by Contributing to expectations about future aggregate demand. The existence of important relationships between Federal budget policy and aggregate demand that in turn affect inflation does not, however, support the simple view that budget deficits cause inflation and that inflation could be eliminated if Federal deficits were eliminated. Federal deficits are not the sole—or even the primary—determinant of aggregate demand. The Federal deficit is likely to be largest when private demand is weak, incomes are low, and inflationary pressures from the private demand side are absent. That is the situation in a recession. In the second column in Table 4, which shows the Federal budget deficit as a percentage of GNP, the effects of recession in 1958, 1970-71, 1974-75, and 1980 show up as large increases in the deficit in the fiscal years during and immediately after the recession. Conversely, a truly inflationary budget may exhibit a small deficit, or even a surplus, as a result of an inflation-caused increase in Federal revenues. In 1969, as inflation was surging, the 40 Federal budget achieved a surplus. In 1974, when another inflationary surge occurred, the deficit was quite small. TABLE 4.—Governmental surplus or deficit and gross national product, 1958-80 [Amounts in billions of dollars] Fiscal years—unified budget Federal surplus1or deficit ( - ) Year Amount As percent of GNP Calendar years—government sector, national income and product accounts Federal surplus or deficit ( - ) Amount Federal and State and local surplus or deficit ( - ) As percent of GNP Amount As percent of GNP -2.9 -12.9 -0.7 -2.7 -10.3 -1.1 -2.3 -.2 -12.6 -1.6 -2.8 -.3 I960.... 1961 1962 1963... 1964... .3 -3.4 -7.1 -4.8 -5.9 .1 -.7 -1.3 -.8 -1.0 3.0 -3.9 -4.2 .3 -3.3 .6 -.7 -.7 .1 -.5 3.1 -4.3 -3 8 .7 -2.3 .6 -.8 -.7 .1 -.4 1965... 1966.... 1967.... 1968Z 1969«. -1.6 -3.8 -8.7 -25.2 3.2 -.2 -.5 -1.1 -3.0 .4 .5 -1.8 -13.2 -6.0 8.4 .1 -.2 -1.7 -.7 .9 .5 -1.3 -14.2 -6.0 9.9 .1 -.2 -1.8 _J 1.0 1970 1971.... 1972.... •••" 1973.... 1974.... -2.8 -23.0 -23.4 -14.9 -6.1 -.3 -2.2 -2.1 -1.2 -.4 -12.4 -22.0 -16.8 -5.6 -11.5 -1.2 -2.0 -1.4 -.4 -.8 -10.6" -19.4 -3.3 7.8 -4.7 -1.1 -1.8 -.3 .6 -.3 1975 1976 1977... 1978.. 1979 -53.2 -73.7 -53.6 -59.2 -40.2 -3.6 -4.5 -2.9 -2.8 -1.7 -69.3 -53.1 -46.4 -29.2 -14.8 -4.5 -.3.1 -2.4 -1.4 -.6 -63.8 -36.5 -18.3 -.2 -11.9 -4.1 -2.1 -1.0 .0 .5 1980 \ -73.8 -2.9 -62.3 -2.4 -34.8 -1.3 1958 1959 ••••• ' Includes off-budget outlays. 2 A 10-percent income tax surcharge was introduced in July 1968—thus entering calendar year 1968 but fiscal year 1969. 3 Preliminary. Sources: Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic Analysis), Department of the Treasury, and Office of Management and Budget. If government budget deficits are the cause of inflation, it should make no difference whether the deficit occurs at the Federal, State, or local level. For example, the Federal revenue-sharing program, which grants Federal tax revenues to State and local governments, has the effect of reducing State and local deficits (or increasing their surpluses) by increasing the Federal deficit. If the program were eliminated, but both levels of government continued to tax the same amount and maintain the same level of services, the Federal deficit would be reduced—but the total deficit, and its inflationary consequences, would be unchanged. In fact, principally because the State and local governments accumulate funds to pay employee pension costs, their budgets usually show a surplus. As the figures in the final column in Table 4 show, the combined budgets of Federal, State, and local governments have either showed a surplus or a very small deficit during the past two decades, except during recessions and for 2 years when Federal spending on the Vietnam war was at its peak. 41 The notion that budget deficits are the chief cause of inflation also founders on a comparison of budget deficits and inflation among different countries. Japan and Germany in recent years have had much better success in combating inflation than the United States. Yet their budget deficits, especially those of Japan, have been much higher relative to the size of their economies than has been the case in the United States (Table 5). TABLE 5.—International comparison of deficits and inflation, 1977-79 9 annual avcrage Country and item United States: Public sector surplus or deficit ( - ) as percent of GNP1.. Inflation rate 2 . . -0.1 8.4 Germany: Public sector surplus or deficit (—) as percent of GNP1 Inflation rate 2 -2.7 3.5 Japan: Public sector 2surplus or deficit (—) as percent of GNP1 Inflation rate -4.8 5.1 1 a Standardized national accounts basis. Percent change in consumer price index. Sources: Department of Labor (Bureau of Labor Statistics) and Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Stating that deficits are not the sole cause of inflation does not, of course, imply the opposite proposition—that the size of the budget deficit is unimportant to the control of inflation. Subsequent sections of this chapter emphasize the importance of fiscal restraint in a longterm program to reduce inflation. Supply Shocks as a Source of Inflation Sharply higher prices in one sector of the economy can lead to surges in inflation even when excess aggregate demand is absent. These sudden and massive changes generally spring from conditions that cannot be controlled. The most important of these have been increases in food prices resulting from shortages and increases in oil prices mandated by OPEC. These events are no different from such common supply disruptions as strikes, accidents, and natural disasters, but they are much larger, and it is their size which makes their effects exceptional. Price shocks have both direct and indirect effects. Consumers feel the price increases directly, and these direct effects may be magnified by the brevity of the time in which they occur, resulting in extraordinary jumps in reported inflation rates. In addition, price increases in agricultural or energy raw materials translate indirectly into price increases in the final products that utilize those materials, although the degree and timing of the pass-through depend on market conditions. This secondary impact is quite important in the case of petroleum, half of which is used by businesses in production and transportation. 42 As an abrupt increase in the price of an important commodity translates into an increase in the cost of living, pressure builds for wage gains to match the new inflation. Some gains take place automatically where wages are linked to prices through cost-of-living clauses in union contracts. Additional acceleration occurs as new contracts are negotiated. As businesses observe the rising wage-price spiral, they are likely to expect a higher future level of inflation. They are then somewhat more likely to grant larger wage increases, both in the belief that rising inflation will make it possible to pass through increases in higher prices and in order to avoid losing workers. Through this process, a sharp increase in food or oil prices can lead to a rise in the underlying inflation rate. The magnitude of the inflationary process set in motion by an oilprice increase or some other supply shock depends on the state of the economy. The more prosperous the economy and the lower the unemployment level, the more likely it is that the initial increase in prices will lead to higher wage increases and a higher underlying inflation rate. In addition to their inflationary consequences, supply shocks also create recessionary forces. The very large increases in oil prices in 1974 and 1979 not only spurred inflation but simultaneously depressed aggregate demand. They were therefore largely responsible for the recessions of 1974-75 and 1980. After paying sharply higher prices for petroleum products, consumers had less to spend on other goods and services. But those who received the revenues from higher oil prices—foreign and domestic oil producers—increased their demands for U.S. exports and investment goods only gradually. On balance, therefore, aggregate demand and spending fell, leading to lower output and reduced employment. Such a simultaneous increase in inflation and unemployment brought on by supply shocks creates a dilemma for economic policy. If monetary and fiscal policies produce additional aggregate demand to "compensate" for the recessionary forces set in motion by a supply shock, there is likely to be a large induced rise in inflation. If, on the other hand, no effort is made to compensate, aggregate demand will fall. But given the relative insensitivity of wage and price decisions to moderate slack in the economy, some increase in the underlying inflation rate is nonetheless likely. Only sharply restrictive monetary and fiscal policies, which strengthen the forces leading to recession, can prevent an increase in the underlying inflation rate. While recessionary forces came into play in 1974 and 1980, the slackening of aggregate demand was not sufficient to avoid another upward ratcheting of the inflation rate. 43 The Role of Declining Productivity Growth Over the past decade—and perhaps since the mid-1960s—the rate of productivity growth in the United States has slackened. (A later section of this chapter examines this trend in more detail.) This slackening has been an unwelcome development, since productivity growth can offset the effects of rising wages on business costs and prices. When productivity growth slows but increases in wages continue, the rate of increase in costs and prices rises. While short-term variations in productivity growth may not be recognized in setting prices, a longer-lasting slowdown in productivity will be reflected in higher prices. Once prices begin to rise in response to this pressure, another round of wage demands is stimulated as workers try to offset the increased cost of living. This raises the underlying inflation rate yet again. The Downward Insensitivity of Wages and Prices If wages and prices were sensitive to a moderate degree of slack in the economy, careful control of aggregate demand through monetary and fiscal policy could bring rising inflation to a halt quickly and at a modest cost. True, mistakes in policy might occur from time to time, and supply shocks over which the government has no control would still take place. But inflation could be brought down relatively quickly and easily if it did not have—as it has now—a large degree of inertia. Before World War II, and perhaps in the immediate postwar years, wages and prices were more sensitive in a downward direction. (See Chart 3, for example.) Several careful economic studies show that in that earlier period a moderate or short-lived slackening of aggregate demand tended to reduce the rate of inflation significantly. Those who have compared that earlier era with more recent times differ in their views as to precisely why things have changed, but the basic causes are clear. During the past several decades the vast majority of firms, labor unions, and workers have come to expect that expansionary government policies will be applied sooner or later to reverse recessionary tendencies in the economy. Since current wage and price decisions are strongly influenced by what workers and firms think the future will hold, the expectation of stimulus removes much of the motivation for moderating wage and price behavior. Businesses and unions have also developed a growing tendency to turn to government for relief, often with some success, when their high prices and wages lead them into competitive difficulties. All of these factors have weakened the incentive for businesses and workers to restrain their wage and price demands, even in the face of softening markets. These actions do not depend on specific knowledge about future government 44 policies but are based on the widespread view that "the government won't allow things to get too bad." Prior to World War II, however, popular expectations were different. The Federal Government had historically played little role in smoothing the economic cycles, and substantial depressions as well as mild recessions occurred periodically. Up until the 1930s there was no unemployment insurance, social security, or deposit insurance to ameliorate the consequences of economic downturns. When markets started to weaken, there was no reason to believe that any support—in the aggregate or for individuals—woul<j be forthcoming from the government. As a consequence, wages and prices quickly subsided as businesses and workers scrambled to survive. The cycle, furthermore, was self-reinforcing. Because inflation often led to a slump, followed by a speedy reduction in inflation, businessmen and others came to expect that inflation would not last long; this expectation itself moderated their behavior with respect to wages and prices. After World War II, however, the United States and other industrial countries decided that the costs of this kind of painful adjustment were too high. Thus, countercyclical policy was founded. The success of that policy, and the existence of various programs of income support to protect individuals in case of unemployment, have changed the character of expectations. In the new environment the appearance of slack markets, idle capacity, and higher unemployment leads to far less moderation in wage and price increases. Downward flexibility has not disappeared, but it has diminished. Current wage and price behavior has deep-seated structural origins and is not based solely on current expectations about governmental behavior. Since most large wage contracts run for 2 or 3 years, the rate of wage increase in any particular year will have been determined in part by negotiations in earlier years under different conditions. In addition, the expiration dates of multiyear wage contracts for different industries are staggered, and the wage increases negotiated in any industry will be influenced to some extent by the size of earlier increases won by unions in other industries. Moreover, the prospect of further inflation over the life of these contracts has led to the inclusion of cost-of-living clauses, which provide wage increases even when markets are slack. Although union contracts cover less than one-quarter of the civilian labor force, the partial insulation of these contracts from current economic events has some effect on the wages that nonunion firms must pay. Quite apart from the existence of written contracts, there are mutual advantages to both firms and workers from wage-setting practices that are relatively insensitive to economic slack. In complicated modern societies the costs of acquiring information about alternative 333-5U0 0 - 81 - 4 : QL 3 45 job opportunities are very high for workers, and the costs of training a skilled work force are very large for businesses. Both workers and firms see benefits in establishing long-term relationships. One way for a firm to attract and hold a skilled work force is an implicit agreement not to engage in extensive wage-cutting during periods of weak markets. As a consequence, many firms are unwilling to take a chance of losing out in the labor market by being among the first to reduce wage increases. Other institutions besides those of wage-contracting contribute to the downward insensitivities of prices and wages. In the case of prices, the downward pressure that would normally be exerted by competitive forces in slack markets is significantly muted in large oligopolistic industries by market strategy considerations and various forms of administered prices. Finally, government intervention in individual markets through regulation, which may fix wages, the price or quality of the product, or the conditions under which production takes place, adds further rigidity. Some of the economic institutions and practices that contribute to wage and price rigidity themselves evolved in response to expectations that government economic policy would continue to be supportive. Although the persistent application of demand restraint is likely to reduce them, they should not be expected to disappear easily or quickly. Downward wage and price rigidity makes the costs of reducing inflation through monetary and fiscal restraint quite large. It is difficult to estimate the costs with precision, but representative econometric studies suggest that reducing inflation by 1 percentage point would require a sacrifice of $100 billion in lost output (in 1980 pYices) and a one-half percentage point rise in the unemployment rate over a period of about 3 years. Most of the costs would be incurred in the first half of the period. These statistical estimates, however, are based on historical relationships. There has never been a period of sustained economic restraint in recent times from which direct evidence of the costs could be drawn. The possibility that they would grow significantly smaller if restraint persisted is discussed later in this chapter. In sum, it is the costs imposed on society when demand restraint clashes with the downward insensitivity of wages and prices that makes it so difficult to reduce inflation by applying monetary and fiscal restraint. Viewed in this perspective, the central problem of economic policy is not how to reduce inflation. If that were the only objective, a sufficiently draconian level of demand restraint could be found to do the job. The real issue is twofold: How large are the costs society is willing to bear to realize the benefits of lower infla- 46 tion, and can policies be designed to lower those costs so that inflation can be reduced faster with smaller losses in output and employment? MANAGING AGGREGATE DEMAND Monetary and fiscal policy must be designed to prevent aggregate spending that is so high or growing so fast relative to the Nation's productive capacity that it encourages a speedup in the rate at which wages and prices are rising—i.e., an increase in inflation. To play a role in lowering the underlying inflation rate, growth in aggregate demand must be further restrained to a point where firms and workers reduce the rate at which they raise wages and prices. This section starts by specifying a policy of demand management that aims at a gradual reduction of inflation in a world where the inflation rate is highly resistant to downward pressures. Particular attention is paid to the problem of establishing the credibility of antiinflation policies so as to influence popular expectations in a favorable way. The section then considers some of the special problems of managing monetary policy in a period of high inflation and frequent economic disturbances. BROAD PRINCIPLES Three broad principles, discussed at length in last year's Report, can guide monetary and fiscal policy as it seeks to reduce inflation while providing for reasonable growth: First, monetary and fiscal policy should aim for a long-term reduction in the growth of nominal GNP (aggregate spending). That reduction should not be abrupt, or it will produce large decreases in employment and production while reducing inflation only modestly. But the restraint must be maintained, since wages and prices tend to resist the downward pressure. Second, the pace of nominal GNP growth will undoubtedly need to fluctuate along a declining trend. Realistically, even if there is a decrease in the inflation rate in 1981, for example, some rise in nominal GNP growth will be required to accommodate a modest recovery from the 1980 recession. A policy of fiscal and monetary restraint to produce a long-term reduction in the growth rate of nominal GNP may thus need to be adjusted from time to time to take account of short-term changes in economic conditions. But several cautions are required. Unless clearly warranted and carefully explained, shorterterm adjustments to economic policy can threaten the credibility of longer-term restraint. Moreover, because an increase in inflation once underway is so very hard to eliminate, an inflationary mistake takes much longer to reverse than its opposite. The risks that policy- 47 makers face are not symmetrical and, as a consequence, uncertainty must be resolved in favor of caution. Third, no matter how well designed, monetary and fiscal policies cannot prevent large outside shocks to the economy from imposing some damage on employment, price stability, or growth. A practical approach would be to "accommodate" the direct inflationary effect of external price shocks but restrain aggregate demand sufficiently to minimize the indirect inflationary effects that would result if individuals attempted to raise wages and other incomes to "catch up" with higher prices. Without huge costs in terms of lost production, however, it would probably be impossible to restrain demand sufficiently to eliminate all induced increases in inflation. In these circumstances a voluntary incomes policy may be able to make a significant contribution. This seems to have occurred in 1979, when the response of wages to the large rise in inflation was substantially muted. Because the rate of increase in wages and prices tends to resist downward pressures, a policy of continued restraint on the growth of aggregate demand sufficient to induce a decline in inflation will mean sustained slack in the economy and will result in a period of relatively slow growth in production and employment. This outlook could be improved if it were possible to change the behavior of wages and prices so that they responded to demand restraint more rapidly and by larger amounts. THE ROLE OF EXPECTATIONS AND THE CREDIBILITY OF DEMAND RESTRAINT Earlier in this chapter the downward resistance of wage and price inflation was attributed in part to a widespread expectation that expansionary government policies will rather quickly be applied to reverse recessionary tendencies. If firms and workers became convinced that the government meant business, that the markets for their products would not be supported by easier money or fiscal stimulus, and that they could continue raising wages and prices only at their own peril, their decisions about wage demands and pricing policies would undoubtedly be affected. The downward "stickiness" of wage and price inflation would be eased. Does the government need to put the economy through one or more prolonged periods of economic slack in order to demonstrate the firmness of its anti-inflation commitment? Or can it avoid that necessity by somehow convincing the Nation in advance of its determination? Some observers have suggested, for example, that the government could show its resolve by announcing a target path for nominal GNP or for money supply growth (or both) and by committing itself to pursuing those targets whatever the consequences for unemployment and production. The target path would permit pro- 48 duction and employment to grow only if they were accompanied by significant reductions in wage and price inflation. But simply announcing a set of targets does not guarantee that they will steadfastly be pursued in the face of mounting losses in employment, profits, and sales. Indeed, the tougher the targets and the greater the demand restraint they seem to require, the less likely they are to be credible, for their success will rely on an uncharacteristic willingness on the part of the Administration, the Congress, and the public to accept large reductions in employment and production rather than abandon the targets. The mere announcement of government intentions is, therefore, unlikely to produce a significant change in wage and price behavior. The actual experience of persistent demand restraint, followed by a substantial number of individual firms and unions pricing themselves out of the market, would almost certainly be necessary before the credibility of the policy was established. In addition, the government would have to refuse pleas for trade restrictions, subsidies, or other relief for those who failed to moderate their wage and price increases. Even if firms and workers became convinced that the government was determined to persist in its demand restraint regardless of the consequences, to what extent would they respond with a greater willingness to cut wage and price increases, especially if the demand restraint were moderate instead of very severe? The answer would depend in part on whether they expected inflation or production to fall first. If individual firms believed that demand restraint was synonymous with lower inflation, they would undoubtedly restrain their own wage and price increases, since they would be reluctant to get far out of line with the wages and prices of other firms and industries. But given the downward insensitivity of wages and prices experienced over the past several decades, demand restraint might at the present time lead instead to expectations of lower output. It is not at all clear, therefore, how sharply wages and prices would respond to a moderate decline in demand even if it was expected to last for a long while. Equally important, strong structural components of wage and price stickiness discussed earlier in this chapter would remain. These structural factors are, in the near term, independent of expectations. As a consequence, other measures would also have to be pursued as a means of speeding a reduction in inflation and raising the growth of production and employment in th£ face of continued demand restraint. The foregoing discussion suggests that one of the most critical questions in designing anti-inflation policies is determining the 49 extent to which the downward stickiness of wage and price inflation has been due to popular expectations rather than to structural factors. While there is no clear-cut answer to this question at the moment, it is surely true that expectations about the persistence of government policies of demand restraint affect the responsiveness of wages and prices. To the extent that the credibility of government policies can be strengthened, the reduction in inflation will come more quickly and the social costs will be reduced. The fact of persistence in an anti-inflation policy—as happened in 1980, when no fiscal stimulus was offered and a restrictive monetary policy was maintained in the face of a weakening economy—should gradually help to modify business and worker behavior. But it would be imprudent to expect entrenched expectations to be changed quickly. MONETARY POLICY The Federal Reserve bears a substantial share of the responsibility for carrying out aggregate demand management. As discussed above, the monetary authorities must first confront the question of the appropriate degree of economic restraint. The problem is to achieve the proper balance in order to reduce inflationary pressures at a minimum cost in lost jobs and production. Formulating and implementing policies to achieve this balance in a period characterized by wide fluctuations in economic and financial conditions confronts the monetary authorities with a number of serious additional challenges. While these problems are generally technical in nature, the manner in which they are resolved can have a significant impact on the degree of monetary restraint. Monetary policy can exert no direct control over aggregate demand. It must exert its influence indirectly, that is, by affecting actual and expected conditions in the money and credit markets. The linkages between what it can control (the cost and availability of bank reserves), its intermediate indicators of conditions in the money and credit markets (the monetary aggregates and interest rates), and its ultimate goals (the impact on real growth and prices) are imperfect and often are not directly observable, even after the fact. In evaluating these linkages, the monetary authorities must rely on predicted relationships based on economic theory and historical experience, and there is plenty of room for slippage. These technical problems create considerable uncertainty for the makers of monetary policy. A related issue is that the effectiveness of the monetary authorities in bringing down inflation depends on how firms and individuals perceive monetary policy. Private sector expectations of the likely success of monetary policy influence its actual success. Consequently, it is important that the monetary authorities demonstrate that they have chosen a strategy that will achieve their anti-inflation objectives. 50 Moreover, their actions must indicate that they have the technical capability to meet these objectives while responding forcefully to new situations and to any divergence between desired and actual developments. In recent years the debate on these issues has focused on the Federal Reserve's target growth ranges for monetary aggregates and on the process of setting and implementing these targets. The targets are defined in terms of the narrow measures of the money stock (formerly M-l and now M-1A and M-1B, which include currency and various types of checkable deposits), the broader measures of the money stock (M2 and M3, which include currency and checkable deposits as well as time and savings deposits and other deposit-like instruments), and bank credit. The Federal Reserve has used monetary growth targets internally since the early 1970s, and since 1975 it has announced them publicly in testimony before the Congress. In October 1979 the Federal Reserve modified its procedures for implementing monetary policy in order to give greater emphasis to keeping the growth of the aggregates within the target ranges, even if that meant more variation in interest rates. By this change, the Federal Reserve was widely perceived as having established the realization of its targets as a benchmark for measuring the performance of monetary policy. While the notion of monetary targeting may appear quite straightforward, in practice there are a number of questions that must be resolved in carrying out a targeting strategy. Among these, three in particular deserve attention here: • How should the Federal Reserve set its monetary growth targets, both in terms of choosing particular measures of money and choosing numerical targets? • What is the appropriate monetary policy response when the relationships among economic variables, on which the initial targets were set, appear to shift? • How rigidly should the Federal Reserve adhere to its longer-run growth ranges over the short run? Choosing the Appropriate Measure of Money Debate over selection of the appropriate measure by which to guide monetary policy must take into account the tradeoff between the ability of the Federal Reserve to control any monetary aggregate and the influence of that aggregate on overall demand. For example, the monetary base, composed of currency held by the public plus bank reserves, is probably the easiest for the Federal Reserve to control. But studies have shown that the relationship between the monetary base and aggregate demand is not very close. The narrow meas- 51 ures of the money stock (M-1A and M-1B) are somewhat harder to control but in general have been more closely tied to aggregate demand. Some economists argue that a broader measure of the money stock, such as M-2, has the most stable relationship with aggregate demand, but the very breadth of this measure—including as it does a mixture of the liabilities of several types of financial institutions—makes it rather difficult to control. A related issue is how the various measures of the money stock should be defined. The rapid evolution of the financial markets in recent years (see the discussion in Chapter 2) has blurred the historical distinctions between the types of financial instruments and rendered somewhat ambiguous what should be treated as "money." These developments have been partly responsible for the recent instabilities in the relationship among the narrow monetary measures, economic activity, and interest rates—instabilities commonly referred to as shifts in money demand. In light of these considerations, the Federal Reserve has chosen to consider a family of monetary aggregates to impart a needed degree of flexibility. Thus, while a narrow aggregate like M-1B has been accorded primary emphasis, there may be periods when it provides an uncertain guide for monetary policy. At such times the Federal Reserve may put more emphasis on the broader measures of the money stock, such as M-2. Setting Numerical Targets Once the Federal Reserve determines which monetary aggregates to target, numerical target ranges must be set to achieve the appropriate degree of aggregate demand restraint. The targeting procedure could, for example, begin by determining the appropriate path for nominal GNP that would be consistent with a gradual decline in inflation. Abstracting from cyclical variations in real economic expansion, a steady reduction of inflation would imply a gradual decline in nominal GNP growth. Given this objective, the monetary authorities would need to estimate growth rates for the monetary aggregates that would satisfy the needs of an economy moving along the presumed declining path of nominal GNP. These would then become the basis for choosing the target growth ranges. Over the past two decades a given growth rate of the narrow measures of money has, on average, financed a 2 to 3 percentage point faster rate of expansion of nominal GNP, although the pattern has varied from year to year. This relationship suggests that the goal of a gradual decline in the growth of nominal GNP would be consistent with a gradual lowering in the target ranges, although not necessarily every year. 52 Starting with its 1975 targets as a base, the Federal Reserve has, in fact, adhered to a policy of lowering the target ranges by a small amount in each year (Table 6). What has been the result? In some years (1977, 1978, and 1980) the targets were exceeded. In the others there were apparent shifts in money demand such that actual money growth was much lower than would be predicted on the basis of historical relationships. Predicted M-l growth for the last 5 years is shown in the third column of Table 6, and the difference between predicted and actual money growth is in the last column. As the figures indicate, those years when actual money growth was in the target ranges (1976 and 1979) were periods in which there were the largest downward shifts in money demand. In effect, actual money growth during these periods supported a greater-than-expected growth of nominal GNP. In the remaining years money growth was nearer the rate expected from historical money-demand relationships, but that growth was above the target range. These two factors—money demand shifts and missing the targets—help to explain how such low values for the monetary growth targets could have persisted in a period of high nominal GNP growth. Over the entire period more nominal growth was accommodated than is implied by the monetary targets and the historical relationships. TABLE 6.—Monetary growth rates, 1975-80 Money growth (percent change from Predicted fourth quarter a year earner) minus actual growth Target Actual Predicted1 (percentage points) Period Fourth quarter: 1976 M-l 1977 M-l .. 1978 M-l .... 1979 M-l! .. 1980 M-lfe).. 4%6Vfe 4 -GYz 3 -6 3 4 -6Vfe 5.8 2 7.9 = 7.2 5.5 2*7.1 10.0 9.9 7.8 7.3 4.2 2.0 1.6 2.4 1 Predicted money growth based on Council of Economic Advisers money demand equation using actual historical data for GNP, interest rates, and prices. 2 Above target range. 3 The target range for 1980 based on the newly defined aggregate M-1B was chosen to be consistent with a slowing in monetary growth as compared to 1979. * Preliminary. Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (target ranges and actual money growth) and Council of Economic Advisers (predicted money growth). Although the continuing application of monetary restraint could call for reductions of the monetary growth ranges over time, there are a number of problems which have to be faced. In particular, the question arises about the extent to which adjustments in monetary targets ought to be made when structural changes occur in the economy. In the last decade there have been several abrupt shifts in the relationships among important economic factors—disruptions related to 53 jumps in oil and food prices as well as to shifts in money demand. The problem for the Federal Reserve is how, if at all, to adjust monetary growth targets in response to these changes. This requires an evaluation of the likely direct impact of monetary and credit conditions on economic activity, as well as an assessment of how altering the monetary targets would affect wages and prices. Response to Supply-Side Shocks When the economy experiences a supply shock such as the recent surge in oil prices, the initial results are likely to be a reduction in aggregate demand and a rise in unemployment and inflation. As discussed earlier, the Federal Reserve can respond in several ways. At one extreme, the response would aim at accommodating the shock completely, thus restoring real aggregate demand to its level before the shock and avoiding any rise in unemployment. At the other extreme, the response would attempt to offset fully both the direct and indirect inflationary effects. The intermediate position suggested earlier would be to accommodate the direct effects of the price shock but seek to minimize indirect effects. If the latter strategy were adopted, the monetary targets necessary to pursue it would be identical to those prevailing before the shock only by pure chance. Some adjustment would almost invariably be required, but whether the appropriate response entailed greater or less monetary growth than the original target ranges would depend on conditions prevailing in the economy at the time as well as on the complex dynamic responses of wages and prices after the shock. Moreover, the monetary authorities must remember that their credibility may be damaged if this strategy were to entail an upward adjustment in targets. Such a consideration may lead to a less accommodative position than analysis based strictly on aggregate demand conditions would warrant. Changes in Money Demand Shifts in money demand confront the monetary authorities with a different set of problems. Here the appropriate policy response is clear in theory. For example, money-demand shifts have at times in recent years resulted in sudden reductions in the amount of money necessary to support a given amount of economic activity. Holding to predetermined monetary targets in the face of such shifts would mean a more accommodative policy than previously intended. Alternatively, by reducing monetary growth targets commensurate with the demand shift, an unchanged degree of monetary restraint would be maintained. Although the response is clear in theory, in practice there are many problems. It is difficult for the Federal Reserve to know until 54 well after the fact whether the money-demand relationship has changed permanently. If one could observe money, interest rates, and nominal GNP contemporaneously, one could judge whether these developments were roughly in line with historical patterns. If they appeared to be out of line, a shift in demand might be suspected. Two problems in ascertaining a shift are the long delay before data on GNP are available, and the frequent revisions subsequently undergone by both GNP and money data. Another problem is that the "normal" demand for money cannot be estimated precisely, so that even with timely data it may take several quarters before the shift becomes evident. Suppose that a money-demand shift is suspected of having occurred, but its magnitude is uncertain. How should the monetary authorities adjust the targets in a way that maintains a steady degree of monetary restraint? First, the targets for the narrow aggregates might be adjusted by shifting the midpoints of the longer-run target ranges according to the "best guess" of how the structural shift will affect the growth rate. Second, if the impact of the structural change is uncertain, the upper and lower bounds of the growth range may have to be widened to reflect that uncertainty. Third, if—as in the past— the broader money measures do not appear to be affected as much by the structural changes, more emphasis could then be put on the broader aggregates in guiding monetary actions. At such times the relatively greater stability of the relationship of the broader aggregates to income and interest rates may give the monetary authorities a somewhat better measure of monetary stringency. The risk in making these adjustments is that the public may lose sight of why such changes are being made—interpreting them as mere tinkering or as devices aimed at loosening monetary restraint. Thus, the monetary authorities stand to lose credibility unless they can convince the public of the need for such adjustments when they are appropriate. Problems of Short-Run Variability Once the annual numerical targets have been set, and adjusted for major supply shocks or shifts in money demand if necessary, the next question is how rigidly the targets should be followed during the year. It is important to recognize that random and temporary fluctuations will inevitably occur, affecting both the demand and supply sides of the financial markets. Empirical evidence suggests, however, that deviations from a desired money growth path lasting as long as a quarter do not destabilize aggregate demand if they are subsequently corrected. Hence, rigid adherence to a longer-run target over periods as short as a month or a quarter would require wide fluctuations in interest rates, which could disrupt the economy unnecessarily. In view of the importance of preserving Federal Reserve credibility, it is 55 essential for the public to understand that such short-run deviations are not nearly as consequential as they are sometimes made out to be. The problem for the Federal Reserve is to distinguish these temporary disturbances from more permanent shifts in economic relationships for which some response may be necessary. Since the monetary authorities cannot determine until well after the fact whether a divergence in money growth is permanent or self-correcting, they must establish short-run procedures that partially accommodate temporary disturbances but respond with increasing intensity to systematic trends. The current procedures for implementing the longer-run growth target ranges include setting short-run money targets periodically during the year and managing reserves on a day-to-day basis to meet those targets. These procedures are designed to achieve a proper balance between avoiding unnecessary disturbances in the money markets and responding in a timely fashion to sustained movements of actual money growth away from the desired path. In practice, this process is subject to a number of slippages, both in the relationship between reserves and money and in the actual control of reserves. Because different components of the money stock are subject to different reserve requirement ratios—and some are subject to no reserve requirements-r-the ratio of reserves to money can vary unpredictably when funds are shifted among types of deposits and among institutions. This hinders short-run monetary control. Changes in reserve requirements and reserve coverage associated with the Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary Control Act of 1980, discussed in Chapter 2, should reduce the variation in the money-reserve ratio, but only gradually. Until this transition period is completed, the variation in this crucial ratio will continue. Even if the linkage between money and reserves were perfectly stable and predictable, the Federal Reserve would still need to be able to control total reserves. Current problems in forecasting the various uncontrollable factors affecting reserves, in reserve accounting procedures, and in the management of the discount window make it difficult to achieve the target for total reserves. The Federal Reserve is working to improve its forecasting techniques and is considering other reforms that would increase its control over reserves. Thus, one should not expect the Federal Reserve to adhere rigidly to its annual monetary targets in every period during the year. Temporary and largely self-correcting disturbances will inevitably lead to short-run deviations, but these deviations should have few permanent economic consequences. The current targeting process of the Federal 56 Reserve provides some flexibility in the face of such temporary disturbances, even with unchanged annual monetary targets. Conclusions One of the major lessons that emerges repeatedly in the preceding discussion is the need for understanding, by the public generally and the financial community in particular, of the complexities of monetary policy. Monetary targeting provides an invaluable tool to increase monetary discipline, to communicate Federal Reserve intentions, and to evaluate performance. But the advantages of a semiautomatic rule to guide the monetary authorities are not absolute. In a world where economic and financial markets are subject to major and unpredictable changes, deviations from the Federal Reserve's announced intention to reduce steadily the annual target ranges may sometimes be necessary. Targets, once set, may occasionally have to be modified. And allowing short-run deviations of actual from targeted money growth may be called for if care is taken not to let them persist. But if the public interprets occasional necessary changes in the longer-run monetary target ranges, or short-run deviations of actual money growth from those targets, as evidence that the Federal Reserve has lessened its determination to fight inflation, the monetary authorities will be put in an untenable position. If they fail to make the adjustment in the monetary targets that is called for by a major change in economic circumstances, or if they attempt to avoid all short-run deviations of actual from targeted money growth, monetary policy may produce unwanted results. If, on the other hand, they do change the targets or allow temporary deviations, their actions may be misunderstood by the public and their credibility consequently impaired. The monetary authorities will face this problem once again in 1981, as is discussed in Chapter 3. INCOMES POLICIES Even if they are followed with persistence and acquire a credibility that favorably affects expectations, monetary and fiscal restraints are likely to reduce inflation only slowly and at significant cost in lost output and employment. Incomes policies attempt to lower these costs. By directly influencing the setting of wages and prices, incomes policies seek to decrease the inflation and increase the growth of output and employment that result from any given degree of demand restraint. A tight monetary target, for example, is compatible either with a small reduction in inflation and zero economic growth or a larger reduction in inflation and positive economic growth. By persuading workers and employers to accept lower pay and price in- 57 creases, an incomes policy tries to make the second combination possible. Incomes policies range from the informal pressure on a few large corporations and unions exerted by the Kennedy Administration to the formal review of price and wage increases by the Council on Wage and Price Stability (CWPS) to even more formal schemes based on the tax system, examined in detail below. While mandatory wage and price controls are the extreme form of an incomes policy, the discussion in this chapter is confined to voluntary forms, that is, forms which do not involve legal prohibition of excessive wage and price increases. An effective incomes policy encourages various groups in society to accept lower wages and prices for the goods and services they supply in the expectation that the wages and prices they pay will also be lower. An incomes policy that gains widespread support can meet these expectations. Workers agree to lower their wage demands, and thus unit labor costs rise more slowly. Firms moderate their price increases, and therefore workers* costs of living rise more slowly. The implicit agreement made among government, workers, and firms to take simultaneous actions to slow the wage-price spiral through the mechanism of the incomes policy is thus successful principally to the extent that people believe it will be successful. To have a lasting influence on inflation, an incomes policy must do more than lower the current rate of increase in wages and prices. It must also lower expectations about the future rate of inflation. Workers must believe that they can achieve their real wage demands with lower nominal wage gains, and firms must believe that large nominal wage gains or other cost increases will be hard to pass on into prices. While our knowledge about the formation of expectations leaves much to be desired, it does suggest that a short-lived reduction in inflation may be insufficient to change expectations sharply. To be successful in lowering inflationary expectations, therefore, an incomes policy probably has to be in effect for more than a single year. Even more important, an incomes policy will have no hope of a lasting effect unless it is accompanied by monetary and fiscal restraint. If there is excess demand in labor and product markets, or if monetary and fiscal policies create expectations of excess demand, the basic tenet of an incomes policy is destroyed. Individual employers or groups of workers cannot then assume that their own moderation will be matched by moderation from others. Although incomes policies can help to reduce inflation, they also tend to create losses of economic efficiency. Ideally, economic policy seeks to lower the average rate of wage and price increase while leaving individual wages and prices to adjust freely around that average 58 in response to circumstances in particular markets. In reality, of course, an incomes policy cannot operate on a statistical average but must deal with the wages and prices of individual firms. Therefore, incomes policies inevitably discourage to some extent movements in prices and wages relative to each other. Over time, the failure of relative prices to adjust in response to changing conditions leads to mounting losses of economic efficiency. The more rigid and mandatory in character the incomes policy, and the longer it is kept in place, the greater will be the efficiency costs. This Administration has judged the benefits of a relatively flexible and voluntary incomes policy to be significantly greater than its costs. In late 1978 the Administration set forth voluntary standards for pay and price increases as the centerpiece of an incomes policy. This section of Chapter 1 briefly reviews that program, and then evaluates a wide range of measures known as tax-based incomes policies (TIPs) under which tax penalties or rewards are employed as a means of inducing moderation in wage and price increases. THE PAY AND PRICE STANDARDS For the past 2 years the Administration's incomes policy has centered on the voluntary pay and price standards. Administered by CWPS, this program applied to firms of all sizes, but only large firms were asked to submit data on pay and either prices or margins. The standards set by CWPS were designed to reflect the structures of different industries. Compliance was encouraged by appealing to firms and workers to restrain price and pay increases in the public interest. CWPS also used public opinion and the threatened loss of government contracts to encourage compliance. Although the standards were voluntary and were in place during the difficult period of the 1979 OPEC oil price explosion, they appear to have played a role in moderating inflation. Studies by CWPS and the Council of Economic Advisers have estimated that annual wage increases were 1 to IV2 percentage points lower during 1979 than they would have been without the standards. The consequent reductions in labor costs also appear to have been passed on to consumers through lower price increases. A more recent evaluation of the pay and price standards by CWPS suggests that the program continued to have a moderating effect in the second year. After 2 years of operation there seems to be general agreement that the current pay and price standards could not continue to be effective if simply extended in their present form. Workers and firms no longer appear to be willing to moderate wage and price rises in the expectation that the standards will restrain inflation. 59 TAX-BASED INCOMES POLICIES One way of strengthening a voluntary standards program would be to supplement it with a tax-based incomes policy, or a TIP. Such a policy would use the tax system to provide tangible incentives to firms and workers to slow the rate of inflation. As the discussion in this section later concludes, the most effective kind of TIP would be one that rewarded employees of firms whose rate of wage increase was below the standard. Such a program would significantly reinforce the spirit of cooperation used in other voluntary forms of incomes policies without creating as many distortions as a mandatory program. Firms and workers that agreed to moderate their price and wage increases would be making less of a sacrifice under a TIP than under other voluntary programs. And in sectors of the economy in which relative prices and wages were too low, a TIP would allow adjustments. The most serious distortions in relative prices and wages that develop under mandatory controls would be avoided under a TIP. Several years ago the Carter Administration proposed to the Congress one particular version of a TIP—the "real wage insurance*' program—but the proposal was not acted upon by the Congress, and in fact was not subjected to widespread public discussion and debate. TIPs continue to represent an important untried innovation in the area of anti-inflation policy. While TIPs may impose administrative and efficiency costs, those costs appear to be far less than would be incurred by reducing inflation solely through restraining aggregate demand. Various kinds of TIPs have been suggested. Under a pay TIP, for example, the government would set a standard for pay increases over the coming year. Groups of workers whose average pay increase did not exceed the standard would be in compliance. In one version of the pay TIP, firms whose wage increases exceeded the standard would be assessed a tax penalty. In another version, all workers in a complying group would receive a tax credit, including individuals within the group whose pay raises were above the standard. Similarly, a price TIP would provide penalties or rewards to firms on the basis of their average price increases relative to a set of standards. In virtually all versions of the TIP it is the average rate of wage or price increase within the firm that is compared with the standard for purposes of determining tax penalties or rewards. With this approach, firms are able to change the relative pay and prices of subgroups of workers and products. Merit pay plans and promotions that give individual pay raises in excess of the standard can still be used to encourage productivity. 60 Although the flexibility of TIPs makes them attractive, using the tax system to reduce inflation poses serious administrative problems. These problems present the major obstacles to designing an effective TIP program. The following sections discuss issues of design in some detail, and a Technical Appendix to this chapter examines other problems in measuring average pay increases. Several choices must be made in designing a TIP. First, should it dispense rewards or levy penalties? Second, should receiving the penalty or reward depend only on being above or below the standard (a "hurdle" TIP), or should the size of the penalty or reward be graduated in accordance with the difference between the standard and the actual pay or price increase (a "continuous" TIP)? Third, should the TIP be a permanent or a temporary program? Finally, should the TIP apply to pay, to prices, or to both? These choices require striking a balance among equity, efficiency, administrative ease, and effectiveness in reducing inflation. The next section discusses the first three choices in the context of a pay TIP, and presents estimates of the cost and effect of a specific pay TIP. Another section discusses price TIPs. Varieties of Pay TIPs For several reasons, a reward pay TIP is probably preferable to a penalty pay TIP. A reward TIP encourages workers to cooperate with a voluntary incomes policy by compensating them for accepting lower nominal pay increases than they would otherwise receive. A penalty TIP, whether levied on firms or on individuals, will tend to undercut the spirit of cooperation necessary for a successful incomes policy. This is especially true because incomes policies are often thought to be more effective in restraining pay increases than in limiting price or profit increases. In addition, although lower rates of increase in wage rates and unit labor costs eventually result in lower price increases, the effect is not immediate. In the short run, wages may increase more slowly but prices might not. Workers would therefore be more willing to cooperate with an incomes policy that partially compensated them for accepting, at least in the short run, lower real incomes than they would have earned in the absence of a TIP. Since a reward TIP provides such compensation, at least in part if not in full, it would be both more equitable and more acceptable to workers than a penalty TIP. Furthermore, a penalty TIP has other drawbacks. If levied against firms, it might increase the rate of inflation. Some of these firms would be able to pass on the cost of the TIP penalty to consumers, especially if the above-standard increase were industry-wide. Some prices therefore would rise as a result of the TIP. Levying the penalty on individuals rather than firms raises different objections. Such a 333-5H0 0 - 81 - 5 : QL 3 61 penalty TIP would occasionally penalize employees who received little or no pay increase but who worked for firms with large average pay raises. For such individuals, a penalty TIP would add injury to insult and would be perceived as very unfair. A penalty TIP would raise government revenues, which could be returned to the private sector through offsetting tax cuts. By contrast, a reward TIP would cost the Federal Government a substantial amount in forgone tax revenues. In practice, this means that a reward TIP would only be feasible when tax cuts were being considered. Since inflation and economic growth tend to drive up average effective tax rates, however, periodic tax reductions will be feasible if the share of Federal spending in GNP is kept from rising. Therefore, the key budgeting issue posed by a reward TIP is its effectiveness, compared to other forms of tax reduction, in meeting economic goals. One difficult problem that must be addressed in designing a TIP is the administrative burden it would impose on private firms and on the government. A TIP limited to a few thousand large firms with computerized personnel records would have much smaller public and private administrative costs than a TIP that included millions of small firms. But limiting a pay TIP to large firms seems very unlikely to secure the kind of support needed to enact and operate a successful incomes policy. A limited reward TIP would be vigorously opposed by workers in small firms, who would argue, rightly, that they were being deprived of a potential tax cut. But a limited penalty TIP would tend to reduce the real income of workers in large firms and would be vigorously opposed by large firms and large unions. A second issue in the design of a pay TIP is whether the penalty or reward should be a single amount based only on the wage increase being above or below the standard (hurdle TIP), or whether it should be graduated according to the difference between the standard and the actual increase (continuous TIP). A hurdle TIP only encourages firms and workers to have pay raises below the standard. It provides no direct incentive to lower pay raises that were already below the standard or, realistically, to reduce pay raises that were far above the standard. In contrast, a continuous TIP whose penalty or reward depended on the difference between the standard and the actual pay raise would provide an incentive to lower all pay increases. Lowering a pay raise that was above the standard would result in a smaller penalty. Lowering a pay raise that was already below the standard would mean a larger reward. The main advantage of a hurdle TIP is administrative. Under a hurdle TIP, firms that expected to grant pay raises above the stand- 62 ard or that thought the administrative costs of compliance were too high would not be required to keep records. In contrast, under a continuous TIP that penalized firms or workers above the standard as well as rewarded those below, all firms would have to keep detailed records and would have to file additional schedules with their tax returns. A reward-only continuous TIP would eliminate record-keeping requirements for noncomplying firms, and, as emphasized above, it would also be more equitable than a continuous TIP that included penalties. Such a TIP could offer tax credits, for instance, of 3, 2, or 1 percent of earnings, to employees of firms with average pay raises that did not exceed 50 percent, 75 percent, or 100 percent of the standard. However, even this simple continuous TIP would probably generate more disputes than a hurdle TIP, since firms would have incentives to understate their pay increases to appear to be in a lower bracket. Under a hurdle TIP, only firms near the standard would face such incentives. The final major issue in designing a TIP is whether it should be permanent or temporary. The answer seems to be that a permanent TIP would not be feasible because of the distortions it would create by discouraging changes in relative wages. A TIP might introduce further distortions as people changed their behavior to circumvent the intent of the policy while remaining technically in compliance with the standard. For a while the distortions created by a carefully designed TIP would probably be small. But as relative prices and wages wandered farther from equilibrium levels, the distortions would become larger and the effects on inflation smaller. The economic costs from the distortions of an effective temporary TIP would be acceptable when balanced against the larger costs of relying solely on demand restraint to lower inflation. Because the distortions would build up over time, however, the costs of a permanent TIP would eventually exceed benefits. On balance, given all the foregoing economic and administrative considerations, a temporary hurdle TIP—a tax credit to groups of workers whose average pay increase does not exceed a specified standard—seems superior to the other variants. Because keeping records and complying with the standard would be voluntary in this type of TIP, firms that found the administrative costs too high could choose not to participate. As with all forms of TIPs, relative wage changes could still occur in response to economic and other developments, although increases in excess of the standard would "cost" workers the TIP tax credit. The efficiency costs would be small at first, but over time the distortions of the TIP would rise and its effectiveness would fall. 63 Together with a "jawboning" campaign aimed at producing widespread compliance with the standard by lowering expectations of inflation, such a TIP could lower the rate of inflation. Without jawboning, the cost of inducing compliance among workers with anticipated pay raises far above the standard would be prohibitive. Even workers who expected pay raises near the standard might be reluctant to sacrifice part of a pay raise that might be built into future wages in exchange for a small tax credit that only lasted for 1 or 2 years. The major appeal of wage moderation is that if everyone cooperates by accepting a smaller wage increase, the lower nominal wage gains will be matched by lower price increases. Real wages will not fall, but inflation will. A TIP alone cannot provide sufficient economic incentives to make a low wage increase more attractive than a large one. However, with public appeals to moderation and clear evidence of fiscal and monetary restraint, a TIP can contribute to slowing the inflationary spiral. Costs and Effects of a Reward Pay TIP The preceding discussion concluded that the most desirable type of pay TIP would be a temporary hurdle type that provided a reward for keeping pay raises below the standard. To examine the possible usefulness of such a TIP in dampening inflation, the Council of Economic Advisers attempted to estimate the costs and effects of a reward TIP open to all employees, public and private. The reward was assumed to be a fixed percentage of wage income, up to the maximum social security wage base of $29,700. It was also assumed to be taxable and to be refundable to workers whose income tax liability was less than the reward. The average rate of wage increase in the absence of a TIP was assumed to be 9.7 percent. The probability that a group of workers would accept a wage increase at or below the standard was assumed to depend upon the size of the reward and the relationship of the group's potential wage increase to the standard. The smaller the potential wage increase relative to the standard and the greater the reward, the higher the probability of compliance. The results of this estimating procedure obviously depend very heavily on the specific relationships used to calculate the probabilities of compliance for various groups of workers. Since there is no historical experience on which to base these relationships, the estimates presented below are simply examples based upon a considered judgment of the issues. The costs, effects, and compliance rates that would result from various combinations of standards and rewards were estimated under the assumptions mentioned above. Illustrative combinations of standards and rewards at two levels of cost to the Federal budget are presented in Table 7. These estimates suggest three things. First, for a 64 given standard, as the reward and the cost rise, so does the reduction of wage inflation. Second, there is some tradeoff between standard and reward. That is, a program with a high standard and a low reward may cost the same as a program with a lower standard and higher reward. Third, for a given budgetary cost, a low-standard, highreward combination tends to be more effective in reducing wage inflation than a high-standard, low-reward combination. The selection of that combination may create a problem of credibility. A TIP that is relatively effective in restraining pay increases for a given cost will tend to have lower compliance rates than a program with a higher standard and lower reward but which has less of the desired effect on compensation. This happens because higher standards put more people in compliance who do not have to modify their wage behavior. TIPs TABLE 7 .—Estimated effects and compliance rates of various pay Standard — Reward (percent) Compliance rate (percent)* Effect on wage inflation (percentage points) $12 billion budgetary cost:2 7 7y 2 8 — 2Y2 _ 2V* 2 . 50 2 55 9 61.8 -0 93 54.6 59.8 65.3 -1.09 -1.01 -.91 87 -.79 $16 billion budgetary cost:2 7 7y2 8 - 3 2%. 2V2 . 1 2 Percent of workers in establishments that have an average pay raise less than or equal to standard. Net tax expenditure less reduction in Federal compensation. Federal Government pay increase assumed to comply with standard—reduced from assumed economy-wide wage increase in absence of pay TIP. Source: Council of Economic Advisers. A TIP should be judged not only on its initial impact, but on its full effect over a 2- or 3-year period. A TIP continued for 2 years with a reduced pay standard in the second year could make a significant contribution to lowering inflation. PRICE TIPS Experience with incomes policies here and abroad, including the pay and price standards, suggests that a pay TIP is easier to administer and likely to cause fewer distortions than a price TIP. Nevertheless, a price TIP may be a necessary complement to a pay TIP because restraints on pay alone, even with a reward TIP, might appear inequitable. Furthermore, a price TIP could speed up the effect of a pay TIP by shortening the lag between the lowering of pay increases and their effect on price increases. It would be unrealistic to set a single price standard for all firms. Productivity growth among industries varies substantially, as do changes in the prices of raw materials and other costs of production. 65 Recognizing this, CWPS in 1978 established a price deceleration standard which called for all firms to reduce the rate of their average price increases in the program year by one-half percentage point below their increases in a base period. Systematically different movements in productivity and other cost elements among firms and industries should be at least roughly reflected in their base year experience. CWPS found, however, that it had to permit firms to devise various ways of adjusting for uncontrollable cost increases and had to provide separate standards for certain industries, like retailing and food processing. For several reasons, prices are more difficult to measure than pay. In some industries, such as wholesale and retail trade, prices for the same item vary from week to week. Some firms also give quantity discounts, so that prices for the same item vary from customer to customer. Even if the price of each item did not fluctuate, a small store with only a few employees may sell thousands of different products. Such a firm might have little trouble with the paperwork necessary for a pay TIP, but a price TIP would probably be beyond its administrative capabilities. Furthermore, a price TIP would face problems posed by new products and quality change in old products. Since new products do not have old prices, no price increase can be calculated for them. Instead, a price standard might have to be based on the firm's average markup over input costs or on the prices of similar products sold by the same firm or other firms. A related issue is the treatment of quality changes. Disregarding these changes might be the best solution for a temporary price TIP, even though doing so would tend to discourage innovation. Alternatively, a program that exempted goods whose quality had changed, and therefore allowed price increases above the standard, would encourage minor product changes that did not really increase quality. Finally, products whose quality improved could be treated like new products, with price increases based on average markup or on the price changes of similar goods. A price TIP would have to allow firms to pass through to consumers certain increases in the cost of their inputs. For instance, a utility company could not be expected to keep price increases below a TIP standard for long if the price of the oil it used to generate electricity suddenly doubled. To treat the utility fairly, a price TIP would have to allow the firm to raise electricity prices to cover the increased cost of oil. The problem in designing a price TIP is to decide which costs should be granted exemptions, while still encouraging firms to substitute cheaper inputs for more expensive ones. Given the greater complexity of devising a workable price standard, a price TIP should probably levy penalties and be confined to 66 large firms. Even among large firms it may be desirable to exempt industries like retailing, in which competition is likely to keep average prices in reasonable relationship to costs. Market forces also make it unlikely that exempting small firms and competitive industries would lead to substantial inequities or to a failure to pass on to consumers the benefits of wage moderation. CONCLUSIONS There are no costless ways to reduce inflation. Using demand restraint alone imposes very large costs of forgone output and unemployment for modest reductions in inflation. A successful TIP can shift more of the effect of demand restraint from output to prices and thus can cut substantially the costs of reducing inflation. Although a TIP would itself impose administrative and efficiency costs on the economy, the costs for a short period of time would be small. They would surely be outweighed by the benefits in reduced inflation and lower unemployment that a TIP would bring. It is useful to distinguish between two broad types of TIP, each of which would have quite different economic objectives. The first would be a continuous TIP that would be made a permanent part of the tax code and that would set graduated rewards and penalties according to the size of a firm's wage (and possibly price) increases. Such a TIP would be an attempt to make a major and permanent change in the market system so as to encourage less inflationary wage and price behavior on the part of individual firms. This chapter has suggested that the administrative problems and the distortions introduced into the wage structure would tend to grow over time, while the effect on inflation would decline. Thus, the costs of a permanent wage TIP would soon exceed its anti-inflationary benefits. A second form would be a temporary hurdle TIP based on rewards for wage moderation and would be part of a broad public campaign for voluntary restraint in wage and price increases. The objective of such a TIP, perhaps applied for 2 successive years, would be to provide several downward shocks to the inflationary process, in effect reversing some of the upward shocks which contributed to today's inflation rate. Although such a TIP would also involve administrative costs and distortions in labor-market behavior, these costs would initially be far less than the benefits of the TIP in shortening the period of restraint and slow growth needed to reduce inflation. As emphasized earlier, a TIP cannot substitute for demand restraint. The latter must also be present; otherwise, any gains produced by a TIP are likely to vanish quickly under the pressure of excess demand. Since a reward TIP would reduce budget revenues like any other tax cut, it must fit into a budget plan that makes tax cuts possible. But if the growth of Federal spending is restrained, pe- 67 riodic tax reductions will be both feasible and necessary in the years ahead as inflation and economic growth push taxpayers into higher brackets and raise average effective tax rates. TIPs are novel, and most people are unfamiliar with either the opportunities they present or the difficulties they pose. It is therefore highly unlikely that a TIP could take effect in 1981. But it would be useful for the public in general, and the Congress in particular, to begin evaluating the pros and cons of TIPs so that when the time comes for the next round of Federal tax cuts a TIP program will be seriously considered. INCREASING INVESTMENT, SUPPLY, AND PRODUCTIVITY Economic policy must place greater emphasis on supply-oriented measures during the decade of the 1980s for a number of reasons. First, an increase in the growth of aggregate supply, and especially in the growth of productivity, can raise the growth of output and employment that is consistent with a steady reduction in inflation. Second, reducing this country's vulnerability to higher oil import bills will require a substantially increased investment in alternative energy sources over the next 10 years. Finally, even if inflation were not a problem, a speedup in the lagging rate of productivity growth would be essential to maintain the historic advance in our standard of living. The remainder of the chapter summarizes what has been happening to productivity in the United States and briefly examines some of the reasons why the rate of productivity growth has declined. It also examines the need to increase the share of national resources allocated to capital formation and the Administration's response to that need. Finally, it discusses the relationship between demand- and supply-side policies, and suggests how they must be integrated. PRODUCTIVITY Advances in productivity are the foundation of advances in our standard of living. Increases in output per worker lead to increases in real income. Healthy increases in productivity can free the funds needed to improve the conditions of disadvantaged groups while lessening the need for sacrifice elsewhere. Thus, when productivity growth declines, these other advances also are delayed. But expectations of a rising living standard persist. They perpetuate demands for real income gains which can no longer be met and which lead to inflationary increases in wages and to growth in government spending. Since the mid-1960s, the growth rate of labor productivity has been declining from its postwar highs. In recent years the decline has been so marked as to pose a major challenge to public policy. Be- 68 cause declining productivity growth brings with it prospects for slower improvement in our standard of living and contributes to inflation, a program to stimulate productivity growth must be a keystone of economic policy. Table 8 summarizes the postwar history of growth in productivity. The data show a gradual worsening of the productivity decline as time has passed, with the last few years showing sharp declines. While just completed revisions of the data may change the magnitude and timing of the slowdown, its existence and its costliness are unarguable. TABLE %.—Labor productivity growth, 1948-80 [Percent change per year] 1948 to 1965 Sector Private business sector.. Nonfarm 1965 to 1973 1973 to 1979 1978 IV to 1979 III to 1979 IV 1980 III 3.2 0.8 -0.9 -0.1 2.6 .6 -1.1 .1 Note.—Data relate to output per hour for atl persons. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Some of the decline in productivity results from the way we measure it. In particular, productivity measurement counts as an input the costs of governmental and private actions to ensure a cleaner environment, a healthier workplace, and safer consumer products, but it does not count the benefits of these actions as forms of output. It is difficult to interpret measures of productivity such as those in Table 8 without first distinguishing between changes caused by the business cycle and changes caused by longer-term factors. Because it is costly to hire or to fire, businesses typically do not reduce their work force proportionally when demand slackens or increase it proportionally when demand is expanding. Chart 4 presents the recent history of productivity growth after correction for these cyclical influences. As the chart vividly shows, productivity grew very slowly during most of the years since 1973, and on several occasions actually declined. It would not be surprising to discover that the slowdown has many causes. Measured productivity growth is a distillation of a number of changes and influences. Many researchers have been in agreement that a number of factors have contributed in roughly equal magnitude to the slowdown. These factors have been discussed in past Reports. In addition to increased governmental regulation, particular attention has focused on increases in energy prices, declines in the rate of growth of capital relative to labor, and decreases in spending on 69 Chart 4 Productivity Adjusted for Cyclical Variation PERCENT CHANGE FROM 4 QUARTERS EARLIER -1 - 2 I • •. I . • i I • • • I • . . Ii • . I • i • I . . . I i . . I .i. I M ) I i • i L i > I • i • I • i i I 1965 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 NOTE.—DATA ARE FOR PRIVATE NONFARM BUSINESS, ALL PERSONS. SOURCE: COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS. research and development. But there has also been widespread agreement that a large portion of the slowdown has not yet been explained. INVESTMENT NEEDS One of the causes of the decline in productivity growth has been the decline in growth of the capital stock relative to the labor force. Because a rising'share of capital formation has been devoted to adjustments to cope with higher energy prices and to complying with environmental and safety regulations, a diminishing fraction of investment has been available to effect gains in productivity. Although these developments may not have been the primary causes of the productivity slowdown, increasing capital formation would nevertheless be an effective way of reversing the slowdown. Many of the factors affecting productivity cannot be directly or immediately influenced by the government, but economic policy—especially tax policy—can influence the pace of capital formation. As a general rule, an increase in the amount of capital invested per worker is associated with an increase in output per worker—i.e., in increased productivity. There are two reasons for this. First, processes that generate more output per worker usually require more capital per worker, and second, increasing the ratio involves putting newer capital into place. The newer capital is likely to* embody more ad- 70 vanced technology and will therefore increase the efficiency of the capital stock. During the decade of the 1960s the capital-labor ratio grew at an average rate of about 3 percent per year; over the last 5 years, however, the ratio has remained roughly constant. This development has been due to both the slower growth in the capital stock and to the more rapid growth in employment and hours worked (Table 9). The 1974-79 deceleration in the growth of capital is somewhat at odds with the rough stability in the investment share of GNP over the same period and requires some explanation. A greater share of investment is now being spent on relatively short-lived assets. The ratio of investment in equipment to investment in nonresidential structures has increased in recent years. The result is that each dollar of gross investment now yields less net investment because the capital stock is depreciating more rapidly. TABLE 9.—The investment share, and growth in the capital-labor ratio, 1949-79 Percent change, average annual rate (end of year to end of year) Real business fixed investment as percent of1 real Net capital Capital- CapitalGNP stock EmployHours3 employhours (nonresi-s ment 3 ment ratio dential) ratio Period 1949-59 9.1 4.0 1.1 0.7 2.9 3.2 9.8 4.6 1.6 1.2 3.0 3.3 1969-74 10.5 4.2 1.2 .5 2.9 3.7 1974-79 10.3 3.0 3.1 2.8 -.1 .2 1959-69 .... 1 Average annual investment-GNP ratio, in percent. Net fixed nonresidential business capital, 1972 dollars, end of year. For private business, all persons. End of year calculated as average of year's fourth quarter and following year's first quarter. Sources: Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic, Analysis) and Department of Labor (Bureau of Labor Statistics). 2 3 To restore the growth of the capital stock per worker to that of the 1960s would require that the share of investment in GNP rise by at least 1 percentage point from its recent average of about 10 Vz percent. Such a development should, at a minimum, restore the productivity growth lost from this source. Further improvement would require yet more investment. Apart from the necessity of improving the productivity growth rate, there are other reasons why future economic policy should encourage increased investment. Last year's Report discussed these needs in detail. The average age of the capital stock at the end of 1979 was 7.1 years. This suggests that much of our plant and equipment was put in place when oil prices were much lower than they are now. Higher energy prices have shortened the service life of older and less energy-efficient capital and made it in the national interest to speed up its replacement. The magnitude of these investments is difficult to 71 estimate, but it could represent perhaps another 1 percent of GNP per year. Additional investment requirements arise from the need to continue domestic production of oil, coal, and natural gas at sharply higher investment costs per unit of energy produced, and to expand the investment devoted to alternative energy sources. Conservatively estimated, they amount to about another one-half percent of GNP. During the late 1960s and early 1970s, before the first surge in oil prices, real business fixed investment averaged about lOVfe percent of GNP. In 1978-79, the investment share averaged slightly higher, around 10% percent, probably reflecting additional investment in the energy industries. On the basis of a rough judgment, continuation of investment in the neighborhood of 10y2 percent of GNP would meet the "normal" requirements of a moderately growing economy and hold the capital stock per worker approximately constant, as it has been in the past 5 years. But it would not provide for an expansion of capital per worker or for the Nation's increased needs for energy investment. Meeting these objectives will require substantial additional investment. Since the growth of aggregate demand and total GNP will be constrained in the years immediately ahead by the need to reduce inflation, the extra investment cannot come from additional GNP growth but will have to displace consumption or government spending, the other major components of GNP. According to the estimates presented earlier, the share that investment takes in total output will have to rise substantially from a normally expected lOVa percent or so to 12V2 to 13 percent, and the combined share of consumption and government spending will have to fall by a corresponding amount. It is virtually certain that such a large increase in the investment share will not be forthcoming without deliberate government policies. The major elements of such a policy lie in a combination of Federal tax measures and expenditure control. In the future, Federal personal tax receipts will take a steadily increasing share of personal income as inflation pushes taxpayers into higher brackets. As oil prices are decontrolled, revenues will be transferred from purchasers—who will pay the higher prices—to the Federal Government through the windfall profits tax. For both of these reasons the ratio of taxes to GNP will tend to rise and the growth of consumption will be depressed. If Federal expenditures are controlled so that their share of GNP does not rise, periodic tax reductions will be possible. Indeed, they will be necessary to prevent even moderate economic growth from being choked off. If a sizable fraction of those tax reductions are of a kind which concentrate on encouraging investment 72 rather than restoring the growth of consumption, the share of investment in GNP can be raised. Of course, if the share of Federal expenditures in GNP is not merely stabilized but reduced, the room for increasing the investment share of GNP through investment-oriented tax cuts will be even larger. Within this framework, tax reductions designed to increase the share of investment in GNP must meet two requirements: They must increase the demand for investment goods, and simultaneously they must increase saving—i.e., they should not increase consumption. These two requirements are closely related, but they are not the same. There are a number of measures that might seek to increase saving but have little if any effect on the volume of business investment. Forgoing tax cuts, letting effective tax rates increase, and creating a large Federal budget surplus, for example, would appear to be one way of increasing national saving. Although such a policy would make possible a decline in interest rates, it would also create a substantial fiscal drag, reduce economic growth and private saving, and probably yield no increase in business investment spending. Conversely, measures that increase investment demand without making room for it with an increase in saving will yield an excessive growth in total demand and renewed inflationary pressure. Both aspects of the problem are important. Given the determinants of investment, what tax policies can best increase the demand for investment goods? What form of tax reductions are most likely to be channeled into saving rather than consumption? INVESTMENT DETERMINANTS AND INFLATION Expectations about future growth are critical in determining the volume of investment demand for the economy as a whole. But the essence of the earlier discussion was that investment needs to increase by more than the amount that would be associated simply with a normal expansion of output. A number of factors influence the amount of capital that firms want to use to produce a given amount of output. Chief among them are the attractiveness of the return on capital investment as compared with other uses of investors' funds, the perceived riskiness of corporate investment, and the cost and availability of capital. One lesson that has been learned in recent years is the deleterious effect of inflation on investment. High inflation rates increase the perceived riskiness of investment, and this increased uncertainty makes planning for future capital needs more difficult. The information about relative demand that is contained in price changes becomes clouded when inflation is high. In addition, increasing rates of inflation are ordinarily accompanied by the expectation of sharply 73 higher interest rates and monetary stringency. The expected slowing of growth in demand reduces the incentive to add capacity. But by far the most important effect of inflation on investment is its impact on tax accounting provisions and depreciation allowances. Depreciation is a cost of earning income from fixed capital assets. This cost is the reduced value of the asset due to use, aging, and obsolescence. The depreciation allowed for tax purposes is based on the historical cost of an asset. When inflation occurs, allowable depreciation is reduced relative to the cost of replacing the asset at today's price. Inflation therefore raises the tax on capital and reduces the rate of return on investment, and this problem worsens as the rate of inflation increases. The inflation-induced increase in the tax on income from business plant and equipment is partly offset by the inflation-induced reduction in the tax burden of borrowers. Firms are allowed to charge the full value of their interest payments against income, even though a portion of these higher interest payments amounts to the repayment of real capital to lenders. The effect on the return to investment of this "excess" deduction varies with the proportion of investment that is debt-financed. It also varies with the extent to which inflation is reflected in interest rates. Since an important part of investment is not debt-financed, it is clear that inflation's tax-increasing impact on the value of depreciation allowances outweighs the tax-decreasing impact of excess deductions on the return to business investment. Some have suggested that the inflation-induced distortion of tax depreciation could be corrected by indexing the value of existing business assets to allow replacement—rather than historical—cost depreciation. But indexing the value of assets would ignore the interest rate offset described in the prior paragraph. Moreover, as with all indexing schemes its administrative and accounting problems would be quite severe, and almost any simple index imaginable would introduce distortions of its own. For these and other reasons, indexing is not an attractive means of correcting the inflation-induced distortion in depreciation allowances. TAX MEASURES TO INCREASE INVESTMENT Policymakers have three principal measures to influence investment through the tax system: changes in depreciation allowances, changes in the investment tax credit, and changes in the corporate income tax rate. Since the effect of inflation in depressing the value of depreciation is such an obvious factor in the recent decline in after-tax rates of return on capital assets, the liberalization of depreciation allowances is an attractive way to enhance investment. It not only provides an overall incentive for investment but, if carefully designed, it can also 74 correct some of the distortions in investment that accompany inflation. Under proposals for accelerated depreciation, the allowable depreciation on capital assets would be increased. This would permit firms to write off their capital purchases faster. The changes would affect two determinants of business investment. First, they would increase the after-tax yield of capital investment, and thus its attractiveness. Second, they would increase business cash flow and thereby supply a portion of the funds needed to finance additional investment. Increases in the investment tax credit would have a similar impact on investment incentives. The investment tax credit reduces the purchase price of eligible equipment. It thus provides a direct incentive by raising net return and by increasing after-tax cash flow. A reduction in corporate income tax rates, on the other hand, influences investment by increasing after-tax profits. This tends to be a less effective stimulus to investment than either accelerated depreciation or increases in the investment tax credit because it has a smaller impact on the net return from new purchases of capital assets. In addition, depreciation liberalization or an increased investment tax credit are only available to a firm to the extent it invests, but a corporate tax reduction would be available whether investment is undertaken or not. The President's Economic Revitalization Program contains several elements that would significantly improve the outlook for business investment by offering direct incentives to invest in new plant and equipment as well as support for business cash flow. The two major investment incentives in the program are expansion in the coverage of the investment tax credit and a simplified and liberalized form of depreciation allowances. The proposed changes in the investment tax credit would allow firms to claim full credit for all equipment purchases, even shortlived assets that currently are allowed only a portion of the tax credit. In addition, the investment tax credit would be made partially refundable. Under the current law, the credit can be used to offset the first $25,000 of tax liabilities plus up to 70 percent (rising to 90 percent by 1982) of liabilities in excess of $25,000. But the proposed change would allow firms to claim 30 percent of the value of the credit even if they had no tax liabilities for the year. In this way, firms with substantial investment needs but with little or no current earnings would be supported in their efforts to rejuvenate and expand their capital assets. Among these are both younger and smaller firms that are just beginning to grow and larger industries undergoing transition, such as autos and steel. 75 The proposal for tax depreciation—the Constant Rate Depreciation (CRD) proposal—would allow firms to accelerate depreciation on new equipment and new structures. Under this proposal, the rate of depreciation allowable over the life of the typical capital asset would be roughly 40 percent larger. In addition, the CRD proposal would greatly simplify depreciation accounting. The President's proposed depreciation reforms share certain common features with two recent tax proposals: the bill reported by the Senate Finance Committee last fall, and the so-called "10-5-3" proposal. Both proposals would liberalize depreciation allowances by shortening the tax life of capital investments. Both would also simplify business accounting by significantly reducing the number of asset categories that firms would have to keep track of. There are important differences, however. In the President's proposal the reductions in tax life have been designed so that there would be, on average, a similar increase in depreciation allowances across all kinds of assets. The "10-5-3" proposal provides very large increases in the allowed depreciation for longer-lived assets but little or no change in the depreciation allowed for many shorter-lived assets. The tax life for structures would be reduced from an average 30-35 years to just 10 years, but, for example, automobile purchases would be allowed a lifetime of 3 years, exactly the same as under current tax laws. Because the "10-5-3" proposal would grant uneven benefits across asset types, the demand for investment goods would be significantly skewed from what would be dictated by economic considerations alone. In addition, the "10-5-3" proposal includes a complex phasein schedule that may have the perverse effect of delaying capital investment. Late in the last session of the Congress, the Senate Finance Committee reported a tax bill which also included a depreciation proposal. The Committee's bill would have established a limited number of asset classes with shorter tax lives than under current law. While the Committee's proposal differed from the open-end accounting of depreciation embodied in the President's proposal, its impact on the value of depreciation and on investment incentives would have been closer to that of the President's approach than is the "10-5-3" proposal. THE IMPACT OF THE ADMINISTRATION'S INVESTMENT INCENTIVES The investment tax credit and depreciation proposals in the Economic Revitalization Program would reduce the cost of capital to firms by roughly 5 percent and increase corporate cash flow by $9 billion during 1981 through reduced tax liabilities. By 1985 the increases in cash flow would total nearly $30 billion annually. It is anticipated that business fixed investment will be 5 to 10 percent 76 higher than it would otherwise be by the end of 1982, with smaller additional gains thereafter. These estimates are derived from statistical relationships which link business investment demand not only with investment incentives, such as accelerated depreciation or increases in the investment tax credit, but also with expected capacity needs and demands for output. According to the historical experience which underlies these estimates, increases in investment demand can be affected by accelerated depreciation even when capacity utilization is relatively low—as it is forecast to be over the near term (Chapter 3). Indeed, the recent historical evidence offers additional support for the view that investment spending could proceed at a rapid pace without extraordinary tightness in industrial capacity. During 1976, the first full year of growth following the 1974-75 recession, real business fixed investment grew 5.3 percent despite the relatively low (79.5 percent) rate of manufacturing capacity utilization during that year. In the following year, growth in real business fixed investment was 11.9 percent, while the utilization rate rose to only 81.9 percent. SAVING Any increase in the investment share of GNP must be accompanied by a corresponding increase in the saving share of GNP. Total national saving comes from three sources: individuals save out of their personal income; businesses retain, and thereby save, some of their profit income; and governments save when they run a budget surplus, or dissave when they run a budget deficit. It is total national saving that supports total investment. A portion of saving flows into residential investment, investment in inventories, and net foreign investment. The remainder is available to finance business purchases of plant and equipment. The Federal Government has numerous policy options for changing the level of national saving and thereby supporting a higher level of aggregate investment. But it is important to realize that no one sector works in isolation. A given sector's increase in saving may be partially or fully offset by another sector's dissaving. Personal tax cuts designed to increase specific types of saving, such as an increase in the amount of tax-free interest from passbook savings accounts, are likely to be the least effective ways to increase total saving. They will increase the flow of saving into those instruments whose after-tax returns have been raised, but they will do so primarily at the expense of those forms of household saving whose after-tax returns have not been raised. They will reshuffle personal saving but increase its amount very little. General reductions in personal tax rates would increase personal income, which would itself lead to higher saving. In addition, the 333-540 0 - 8 1 - 6 : QL 3 77 higher after-tax return on saving may induce still further increases in saving. This is more likely to occur if the personal tax cuts are directed at higher-income individuals who tend to save relatively more of their additional after-tax income. But there is substantial evidence that, in any case, the personal saving rate responds very little to changes in rates of return or in the tax structure. A large part of the personal tax reduction would therefore go toward increasing consumption. The most effective avenue at the disposal of the Federal Government to increase the volume of saving is to reduce taxes on business income. Cuts in business taxes would lower government saving, but a large part of the tax cut would flow into business saving. Business after-tax cash flow would be increased. In time, part of the increased cash flow would lead to higher corporate dividends. A very large part, however, would be allocated to an increase in retained earnings—i.e., saving. Evidence suggests, for example, that corporations save more than 50 cents from every additional dollar of after-tax income. Furthermore, some portion of any dividend increase would find its way into personal saving. By contrast, giving the tax cut directly to households would have a smaller effect on saving because households are likely to save a much smaller fraction of every dollar of additional disposable income. It seems wise, then, to focus government efforts on the sector most likely to allocate a large part of any tax relief to saving—business. A business tax cut would result in relatively large saving, and incentives to expand investment demand would simultaneously be improved. It is this approach that lies at the heart of the President's Economic Revitalization Program. THE INTEGRATION OF DEMAND-SIDE AND SUPPLY-SIDE POLICIES Tax reductions which induce additional saving and investment will contribute to faster productivity growth, and this in turn will help reduce inflation. A number of critical questions arise, however, in determining the appropriate type, magnitude, and timing of any tax reductions. First, what kind of an increase in productivity might reasonably be expected from investment-oriented tax cuts of various sizes, and what would be the associated reduction in inflation? Second, to what extent would the improvements in productivity and other supply-creating aspects of a tax reduction offset the increase in aggregate demand they would cause? More generally, how would tax cuts aimed at increasing supply fit into the framework of fiscal restraint that is required to reduce inflation? 78 EXPECTED PRODUCTIVITY GAINS Although the effect on investment from a given loss of tax revenues would vary with the form of the reduction (accelerated depreciation, larger investment tax credit, or lower corporate income tax rates), the evidence suggests that each dollar of reduction in annual business taxes might, at the outside and after several years, generate slightly more than a dollar in business fixed investment. To increase investment by 10 percent, a business tax reduction of at least $30 billion—or about 1 percent of GNP—would be necessary. This larger volume of investment, maintained from 1981 through 1985, would increase the capital stock by about 5 percent after allowing for depreciation. On the basis of the historical relationships between output and capital, such an addition to the capital stock might generate a total increase in the level of productivity of at most 1.5 percent by 1985, or about 0.3 percent per year. In view of the declining rate of productivity growth which the Nation has experienced in recent years, however, this small improvement would be significant. Such a rise in the productivity growth rate would not be likely to induce a faster rise in money wage demands. Therefore, since the growth of unit labor costs is equal to the increase in compensation per hour minus the rate of growth in productivity, the faster productivity growth rate should lead to a slower rise in costs and prices. In turn, a slower rise in prices would help to reduce the growth of wages, leading to a still further slowdown of inflation. All told, an investment-oriented tax cut amounting to about 1 percent of GNP might produce a 0.3 percentage point rise in productivity growth that would translate, after several years, to just over one-half percentage point reduction in the inflation rate. DEMAND VERSUS SUPPLY RESPONSES TO TAX CUTS Tax reductions have two principal effects. On the one hand, individuals and firms will buy more goods and services. As a tax cut is spent and respent throughout the economy, the resulting increase in nominal GNP will exceed the original tax cut. As a result of this multiplier process, aggregate demand will rise by more than the tax cut. But tax cuts also increase the supply of goods and services. Since lower tax rates allow individuals and firms to keep a larger fraction of their income after taxes, the lower rates affect incentives to work, to save, and to invest the savings, increasing potential GNP. Although the magnitude of the multiplier varies according to the nature of the tax cut, aggregate demand typically rises by about twice the size of a reduction in taxes. Thus, a tax cut equal to 1 percent of GNP will increase aggregate demand by about 2 percent. To match the increase in demand, a 2 percent increase in supply would also be 79 required. To the extent that its supply response is less than the additional demand it creates, any tax reduction adds to the pressures of demand on the rate of inflation. But there are two ways in which such tax cuts can be made while still restraining demand. First, tax reductions may offset increases in other taxes. As discussed earlier, inflation pushes taxpayers into higher tax brackets, so that the average effective tax rate—the ratio of tax revenues to GNP—rises. Consumption is depressed and economic growth reduced. In the years ahead, periodic tax reductions will therefore be both possible and necessary to keep aggregate demand from falling. Second, a tax reduction accompanied by Federal spending reductions of roughly the same magnitude will not change aggregate demand; hence, even if the supply response to a tax cut is smaller than the demand response, inflationary pressures will not be generated. Thus, it is clear that the design and timing of supply-oriented tax cuts depend importantly on the specific relationship between the demand-side and supply-side responses. If such tax reductions fail to generate enough supply to offset the additional demand they create—and the evidence discussed below suggests this to be the case, particularly for personal tax reductions—they must then be integrated like any tax cut into policies of demand management. THE SUPPLY-SIDE RESPONSE TO PERSONAL TAX CUTS A 10 percent reduction in marginal tax rates on individuals (approximately a $30-billion personal tax cut in 1981) would increase the total demand for goods and services by $60 billion, or 2 percent of GNP. It could also lead to increases in individual work and saving in response to the lower tax rates and thereby increase potential GNP. How much of the increase in demand would be matched by such increases in supply? The Supply of Labor The additional production that results from lowering taxes on labor income depends both on changes in the quantity of labor supplied (i.e., the total number of hours worked) and on changes in the average productivity of labor. Higher after-tax wages make work more attractive. This encourages new entrants to join the labor force and those already employed to work longer hours. Since after-tax incomes have risen, however, people can also afford to work less—to take longer vacations or to shorten their workweeks. Whether the former effect would or would not exceed the latter effect is hard to predict. A preponderance of the evidence suggests that for adult men the two effects approximately offset each other; that is, a cut in income taxes increases the 80 supply of adult men in the work force only slightly, if at all. Women, on the other hand, and particularly married women, respond much more strongly to higher wages. In the past, the number of adult women in the work force may have increased by as much as 1 percent for every 1 percent increase in take-home pay. Although women are more responsive to changes in their wages than are men, men still outnumber women in the labor force and on average earn substantially more. Therefore, a reduction in personal income tax rates would increase the total supply of labor only slightly. Whether an increase in the labor supply would be accompanied by an increase in productivity is uncertain. While most business investment enhances productivity, an increase in the labor supply would not improve productivity unless it increased the average quality of work performed or the intensity of effort. Productivity might actually fall as the supply of labor increased if the additional labor supply consisted, on balance, of less skilled or less experienced workers. Alternatively, some have argued that the increased supply of labor from high-income, high-productivity workers would outweigh the increased supply from other workers, so that the average productivity of the labor force would rise. This could happen if high-productivity workers were more sensitive to a given percentage change in aftertax earnings, or if the tax reduction represented a larger percentage change in their take-home pay. Since high-income workers are a small fraction of the labor force, these influences would have to be large to alter total productivity significantly. Studies of high-income workers generally do not find them much more responsive to equal percentage increases in after-tax income. However, a 10 percent across-the-board reduction in tax rates would also mean a larger percentage increase in the after-tax earnings for these workers because their households are in high marginal tax brackets. A 10 percent tax cut is, therefore, likely to produce a somewhat larger change in the supply of high-income workers. Still, even in high-income households it is in fact second-income earners—generally those who have lower productivity—who are apt to be the most responsive to lower tax rates. Balancing the two opposing forces—the lack of experience of new workers and the possibility of a greater-than-average influx of higherincome workers—it seems unwise to assume that the average productivity of the labor force will be improved by a personal tax cut. Taking all the relevant factors into account, the limited response of the supply of labor and of productivity to a 10 percent reduction in personal income tax rates is likely to produce an increase in potential GNP of perhaps 0.2 percent to at most 0.6 percent. This result follows in part from evidence suggesting that such a tax cut would 81 induce an increase in labor supply between 0.3 and 1.0 percent. According to past relationships between labor and production, such an increase in labor supply would lead to the modest increase in potential GNP mentioned above. The Supply of Saving A reduction in personal income tax rates increases both the income out of which an individual worker can save and the after-tax return to saving. It would also tend to discourage borrowing by reducing the value of the income tax deduction for interest payments. If the increases in personal saving find their way into additional business investment, productivity will rise. Most empirical studies have concluded that changes in personal income tax rates would have only a small effect on personal saving. At best, a 10 percent reduction in tax rates would increase personal saving less than 3 percent. This means that the saving rate—the average share of personal saving in disposable income, which over the last 5 years has averaged 5.7 percent—would rise by no more than 0.2 percentage point. The additional saving would at most be equivalent to only about 0.2 percent of GNP. Even if every dollar of personal saving that resulted from a 10 percent tax cut were invested in business plant and equipment—and some, in fact, would flow into housing—the effects on output and on productivity would be small. If the tax cut and the higher saving continued for 5 years, the additional saving and investment would increase potential GNP by less than 0.3 percent and lead to a negligible increase in the annual rate of productivity growth. This examination of likely responses thus suggests that even under the most optimistic circumstances, a 10 percent reduction in tax rates would not induce enough additional work, saving, or investment to offset more than a fraction of the 2 percent increase in aggregate demand that would accompany the tax cut. BUSINESS TAX CUTS It was pointed out earlier that a tax cut that liberalized the business depreciation allowance or increased the investment tax credit could, after a time, have a fairly substantial effect on the Nation's productive potential. Such a tax cut, amounting to 1 percent of GNP, could raise potential output by perhaps \xk percent over a 5-year period. This would still be less than the 2 percent rise in aggregate demand that would also be generated, however. More important, the increase in demand would come relatively quickly, most of it within lVa to 2 years. The increase in supply, on the other hand, would occur very gradually. As a consequence, the tax cut would tend to 82 increase demand pressures, especially in the years immediately following it. While tax reductions that are effective in raising investment are essential in a long-term strategy to promote economic growth, business tax cuts, like personal tax cuts, must be designed to fit into an overall framework of fiscal restraint. CONCLUSIONS This analysis of the macroeconomic effects of Federal tax reductions suggests several conclusions for the development of fiscal policy: First, specific investment-oriented tax reductions for business are likely to increase saving, investment, and productivity by a much more significant degree than cuts in personal income taxes. Second, productivity-oriented tax reductions will yield improvements in the inflation rate that are helpful and significant, but still relatively modest in the context of a 10 percent underlying inflation rate. Third, the supply response, while a critically important feature of any tax reduction, will be substantially less than the demand response, particularly in the short run. Fourth, since reductions in both business and personal taxes will increase demand faster than supply, they must be designed and carried out in ways that are consistent with the demand restraint needed to reduce inflation. It is sometimes alleged that the potentially inflationary effects of a large tax cut can be avoided if the Federal Reserve steadfastly pursues its goal of keeping the growth of the monetary aggregates within tight targets. But if taxes are reduced while the Federal Reserve pursues an unchanged monetary policy, aggregate demand will nevertheless increase, especially in the short run. The increase in demand would lead to a rise in interest rates that would dampen the increase in aggregate demand but not eliminate it. Additional inflationary pressure would then result. A very large tax cut unaccompanied by the necessary spending cuts would lead to both an increase in inflation and a sharp rise in interest rates. Some, and perhaps all, of the stimulus to investment from tax reductions would be undone by the higher interest rates and the greater uncertainty engendered by a new round of inflation. Monetary restraint is an absolutely essential element of inflation control and reduction. Tax measures focused on increasing supply can make a significant contribution. But there will be a continuing need for careful and prudent fiscal policies to restrain demand. In recent years the Nation has come to appreciate the potential value of supply-oriented tax policies. In the process of learning some needed lessons about supply-side economics, however, the Nation cannot 83 afford to forget its hard-learned lessons about the need for demandside restraint. The three central elements of a macroeconomic policy to reduce inflation and advance the Nation's prospects for healthy economic growth have been set forth in this chapter: maintaining a persistent and prudent course of demand restraint; putting in place an improved incomes policy using tax incentives to induce wage moderation; and increasing the share of the Nation's output going to investment. The next chapter deals with the challenge of inflation and growth at the level of individual markets and sectors. It concentrates on measures to increase the economy's flexibility and capacity for adjusting to change. Carrying out these policies will require patience and, in the interim, some sacrifice. But if they are followed with persistence they promise a substantial payoff in improved economic performance. TECHNICAL APPENDIX TO CHAPTER 1 MEASURING PAY INCREASES UNDER A TIP Once the basic features of a pay TIP have been chosen, several problems in the measurement of average pay increases must be solved. These problems arise from changes in the composition of a firm's work force, from fringe benefits, and from multiyear union contracts with cost-of-living adjustments. Resolving these problems requires striking a balance among administrative convenience, equity, efficiency, and the effect on inflation. COMPOSITION OF THE WORK FORCE Like any well-designed tax, a successful TIP must use a measure of average pay increase that is unambiguous, that alters behavior in undesirable ways as little as possible, and that is fair in its treatment of different types of firms and workers. The simplest indicator of average pay—total wages received by a group of workers divided by the total number of hours they work—is a poor measure because it changes both with hourly wage rates and with the number of overtime hours. Even if wage rates increased by less than the TIP standard, an increase in the average amount of overtime, paid at a premium, could put the group out of compliance. Using this measure would therefore discourage overtime work, an undesirable distortion. A better measure would use straight-time wages divided by straighttime hours, with adjustments to reflect changes in the length of the standard workweek or the size of the overtime premium. Because of possible changes in the composition of the group, however, a simple measure of straight-time wages divided by straight- 84 time hours also has drawbacks. For example, during a recession a firm may grant a pay raise far below the TIP standard and also lay off large numbers of low-seniority workers. Because low-seniority workers tend to have below-average wages, the remaining workers will have higher wages than the original group. Consequently, this measure of wage change may well show that the increase in average pay exceeded the standard even if no individual worker received such a large raise. Conversely, when firms hire additional low-seniority, low-wage workers during expansion, the group may appear to be in compliance even if all continuing workers receive pay raises above the standard. This measure is also affected by changes in the skill-mix of the work force. If a firm increases the proportion of low-wage, less skilled workers in its work force, the measure will show a calculated wage increase less than the "true" wage increase. A decrease in the proportion of less skilled workers will show just the opposite. Because of these features, the measure also discriminates in favor of growing firms and against declining firms, since new workers are, on average, likely to be paid less than those already on the payroll. More important, this measure introduces an element of uncertainty. A firm could agree with its workers to grant pay increases that met the standard—citing the TIP reward as an offsetting factor—and then unexpectedly discover at the end of the year that small changes in the composition of the work force had put the group out of compliance. Firms and workers who had negotiated small pay raises in anticipation of receiving a TIP reward or avoiding a penalty might find themselves above the standard, while others who had ignored the standards could be surprised to find themselves in compliance. An unpredictable measure is not only unfair; it also will have less effect, since firms and workers will tend to ignore the standard if they cannot be sure that small pay raises will result in compliance. Data collected by the Bureau of Labor Statistics from a large sample of establishments suggest that significant changes in the composition of a firm's work force are common. As Table 10 shows, 22 percent of the workers in the motor vehicle industry were in establishments that experienced an increase in their calculated straighttime hourly earnings of more than 13 percent between December 1978 and December 1979. During this period the United Auto Workers' contract, which covered a majority of the workers in these establishments, provided for an increase of about 11 percent, including cost-of-living adjustments (COLAs). Therefore, most of the establishments with increases in calculated average hourly earnings larger than this must have experienced a change in the composition of their work force. 85 TABLE 10.—Distribution of workers by percentage change in average establishment wage, selected manufacturing industries, December 1978 to December 1979 Percentage change in average establishment wage All manufacturing Motor vehicles Food processing Percent distribution 5.1 Less than 0 . 5.9 8.5 0 to 6.9 18.6 7.8 24.8 7 0 to 9 9 27.4 19.3 28.6 10.0 to 12.9 25.4 44.8 17.8 17.2 13.7 13.2 6.3 8.5 7.1 13.0 to 19.9.. . .. 20 and over Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Additional evidence suggesting large shifts in the composition of the work force is provided by the percentage of workers in establishments who experienced actual declines in their average nominal wage. For all manufacturing, 5.1 percent of workers were in establishments that reported declining money wage rates, and 8.5 percent of those in food processing were in establishments that reported nominal wage declines. It is hard to believe that such a large percentage of workers were in establishments that actually cut the average nominal wage for their entire work force during a period in which the CPI rose by 13.3 percent. Clearly, a satisfactory measure of wage changes will be one that is not affected by systematic changes in work force composition. The problem can be solved either by a wage index or by a measure that counts only the hours and payroll for those workers who were with the firm throughout the year. A wage index, like a price index, combines the wage rates for specific types of jobs into one measure. The weights used reflect the percentage of a firm's workers in each skill or seniority level. A wage index reflects the "true" average pay increase for all employees and is not affected by changes in composition or seniority. Such an index would be relatively easy to construct for many firms. Union contracts already set wage rates for specific jobs. Some large nonunion firms and many States and local governments also have pay scales that list the salary levels of workers in each job category and seniority step. These union and nonunion pay scales could be used with the base period percentages of workers in each job category to calculate a firm's average pay raise, just as a price index is used along with a base period market basket of goods to measure price increases. To ensure that the firms did not give raises above the standard by promoting workers, rates of promotion above past experience would be included in the calculation of pay raises. Doing so, of course, may 86 reintroduce the problem of changing skill mix if the additional promotions reflect an upgrading of skills. Nonunion firms that do not have pay scales could calculate their average pay raise from the wages and hours of those workers who continued to work for the firm throughout the year. Such a measure would not be affected by changes in the composition of the work force, since the wage rates of former or new employees would not enter into the calculation. Because firms generally hire new workers at the bottom and retire or lose workers from the top, the average pay raise for continuing workers will exceed the average pay raise for all workers in a firm with stable composition but high turnover. Therefore, measures for continuing workers must be adjusted to allow for promotions. MEASURING FRINGE BENEFITS A critical element in the measurement of pay increases is the treatment of fringe benefits. The cost of a given package of fringe benefits can increase for either of two reasons: because the package has become more generous (the employer is buying more services for the employees) or because the price of a given set of services has risen. For example, an employer who adds dental benefits onto the health insurance provided for employees would increase the cost of health insurance by improving the package of benefits. Health insurance premiums might also rise for a given set of benefits simply because medical care in general becomes more expensive. Which increases in the costs of fringe benefits should the TIP include as increases in compensation? One approach is to include all increases in the cost of fringe benefits, both those that reflect higher prices for a fixed package as well as those that reflect improvements in the package. This would treat each dollar paid in fringe benefits exactly like a dollar paid in cash wages. Such an approach, however, would require extensive work to evaluate the cost of all benefits. Although determining the cost of fringe benefits purchased from other organizations, such as medical insurance, would be simple, determining the cost of other fringes, like unfunded pension benefits, would be more difficult. Another drawback is that firms and workers might object to being ruled out of compliance for cost changes they could not control, such as the cost of employer health plans. An alternative treatment would be to exclude fringe benefits completely from the calculation of a group's average pay raise. This would involve the fewest administrative problems. It would, however, provide a strong incentive for firms to give all increases above the standard in the form of fringes rather than cash, since the group would be in compliance as long as cash remuneration did not increase by more than the standard. This would defeat the purpose of 87 the TIP and would also distort the structure of labor compensation for a long period. A compromise solution would be to include only the cost of improvements in benefit packages. For example, the cost of new medical benefits would be charged against the standard but increases in the cost of existing benefits would not. This would reduce the difficulty of estimating the costs of some types of fringes without creating an incentive to divert all pay increases above the standard into benefit improvements. Although fringes would still be treated more generously than cash wages, this compromise would eliminate a certain amount of paperwork. MULTIYEAR CONTRACTS A third problem in measuring wage increases is the evaluation of new multiyear union contracts. A TIP will have its greatest effect on the wage settlement if the firm and union know when they are bargaining whether the contract's provisions are in compliance with the standard. For this reason, and to prevent firms and unions from postponing large wage increases to the later years of a contract in order to be in compliance during the first year, the entire contract would have to be evaluated in advance. Since most major union contracts include COLAs, evaluating wage increases in new multiyear contracts requires predicting future price inflation. (A TIP can have no direct effect on pay increases in existing multiyear union contracts. Therefore, they can be evaluated at year-end like the pay increases of nonunion workers.) Because the number chosen will affect expectations and thus will affect the success of the TIP, there may could be a temptation to use an overly optimistic prediction of future price increases. If this occurred, union workers with COLAs would often be judged to be in compliance but then receive wage increases above the standard because the actual price increase exceeded the prediction used to evaluate the COLA. This would seem unfair to firms and workers who do not have COLAs and, if substantial, would set in motion catch up pressures on the part of nonunion workers that could increase inflation in subsequent years. To some extent, these considerations are counterbalanced by the fact that union workers would have to restrain their wage increases for a 2- or 3-year contract period in order to be in compliance with a TIP that may only last 1 year. 88 CHAPTER 2 Improving the Adaptability of the Economy THE PAST DECADE witnessed a substantial expansion of Federal involvement in many sectors of the economy. During this period many economists devoted a good deal of attention to ascertaining the benefits and costs of that involvement. Much less attention was paid to the loss of flexibility that accompanied greater government influence over private economic decisionmaking. But as new government programs increased the number of objectives to be satisfied in the making of economic decisions, the net result was to restrict the Nation's ability to respond quickly to economic and technological change. Limitations on flexibility are sometimes desirable. Federal requirements for the safe disposal of toxic wastes, for example, are undoubtedly a legitimate way to reduce the flexibility of chemical manufacturers and users. But programs that are excessively complex or overly stringent reduce flexibility unnecessarily. Efficiency suffers, productivity declines, and the economy becomes even less responsive to change. As government involvement in the economy has grown, so have the overtly political aspects of economic decisions. Representative government is quite responsive to claims from individuals, groups, or regions that proposed policies will benefit them or do them harm. Since all interventions, no matter how small, have the effect of harming some and benefiting others, there has been growing pressure to "manage" these gains and losses to produce "fairness" rather than economic efficiency. Many of the recent arguments over deregulation, for example, have tended to focus less on the benefits of deregulated markets than on the income losses of the persons or industries that have been protected in the past by Federal economic regulation. Similarly, discussions of the problems of declining industries have concentrated on the immediate fate confronting the companies and workers in those industries rather than on the more diffuse benefits associated with greater national economic efficiency. Compassion for the human problems that accompany rapid economic adjustment may often be a valid argument for policies which 89 slow the pace of adaptation. But excessive concern over who gets what can add rigidities to the economy and lead to the result that almost everyone gets less. The shocks to the world economy that occurred in the 1970s— huge and abrupt increases in energy prices, unprecedented strains on the financial markets, major fluctuations in agriculture—would have tested even the most flexible and adaptable of economies. Since the adaptability of our economy was already less than ideal, these shocks hurt us more than they might have in other circumstances. Similar shocks are likely to occur in the next decade or two. The Nation therefore must prepare itself to deal with these shocks by increasing the adaptability of its economic institutions. This will pay important dividends in the Nation's fight against inflation. As pointed out in Chapter 1, rigid economic institutions sharply limit the effectiveness of macroeconomic policies. They can turn what otherwise would be transitory pressures for higher prices into permanent price increases. Public and private barriers that prevent resources from flowing out of inefficient sectors to more efficient ones help create bottlenecks that impede efforts to promote economic growth. The need, therefore, is for greater flexibility, not merely to permit individual sectors to respond more effectively to rapid economic change, but also to permit the economy as a whole to withstand such change without continual increases in the rate of inflation. Because energy markets are such an important example of an area in need of added flexibility, this chapter first addresses energy problems. The second section addresses two major types of regulatory reform: eliminating obsolete regulatory structures and improving the functioning of necessary regulation. Both kinds of reform serve to eliminate unnecessary costs and reduce unjustified rigidities. The third section describes some of the far-reaching changes taking place in the financial markets and the strains these changes are creating. The fourth section describes the changed role of the agricultural sector and the corresponding need for more flexible instruments of agricultural policy. The fifth section addresses the problems of structural adjustment that are being created by changing demographic and industrial conditions, while a final section discusses the growing pressures on government to identify and aid promising industries and sectors. ADAPTING TO ENERGY UNCERTAINTY No sector of the economy better illustrates the increasing need for flexibility and adaptability than energy. The challenge is not only to 90 use less and produce more energy in the face of higher energy prices, but also to deal with the uncertainties of supply and price. ADJUSTING TO HIGHER ENERGY PRICES Available evidence suggests that the adjustment to higher energy prices is well underway. Between 1973 and the third quarter of 1980, real energy prices increased by 59 percent and the energy input per dollar of real gross national product (GNP) dropped by 19 percent. As energy prices rose, conservation of energy resources became increasingly attractive in economic terms. Shortages and uncertainty of supply also induced conservation, sometimes very rapidly. While many uses of energy can be adapted relatively quickly to higher prices, others require more time. Consider the time required, for example, for the economy to feel the full effect of a 10 percent increase in the real price of gasoline. Studies suggest that the initial adjustment of consumers to such a higher price—perhaps by carpooling or taking shorter recreational trips—would reduce gasoline use by only 2 percent. But over a longer period, as consumers are able to buy more fuel-efficient vehicles, change residential locations, and the like, the fall in gasoline use may amount to perhaps 8 percent. Thus, a major portion of the savings in energy use compelled by the substantial 1979-80 increases in oil prices is still before us. Rising prices also encourage suppliers to develop new energy sources. In the first 6 months of 1980, domestic oil producers drilled 19 percent more wells in the United States than they did during a comparable period in 1979 and opened 15 percent more oil and gas wells than they did in the entire year of 1973. For the first time in years, additions to proven natural gas reserves may have exceeded withdrawals. The development of nonconventional fuel sources—gasohol, solar energy, and so on—has also been occurring at a steppedup pace. ADJUSTING TO PRICE AND SUPPLY UNCERTAINTY Perhaps the biggest challenge in energy today is to minimize the economy's vulnerability to disruptions in the supply of oil. Disruptions can vary both in size and duration. The ones experienced so far, though painful to the world's economies, have been relatively small. But much larger ones are conceivable. There is little doubt that a prolonged reduction in Middle Eastern oil supplies could severely damage the U.S. economy. A recent simulation study by the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) indicated that a yearlong cutoff of oil supplies from the Persian Gulf might reduce oil supplies available to the United States by about one-third, and output by nearly 10 percent—almost $3,000 per household. Although estimates of this sort are necessarily subject to a high degree of uncertainty, the con- 91 sequences of such an interruption on employment, wages, and prices clearly would be massive. Moreover, the threat of disruption, small or large, hangs like a cloud over the economy and thus affects consumer and investor expectations. It is therefore imperative that the Nation have policies to reduce its vulnerability to oil supply disruptions and to deal effectively with the consequences of any vulnerability that remains. One simple and often-used measure of vulnerability is the level of the Nation's dependence on imported oil. In 1977 the United States imported a record average of 8.8 million barrels of crude oil and petroleum products per day. By late 1980, however, imports had fallen to about 6.5 million barrels per day. Although some of this drop was due to the recession and high inventory levels, a larger part of the decline can only be accounted for by conservation and additional domestic production. Dependence on imported oil, however, is not equivalent to vulnerability. If imported oil came from many small geographically dispersed producers, each unlikely to cease production suddenly, even a high level of oil imports would mean little vulnerability to interruption. At the other extreme, even a zero level of oil imports would not totally protect the U.S. economy in the event of extreme instability in the world oil market. The United States could not stand by and watch the rest of the world's economies collapse without suffering irreparable economic harm itself, and would not do so, even if it were possible to isolate itself from such damage. Thus, vulnerability is not easily measured. It is related in part to the ability of the Nation's capital stock to adjust rapidly enough to changes in the world price of oil, and in part to the fact that an oil supply interruption would result in large domestic and international transfers of wealth, large losses in output, losses of consumer and investor confidence, and a sharp surge in inflation. The experience of past episodes of supply disruption has taught policymakers to appreciate the limited ability of governments to allocate scarce petroleum supplies and the long-run problems that result from attempts to shield consumers from the consequences of higher prices. These same episodes have also shown that such disruptions are accompanied by other impacts that private markets cannot be expected to take into account. For example, private economic decisionmakers—consumers and business firms—are unlikely or unable to factor the substantial macroeconomic effects of an oil supply disruption into their individual responses. Therefore, they will tend to take fewer preventive measures than is socially desirable. Moreover, the expectation of government intervention is also likely to affect private behavior. The experience of past disruptions may have created the 92 expectation of price controls or fuel allocation in the event of another disruption and thus further reduced the incentive for individual consumers or business firms to take steps to protect themselves. Large disruptions would not only intensify these effects but pose the added risk that energy markets would be overwhelmed—at least for a while—by rapidly changing information, bottlenecks in distribution to industry, supply uncertainty, and the potentially destabilizing influence of hoarding. Thus, the proper mix of public and private responses to an oil supply disruption will depend upon a number of factors, including the magnitude and expected duration of the disruption and the steps taken in advance to reduce its impact. Improving Adaptability One way to reduce the economy's vulnerability to disruptions of foreign oil supplies would be to increase the short-run responsiveness of domestic production and consumption to short-term changes in price and supply. If domestic producers could easily expand supply and users could easily reduce demand, large transfers of income would not be generated by the price movements needed to balance supply and demand. Thus, the more elastic the demand and supply of energy are in the short run, the less vulnerable the economy will be to a disruption in foreign oil supplies. Flexibility in fuel use is one way to increase short-run elasticity in demand. Today, for example, U.S. industrial facilities that burn over one million barrels of oil per day have the technical capability to substitute domestic natural gas on very short notice. The potential flexibility of the country's industrial users of energy is apparently several times this level, however. According to one source, it is possible to develop the capability to substitute coal and natural gas for an additional four million barrels per day—for a total in excess of one-fourth of present U.S. oil consumption. Just what degree of fuel-switching capability is economically attractive is another matter. Building fuel-use adaptability into industrial facilities is costly; it requires additional capital investment and may increase operating expenses. Further, to utilize such flexibility, there must exist both sufficient supplies of other fuels and the ability to deliver them where needed. The general dilemma is that the Nation's capital stock must be sharply modified in the face of higher energy prices, but it also must be enabled to function despite uncertainty of energy supply. As a result, the energy-using capital stock of the future will embody a compromise between greater productivity and fuel-use flexibility. Actions can also be taken to increase the short-run elasticity of energy supply. Sizable fuel inventories, in particular, would provide a substantial degree of flexibility. At the outset of the Iran-Iraq war in 93 September 1980, world oil stocks were at record levels. U.S. domestic stocks, including oil not yet ashore, were some 300-400 million barrels above the minimum operating needs. In contrast, world reserves were quite low when the supply of Iranian oil was disrupted in late 1978. The shortfall associated with the 1980 interruption was comparable in size to the shortfall of 1978-79. Yet the earlier disruption resulted in a sudden and rapid escalation of world oil prices, while no such shock occurred after the 1980 disruption. The substantial size of world and domestic oil reserves played an important role in preventing panic and maintaining relative price stability. Thus, private contingency stocks and public stocks such as the Strategic Petroleum Reserve can provide an important buffer to future disruptions. The strategic reserve is far less than adequate, however, and an increase in its size is essential to reducing our vulnerability to foreign supply disruptions. But care must be taken to assure that such a buildup, by its effect on the world oil market, not be destabilizing. Furthermore, the reserve program should not merely substitute a stockpile created at government expense for an increase in private precautionary inventories. This could be partially avoided by announcing a plan that would use the strategic reserve only in the event of a relatively large disruption and allow market forces to come into play during smaller ones. To date, attention has focused on oil stockpiles. But the installation of additional industrial facilities with the flexibility to use more than one type of fuel would make stockpiles of other fuels equally useful in reducing upward pressure on world oil prices. Flexibility in fuel use would not reduce our vulnerability, however, if constraints in the distribution network impeded the use of available alternative fuels. Propane, for example, is a frequently used alternative to natural gas, but distribution problems limited its use during natural gas curtailments in 1976 and 1977. One solution would be to maintain supplemental distribution capacity: additional handling or line-haul facilities in the case of coal, additional pipeline or surge pumping capacity in the case of natural gas, and additional wheeling and coal generating capacity in the case of electricity. Certain of these strategies, particularly the wheeling of electricity, have been utilized in the past to reduce the effects of temporary fuel curtailments. Dealing with a Disruption Increasing private and public stocks of the different types of fuels and improving fuel-use flexibility cannot completely eliminate the Nation's vulnerability to a major interruption in oil supply. Both international obligations and the high cost of any actions to reduce our 94 dependence on foreign oil mean that some degree of U.S. vulnerability to oil supply disruptions will persist for a long time to come. Even as a theoretical question, it is hard to know the level of oil reserves that would be needed to totally insulate the United States from a supply disruption. Present plans call for a Strategic Petroleum Reserve of approximately one billion barrels, which is the equivalent of about 150 days of imports at current import levels. But the reserve is only intended to reduce our vulnerability, not to eliminate it. Let us suppose that a publicly owned stockpile of oil equivalent to a year's imports (about two billion barrels) would provide close to absolute protection from a disruption of Middle Eastern supplies. And suppose further that the acquisition of such a stockpile would not raise the world price of oil, although there can be no doubt that it would. Such a stockpile would then cost approximately $70 billion to acquire at the current price of about $35 per barrel. It would also require the expenditure of about $9 billion per year in storage and carrying costs. This is expensive insurance. Moreover, it would take several years of uninterrupted accumulation to acquire such a stockpile. Since it is impractical to eliminate our vulnerability, it is essential to develop policies and programs that would assure fair and efficient distribution of fuel supplies during a period of substantial disruption and minimize the negative impact of such a disruption on the economy. The Nation's current emergency plan, the authority for which expires on September 30, 1981, has two steps: a program of oil product allocation during the early stages of a major disruption, supplemented by a program of gasoline rationing if the disruption is large enough and continues long enough. The operation of this plan requires either standby price control authority or the ability to grant and implement this authority on extremely short notice. The current plan is designed to reduce the large transfers of income from domestic energy users to domestic energy producers that would otherwise occur during a major disruption. The plan is thus especially responsive to the goal of equity. By reducing transfers of income the plan is also intended to meet the macroeconomic goals of reducing the economic drag caused by increases in oil prices and preventing temporary energy price surges from becoming permanent through formal and informal wage and price indexing. But the plan has many deficiencies, only some of which are administrative. Although the allocation part of the program would use an existing bureaucratic structure—albeit one scheduled to expire in September 1981—the rationing part of the plan would require the creation of an untested bureaucracy that would use the postal system 95 to distribute rationing coupons and the banking system to account for them. An even more important drawback is the plan's adverse impact on efficiency. Its allocation and price control aspects may already have had the effect of discouraging private parties from taking self-protective measures, since they would deny those who invest in emergency fuel stocks or fuel flexibility the benefits of that investment. The plan's intended reliance on historic patterns of fuel use in making allocations would reduce flexibility by preventing users from switching to more abundant fuels because they had not previously used those fuels in substantial quantities. Finally, the plan emphasizes a reduction in gasoline use in the event of a disruption. Gasoline alone, however, could not absorb the brunt of a major emergency. If a complete cutoff of oil supplies from the Persian Gulf were handled by reducing the amount of oil refined into gasoline, the availability of gasoline in the United States would be reduced by over 75 percent. Thus, the present strategy for dealing with a major disruption is a three-way compromise between the administrative problems of implementing an emergency plan, the allocation deficiencies of such a plan, and the need to deal effectively with the severe macroeconomic consequences of a major disruption. One alternative plan would be to let uncontrolled market prices apportion available supplies. Such a plan would eliminate the problems of bureaucratic administration, but it would expose the economy to the consequences which might result from the building of fuel inventories at peak prices when the Nation's interests would be served by drawing inventories down. Such hoarding, as well as other complications, might occur because the problems of rapidly communicating market information during uncertain supply conditions would make it difficult for the market to cope with a large disruption. Furthermore, public declarations that the market would be permitted to operate without constraint during a large disruption would be likely to lack credibility, since the market has not been permitted to act freely during previous relatively small disruptions. Private parties are likely to assume that the government will also intervene during a major disruption, and they may modify their own actions accordingly. For example, given their political visibility and small numbers, the Nation's oil producers and distributors might pass up the opportunity to maximize short-run profit and engage instead in their own form of product allocation. Thus, the choice might not be between a market solution and government allocation, but between public and private allocation plans. 96 While the market solution might promise the greatest degree of allocative efficiency, it would not respond to the problems associated with the transfer of tens of billions of dollars from domestic consumers to overseas producers. More importantly, a "business as usual" strategy would fail to address any of the macroeconomic consequences associated with the large and sudden transfers of income among sectors of the domestic economy—possibly amounting to hundreds of billions of dollars—that would occur when business was quite decidedly not "as usual/' Another proposal—one that attempts to deal with the macroeconomic effects—would allow the market to allocate oil supplies during a major disruption but tax the resulting windfalls reaped by domestic suppliers and rebate these new tax revenues in a way that would address the income distribution and macroeconomic problems accompanying the disruption. Although attractive in theory, such a plan would present many practical difficulties. For one thing, as already noted, the magnitude of the fiscal drag that would occur from allowing the free play of the market to determine prices might be immense, and the amount of administrative effort that would be required to capture the windfall profits on such huge sums and recycle them efficiently would be substantial. This administrative burden might even rival that of the present rationing plan. Neither the present plan nor the tax rebate alternative would limit the large international transfers of wealth that would accompany a severe oil-supply disruption. Some economists have recommended the imposition of an import fee during a disruption to capture these windfalls. The ability of such a plan to achieve this goal is uncertain, however, since its success would depend a great deal both on precise timing and on the response of the oil-supplying nations: major overseas suppliers, having political as well as economic goals, might simply respond to such a fee by raising their prices and reducing quantities in an attempt to maintain a constant net revenue. While the success of an import tax or fee is not certain, it nonetheless merits further exploration because it is presently the only proposed method of responding directly to a,transfer of income from domestic consumers to foreign producers. Toward a Policy to Deal with Vulnerability Developing an appropriate set of policies to deal with vulnerability to energy price and supply shocks is an immense challenge. The dilemma facing the policymaker is when to rely on private market responses and when to take the risks that accompany government-operated price control, allocation, and taxation schemes. The answer would appear to have three parts. First, use the superior allocative abilities of private markets whenever possible. The markets appear 97 capable of handling small- and medium-sized disruptions, such as those experienced to date. Second, take technological and stockpiling initiatives to increase short-run flexibility in energy use and supply. This will increase the size of disruptions where a market response remains appropriate. To achieve such increased energy-use flexibility, it would be beneficial to develop strategic stockpiles of fuels in addition to oil. The use of these fuels during emergencies would require investments in supplementary distribution capacity. Finally, since measures to reduce vulnerability will take time to put into place, and since the Nation will never be totally invulnerable, contingency plans must be developed to deal with disruptions so large that they might overwhelm the private market. For both political and economic reasons, a program of allocation by price alone is unlikely to be adequate during a very large disruption. Too many problems would flow from any policy that placed a short-term "tax" amounting to as much as several thousand dollars per year on each U.S. household. Although any nonmarket mechanism would be administratively cumbersome and lack the allocative efficiencies of a pure market response, proper design could materially reduce these administrative and allocative problems. The present rationing scheme has much more precisely targeted distributional goals than most of the proposed programs of general tax rebates. Thus, differences in the value placed on achieving equity explain much of the difference in administrative complexity. A rationing plan that gave primary weight to minimizing the macroeconomic consequences of a disruption, however, would have far fewer administrative complexities. Such a plan might forgo the establishment of the hundreds of local boards that would otherwise be needed to adjudicate individual inequities. Responding to the challenge of energy vulnerability will not be made easier by ignoring the limits and complexities of alternative policies. Thus, while the benefits of a large and well-managed Strategic Petroleum Reserve are very substantial, it is also true that a preoccupation with the reserve's potential may divert attention from the fact that the acquisition of reserves takes time, and that even substantial reserves will not eliminate vulnerability. Similarly, the allocative efficiency of the market would be superior to any government-run price control and allocation scheme, yet the market alone would not be able to cope with all of the problems associated with a major interruption. There is no doubt that the present contingency plan for gasoline rationing has major shortcomings, but it is also true that new and untested schemes for taxing and rebating windfall profits could mirror in their complexity the rationing they seek to avoid. 98 High energy prices and excessive dependence on imported oil supplies are two major dimensions of the energy problem. However, the uncertain timing of increases in energy prices and the uncertainty of supply are two other dimensions which must command the attention of policymakers. Higher prices alone—if known in advance with a fair degree of certainty—would pose a costly but otherwise straightforward problem of economic adjustment. Supply uncertainty, however, adds a potentially dangerous complication. The Nation's capital stock must be made more energy efficient, and the Nation must change its energy-using habits, but both of these changes must be accomplished in ways that assure the flexibility to respond to sporadic episodes of price escalation and shortage. The challenge to policymakers is to adopt energy policies which effectively respond to legitimate concerns about equity and macroeconomic problems but neither penalize private efforts to respond to energy uncertainty nor unduly rigidify economic decisionmaking. IMPROVING REGULATORY PRACTICES Over the past decade there has been a growing awareness that Federal regulatory activities exert substantial influence on the economy. In trying to measure this influence, some have focused on the amount of capital required to comply with Federal regulations, some have focused on the rate and direction of technological change, and still others have focused on the regulatory burden facing small business. None of these measures fully captures one of regulation's most important consequences—its tendency to reduce the ability of the economy to adjust efficiently and swiftly to change. Regulation's tendency to produce rigidity has sometimes been directly observable. In the past, for example, the Interstate Commerce Commission severely restricted common carrier trucking firms trying to choose the most efficient routes for their trucks. The fuel-adjustment charges still permitted by State regulatory agencies have reduced the interest of electric utilities in making fuel-saving investments, while the Federal regulations that rigidly segmented both the telecommunications and financial industries helped thwart innovations that would have improved productivity. In other situations, however, the way in which regulation reduces flexibility is less obvious but nonetheless real. Some legislation, for example, prevents regulators from considering—much less balancing—competing national goals in establishing regulatory priorities. There are Federal statutes that prescribe the specific dates at which compliance with regulations must be achieved, and some statutes even specify compliance methods. Furthermore, the compartmentaliz- 99 ing of regulatory functions often prevents the different agencies responsible for regulating different aspects of a given industry's performance from developing mutually consistent regulatory strategies. Once regulations are issued, they are seldom given a fresh look to see if they should be altered in the light of new knowledge or new conditions. Each of these facets of regulation has made our economic system less flexible. During the coming decade, however, the need to increase the economy's adaptability and flexibility will grow. Regulatory reform must play an important role in meeting this need. THE ROLE OF "DEREGULATION" In several industries—railroads, trucking, airlines, energy, telecommunications, banking—where the existing regulatory structures have largely outlived their usefulness, this Administration has achieved significant reform. Regulatory bodies like the Interstate Commerce Commission (ICC), the Civil Aeronautics Board (CAB), and the Federal Communications Commission (FCC), have acted administratively to reduce the burden of regulation where their statutes allowed them to do so, and new legislation has carried the process even further. Since the passage of the Airline Deregulation Act of 1978, Congress has also substantially deregulated common carrier trucking, interstate movers of household goods, railroads, and financial institutions. Meanwhile, the phased decontrol of natural gas and domestic crude oil prices continued to provide a powerful spur to energy conservation and to the exploration and development of new domestic sources of oil and natural gas. By the last quarter of 1980 an estimated 62 percent of all domestically produced crude oil was free of controls. Transitions to Deregulation As regulatory structures have been dismantled, the importance of properly designing the regulatory transition—the period during which an industry moves toward deregulation—has become more evident. Changing the "rules of the game" can cause serious dislocations in a previously regulated industry, and these dislocations must be taken into account. Users of the industry's services have made investments on the basis of the prices regulation has produced. Even if these price signals were in some sense "wrong," these investments cannot easily be undone. Similarly, workers and stockholders in the industry adapted their behavior to the realities of a regulated environment long ago, and changes in the industry's regulatory structure will affect their earnings. Legislative debates have been dominated by the desire to cushion those with a stake in the existing system—customers, workers, and shareholders alike—from the shock of deregulation. For the most 100 part, the interests of these parties have been protected. Requirements for substitute service, provisions for notice of intention to suspend service, and provisions to protect the economic position of workers have generally been written into deregulation legislation. Unfortunately, much less care has been taken to make the course of deregulation sufficiently flexible to withstand the shock of sharp changes in the external environment. The best example of this is the deregulation strategy chosen for natural gas. The decontrol schedule adopted in the Natural Gas Policy Act of 1978 will allow the price of "new" natural gas to gradually move up to the equivalent of $15 for a barrel of oil (in 1978 dollars) by 1985, a level thought at the time to be more than adequate to permit a smooth transition to uncontrolled prices. By the end of 1980, however, the world price of oil (in 1978 dollars) had already reached $28.50 per barrel. By 1985, oil prices will probably be more than double the level anticipated when the natural gas decontrol legislation was enacted. Thus, there will still be a large gap between the controlled price of "new" gas and the price of "decontrolled" gas. There will then be an obvious temptation to delay complete decontrol in the hope of minimizing the shock that would occur if this price gap was closed in one step. But delay would be unwise. A better solution would be to reconsider the decontrol schedule soon for the purpose of making the necessary alterations in the decontrol path. The previous strategy of preventing windfall profits by ensuring a slow transition to decontrol will probably have to be abandoned in favor of a strategy which deals directly with the windfall issue. The sharp increase in world energy prices has also placed strains on the transition toward deregulation in other industries, particularly airlines and railroads. The increase in energy prices has created the inaccurate perception that the principal promise of deregulation of the airlines—lower fares—was illusory. As discussed in last year's Report, however, only the productivity improvements permitted by deregulation prevented the sharp rise in energy prices from resulting in even larger increases in unit costs and thus in still higher air fares. Higher energy prices have also made service to smaller communities by large aircraft an even less attractive financial proposition than it was earlier. However, the increased flexibility permitted by deregulation has helped to preserve air service to smaller communities by making it easier to substitute commuter carriers. Had this flexibility been unavailable, the short-run consequences would have been an enormous increase in Federal subsidies to the airlines, followed by the termination of service to many smaller communities. With the increased fare and route flexibility permitted by deregulation, the airline industry has been weathering the most recent reces- 101 sion relatively well. Although substantial losses are being experienced by many carriers, most analysts consider the general condition of the industry to be sound. Most importantly, substantial investment in more fuel-efficient aircraft is continuing. Rising energy prices have caused a different problem for railroad deregulation. Federal legislation enacted in 1976 provided the railroads with increased rate flexibility, but this initial dose of "deregulation" proved inadequate. In the meantime, the booming demand for coal prompted the railroads to raise coal-hauling rates sharply. These higher rates reflect the need to generate sufficient revenues to finance large investments in additional coal-hauling capacity, but they may also reflect some exercise of monopoly power. In any case, the rapid increase in coal-hauling rates, and the fear of even more rapid increases if the ICC controls were lifted, caused opponents of further deregulation to press for continuing ICC surveillance of coal-hauling and other bulk commodity rates. A compromise was reached that permitted a relaxation of the ICC's rate-approval authority on a prearranged schedule. The railroads have been given significant freedom to alter rates to meet shifting market conditions, while rail users have been given some protection against abuse of this freedom. The result should be better service and the substitution of coal for oil where lower total coal costs (including the cost of transportation) warrant. Unexpectedly sharp increases in energy prices are not the only factor that has complicated regulatory transitions. Any unforeseen alteration in economic conditions can produce tensions. For example, the unprecedented swings in interest rates that occurred in 1980 placed additional strains on the .already complex deregulation process of eliminating statutory differences between the various types of financial institutions. This discussion leads to one conclusion. Inflexible transition paths are likely to encounter problems, particularly if the period preceding deregulation is stretched out to protect the economic positions of workers, shareholders, or consumers. Flexible transition paths, on the other hand, can allow industries to weather even large unanticipated shocks by permitting innovation. Transition paths should therefore be made as flexible as possible. Although the political difficulties of doing so should not.be underestimated, it seems preferable to dismantle the regulatory barriers to efficient pricing relatively quickly and to take separate action to provide compensation for capital losses or to prevent windfall gains, if necessary. EFFORTS TO IMPROVE THE PROCESS OF SOCIAL REGULATION While much of the economic regulation placed on the statute books over the years has been eliminated or substantially reduced, 102 Federal regulations designed to protect the natural environment and the health and safety of both workers and consumers are necessary, and will remain so. The unaided market has not produced socially acceptable levels of pollution or worker exposure to hazardous conditions, and there is little evidence that it will. But Federal regulation designed to protect the environment and the health and safety of both workers and consumers has not always produced the hoped-for results. The challenge to those who would reform these regulations is to design regulatory systems which intrude only to the extent required to achieve their goals and which use enforcement techniques that are appropriate, flexible, and efficient. Means must also be found to assure that the regulatory goals themselves reflect a proper balancing of national priorities. This may require new oversight methods or new regulatory tools. Oversight Activities and Institutions This Administration has utilized a number of methods to supervise the regulatory process. By Executive order, any executive agency proposing a major new regulation must develop an analysis of the expected economic consequences of its preferred alternative and of other possible approaches. Although this requirement only applies to a relatively small number of the regulations issued by the Federal Government each year, it has helped to upgrade the entire structure of regulatory decisionmaking. Many agencies now estimate the costs and benefits of all proposed regulations, even though these estimates are not always made public. The regulatory analyses prepared by the agencies are subjected to independent review and comment by two institutions: the Regulatory Analysis Review Group (RARG) and the Council on Wage and Price Stability (CWPS). The RARG, an interagency body chaired by the Council of Economic Advisers, is composed principally of representatives from the executive branch agencies with regulatory responsibilities. It reviews approximately 10 regulations per year, concentrating on those that may impose especially large costs or that promise to be precedent setting. CWPS reviews approximately 50 regulations per year and is the only Executive Office unit having explicit statutory authority to review and comment on the proposed regulations of the independent regulatory agencies. This ability to provide credible estimates of the costs and benefits of proposed regulations, to suggest alternatives that might not ordinarily be suggested during the course of a rulemaking, and to serve as a source of quality control over agency analytical activities has proved crucial to effective regulatory oversight. Whenever a RARG report has been filed, and in a small number of additional executive branch rulemakings, the Council of Economic 103 Advisers and other Presidential advisers have discussed the regulation with the agency prior to its issuance but after the period for public comment has ended. The purpose has been to assure the President that the agency head, in making the final decision, has considered the full range of alternatives allowed by statute and has taken cost-effectiveness criteria into account. The task of following the development of important regulations has been made far easier by another innovation, the Regulatory Calendar. This list of important forthcoming regulations has become indispensable to understanding the cumulative impact of regulation on the economy. The Regulatory Council, which publishes the Calendar, has increased the amount of crosscutting analysis in it and is also developing industry-specific calendars. The first of these will catalog all Federal activities intended to affect the manufacture, sale, or use of automobiles. Through the use of the Calendar, the Council also seeks to identify overlapping regulations and tries to improve coordination between agencies where overlap is inevitable. In addition to these regulatory oversight activities, there have been special reviews of all of the significant regulations affecting a few major industries. The most widely publicized of these were studies of the steel and auto industries conducted, respectively, by the Environmental Subcommittee of the Steel Tripartite Committee and by an interagency committee under the leadership of the Secretary of Transportation. Another is the review of important regulations affecting the nonferrous metals industry, announced by the Regulatory Council in October. Special reviews of this kind are likely to become more common in the years ahead. Further Improvements in Regulatory Oversight Activities The oversight practices described above have been central to this Administration's effort to develop new techniques in an area where the proper relationship between centralized oversight and agency decisionmaking is unclear and where analytical techniques require further improvement. Both the relationship and the analytical tools will be refined in the future. Formal consideration of the anticipated costs of any regulation is an obvious necessity. Our national resources are not infinite. There must be some determination of whether the anticipated costs are within our means and our willingness to pay. Moreover, it is clearly desirable to maximize the benefits of any given level of regulation. Although the preceding statements may seem elementary, consideration of the anticipated costs of a regulation is sometimes prohibited by statute. The Clean Air Act, for example, has recently been interpreted in court as prohibiting the Environmental Protection 104 Agency (EPA) from considering prospective costs in setting ambient air quality standards. Even when consideration of costs is permitted or required by statute, agencies and courts must still decide whether this has been done in an appropriate manner. Agency procedures and court opinions on this subject vary. There is no universal test of economic feasibility and no agreed-upon "best" relationship between the economic costs of a proposed regulation and its expected benefits. For these reasons, any sustained effort to ensure formal consideration of costs in regulatory decisions must involve the Congress, the courts, the White House, and the agencies charged with implementing regulatory statutes. Without such broad involvement, the matter will only be resolved on a case-by-case basis over many years. That slow process would provide no guarantee of uniformity, but it might well produce a regulatory paralysis arising from delay and uncertainty. One suggested device for reconciling regulatory priorities within and between programs is the "regulatory budget." Most of its proponents envision this device as analogous to the Federal fiscal budget, with specific amounts of "permissible regulatory expenditures" assigned to each program and each agency. Some even envision a process of formal congressional authorization. Although economists have made considerable progress in estimating the direct costs of complying with regulation, it is not likely that the techniques for a full-scale regulatory budget will exist soon. But it is feasible—and necessary—to incorporate budgetary principles, especially the establishment of priorities, into regulatory programs. This has been the aim of the Administration's regulatory oversight activities. EFFORTS AT "SMARTER" REGULATION With the direct encouragement of the President and the Regulatory Council, regulatory agencies have been experimenting with different ways to reduce the cost burden of regulation. A good example is EPA's "bubble concept." This concept is based on the fact that it is often possible to reduce emissions of a given pollutant from one source far less expensively than from another source. Thus, instead of compelling each source to meet a standard, EPA figuratively places a "bubble" over an area (a large industrial plant, or, in some cases, an even larger geographic area) and lets private decisionmakers decide how to meet the standard for the area at the lowest cost. EPA initially intended to apply the concept quite narrowly, but during 1980 it gradually found ways to broaden its application. Means were found to eliminate many time-consuming procedures. The ability to develop acceptable "bubbles" for sulfur oxides 105 and particulates was demonstrated. Finally, and perhaps most importantly, a solution to a problem once thought to be insurmountable— namely, how to permit the concept to be applied in areas of the country not already meeting ambient air quality standards—appeared to be in sight. As the year came to an end, numerous "bubbles" were in the final stages of design and approval. In some situations where the bubble concept is applied the cost savings will approach 60 percent. Furthermore, the concept so increases engineering flexibility that it offers the prospect of sharply reduced emissions in some cases. Experimentation with a second regulatory innovation—the use of marketable permits—is just beginning. EPA recently suggested an overall limit on fluorocarbon production (and, hence, fluorocarbon emissions), combined with the creation of a market for buying and selling emission rights. While this approach promises substantial savings in the cost of reducing emissions, it transfers income from fluorocarbon users and producers to the government. If ways can be found to deal with the income transfer issues, and certain other technical difficulties overcome, the use of such a strategy would permit the continued use of fluorocarbons in those products that consumers value most while eliminating the need for administrative agency determinations of "essential" and "nonessential" uses. It will also stimulate the development of products that make more efficient use of these chemicals. A third kind of effort at "smarter" regulation is the attempt to tailor regulations to the organization being regulated. The burden of compliance (especially the paperwork burden) often falls disproportionately on small businesses, some local governments, and certain nonprofit organizations. While a blanket exemption of small entities from regulation would not be feasible, it is often possible to reduce their regulatory burden. This approach was incorporated into statute by the Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980, which requires the Federal Government to estimate the costs of new regulations for small organizations and to review its existing regulations to see whether the burden could be reduced. Another way of improving the regulatory process is to examine existing regulations in a systematic way and eliminate those that are outmoded or unnecessary. On the basis of such a review, the Occupational Safety and Health Administration (OSHA) has eliminated nearly one thousand regulations during the past 4 years. And in September the Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD) proposed to eliminate significant portions of its Minimum Property Standards, a large body of regulations going back almost 40 years. These regulations had been originally designed to ensure, among 106 other things, that federally assisted housing is safe and sanitary, and that federally guaranteed mortgages are marketable. HUD's review of the entire set of regulations was prompted by its belief that the private market now adequately performs some of these functions. Still other alternatives to "command-and-control" regulation are possible. In choosing among alternatives, policymakers should seek the least intrusive ways of achieving regulatory goals. As a matter of course, regulators should look for techniques closely matched to the marketplace failure which was the original justification for regulatory intervention. Resort to a command-and-control solution should be the last step considered, not the first or second. FINANCIAL MARKETS ADAPTING TO CHANGE The financial markets have proved remarkably adaptable to changing economic conditions over the past two decades. In general, the markets' adaptations have occurred despite a slow response on the part of legislators and regulatory agencies. In the mid-1960s there were many restrictions on depository institutions, including the following: • limitation of the right to offer checking accounts to commercial banks; • prohibition of interest payments on checking account balances; • interest rate ceilings on savings accounts and other deposits in commercial banks and thrift institutions, with thrifts permitted to pay a differential of as much as three-fourths of 1 percent more on accounts of similar maturity; • ceilings on the maximum interest rate that could be charged for loans; • limitations on the types of assets that could be held; and • geographic limitations on the establishment of branch offices and on the acquisition of other institutions. These restrictions—motivated by such concerns as maintaining a sound financial system and a sufficient flow of funds for home mortgages—helped sustain the compartmentalization of depository institutions, both by function and by geographic area. Commercial banks provided "full service" banking to households and businesses, while thrift institutions were the principal repository for household savings and the dominant source of funds for residential mortgages. This rigidly segmented system worked tolerably well from the 1940s through the mid-1960s. Market interest rates generally did not rise much above the regulatory ceilings on interest rates on deposits, 107 and most depository institutions were able to maintain a general degree of customer loyalty while still competing for deposit and loan business. ADAPTING TO RISING INTEREST RATES Since the mid-1960s, however, sharp swings in market interest rates and a general upward ratcheting of the interest rate cycle due to inflation have induced sweeping changes in the financial markets. Ceilings on deposit interest rates lagged behind rising market interest rates, creating gaps between the yields from deposits with regulated interest rates and the yields available on instruments with unregulated interest rates. Depository institutions then found it difficult to attract enough funds in regulated deposit markets to sustain their dominance in the lending markets. Moreover, member banks of the Federal Reserve System were further disadvantaged because they had to maintain a portion of their deposits as reserves in noninterest bearing balances, and the burden of these reserve requirements grew as interest rates rose. Throughout the late 1960s and the 1970s, banks and thrifts sought to hold their competitive position by finding ways to attract funds less restricted by government regulations. For example, they developed a mechanism to sell U.S. Government securities to large corporate customers, agreeing to repurchase them later. Because this instrument (called a "repurchase agreement") was not subject to interest rate ceilings—and, for member banks, bore no reserve requirement—an institution could offer its corporate customers a competitive rate on short-term balances. By 1980, repurchase agreements outstanding at commercial banks had grown in value to roughly $30 billion. In the early 1970s some State-chartered thrift institutions in Massachusetts and New Hampshire found that they could legally offer Negotiable Order of Withdrawal (NOW) accounts, which are similar to demand deposit (checking) accounts. With NOWs, which also can earn interest, the thrifts began to compete with commercial banks for transactions balances. Meanwhile, many commercial banks gave up their membership in the Federal Reserve in order to avoid the burden of its reserve requirements. Despite these actions, banks and thrifts still were unable to provide a fully competitive range of financial services. Nondepository institutions, less burdened by regulation, found the banking market profitable as they began issuing deposit-like instruments and offering bank-like services. Money-market mutual funds, for example, were able to offer small savers substantial liquidity while offering a yield competitive with market interest rates. Many of these funds allow "deposits" (uninsured equity interests, called shares) to be maintained in almost any amount, and most of them offer limited check- 108 ing services. Money-market mutual funds did not exist until 1971, but by August 1980 they had grown in value to over $80 billion. Corporate borrowers found it cheaper to bypass their traditional lending relationships with commercial banks and increased their reliance on nonbank sources of funds like the commercial paper market, where corporations sell direct short-term liabilities. The issuance of commercial paper by nonfinancial firms grew from 4 percent of the total short-term debt of business firms in 1972 to 7 percent in 1979. Meanwhile, foreign banks, which were not burdened by Federal Reserve requirements and which had well-developed foreign sources of funds, also began moving into U.S. markets, especially business lending. By capitalizing on the expansion of international trade and by pricing their loans aggressively, they increased their share of U.S. business loans from 4 percent in 1972 to 9 percent in 1979. U.S. banks have tried to keep their share of business loans by reducing their interest rates on loans to corporations with access to such alternative sources of funds. While the so-called prime rate is still the lowest rate offered to good customers lacking these alternatives, loans made at rates less than the prime rate are now commonplace. Nevertheless, the share of total short-term business debt held by domestic commercial banks shrank from 86 percent in 1972 to 60 percent in 1979. Even as they sought innovative ways to bypass the regulatory structure and to maintain their markets, some depository institutions urged regulatory agencies to loosen their restrictions. The call for deregulation was less than unanimous, however, since many institutions believed that the regulatory structure still protected their profitable markets from encroachment by competitors. Nevertheless, experiments in deregulation were conducted by both Federal and State financial regulators in the 1970s (Table 11). In the early 1970s, for example, interest rate ceilings on large time deposits ($100,000 or more) were removed, in part to permit banks to meet the strong demand for bank credit that developed when the failure of the Penn Central temporarily destabilized the commercial paper market. This action provided banks and thrift institutions with new access to the open market, and by the end of 1980 they held more than $250 billion in such deposits. More recent regulatory changes have allowed banks and thrifts to compete for the funds of smaller savers by issuing 6-month money-market certificates (MMCs) and 2V2-year small saver certificates (SSCs). These instruments, whose interest rate ceilings are adjusted frequently to keep pace with market interest rates, had attracted roughly $475 billion to banks and thrift institutions by the end of 1980. 109 TABLE 11.—Selected financial regulatory changes, 1970-80 Change Date June 1970 September 1970 June 1972 May 1973 January 1974 August 1974 November 1974 April 1975 November 1975.. February 1976 May 1976 June 1978 October 1978 November 1978 July 1979 January 1980 March 1980 Regulation Q ceilings on time deposits of $100,000 or more with maturities of 30-89 days suspended. Federally chartered savings and loan associations permitted to make preauttiorized nonnegotiable transfers from savings accounts for household-related expenditures. State-chartered mutual savings banks in Massachusetts began offering NOW accounts. Regulation Q ceilings on time deposits of $100,000 or more with maturities exceeding 90 days suspended. All depository institutions in Massachusetts and New Hampshire authorized by Congress to offer NOW accounts. Selected Federal credit unions permitted to issue credit union share drafts, check-like instruments payable through a commercial bank. Commercial banks permitted to offer savings accounts to State and local government units. Member banks authorized by the Federal Reserve to make transfers from a customer's savings account to a demand deposit account upon telephone order from the customer. . . ., Commerciat banks authorized to offer savings accounts to businesses. Congress extended NOW accounts to all New England states. New York permitted checking accounts at State-chartered mutual savings banks and savings and loans.' Six-month money market certificates (MMCs) introduced at banks and thrifts. Congress extended NOW account authority to New York State. Commercial banks and mutual savings banks authorized to offer automatic transfer (ATS) from a savings account to a checking account or other type of transactions account. A floating ceiling for time deposits at banks and thrifts with a maturity of 4 years or more established. The floating ceiling extended to time deposits with a maturity of 2Vz years or more. The Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary Control Act of 1980 enacted. ADAPTING TO GREATER RATE VARIABILITY While the depository institutions were adapting to greater competition and the high interest rate environment, they also faced the problem of growing interest rate risk. Increased rate variability and the upward ratcheting of interest rates have been especially troublesome to these institutions because their liabilities have traditionally matured more quickly than their assets. Moreover, while the new types of variable-rate instruments have allowed them to keep many of their depositors, these instruments have facilitated a shift of funds from stable, low-interest savings accounts to more variable and higher interest liabilities. Consequently, as market interest rates rise, so do the rates they must pay on their liabilities. When this happens, banks and thrifts lose income because the yield on their longer-term assets does not rise commensurately. Depository institutions have responded to this problem by shortening the maturities of their loans and by offering loans whose interest rates are frequently adjusted over the course of the loan to prevailing market rates. In 1980, for example, almost 70 percent of term business loans extended by commercial banks had floating interest rates. Similarly, banks and thrift institutions have introduced new mortgage instruments—including the variable-rate mortgage and the rolloverrate mortgage—whose rates are adjusted every year or so—in stark contrast to the traditional 30-year, fixed-rate mortgage. The thrift institutions also sought to remove the legislative restrictions on their 110 holdings of consumer and business loans, which have shorter maturities than mortgages. PRESSURES FOR COMPREHENSIVE LEGISLATION In the late 1970s there was a growing realization throughout the financial community that despite piecemeal modernization, regulations affecting depository institutions needed more sweeping reform. The regulatory structure no longer was satisfying its original objectives. Instead, it was creating inefficiencies and inequities. It even diminished the effectiveness of monetary policy as banks left the Federal Reserve System. Pressures from various sources finally resulted in a compromise bank reform bill, the Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary Control Act of 1980. Under this law, interest rate ceilings on time savings deposits will be phased out over 6 years. Moreover, beginning December 31, 1980, all depository institutions were allowed to issue NOW accounts to individuals and nonprofit organizations. In addition, uniform reserve requirements will apply to all depository institutions by the end of an 8-year transition period. As a result, the burden of reserve requirements will be spread more equitably among all institutions, and the Federal Reserve's control over the deposit base will be improved. The law also expands the asset flexibility of savings and loan associations, which will now be allowed to place up to 20 percent of their assets in consumer loans, while mutual savings banks will be allowed to invest up to 5 percent of their assets in business loans. Finally, the act repealed State usury ceilings on mortgage interest rates and relaxed State usury ceilings on consumer and business loan interest rates. These ceilings had seriously depressed such lending in certain States at various times during the past decade. THE FINANCIAL STRUCTURE OF THE 1980s: BENEFITS, RISKS, AND PUBLIC POLICY Today's financial environment is very different from the placid conditions of two decades ago, and it is likely never to revert to that earlier state. Changes in the financial markets have had significant impacts on the behavior of depositors, borrowers, and depository institutions who—along with the financial regulatory agencies—will face further challenges in coming years. Depositors Higher and more volatile interest rates have increased depositor awareness of the importance of actively managing their financial assets. Moreover, the proliferation of savings alternatives has provided depositors with access to new markets where they can receive a higher average return on their savings than previously. Even if inter- 111 est rates return to lower levels, it is likely that the market for deposits will remain more competitive and that savers will continue to be more interest-sensitive. This should work to encourage greater saving at a time when an increase in the Nation's rate of saving and investment would be welcome. While savers as a whole benefit from these reforms, however, not all individual savers will achieve a higher overall rate of return. In many cases the depository institutions have offset part of the increase in interest which they must pay for deposit funds by raising the prices of their checking and other financial services. Depositors who maintain high balances but use relatively few services will benefit considerably, while depositors who maintain relatively low balances and who benefited in earlier years from free or low-cost services may find these new practices to their disadvantage. Borrowers Many of the innovations adopted by depository institutions to make loan rates vary in accordance with changes in market rates have shifted the risk of interest rate variation to borrowers. As finance costs have risen and become more variable, financial management has assumed more prominence as a corporate management function. In the past decade, corporations have significantly improved their cash management and have increased their use of alternative sources of funding, such as commercial paper. Meanwhile, corporations have relied much more heavily on short-term debt to finance their activities and have shortened the maturities of their bond issues. Some observers have expressed concern that this tendency toward shorter maturities of liabilities could lead corporations to reduce their commitments to long-lived capital investments in plant and equipment, which would limit the Nation's ability to improve productivity. It should be recognized, however, that corporations are at least partially protected against inflation-induced changes in interest costs if borrowed funds are invested in real capital. That is, if changes in the expected rate of inflation account for fluctuations in interest rates, the expected nominal revenue from capital investment is likely to shift in the same direction as nominal borrowing costs. If corporations want further protection from changes in interest rates, they can pay to get it. They might, for example, make use of the financial futures markets which have developed quite rapidly in recent years. The total volume of 3-month Treasury bill contracts on the financial futures markets rose from $100 billion in 1976 to over $2.7 trillion in the first 10 months of 1980. One specific borrowing sector that has lost much of its protected status as a result of the new competitive environment is housing. The thrift institutions no longer enjoy many of the special advantages 112 they once had and thus cannot continue to channel funds to housing at artificially low interest rates. Although changing competitive conditions may mean a somewhat higher and more variable cost of funds for thrifts, the new regulatory environment should help to stabilize their deposit flows and hence the supply of mortgage funds. Furthermore, the Federal Government has supported the expansion of secondary mortgage markets to attract additional capital into housing. The secondary market institutions—the Federal National Mortgage Association (FNMA), the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation (FHLMC), and the Government National Mortgage Association (GNMA)—have expanded the scope and volume of their activities. Market acceptance of new financial instruments like the mortgagebacked securities issued by these institutions has grown, thus cementing more firmly the link between capital markets and mortgage credit. GNMA securities alone have increased to more than $90 billion in the past 3 years. While these developments in financial markets should tend to increase the variability of mortgage interest rates, they should also tend to reduce the cyclical swings in mortgage money availability. It is too early to tell whether these changes will mean more or less cyclical variation in home sales and residential construction. Depository Institutions Banks and thrift institutions now operate in a much more competitive environment, and the risks associated with interest rate swings are much greater. Partially offsetting these developments are the broader range of financial instruments they can offer and their expanded lending powers. But legal and regulatory limitations still exist that, if liberalized, would allow further adjustment to new financial conditions. Current law, for example, restricts banks and thrifts from expanding into natural market areas. A recent Administration study concluded that a liberalization of Federal restrictions on geographic expansion by commercial banks would increase banking competition in local markets and result in more and lower priced services. Some tentative steps toward the removal of the barriers to geographic expansion likely will occur in coming years. There may also be a further loosening of the asset restrictions on thrifts and commercial banks—for instance, allowing thrift institutions more leeway to make business loans or allowing both types of depository institutions broader powers to hold financial futures contracts and stocks, and to underwrite bond issues and insurance. Even with changes like these, however, some institutions will find it difficult to adjust. Since the government shaped the financial world that existed when these institutions were founded, it now faces the 113 task of helping them evolve in an orderly manner. Success will depend in part on general economic conditions, and as these conditions change, the regulators must be prepared to react. A case in point is the gradual removal in the last few years of ceilings on deposit interest rates. It was initially anticipated that relaxation of the ceilings, combined with an eventual liberalization of the types of assets that could be held, would allow thrift institutions to gradually correct imbalances in their portfolio maturities and thus limit their exposure to rising interest rates. But quick acceptance of floating-rate certificates by small savers at a time of rapidly rising interest rates has raised the interest expense of these institutions much faster than they have been able to increase the revenues on their loans. While most of the thrifts will achieve a better asset/liability balance in the long run, the current squeeze on profits resulting from rapidly rising market interest rates threatens some of them with serious financial difficulties. One way to deal with this problem would be to subsidize endangered institutions, perhaps by buying their low-yield, long-maturity assets (mortgages) at above-market prices. This would involve a substantial budgetary outlay, however. Another option would be to permit the troubled institutions to fail outright, but this approach would risk destabilizing the financial markets arid could result in significant losses to uninsured depositors and the Federal insurance organizations. Neither of these approaches responds directly to the inefficiencies created by remaining regulatory practices which continue to compartmentalize depository institutions. Thus, a third and preferred alternative would be to remove restrictions that now prevent efficient consolidation among financial firms. This would require further deregulation to allow mergers across State lines and between different types of institutions, since these restrictions remain a major obstacle to the efficient reorganization of financial institutions. As a result of these changes, the weakest institutions would find more opportunities for mergers. While this would not solve the problems of all endangered institutions, it would allow a more stable reordering of the financial sector where appropriate while minimizing the budgetary cost and sharply reducing the risk to financial markets of policies aimed at the remaining problem. Conclusions During the last two decades the pace of innovation in the financial markets has been quite rapid as depositors, borrowers, and financial institutions have sought new ways to adapt to high and variable interest rates. Unfortunately, a lag in both legislation and financial regulation meant that a considerable amount of innovation was applied to 114 finding ways around outdated regulatory barriers. But changes in the regulatory structure in the seventies, culminating with the Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary Control Act of 1980, have aided greatly in making regulation compatible with the new financial environment. The challenge for financial regulatory policy during the 1980s will be to rationalize regulation even further to achieve the appropriate balance between unnecessary restraints on the market and the regulatory goals of preserving the safety and soundness of the financial system and providing the tools for an effective monetary policy. THE ALTERED ROLE OF AGRICULTURE For decades, U.S. agriculture was a sector with chronic excess capacity and low returns. Productivity increases that exceeded growth in demand resulted in declining real food prices for more than a quarter of a century. The decade of the seventies saw virtually all of these circumstances change. Farm and food prices increased and became more volatile (Charts 5 and 6). A modest shortfall in the world crop and major trade policy changes in the United States and the Soviet Union contributed to the initial price shock in 1972, and the growing worldwide demand for food helped sustain demand pressures from 1973 on. The large surpluses of grain purchased by the Federal Government in earlier years to increase farm income had been sold by 1973 and, by 1974, for the first time in more than two decades, the cropland base was nearly fully employed. It has remained that way since then. To produce more from the available land, the use of industrial inputs increased. Chemical use, for example, increased nearly 37 percent from 1970 to 1980. The cash receipts of farmers increased dramatically after 1972, but production cost increases eroded much of the apparent gain in purchasing power. Prices paid for production inputs in 1980 were more than 2V2 times their 1970 levels. The price of agricultural real estate increased an average of 13 percent per year, nearly twice the average annual inflation rate for the decade. Still, the average per capita disposable income of all farmers during the 1970s from both farm and nonfarm sources was nearly 90 percent of that earned by the nonfarm population, up sharply from the 65 percent average figure of the 1960s. Meanwhile, the rapid exodus of labor from agriculture virtually stopped as the farm labor force stabilized at about four million persons. Not only was there a substantially smaller and more stable farm population, but there were substantially fewer farms, and a smaller 115 Chart 5 Prices Received by Farmers 1967=100 260 _ ALL FARM PRODUCTS I 220 \ r 180 A V / V 1970 80 V *^ I 140 _ 1960-70 100 >ffi^7ffT^hT^| I ln.nl I.....I.....I IM.MI I 1960-1980 MONTHLY SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURE. Chart 6 Relative Food Prices RATIOV 1.21 SEASONALLY ADJUSTED 9 lifl tilifilitiT 1947 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 OF IMPLICIT PRICE DEFLATOR FOR FOOD TO IMPLICIT PRICE DEFLATOR FOR ALL PERSONAL CONSUMPTION EXPENDITURES. SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE. 116 1980 proportion of the existing farms produced most of the Nation's food and fiber. In 1940, when there were more than six million farms, the largest 2 percent accounted for about 25 percent of all sales. By 1980 less than half as many large farms accounted for nearly 40 percent of all sales. EXPANDING AGRICULTURAL EXPORTS Perhaps the most significant change in American agriculture during the seventies, however, was the huge expansion in exports. Grain exports tripled in volume, while the dollar value of all agricultural exports increased nearly sixfold. But this growth in value and volume came with increased volatility in prices and production. The present competitive advantage of U.S. agriculture is impressive. In the 1960s, exports represented 14 percent of total farm cash receipts; in 1980, cash receipts from exports represented nearly 30 percent of the total (Table 12). To accommodate the increase in export volume, the amount of land devoted to the production of crops for export nearly doubled. Transport systems and storage facilities have been pushed to their limits at times. Nonetheless, agricultural exports have not increased their share of total U.S. exports. Since the end of World War II, agriculture's share of total exports has remained at approximately 20 percent. TABLE 12.— The role of agricultural exports, 1930-80 [Calendar years] Agricultural exports Value (millions of dollars) 1 Period 1930-39 1940-49 1950-59 1960-69 1970-79 ... .. 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 2 As percent of all exports As percent of farm cash receipts 785 2,294 3,593 5,864 19,668 30.6 22.5 22.3 21.6 20.5 10.5 10.7 11.4 13.9 22.1 22,997 23,636 29,384 34,745 20.3 19.9 20.8 19.5 24.1 24.2 25.4 26.2 40,500 19.3 29.1 1 F.a.s. (free alongside ship) value. 2 Estimates. Sources: Department of Agriculture and Council of Economic Advisers. The increased importance of exports, coupled with the disappearance of surplus grain stocks and nearly full use of the cropland base, has exposed U.S. farmers and consumers to an unaccustomed degree of instability in commodity prices. Part of this instability comes about because of unpredictable world weather, but much of it has been the result of our own policies and those of our trading partners. 117 Many nations have policies to shelter their economies from extreme fluctuations in commodity prices. The European Community, for example, maintains higher farm prices in member countries by varying duties on farm commodity imports and the subsidies on exports. These practices tend to make world commodity prices more variable by increasing the variability of European Community export and import levels. European food prices are therefore more stable than ours but are generally higher, with a resulting reduction in the European standard of living. Centralized trading decisions by other grain exporters and by most of the grain-importing countries have also tended to increase the volatility of world grain prices. Canada and Australia, for example, routinely impose quantitative restrictions on grain exports when domestic price stability is threatened. Furthermore, an increasing proportion of exported grain is going to countries that do not allow the free movement of prices to allocate resources internally. The centrally planned and certain developing countries, for example, rely on the United States and other major exporters for marginal supplies, making "needed" purchases without much apparent regard for price. Taken together, the efforts by other countries to stabilize their domestic food prices and supplies have shifted the costs of increased price variability onto farmers and consumers in the United States. Prices and income may vary at times as a result of international political considerations. The January 1980 ban on the sale of certain agricultural products to the Soviet Union originated from considerations other than the typical tug-of-war between consumer prices and farm income, namely, foreign policy considerations following the Soviet invasion of Afghanistan. The Administration was obviously aware of the potentially adverse economic effects of that sales suspension and took significant steps to minimize them. Unpredictable actions of other countries can also impose price shocks on the United States. A unilateral reversal in agricultural policy by the Soviet Union or China or a deterioration in East/West relations would have major implications for the U.S. farm sector. Thus, the fact that our growing food trade is now affected by international political affairs is a source of added risk to private investors in the agricultural sector. The need for stabilization mechanisms in this environment should be evident. Agricultural demand and supply are both quite inelastic in the short run. Small changes in either can lead to large changes in price. While such price movements serve the important economic purpose of allocating available supplies, they can also have disruptive consequences. Rising corn prices, for example, set in motion adjustments in the livestock sector that have implications for domestic meat 118 prices for years in the future, regardless of the size of succeeding corn harvests. The domestic livestock sector, in fact, is still making adjustments stemming from the very high grain prices of 1972-74. Grain Reserves Reserve stocks stand as the only real source of protection against inflationary rises in the price of food in market economies during periods of short supply. They also cushion farmers against declines in the prices of agricultural commodities during temporary periods of overproduction. If the flow of information and the credit markets were perfect, private agricultural stocks might be expected to provide the needed price stabilization. But the flow of information and the credit markets are not perfect. Moreover, private holders of agricultural commodities are unlikely or unable to take account of macroeconomic effects when they make decisions on whether or not to store commodities. The program of farmer-owned grain reserves implemented by the Administration in 1977 (discussed in the 1980 Report) has proved to be a popular, flexible, and efficient mechanism to cushion price shocks. The Administration's initial stock objective was achieved by early 1979, when more than 11 million tons of wheat and 20 million tons of feed grains had been placed in reserve. When prices then increased because of reports of a smaller-than-expected Soviet harvest, the stocks were released. By mid-October 1979 farmers had withdrawn over 40 percent of the wheat and sorghum and more than 25 percent of the corn in the reserve. When sales to the Soviet Union were halted in early 1980, stocks flowed back into the reserve and helped keep farm prices from falling as much as they would have without it. Those stocks are now available to help offset the adverse effects of the 1980 summer drought. Clearly, grain prices and farm income over the past 4 years would have been more volatile without such a compensating mechanism. It is also probable that export earnings were increased because more grain was available for export during periods of high prices. In any case, the availability of large reserves allowed us to retain our export markets and enhance our reputation as a reliable supplier even in periods of short world supply and high prices. Moreover, the only nonrecoverable taxpayer costs of this program have been payments for storage and interest costs on the Commodity Credit Corporation (CCC) loans extended to farmers when grain was placed in the reserve. The Reduced Need for Subsidies The improving economic health of the Nation's farmers suggests that subsidizing farm income is less essential today than it was in the 119 past. The growing importance of exports makes it more likely that the benefits of U.S. grain reserves will accrue disproportionately to foreign customers. Together, these observations suggest two things: first, that grain sold from the reserve should be priced high enough to cover not only the cost of grain production but, if possible, program costs as well; and second, that the incentives to place grain in reserve should be no greater than necessary to meet our objective of price stabilization. Present policy, including administrative procedures and legal authority, does not serve either of these objectives as well as it might. Current law, for example, requires waiver of the interest that would normally be paid by farmers on CCC loans and taxpayer payment of the storage costs. Thus, if the grain is sold at a lower price than would be required to cover these carrying costs, export customers benefit because American taxpayers subsidize the storage of grain. But if grain from the reserve is sold at prices high enough to cover these costs, farmers receive a windfall profit that may be unnecessary to assure the accumulation of reserves that will accomplish the price stabilization objective. By requiring farmers to pay the storage costs and the interest on the loans, the beneficiaries of the reserve (both U.S. and foreign customers) would be paying for the system's operation. Requiring farmers to pay such costs would, however, probably result in reserves too small to accomplish the price stabilization objective. To attract the desired stocks, farmers might be offered higher loans for grain entering the reserve. The most efficient way to acquire a reserve of a given size would be to require farmers to bid for the right to place grain into the reserve. Under such a plan, farmers offering to place grain in reserve at the lowest loan rates would be authorized entry. The flexibility granted by the Agricultural Act of 1980, which authorizes higher-than-normal loan rates for grain entering the reserve, might be used to implement such a plan. Legislative changes would, however, be required to allow the farmer to pay storage and interest costs. In addition to subsidizing the grain reserve, the Federal Government has subsidized the use of key agricultural inputs. Programs under which the Federal Government has shared with farmers the costs of soil conservation, land development, pest control, and the like, have been commonplace. As farm exports grow, so will the extent to which such subsidies transfer national wealth to export customers. To avoid unintended transfers, the resources committed to agriculture must be properly priced. This means, for example, that the price of exported grain should reflect the full costs of transporting it. Similarly, the Nation's limited natural resources, such as un- 120 derground water resources once thought virtually unlimited, should now be priced to more appropriately reflect their limited availability. FUTURE CAUSES OF RISING FOOD PRICES When food prices soared upward in 1973, many economists saw it as a temporary deviation from the longer-term trend, and the apparent return of surplus production in 1976-77 helped support this notion. But food prices did not fall to their earlier trend line (Chart 6). While exhibiting the same increase in variability as commodity prices, food prices remained high relative to other prices throughout the 1970s, and additional price increases are likely for at least the first half of the 1980s. The Rising Demand for Output Projected increases in exports and in the use of grain domestically for animal feed indicate sustained upward pressure on commodity prices for the next several years. Other economic forces will place still more pressure on agricultural resources, particularly cropland. Rising energy prices, for example, are increasing the demand for natural fibers, primarily cotton. High sugar prices and the expanding use of sugarcane for ethanol production in Latin America are expected to double the demand in the United States for corn as a sweetener by 1985. But perhaps most important is current energy policy which encourages the production of alcohol fuels from corn. This policy implies the need for an additional 370 million bushels of corn and a 5 percent increase in corn cropland by the end of 1982. The ethanol produced from the corn would replace about 60,000 barrels of oil per day—about 1 percent of U.S. oil imports. Other things being equal, such an increase in demand would increase the season average price of corn about 10 percent. The high cost of producing ethanol and the higher corn price, even when offset by the value of the ethanol by-products and an increase in export earnings, would mean that the Nation was paying nearly twice the present world price for each barrel of foreign oil displaced. The benefits of the gasohol program may be substantial and difficult to quantify, but its costs are large and its pressures on cropland significant. Furthermore, given the incentives already authorized, the amount of corn required for gasohol could more than double by 1985. Pressures on Farm Input Use By itself, a growing demand for agricultural products would not necessarily mean rising real prices. Advances in crop yield and other productivity gains throughout much of the postwar period made it possible to increase production in line with steadily growing demand without bringing high-cost, marginal resources into use. But this is 121 unlikely to happen in the future in part because of energy. In 1975, when data first became available, energy-intensive inputs (excluding fertilizer) accounted for 23 percent of the variable cost of producing an acre of corn. Those same inputs accounted for 31 percent of the variable cost in 1980. Higher real prices for these inputs will be a disincentive to their use and intensify the pressure to use additional land and water resources. These resources are also more limited. In 1972, for example, more than 16 percent of the cropland base was being withheld from production by government policies. None is being withheld today. To raise production further, land will have to be diverted from other uses and developed for crop production. The cost of doing so will be reflected in higher agricultural prices. Changes in policy, however, could help to ameliorate future increases in food prices. Certain land-use patterns remain fixed by acreage allotments. Fruit and vegetable growers sometimes restrict output or otherwise control marketing to enhance prices and then seek restrictive trade policies to protect those higher prices. Certain regulatory procedures now impose economic penalties on the use of technologies that would raise productivity in the food system. Such policies deny both producers and consumers the benefits of technological change. Finally, certain price support decisions continue to be statutorily dependent on movements in an outdated parity index that has little relation to product-specific costs of production. The dairy price support program is perhaps the best known example here. Such policies enhance the economic position of some farmers, while they perpetuate existing—but not necessarily efficient—patterns of resource use. Such inefficiency is particularly costly in a period of relative resource scarcity and limits agriculture's potential contribution to economic growth. POLICY DIRECTIONS FOR THE 1980s Significant progress has been made over the past 30 years in adjusting U.S. agricultural policies to a changing world. More importance has been placed on the allocative function that can be performed by prices, and there is significantly less direct government interference with producer decisionmaking. This Administration's farm policies have contributed to the evolutionary process. The implementation of a farmer-owned grain reserve program stands out because of its flexibility and its success in moderating price fluctuations stemming from changes in production and consumption levels. Additionally, the recent formation of a government-owned food reserve increases the likelihood that food will be available to foreign nations during emergency situations, even when world prices are high and commercial supplies are limited. The 1980 passage of a statute permitting the creation of a partially subsidized, 122 comprehensive, actuarial crop insurance program means that there will be a more equitable sharing of natural disaster risk between farmers and taxpayers. Eventually this new program—which expands the private sector's role in insuring farmers against such risks—will replace the more limited free insurance that is now provided for certain farmers through the fully subsidized disaster payments program. Future changes in agricultural policy must build on this foundation. In particular, attention must be given to the use of natural resources. Past agricultural policies have treated land and water as gifts of nature. The need for pricing them in ways that more appropriately reflect their true social value will intensify. Specific programs must be developed for this purpose; conservation of soil and pricing of other natural resources can no longer simply be by-products of programs to enhance farm income. Taken together, these policy issues point to a broader reliance on market forces, but the critical importance of food to national security will dictate a continued role for government in determining agricultural policy. Finding new and more flexible ways to use resources more efficiently while guarding against price volatility will be the principal farm policy challenge of the 1980s. TRENDS IN INDUSTRIAL AND LABOR MARKETS The preceding sections described developments in energy, regulation, the financial markets, and agriculture that have put severe pressure on the economy's adaptive capabilities. Each case illustrated the need for policies that facilitate adaptation to future as well as current developments. These four areas are not unique, however. Throughout the economy, deep-seated trends are increasing the need for greater adaptability. INDUSTRIAL CHANGE One such trend is the elimination of previous competitive advantages in some sectors and the creation of new ones in others. In the case of automobiles, for example, competition on the basis of technological advances and fuel economy is replacing competition based on style and performance. Vehicles manufactured in large volume according to stringent quality standards and utilizing the latest technology are replacing vehicles whose style changed annually but whose technology evolved more slowly. The emergence of the so-called "world car," with its international sources of key components, is evidence that this remarkable change has not been limited to the United States. Nor are these kinds of competitive pressures new. Similar pressures over the years have occurred in textiles, apparel, and footwear. 123 In each of these industries today, the profitable U.S. producers compete in ways very different from their predecessors, whether by manufacturing specialty fabrics, blue jeans, or canvas shoes. What is new, however, are the widespread pressures for substantial adaptation due to recent changes in energy and capital markets. These pressures are also occurring at a time when the economy is growing slowly. In the past, growth has often served as a "shock absorber" to cushion change, but the slow pace of growth has made the problems of readjustment more painful. Furthermore, some of the industries experiencing intense change are large and highly visible regional employers. There is simply no easy way to absorb the closing of an integrated steel facility or an automobile plant that dominates its local labor market. Lastly, these pressures for job protection are occurring at a time when the changing composition of the labor force may be tending to reduce mobility. CHANGING LABOR FORCE COMPOSITION During the past decade, the number of people with jobs grew at record rates, and the average age and experience of workers fell. During the coming decade, the growth of the labor force will slow considerably, and the average worker will be older and more experienced. Both of these changes result from two related demographic phenomena: the maturing of the baby-boom generation and the rise in female labor force participation rates. From the end of World War II until the beginning of the 1960s, the Nation experienced a sharp rise in the number of births which temporarily reversed the long-term decline in birth rates. This generation began entering the labor market in the 1960s and the influx of new workers continued during the 1970s. The percentage of the population aged 16 to 24 rose from 12.1 percent in 1960 to 15.8 percent in 1970 and 17.0 percent in 1979. Female participation rates increased gradually during the babyboom years. An even greater increase in the number of women workers has occurred in more recent years. The rate of participation in the labor force increased from 34 percent to 39 percent between 1950 and 1965; by 1980, more than 51 percent of the country's adult women were in the labor market. The maturing of the baby-boom generation and the sharp rise in the number of working women meant that U.S. labor markets had to absorb record numbers of new and inexperienced workers. During the 1970s the civilian labor force increased at an average annual rate of 2.5 percent, compared to 1.1 percent during the 1950s and 1.7 percent during the 1960s. The influx of young workers, combined with an increase in the number of older workers retiring early, pro- 124 duced a decline in the median age of the labor force from 39 years in 1965 to 34 years in 1980. As discussed in Chapter 1, the economy did remarkably well in providing jobs for these new workers. In fact, the unemployment rates for white youths and adult women have not increased relative to those of prime-age men. Unfortunately this success was not evenly spread across demographic groups. The high unemployment rate for young blacks, which has deteriorated considerably and is currently well above 30 percent, indicates serious shortcomings in labor markets or other social institutions. This unemployment problem has persisted in spite of substantial Federal efforts to improve the quality of primary and secondary education for minorities, to expand postsecondary training programs, and to provide on-the-job training in public sector jobs. During the next decade the number of people reaching adulthood will continue to be larger than the number reaching retirement age, but the generation entering the work force will be considerably smaller than the cohort which began work in the 1960s and 1970s. Even if female labor force participation rates continue their rapid rise, the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) projects that labor force growth will average only 1.3 percent per year during the 1980s. The decrease in entrants into the labor force during the next decade should have several effects. First, the increasing average age of the labor force will tend to lower the aggregate unemployment rate. The rate was higher during the 1970s at least in part because the transition from school or home to a job takes time; young people and women entering the labor market may be counted as unemployed during that search period. In addition, as they try out different career possibilities, new workers tend to change jobs more often than experienced workers, often with spells of unemployment between jobs. The transition to an older labor force will probably lead to some increase in productivity as the average level of experience rises. One estimate suggests that shifts in the age-sex composition toward groups with below-average experience reduced productivity growth by 0.4 percentage point per year between 1966 and 1973. Since then, the reduction has been about 0.2 percentage point per year. During the 1980s, changes in the age-sex ratio should raise productivity by 0.1 percentage point annually. Demographic changes will also tend to raise productivity by making it easier to increase the capital-labor ratio. Even if the capital stock only grows at past rates during the 1980s, the amount of capital per worker will grow as the rate of growth in the number of workers falls. Moreover, the relative growth in the number of middle-aged 125 members of the population, who typically have higher rates of saving than either the young or the elderly, should increase the Nation's saving rate and facilitate growth in the capital stock. But a third effect of the rising average age and experience of the labor force will be a decrease in flexibility. Shifts in the demand for labor by region, industry, and occupation are most easily met when young workers just entering adulthood are available to move to areas where the growing sectors of the economy are located. These younger workers are not tied to the skills gained from long experience in one job, they generally do not own homes, and their ties to communities are weaker. Further, young workers normally have more years over which to recoup the costs of acquiring new skills or moving to a new community. Older experienced workers and individuals in two-earner families are often much less flexible in changing jobs, industries, occupations, or communities. If there is a decline in the demand for the type of labor they supply, they are less able and willing than younger workers to move or to abandon old skills or to learn new ones. Firms are less interested in absorbing the costs of training older workers for new careers. Therefore, although older workers are less likely to lose their jobs, if their jobs do disappear they are likely to have a harder time than young workers in finding a new job and are likely to be unemployed for a longer time. Thus, although total unemployment rates will tend to fall as the labor force ages, the percentage of workers unemployed for extended periods may rise. Although U.S. labor markets may become less flexible in the future, we currently appear to be able to find new jobs for displaced workers more rapidly than several major European economies. The more rapid the adjustment to employment shocks, the lower will be the percentage of workers unemployed for extended^ periods. Table 13 presents the long-term unemployed as a percentage of the total labor force for the United States, Germany, France, and the United Kingdom. Although these percentages undoubtedly reflect international differences in definitions of employment and in stages of the business cycle, they do suggest that American workers suffer less long-term unemployment than their European counterparts. However, the adjustment to new patterns of labor demand -in the economy of the 1980s may be more difficult than it has been in the past, and government assistance may be necessary to soften the shocks of structural change while promoting flexibility. Such programs can be designed to move workers to jobs or jobs to workers. The former include retraining programs for the unemployed as well as relocation subsidies to encourage them to move from depressed areas to communities with excess demand for labor. The latter in- 126 elude government investments in local infrastructure and investment subsidies to encourage expanding firms to replace contracting ones. Whatever combination of policies is chosen, efforts to cushion the shocks of adjustment should not themselves discourage adaptation. TABLE 13.—Long-term unemployment as percent of labor force, United States Year 1973 1974 1973-80 Germany France United Kingdom 0.89 1.00 0.43 0.94 1.57 1.66 1.22 1.11 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 2.63 2.41 1.92 1.34 1.14 2.38 2.40 2.34 2.25 1.92 2.64 3.06 3.47 3.72 4.42 1.80 2.73 3.25 3.40 3.35 1980 1.71 (M n 0) ... 1 Not available. Note.—Long-term unemployment is defined as 15 weeks or longer for the United States, 14 weeks for the United Kingdom, and 3 months for France and Germany. Source: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Devefopment. THE DILEMMA OF INDUSTRIAL POLICY Chapter 1 of this Report and the preceding sections of this chapter describe an economy facing increased pressure to adjust to changing economic circumstances in a period of restrained growth. The increase in Federal involvement in areas previously considered to be the domain of private decisionmakers has also been detailed. The recognition that increased adjustment is needed and that the resources to smooth the path of this adjustment are limited, has led some to propose an explicit "industrial policy" to guide the broad collection of Federal activities affecting individual industries and sectors. These proposals, and the conflicting pressures they have created, illustrate the dilemma stated at the beginning of this chapter: Increased Federal involvement in the economy carries with it both the potential to improve and the threat of reducing the economy's efficiency and adaptability. The steel industry, for example, faces a major financial burden in complying with clean air and water mandates. It is also beset with major problems of economic adjustment because of vigorous foreign competition, technological evolution, changes in labor and raw material costs, and geographic and compositional shifts in the demand for steel. Similarly complex circumstances have been developing in the auto sector for several years. In 1980 the combination of recession and sharply higher gasoline prices focused public attention on the domestic industry's longer term problems of coping with foreign competition, improving productivity, and retooling to meet the 127 changed needs of customers. Rubber is a third large U.S. industry that has been confronted by intense structural problems. The realization that many of the dislocations brought about by new conditions have been disproportionately concentrated in certain regions of the country, and growing recognition of the scale of investment in our industrial infrastructure necessary to meet all our social and economic goals, led to a broad-scale Federal review of policies for promoting and channeling investment, encouraging innovation, and dealing with labor-market disruptions. The President's Economic Revitalization Program, described in Chapter 3 of this Report, emerged from this review. Two central issues arose in these discussions: first, the extent to which the Federal Government ought to be involved in determining the pace of growth and decline in individual industries and regions— in other words, the extent to which the government ought to be involved in "picking winners" or supporting older industries that are faced with major adjustments; second, the extent to which the government ought to supplant the private sector in allocating capital if that is required by the objectives of industrial policy. The review concluded that either type of Federal intervention would go beyond the legitimate needs for balance, consistency, and flexibility in Federal actions affecting individual industrial sectors. For one thing, it is presumptuous to assume that successful identification of winning and losing industrial sectors is possible. Moreover, even within so-called "losing" sectors, individual firms often outperform many of the firms in "winning" sectors. As an example, one need only compare the outstanding performance of many "minimill" operators in the beleaguered steel industry to that of many less profitable firms in the highly touted semiconductor industry. Attempts to pick winners or reinvigorate declining industries introduce considerations into strategic industrial decisions that, while not now absent, are certainly less directly felt. Greater government involvement in the detailed workings of the economy has already increased the political aspect of economic decisionmaking and led to constant pressures for the Federal Government to aid firms, regions, and industries. Establishment of an explicit industrial policy, together with the authorities for implementing it, would intensify these trends. The consequences to the economy of reductions in efficiency and flexibility that often accompany government intervention have already been detailed in this chapter. But at least three special dangers would be associated with the development of an overt government role in picking winners: First, a successful policy of identifying and supporting promising sectors implies a willingness on the part of the government to let 128 some of the firms in the chosen sectors fail. A portfolio of venture capital investments designed to pick only winners typically ends up with a few large winners and many losers. However, the government's necessary sensitivity to income losses, intensified by the fact that it would bear a special responsibility for a chosen sector, makes it difficult, if not impossible, to tolerate such a portfolio. The more likely outcome—one frequently observed in other countries—would be a reluctance to abandon individual firms that fail. This could more than offset any gains achieved by the successful few among the chosen firms. Second, there could be a tendency to implement a strategy of picking winners by excessive reliance upon policies where the government has broader discretion (e.g., trade policies) rather than designing policies specific to the problem at hand. The resulting use of easily available, but not necessarily efficient, policy instruments would create an unbalanced response and introduce additional distortions and rigidities into the economy. Adding to this tendency would be the policymaker's inevitable recognition that a policy tool designed for one purpose can often be used for another. For example, the economic prospects of an industry could be indirectly manipulated by changes in the stringency of government regulation. Such changes, however, when motivated by objectives of industrial policy, might be counterproductive to achieving the purpose for which the regulation was intended. Third, to avoid "wasteful duplication," the government would be likely to centralize the process of picking winners. Such centralization would forgo the advantages of risk-diversification that come from decentralized decisionmaking and would further heighten the pressures to protect losers among the chosen sectors. Similar arguments would apply to policies aimed at manipulating the normal workings of capital markets. While prudence argues strongly for policies which remove impediments to the efficient allocation of capital, prudence also suggests that a centralization of explicit allocation authority would run counter to the overriding need for flexibility in the present economic environment. PREFERRED POLICY APPROACHES While it is inappropriate for the government to utilize its policy instruments to support winners and discourage losers or to centralize the allocation of capital resources, government policies can be used in appropriate ways to make a difference in the economy at large and in individual industries. Tax policies, for example, can influence the level of investment and risk-taking in the economy as a whole without excessive intrusion into the affairs of individual firms or industries. Although regulatory policies, by their very nature, constitute greater 129 involvement in the operation of individual firms or individual sectors, they too can be designed to attain their goals with minimal intrusion and can take into account the circumstances of individual industries. Trade policies also shape decisions in individual markets. Without choosing winners and losers, it is still possible for the government to reduce constraints to free international transactions, to police these transactions for violations of national law and international trade agreements, and to screen individual cases carefully to afford relief from unfair import competition. Agricultural policy decisions can be designed to reduce instability in that sector and to ensure that those receiving the benefits of such policies also pay for the burden such policies impose. Similarly, the continued deregulation of financial institutions can assure the aggressive pursuit of efficiency and innovation in that sector. Labor market policies can try to help workers in declining regions or industries adapt more rapidly and with less human suffering to changing conditions. In sum, recognition that the numerous policies of the Federal Government exert a substantial influence on individual sectors of the economy leads logically to a search for coherence in policy. The pursuit of such coherence is both justified and desirable when it involves the thoughtful coordination of policies in areas where government intervention is necessary. The danger lies in the unwise manipulation of policy variables designed for one set of purposes to attain goals which can be better achieved by the private market. 130 CHAPTER 3 The Economy: Review and Prospects THE U.S. ECONOMY IN 1980 felt the effects of the huge 1979 oil-price shock. The 5-year recovery and expansion that followed the 1974-75 downturn came to an end with a sharp but brief recession and the underlying rate of inflation moved up to the 9- to 10-percent range. The most striking feature of the year, however, was the volatility of economic developments. Real gross national product (GNP) declined at a record rate in the second quarter but advanced thereafter, producing the briefest recession on record. Interest rates surged to record heights, plunged downward, and then rose to new peaks and declined again, all within the space of 9 months. Overall, these developments made for a historically unprecedented year. While the outlook is for only a modest pace of recovery in 1981, the persistence of unacceptably high inflation and the Nation's vulnerability to energy shocks call for continued restraint in both monetary and fiscal policy. A modest-sized tax cut combined with restraint in Federal spending, however, would be compatible with this prudence. And if, as the Administration has proposed, a substantial part of the tax cut is oriented toward business investment, we can help support the recovery in a way that comes to grips with the country's longer-run needs. A REVIEW OF 1980 The resilience that had characterized the economy during 1979 ultimately gave way to pressures from sharply higher energy prices and policy measures undertaken in the fight to cool inflation. Over the 4 quarters of 1980 real GNP fell 0.3 percent, but the pattern during the year was quite uneven. The first quarter's 3.1 percent annual rate of growth in real GNP was followed by a record 9.9 percent rate of decline in the second. After midyear, much to the surprise of most economic forecasters, the economy rebounded; real GNP grew at a 3.1 percent rate during the second half of the year. (All national income and product account data for the fourth quarter of 1980 are based on highly preliminary estimates.) The weakness of the economy during the first half of 1980 led to significant deterioration in labor markets. The unemployment rate 131 rose from 6.0 percent in December 1979 to 6.3 percent in March and then spurted to a peak of 7.6 percent in May. The rate remained between 7.4 and 7.6 percent for the rest of the year. During the first half of the year, employment declined by 1.0 percent, a decline of 1 million jobs. From June to December, employment grew 0.5 million, thus reversing a substantial portion of the first-half loss. The labor force grew 1.3 percent over the 4 quarters of the year. The rate of inflation increased in 1980. The implicit price deflator for GNP rose 10.0 percent over the 4 quarters of 1980, a 1.9 percentage point increase over the 1979 rate. For the 12 months ending November 1980 the consumer price index (CPI) for all urban consumers rose 12.6 percent—the same rate of increase as in the 12 months ending in November 1979. Due to the special circumstances created by increases in the prices of food and energy, and the treatment of home purchase and finance in the CPI, this latter comparison understates the rise in inflation in 1980. Excluding these factors, the CPI rose 9.9 percent as compared with 7.2 percent in 1979. Wage rates, which had shown moderation during 1979 despite the rise in inflation, accelerated in 1980. Average hourly earnings grew 9.3 percent, up 1 percentage point from the 1979 rate. For the year ending with the third quarter of 1980 productivity was virtually unchanged, although this was an improvement as compared with the 1-percent decline recorded in 1979. The year saw continued improvement in the U.S. international position. After absorbing the huge 1979 increases in our foreign oil bill, the U.S. balance of payments moved sharply into surplus in the second half of the year. All other major oil-importing countries, by contrast, are experiencing substantial current-account deficits. The U.S. dollar remained strong in relationship to other currencies throughout much of the year. At year-end, on an average weighted basis, its value was 6 percent higher than at the beginning of the year. The United States reduced its total energy use in 1980. In addition, as compared with 1979, oil imports declined by 20 percent to about 6x/2 million barrels per day at year-end. In 1980 we imported less oil than in any year since 1975. While a portion of this reduction can be traced to weakness in economic activity, much was due to intensified conservation efforts that have followed the recent rapid increases in energy prices. AN OVERVIEW OF THE YEAR The slowing in the growth of the economy that occurred in 1980 was largely the consequence of events that began in 1979. The first of these was the significant disruption in the world oil market triggered by lost Iranian oil production. Extensive efforts to 132 build up oil inventories and maintain adequate supplies boosted the price of imported oil purchased by U.S. refiners by 94 percent during 1979. This, together with the phased decontrol of the prices of domestically produced oil, resulted in the average refiners* acquisition price for all oil in the United States rising from $13 per barrel in January 1979 to $24 per barrel in December 1979. This huge increase added to inflationary pressures and reduced purchasing power. The Council of Economic Advisers has calculated that the drag on purchasing power due to these higher oil prices reached 2 percent of GNP during 1979. A second restraining force evident at the end of 1979 was the stance of monetary and fiscal policy. A major goal of macroeconomic policy since early 1979 has been to minimize the inflationary consequences of the oil-price shock by avoiding the spillover of accelerating consumer prices into wage demands, then higher business costs, and eventually higher long-term inflation. The Federal high-employment budget surplus (discussed in more detail later in this chapter), which had increased by $7V2 billion in 1978, tightened an additional $13Y2 billion in 1979. Efforts to restrain growth in money and credit resulted in rising short-term interest rates during 1979, especially in the second half. From July to December 1979 the 91-day Treasury bill rate rose from 9.3 to 12.1 percent, while the prime rate increased from 11.5 to 15.5 percent. A third source of potential demand restraint, which became evident at year-end 1979, stemmed from imbalances in the spending behavior of households. In the last half of 1979 real disposable income rose 1 percent, while real consumption spending advanced 2 percent. As a consequence, the personal saving rate fell 0.9 percentage point during the last half of 1979 to a 28-year low of 4.7 percent in the fourth quarter. At the same time, consumer debt burdens remained high and delinquency rates on consumer loans continued to rise. It seemed clear that some significant retrenchment by the consumer was likely, even in the absence of further oil drag and continued policy restraint. In light of these developments, it was expected that 1980 would be a year of declining economic activity. Indeed, 1 year ago this Report stated: "The expected recession is likely to be mild and brief. Declines in real gross national product (GNP) should not extend much past midyear, and economic growth will resume later this year, albeit slowly at first. Over the 4 quarters of 1980 real GNP is forecast to decline by 1 percent . . . the unemployment rate is likely to rise . . . to 7V2 percent in the fourth quarter . . . " Despite the general accuracy of last year's forecast, views about the likely course of the economy went through several rapid changes as the year unfolded. 133 Early in 1980 there were few signs of recession. If anything, activity seemed to be picking up. The evidence available at the time hinted that households, far from retrenching, were on a buy-in-advance spending spree. Retail sales, which had risen at an annual rate of 13 percent from October 1979 to December 1979, accelerated to an annual rate of nearly 43 percent in January 1980. Auto sales, which had been running at an annual rate of 9.4 million units in October 1979, spurted to 10.3 million units in December 1979 and to 11.9 million units in January 1980. International events contributed to the sense that demand could be stronger than anticipated. Continued Mideast instability, the unresolved issue of the American hostages in Iran, and the Soviet invasion of Afghanistan all raised the possibility of greatly expanded defense spending, perhaps enough to sustain economic growth despite a predicted slowing in private demand. The inflation data also seemed to reflect an apparent acceleration in economic activity. The CPI, which had increased at an annual rate of between 13 and 14 percent during the last 3 months of 1979, rose at a rate of 18 percent in January and February. Although a large part of this speedup was due to higher oil prices, other prices also accelerated. For the 3 months ending in February, the CPI excluding energy prices rose at an annual rate of 12.9 percent, in contrast to the 12.2 percent rate during the 3 months ending in November 1979. The producer price index (PPI) for finished goods other than energy rose at an annual rate of 16% percent in January 1980. More ominously, wage rate increases, which had remained moderate throughout most of the year, accelerated in late 1979 and early 1980. Meanwhile, business demand for credit accelerated, with business loans growing at a rapid 24 percent annual rate from December 1979 to February 1980. Speculative activity in commodity and financial futures markets intensified, and interest rates continued their rapid climb (Chart 7). In early March the 91-day Treasury bill rate rose to 15.7 percent while the prime rate hit 17.75 percent. Several forces were apparently at work. Each new increase in short-term interest rates brought fears of higher rates, and thus further pressures to borrow immediately. In addition, hints of credit controls apparently motivated firms to borrow in advance of actual need. 134 Chart 7 Selected Interest Rates and Bond Yields PERCENT PER ANNUM 20 - 1111 j i 1111111 u 111111111111111111 1973 I.,,,.111...Inn.lnn.l.ni.ini..In...l.nnln..^ 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 LONG-TERM 14 12 10 1973 -L/EFFECTIVE RATE ON CONVENTIONAL MORTGAGES IN THE PRIMARY MARKET, SOURCES: DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY, BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM, FEDERAL HOME LOAN BANK BOARD, AND MOODY'S INVESTORS SERVICE. 135 By early March there was fear that inflationary pressures and inflationary expectations were mounting despite the restraining influences of fiscal and monetary policy, and that without some additional action these would validate and further accelerate wage demands and ultimately lead to an explosion of prices. This would have ended any chance of containing the 1979 oil-price shock. It was in this environment that the Administration and the Federal Reserve moved to suppress the speculative fever and return order to financial markets. On March 14 the President announced a series of budgetary and administrative actions designed to stabilize the situation. These included measures to reduce Federal expenditures, to strengthen wage and price monitoring, and to encourage energy conservation. In addition, the President authorized the Federal Reserve to institute a program of selective controls on credit. The controls program—explained in more detail below—induced banks and other financial institutions to intensify actions to restrict the availability of virtually all types of credit. The growth of bank business loans and other lending covered by the program was curtailed sharply. The program also had the important psychological effect of curtailing household borrowing, as many forms of credit not explicitly covered by the program, such as home mortgages and auto loans, also fell sharply. A good part of these declines, however, probably stemmed from the rapid rise in interest rates. Economic activity was apparently beginning to slow even before the imposition of the credit controls, but the subsequent decline in consumer demand was intensified by the controls. The economy reached its cyclical peak in January. Nevertheless, the first-quarter growth in real GNP was at an annual rate of 3.1 percent. During the second quarter real GNP dropped at an annual rate of 9.9 percent, exceeding the previous record of 8.2 percent set in the first quarter of 1975. Furthermore, the decline of 10.4 percent at an annual rate in real final sales was far and away the sharpest postwar drop in that category. Housing and automobile sales were the key sectors of weakness, accounting for about two-thirds of this drop in final demand. There was a modest amount of inventory accumulation but it was surprisingly small given such a large decline in final sales. Interest rates, which had continued to rise for a brief time after the introduction of the credit controls program, fell sharply due to weakening loan demand and a declining economy. Rates peaked around the end of March and then fell further and more quickly than they 136 had risen just 2 months earlier. By late June the credit controls were no longer constraining the demand for credit, and by July the prime rate had fallen to 11 percent, down from its peak of 20 percent. In light of these developments, the controls were removed in early July. After the second quarter's record drop in real GNP, most observers predicted that the economy would experience 2 more quarters of decline. There were fears that the downturn might approach the severity of the 1974-75 recession. Indeed, the unemployment rate, which had jumped to 7.6 percent in May, was forecast by many to be between 8¥2 and 9 percent by year-end. In fact, private demand rebounded with surprising alacrity. The sharp decline in interest rates, combined with the absence of a significant stock of unwanted inventories, contributed to the brevity of the recession. The two sectors that had led the decline in the second quarter recovered quickly in the third. By September, housing starts had increased 70 percent above their May low—by far the quickest bounceback on record. Car sales also regained some of their lost ground. October sales ran at an annual rate of 9.2 million units, still lower than their year-earlier levels, but 28 percent above their May low rate of 7.2 million units. The third quarter rebound in real final sales was a strong 4.1 percent, but inventory liquidation held the growth in real GNP to a more modest 2.4 percent. In the fourth quarter real growth picked up to a 3.7 percent annual pace, with continued strength evident in personal consumption and housing. With the turnabout in economic activity in the second half of the year, the labor market also improved. At the same time that the recovery was taking place, tightening monetary conditions produced another upswing in the interest rate roller coaster (Chart 7). From July to December the prime rate advanced from 11 percent to a record level of 21% percent, while the Treasury bill rate rose from 8 percent to 17 percent. Long-term interest rates also rose by about 2 to 3 percentage points over the same period. After mid-December interest rates dropped sharply for a time but nevertheless remained unusually high. These developments raise serious doubts about the future of the recovery and bring prospects of a leveling off or possibly a decline in output during the early part of 1981. Furthermore, the persistence of the Iran-Iraq war raises the possibility of sharply higher energy prices during 1981. At the end of 1980 the key features which had characterized the U.S. economy over most of the previous 18 months remain dominant: a surprising strength of demand straining against high interest rates, a stubborn inflation, and continued vulnerability to external oil shocks. 137 THE MAJOR SECTORS OF AGGREGATE DEMAND The decline of the economy during 1980 as a whole was dominated by drops in expenditures on real consumer durable goods (down 7.7 percent over the 4 quarters), residential structures (down 18.0 percent), and real business fixed investment (down 6.0 percent) (Table 14). The sectors of real demand that grew during the year were personal consumption of services, Federal Government purchases, and net exports. Service consumption grew 2.8 percent over the 4 quarters of 1980. Federal Government purchases were up 4.7 percent. Real net exports grew from $42.2 billion in the fourth quarter of 1979 to $55.7 billion in the fourth quarter of 1980. A 6.7 percent reduction in imports combined with a 3.9 percent rise in exports to produce this result. TABLE 14.—Growth in major components of real gross national product, 1976-80 [Change, fourth quarter to fourth quarter] ,1976 Component 1977 1978 1979 Percent change: Real gross national product Personal consumption expenditures Business fixed investment Residential fixed investment . ... Government purchases of goods and services Federal. State and local Real domestic final sales 2 4.4 5.8 5.3 1.7 -0.3 57 7.8 19.8 -1.3 50 13.5 12.5 3.6 48 9.0 -.0 1.6 20 2.9 -6.1 1.9 =6.0 -17.6 1.5 -.8 -1.7 5.0 2.7 -1.3 3.3 21 1.7 4.7 -.3 4.9 5.9 4.4 1.7 -1.3 .4 -.7 .4 .4 .2 .9 -.8 .8 .0 .9 Change as a percent of GNP: Inventory accumulation ... Net exports of goods and services . 1 Preliminary. GNP excluding change in business inventories and net exports of goods and services. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 2 Personal Consumption Expenditures The year 1980 began with the personal saving rate at a 28-year low, with consumer debt burdens near record highs, and with attitude surveys showing consumer pessimism about the outlook. The modest strength in consumption that had been evident in 1979 despite the deceleration in real incomes had worsened the budget position of households. This, together with high interest rates and the imposition of credit controls, produced a retrenchment in consumer outlays. Real personal consumption expenditures fell in 1980 for the first time in 6 years. The 0.3 percent decline in consumption over the year, combined with the modest 0.5 percent increase in disposable income, helped to increase the saving rate from 4.7 percent in the fourth quarter of 1979 to 5.7 percent in the fourth quarter of 1980 (Chart 8). 138 Chart 8 Personal Saving Rate PERCENT 15.0 12.5 - 10.0 - 2.5 - 1969 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE. The decline in consumption in 1980, which was largely the result of a decline in credit-sensitive purchases—particularly durable goods—was concentrated in the second quarter. In that quarter total real consumption fell at a record rate of 9.8percent. The improvement in household debt positions that had begun in late 1979 was accelerated during the late spring and early summer by the credit controls program. Extensions of consumer credit in the second quarter fell at nearly a 60 percent annual rate. Outstanding consumer debt declined for 4 straight months from April to July, and for the second quarter as a whole it fell at a record 13.8 percent annual rate. The rapid drop in interest rates helped to bring a quick reversal of the second quarter's consumption decline. In June real retail sales grew at a 17.8 percent annual rate; the gain in July was at an even greater 27.3 percent pace. For the third quarter as a whole real consumption advanced at an annual rate of 5.1 percent, regaining nearly one-half of the second quarter's drop. In the fourth quarter real consumption grew at a 3.3 percent annual rate. Durable Goods. Real expenditures on consumer durables fell 7.7 percent during 1980, their second year of decline. The consumer durables cycle during 1979 and 1980 was much like that of the 1974-75 recession. During the first half of 1980 real consumer durable goods 139 expenditures continued the virtually unbroken decline that had begun after the fourth quarter of 1978. Over this period purchases of real consumer durables declined 16.3 percent, with the steepest drop concentrated in the second quarter of 1980. A long and gradual slide culminating in 1 quarter of very steep decline was also the pattern during 1974-75; the peak-to-trough decline then was also 16.3 percent. During the last half of 1980 real consumer durable expenditures regained nearly one-half of the second quarter's decline. Growth in the third quarter was at an annual rate of 21.9 percent. Growth in the fourth quarter was at a rate near 7 percent. Automotive purchases dominated quarter-to-quarter movements in consumer durables during the year, leading the first-half declines as well as the last-half gains. By year-end car sales were running at a 9-million unit rate, but sales were apparently being held back by a combination of the high interest rates on consumer loans and high car prices. Real automotive purchases fell 12.9 percent during 1980oas a whole. Similar weakness was evident in real consumer demand for other durable goods, which fell 4.0 percent over the 4 quarters of 1980. Other Consumption. Real nondurable goods consumption fell 1.2 percent during 1980. Purchases of gasoline, oil, and other fuels fell 3.2 percent. In part this reflected the effects of the recession, but much of the decline in these energy demands was due to conservation efforts in response to sharply higher prices. By year-end the consumption of these goods was 11 percent below the peak levels set in 1978. Real consumption of services grew at a sluggish 2.8 percent over the 4 quarters of 1980, down from the 1979 pace of 3.6 percent. Service consumption tends to be much more stable than goods consumption over the business cycle because many of these expenditures, such as housing and medical care, cannot be delayed or postponed. Nevertheless, important cyclically sensitive components of service consumption were quite weak during the year. Transportation services, for instance, fell at an annual rate of 11.9 percent in the second quarter and 2.0 percent over the entire year. Residential Investment The path of real investment in residential structures over the last 2 years was like that of consumer durables. It was marked by a slow and gradual slide throughout 1979, ending with a very sharp decline in the spring of 1980. Residential construction picked up rapidly thereafter, but at year-end housing starts had leveled off in response to higher mortgage interest rates. The pattern of housing activity in 1979 and 1980 reflected new developments in housing finance. As noted in Chapter 2, mortgage lenders now compete for loanable funds on a more even footing with other lenders. Consequently, the 140 chief cyclical determinant of housing activity has become interest rates rather than credit availability. As events have demonstrated, however, these institutional changes did not insulate housing from tighter monetary conditions. The financial environment that determines the health of the housing sector had been weakened by the sharp rise in interest rates that began in 1979. By October of that year, most mortgage rates had risen to around 13 percent, a level that discouraged many potential home buyers. At the same time, increases in construction loan rates stretched the ability of homebuilders to finance new construction and carry inventories of unsold homes. This trend was accentuated in early 1980 by a further rise in interest rates on mortgage commitments to a record 16 percent in April. The increased interest rates pushed monthly mortgage payments higher than many could afford. In addition, even though mortgage finance was largely exempt from the provisions of the credit controls program, mortgage lenders were less willing to commit long-term funds in such an uncertain environment. During the year State and local government housing authorities continued to provide a substantial amount of mortgage support through purchase of residential mortgages at below-market interest rates financed by tax-exempt bonds. But Federal and related agencies provided only modest support to the mortgage market as compared with the last cyclical downturn. Home sales reached their nadir by late spring. Housing starts in May plummeted to a 906,000-unit annual rate, down 36 percent from their January level and down nearly 50 percent from their average 1979 level. During the second quarter single-family starts averaged 671,000 units at an annual rate, which was only slightly more than one-half 1979's total. Multifamily units fell to a rate of 382,000 units in the second quarter after averaging 551,000 units during 1979. The midyear decline in mortgage interest rates lagged somewhat behind the drop in other long-term yields, but by August most mortgage rates had fallen to near 12 percent. Even with the high interest rates, however, sales of new homes had begun to increase in May, and construction activity followed quickly. Housing starts increased in June for the first time in 6 months. The surprisingly quick increase in starts probably stemmed from the relatively low level of new home inventories during the spring. With very few houses for sale, the increase in sales provided the needed stimulus for new building. During the fall and early winter of 1980 mortgage rates again began to creep upward. Nonetheless, sales of new homes and total housing starts remained moderately strong through November. Although some weakening in sales was evident during the fourth quar- 141 ter, the low level of inventories encouraged a continuation of building activity. The average price of a new home (adjusted for changes in quality) increased at an 11 percent annual rate in the first 3 quarters of 1980, which was about as fast as in the preceding year. Many of the homes built in 1980 were smaller and more austere than those constructed in preceding years, reflecting the recession weakness in incomes and the high cost of mortgage finance. Business Fixed Investment Real business fixed investment declined 6.0 percent over the 4 quarters of 1980. Business fixed investment averaged 10.7 percent of GNP, somewhat lower than the 11.0 percent level in 1979. Producers* durable equipment declined 4.8 percent during 1980. The volatile automotive portion of equipment purchases fell 16.2 percent during the year, its second year of very large declines. The remaining components declined 2.4 percent. Investment in nonresidential structures dropped 9.1 percent over the same period (Table 15). TABLE 15.—Changes in real businessfixedinvestment, 1975-80 [Percent change, fourth quarter to fourth quarter] 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 > -7.4 7.8 13.5 9.0 2.9 -6.0 Structures Producers' durable equipment -56 -8.0 2.6 10.2 48 17.4 118 7.7 95 -91 -4.8 Autos, trucks, and buses Other 2.0 -10.4 17.2 8.5 23.9 15.7 Nonresidential fixed investment 9.8 - 2 2 . 9 - 1 6 . 2 7.2 7.4 = 2.4 1 Preliminary. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. Several factors contributed to the decline in business fixed investment. First, the deceleration in final sales reduced the need for immediate additions to capacity. The Federal Reserve Board's index of capacity utilization rates in manufacturing dropped from 83.9 percent in January to a 5-year low of 74.9 percent following the spring decline. The sizable drop in this aggregate index, however, masked some important differences among certain industries. In the durable goods materials industries, for instance, capacity utilization rates fell below 70 percent. Thus key suppliers of hard goods found themselves with plenty of capacity to satisfy demand over the near term. In addition, forecasts of recession indicated that capacity needs would not be rising until early 1981. These forecasts, in conjunction with the high cost of funds during the early part of 1980—widely perceived as temporary—made the delay of capital investment plans more attractive. Finally, shrinking sales and increasing debt service costs seriously reduced corporate cash flow. Internally generated funds for invest- 142 ment were sharply diminished by the 13.3 percent decline in profits during the second quarter of 1980. While aggregate measures of profitability and corporate cash flow reflected cyclical weakness, these measures understated the extent of the problem by masking important distributional imbalances. In particular, oil and coal industry profits represent a growing share of the aggregate. From the first quarter of 1979 to the third quarter of 1980 corporate profits in the petroleum and coal industries grew from $15.0 billion, or 6.9 percent of total corporate profits, to $22.2 billion, or 11.3 percent. Inventory Accumulation Cautious inventory policies continued throughout 1980. Real inventory accumulation in the fourth quarter was virtually unchanged from its level in the fourth quarter of 1979 and thus had almost no impact on the overall growth in real GNP over the 4 quarters of 1980. Chart 9 Real Inventory—Final Sales Ratio, Nonfarm Business RATION 3.15 SEASONALLY ADJUSTED 3.10 3.05 3.00 2.95 2.90 2.85 2.80 275 < y Q < , , . 1 . . . 1968 69 I . , , 70 I , I 71 • I . I . 72 I • I I 73 1 . • • 74 I I . I 75 I . . • 76 I • I . 77 I 1 . I 78 I . I I 79 I . I I > 80 VRATIO OF REAL INVENTORIES AT END OF QUARTER TO REAL FINAL SALES AT MONTHLY RATES. SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE. As compared with the 1970s, inventory-to-sales ratios remained relatively low during 1980 (Chart 9). What was more interesting was the rapid response of production to the changes in final sales. As 143 Table 16 shows, the pattern of output, sales, and inventories in the nonfarm business sector in 1980 was quite different from the pattern of the 1974-75 recession. A sharp drop in final sales in the fourth quarter of 1974 was accompanied by a smaller percentage reduction in output. This resulted in an unintended accumulation of inventories, with real inventory investment of $13.3 billion at an annual rate. The inventory-to-sales ratio rose markedly. This set off a sharp adjustment in subsequent quarters, and over the first half of 1975 inventories were decumulated at a $13.9 billion annual rate. TABLE 16.—Real output, sales, and inventories, nonfarm business sector, 1974-75 and 1980 [Seasonally adjusted annual rates] Item 1974 III 1975 IV 1 ||. II 1980 |] 1 II IV1 III Percent change Output -2.8 -5.9 -10.6 6.1 1.7 -10.8 3.1 4.9 Contribution ofr32 Final safes Inventory accumulation -.9 -1.9 -8.0 2.2 -in 4.6 1.4 1.2 -11.4 4.3 -1.2 3.3 1.6 7.8 13.3 .6 =3.1 1.6 Billions of 1972 dollar Inventory accumulation -15.6 - 1 2 . 2 II - 1 . 4 1 Preliminary. 2 Change as percent 3 of output. Includes a small amount of final sales by farms. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. This sharp inventory cycle was not in evidence in 1980. Final sales fell at an annual rate of 10.8 percent in the second quarter, the most rapid decline ever recorded. But the output response was nearly as rapid and inventories increased at an annual rate of only $0.6 billion. While inventories did decline in the third quarter of 1980, indicating efforts to trim unwanted inventories, the swing was distinctly more modest than in 1974-75. Several factors account for the improved management of inventories. Inventory control and information systems continue to improve the ability of production managers to maintain the proper balance between raw material stocks and market demand. Also, unlike the earlier period, there were no serious doubts about the availability of raw materials and supplies this time around. Thus, precautionary overstocking of inventories to ensure adequate supplies of inputs for production was not apparent in 1979-80. In addition, high and volatile interest rates have increased both the cost and risk of holding large inventory stocks. The External Sector Following 2 years of rapid expansion, the growth in the volume of U.S. merchandise exports fell in 1980 as world economic activity slowed. At the same time, however, the volume of U.S. imports 144 dropped even faster, in large part because of the recession here. As a result, net exports measured in constant 1972 dollars showed a very large $13.5-billion increase during the year. In value terms, shifts in the U.S. trade balance were importantly affected by payments for oil. From the third quarter of 1979 to the first quarter of 1980 the oil import bill increased by about $20 billion at an annual rate because of much higher oil prices. Other trade flows only partially offset this increase, and the merchandise trade deficit widened by $15 billion to an annual rate of $43 billion in the first quarter. After the first quarter, however, the volume of oil imports declined sharply. Thus, despite some further increases in oil prices, the oil bill fell, contributing to the marked narrowing of the trade deficit. The merchandise trade deficit for the whole of 1980 was an estimated $26 billion, $3.5 billion smaller than in 1979. Invisibles transactions, which reached a record surplus of $33 billion at an annual rate in the first quarter, more than offset the deficit on merchandise trade during 1980. For 1979 the U.S. current-account deficit was a small $788 million. It was in deficit by about $10 billion at an annual rate in the first half of 1980, moved sharply into surplus in the third quarter, and is likely to show a surplus of $3-$6 billion for 1980 as a whole. The most noteworthy feature of recent U.S. trade performance has been its strength. From 1977 to the second quarter of 1980 the volume of U.S. exports grew by 40 percent. More significantly, the share of U.S. exports as a percentage of the total exports of the industrial countries over this period increased by about 1XA percentage points, reversing a declining trend visible since the 1950s. At the same time, the volume of U.S. imports showed almost no growth, even though real GNP rose by about 7 percent. This was a major break in longer-term trends, which have shown U.S. imports growing at rates well above the growth of real GNP. These aggregate indicators of recent trade performance are all the more striking in view of the widespread popular notion that the United States is losing its ability to compete in both foreign and domestic markets. It may be that these views stem from unwarranted generalizations from particular sectors—such as automobiles, where foreign pressure clearly has increased—to aggregate trade. In addition, it may be that losses in relative terms vis-a-vis certain trading partners—most notably Japan and a certain number of newly industrializing developing countries—are viewed as more significant. Each of these concerns is certainly legitimate to some extent, but they should not obscure the overall success of the United States in foreign trade. Encouragement can be drawn from our recent aggregate performance, which most analysts ascribe to the increased competitive- 145 ness of U.S. producers in the wake of the depreciation of the dollar in 1977 and 1978, Government Purchases of Goods and Services Real government purchases of goods and services grew 1.5 percent during 1980, as gains in Federal purchases more than offset the decline in State and local purchases. Over the 4 quarters of 1980 State and local purchases fell 0.3 percent. Reduced purchases of durable goods (down 1.6 percent) and structures (down 6.5 percent) were the key factors. Real compensation of employees grew 0.7 percent in 1980, a significant deceleration from the 2.4 percent average rate in the previous 3 years. There had been widespread expectations that reductions in Federal grant-in-aid support, particularly for public service employment payrolls, combined with the recession squeeze on tax receipts and political pressures for reduced growth, would force an even sharper cutback in the growth of State and local payrolls. Instead, State and local governments have attempted to insulate payrolls from the worst of the budget pressures while cutting expenditures elsewhere. The decline in structures investment over the year was heavily concentrated in those areas dependent on the housing cycle: sewer system construction and highway and street construction and renovation. Real Federal purchases of goods and services grew 4.7 percent during 1980. Real defense spending grew 5.7 percent during 1980, with the pace of spending picking up in the last half of the year. Real nondefense purchases grew at a slower 3.2 percent for the year as a whole. LABOR MARKET DEVELOPMENTS The volatility in demand for goods and services during 1980 produced similar swings in the demand for labor (Table 17). Civilian employment peaked at 97.8 million in February 1980. Then during the next 4 months employment fell sharply (1.1 percent) to 96.8 million in June. Over this same period unemployment rose from 6.5 million to 7.8 million. Automobile and construction employment were especially hard hit. Although these two industries constituted only about 6 percent of total payroll employment, they accounted for nearly two-fifths of the decline in employment from February to June. Employment growth resumed at midyear. The magnitude of the subsequent recovery differs, depending on which of the two standard measures of employment is utilized. Judged by the household survey, employment growth after midyear was relatively modest so that by year-end total employment was still 500,000 lower than in December 1979. When measured by data from business payrolls, however, em- 146 ployment grew more vigorously after midyear and by December 1980 stood some 450,000 higher than a year earlier. Statistical discrepancies of this sort are not unusual for changes over short periods of time. Even with this difference, both measures clearly indicate that the decline in overall employment during 1980 ended quickly. TABLE 17'.—Labor market developments, 1976-80 Component 1976 IV 1977 IV 1978 IV 1979 IV Percent change from year earlier Increase in civilian employment, total... 1980 IV l 3.4 4.4 3.6 2.1 -0.3 Males 20 years and over Females 20 years and over Both sexes 16-19 years 2.6 4.6 3.0 3.3 5.2 8.0 2.5 5.4 2.6 1.3 3.9 -.7 1.5 -6.7 White Black and other.. 3.3 4.2 4.3 4.7 3.2 7.0 2.0 2.9 -.2 -.9 Percent 2 Unemployment rate, total 3 .... 7.8 6.6 5.9 5.9 7.5 Males 20 years and over Females 20 years and over Both sexes 16-19 years 6.0 7.4 19.1 4.8 6.7 16.6 4.1 5.7 16.3 4.4 5.7 16.2 6.3 6.7 18.3 White Black and other.... 7.0 13.3 5.7 13.3 5.1 11.5 5.2 11.3 6.6 14.1 Participation rate, total * 61.8 62.6 63.5 63.8 63.7 Males 20 years and over Females 20 years and over.. Both sexes 16-19 years 79.9 47.4 54.4 79.9 48.6 56.8 79.8 50.1 58.4 79.6 51.0 58.1 79.2 51.4 56.4 White Black and other.., 62.1 59.6 62.9 60.6 63.7 61.8 64.1 61.7 64.1 61.2 1 Changes for 1978 IV adjusted for the increase of about 250,000 in employment and labor force in January 1978 resulting from changes in the sample and estimation procedures introduced into the household survey. 2 Seasonally adjusted. 3 Unemployment as percent of civilian labor force. 4 Civilian labor force as percent of civilian noninstitutional population. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. The impact of the year's labor-market weakness was spread unevenly across demographic groups. The unemployment rate for adult men rose by a much greater percentage than did the unemployment rates for women and teenagers. The total unemployment rate rose from 5.9 percent in the fourth quarter of 1979 to 7.5 percent in the fourth quarter of 1980. The unemployment rate for men 20 years and over rose from 4.4 percent to 6.3 percent during this period. By contrast, the unemployment rate for women 20 years and over only increased from 5.7 to 6.7 percent. In the third quarter of 1980 the adult male unemployment rate exceeded the adult female rate. While this is highly unusual, adult male unemployment rates typically rise more than adult female rates during recession. This is because output declines tend to be concentrated in construction and durable goods manufacturing, sectors with a much higher proportion of adult male workers than, say, the relatively stable service sector. In the fourth quarter employment recalls in such industries as autos, steel, 147 and construction helped to reduce the adult male unemployment rate below that of adult females. Unemployment duration lengthened significantly in 1980. In the last quarter of 1979, before the recession began, 48 percent of the unemployed had been looking for work for less than 5 weeks, and only 8.5 percent, or 524,000 people, had been without jobs for 27 weeks or more. By the last quarter of 1980 about 1.1 million people, or 14 percent of the unemployed, had been looking for work for 27 weeks or more. Many of these workers were eligible for up to 39 weeks of unemployment compensation, with additional benefits if their job loss was due to foreign competition or if their firms or unions provided supplemental unemployment benefits. During the 4 years of economic expansion from 1976 to 1979 the civilian labor force grew at an average annual rate of 2.8 percent. The rise in unemployment during 1980 dampened this growth to 1.3 percent. After increasing by about 1 percentage point per year during the last half of the 1970s, the female labor force participation rate grew by about one-half, rising to 51.6 percent in 1980. The male labor force participation rate of 77.4 percent was down slightly over the year. PRICE DEVELOPMENTS Inflation dominated the economic news in 1980 as it did in 1979. The implicit price deflator for GNP rose 10.0 percent over the 4 quarters of 1980, substantially faster than the 8.1 percent rate of increase in the deflator during 1979 (Table 18). The producer price index for finished goods increased 11.7 percent from December 1979 to December 1980, following a 12.6 percent rise during the preceding 12 months. For the 12 months ending in November 1980, the CPI increased 12.6 percent, the same as over the corresponding period in 1979. These measures all reflected energy price surges early in the year and farm price increases late in the year. The most disappointing news, however, was the acceleration in various price measures which exclude the direct effects of such special factors as energy and food. As explained in Chapter 1, such measures are often used as a proxy for the "underlying" rate of inflation. After remaining surprisingly stable during most of 1979 in the face of very large oil-price increases, these measures showed significant increases in 1980. The spring decline in aggregate demand brought rapid changes in the prices of certain sensitive industrial commodities. Sharp decreases were registered by producer prices of nonferrous metals as well as lumber and wood products. These price reductions had an important—if temporary—moderating influence on producer price measures. Excluding food and energy, producer prices of crude ma- 148 terials fell for a full third of the year. One other measure, the Bureau of Labor Statistics measure of spot market prices, fell 11.5 percent from February 1980 to June 1980. The turnaround in activity in the second half-year once again tightened industrial markets by enough to erase the early-year declines. Producer prices for crude materials excluding food and energy rose 10.6 percent in the 12 months ending in December 1980. TABLE 18.—Measures of price change, 1976-80 [Percent change, fourth quarter to fourth quarter] Item Implicit price deflators 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 > 2 Gross national product Personal consumption expenditures Private nonfarm business output Consumer prices, total Farm value of food Energy4 Home purchase and finance 5 All other ... .. . . . . .... Producer prices of finished goods, total Food Energy All other .... . . . . . . . 4.7 5.0 4.9 6.1 5.9 5.7 8.5 7.8 8.3 8.1 9.5 8.3 5.0 6.6 9.0 12.7 3 -12.9 6.2 3.8 63 6.4 8.2 8.9 61 17.5 7.5 13.4 73 7.4 36.5 19.8 79 •14.5 U8.9 =>17.7 3 98 2.7 6.9 8.7 12.6 12.0 -4.4 5.0 5.6 7.4 9.2 6.4 11.6 6.4 7.9 7.8 62.0 9.3 7.4 28.4 11.1 10.0 10.4 10.3 12.6 1 2 Preliminary. Seasonally adjusted data. November 1979 to November 1980. 4 Includes only prices for direct consumer purchases of energy for the home and for motor vehicles. 5 In both the table and the text, "home purchase and finance" consists of home purchase and financing, taxes, and insurance on owner-occupied homes. Sources: Department of Agriculture, Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic Analysis), and Department of Labor (Bureau of Labor Statistics). Consumer Prices As in 1979, the behavior of energy and food prices, together with the effects of mortgage interest rates on the CPI, attracted attention throughout the year. These are discussed in more detail below. Less marked by the public, but of more concern for the longer-run outlook, was the increase in the underlying rate of inflation as evidenced in the behavior of consumer prices after these special factors are excluded. The underlying rate, as approximated by the CPI excluding food, energy, and home purchase and finance, jumped from 7.2 percent in the 12 months ending November 1979 to over 11 percent in December, and it stayed in the neighborhood of 12 percent during the first quarter of 1980. From April to November the measure grew at an average annual rate of 9.0 percent, a slowdown from the pace in the first quarter, but noticeably above the 1979 performance. A second measure of the underlying inflation rate is the fixedweight price index for personal consumption expenditures excluding energy and food. This measure, shown in Table 19 along with the 149 previously discussed CPI measures, reflects a similar acceleration over the year as a whole. Over the 4 quarters of 1980 the index rose 9.6 percent, up from the 7.2 percent increase over the 4 quarters of 1979. TABLE 19.—Alternative measures of consumer price changes, 1980 [Percent change; seasonally adjusted annual rates] 1979 1980 Item Consumer prices, total Food 2 Energy Home purchase and finance 3 .... Other 137 16.9 13.6 7.2 12.1 10.2 25.6 26.7 7.6 5.9 53.3 25.9 11.3 6.5 22.5 27.4 9.3 13.3 3.8 .1 8.7 153 1.0 20.5 9.9 10.7 12.0 9.8 8.8 10.9 11.3 9.9 31.2 9.0 12.8 3.4 53.4 10.3 9.8 5.7 20.5 9.3 9.6 16.9 2.1 8.7 11.0 16.2 6.5 10.1 Personal consumption expenditures deflators: Implicit deflator, total price index, total.. Energy4 Other 1 Preliminary; changes for consumer prices based on 2 Includes only prices for direct consumer purchases 3 data through November. of energy for the home and for motor vehicles. In both the table and the text, "home purchase and finance" consists of home purchase and financing, taxes, and insurance on owner-occupied homes. * Gasoline and oil, fuel oil and coal, and electricity and gas. Note.—Fixed-weight price indexes are preliminary and subject to revision. Sources: Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic Analysis) and Department of Labor (Bureau of Labor Statistics). It is difficult to ascribe the acceleration of these measures at the beginning of 1980 to any single factor. It is likely that the most important cause was the pass-through of oil-price increases into other commodities. About half of all oil is used in the production and distribution of other goods and services. Oil-price increases therefore must eventually be reflected in final product prices. Similarly, as described below, the rapid advance in unit labor costs during 1979 and 1980 exerted further upward pressures on prices. Finally, the latter part of 1979 and the early months of 1980 saw an upsurge in expectations about inflation and an upsurge in consumer buying. In such an atmosphere business may well have raised prices ahead of increases in costs. The relative improvement in the underlying rate following the spring's decline in demand offers some support for this view. Prices of Energy, Food, and Housing The measures of the underlying rate of inflation omit the primary sources of month-to-month variability in consumer prices. In particular, half of the CPI is accounted for by energy, food, and home purchase and finance. And 1980 saw very volatile movements in these prices. Energy. Energy prices as measured by the CPI, which had climbed at a 55 percent rate in the 6 months between March and September 150 1979, slowed to a 19 percent annual rate in the last months of that year. During the fall of 1979 the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) announced an increase in the price of Saudi Arabian light crude oil of $6.00 per barrel. That was followed by a series of $2.00 per barrel increases in January, April, and August. These price increases were accompanied by the phased decontrol of domestic crude oil prices, which had begun in June 1979. The effect of these actions was a burst of price increases for oil products during the first 3 months of 1980, averaging an annual rate of almost 100 percent. Gasoline, for instance, which was priced at $1.04 per gallon in December, moved up to $1.23 per gallon in March. Similar increases were registered in other oil-related energy components of the CPI, in particular home heating oil. By the second quarter the burst of OPEC-related energy price increases began to play itself out. In the 5 months between May and October 1980 the energy component of the CPI grew at an average annual rate of just 1.7 percent. This was in quite marked contrast to the 40.4 percent average annual rate of increase experienced over the prior 5 months. By November gasoline was actually 0.8 cents per gallon lower than it had been in March, and heating oil was up only 1.9 cents during the same period. Thus, although the energy sector spent the year in the limelight, it was a major direct source of inflation only in the first quarter of the year. Food. Food prices in the CPI increased 10.6 percent in the 12 months ending November 1980, as compared with a 9.8 percent rise over the previous 12 months. The farm value of food increased nearly 15 percent over the period. Marketing costs increased about 9 percent. Over the course of 1980 the food price situation was quite volatile. During the first half, food prices increased less than 5 percent at an annual rate. During the second half, however, the rate of increase more than doubled. Recession-induced weakness in demand during the spring, followed by drought during the summer growing season, contributed to the acceleration in monthly food price movements. Prices of retail meat, which accounts for nearly 30 percent of all food spending at home, actually fell at an annual rate of 11.8 percent during the first half, and rose at a rate of 35 percent from June to November. The extended period of very hot and dry weather damaged crops in the Southwest (cotton, soybeans, sorghum, and peanuts) during the early summer. The adverse weather conditions persisted and moved north and east affecting the corn crop and meat production in July and August. As the summer progressed the full extent of the 151 crop damage became evident. Prices received for the major crops increased 20 to 30 percent during the second half of 1980. Housing. The home purchase, finance, insurance, and taxes component of the CPI is a matter of controversy. Ideally, a cost-of-living index should reflect the cost of shelter services provided by owneroccupied houses. For rented houses, this is precisely what is captured by market rents. Under current practice, however, the home purchase and finance component of the CPI in effect treats the purchase of a house as it would any ordinary good. But houses do not only provide shelter; they are also assets which yield a return. As a consequence, the movement of house prices reflects not only the cost of shelter but also the value of the investment. Since the CPI also assumes that part of the mortgage used to finance a house is "purchased," the confounding of consumption and investment considerations is exacerbated by the treatment of mortgage interest costs. The Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) has been concerned for some time with the adequacy of the homeownership component of the CPI. BLS, in fact, currently publishes several experimental indexes based on alternative treatments of homeownership. For the present, at least, the CPI tends to overstate the importance of home purchase and finance and, given the volatility of mortgage rates, to produce startling monthly variations in the CPL During the first 6 months of 1980 the home purchase and finance component of the CPI increased at a 27.6 percent rate, adding about 3 percentage points to the annual rate of inflation over the period. In July and August the fall in mortgage rates dominated the index. The home purchase and finance component fell at an annual rate of over 25 percent in July, and this decline was large enough to offset the increase in the other components of the index, resulting in an unchanged CPI from June to July. While this zero change in prices was widely regarded as a statistical anomaly, it was no more or less anomalous than the inflationary influence that the home purchase and finance component had imparted to the CPI throughout the first half of the year. This influence began to be felt again during the late fall and early winter as mortgage rates climbed to near their spring peaks. The home purchase and finance component promises to have a heavy impact on the CPI in the early months of 1981. WAGES, PRODUCTIVITY, AND INCOME SHARES As discussed in Chapter 1, the primary goal of anti-inflation policy during 1980 was to prevent the increase in oil prices from becoming a stimulus to higher wage settlements. The policy was motivated by the facts that the long-term behavior of prices of goods and services closely reflects the behavior of business costs and that wages, salaries, and fringe benefits account for roughly two-thirds of the total 152 costs of production. The evidence suggests that while the policy was partially successful, it was not able to prevent an acceleration of wages. As shown in Table 20, all measures of labor compensation accelerated between 1979 and 1980 to a level of about 9 or 10 percent. The largest wage gains were in manufacturing, where average hourly earnings grew 10.8 percent over the 12 months ending in December 1980. The smallest gains were in the construction industry (7.2 percent over the same period). TABLE 20.—Measures of compensation and-employment costs, 1977-80 [Percent change, third quarter to third quarter] Measure 1977 Average hourly earningsl index Compensation per hour . . Employment cost index2 Union. Nonunion .... . Union wage changes (total effective adjustment) . Adjustment resulting from:... Current settlement Prior settlement Escalator provision 1978 1979 1980 7.4 7.5 8.3 8.6 8.0 9.6 9.2 10.0 7.2 7.7 6.9 8.0 7.9 8.0 7.7 8.4 7.3 9.4 10.9 8.6 8.6 7.9 8.7 9.1 3.5 3.3 1.7 2.1 3.5 2.2 2.8 3.1 2.8 3.4 3.2 2.5 1 3 Data are for private nonfarm business sector, all persons. Changes are from September to September. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Although acceleration in wages, salaries, and fringe benefits seems to have taken place in both union and nonunion sectors, union wage gains continued to exceed nonunion wage gains. Uncertainty exists as to whether or not these results reflect the relative bargaining strength of union over nonunion workers, as well as the extent to which they mirror conditions specific to individual industries. These differentials may also result from the more prevalent use of cost-ofliving adjustments (COLAs) in union contracts. To the extent that inflation is unanticipated, workers under contracts with COLAs will tend to receive larger wage settlements than those without COLAs. For this reason, sudden increases in inflation rates may tend to widen union-nonunion wage differentials. Finally, the 1980 wage differentials may result from the fact that a number of important unions were able to maintain wage gains even though aggregate labor markets were slack. Major contracts were settled in 1980 in the aerospace, steel, telephone, and clothing and apparel industries. Despite the step-up in nominal wage increases, real wages continued to fall throughout 1980. However, as was pointed out in last year's Report, customary calculations of the real wage which use the CPI can be deceptive. Table 21 sets forth several calculations of real wage change utilizing alternative price indexes. The additional cost of imported energy was a major factor in real wage declines in 1980, as it was in 1979. Increases in the price of 153 imported energy eventually will reduce real incomes in the United States. This reduction must be achieved by some combination of price inflation, wage moderation, or shrinking profit shares. Wage bargaining aimed at preventing this can only transform the adjustment into a more inflationary one. TABLE 21.—Alternative measures of changes in real earnings per hour, 1978-80 [Percent change, fourth quarter to fourth quarter] Item 1978 1979 1980 l Average hourly earnings index Deflated by: Consumer price index (CPI) CPI with rent substituted for home-ownership CPI with rent substitution and excluding energy... Fixed-weight price index for personal consumption expenditures (PCE).. Fixed-weight price index for PCE excluding energy -4.3 -2.3 .1 =2.6 -1.1 -.2 -1.9 -1.1 -.2 -2.7 — 9 l!6 -2.5 Compensation per hour Deflated by: Consumer price index (CPI) CPI with rent substituted for home-ownership CPI with rent substitution and excluding energy.... Fixed-weight price index for PCE Fixed-weight price index for PCE excluding energy.. -.8 .9 ~u 1 Preliminary: CPI for fourth quarter 1980 based on data through November. Data are for the private nonfarm business sector, all persons. Changes for 1980 are third quarter to third quarter. Note.—CPI for all urban consumers used. Fixed-weight price indexes are preliminary and subject to revision. Sources: Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic Analysis) and Department of Labor (Bureau of Labor Statistics). 2 Incomes policies can help to moderate the inflationary response to an oil-price increase, but only if business and labor cooperate to achieve the necessary adjustment. Such a willingness supported the Council on Wage and Price Stability (CWPS) standards program through its first year, 1979. In that year, as was noted in the last Report, evidence suggested that the standards had helped to restrain wage inflation by 1 to IV2 percentage points. Since there was no evidence of widening profit margins, it appears that the CWPS program contributed to smoothing the adjustment to higher oil prices. While there is evidence that cooperation with the standards was also high in its second year, a combination of several program features seems to have reduced but not eliminated its impact. A widening of the allowable range of wage increase and an undervaluation of cost-of-living adjustments in multiyear contracts were important factors. Productivity Productivity growth continued weak in 1980, advancing a tiny 0.1 percent over the year ending with the third quarter. In 1979 private nonfarm business productivity had declined 1.1 percent. During the course of 1980 productivity growth fluctuated sharply. In the first quarter productivity was essentially unchanged. With the 154 sharp decline in output in the second quarter, productivity declined at a rapid 3 percent annual rate. This marked the seventh consecutive quarterly drop. With the resumption of modest economic growth in the third quarter, productivity rebounded sharply, rising at a 4 percent rate. The faltering productivity during the first half of 1980, combined with a more rapid rise in wages, resulted in an acceleration in unit labor costs. However, with the improvement in productivity in the third quarter, the increase in unit labor costs moderated substantially. For the year ending with the third quarter, unit labor costs rose 10 percent, a modest improvement from the increase recorded during 1979. Distribution of National Income The recession's impact was evident in the shifting distribution of national income during 1980 (Table 22). Compensation of employees, which had averaged 74.6 percent of national income over the years 1976-79, rose to 75.3 percent in 1980. This increase in the share of national income going to wage earners is the normal pattern in a recession. Employer contributions for social insurance continued to account for a growing share of the compensation total. Corporate profits and proprietors' income as a share of national income fell sharply to 14.8 percent in 1980, down from the 17.1 percent average share during 1976-79. The corporate profits share fell to 8.6 percent. The unusually high level of interest rates was responsible for boosting the net interest share of national income to 8.5 percent, its highest level in the postwar period. Net farm income fell in 1980 from its relatively high level in 1979. After adjusting for changes in inventory, net income from farming was about $24 billion for the TABLE 22.—Shares of national income, 1976-80 [Percent of total] 76 Item 1977 1978 1979 19801 Third quarter 1979 1980 Compensation of employees 75.1 74.5 74.5 74.4 75.3 74.3 75.3 Wages, salaries, fringe benefits, and other Employer contributions for social insurance Proprietors' income2 70.0 5.1 69.4 5.1 69.2 5.3 69.0 5.4 69.8 5.5 68.9 5.4 69.8 5.5 6.8 6.7 6.7 6.7 6.2 6.7 6.1 5.4 1.4 5.5 1.2 5.2 1.5 5.1 1.6 5.1 1.1 5.2 1.5 5.1 1.0 Nonfarm 2 .. Farm 2 Rental income3 Corporate profits 2 1.7 1.6 1.6 1.6 1.5 1.5 1.5 10.0 10.7 10.6 10.0 8.6 10.0 8.4 6.3 6.5 6.6 7.3 8.5 7.4 8.7 Net interest 1 Preliminary, 2 With inventory 3 valuation and capital consumption adjustments. Rental income of persons, with capital consumption adjustment. Note.—Quarterly figures based on seasonally adjusted data. Detail may not add to 100 percent because of rounding. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 155 year, 23 percent lower than in 1979. Net cash income, the cash available to farmers for capital expenditures and operator income, was less affected and fell about 6 percent. The deceleration in cash receipts for livestock and continued inflation in farm production expenses were the principal factors in the decline. ECONOMIC POLICY As in 1979, economic policy in 1980 aimed at stemming an acceleration in prices and wages. Both fiscal and monetary policy sought to restrain aggregate demand. As noted above, these policies were supplemented by a program of voluntary standards for wage and price behavior. Fiscal Policy Changes in the high-employment surplus (HES) are a useful measure of discretionary fiscal policy. The actual Federal budget deficit is affected not only by changes in discretionary policy, such as changes in tax rates or more rapid spending on defense programs, but also by the state of the economy. In particular, cyclical swings in incomes and employment affect tax receipts. Outlays for such programs as unemployment compensation and food stamps are similarly affected. These changes in receipts and outlays alter the budget deficit without any action by the Congress or the President. Thus, the actual surplus or deficit is a poor measure of discretionary fiscal policy. The HES measures what the surplus would be if the economy were at high employment. By evaluating the budget at a standard level of GNP, the measure abstracts from those changes in budget receipts and outlays that result from cyclical changes in GNP. The High-Employment Budget. When judged by this measure, discretionary fiscal policy remained tight in 1979. The high-employment surplus increased $13.5 billion in 1979 (Table 23). The chief factors in the tightening were the sluggish pace of outlay growth during 1979 (particularly for grants-in-aid), the inflation-induced increases in personal income taxes, and legislated increases in social insurance taxes. Over the 4 quarters of 1980, however, the HES fell by $6.8 billion. Two unusual factors were responsible for the apparent move toward expansion during 1980. First, the delayed effect on individual tax refunds and final settlements from the Revenue Act of 1978 lowered the HES by roughly $8 billion, starting in the first quarter of 1980. Second, due to large increases in interest outlays caused by 156 record high interest rates during the year, discretionary outlay changes appear larger than they actually were. By convention, interest payments are unadjusted in the calculation of high-employment outlays. In other words, high-employment interest payments are defined to be equal to actual interest payments. Thus, the high-employment surplus tends to understate the degree of discretionary fiscal restraint when interest rates increase, and vice-versa. Excluding these two factors, the high-employment budget surplus actually tightened by roughly $10 billion over the 4 quarters of 1980. TABLE 23.—Actual and high-employment Federal receipts and expenditures, national income and product accounts, calendar years 1973-80 [Amounts in billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] High-employment1 Actual Calendar year or quarter Receipts Expenditures Surplus or deficit ( - ) Receipts Amount Percent of 6NP Expenditures Surplus or deficit {-) Amount Percent of GNP2 1973 1974 258.6 287.8 264.2 299.3 -5.6 -11.5 -0.4 -.8 252.7 296.9 264.0 297.6 -1U -.7 -0.9 -.1 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 287.3 331.8 375.1 431.5 494.4 356.6 384.8 421.5 460.7 509.2 -69.3 -53.1 -46.4 -29.2 -14.8 -4.5 -3.1 -2.4 -1.4 315.8 354.7 390.7 441.1 504.2 344.9 374.8 413.8 456.8 506 5 29.1 201 23.1 -15.7 -2.2 -2.2 -1.5 -1.6 -1.1 3 538.9 601.2 -62.3 -2.4 573.2 591.6 -18.3 -1.2 I II |f| 488.4 494.0 515.8 538.6 -11.5 -8.1 -15.2 -24.5 -.5 IV 477.0 485.9 500.6 514.0 481.0 496.8 510.9 528.3 485.9 491.4 513.0 535.5 -2.1 -7.2 | || Ill IV3 528.4 520.9 540.8 565.4 564.7 587.3 615.0 637.9 -36.3 -66.5 -74.2 -72.5 543.2 556.6 581.8 611.2 560.6 577.9 602 5 625.3 17 4 21.3 -20.7 -14.0 1980 ... -.6 _,1 1979: 1980: -.3 -.6 -1.0 -1.4 -2.6 -28 -2.6 4.8 5.3 -.3 .4 -.1 -.5 -1.1 -1.4 -1.3 -.9 1 These totals differ from those published in the November 1980 Survey of Current Business because of revisions to both actual and potential GNP. For more information on these revisions, see Ihe supplement to this chapter. 2 High-employment surplus or deficit as percent of high-employment gross national product. 3 Preliminary. Note.—Detail may not add to totals because of rounding. Sources: Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic Analysis), Office of Management and Budget, and Council of Economic Advisers. Budget Outlays and Receipts. Federal budget outlays for fiscal 1980 were $579 billion, an increase of $85 billion, or 17 percent over the fiscal 1979 level. This marked acceleration in budget outlays was due largely to the combined impact of higher interest rates, growing unemployment, and increases in the cost of entitlement programs due to cost-of-living increases. Interest outlays jumped 23 percent in fiscal 1980, while outlays for income security and health, which include social security, unemployment insurance, and other major Federal entitlement programs, grew 19 percent. Together these three areas—health, income security, and interest—accounted for 61 percent of the change. In addition, defense outlays grew 17 percent in 157 fiscal 1980, up sharply from the 10 percent growth of the prior fiscal year. Federal budget receipts rose by 12 percent compared to 16 percent during fiscal 1979. The recession-induced weakness in incomes and the delayed impact of the Revenue Act of 1978 on individual tax refunds and final settlements combined to produce this result. Individual tax receipts grew 12 percent in fiscal 1980, down sharply from the 20 percent fiscal 1979 gain. Corporate tax receipts fell 2 percent in fiscal 1980. The Federal budget deficit increased from $28 billion in fiscal 1979 to $59 billion in fiscal 1980. Monetary Policy and Financial Markets As discussed in Chapter 1, the Federal Reserve adopted a new procedure in October 1979 to guide its daily open market operations. Under the new procedure, designed to exert better control over the growth of the monetary aggregates, the Federal funds rate is allowed to vary over a much wider range. In a report submitted to the Congress in February 1980, the Federal Reserve set forth its objectives regarding increases in the money and credit aggregates during 1980 (Table 24). These ranges called for a deceleration in monetary expansion in 1980 from the preceding year. TABLE 24.—Growth in monetary and bank credit aggregates, 1979-81 [Percent change] Federal Reserve longer-run ranges Actual 1980 IV to 1981 IV Item 1978 IV to 1979 IV to 1980 IV * 1979 IV M-1A M-1B M-2 M-3 Bank credit 5.0 7.6 8.9 9.8 11.5 2 1979 IV to 1980 IV Unadjusted for nationwide NOWs Adjusted for nationwide NOWs 5.1 7.1 9.6 9.7 3^ 4 6 6V& to 6 to SYz to 9 to 9 ^ 3 toSVfe 3% to 6 5Vfe to 8V6 6Y2 to 9% 0 to 2 % 5 to7Vi 5% to SYz SYz to SYz 7.8 6 to 9 6 6 to 9 to 9 1 Preliminary. 2 Estimate for fourth quarter 1980 based on November data. Note.—M-1A is currency plus private demand deposits, net of deposits due to foreign commercial banks and official institutions. M-1B is M-1A plus other checkable deposits (negotiable order of withdrawal accounts, accounts subject to automatic transfer service, credit union share draft balances, and demand deposits at mutual savings banks). M-2 is M-1B plus overnight repurchase agreements (RPs) issued by commercial banks, overnight Eurodollar deposits held by U.S. nonbank residents at Caribbean branches of U.S. banks, money market mutual fund shares, and savings and small time deposits at all depository institutions. M-3 is M-2 plus large time deposits at all depository institutions and term RPs issued by commercial banks and savings and loan associations. Bank credit is total loans and investments plus loans sold at all commercial banks. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Except for M-1B, the rates of growth of the various monetary aggregates during the year roughly matched or exceeded their 1979 pace. Some of the relative movements in the various monetary aggregates in 1980 were the result of special factors. At the beginning of the year the Federal Reserve had anticipated that funds attracted to 158 automatic transfer services (ATS) nationwide and negotiable order of withdrawal (NOW) accounts in the Northeast would cause M-1A to grow about one-half percentage point slower than M-1B. In fact, more funds flowed into these accounts from both regular savings accounts and demand deposits than was originally forecast. These developments boosted M-1B growth and lowered M-1A growth, each by about three-quarters of a percent relative to what they otherwise would have been. For the year as a whole M-1B, M-2, and M-3 exceeded their target ranges while M-1A did fall within its range. However, if one adjusts the target ranges for M-1A and M-1B in light of the actual experience with NOW and ATS accounts, then both of these measures fall roughly at the upper end of the adjusted range. Within the year, money growth, credit flows, and interest rates experienced unusually wide variations. The year began with money and credit demands apparently accelerating despite the sharp increase in interest rates in the fourth quarter of 1979. In February the growth of money and credit surged, boosting demand for reserves above the level consistent with the Federal Reserve's monetary growth ranges. The resulting pressures in money markets, combined with deteriorating inflationary expectations, forced both short- and long-term rates up sharply. Data available in early March suggested that credit growth had not been deterred by the general monetary tightening and the sharp increases in interest rates. Moreover, the increasing speculative activity in financial and commodities markets raised concern among many in the financial community about the threat of a financial panic. Extraordinary measures were called for to dampen excessive credit demands, reduce the spiraling inflationary expectations, and ease the strains in financial markets. On March 14 the President announced an extensive anti-inflation plan that included authorizing the Federal Reserve Board to implement certain types of credit controls under the provisions of the Credit Control Act of 1969. Operating under its own authority, the Federal Reserve also introduced a voluntary credit restraint program and tightened some already existing regulations, as detailed below. Taken together, the credit restraints were intended to reinforce traditional monetary policy measures that control overall money and credit growth while limiting the burden on certain sectors hard hit by high interest rates. Those sectors included small businesses, farmers, home buyers and builders, and auto dealers and purchasers. The measures were designed to restrain the growth of certain types of consumer credit as well as those liabilities of large banks that had been used to support a rapid buildjup in business loans. These 159 actions included: (1) a requirement that all types of lenders maintain on deposit at a Federal Reserve Bank a certain percentage of increases in credit card lending and otfrer categories of unsecured consumer credit; (2) an increase in the marginal reserve requirement on managed liabilities—including large time deposits ($100,000 or larger) with maturities of less than a year, Eurodollar borrowings, and security repurchase agreements—of large member banks and U.S. branches and agencies of large foreign banks; (3) an extension of special deposit requirements to increases in managed liabilities of large nonmember banks and to increases in total assets of moneymarket mutual funds; and (4) a surcharge of 3 percentage points on frequent borrowing by large member banks from Federal Reserve Banks. In addition, the Board announced a voluntary program under which commercial banks and finance companies would limit the growth in total loans to U.S. customers to 6 to 9 percent for the period from the fourth quarter of 1979 to the fourth quarter of 1980. Expansion of credit and money slowed abruptly after these measures were announced. The reaction of financial institutions, households, and businesses was sharper than anticipated. Banks and other financial institutions responded by accelerating and intensifying measures to restrict credit availability already in train; consumers and business sharply altered their credit behavior. Credit card sales and applications dropped off abruptly in March. Consumer installment credit outstanding declined in April for the first time in 5 years. Commercial bank lending to businesses moderated in March and then declined for the next 3 months. Over this same period the pace of monetary expansion slowed. During April all the monetary aggregates actually fell below their target ranges. The narrower aggregates declined for the second quarter as a whole. As evidence mounted that credit growth had been arrested, the Federal Reserve began to relax various provisions of the program. In early July the Board ended the program entirely, and the President revoked the Board's authority under the Credit Control Act. In retrospect, it appears that another factor contributing to the abrupt decline in credit growth was that interest rates finally had reached levels in late February and early March which were sufficient to discourage borrowing. However, data available at the time did not show this development. For example, business loans at large banks had increased rapidly from December to mid-February, in part due to borrowing in anticipation of the rumored adoption of credit controls, but in late February and early March business borrowing from these large banks stagnated—a pattern that could not be discerned until late March. Similarly, new home sales fell slightly in February and 160 plunged in March, although the only information available in early March had shown that sales advanced in January. The mid-March announcement of credit controls did not immediately break the upward spiral in interest rates. In late March and early April the Federal funds rate came within a few basis points of 20 percent, and rates on most short-term and long-term market instruments rose to record highs before falling sharply over the course of the second quarter. The Federal funds rate fell faster than other short-term market rates from April to mid-June, but the funds rate then stabilized for the next 2 months at around 9 percent. During this period there were occasions when the Federal Reserve kept the Federal funds rate from falling below the 8V2 percent lower bound set in May by the Federal Open Market Committee. Longer-term rates also declined as the spiral of inflationary expectations apparently was reversed in light of the growing slack in the economy and the weakness in the monetary aggregates. Downward adjustments in administered rates, like the prime rate and home mortgage rates, lagged the declines in market yields. The downswing in most interest rates ended in June and July as monetary aggregates accelerated and credit demands again surged. The Federal Reserve did not accommodate the strong demand for bank reserves associated with acceleration of the monetary aggregates through the summer and fall, and the rate of expansion of adjusted nonborrowed reserves slowed from 31 percent at an annual rate in the second quarter to 4 percent in the third. Meanwhile, between late August and early December the discount rate was raised in three steps to 13 percent, and the Federal Reserve reimposed an additional surcharge on frequent borrowings by large banks. The Federal funds rate increased to over 20 percent in December. Other short-term market rates followed this upward climb. The prime rate adjusted more rapidly on the upswing than it had when rates had come down earlier in the year. Long-term rates, responding once again to continued inflationary pressures, reached rates at the end of the year near or above their March-April peaks. In mid-December short-term interest rates reached new peaks and began to fall rapidly once again. By early January the commercial paper rate, for instance, had fallen 3% percentage points from its mid-December peak. Longterm interest rates fell about 1V4 percentage points over the same period. The volatile movements of the narrow monetary aggregates over the course of the year reflected in part the pattern of economic activity. But the atypical behavior of the demand for money during 1980 also contributed to this volatility. As noted in Chapter 1, the demand for money—which is used by economists to characterize the relation- 161 ship among money, interest rates, and economic activity—has shown a tendency toward abrupt shifts in recent years. In particular, such shifts in 1975 and in 1976 led to monetary growth in the narrower aggregates, M-1A and M-1B, that was well below that expected on the basis of the historical relationship between money, income, and interest rates. While not fully understood, such shifts have followed rapid increases in interest rates to record levels, which appear to induce firms and households to adopt cash-economizing financial innovations. (These were discussed in detail in the 1978 Report.) In the second quarter of 1980 another shift in money demand apparently took place. Declines in M-1A and M-1B were greater than would have been expected even in the face of the sharp fall-off in economic activity and high interest rates. But the current episode appears to differ somewhat from the previous shifts in that this time the shift was largely offset in the subsequent 2 quarters. This offset suggests that some special factors may have been at work. One hypothesis is that the imposition of credit controls may have temporarily led holders of currency and demand deposits to draw down these balances in the second quarter. With the end of the controls program in July this temporary depressant disappeared, and households were able to rebuild their cash balances. Whether this explanation is correct or not, it seems likely that a temporary moneydemand shift contributed to the pattern of a decline in the money supply in the second quarter followed by an unusually rapid money growth in the second half of the year. Thrift Institutions. In the first quarter of 1980, deposit flows to thrift institutions—mutual savings banks and savings and loan associations—slowed to the lowest rate since the fall of 1974. But after market interest rates peaked in late March and early April thrift deposits once more began to expand at the healthier pace registered in the preceding year. From December through April the decline in thrift deposit flows was softened by an inflow of funds attracted to the variable rate instruments offered to savers—the 6-month money market certificates (MMCs) and the new 2V2-year small saver certificates (SSCs). For the next 5 months, however, there were net withdrawals of MMCs as depositors shifted funds into the higher yielding SSCs. From April to July funds were also shifted into money market mutual funds, where the technical method for calculating return gave these funds a temporary yield advantage over MMCs. By October MMCs had resumed healthy expansion, and for the first 11 months of the year MMCs and SSCs at thrift institutions together grew by $115 billion. The other major sources of funds for thrifts also had interest costs tied to market rates. Members of the Federal Home Loan Bank 162 (FHLB) System increased their borrowing from the FHLB by over $7 billion to a level of about $47 billion. Many large institutions also augmented their small-account deposit flows by issuing "jumbo" ($100,000 or larger) certificates of deposit. Small denomination accounts with interest rates fixed by regulation experienced net withdrawals throughout the year. By the end of 1980 these fixed-ceiling deposits accounted for just over half of total thrift deposits, compared to roughly two-thirds at the end of 1979. While the new deposit instruments and FHLB borrowings helped the thrifts sustain asset growth by allowing them to compete for funds at market interest rates, this new-found competitive status was achieved at considerable peril to the short-run profitability of these institutions. For much of last year the interest cost on such funds was well above the return on the longer-term asset portfolios, thereby de-pressingTHrift industry profits. In an environment of growing uncertainty regarding the direction of interest rates and their ability to sustain deposit flows, thrifts apparently became somewhat more cautious in their asset management in early 1980. When high interest rates curtailed deposit inflows in earlier cycles, thrifts generally sustained their mortgage lending activity by selling off their liquid asset portfolios. From March to May 1980, however, savings and loans (S&Ls) reduced their home mortgage commitments at a record rate but continued to acquire liquid assets. The percentage of assets held by insured S&Ls in liquid instruments actually increased over most of 1980—an unprecedented development in a period of weak deposit flows. Home mortgage commitments rebounded sharply from June through September following the declines in interest rates and the resumption of deposit flows. In the fourth quarter commitments fell off slightly as rising mortgage interest rates once again led to a reduction in housing sales. Credit Flows. Credit extended to the nonfinancial sectors of the economy during the first 3 quarters of 1980 was well below the pace of the preceding year, even though Federal borrowing doubled. Funds raised by private nonfinancial borrowers (including State and local governments) plummeted in the second quarter in the face of high costs, restricted credit availability, and the recession-induced reduction in demand. While private credit flows rebounded somewhat in the third quarter, they continued to lag behind the 1979 pace. The household sector experienced the sharpest reduction in borrowing during 1980. In late 1979 the ratio of consumer installment and mortgage credit repayments to disposable personal income—a common measure of the burden of household debt—reached its historical peak. Thereafter, the rate of increase of these household debt 163 categories gradually abated through the first quarter of 1980. As reported earlier, the credit controls program induced consumers to reduce their installment debt sharply in the second quarter, and their rate of mortgage borrowing nearly halved. Even with some recovery of borrowing in the third quarter, required household debt repayments as a percent of disposable personal income continued to fall throughout 1980. At year-end this measure of household debt burdens was well below the mid-1979 peak. Moreover, real financial net worth per capita rose over the year. Taken together, these trends suggest that the household debt burden may not be as serious a constraint on consumer spending in 1981 as it was in late 1979 and 1980. Borrowing by nonfinancial businesses followed a pattern similar to that of the household sector, though not as severe. Second quarter borrowing fell much more sharply than the decline in the financing gap (the excess of capital expenditures, including inventory accumulation, over internally generated funds), as businesses liquidated some of the short-term assets built up over the previous 3 quarters. In the third quarter businesses once again began to increase their liquid asset portfolios, and corporate borrowing increased despite a further reduction in the financing gap. Corporations took advantage of the precipitous drop in long-term rates in May and June by issuing a record volume of long-term bonds, but when long-term rates moved upward later in the summer they returned to short-term credit expansion to meet their financing needs. The liquidity positions of nonfinancial corporations have deteriorated significantly since 1976, when the ratios of liquid assets and long-term debt to short-term debt reached their cyclical highs. By the end of the second quarter of 1980 the corporate liquidity ratio (liquid assets relative to short-term debt) had reached an all-time low, and long-term debt as a percent of total debt was considerably lower than the previous low reached in early 1975. Historically, businesses have tended to restore their liquidity and move to a healthier balance in their liability structures near the end of recessions, when reduced credit needs and lower long-term rates allow them to liquidate their short-term borrowing and extend the maturity of their liability structure. This time, however, the sharper-than-usual increases in interest rates have attenuated this normal restructuring process and threaten to induce further deterioration of the financial health of corporations in 1981. 164 THE PROSPECTS FOR 1981 AND 1982 In 1981 the economy should continue its modest recovery from the 1980 recession. Real growth is projected to be about 1% percent over the 4 quarters of the year, with virtually all of it coming in the last 2 quarters. Although both employment and the labor force are expected to rise about Wz million during the year, the labor force gain is likely to be a shade larger. In consequence, the unemployment at year-end 1981 is anticipated to be slightly above its current level. The overall rate of inflation is forecast to be little changed from its 1980 pace. Given public concern with inflation, both fiscal and monetary policy are expected to be a restraining influence on economic activity in 1981 and beyond. However, there is both need and room for a prudently designed tax cut which would be phased in gradually over the next 2 years. Over the 4 quarters of 1982 real growth is expected to be 3Vz percent, with the proposed tax cuts providing significant stimulus. The somewhat faster pace of economic activity should yield employment gains of roughly 2 million during the year. The unemployment rate is expected to decline gradually throughout 1982. The continued moderation in economic activity is projected to produce a slowing in the overall rate of inflation of about Wz percentage points during 1982. FISCAL POLICY The forecast presented below is based on the economic policy measures described in the 1982 budget. In fiscal 1981 Federal outlays are projected to be $662.7 billion. This amounts to a 14 percent increase, a slowdown from the 17 percent growth in fiscal 1980. A further slowdown is projected in fiscal 1982, with outlays rising 12 percent to $739.3 billion. Most of the increase in Federal outlays over the 2 years stems from the effects of inflation. Adjusted for inflation, total outlays will increase about 2 percent, with sizable real gains in defense spending partially offset by declines in nondefense spending. In fiscal 1981 receipts are projected to be $607.5 billion, rising to $711.8 billion in fiscal 1982. Both these receipts, and to a lesser extent expenditures, reflect the President's proposed Economic Revitalization Program (ERP), designed to moderate the rise of tax burdens and provide incentives for business capital investment. The budget cost of the program is $3.3 billion in fiscal 1981, rising to $22.5 billion in fiscal 1982. The fiscal 1982 budget also includes a proposal to increase the Federal tax on motor fuels by 10 cents per gallon on June 1, 198L Thereafter, the tax per gallon would increase with inflation. The proposed increase in the motor fuels tax is expected 165 to yield approximately $13 billion in fiscal 1982 and larger amounts thereafter. The tax reductions embodied in the ERP will not totally offset increases in other taxes. Social security taxes, the windfall profits tax on oil company revenues, and inflation-induced increases in personal taxes will combine with the proposed motor fuels tax and withholding of tax on interest and dividends to produce a rising tax burden in 1981 and 1982 despite the ERP. In addition, even with the budgeted acceleration in defense spending and continued increases in interest outlays, overall growth in Federal spending will be relatively modest in real terms. Thus, the high-employment surplus is expected to increase substantially in both 1981 and 1982, helping to moderate demand and lower inflation. The Economic Revitalization Program The major focus of the ERP is on increasing investment and encouraging innovation. Depreciation rules would be both liberalized and simplified under the plan. This would increase the rate of return on new investment and the cash flow of firms making investments. The program would also make the current investment tax credit (ITC) partially refundable. The ITG and accelerated depreciation proposals would be retroactive to January 1, 1981. These two proposals are explained in detail in Chapter 1. To shift additional national resources into investment, a largerthan-usual share of the funds available for tax reduction will have to be devoted to investment incentives. But some other forms of tax relief are both feasible and desirable. The President's program proposes three principal areas of such relief. First, individuals and employers would receive an income tax credit sufficient to offset the rise in social security taxes which took place at the start of the year. This type of tax cut was chosen because it not only would reduce tax burdens but also lower business costs and thus help modestly with our inflation problem. Second, for workers who face a growing social security tax burden but earn too little to pay income taxes, the program would expand the earned income tax credit. This would more than offset the increase in social security taxes for our lowest-paid workers. Third, the program proposes a phased reduction in the tax burden on two-earner families by reducing the so-called "marriage penalty" that taxes married couples with roughly equal incomes at rates higher than unmarried couples with the same incomes. These reductions in individual income taxes would not become effective until January 1, 1982. The program, as originally proposed in August 1980, had provided for implementation of these tax cuts immediately upon passage. The delay in the effective date is dictated by budgetary prudence and the desire to avoid rekindling inflationary 166 expectations. Of course, if the economy should weaken seriously during 1981, the Congress would have reason to advance the effective date of these tax cuts. MONETARY POLICY In July 1980 the Federal Reserve tentatively set its monetary aggregate growth target ranges for the period from the fourth quarter of 1980 to the fourth quarter of 1981 generally one-half percentage point below the previous year's targets (Table 24). As discussed in Chapter 1, this reduction is intended to provide sustained monetary restraint consistent with an eventual return to price stability. There is little doubt that these target ranges will restrain the economy in 1981, but the amount of that restraint is less certain. A rough method of assessing the restrictiveness of monetary policy in the period ahead is the increase in velocity implied by keeping monetary growth within the target ranges while still supporting expansion of nominal GNP sufficient to permit a modest recovery from the 1980 recession. Given the likelihood that inflation will sustain considerable momentum over the year, the implied increases in the velocities of the key monetary aggregates are well above the longterm historical averages. Historically, such large increases in velocity have been associated with a substantial rise in interest rates, a rise that could threaten the prospects for a moderate economic recovery in 1981. Several potential developments during 1981 could alter the degree of monetary restraint implied by the money growth targets. First, as discussed earlier, in 1975 and 1976 there were sizable shifts in the demand for money in a direction that tended to increase velocity and thus accommodate more nominal GNP growth for a given monetary growth. One factor thought by many to be associated with the earlier shifts—a rapid runup in interest rates piercing previous peak levels— occurred in late 1980. While a money-demand shift cannot be predicted with any confidence for 1981, the possibility that another shift may materialize raises the difficulty of interpreting the degree of restrictiveness of the money growth ranges. In addition, the introduction of NOW accounts on a nationwide basis in January will alter to some degree the relationships among the various aggregates and their relationship to economic activity. Shifts out of demand deposits into NOWs will depress the rate of growth of M-1A. On the other hand, NOW accounts probably will attract some savings deposits and other interest-bearing deposits, thereby boosting M-1B. The degree of the shift into NOW accounts will depend on the aggressiveness with which depository institutions price these new instruments and promote them, as well as on the public response. Partly oh the basis of NOW account growth in New 167 England, the Federal Reserve has adjusted the midpoints of the target ranges for these narrow aggregates in an attempt to account for these structural changes (Table 24). But whether the adjusted targets will in fact yield the same degree of monetary restrictiveness in 1981 as the announced unadjusted targets would have yielded in the absence of nationwide NOWs is unknown. Shifts into NOWs from demand and most interest-bearing deposit categories at banks and thrifts will have no impact on the rates of expansion of M-2 and M-3. However, other financial developments could influence their growth patterns. In particular, there is considerable uncertainty about whether money-market mutual funds and the variable rate SSCs—both of which are included in M-2 and M-3— will continue their unusually rapid growth in 1981. There is also uncertainty as to whether these instruments will draw funds from deposit categories in M-2 and M-3 or from sources not included in these broader aggregates. Finally, several technical problems associated with the Monetary Control Act of 1980 will confront the Federal Reserve in 1981, further complicating the implementation of monetary policy. As discussed in Chapter 2, the act requires a sweeping restructuring of reserve requirements and extends both reserve requirements and access to the discount window to nonmember banks and thrift institutions. It will take some time for these institutions to develop a stable pattern of reserve management and borrowing behavior. During this transition period the Federal Reserve will find it more difficult than usual to predict borrowings, excess reserves, and other reserve measures. Thus, the relationship between reserves and money, which is the key to controlling money growth, will probably be less certain during 1981 and perhaps over a longer period. In the face of all these technical difficulties and uncertainties, the danger in rigidly keeping the growth of M-1A, M-1B, or any single monetary aggregate within a narrow preset range regardless of other developments is obvious. With the long-run monetary growth ranges for 1981 already implying considerable tightness, there is a great risk that developments unrelated to the basic course of economic activity could artificially boost the growth rates of some of the aggregates and induce excessive monetary stringency. The Federal Reserve has attempted to account for the structural changes by adjusting the ranges for the narrow aggregates. Another option could be to place more emphasis on the broader aggregates like M-2, which are unlikely to be so greatly affected by the structural changes. An additional adjustment that would reflect the greater uncertainty of financial relationships in 1981 would be to widen the limits of the longer-run ranges. 168 The uncertainty of developments in 1981 calls for flexible response on the part of monetary policy. Since the Federal Reserve began announcing its longer-run targets in 1975, it has been understood that "The longer-run ranges will be reconsidered as conditions warrant." In 1981, this statement assumes even greater importance than usual. WORLD AND DOMESTIC OIL MARKETS As has been the case in the recent past, developments in world oil markets will continue to influence U.S. inflation and growth. World oil demand is likely to remain weak during 1981 due to the sluggish pace of economic activity in the industrialized nations and the continued adjustment to 1979's rapid increase in oil prices. In addition, oil inventories, which prior to the outbreak of the war between Iran and Iraq were very high by historical standards, may still insulate the consuming nations from limited supply disruptions. Nevertheless, even with these elements tending to limit price pressures, the price of imported oil is expected to increase somewhat faster than inflation in 1981 and 1982. Decontrol of U.S. oil prices will bring still sharper increases in domestic oil prices during 1981. In November 1980 the average price of domestic oil was about $28 per barrel. That price will rise to the world market level by October 1981, at which time the price is expected to be in the neighborhood of $40 per barrel. The total burden to U.S. consumers of the relative price increases in oil during 1981 is expected to reach about $30 billion by the end of the year. The bulk of this will go to the Federal Government in the form of higher receipts from the windfall profits tax and increased revenues from corporate taxes on the profits of oil companies. This increase in Federal revenues is one source of the estimated increase in the high-employment surplus during 1981. Of the remaining total, roughly $3 billion will accrue to foreign producers and about $8 billion to domestic producers. Some small fraction of these amounts will be respent in the United States in 1981, but the economic drag caused by the increase in oil prices during 1981 will still amount to roughly $10 billion. THE ECONOMIC FORECAST The economy has now experienced 2 quarters of moderate real growth following the sharp decline in the second quarter of 1980. At the same time there was a rapid runup in interest rates through midDecember. While significant declines in interest rates were recorded thereafter, the effects of taut financial conditions during 1980 are likely to weaken the pace of recovery during the first half of 1981. These weak conditions should be particularly evident in housing and in spending for consumer durables. Overall, it is likely that real GNP 169 will be essentially flat in the first half of the year, with a distinct possibility of 1 quarter of actual decline. After midyear the pace of activity should pick up, although by historical standards growth will remain modest for a period of recovery (Table 25). The restrictive stance of monetary and fiscal policy will contribute to this result. In addition, consumers' real incomes will be restrained by rising oil prices. Over the 4 quarters of 1981 the combination of fiscal and oil-price imposed restraint is estimated to rise by about $60 billion, or 2 percent of GNP. TABLE 25.—Economic outlook for 1981 Forecast range 1981 Item Growth, fourth quarter to fourth quarter (percent): Real gross national product 1V2 to 2 Personal consumption expenditures.... Presidential fixed investment Residential investment Federal purchases State and local purchases 1 to Vh 1 to Wz 6 to 7 3 to ZVz - % to 0 10 to 10 xh GNP implicit price deflator.., Compensation per hour Output per hour 2 Level, fourth quarter: 3 2 IOY2 to 11 % to 1 Unemployment rate (percent) Housing starts (millions of units) 4 7% to V¥A lVMo 1% 1 2 Preliminary. Private nonfarm business, all persons. Changes for 1980 are fourth quarter 1979 to third quarter 1980 at annual rates. *4 Seasonally adjusted. Annual rates. October-November average used for fourth quarter 1980. Sources: Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic Analysis), Department of Labor (Bureau of Labor Statistics), and Council of Economic Advisers. As the economy moves into 1982 it should maintain the momentum of the last half of 1981. Business fixed investment is expected to be a particular source of strength because of the proposed tax incentives for capital spending. Consumer Expenditures Consumer spending in 1981 will be constrained by sluggish growth in after-tax income due in part to inflation-induced increases in effective personal tax rates and the step-up in social security taxes. Overall, real after-tax incomes will show only a very small gain. Rising energy prices will also continue to put pressure on consumer purchasing power. As a consequence, consumer spending is projected to grow less rapidly than real GNP during 1981. Last year the personal saving rate rose somewhat, ending the year at 5% percent. Over the last 4 years the saving rate has averaged a shade under SVfe percent, roughly 2 percentage points below the average of the preceding 10 years. Nevertheless, the attempt to maintain living standards in the face of sluggish income growth is likely to 170 produce a slight decline in the saving rate during 1981. Despite this, real consumer purchases of goods and services are only projected to rise by slightly more than 1 percent over the 4 quarters of 1981. Consumer spending is expected to be particularly sluggish in the first half of the year. Purchases of autos and other credit-sensitive goods are likely to be the most affected, leading to a decline in durables spending during 1981. In contrast, expenditures by consumers on both nondurable goods and services are projected to rise during the year. A somewhat healthier growth in real consumer spending should be evident in 1982 partly due to the gains in disposable incomes that will follow the personal tax cuts proposed for the start of that year. Business Fixed Investment Surveys of capital spending plans by business for 1981 are currently showing surprising strength. One private survey indicates that for 1981 as a whole real spending on plant and equipment will increase 2 percent. The most recent Department of Commerce survey is slightly less optimistic, suggesting that business plans to increase real investment outlays by about 1 percent. The year-over-year increase indicated by these surveys would involve vigorous gains in investment during 1981. These surveys need to be interpreted with, caution. Business spending plans tend to be revised downward when the economy weakens, as it is projected to do in the first half of 1981. Thus despite the surveys, some continued weakness is expected during the first half of 1981. However, business capital spending should begin accelerating in the second half of 1981. An important source of this growth will be the proposed liberalization of both depreciation allowances and the investment tax credit. These are assumed to go into effect in mid-1981, retroactive to the start of the year. But given the lags in the investment process, these tax incentives should have their major impact in 1982 and beyond. Indeed, real business capital spending during 1982 is expected to increase substantially faster than real GNP. One further reason for the strength in this sector is the marked increase in capital spending anticipated in the energy industry. Housing During the last several months of 1980 the short-term prospects for the housing market worsened somewhat. After the swift rebound during the summer, housing starts leveled off at roughly a 1.55-million unit annual rate for September through November. Many observers were surprised that housing starts were maintained at that level, especially in November, in light of very high and rising interest rates. Part of the explanation appears to be that multifamily starts— 171 which increased from September to November—were bolstered somewhat by Federal subsidy programs. Single-family starts declined during this period partly due to a reduction in the rate of new home sales in September and October, but sales unexpectedly turned up slightly in November despite a rise in mortgage rates to 14 percent and above. The high mortgage rates that are likely to prevail during much of 1981 will delay any further rebound in homebuilding activity. At current interest rates, many potential home buyers—especially those looking for their first home—cannot afford the required monthly mortgage payments. Nevertheless, with the continued high rate of household formation by the postwar baby-boom generation and the tax advantages of homeownership, potential housing demand is quite strong. Moreover, new financing arrangements may help reduce the problems of affordability. Thrift institutions are now offering several versions of the graduated-payment mortgage and have begun to offer shared-appreciation mortgages in which the lender receives an equity interest in the house in exchange for lower mortgage rates. In addition, there have been reports of homebuilders offering to meet part of the buyer's monthly mortgage payments in exchange for a higher sales price. These factors suggest that housing starts may fall somewhat during the first half of 1981 in response to high mortgage rates. But thereafter, growing housing demand and the further development of innovative financing arrangements should lead to some rebound in homebuilding even if interest rates remain high. By the end of 1981 housing starts are expected to be in the range of 1.5 to 1.7 million units, with further gains probable during 1982. Inventories As observed above, recent inventory behavior has been noteworthy for its relatively quick adjustment to changes in final sales. As a consequence, unlike previous periods of recession and recovery, there has been no major inventory cycle this time around. Over the coming months the sluggish pace of economic activity will create continued pressure for moderation in inventory accumulation. In addition, the current high level of interest rates provides an additional incentive to hold down inventories. This suggests that inventory investment will be quite modest in the first half of 1981 and should gradually gain thereafter, roughly in line with sales, as economic growth quickens. The Foreign Sector The pattern of economic growth projected for the other industrial countries is quite similar to the one projected for the United States: very slow growth in the first half of this year, followed by somewhat 172 more rapid growth thereafter. During this year and next, growth abroad is likely to average between 2 and 3 percent—roughly comparable to average growth in this country. As a result of this similarity in growth patterns, net exports are not expected to show major swings over the coming 2 years. From the fourth quarter of 1980 to the end of 1982 a modest decline in net exports—about $2 billion in constant dollars—is projected. This decline will result primarily from a somewhat more rapid rise in import volumes than in export volumes, although neither of these is projected to grow very strongly. Some loss in U.S. competitiveness is implicit in these projections. American goods are likely to become somewhat more expensive in relation to foreign goods, both because of somewhat higher inflation in the United States and because of the strength of the dollar in foreign exchange markets. The strength of the dollar is likely to persist so long as interest rates in the United States remain high relative to interest rates abroad and if, as predicted, the U.S. current account remains in surplus. While the surplus is projected to diminish somewhat during the course of 1981 from the very high level reached in the second half of 1980, it should remain large through 1982 in the absence of any future oil-price shock. Government Purchases Real Federal purchases are projected to increase by about 3*A percent during the course of 1981, and by a smaller amount in 1982. During both years real defense purchases are anticipated to increase substantially, offsetting projected declines in real nondefense purchases. State and local government spending in real terms fell in 1980 and is forecast to decline again during 1981. The economy's sluggish growth, continued taxpayer resistance to new spending programs, and budget tightness will serve to hold down spending. With the resumption of healthier economic growth in 1982, State and local government purchases are expected to increase in real terms, although substantially more slowly than GNP. Employment and Unemployment Employment is likely to increase by slightly less than IV2 percent during 1981 and, with the pickup in economic activity in the following year, to advance by a shade more than 2 percent during 1982. Growth in the labor force is projected to average about 1% percent over the next 2 years, advancing at a somewhat slower rate in 1981 and speeding up in 1982. This pace is in line with average annual growth over the last 30 years, although it does represent a distinct slowdown from the 2x/z percent annual gain recorded in the 1970s. 173 These projections for employment and the labor force imply that the unemployment rate at year-end 1981 will be between 7V% and 7% percent, although it is likely to be above this range in the early part of 1981. During 1982 the unemployment rate is projected to decline steadily, ending the year in the range of 7Vi to 7V2 percent. Wage and Price Developments Wages and prices should decelerate over the next several years. Several factors will be at work. With both fiscal and monetary policy aimed at continued restraint in aggregate demand, the prospects are for modest economic growth through 1982. These developments should limit demand relative to supply in both labor and product markets, gradually reduce inflationary expectations, and ultimately yield a better wage and price performance. At the same time, expanded tax incentives will spur investment and thus improve productivity growth. This too should contribute to moderating wage and price increases. As discussed in Chapter 1, however, reducing inflation via demand restraint and increased productivity does not yield quick results. Furthermore, a number of factors will serve to keep inflation relatively high in the near future. These will include higher food price inflation, the recent increases in social security taxes and the minimum wage, and the continued rise in energy prices resulting from further oil-price increases and the decontrol of domestic energy prices. These factors suggest that wage and price increases during 1981 may nearly match those recorded in 1980. Wages and Unit Labor Costs. After showing moderation through most of 1979, wage rates accelerated last year. While the relatively slack labor market will limit further wage acceleration this year, there is unlikely to be any noticeable slowdown. Both oil and food prices will rise sharply in 1981, maintaining the pressure for sizable wage gains. But by 1982, with continued restraint in aggregate demand and lower food- and oil-price rises (decontrol will be completed), the rate of pay increase should diminish, returning to the vicinity of wa^e gains seen in 1979. Private wages and fringe benefits are projected to increase 10 to lOVfe percent during 1981. In addition, the jump in payroll taxes which occurred on January 1, 1981 added slightly over one-half percent to the level of compensation. As a result, increases in total hourly compensation should average about lOVa to 11 percent over the 4 quarters of 1981, with a large bulge in the first quarter. With only a modest boost in payroll taxes scheduled for 1982, the rate of increase in total hourly payroll costs should slow noticeably. In the face of sluggish economic activity in the first half of 1981, productivity could well record a slight decline. Thereafter, with the 174 reemergence of modest but sustained economic growth, productivity is projected to increase slightly faster than its underlying trend rate of 1 to IV2 percent. This productivity performance, in conjunction with the slowdown in the increase in hourly compensation projected for late 1981 and into 1982, should substantially moderate increases in unit labor costs. Product Prices. The large share of wage and salary payments in total business costs makes the advance of unit labor costs a fundamental determinant of the trend increase in product prices. Thus, the prospects for product prices basically mirror those for unit labor costs, with the overall rate of price inflation as measured by the GNP deflator expected to be noticeably improved by 1982. Over the 4 quarters of 1982 the overall inflation rate is expected to drop to about 8% percent. During 1981, however, the rise in the deflator should roughly match the 1980 increase of 10 percent. Adoption of the motor fuels tax could add another one-fourth to one-half percentage point to growth in the deflator. The near-term projection for inflation reflects developments in energy discussed above and agricultural markets, which deserve special attention. Food Prices. Significantly higher prices for food are anticipated for 1981, with a rise of about 12 percent likely. The production adjustments already underway by meat producers, together with the effects of the summer-long drought, will exert upward pressure on commodity prices. Continued increases in energy costs and labor wage rates imply that food marketing costs will increase at about the rate of general inflation. Meat price increases will probably be most visible to the average consumer. After 5 years of steady increase, pork production is expected to fall 6 to 8 percent. Beef production is likely to be only slightly higher than its low level in 1980. Live animal prices are forecast to be much higher than in 1980. High prices (and limited supplies) of feedgrains will limit increases in poultry production. Meat supplies will also be tight on a world scale. While the seasonal pattern of the 1981 meat price increase is still in doubt, it appears that retail meat prices will rise most notably from April through August before stabilizing (and perhaps declining) late in the year. Crop conditions in the United States and worldwide will determine this pattern. Generally poor crop conditions early in the year could push grain prices much higher. Under these conditions, retail meat prices would be lower in the first half (as herds are liquidated) but higher in the second half than is now expected. Agricultural conditions also point to higher prices for most other food items during 1981. Commodity price increases resulting from 175 the drought in 1980 will be reflected in food prices during most of 1981. The Consumer Price Index. The CPI merits special attention because of its high visibility and its key role in the indexing of both wage contracts and benefit levels under Federal entitlement programs. The CPI is expected to increase by \2x/z percent over the 4 quarters of 1981, with roughly one-half percentage point of this increase accounted for by the proposed increase in the motor fuels tax. This increase, which is roughly the same as was registered during 1980, is about 2 percentage points higher than the increase forecast for the GNP deflator. Among other reasons for this difference, the CPI is more sensitive to increases in oil and food prices. Further, mortgage interest rates have no direct effect on the deflator. Although the increase in the CPI in 1981 is likely to match the 1980 increase, the first quarter of the year is likely to see a surge of inflation in the CPI due to already recorded mortgage interest rate increases. After this effect has passed the outlook is for improvement during the remainder of the year and continuing through 1982. During 1982 CPI inflation is expected to decline to about 9 Vz percent. Uncertainties in the Outlook Among the various uncertainties in the outlook, two deserve particular attention: the possibility of a serious collision between the demand for funds and the monetary targets of the Federal Reserve, and the possibility of sharply higher oil prices should the continued loss of Iraqi and Iranian oil, or some other shock, tighten oil markets. Interest rates now appear to have peaked in mid-December of last year. Most short-term rates have already fallen sharply, some by as much as 3V2 percentage points. While long-term interest rates have fallen by much smaller amounts, the peaks in these rates also seem to have passed. But additional dramatic declines—like those of last spring—are not likely this year. There remains considerable uncertainty as to what the Federal Reserve's operating targets imply for the path of interest rates between now and the end of 1982. Furthermore, interest rates are still unusually high for the early stages of a recovery. Should rates surge upward again, it is likely that housing and other interest-sensitive sectors would suffer serious setbacks. In this event, weakness in economic activity could continue past midyear, and the rise in the unemployment rate might continue throughout the year. A second risk is the possibility of a major hike in oil prices. Such a shock would contribute significantly to inflationary pressures at the same time that it would depress real economic activity and drive up the unemployment rate. The precise quantitative effects of such a 176 hike would depend on many factors, including the response of the Federal Reserve. Under plausible assumptions, if in early 1981 the world market price of oil were to rise $10 per barrel above that already assumed, then by year-end this would add about 2 percentage points to the inflation rate and reduce the growth of real GNP from what it otherwise would have been by 2 percentage points. Some further effects would be felt in 1982, and by year-end the unemployment rate would be about 1 percentage point higher than it would have been without this increase in oil prices. While the two major uncertainties in the outlook raise the possibility that the recovery will be weaker than forecast, a stronger recovery is entirely possible. Any improvement in the outlook must have at its core a reduction in the rate of inflation. A better inflation performance could result from several causes, the chief among them being improved productivity, more moderate wage gains, or favorable crop developments. If, for example, that part of the slowdown in productivity which had remained ^a bit of mystery were to reverse itself, the outlook for business costs and prices could be greatly improved. Reductions in inflationary expectations would follow, reinforcing the direct effects of the productivity improvement. Presuming the Federal Reserve maintained its monetary targets, the improved inflation outlook would tend to reduce interest rates and generally ease conditions in financial markets. As a consequence, real economic activity could advance more rapidly than forecast. THE GOALS OF ECONOMIC POLICY The Humphrey-Hawkins Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act sets forth both general and highly specific objectives for two of the most important indicators of the country's economic health, the unemployment rate and inflation, and establishes the target of reducing Federal outlays to 20 percent of GNP. The act establishes specific milestones for the achievement of these objectives. An interim goal of Federal outlays equal to 21 percent of GNP is set for 1981; interim goals of 4 percent for the overall unemployment rate (3 percent for adults) and 3 percent inflation are both set for 1983. According to the act, beginning with the 1980 Economic Report the President may, if he deems it necessary, modify the timetable for achievement of the interim and final goals for unemployment, inflation, and Federal outlays as a share of GNP. Last year's Economic Report discussed in some detail the degree of progress toward these goals and the reasons why their achievement by 1983 was not possible. The chief reason was the 1979 rise in oil prices. Federal policies 177 in 1979 and 1980 were of necessity aimed at limiting the negative impact of these oil-price increases. Economic policy now faces a stiff challenge: to reduce a stubborn inflation, improve the growth of productivity, and expand output and employment. The policies required to meet this challenge are discussed in Chapters 1 and 2 of this Report, and they will lead to substantial progress toward the goals of reduced inflation and lower unemployment over the next 5 years. Longer-term projections are shown in Table 26. But even with this progress, it will not be simultaneously possible to achieve 4 percent unemployment and 3 percent inflation in the time envisioned in the Humphrey-Hawkins Act or in last year's Report Attempts to reach either goal on the act's timetable would frustrate progress toward the other goal and could substantially impair the prospects for improved economic performance. In the long run such attempts would prove self-defeating and result in very harmful economic and social consequences. The more gradual path shown in the table will allow us to make progress toward our goals and to maintain them once achieved. Over the years ahead Federal spending as a share of GNP will decline, but the level of spending required to meet national needs and priorities, especially in the defense area, will not permit a reduction to the numerical target set forth in the act. TABLE 26.—Economic projections, 1981-86 Item Unemployment rate (percent), fourth quarter1 1981 1982 7.7 7.4 1983 7.0 1984 1985 6.6 6.2 1986 5.9 Percent change, fourth quarter to fourth quarter Consumer price index Real GNP 12.6 9.6 8.2 7.5 6.7 6.0 1.7 3.5 3.7 3.7 3.7 3.7 1 Seasonally adjusted. Source: Council of Economic Advisers. SUPPLEMENT National Income and Product Account Revisions The national income and product accounts (NIPA), which provide data on aggregate output and income, were substantially revised in 1980 by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) of the U.S. Department of Commerce. The revisions included a refining of accounting concepts and estimation procedures, and introduced new and more recent sources of data. The last 178 major revision of the NIPA occurred 5 years ago and was reported in the January 1976 Survey of Current Business published by the Commerce Department. The current revision will be described in an article in the December 1980 Survey. All of the NIPA data discussed in this Report are the revised data, except as noted. The major features of the revision are these: • The data from three major new sources are now incorporated in the NIPA. These are 3EA's 1972 input-output tables, the 1977 censuses, and the 1973 and 1976 Compliance Measurement Program of the Internal Revenue Service (IRS). • Normal data sources which would have been used in the postponed July 1980 annual revisions of the NIPA (e.g., IRS tax return information, annual surveys of manufacturers, housing, and retail trade) were also utilized in these revisions. • The major conceptual change in the NIPA involves the treatment of certain international transactions. The reinvested earnings of incorporated foreign affiliates of U.S. companies are now included in exports of services. The repatriated earnings of these affiliates were previously included in exports of services. The reinvested earnings of incorporated foreignowned affiliates in the United States receive similar treatment thus adding to imports of services. Because the U.S. earnings abroad are larger than the foreign earnings here, the net result is higher net exports and gross national product especially since the late 1960s. Gross domestic product is, of course, unaffected by the change. This change makes the handling of foreign earnings in the NIPA consistent with that used in the balance of payments accounts since 1978. • The treatment of international transactions has also been changed by using a new procedure for estimating the prices of service exports and imports. • More detailed analysis of Federal purchases has allowed separate constant dollar estimates for both nondefense and defense purchases beginning in 1972. • The level of detail at which output is deflated has been increased. • Estimating procedures now allow a more complete differentiation between dividend and interest income than was previously reported. The revisions have raised estimates of real GNP by about 3 Vz percent for 1979, by about 2V2 percent for 1974, and by lesser amounts for earlier years. About one-third of the upward revision for the years 1977-79 was due to the conceptual change in the handling of foreign earnings. In addition, the revision in the deflators has, on balance, reduced estimates of prices, thus raising real output. Finally, estimates of real nonresidential fixed investment have been substantially increased, especially since 1973. The ratio of real 179 nonresidential fixed investment to real GNP, which had previously averaged 9.9 percent between 1974 and 1979, now averages 10.4 percent. Past business cycle patterns have been little changed by the revisions. The GNP-measured turning points are all as previously reported. However, the peak-to-trough declines have been reduced by one-half percent and 1 percent for the 1970 and 1974-75 contractions, respectively. The NIPA now show the 1974-75 contraction being interrupted by 1 quarter of slight expansion in the second quarter of 1974, immediately following the period of the Arab oil embargo. Total compensation remained roughly the same as before revision, but its composition changed. Wages and salaries in the most recent years are now higher and supplements lower than had been previously reported. Business net interest was revised upward by significant amounts especially in recent years. These revisions rise to $13.7 billion for 1979. Corporate profits were raised significantly, but chiefly because of the conceptual change in reinvested foreign earnings. Lowered estimates of corporate taxes contributed to higher corporate retained earnings and saving estimates for the most recent years. Personal saving estimates were also raised. This is because estimates of personal consumption were barely changed, while personal income was revised upward considerably. The personal saving rate in the 1970s was revised upward from an average 6.4 percent under the old estimates to 7.1 percent under the new estimates. Potential GNP Until a formal reappraisal of the historical growth in real potential output can be completed in the light of the 1980 benchmark revisions to the NIPA, a provisional procedure has been used to estimate real potential GNP. The provisional procedure includes two major changes. First, revised data on business output indicate a somewhat more rapid gain in worker productivity since 1973. As a result, the trend rate of growth in potential GNP has been increased by one-fourth of a percentage point from 1973 on. Thus the onehalf percentage point deceleration in the old potential series that occurred in 1973, principally due to reduced productivity growth, has been changed to a one-fourth point deceleration. The further one-half point deceleration in potential that had been assumed starting in the first quarter of 1979 is still maintained. The second major change in the series was to add directly to potential the dollar estimate of the conceptual change to rest of world output that occurred from the revisions in the handling of reinvested foreign earnings. In this manner, the gap between actual and potential GNP is unaffected by conceptual changes to the NIPA. The dollar amount of these conceptual revisions has been growing very rapidly recently. As a result^theseichanges actually increase the estimated growth of potential in recent years by nearly 0.2 percentage point. The newly-constructed series grows somewhat less than 3 percent since the first quarter of 1979. This growth rate is expected to continue through 1981. Thereafter the series is projected to grow at 3 percent 180 per year. This modest acceleration is due to the combined effect of a small assumed increase in the growth rate of worker productivity offset by an expected decline in the contribution to growth of the conceptual changes to the NIPA. On balance, these changes to actual and potential GNP result in smaller output gaps over the recent past (Table 27). TABLE 27.—Revisedpotential GNP, 1973-80 Potential GNP (billions of 1972 dollars) Year 1973 1974 .... 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 2 1 Potential minus 2 Preliminary. 3 .. Prerevision -1.6 2.3 -0.7 3.7 1,320.6 1,365.1 1,411.4 1,459.3 1,504.6 6.6 4.7 2.8 1.5 1.4 7.7 5.1 3.0 1.7 2.0 1,548.5 4.4 (3) actual as a percent of potential. 181 Revised 1,234,9 1,277.5 Not available. Sources: Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic Analysis) and Council of Economic Advisers. GNP gap (percent)' CHAPTER 4 The World Economy: Coping with Transition The economic challenges facing the United States which have been discussed in previous chapters of this Report are not unique to this country. The problem of continuing high inflation is broadly shared by many of the industrial (and developing) countries. The enormous increase in the price of energy has created difficult problems of adjustment everywhere. Productivity growth has slowed not only in the United States but also in other countries. At the same time that all countries individually take actions to deal with these problems, cooperation among countries is required to manage the ever increasing interdependence of the world's economies. Over the next several years four major challenges will have to be surmounted to bring about the transition to a world economy with less inflation and higher growth. First, a combination of demand restraint and vigorous efforts to improve supply must be employed to bring down inflation and raise productivity. Second, the constraints placed on world economic expansion by limited supplies of energy must be loosened by policies to increase energy availability and reduce energy demand. Third, continued close attention is needed to assure that the international financial system effectively handles the much enlarged flow of financial resources among countries. Finally, the open trading system that contributed so importantly to rising prosperity in past decades must be strengthened in the face of increasing pressures to adopt protective measures and the temptation to indulge in "beggar-thy-neighbor" policies. The energy challenge is well understood and its international aspects were discussed extensively in last year's Report. It will therefore be dealt with only briefly in this chapter. Following an initial discussion of recent and prospective economic performance in the major industrial countries, the chapter examines each of the remaining three challenges—the challenge to the conduct of macroeconomic and structural policies, the challenge to the financial system, and the challenge to trade relations. 182 THE INDUSTRIAL ECONOMIES: TRENDS AND PROSPECTS In 1974-75, following the tripling of oil prices by the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), the industrial world experienced its largest recession since the second World War. In 1980, following a second major rise in oil prices, economic expansion again came to a halt. It is abundantly clear that price shocks of the size experienced in recent years cannot be absorbed without serious strains and disruptive side effects: real incomes are squeezed, inflationary forces are intensified, and output and employment are reduced. Fiscal and monetary policies cannot substantially offset or counteract all of these effects. Expansionary fiscal and monetary policies could moderate the decline in output, but at the cost of building yet higher inflation into the economy. Restrictive policies, on the other hand, could limit the rise in inflation, but they would also tend to accentuate the decline in output and employment. Following the second oilprice shock, most countries have opted for policies of moderate restraint. This choice reflects the judgment that such policies would stand the best chance of reducing secondary distortions in the structure of costs and prices and in the distribution of income among sectors, and thus would help speed the process of adjustment to the higher oil prices. That judgment appears to have been correct. ECONOMIC ACTIVITY Although all the evidence is not yet in, it appears that the second oil-price shock is being absorbed more smoothly than the first one was. Recent indicators and current projections show a smaller swing in output and a lesser surge in inflation for most countries. Table 28 shows recent growth rates and Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) projections for the major countries. Except for the United Kingdom, the general pattern is one of relatively mild and brief recession concentrated in the second half of 1980, followed by a very modest but strengthening recovery in 1981. TABLE 28.—Real GNP growth in major industrial countries, 1976-82 [Percent change from previous period; seasonally adjusted annual rates] Country United States Japan Germany France 3 United Kingdom Italy 3 Canada 1976 to 1979 annual average 3.9 5.9 3.8 3 12 2.9 3.9 Total of above countries 1 2 3 OECD estimate. OECD projection. Gross domestic product. Source: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). 183 1981 1980 Year1 % 1% 1% -2V* 3% Second half 1 First half 2 2A -1% 2% 4>/4 V/z ~ % -2 l /2 2V4 2 -5% -3>/2 -y2 -1V4 Second half 2 1V4 2% 1982 first half ^ 3V2 4% b 3V* There are several reasons why the recession appears to have been milder, and the rise in inflation less, after the second oil-price shock than after the first. In the first place, inventory movements are substantially smaller in the current cycle than they were in 1974-75. The massive inventory liquidation that marked the earlier recession is not being repeated. As a result, the decline in output has been smaller and the projected pace of recovery is initially slower. Consumer spending also has been better maintained in relation to income. Saving rates rose sharply in all countries following the first oil-price shock, but they have not done so recently, except in the United Kingdom. Slowing consumer demand is fully accounted for in most countries by weakening household incomes, rather than by marked changes in saving behavior. Finally, real wages in most countries have adjusted downward more rapidly in the wake of the recent oil-price rise than they did after the first one, and they have done so with a smaller acceleration of nominal wages. Both the different response of real wages and that of nominal wages have important consequences. When the world price of oil rises, countries that import oil lose real income. This loss can be absorbed in several ways. If nominal wages rise in line with traditional productivity increments and also to match all increases in consumer prices that result when higher energy costs are passed through, then real wage incomes are protected. Corporate profits, however, are squeezed. In this case household consumption opportunities are preserved, but investment demand is likely to be curtailed as firms grapple with reduced cash flow and lower returns on new investment. Alternatively, if nominal wages rise by a lesser amount in relation to prices, then real wage incomes are squeezed, but the associated decline in real labor costs provides firms with a margin that offsets, in whole or in part, the increase in their energy costs. In this case, consumption may be curtailed, but investment incentives are better maintained. Chart 10 shows the difference in how the real income loss was absorbed abroad following the two oil-price shocks. In 1974-75 unit labor costs rose much more than value-added deflators for manufacturing. This implied a sharp rise in the labor share of total value added, and a corresponding fall in the profit share, which was only gradually restored in subsequent years. The squeeze on profits was a major cause of low rates of investment in most foreign countries during the following years. And lagging investment largely explains the "hesitant recovery" abroad that was described in the 1978 Report In contrast to the experience abroad, real wages fell in the United States in 1974-75, and investment demand grew apace during the subsequent recovery. 184 Chart 10 Labor Costs, Value-Added Deflators, and Labor Share in Six Major Foreign Countries PERCENT CHANGE PERCENT 20 UNIT LABOR COSTS IN MANUFACTURING (Left scale) VALUE-ADDED DEFLATORS IN MANUFACTURING (Left scale) LABOR SHARE OF VALUE ADDED IN MANUFACTURING (Right scale) \ 1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 NOTE—INCLUDES JAPAN, GERMANY, FRANCE, UNITED KINGDOM, ITALY, AND CANADA. SOURCE; ORGANIZATION FOR ECONOMIC COOPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT. In 1979-80, the* increase in unit labor costs in major foreign countries remained less than the rise in value-added deflators, thus giving manufacturers some room to absorb increased energy costs without a major squeeze on profit margins. Largely for this reason, but also because the needs to modernize production and improve energy efficiency are substantial, business investment abroad may not weaken unduly in the current recession and may begin to rise again at an early stage of the projected recovery. The necessary reduction in real incomes, whether it is initially absorbed by wage earners or by their employers, can be associated with a larger or smaller acceleration in inflation. If nominal wages rise sharply, and firms resist the erosion of profit margins by further raising prices, then the adjustment will take place in an environment of rising inflation. By contrast, if nominal wages do not accelerate, then real wages will initially fall as higher oil prices are passed through, but the underlying rate of inflation will not accelerate. And once the pass-through of higher oil costs is completed, actual price rises will 185 begin to moderate. The second pattern is preferable, not only because it is more likely to sustain investment but also because it generates less inflation. The relative moderation of nominal wage increases in most countries recently, in sharp contrast to the nominal wage explosions that occurred in 1974, is therefore encouraging. Despite these generally favorable developments, only sluggish growth is now projected for most countries during 1981. Two major factors account for this. First, as already noted, inventory building will not provide added strength. Second, fiscal and monetary policies will remain restrictive. Fiscal deficits in 1980 were little changed from those of 1979 in the major foreign t countries, despite the slowing revenue growth and expenditure increases associated with weakening economic activity. Discretionary fiscal policy actions tended to work toward restraint. Announced policy intentions in most countries suggest a further shift toward restraint in 1981. Growth in government expenditures, in particular, is planned to stay below anticipated growth in gross national product (GNP) in most countries, thus reducing the share of government and limiting the rise in budget deficits. EXTERNAL POSITIONS For the OECD countries as a group, the two oil-price shocks have had similar effects on trade and current-account positions. In nominal terms, the current account of the OECD as a whole shifted from surplus to deficit by about 1 percent of GNP in 1974 and by about P/2 percent of GNP in 1979-80. In both periods, however, the volume of real imports fell relative to exports; real trade balances therefore rose, moderating the decline in GNP relative to domestic demand. But in one important respect the 1974-75 and 1979-80 periods have been very different. Both the volume of imports and of exports declined precipitously after 1974, even in relation to the large fall in GNP. The current decline in trade volumes has been much more moderate, and more nearly in line with the path of GNP. A renewed expansion of world trade, albeit at moderate rates, is anticipated as recovery proceeds. Although the aggregate shift in current-account positions was broadly similar after the two oil-price shocks, there are some important differences in the way this shift was distributed among the major OECD countries (Table 29). In general, a larger share of the total shift has been absorbed by those countries whose relatively good inflation performance and previously strong external positions made them better able to finance these deficits. Most notably, the remarkable performance of Germany in 1974, when its surplus increased by $5.7 billion despite the rise in its oil bill, has not been repeated. 186 Rather, the German current account shifted from a surplus of about $9 billion in 1978 to an estimated deficit of $17 billion in 1980. The Japanese current account also moved sharply, from a $17-billion surplus in 1978 to an estimated $13-billion deficit in 1980. This shift reflected not only higher oil payments but also the adverse shortterm effect of yen depreciation during 1979 and the first quarter of 1980 on the nominal trade balance. These two effects more than offset the strong Japanese trade performance, in volume terms, during the past year. TABLE 29.—Current-account balances in major industrial countries, 1978-81 [Billions of U.S. dollars >] Country United States Japan . , . Germany France United Kingdom Italy Canada . . Other OECD Total OECO 1 2 3 1979 1978 1980 2 19813 19% -6% -14.3 16.5 8.7 3.7 1.2 6.2 -4.4 -8.7 -0.8 -8.8 -5.5 1.2 -3.9 5.1 -4.4 -18.4 -3% -37 -IOV2 -6>/4 4>/4 -2>/4 —3 -35V4 9.0 -35.5 -73l/2 -40 5y 2 -13V4 -17V4 -7% 4% -5V4 Current account balances inclusive of official transfers. Preliminary OECO estimates. OECO projection. Source: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). By contrast, the current account of the United States improved by an estimated $20 billion over this same period, as discussed more fully in Chapter 3. Similarly, the United Kingdom moved into substantial surplus during 1980, both because that country has become largely self-sufficient in oil—so that its trade account was not strongly affected by the rise in oil prices—and because the recession has been relatively more severe in the United Kingdom than elsewhere, thus limiting imports. INFLATION The different pattern of absorption of the recent oil-price shock compared to the earlier one shows up clearly in the movements of wages and prices. Chart 11 traces the movements of consumer prices and hourly earnings in manufacturing over the past decade for the major industrial countries. As measured by consumer prices, rates of inflation outside the United States tended to decline during 1978 to levels comparable to those prevailing in the early 1970s—though with substantial dispersion among countries. But consumer price inflation accelerated everywhere during 1979 and into 1980 under the impact of higher energy prices. In sharp contrast to the earlier period, however, hourly earnings accelerated only moderately, and lagged behind consumer prices in almost all countries. As oil prices 187 stabilized in mid-1980, inflation rates peaked and then began to recede in the second half of the year. On current projections, and assuming that oil prices do not again rise sharply, a continued reduction in inflation rates is in prospect for most countries during 1981 — indeed, a somewhat more rapid reduction abroad than in the United States (Table 30). Chart 11 Wage and Price Changes in Seven Major Countries PERCENT C H A N G E F R O M 4 Q U A R T E R S EARLIER 25 20 _ HOURLY EARNINGS IN M A N U F A C T U R I N G rCONSUMER 0 , 1971 I • , • I 72 , . 73 . I • . 74 . I , . . I 75 • • 76 . PRICES I . , 77 . I , , . I 78 , . , I 79 , t • 80 NOTE.—INCLUDES UNITED STATES, JAPAN, GERMANY, FRANCE, UNITED KINGDOM, ITALY, AND CANADA. SOURCE: ORGANIZATION FOR ECONOMIC COOPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT. Substantial differences among the major countries will persist, however. At one extreme, inflation rates in Germany and Japan during 1981 are likely to return to the moderate levels that were achieved in 1977-78. On the other hand, relatively high inflation is likely to persist in a number of other countries—especially Italy, but also the United States, France, and Canada—where wage rigidities appear to be more significant. In the United Kingdom, the continued adherence to restrictive fiscal and monetary policies, the strength of the pound, and substantial slack in labor and product markets appear to be causing a rapid decline in inflation from the high levels reached in 1979 and early 1980. But even so, inflation in the United Kingdom will remain relatively high. 188 TABLE 30.—Inflation in major industrial countries, 1976-82 [Percent change in prices *] 1976 to 1978 annual average Country United States Japan Germany France United Kingdom. Italy. Canada. . . Total of above countries.. 1979 6.2 5.5 3.2 9.4 11.7 12.0 9.8 8.9 3.1 3.9 10.9 12.2 14.8 9.1 6.8 8.1 1980 2 1981 3 1982 first half 3 5>/4 9% 5 13% 15 % 20% 93A 11% 12 15% 10 9 13 Vz 9% 10 »/2 9>/4 10% 6>/4 5>/4 10 9>/2 Change in implicit price deflator for private consumption expenditures for United States, Japan, Germany, United Kingdom, and Canada. Change in consumer prices for France and Italy. Percent changes for first half 1982 are from previous half year at seasonally adjusted annual rates, except France and Italy, not seasonally adjusted annual rates. 2 Preliminary. 3 OECD forecast. 4 Based on 1979 GNP/GDP weights and exchange rates. Source: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). SUMMARY ASSESSMENT It is not possible to provide a definitive explanation of why the oilprice rise was absorbed more easily during the current cycle than it was in 1974-75. Timing is certainly one important consideration. The most recent runup in oil prices came at a time when most countries were still on an upswing from the previous recession, rather than at a peak. Hence, cyclical factors tended to offset, rather than accentuate, the 1979 price shock. In addition, the 1974 shock followed hard upon a major surge in industrial and agricultural commodity prices, which generated strong speculative pressures and excessive inventory accumulation. Commodity prices—except for the explosion in prices of precious metals in 1979 and early 1980—have shown a less marked upward trend in the recent period. The key element promoting smoother adjustment, however, has been the restrained response of nominal wages to rising prices in most countries. This restraint has served a double furiction. It has helped to preserve a relationship between costs and prices that will encourage a more rapid resumption of growth by maintaining profitability and thus investment. It has also limited the rise in underlying inflation rates and thus reduced the probable duration and severity of the fiscal and monetary policy restraint that is required. A number of factors may explain the moderate behavior of wages, and different factors may be more important in some countries than in others. The unambiguous adoption, in almost all countries, of monetary policies that did not seek to finance the rise in oil prices with faster rates of monetary expansion has certainly been an important factor, as has the pursuit of moderately restrictive fiscal policies. "Jawboning" by government officials may also have had an effect in 189 some countries, and in the United States a more formal incomes policy has played a role. Wage moderation may also have reflected the higher average levels of unemployment and associated labor market slack that prevailed in 1979. In some countries—especially those where the oil-price shock has been absorbed most rapidly such as Germany and Japan—wage moderation may reflect an implicit social consensus under which unavoidable reductions in real incomes are accepted by wage earners in the understanding that the distribution of income will not thereby be shifted to their disadvantage. Although the adjustment to the recent runup in oil prices has proceeded relatively smoothly in most countries, it cannot be denied that the process is very costly. While the increased oil bill due to the price rises of 1979-80 amounts to about 2V2 percent of the combined GNP of the OECD member countries, the cost in lost output is much larger. Taking into account the effects of both the oil-price rise itself and the restrictive monetary and fiscal policies it called forth, the OECD estimates that the level of GNP in the OECD member countries may be some 6 percent, or about $500 billion, lower by the beginning of 1982 than it would have been in the absence of the oilprice rise. While this estimate might be somewhat on the high side, it is nevertheless clear that even smooth adjustment cannot prevent major secondary repercussions. RISKS IN THE OUTLOOK Excluding the United States, real GNP in the major industrial countries is projected to rise at about a 2 percent annual rate from the second half of 1980 to the first half of 1982—a pace unlikely to be rapid enough to prevent some further increases in unemployment. Inflation rates in the industrial countries outside the United States are projected to slow—averaging about 8.5 percent by the first half of 1982, as compared to 11 percent in the second half of 1980. The possibility of worse outcomes cannot be dismissed, however. In particular, one cannot be entirely confident that the pattern of wage moderation will continue, inasmuch as the reasons for it are not fully understood. A continuation of relatively restrictive monetary and fiscal policies in most countries is widely viewed as necessary to contain this risk, but these policies may also slow recovery by more than is now projected. More critically, the situation in the oil market is once again precarious following the interruption of supplies from Iran and Iraq. A further large increase in oil prices in 1981 could undermine the still fragile process of consolidation and recovery. The following section addresses this issue in more detail. 190 THE GLOBAL OIL MARKET Table 31 summarizes world petroleum production and use patterns over the past 8 years. The most striking aspect of the table is how small the year-to-year fluctuations in production have been. The major disruptions of 1974 and 1979 were associated with very modest shifts in the balance between consumption and production. It is the low price elasticities of supply and demand in the short run, rather than wide fluctuations in the quantities supplied or demanded, that make disruptive price movements possible. TABLE 31.—Global oil balances, 1973-80 [Millions of barrets per day, except as noted] Item 1973 OECD consumption Less: OECD production Equals: Required OECD imports for consumption (A) 39.3 13.9 OPEC production Less: Non-OECD consumption minus non-OPEC, non-OECD production Equals: Available to OECD from rest of world (B) Balancing item (B minus A ) 3 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979» 1980 * 40.4 14.8 38.0 15.0 37.6 13.4 36.3 12.8 38.5 12.7 39.4 13.3 40.3 14.2 25.4 24.2 23.5 25.8 26.1 26.1 25.6 23.0 31.3 31.1 27.6 31.2 31.8 30.5 31.5 27.8 5.4 5.2 4.8 4.9 4.9 5.0 4.8 25.9 25.9 23.3 26.4 26.9 25.6 26.5 23.0 1.7 -.2 .6 .8 -.5 .9 .0 (*) 3.6 4.0 3.9 4.2 4.2 .5 Estimated stock levels, end of year (billions of barrels).. 4.3 1 Preliminary. 2 Forecast. 3 Stock-buttding and/or statistical errors. *Not available. Source: Council of Economic Advisers. The 1979 rise in oil prices occurred despite increased oil production. The curtailment of Iranian supplies in late 1978 was more than made up in 1979 by production increases elsewhere. Nevertheless, a number of prior developments had created conditions favorable to price increases. First of all, world consumption of petroleum, though rising more slowly after 1975 than in the previous decade, nonetheless increased steadily from 1975 to 1978, reducing the excess production capacity that had emerged after the first oil-price shock. Second, the real price of oil fell during this period, thus encouraging consumption and also reducing the real value of OPEC revenues. Finally, stocks were drawn down during the course of 1978—perhaps because falling real oil prices had made stock building appear unprofitable. As a result, the margin of flexibility available to accommodate the curtailment of Iranian supplies was small, and the incentives for OPEC countries to raise prices were strong. It is clear that smaller price increases than actually occurred would have been sufficient to balance consumption and production. Rising demand for stocks, however, kept pushing prices higher well into 191 1980. After midyear, when consumption had fallen sufficiently to accommodate and moderate the stock buildup, price pressures began to ease. In fact, excess supply conditions were avoided only because a number of OPEC countries cut back their production. Hindsight also shows that a less ambitious restocking pattern during 1979 and up to mid-1980 would have made a smoother adjustment possible. One cannot be certain of all the reasons why this restocking occurred, but several factors may have been important. First, additional stocks may have been needed to keep the distribution system operating smoothly, given the growing fragmentation of the world oil market and the resulting decreased ability of the major oil companies to shift supplies around to accommodate shifting needs. In addition, the disruption in late 1978 and early 1979 greatly increased feelings of uncertainty about future supplies and thus raised the precautionary demand for stocks. Finally, the rise in prices itself tended to increase the incentives for stock accumulation in anticipation of capital gains—at least until prices had risen sufficiently to make further price rises appear less probable. This speculative motive may have been strengthened by the belief that OPEC countries respond asymmetrically to market conditions. If OPEC producers respond to tight market conditions by raising prices but cut back on production when markets weaken rather than allowing prices to fall, they in effect build a ratchet under existing prices. Stock building then becomes a particularly attractive form of speculation when prices begin to rise, since the risk of major financial loss from a subsequent fall in prices is much reduced. Although the massive buildup of stocks during 1979 and 1980 was very costly because of the added pressure it placed on oil prices, these stocks have subsequently proved valuable because they have provided a cushion in the face of the Iran-Iraq war. The oil market would in all probability have been slack in 1981, with little pressure on oil prices, if the Iran-Iraq war had not occurred. Prior to the onset of hostilities, consumption per day was several million barrels below world capacity, and stocks were at very high levels. Now, however, the situation is more difficult to assess. The war has removed nearly 4 million barrels a day from world oil supplies for an undetermined length of time, but some of this loss is being offset by increased production elsewhere. At the moment, stocks are still above their normal historical levels, and severe market pressures have not emerged. The margin, however, is a narrow one. If oil consumption continues to decline as further adaptation to higher prices outweighs the effects of resumed economic growth, if the war does not widen, and if stock drawdowns are permitted to occur as needed, then a balance 192 may be preserved. Stocks are in fact being drawn down, consistent with the objectives set for the major oil-consuming countries at the meeting of the International Energy Agency late last year. But if the disruption is more severe, or mismatches on a country-by-country basis between demands and stocks induce a scramble for extra supplies and a bidding up of prices in spot markets, or if expectations of price rises—warranted or not—induce speculative withholding of stocks in anticipation of capital gains, then acute market pressures could once again develop. DIRECTIONS FOR ECONOMIC POLICY: NEEDS AND CHALLENGES Despite the progressive absorption of the 1979 oil shock and the projected beginning of moderate recovery this year, the world economy will be grappling with several difficult problems in the years immediately ahead. First, policies of demand restraint are needed in all countries to fight inflation. This need is felt not only in those countries where inflation rates are highest, but also in those where considerable progress has already been made in bringing inflation down. For these latter countries, the concern is that an early relaxation of restrictive policies before inflationary expectations have been firmly laid to rest would allow inflation to reaccelerate. This would not only undo the progress achieved but would also undermine the credibility—and hence the effectiveness—of subsequent anti-inflation policies. The degree and duration of needed restraint, of course, varies among countries. Where inflation rates have been persistently high, continued restraint for a number of years may be necessary to bring inflation down and to convince people that it will stay down. Where inflationary expectations are less deeply entrenched and where inflation is lower, a shift to less restrictive policies may be possible sooner. Because of the momentum of inherited inflation and rigidities in the setting of wages and prices, restrictive demand policies that aim to reduce inflation will also slow the growth of production and keep unemployment relatively high for some time. In this way, the inflation problem gives rise to an unemployment problem. Unemployment rates have risen in most countries during the 1970s, and no early reversal of this trend is in sight. High unemployment is costly not only because it imposes hardships on those who do not have jobs, but also because it fosters "preservationist" attitudes among society generally. Economic restructuring becomes more difficult when workers in declining firms or industries fear they will be unable to find other work, when pressure on governments to subsidize unprof- 193 itable activities intensifies, and when trade protection becomes more attractive. The second fundamental problem is that in most industrial countries the growth of potential output has fallen because of lower productivity gains. The decline in productivity growth has generally been less marked abroad than in the United States, but it has occurred to some extent in all countries. Although all the reasons for this decline are not known, several common factors can be identified. Higher energy prices lead to the substitution of labor for energy, and thereby induce a slowing in productivity. Productivity growth has been slowed also by lower rates of investment in many countries, leading to a smaller rise in capital per worker and a slower pace of adoption of the technological innovations embodied in new capital goods. Finally, productivity growth outside the United States has been reduced because opportunities for technological borrowing have diminished as the "technology gap" between the United States and other industrial countries has diminished or, in many sectors, disappeared. The decline in productivity growth directly reduces the scope for increases in real incomes and standards of living. Nevertheless, some have argued that as long as the growth of production is also limited by restrictive demand policies the decline in productivity is not all bad because it leads to more employment, and hence less of an unemployment problem, than would be the case if productivity growth remained higher. This argument, however, ignores the fact that lower productivity growth increases cost-push inflation. Since wage demands do not adjust downward when productivity growth slows, unit labor costs rise faster, putting increased upward pressure on prices. If nominal wage demands then accelerate in an attempt to achieve the real income gains obtained in the past when productivity growth was higher, the underlying inflation rate is increased still further. As a result, demand policies have to be more restrictive than otherwise to achieve a deceleration of inflation. In this way a slowing of productivity imposes a double burden. It reduces the growth of potential output, and at the same time it increases the degree of economic slack that is needed to achieve a given deceleration of inflation. THE SEARCH FOR SOLUTIONS While restrictive demand policies are needed to fight inflation, other policies must be put in place to reduce the costs that restrictive demand policies inevitably impose on the economy and to restore over time a more normal growth in productivity and living standards. Three broad approaches need to be pursued. First, supply-oriented policies that raise productivity and increase economic flexibility need to be put in place. Second, policies to increase energy supply and to reduce the demand for energy are needed to weaken the energy con- 194 straint on growth. Finally, policies that directly influence wage an price setting can play a role in some nations in lowering actual an expected inflation. Supply-Oriented Policies As discussed in Chapters 1 and 2 with respect to the U.S. econo my, supply-side measures can make a significant contribution to improved economic performance. Beyond the direct benefits that such measures can provide by increasing the efficiency with which resources are allocated, they can also serve to reduce the costs of restrictive demand policies. If flexibility in labor or product markets is increased, the effectiveness of demand restraint in slowing inflation also improves. If productivity growth is enhanced, not only does potential output rise but higher levels of capacity utilization can also be achieved, since cost-push inflation is reduced. There is no master plan of supply-side policies that will be equally useful to all countries, given their different institutional arrangements and structural relationships. Earlier chapters of this Report discuss a number of policy approaches appropriate to the United States, and many of these may also be useful in other countries. Two approaches, in particular, stand out as important in most countries. First, policies are needed to raise the share of GNP that is invested in new plant and equipment. Higher investment is necessary to raise productivity growth, to increase domestic energy production, and to accelerate the economic restructuring that higher oil prices and global shifts in patterns of comparative advantage have made necessary. A potential problem exists with respect to greater investment, a problem which some have called the "low-growth trap." The argument is that if restrictive demand policies are used to fight inflation, investment will also be reduced because the existence of unutilized capacity will make companies unwilling to undertake investments that may not be needed until the more distant future. Lower investment, in turn, would reduce productivity growth and potential output, and hence reinforce the need for demand restraint. Thus, the final outcome might be a prolonged period of stagflation. While there are indeed difficulties in trying to increase investment during a period of demand restraint, one need not accept the "lowgrowth trap" argument. Low rates of capacity utilization do, by themselves, have a negative effect on investment. Other factors, however, are also important and can offset this effect. As was emphasized earlier in this chapter, the recent oil shock has been absorbed in a way that has limited the erosion of profitability and cash flow to enterprises, and thus has supported investment. Moreover, the need for restructuring may require substantial investment even in sectors where 195 capacity utilization is low. The U.S. automobile sector is a clear example, and similar requirements exist in most countries. Finally, as discussed in Chapter 1 with reference to the United States, there is a good deal of evidence that policies to raise the return on capital investment or to lower the cost of capital can have substantial impacts on investment demand even when significant excess capacity exists. For all of these reasons it seems probable that countries can avoid a low-growth trap and, by pursuing vigorous investment-oriented policies, raise the share of investment in GNP even while continuing with policies of overall demand restraint. The second supply-oriented approach is to increase the flexibility of labor and product markets by reducing unnecessarily burdensome regulation, by increasing competition within and across borders, and by improving policies for structural adjustment in industry and agriculture. Policies, for instance, that improve flexibility in labor markets through job training or other programs, or which reduce the downward rigidity of wages in the face of high unemployment, achieve several important objectives simultaneously. They reduce unemployment directly by easing frictional unemployment and stimulating the demand for labor in sectors where prevailing wage rigidities have made hiring unprofitable. Perhaps more important, greater labor-market flexibility increases the speed with which restrictive demand policies translate into lower rates of inflation. To the extent that this occurs, higher rates of real growth can be accommodated. Even if demand policies do not change so that nominal income growth is limited, real income growth is larger to the extent that inflation is less. Moreover, if inflation declines more quickly in response to demand restraint, both the severity and the duration of the needed demand restraint are reduced, thus further improving the prospects for higher growth and a more rapid absorption of the unemployed. Other examples of policies that enhance flexibility include U.S. efforts in deregulation and regulatory reform, the progressive dismantling of price controls in France during the past several years, and the moves in some countries to allow more realistic pricing policies in nationalized sectors. There are serious difficulties to be overcome, however. In many cases governments lack the tools for evaluating the costs and benefits of structural policies. Divisions of authority among agencies with different objectives or loyalties make coherent policy formulation, implementation, or evaluation difficult. There is, in general, a need to increase the "transparency" of government operations—both internally, so that governments themselves can come to a clearer perception of just what it is they are doing, and externally, so that those 196 outside government, both at home and abroad, can form a clearer idea of what is to be expected. A further inescapable difficulty is that strong political pressures arise to influence structural policies when potential gains or losses to particular sectors are at issue. More powerful techniques to enhance transparency can serve not only to improve the quality of decisionmaking, but also—by making costs and benefits clearer—to stiffen the resistance of governments to unbalanced political pressure. Energy Policies Increased investment in alternative energy sources, efforts to promote more efficient use of existing supplies, and measures to reduce vulnerability to supply disruptions are needed to improve growth prospects over the longer-term. So long as oil supplies are scarce and uncertain, and energy markets lack the flexibility to absorb disruptions in the flow of oil, the risk of recurrent oil-price shocks cannot be avoided. While the market incentives provided by sharply higher energy prices will furnish the major impetus for many of the needed adjustments, government actions will also be needed in some cases. The development of some new sources of energy, for instance, may require government participation because of the long lead-times, very large scale, and technological risks associated with them. Furthermore, the building up and management of petroleum stockpiles requires a government role since private stocking provides insufficient protection against oil-supply disruptions for the reasons discussed in Chapter 2. There is also a strong rationale for a broader international coordination of energy policies. The potential gains from a more rapid expansion of U.S. coal production, for instance, are increased if other countries, anticipating the increased availability of coal, at the same time increase the capacity of their electric-power systems to use coal instead of other fuels. More broadly, part of the social benefits that arise when one country increases its energy production or reduces its energy demand accrue abroad, since energy consumers in all countries will benefit from the resulting reduced pressure on world energy prices. Joint projects and other forms of international cooperation may therefore be particularly appropriate in the field of energy. The rationale for international coordination of government policies is especially strong with regard to oil stocks. If countries attempt to increase their own security by bidding for stocks and thereby create conditions of excess demand, all countries will suffer the consequences of sharply higher oil prices. Conversely, the willingness of one country to use existing stocks in times when markets are tight may depend on the extent to which other countries do the same. A 197 coordinated use of stocks may forestall a surge in oil prices, but few countries would act individually to draw down their stocks if they thought that others would then exploit the opportunity to protect or increase their own. Incomes Policies The adoption of policies to influence directly the process of wage and price setting is another approach to improving economic performance. Elsewhere in this Report the possibilities as well as the problems of implementing tax-based policies to encourage wage and price restraint in the United States are discussed. The major foreign countries do not now have formal incomes policies—though interest in using them has at various times been evident in several of them. It does appear to be the case, however, that those countries with the greatest downward flexibility in wage and price behavior, and hence also the lowest inflation rates, have a stronger social consensus than those countries with higher inflation. Ironically, it may be that explicit incomes policies would be easiest to implement in those countries where the implicit social consensus makes them least needed. MONETARY POLICY AND EXCHANGE RATES In addition to the fundamental economic and social issues involved in designing and carrying out sustained policies of demand restraint and supply enhancement, there are problems of a more technical nature that must be dealt with. One of these, which has received a good bit of attention recently, arises from the interaction between domestic monetary policy and the foreign-exchange markets. If it is perceived that different countries, through their monetary and fiscal policies, have significantly different objectives, especially with respect to inflation, then exchange rates are likely to move. For instance, if some countries use monetary policies aggressively to achieve a rapid decline in inflation while others pursue more expansionary policies that are judged likely to increase inflation, the currencies of the former countries will tend to appreciate against those of the latter. Such exchange-rate adjustments are both unavoidable over the longer run and necessary to prevent the building up of distortions in relative price levels across countries, so long as different policy objectives persist. Exchange-rate adjustments do not always proceed smoothly, however. Exchange markets may at times become disorderly, and exchange rates may move more* sharply than necessary to accommodate differences in policies or in other fundamental economic variables. Such risks probably increase when the divergence in policy objectives becomes more marked and expectations about future economic performance correspondingly more diverse. Particularly when inflation 198 rates are high, differences in policy objectives may have a magnified effect on exchange rates if the countries that attempt to ease policy are viewed as giving up on the fight against inflation. For these reasons, some combination of broad consistency in economic policy objectives and cooperation in exchange-market policies is probably necessary to ensure the smooth functioning of the international monetary system. As discussed earlier in this chapter, most countries are now pursuing broadly similar policies of demand restraint aimed at reducing inflation, and exchange markets have not been subject to major disruptions over the past 2 years. Monetary policies in many countries have focused on keeping the rates of money growth—differently defined in different countries—on target or within target ranges. These targets are themselves set with an eye toward steady reduction in the rate of monetary expansion so as to be consistent with the hoped-for reduction in inflation. Even though monetary policies have shared the same general objectives and approach, they have had different consequences in different countries with respect to both the level and the variability of interest rates. For various reasons these differences have been particularly wide in the recent past and have raised several questions about the relationship between domestic monetary policies and the variability of exchange rates. To the extent that actual and expected rates of inflation differ across countries, nominal rates of interest tend to be different even when monetary authorities pursue policies that restrict nominal demand growth to a comparable extent. If different interest rates simply reflect differences in underlying inflation expectations, international financial markets should not, in theory, be disrupted. Market participants would recognize that higher nominal yields on assets denominated in some currencies do not necessarily translate into higher rates of return if exchange rates move over time to reflect differences in inflation. For a variety of reasons, however, this mechanism may not always function smoothly. Purchasing power parities do not hold with any great precision in the short or even the more medium term. Therefore, market participants need not assume that depreciation will offset higher nominal yields over the period during which the asset is held. Furthermore, if asset holders perceive that monetary authorities are likely to resist incipient currency depreciations through intervention, they may be tempted to seek out high nominal returns on the expectation that they will be able to unwind their positions before the depreciation occurs. In such circumstances downward pressure on the exchange rates of countries with lower inflation and nominal interest rates might arise. 199 The large differences in monetary structures and instruments of monetary control across countries may also produce substantial differences in real interest rates for comparable degrees of monetary restraint. In particular, monetary systems which rely more heavily on nonprice rationing effects to achieve restraint may tend to have lower real rates of interest than those which have fewer such rigidities (though such rigidities may also cause greater dispersion of interest rates across different financial markets). Where such real interest rate differences arise, exchange-rate pressures may emerge even when nominal interest rates are properly discounted for inflation. A second problem on which attention has focused has been the greater volatility of interest rates. As discussed in other chapters of this Report, both the change in the operating procedures of the Federal Reserve and major changes in the structure of U.S. financial markets have led to increased variability in U.S. interest rates. If foreign exchange markets are highly sensitive to interest rate movements, then variations in U.S. interest rates may lead either to greater variability in the exchange rates of other countries vis-a-vis the dollar or else to greater fluctuations in their interest rates. Of course, a reduction in the volatility of interest rates in the United States would be desirable on domestic grounds as well, if it could be accomplished without compromising the ability of the Federal Reserve to achieve its monetary growth objectives. Although it is clear that considerations of exchange-rate volatility may sometimes reduce the freedom of monetary authorities to conduct monetary policies solely on the basis of domestic objectives, the problem may have been overstated in recent public discussions. Moderate movements in exchange rates, even if not strictly necessary from the perspective of fundamental economic conditions, need not impose significant costs on economic performance. Furthermore, if longer-run expectations concerning inflation and current-account balances are such as to provide stability to exchange rates, interest rate differences are not likely to be a major and continuing source of trouble. The strength of the dollar in the latter part of 1980, for instance, reflected not only high interest rates but also the strong current-account position of the United States. At the same time, the weakness of the German mark, not only vis-a-vis the dollar but also against the other currencies of the European Monetary System, was also due to the large and unaccustomed German current-account deficit in 1980. The yen, to take another example, strengthened during the second half of last year and yet further in early 1981 despite a lowering of Japanese interest rates and a large, although declining, current-account deficit. This strength probably reflects the relatively buoyant 200 Japanese trade performance in volume terms, and also perhaps the ability of the Japanese authorities to attract OPEC funds. Again, the continued strength of sterling during 1980 was only in part the result of high nominal interest rates. Oil independence, the strengthening current-account position, and the general credibility of the British government's commitment to policies of restraint were also important. To sum up, it appears that even with broad consistency in monetary policy objectives, problems can sometimes arise from the potential flow of funds across borders in response to differences in nominal interest rates. While the threat of such flows can complicate the conduct of monetary policy, this threat need not be so severe as to deprive carefully managed monetary policies of the flexibility they need to meet domestic objectives. Flexibility in monetary policy may, of course, occasionally require somewhat greater fluctuations in exchange rates than would otherwise be the case, but if fundamental economic conditions are such as to promote stability, such movements should not pose major problems. CHALLENGES TO THE INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL SYSTEM The international community possesses a marvelously articulated set of private and public financial institutions through which funds are channeled from short-term lenders to long-term borrowers, from surplus to deficit countries, from one currency to another, and from capital-rich countries to capital-poor developing ones. The smooth functioning of this financial system has helped to make possible a rapid expansion of international trade and a relatively sizable transfer of resources to developing countries, both of which have contributed importantly to postwar economic growth and development. While the system has periodically required attention to keep it up to date with changing financial conditions, it has adapted and performed its critical functions well over the last three-and-a-half decades. The huge increase in the volume of international financial flows occasioned by the recent oil-price rise, following upon a similar increase only 5 years earlier, has placed a major strain upon international financial institutions. Making sure that these institutions can continue to conduct vitally needed financial transfers soundly and efficiently is a second major challenge to economic policymaking in the years immediately ahead. If the needed transfers of resources from surplus to deficit countries are not made, or if they occur in ways that permit countries to avoid the painful adjustment to higher oil prices, the prospects for sustainable world economic growth and development will be seriously harmed. 201 The volume of international financing is reflected in Table 32, which describes current-account positions, net of official transfers, for broad country groupings, as compiled and projected by the OECD. The table provides an indication of the orders of magnitude involved, but specific numbers should not be overemphasized since even the historical numbers are subject to substantial margins of error. The projections for 1981 are particularly uncertain because the assumption of a constant real oil price that underlies these projections is at risk on account of the Iran-Iraq struggle. Very large financing needs will persist over the next several years. While the OPEC surplus is expected to decline if oil prices do not rise sharply again, the decline will be more than matched by a projected improvement in the current-account positions of the larger OECD countries. The deficits of the smaller OECD countries will remain roughly unchanged at levels that—while broadly financeable—are nevertheless viewed as a problem by the countries themselves. The already substantial deficits of a number of the non-oil developing countries are projected to rise further, but whether financing on the scale implied by such deficits will be forthcoming must remain a question of serious concern. TABLE 32.—Global current-account balances, exclusive of official transfers, 1978-81 [Billions of U.S. dollars; OECD basis] Country 1978 OECD Bis Seven » Other .. .. 1980' -13 -47 -12 35 2 -14 -33 -33% 5 Non-oil developing countries.. -30% Other « -9% . . . 19812 28 -15 OPEC Residual« 1979 7 70 -47 -3 21% 120 86 -62 -69 -6 -9 -5 4 1 Preliminary. *:i OECD projection. United States, Japan, Germany, France, United Kingdom, Italy, and Canada. 4 Centrally planned economies, Gibraltar, Malta, South Africa and Yugoslavia. A Reflects statistical errors and asymmetries. Given the very large gross flows of world balance of payments transactions, statistical errors and asymmetries easily give rise to world totals (balances) that are significantly different from zero. Source: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). At an aggregate level, of course, the borrowing needed to finance deficits must be matched by the lending that surplus countries undertake. The relative ease, compared to expectations, with which the "recycling" of funds was carried out after the first oil-price shock no doubt owes a great deal to this "adding-up" property. The sharp increases in liquidity arising from massive inflows of OPEC funds into the major national and Eurocurrency banks provided the funding for the large increase in lending by these banks to the deficit countries. 202 No "Say's Law" operates in international financial markets, however, to assure that desired lending matches intended borrowing on a country-by-country basis. Much of the money available for lending comes from countries, especially OPEC countries, who wish to place their funds in short-term liquid deposits. But much of the borrowing, especially on the part of newly industrialized countries with relatively fragile debt-servicing capacity, is for long-term needs. Between these two different sets of preferences stand the intermediaries—some official international institutions and some international capital markets, but principally the large private banks of the industrial countries which accept liquid short-term deposits, make illiquid long-term loans, and in return for the profits they earn bear most of the risks involved. Channels of intermediation, however, can become clogged or overburdened. Perceptions of risk may limit the willingness of intermediaries to expand their lending to certain countries, or high borrowing costs may simply preclude countries with low incomes from borrowing, since they lack the resources needed to service this debt. FINANCING THE DEFICITS OF THE NON-OIL DEVELOPING COUNTRIES The broad financing pattern for the non-oil developing countries over the period from 1973 to 1979 is shown in Table 33, taken from IMF compilations. The character of the flows that finance these countries' deficits has changed markedly since 1973 when a large share of the financing was with funds, such as government transfers, that did not create debt. Since 1975, however, deficit financing has come to depend increasingly on sources that do create debt, especially on long-term borrowing on market terms from private sources. Beginning in 1979—and partial evidence suggests the trend continued into 1980—the share of private long-term financing declined. Offsetting that decline were a small rise in official financing, a stronger increase in short-term borrowing, and a slowing of reserve accumulation. The aggregate data in Table 33 mask considerable diversity among countries, but two main groups can be identified. One group consists of the low-income developing countries which, largely unable to afford market terms, rely heavily on official financing on concessional terms. For them the continued availability of official finance on affordable terms is a major concern. In particular, the expansion of World Bank resources through the Sixth Replenishment of its soft-loan affiliate, the International Development Association (IDA), is critical for these countries. Yet without the approval of the U.S. Congress, IDA resources cannot be replenished. Unfortunately, that approval did not come out of the post-election Congressional session. If replenishment is not forthcoming, IDA will exhaust its commitment authority in March, and it will have no resources with which to meet the rising 203 requirements of the low-income countries it serves. Speedy action by the new Congress is therefore essential. TABLE 33.—Non-oil developing countries: current-accountfinancing,1973-79 [In billions of U.S. dollars] 1973 Item Current-account deficit' 1974 36.9 11.5 1975 45.9 Less: Financing through transactions that do not affect net debt positions2 9.8 M3.2 Plus: Accumulation of reserve assets (decumulation-)... 9.3 1.2 -2.0 24.9 32.2 Equals: Net external borrowing4 11.0 3 n.7 1976 1977 1978 1979 35.8 52.9 14.4 16.2 19.4 11.9 18.2 11.0 33.5 26.1 37.8 44.5 32.9 28.6 12.1 12.7 Long-term from official sources, net 6 5.5 3 9.6 11.4 10.2 12.4 13.3 15.9 Other long-term borrowing from nonresidents, net 6.6 10.2 14.7 17.6 15.8 25.1 23.4 From financial institutions6 4.0 8.6 9.2 10.9 15.6 19.3 17.3 Other.net 6 2.6 1.6 5.5 67 .2 5.8 6.1 i'>4 1.6 5.1 -1.6 2.4 6.5 -2.8 4.3 3.9 -2.5 J 1.1 -2.4 .2 5.0 Use of reserve-related credit facilities, net 7 .. Other short-term borrowing, net Residual errors and omissions8 -1.7 1 Net 2 Net 3 total of balances on goods, services, and private transfers (with sign reversed). unrequited transfers, net direct investment, SDR allocations, gold monetization, and valuation adjustments. Excludes the effect of a revision of the terms of the disposition of economic assistance loans made by the United States to India and repayable in rupees, and of rupees already acquired by the U.S. Government in repayment of such loans. The revision has the effect of increasing government transfers by about $2 billion, with an offset in net official loans. •Includes any net use of nonreserve claims on nonresidents, errors and omissions in reported balance of payments statements for individual countries, and minor deficiencies in coverage. 6 Public and publicly guaranteed borrowing only. 6 Principally bond issues (public and publicly guaranteed borrowing only) and supplier credits, net of acquisitions of long-term assets. Comprises use of Fund credit and short-term borrowing by monetary authorities from other monetary authorities. 8 Errors and omissions in reported balance of payments statements for individual countries, plus minor omissions in coverage. 9 Less than $50 million. Source: International Monetary Fund. A different set of concerns arises for other developing countries such as the exporters of manufactured goods whose long-term deficit financing has come to a large extent from the private capital markets. For them it is obviously critical, first, whether the slowdown in longterm bank lending since 1978 is a "pause" that will shortly be reversed or a more permanent development; and, second, whether official resources—on which the poorer countries often have first claim—will be adequate to fill any remaining gap. Private Financing It is probable that the slowing of long-term bank lending to developing countries reflects both a greater unwillingness on the part of the banks to lend and an increased reluctance on the part of some developing countries to borrow. The relative importance of these two factors is hard to establish. There is considerable evidence that a number of developing countries have deferred borrowing. Whether they have done so because of high interest rates or, perhaps more critically, because they are unwilling to accept higher spreads over the London interbank rate (LIBOR) is unclear. Higher spreads raise 204 the cost of the loans, and they may also be interpreted in the financial markets as evidence that the borrowers are less creditworthy than countries borrowing at lower spreads. There are also clear indications of reluctance on the part of the banks to continue to increase their exposure in developing countries, either because of portfolio management considerations or because of pressures from bank examiners to limit and diversify risks. Numerous factors affect the willingness of banks to extend loans to particular countries. Chief among these are the external debt which a country has already incurred and judgments by potential lenders about the risk that a country may become unable to service its debt. The problem of country risk arises most acutely if borrowing is perceived to lead to debt-service payments which can be managed only by still larger borrowing in the future. Several implications flow from this perspective. First, the willingness of banks to continue lending depends importantly on their perception of the longer-run economic prospects of the borrowing country. A country that borrows to finance consumption—including the consumption of petroleum—is a riskier proposition than one borrowing to finance productive investment. The investment generates a return that can, in turn, be used to service the debt. Second, while the additional loan needs of many borrowers stem from the need to pay for an increased oil bill, the ability to obtain financing depends partly on how well the borrower is deemed to be adjusting its economy to the reality of higher oil prices. To some extent, the greater the signs of progress toward reducing oil imports or expanding exports to pay for them, the easier it is to finance the remaining deficit. Third, banks* concerns about debt rescheduling may be an important influence on the pattern of lending, but the direction of influence is ambiguous. If countries which were unable to service all of their external debts were to reschedule their official debts while continuing to meet payments to private lenders, the banks would have little incentive to assess borrowers' long-term prospects, or to lend in ways that foster appropriate adjustment by borrowers. Instead, banks have a clear incentive for caution when they are required to participate in rescheduling and to bear some reasonable portion of the burden. Banks are then more careful about making loans to countries where the longer-term prospects are uncertain. For this reason, the United States and other official creditors have insisted on requiring countries experiencing debt crises to seek relief from private as well as official creditors in order to assure a comparable sharing of burdens among all categories of creditors. When rescheduling is unat- 205 tractive to banks, however, a somewhat contradictory possibility arises: banks can defer rescheduling by continuing to lend. Delay may enable both borrower and lender to ride out a troubled period, but it can also exacerbate the troubles to be faced later on. Of course, banks' willingness to postpone rescheduling in this manner is limited by the increased risks involved. Furthermore, bank examination procedures—particularly in the United States and increasingly in other countries as well—are designed to signal the emergence of excessive exposure to risk. Fourth, the future scope for bank lending will depend strongly on the continued expansion of world trade and the ability of developing countries to participate fully in that expansion. If export opportunities are blocked, then even borrowing for productive investment may not be sustainable because such investment may not yield, either directly or indirectly, enough foreign exchange to service the debt. Conversely, with ample trade opportunities, developing countries can earn the foreign exchange that enables them not only to service existing debt but also to demonstrate their continuing dependability as borrowers. This interaction provides one of the major avenues for developing countries to accelerate adjustment without sacrificing longer-run growth prospects. Although it is possible to set forth in general terms the considerations that will determine the extent of private bank lending to the developing countries, it is impossible to predict with any precision or confidence the extent to which the recent pause in long-term lending will be reversed. On balance, the likelihood of somewhat reduced growth in private lending is high enough to place great importance upon the role of official agencies like the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank. Official Financing Over the past year, the ability of the IMF and the World Bank to take the lead in promoting financing and adjustment patterns that are appropriate in current economic circumstances has been strengthened. The resources available to these institutions have been increased, and their operating procedures have been modified. The role of the IMF has been substantially enhanced. A 50-percent increase in quotas, negotiated in 1978, went into effect on January 1 of this year. It will raise substantially the liquid resources available to the Fund over the coming years. Beyond this, the IMF is exploring the possibility of further increasing its resources by borrowing—first from member countries, particularly OPEC countries with large surpluses, but, if appropriate, from private sources as well. While such borrowing could not, and should not, supplant quotas as the primary source of Fund liquidity, it could play an important supporting role. 206 At the same time, access to the IMF by countries facing actual or incipient balance of payments difficulties has also been substantially increased. The quota increase itself has this effect, and it has been complemented by adaptations in the structure of Fund lending programs. The adaptations effectively increase the cumulative amounts that countries can borrow in relation to their quotas and lengthen the adjustment period for IMF supported programs. Finally, increased emphasis is being placed on structural considerations in the formulation of IMF stabilization and adjustment programs. World Bank resources have also increased, albeit without full U.S. participation. In the last days of its 1980 session, Congress did appropriate $328 million toward the Bank's 1977 Selective Capital Increase. But the Congress has yet to approve the U.S. share of the 1980 General Capital Increase. This increase went into effect in October 1980 with the formal agreement of 75 percent of the Bank's voting power. The World Bank, too, has modified its programs in the past year. While continuing to expand its traditional project and sector lending, the Bank has begun to develop a new type of lending program aimed specifically at structural adjustment. This lending is intended to complement the shorter-term borrowing that countries engage in for balance of payments reasons with long-term funding to restructure economies in ways that will strengthen their underlying external positions. Furthermore, ways are actively being sought—perhaps through a new energy affiliate of the Bank—to increase sharply the resources available for energy exploration and development in developing countries. Over time, the resulting increase in domestic energy availability will tend to ease the financial burden of developing countries by lowering their oil imports. Increased world supplies and more suppliers may also make future energy price shocks less likely. The extent to which the official institutions will be able to meet the future financing needs of the non-oil developing countries will depend in part upon the size of the gap which must be filled after private financing and bilateral assistance—particularly OPEC assistance for oil-deficit countries—has been accounted for. The size of this gap is very difficult to predict. But the recent expansion in the resources of the official institutions and their demonstrated capacity to adapt to changing needs suggest that they are capable of dealing with a very wide range of possible problems. CHALLENGES TO INTERNATIONAL TRADE RELATIONS The progressive dismantling of trade restrictions during the postWorld War II period and the resulting rapid growth of world trade 207 were of central importance to the worldwide rise in prosperity during the 1950s and 1960s. But the open trading system has come under increasing pressure in the 1970s. Economic growth has slowed, unemployment rates have risen, and the balance of payments positions of oil-importing countries have deteriorated. As a result, protectionist sentiments have strengthened, and the promotion of exports has become a more explicit aim in many countries. Furthermore, mounting structural difficulties in a number of key sectors have encouraged the view that cartelization or market-sharing agreements among countries can ease the burdens of adjustment. As a consequence, the climate for trade has become more clouded despite the ratification in 1979 of the agreements reached in the Multilateral Trade Negotiations. These agreements strengthen the international trading system by limiting the use of trade-restrictive practices and improving the mechanisms for the settlement of disputes and thus represent an important step forward. They are unlikely to prevent an intensification of trade frictions, however, if the underlying commitment of governments to open trade is eroded. An important but perhaps inevitable cause of the emergence of a more difficult environment for trade is the decline in the relative dominance of the United States in the world economy. In the early post-World War II period the United States was in a strong position to promote a more liberal trading order without much regard to strict reciprocity. Because imports constituted only a small share of the U.S. market, the growth in imports that freer trade entailed was not viewed as disruptive. At the same time, the demand for U.S. exports was strong because foreign production capacities had been damaged by the war and because American goods embodied technologies not available elsewhere. Thus, open trade was not perceived as a threat to the overall U.S. trade position. For other countries, on the other hand, the promise of increased access to the vast U.S. market made the opening of their own borders to imports seem a favorable exchange. While the conditions that made it so easy to support no longer prevail, open trade nevertheless confers substantial benefits on the world economy. Preservation of an open trading system must therefore become a truly multilateral effort and the shared responsibility of the major trading nations. It is probable that few governments today can effectively resist taking actions to redress what are viewed domestically as the unfair trade practices of others. All countries must therefore practice self-restraint, not only in the traditional sense of minimizing protectionist measures against imports, but also in avoiding measures that artificially promote exports at the expense of other countries. It must be recognized that the only real alternative 208 to closer cooperation is to risk a cycle of trade retaliation that would leave all countries substantially worse off. Three specific challenges to open trade are taken up in the following pages: the heightened pressures to use trade barriers to save domestic jobs, the increased use of direct and indirect subsidies to promote exports, and the emerging reliance on market-sharing arrangements to ease adjustment. PROTECTION AND EMPLOYMENT The pressure to protect domestic sectors from import competition is, to a large degree, a pressure to preserve jobs. Imports are seen as substituting foreign for domestic employment and income abroad for income at home. This pressure increases when economic growth slows and unemployment levels rise, since alternative employment possibilities are reduced. Job losses of course occur continually within an economy as some sectors contract. But meanwhile new jobs are being created in expanding sectors. International trade is but one of the pressures behind such shifts. Indeed; the evidence suggests quite strongly that, at least in the United States, changes in consumer demands and differential productivity gains from capital investment and technological change have been far more important than increased imports in accounting for relative employment declines in lagging sectors. But regardless of the source from which the pressures for adjustment come, intersectoral shifts in employment cannot be achieved without transition costs. The skills no longer needed in declining sectors may not match the skills required in growing sectors. The regional distribution of employment opportunities may shift, but workers may not be in a position to move. And, even if workers who lose jobs find new ones, their wages and job satisfaction may be lower if specialized skills acquired over many years are made obsolete. The more rapid the pace of adjustment, furthermore, the greater these transition costs will be, since less of the adjustment can then be accomplished through natural employee attrition and ongoing demographic shifts. Because of transition costs, governments are often tempted to intervene in an attempt to slow the pace of adjustment. Such policies can perhaps be justified when the pressure for rapid adjustment is very strong or when it is thought that the pressure will subsequently be reversed. The risk is, however, that government efforts to ease adjustment may have the effect of deferring or preventing it. Experience suggests that this has often been the case. Such outcomes are costly. Although transition costs are avoided for a time, productivity is impaired, inefficiency is increased, inflationary pres- 209 sures are strengthened, and in the longer term employment too may suffer. In seeking a balance between justified intervention to reduce transition costs and undue protection of uneconomic sectors, careful assessment of the broad range of costs and benefits is needed. This is particularly the case with regard to the use of trade-restrictive policies, for three reasons. First, pressure to restrict imports can easily arise even when imports are not themselves the major threat to existing jobs because the tools are more readily at hand to restrict imports than to deal with other adjustment problems. In the United States the President has considerable discretionary power to impose trade restrictions— subject, however, to prior findings of injury by the International Trade Commission. In other countries too, import restriction is generally easier to implement than adjustment policies requiring government budget resources. Second, there is mounting evidence that trade protection is a very expensive way to preserve jobs. In case after case that has been examined, the cost to consumers per job saved—that is, the extra costs faced by consumers in the form of higher prices when imports are restricted—has turned out to be at least several times higher than an average worker's income. Although these consumer costs are large in the aggregate, in no one instance do they seem large on a per capita basis. As a consequence they are not highly visible and therefore easy to overlook. Finally, trade restriction, like other forms of domestic protection but more clearly so, impairs employment prospects over the longer run. Jobs saved in the protected sectors are saved in part at the expense of jobs elsewhere in the domestic economy. Higher prices for protected goods reduce consumers' ability to purchase other goods, and thereby limit employment growth. If imports are restrained, export opportunities and employment in the export sector are also reduced—directly if foreign countries retaliate, and indirectly even if they do not, because the exchange rate tends to appreciate to restore balance between exports and imports over the longer term. Moreover, trade restrictions increase prices directly and further exacerbate inflation by limiting productivity growth. As a result, the ability of governments to pursue expansive policies to support employment is further reduced. Thus the jobs saved by trade restrictions are likely to be matched by job losses elsewhere. As is so often the case, however, the jobs saved are immediate, specific, and highly visible; the jobs lost are in the future, diffused throughout the economy, and almost invisible. 210 While all countries, in attempting to balance long-term gains against short-term pressures, may find the need for trade-restrictive actions compelling from time to time, the risks are that such policies will be resorted to excessively. These risks become considerably larger to the extent that other countries aggressively use subsidies to promote exports. The following section takes up this issue. EXPORT SUBSIDIES Countries subsidize exports directly or indirectly for a variety of reasons. Faster export growth is seen as a way of overcoming the balance of payments deficits that higher oil bills have caused for many countries. Subsidies may form part of an industrial strategy to promote the growth of key sectors and to exploit economies of scale when they dictate a global marketing approach. Subsidies may also be a counterpart to other policies, for instance, policies to limit excess capacity and job losses in declining sectors by selling abroad. Subsidies to exports can also arise indirectly—for instance, from domestic policies that keep the price of energy, and hence the cost of production in energy-intensive sectors, artificially low. Or they can arise when investment incentives to particular regions or industries reduce the cost of capital to firms that produce certain goods. The Subsidies Code that was negotiated in the Multilateral Trade Negotiations places certain restrictions on the use of subsidies and permits the adoption of countervailing duties in cases where subsidies can be shown to cause injury to trading partners. However, given the various and often complex forms that subsidies can take, and the fact that subsidies of exports may often arise as by-products of policies directed at domestic goals, the Code by itself is unlikely fully to resolve the problems that subsidies sometimes create. Selfrestraint among countries in the use of subsidies is therefore necessary. Two considerations are of critical importance in this regard. First, subsidies often end up losing their effectiveness in promoting exports. Initially, profits and employment in a subsidized activity will increase and a competitive advantage will emerge. Gradually, however, the extra profits that are created by the subsidy may be diluted by higher wages for the workers in that activity, or—if the activity is a large user of scarce resources—in higher prices for those resources. A familiar example is the bidding up of the price of farm land suitable for a particular crop when the price of that crop is supported by the government at higher levels. The bidding up of costs of production in this way ultimately tends to eliminate the competitive advantage that the subsidy provides, thus increasing pressures for yet further subsidization to restore the advantage and making removal of the subsidy increasingly difficult. 211 Second, the pressure for countries to match the subsidies provided by other countries means that the opportunity to increase market shares through subsidies is far less than it appears to each country in isolation. This consideration is particularly important in the area of export-credit subsidization, which has increased sharply in recent years. Most of the major industrial countries have official exportcredit agencies that provide medium and long-term financing at fixed rates of interest for "big ticket" exports, such as power plants, aircraft, and manufacturing plants. These interest rates have not risen in step with rises in market rates, thus greatly increasing the subsidy element of such trade financing. Yet, because export agencies in all countries are under pressure to match or perhaps improve on the terms provided by others so as to help secure the sale for a domestic producer, the likely result is a costly standoff, with global overcapacity in subsidized sectors persisting. The heads of state of the major countries made a specific commitment at the Venice Summit in June of last year to bring export-credit rates more closely into line with market rates. Efforts to renegotiate an export-credit agreement based on this commitment failed, but negotiations may resume this year. In some countries—particularly some members of the European Community—it may not be clearly perceived how wasteful and counterproductive export-credit subsidies are. MARKET SHARING Antitrust laws in the United States prohibit firms from attempting to divide up markets by allocating market shares, formally or informally. The anticompetitive and price-raising consequences of such arrangements are well known. On an international level, however, there are increasing temptations for governments themselves to develop or to bless such market-sharing arrangements for sectors facing structural difficulties. The Multi-fiber Agreement, which sets a framework within which individual countries have negotiated a complex system of quotas on textile and apparel imports, is an example. Relatively longstanding agreements exist with respect to shipbuilding. The issue of automobile imports, so important in the United States, has also been of great interest and concern internationally—and indeed informal or formal industry agreements between European and Japanese auto producers are widespread. The temptation to "organize** world markets when adjustment pressures arise is understandable. If a number of countries need to adjust, the pressures to assure that each country bears its fair share of the adjustment burden are powerful. Negotiated arrangements may appear both more effective and less confrontational than the use of formal grievance procedures under the General Agreement on Trade and Tariffs (GATT). As short-term responses to serious 212 threats of disruption, market-sharing arrangements may indeed be preferred if the alternative is a resort to predatory behavior. There are serious risks, however, in following this course. First, the substitution of informal, ad hoc agreements for the more formal mechanisms of the GATT reduces the transparency of the trading system. The "rules of the game" become more complex and less visible to public scrutiny, and procedures for redress become uncertain. Second, such agreements may perpetuate themselves. In seeking to assure that adjustment is fairly distributed, they may in fact delay the needed adjustments and perpetuate the excess capacities that gave rise to the problem in the first place. Finally, such arrangements, by requiring balance among countries in the degree of adjustment, almost always guarantee that it is not the least efficient capacity which is eliminated. NEEDED RESPONSES Pressures on all countries to use trade policies to promote shorterterm gains for particular sectors, to ease the process of adjustment, or to protect jobs in sensitive areas will almost certainly remain acute. It is also quite certain that in some cases such pressures will not be resisted. Indeed a simon-pure attitude is unwarranted on the part of any country, and unrealistic when other countries also yield to such pressures. From a broader perspective, however, it is highly important to keep restrictive trade policies within circumscribed limits. First, the achievement of both higher exports and lower imports is not feasible—strictly so for the world as a whole, and to a very large extent for individual countries. The only effective choice is one between slow trade growth or more rapid trade growth, and the historical record makes clear that the latter is to be preferred. Second, it is imperative to aim for consistency in the formulation of policy. The overriding need in all countries is to reduce the current inflation, and also to reduce the inflation-proneness of economies that have become more inflexible and less competitive. Trade policies that aim for short-term protection intensify inflation directly by reducing competitive pressures, and they increase economic rigidities by sheltering excessive wages, profits, and other incomes in particular sectors from the discipline of the market. Better integration of trade policy into overall economic policy formulation is needed in all countries to provide a clearer perspective on its real costs and benefits. 213 Appendix A REPORT TO THE PRESIDENT ON THE ACTIVITIES OF THE COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS DURING 1980 215 LETTER OF TRANSMITTAL COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS, Washington, D.C, December 31, 1980. MR. PRESIDENT: The Council of Economic Advisers submits this report on its activities during the calendar year 1980 in accordance with the requirements of the Congress, as set forth in section 10(d) of the Employment Act of 1946 as amended by the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978. Cordially, CHARLES L. SCHULTZE, Chairman GEORGE C. EADS STEPHEN M. GOLDFELD 217 Report to the President on the Activities of the Council of Economic Advisers during 1980 The Council of Economic Advisers was established by the Employment Act of 1946 to provide economic analysis and advice to the President and thus to assist in the development and implementation of national economic policies. The Council also advises the President with regard to decisions on other matters that affect the health and operations of the Nation's economy. The enactment of the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978—the Humphrey-Hawkins Act—substantially revised the chartering legislation of the Council of Economic Advisers for the first time since 1946. This revision left unchanged the basic mission of the Council of Economic Advisers but created a new framework for the government's pursuit of its economic policies. This act and its requirements were discussed in detail in the 1979 Economic Report. Charles L. Schultze, Chairman, and George C. Eads, Member, continued to serve in these positions throughout 1980. On May 27, 1980, Lyle E. Gramley resigned to become a Governor on the Board of the Federal Reserve System. On August 20, 1980, Stephen M. Goldfeld became a Member of the Council. Mr. Goldfeld was formerly Professor of Economics at Princeton University. RESPONSIBILITIES The responsibilities of the Council of Economic Advisers have grown steadily as new economic problems have placed new demands on the Council and its staff. Over the last decade especially, the growing recognition that many "noneconomic" decisions have major consequences for our economy has led to a broadening of the Council's activities. Today, the Council is responsible for advising the President not only on Federal fiscal policies but also on policies affecting specific sectors of the economy, on regulation and regulatory reform, on energy policies, and on international economic policies. 219 Past Council Members and their dates of service are listed below: Name Edwin G. Nourse Leon H. Keyserling John D. Clark Roy Blough. . .. Robert C. Turner Arthur F. Burns Neil H. Jacoby Walter W. Stewart Raymond J. Saulmer Joseph S. Davis Paul W. McCracken Karl Brandt Henry C. Walllch Walter W. Heller James Tobin Kermit Gordon Gardner Ackley John P. Lewts Otto Eckstein Arthur M. Okun James S. Duesenberry Merton J. Peck Warren L. Smith Paul W. McCracken Hendrik S. Houthakker Herbert Stein Ezra Solomon Marina v.N. Whitman Gary L. Seevers Wilfiam J. Fellner Alan Greenspan Paul W. MacAvoy Burton G. Malktel William D. Nordhaus Lyle £. Gramtey Oath of office date Position Chairman Vice Chairman Acting Chairman Chairman . Member Vice Chairman Member ... Member Chairman Member Member.. Member. Chairman Member Member.... Member Member Chairman Member Member Member Chairman Member Member Member Chairman Member Member Member Chairman Member Member Chairman Member Member Member Member Chairman Member . Member Member Member August 9,1946 August 9, 1946 November 2, 1949 May 10, 1950 August 9, 1946 May 10, 1950 June 29, 1950 September 8, 1952 . . March 19, 1953 September 15, 1953 December 2, 1953 April 4. 1955 December 3, 1956 May 2. 195$ December 3, 1956 November 1,1958. May 7, 1959 January 29, 1961 .. January 29, 1961 January 29. 1961 August 3. 1962 November 16, 1964 May 17, 1963 September 2, 1964 November 16, 1964 February 15. 1968 February 2, 1966 February 15, 1968 July 1. 1968 February 4, 1969 February 4, 1969 February 4, 1969 January 1, 1972 September 9, 1971 March 13, 1972 July 23, 1973 October 31, 1973 September 4, 1974 June 13, 1975... July 22, 1975 March 18, 1977 March 18, 1977 Separation date November 1, 1949. January 20, 1953. February 11, 1953. August 20, 1952. January 20, 1953. December 1, 1956. February 9, 1955. April 29, 1955. January 20, 1961. October 31, 1958. January 31, 1959. January 20, 1961. January 20, 1961. November 15, 1964. July 31, 1962. December 27, 1962. February 15, 1968. August 31, 1964. February 1, 1966. January 20, 1969. June 30, 1968. January 20, 1969. January 20, 1969. December 31, 1971. July 15.1971. August 31, 1974. March 26.1973. August 15, 1973. April 15, 1975. February 25, 1975. January 20, 1977. November 15, 1976. January 20. 1977. February 4, 1979. May 27, 1980. MACROECONOMIC POLICIES From the outset, the Council's fundamental role has been to advise the President on comprehensive economic policies designed to achieve the government's objectives for price stability, employment, and output. To fulfill this responsibility the Council develops economic forecasts several times each year with the assistance of an Interagency Forecasting Committee. The members of this Committee include, in addition to the Council, representatives from the Office of Management and Budget and the Departments of the Treasury, Commerce, and Labor. This group, which is chaired by a Member of the Council, meets to analyze the outlook for individual sectors of the economy and to develop detailed economic forecasts for the period immediately ahead. The Chairman of the Council presents these forecasts to the Economic Policy Group (EPG), which is made up of the President's principal economic advisers and meets each week to discuss and develop the Administration's proposals touching on economic policy. The Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers is a member of the EPG and of its steering group. 220 In the final months of each year, during the preparation of the President's annual budget, the Council works with other members of the EPG to develop and present to the President proposals for both the stance and the design of Federal fiscal policies during the coming fiscal year. The Council monitors the progress of the economy and offers advice on when changes in fiscal policies are in order. Advising the President on macroeconomic policy has remained one of the Council's major responsibilities. The Chairman of the Council took an active role in the March budget revisions, in the decision to invoke the Credit Control Act, and in the design of other steps taken at that time to halt inflationary expectations. In addition, the Council continued its involvement in the program of voluntary pay and price standards, including monitoring the progress of the second program year. On November 12 the Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers resumed the position of Chairman of the Council on Wage and Price Stability. During the late spring and summer, the Council actively participated in the development and presentation of the Administration's Economic Revitalization Program. The Chairman of the Council also chairs the Interagency Committee on Housing and Housing Finance. In 1980 the Council again coordinated special surveys of the conditions in housing markets. The Council co-chaired with the Office of Management and Budget a congressionally mandated study on the indexing of Federal programs. The Council chaired the subgroup on issues involved in the choice of an index. This report will be presented to the Congress at the beginning of 1981. MICROECONOMIC POLICIES The Council of Economic Advisers has become increasingly involved in the analysis of microeconomic issues—the economic developments and the policy actions that affect individual industries, markets, or sectors of the economy. In 1980 the Council took part in formulating and articulating the Administration's policies on agriculture, energy, hospital cost containment, industrial adjustment, regulation, regulatory reform, and international trade. Especially important in 1980 were the interagency studies of the automobile and steel industries. The Council took an active role in these studies and in the development of policy responses to problems in these two industries. In addition, the Council is a major participant in an ongoing study of the potential economic consequences of, and policy responses to, a major oil-supply disruption. In 1980 the Council continued to chair the Regulatory Analysis Review Group (RARG). This interagency group was created late in http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/ 333-5H0 0 - 81 - 15 : QL 3 Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 221 1977 to review selected analyses of the economic effects of major regulatory proposals. The President has ordered that each major regulatory proposal issued by a nonindependent regulatory agency must be accompanied by a regulatory analysis. The agency originating the proposal develops the analysis and makes it available in draft form for public comment before the final regulation is issued. During the period for public comment the Regulatory Analysis Review Group evaluates a select few of these regulatory analyses and files its appraisal in the agency's record of public comment. In 1980 eight regulations were reviewed by RARG: the Environmental Protection Agency's air carcinogen policy, its guidelines for water effluents in the leather tanning and finishing industry, its visibility regulations for Federal Class I areas, and its ambient air quality standards for carbon monoxide; the Department of Energy's building energy performance standards and its consumer appliance energy efficiency standards; the Department of Education's rules concerning the education of students not proficient in English, and the Department of Housing and Urban Development's revisions of its minimum property standards. At year's end the Environmental Protection Agency's premanufacture notification requirements for new chemical substances were being reviewed. Together with the staff of the Council on Wage and Price Stability, the Council's staff served as the analytic staff for the RARG. In addition, the Council and the staff continued their active involvement in proposed regulatory reform legislation and in the development of administrative means to lessen the burden of regulation. INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC POLICIES During 1980 the Council of Economic Advisers again took an active part in international economic affairs. The Chairman of the Council continued to serve as Chairman of the Economic Policy Committee of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). As such, he chaired two meetings of senior economic officials from OECD member governments to assess appropriate economic policies following the sharp rise in energy prices and to achieve improved policy coordination among countries. In consultation with senior officials from other countries, the Chairman also prepared a position paper on economic policy issues for the Venice Summit. The Council is active in the OECD Economic Policy Committee's working parties on short-term economic prospects, balance of payments adjustment, and macroeconomic structural and policy analysis. Council Members or staff economists represent the U.S. government at periodic meetings of these working parties during the year. 222 A Member of the Council represents the U.S. government at meetings of the OECD Special High-Level Group on Positive Adjustment Policies, and in 1980 made an extended presentation on U.S. structural policies to this group. He also chairs a task force of the Special Group that has been examining the alternatives used by governments to identify and evaluate subsidies. PUBLIC INFORMATION The annual Economic Report is the principal medium through which the Council informs the public of its work and its views. It is also an important vehicle for presenting and explaining the Administration's economic policies, both domestic and international. Distribution of the Report in recent years has averaged about 50,000 copies. The Council also assumes primary responsibility for the monthly Economic Indicators, a publication prepared by the Council's Statistical Office, under the supervision of Catherine H. Furlong. The Joint Economic Committee issues the Indicators, which has a distribution of approximately 10,000 copies. Information is also provided to members of the public through speeches and other public appearances by the Chairman, Members, and staff economists of the Council. Finally, in 1980 the Chairman and Members made 13 appearances before Committees of the Congress to testify on the Administration's economic policies. ORGANIZATION AND STAFF OF THE COUNCIL OFFICE OF THE CHAIRMAN The Chairman is responsible for communicating the results of the Council's work and for providing advice to the President. This duty is performed through discussions with the President and in written reports on economic developments. The Chairman also represents the Council at Cabinet meetings and at many other formal and informal meetings of government officials. He exercises ultimate responsibility for directing the work of the professional staff. On November 12, 1980, the Chairman replaced Alfred E. Kahn, who had resigned, as Chairman of the Council on Wage and Price Stability. COUNCIL MEMBERS The two Council Members directly supervise the work of the Council's professional staff and are responsible for all subject matter studied by the Council. They represent the Council at numerous meetings of public and private groups, and they assume major responsibility for the Council's involvement in the activities of the government that affect the economy. 223 The Chairman and the Council Members work together on most policy issues. Operationally, however, responsibility over major topics of concern is divided between the two Members. Mr. Eads has supervised microeconomic analysis, including analysis of policies related to such matters as energy, agriculture, social welfare, and international trade. Mr. Eads also oversees regulatory reform activities. Mr. Goldfeld has the primary responsibility for macroeconomic analysis, including international monetary developments and the preparation of economic forecasts, and for labor market policies. PROFESSIONAL STAFF At the end of 1980 the professional staff consisted of the Special Assistant to the Chairman, the Senior Statistician, 12 senior and staff economists, and 5 junior staff economists. The professional staff and their special fields at the end of the year were: Susan J. Irving Special Assistant to the Chairman Senior and Staff Economists William T. Boehm Stephen H. Brooks Geoffrey O. Carliner Jose A. Gomez-Ibanez Val L. Koromzay Robert A. Leone Michael J. McKee David C. Munro Susan C. Nelson Perry D. Quick Elinor Y. Sachse Andrew J. Strenio Agriculture and Food Policy Macroeconomic Analysis and Forecasting, and Fiscal Policy Labor Market Policies and Pension Issues Regulation, Natural Resources, and Transportation International Financial and Economic Developments Industrial Policy Issues and Energy Macroeconomic Analysis and Forecasting, Productivity, Prices, Anti-Inflation Policies, and Energy Macroeconomic Analysis and Forecasting Public Finance, Taxes, Social Security, Health and Welfare Finance, Money, Housing, and Economic Development International Financial Developments and Trade Regulation Statistician Catherine H. Furlong Senior Statistician Junior Economists Martin A. Asher Labor Market Policies 224 Elizabeth J. Jensen Stephen A. O'Connell Regulation International Economic Developments and Trade David H. Romer Macroeconomic Analysis and Forecasting Robert W. Turner Public Finance Catherine H. Furlong, Senior Statistician, continued to be in charge of the Council's Statistical Office. Mrs. Furlong has primary responsibility for managing the Council's statistical information system. She supervises the publication of Economic Indicators and the preparation of all statistical matter in the Economic Report. She also oversees the verification of statistics in memoranda, testimony, and speeches. Natalie V. Rentfro, Earnestine Reid, and Barbara L. Sibel assist Mrs. Furlong. In preparing the Economic Report the Council relied upon the editorial assistance of John Phillip Sawicki. Also called on for special assistance in connection with the Report was Dorothy Bagovich. SUPPORTING STAFF The Administrative Office of the Council of Economic Advisers provides general support for the Council's activities. Nancy F. Skidmore, Administrative Officer, prepares and analyzes the Council's budget and provides general administrative services. Elizabeth A. Kaminski, Staff Assistant to the Council, handles general personnel management, coordinates the schedule for the Economic Report, and provides general assistance to the Council and the Special Assistant in the management of the Council's activities. Members of the secretarial staff for the Chairman and Council Members during 1980 were Patricia A. Lee, Linda A. Reilly, Lisa A. Stockdale, and Alice H. Williams. Secretaries for the professional staff were Catherine Fibich, Bessie M. Lafakis, Joyce A. Pilkerton, Margaret L. Snyder, and Lillie M. Sturniolo. Elizabeth A. Cralle provided secretarial assistance during the summer months and during the preparation of the Report. Joseph Henley served as a clerk during the preparation of the Report. DEPARTURES The Council's professional staff members are in most cases on leave from universities, other government agencies, or research institutions. Their tenure with the Council is usually limited to 1 or 2 years. Senior staff economists who resigned during the year were Paul N. Courant (University of Michigan), K. Burke Dillon (International Monetary Fund), David Harrison, Jr. (Harvard University), David S. McClain (Boston University), V. Vance Roley (Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City), Daniel H. Saks (National Commission for Employment Policy), and Charles L. Trozzo (George Washington 225 University). Kate Stith Pressman, staff economist, resigned to accept a position with the Department of Justice. Junior economists who resigned in 1980 were David W. Berson (University of Michigan), Lisa L. Blum (Department of Commerce), Stephen G. Cecchetti (University of California, Berkeley), Judith R, Gelman (Federal Trade Commission), and Matthew D. Shapiro (Massachusetts Institute of Technology). 226 Appendix B STATISTICAL TABLES RELATING TO INCOME, EMPLOYMENT, AND PRODUCTION 227 CONTENTS NATIONAL INCOME OR EXPENDITURE: Page B-l. B-2. B-3. B-4. B-5. B-6. B-7. B-8. B-9. B-10. B-ll. B-12. B-13. B-14. B-15. B-16. B-17. B-18. B-19. B-20. B-21. B-22. B-23. B-24. B-25. Gross national product, 1929-80 Gross national product in 1972 dollars, 1929-80 Implicit price deflators for gross national product, 1929-80 Fixed-weighted price indexes for gross national product 1972 weights, 1959-80 Implicit price deflators and alternative price measures for gross national product and gross domestic product, 1929-80 Gross national product by major type of product, 1929-80 Gross national product by major type of product in 1972 dollars, 1929-80 : Gross national product: Receipts and expenditures by major economic groups, 1929-80 Gross national product by sector, 1929-80 Gross national product by sector in 1972 dollars, 1929-80 Gross domestic product of nonfinancial corporate business, 192980 ; Output, costs, and profits of nonfinancial corporate business, 1948-80 Personal consumption expenditures, 1929-80 Gross private domestic investment, 1929-80 Inventories and final sales of business, 1946-80 Inventories and final sales of business in 1972 dollars, 1947-80 Relation of gross national product and national income, 1929-80 ... Relation of national income and personal income, 1929-80 National income by type of income, 1929-80 Sources of personal income, 1929-80 Disposition of personal income, 1929-80 Total and per capital disposable personal income and personal consumption expenditures in current and 1972 dollars, 1929-80. Gross saving and investment, 1929-80 Saving by individuals, 1946-80 Money income (in 1979 dollars) and poverty status of families and unrelated individuals by race of householder, 1952-79 233 234 236 238 239 240 241 242 244 245 246 247 248 249 250 251 252 253 254 256 258 259 260 261 262 POPULATION, EMPLOYMENT, WAGES, AND PRODUCTIVITY: B-26. B-27. B-28. B-29. B-30. B-31, B-32. B-33. Population by age groups, 1929-80 Noninstitutional population and the labor force, 1929-80 Civilian employment and unemployment by sex and age, 1947-80.. Selected employment and unemployment data, 1948-80 Civilian labor force participation rate by demographic characteristic, 1954-80 , Unemployment rate by demographic characteristic, 1948-80 Unemployment by duration, 1947-80.. Unemployment by reason, 1967-80 229 263 264 266 267 268 269 270 271 POPULATION, EMPLOYMENT, WAGES, AND PRODUCTIVITY—Confd Page B-34. B-35. B-36. B-37. B-38. B-39. Unemployment insurance programs, selected data, 1946-80 Wage and salary workers in nonagricultural establishments, 192980 Average weekly hours and hourly earnings in selected private nonagricultural industries, 1947-80 Average weekly earnings in selected private nonagricultural industries, 1947-80 Productivity and related data, private business sector, 1947-80 Changes in productivity and related data, private business sector, 1948-80 272 273 274 275 276 277 PRODUCTION AND BUSINESS ACTIVITY: B-40. B-41. B-42. B-43. B-44. B-45. B-46. B-47. B-48. B-49. Industrial production indexes, major industry divisions, 1929-80.... Industrial production indexes, market groupings, 1947-80 Industrial production indexes, selected manufactures, 1947-80 Capacity utilization rate in manufacturing, 1948-80 New construction activity, 1929-80 New housing units started and authorized, 1959-80 Nonfarm business expenditures for new plant and equipment, 1947-81 Sales and inventories in manufacturing and trade, 1947-80 Manufacturers' shipments and inventories, 1947-80 Manufacturers' new and unfilled orders, 1947-80 278 279 280 281 282 284 Consumer price indexes, major expenditure classes, 1929-80 Consumer price indexes, selected expenditure classes, 1939-80 Consumer price indexes by commodity and service groups, 193980 \ Changes in consumer price indexes, major groups, 1948-80 Changes in special consumer price indexes, 1958-80 Producer price indexes by stage of processing, 1947-80 Producer price indexes by stage of processing, special groups, 1974-80 Producer price indexes by major commodity groups, 1940-80 .'.. Changes in producer price indexes for finished goods, 1948-80 289 290 285 286 287 288 PRICES: B-50. B-51. B-52. B-53. B-54. B-55. B-56. B-57. B-58. 292 293 294 295 297 298 300 MONEY STOCK, CREDIT, AND FINANCE: B-59. B-60. B-61. B-62. Money stock measures and liquid assets, 1959-80. Components of money stock measures and liquid assets, 1959-80... Commercial bank loans and investments, 1939-80 Total funds raised in credit markets by nonfinancial sectors, 197280 304 B-63. B-64. B-65. B-66. B-67. B-68. Federal Reserve Bank credit and member bank reserves, 1929-80... Aggregate reserves and member bank deposits, 1959-80 Bond yields and interest rates, 1929-80 Consumer credit outstanding and net change, 1950-80 Consumer installment credit extended and liquidated, 1950-80 Mortgage debt outstanding by type of property and of financing, 1939-80 B-69. Mortgage debt outstanding by holder, 1939-80 GOVERNMENT FINANCE: B-70. Federal budget receipts, outlays, and debt, fiscal years 1971-82 B-71. Federal budget receipts and outlays, fiscal years 1929-82 301 302 303 230 306 307 308 310 3U 312 313 314 316 GOVERNMENT FINANCE'—Continued B-72. B-73. B-74. B-75. B-76. B-77. B-78. B-79. Relation of Federal Government receipts and expenditures in the national income and product accounts to the unified budget, Page 1980-82 317 Government receipts and expenditures, national income and product accounts, 1929-80 318 Federal Government receipts and expenditures, national income and product accounts, 1958-82 319 State and local government receipts and expenditures, national income and product accounts, 1946-80 320 State and local government revenues and expenditures, selected fiscal years, 1927-79 , 321 Interest-bearing public debt securities by kind of obligation, 196780 322 Estimated ownership of public debt securities, 1967-80 323 Average length and maturity distribution of marketable interestbearing public debt securities held by private investors, 1967-80. 324 CORPORATE PROFITS AND FINANCE: B-80. B-81. B-82. B-83. B-84, B-85. B-86. B-87. B-88. B-89. B-90. B-91. Corporate profits with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments, 1946-80 Corporate profits by industry, 1929-80 Corporate profits of manufacturing industries, 1929-80 Sales, profits, and stockholders' equity, all manufacturing corporations, 1950-80 Relation of profits after taxes to stockholders' equity and to sales, all manufacturing corporations, 1947-80 Relation of profits after taxes to stockholders' equity and to sales, all manufacturing corporations, by industry group, 1979-80 Determinants of business fixed investment, 1955-80 Sources and uses of funds, nonfarm nonfinancial corporate business, 1946-80 ; Current assets and liabilities of U.S. corporations, 1939-80 State and municipal and corporate securities offered, 1934-80 Common stock prices and yields, 1949-80 Business formation and business failures, 1929-80 325 326 327 328 329 330 331 332 333 334 335 336 AGRICULTURE: B-92. B-93. B-94. B-95. B-96. B-97. Farm income, 1929-80 Farm output and productivity indexes, 1929-80 Farm input use, selected inputs, 1929-80 Indexes of prices received and prices paid by farmers, 1940-80 U.S. exports and imports of agricultural commodities, 1940-80 Balance sheet of the farming sector, 1929-81 337 338 339 340 341 342 INTERNATIONAL STATISTICS: B-98. Exchange rates, 1973-80 B-99. U.S. international transactions, 1946-80 B-100. U.S. merchandise exports and imports by principal end-use category, 1965-80 B-101. U.S. merchandise exports and imports by area, 1973-80 B-102. U.S. merchandise exports and imports by commodity groups, 1958-80 B-103. International investment position of the United States at year-end, selected years, 1970-79 B-104. World trade: Exports and imports, 1965, 1970, 1975, and 1977-80 231 343 344 346 347 348 349 350 INTERNATIONAL STATISTICS—Continued B-105. World trade balance and current account balances, 1965, 1970, Page 1975, and 1977-80 351 B-106. International reserves, selected years, 1952-80 352 B-107. Growth rates in real gross national product, 1960-80 353 B-108. Industrial production and unemployment rate, major industrial countries, 1960-80 354 B-I09. Consumer prices and hourly compensation, major industrial countries, 1960-80 355 B-110. Summary of major U.S. Government net foreign assistance, July 1, 1945 to December 31, 1979 356 General Notes Detail in these tables may not add to totals because of rounding. Unless otherwise noted, all dollar figures are in current dollars. Symbols used: p Preliminary. --Not available (also, not applicable). Note.—Data for the national income and product accounts series appearing in this appendix reflect benchmark revisions by the Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. See Survey of Current Business for details. 232 NATIONAL INCOME OR EXPENDITURE TABLE B-l.—Gross national product, 1929-80 [Billions of dollars, except as noted; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Net exports of goods and services Gross national product Year or quarter Net exports 16.2 1.1 7.0 5.9 8.8 1.4 7.4 2.4 2.0 8.2 2.1 6.1 103,4 1929 Government purchases of goods and services Gross Personal private con: sumption domestic investexpendiment tures • 77.3 Federal Exports Imports Total Total NonNational defense defense State and local Percent change from preceding period, gross national product1 1933 55,8 45.8 1.4 A 1939 90.9 67.0 9.3 1.2 4.6 3.4 13.5 5.2 1.2 3.9 8.3 7.0 1940 . . . 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945. . . 1946 1947 1948 1949 . . 100.0 125.0 158.5 192.1 210.6 212.4 209.8 233.1 259.5 258.3 71.0 80.8 88.6 99.4 108.2 119.5 143.8 161.7 174.7 178.1 13.1 17.9 9.9 5.8 7.2 10.6 30.7 34.0 45.9 35.3 1.8 1.5 .2 -1.9 -1.7 -.5 7.8 11.9 6.9 6.5 5.4 6.1 5.0 4.6 5.5 7.4 15.1 20.2 17.5 16.3 3.6 4.7 4.8 6.5 7.2 7.9 7.3 8.3 10.5 9.8 14.2 24.9 59.8 88.9 97.0 82.8 27.5 25.5 32.0 38.4 6.1 16.9 52.0 81.3 89.4 74.6 17.6 12.7 16.7 20.4 2.2 13.7 49.4 79.7 87.4 73.5 14.8 9.0 10.7 13.2 3.9 3.2 2.6 1.6 2.0 1.1 2.8 3.7 6.0 7.2 8.1 8.0 7.8 7.5 7.6 8.2 9.9 12.8 15.3 18.0 10.0 25.0 26.7 21.3 9.6 .9 -1.2 11.1 11.3 -.5 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 286.5 330.8 348.0 366.8 366.8 400.0 421.7 444.0 449.7 487.9 192.0 207.1 217.1 229.7 235.8 253.7 266.0 280.4 289.5 310.8 53.8 59.2 52.1 53.3 52.7 68.4 71.0 69.2 61.9 78.1 2.2 4.4 3.2 1.3 2.5 3.0 5.3 7.3 3.3 1.4 14.4 19.7 19.1 18.0 18.7 21.0 25.0 28.1 24.2 24.8 12.2 15.3 15.9 16.7 16.2 18.0 19.8 20.8 21.0 23.4 38.5 60.1 75.6 82.5 75.8 75.0 79.4 87.1 95.0 97.6 18.7 38.3 52.4 57.5 47.9 44.5 45.9 50.0 53.9 53.9 14.0 33.5 45.8 48.6 41.1 38.4 40.2 44.0 45.6 45.6 4.7 4.8 6.5 8.9 6.8 6.0 5.7 5.9 8.3 8.3 19.8 21.8 23.2 25.0 27.8 30.6 33.5 37.1 41.1 43.7 10.9 15.5 5.2 5.4 .0 9.0 5.4 5.3 1.3 8.5 506.5 524.6 565.0 596.7 637.7 691.1 756.0 799.6 873.4 944.0 324.9 335.0 355.2 374.6 400.5 430.4 465.1 490.3 536.9 581.8 75.9 74.8 85.4 90.9 97.4 113.5 125.7 122.8 133.3 149.3 5.5 6.6 6.4 7.6 10.1 8.8 6.5 6.3 4.3 4.2 28.9 29.9 31.8 34.2 38.8 41.1 44.6 47.3 52.4 57.5 23.4 23.3 25.4 26.6 28.8 32.3 38.1 41.0 48.1 53.3 100.3 108.2 118.0 123.7 129.8 138.4 158.7 180.2 199.0 208.8 53.7 57.4 63.7 64.6 65.2 67.3 78.8 90.9 98.0 97.6 44.5 47.0 51.1 50.3 49.0 49.4 60.3 71.5 76.9 76.3 9.3 10.4 12.7 14.3 16.2 17.8 18.5 19.5 21.2 21.2 46.5 50.8 54.3 59.0 64.6 71.1 79.8 89.3 101.0 111.2 3.8 3.6 7.7 5.6 6.9 8.4 9.4 5.8 9.2 8.1 992.7 1,077.6 1,185.9 1,326.4 1,434.2 1,549.2 1,718.0 1,918.0 2,156.1 2,4119 621.7 672.2 737.1 812.0 888.1 976.4 1,084.3 1,205.5 1,348.7 1,510.9 144.2 166.4 195.0 229.8 228.7 206.1 257.9 322.3 375.3 415.8 6.7 4.1 .7 14.2 13.4 26.8 13.8 -4.2 -.6 13.4 65.7 68.8 77.5 109.6 146.2 154.9 170.9 183.3 219.8 281.3 59.0 64.7 76.7 95.4 132.8 128.1 157.1 187.5 220.4 267.9 220.1 234.9 253.1 270.4 304.1 339.9 362.1 394.5 432.6 473.8 95.7 96.2 101.7 102.0 111.0 122.7 129.2 143.9 153.4 167.9 73.6 70.2 73.1 72.8 77.0 83.0 86.0 93.3 100.0 111.2 22.2 26.0 28.5 29.1 33.9 39.7 43.2 50.6 53.4 56.7 124.4 138.7 151.4 168.5 193.1 217.2 232.9 250.6 279.2 305.9 5.2 8.6 10.1 11.8 8.1 8.0 10.9 11.6 12.4 12.0 1980 p 2,627.4 1,670.1 395.1 27.5 341.2 313.6 534.8 198.9 132.0 66.9 335.9 8.8 1978: I II III.... IV 2,032.4 2,129.6 2,190.5 2,271.9 1,278.3 1,330.1 1,369.9 1,416.6 350 7 377.7 380 4 392.6 -12.3 -3.3 1.9 11.4 195.9 214.8 225.3 243.5 208.2 218.1 223 3 232.0 415.7 425.1 438 3 451.3 149.5 149.1 154.1 160.7 96.5 98.4 100.9 104.0 53.1 50.7 53.2 56.7 266.2 276.0 284.2 290.6 9.1 20.5 11.9 15.7 1979: 1 II III IV 2 340 6 2 374 6 2,444.1 2,496.3 1,454.1 1478 0 1,529.1 1,582.3 408.3 423 2 421.7 410.0 19 9 82 17.9 7.6 259.1 266 8 293.1 306.3 239 2 258 6 2752 298.7 458.2 4651 475.4 496.4 164.8 163 6 165.1 178.1 106.0 1081 112.0 118.7 58.8 55 5 53.1 59.4 293.4 301.6" 310.4 318.3 12.7 59 12.2 8.8 2 5717 2,564.8 2,637.3 16310 1,626.8 1,682.2 415 6 390^9 377.1 82 17.1 44.5 337 3 333.3 342.4 329 1 316.2 297.9 516 8 530.0 533.5 190 0 198.7 194.9 125 0 128.7 131.4 64 9 70.0 63.5 326 8 331.3 338.6 12 6 -1.1 11.8 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 . .. . . . 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975. 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980: 1 II III.... . . ... . .. . . .. .. -4.2 1 Changes are based on unrounded data and therefore may differ slightly from those obtained from data shown here. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 233 TABLE B-2.—Gross national product in 1972 dollars, 1929-80 [Billions of 1972 dollars, except as noted; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Gross private domestic investment Personal consumption expenditures Fixed investment Gross national product Year or quarter Total Durable goods Nondurable goods Npnresidential Services Total Total Total Structures Producers' durable equipment 16.4 315.7 215.1 20.9 98.1 96.1 55.8 51.2 37.5 21.1 222.1 170.5 10.7 82.9 76.9 8.4 13.2 10.4 5.0 5.5 319.8 219.8 18.6 115.1 86.1 33.6 32.0 20.9 8.7 12.1 344.1 400.4 461.7 531.6 569.1 560.4 478 3 470.3 489.8 492.2 229.9 243.6 241.1 248.2 255.2 270.9 301.0 305.8 312.2 319.3 21.2 24.2 15.7 14.0 13.0 14.4 25.4 30.1 32.5 35.5 119.9 127.6 129.9 134.0 139.4 150.3 158.9 154.8 155.0 157.4 88.8 91.8 95.5 100.2 102.8 106.3 116.7 120.9 124.7 126.5 44.5 55.8 29.5 18.1 19.7 27.7 70.9 70.0 82.1 65.4 38.3 43.8 24.3 18.0 22.0 31.4 58.7 70.2 76.6 69.8 25.8 30.4 17.6 14.0 18.7 27.6 42.1 48.9 51.1 46.0 10.0 12.0 6.8 4.2 5.5 8.3 18.9 17.4 18.4 17.9 15,8 18.5 10.9 9.8 13.2 19.2 23.2 31.5 32.6 28.1 534.8 579.4 600.8 623.6 616.1 657.5 671.6 683 8 680.9 721.7 337.3 341.6 350.1 363.4 370.0 394.1 405.4 413.8 418.0 440.4 42.6 39.1 38.0 42.1 42.5 51.1 48.8 48.6 45.3 50.7 161.8 165.3 171.2 175.7 177.0 185.4 191.6 194 9 196.8 205.0 132.9 137.2 140.9 145.6 150.5 157.6 165.0 170.3 175.9 184.8 93.5 93.9 83.0 85.3 83.1 103.8 102.6 97 0 87.5 108.0 83.0 80.2 78.7 83.8 85.3 96.1 96.8 95 5 89.3 100.9 50.0 52.9 52.1 56.3 55.4 61.3 65.4 66.2 59.3 63.6 19.2 20.7 20.6 22.6 23.6 25.4 28.3 284 26.8 27.4 30.8 32.2 31.5 33.7 31.8 35.9 37.0 37.8 32.5 36.2 1960. . 1961.. . . 1962 1963 1964.... 1965 . . . 1966 1967 1968 1969 737.2 756.6 800.3 832.5 876.4 929.3 984.8 1,011.4 1,058.1 1,087.6 452.0 461.4 482.0 500.5 528.0 557.5 585.7 602.7 634.4 657.9 51.4 49.3 54.7 59.7 64.8 72.6 78.4 79.5 88.3 91.8 208.2 211.9 218.5 223.0 233.3 244.0 255.5 259.5 270.5 277.3 192.4 200.2 208.8 217.8 229.8 240.9 251.8 263.7 275.6 288.8 104.7 103.9 117.6 125.1 133.0 151.9 163.0 154.9 161.6 171.4 101.2 100.9 109.7 117.5 125.9 140.1 146.2 142.7 152.6 160.4 66.9 66.7 72.0 75.1 82.7 97.4 108.0 105.6 109.5 116.8 29.5 30.2 31.6 31.9 34.4 40.6 43.4 42.0 42.8 45.0 37.4 36.5 40.4 43.1 48.3 56.8 64.5 63.6 66.8 71.8 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 . . . . 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979.. .. 1,085.6 1,122.4 1,185.9 1,255.0 1,248.0 1,233.9 1,300.4 1,371.7 1,436.9 1,483.0 672,1 696.8 737.1 768.5 763.6 780.2 823.7 863.9 904.8 930.9 89.1 98.2 111.1 121.3 112.3 112.7 126.6 138.4 146.3 146.6 283.7 288.7 300.6 308.0 303.3 308.2 322.5 334.0 345.7 354,6 299.3 309.9 325.3 339.2 348.0 359.3 374.7 391.5 412.8 429.6 158.5 173.9 195.0 217.5 195.5 154.8 184.5 213.5 229.7 232.6 154.8 165.8 184.8 200.4 183.9 161.5 176.7 201.2 215.8 222.5 113.8 112.2 121.0 138.1 135.7 119.3 125.6 140.6 153.4 1G3.3 43.9 42.8 44.1 47.4 43.6 38.3 39.5 40.5 44.6 48.5 69.9 69.3 76.9 90.7 92.1 81,1 86.1 100.0 108.8 114.8 1980 » 1480 7 933 0 134 8 357 5 440 7 204 0 205 2 157 7 48 0 109 7 IV 1,402.3 1,432.8 1,446.7 1,465.8 884.1 900.6 911.2 923.4 139.5 148.1 147.0 150.7 339.8 342.4 347.2 353.5 404.8 410.1 417.1 419.2 224.9 232.9 229.3 231.8 207.2 216.9 217.8 221.3 145.7 153.5 155.0 159.4 42.1 44.7 45.3 46.3 103.6 108.9 109.7 113.1 1979. 1 II III IV 1,479.9 1,473.4 1,488.2 1,490.6 925.5 922.8 933.4 941.6 149.6 144.2 146.7 146.0 351.1 350.6 355.4 361.3 424.8 428.0 431.3 434.3 237.7 238.7 232.6 221.5 222.3 220.4 225.0 222.2 161.4 161.3 166.4 164.1 45.8 48.0 49.4 50.7 115.6 113.2 117.0 113.5 1,501.9 1,463.3 1,471.9 943.4 919.3 930.8 145.4 126.2 132.6 361.5 356.6 354.9 436.5 436.5 443.3 218.3 200.5 195.3 219.2 199.2 200.2 165.0 156.1 155.5 50.5 48.7 46.8 114.5 107.4 108.8 1929 " 1933 1939 . 1940.. 1941 ... 1942. .. 1943 1944.. 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949.. . . 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 . . . . 1957 .. 1958 1959 1978: I ii II! . . . '.;... .... 1980 1 II . . Ill . See next page for continuation of table. 234 TABLE B-2.—Gross national product in 1972 dollars, 1929-80—Continued [Billions of 1972 dollars, except as noted; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Net exports of goods and services Gross private domestic investment— continued Government purchases of goods and services Fixed investment—continued Residential Year or quarter Total 1929 1933 13.7 2.B Change in business inventories Net exports Exports Imports Total Federal State and local Percent change from preceding period, gross national product1 Nonfarm structures Farm structures Producers' durable equipment . 13.0 0.6 0.1 4.6 3.7 16.7 12.9 41.0 7.0 33.9 2.5 .2 .1 -4.9 .4 9.1 8.6 42.9 10.9 32.0 3.4 14.3 10.9 63.0 22.8 40.3 7.8 4.4 ; 3.2 -.6 -5.9 -6.2 -3.7 13.2 18.9 10.8 10.7 I5t5 16.4 11.4 9.8 10.5 13.8 27.3 32.2 26.3 25.8 11.1 13.2 12.0 15.7 16.8 17.5 14.0 13.3 15.5 15.2 65.3 97.8 191.6 271.3 300.4 265.4 93.1 75.7 84.7 96.8 26.7 61.0 157.4 239.6 269.7 233.7 58.2 36.3 42.8 49.2 38.6 36.8 34.3 31.7 30.7 31.7 34.9 39.4 41.9 47.5 7.6 16.3 15.3 15.1 7.1 -1.5 -14.7 -1.7 4.1 .5 -2.2 1939 11.1 10.4 .6 .1 1.6 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 12.5 13.3 6.7 4.0 3.4 3.8 16.6 21.3 25.6 23.8 11.6 12.3 6.0 3.5 3.0 3.4 15.3 19.7 23.8 22.1 .8 .9 .6 .4 .4 .3 1.1 1.3 1.5 1.4 .1 .2 .1 .0 .0 .1 .2 .3 .3 .3 6.2 12.0 5.2 .1 -2.3 -3.6 12.2 -.2 5.5 -4.4 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 33.0 27.3 26.6 27.5 29.9 34.8 31.5 29.2 30.0 37.4 31.3 25.7 25.1 26.1 28.5 33.5 30.0 27.8 28.6 35.9 1.3 1.3 1.2 1.2 1.1 .9 1.0 1.0 .9 1.0 .3 .3 .3 .3 .3 .4 .4 .4 .5 :6 10.6 13.7 4.3 1.5 -2.2 7.7 5.8 1.5 -1.8 7.0 5.9 10.1 7.9 4.8 6.9 7.3 10.1 11.8 5.6 2.7 23.6 28.6 27.9 26.6 27.8 30.7 35.3 38.0 33.2 33.8 17.7 18.5 20.0 21.8 20.9 23.4 25.2 26.1 27.6 31.1 98.1 133.7 159.8 170.1 156.0 152.3 153.5 161.2 169.9 170.6 47.3 82.2 107.2 114.7 96.1 88.2 86.8 90.6 93.4 91.4 50.8 51.5 52.7 55.3 59.9 64.1 66.7 70.6 76.5 79.2 8.7 8.3 3.7 3.8 -1.2 6.7 2.1 1.8 -.4 6.0 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 34.2 34.3 37.7 42.5 43.1 42.7 38.2 37.1 43.1 43.6 32.9 32.8 36.3 40.9 41.5 41.2 36.6 35.4 41.3 41.7 .8 1.0 .9 .9 .9 .8 .9 .9 .8 .9 .5 .5 .6 .6 .7 .7 .8 .8 .9 1.1 3.5 3.0 7.8 7.5 7.1 11.8 16.8 12.2 9.0 11.1 7.7 8.5 7.5 9.4 12.8 10.1 6.5 5.4 1.9 .9 38.4 39.3 41.8 44.8 50.3 51.7 54.4 56.7 61.2 65.0 30.7 30.9 34.3 35.4 37.5 41.6 47.9 51.3 59.3 64.1 172.8 182.9 193.2 197.6 202.6 209.8 229.7 248.5 260.2 257.4 90.4 95.3 102.8 101.8 100.2 100.3 112.6 125.1 128.1 121.8 82.4 87.5 90.4 95.8 102.4 109.5 117.1 123.4 132.1 135.6 2.2 2.6 5.8 4.0 5.3 6.0 6.0 2.7 4.6 2.8 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 41.0 53.7 63.8 62.3 48.2 42.2 51.2 60.6 62.4 59.1 39.2 51.6 61.5 59.9 45.3 39.8 48.7 57.8 59.5 56.2 .6 .7 .7 .6 1.1 .8 .8 1.0 1.0 .9 1.1 1.3 1.5 1.7 1.7 1.6 1.7 1.8 1.9 2.0 3.8 8.1 10.2 17.2 11.6 -6.7 7.8 12.3 14.0 10.2 3.9 1.6 .7 15.5 27.8 32.2 25.4 21.9 24.6 37.7 70.5 71.0 77.5 97.3 108.5 103.6 110.1 113.2 127.5 146.9 66.6 69.3 76.7 81.8 80.7 .71.4 84.7 91.3 103.0 109.2 251.1 250.1 253.1 253.5 261.2 266.7 266.8 272.3 277.8 281.8 110.6 103.7 101.7 95.9 96.6 97.4 96.8 100.7 99.8 101.7 140.5 146.4 151.4 157.6 164.5 169.3 170.0 171.6 178.0 180.1 -.2 3.4 5.7 5.8 = .6 -1.1 5.4 5.5 4.8 3.2 1980 *. 47.5 44.6 .9 2.0 -1.2 53.8 161.9 108.2 289.9 108.3 181.7 = .2 61.5 63.3 62.8 61.9 58 5 60.6 59.8 58.8 1.1 .8 1.1 1.0 1.9 1.9 1.9 2.0 17.7 16.0 11.5 10.6 18.7 23.0 26.1 30.5 118.3 125.4 129.8 136.6 99.5 102.4 103.7 106.2 274.6 276.3 280.0 280.1 99.4 98.0 100.8 101.0 175.3 178.3 179.2 179.2 3.2 9.0 3.9 5,4 60.8 59.1 58.6 58.1 58.1 56.3 55.5 54.9 .8 .8 .9 1.1 2.0 2.0 2.1 2.1 15.4 18.4 7.6 -.7 36.0 31.6 41.1 42.2 141.1 140.5 151.3 154.8 105.1 108.8 110.2 112.6 280.6 280.3 281.1 285.3 102.9 100.8 99.9 103.1 177.7 179.4 181.2 182.2 3.9 -1.7 4.1 .6 54.2 43.1 44.7 51.2 40.3 41.9 1.0 .8 .7 2.1 2.0 2.0 -.9 1.3 -5.0 50.1 51.7 57.6 165.9 160.5 160.5 115.8 108.9 102.8 290.1 291.9 288.2 107.6 110.7 106.9 182.5 181.2 181.3 3.1 -9.9 2.4 1978: II Ill IV 1979: 1. . . II Ill IV. ... 1980: 11".."."."""..' Ill 1 Changes are based on unrounded data and therefore may differ slightly from those obtained from data shown here. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 235 TABLE B-3.—Implicit price deflators for gross national product, 1929-80 [Index numbers, 1972-100, except as noted; quarterly data seasonally adjusted] Personal consumption expenditures Gross national product1 Year or quarter 1929 1933 1939 1940.... 1941. . 1942. .. 1943 1944 .. 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953. . .. 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960. . 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965. ... 1966... 1967 1968 1969... 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 ."." *.'"..'".....' 1976 1977... . '.' 1978 1979 '""'. 1980 ". Gross private domestic investment * Fixed investment Total Durable Nondurable Services goods goods Presidential Total Total Structures Producers' durable equipment 33.4 35.9 44.2 38.4 31.6 28.3 28.3 24.3 26.9 32.5 26.8 26.1 22.4 22.9 19.2 26.2 30.5 35.9 30.5 29.2 27.7 28.2 23.0 32.0 30.9 33.2 36.7 40.1 42.4 44.1 47.8 52.9 56.0 55.8 36.7 40.0 43.7 46.7 51.3 55.5 62.1 67.8 70.3 70.5 30.9 33.6 39.1 43.7 46.2 47.8 52.1 58.7 62.3 60.3 29.5 30.8 32.4 34.2 36.1 37.3 38.8 41.7 44.4 46.0 28.5 30.7 33.5 35.7 37.0 37.2 41.3 49.0 53.7 54.9 29.1 31.0 33.9 35.9 36.8 36.7 40.0 46.9 51.5 53.0 23.4 24.9 28.4 32.4 33.8 33.9 36.6 44.0 48.8 48.4 34.9 37.3 37.3 38.0 37.9 42.8 48.6 53.0 56.0 53.56 57.09 57.92 58.82 59.55 60.84 62.79 64.93 66.04 67.60 56.9 60.6 62.0 63.2 63.7 64.4 65.6 67.8 69.2 70.6 72.2 76.3 76.7 77.2 75.0 75.6 77.7 80.9 81.3 83.8 60.7 65.8 66.5 66.3 66.6 66.3 67.3 69.4 71.0 71.4 47.4 49.9 52.6 55.4 57.2 58.4 60.1 62.2 64.1 66.0 56.7 60.9 62.3 63.1 63.6 65.0 68.5 71.1 71.0 71.8 54.5 59.1 60.1 61.2 61.7 62.9 67.3 71.0 70.9 72.2 49.3 55.1 56.3 57.4 56.5 57.6 62.4 64.9 63.9 64.2 57.8 61.7 62.6 63.8 65.5 66.6 71.1 75.5 76.6 78.3 68.70 69.33 70.61 71.67 72.77 74.36 76.76 79.06 82.54 86.79 91.45 96.01 100.00 105.69 114.92 125.56 132.11 139.83 150.05 162.77 177.45 71.9 72.6 73.7 74.8 75.9 77.2 79.4 81.4 84.6 88.4 83.8 84.3 85.4 86.2 87.1 86.8 86.7 88.2 91.1 93.3 72.6 73.3 73.9 74.9 75.8 77.3 80.1 81.9 85.3 67.9 69.0 70.4 71.7 72.7 74.2 76.4 78.7 81.9 86.0 72.1 71.8 72.2 72.3 72.9 74.0 76.3 78.8 82.2 87.0 72.5 72.0 72.5 73.1 73.8 74.7 76.9 79.5 82.8 86.7 63.7 63.3 63.6 64.1 64.9 66.4 69.2 72.2 75.8 81.5 79.4 79.3 79.4 79.7 80.1 80.6 82.1 84.3 87.2 89.9 92.5 96.5 100.0 105.7 116.3 125.2 131.6 139.5 149.1 162.3 95.7 99.0 100.0 101.7 108.2 117.3 123.9 129.2 136.2 144.8 93.6 96.6 100.0 108.3 123.1 132.1 137.0 143.4 153.2 169.8 90.5 95.6 100.0 104.7 113.0 121.6 129.6 139.9 150.1 162.1 91.1 95.7 100.0 105.5 116.7 131.9 139.2 149.7 163.7 179.1 91.3 96.2 100.0 103.8 115.4 132.2 138.6 146.2 157.7 171.3 88.2 94.5 100.0 107.7 128.2 144.8 149.0 159.4 176.4 198.6 93.2 97,2 100.0 101.8 109.3 126.2 133.9 140.9 150.1 159.7 179.0 156.0 188.6 178.2 194.5 187.1 225.2 170.4 144.93 148.63 151.42 154.99 144.6 147.7 150.3 153.4 132.6 135.1 137.4 139.4 148.3 152.0 154.5 157.9 145.6 148.6 151.4 154.6 157.2 161.7 165.9 169.4 152.8 155.9 159.4 162.3 166.8 173.2 179.5 185.1 147.1 148.9 151.2 153.0 158.16 161.17 164.23 167.47 157.1 160.2 163.8 168.0 142.0 143.9 145.4 148.0 162.9 167.3 172.1 176.9 157.7 159.9 163.3 167.4 172.8 177.0 181.5 184.9 165.5 169.2 173.4 176.8 190.6 194.0 201.4 207.4 155.6 158.7 161.5 163.2 171.23 175.28 179.18 172.9 177.0 180.7 151.9 154.1 157.5 182.9 186.2 190.0 171.6 176.0 180.3 188.5 192.5 196.4 180.5 185.7 189.1 214.3 222.4 229.5 165.6 169.0 171.7 32,76 25.13 28.43 29.06 31.23 34.32 36.14 37.01 37.91 43.88 49.55 52.98 52.49 32.8 1978: n"Z '.'..... HI IV 1979: I II III IV 1980: I j| lit See next page for continuation of table. 236 TABLE B-3.—Implicit price deflators for gross national product, 1929-80—Continued [Index numbers, 1972=100, except as noted; quarterly data seasonally adjusted] Gross private domestic investmentl—continued Fixed investment—continued Exports and imports of goods and services1 Residential Yea* or quarter Total Nonfarm structures ProFarm ducers' Exports Imports struc- durable tures equipment Percent change from preceding period 2 Government purchases of goods and services Total Federal State and local Gross domestic Gross Gross product national domestic product product implicit implicit price price deflator deflator 1929 28.2 27.8 28.6 77.2 42.2 45.5 21.5 20.5 21.8 32.8 1933 20.7 19.8 19,5 58.8 26.5 23.6 19.2 19.4 19.1 25.1 1939 26.6 26.3 23.4 61.1 32.1 31.0 21.4 22.7 20.7 28.4 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 . 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 27.4 30.0 32.4 34.9 38.1 40.8 44.6 53.7 58.1 58.7 27.2 29.7 31.8 34.3 37.3 40.0 43.9 53.0 57.5 58.1 23.6 26.6 30.7 35.7 40.8 42.9 46.6 52.8 57.3 58.0 59.6 63.8 71.3 71.4 75.0 84.6 95.2 105.6 111.5 107.9 34.9 37.3 43.6 46.8 51.9 53.6 55.4 62.8 66.5 63.1 32.8 35.4 40.0 41.3 42.7 44.9 51.8 62.3 67.8 64.6 21,7 25.5 31.2 32.8 32.3 31.2 29.6 33.6 37.7 39.7 22.7 27.8 33.0 34.0 33.1 31.9 30.2 35.0 39.0 41.4 20.9 21.7 22.8 23.7 24.8 25.8 28.5 32.4 36.4 37.8 29.1 31.2 34.3 36.1 37.0 37.9 43.9 49.5 53.0 52.5 2.2 7.5 9.9 5.3 2.4 2.4 15.7 12.9 6.9 -.9 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 60.0 64.4 66.4 66.9 67.1 68.7 71.0 71.4 71.2 71.1 59.5 63.8 65.8 66.3 66.6 68.2 70.5 70.9 70.7 70.6 59.4 63.7 65.7 66.2 66.5 68.3 70.6 70.9 70.8 70.7 107.4 114.9 114.6 114.2 112.4 109.1 104.3 103.4 101.9 101.8 61.0 68.8 68.6 67.5 67.2 68.5 71.0 74.0 73.1 73.5 68.8 82.6 79.9 76.7 77.2 77.1 78.4 79.6 76.1 75.2 39.2 45.0 47.3 48.5 48.6 49.2 51.7 54.0 55.9 57.2 39.6 46.6 48.9 50.1 49.9 50.4 52.9 55.1 57.7 59.0 38.9 42.3 44.1 45.2 46.5. 47.6 50.2 52.6 53.8 55.1 53.6 57.1 57.9 58.8 59.5 60.8 62.8 64.9 66.0 67.6 2.1 6.6 1.4 1.6 1.2 2.2 3.2 3.4 1.7 2.4 1960 1961 1962 1963 .. . 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 71.4 71.3 71.5 70.9 71.2 72.3 74.6 77.0 80.7 87.7 70.9 70.9 71.1 70.5 70.8 72.0 74.3 76.7 80.5 87.5 71.1 70.7 71.2 70.6 70.9 72.2 74.2 76.7 80.6 87.5 100.8 99.0 96.8 95.3 94.3 92.1 90.8 91.0 93.5 95.7 75.2 76.1 76.0 76.3 77.2 79.4 81.9 83.5 85.5 88.5 76.1 75.5 74.2 75.2 76.8 77.7 79.4 79.9 81.1 83.2 58.0 59.1 61.1 62.6 64.1 . 66.0 69.1 72.5 76.5 81.1 59.4 60.2 62.0 63.5 65.1 67.1 70.0 72.7 76.5 80.1 56.5 58.0 60.1 61.6 63.1 64.9 68.2 72.4 76.4 82.0 68.7 69.3 70.6 71.7 72.8 74.4 76.8 79.1 82.5 86.8 1.6 .9 1.8 1.5 1.5 2.2 3.2 3.0 4.4 5.1 1970... 1971 1972.... 1973. . 1974 1975 . 1976 1977 ... 1978, 1979 90.5 94.8 100.0 109.1 120.3 131.0 140.7 158.0 178.3 200.5 90.3 94.7 100.0 109.4 120.8 131.6 141.3 159.0 179.8 202.7 90.6 95.0 100.0 109.2 120.5 131.9 140.7 157.2 179.0 202.0 97.8 99.3 100.0 100.6 106.8 116.9 122.7 126.6 132.7 140.3 93.2 97.0 100.0 112.7 134.7 149.6 155.2 161.9 172.4 191.5 88.6 93.3 100.0 116.7 164.6 179.5 185.5 205.4 214.0 245.4 87.7 93.9 100.0 106.7 116.4 127.5 135.7 144.8 155.7 168.1 86.6 92.7 100.0 106.3 114.9 126.0 133.5 142.9 153.7 165.1 88.6 94.7 100.0 106.9 117.4 128.3 137.0 146.0 156.9 169.8 91.4 96.0 100.0 105.7 114.9 125.6 132.1 139.8 150.1 162.8 5.4 5.0 4.2 5.7 8.7 9.3 5.2 5.8 7.3 8.5 1980 *. 219.1 222.2 220.0 149.5 210.7 289.9 184.4 183.7 184.9 177.5 9.0 III . IV 167.8 175.7 181.8 187.9 169.0 177.1 183.3 189.6 168.7 176.0 182.5 188.3 129.5 131.6 133.7 135.9 165.6 171.3 173.5 178.2 209.1 212.9 215.3 218.5 151.4 153.8 156.5 161.1 150.5 152.1 152.9 159.2 151.9 154.8 158.6 162.2 144.9 148.6 151.4 155.0 5.8 10.6 7.7 9.8 1979: I.. II... Ill IV .. 191.9 198.4 204.6 207.7 193.7 200.4 207.0 210.1 192.1 199.7 205.5 207.7 138.4 139.7 140.5 142.4 183.7 189.9 193.7 197.9 227.7 237.6 249.8 265.2 163.3 166.0 169.2 174.0 160.1 162.2 165.2 172.8 165.1 168.1 171.3 174.7 158.2 161.2 164.3 167.5 8.4 7.8 7.8 8.1 212.6 217.4 221.9 215.2 220.7 225.2 213.6 219.4 223.1 145.5 148.5 151.0 203.4 207.6 213.4 284.2 290.4 289.7 178.1 181.6 185.1 176.5 179.5 182.4 179.1 182.8 186.7 171.3 175.3 179.2 9.3 9.8 9.2 1978: I It.... -2.1 1980: I It . III... 1 Separate deflators are not available for gross private domestic investment, change in business inventories, and net exports of goods and services. 2 Changes are based on unrounded data and therefore may differ slightly from those obtained from data shown here. Quarterly data are at annual rates. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 237 TABLE B-4.—Fixed-weighted price indexes for gross national product 1972 weights, 1959-80 [Index numbers, 1972=100; quarterly data seasonally adjusted] Years or quarter Gross national product Personal consumption expenditures Gross private domestic investment1 Fixed investment Total Nonresidential Residential Exports and imports of goods and services1 Exports Imports Government Total Feder- State and local Gross domestic product 1959 69.1 72.1 74.3 73.9 74.9 73.8 75.0 56.8 56,8 58.5 69.1 1960 1961... . 1962... 1963... 1964 70.2 71.0 72.0 72.8 73.7 73.3 74.0 74.8 75.7 76.6 74.5 74.4 74,2 74.0 74,3 74.4 74.3 74,3 74.7 75.2 74.9 74.7 73.9 72.6 72.6 75.4 76.4 76,3 76.6 77.4 76.1 75.4 73.8 74.7 76.4 58.2 59.4 61.2 62.7 64.3 59.6 60.5 61.7 63.3 65.3 57.2 58.7 60.8 62.3 63.7 70,3 71.1 72.0 72.8 73.7 1965... . 1966 1967.... 1968... 1969 75.0 77.2 79.5 83.0 87.2 77.7 79.7 81.6 84.8 88.5 75.2 77.0 79.3 82.5 87.3 76.1 77.9 80.3 83.3 87,0 73.5 75.3 77.5 81.0 87.8 79.7 82.1 83.4 85.4 88.4 77.1 78.8 79.3 80.7 83.0 66.1 69.1 72.3 76.4 81.3 67.2 69.7 71.6 75.7 79.8 65:4 68.6 72.9 76.9 82.3 75.0 77.2 79.5 83.0 87.2 1970... 1971... 1972... 1973... 1974... 91.7 96.1 100.0 105.8 115.6 92.6 96.5 100.0 105.8 116.8 91.2 95.8 100.0 105.8 117.9 91.6 96.3 100.0 104.0 116.5 90.6 94.9 100.0 109.2 120.5 93.1 96.9 100.1 112.6 137.4 88.4 93.3 100.0 116.6 161.2 87.9 94.0 100.0 106.8 117.2 86.7 93.0 100.0 106.6 116.6 88.7 94.8 100.0 106.9 117.7 91.7 96.1 100.0 105.8 115.6 1975... 1976... 1977... 1978... 1979... 126.0 133.1 141.6 152.3 166,3 125.8 132.4 140.6 150.6 164.8 132.3 140.2 151.8 167.1 185.0 132.9 139.9 148.5 161.1 176.7 131.2 140.8 158.0 178.3 200.9 151.7 156.9 164.1 174.8 196.8 174.5 178.6 194.6 209.6 243.3 128.2 136.2 145.5 156.4 170.4 127.4 134,8 144.6 154,2 168.0 128.8 137.2 146.1 157.8 172.0 126.0 133.2 141.6 152.3 166.4 1980 » 182.0 182.8 204.0 195.6 220.0 216.8 300.0 188.2 188.9 187.8 182.1 III! 147.1 150.6 153.7 157.6 145.8 149.3 152.0 155.3 159.7 164.8 169.5 173.9 155.4 159.1 163.0 166.5 167.9 175.7 181.7 188.0 168.5 172.9 175.6 181.4 203.5 208.1 211.3 215.3 151.7 154.1 157.5 162.1 150.7 152.1 154.5 159,8 152.4 155.4 159.5 163.6 147.1 150.6 153.8 157.6 1979: I II Ill IV 161.1 164.4 167.9 171.9 159.1 162.5 166.6 171.1 177.8 182.8 187.9 191.7 170.3 174.4 178.8 183.0 192.1 198.6 205.1 208.1 188.1 195.5 199.5 203.4 224.7 234.8 249.5 265.3 165.1 167.7 171.7 177.5 162.0 164.1 169.0 178.1 167.1 170.2 173.5 177.0 161.1 164.5 168.0 171.9 175.9 179.8 183.8 176.4 180.5 184.7 196.7 202.4 207.1 188.0 193.9 198.6 213.2 218.4 223.1 210.0 213.1 218.9 287.9 296.9 305.8 182.1 185.9 189.7 182.8 186.0 189.4 181.7 185.8 189.9 176.0 179.9 183,9 1978: III.... IV.... 1980: I 1 Separate deflators are not available for gross private domestic investment, change in business inventories, and net exports of goods and services. Note.—Data are preliminary and subject to further revision. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 238 TABLE B-5.—Implicit price deflators and alternative price measures for gross national product and gross domestic product, 1929-80 [Quarterly data seasonally adjusted] Percent change from preceding periodl Index numbers, 1972=100 Year or quarter Gross national product Implicit price deflator Fixedweighted price index (1972 weights) Gross domestic product Implicit price deflator Fixedweighted price index (1972 weights) Gross national product Implicit price deflator Fixedweighted price index (1972 weights) Gross domestic product Chain price index Implicit price deflator FixedA weighted price index (1972 weights) Chain price index 1929 32.76 32.8 1933 25.13 25.1 21 - 2.1 1939 28.43 28.4 - 8 - 8 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 29,06 31.23 34.32 36.14 37 01 37 91 43.88 49.55 52.98 52 49 29.1 31.2 34.3 36.1 37.0 37 9 43.9 49 5 53.0 52 5 2.2 7.5 9.9 5.3 2.4 24 15.7 12 9 6.9 g 2.2 7.5 9.9 53 2.4 24 15.7 12.9 6.9 g 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 53.56 57.09 57.92 58 82 59.55 60 84 62.79 64.93 66.04 67.60 69.1 53.6 57.1 57.9 58.8 59.5 60.8 62.8 64.9 66.0 67.6 69.1 2.1 6.6 14 16 1.2 22 3.2 3.4 1.7 2.4 2.1 6.6 1.4 16 1.2 2.2 32 3.4 1.7 2.4 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 . ... 68.70 69.33 70.61 71.67 72.77 74.36 76.76 79.06 82.54 86.79 70.2 71.0 72.0 72.8 73.7 75.0 77.2 79.5 83.0 87.2 68.7 69,3 70.6 71.7 72.8 74.4 76.8 79.1 82.5 86.8 70.3 71.1 72.0 72.8 73.7 75.0 77.2 79.5 83.0 87.2 1.6 .9 1.8 1.5 1.5 2.2 3.2 3.0 4.4 5.1 1.6 1.1 1.3 1.2 1.2 1.8 3.0 3.0 4.2 5.1 1.6 1.0 1.3 1.3 1.5 1.8 3.1 2.8 4.3 5.1 1.6 .9 1.8 1.5 1.5 2.2 3.2 3.0 4.4 5.2 1.6 1.1 1.3 1.2 1.2 1.8 3.0 3.0 4.2 5.1 1.6 1.0 1.3 1.3 1.4 1.8 3.1 2.8 4.3 5.1 91.45 96.01 100.00 105.69 114.92 .. .. 125.56 132.11 139.83 150.05 162.77 91.7 96.1 100.0 105.8 115.6 126.0 133.1 141.6 152.3 166.3 91.4 96.0 100.0 105.7 114.9 125.6 132.1 139.8 150.1 162.8 91.7 96.1 100.0 105.8 115.6 126.0 133.2 141.6 152.3 166.4 5.4 5.0 4.2 5.7 8.7 9.3 5.2 5.8 7.3 8.5 5.2 4.8 4.0 5.8 9.3 9.0 5.7 6.3 7.6 9.2 5.4 4.9 4.1 5.8 9.0 9.1 5.7 6.1 7.5 8.6 5.4 5.0 4.2 5.7 8.7 9.3 5.2 5.8 7.3 8.5 5.2 4.8 4.0 5.8 9.3 9.0 5.7 6.3 7.6 9.2 5.4 4.9 4.1 5.8 9.0 9.1 5.7 6.2 7.5 8.7 177.45 182.0 177.5 182.1 9.0 9.5 8.6 9.0 9.5 8.6 144.93 148.63 151.42 154.99 147.1 150.6 153.7 157.6 144.9 148.6 151.4 155.0 147.1 150.6 153.8 157.6 5.8 10.6 7.7 9.8 5.9 9.8 8.7 10.4 6.1 9.6 8.4 10.0 5.8 10.6 7.7 9.8 5.9 9.8 8.7 10.4 6.2 9.6 8.4 10.0 U Ill IV 158.16 161.17 164.23 167.47 161.1 164.4 167.9 171.9 158.2 161.2 164.3 167.5 161.1 164.5 168.0 171.9 8.4 7.8 7.8 8.1 9.1 8.5 8.9 9.7 8.8 8.0 7.4 8.5 8.4 7.8 7.8 8.1 9.2 8.5 8.9 9.7 8.8 8.0 7.4 8.5 1980: 1 II III 171.23 175.28 179.18 175.9 179.8 183.8 171.3 175.3 179.2 176.0 179.9 183.9 9.3 9.8 9.2 9.8 9.1 9.2 8.3 8.5 9.4 9.3 9.8 9.2 9.8 9.1 9.2 8.2 8.5 9.4 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 ... 1976 1977 1978 1979 .. . 1980" 1978: | III IV 1979: . ... 1 Changes are based on unrounded data and therefore may differ slightly from those obtained from published indexes shown here. Quarterly percent change data are at annual rates. Note.—Data for fixed-weighted and chain price indexes are preliminary and subject to revision in late January 1981. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 239 TABLE B-6.—Gross national product by major type of product, 1929-80 [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Goods Gross national product Year or quarter Final sales Inventory change Durable goods Total Total Inventory change Final sales Final sales Inventory change Nondurable goods Final sales Services Structures Auto output Inventory change 103.4 101.7 1.7 56.1 54.4 1.7 16.1 1.4 38.3 0.3 35.9 11.4 1933 55.8 57.4 -1.6 27.0 28.6 -1.6 5.4 -.5 23.2 = 1.1 25.9 2.9 1939 90.9 90.5 .4 49.0 48.6 .4 12.4 .3 36.2 .1 34.4 7.5 100.0 125.0 158.5 192.1 210.6 212.4 209.8 233.1 259.5 258.3 97.8 120.6 156.7 192.8 211.6 213.5 203.5 233.5 254.8 261.4 2.2 4.5 1.8 56.0 72.5 93.7 120.4 132.3 128.9 125.3 139.8 154.4 147.7 53.8 68.0 91.9 121.0 133.3 129.9 118.9 140.3 149.7 150.8 2.2 4.5 1.8 -.6 15.4 23.8 34.5 54.2 58.5 50.1 31.8 44.4 48.0 50.0 1.2 38.4 44.2 57.4 66.8 74.8 79.8 87.1 95.9 101.7 100.9 1.0 1.4 .7 -.6 -.3 .2 1.1 35.7 40.8 50.8 63.0 72.3 77.0 68.8 71.6 77.2 82.2 15.7 21.7 28.0 28.4 11.9 286.5 330.8 348.0 366.8 366.8 400.0 421.7 444.0 449.7 487.9 279.7 320.5 344.8 366 3 368.4 394.1 417.0 442.6 451.2 482.2 162.4 189.5 194.6 203.1 196.1 214.5 223.3 232.3 228.2 248.5 155.6 179.2 191.5 202.7 197.6 208.5 218.6 231.0 229.7 242.9 88.5 103.5 113.9 121.6 126.2 136.1 146.2 158.7 167.7 179.8 35.6 37.8 39.4 42.0 44.5 49.5 52.2 53.0 53.8 59.5 15.4 13.3 12.0 16.1 14.7 21.2 16.9 19.4 14.4 19.4 506.5 524.6 565.0 596.7 637.7 691.1 756.0 799.6 873.4 944.0 503.6 522.2 558.8 590.7 632.1 681.2 741.9 789.3 865.5 934.2 254.2 257.4 278.5 290.3 309.8 338.4 375.0 389.4 421.3 450.2 251.3 255.0 272.2 284.3 304.2 328.5 360.9 379.1 413.4 440.4 193.8 207.0 222.0 237.1 255.0 273.3 299.0 326.5 358.2 391.9 58.5 60.2 64.5 69.3 72,9 79.3 82.0 83.6 94.0 101.8 21.3 17.8 22.5 25.2 25.9 31.2 30.4 28.0 35.1 34.9 992.7 1,077.6 1,185.9 1,326.4 1,434.2 1,549.2 1,718,0 1,918.0 2,156.1 2,413.9 989.5 1,070.0 1,175.7 1,307.9 1,420.1 1,556.1 1,706.2 1,897.0 2,133.9 2,396.4 10.2 18.5 14.1 -6.9 11.8 21.0 22.2 17.5 459.9 485.3 529.6 604.1 646.7 694.0 771.1 852.6 946.6 1,055.9 456.6 477.7 519.4 585.6 632.5 700.9 759.3 831.6 924.4 1,038.5 10.2 18.5 14.1 -6.9 11.8 21.0 22.2 17.5 179.2 187.1 207.4 237.6 250.7 279.4 312.5 353.9 392.0 439.7 13.1 12.0 = 8.4 17.8 11.5 277.5 290.6 312.0 348.0 381.8 421.5 446.7 477.7 532.5 598.8 6.0 429.9 472.0 519.0 571.5 636.1 705.2 779.3 869.0 976.2 1,097.2 102.9 120.3 137.3 150.8 151.4 150.0 167.6 196.4 233.2 260.8 28.7 39.1 41.6 46.2 39.2 40.7 55.9 65.3 69.6 68.0 1980 * 2,627.4 2,631.3 -3.9 1,132.0 1,135.9 -3.9 463.8 -4.9 672.1 1.0 1,231.1 264.3 59.0 1978: 1 II Ill IV 2,032.4 2,129.6 2,190.5 2,271.9 2,007.5 2,102.6 2,171.4 2,254.2 24.9 27.0 19.1 17.7 885.7 938.9 959.5 1,002.2 860.9 911.9 940.5 984.5 24.9 27.0 19.1 17.7 359.0 390.7 399.4 418.9 21.8 16.9 15.1 17.3 501.9 521.2 541.1 565.6 3.1 10.0 3.9 .4 935.1 959.1 989.3 1,021.5 211.5 231.6 241.6 248.2 65.8 72.2 67.8 72.6 2 340 6 2,374.6 2,444.1 2,496.3 2 316 2 2.34L5 2,430.8 2,497.1 24 3 33*1 13.3 — .8 1038 6 1014 3 l]04L9 l!00&8 1,064.9 1,051.6 1,078.3 1,079.1 24 3 13.3 3 434 7 426.4 449.2 448.4 18 9 20.9 6.7 = .4 579 5 582.4 602.4 630.7 1 055 5 l|078!5 1,112.0 1142.8 246 5 254^2 267.3 275.1 2,571.7 2,564 8 2,637.3 2,569.1 2 557 4 2,653.3 2.5 74 -16.0 1,116.9 1,114.4 1 106 4 1099 0 2.5 74 468.2 441 3 = 11.8 33 =8.4 646.2 657 7 680^5 1,178.6 1 205 6 276.2 252 8 258^9 1929 ... 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946. 1947... 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 ,.,, .. . .. . . . . , 1960. .., 1961 .. 1962. .. 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971. 197? 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1979: | II Ill IV 1980: 1 || III ,. . = .6 -1.0 -1.0 6.4 -.5 4.7 -3.1 6.8 10.3 3.1 .4 = 1.5 6.0 4.7 1.3 -1.5 5.7 3.0 2.3 6.3 6.0 5.6 9.9 14.1 10.3 7.9 9.8 3.2 7.7 -1.0 -1.0 6.4 — 5 47 = 3.1 6.8 10.3 3.1 .4 -1.5 6.0 4.7 1.3 -1.5 5.7 3.0 2.3 6.3 6.0 5.6 9.9 14.1 10.3 7.9 9.8 3.2 7.7 311 93.3 92.7 102.9 109.4 118.9 131.6 147.0 153.5 167.9 178.5 \M%A l,U5A — 16!o 464^9 Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 56.2 66.4 72.5 77.8 73.9 81.4 85.9 91.3 84.4 90.8 240 3.1 1.0 .0 = .6 -1.3 5.3 1.4 1.0 -1.8 3.6 6.1 1.2 1.5 =2.5 3.4 2.1 .5 -2.8 3.1 1.6 = .1 3.4 2.7 4.0 6.7 10.2 5.5 4.7 6.4 -=.1 2.8 7.2 7.7 8.8 99.4 112.8 119.0 124.9 123.7 127.1 132.7 139.6 145.3 152.1 158.0 162.4 169.3 174.9 185.3 196.9 213.9 225.6 245.5 261.9 -1.9 3.7 -1.3 3.2 4.2 2.0 = 1.1 1.0 2.6 2.6 .8 1.3 2.5 1.3 2.4 2.8 3.3 1.6 3.2 3.9 4.9 3.1 3.4 3.3 4.8 3.0 5.3 2.2 1.5 4.2 12.2 4.4 55 \Z2 6.6 —.5 14.3 41 -77 U49i0 8.3 11.8 14.0 8.7 6.1 6.5 7.2 8,8 76 0 6*5 64.9 61.8 64.4 53 6 543 TABLE B-7.—Gross national product by major type of product in 1972 dollars, 1929-80 [Billions of 1972 dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual'rates] Goods Gross national product Year or quarter Final sales Inventory change Total Total Final sales ) Durable goods Inventory change Final sales Inventory change Nondurable goods Final sales Services Structures Auto output 43.9 II Inventory change 1929 315.7 311.0 4.6 144.3 139.7 4.6 40.4 3.5 99.3 1933 222.1 227.0 =4.9 97.5 102.3 -4.9 17.5 -2.1 84.9 -2.8 110.7 14.0 1939 . 319.8 318.2 1.6 154.3 152.7 1.6 35.5 .7 117.2 .9 135.2 30.3 344.1 400.4 461.7 531.6 569.1 560.4 478.3 470.3 489.8 492.2 337.9 388.4 456.5 531.5 571.4 564.0 466.1 470.6 484.3 496.6 6.2 6.2 21&2 263.3 289.6 282.2 226.2 237.9 239.4 244.7 43.1 57.8 75.7 118.8 135.9 121.2 60.3 75.5 77.3 78.3 3.4 8.2 3.5 .7 122.4 128.7 140.5 144.4 153.7 161.0 165.8 162.4 162.1 166.4 2.8 3.8 1.7 -4.4 171.7 198.6 221.4 263.3 287.3 278.5 238.3 237.7 244.8 240.3 139.9 158.5 193.9 242.0 263.7 263.0 200.8 188.1 192,5 198.3 32.5 43.3 46.3 26.2 18,1 18.8 39.1 44.6 ""12.3 52.4 13.9 53.6 18.0 534.8 579.4 600.8 623.6 616.1 657.5 671.6 683.8 680.9 721.7 524.2 565.6 596.5 622.1 618.2 649.8 665.8 682.2 682.8 714.7 10.6 13.7 2615 283.7 1.5 3.2 2.9 .6 1.6 3.1 207.4 231.3 243.2 247.5 249.1 260.1 270.2 282.4 287.6 299.4 65.9 64.3 65.5 69.3 74.3 80.7 80.5 79.7 81.7 89.8 23.0 19.3 17.1 22.6 21.6 29.8 23.0 24.5 18.6 23.2 737.2 756.6 800.3 832.5 876.4 929.3 984.8 1,011.4 1,058.1 1,087.6 733,7 753.7 792.4 825.0 869.3 917.5 968.0 999.2 1,049.1 1,076.6 216.6 220.3 227.8 232.2 243.7 253.6 265.6 272.9 286.7 291.9 1.6 3.0 3.7 4.2 1.9 3.6 4.5 5.6 3.6 3.9 312.5 326.9 341.5 356.2 374.0 390.7 412.6 434.1 453.0 469.2 89.0 91.7 97.4 104.1 108.6 116.0 115.9 113.9 122.0 122.5 25.3 21.2 26.0 28.7 29.4 35.7 34.8 31.8 38.5 37.4 1970 . 1971 .. . 1972 1973 1974 1975 . .. 1976 . . 1977..,. 1978 . 1979 . . .. 1,085.6 1,122.4 1,185.9 1,255.0 1,248.0 1,233.9 1,300.4 1,371.7 1,436.9 1,483.0 1,081.8 1,114.3 1,175.7 1,237.8 1,236.4 1,240.6 1,292.7 1,359.3 1,423.0 1,472.9 3.7 5.1 4.5 2.2 -.3 2.4 6.5 3.0 3.5 482.4 497.8 519.0 542.9 563.0 576.4 595.6 618.2 649.0 678.0 116.3 127.3 137.3 139.1 121.0 108.3 116.0 124.6 132.1 130.6 29.8 38.9 41.6 46.4 37.1 35.7 45.3 50.7 50.2 46.8 1980 *.. 1,480.7 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 . ... . . . . 1950 . . . 1951 . . . . 1952 1953 1954 1955 . 1956 . 1957 1958 1959 1960. . 1961 1962. 1963 1964. 1965 1966 1967. . 1968 . 1969 . 1978. 1 II Ill IV 12.0 5.2 .1 -2.3 -3.6 12.2 -.2 5.5 IV. . . 12.0 311.6 332.5 250.9 270.0 287.8 305.3 294.9 309.0 315.1 320.2 313.4 325.5 335.8 338.0 361.3 372.2 393.8 422.6 456.4 463.4 483.1 496.0 332.3 335.0 353.5 364.7 386.7 410.8 439.6 451.2 474.1 484.9 12.3 14.0 10.2 486.9 497.2 529.6 573.0 564.0 549.2 588.9 628.8 655.9 674.5 483.2 489.1 519.4 555.8 552.4 555.9 581.1 616.5 641.9 664.3 1,481.8 -1.2 665.9 1,402.3 1,432.8 1,446.7 1,465.8 1,384.6 1,416.8 1,435.2 1,455.3 17.7 16.0 11.5 10.6 1,479.9 1,473.4 1,488.2 1,490.6 1,464.4 1,455.0 1,480.6 1,491.3 1,501.9 1,463.3 1,471.9 1,502.8 1,462.0 1,476.9 4.3 292.1 1.5 306.8 -2.2 292.7 7.7 316.7 5.8 320.9 1.5 321.7 -1.8 7.0 5.2 .1 -2.3 -3.6 12.2 -.2 5.5 -4.4 10.6 13.7 4.3 1.5 -2.2 7.7 5.8 1.5 -1.8 7.0 86.1 98.2 107.9 116.2 109.0 117.2 117.8 119.4 109.2 113.6 -1.8 -3.7 10.8 1.4 1.6 -2.9 5.5 9.0 1.7 2.3 -3.7 4.5 2.9 .9 -3.4 3.9 111 3.8 -1.5 5.1 4.7 2.6 = .8 .0 3.0 12.3 14.0 10.2 187.5 188.7 207.4 236.1 234.1 230.3 242.8 264.2 278.6 290.2 6.7 295.7 300.4 312.0 319.7 318.3 325.7 338.3 352.3 363.3 374.1 667.1 -1.2 281.4 -2.0 385,6 .8 696.1 118.7 37.9 635.4 655.1 659.5 673.5 617.7 639.0 648.0 662.9 17.7 16.0 11.5 10.6 261.6 280.5 282.4 290.1 13.8 10.1 356.1 358.5 365.6 372.8 3.9 5.9 2.3 = .1 639.9 644.2 652.8 658.9 127.0 133.6 134.4 133.4 48.5 52.4 48.4 51.4 15.4 18.4 7.6 -.7 681.8 669.1 673.6 673.3 666.4 650.8 666.0 674.0 15.4 18.4 7.b -.7 295.0 283.8 292.1 289.9 11.4 11.9 371.3 367.0 373.8 384.1 4.0 6.4 3.8 -.4 669.1 674.8 683,0 684.9 129.0 129.5 131.6 132.4 53.2 48.4 44.0 41.4 -.9 1.3 -5.0 682.1 658.1 657.5 683.0 656.8 662.4 -.9 1.3 -5.0 295.2 270.1 278.4 -4.6 387.7 386.7 384.0 3.7 -1.1 690.7 690.6 699.9 129.1 114.6 114.5 42.5 34.6 34.6 11.8 16.8 12.2 9.0 11.1 3.8 8.1 10.2 17.2 11.6 -6.7 7.8 11.8 16.8 12.2 9.0 11.1 3.8 8.1 10.2 17.2 11.6 -6.7 7.8 Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. -1.6 2.0 -.1 4.2 3.4 5.1 8.2 3.5 3.0 7.8 7.5 7.1 12.3 6.6 5.4 7.2 7.2 12.7 9.4 -6.4 5.4 5.8 10.9 9.2 10.6 3.8 -.3 1980. II 164.8 171.8 179.9 189.1 185.9 191.9 197.2 200.8 204.3 211.9 = .6 -.5 .1 1.3 127.4 115.6 114.7 125.7 132.5 143.0 157.2 174.0 178.3 187.4 193.0 3.5 3.0 7.8 7.5 7.1 1979: II " . Ill . 165.5 1.1 241 .7 -3.8 3.0 .6 TABLE B-8.—Gross national product: Receipts and expenditures by major economic groups, 1929-80 [Billions of dollars) (lover n ment Persons Expenditures Net receipts Surplus or PerLess: Less: Equals: deficit Personal sonal TransPurTransEquals: saving Tax and fers, confers, chases national Total Equals: Total or nontax mterof interexcluding sumption income expendiNet disreceipts interest expendigoods and tures saving or receipts tures paid and and and and product accruals transfers serv- accounts subsisubsi3 3 ices dies dies Disposable personal income Year or quarter Total1 Less: Interest paid and transfers 2 1929 . 82.4 1.9 80.5 77.3 1933 45.6 .7 44.9 45.8 3.3 -.9 11.3 1.5 9.8 10.3 1.5 8.8 1.0 9.3 2.5 6.9 10.7 2.5 8.2 -1.4 -2.2 1939. ... 70.0 .9 69.2 67.0 2.2 15.4 4.1 11.3 17.6 4.1 13.5 1940.. 1941 194? 1943. 1944 1945.. 1946 1947 1948 1949 .. 75.3 92.2 116.6 133.0 145.6 149.1 1589 168.7 188.0 187.9 1.0 1.1 .8 .7 .8 .9 1.4 1.7 2.1 2.3 74.4 91.1 115.8 132.3 144.8 148.2 157,5 167.0 185.9 185.6 71.0 80.8 88.6 99.4 108.2 119.5 143.8 161.7 174.7 178.1 3.4 4.3 3.8 4.2 4.4 6.0 9.9 18.0 17.1 18.5 20.9 13.5 21.2 28.4 44.7 45.2 43.3 33.0 39.9 40.4 35.0 18.4 28.8 64.0 93.3 103.0 92.7 45.6 42.5 50.5 59.3 4.3 3.8 4.2 4.4 6.0 9.9 7.5 17.7 25.0 32.6 49.2 51.2 53.2 51.0 56.9 58.9 55.9 18.0 17.1 18.5 20.9 14.2 24.9 59.8 88.9 97.0 82.8 27.5 25.5 32.0 38.4 206.6 226.0 237.7 252.2 257.1 275.0 292.9 308.6 319.0 338.4 2.7 2.9 3.3 4.0 4.3 4.8 5.6 5.9 6.0 6.5 203.9 223.1 234.5 248.2 252.8 270.1 287.3 302.7 313.0 331.9 192.0 207.1 217.1 229.7 235.8 253.7 266.0 280.4 289.5 310.8 11.9 16.1 17.4 18.5 17.0 16.4 21.3 22.3 23.6 21.1 69.0 85.2 90.1 94.6 89.9 101.1 109.7 116.2 115.0 129,4 22.5 19.1 18.3 19.0 21.3 23.0 25.1 28.2 32.6 33.4 46.5 66.2 71.8 75.6 68.6 78.1 84.6 88.0 82.4 96.0 61.0 79.2 93.9 101.6 97.0 98.0 104.5 115.3 127.6 131.0 22.5 19.1 18.3 19.0 21.3 23.0 25.1 28.2 32.6 33.4 38.5 60.1 75.6 82.5 75.8 75.0 79.4 87.1 95.0 97.6 352.0 365.8 386.8 405.9 440.6 475.8 513.7 547.9 593.4 638.9 7.4 7.7 8.3 9.4 10.5 11.7 12.6 13.3 14.6 16.6 344.6 358.0 378.5 396.5 430.1 464.0 501.1 534.5 578.8 622.4 324.9 335.0 355.2 374.6 400.5 430.4 465.1 490.3 536.9 581.8 19.7 23.0 23.3 21.9 29.6 33.7 36.0 44.3 41.9 40.6 139.5 144.8 156.7 168.5 174.0 188.3 212.3 228.2 263.1 296.7 36.1 40.9 42.4 44.1 46.5 49.5 54.9 62.2 70.1 78.0 103.4 103.9 114.3 124.4 127.5 138.9 157.4 166.0 193.0 218.7 136.4 149.1 160.5 167.8 176.3 187.8 213.6 242.4 269.1 286.8 36.1 40.9 42.4 44.1 46.5 49.5 54.9 62.2 70.1 78.0 100.3 108.2 118.0 123.7 129.8 138.4 158.7 180.2 199.0 208.8 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 .. 1976 1977 1978 1979 695.3 751.8 810.3 914.5 998 3 1,096.1 1,194.4 1,311.5 1,462.9 1,641.7 17.8 18.9 20.7 23.6 25 1 25.3 27.6 32.0 37.9 44.6 677.5 732.9 789.7 890.9 973 2 l,070J 1,166.8 1,279.6 1,425.1 1,597.1 621.7 672.2 737.1 812.0 888 1 97M 55.8 60.7 52.6 79.0 85 1 943 1,084.3 1,205.5 1,348.7 1,510.9 82.5 74.1 76.3 86.2 302.8 322.6 368.3 413.1 455 2 470:5 538.4 605.7 681.6 765.2 93.3 107.1 118.5 134.8 155 9 194^ 212.8 229.5 249.3 279.5 209.6 215.4 249.8 278.3 299 3 2761 325.6 376.1 432.4 485.7 313.4 342.0 371.6 405.3 460 0 5343 574.9 624.0 681.9 753.2 93.3 107.1 118.5 134.8 155 9 19^4 212.8 229.5 249.3 279.5 220.1 234.9 253.1 270.4 304 1 339^ 362.1 394.5 432.6 473.8 1980 " 1,821.8 47.5 1,774.3 1,670.1 104.2 834.2 334.2 500.0 869.0 334.2 534.8 1950.. 1951 1952.. 1953. 1954, 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 .. .. ... .. .... 1960 1961 1962.... 1963.. . . 1964 1965... . 1966 1967 1968 ... 1969 10.3 27.2 32.9 36.6 28.7 13.7 5.2 11.1 See next page for continuation of table. 242 -.7 -3.8 =31.4 -44.1 = 51.8 -39.5 5.4 14.4 8.4 -3.4 8.0 6.1 -3.8 -6.9 -7.1 3.1 5.2 .9 -12.6 -1.6 3.1 -4.3 -3.8 .7 -2.3 .5 -1.3 -14.2 -6.0 9.9 -10.6 -19.4 -3.3 7.8 47 -618 -36.5 = 18.3 -.2 11.9 -34.8 TABLE B-8.—Gross national product: Receipts and expenditures by major economic groups, 1929- 80—Continued [Billions of dollars] International Business Year or quarter Gross retained earnings4 uross private domestic investment5 Excess of Net transearnings fers and or of interest investpaid to foreignment ers® (-) Net exports of goods and services Excess Total of net income transfers or and Equals: interest receipts or of Net Less: Exports Imports exnet ports exports (-)7 . Statistical discrepancy Gross national product or expenditure 103.4 11.6 16.2 -4.6 0.4 7.0 5.9 1.1 -0.8 102.3 1.1 3.1 1.4 1.7 .2 2.4 2.0 .4 -.2 55.1 .7 55.8 8.8 9.3 -.4 .2 4.6 3.4 1.2 -1.0 89.5 1.4 90.9 10.8 12.1 14.8 16.7 17.6 16.b 15.9 22.1 30.2 31.5 13.1 17.9 -2.3 -5.8 5.4 3.6 4.9 10.9 10.5 1.8 1.5 .2 -1.5 -1.3" 9.9 5.8 7.2 -147 -11.9 -15.6 -3.8 98.9 124.5 159.3 193.9 207.9 208.3 209.3 231.5 261.1 257.8 1.1 .6 -.8 10.6 30.7 34.0 45.9 35.3 .2 .2 .2 .2 .3 .8 2.9 2.6 4.5 5.6 100.0 125.0 158.5 192.1 210.6 212.4 209.8 233.1 259.5 258.3 30.7 34.8 37.4 38.2 41.1 47.9 49.4 52.0 51.7 58.7 53.8 59.2 52.1 53.3 52.7 68.4 71.0 69.2 61.9 78.1 -23.1 -24.4 -14.7 -15.1 -11.6 -20.5 -21.6 -17.2 -10.2 -19.4 4.0 3.5 2.6 2.5 2.3 2.5 2.5 2.5 58.3 60.0 67.2 71.0 76.7 86.0 92.7 95.6 100.0 103.0 75.9 74.8 85.4 90.9 97.4 113.5 125.7 122.8 133.3 149.3 -17.6 -14.8 -18.3 -19.9 -20.6 -27.5 -33.0 -27.2 -33.3 -46.2 2.6 2.8 3.0 3.2 3.2 3.3 3.5 3.7 1970 _ 1971. . . 1972 1973 1974. 1975 1976. 1977 1978 . 1979 102.8 119.7 136.6 148.7 149.4 188.4 211.9 248.3 279.1 312.7 144.2 166.4 195.0 229.8 228.7 206.1 257.9 322.3 375.3 415.8 -41.4 -46.7 -58.4 -81.1 -79.2 -17.7 -46.0 -74.0 -96.3 -103.1 4.3 5.5 6.5 7.7 8.5 8.5 1980" . . . . 333.4 395.1 -61.6 1929 1933.... 1939 .... 1940... 1941 1942 1943 .. 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949. . .. ... .. . . 1950 1951 . . .. 1952 . . 1953 . . 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 ' ...." 1959. 1960 1961. 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 . . .. . . . . .. 5.4 6.1 5.0 4.6 5.5 7.4 15.1 20.2 17.5 16.3 4.7 4.8 6.5 7.2 7.9 7.3 8.3 -1.9 -1.7 -.5 7.8 11.9 .1 2.1 2.0 1.3 -4.9 -9.3 -2.4 9.8 6.9 6.5 14.4 19.7 19.1 18.0 18.7 21.0 25.0 28.1 24.2 24.8 12.2 15.3 15.9 16.7 16.2 18.0 19.8 20.8 21.0 23.4 2.2 4.4 3.2 1.3 2.5 3.0 5.3 7.3 3.3 1.4 28.9 29.9 31.8 34.2 38.8 41.1 44.6 47.3 52.4 57.5 23.4 23.3 25.4 26.6 28.8 32.3 38.1 41.0 48.1 53.3 5.5 6.6 6.4 7.6 13.2 16.2 65.7 68.8 77.5 109.6 146.2 154.9 170.9 183.3 219.8 281.3 59.0 64.7 76.7 95.4 132.8 128.1 157.1 187.5 220.4 267.9 14.2 13.4 26.8 13.8 -4.2 -.6 13.4 -6.5 -4.9 -18.3 -5.1 13.9 13.8 18.0 341.2 313.6 27.5 2.4 2.6 3.7 3.8 8.7 9.6 1 2 3 10.5 -.9 1.8 -.9 -.6 1.3 -.2 -.4 -1.8 2.7 4.1 .5 1.5 -1.6 .6 1.3 3.2 1.7 2.3 2.0 1.3 -.9 1.2 285.2 327.6 346.2 364.5 364.8 398.7 423.8 445.2 449.5 489.2 4.3 4.2 -2.8 -3.8 -3.4 -4.4 -6.8 -5.4 -3.0 -2.6 —6 -•4 508.9 524.7 562.9 595.0 637.6 692.3 754.6 799.8 875.5 947.9 6.7 4.1 -2.3 1.4 5.8 2.8 994.2 1,073.5 1,182.6 1,325.6 1,430.5 1,543.7 1,712.9 1,913.6 2,149.7 2,411.7 -1.5 .7 6.4 2.2 992.7 1,077.6 1,185.9 1.326.4 1,434.2 1,549.2 1,718.0 1,918.0 2,156.1 2,413.9 -9.5 2,625.7 1.7 2,627.4 10.1 8.8 6.5 6.3 -2.8 -4.8 -2.1 -1.2 .2 -1.3 -2.4 __ j 2il 1.7 .1 -1.2 1.4 -.3 -2.1 -3.9 4.1 3.3 .8 3.7 5.5 5.1 4.4 286.5 330.8 348.0 366.8 366.8 400.0 421.7 444.0 449.7 487.9 506.5 524.6 565.0 596.7 637.7 691.1 756.0 799.6 873.4 944.0 Personal income less personal tax and nontax payments (fines, penalties, etc.). Interest paid by consumers to business and net personal transfer payments to foreigners. Government transfer payments to persons and foreigners, net interest paid by government less dividends received by State and4 local government, subsidies less current surplus of government enterprises, and disbursements less wage accruals. Undistributed corporate profits with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments, corporate and noncorporate capital consumption allowances with capital consumption adjustment, and private wage accruals less disbursements. 5 See Table B-14. 8 Net transfers to foreigners by persons and government and interest paid by government to foreigners. 7 Capital grants received by the United States (net) less net foreign investment. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 243 TABLE B-9.—Gross national product by sector, 1929-80 [Billions of dollars, except as noted; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Gross domestic product Government2 Business Year or quarter Gross national product Total Total nofi- Farm farm1 Households static tiral and iicai discrepancy institutions Total Federal State and local Percent change from Pact KcSI precedof the ing world period, gross domestic product3 103.4 102.6 95.4 84.7 9.7 1.1 2.9 4.3 0.9 3.5 0.8 55.8 55.5 49.1 43.8 4.6 .7 1.7 4.7 1.2 3.5 .3 1939 90.9 90.5 80.6 72.9 6.3 1.4 2.3 7.6 3.4 4.2 .5 7.0 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 100.0 125.0 158.5 192.1 210.6 212.4 209.8 233.1 259.5 258.3 99.6 124.5 157.9 191.6 210.1 212.0 209.0 231.8 257.9 256.9 89.4 112.6 139.9 162.8 174.2 172.8 183.8 210.0 234.9 231.5 81.8 103.1 127.7 149.3 156.2 152.7 164.4 188.2 213.1 212.2 6.4 8.9 13.0 15.3 15.3 16.0 18.8 20.2 23.3 18.8 1.1 .6 = .8 -1.8 2.7 4.1 .5 1.5 -1.6 .6 2.4 2.5 2.9 3.2 3.7 4.1 4.5 5.1 5.6 5.9 7.8 9.4 15.1 25.6 32.2 35.2 20.8 16.7 17.4 19.4 3.5 5.0 10.6 20.9 27.2 29.8 14.6 9.4 8.9 10.0 4.3 4.4 4.5 4.7 4.9 5.4 6.2 7.3 8.5 9.4 .4 .5 ,5 .5 .5 .4 .8 1.2 1.6 1.4 10.1 25.0 26.8 21.4 9.6 .9 -1.4 10.9 11.3 = .4 286.5 330.8 348.0 366.8 366.8 400.0 421.7 444.0 449.7 487.9 284.8 328.7 345.7 364.6 364.5 397.3 418.5 440.5 446.6 484.6 257.5 294.4 307.3 324.9 323.9 354.0 372.1 390.8 393.1 428.3 236.3 268.3 283.4 302.3 302.3 333.9 355.7 373.7 372.2 410.6 20.0 22.9 22.2 20.3 19.7 18.8 18.6 18.4 20.7 19.0 1.3 3.2 1.7 2.3 2.0 1.3 -2.1 -1.2 .2 -1.3 6.4 6.9 7.2 7.8 8.1 9.1 9.8 10.5 11.4 12.3 20.9 27.4 31.2 31.9 32.5 34.2 36.6 39.1 42.1 44.0 10,7 16.2 18.9 18.6 17.8 18.4 19.0 19.6 20.5 20.9 10.1 11.2 12.3 13.3 14.7 15.8 17.6 19.6 21.6 23.1 1.6 2.1 2.3 2.2 2.3 2.8 3.2 3.5 3.0 3.3 10.9 15.4 5.2 5.5 -.0 9.0 5.3 5.2 1.4 8.5 506.5 524.6 565.0 596.7 637.7 691.1 756.0 799.6 873.4 944.0 502.9 520.7 560.5 591.8 632.3 685.2 750.3 793.7 866.7 937.1 442.0 455.7 490.6 517.2 551.6 598.4 652.6 685.1 745.4 803.2 424.2 435.7 468.1 495.0 532.2 577.7 628.4 663.3 725.0 782.1 20.2 20.2 20.4 20.5 19.3 21.9 22.8 22.1 22.6 25.1 ^2.4 = .1 2.1 1.7 .1 -1.2 1.4 -.3 -=2.1 -3.9 13.8 14.4 15.5 16.6 17.8 19.2 21.1 23.4 26.1 29.4 47.1 50.5 54.3 58.0 62.9 67.6 76.5 85.1 95.2 104.5 21.7 22.6 24.1 25.2 27.0 28.3 32.4 35.6 39.3 41.9 25.5 27.9 30.2 32.9 35.9 39.3 44.1 49.5 55.9 62.6 3.6 3.9 4.6 4.9 5.5 5.9 5.6 5.9 6.7 6.9 3.8 3.5 7.7 5.6 6.8 8.4 9.5 5.8 9.2 8.1 992.7 1,077.6 1,185.9 1,326.4 1,434.2 1,549.2 1,718.0 1,918.0 2,156.1 2,413.9 985.4 1,068.5 1,175.0 1,310.4 1,414.4 1,531.9 1,697.5 1,894.5 2,126.2 2,370.1 837.3 907.1 998.6 1,118.7 1,206.4 1,301.7 1,447.3 1,623.1 1,829.4 2,046.3 813.1 875.4 963.4 1,068.0 1,155.0 1,247.3 1,396.3 1,571.1 1,765.1 1,974.1 25.8 27.6 31.9 49.9 47.7 48.9 45.9 47.6 57.9 70.0 -1.5 4.1 3.3 .8 3.7 5.5 5.1 4.4 6.4 2.2 32.3 35.4 38.6 42.1 45.8 50,6 55.6 61.0 67.5 75.7 115.8 126.0 137.8 149.6 162.2 179.6 194.6 210.4 229.2 248.1 44.8 46.8 50.1 51.9 54.9 59.0 62.4 66.3 71.7 75.8 71.1 79.3 87.7 97.7 107.3 120.6 132.3 144.0 157.5 172.3 7.3 9.2 10.9 16.0 19.8 17.3 20.5 23.5 29.9 43.8 5.2 8.4 10.0 11.5 7.9 8.3 10.8 11.6 12.2 11.5 2,627.4 2,577.3 2,222.2 2,152.4 68.0 1.7 85.9 269.3 81.9 187.4 50.1 8.7 2 032 4 2,129.6 2,190.5 2,271.9 2 004 2 2,103.2 2,161.0 2,236.2 1 715 9 1,810.4 1,862.2 1,929.2 1663 6 1J4&6 1,793.0 1,857.2 52 9 564 59.1 63.3 10.0 8.7 65 4 66*6 68.1 70.0 222 9 226^3 230.6 237.1 70 2 70^9 71.5 74.4 152 7 155^5 159.1 162.7 28 2 2&3 29.5 35.7 8 1 2U 11.4 14.7 2,340.6 2,374.6 2,444.1 2,496.3 2,301.0 2,333.7 2,396.0 2,449.7 1,987.3 2,014.2 2,069.8 2,113.9 1,913.5 1,942.9 1,996.5 2,043.6 68.0 70.6 70.4 71.0 5.8 .7 2.8 -.7 72.3 74.2 76.9 79.4 241.4 245.4 249.4 256.4 74.6 74.6 74.9 79.0 166.8 170.8 174.5 177.3 39.6 40.9 48.1 46.6. 12.1 5.8 11.1 9.3 2,571.7 2,564.8 2,637.3 2,520.2 2,516.7 2,586.9 2,176,9 2,166.4 2,230.0 2,106.4 2,100.8 2,159.1 67.7 67.5 67.9 2.8 -1.9 3.0 82.1 84.4 86.9 261.2 265.9 269.9 79.6 80.5 80.7 181.6 185.4 189.3 51.5 48.1 50.5 12.0 = .6 11.6 1929 1933 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 . . . . .. . .. . ... . . .. . . .... 1960 1961 . . 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 .. 1967 .. . . 1968. . 1969 .. . 1970 . 1971 1972.... 1973 1974 . . . 1975 . . 1976 .... 1977 . . . . 1978 1979 1980 p 1978: | II III IV 1979: 1 II Ill IV 1980. I II Ill . . 1 -4.1 Includes compensation of employees in government enterprises. Compensation of government employees. Changes are based on unrounded data and therefore may differ slightly from those obtained from data shown here. See Table B - l for percent changes in gross national product. 2 3 Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 244 TABLE B-10.—Gross national product by sector in 1972 dollars, 1929-80 [Billions of 1972 dollars, except as noted; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Gross domestic product Percent Government2 Business Year or quarter Gross national product Total Total Nonfarm 1 farm Statistical discrepancy Households and institutions Total Federal State and local Rest, of the world from preceding period, gross domestic product3 1929 315.7 313.2 271.5 244.7 23.6 3.1 15.6 26.2 5.2 21.0 2.4 1933 222.1 220.9 180.0 152.5 24.9 2.6 12.2 28.8 6.6 22.1 1.3 -2.1 1939 319.8 318.2 261.0 231.3 25.2 4.6 15.1 42.1 16.9 25.2 1.6 7.8 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 344.1 400.4 461.7 531.6 569.1 560.4 478.3 470.3 489 8 492.2 342.8 398.7 460.1 530.3 567.7 559.3 476.4 467.8 486.8 489.4 282.7 327.6 361.8 385.6 403.6 397.9 385.5 393.8 412.0 409.8 254.6 299.8 335.3 362.1 370.1 362.8 358.6 367.0 389.0 383.4 24.5 26.2 28.6 27.7 27.1 25.6 25.8 24.0 25.8 25.6 3.6 1.6 -2.1 -4.2 6.4 9.4 1.1 2.9 -2.8 .8 16.1 15.9 16.4 15.2 15.1 15.0 15.1 16.0 16.7 17.3 44.0 55.2 81.9 129.4 149.1 146.4 75.9 58.0 58.1 62.3 18.6 29.6 56.7 105.0 125.2 121.8 49.7 29.8 29.2 31.3 25.4 25.6 25.2 24.5 23.9 24.6 26.2 28.2 29.0 31.0 1.4 1.7 1.5 1.3 1.4 1.1 1.8 2.5 3.0 2.7 7.7 16.3 15.4 15.2 7.1 -1.5 -14.8 -1.8 4.1 .5 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 534.8 579.4 600.8 623.6 616.1 657.5 671.6 683.8 680.9 721.7 531.8 575.6 596.9 619.8 612.1 653.0 666.5 678.3 676.3 716.8 448.7 478.0 492.8 515.6 508.5 547.0 557.4 566.1 561.7 600.0 419.4 447.2 463.7 484.3 477.0 516.0 531.5 539.5 532.0 574.0 27.0 25.8 26.4 27.7 28.4 29.3 28.9 28.2 29.3 27.8 2.4 5.0 2.6 3.6 3.1 1.8 -3.0 -1.7 18.3 18.7 18.6 19.3 19.4 21.4 22.5 23.1 24.2 24.7 64.7 79.0 85.5 85.0 84.1 84.6 86.7 89.1 90.4 92.2 32.7 46.2 51.6 49.6 47.2 45.9 45.6 45.8 44.5 44.5 32.0 32.8 33.9 35.4 36.9 38.6 41.0 43.3 45.9 47.7 3.0 3.7 3.9 3.7 4.0 4.5 5.1 5.5 4.6 4.9 8.7 8.3 3.7 3.8 -1.2 6.7 2.1 1.8 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 737 2 756.6 800.3 832.5 876.4 929.3 984.8 1011.4 1,058.1 1,087.6 732 0 751.0 793.8 825.6 868.9 921.4 977.5 1,003.9 1,050.0 1,079.7 610.1 625.1 663.2 691.6 730.3 777.7 824.0 842.0 882.1 907.1 584.2 596.3 631.5 659.7 701.3 749.6 794.1 812.8 855.6 881.9 29.2 28.9 28.8 29.6 28.8 29.8 28.2 29.5 29.0 29.5 -3.3 -.2 2.9 2.3 26.6 27.0 28.1 28.9 29.8 30.9 32.6 34.3 35.4 37.0 95.3 98.9 102.5 105.2 108.8 112.7 120.8 127.7 132.4 135.7 45.2 46.2 48.3 48.2 48.5 48.7 53.0 57.2 58.0 58.2 50.1 52.7 54.3 57.0 60.4 64.0 67.9 70.5 74.4 77.4 5.2 5.7 6.5 6.9 7.5 7.9 7.4 7.5 8.2 7.9 2.1 2.6 5.7 4.0 5.2 6.0 6.1 2.7 4.6 2.8 1,085.6 1,122.4 1,185.9 1 255.0 1,248.0 1,233.9 1,300.4 13717 1436 9 1,483.0 1,077.6 1,112.9 1,175.0 1,239.9 1,230.7 1,220.0 1,284.8 1354 7 1416 8 1,455.9 904.8 938.6 998.6 1,061.4 1,049.1 1,034.7 1,097.6 1,165.1 1222 6 1,'258.3 875.4 901.7 963.4 1,029.1 1,014.1 996.7 1,061.6 1,1289 1185 5 1,222.1 31.1 32.6 31.9 31.6 31.8 33.6 32.1 33.0 32 9 34.9 -1.7 4.2 3.3 3.2 4.4 3.9 3.2 42 1.4 36.7 37.6 38.6 39.4 39.3 40.5 40.9 41.3 42 3 43.7 136.1 136.7 137.8 139.1 142.3 144.9 146.3 148.4 1519 153.9 55.2 52.5 50.1 48.2 48.5 48.4 48.5 48.6 49.3 49.0 80.9 84.2 87.7 90.8 93.8 96.5 97.8 99 7 102 6 104.9 8.0 9.5 10.9 15.1 17.3 13.9 15.6 16.9 20 1 27.2 -.2 3.3 5.6 5.5 -.7 — 9 5!3 5.4 4.6 2.8 1,480.7 1,452.1 1,251.6 1,215.4 35.2 1.0 45.3 155.2 49.2 106.0 28.6 -.3 1,402.3 1432 8 1,446.7 1,465.8 1,382.7 1414 9 1,427.0 1,442.6 1,189.4 1,221.0 1,232.4 1,247.6 1,156.3 1,184 5 1,192.7 1,208.7 33.5 315 33.0 33.4 -.4 4.9 6.6 5.6 42.2 42 2 42.3 42.6 151.0 151.8 152.3 152.3 49.0 49.3 49.5 49.2 102.0 102.5 102.8 103.1 19.6 17.9 19.7 23.2 2.2 9.7 3.4 4.4 1479 9 1,473.4 1,488.2 1,490.6 1,454 6 1,447.8 1,458.6 1,462.4 1,258.8 1,250.8 1,260.0 1,263.6 1,221 8 1,215.0 1,223.2 1,228.2 33.3 35.3 35.1 35.8 3.7 1.7 42.9 43.3 44.2 44.4 152.9 153.7 154.4 154.5 49.1 49.0 49.0 48.9 103.8 104.7 105.3 105.6 25.3 25.6 29.6 28.1 3.4 -1.9 3.0 1.0 1,501.9 1463 3 1,471.9 1,471.5 1435 5 1,443.4 1,271.9 1235 2 U42.3 1,233.3 1,198 5 1,207.6 37.0 37 8 33.1 1.6 -1.1 1.7 44.8 44 9 45.6 154.8 1554 155.5 49.0 49 4 49.4 105.8 105 9 106.1 30.4 27 8 28.5 2.5 -9.4 2.2 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980". . . . ... . -L9 -l!6 1.7 -2.5 -4.4 1978: || III IV 1979: II III IV 1980: II III 1 Includes compensation of employees in government enterprises. Compensation of government employees. Changes are based on unrounded data and therefore may differ slightly from those obtained from data shown here. See Table B-2 for percent changes in gross national product in 1972 dollars. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 2 3 245 T A B L E B - l l . — G r o s s domestic product of nonfinanciaI corporate business, 1929-80 [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Net domestic product Year or quarter Capital Gross domes- consumptic tion product allowof ances with nonfinancial capital corpo- consumprate tion busiadjustness ment Domestic income Total Indirect business tax, etc. 1 Corporate profits with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments Total CompenProfits sation of Profits after tax Prof- Profemploy- Total its its ees tax beUndisfore lia- Total Divi- tributed dends tax bility profits Inventory valuation adjustment Net consumption adjustment interest 1929 50.1 5.5 44.5 3.4 41.2 32.3 7.5 8.4 1.2 7.3 5.1 2.2 0.5 -1.4 1.4 1933 24.4 4.3 20.2 3.8 16.3 16.7 =2.1 .6 .5 .1 2.0 -1.9 =2.1 -.6 1,7 1939 43.7 4.8 39.0 5.1 33.9 28.2 4.2 6.1 1.4 4.7 3.3 1.4 =.7 -1.1 1.5 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 50.4 65.6 82.9 98.7 102.1 95.3 99.3 120.0 137.3 133.5 4.9 5.4 6.1 6.2 6.3 6.5 7.6 9.3 5.5 6.4 6.8 7.3 8.1 8.9 31.2 7.4 39.8 12.7 51.0 17.7 62.2 21.8 65.1 21.6 61.9 17.1 67.2 13.8 79.1 19.7 87.8 25.6 85.3 22.9 2.7 7.5 6.1 9.0 8.9 9.8 9.6 7.6 3.5 3.9 3.7 3.9 4.1 4.1 4.8 5.5 6.0 6.0 2.6 5.0 5.2 5.8 5.6 3.5 8.6 -.2 -2.5 -1.2 -1.2 -1.3 -1.2 -.8 -.9 10.1 11.2 12.1 12.6 40.0 53.8 70.0 85.2 87.7 79.9 81.6 99.6 114.3 109.2 8.8 10.9 11.7 45.4 60.2 76.8 92.4 95.8 88.8 91.8 110.7 126.4 121.8 =3.5 -4.0 -3.9 1.4 1.3 1.3 1.1 1.0 1.0 .7 .8 .9 1.0 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 151.9 174.5 182.3 195.0 191.9 216.7 231.6 242.3 236.3 266.0 12.6 14.6 15.8 16.8 17.9 19.1 21.8 23.8 24.8 25.8 139.3 159.9 166.6 178.2 174.0 197.6 209.8 218.5 211.6 240.2 14.1 15.2 16.8 18.2 17.4 19.2 20.8 22.4 22.8 25.4 125.2 144.7 149.7 160.0 156.6 178.4 189.0 196.1 188.8 214.8 94.7 110.2 118.3 128.7 126.5 138.5 151.4 159.1 155.9 171.6 29.6 33.4 30.2 30.0 28.6 38.3 35.9 34.9 30.2 40.1 21.6 17.9 16.0 16.4 16.4 21.8 21.8 20.7 17.5 22.4 10.0 12.4 -3.9 -4.6 -4.5 = 3.9 = 3.2 = 2.0 = 3.2 =3.4 =3.2 =2.7 .9 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.5 1.6 1.7 2.2 2.7 3.1 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 277.0 285.0 311.3 331.8 358.4 393.6 431.5 454.1 500.2 544.1 26.8 27.5 28.4 29.4 30.8 32.7 35.6 38.9 42.6 47.1 250.2 257.5 283.0 302.3 327.6 360.9 395.9 415.2 457.6 497.0 28.3 30.1 33.0 35.6 38.4 41.1 42.9 45.8 51.5 58.0 221,9 227.3 249.9 266.8 289.3 319.8 353.0 369.5 406.1 439.1 181.1 185.1 199.8 210.7 226.3 246.1 273.5 291.9 322.8 358.5 37.4 39.7 19.2 20.5 38.3 39.5 19.5 20.1 45.6 44.2 20.6 23.5 51.2 48.9 22.8 26.2 57.7 55.4 24.0 31.4 67.7 65.2 27.2 38.0 72.2 70.3 29.5 40.8 68.8 66.3 27.7 38.6 73.3 72.9 33.4 39.5 67.5 69.4 33.1 36.2 10.6 10.6 11.4 12.6 13.7 15.6 16.8 17.5 19.1 19.1 12.2 13.5 17.7 22.4 24.0 21.2 20.4 17.1 -2.1 -1.6 -3.7 -5.9 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 563.7 609.9 678.0 759.4 818.9 890.0 1,001.3 1,129.5 1,270.7 1,417.0 52.2 511.4 63.4 448.1 57.3 552.6 70.5 482.1 62.6 615,5 76.7 538.7 67.9 691.6 83.7 607.9 79.5 739.4 89.7 649.7 94.9 795.1 97.1 697.9 104.8 896.5 105.3 791.2 116.6 1,012.8 115.1 897.8 129.7 1,141.0 125.2 1,015.8 147.5 1,269.5 133.6 1,135.9 378.4 402.0 447.0 506.2 556.5 581.1 654.4 738.2 841.4 954.0 29.8 35.6 43.0 56.0 63.3 66.1 82.3 94.1 107.0 123.7 18.5 18.5 20.1 21.1 21.4 25.7 30.1 31.9 36.0 37.3 11.3 17.1 22.9 35.0 41.9 40.4 52.2 62.2 70.9 86.3 -6.6 -4.6 -6.6 -20.0 =40.0 -11.6 -14.7 -15.8 -24.3 -42.6 -1.8 -9.7 = 13.0 = 11.4 -12.4 = 14.1 29.6 30.8 29.5 33.2 36.8 45.2 1,533.9 166.2 1,367.7 152.1 1,215.7 1,036.8 122.8 179.5 61.3 118.2 40.3 77.9 -42.0 = 14.7 56.1 1,196.3 1,260.1 1,289.9 1,336.5 124.0 127.3 131.6 135.7 1,072.3 1,132.9 1,158.3 1,200.7 121.3 951.0 125.5 1,007.3 125.5 1,032.9 128.6 1,072.1 797.2 830.2 853.4 884.7 118.5 141.1 142.3 148.6 150.6 175.5 178.6 192.6 56.9 93.7 68.1 107.4 69.0 109.6 75.3 117.2 34.8 33.2 37.5 38.6 58.9 74.1 72.1 78.6 -21.6 -23.2 = 22.6 -29.8 -10.5 -11.2 -13.6 = 14.2 35.3 36.0 37.1 38.9 1,378.7 1,399.5 1,432.1 1,457.7 140.5 146.0 150.7 152.9 1,238.2 1,253.5 1,281.5 1,304.8 130.9 131.5 134.8 137.3 919.9 939.8 965.2 991.1 146.0 138.6 134.8 127.3 195.7 191.4 195.5 191.1 71.2 68.9 70.5 68.4 124.5 122.5 125.0 122.7 38.2 37.9 34.9 38.2 86.3 84.5 90.1 84.5 -35.3 -37.9 -46.5 -50.8 = 14.4 -14.8 -14.2 = 13.0 41.4 43.5 46.7 49.1 1,502.1 1,496.3 1,537.7 158.2 1,343.9 141.7 1,202.3 1,017.3 132.6 207.2 74.3 132.9 163.6 1,332.7 147.7 1,185.0 1,018.0 112.5 158.6 52.0 106.6 168.6 1,369.1 155.4 1,213.6 1,034.8 121.2 177.9 60.3 117.6 36.9 41.1 40.8 96.0 65.5 76.8 -61.4 -31.1 -41.7 = 13.1 -14.9 = 15.0 52.3 54.4 57.6 1980 P. 52.7 62.1 72.7 78.6 63.6 86.1 107.3 126.3 137.6 136.7 16.4 20.1 23.6 22.2 17.8 22.0 29.1 31.8 24.9 38.5 39.1 33.8 34.9 32.1 42.0 41.8 39.8 33.7 43.1 56.8 65.4 76.6 96.0 105.3 107.3 135.0 153.5 174.3 193.4 11.2 13.8 12.6 10.2 8.6 13.4 10.8 18.3 11.8 20.0 9.3 15.6 16.9 21.2 17.8 18.5 15.6 20.2 20.1 19.1 16.2 20.7 27.0 29.8 33.6 40.0 42.0 41.2 52.6 59.4 67.3 69.7 7.5 7.1 7.1 7.3 7.4 8.5 9.0 9.3 9.3 12.8 14.0 — 3 —6 = 5^3 -5.9 = 2.2 9.6 1.9 14.1 10.8 = 5.0 -1.2 8.8 9.1 9.0 1.0 13.4 12.7 11.4 8.2 9.9 9.5 -1.0 -.3 -1.7 -=2.7 = 1.5 = .3 = .3 - 2 '.3 .0 .1 — 5 -\2 2 -3d 3.5 3.9 1.4 4.5 2.3 4.8 2.9 5.3 3.7 6.1 3.9 7.4 4.0 8.7 4.0 10.1 4.0 13.1 = 2.1 -1.5 2.4 17.0 1.3 18.0 2.7 19.1 2.6 23.0 1978: I II Ill IV 1979: | ii...; in tv 1980: 1 II Ill 1,107.3 1,122.0 1,146.7 1,167.5 1 Indirect business tax and nontax liability plus business transfer payments less subsidies. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 246 TABLE B-12.—Output, costs, and profits of nonfinancial corporate business, 1948-80 [Quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Current-dollar cost and profit per unit of output (dollars)' Gross domestic nonfinancial corporate business (billions of dollars) Year or quarter Tota! cost and profit2 Current dollars 1972 dollars 137.3 133.5 229.7 219.9 0.598 .607 151.9 174 5 182.3 195 0 191.9 247.5 270.2 275.2 292.0 283.4 .614 646 .663 668 .677 216.7 2316 242.3 236.3 266.0 315.1 324.1 328.3 313.4 347.4 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 277.0 285.0 311.3 331.8 358.4 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 Capital consumption allowances with capital consumption adjustment Indirect business tax, etc. 3 Compensation Net of interest employees Corporate profits with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments Total Profits tax liability Profits after tax* 0.047 0.053 .053 .057 0.382 .388 0.004 .004 0.112 .104 0.051 .042 0.060 .062 .051 .054 .057 .058 .063 .057 056 .061 062 .061 .383 408 .430 .441 .446 .004 .004 .004 .004 .005 .120 124 .110 103 .101 .068 079 .065 .063 .055 .051 045 .045 040 .046 .688 715 .738 .754 .766 .061 .067 .073 .079 .074 .061 064 .068 .073 .073 .439 .467 .484 .497 .494 .005 .005 .007 .009 .009 .122 111 .106 .097 .116 .064 .062 .058 .052 .060 .057 049 .048 .045 .056 358.4 367.2 399.7 426.3 455.6 .773 .776 .779 .778 .787 .075 .075 .071 .069 .068 .079 .082 .083 .083 .084 .505 .504 .500 .494 .497 .010 .011 .011 .011 .012 .104 .104 .114 .120 .127 .054 .053 .052 .053 .053 .051 .051 .062 .067 .074 393 6 431.5 454.1 500 2 544.1 495.2 530.7 543.0 578.9 604.0 795 .813 .836 864 .901 .066 .067 .072 .074 .078 .083 .081 .084 .089 .096 .497 .515 .538 .558 .594 .012 .014 .016 .017 .022 .137 .136 .127 .127 .112 .055 .056 .051 .058 .055 082 .080 .076 .069 .057 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 563 7 609.9 678.0 759.4 818.9 599.6 626.8 678.0 731.9 708.2 940 .973 1000 1.038 1.156 .087 .091 .092 .093 .112 .106 .113 .113 .114 .127 .631 .641 .659 .692 .786 .028 .029 .028 .031 .042 .088 .099 .107 .107 .090 .045 .047 .049 .055 .059 043 .052 .058 .053 .030 1975 1976 1977 1978 890.0 10013 1,129.5 1,270.7 1,417.0 694.2 745.5 799.0 845.1 873.3 1.282 1.343 1.414 1.504 1.623 .137 .141 .146 .153 .169 .140 141 .144 .148 .153 .837 .878 .924 .996 1.092 .044 .040 .042 .044 .052 .124 .144 .158 .163 .157 .059 .071 .074 .080 .080 .065 073 .084 .083 .077 1,533.9 866.2 1.771 .192 .176 1.197 .065 .142 .071 .071 1,196.3 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952. 1953 1954 „ 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 nil ;..'i . . . 1979 '.ZZL1 1980 p ;. 1978: til IV 1,289.9 1,336.5 821.8 845.8 849.8 862.9 1.456 1.490 1.518 1.549 .151 .150 .155 .157 .148 .148 .148 .149 .970 .982 1.004 1.025 .043 .043 .044 .045 .144 .167 .168 .172 .069 .081 .081 .087 .075 .086 .086 .085 1979. 1 II Ill IV 1,378.7 1,399.5 1,432.1 1,457.7 874.7 870.8 874.3 873.4 1.576 1.607 1.638 1.669 .161 .168 .172 .175 .150 .151 .154 .157 1.052 1.079 1.104 1.135 .047 .050 .053 .056 .167 .159 .154 .146 .081 .079 • .081 .078 .086 .080 .074 .067 1,502.1 1496 3 1,537.7 878.2 853.2 860.4 1.710 1754 1.787 .180 .192 .196 .161 173 .181 1.158 1.193 1.203 .060 .064 .067 .151 .132 .141 .085 .061 .070 .066 .071 .071 1,260.1 ii...'.". .'...". ZZZ~"ZZ ""."ZZ 1980: ii ..' .7.711" Ill 1 Output is measured by gross domestic product of nonfinancial corporate business in 1972 dollars. 2 This is equal to the deflator for gross domestic product of nonfinancial corporate business with the decimal point shifted two places to the left. 3 Indirect business tax and nontax liability plus business transfer payments less subsidies. 4 With inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments. Source!: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 247 TABLE B-13.—Personal consumption expenditures, 1929-80 [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Year or quarter Services 1 Nondurable goods 1 Durable goods1 FurniPersonal conture Motor sumption vehicles and expendi- Total and household tures parts equipment Total Food Cloth- Gaso- Fuel line oil and and and coal shoes oil Household operation' Total Hous-2 ing Total Elec- Transportricity tation and gas 1929 77.3 9.2 3.3 4.7 37.7 19.5 9.4 1.8 1.6 30.3 11.7 4.0 1.2 1933 45.8 3.5 1.1 1.9 22.3 11.5 4.6 1.5 1.2 20.1 8.1 2.8 1.1 1.5 1939 67.0 6.7 2.3 3.4 35.1 19.1 7.1 2.2 1.4 25.2 9.4 3.8 1.4 2.0 1940 1941 1942 . 1943 1944 1945 . 1946 1947... 1948 1949 71.0 80.8 88.6 99.4 108.2 119.5 143.8 161.7 174.7 178.1 7.8 9.7 6.9 6.5 6.7 8.0 15.8 20.4 22.9 25.0 2.8 3.5 .7 .8 .8 1.0 4.1 6.6 8.0 10.6 3.8 4.8 4.6 3.9 3.8 4.5 8.4 10.6 11.5 11.3 37.0 42.9 50.8 58.6 64.3 71.9 82.7 90.9 96.6 94.9 20.2 23.4 28.4 33.2 36.7 40.6 47.4 52.3 54.2 52.5 8.8 11.0 13.4 14.6 16.5 18.2 18.8 20.1 19.3 7l5 2.3 2.6 2.1 1.3 1.4 1.8 3.4 4.0 4.8 5.3 1.5 1.7 1.9 2.0 2.0 2.2 2.5 3.0 3.4 3.1 26.2 28.2 31.0 34.3 37.1 39.6 45.3 50.4 55.3 58.2 9.7 10.4 11.2 11.8 12.3 12.8 14.2 16.0 17.9 19.6 4.0 4.3 4.8 5.2 5.9 6.4 6.8 7.5 8.1 8.5 1.5 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.8 1.9 2.1 2.3 2.6 2.9 2.1 2.4 2.7 3.4 3.7 4.0 5.0 5.3 5.8 5.9 1950 1951.. . . 1952. . . 1953 . .. 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 .. .. 192.0 207.1 217.1 229.7 235.8 253,7 266.0 280.4 289.5 310.8 30.0 29.8 29.1 32.5 31.8 38.6 37.9 39.3 36.8 42.4 13.7 12.2 11.3 13.9 13.0 17.8 15.8 17.2 14.8 18.9 13.7 14.0 14.0 14.6 14.6 16.2 17.1 16.9 16.6 17.8 98.2 108.8 113.9 116.5 118.0 122.9 128.9 135.2 139.8 146.4 53.9 60.4 63.4 64.4 65.4 67.2 69.9 73.6 76.4 79.1 19.6 21.2 21.9 22.1 22.1 23.1 24.1 24.3 24.7 26.1 5.5 6.1 6.8 7.4 7.8 8.6 9.4 10.2 10.6 11.3 3.4 3.5 3.4 3.4 3.5 3.8 3.9 4.1 4.2 4.0 63.0 68.5 74.0 80.6 86.1 92.1 99.2 105.9 112.8 121.9 21.7 24.3 27.0 29.8 32.2 34.3 36.7 39.3 42.0 45.0 9.5 10.4 11.1 12.0 12.6 14.0 15.2 16.2 17.3 18.5 3.3 3.7 4.1 4.5 5.0 5.5 6.1 6.5 7.1 7.6 6.2 6.7 7.1 7.8 7.9 8.2 8.6 9.0 9.3 10.1 1960 .... 1961... 1962 1963 .. . 1964.. 1965 . . 1966. 1967 1968 1969 . . 324.9 335.0 355.2 374.6 400.5 430 4 465.1 490.3 536.9 581.8 43.1 41.6 46.7 51.4 56.4 630 68.0 70.1 80.5 85.7 19.7 17.8 21.5 24.4 26.1 30 0 30.4 30.1 36.3 38.7 17.7 17.9 18.9 20.3 22.8 24 7 27.7 29.5 32.3 34.1 151.1 155.3 161.6 167.1 176.9 188 6 204.7 212.6 230.6 247.8 81.1 83.2 85.5 87.8 92.7 98 9 106.6 109.6 118.7 127.5 26.7 27.4 28.7 29.5 31.9 33 5 36.6 38.2 42.1 45.5 12.0 12.0 12.6 12.9 13.5 14 7 16.0 17.0 18.6 20.7 3.8 3.7 3.7 4.0 4.1 4.4 4.7 4.8 4.7 4.5 130.7 138.1 147.0 156.1 167.1 178 7 192.4 207,6 225.8 248.2 48.1 51.2 54.7 58.0 61.4 65.5 69.5 74.1 79.8 87.0 20.1 21.0 22.2 23.4 24.8 26 3 28.0 30.0 32.2 35.0 8.3 8.8 9.4 9.9 10.4 10.9 11.5 12.2 13.1 14.2 10.7 11.2 11.7 12.2 12.8 13.7 15.0 16.2 17.6 19.5 1970 1971. . 1972 .... 1973 1974 . ... 1975 1976. ... 1977 1978 1979 1980 p 621.7 672.2 737.1 812.0 888.1 976.4 1,084.3 1,205.5 1,348.7 1,510.9 1,670,1 85.2 97.2 111.1 123.3 121.5 132.2 156.8 178.8 199.3 212.3 210.2 36.2 45.4 52.4 57.1 50.4 55.8 72.6 85.0 94.3 95.5 89.0 35.2 37.2 41.7 47.1 50.6 53.5 59.1 65.8 72.9 81.1 84.1 265.7 278.8 300.6 333.4 373.4 407.3 441.7 479.0 529.8 602.2 674.4 138.9 144.2 154.9 172.1 193.7 213.6 230.6 250.3 276.4 312.1 46.8 50.6 55.4 61.4 64.8 69.6 75.3 82.1 91.9 98.9 22.4 23.9 25.4 28.6 36.6 40.4 44.0 48.2 52.7 68.4 270.8 296.2 325.3 355.2 393.2 437.0 485.7 547.7 619.6 696.3 345.0 104.7 89.0 4.4 4.5 5.0 6.2 7.7 8.2 9.8 10.6 11.7 16.0 20.0 785.5 93.9 37.7 102.7 41.0 112.5 45.2 123.8 49.6 137.4 55.2 149.8 63.3 166.5 71.6 186.8 80.8 213.1 89.5 241.9 98.7 272.4 111.7 15.4 17.0 18.8 20.5 24.0 29.2 32.9 38.2 42.4 47.3 55.8 22.0 25.1 27.5 28.8 30.9 33.2 38.6 45.3 51.0 57.2 64.1 1,278.3 1,330.1 1,369 9 1,416.6 185.0 200.1 202.0 210.2 86.8 96.4 95.5 98.5 68.2 72.2 73 9 77.3 504 0 520.4 536.3 558.3 2641 271.4 279.5 290.4 86 3 91.0 93.4 96.9 49 8 51.0 53.3 56.8 11.9 11.8 11.3 11.9 589 3 609.5 631.6 648.1 201.8 209.2 216.8 224.6 87 2 87.8 90.8 92.3 41.8 41.4 42.9 43.5 49.0 50.6 51.6 52.7 1,454.1 1,478.0 1,529.1 1,582.3 212.5 207.4 213.3 216.1 100.1 91.7 94.7 95.4 78.0 80.1 82.4 83.8 571.8 586.4 611.5 639.2 299.1 95.8 306.0 97.0 314.3 100.3 329.0 102.5 60.6 63.2 72.1 77.6 13.1 14.9 17.9 18.1 669.9 684.2 704.3 727.0 231.4 96.1 238.1 96.4 244.9 99.5 253.0 102.7 46.4 45.9 47.3 49.8 54.4 56.5 58.2 59.9 1,631.0 220.9 1,626.8 194.4 1,682.2 208.8 100.6 77.5 87.0 83.6 81.3 84.6 661.1 664.0 674.2 336.2 102.2 338.4 102.3 347.7 105.3 89.4 90.9 85.3 18.8 19.2 20.7 749.0 768.4 799.2 259.8 104.2 267.3 109.3 275.7 116.1 50.0 54.5 59.3 61.4 61.6 65.8 1978: || in"Z ZZ. IV 1979: H. ' " . . . ' Ill IV ... 1980: uZZZZZZZ. HI 1 Total includes "other" category, not shown separately. Includes imputed rental value of owner-occupied housing. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 2 248 2.6 TABLE B-14.—Gross private domestic investment, 1929-80 [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Fixed investment Change in htieinaec Gross private domestic investment Year or quarter Residential Nonresidential Total Total Structures Producers' durable equipment Total Nonfarm structures inventories ProFarm ducers' struc- durable tures equipment Total Nonfarm 1929 16.2 14.5 10.6 5.1 5.5 3.9 3.6 0.2 0.1 1.7 1.8 1933 1.4 3.0 2.4 1.0 1.4 .6 .5 .0 .0 -1.6 -1.4 1939 9.3 8.8 5.9 2.0 3.9 2.9 2.7 .1 .1 .4 .3 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 13.1 17.9 9.9 5.8 7.2 106 30.7 34.0 45.9 35.3 10.9 13.4 8.1 6.4 8.1 11.7 24.3 34.4 41.1 38.4 7.5 9.4 6.0 5.0 6.9 10.1 16.9 23.0 26.3 24.4 2.3 3.0 1.9 1.4 1.9 2.8 6.9 7.7 9.0 8.7 5.2 6.4 4.1 3.7 5.0 7.3 9.9 15.3 17.3 15.7 3.4 4.0 2.2 1.4 1.3 1.5 7.4 11.4 14.9 13.9 3.2 3.6 1.9 1.2 1.1 1.4 6.7 10.4 13.7 12.8 .2 .1 .1 2.2 4.5 1.8 -.6 -1.0 -1.0 6.4 *4J -3.1 1.9 4.0 .7 -.6 -.6 -6 6.4 1.3 3.0 22 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 53.8 59.2 52.1 53.3 52.7 68.4 710 69.2 619 78.1 47.0 48.9 49.0 52.9 54.3 62.4 66 3 67.9 63 4 72.5 27.3 31.3 31.3 34.5 34.2 38.5 440 47.0 42 0 45.9 9.5 11.4 11.6 12.9 13.4 14.6 17 7 18.4 17 2 17.6 17.8 19.9 19.7 21.5 20.8 23.9 26 3 28.6 24.9 28.3 19.8 17.6 17.7 18.4 20.1 23.9 22 3 20.9 214 26.6 18.6 16.4 16.5 17.3 19.0 22.8 212 19.7 20.3 25.3 6.8 10.3 3.1 .4 -1.5 6.0 47 1.3 -15 6.0 9.1 2.1 1.1 -2.1 5.5 51 .8 23 5.7 5.7 I960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 75.9 74.8 85.4 909 97.4 113 5 125.7 122.8 133.3 149.3 72.9 72.5 79.2 849 91.7 103.7 111.6 112.5 125.4 139.5 48.5 48.0 52.2 54.8 61.0 72.7 83.1 83.9 90.7 101.3 18.8 19.1 20.1 205 22.4 27 0 30.1 303 32.4 36.7 29.7 28.9 32.1 34.4 38.7 45.8 53.0 53.7 58.2 64.6 24.5 24.5 27.0 301 30.7 30 9 28.5 28 6 34.8 38.2 23.3 23.2 25.8 28.9 29.4 29 6 27.1 27 2 33.3 36.5 3.0 2.3 6.3 6.0 5.6 99 14.1 10 3 7.9 9.8 2.7 2.0 5.5 52 6.2 89 14.3 96 7.8 9.7 1970.... 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 . . . 1977. 1978 1979 144.2 166.4 195.0 229.8 228.7 206.1 257 9 322.3 375.3 415.8 141.0 158.8 184.8 211.3 214.5 213.0 2460 301.3 353.2 398.3 103.9 107.9 121.0 143.3 156.6 157.7 174.1 205.5 242.0 279.7 38.7 40.5 44.1 51.0 55.9 55.4 58 8 64.6 78.7 96.3 65.2 67,4 76.9 92.3 100.7 102.3 115 3 140.9 163.3 183.4 37.1 50.9 63.8 68.0 57.9 55.3 72 0 95.8 111.2 118.6 35.4 48.9 61.5 65.6 54.8 52.4 68 8 91.9 106.9 113.9 1980 p 395.1 399.0 295.0 108.1 186.9 104.0 350.7 377 7 380 4 392.6 325.8 350.7 3613 374.9 222.6 239.4 2471 258.7 70.3 77 3 85.7 152.3 1621 165 8 173.0 HI IV 408 3 423.2 421.7 410.0 384 0 390.1 408.3 410.8 267.3 272.9 288.5 290.2 87 3 93.2 99.6 105.1 1980: | || Ill 415.6 390.9 377.1 413.1 383.5 393.2 297.8 289.8 294.0 108.2 108.4 107.3 .... .2 .1 .0 .0 .0 .5 3 .9 .8 .8 .8 .8 .8 '.S .7 3 .4 .4 .4 .4 .4 .4 7 .7 '5 .6 .6 .5 .5 .6 j .6 j '7 .6 .7 .9 1.0 .6 1.3 1.0 1.1 1.5 1.8 1.8 1.1 1.3 1.5 1.7 1.8 1.9 21 2.3 2.6 2.9 3.1 3.2 6.4 7.7 9.6 10.2 15.2 18.5 16.0 14.1 -6.9 -10.5 13 9 118 20.2 21.0 21.8 22.2 13.4 17.5 99.1 1.9 3.0 -3.9 26 103.2 1113 114 2 116.2 98.9 107 4 109 6 111.6 2.0 1.8 1.4 2.4 25 24,9 27 0 1.9 2.7 17.7 24.6 26 7 18 6 17.2 179 9 179.7 189.0 185.1 116 7 117.2 119 8 120.6 112 5 112.9 114.9 115.4 16 1.6 2.0 2.3 27 2.8 2.9 3.0 24 3 33.1 13.3 -.8 20 8 29.2 7.8 -4.4 189.7 181.4 186.8 115.2 93.6 99.2 110.1 88.9 94.5 2.2 1.8 1.7 2.5 3.0 7.4 2.9 3.0 -16.0 1.5 6.1 12 3 .7 1978: It Ill IV 1979: 1 II 813 Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 249 26 191 TABLE B-15.—Inventories and final sales of business, 1946-80 [Billions of dollars, except as noted; seasonally adjusted] Inventories' Inventory—final sales ratio Nonfarm Year and quarter Total Fourth quarter: 1946 1947 1948 1949 Farm Total Manufacturing Wholesale trade Final sales 2 Retail trade Other Total Nonfarm3 72.0 82 6 87.2 78.7 22.7 251 22.9 19.8 49.3 57 5 64.3 59.0 267 29.3 32.5 28.9 10.1 10.5 11.7 11.8 11.4 131 15.1 14.0 3.5 4.6 5.0 4.3 16.0 18 3 19.6 19.5 4.500 4.514 4.438 4.028 3.081 3.143 3.274 3.016 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 98.0 110.5 109.2 110.1 107.6 26.1 28.3 26.0 24.6 23.8 71.9 82.2 83.1 85.5 83.9 35.2 43.4 44.4 46.4 44.3 13.8 14.6 14.8 15.0 15.3 17.5 18.0 17.7 18.3 18.5 5.4 6.1 6.2 5.8 5.9 21.7 24.6 26.1 27.2 27.5 ' 4.525 4.485 4.181 4.053 3.913 3.322 3.336 3.183 3.148 3.050 1955.. 1956 1957 1958 1959 114 8 124.0 127.6 127.3 132.0 22 5 22.9 24.3 25.6 24.4 92 2 101.0 103.3 101.7 107.6 48.8 54.5 54.8 53.2 55.7 16.6 17.9 18.2 18.3 20.0 20 9 21.7 22.9 22.9 23.9 6.0 6.9 7.3 7.3 8.0 29 7 31.4 32.7 33.7 35.6 3.863 3.945 3.898 3.773 3.709 3105 3.216 3.155 3.013 3.025 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 136.0 137.9 144.6 150.4 156.2 25.6 25.9 27.3 27.6 26.5 110.4 112.1 117.3 122.7 129.7 56.6 57.7 60.9 62.9 66.4 20.4 20.9 21.5 23.1 24.4 25.3 24.9 26.3 27.6 29.0 8.1 8.7 8.6 9.2 9.9 36.9 38.8 41.1 43.7 46.2 3.687 3.555 3.518 3.438 3.382 2.993 2.889 2.853 2.806 2.809 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 170.5 187.4 199.4 213.5 234.6 29.9 29.6 29.5 30.6 33.3 140.6 157.8 169.9 182.9 201.3 71.5 81.7 88.7 95.2 104.8 26.3 29.9 32.4 34.3 37.7 31.9 34.6 35.3 39.0 42.8 10.9 11.6 13.5 14.4 16.0 51.0 54.1 57.6 63.3 67.4 3.342 3.465 3.463 3.371 3.480 2.756 2.918 2.950 2.888 2.986 244.0 260.8 288.7 357.7 434.4 32.3 36.7 45.6 66.6 62.4 211.6 224.1 243.1 291.2 372.0 108.4 109.9 116.8 141.1 189.6 41.7 44.9 49.4 60.2 76.9 44.3 50.5 55.7 64.8 74.1 17.3 18.8 21.2 25.0 31.3 70.8 77.2 85.8 94.5 102.0 3.446 3.376 3.366 3.787 4.257 2.990 2.901 2.834 3.082 3.646 439.4 473.6 520.9 600.5 7101 64.5 60.6 61.4 76.0 84 3 374.9 413.0 459.5 524.5 625 9 189.8 207.5 225.6 254.7 3112 77.3 86.9 98.5 114.2 134 6 74.6 82.9 93.7 108.4 122 6 33.3 35.7 41.6 47.2 57 5 113.6 124,1 1392 159.3 176 2 3.867 3.815 3.743 3.770 4 030 3.300 3.327 3.301 3.292 3 551 1978: I II Ill IV 539.9 560.2 578.3 600.5 65.6 69.2 72.0 76.0 474.2 491.0 506.2 524.5 232.1 239.1 246.4 254.7 103.3 106.3 109.2 114.2 97.3 101.2 104.8 108.4 41.6 44.4 45.8 47.2 140.9 148.6 153.6 159.3 3.831 3.770 3.765 3.770 3.365 3.304 3.296 3.292 1979: | tl Ill IV 626.2 654.5 681.9 7101 79.4 80.5 83.4 84 3 546.7 574.0 598.5 625 9 267.6 281.9 295.0 3112 118.8 123.9 129.4 134 6 111.3 116.3 119.7 122 6 49.0 51.9 54.5 57 5 163.6 165.1 171.4 176 2 3.828 3.964 3.979 4 030 3.342 3.477 3.492 3 551 724.5 740.4 765.8 77.8 81.8 92.6 646.6 658.5 673.2 325.0 331.2 335.3 138.5 142.0 146.3 122.8 124.0 127.3 60.3 61.3 64.3 181.2 179.9 187.2 3.998 4.115 4.092 3.568 3.660 3.597 1970... . 1971 .. 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 .. . . . 1980: II. " " " Ill V .. 1 2 3 End of quarter. Monthly rates. Ratio based on total final sales, which include a small amount of final sales by farms. Note.—The industry classification of inventories is on an establishment basis and is based on the 1972 Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) beginning in 1948 and on the 1942 SIC prior to 1948. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 250 TABLE B-16.—Inventories and final sales of business in 1972 dollars, 1947-80 [Billions of 1972 dollars, except as noted; seasonally adjusted] Inventories1 Inventory—final sales ratio Nonfarm Final sales 2 Year and quarter Total Farm Total Fourth quarter: 1947 1948 1949 Manufacturing Wholesale trade Retail trade Other Total Nonfarm^ 1161 121.6 117.2 257 26 7 26.2 90 5 94.8 91.0 47.4 48.8 46.2 160 17.2 17.2 18.3 20.3 19.8 87 8.6 7.8 33.2 34.4 34.6 3.500 3.535 3.382 2.727 2.758 2.626 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 127 7 141.4 145.7 147.2 145.0 27 5 29.1 30.4 30.2 31.1 100 2 112.3 115.4 117.1 114.0 49 3 60.0 62.7 64.5 60.9 19 2 19.7 20.1 20.3 20.6 23.0 23.0 23.0 23.6 23.7 87 9.5 9.6 8.7 8.8 36.9 39.8 41.6 43.0 43.1 3 462 3.553 3.505 3.423 3.364 2 716 2.821 2.775 2.722 2.643 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 152.8 158.6 1601 158 3 165.3 31.5 30 7 314 32 4 32.4 121.2 127 8 128 7 1259 132.9 64.3 69.1 68 7 66.1 69.1 22.1 22.8 22 5 22.5 24.6 26.5 26.8 27.8 27.5 28.7 8.4 92 98 9.8 10.5 45.6 46.5 47.1 48.1 49.7 3.348 3.413 3 399 3.292 3.329 2.657 2.751 2.733 2.618 2.676 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 168 8 171.8 179 7 187.2 194.3 32 8 33.2 34 5 35.7 35.1 1361 138.6 145 2 151.5 159.2 699 71.7 75 6 78.2 82.0 251 25.7 26 6 28.4 29.9 30.3 29.8 31.6 33.0 34.5 10 7 11.4 11.4 12.0 12.8 50.7 53.1 55.3 58.3 60.9 3 329 3.237 3.248 3.212 3.190 2 683 2.611 2.625 2.600 2.614 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 2061 222.9 2351 244.1 255.1 36 2 36.0 36 8 37.0 37.3 169 9 186.8 198 3 207.0 217.8 87.0 97.2 104.1 108.4 112.8 316 35.3 37.8 38.9 41.2 37.4 40.0 40.0 43.0 45.9 13.8 14.3 16.3 16.8 17.9 66.1 67.5 70.1 73.8 74.7 3.120 3.301 3.356 3.307 3.415 2.571 2.767 2.830 2.805 2.915 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 258 9 267.0 277.2 294.4 306.0 37 7 39.2 39.8 42.1 41.8 2212 227.8 237.4 252.3 264.2 112.9 111.8 114.4 121.8 130.9 44 0 45.9 47.9 50.4 54.1 46.1 51.2 54.6 58.8 58.3 18.2 19.0 20.5 21.4 20.9 75.2 78.9 84.7 87.3 85.1 3.442 3.384 3.274 3.373 3.593 2.940 2.887 2.804 2.891 3.103 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 299.2 307.0 319.3 333.3 343.5 43.0 41.1 41.1 41.1 43.5 256.3 265.9 278.3 292.2 300.0 127.1 130.9 133.9 139.1 145.9 52.2 55.5 59.5 63.2 64.2 55.8 58.8 63.0 66.8 66.8 21.1 20.8 21.9 23.0 23.1 88.3 92.4 97.9 103.1 105.4 3.388 3.321 3.261 3.233 3.260 2.901 2.877 2.841 2.834 2.847 323 8 327.8 330 7 333.3 411 41.1 411 41.1 282 7 286 7 289 6 292.2 135 5 136.9 138 2 139.1 612 61.8 62.1 63.2 64 2 65.2 66.3 66.8 217 22.7 23.0 23.0 97.6 100.4 101.7 103.1 3 316 3.265 3.250 3.233 2.895 2.855 2.846 2.834 337.2 341.7 343.7 343.5 41.6 42.2 43.0 43.5 295.5 299.5 300.7 300.0 141.8 143.9 145.0 145.9 63.9 64.1 64.5 64.2 66.8 68.4 68.1 66.8 23.0 23.2 23.1 23.1 103.6 102.7 104.4 105.4 3.254 3.328 3.293 3.260 2.852 2.917 2.881 2.847 343 3 343.6 342.3 43 6 43.8 43.4 299 6 299.8 299.0 147 3 147.2 145.9 64.1 64.5 64.7 64.9 64.7 65.1 234 23.4 23.4 106.1 102,8 103.9 3.236 3.341 3.294 2.825 2.915 2.877 1978: 1 || III IV 1979: I II Ill tv S . .. 1980: II III 1 2 3 End of quarter. Monthly rates. Ratio based on total final sales, which include a smalt amount of final sates by farms. Note.—The industry classification of inventories is on an establishment basis and is based on the 1972 Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) beginning in 1948 and on the 1942 SIC prior to 1948. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 251 TABLE B-17.—Relation of gross national product and national income, 1929-80 [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Year or quarter Gross national product Less: Capital consumption allowances with capital consumption adjustment Equals: Net national product PIUS: Subsidies less current surplus of government enterprises Less: Indirect business tax and nontax liability Business transfer payments Statistical discrepancy Equals: National income 103.4 9.7 93.7 -0.2 7.1 0.6 1.1 84.8 1933 55.8 7.4 48.4 -.0 7.1 .7 .7 39.9 1939 90.9 8.7 82.2 .4 9.4 .5 1.4 71.4 100 0 125.0 158.5 192.1 210.6 212.4 209 8 233.1 259 5 258.3 9.1 10.0 11.2 11.5 11.7 12.2 14.0 17.3 20.2 21.8 91.0 115.0 147.3 180.7 198.9 200.2 195.8 215.7 239.3 236.5 4 .1 1 .1 6 .7 .9 -.2 - 1 -.3 10.1 11.3 11.8 12.8 14.2 15.5 17.1 18.4 20.1 21.3 4 .5 5 .5 5 .5 5 .6 7 .8 11 .6 - 8 -1.8 27 4.1 5 1.5 -16 .6 79 7 102.7 135.9 169.3 1821 180.7 178.6 194.9 2199 213.6 1950 1951... 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 .. 1958 1959 286.5 330.8 348 0 366.8 366 8 400 0 421.7 444.0 449.7 487.9 23.5 27.2 29 3 31.0 32.7 34 8 38.7 41.7 43.5 44.9 263.0 303.6 318.7 335.8 334.1 365.3 383.0 402.3 406.2 443.0 .1 _.l _ 3 J 1.1 .1 23.4 25.3 27.7 29.7 29.6 32 2 35.1 37.5 38.7 41.8 .8 9 10 1.2 11 12 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.8 1.3 3.2 17 2.3 20 13 -2.1 -1.2 .2 -1.3 237.6 274.1 287 9 302.1 301.1 330 5 349.4 365.2 366.9 400.8 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 506 5 524.6 565.0 596.7 637.7 691.1 756.0 799 6 873.4 944.0 46 3 47.5 49.0 50.6 52.9 56.0 60.7 65 9 72.1 80.0 460.2 477.0 516.1 546.1 584.8 635.0 695.3 733 7 801.3 864.0 4 1.7 1.8 1.1 1.7 1.6 2.5 16 1.4 1.9 45.4 48.0 51.6 54.6 58.8 62,6 65.3 70 2 78.9 86.6 20 2.0 2.1 2.4 2.7 2.8 3.0 31 3.4 3.9 -2 4 -.1 2.1 1.7 .1 -1.2 1.4 - 3 -2.1 -3.9 415 7 428.8 462.0 488.5 524.9 572.4 628.1 662 2 722.5 779.3 992 7 1,077.6 1,185.9 1,326 4 1,434.2 1,549.2 1,718.0 1,918.0 2,156.1 2,413.9 88.1 96.5 106.4 116.5 136.0 159.3 175.0 196.0 221.2 253.6 904.7 981.1 1,079.5 1 209.9 1,298.2 1,389.9 1,543.0 1,722.0 1,934.9 2,160.3 29 2.6 3.8 34 1.1 2.4 1.0 3.1 3.6 3.1 94.3 103.7 111.5 120.9 129.1 140.1 151.7 166.0 178.1 188.4 41 4.4 4.9 55 5.8 7.4 7.9 8.2 8.7 9.4 -15 4.1 3.3 8 3.7 5.5 5.1 4.4 6.4 2.2 810.7 871.5 963.6 1 086.2 1,160.7 1,239.4 1,379.2 1,546.5 1,745.4 1,963.3 2,627.4 287.8 2,339.6 4.7 211.7 10.5 1.7 2,120.5 II III IV 22il29.6 032 4 2,190.5 2,271.9 210 217.10 224.9 232.7 1822 4 1,912.5 1,965.6 2,039.2 43.7 5 1.8 4.4 174.3 179.6 177.0 181.4 85 8.6 8.7 8.9 - 7.3 .5 10.0 8.7 11,720.7 644.6 1,771.7 1,844.6 1979: 1 II III IV..., 2,340.6 2,374.6 2,444.1 2,496.3 240.1 249.8 259.6 265.1 2,100.5 2,124.8 2,184.6 2,231.2 2.4 3.0 4.0 2.7 184.5 185.8 190.0 193.5 9.1 9.3 9.6 9.8 5.8 .7 2.8 -.7 1,903.6 1,932.0 1,986.2 2,031.3 1980: 1 li Ill 2,571.7 2,564.8 2,637.3 274.6 283.7 291.8 2,297.1 2,281.1 2,345.5 3.1 3.7 6.3 198.9 206.3 215.8 10.1 10.3 10.6 2.8 1.9 3.0 2,088.5 2,070.0 2,122.4 1929 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946.. 1947 1948 1949 1970 1971 1972 1973., . 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 . . . . .. . 1980 " -3 - 0 1978: Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 252 TABLE B-18.—Relation of national income and personal income, 1929-80 [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Plus: Less: National income Year or quarter Corporate profits with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjust- Wage Equals: Govern- ment Contribuaccruals transfer Personal Personal Business Personal tions for Net less payments interest dividend transfer interest social disburseincome income payments income to insurance ments persons ments 1929 1933 ..... 84.8 9.0 4.7 0.2 0.0 0.9 6.9 5.8 0.6 85.0 39.9 -1.7 4.1 .3 .0 1.5 5.5 2.0 .7 47.0 1939 71.4 5.3 3.6 2.1 .0 2.5 5.4 3.8 .5 72.4 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 79.7 102.7 135.9 169.3 182.1 180.7 178.6 194.9 219.9 213.6 8.6 14.1 19.3 23.5 23.6 19.0 16.6 22.3 29.4 27.1 3.3 3.3 3.1 2.7 2.4 2.2 1.8 2.3 2.4 2.7 2.3 2.8 3.5 4.5 5.2 6.1 6.1 5.8 5.4 5.9 .0 .0 .0 .2 -.2 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 2.7 2.6 2.7 2.5 3.1 5.6 10.8 11.2 10.6 11.7 5.3 5.3 5.2 5.1 5.2 5.9 6.6 7.6 8.1 8.7 4.0 4.4 4.3 4.4 4.6 4.6 5.6 6.3 7.0 7.2 .4 .5 .5 .5 .5 .5 .5 .6 .7 .8 77.9 95.4 122.6 150.8 164.5 170.0 177.6 190.1 209.0 206.4 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957.. 1958. . . 1959 237.6 274.1 287.9 302.1 301.1 330.5 349.4 365.2 366.9 400.8 33.9 38.7 36.1 36.3 35.2 45.5 43.7 43.3 38.5 49.6 3.0 3.5 4.0 4.4 5.3 5.9 6.6 7.9 9.6 7.1 8.5 9.0 9.1 10.5 11.2 12.5 13.7 14.9 16.7 18.8 20.3 22.5 8.8 8.5 8.5 8.8 9.1 10.3 14.4 11.6 12.1 12.9 15.1 16.2 17.3 20.1 24.3 25.2 9.7 10.1 11.5 12.9 14.9 15.2 18.0 .0 .1 .0 -.1 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 10.3 11.1 11.5 11.3 12.2 .8 .9 1.0 1.2 1.1 1.2 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.8 227.2 254.9 271.8 287.7 289.6 310.3 332.6 351.0 361.1 384.4 415.7 428.8 462.0 488.5 524.9 572.4 628.1 662.2 722.5 779.3 47.6 48.6 56.6 62.1 69.2 80.0 85.1 82.4 89.1 85.1 11.4 13.0 14.7 16.4 18.3 21.0 24.4 27.6 30.0 34.8 21.1 21.9 24.3 27.3 28.7 30.0 38.8 43.4 47.9 55.0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 27.0 30.8 31.6 33.4 34.8 37.6 41,6 49.5 56.4 62.8 25.0 26.4 29.0 32.2 35.6 39.7 44.4 48.3 53.4 61.1 12.9 13.3 14.4 15.5 17.3 19.1 19.4 20.2 21.9 22.4 2.0 2.0 2.1 2.4 2.7 2.8 3.0 3.1 3.4 3.9 402.3 417.8 443.6 466.2 499.2 540.7 588.2 630.0 690.6 754.7 810.7 871.5 963.6 1,086.2 1,160.7 1,239.4 1,379.2 1,546.5 1,745.4 1,963.3 71.4 83.2 96.6 108.3 94.9 110.5 138.1 -164.7 185.5 196.8 41.4 46.5 51.2 60.2 76.1 84.5 87.2 100.9 115.8 143.4 58 6 64.6 74.2 92.4 104.3 110.9 126.0 140.6 161.8 187.1 .0 -.2 76.1 90.0 99.8 114.0 135.4 170.9 186.4 199.3 214.6 239.9 69.4 74.8 80.9 93.9 112.4 123.2 132.5 151.6 173.2 209.6 22.2 22.6 24.1 26.5 29.1 29.9 36.5 38.7 43.1 48.6 4.1 4.4 4.9 5.5 5.8 7.4 7.9 8.2 8.7 9.4 811.1 868.4 951.4 1,065.2 1,168.6 1,265.0 1,391.2 1,538.0 1,721.8 1,943.8 2,120.5 181.7 179.8 203.7 .0 284.0 256.3 54.4 10.5 2,160.5 1,644.6 1,720.7 1,771.7 1,844.6 163.6 185.2 190.5 202.7 107.3 112.3 117.8 125.7 155.3 159.9 163.4 168.5 .0 .0 .5 .4 208.5 209.7 218.7 221.6 161.7 168.5 176.9 185.6. 40.8 42.0 43.9 45.8 8.5 8.6 8.7 8.9 1,637.9 1,692.1 1,747.7 1,809.3 1,903.6 1,932.0 1,986.2 2,031.3 201.9 196.6 199.5 189.4 133.4 136.9 146.8 156.5 182.3 185.3 188.5 192.2 .1 -.9 -.1 .2 226.3 232.0 248.3 253.3 195.8 202.6 214.3 225.7 47.5 48.3 48.6 50.1 9.1 9.3 9.6 9.8 1,864.6 1,906.3 1,972.3 2,032.0 2,088.5 2,070.0 2,122.4 200.2 169.3 177.9 165.4 175.3 185.3 198.8 199.5 204.1 -.2 .0 .5 261.6 270.3 300.1 239.9 253.6 261.8 52.4 54.2 55.1 10.1 10.3 10.6 2,088.2 2,114.5 2,182.1 1960 1961. 1962.... 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 . 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 . 1978. 1979 . . . .. ... . . .. 1980 ". . . 1978 ii V " .. . Ill IV . . . . 1979: 1 II IJI IV 1980: 1 II IF) Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 333-5HO 0 - 8 1 - 1 7 : QL 3 253 .0 -.1 -.5 .0 .0 .0 .2 TABLE B-19.—National income by type of income, 1929-80 [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual ratesj Proprietors' itcome with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments Compensation of employees National incomel Year or quarter Total Wages and salaries Supplements to wages and salaries2 Nonfarm Farm Total Total Proprietors' in in- come 3 Capital consumption adjustment 1 riven- Total Proprietors' in income4 Capital tory" valua- consumption finn iion adjustadjustment ment 84.8 51.1 50.5 0.6 15.0 6.1 6.3 -0.2 8.9 8.8 0.1 -0.1 39.9 29.5 29.0 .5 5.9 2.5 2.6 .0 3.3 3.9 -.5 .0 71.4 48.1 46.0 2.1 11.8 4.4 4.5 -.1 7.4 7.6 -.2 .0 1940 1941 ... 1942 1943 . . . 1944 1945 . .. . 1946 1947 1948 . 1949 79.7 102.7 135.9 169.3 182.1 180.7 178.6 194.9 219.9 213.6 52.1 64.8 85.3 109.5 121.2 123.1 U8.1 129.2 141.4 141.3 49.9 62.1 82.1 105.8 116.7 117.5 112.0 123.1 135.5 134.7 2.3 2.7 3.2 3.8 4.5 5.6 6.0 6.1 5.9 6.6 13.0 17.5 24.2 29.1 30.4 31.8 36.7 35.9 40.9 36.4 4.4 6.4 10.1 12.0 12.0 12.4 14.9 15.1 17.6 12.8 4.5 6.5 10.3 12.2 12.2 12.7 15.2 15.7 18.2 13.5 8.6 -.1 - . 2 * 11.1 14.1 -.2 17.1 -.2 18.4 -.3 19.4 -.3 21.8 -.3 20.8 -.5 23.3 -.6 23,6 -.7 8.6 117 14.4 17,1 18.3 19.3 23.3 21.8 23.1 .0 -.6 -.4 -.2 -.1 -.1 .0 .0 .1 .2 .2 .2 .2 .5 .6 .9 1950 .. . . 1951 1952... . 1953.... 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 .. . . 1959 237.6 274.1 287.9 302.1 301.1 330.5 349.4 365.2 366.9 400.8 154.8 181.0 195.7 209.6 208.4 224.9 243.5 256.5 258.2 279.6 147.0 171.3 185.3 198.5 196.8 211,7 228.3 239.3 240.5 258.9 7.8 9.7 38.7 43.2 43.4 41.8 41.2 42.9 43.9 45.3 47.7 47.6 137 16.1 15.1 13.1 12.5 11.5 11.2 11.1 13.2 10.9 14.4 16.9 16.0 13.9 13.3 12.2 12.1 12.1 14,1 11.9 -.7 -.8 -.8 -.8 -.8 -.8 -.9 -.9 -.9 25.1 26.4 26.9 27.6 27.6 30.5 31.8 33.1 33.2 35.3 -1.1 10.4 11.0 11.6 13.2 15.2 17.2 17.7 20.6 1960 1961.. . 1962. . .. 1963 . . . . 1964 .. . 1965 . . .. 1966 . .. 1967 1968 . .. 1969 .. 415.7 428.8 462.0 488.5 524.9 572.4 6281 662.2 722.5 779.3 294.9 303.6 325.1 342.9 368.0 396.5 439 3 471.4 519.9 572.9 271,9 279.5 298.0 313.4 336,1 362.0 398 4 427.0 469.6 515.7 23.0 24.1 27.1 29.5 31.8 34.5 40 9 44.4 50.3 57.2 47.2 48.6 49.9 50.5 52.5 56.9 60 5 61.2 64.0 67.0 11.7 12.1 12.3 12.0 10.8 13.1 14 1 34.2 35.3 36.4 37.2 40.2 .0 .0 .0 .0 -.1 -.2 1970 1971 1972 ... . 1973 . . .. 1974 1975 .. 1976 . 1977 ... 1978 1979 810.7 871.5 963.6 1,086.2 1,160.7 1,239.4 1,379.2 1,546.5 1,745.4 1,963.3 612,0 652.2 718.0 801.3 877.5 931.4 1,036.3 1,152.3 1,299.7 1,460.9 548.7 581.5 635.2 702.6 765.2 806.4 889.9 983.8 1,105.4 1,235.9 63.2 70.7 82.8 98.7 112.3 125.0 146.4 168.5 194.3 225.0 1980 P. 2,120.5 1,596.5 1,343.6 1,644.6 1,720.7 1,771.7 1,844.6 1,238.1 1,282.3 1,316.5 1,361.7 1,903.6 1,932.0 1 986.2 2,031.3 2,088.5 1929 . . 1933.... 1939 . . 1978: I II . Ill IV 1979: I jj lit IV '„ 25.0 27.2 28.2 28.6 28.7 31.4 32.7 34.2 34.5 -1.0 367 -.9 -.8 -.8 35.5 36.5 37.6 38.5 41.7 43.8 111 -1.7 -1.5 -.4 .5 -.3 .2 -.2 .0 -.2 -.5 -.3 -.1 .0 1.0 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.2 1.2 1.4 1.4 1.4 1.4 -.9 464 48* 45 3 12.7 14.6 12.6 12.9 13.0 12.8 11.5 13.8 14 9 13.5 13.7 15.7 -1.0 -1.2 51.3 52.5 50.6 51.9 1.4 -.5 66.2 69.4 76.9 93.8 88.7 90.0 94.1 103.5 117.1 131.6 14.3 15.0 18.7 32.8 26.5 24.6 19.1 18.4 26.1 30.8 15.6 16.4 20.4 34.6 29.0 28.0 22.8 22.6 31.0 36.6 -1.3 -1.4 -1.6 -1.8 -2.5 -3.4 -3.7 -4.3 -4.9 -5.8 51.9 54.4 58.1 61.0 62.2 65.4 75.0 85.1 91.0 100.7 517 54.5 58.1 62.3 65.8 67.4 77.1 87.1 93.8 105.2 -.5 -.6 -7 =2.0 =-3.7 -1.2 -1.2 -1.3 -2.2 -3.4 -1.0 252.9 130.6 23.4 30.3 -6,9 107.2 112.6 -3.4 -1.9 1,052.8 1,091.0 1,119.8 1,157.9 185.4 191.3 196.8 203.8 110.3 115.5 118.2 124.6 22.9 24,9 26.1 30.6 27.5 29.7 31.1 35.8 -4.6 -4.8 -5.0 -5.2 87.4 90.5 92.1 94.0 89.7 93.1 94.9 97.4 -1.7 =2.1 -2.2 1,409.9 1,439.0 1,476.7 1,518.1 1,194.9 1,217.8 1,248.5 1,282.4 215.0 221.2 228.2 235.7 127.8 129,4 132 9 X3S*3 30.9 32.6 30.2 29*5 36.3 38.3 36.2 35.7 -5.4 —5.9 62 96.8 96.8 102.7 106.8 100.5 100.6 107.3 112 2 -3.0 -3.1 —3.5 1,558.0 1,569.0 1,597.4 1,314.5 1,320.4 1,342.3 243.5 248.6 255.0 133.7 124.9 129.7 25.7 23.3 22.1 32.3 30.2 29,0 -6.5 -6.9 -6.9 107.9 101.6 107.6 114.8 105.5 113.1 -5.3 -2.0 -3.5 its —7 -7 -.7 —8 -57 427 — .2 415 -27 =40 1.3 1.2 1.2 1.4 1.5 1.3 13 U 1.1 1.1 .8 '.8 .6 .1 -.8 =.9 -7 -.6 _=. 7 ~'.8 -.7 =.8 17 •*- l.t 1 *\ —1.3 1980: nZZZZZZ'. 2,070.0 III 2,122.4 See next page for continuation of table. 254 -1.6 -1.9 -2.0 TABLE B-19-—National income by type of income, 1929-80—Continued [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Rental income of persons with capital consumption Corporate profits with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments Profits with inventory valuation adjustment and without capital consumption adjustment Year or quarter Rental Capital conTotal Total income of sumption persons adjustment Net Capital Invencon- interest sumption tory Profits after tax valua- adjustTotal Profits Profits ment tion before tax Undis- adjustDivitaxes liability Total dends tributed ment profits Profits 1933 1939 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959.. 1960 . ... 1961 1962. 1963 1964 . .. 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 4.9 2.2 2.6 2.7 3.1 4.0 4.4 4.5 4.6 55 5.3 5.7 6.1 7.1 7.7 8.8 10.0 11.0 11.3 11.6 12.2 12.9 13.6 14.5 15.0 15.8 16.5 17.1 18.0 18.7 19.7 19 5 19.6 19 7 20.2 21.0 22.6 23 5 23^0 23.5 25.1 27.4 30.5 5.7 2.3 3.1 3.3 3.9 5.0 5.6 5.9 6.2 7.3 7.7 8.5 8.9 10.0 11.0 12.2 13.4 14.4 14:8 15.2 15.9 16.7 17.4 18.0 18.4 19.1 19.7 20.2 21.2 22.3 23.6 24.0 25.2 258 27.1 29.0 32.1 35 3 36*8 39.2 44.2 50.8 58.9 08 9.0 -.1 -1.7 5.3 -.6 -.6 8.6 - . 8 14.1 19.3 -12 23.5 - 1 . 4 23.6 - 1 . 6 19.0 - 1 . 8 166 - 2 . 5 22.3 - 2 . 8 29.4 - 2 . 8 27.1 - 2 . 9 33.9 - 3 . 3 38.7 - 3 . 4 36.1 - 3 . 4 36.3 - 3 . 3 35.2 - 3 . 5 45.5 - 3 . 6 43.7 - 3 . 6 43.3 - 3 . 8 38.5 - 3 . 8 49.6 - 3 . 5 47.6 - 3 . 4 48.6 - 3 . 4 56.6 - 3 . 2 62.1 - 3 . 2 69.2 - 3 . 3 80.0 - 3 . 6 85.1 - 3 . 9 82.4 - 4 5 891 - 5 . 6 85.1 - 6 1 714 - 6 . 9 83.2 - 8 . 0 96.6 - 9 . 5 108.3 — 118 94 9 — 1318 nois - 1 5 . 6 138.1 - 1 9 . 1 164.7 - 2 3 . 4 185.5 - 2 8 . 3 196.8 1980" 31.9 65.1 -33.3 181.7 199.2 241.2 25.3 25.4 28.7 30.0 46.7 48.3 52.7 55.3 -21.5 -22.9 -24.0 -25.3 163.6 185.2 190.5 202.7 174.9 197.4 205.4 218.3 196.5 220.6 227.9 248.1 30.7 30.1 30.3 31.0 56.7 57.6 59.7 61.4 -26.0 -27.5 -29.4 -30.4 201.9 196.6 199.5 189.4 217.8 213.0 215.6 204.5 253.1 250.9 262.0 255.4 312 31.5 32.0 62.9 64.5 65.9 - 3 1 . 6 200.2 215.6 277.1 - 3 3 . 0 169.3 186.9 217.9 - 3 3 . 9 177.9 195.9 237.6 1929 1978: ii;.'."."."...." *" HI IV 1979: 1 II Ill [V 1980: II Ill 10.5 -1.2 6.5 9.8 15.4 20.5 24.5 24.0 19.3 19.6 25.9 33.4 31.1 37.9 43.3 40.6 40.2 38.4 47.5 46.9 46.6 41.6 52.3 49.7 50.0 55.1 59.7 66.0 76.0 80.9 78.1 84.9 80.8 68.9 94^0 105.6 96 7 120.6 151.6 176.7 199.0 212.7 10.0 1.0 7.2 10.0 17.9 21.7 25.3 24.2 19.8 24.8 31.8 35.6 29.2 42.9 44.5 39.6 41.2 38.7 49.2 49.6 48.1 41.9 52.6 49.8 49.7 55.0 59.6 66.5 77.2 83.0 79.7 88 5 86.7 754 86.6 100.6 125.6 136 7 132.1 166.3 192.6 223.3 255.4 1.4 .5 1.4 2.8 7.6 11.4 14.1 12.9 10.7 9.1 11.3 12.4 10.2 17.9 22.6 19.4 20.3 17.6 22.0 22.0 21.4 19.0 23.6 22.7 22.8 24.0 26.2 28.0 30.9 33.7 32.5 39.2 39.5 34 2 37.5 41.6 49.0 51.6 50.6 63.8 72.6 83.0 87.6 8.6 .4 5.7 7.2 10.3 10.3 11.2 11.3 9.1 15.7 20.5 23.2 19.0 25.0 21.9 20.2 20.9 21.1 27.2 27.6 26.7 22.9 28.9 27.1 26.9 31.1 33.4 38.5 46.3 49.4 47.2 49 4 47.2 413 49.0 58.9 76.6 85.1 81.5 102.5 120.0 140.3 167.8 5.8 2.0 3.8 4.0 4.4 4.3 4.4 4.6 4.6 5.6 6.3 7.0 7.2 8.8 8.5 8.5 8.8 9.1 10.3 11.1 11.5 11.3 12.2 12.9 13.3 14.4 15.5 17.3 19.1 19.4 20.2 22 0 22.5 22 5 22.9 24.4 27.0 29.9 30.8 37.4 39.9 44.6 50.2 2.8 -1.6 2.0 3.2 5.8 6.0 6.7 6.7 4.5 10 2 14.2 16.2 11.8 16.2 13.4 11.8 12.1 11.9 16.9 16.6 15.2 11.6 16.7 14.3 13.6 16.6 17.9 21.2 27.2 29.9 27.0 27 3 24.7 18 8 26.1 34.5 49.6 55.2 50.7 65.1 80.1 95.7 117.6 80.1 161.1 71.2 83.3 85.0 92.3 125.4 137.2 142.9 155.8 88.5 86.4 88.4 87.2 0.5 .1 -.5 -1.2 -2.1 -1.6 -3 7 -5.9 -66 -4.6 -6.6 -20.0 -40.0 -11.6 -14.7 -15.8 -24.3 -42.6 -1.4 -.6 -1.1 -1.2 -1.3 -1.2 -1.0 -.3 —2 -30 -3.6 -4.0 -3.9 -4.0 -4.6 -4.5 -3.9 -3.2 -2.0 -3.2 -3.4 -3.2 -2.7 -2.0 -1.4 1.5 2.5 3.1 4.0 4.2 4.3 43 4.3 25 1.3 2.7 2.7 -1.8 -10.1 -13.5 -12.0 -13.5 -15.9 4.7 4.1 3.6 3.3 3.3 3.1 2.7 2.4 2.2 18 2.3 2.4 2.7 3.0 3.5 4.0 4.4 5.3 5.9 6.6 7.9 9.6 10.3 11.4 130 14.7 16.4 18.3 21.0 24.4 27.6 30 0 34.8 41.4 46.5 51.2 60.2 76.1 84.5 87.2 100.9 115.8 143.4 56.0 105.1 - 4 2 . 0 -17.5 179.8 42.3 43.5 45.4 47.3 83.1 93.8 97.4 108.4 -21.6 -23.2 -22.6 -29.8 -11.3 -12.2 -14.9 -15.6 107.3 112.3 117.8 125.7 164.6 49.0 164.6 49.8 173.6 50.2 168.2 51.6 115.5 114.8 123.5 116.6 -35.3 -37.9 -46.5 -50.8 -15.9 -16.4 -16.1 -15.1 133.4 136.9 146.8 156.5 128.9 - 6 1 . 4 90.7 - 3 1 . 1 102.4 - 4 1 . 7 -15.4 -17.6 -17.9 165.4 175.3 185.3 94.2 182.9 53.9 71.5 146.5 55.7 78.5 159.1 56.7 -2.1 -.7 -.2 -2.5 -1.2 -.8 -.3 -.6 -5.3 -5.9 -2.2 1.9 -5.0 -1.2 1.0 -1.0 -.3 -1.7 -2.7 -1.5 -.3 -.3 —.2 Q 1 National income is the total net income earned in production. It differs from gross national product mainly in that it excludes depreciation charges and other allowances for business and institutional consumption of durable capital goods and indirect business taxes. See Table B-17. 2 Employer contributions for social insurance and to private pension, health, and welfare funds; workmen's compensation,directors' fees; and a few other minor items. 3 With inventory valuation adjustment and without capital consumption adjustment. 4 Without inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 255 TABLE B-20.—Sources of personal income, 1929-80 [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Wage and salary disbursements l Personal income Year or quarter Commodityproducing industries Total Total Manufacturing Distributive industries Service industries Government and government enterprises Other labor income 1 Proprietors' income with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments Farm Nonfarm 1929 85.0 50.5 21.5 16.1 15.6 8.4 5.0 8.9 47.0 29.0 9.8 7.8 8.8 5.2 5.2 0.5 .4 6.1 1933 2.5 3.3 1939 72.4 46.0 17.4 13.6 13.3 7.1 8.2 .6 4.4 7.4 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 77,9 95.4 122.6 150.8 164.5 170.0 177.6 190.1 2090 206.4 49.9 62.1 82.1 105.6 116 9 117!5 112.0 123.1 135 5 134.8 19.7 27.5 39.1 49.0 504 45.9 46.0 54.2 611 57.8 15.6 21.7 30.9 40.9 429 38.2 36.5 42.5 471 44.6 14.2 16.3 18.0 20.1 22.7 24.8 31.0 35.2 37 5 37.7 7.5 8.1 9.0 9.9 10.9 11.9 14.3 16.1 179 18.5 8.5 10.2 16.0 26.6 33.0 34.9 20.7 17.5 19 0 20!8 .6 7 .9 1.1 1.5 1.8 2.0 2.4 27 2.9 4.4 6.4 10.1 12.0 12.0 12.4 14.9 15.1 17 6 12.8 8.6 11.1 14.1 17.1 18.4 19,4 21.8 20.8 23 3 23.6 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 227.2 254.9 271.8 287.7 289.6 310.3 332.6 351.0 361.1 384.4 147.0 171.3 185.4 198.6 196.8 211.7 228.3 239.3 240.5 258.9 64.8 76.3 82.0 89.6 85.7 93.1 100.6 104.2 100.0 109.6 50.3 593 64.1 71.2 67.5 73.8 79,4 82.4 78.6 86.8 39.8 44,3 46.9 497 50.1 53.4 577 60.5 60.8 64.8 19.8 215 23.1 24.9 26.1 28.6 31.3 33.6 35.6 38.5 22.6 292 33.3 34.4 34.9 36.6 38.8 41.0 44.1 46.0 37 46 5.2 5.9 6.1 7.0 8.0 9.0 9.4 10.6 13.7 161 15.1 13.1 12.5 11.5 11.2 11.1 13.2 10.9 25.0 27 2 28!2 28.6 28.7 31.4 32.7 34.2 34.5 36.7 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 . 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 4023 417,8 443.6 466.2 499.2 540.7 588.2 630.0 690.6 754.7 2719 279!5 298.0 313.4 336.1 362.0 398.4 427.0 469.6 515.7 1131 1137 121.8 126.9 135.4 146.0 161.0 168.3 183.4 199.6 89 7 89.8 967 100.6 107.1 115.5 128.0 134.1 145.8 157.5 68 2 69.3 72.8 76.3 81.4 87.2 94.4 100.9 110,0 120.8 414 44! 1 47.2 50.2 54.4 58.9 647 71.3 79.6 897 49 2 52!4 56.3 60.0 64.9 69.9 78.3 86.4 96.6 105.5 112 ILB 13.0 14.0 15.7 17.8 19.9 217 25.2 28.5 117 12!l 12.3 12.0 10.8 13.1 14.1 12.6 127 14.6 35 5 36!5 37.6 38.5 41.7 43.8 46.4 48.6 51.3 52.5 811.1 868.4 951.4 1065 2 U68.6 1,265.0 1 391.2 1,538.0 1,721.8 1,943.8 548.7 580.9 635.2 702 7 7657 806.4 889.9 983.8 1,105.2 1,236.1 203.0 208.3 227.3 2543 2747 275.0 307.3 343.5 389.1 437.9 158.2 160.3 175.4 196 2 21l!4 211.0 237.4 266.0 299.2 333.4 130.3 139.4 152.1 168 3 184!6 195.6 216.6 239.4 270.5 303.0 98.3 106.7 118.2 1313 i4s!e 159.7 177.4 198.6 226.1 259.2 117.1 126.5 137.5 148 7 16(19 176.1 188 7 2023 219.4 236.1 32.5 367 43.0 48 8 55!S 64.5 75 9 89.0 102.2 118.6 14.3 15.0 18.7 32 8 26!5 24.6 191 18.4 26.1 30.8 51.9 54.4 58.1 610 62!2 65.4 750 85!l 91.0 100.7 2,160.5 1,343.6 464.9 350.2 329.1 295.9 253.6 136.9 23.4 107.2 1,637.9 1,692.1 1,747.7 1,809.3 1,052.8 1,091.0 1,119.3 1,157.6 365.6 384.8 395.9 410.3 285.8 294.5 302.5 314.0 2587 266.9 273.4 283.0 214.8 222.3 229.4 2377 2137 216.9 220.5 226.5 97.2 100.4 1037 107.4 22.9 24.9 26.1 30.6 87.4 90.5 92.1 94.0 1,864.6 1,906.3 1,972.3 2,032.0 1,194.8 1,218.6 1,248.6 1,282.2 425.1 434.3 441.6 450.4 326.1 3317 335.5 340.4 292.8 297.5 306.5 315.0 247.0 252.6 263.4 273.7 229.8 234.2 237.1 243.1 111.6 115.9 120.9 126.0 30.9 32.6 30.2 29.5 96.8 96.8 102.7 106.8 2,088.2 2,114.5 2,182.1 1,314.7 1,320.4 1,341.8 461.7 456.0 460.1 347.9 343.2 346.7 322.6 323.2 329.2 283.6 290.8 298.7 246.8 250.5 253.9 130.9 135.1 139.1 257 23.3 22.1 107.9 101.6 107.6 . . 1970 . 1971 . . . 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 . . 1979. . . ... . . .. . 1980 P 1978. if! III IV . . . * 1979: if. Ill IV . 1980. if III See next page for continuation of table. 256 TABLE B-20.—Sources of personal income, 1929-80—Continued [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Rental income of persons Personal Personal with dividend interest capital incomes income consumption adjustment Year or quarter Transfer payments Total Old-age, Govern- Aid to survivors, Government ment families disabilwith unem- Veterans employity, and ployment dependee health benefits ent insurretireinsurance ment children ance benefits benefits (AFOC) benefits 0.8 1.4 .1.7 0.1 2 1.7 1.8 1.8 1.8 2.0 2.0 2.1 .3 .4 .5 2.5 2.9 3.3 .7 .8 1.2 1.8 2.2 23 2.0 2.1 2.2 2.2 159.9 171.9 188.2 190.4 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.4 1.5 1.7 1.9 2.2 2.5 2.8 .6 .6 .5 .5 .6 .6 .6 .7 .8 .9 3.5 3.6 3.8 4.1 4.1 4.3 4.5 4.9 5.3 5.8 2.9 3.4 3.8 4.0 46 5.2 5.8 6.7 6.9 7.9 210.2 235.4 253.1 271.3 273.9 295.5 318.0 336.6 344.4 369.8 4.6 5.0 4.7 4.8 4.7 4.9 4.9 5.6 5.9 6.7 7.7 8.8 9.7 10.4 11.8 14.5 14.4 13.8 13.9 14.4 15.0 3.1 3.4 3.7 A.2 4.7 5.2 6.1 6.9 7.6 8.7 10.2 11.8 13.8 16.0 19.0 22.7 26.1 29.0 32.7 37.0 42.8 1.0 1.1 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.7 1.9 2.3 2.8 3.5 4.8 6.2 6.9 7.2 7.9 9.2 10.1 10.6 10.7 11.0 12.4 6.2 6.4 6.7 7.3 7.8 8.3 9.2 10.2 11.1 12.5 15.0 17.4 19.0 21.1 25.6 32.8 35.1 36.5 40.1 45.4 54.4 9.3 9.7 10.3 11.8 12.6 13.3 17.§ 20.6 22.9 26.2 27.9 30.7 34.5 42.6 47.9 50.4 55.5 61.1 69.6 80.6 87.9 386.7 401.6 427.1 449.7 483.7 522.6 568.9 611.9 672.1 733.9 790.0 846.5 925.3 1,023.7 1,131.8 1,229.1 1,359.3 1,505.0 1,679.2 1,892.9 2,112.8 10.9 9.7 9.5 8.8 14.0 13.7 13.7 14.1 31.2 32.2 32.9 34.3 10.7 10.7 10.7 10.7 38.7 39.6 40.9 41.1 67.1 69.0 70.4 72.1 1,599.6 1,651.1 1,705.0 1,761.1 1216 126.5 137.8 139.3 9.2 9.4 9.8 10.6 14.4 14.2 14.4 14.6 35.0 36.4 37.3 39.2 10.7 10.8 11.1 11.5 42.5 44.1 47.3 47.8 79.0 80.0 81.2 82.4 1,814.8 1,853.9 1,921.5 1,981.2 142.0 144.7 163.2 11.4 16.0 19.0 14.8 14.6 14.9 40.2 42.3 43.1 11.7 12.0 12.8 51.6 51.0 57.7 86.2 85.9 88.1 2,039.6 2,067.3 2,135.3 1929 1933 1939 .4.9 2.2 2.6 5.8 2.0 3.8 6.9 5.5 5.4 1.5 2.1 3.0 0.0 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 2.7 3.1 4.0 4.4 4.5 46 5.5 5.3 5.7 6.1 4.0 4.4 4.3 4.4 4.6 4.6 5.6 6.3 7.0 7.2 5.3 5.3 5.2 5.1 5.2 5.9 6.6 7.6 8.1 8.7 3.1 3.1 3.1 3.0 3.6 6.2 11.3 11.7 11.3 12.5 .0 .1 .1 .2 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 7.1 7.7 8.8 10.0 11.6 12.2 12.9 13.6 8.8 8.5 8.5 8.8 9.1 10.3 11.1 11.5 11.3 12.2 9.7 10.5 11.2 12.5 13.7 14.9 16.7 18.8 20.3 22.5 15.2 12.6 13.1 14.1 16.2 17.5 18.7 21.6 25.9 27.0 .... 14.5 15.0 15.8 16.5 17.1 18.0 18.7 19.7 19.5 19.6 19.7 20.2 21.0 22.6 23.5 23.0 23.5 25.1 27.4 30.5 31.9 12.9 13.3 14.4 15.5 17.3 19.1 19.4 20.2 21.9 22.4 22.2 22.6 24.1 26.5 29.1 29.9 36.5 38.7 43.1 48.6 54.4 25.0 26.4 29.0 32.2 35.6 39.7 44.4 48.3 53.4 61.1 69.4 74.8 80.9 93.9 112.4 123.2 132.5 151.6 173.2 209.6 256.3 II.!"".". . Ill IV. .. 25.3 25.4 28.7 30.0 40.8 42.0 43.9 45.8 1979: 1 II Ill IV 30.7 30.1 30.3 31.0 1980: 1 II Ill 31.2 31.5 32.0 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957. .. 1958 1959 1960. 1961.. 1962 1963 . 1964 1965.. 1966. 1967 1968. 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 o no 11.3 , .. .. .. . . . .. 1978: Other Less: Persona* Nonfarm contribu- personal tions for income2 social insurance 0.1 2 0.4 0.6 .6 .5 .5 .4 .4 .1 .1 .4 1.1 .8 .9 1.9 .5 .5 .5 .5 1.0 3.0 7.0 7.0 5.9 5.3 .3 .3 .3 .4 .4 .5 7 .7 .9 1.0 1.9 2.2 3.0 3.6 4.9 5.7 7.3 8.5 10.2 1.5 .9 1.1 1.0 2.2 1.5 1.5 1.9 4.1 2.8 7.7 4.6 4.3 4.1 4.2 4.4 4.4 4.5 4.7 4.6 28.9 32.8 33.8 35.8 37.4 40.4 44.7 52.6 59.8 66.7 80.1 94.4 104.7 119.5 141.2 178.3 194.3 207.5 223.3 249.4 294.5 11.1 12.6 14.3 15.2 16.0 18.1 20.8 25.5 30.2 32.9 38.5 44.5 49.6 60.4 70.1 81.4 92.9 104.9 116.2 131.8 153.9 3.0 4.3 3.1 3.0 2.7 2.3 1.9 2.2 2.1 2.2 4.0 5.8 5.7 4.4 6.8 17.6 15.8 12.7 9.7 9.8 16.0 161.7 168.5 176.9 185.6 216.9 218.2 227.4 230.5 111.4 112.3 119.7 121.5 47.5 48.3 48.6 50.1 195.8 202.6 214.3 225.7 235.4 241.3 257.8 263.1 52.4 54.2 55.1 239.9 253.6 261.8 271.7 280.7 310.7 .3 .6 1 The total of wage and salary disbursements and other labor income differs from compensation of employees in Table B-19 in that excludes employer contributions for social insurance and the excess of wage accruals over wage disbursements. 2 Personal income exclusive of farm proprietors'-income, farm wages, farm other labor income, and agricultural net interest. Note.—The industry classification of wage and salary disbursements and proprietors' income is on an establishment basis and is ised on the 1972 Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) beginning 1948 and on the 1942 SIC prior to 1948. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 257 TABLE B-21.—Disposition of personal income, 1929-80 [Billions of dollars, except as noted; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Percent of disposable personal income Less: Personal outlays Personal income Year or quarter Equals: Less: Personal Ol s tax and nontax Income payments personal a ar Total Personal consumption expenditures Interest paid by consumers to business Personal transfer payments to foreigners (net) Personal outlays Equals: Personal saving Total Consump- Personal tion saving expenditures 1929 85.0 2.6 82.4 79.1 77.3 1.5 0,3 3.3 1933 47.0 1.4 45.6 46.5 45.8 .5 .2 -0.9 • 96.0 93.8 4,0 102.0 100.5 -2.0 72.4 2.4 70.0 67.8 67.0 .7 .2 2.2 96.9 95.6 3.1 77.9 95.4 122.6 150.8 164,5 170.0 177.6 190.1 209.0 206.4 2.6 3.3 5.9 72.0 81.8 89.4 100.1 109.0 120.4 145.2 163.5 176.9 180.4 71.0 80.8 88.6 99.4 108.2 119.5 143.8 161.7 174.7 178.1 .8 .9 .7 .5 .5 .5 .7 1.0 1.4 1.7 .2 .2 .1 .2 .4 .5 .7 .7 .7 .5 3.4 7.5 95.5 88.8 76.7 75.3 74.8 80.8 91.4 96.9 94.1 96.0 94.2 87.6 76.0 74.7 74.3 80.1 90.5 95.9 93.0 94.8 4.5 17.8 18.9 20.8 18.7 21.4 21.0 18.5 75.3 92.2 116.6 133.0 145.6 149.1 158.9 168.7 188.0 187.9 1950 1951 . 1952 . 1953 1954 1955 1956 .. 1957 1958 1959 227.2 254.9 271.8 287.7 289.6 310.3 332.6 351.0 361.1 384.4 20.6 28.9 34.0 35.5 32.5 35.4 39.7 42.4 42.1 46.0 206.6 226.0 237.7 252.2 257.1 275.0 292.9 308.6 319.0 338.4 194.7 210,0 220.4 233.7 240.1 258.5 271.6 286.4 295.4 317.3 192.0 207.1 217.1 229.7 235.8 253.7 266.0 280.4 289.5 310.8 2.3 2.5 2.9 3.6 3.8 4.4 5.1 5.5 5.6 6,1 .4 .4 .4 .5 .5 .4 .5 .5 .4 .4 11.9 16.1 17.4 18.5 17.0 16.4 21.3 22.3 23.6 21.1 94.2 92.9 92.7 92.7 93.4 94.0 92.7 92.8 92.6 93.8 92.9 91.6 91.3 91.1 91.7 92.3 90.8 90.9 90.7 91.8 5.8 7.1 7.3 7.3 6.6 6.0 7.3 7.2 7.4 6.2 1960 1961 . 1962 . 1963 . 1964 1965.. .. 1966 1967 1968 1969. 402.3 417.8 443.6 466.2 499.2 540.7 588.2 630.0 690.6 754.7 50.4 .52.1 56.8 60.3 58.6 64.9 74.5 82.1 97.2 115.7 352.0 365.8 386.8 405.9 440.6 475.8 513.7 547.9 593.4 638.9 332.3 342.7 363.5 384.0 411.0 442.1 477.7 503.6 551.5 598.3 324.9 335.0 355.2 374.6 400.5 430.4 465.1 490,3 536.9 581,8 7.0 7.3 7.8 8.8 9.9 11.1 12.0 12.5 13.8 15.6 .4 .4 .5 .6 .6 .7 .7 .9 .8 .9 19.7 23.0 23.3 21.9 29.6 33.7 36,0 44.3 41.9 40.6 94.4 93.7 94.0 94.6 93,3 92.9 93.0 91.9 92.9 93.6 92.3 91.6 91.8 92.3 90.9 90.5 90.5 89.5 90.5 91.1 5.6 6.3 6.0 5.4 6.7 7,1 7.0 8.1 7.1 6.4 1970. 1971 . 1972 1973 . . . . 1974 . 1975... 1976 . 1977 1978. 811.1 868.4 951.4 1,065.2 1,168.6 1,265.0 1,391.2 1,538.0 1,721.8 1,943.8 115.8 116.7 141.0 150.7 170.2 168.9 196.8 226.5 258.8 302.0 695.3 751.8 810.3 914.5 998.3 1,096.1 1,194.4 1,311.5 1,462.9 1,641.7 639.5 691.1 757.7 835.5 913.2 1,001.8 1,111.9 1,237.5 1,386.6 1,555.5 621.7 672.2 737.1 812.0 888.1 976.4 1,084.3 1,205.5 1,348.7 1,510.9 16.7 17.7 19.5 22.3 24.1 24.4 26.7 31.1 37.1 43.7 1.1 1,1 1.1 1.3 1.0 .9 .9 .9 .8 1.0 55.8 60.7 52.6 79.0 85.1 94.3 82.5 74.1 76.3 86.2 92.0 91.9 93.5 91.4 91.5 91.4 93.1 94.4 94.8 94.8 89.4 89.4 91.0 88.8 89.0 89.1 90.8 91.9 92.2 92.0 8.0 8.1 6.5 8.6 8.5 8.6 6.9 5.6 5.2 5.3 . 2,160.5 338.7 1,821.7 1,717.6 1,670.1 46.4 1.1 104.2 94.3 91.7 5.7 239.9 251.4 265.7 278.3 1,398.0 1,440.7 1,482.1 1,531.0 1,313.4 1,367.1 1,408.7 1,457.1 1,278.3 1,330.1 1,369.9 1,416.6 34.4 36.2 38.0 39.7 .7 .8 .7 .9 84.6 73.6 73.4 73.8 94.0 94.9 95.0 95.2 91.4 92.3 92.4 92.5 6.1 ... 1,637.9 1,692.1 1,747.7 1,809.3 5.1 5.0 4.8 . 1,864.6 1,906.3 1,972.3 2,032.0 284.4 293.5 308.4 321.8 1,580.2 1,612.8 1,663.8 1,710.1 1,496.3 1,521.9 1,574.5 1,629.4 1,454.1 1,478,0 1,529.1 1,582.3 41.4 43.1 44,5 45.8 .8 .8 .9 1.3 83.8 90.9 89.3 80.7 94.7 94.4 94.6 95.3 92.0 91.6 91.9 92.5 5.3 5.6 5.4 4.7 2,088.2 2,114.5 2,182.1 323.1 330.3 341,5 1,765.1 1,784.1 1,840.6 1,678.7 1,674.1 1,729.2 1,631.0 1,626.8 1,682.2 46.7 46.3 46.0 1.0 .. 1.0 1.0 86.4 110.0 111.4 95.1 93.8 93.9 92.4 91.2 91,4 4.9 6.2 61 1939 1940 1941. 1942 1943 1944. 1945. 1946 1947 1948 1949 .. .. 1979 1980" 1978: 1.... II... III. IV. 10.3 27.2 32.9 36.6 28.7 13.7 5.2 11.1 11.2 23.3 24.7 25.2 19.2 8.6 3.1 5.9 4.0 1979: IL.. III. IV... 1980: IL III.. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 258 TABLE B-22.—Total and per capita disposable personal income and personal consumption expenditures in current and 1972 dollars, 1929-80 [Quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates, except as noted] Personal consumption expenditures Disposable persona! income Year or quarter Per capita (dollars) Total (billions of dollars) Total (billions of dollars) Per capita (dollars) Population /thnn ^inousands) » Current dollars 1972 dollars Current dollars 1972 dollars Current dollars 1972 dollars Current dollars 1972 dollars 1929 82.4 229.5 676 1,883 77.3 215.1 634 1,765 1933 45.6 169.6 363 1,349 45.8 170.5 364 1,356 125,690 70.0 229.8 534 1,754 67.0 219.8 511 1,678 131,028 75.3 92.2 116.6 133.0 145.6 149.1 158.9 168.7 188.0 187.9 244.0 277.9 317.5 332.1 343.6 338.1 332.7 319.0 336.0 336.9 570 691 865 973 1,052 1,066 1,124 1,170 1,282 1,259 1,847 2,083 2,354 2,429 2,483 2,416 2,353 2,214 2,291 2,258 71.0 80.8 88.6 99.4 108.2 119.5 143.8 161.7 174.7 178.1 229.9 243.6 241.1 248.2 255.2 270.9 301.0 305.8 312.2 319.3 537 605 657 111 781 854 1,017 1,122 1,192 1,194 1,740 1,826 1,788 1,815 1,844 1,936 2,129 2,122 2,129 2,140 132,122 133,402 134,860 136,739 138,397 139,928 141,389 144,126 146,631 149,188 206.6 226.0 237.7 252.2 257.1 275.0 292.9 308.6 319.0 338.4 362.9 3727 383.2 399.1 403.3 426.9 446.3 455.6 460.7 479.7 1,362 1,465 1,515 1,581 1,583 1,664 1,741 1,802 1,832 1,903 2,393 2,415 2,441 2,501 2,484 2,583 2,653 2,660 2,645 2,697 192.0 207.1 217.1 229.7 235.8 253.7 266.0 280.4 289.5 310.8 337.3 341.6 350.1 363.4 370.0 394.1 405.4 413.8 418.0 440.4 1,266 1,342 1,383 1,439 1,452 1,535 1,581 1,637 1,662 1,747 2,224 2,214 2,230 2,277 2,278 2,384 2,410 2,416 2,400 2,476 151,684 154,287 156,954 159,565 162,391 165,275 168,221 171,274 174,141 177,888 352.0 365.8 386.8 405.9 440.6 475.8 513.7 547.9 593.4 638.9 489.7 •503.8 524.9 542.3 580.8 616.3 646.8 673.5 701.3 722.5 1,947 1,991 2,073 2,144 2,296 2,448 2,613 2,757 2,956 3,152 2,709 2,742 2,813 2,865 .3,026 3,171 3,290 3,389 3,493 3,564 324.9 335.0 355.2 374.6 400.5 430.4 465.1 490.3 536.9 581.8 452.0 461.4 482.0 500.5 528.0 557.5 585.7 602.7 634.4 657.9 1,797 1,823 1,904 1,979 2,087 2,214 2,366 2,467 2,674 2,870 2,501 2,511 2,583 2,644 2,751 2,868 2,979 3,032 3,160 3,245 180,760 183,742 186,590 189,300 191,927 194,347 196,599 198,752 200,745 202,736 751.6 695.3 779.2 751.8 810.3 810.3 865.3 914.5 858.4 998.3 875.8 1,096.1 907.4 1 194 4 939.8 1,311.5 981.5 1,462.9 1,641.7 1,011.5 3,393 3,630 3,880 4,346 4,710 5,132 5,550 6,046 6,688 7,441 3,668 3,763 3,880 4,112 4,050 4,101 4,216 4,332 4,487 4,584 621.7 672.2 737.1 812.0 888.1 976.4 1,084.3 1,205.5 1,348.7 1,510.9 672.1 696.8 737.1 768.5 763.6 780.2 823.7 863.9 904.8 930.9 3,034 3,246 3,529 3,858 4,190 4,572 5,038 5,557 6,166 6,848 3,280 3,365 3,529 3,652 3,603 3,653 3,828 3,982 4,136 4,219 204,918 207,084 208,873 210,440 211,945 213,566 215,203 216,928 218,749 220,643 1,821.8 1,017.7 8,176 4,567 1,670.1 933.0 7,496 4,188 222,804 1,398.0 1,440.7 1,482.1 1,531.0 966.8 975.5 985.9 998.0 6,411 6,594 6,768 6,975 4,434 4,465 4,502 4,547 1,278.3 1,330.1 1,369.9 1,416.6 884.1 900.6 911.2 923.4 5,862 6,088 6,256 6,454 4,054 4,122 4,161 4,207 218,052 218,483 218,983 219,478 1,580.2 1,005.7 1,612.8 1,006.9 1,663.8 1,015.7 1,710.1 1,017.7 7,186 7,320 7,533 7,722 4,574 4,570 4,598 4,596 1,454.1 1,478.0 1,529.1 1,582.3 925.5 922.8 933.4 941.6 6,613 6,708 6,923 7,145 4,209 4,188 4,226 4,252 219,896 220,335 220,884 221,455 1,765 1 1,021.0 17841 1,008.2 1,840.6 1,018.5 7,953 8 020 8,249 4,600 4,532 4t565 1,631.0 1,626.8 1,682.2 943.4 919.3 930.8 7,349 7313 7,539 4,251 4[l33 4,172 221,938 222,447 223,126 1939 . 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 .. 1947 1948 1949 . . . . . . . . 1950 . 1951 . 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 . 1957 1958 1959 . . . . . .. . . . . . . . . . 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 .. 1973 1974 1975 . 1976 1977 1978 . 1979 . . . .. . . . _ . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. . 1980" 1978: I II HI IV . ... . . . . . . 1979: i II .. . . . . . Ill IV 1980: II 111 121,875 1 Population of the United States including Armed Forces overseas; includes Alaska and Hawaii beginning 1959. Annual data are (or July 1 through 1958 and are averages of quarterly data beginning 1959. Quarterly data are average for the period. Data from 1980 census not yet available. Source: Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census). 259 TABLE B-23.—Gross saving and investment, 1929-80 [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Gross investment Gross saving Government surplus or deficit ( - ) , national income and product accounts Gross private saving Year or quarter Total Total 1929 15.9 Gross Personal business saving saving' 3.3 14 9 -.9 Total 11.6 1.0 Federal State and local 12 -0 2 Capital grants received by the United States {net) ^ Total 17 0 Gross private domestic investment 16.2 Net foreign investment3 0.8 Statistical discrepancy 11 1933 .9 2.2 3.1 -1.4 -1.3 1.6 1.4 .2 .7 1939 8.8 n.o 2.2 8.8 -2.2 -2.2 0 10.3 9.3 1.0 1.4 13.5 18.6 10.7 5.4 2.4 5.2 35.1 41.7 49.8 35.6 3.4 10.3 27.2 32.9 36.6 28.7 13.7 5.2 11.1 75 10.8 12.1 14.8 16.7 17.6 16.0 15.9 22.1 30.2 31.5 -.7 -3.8 -31.4 -44.1 -51.8 -39.5 5.4 14.4 8.4 -3.4 -1.3 -5.1 -33.1 -46.6 -54.5 -42.1 3.5 13.4 8.3 -2.6 .6 13 18 2.5 27 2.6 ].9 14.7 19.2 9.8 3.7 5.2 9.3 35.6 43.2 48.3 36.2 13.1 17.9 9.9 5.8 7.2 10.6 30.7 34.0 45.9 35.3 1.5 1.3 -.1 -2.1 -2.0 -1.3 4.9 9.3 2.4 .9 1.1 .6 -.8 -1.8 2.7 4.1 50.7 56.9 51.0 49.8 50.9 67.5 75.9 75.2 62.6 78.3 14.2 22.4 42.0 49.6 54.3 44.7 29.6 27.3 41.4 39 0 i 42.7 50.8 54.8 56.7 58.1 64.4 70.7 74.3 75.3 79.9 11.9 16.1 17.4 18.5 17.0 16.4 21.3 22.3 23.6 21.1 30.7 34.8 37.4 38.2 41.1 47.9 49.4 52.0 51.7 58.7 8.0 6.1 -3.8 -6.9 -7.1 3.1 5.2 .9 -12.6 -1.6 9.2 6.5 -3.7 -7.1 -6.0 4.4 6.1 2.3 -10.3 -1.1 52.0 60.1 52.7 52.1 52.9 68.8 73.8 74.0 62.8 77.0 53.8 59.2 52.1 53.3 52.7 68.4 71.0 69.2 61.9 78.1 -1.8 .9 .6 -1.3 .2 .4 2.8 4.8 .9 -1.2 1.3 3.2 1.7 2.3 2.0 1.3 -2.1 -1.2 1960.... 1961 . 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 81.1 78.7 86.7 93.6 104.0 120.2 127.3 125.7 136.0 153.6 78.0 83.0 90.5 92.9 106.3 119.7 128.6 139.9 142.0 143.6 19.7 23.0 23.3 21.9 29.6 33.7 36.0 44.3 41.9 40.6 58.3 60.0 67.2 71.0 76.7 86.0 92.7 95.6 100.0 103.0 3.1 -4.3 -3.8 .7 -2.3 3.0 -3.9 -4.2 .3 -3.3 .1 -.4 .5 .5 10 -.0 9.9 -L8 -13.2 -6.0 8.4 -1.1 .1 1.5 75.9 74.8 85.4 90.9 97.4 113.5 125.7 122.8 133.3 149.3 2.8 3.8 3.4 4.4 6.8 5.4 3.0 2.6 .6 .4 -2.4 -.1 2.1 1.7 -1.3 -14.2 60 78.7 78.6 88.8 95,3 104.2 119.0 128.7 125.4 133.9 149.7 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975. 1976 1977 1978 19.79 148.9 161.6 186.6 235.5 227.8 218.9 257.9 304.0 355.2 411.9 158.6 180.3 189.2 227.7 234.5 282.7 294.4 322.4 355.4 398.9 55.8 60.7 52.6 79.0 85.1 94.3 82.5 74.1 76.3 86.2 102.8 119.7 136.6 1487 149.4 188.4 211.9 248.3 279.1 312.7 -10.6 -19.4 -3.3 7.8 -4.7 -63.8 36 5 -18.3 -.2 11.9 -12.4 -22.0 -16.8 -5.6 -11.5 -69.3 -53.1 -46.4 -29.2 -14.8 1.9 2.6 13.5 13.4 6.8 5.5 16.6 28.1 29.0 26.7 7 ,0 -2.0 .0 .0 .0 .0 1.1 147.4 165.7 189.9 236.3 231.5 224.4 263.0 308.4 361.6 414.1 144.2 166.4 195.0 229.8 228.7 206.1 257.9 322.3 375.3 415.8 6.5 2.9 18.3 5.1 -13.9 -13.8 -1.7 -1.5 4.1 3.3 .8 3.7 5.5 5.1 4,4 6.4 2.2 1980 " 403.9 437.6 104.2 333.4 -34.8 -62.3 27.6 1.1 405.7 395.1 10.6 1.7 1978: | II III.... IV 326.9 354.0 359.4 380 4 344.7 349.1 358.3 3696 84.6 73.6 73.4 73 8 260.1 275.5 284.9 295 8 17 7 4.9 1.1 108 -48.8 -27.4 -22.8 17 9 31.1 32.3 23.9 28 7 .0 .0 .0 326.4 361.3 369.4 350.7 377.7 380.4 -3OQ 1 -.5 7.3 10.0 o 7 1979: I || III IV o -24.2 -16.4 -10.9 o c 407.4 416.2 422.3 402.0 388.2 401.2 409.8 396.4 83.8 90.9 89.3 80.7 304.4 310.3 320.5 315.7 18.1 13.9 M.3 4.4 -11.5 -8.1 -15.2 -24.5 29.5 21.9 26.5 28.9 1.1 1.1 1.1 1.1 413.2 416.9 425.1 401.3 408.3 423.2 421.7 410.0 4.9 -6.3 3.4 = 8.7 5.8 .7 2.8 404.5 394.5 402.0 413.0 435.9 446.5 86.4 110.0 111.4 326.7 325.8 335.1 -9.6 -42.5 -45.6 -36.3 -66.5 -74.2 26.6 23.9 28.6 1.1 1.1 1.1 407.3 392.5 405.0 415.6 390.9 377.1 -8.3 1.7 27.8 2.8 -1.9 3.0 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947.. 1948 1949. . . . . 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 .". 1 -, -.1 •"•••• ]0 .1 _ 7 -1.2 —4 ~'o .1 -1.1 -1.3 -.9 -1.4 -2.4 - 4 • 0.9 3.2 ~l!l L5 -1.6 6 -13 -U 1.4 -.3 -2.1 -3.9 1980: ii HI 1 Undistributed corporate profits with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments, corporate and noncorporate capital consumption allowances with capital consumption adjustment, and private wage accruals less disbursements. 2 Allocations of special drawing rights (SDRs), except as noted in footnote 4. 3 Net exports of goods and services less net transfers to foreigners and interest paid by government to foreigners plus capital grants received by the United States, net. 4 In February 1974, the U.S. Government paid to India $2,010 million in rupees under provisions of the Agricultural Trade Development and Assistance Act. This transaction is being treated as capital grants paid to foreigners, i.e., a =$2.0 billion entry in capital grants received by the United States, net. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 260 TABLE B-24.—Saving by individuals, 1946-801 [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Net investment in Increase in financial assets Year or quarter Total NonSecuritie s CurInsurMoney Con- corMiscelrency Savance porate Nonmarsumer laneous ings Govern- Corpoand busifarm Other and Total ket rate ment demand acpension financial homes dura- ness fund securi- equi- securibles assets 6 depos- counts re4 asshares ties 2 ties 3 ties 5 its serves sets 7 1946. 1947 1948 1949 24.4 20.2 24.5 21.3 18.8 13.2 5.6 9.1 9.9 -2.9 -2.0 6.3 3.4 2,2 2.6 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 30.9 34.7 30.7 31.6 27.7 13.7 19.1 23.2 22.8 22.2 2.6 4.6 1.6 1.0 2.2 2.4 4.7 7.8 8.1 9.1 -.1 -.6 2.5 2.5 1.0 33.4 36.7 35.8 33.4 35.6 28.0 30.2 28.6 31.6 37.4 1.2 1.8 -.4 3.8 .8 11.9 13.9 11.1 8.6 9.4 5.8 3.9 2.3 35.6 34.1 40.3 45.2 55.7 32.5 35.9 40.6 47.3 56.1 63.8 72.1 77.6 82.2 73.7 59.0 58.4 70.4 76.2 64.5 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 86.1 98.7 116.3 138.4 128.9 78.8 103.0 128.8 148.5 142.4 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 150.0 164.6 172.8 198.2 198.8 167.2 208.1 241.7 275.3 291.6 14.9 22.7 18.3 14.2 176.6 ." 196.7 205.4 214.2 243.4 286.4 288.6 282.9 26.7 91.2 17.2 113.7 14.7 117.1 14.7 98.8 6.9 5.4 5.8 184.4 213.3 204.2 193.2 273.6 305.3 313.3 271.1 - 8 . 3 85.9 23.7 67.8 31.3 103.5 9.8 66.7 28.8 31.6 33.1 44.1 221.6 311.9 220.1 232.8 215.1 314.8 - 4 . 5 82.7 - 3 . 9 106.1 27.7 122.8 61.3 62.5 1955 .. 1956 1957 1958 1959. . 1960 1961 1962 . 1963.... 1964 1965. . 1966 1967 1968 1969 . . 1.0 -.9 -1.2 4.2 5.2 7.5 2.4 9.9 11.1 -2.5 8.9 12.2 13.9 14.1 7.1 4.0 3.6 4.7 4.6 4.4 3.1 3.7 3.2 3.2 -0.5 11.8 11.7 11.3 12.3 12.7 14.9 11.3 7.0 4.4 2.0 .8 1.5 6.7 6.6 6.2 7.6 8.7 4.8 1.6 5.3 4.2 1.5 5.0 3.6 2,8 1.9 5.5 16.7 15.6 13.2 12.1 15.9 11.9 10.4 11.9 2.1 2.5 2.8 3.5 3.3 2.4 12.2 .5 11.2 2.1 8.9 2.3 9.5 3.4 12.8 7.2 3.9 2.9 .5 8.0 6.4 3.2 3.8 6.0 7.2 2.4 .1 .1 1.4 .4 11.5 12.1 12.7 13.9 16.1 3.6 4.3 3.2 2.9 3.2 14.3 12.0 12.8 13.4 13.9 6.7 4.1 8.2 11.7 12.2 14.1 16.2 17.5 4.4 2.5 6.3 8.9 9.8 4.8 6.5 7.2 11.8 15.1 3.1 3.3 6.3 8.5 7.7 1.3 2.4 4.8 6.8 16.9 19.2 18.6 19.8 21.5 3.7 4.4 6.7 8.1 4.0 13.4 12.6 10.9 14.3 14.2 20.2 22.8 20.9 26.3 26.2 11.2 17.0 13.8 12.5 17.1 18.5 10.6 23.9 27.4 29.4 33.0 36.2 5.4 11.7 20.2 5.8 18.8 26.2 11.4 3.9 2.7 6.3 2.8 2.8 2.4 2.2 1.6 .7 1.8 1.6 1.0 .8 -.7 .3 .0 .3 -.9 6.9 6.3 7.7 7.9 7.8 1.9 1.9 2.0 2.1 2.1 1.0 2.0 1,5 1.5 .6 .8 1.2 1.0 1.1 -.4 8.5 9.5 9.5 12.1 18.3 26.1 26.3 26.1 2.4 - . 5 .3 1.8 1.8 - 2 . 0 1.2 - 2 . 6 5.1 -.1 27.8 19,0 35.3 31.1 3.9 - 2 . 1 11.7 - . 6 -.7 - 4 . 2 5.7 - 6 . 4 -2.5 • 10.1 9.1 25.3 - 3 . 6 10.7 43.6 67.8 74.5 63.8 55.9 -7.2 -1.5 -10.1 -5.1 1.9 - 5 . 6 24.1 - 6 . 7 27.7 - 2 . 2 5.7 5.0 3.3 84.0 109.3 109.2 105.2 81.0 1978: IL'.".". Ill IV 2.1 2.0 7.1 2.0 5.3 5.4 5.3 5.6 1.6 1.3 1.8 2.4 1.3 -.0 .2 6.9 34.4 9.6 IV 1980: | ||. ' Ill 5.1 8.4 9.4 6.9 8.7 7.6 3.4 6.9 9.4 8.5 9.4 11.4 9.8 14.1 6.5 5.7 11.5 10.8 5.4 2.2 2.8 2.2 10.6 9.8 12.6 10.8 15.0 15.3 13.3 14.8 21.7 29.9 26.5 22.7 9.1 8.5 26.0 28.2 23.1 35.1 41.1 28.6 26.4 41.5 47.1 35.4 14.7 19.8 26.0 43.5 52.6 65.3 77.9 74.7 11.0 19.7 25.8 29.7 32.9 20.8 33.1 48.1 59.2 55.6 26.6 - . 2 38.1 40.6 - 1 . 0 61.3 50.9 5.9 93.2 57.5 6.9 103.8 52.6 10.5 110.2 9.7 71.0 73.2 90.7 76.4 25.4 31.3 32.4 29.8 56.6 58.3 59.8 62.0 48.1 59.5 58.8 63.4 10.4 113.2 53.3 38.1 53.0 55.7 38.0 4.7 63.1 81.1 76.7 77.8 29.1 34.3 34.4 31.6 59.3 56.9 54.3 52.0 60.1 50.8 50.8 48.5 8.5 112.3 9.7 110.8 10.3 108.5 13.7 109.3 51.4 45.2 46.9 31.1 53.3 53.4 69.0 51.8 84.3 - 1 7 . 4 - 6 . 1 -39.6 7.8 - 1 7 . 5 38.1 - 9 . 2 6.0 76.8 91.7 89.9 34.7 25.8 34.5 45.7 35.2 22.9 7.5 104.4 25.9 47.8 18.6 - 5 . 3 56.5 - 4 4 . 2 27.3 - 2 . 6 77.2 6.1 61.0 48.9 64.1 23.0 12.1 18.3 30.3 50.3 -3.5 -3.2 -6.1 -6.2 -11.9 35.3 - 8 . 8 32.5 26.5 -~5.'l 27.1 - 1 0 . 2 11.2 6.8 13.2 16.0 13.8 6.6 36.8 1979: iiIII .' .71 Mortgage debt Conon sumer Other non- credit debt *« farm homes 3.6 6.1 6.7 8.8 9.1 9.8 8.4 10.9 1.1 - 0 . 9 1.1 -.8 .0 1.0 .7 - . 4 -1.5 Less: Net increase in debt 66.5 60.7 22.5 51.3 -7.5 -10.6 -14.3 -15.0 1 2 16.0 16.7 26.0 13.5 17.7 20.3 2.8 9.9 25.6 40.6 50.6 44.2 5.3 95.3 43.4 5.2 102.8 56.9 6.7 104.1 48.8 16.7 29.2 40.0 46.2 57.2 Saving by households, personal trust funds, nonprofit institutions, farms, and other noncorporate business. Consists of U.S. savings bonds, other U.S. Treasury securities, U.S. Government agency securities and sponsored agency securities, and3 State and local obligations. Includes investment company shares. 4 Corporate and foreign bonds and open market paper. 6 Private life insurance reserves, private insured and noninsured pension reserves, and government insurance and pension reserves. 6 Noncorporate business proprietors' equity, etc. 7 Includes data for corporate farms. 8 Other debt consists of security credit, policy loans, noncorporate business mortgage debt, and other debt. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 261 TABLE B-25.—Money income (in 1979 dollars) and poverty status of families and unrelated individuals by race of householder, 1952-79 Total Year number (millions) FAMILIES1 1952 1953 1954 ..'. . . ' . . . 1955 1956. " . 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 .... 1962 .. 1963 . . . 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 . 1971. 1972 . . 1973 1974 1974* . . . 1975 1976 .. . 1977 1978 1979«> 40.8 41.2 42.0 42 9 43.5 43.7 44.2 45.1 3 45.5 3 46.4 3 47.1 3 47.5 3 48.0 3 48.5 3 49.2 3 50.1 3 50.8 351.6 3 52 2 53.3 54.4 55.1 55.7 55.7 56.2 56.7 57.2 57.8 58.4 $10,638 11513 11,254 11976 12,766 12,807 12,770 13,490 13,774 13.915 14,292 14,815 15,372 16,005 16,846 17.246 18,010 18,677 18,444 18,433 19,287 19,684 18,893 18,990 18,502 19,073 19,176 19,626 19,684 . .. . . 9.7 9.5 9.7 9.9 9.8 10.4 10.9 10.9 3 11.1 3 11.2 3 11.0 3 3 3 . . . 1966 1967 1968 . . 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1974* 1975 1976 1977 . . . 1978 . 1979 T&5 18.1 18.1 17.2 15.9 15.0 13.9 11.8 11.4 10.0 • 9.7 10.1 10.0 9.3 8.8 9.2 8.8 9.7 9.4 9.3 9.1 9.1 5.5 71 7.3 80 9.7 9.3 10.1 12.2 13.4 14.5 15.5 17.0 18.6 20.1 22.6 24.4 27.4 29.3 28 7 283 32.5 33.6 29.4 32.3 30.4 31.9 33.1 34.0 34.7 38.2 39 0 39.5 39.7 40.2 40.9 41.1 41,9 42.4 42.7 43.1 43.5 44.1 44.8 45.4 46.0 46.5 47.6 48.5 48.9 49.5 49.4 49.9 50.1 50.5 50.9 51.4 Percent with incomes— Total number Median (milincome Betow $25,000 lions) poverty and over level $11,250 11,937 11,715 12 505 13,359 13,328 13,305 14,053 14,301 14,512 14,966 15,524 16,049 16,681 17,502 17,901 18,646 19,392 19134 19,127 20,038 20,572 19,659 19,735 19,242 19,811 20,051 20,436 20,524 Below $15,000 poverty and over level UNRELATED INDIVIDUALS* 1952... 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961... 1962 1963 1964 1965 Percent with incomes— Total number (milincome Below $25,000 lions) poverty and over level Martian wieuian . .. 3 . . 11.2 12.1 12.2 12.5 3 13.2 3 13.9 3 14.6 3 15 5 16.3 16.8 18.3 18.9 18.9 20.2 21.5 23.1 24.6 25.6 $3,853 3,789 3,300 3.570 3,809 3,850 3,730 3,877 4,216 4,256 4,206 4,267 4,641 4,953 5,122 5,172 5,813 5,803 5 864 5^943 6,109 6,752 6.534 6,775 6,584 6,854 7,075 7,460 7,578 Black White Total 46.1 45.2 45.9 45.4 44.2 42.7 39.8 38.3 38.1 34.0 34.0 32 9 3li6 29.0 25,6 25.5 24.1 25.1 24.9 22.6 22.1 21.8 3.6 3.8 3.7 4,3 4.5 5.8 6.6 6.7 7.2 8.7 9.7 10.4 11.2 12.2 12.1 13.4 15.9 15.3 16 2 16ll 17.1 18.6 17.1 17.8 16.9 17.8 18.9 20.2 20.5 15 2 14.9 14.8 13.9 12.8 12.2 11.1 9.3 9.0 8.0 7.7 80 7.9 7.1 6.6 7.0 6.8 7.7 7.1 7.0 6.9 6.8 6.2 7.5 7.9 8.8 10.5 10.0 10.9 13.1 14.3 15.7 16.8 18.4 19.8 21.6 24.2 25.9 29.0 31.0 30.4 30.5 34.4 35.7 31.2 34.1 32.2 34.0 35.1 36.0 36.7 MoHian median income 2 i'3.8 2 39 2 4.0 2 4.0 2 4.0 M.2 M.3 M.5 M.6 2 4.8 2 4.8 2 4.8 2 5.0 4.6 4.6 4.8 49 5.2 5.3 5.4 5.5 5.5 5.6 5.8 5.8 5.9 6.0 "BJ 8.5 8.5 8.9 9.2 9.3 9.6 9.6 9.5 9.7 10.4 10.5 10.7 11.3 12.0 12.5 13 4 R2 14.5 15.8 16.3 16.3 17.5 18.6 19.9 21.3 22.1 "44"l 43.0 43.2 42.7 42.0 40.7 38.1 36.1 36.5 32.2 32.1 30 8 29^6 27.1 23.7 23.2 21.8 22.7 22.7 20.4 19.8 19.6 3.8 4.5 4.2 4.9 5.0 6.8 7.3 7.5 7.8 9.5 10.7 11.6 12.2 13.4 13.3 14.5 17.0 16.7 17 4 V.3 17.9 19.6 18.1 18.9 18.0 19.0 19.9 21.0 21.4 Below poverty level 7,986 2 8,215 2 8,982 2 9,186 2 10,492 10,598 11,183 11,878 11737 11,542 11,909 11,873 11,493 11,784 11,840 11,784 11,455 12,104 11,648 $25,000 and over 2 6,394 2 6 693 2 6,525 2 6 896 2 7,029 2 7,126 2 6,816 2 7.259 2 7,917 2 7,742 2 Below $15,000 poverty and over level 4,154 3,998 3,551 3,795 3,910 4,121 3,997 4,144 4,559 4,574 4,502 4,474 4,886 5,165 5,386 5,370 6,159 6,094 6 137 6>10 6,380 6,974 6,824 7,020 6,877 7,148 7,344 7,822 7,855 Percent with incomes— 2 2 0.9 11 1.2 2 .9 2 1.5 1.5 2 2.4 2 2.4 2 ... „„... 2 49.0 2 49.0 2 48.0 2 43.7 2 40.0 2 39.7 35.5 33.9 29.4 27.9 29 5 28.8 29.0 28.1 27.8 26.9 27.1 27.9 28.2 27.5 27.6 24.4 25.O 4.3 24.8 2 6.4 2 6.7 2 82 9.2 11.3 12.1 131 12.7 157 14.6 12.5 14.8 13.7 14.9 15.2 17.2 17.0 2 Below $15,000 poverty and level over 2 nJ 1.4 2 2 1.3 1.5 2 1.6 2 1.6 2 1.5 2 1.6 2 1.5 2 1.5 2 1.6 2 1.7 2 21.6 1.6 1.7 1.8 1 7 1./ 1.9 2.0 2.2 2.3 2.4 2.4 2.6 2.9 2.9 3.1 2 2 874 2 3,143 2 2,358 2 2,535 2 2 903 2 2,618 2 2,711 2 2,677 2 2,618 2 2,807 8 3,004 2 3,070 2 3,349 23J66 2 3,386 3,826 4,098 4,170 O QC7 j,yo/ 4,033 4,457 5,153 4,503 4,735 4,433 4,806 5,313 4,908 5,444 2 57!6" 22 59.3 62.7 2 62.1 2 58.3 2 55.0 2 50.7 54.4 49.3 46.3 46.7 to.o 46.0 42.9 37.9 41.0 39.3 42.1 39.8 37.0 38.6 36.9 10 *.3 2.5 M 11 2.9 8 1.5 2 2.4 2 2.4 2 3.0 2 3.4 *3.3 2 5.1 2 5.2 2 4.6 5.6 7.3 6.2 7 9 /,& 7.5 101 12^4 10.0 11.1 10.2 10.8 12.5 13.4 14.6 'The term family refers to a group of two or more persons related by blood, marriage, or adoption and residing together; all such persons are considered members of the same family. 2 Data for "black" include "other" races. 3 Revised using population controls based on the 1970 census. Such controls are not available by race. 4 Based on revised methodology; comparable with succeeding years. 9 Based on householder concept. Restricted to primary families. •The term "unrelated individuals" refers to persons 15 years old and over as of March 1980 and 14 years old and over for previous years (other than inmates of institutions) who are not living with any relatives. .. Note.—The poverty level is based on the poverty index adopted by a Federal interagency committee in 1969. That index reflects different consumption requirements for families based on size and composition, sex and age of family householder, and farm-nonfarm ^ Source: ^ ZDepartment & W of ^Commerce, ^ T Bureau ^ Tof the^ Census. J S K t changes in the co sumer price indexFor lurther det8ls see " 262 - TABLE B-26.—Population by age groups, 1929-80 [Thousands of persons] Age (years) July 1 1929 1933. 1939 1940 . 194].. 1942 1943... 1944.. 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950. . 1951 195?. 1953 . 1954 . 1955... 1956... 1957.. 1953 1959 1960 . 1961... 1962. 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970. 1971 1972.. 1973.. 1974 1975 . 1976.. 1977 1978,. 1979 1980 Total Under 5 121,767 125,579 130,830 132,122 133,402 134,860 136,739 138,397 11,734 10,612 10,418 10,579 10,850 11,301 12,016 12,524 139,928 141,389 144,126 146,631 149,188 12,979 13,244 14,406 14,919 15,60.7 152,271 154,878 157,553 160,184 163,026 165,931 168,903 171,984 174,882 177,830 180,671 183,691 186,538 189,242 191,889 194,303 196,560 198,712 200,706 202,677 16,410 17,333 17,312 17,638 18,057 18,566 19,003 19,494 19,887 20,175 20,341 20,522 20,469 20,342 20,165 19,824 19,208 18,563 17,913 17,376 204,878 207,053 208,846 210,410 211,901 213,559 215,152 216,880 218,717 220,584 222,807 5-15 16-19 26,800 26,897 25,179 9,127 9,302 9,822 24,811 24,516 24,231 24,093 23,949 23,907 24,103 24,468 25,209 25,852 26,721 27,279 28,894 30,227 31,480 8,542 8,446 8,414 8,460 8,637 32,682 8,744 33,994 35,272 36,445 37,368 8,916 9,195 9,543 10,215 38,494 39,765 41,205 41,626 42,297 10,683 11,025 11,180 12,007 12,736 42,938 43,702 44,244 44,622 44,840 13,516 14,311 14,200 14,452 14,800 17,148 17,177 16,990 16,694 16,288 44,774 44,441 43,948 43,227 42,538 15,275 15,635 15,946 16,310 16,590 15,879 15,345 15,248 15,378 15,649 41,956 41,459 40,575 39,623 38,643 16,793 16,928 16,966 16,935 16,838 1 9,895 9,840 9,730 9,607 9,561 9,361 9,119 9,097 8 952 8,788 t1) t) 1 20-24 25-44 45-64 10,694 11,152 11,519 11,690 11,807 11,955 12,064 12,062 12,036 12,004 11,814 11,794 11,700 11,680 11,552 11,350 11,062 10,832 35,862 37,319 39,354 21,076 22,933 25,823 26,249 26,718 27,196 27,671 28,138 28,630 29,064 29,498 29,931 30,405 10,714 10,616 10,603 10,756 10,969 11,134 11,483 11,959 12,714 13,269 13,746 14,050 15,248 15,78616,480 17,184 18,032 18,345 18,741 19,229 19,630 20,077 20,461 20,726 (M 39,868 40,383 40,861 41,420 42,016 42,521 43,027 43,657 44,288 44,916 45,672 46,103 46,495 46,786 47,001 47,194 47,379 47,440 47,337 47,192 47,140 47,084 47,013 46,994 46,958 46,912 47,001 47,194 47,721 48,064 48,435 48,811 50,254 51,411 52,593 53,735 55,129 56,706 58,380 60,161 1 65 and over 6,474 7,363 8,764 9,031 9,288 9,584 9,867 10,147 10,494 10,828 11,185 11,538 11,921 12,397 12,803 13,203 13,617 14,076 30,849 31,362 31,884 32,394 32,942 33,506 34,057 34,591 35,109 35,663 36,203 36,722 37,255 37,782 38,338 38,916 39,534 40,193 40,846 41,437 18,451 18,755 19,071 19,365 19,680 41,975 42,413 42,785 43,077 43,319 43,546 43,707 43,795 43,876 43,910 20,087 20,488 20,892 21,346 21,833 22,420 22,954 23,513 24,064 24,658 14,525 14,938 15,388 15,806 16,248 16,675 17,089 17,457 17,778 18,127 t) Not available. Note.—Includes Armed Forces overseas beginning 1940. Includes Alaska and Hawaii beginning 1950. Data from 1980 census not yet available. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 263 TABLE B-27.—Noninstitutional population and the labor force, 1929-80 [Monthly data seasonally adjusted, except as noted] Civilian labor force Year or month Noninstitutional Armed1 populaForces tion 1 Employment Total Total Agriculiural Nonagricultural Civilian labor force participation rate 8 Unemployment rate (percent of civilian labor UnemTotal Males Females force) ployment Thousands of persons 14 years of age and over 1929 1933 1939 .... . 1940 . 1941 1942 1943 . 1944 1945.... 1946. 1947 .. . 260 250 370 100,380 540 101,520 1,620 102,610 3,970 103,660 9,020 104,630 11,410 105,530 11,440 106,520 3,450 107,608 1,590 47,630 10,450 38,760 10,090 45,750 9,610 47,520 9,540 50,350 9,100 53,750 9,250 54,470 9,080 53,960 8,950 53,860 52,820 8,580 57,520 55,250 8,320 60,168 57,812 8,256 49,180 51,590 55,230 55,640 55,910 56,410 55,540 54,630 37,180 28,670 36,140 37,980 41,250 44,500 45,390 45,010 44,240 46,930 49,557 Percent 1,550 3.2 12,830 24.9 9,480 17.2 8,120 5,560 2,660 1,070 670 14.6 9.9 4.7 1.9 1.2 55.7 56.0 57.2 58.7 58.6 837 84.3 85.6 86.4 87.0 28,2 28.7 31.3 36.0 36.5 1,040 2,270 2,356 1.9 3.9 3.9 57.2 55.8 56.8 84.8 82.6 84.0 31.0 3,637 3.9 3.8 5,9 58.3 58.8 58.9 86.4 86.6 86.4 31.8 32.7 33.1 59,2 59.3 59.0 58.9 58.8 86.4 86.5 86.3 86.0 85.5 33.9 34.6 34.7 34.4 34.6 35.9 31.2 Thousands of persons 16 years of age and over 1947. 1948 1949 1950 .. 1951 19523 1953 1954. 1955 .. 1956.. 1957 .. 1958 1959... 1960 * 1961 . 1962^ 1963 . 1964 1965 1966 . 1967 1968... 1969 . 1970 1971.. 197233. 1973 .. 1974 ... 1975.. 1976 . 1977. . 1978». 1979. 1980 7,160 6,726 6,500 6,260 6,205 49,148 50,714 49,993 51,758 53,235 53,749 54,919 53,904 1,834 ' 3,532 5.3 3.3 3.0 2.9 5.5 62,170 63,799 64,071 63,036 64,630 6,450 6,283 5,947 5,586 5,565 55,722 57,514 58,123 57,450 59,065 2,852 2,750 2,859 4,602 3,740 4.4 4.1 4.3 6.8 5.5 59.3 60.0 59.6 59.5 59.3 85.3 85.5 84.8 84.2 83.7 35.7 36,9 36.9 37.1 37.1 69,628 65,778 70,459 65,746 70,614 66,702 71,833 67,762 73,091 69,305 74,455 71,088 2,723 75,770 72,895 3,123 77,347 74,372 3,446 78,737 75,920 3,535 80,734 77,902 3,506 3,188 82,715 78,627 2,816 84,113 79,120 2,449 86,542 81,702 2,326 88,714 84,409 2,229 91,011 85,935 92,613 84,783 2,180 2,144 94,773 87,485 2133 97,401 90,546 2,117 100,420 94,373 2,088 102,908 96,945 2,102 104,719 97,270 5,458 5,200 4,944 4,687 4,523 60,318 60,546 61,759 63,076 64,782 66,726 68,915 70,527 72,103 74,296 3,852 4,714 3,911 4,070 3,786 5.5 6.7 5.5 5.7 5.2 59.4 59.3 58.8 58.7 58.7 83.3 82.9 82.0 81.4 81.0 37.7 38.1 37.9 38.3 38.7 3,366 2,875 2,975 2,817 2,832 4.5 3.8 3.8 3,6 3.5 58.9 59.2 59.6 59,6 60.1 80.7 80.4 80.4 80.1 79.8 39.3 40.3 41.1 41.6 42.7 103,418 104,527 105,611 1,591 1,459 1,617 59,350 60,621 61,286 106,645 107,721 108,823 110,601 111,671 112,732 113,811 115,065 116,363 117,881 119,759 121,343 122,981 125,154 127,224 129,236 131,180 133,319 135,562 137,841 140,182 142,596 145,775 148,263 150,827 1,650 3,100 3,592 3,545 3,350 3,049 2,857 2,800 2,636 2,552 153,449 156,048 158,559 161,058 163,620 166,246 62,208 62,017 62,138 63,015 63,643 57,038 58,343 57,651 58,918 59,961 60,250 61,179 60,109 65,023 66,552 66,929 67,639 68,369 2,514 2,572 2,828 2>38 2,739 See next page for continuation of table. 264 7,890 7,629 7,658 4,361 3,979 3,844 3,817 3,606 3,288 2,055 1,883 4,993 4,840 4,304 5,076 4.9 5.9 5.6 4.9 5.6 60.4 60.2 60.4 60.8 61.2 79.7 79.1 79.0 78.8 78.7 43.3 43.3 43.9 44.7 45.6 3,380 3,297 3,244 3,342 3,297 75,165 75,732 78,230 80,957 82,443 81,403 84,188 87,302 91,031 93,648 7,830 7,288 6,855 6,047 5,963 8.5 7.7 7.0 6.0 5.8 61.2 61.6 62.3 63.2 63.7 77.9 77.5 77.7 77.9 77.9 46.3 47.3 48.4 50.0 51.0 3,310 93,960 7,448 7.1 63.8 77.4 51.6 3,462 3,387 3,472 3,452 3,492 TABLE B-27.—Noninstitutional population and the labor force, 1929-80—Continued [Monthly data seasonally adjusted, except as noted] Civilian labor force participation rate 2 Civilian labor force Year or month Noninstitutional population 1 Armed Forcesl Employment Unemployment Total Total ctilfuriral Unemployment rate (percent of civilian labor force) Total Males Females Nonagricultural Thousands of persons 16 years of age and over Percent 1978: 3 159,937 160,128 160,313 160,504 160,713 160,928 2,121 2,124 2,122 2,118 2,113 2,098 99,101 99,031 99,336 99,823 100,201 100,507 92,752 92,863 93,133 93,780 94,177 94,680 3,400 3,276 3,305 3,305 3,282 3,436 89,352 89,587 89,828 90,475 90,895 91,244 6,349 6,168 6,203 6,043 6,024 5,827 6.4 6.2 6.2 6.1 6.0 5.8 62.8 62.7 62.8 63.0 63.2 63.3 77.9 77.7 77.8 77.8 77.9 77.9 49.2 49.2 49.4 49.7 49.9 50.1 161,148 161,348 161,570 161,829 162,033 162,250 2,116 2,122 2,123 2,122 2,117 2,108 100,603 100,719 100,937 101,171 101,576 101,831 94,494 94,837 94,991 95,374 95,653 95,715 3,392 3,360 3,356 3,365 3,236 3,346 91,102 91,477 91,635 92,009 92,417 92,369 6,109 5,882 5,946 5,797 5,923 6,116 6.1 5.8 5.9 5.7 5.8 6.0 63.3 63.3 63.3 63.3 63.5 63.6 77.8 77.8 77.7 77.8 78.0 78.1 50.2 50.2 50.4 50.4 50.5 50.6 162,448 162,633 162,909 163,008 163,260 163,469 2,094 2,094 2,090 2,082 2,078 2,076 102,014 102,393 102,578 102,213 102,366 102,556 96,056 96,400 96,622 96,295 96,590 96,838 3,275 3,312 3,304 3,234 3,226 3,276 92,781 93,088 93,318 93,061 93,364 93,562 5,958 5,993 5,956 5,918 5,776 5,718 5.8 5.9 5.8 5.8 5.6 5.6 63.6 63.8 63.8 63.5 63.5 63.5 78.2 78.2 78.0 77.9 77.8 77.7 50.5 50.8 51.0 50.6 50.7 50.8 163,685 163,891 164,106 164,468 164,682 164,898 2,082 2,090 2,092 2,093 2,092 2,089 103,015 103,105 103,492 103,566 103,605 104,053 97,277 97,048 97,521 97,434 97,501 97,781 3,282 3,342 3,332 3,281 3,378 3,323 93,995 93,706 94,189 94,153 94,123 94,458 5,738 6,057 5,971 6,132 6,104 6,272 5.6 5.9 5.8 5.9 5.9 6.0 63.7 63.7 63.9 63.8 63.7 63.9 77.9 77.7 78.0 77.7 77.5 77.7 51.0 51.2 51.2 51.3 51.3 51.5 fr. 165,101 165,298 165,506 165,693 165,886 166,105 2,081 2,086 2,090 2,092 2,088 2,092 104,208 104,271 104,171 104,427 105,060 104,591 97,708 97,817 97,628 97,225 97,116 96,780 3,287 3,329 3,337 3,262 3,352 3,232 94,421 94,488 94,291 93,963 93,764 93,548 6,500 6,454 6,543 7,202 7,944 7,811 6.2 6.2 6.3 6.9 7.6 7.5 63.9 63.9 63.7 63.8 64.1 63.8 77.6 77.7 77.5 77.5 78.0 77.4 51.6 51.5 51.3 51.5 51.7 51.5 June.. July . Aug.. Sept... Oct Nov.... Dec... 166,391 166,578 166,789 167,005 167,201 167,396 2,099 2,114 2,121 2,121 2,119 2,124 105,020 104,945 104,980 105,167 105,285 105,067 96,999 97,003 97,180 97,206 97,339 97,282 3,267 3,210 3,399 3,319 3,340 3,394 93,732 93,793 93,781 93,887 93,999 93,888 8,021 7,942 7,800 7,961 7,946 7,785 7.6 7.6 7.4 7.6 7.5 7.4 63.9 63.8 63.8 63.8 63.8 63.6 77.5 77.3 77.4 77.4 77.3 77.0 51.7 51.7 51.5 51.6 51.6 51.5 Jan Feb Mar fc .:.June July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 1979. Jan.. Feb.... Mar.. Apr... fay June. July... Aug.. Sept. Oct Nov Dec 1980: Jan.. . Feb . Mar 1 Not seasonally adjusted. Civilian labor force as percent of civilian noninstitutionaf population. Not strictly comparable with earlier data due to population adjustments as follows: Beginning 1953, introduction of 1950 census data added about 600,000 to population and about 350,000 to labor force, total employment, and agricultural employment. Beginning 1960, inclusion of Alaska and Hawaii added about 500,000 to population, about 300,000 to labor force, and about 240,000 to nonagricultural employment. Beginning 1962, introduction of 1960 census data reduced population by about 50,000 and labor force and employment by about 200,000. Beginning 1972, introduction of 1970 census data added about 800,000 to civilian noninstitutional population and about 333,000 to labor force and employment. A subsequent adjustment based on 1970 census in March 1973 added 60,000 to labor force and to employment. Beginning 1978, changes in sampling and estimation procedures introduced into the household survey added about 250,000 to labor force and to employment. Unemployment levels and rates were not significantly affected. 2 3 Note.—Labor force data in Tables B-27 through B-33 are based on household interviews and relate to the calendar week including the 12th of the month. For definitions of terms, area samples used, historic comparability of the data, comparability with other series, etc., see "Employment and Earnings." Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 265 TABLE B-28.—Civilian employment and unemployment by sex and age, 1947-80 [Thousands of persons 16 years of age and over; monthly data seasonally adjusted] Unemployment [mployment Year or month Total Total 16-19 years 20 years and over Total 16-19 years Females Males Females Males 20 years and over Total Total 16-19 years 20 years and over Total 20 16-19 years years and over 475 564 841 854 689 1947 1948 1949 57,038 40,995 58,343 41,725 57,651 40,925 2,218 38,776 16,045 2,345 39,382 16,617 2,124 38,803 16,723 1,691 14,354 1,683 14,937 1,588 15,137 2,311 2,276 3,637 1,692 1,559 2,572 270 255 352 1,422 1,305 2,219 619 717 1,065 223 1950 1951 1952 1953» 1954 58,918 59,961 60,250 61,179 60,109 41,578 41,780 41,682 42,430 41,619 2,186 39,394 17,340 2,156 39,626 18,181 2,106 39,578 18,568 2,135 40,296 18,749 1,985 39,634 18,490 1,517 1,611 1,612 1,584 1,490 15,824 16,570 16,958 17,164 17,000 3,288 2,055 1,883 1,834 3,532 2,239 1,221 1,185 1,202 2,344 318 191 205 184 310 1,922 1,029 980 1,019 2,035 1,049 834 698 632 1,188 195 145 140 123 191 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 62,170 63,799 64,071 63,036 64,630 42,621 43,379 43,357 42,423 43,466 2,095 2,164 2,U7 2,012 2,198 40,526 41,216 41,239 40,411 41,267 19,551 20,419 20,714 20,613 21,164 1,548 1,654 1,663 1,570 1,640 18,002 18,767 19,052 19,043 19,524 2,852 2,750 2,859 4,602 3,740 1,854 1,711 1,841 3,098 2,420 274 269 299 416 398 1,580 1,442 1,541 2,681 2,022 998 1,039 1,018 1,504 1,320 176 209 197 262 256 823 832 821 1,242 1,063 I960 1 1961 1962 * 1963 1984 65,778 65,746 66,702 67,762 69,305 43,904 43,656 44,177 44,657 45,474 2,360 2,314 2,362 2,406 2,587 41,543 41,342 41,815 42,251 42,886 21,874 22,090 22,525 23,105 23,831 1,769 1,793 1,833 1,849 1,929 20,105 20,296 20,693 21,257 21,903 3,852 4,714 3,911 4,070 3,786 2,486 2,997 2,423 2,472 2,205 425 479 407 500 487 2,060 2,518 2,016 1,971 1,718 1,366 1,717 1,488 1,598 1,581 286 349 313 383 386 1,080 1,368 1,175 1,216 1,195 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 71,088 72,895 74,372 75,920 77,902 46,340 46,919 47,479 48,114 48,818 2,918 3,252 3,186 3,255 3,430 43,422 43,668 44,293 44,859 45,388 24,748 25,976 26,893 27,807 29,084 2,118 2,469 2,497 2,525 2,686 22,630 23,510 24,397 25,281 26,397 3,366 2,875 2,975 2,817 2,832 1,914 1,551 1,508 1,419 1,403 479 432 448 427 441 1,435 1,120 1,060 993 963 1,452 1,324 1,468 1,397 1,429 395 404 391 412 412 1,056 1,078 985 1,016 1970 1971 1972 * 1973* 1974 78,627 79,120 81,702 84,409 85,935 48,960 49,245 50,630 51,963 52,518 3,407 3,470 3,750 4,017 4,074 45,553 45,775 46,880 47,946 48,445 29,667 29,875 31,072 32,446 33,417 2,734 2,725 2,972 3,219 3,329 26,933 27,149 28,100 29,228 30,088 4,088 4,993 4,840 4,304 5,076 2,235 2,776 2,635 2,240 2,668 599 691 707 647 749 1,636 2,086 1,928 1,594 f918 1,853 2,217 2,205 2,064 2,408 506 567 595 579 660 1,347 1,650 1,610 1,485 1,748 1975 1976 1977 1978> 1979 84,783 87,485 90,546 94,373 96,945 51,230 52,391 53,861 55,491 56,499 3,803 3,904 4,124 4,279 4,236 47,427 48,486 49,737 51,212 52,264 33,553 35,095 36,685 38,882 40,446 3,243 3,365 3,486 3,702 3,748 30,310 31,730 33,199 35,180 36,698 7f830 7,288 6,855 6,047 5,963 4,385 3,968 3,588 3,051 3,018 957 3,428 3,041 2>27 2,252 2,223 3,445 3,320 3,267 2,996 2,945 795 928 861 799 795 773 781 760 733 2,649 2,546 2,486 2,236 2,213 1980 97,270 55,988 4,016 51,972 41,283 3,587 37,696 7,448 4,157 896 3,261 3,291 744 2,547 96,056 96,400 96,622 96,295 96,590 96,838 56,293 56,396 56,379 56,322 56,426 56,586 4,292 4,264 4,267 4,237 4,224 4,299 52,001 52,132 52,112 52,085 52,202 52,287 39,763 40,004 40,243 39,973 40,164 40,252 3,794 3,831 3,841 3,762 3,727 3,731 35,969 36,173 36,402 36,211 36,437 36,521 5,958 5,993 5,956 5,918 5,776 5,718 3,036 3,024 3,009 2,980 2,888 2,801 835 836 2,201 2,188 2,188 2,165 2,083 2,097 2,922 2,969 2,947 2,938 2,888 2,917 717 2,205 718 2,251 701 2,246 760 2,178 741 2,147 740 2,177 97,277 97,048 97,521 97,434 97,501 97,781 56,667 56,473 56,780 56,594 56,505 56,617 4,260 4,123 4,260 4,179 4,205 4,253 52,407 52,350 52,520 52,415 52,300 52,364 40,610 40,575 40,741 40,840 40,996 41,164 3,742 3,621 3,693 3,715 3,762 3,743 36,868 36,954 37,048 37,125 37,234 37,421 5,738 6,057 5,971 6,132 6,104 6,272 2,932 3,023 3,056 3,101 3,169 3,241 788 824 768 784 806 2,177 2,235 2^32 2,333 2,385 2,435 2,806 3,034 2,915 3,031 2,935 3,031 684 2,122 731 2,303 97,708 97,817 97,628 97,225 97,116 96,780 96,999 97,003 97,180 97,206 97,339 97,282 56,458 56,631 56,489 56,054 55,914 55,597 4,195 4,195 4,259 4,119 4,043 3,973 52,263 52,436 52,230 51,935 51,871 51,624 41,250 41,186 41,139 41,171 41,202 41,183 3,712 3,626 3,589 3,574 3,602 3,570 37,538 37,560 37,550 37,597 37,600 37,613 6,500 6,454 6,543 7,202 7,944 7,811 3,448 3,378 3,500 3,994 4,543 4,496 819 797 764 802 974 938 2,629 2,581 2,736 3,192 3,569 3,558 3,052 3,076 3,043 3,208 3,401 3,315 738 765 748 707 808 746 2.314 2,311 2,295 2,501 2,593 2,569 55,678 55,589 55,754 55,881 55,897 55,920 3,964 3,798 3,931 3,918 3,890 3,875 51,714 51,791 51,823 51,963 52,007 52,045 41,321 41,414 41,426 41,325 41,442 41,362 3,593 3,524 3,622 3,571 3,533 3,542 37,728 37,890 37,804 37,754 37,909 37,820 8,021 4,593 7,942 4,558 7,800 4,566 7,961 4,498 7,946 4,491 7,785 4,334 963 946 914 966 959 909 3,630 3,612 3,652 3532 3,532 3,425 3,428 3,384 3,234 3,463 3,455 3,451 773 751 721 731 735 701 2,655 2,633 2,513 2J32 2,720 2,750 1979: Jan Feb Mar Apr May. July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 1980: Jan Feb Mar June July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 1 See footnote 3, Table B-27. Note.-See Note, Table B-27. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 266 821 815 805 704 755 144 152 559 510 997 921 735 2,180 791 2,240 721 2,214 755 2,276 TABLE B-29.—Selected employment and unemployment data, 1948-80 [Percent;1 monthly data seasonally adjusted] Unemployment rate1 By sex and age Employment as percent of population5 By selected groups ExperiWomen Both All Females enced Married who BlueBlack Full-time workers sexes 20Males wage and 3 20 years collar 4 Total White and years 16-19 men workers 3< workers salary tain other years and over and over workers families Year or month 3.8 5.9 9.2 13.4 3.2 5.4 3.6 5.3 4.3 6.8 3.5 57 5.3 3.3 3.0 29 5.5 44 4.1 43 6.8 55 12.2 8.2 8.5 76 12.6 110. 11.1 116 15.9 14.6 4.7 2.5 2.4 2.5 4.9 3.8 3.4 3.6 6.2 4.7 5.1 4.0 3.2 2.9 5.5 4.4 4.2 4.1 6.1 5.2 6.0 3.7 3.3 3.2 6.2 4.8 4.4 4.6 7.2 5.7 4.6 1.5 1.4 1.7 4.0 2.8 2.6 2.8 5.1 3.6 5.0 2.6 2.5 5.5 6.7 55 5.7 52 4.5 3.8 3.8 3.6 3.5 14.7 16.8 14 7 17.2 162 14 8 12.8 12.9 12.7 12.2 4.7 5.7 4.6 4.5 39 3.2 2.5 2.3 2.2 2.1 5.1 6.3 54 5.4 5.2 4.5 3.8 4.2 3.8 3.7 5.7 6.8 56 5.5 5.0 4.3 3.5 3.6 3.4 3.3 3.7 4.6 36 3.4 2.8 2.4 1.9 1.8 1.6 1.5 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 4.9 5.9 5.6 49 5.6 8.5 77 7.0 6.0 5.8 15.2 16.9 16.2 14 5 16.0 19.9 19 0 17.7 16.3 16.1 3.5 4.4 4.0 32 3.8 6.7 5.9 5.2 4.2 4.1 4.8 5.7 5.4 48 5.5 8.0 7.4 7.0 6.0 5.7 4.8 5.7 5.3 45 5.3 8.2 7.3 6.6 5.6 5.4 1980 7.1 17.7 5.9 6.3 5.8 5.9 5.8 5.8 5.6 56 16.1 16.1 15.8 16.5 163 15 2 4.1 4.0 4.0 4.0 3.8 39 5.6 59 5.8 5.9 5.9 6.0 15.2 16.4 16.4 16.5 15.9 16.3 4.0 4.1 4.1 4.3 4.4 4.4 6.2 62 6.3 6.9 76 7.5 16.5 16 6 16.2 16.4 18 9 18.3 7.6 7.6 7.4 7.6 7.5 7.4 18.7 18.8 17.8 18.5 18 6 17.8 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 . .;..'... ....'..'. . .; '. .. " 1979: Jan Feb Mar May.. June July Aug Sept . . . Oct Nov Dec 1980: Jan Feb Mar Apr May inrte til Oct Nov Dec .'. 4.2 8.0 55.8 54.6 12 3.9 3.6 34 .7.2 58 5.1 62 10.2 7.6 55.2 55.7 55.4 55.3 53.8 55.1 56.1 55.7 54.2 54.8 54.9 54.2 54.2 54.1 54.5 55.0 55.6 55.8 56.0 56.5 54.0 54.3 54.8 55.4 55.7 55.9 56.5 55.2 561 -4-g4.4 4.4 5.5 4.9 4.2 3.5 3.4 3.1 3.1 7.8 9.2 74 7.3 6.3 5.3 4.2 4.4 4.1 3.9 2.6 3.2 2.8 23 2.7 5.1 4.2 3.6 2.8 2.7 5.4 7.3 7.2 70 7.0 10.0 10 0 9.3 8.5 8.3 4.5 5.5 5.1 43 5.1 8.1 73 6.5 5.5 5.3 6.2 7.4 6.5 53 6.7 11.7 9.4 8.1 6.9 6.9 56.1 55.5 56.0 56 9 57.0 55.3 56.1 57.1 58.6 59.3 56.2 55.7 56.4 57 3 57.5 55.9 56.8 57.9 59.3 60.0 55.5 53.7 53.0 53 9 53.0 50.0 50 6 51.1 53,3 53.6 6.8 4.2 9.1 6.8 10.0 58.5 59.5 51.9 5.8 5.9 5.8 5.7 5.6 56 5.4 5.4 5.4 5.3 5.3 52 3.7 3.7 3.6 3.6 3.4 35 7.9 8.3 8.2 8.0 85 9.0 5.3 5.4 5.3 5.3 5.1 5.0 6.6 6.7 6.7 6.9 6.6 6.4 59.1 59.3 59.3 59.1 59.? 59.9 60.1 60.0 59.9 59,9 60.0 53.4 53.4 53.9 53.5 53.4 53.fi 5.4 5.9 5.6 5.7 5.6 5.7 5.3 5.6 5.5 5.6 5.6 5.6 3.5 3.7 3.6 3.7 3.7 3.8 8.1 8.0 8.0 8.4 8.5 8.5 5.1 5.3 5.3 5.4 5.4 5.5 6.7 7.1 7.0 7.2 7.6 7.5 59.4 59.2 59.4 59,? 59.2 59.3 60.2 60.0 60.2 60,1 60.0 60.2 54,0 53.6 54.0 53 7 53 4 53.3 4.8 4.7 5.0 5.8 6.4 6.4 5.8 5.8 5.8 6.2 6.5 6.4 5.9 5.9 6.0 6.6 7.4 7.3 4.1 4.1 4.2 4.7 5.2 5.1 9.0 8.5 8.6 9.0 8.3 8.5 5.8 5.8 5.9 6.5 7.3 7.2 8.1 7.9 8.2 9.6 10.9 11.1 59.2 59.2 59.0 58.7 58.5 58.3 60.1 60.1 59.9 59,6 59.5 59.2 53,1 5? 8 52.3 6.6 6.5 6.6 6.4 6.4 6.2 6.6 6.5 6.2 6.7 6.7 6.8 7.4 7.4 7.2 7.3 7.2 7.1 5.3 5.3 5.1 5.1 5.0 4.9 8.8 9.0 9.0 10.2 9.9 10.4 7.4 7.3 7.3 7.3 7.4 7.3 11.3 11.1 10.8 10.8 10.7 10.5 58.3 58.2 58.3 58.2 58? 58.1 59.2 59.1 59.2 59.2 59.2 59.1 51.9 51.8 51,6 51.4 515 51.3 v 1 2 3 4 5.2 3.8 3.7 40 7.2 6.7 •59.? 57.2 56.6 56.7 ftffl 51.7 Unemployment as percent of civilian labor force in group specified. Married men living with their wives. Data for 1949 and 1951-54 are for April; 1950, for March. Data for 1949-61 are for May. Includes craft and kindred workers, operatives, and nonfarm laborers. Data for 1948-57 are based on data for January, April, July, and8 October. Civilian employment as percent of total noninstitutional population. Note.—See footnote 3 and Note, Table B-27. Source.- Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 267 TABLE B-30..—Civilian labor force participation rate by demographic characteristic, 1954-80 [Percent1, monthly data seasonally adjusted] Black and other White All workers Total Year or month Females Males Females Males 20 20 16-19 years Total years Total 16-19 years and Total years and over over 20 16-19 years Total years and over Total 20 16-19 years years and over 1954 58.8 58.2 85.6 57,6 87.8 33,3 40.6 327 64.3 85.2 61.2 87.1 46.1 31.0 47,7 1955 1956... 1957 1958 1959 59.3 60.0 59.6 59.5 59.3 58.7 59.4 59.1 58.9 58.7 85.4 85.6 84.8 84.3 83.8 58.6 60.4 59.2 56.5 55.9 87.5 87.6 86.9 86.6 86.3 34.5 35.7 35.7 35.8 36.0 40.7 43.1 42.2 40.1 39.6 34.0 35.1 35.2 35.5 35.6 64.2 64.9 64.4 64.8 64.3 85.0 85.1 84.3 84.0 83.4 60.8 61.5 58.8 57.3 55.5 87.8 87.8 87.0 87.1 86.7 46.1 47.3 47.2 48.0 47.7 32.7 36.3 33.2 31.9 28.2 47.5 48.4 48.6 49.8 49.8 I960; 1961 1962 1963 1964 59.4 59.3 58.8 58.7 58.7 58.8 58.8 58.3 58.2 58.2 83.4 83.0 82.1 81.5 81.1 55.9 54.5 53.8 53.1 52.7 86.0 85.7 84.9 84.4 84.2 36.5 36.9 36.7 37.2 37.5 40.3 40.6 39.8 38.7 37.8 36.2 36.6 36.5 37.0 37.5 64.5 64.1 63.2 63.0 63.1 83.0 82.2 80.8 80.2 80.0 57.6 55.8 53.5 51.5 49,9 86.2 85.5 84.2 83.9 84.1 48.2 48.3 48.0 48.1 48.5 32.9 32.8 33.1 32,6 31.7 49.9 50.1 49.6 49.9 50.7 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 58.9 59.2 59.6 59.6 60.1 58.4 58.7 59.2 59.3 59.9 80.8 80.6 80.7 80.4 80.2 54.1 55.9 56.3 55.9 56.8 83.9 83.6 83.5 83,2 83.0 38.1 39.2 40.1 40.7 41.8 39.2 42.6 42.5 43.0 44.6 38.0 38.8 39.8 40.4 41.5 62.9 63.0 62.8 62,2 62.1 79.6 79.0 78.5 77.6 76.9 51.3 51.4 51.1 49.7 49.6 83.7 83.3 82.9 82.2 81.4 48.6 49.3 49.5 49.3 49.8 29.5 33.5 35.2 34.8 34.6 51.1 51.6 51.6 51.4 52.0 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 60.4 60.2 60.4 60.8 61.2 60.2 60.1 60.4 60.9 61.4 80.0 79.6 79.6 79.5 79.4 57.5 57.9 60.1 62.0 63.0 82.8 82.3 82.0 81.6 81.4 42.6 42.6 43.2 44.1 45.2 45.6 45.5 48.2 50.1 51.8 42.2 42.3 42.7 43.5 44.4 61.8 60.9 60.0 60.3 60.0 76.5 74.9 73.7 73.8 73.3 47.3 44.7 46.0 46.3 47.2 81.4 79.9 78.5 78,4 77.7 49.5 49.2 48.7 49.1 49.1 34.0 31.3 32.2 34.4 34.1 51.7 51.8 51.1 51.3 51.3 1975 1976.... 1977 1978 1979 61.2 61.6 62.3 63.2 63.7 61.5 61.9 62.6 63.4 64.0 78.7 78.4 78.5 78.6 78.6 61.9 62.4 64.1 65.1 64.8 80.7 80.3 80.3 80.2 80.2 45.9 46.9 48.1 49.5 50.6 51.6 52.9 54.7 56.9 57.6 45.3 46.2 47.4 48.7 49.9 59.3 59.4 60.0 61.8 61.8 71.5 70.7 71.0 72.1 71.9 42.7 42.1 43.4 45.4 43.9 76.4 75.6 75.6 76.5 76.4 49.2 50.2 50.9 53.3 53.5 35.6 33.5 33.6 38.1 38.0 51.2 52.6 53.4 55.5 55.6 1980 63.8 64.2 78.3 63.8 79.9 51.3 56.4 50.8 61.2 70.8 43.3 75.1 53.4 35.9 55.8 63.6 63.8 63.8 63.5 63.5 63.5 63.9 64.0 64.0 63.8 63.8 63.8 79.0 79.0 78.8 78.6 78.5 78.6 66.1 65.2 65.3 64.8 64.4 64.3 80.5 80.5 80.3 80.2 80.1 80.2 50.2 50.4 50.5 50.2 50.4 50.4 57.8 58.3 58.5 57.8 57.3 57.4 49.4 49.6 49.7 49.4 49.6 49.7 61.5 61.9 62.2 61.9 61.5 61.8 71.9 72.3 72.5 71.9 71.9 72.1 44.9 46.5 46.8 45.1 45.0 43.5 76.2 76.4 76.6 76.2 76.2 76.6 53.0 53.4 53.8 53.7 53.0 53.5 38.5 39.6 37.2 41.4 37.1 36.9 55.0 55.3 56.0 55.4 55.2 55.7 63.7 63.7 63.9 63.8 63.7 63.9 64.0 64.0 64.2 64.1 64.0 64.3 78.7 78.5 78,7 78.4 78.4 78.5 64.3 63.4 65.5 63.9 64.9 66.1 80.3 80.2 80.2 80.1 80.0 80.0 50.6 50.8 50.9 51.0 50.9 51.2 57.2 56.3 57.3 57.8 57.9 57.9 50.0 50.2 50.2 50.3 50.2 50.5 61.8 61.7 61.9 62.0 61.4 61.6 72.0 72.2 72.5 71.9 70.9 71.1 41.8 45.2 43.1 42.5 41.3 41.0 76.9 76.5 77.2 76.6 75.6 75.8 53.4 53.1 53.1 54.0 53.7 53.9 37.1 34.6 36.5 38.7 38.1 39.7 55.6 55.6 55.4 56.1 55.7 55.8 63.9 63.9 63.7 63.8 64.1 63.8 64.3 64.3 64.1 64.3 64.5 64.2 78.5 78.6 78.5 78.5 78.9 78.3 65.1 65.0 65.6 64.1 64.8 63.5 80.0 80.1 79.9 80.1 80.5 80.0 51.3 51.2 51.1 51.3 51.4 51.3 57.5 56.6 56.1 55.9 57.1 56.1 50.7 50.7 50.6 50.8 50.8 50.8 61.6 61.2 60.7 61.0 61.5 61.1 71.2 70.8 70.3 70.6 70.8 70.8 43.2 42.0 41.7 41.7 44.0 43.5 75.6 75.3 74.8 75.0 75.0 75.0 53.8 53.3 52.8 53.1 53.9 53.2 38.0 39.1 36.9 34.8 37.1 35.4 55.9 55.2 55.0 55.5 56.2 55.5 63.9 63.8 63.8 63.8 63.8 63.6 64.2 64.1 64.1 64.2 64.1 63.9 78.3 78.2 78.2 78.2 78.1 77.9 63.6 62.7 62.5 63.6 63.1 62.4 80.0 79.9 79.9 79.8 79.8 79.6 51.4 51.3 51.3 51.3 51.4 51.2 56.9 55.6 56.8 56.5 56.3 56.0 50.8 50.9 50.7 50.8 50.9 50.7 61.7 61.4 61.5 61.4 61.3 61.0 71.4 70.8 71.6 70.9 70.9 70.3 44.6 39.7 45.7 44.8 45.3 44.0 75.6 75.7 75.6 75.0 74.9 74.4 53.8 53.8 53.2 53.6 53.5 54.8 36.3 34.9 36.2 34.2 34.1 34.3 56.1 56.2 55.5 56.1 56.0 55.9 1979: Jan.... Feb.. Mar.. .. ft: •. •. June July.. Aug... Sept. Oct Nov.., Dec... 1980: Jan..., Feb... Mar.., May .. June. July... AUg... Sept.... Oct.... Nov... . Dec... . . . . 1 Civilian labor force as percent of civilian noninstitutional population in group specified. Note.—See footnote 3 and Note, Table B-27. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 268 TABLE B-31.—Unemployment rate by demographic characteristic, 1948-80 [Percent; l monthly data seasonally adjusted] White Females Males All Year or month Black and other Males Females work- ers 20 Total Total 16-19 years years and over 20 Total 1948 1949 3.8 5.9 3.5 5.6 3.4 5.6 3.8 5.7 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 5.3 .4.9 3.3 3.1 3.0 28 2.9 2.7 5.5 5.0 4.7 2.6 2.5 2.5 4.8 114 4*4 5.3 4.2 33 3.1 5.5 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 4.4 4.1 4.3 6.8 5.5 3.9 3.6 3.8 6.1 4.8 3.7 3.4 3.6 6.1 4.6 11.3 10.5 11.5 15.7 14.0 3.3 3.0 3.2 5.5 4.1 4.3 4.2 4.3 6.2 5.3 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 5.5 6.7 5.5 5.7 5.2 4.9 60 4.9 5.0 4.6 4.8 5.7 4.6 4.7 4.1 14.0 15.7 13.7 15.9 14.7 4.2 5.1 4.0 3.9 3.4 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 4.5 3.8 3.8 3.6 3.5 4.1 3.3 3.4 32 3.1 3.6 2.8 2.7 2.6 2.5 12.9 10.5 10.7 10.1 10.0 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 4.9 5.9 5.6 4.9 5.6 4.5 5.4 5.0 4.3 5.0 4.0 4.9 4.5 3.7 4.3 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 8.5 7.7 7.0 6.0 5.8 7.8 7.0 6.2 5.2 5.1 1980 7.1 5.8 16-19 years .... .... 20 Total years and over Total 16-19 years years and over 20 16-19 years years and over 20,6 8.4 19.2 22.8 20.2 28.4 27.7 7.7 7.8 6.4 9.5 8.3 24.8 29.2 30.2 34.7 31.6 8.3 106 9.6 9.4 9.0 31.7 29.6 28.7 27.6 7.5 6.6 7.1 6.3 5.8 10.5 10.7 34.4 35.4 38.5 34.5 34.6 6.9 8.7 8.8 8.2 8.4 38.5 39.0 39.9 38.4 35.7 U.5 U.3 Total 5.9 8.9 5.8 9.6 6.1 7.9 9.0 5.3 5.4 4.5 9.9 9.4 4.9 5.2 4.8 10.3 14 4 9.9 8.4 6.1 57 4.1 9.2 8.7 8.3 7.9 8.8 7.9 8.3 8.4 7.4 7.6 8.5 8.9 7.3 12.6 10.7 12.7 10.5 10.8 U.5 13.4 15.0 18.4 26.8 25.2 9.6 117 9.4 10.0 9.2 7.7 11.9 11.0 11.2 10.7 9.2 8.7 9.1 8.3 7.8 10.4 5.1 9.1 9J 9.5 12.7 12.0 3.9 3.7 3.8 5.6 4.7 5.3 6.5 5.5 5.8 5.5 12.7 14.8 12.8 15.1 14.9 4.6 5.7 4.7 4.8 4.6 10.2 12.4 10.9 10.8 10.7 12.8 10.9 10.5 9.6 8.9 24.0 26.8 22.0 27.3 24.3 2.9 2.2 2.1 2.0 1.9 5.0 4.3 4.6 43 4.2 14.0 12.1 11.5 12.1 11.5 4.0 3.3 3.8 3.4 3.4 8.1 7.3 7.4 6.7 6.4 7.4 6.3 6.1 5.6 5.3 23.3 21.3 23.9 22.1 21.4 6.0 4.9 4.3 3.9 3.7 13.7 15.1 14.2 12.3 13.5 3.2 4.0 3.6 2.9 3.5 5.4 6.3 5.9 5.3 6.1 13.4 15.1 14.2 13.0 14.5 4.4 5.3 4.9 4.3 5.0 10.0 8.2 9.9 8.9 9.9 7.3 9.1 8.9 7.6 9.1 25.0 28.9 29.7 26.9 31.6 5.6 7.2 6.8 5.7 6.8 7.2 6.4 5.5 4.5 4.4 18.3 17.3 15.0 13.5 13.9 6.2 5.4 4.6 3.7 3.6 8.6 7.9 7.3 6.2 5.9 17.4 16.4 15.9 14.4 13.9 7.5 6.8 6.2 5.2 5.0 13.9 13.1 13.1 11.9 11.3 13.7 12.7 12.4 10.9 10.3 35.4 35.4 37.0 34.4 31.5 11.7 10.6 10.0 8.6 8.4 14.0 13.6 14.0 13.1 12.3 6.3 6.1 16.2 5.2 6.5 14.8 5.6 13.2 13.3 34.9 11.4 13.1 36.9 11.1 51 5.0 4.5 ivfay ",'„'. ' ". ". 4.3 4.2 3.6 3.5 3.5 3.4 3.3 3.4 6.0 6.0 6.0 5.9 5.9 5.8 13.8 13.4 13.4 14.0 13.7 13.9 5.0 5.1 5.1 4.9 4.9 4.9 11.9 11.3 11.7 11.3 10.2 11.0 10.9 10.6 10.1 U.I 9.9 33.6 33.3 31.9 32.7 31.0 32.0 8.9 8.9 8.5 8.2 7.9 12.5 12.9 11.8 13.0 12.5 12.5 32.0 34.9 31.8 38.7 42.4 35.7 10.6 10.7 10.0 10.3 June 5.1 5.0 4.9 4.8 14.2 14.3 14.2 14.1 14.2 12.0 8.0 5.8 5.8 5.6 5.6 4.4 U.3 5.9 July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 4.9 5.2 5.1 4.3 4.5 4.6 4.7 4.8 3.5 3.6 3.6 3.7 3.8 3.9 5.7 6.1 5.8 6.0 5.9 6.0 13.7 14.4 14.2 14.6 13.7 14.3 5.2 4.9 5.0 5.0 5.1 10.7 11.1 10.7 11.4 11.0 11.5 30.5 28.7 28.9 31.4 31.5 31.9 8.1 8.0 7.8 8.7 8.6 9.0 U.5 5.3 13.3 14.4 14.6 13.6 13.9 14.1 9.9 9.7 9.5 . . . 5.6 5.9 5.8 5.9 5.9 6.0 30.2 38.3 35.1 38.5 34.8 35.6 5.5 5.4 5.5 6.1 6.8 6.7 5.1 4.9 5.2 6.0 6.8 6.7 14.4 13.8 13.5 15.0 17.8 17.4 4.2 4.1 4.5 5.2 5.8 5.7 6.1 6.2 6.0 6.4 6.7 6.6 14.0 14.6 14.7 14.5 16.3 14.7 5.1 5.2 5.0 5.5 5.7 5.7 11.9 11.7 11.9 12.6 13.6 13.5 U.5 U.5 11.2 12.3 13.5 14.0 32.4 34.2 31.1 29.1 32.9 33.5 9.7 9.5 Apr. ... May June ... 6.2 6.2 6.3 6.9 7.6 7.5 9.5 10.8 11.7 12.2 12.6 12.9 13.7 12.9 36.5 39.6 36.4 34.8 37.9 36.3 7.6 7.6 7.4 7.6 7.5 6.8 6.7 6.5 6.6 6.6 6.5 6.8 6.7 6.6 6.6 6.6 6.4 17.5 17.5 16.2 17.3 17.7 16.4 5.8 5.8 5.8 5.7 5.7 5.5 6.8 6.8 6.4 6.7 6.7 6.7 15.4 15.5 13.8 14.5 14.9 14.2 5.8 5.8 5.5 5.8 5.8 5.9 13.9 13.7 14.1 14.2 14.0 14.0 14.4 14.6 15.3 14.3 14.1 13.9 35.0 39.4 37.7 38.2 35.9 38.8 12.5 12.5 13.2 12.1 12.0 11.6 13.3 12.7 12.8 14.1 14.0 14.1 37.0 35.7 37.9 36.4 37.4 36.1 1979: Jan Feb .... Mar .. 1980Jan Feb Mar July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec ... 7.4 4.4 4.1 4.5 5.1 5.2 1 Unemployment as percent of civilian labor force in group specified. Note.—See footnote 3 and Note, Table B-27. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 333-Si+O O - 81 - 18 : QL 3 269 4.7 13.7 10.5 10.4 10.8 9.4 9.3 10.8 U.3 12.6 12.0 12.4 11.7 12.2 12.3 U.9 3L3 11.7 10.6 10.1 9.8 10.4 9.8 10.4 10.0 10.0 9.6 10.0 10.1 9.3 10.5 11.1 11.6 10.9 U.3 10.9 10.6 12.3 12.2 12.3 TABLE B-32.—Unemployment by duration, 1947-80 [Monthly data seasonally adjusted1] Year or month Total unemployment Duration of unemployment Less than 5 weeks 5-14 weeks 15-26 weeks 27 weeks and over (mean) duration in weeks Thousands of persons 16 years of age and over 704 669 234 193 428 164 116 256 1,055 425 166 148 357 137 84 1947,. 1948. 1949.. 2,311 2,276 3,637 1,210 1,300 1,756 1950 1951. 1952 1953 1954 3,288 2,055 1,883 1,834 3,532 1,450 1,177 1,135 1,142 1,605 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 2,852 2,750 2,859 4,602 3,740 1,335 1,412 1,408 1,753 1,585 1,396 1,114 1960 . 1961 1962. 1963 1964 3,852 4,714 3,911 4,070 3,786 1,719 1,806 1,663 1,751 1,697 1,176 1,376 1,134 1,231 1,117 1965 . 1966 1967 1968 1969.. 3,366 2,875 2,975 2,817 2,832 1,628 1,573 1,634 1,594 1,629 983 779 893 810 827 1970 1971 . 1972 . 1973 1974 4,088 4,993 4,840 4,304 5,076 2,137 2,234 2,223 2,196 2,567 1975. . 1976.., 1977 1978 1979 7,830 7,288 6,855 6,047 5,963 1980 1,194 8.6 10.0 317 12.1 9.7 8.4 8.0 11.8 336 232 239 667 571 13.0 11.3 10.5 13.9 14.4 454 804 585 553 482 12.8 15.6 14.7 14.0 13.3 256 242 351 239 177 156 133 11.8 10.4 8.8 8.5 7.9 1,289 1,578 1,459 1,296 1,572 427 665 597 475 563 235 517 562 337 373 11.4 12.1 10.0 9.7 2,894 2,790 2,856 2,793 2,869 2,452 2,159 2,089 1,875 1,892 1,290 1,003 896 746 684 1,193 1,336 1,015 633 518 14.1 15.8 14.3 11.9 10.8 7,448 3,208 2,411 1,028 802 11.9 5,958 5,993 5,956 5,918 5,776 5,718 2,737 2,822 2,774 2,842 2,725 2,848 1,947 1,915 1,885 1,875 1,861 1,753 693 704 745 675 686 653 524 547 569 530 505 504 11.2 11.3 11.7 11.0 10.9 10.5 Nov 5,738 6,057 5,971 6,132 6,104 6,272 2,775 3,156 2,851 2,972 2,976 2,984 1,868 1,735 2,009 1,962 1,880 2,000 629 657 635 681 680 717 445 517 507 510 531 530 10.3 10.6 10.6 10.5 10.6 10.6 Jan. Feb. Mar Apr May June 6,500 6,454 6,543 7,202 7,944 7,811 3,163 3,049 3,005 3,258 3,714 3,281 1,994 2,134 2,207 2,373 2,589 2,812 776 794 796 931 980 1,024 543 505 595 668 706 753 10.6 10.7 11.0 11.2 10.6 11.7 July Aug Sept 8,021 7,942 7,800 7,961 7,946 7,785 3,317 3,255 3,042 3,186 3,108 3,115 2,649 2,533 2,586 2,500 2,524 2,217 1,093 1,239 1,366 1,256 1,213 1,231 842 11.8 12.5 13.0 13.3 13.6 13.5 1979: Jan Feb.. Mar t June. July Aug. Sept Oct . Dec... 1980: Oct Nov . Dec 574 516 482 132 495 366 301 321 785 469 503 728 534 535 491 404 287 271 1,116 815 805 891 1 Because of independent seasonal adjustment of the various series, detail will not add to totals. Note.—See footnote 3 and Note, Table B-27. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 270 78 911 929 1,036 1,116 1,147 TABLE B-33.—Unemployment by reason, 1967-80 [Monthly data seasonally adjusted 1 ] Year or month Total unemployment Job losers Job leavers Reentrants Thousands of persons 16 years of age and over 1967 1968 1969 2,975 2,817 2,832 1,229 1,070 1,017 1970 1971 . .. 1972 .. . 1973 1974 4,088 4,993 4,840 4,304 5,076 1975 1976 1977 1978 . 1979 1980 945 909 965 1,809 2,313 2,089 1,666 2,205 438 431 436 549 587 635 674 756 1,227 1,466 1,444 1,323 1,441 7,830 7,288 6,855 6,047 5,963 4,341 3,625 3,103 2,514 2,555 812 886 889 851 854 1,865 1,895 1,926 1,814 1,758 7,448 3,860 863 1,875 6,500 7,202 7,944 7,811 3,038 2,979 3,102 3,581 4,164 4,468 807 831 804 905 930 887 1,797 1,812 1,909 1,975 1,834 8,021 7,942 7,800 7,961 7,946 7,785 4,364 4,319 4,387 4,240 4,229 4,226 866 890 855 870 897 813 1,868 1,883 1,844 2,013 1,896 1,869 1967.. 1968.. 1969. 3.8 3.6 3.5 1.6 1.3 1.2 0.6 1970. ... 1971 1972 1973.. .. 1974 .. 4.9 5.9 5.6 4.9 5.6 2.2 2.8 2.4 1.9 2.4 .7 .7 .7 1975.. 1976. 1977 1978 . 1979 8.5 7.7 7.0 6.0 5.8 4.7 3.8 3.2 2.5 2.5 2.0 2.0 2.0 1.8 1.7 1980.., 7.1 3.7 1.8 6.2 6.2 6.3 6.9 7.6 7.5 2.9 2.9 3.0 3.4 4.0 4.3 1.7 1.7 1.7 1.8 1.9 1.8 7.6 7.6 7.4 7.6 7.5 7.4 4.2 4.1 4.2 4.0 4.0 4.0 1980: Jan.. . Feb Mar .. Apr . ... f^ June July . Aug Sept ... Oct Nov Dec. . . Percent of civilian labor force 1980: Jan Feb. Mar. May' June July.. Aug.. Sept Ocf Nov. Dec 1 Because of independent seasonal adjustment of the various series, detail will not add to totals. Note.-See footnote 3 and Note, Table B-27. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 271 is .9 .9 .8 .8 .8 .8 .8 .9 1.2 1.2 1.2 1.5 1.7 1.7 1.5 1.6 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.9 1.8 1.8 TABLE B-34.—Unemployment insurance programs, selected data, 1946-80 All programs Year or month State programs Total Insured benefits , Insured Covered unemployment paid employunem(weekly (millions ployment ment 1 averof 2 age)" dollars) * 31,856 33,876 34,646 33,098 34,308 36,334 37,006 38,072 36,622 40,018 42,751 43,436 44,411 45,728 46,334 46,266 47,776 48,434 49,637 51,580 54,739 56,342 57,977 59,999 59,526 59,375 66,458 69,897 72,451 71,037 73,459 76,419 88,804 '92,062 Exhaustions 5 Weekly average; thousands Thousands 1946 1947 1948. 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953. 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959. 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 .. 1972... 1973 ,. 1974 1975 1976. 1977,, 1978 1979 Initial claims Insured unemployment as percent Total Average (millions of weekly covered of check employ- dollars) * (dollars) 9 ment 2,804 1,793 1,446 2,474 2,878.5 1,785.5 1,328.7 2,269.8 1,295 997 980 1,973 1,605 1,000 1,069 1,067 2,051 1,399 1,323 1,571 2,773 1,860 1,467.6 862.9 1,043.5 1,050.6 2,291.6 1,560.2 1,540.6 1,913.0 4,290.6 2,854.3 1,513 969 1,044 990 1,870 1,265 1,215 1,446 2,510 1,684 2,071 2,994 1,946 7 1,973 1,753 1,450 1,129 1,270 1,187 1,177 3,022.8 4,358.1 3,145.1 3,025.9 2,749.2 2,360.4 1,890.9 2,221.5 2,191.0 2,298.6 1,908 2,290 1,783 7 1,806 1,605 1,328 1,061 1,205 1,111 1,101 2,070 2,608 2,192 1,793 2,558 4,937 3,846 3,308 2,645 2,592 4,209.3 6,154.0 5,491.1 4,517.3 6,933.9 16,802.4 12,344.8 10,998.9 9,006.9 9,401.3 1,805 2,150 1,848 1,632 2,262 3,986 2,991 2,655 2,359 2,434 3,198 3,209 2,921 2,610 2,230 2,119 1,036.6 972.1 1,043.0 844.2 793.2 662.9 2,345 2,329 2,336 2,381 2,307 2,320 2,429 2,377 2,164 2,236 2,559 3,047 715.1 820.2 656.1 741.2 795.9 909.0 2,409 2,492 2,488 2,540 2,643 2,631 3,740 3,730 3,652 3,629 3,680 3,790 1,368.2 1,307.0 1,323.8 1,378.3 1,338.3 1,333.8 2,729 2,685 2,857 3,204 3,717 4,009 4,140 3,911 3,961 3,661 3,726 1,579.5 1,441.8 1,503.0 3,880 3,778 3,802 3,589 3,332 189 187 200 340 236 208 215 218 304 226 227 270 369 277 331 350 302 7 298 268 232 203 226 201 200 296 295 261 247 363 478 386 375 346 388 4.3 3.1 3.0 6.2 1,094.9 775.1 789.9 1,736.0 18.50 17.83 19.03 20.48 4.6 2.8 2.9 2.8 5.2 3.5 3.2 3.6 6.4 4.4 1,373.1 840.4 998.2 962.2 2,026.9 1,350.3 1,380.7 1,733.9 3,512.7 2,279.0 20.76 21.09 22.79 23.58 24.93 25.04 27.02 28.17 30.58 30.41 4.8 5.6 4.4 4.3 3.8 3.0 2.3 2.5 2.2 2.1 2,726.7 3,4227 2,675.4 2,774.7 2,522.1 2,166.0 1,771.3 2,092.3 2,031.6 2,127.9 32.87 33.80 34.56 35.27 35.92 37.19 39.75 41.25 43.43 46.17 3.4 4.1 3.5 2.7 3.5 6.0 4.6 3.9 3.3 2.9 3,848.5 4,957.0 4,471.0 4,007.6 5,974.9 11,754.7 8,974.5 8,357.2 7,717.2 8,612.9 50.34 54.02 56.76 59.00 64.25 70.23 75.16 78.79 83.67 89.67 3.0 3.0 3.0 3.0 2.9 2.9 972.8 915.1 975.6 777.7 725.2 610.3 88.28 90.31 90.28 89.28 88,37 87.25 2.9 3.0 3.0 3.0 3.1 3.1 665.7 765.0 606.3 674.0 728.4 843.9 86.40 88.56 89.10 90.59 92.23 94.54 3.2 3.1 3.3 3.7 4.3 4.7 1,283.9 1,229.9 1,218.2 1,232.2 1,196.8 1,213.6 96.41 98.39 99.19 99.52 99.55 99.88 4.5 4.4 4.4 4.1 3.8 1,397.5 1,249.8 1,144.9 98.75 99.68 99.86 1979: Jan Feb Mar June July Aug Sept. Oct Nov Dec 1980: Jan Feb Mar. . . May!'.' . June July Aug.. Sept Oct.... Nov.... 352 346 359 433 355 380 390 394 394 402 405 416 414 389 455 574 642 617 530 506 494 446 403 **Monthly data are seasonally adjusted. •Includes persons under the State, UCFE (Federal employee, effective January 1955), and RRB (Railroad Retirement Board) programs. Beginning October 1958, also includes the UCX program {unemployment compensation for ex-servicemen). includes State, UCFE, RR, UCX, UCV (unemployment compensation for veterans, October 1952-January 1960), and SRA (Servicemen's Readjustment Act, September 1944-September 1951) programs. Also includes Federal and State extended benefit programs. Does not include FSB (Federal supplemental benefits) and SUA (special unemployment assistance) programs. 3 Covered workers who have completed at least 1 week of unemployment. 4 Annual data are net amounts and monthly data are gross amounts. • 8 Individuals receiving final payments in benefit year. 6 For total unemployment only. 7 Programs include Puerto Rican sugarcane workers for initial claims and insured unemployment beginning July 1963. 8 Latest data available for all programs combined. Workers covered by State programs account for about 97 percent of wage and salary earners. Source: Department of Labor, Employment and Training Administration. 272 TABLE B-35.—Wage and salary workers in nonagricultural establishments, 1929-80 [Thousands of persons; monthly data seasonally adjusted] Year or month Total wage and salary workers Manufacturing Total Non- Mining Construction Durable durable goods goods Government Transpor- Whole- Finance, insurtation sale ance, Services and State and and Federal public and retail real utilities trade estate local 1929 1933 1939 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 ... . 1952.. . 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958. . .. 1959. 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 . . 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975.... 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980". . 31324 10,702 7 397 23 699 30,603 1O',278 32,361 10,985 36,539 13,192 40,106 15,280 42,434 17,602 41,864 17,328 40,374 15,524 41,652 14,703 43 857 15,545 44,866 15,582 43,754 14,441 45,197 15,241 47,819 16,393 48,793 16,632 50,202 17,549 48,990 16,314 50,641 16,882 52,369 17,243 52,853 17,174 51,324 15,945 53,268 16,675 54,189 16,796 53,999 16,326 55,549 16,853 56,653 16,995 58 283 17,274 60 765 18,062 63,901 19,214 65,803 19,447 67,897 19,781 70,384 20,167 70,880 19,367 71,214 18,623 73,675 19,151 76,790 20,154 78,265 20,077 76,945 18,323 79,382 18,997 82,471 19,682 86,697 20,505 89,886 21,062 90,652 20,365 4,715 5,363 6,968 8,823 11,084 10,856 9,074 7,742 8,385 8,326 7,489 8,094 9,089 9,349 10,110 9,129 9,541 9,833 9,855 8,829 9,373 9,459 9,070 9r480 9,616 9,816 10,405 11,282 11,439 11,626 11,895 11,208 10,636 11,049 11,891 11,925 10,688 11,077 11,597 12,274 12,772 12,218 5,564 5,622 6,225 6,458 6,518 6,472 6,450 6,962 7,159 7,256 6,953 7,147 7,304 7,284 7,438 7,185 7,341 7,411 7,321 7,116 7,303 7,337 7,256 7,373 7,380 7,458 7,656 7,930 8,007 8,155 8,272 8,158 7,987 8,102 8,262 8,152 7,635 7,920 8,086 8,231 8,290 8,147 1,087 744 854 925 957 992 925 892 836 862 955 994 930 901 929 898 866 791 792 822 828 751 732 712 672 650 635 634 632 627 613 606 619 623 609 628 642 697 752 779 813 851 960 1,025 1,512 824 1,165 1,311 1,814 2,198 1,587 1,108 1,147 1,683 2,009 2,198 2,194 2,364 2,637 2,668 2,659 2,646 2,839 3,039 2,962 2,817 3,004 2,926 2,859 2,948 3,010 3,097 3,232 3,317 3,248 3,350 3,575 3,588 3,704 3,889 4,097 4,020 3,525 3,576 3,851 4,229 4,483 4,468 3,916 2,672 2,936 3,038 3,274 3,460 3,647 3,829 3,906 4,061 4,166 4,189 4,001 4,034 4,226 4,248 4,290 4,084 4,141 4,244 4,241 3,976 4,011 4,004 3,903 3,906 3,903 3,951 4,036 4,158 4,268 4,318 4,442 4,515 4,476 4,541 4,656 4,725 4,542 4,582 4,713 4,923 5,141 5,155 6,123 4,755 6,426 6,750 7,210 7,118 6,982 7,058 7,314 8,376 8,955 9,272 9,264 9,386 9,742 10,004 10,247 10,235 10,535 10,858 10,886 10,750 11,127 11,391 11,337 11,566 11,778 12,160 12,716 13,245 13,606 14,099 14,705 15,040 15,352 15,949 16,607 16,987 17,060 17,755 18,516 19,542 20,269 20,571 1,494 1,280 1,447 1,485 1,525 1,509 1,481 1,461 1,481 1,675 1,728 1,800 1,828 1,888 1,956 2,035 2,111 2,200 2,298 2,389 2,438 2,481 2,549 2,629 2,688 2,754 2,830 2,911 2,977 3,058 3,185 3,337 3,512 3,645 3,772 3,908 4,046 4,148 4,165 4,271 4,467 4,724 4,974 5,162 3,425 2,861 3,502 3,665 3,905 4,066 4,130 4,145 4,222 4,697 5,025 5,181 5,240 5,357 5,547 5,699 5,835 5,969 6,240 6,497 6,708 6,765 7,087 7,378 7,620 7,982 8,277 8,660 9,036 9,498 10,045 10,567 11,169 11,548 11,797 12,276 12,857 13,441 13,892 14,551 15,303 16,252 17,078 17,736 533 565 905 996 1,340 2,213 2,905 2,928 2,808 2,254 1,892 1,863 1,908 1,928 2,302 2,420 2,305 2,188 2,187 2,209 2,217 2,191 2,233 2,270 2,279 2,340 2,358 2,348 2,378 2,564 2,719 2,737 2,758 2,731 2,696 2,684 2,663 2,724 2,748 2,733 2,727 2,753 2,773 2,867 2,532 2,601 3,090 3,206 3,320 3,270 3,175 3,116 3,137 3,341 3,582 3,787 3,948 4,098 4,087 4,188 4,340 4,563 4,727 5,069 5,399 5,648 5,850 6,083 6,315 6,550 6,868 7,248 7,696 8,220 8,672 9,102 9,437 9,823 10,185 10,649 11,068 11,446 11,937 12,138 12,399 12,919 13,147 13,304 1979: Jan Feb Mar 88,858 89,109 89,455 89,386 89,708 89,909 90,054 90,222 90,283 90,441 90,552 90,678 21,040 21,094 21,130 21,113 21,113 21,132 21,128 21,055 21,071 21,043 20,966 20,983 12,717 12,781 12,814 12,811 12,810 12,837 12,841 12,782 12,822 12,764 12,693 12,706 8,323 8,313 8,316 8,302 8,303 8,295 8,287 8,273 8,249 8,279 8,273 8,277 927 936 940 941 946 953 963 974 976 982 985 992 4,396 4,347 4,467 4,419 4,463 4,472 4,491 4,499 4,507 4,529 4,553 4,615 5,061 5,082 5,103 5,008 5,110 5,168 5,156 5,182 5,185 5,203 5,216 5,212 20,058 20,126 20,159 20,176 20,209 20,217 20,254 20,301 20,352 20,414 20,479 20,448 4,872 4,889 4,905 4,924 4,951 4,970 4,989 5,019 5,017 5,033 5,049 5,064 16,728 16,831 16,928 16.944 17,029 17,074 17,114 17,152 17,192 17,264 17,308 17,362 2,757 2,759 2,758 2,760 2,770 2,783 2,784 2,811 2,762 2,769 2,773 2,773 13,019 13,045 13,065 13,101 13,117 13,140 13,175 13,229 13,221 13,204 13,223 13,229 20,971 20,957 20,938 20,642 20,286 20,014 19,828 19,940 20,044 20,157 20,282 20,349 12,681 12,715 12,707 12,442 12,140 11,947 11,819 11,860 11,955 12,043 12,147 12,185 8,290 8,242 8,231 8,200 8,146 8,067 8,009 8,080 8,089 8,114 8,135 8,164 999 1,007 1,009 1,012 1,023 1,029 1,013 1,013 1,028 1,037 1,054 1,070 4,745 4359 4,529 4,467 4,436 4,379 4,322 4,359 4,404 4,442 4,468 4,497 5,202 5,198 5,202 5,178 5,167 5,134 5,114 5,129 5,124 5,147 5,133 5,135 20,529 20,637 20,610 20,531 20,487 20,459 20,506 20,589 20,620 20,641 20,647 20,626 5,091 5,101 5,115 5,119 5,137 5,150 5,167 5,180 5,194 5,214 5,227 5,240 17,462 17,540 17,580 17,618 17,659 17,652 17,760 17,788 17,861 17,913 17,951 18,025 2,791 2,826 2,886 3,115 2,960 2,951 2,893 2,828 2,765 2,788 2,793 2,808 13,241 13,261 13,275 13,269 13,313 13,279 13,264 13,316 13,344 13,371 13,362 13,372 day!!!!!!!!!!! June July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 1980: 91,031 Jan Feb 91,186 Mar!!!!!.!!..!. 91,144 90,951 90,468 June 90,047 89,867 July Aug 90,142 Sept 90,384 Oct 90,710 Nov" 90,917 Dec" 91,122 X'::::::: Note.—Data in Tables B-35 through 8-37 are based on reports from employing establishments and relate to full- and parttime wage and salary workers in nonagricultural establishments who worked during or received pay for any part of the pay period which includes the 12th of the month. Not comparable with labor force data (Tables B-27 through B-33), which include proprietors, self-employed persons, domestic servants, and unpaid family workers,* which count persons as employed when they are not at work because of industrial disputes, bad weather, etc., even if they are not paid for the time off; and which are based on a sample of the working-age population. For description and details of the various establishment data, see "Employment and Earnings." Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 273 TABLE B-36.—Average weekly hours and hourly earnings in selected private nonagricultural industries, 1947-80 [For production or nonsupervisory workers; monthly data seasonally adjusted] Average gross hourly earnings, current dollars Average weekly hours Year or month Adjusted hourly earnings, total private nonagricultural3 Percent change WholeIndex, Whole- Total Total from a year private sale sale private Manufac1967-100 ConConManufacearlier 4 nonand and nonstruction turing turing struction agriculretail agriculretail Current 1967 1967 l Current 1 tural trade tural trade dollars dollars3 dollars dollars $1,540 $0,940 1.712 1.010 1.792 1.060 42.6 46.0 48.2 63.7 63.8 67.5 So 4.8 0.2 1.100 1.18 1.23 1.30 1.35 50.0 53.7 56.4 59.6 61.7 69.3 69.0 70.9 74.4 76.6 3.7 7.4 5.0 5.7 3.5 2.7 -.4 2.8 4.9 3.0 2.45 2.57 2.71 2.82 2.93 1.40 1.47 1.54 1.60 1.66 63.7 67.0 70.3 73.2 75.8 79.4 82.3 83.4 84.5 86.8 3.2 5.2 4.9 4.1 3.6 3.7 3.7 1.3 1.3 2.7 2.26 2.32 2.39 2.45 2.53 3.07 3.20 3.31 3.41 3.55 1.71 1.76 1.83 1.89 1.97 78.4 80.8 83.5 85.9 88.2 88.4 90.2 92.2 93.7 95.0 2.46 2.56 2.68 2.85 3.04 2.61 2.71 2.82 3.01 3.19 3.70 3.89 4.11 4.41 4.79 2.04 2.14 2.25 2.41 2.56 91.2 95.3 100.0 106.2 113.2 96.6 98.0 100.0 101.9 103.1 3.4 3.1 3.3 2.9 2.7 3.4 4,5 4.9 6.2 6.6 1.8 2.0 2.2 1.6 1.4 1.7 1.4 2.0 1.9 1.2 35.3 35.1 34.9 34.6 34.2 3.23 3.45 3.70 3.94 4.24 3.35 3.57 3.82 4.09 4.42 5.24 5.69 6.06 6.41 6.81 2.72 2.88 3.05 3.23 3.48 120.7 129.2 137.5 146.0 157.5 103.8 106.5 109.7 109.7 106.7 6.6 7.0 6.4 6.2 7.9 .7 2.6 3.0 .0 36.4 36.8 36.5 36.8 37.0 33.9 33.7 33.3 32.9 32.6 4.53 4.86 5.25 5.69 6.16 4.83 5.22 5.68 6.17 6.69 7.31 7.71 8.10 8.66 9.27 3.73 3.97 4.28 4.67 5.06 170.6 183.0 196.8 212.9 229.8 105.9 107.3 108.4 109.0 105.6 8.3 7.3 7.5 8.2 7.9 39.7 37.0 32.1 6.66 7.27 9.93 5.48 250.6 fczz June 35.7 35.7 35.9 35.3 35.6 35.6 40.6 40.6 40.6 39.3 40.2 40.1 36.7 36.9 37.5 35.6 37.1 37.2 32.5 32.6 32.7 32.8 32.6 32.6 5.96 5.99 6.03 6.03 6.08 6.13 6.47 6.52 6.56 6.57 6.65 6.69 8.96 9.06 9.05 9.13 9.20 9.21 4.91 4.93 4.97 4.99 5.01 5.05 222.6 224.0 225.2 226.7 227.6 229.2 108.4 107.8 107.3 106.9 106.3 105.9 8.2 8.4 8.2 8.0 7.8 7.9 -1.1 -1.4 -1.9 -2.4 -2.8 -2.9 July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 35.6 35.7 35.6 35.6 35.6 35.7 40.1 40,1 40.1 40.1 40.1 40.2 36.9 37.3 37.5 36.8 37.0 37.2 32.6 32.6 32.6 32.6 32.6 32.6 6.17 6.22 6.26 6.28 6.34 6.39 6.73 6.75 6.79 6.82 6.87 6.91 9.29 9.33 9.39 9.40 9.48 9.55 5.07 5.11 5.13 5.15 5.20 5.23 230.8 232.3 234.3 235.0 237.3 239.4 105.5 105.2 104.9 104.2 104.1 103.8 7.8 8.0 8.2 7.7 8.2 8.3 -3.3 -3.5 -3.7 -4.2 -4.1 -4.5 May June 35.6 35.5 35.4 35.3 35.1 35.0 40.3 40.1 39.8 39.8 39.3 39.1 37.3 37.1 36.6 36.7 36.8 37.1 32.6 32.4 32.3 32.0 32.1 31.9 6.41 6.45 6.51 6.54 6.57 6.62 6.93 6.99 7.06 7.11 7.15 7.22 9.46 9.64 9.75 9.79 9.83 9.89 5.28 5.31 5.37 5.38 5.42 5.45 240.3 242.4 245.2 246.2 248.3 250.9 102.7 102.2 102.0 101.4 101.4 101.5 7.9 8.2 8.9 8.6 9.1 9.4 -5.3 -5.2 -5.0 -5.2 -4.6 -4.2 July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec" 34.9 35.1 35.2 35.3 35.4 35.4 39.0 39.4 39.6 39.7 39.9 40.2 36.8 36.5 37.4 37.0 37.1 37.0 31.8 32.0 32.1 32.2 32.2 32.2 6.67 6.71 6.77 6.83 6.91 6.95 7.30 7.36 7.42 7.49 7.58, 7.64 9.94 10.04 10.05 10.14 10.20 10.29 5.50 5.53 5.56 5.59 5.65 5.68 252.1 254.0 255.4 257.9 260.7 261.6 102.0 102.0 101.5 101.5 101.6 9.2 9.3 9.0 9.7 9.8 9.3 -3.4 -3.0 -3.2 -2.5 -2.5 1947 1948 1949 40.3 40.0 39.4 40.4 40.0 39.1 38.2 38.1 37.7 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 39.8 39.9 39.9 39.6 39.1 40.5 40.6 40.7 40.5 39.6 37.4 40.5 40.5 38.1 40.0 38.9 37.9 : 39.5 37.2 < 39.5 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 39.6 39.3 38.8 38.5 39.0 40.7 40.4 39.8 39.2 40.3 37.1 37.5 37.0 36.8 37.0 I960... 1961 1962 1963 1964 38.6 38.6 38.7 38.8 38.7 39.7 39.8 40.4 40.5 40.7 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 38.8 38.6 38.0 37.8 37.7 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 37.1 36.9 37.0 36.9 36.5 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980" 1979: Jan Feb Mar 1980: Jan Feb Mar Apr $1,131 1.225 1.275 $1,216 1.327 1.376 1.335 1.45 1.52 1.61 1.65 1.439 1.56 1.64 1.74 1.78 1.863 2.02 2.13 2.28 2.38 39.4 39.1 38.7 38.6 38.8 1.71 1.80 1.89 1.95 2.02 1.85 1.95 2.04 2.10 2.19 36.7 36.9 37.0 37.3 37.2 38.6 38.3 38.2 38.1 37.9 2.09 2.14 2.22 2.28 2.36 41.2 41.4 40.6 40.7 40.6 37.4 37.6 37.7 37.3 37.9 37.7 37.1 36.6 36.1 35.7 39.8 39.9 405 40.7 40.0 37.3 37.2 36.5 36.8 36.6 36.1 36.1 36.0 35.8 35.6 39.5 40.1 40.3 40.4 40.2 35.3 40.5 40.4 40.5 5.8 -2.7 -.7 1.3 1.0 .6 -3.1 9.1 1 Also includes other private industry groups shown in Table 8-35. "Adjusted for overtime (in manufacturing only) and for interindustry employment shifts. 3 Current dollar earnings index divided by the consumer price index (revised index for urban wage earners and clerical workers used beginning 1978). 4 Monthly data are computed from indexes to two decimal places. Note.-See Note, Table B-35. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 274 TABLE B-37.—Average weekly earnings in selected private nonagricultural industries, 1947-80 [For production or nonsupervisory workers; monthly data seasonally adjusted] Percent change from Average gross weekly earnings Total private nonagricultural1 Construction (current dollars) Wholesale and retail (current dollars) Current dollars 1967 dollars private nonagricultural3 Current dollars 1967 dollars2 Manufacturing (current dollars) $45.58 49.00 50.24 $68.13 67.96 70.36 $49.13 53.08 53.80 $58.83 65.23 67.56 $38.07 40.80 42.93 7.5 2.5 -0.2 3.5 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 5313 57.86 60.65 63.76 64.52 73 69 74.37 76.29 79.60 80.15 58.28 63.34 66.75 70.47 70.49 69 68 76.96 82.86 86.41 88.54 44.55 47.79 49.20 51.35 53.33 5.8 8.9 4.8 5.1 1.2 47 .9 2.6 4.3 1955 1956 1957 1958 ... 1959 . 67.72 70 74 73.33 75.08 78.78 84.44 8690 86.99 86.70 90.24 75.30 78.78 81.19 82.32 88.26 90.90 9638 100.27 103.78 108.41 5.0 4.5 3.7 2.4 4.9 90.95 92.19 94.82 96.47 98.31 10101 101.67 101.84 103.39 104.38 89.72 92.34 96.56 99.23 102.97 2.4 2.4 4.0 3.0 3.2 107 53 112.19 114.49 122.51 129.51 112.67 118.08 122.47 127.19 132.06 13838 146.26 154.95 164.49 181.54 5.4 29 .1 -.3 4.1 .8 1.4 2.9 1.7 1.9 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 80.67 82.60 85.91 88.46 91.33 9545 98.82 101.84 107.73 114.61 55.16 57.48 59.60 61.76 64.41 66.01 67.41 69.91 72.01 74.66 76.91 79.39 82.35 87.00 91.39 4.5 3.5 3.1 5.8 6.4 27 .7 .2 1.5 1.0 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 11983 127.31 136.90 145.39 154.76 103 04 104.95 109.26 109.23 104.78 133 33 142.44 154.71 166.46 176.80 19545 211.67 221.19 235.89 249.25 96 02 101,09 106.45 111.76 119.02 4.6 6.2 7.5 6.2 6.4 -13 1.9 4.1 -.0 -4.1 163.53 175.45 189.00 203.70 219.30 101.45 102 90 104.13 104.30 100.73 190.79 209.32 228.90 249.27 268.94 266.08 283.73 295.65 318.69 342.99 126.45 133.79 142.52 153.64 164.96 5.7 7.3 7.7 7.8 7.7 -3.2 1.4 1.2 2 -3.4 288.62 367.41 175.91 7.2 159.58 160.72 162.52 163.67 163.33 164.63 165.28 166.59 167.24 167.89 169.52 170.50 9.6 9.4 8.6 5.4 7.6 7.1 7.2 7.6 7.9 6.9 7.2 7.4 .1 -.5 -1.6 -4.8 -3.0 -3.6 -3.9 -3.9 -3.9 -4.9 -4.9 -5.3 Year or month 1947 1948 1949 I960 1961 1962 1963 1964 ; . 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 . .. . 1980 p 23510 1979: Jan Feb Mar Anr £••: 8. Sept :.• Oct Nov . . . . Dec 1980: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug Sept Oct Nov"p Dec trorfa 212.77 213.84 216.48 212.86 216.45 218.23 103.59 102.96 103.13 100.41 101.10 100.85 262.68 264.71 266.34 258.20 267.33 268.27 219.65 222.05 222.86 223.57 225.70 228.12 100.43 100.52 99.76 99.10 99.03 98.88 269.87 270.68 272.28 273.48 275,49 277.78 328.83 334.31 339.38 325.03 341.32 342.61 342.80 348.01 352.13 345.92 350.76 355.26 228 20 228.98 230.45 230.86 230.61 231.70 97 52 96.53 95.82 95 08 94.16 93.77 279 28 280.30 280.99 282.98 281.00 282.30 352 86 357.64 356.85 359 29 361.74 366.92 172.13 172.04 173.45 172.16 173.98 173.86 6.9 6.8 6.6 8.2 6.5 6.4 -6 2 -6.5 -7.0 -5.6 -6.9 -6.9 232.78 235.52 238.30 241.10 244.61 246.03 94.17 94.62 94.75 94.92 95.33 284.70 289.98 293.83 297.35 302.44 307.13 365.79 366.46 375.87 375.18 378.42 380.73 174.90 176.96 178.48 180.00 181.93 182.90 5.7 6.6 6.4 7.5 8.2 8.2 -6.5 -5.4 -5.5 -4.6 -3.9 jroups shown in Table B-35. 2 the consumer price index (revised index for urban wage earners and clerical workers used Earnings in current dollars dividi beginning 1978). 3 Based on unadjusted data. Note.—See Note, Table 8-35. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 275 TABLE B-38.—Productivity and related data, private business sector, 1947-79 [1967 = 100] Output Year Hours of 2all persons per Output per hour2 of Compensation all persons hour3 Unit labor cost Implicit price deflator4 Private Nonfarm Private Nonfarm Private Nonfarm Private Nonfarm Private Nonfarm Private Nonfarm business business business business business business business business business business business business sector sector sector sector sector sector sector sector sector sector sector sector 1947 1948 1949!;.!:!!.:;: 47.9 50.8 49.9 46.7 49.5 48.6 90.5 91.1 88.1 78.7 80.0 77.0 53.0 55.8 56.6 59.3 61.9 63.2 36.1 39.1 39.8 38.5 41.8 43.1 68.1 70.2 70.3 64.9 67.6 68.2 §5.8 70.4 69.6 63.0 67.3 67.9 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 54.4 57.6 59.5 62.1 60.9 53.2 56.6 58.5 61.0 59.7 89.1 91.7 91.8 92.8 89.7 79.4 83.1 83.9 86.0 83.1 61.1 62.8 64.8 66.9 67.9 67.0 68.1 69.7 70.9 71.9 42.6 46.8 49.7 52.9 54.6 45.6 49.6 52.3 55.2 56.9 69.7 74.5 76.8 79.1 80.4 68.0 72.7 75.0 77.9 79.2 70.7 75.9 76.8 77.5 78.2 69.1 73.6 74.9 76.4 77.4 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 65.8 67.5 68.1 67.1 70.8 64.6 66.4 67.2 66.0 70.0 93.1 94.5 93.1 88.9 92.4 86.5 88.7 88.3 84.6 88.4 70.6 71.4 73.2 75.4 76.6 74.7 74.9 76.2 78.0 79.3 56.0 59.7 63.6 66.4 69.2 59.0 62.5 66.1 68.6 71.3 79.3 83.6 86.9 88.0 90.3 79.0 83.5 86.8 87.9 90.0 79.4 82.1 84.9 86.0 89.1 79.1 81.8 84.8 85.6 89.0 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 73.1 74.4 78.5 81.9 86.8 72.3 73.6 77.9 81.3 86.4 92.6 91.2 92.7 93.2 94.8 88.9 88.0 89.9 90.9 93.0 79.0 81.6 84.7 87.9 91.6 81.2 83.6 86.6 89.4 92.9 72.1 74.8 78.2 81.1 85.3 74.4 76.8 79.9 82.6 86.4 91.3 91.7 92.3 92.3 93.1 91.6 91.8 92.2 92.4 93.0 89.0 89.5 90.8 91.8 92.7 88.8 89.3 90.7 91.8 92.8 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 92.7 97.8 100.0 105.1 108.1 92.4 97.9 100.0 105.3 108.4 97.8 100.0 100.0 101.7 104.4 96.5 99.7 100.0 102.0 105.2 94.9 97.8 100.0 103.3 103.6 95.8 98.2 100.0 103.3 103.0 88.6 94.8 100.0 107.7 115.2 89.3 94.7 100.0 107.4 114.4 93.4 96.9 100.0 104.2 111.2 93.2 96.5 100.0 103.9 111.1 94.5 97.3 100.0 104.0 109.0 94.3 96.9 100.0 104.0 108.9 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 107.2 110.4 117.7 125.6 123.2 107.3 110.4 118.1 126.2 123.7 102.6 102.0 105.1 109.2 109.6 103.8 103.4 106.6 111.1 111.6 104.5 108.2 112.1 115.0 112.4 103.3 106.8 110.8 113.6 110.9 123.7 131.8 140.4 151.7 165.9 122.4 130.4 139.1 149.6 163.7 118.4 121.8 125.3 131.8 147.5 118.4 122.1 125.6 131.7 147.6 114.0 119.0 123.1 129.8 142.0 114.1 119.3 122.8 127.3 140.2 1975 1976 1977"""!"/. 1978 1979 120.9 128.5 136.6 143.0 147.1 121.0 129.1 137.4 144.0 148.0 105.1 108.2 112.6 118.1 122.0 106.9 110.5 115.3 121.2 125.4 115.0 118.8 121.3 121.1 120.6 113.2 116.9 119.1 118.9 117.9 181.8 197.4 212.6 230.5 253.4 179.4 194.0 208.7 226.4 248.0 158.1 166.2 175.3 190.4 210.1 158.5 166.0 175.2 190.4 210.2 155.8 163.2 172.3 185.1 201.4 154.6 162.4 171.9 183.9 199.7 1 2 Output refers to gross domestic product originating in the sector in 1972 dollars. Hours of all persons engaged in the sector, including hours of proprietors and unpaid family workers. Estimates based primarily on establishment data. 3 Wages and salaries of employees plus employers' contributions for social insurance and private benefit plans. Also includes an estimate of wages, salaries, and supplemental payments for the self-employed. 4 Current dollar gross domestic product divided by constant dollar gross domestic product. Note.—Preliminary estimate based on benchmark revisions of national income and product accounts; revised data to be published by Bureau of Labor Statistics the end of January 1981. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 276 TABLE B-39.—Changes in productivity and related data, private business sector, 1948-79 [Percent change from preceding period] Outputl Year Hours of all persons2 Output per hour of Compensation per all persons hour3 Unit labor cost Implicit price deflator4 Private Nonfarm Private Nonfarm Private Nonfarm Private Nonfarm Private Nonfarm Private Nonfarm business business business business business business business business business business business business sector sector sector sector sector sector sector sector sector sector sector sector 1948 1949 6.1 -1.9 6.0 -1.9 0.7 -3.3 1.6 -3.8 5.3 1.5 4.3 2.0 8.5 1.6 8.6 2.9 3.0 .1 4.1 .9 7.0 -1.0 6.8 .9 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 9.1 5.8 3.3 4.3 -1.8 9.4 6.5 3.4 4.2 -2.0 1.1 2.9 .1 1.0 -3.3 3.1 4.6 1.0 2.5 -3.4 7.9 2.8 3.2 3.2 1.6 6.0 1.7 2.3 1.7 1.4 7.1 9.8 6.4 6.4 3.2 5.8 8.8 5.5 5.6 3.2 -.8 6.9 3.0 3.1 1.6 —2 6^9 3.1 3.9 1.7 1.6 7.4 1.1 .9 1.0 1.7 6.6 1.8 2.0 1.4 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 7.9 2.6 1.0 -1.6 5.6 8.2 2.8 1.2 -1.9 6.1 3.8 1.5 -1.5 -4.5 3.9 4.1 2.5 -.5 -4.2 4.4 4.0 1.0 2.5 3.1 1.6 3.9 .3 1.7 2.4 1.6 2.5 6.5 6.5 4.4 4.3 3.6 6.0 5.7 3.8 4.0 -1.4 5.5 3.9 1.3 2.7 -.3 5.7 3.9 1.4 2.3 1.6 3.3 3.5 1.3 3.6 2.2 3.5 3.6 .9 4.0 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 3.3 1.7 5.5 4.3 6.0 3.2 1.8 5.8 4.4 6.4 .2 -1.5 1.6 .6 1.6 .6 -1.1 2.2 1.1 2.4 3.1 3.3 3.8 3.7 4.3 2.5 2.9 3.6 3.2 3.9 4.2 3.8 4.6 3.7 5.2 4.3 3.2 4.0 3.5 4.5 1.1 .5 .7 .0 .8 1.8 .3 .4 .2 .6 -.2 .6 1.5 4.1. 1.0 -.2 ".6 1.5 1.2 1.2 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 6.8 5.5 2.2 5.1 2.9 6.9 5.9 2.1 5.3 2.9 3.2 2.3 .0 1.7 2.6 3.7 3.4 .3 2.0 3.2 3.5 3.1 2.2 3.3 .2 3.1 2.5 1.9 3.3 -.3 3.9 7.0 5.5 7.7 7.0 3.4 6.0 5.6 7.4 6.5 .3 3.8 3.2 4.2 6.7 .3 3.5 3.7 3.9 6.8 1.9 3.0 2.7 4.0 4.9 1.6 2.8 3.2 4.0 4.7 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 -.8 3.0 6.6 6.6 -1.9 -1.0 2.9 6.9 6.9 -1.9 -1.7 -.5 3.0 3.9 .4 -1.4 -.4 3.1 4.2 .4 .9 3.6 3.5 2.7 -2.3 .3 3.3 3.7 2.5 -2.4 7.4 6.6 6.5 8.0 9.4 7.0 6.6 6.7 7.6 9.4 6.4 2.9 2.9 5.2 11.9 6.6 3.1 2.8 4.9 12.1 4.5 4.4 3.4 5.4 9.4 4.8 4.5 3.0 3.7 10.1 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 -1.9 6.3 6.3 4.7 2.8 -2.2 6.7 6.4 4.9 2.7 -4.1 2.9 4.0 4.9 3.3 -4.2 3.4 4.3 5.1 3.5 2.3 3.3 2.1 -.2 -.4 2.1 3.2 2.0 -.2 -.8 9.6 8.6 7.7 8.4 9.9 9.6 8.1 7.6 8.4 9.6 7.2 5.1 5.5 8.6 10.4 7.4 4.7 5.5 8.7 10.4 9.7 4.7 5.6 7.4 8.8 lCf.3 5.1 5.8 7.0 8.6 1 2 Output refers to gross domestic product originating in the sector in 1972 dollars. Hours of all persons engaged in the sector, including hours of proprietors and unpaid family workers. Estimates based primarily on establishment data. 3 Wages and salaries of employees plus employers' contributions for social insurance and private benefit plans. Also includes an estimate of wages, salaries, and supplemental payments for the self-employed. 4 Current dollar gross domestic product divided by constant dollar gross domestic product. Note.—Percent changes are based on original data and therefore may differ slightly from percent changes based on indexes in Table Preliminary estimates based on benchmark revisions of national income and product accounts; revised data to be published by Bureau of Labor Statistics the end of January 1981. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 277 PRODUCTION AND BUSINESS ACTIVITY TABLE B-40.^Industrial production indexes, major industry divisions, 1929-80 [1967=100; monthly data seasonally adjusted] Manufacturing Total industrial production Total Durable 1967 proportion 100.00 87.95 51.98 35.97 6.36 5.69 1929 1933 1939 1940 1941 1942 .. 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 . 1955 1956 1957 1958 . 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1979: Jan Feb Mar . Apr 21.6 13.7 21.7 25.0 316 36.3 44.0 47.4 40.7 35.0 39.4 41.1 38.8 44.9 48.7 50.6 54.8 51.9 58.5 61.1 61.9 57.9 64.8 66.2 66.7 72.2 76.5 81.7 89.8 97.8 100.0 106.3 111.1 107.8 109.6 119.7 129.8 129.3 117.8 130.5 138.2 146.1 152.5 22 8 14.0 21.5 25.4 32 4 37.8 47.0 50.9 42.6 35.3 39.4 409 38.7 45 0 48.6 50 6 55.2 515 58.2 60 5 61.2 57 0 64.2 65 4 65.6 715 75.8 810 89.7 97.9 100.0 106 4 111.0 106 4 108.2 118 9 129.8 129 4 116.3 130.3 138.4 146.8 153.6 22 5 9.1 17.7 23.5 314 39.9 54.2 59.9 45.2 31.6 37.7 39.3 35.7 43 5 48.9 519 58.7 518 59.2 61.1 61.6 53.9 61.9 62 9 61.8 68 6 73.1 78 3 89.0 98.9 100.0 106 5 110.6 102 3 102.4 113 7 127.1 125 7 109.3 122.3 130.0 139.7 146.4 23.2 19.9 26.1 27.5 33.3 34.6 37.1 38.6 38.5 39.7 41.3 42.7 42.0 46 7 48.3 49.2 51.2 51.6 57.2 60.1 61.1 61.6 67.7 69 3 71.5 75 8 80.0 85.2 90.9 96.7 100.0 106.2 111.5 112 3 116.6 126 5 133.8 134 6 126.4 141.8 150.5 156.9 164.0 43.1 30.6 42.1 46.8 49.7 51.3 52.5 56.2 55.1 54.2 61.3 64.4 57.1 63.8 70.0 69.4 71.2 69.9 77:9 82.0 82.1 75.3 78.7 80.3 80.8 83,1 86.4 89.9 93.2 98.2 100.0 104 2 108.3 112 2 109.8 1131 114.7 115 3 112.8 114.2 118.2 124.0 125.5 7.4 6.7 10.7 11.8 13.3 14.9 16.5 17.5 17.8 18.6 20.1 22.4 23.9 27.2 31.0 33.7 36.5 39.3 43.9 48.2 51.5 53.9 59.3 63.4 67.0 72 0 77.0 83.6 88.7 95.5 100.0 108.4 117.3 124 5 130.5 139 4 145.4 143 7 146.0 151.7 156.5 161.4 166.0 152.0 152.5 153.5 151.1 152.7 153.0 153.0 152.1 152.7 152.7 152.3 152.5 153.0 153.6 154.9 151.9 154.1 154.2 154.4 152.9 153.9 153.7 153.3 153.2 147.0 147.2 148.6 144.5 147.6 147.6 147.2 144.4 145.9 146.0 145.2 144.8 161.6 162.9 164.0 162.6 163.6 163.7 164.8 165.2 165.4 164.8 165.0 165.3 124.7 122.6 123.0 123.4 123.3 123.6 124.1 126.8 126.0 127.8 129.9 131.4 166.5 168.1 167.6 167.2 165.7 164.1 164.2 164.6 165.4 165.7 167.2 166.9 152.7 152.6 152.1 148.3 144.0 141.5 153.4 153 0 152.1 147.9 143.4 140.3 144.7 1441 143.4 138.4 133.3 129.9 166.0 165 9 164.7 161.6 158.0 155.3 133.5 132 9 133.0 133.1 133.4 132.9 164.8 1671 172.0 169.1 167.7 169.3 140.4 141.8 143.9 146.5 148.5 139.1 140.6 143.2 146 0 148.0 128.3 129.4 131.7 135 3 137.8 154.7 156.9 159.8 1614 162.7 130.6 129.6 130.5 1318 134.2 171.8 173.8 171.6 170 8 171.4 Year or month . . May : : .:: June July Aug Sept :/.: Set ::::;:..i.::::: Nov :'.::.: v : " " :.: : v :; ::::::::: ;.. Dec 1980: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug Sept.. Octp. Nov" .. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 278 Nondurable Mining Utilities TABLE B-41.—Industrial production indexes, market groupings, 1947-80 [1967=100; monthly data seasonally adjusted] Final products Total industrial production Year or month Total Automotive products Total 1967 proportion Materials * Equipment2 Consumer goods l Home goods Total Business Intermediate products Total NonDuradurable ble goods goods 100.00 47.82 27.68 2.83 5.06 20.14 12.63 12.89 39.4 411 38.8 38.6 400 38.8 42.4 43 7 43.4 45.3 47 4 47:0 37.5 39.1 36.2 30.6 32 2 287 38.0 39 5 34.5 41.9 44 3 42.0 39.5 412 37.6 38.3 39 4 35.3 44.9 48 7 50.6 54.8 51.9 43.7 47 2 50.7 54.1 51.3 49.6 491 50.2 53.2 52.9 59.1 52 3 47.1 59.5 55.4 49.9 43.0 43.0 48.6 44.9 31.1 43 3 51.9 56.3 49.3 37.0 45 2 51.2 53.3 46.8 48.8 513 50.9 54.5 54.3 45.0 49 8 50.5 56.1 51.8 44.4 50 5 51.6 60.3 52.0 45 9 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 58.5 61.1 619 57.9 64.8 55.4 58.6 60 3 57.6 63.2 59.0 61.2 626 62.1 68.1 73.6 60.6 63.5 50.5 63.3 53.0 55.7 54.5 51.4 59.0 50.4 55.3 57 5 51.5 56.5 50.8 58.8 611 51.5 57.9 617 64.4 64 4 63.0 69.5 61.3 62.8 62 8 56.5 65.2 637 63.9 638 537 64.0 52.5 54.9 54 7 54.4 62.1 I960 1961 1962 1963 1964 66 2 66.7 72.2 76.5 81.7 65.3 65.8 71.4 75.5 797 70.7 72.2 77.1 81.3 85.9 72.5 66.1 80.1 877 91.9 59.4 61.3 66.5 71.8 78.4 581 57.3 63.7 67.5 71.4 59 4 577 627 65.8 73.7 700 71.4 757 79.9 85.2 661 66.2 72.1 76.7 82.9 64.8 63.3 70.4 75.1 81.9 63 2 65.8 71.3 75.6 82.2 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 89.8 97 8 100.0 106.3 111.1 87.6 95 9 100.0 106.2 109.6 92.6 97 3 100.0 105.9 109.8 113.3 112.8 100.0 119.4 118.1 88.9 97.9 100.0 106.4 113.2 80.7 84.4 94 0 97 7 100.0 100.0 106.5 105.5 109.3 112.5 90.6 96,2 100.0 106.3 112.9 92.4 100 7 100.0 106.5 112.5 93.8 103 3 100.0 106.2 112.1 90.3 97 5 100.0 108.8 115.7 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 107.8 1096 119.7 129 8 129.3 105.3 106.3 115.7 124.4 125.1 109.0 114.7 124.4 131.5 128.9 98.8 124.4 141.4 153.0 132.8 U0.2 115.6 129.5 142.5 136.8 100.1 107.0 94.7 104.1 103.8 118.0 114.5 134.2 120.0 142.4 112.9 116.7 126.5 137.2 135.3 109.2 111.3 122.3 133.9 132.4 103.8 104.9 117.7 134.6 1327 115.4 120.2 132.9 142.2 142.6 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 117 8 130.5 138 2 146.1 152.5 118 2 127.6 135 9 142.2 147.2 124 0 137.1 145.3 149.1 150.8 125 8 1557 175.6 179.9 1677 118.8 134.1 141.9 1477 149.2 110 2 114.6 123 0 132.8 142.2 128 2 135.4 147 8 160.3 171.3 1231 137.2 145.1 154.1 160.5 115 5 131.7 138 6 148.3 156.4 1091 128.0 136.1 149.0 157.8 126 6 147.8 155.6 165.6 175.9 152 0 152.5 153.5 1511 152.7 153 0 146 5 147.1 148.6 145 4 147.8 147 7 1513 151.8 153.4 149 3 152.2 152.1 1827 179.6 186.8 163 0 1827 176.2 149.2 150.6 150.8 145 6 148.3 149.4 139 9 140.6 141.9 1401 141.8 141.7 168 2 169.3 171.0 168 7 171.2 171.2 161.0 161.3 161.4 1601 160.1 160.7 155.7 156.1 156.9 154 9 156.1 156.8 158.4 158.1 159.4 155 6 158.1 159.6 172.1 173.6 174.2 174.1 174.7 174.4 153.0 152.1 152 7 152 7 152.3 152 5 147.4 145.8 147 3 147 3 147.1 147 2 151.2 1487 150 0 150 0 149.1 148.6 168.5 147.0 157.6 159 2 150.6 141.8 150.2 148.6 149.5 149 7 149.0 149.4 142.1 141.9 143 7 143 6 144.2 145 2 171.3 171.6 173.4 172 3 172.6 174.1 160.3 161.3 160.6 160 6 160.2 159.6 157.4 156.6 156.6 156.6 156.2 156.6 160.3 157.7 157.7 157.2 155.8 155.8 175.5 177.1 177.8 178.8 178.5 180.2 152.7 152.6 1521 148.3 144.0 141.5 147.0 1477 147 7 145.4 143.1 142.3 147.9 148.4 148 6 145.3 142.4 142.1 131.3 142.1 1410 126.3 118.5 121.6 148.5 145.8 145.8 142.0 134.6 132.0 145.8 146.6 146 6 145.6 144.0 142.6 174.9 176.0 1761 174.2 171.9 169.8 160.8 159.2 158.3 150.8 146.2 143.5 157.0 156.5 155.3 151.0 144.3 140.0 156.0 154.8 154.2 148.2 139.8 133.8 181.0 179.9 177.0 173.2 165.2 159.6 140.4 141.8 143.9 146.5 148.5 142.4 142.8 143.8 145.6 146.8 142.0 142.7 144.1 146.4 147.6 129.2 121.5 130.6 141.9 145.6 1277 132.6 134.2 138.2' 139.3 142.9 170.1 142.9 170.3 143.3 1707 144.5 171.9 145.8 173.4 144.5 147.6 150.1 151.3 152.8 136.5 138.6 142.1 146.1 149.0 129.0 131.3 133.7 139.5 144.2 156.2 159.8 169.6 173.6 175.0 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 . . . 1979: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 1980: Jan Feb Mar Apr NTay June July Aug Sept ock..; Nov" 1 Also includes clothing and consumer staples, not shown separately. Also includes defense and space equipment, not shown separately. Also includes energy materials, not shown separately. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2 3 279 39.29 20.35 10.47 TABLE B-42.—Industrial production indexes, selected manufactures, 1947-80 [1967=100; monthly data seasonally adjusted] Nondurable manufactures Ourable manufactures Primary metals Year or month Total Iron and steel Fabricated metal products NonElectrieleccal trical machinmachinery ery Transportation equipment Total Motor vehicles and parts 4.50 Printing ChemLumber irak Apparel ltd 15 and and prodpublish- and products ing products ucts Foods 1967 proportion 6.57 5.93 9.15 8.05 9.27 1.64 3.31 4.72 7.74 8.75 1947 1948... 1949 63.3 65.8 55.4 49.9 50.8 45.8 39.0 39.2 33.4 22.2 23.0 21.6 31.8 34.8 34.9 58.9 61.3 54.1 57.8 60.3 59.7 43.3 45.4 46.6 19.7 21.3 21.0 55.8 55.2 55.9 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 69.7 75.8 69.2 78.5 63.5 70.1 56.1 59.9 58.5 66.0 59.4 37.5 47.7 51.9 54.0 46.1 29.6 29.8 34.0 39.0 34.7 41.8 46.6 54.2 68.0 59.2 60.5 65.7 65.5 64.7 68.4 68.0 64.3 63.1 66.3 67.2 66.4 48.9 49.7 49.7 52.0 54.1 26.2 29.7 31.1 33.6 34.1 57.9 59.0 60.2 61.4 62.7 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 82.5 82.0 78.5 62.3 72.7 93.2 91.5 88.2 66.5 76.5 67.8 68.8 70.6 63.3 71.0 50.6 58.0 57.9 48.6 56.7 39.9 43.1 42.8 39.2 47.6 68.0 66.0 70.7 55.8 63.2 81.2 65.8 69.0 51.0 66.2 75.9 75.0 68.8 69.9 79.3 73.3 75.0 74.9 72.8 80.1 59.5 63.2 65.4 63.9 68.2 39.8 42.7 45.2 46.6 54.3 66.3 70.1 71.1 72.9 76.5 72.4 71.1 76.3 82.3 92.8 77.7 74.2 77.3 84.3 95.9 71.1 69.4 75.4 77.8 82.6 56.9 55.4 62.1 66.3 75.6 51.6 54.8 62.9 64.7 68.4 65.4 61.5 71.1 78.0 80.0 74.7 ' 65.5 79.8 88.3 90.7 74.7 78.2 82.5 86.3 92.7 81.7 82.2 85.5 89.1 92.2 71.0 71,3 73.9 77.8 82.6 56.4 59.2 65.7 71.8 78.8 78.6 80.9 83.4 86.4 90.4 102.1 108.4 100.0 104.3 113.8 105.2 108.4 100.0 103.2 112.6 90.8 97.2 100.0 105.6 107.9 85.0 98.8 100.0 101.8 109.3 81.7 97.9 100.0 105.5 111.9 95.1 102.0 100.0 111.1 108.4 115.9 113.9 100.0 120.3 116.5 96.3 100.0 100.0 105.5 107.9 97.4 99.9 100.0 102.9 106.7 87.9 94.6 100.0 103.2 107.4 87.8 95.7 100.0 109.5 118.4 92.4 96.0 100.0 102.6 106.1 106.6 100.2 112.1 126.7 123.1 104.7 96.1 107.1 122.3 119.8 102.4 103.5 112.1 124.7 124.2 104.4 100.2 116.0 133.7 140.1 108.1 107.7 122.2 143.1 143.8 89.5 97.9 108.2 118.3 108.7 92.3 118.6 135.8 148.8 128.2 105.6 113.8 120.8 126.0 116.2 101.4 104.7 109.4 117.3 114.3 107.0 107.1 112.7 118.2 118.2 120.4 125.9 143.6 154.5 159.4 108.9 112.8 116.8 120.9 124.0 96.4 109.7 111.1 119.9 121.3 95.8 104.8 103.8 113.2 113.2 109.9 123.9 131.0 141.6 148.5 125.1 134.5 143.6 153.6 163.7 116.5 134.8 145.4 159.4 174.0 97.4 111.1 122.2 132.5 135.4 111.1 142.0 161.1 169.9 159.9 107.6 123.2 131.2 136.3 136.9 107.6 125.7 134.2 134.2 134.4 113.3 122.5 127.6 131.5 136.9 147.2 170.9 185.7 197.4 211.8 123.4 133.0 138.8 142.7 147.5 123.3 120.4 123.8 122.0 121.2 124.2 113.3 110.8 116.2 115.8 114.3 118.1 149.1 150.8 150.2 148.8 150.3 149.3 161.2 162.9 164.1 161.4 164.4 164.6 171.2 173.1 174.3 170.6 174.6 175.1 141.5 140.0 143.4 131.6 141.8 139.3 178.7 173.3 179.7 156.0 175.8 169.0 137.3 137.2 137.7 137.2 135.8 136.8 136.0 138.0 138.5 134.0 133.1 136.4 135.6 138.2 137.3 135.7 136.8 136.9 207.5 209.7 210.4 209.3 211.2 209.6 143.9 145.3 147.4 146.8 148.3 149.0 126.7 121.1 122.1 118.4 117.1 115.3 119.0 112.0 115.0 108.8 108.1 106.6 149.3 147.6 146.5 147.5 146.9 146.2 165.5 166.3 165.2 162.9 162.9 163.0 174.7 172.1 176.7 177.3 179.5 181.6 135.2 125.2 131.8 133.3 128.3 127.3 159.2 138.5 150.3 150.1 139.3 137.1 135.2 138.5 138.6 138.7 135.9 132.4 132.7 132.5 135.7 131.5 133.5 131.1 135.6 137.7 137.2 137.2 136.2 137.8 211.8 214.8 212.8 212.9 215.3 216.8 148.9 147.5 148.1 147.7 147.9 148.4 Jan Feb Mar. Apr May. June 116.4 111.9 113.7 106.4 96.1 90.4 107.2 103.4 105.9 97.4 84.4 75.4 145.0 145.7 145.5 141.4 133.2 126.1 167.1 167.0 166.5 163.2 162.1 158.3 181.7 179.2 179.2 177.0 171.4 166.6 122.1 125.7 123.8 115.1 109.8 110.0 126.2 133.9 130.1 114.7 105.9 106.7 131.6 130.2 125.3 105.2 104.5 109.7 131.5 133.8 136.1 131.3 128.6 127.2 138.9 139.9 139.2 136.5 135.5 135.4 218.0 217.4 213.6 209.1 199.2 191.1 148.5 149.0 149.3 147.8 149.5 149.0 July. Aug . Sept. Oct" Nov. 81.7 86.0 89.9 100.0 107.7 68.1 75.3 79.8 93.8 123.8 125.8 129.0 132.4 134.6 158.5 158.8 1591 160 5 161.5 165,0 166.7 167 8 169 9 171.9 110.7 108.3 112 9 118 9 120.9 107.9 104.4 113.4 124 7 128.3 112.8 121.7 122.7 121.4 121.5 123.8 138.6 140.3 1401 141 5 14214 190.3 197.8 206 0 210.4 148.9 148.3 148.7 149.2 I960 1961 1962 1963 . 1964. . .. . . 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969... . . 1970 1971 1972.. 1973.. 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 . . .... 1979: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec . 4 , 4.21 1980 Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 280 TABLE B-43.—Capacity utilization rate in manufacturing, 1948-80 [Percent; quarterly data seasonally adjusted] FRB series Wharton series 3 Commerce series2 J AdTotal NonPrimary- AdvancedPrimary NonTotal Total manufac- process- vanced manufac- Durable durable processed processed manufac- Durable goods durab goods goods processturing turing goods goods ing good; turing ing Year or quarter 1948 1949 82.5 74.2 87.2 76.2 80.0 73.3 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 82.8 85.8 85.4 89.2 80.3 88.5 90.2 84.9 89.4 80.6 79.8 83.4 85.9 89.3 80.1 •"'88.1 85.3 92. 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 87 1 83 7 75.2 81.9 921 89 7 84.7 75.4 83.4 84 3 84 5 83.1 75.1 81.1 90 5 87 9 84.0 74.2 78.9 88 3 85.3 81.6 68.0 73.7 91 87. 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 80.2 77.4 816 83.5 85.6 79.8 77.9 81.6 83.8 87.8 80.4 77.2 81.7 83.4 84.6 76.9 73.7 765 77.7 79.5 71.9 67.7 71.8 73.4 75.6 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 89 6 91.1 86.9 87.1 86.2 91.1 91.4 85.7 87.7 88.5 88.9 91.2 87.6 86.8 85.0 84.2 88.2 86.9 89.2 90.1 82.3 88.0 86.2 88.8 89.4 87. 89. 91. 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 79 3 78.4 83.5 87.6 83.8 82.9 82.3 88.2 92.5 87.8 77.4 76.3 81.0 85.0 81.5 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 72.9 79 5 81.9 84.4 85.7 73.7 81.9 84.0 86.9 88.1 1975: 1 || Ill IV 70.3 70.7 74.6 76.1 78.4 79 5 80.0 80.0 80.7 82.1 82.4 82.6 864 86 86 84 85 85 88 85 89 85 87 83 84 84 86 85 86 86 88 87 86 87 85 83 84 84 93 83. 86. 84. 82 83. 83. 85 86. 88. 80 78 83 82 80 83 86 83 82 85 82 85 86 84 85 89 85 82 84 82 84.0 82.6 87.7 92.9 90.2 80.6 78.1 84.2 91.5 88.7 92. 94. 92. 72.5 78.2 80.8 83.0 84.3 77 81 83 84 83 76 81 84 84 83 79 82 82 83 82 76 82 83 84 84 77 81 83 84 82 79.4 85.5 88.1 90.9 92.6 75.9 81.8 84.8 89.2 91.7 84. 90. 92. 93. 94 69.9 70.4 76.2 78.4 70.4 71.0 73.8 74.9 75 75 79 79 74 73 78 77 76 78 80 81 75 73 78 78 75 76 79 79 77.0 77.3 81.0 82.2 74.8 74.1 77.1 77.5 80. 81.0 77.0 82 81 82 781 82 83 79 81 81 80 81 82 82 83 83 82 80 81 82 79 82 84.7 85.5 85.8 86.0 80.4 82.0 82.7 82.4 90. 819 82.2 84.4 84.5 84.7 79.8 80.8 81.3 81.3 83 84 84 86 82 82 83 84 82 82 82 83 86.8 88.2 88.5 88.7 82.9 84.9 85.4 86.0 92. 93. 82 82 82 82 84 84 82 82 82.0 83.9 85.2 86.4 84.0 86.3 87.9 89.5 80.9 82.7 83.7 84.6 84 84 83 84 84 85 83 85 83 82 82 83 83 84 84 85 84 84 82 84 88.4 90.4 91.6 93.1 85.8 88.5 90.2 92.4 92. 93. 93. 94. 1979: | II Ill IV 86.9 85.9 85.3 84.4 89.0 88.2 88.3 86.9 85.7 84.7 83.7 83.0 84 83 82 81 85 84 82 80 83 82 82 82 85 84 83 83 84 83 81 80 93.7 92.7 92.3 91.8 93.1 91.9 91.0 90.7 94. 93. 94. 93. 1980: 1 || III 83.4 77 9 75.7 85.1 76.3 72.9 82.5 78 7 77.3 80 76 80 74 81 78 78 81 75 80 76 75 91.3 85.7 83.5 89.8 83.4 80.2 93. 88. 1976: 1 II. Ill IV 1977: I II Ill IV 82.6 82.1 78.5 78.8 81 78 83 1978: ii • Ill IV ;.;... 76 1 2 83 74 79 77 88. 89. 81. 86. 89. 90. 90. 90. 92. 92. 88. For description of the series, see "Federal Reserve Measures of Capacity and Capacity Utilization," February 1978. Quarterly data are for last month in quarter. Annual data are averages of the (our indexes, except for 1965 (December index) and 1966-67 {averages of June and December indexes). For description of the series, see "Survey of Current Business," July 1974. 3 Annual data are averages of quarterly indexes. For description of the series, see F. Gerard Adams and Robert Summers, "The Wharton Index of Capacity Utilization: A Ten Year Perspective, 1973 Proceedings of the Business and Economic Statistics Section, American Statisticaf Association. Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic Analysis), and Wharton School of Finance. 281 TABLE B-44;—New construction activity, 1929-80 [Value put in place, billions of dollars; monthly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Public construction Private construction Year or month Total new construction Presidential buildings and other construction l Residential buildings1 Total Total New Total 2 housing units Total 4.7 Commercial Industrial Federal State and local* 0.2 2.3 Other* 1929 10.8 8.3 3.6 3.0 2.6 2.5 1933 2.9 1.2 .5 .3 .5 1.6 1.1 1939... . 8.2 4.4 2.7 2.3 1.2 3.8 3.1 1940 .. 1941 . .., 1942. . . . 1943 1944 8.7 12.0 14.1 8.3 5.3 5.1 6.2 3.4 2.0 2.2 3.0 3.5 1.7 .9 .8 2.6 3.0 1.4 .7 .6 1.3 1.5 1.2 .9 1.1 3.6 5.8 10.7 6.3 3.1 1.2 3.8 9.3 5.6 2.5 2.4 2.0 1.3 1945 1946 5.8 14.3 3.4 12.1 1.3 6.2 .7 4.8 1.3 3.0 2.4 2.2 1.7 .9 .7 1.4 1947 1948 ... 1949 20.0 26.1 267 16.7 21.4 20.5 9.9 13.1 12.4 7,8 10.5 10.0 6.9 8.2 8.0 1.7 1.4 1.0 4.2 5.5 5.9 3.3 4.7 6.3 1.2 1.5 2.5 3.5 4.8 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 33.6 35.4 36.8 39.1 41.4 26.7 26.2 26.0 27.9 29.7 18.1 15.9 15.8 16.6 18.2 15,6 13.2 12.9 13.4 14.9 8.6 10.3 10.2 11.3 11.5 1.4 1.5 1.1 1.8 2.2 1.1 2.1 2.3 2.2 2.0 6.1 6.7 6.8 7.3 7.2 6.9 9.3 10.8 11.2 11.7 1.6 3.0 4.2 4.1 . 46.5 47.6 49.1 50.0 55.4 34.8 34.9 35.1 34.6 39.3 21.9 20.2 19.0 19.8 24.3 18.2 16.1 14.7 15.4 19.2 12.9 14.7 16.1 14.8 15.1 3.2 3.6 3.6 3.6 3.9 2.4 3.1 3.6 2.4 2.1 7.3 8.0 9.0 8.8 9.0 11.7 12.7 14.1 15.5 16.1 2.8 2.7 3.0 3.4 3.7 8.9 10.0 11.1 12.1 12.3 1960, . .. 1961,... 1962 1963 1964 54.7 56.4 60.2 64.8 67.7 38.9 39.3 42.3 45.5 47.3 23.0 23.1 25.2 27.9 28.0 17.3 17.1 19.4 21.7 21.8 15.9 16.2 17.2 17.6 19.3 4.2 4.7 5.1 5.0 5.4 2.9 2.8 2.8 2.9 3.6 8.9 8.7 9.2 9.7 10.3 15.9 17.1 17.9 19.4 20.4 3,6 3.9 3.9 4.0 3.9 12.2 13.3 14.0 15.4 16.5 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 73.7 76.4 78.1 87.1 93.9 51.7 52.4 52.5 59.5 66.0 27.9 25.7 25.6 30.6 33.2 21.7 19.4 19.0 24.0 25.9 23.8 26.7 27.0 28.9 32.8 7.8 9.4 6.0 6.8 15.1 16.6 22.1 24.0 25.5 27.6 28.0 4.0 4.0 3.5 3.4 3.3 18.0 20.0 22.1 24.2 24,7 .. 94.9 110.0 124.1 137.9 138.5 66.8 80.1 93.9 105.4 100.2 31.9 43.3 54.3 59.7 50.4 24.3 35.1 44.9 50.1 40.6 34.9 36.8 39.6 45.7 49.8 9.8 11.6 13.5 15.5 15.9 6.5 5.4 4.7 6.2 7.9 18.6 19.8 21.5 24.0 25.9 28.1 29.9 30.2 32.5 38.3 3.3 4.0 4.4 4.9 5.3 24.8 25.9 25.8 27.7 33.0 1975. .. 1976 1977. . .. 1978 134.5 151.1 174.0 205.5 93.7 111.9 135.8 159.6 46.5 60.5 81.0 93.4 34.4 47.3 65.7 75.8 47.2 51.4 54.8 66.1 12.8 12.8 14.8 18.6 8.0 7.2 7J 11.0 26.4 31.5 32.4 36.6 40.9 39.1 38.2 45.9 6.3 7.0 7.3 34.6 32.1 30.9 37.5 1979.. 229.0 179.9 99.0 78.6 80.9 24.9 15.0 41.0 49.0 . '.S New series 1955 1956. 1957, 1958 1959, 1970. 1971.. 1972. 1973 1974 .... See next page for continuation of table. 282 3 5.2 6.3 6.6 7.1 8.3 40.2 TABLE B-44.—New construction activity, 1929-80—Continued [Value put in place, billions of dollars; monthly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Private construction Public construction Tntal new construction Year or month Residential buildingsl Total Total2 Industrial Other4 and Federal State local» 77.9 76.3 76 8 76.8 78.4 71.6 72.1 76.4 75.9 79.0 81.3 20.1 19.8 21.7 22.5 24.1 25.5 13.3 14.3 15.3 14.6 14.7 14.8 38.2 38.0 39.3 38 8 40.2 41.0 46.7 42.4 45.7 456 47.7 46.7 231.0 231.6 235 3 239.9 2394 244.0 181.3 182.0 184.3 187.3 187 4 191.2 98.5 98.9 100.4 101.5 101.8 102.1 79.0 79.3 804 79.9 79 0 78.5 82.8 83.1 83.9 85.8 85.6 89.1 25.5 26.1 26.4 27.3 27.7 29.4 15.9 14.2 14.7 15.6 15.8 15.9 41.4 42.8 429 42.9 42 0 43.8 49.7 49.6 50.9 52.6 52 0 52.9 2596 248.8 237.1 225.8 218.9 215.0 1981 191.7 180.6 171.5 164.8 161.3 105 8 101.5 94.0 83.5 77.0 73.4 80 7 75.1 68.4 60.7 55.2 51.9 923 31.6 30.7 29.9 30.9 30.1 29.6 15 8 15.7 13.9 13.6 14.2 15.0 44 9 43.8 42.8 43.5 43.5 43.4 615 98 516 90.2 86.6 88.0 87.8 88.0 57.0 56.5 54.3 54.1 53.7 9.2 10.8 10.1 9.9 8.9 47.8 45.8 44.3 44.2 44.7 Mill 8.6 7.9 9.6 101.4 98.6 97.1 96.6 96.2 97.7 214.3 215.1 223.7 226.2 231.8 158.6 162.1 167.9 171.1 178.0 74.3 78.6 84.4 87.4 93.5 52.2 56.1 60.8 63.6 69.0 84.3 83.4 83.5 83.7 84.4 28.1 28.0 27.4 28.4 28.8 13.3 13.0 13.1 13.0 13.3 43.0 42.4 43.0 42.3 42.4 55.7 53.1 55!8 55.1 53.8 11.1 9.8 10.3 9.4 10.3 44.6 43.2 45.5 45.7 43.5 . ... oNovc f : . ; Commercial 3 173.0 170.7 173.4 172.4 175.3 179.0 Mar July Aug Sept Total Total 219.7 2131 219.2 2180 223.0 225.7 Apr May June 81.5 constructionl M i l l 1979: Jan Feb New housing units Nonresidential buildings and other ::.:::„::. -: Dec 1980: Ian 8.1 9.0 8.2 9.0 9.2 9.5 8.4 8.9 9.1 38.1 34.5 36.2 37.4 38.7 38.5 40.7 40.3 415 44.2 431 43.8 MMI : : : : :' II 111 II 111 Mill : :' :' ; :' M i l l M i l l 1 1 - 1 1 1 Mill 1 Beginning 1960, farm residential buildings included in residential buildings; prior to I960, included in nonresidential buildings and other construction. 2 Total includes additions and alterations and nonhousekeeping units, not shown separately. 3 Office buildings, warehouses, stores, restaurants, garages, etc. 4 Religious, educational, hospital and institutional, miscellaneous nonresidential, farm (see also footnote 1), public utilities, and all other private. 5 Includes Federal grants-in-aid for State and local projects. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 283 TABLE B-45.—New housing units started and authorized, 1959-80 [Thousands of units] New private housing units authorized2 New housing units started Private and public1 Private (farm and nonfarm)' Total (farm and Nonfarm nonfarm) Type of structure Year or month Total Type of structure Total 1 unit 2 to 4 5 units units or more 1 unit 2 to 4 units 5 units 1959.. 1,553.7 1,531.3 1,517.0 1,234.0 283.0 1,208.3 938.3 77.1 192.9 1960 1961. 1962. 1963. 1964. 1,296.1 1,365.0 1,492.5 1,634.9 1,561.0 1,274.0 1,336.8 1,468.7 1,614.8 1,534.0 1,252.2 1,313.0 1,462.9 1,603.2 1,528.8 994.7 974.3 991.4 1,012.4 970.5 257.4 338.7 471.5 590.8 108.4 450.0 998.0 1,064.2 1,186.6 1,334,7 1,285.8 746.1 722.8 716.2 750.2 720.1 64.6 67.6 87.1 118.9 100.8 187.4 273.8 383.3 465.6 464.9 1965. 1966 1967. 1968 1969 . 1,509.7 1,195.8 1,321.9 1,545.4 1,499.5 1,487.5 1,172.8 1,298.8 1,521.4 1,482.3 1,472.8 1,164.9 1,291.6 1,507.6 1,466.8 963.7 778.6 843.9 899.4 810.6 86.6 61.1 71.6 80.9 85.0 422.5 325.1 376.1 527.3 571.2 1,239.8 971.9 1,141.0 1,353.4 1,323.7 709.9 563.2 650.6 694.7 625.9 ,84.8 61.0 73.0 84.3 85.2 445.1 347.7 417.5 574.4 612.7 1970. 1971 1972. 1973 1974., 1,469.0 2,084.5 2,378.5 2,057.5 1,352.5 1,433.6 2,052.2 2,356.6 2,045.3 1,337.7 812.9 1,151.0 1,309.2 1,132.0 888.1 120.3 141.3 118.3 68.1 535.9 780.9 906.2 795.0 381.6 1,351.5 1,924.6 2,218.9 1,819.5 1,074.4 646.8 906.1 1,033.1 882.1 643.8 616.7 88.1 885.7 132.9 148.6 1,037.2 820.5 117.0 366.2 64.3 1975 1976 1977 1978.. 1979.. 1,171.4 1,547.6 1,989.8 2,023.3 1,749.2 1,160.4 1,537.5 1,987.1 2,020.3 1,745.1 892.2 1,162.4 1,450.9 1,433.3 1,194.1 64.0 85.9 121.7 125.0 122.0 204.3 289.2 414.4 462.0 429.0 939.2 1,296.2 1,690.0 1,800.5 1,551.8 675.5 893.6 1,126.1 1,182.6 981.5 63.9 93.1 121.3 130.6 125.4 199.8 309.5 442.7 487.3 444.8 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1979: Jan Feb.. Mar Apr . May . June., 88.4 84.7 153.3 161.3 189.1 192.0 1,727 1,469 1,800 1,750 1,801 1,910 1,175 •997 1,275 1,273 1,229 1,276 121 93 119 113 120 123 431 379 406 364 452 511 1,475 1,491 1,692 1,548 1,648 1,639 958 922 1,115 1,044 1,052 1,028 126 103 130 122 123 132 391 466 447 382 473 479 July . . Aug. . Sept. Oct. . Nov.... Dec 165.0 171.4 163.8 169.0 119.2 91.9 1,764 1,788 1.874 1,710 1,522 1,548 1,222 1,237 1.237 1,139 980 1,055 130 152 123 129 114 110 412 399 514 442 428 383 1,563 1,622 1,695 1,478 1,287 1,247 1,015 1,011 996 905 773 776 136 143 138 129 99 116 412 468 561 444 415 355 Jan . Feb . Mar.. . Apr May.... June 73.4 80.6 86.1 96.6 92.0 116.8 1,419 1,330 1,041 1,030 906 1,223 1,002 786 617 628 628 757 127 101 91 100 290 443 333 302 198 391 1,271 1,168 968 789 825 1,078 780 708 556 473 495 628 119 111 94 63 81 93 372 349 318 253 249 357 July . Aug... Sept . Oct. . Nov.... 120.8 130.2 139.3 153.7 112.6 1,265 1,429 1,541 1,561 1,555 1,003 1,059 1,037 987 80 136 142 120 160 316 290 340 404 408 1,236 1,361 1,564 1,333 1,371 781 857 914 819 794 119 131 146 134 144 336 373 504 380 433 1980: 1 Units in structures built by private developers for sale upon completion to local public housing authorities under the Department of Housing and Urban Development "Turnkey" program are classified as private housing. Military housing starts, including those financed with mortgages insured by FHA under Section 803 of the National Mousing Act, are included in publicly owned starts and excluded from 2 Authorized by issuance of local building permit: in 16,000 permit-issuing places beginning 1978; in 14,000 places for 1972-77; in 13,000 places for 1967-71; in 12,000 places for 1963-66; and in 10,000 places prior to 1963. 3 Not available separately beginning January 1970. Note.—-Only the series on private and public nonfarm housing units started is available prior to 1959. See 1976 "Economic Report" for this earlier series. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 284 TABLE B-46.—Nonfarm business expenditures for new plant and equipment, 1947-81 [Billions of dollars,- quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Plant and equipment Nonmanufacturir g Manufacturing Year or quarter Total Plant Ennin tquipment Total Dura- Nonble durable goods goods Total Pub- Trade Comand munication Min- Transpor- lic tation ing utili- serv-1 and ties ices other2 1947 1948 1949 21.80 25.46 23.54 8.45 10 35 10.20 13.35 15.11 13.34 8.73 9.25 7.32 3.39 3.54 2.67 5.34 5.71 4.64 13.07 16.21 16.22 0.69 .93 .88 2.21 2.66 2.30 1.64 2.67 3.28 6.13 6.92 7.13 2.40 3^4 2.63 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 25.32 30.83 31.59 33.58 33.13 10.94 13.08 13.14 13 82 14.09 14.37 17.74 18.45 19.76 19.03 7.73 11.07 12.12 12.43 12.00 3.22 5.12 5.75 5.71 5.49 4.51 5.95 6.37 6.72 6.51 17.59 19.76 19.47 21.16 21.13 .84 1.11 1.21 1.25 1.29 2.38 3.05 2.99 2.97 2.42 3.42 3.75 3.96 4.61 4.23 8.37 8.83 8.05 8.94 9.59 2.58 3.03 3.25 3 38 3.60 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 36.58 44.76 48.12 4217 44.78 15.97 19 34 20.94 19 41 19.89 20.60 25.42 27.19 22.76 24.89 12.50 16.33 17.50 12.98 13.76 5.87 8.19 8.59 6.21 6.72 6.62 8.15 8.91 6.77 7.04 24.08 28.43 30.62 29.19 31.02 1.31 1.64 1.69 1.43 1.35 2.60 3.07 3.35 2.34 3.17 4.26 4.78 5.95 5.74 5.46 11.49 13.64 13.68 14.11 15.40 4.42 5 30 5.96 5 58 5.63 I960 1961 1962 1963 1964 48.63 47 82 51.28 53 25 61.66 20.94 2112 22.12 22 23 24.96 27.70 2670 29.16 3103 36.70 16.36 8.28 15 53 7.43 16.03 7.81 17 27 8.64 21.23 10.98 8.08 8.10 8.22 8.63 10.25 32.28 32 29 35.25 35.99 40.43 1.29 126 1.41 126 1.33 3.19 2.82 3.26 3.36 4.46 5.40 5.20 5.12 5.33 5.80 16.15 16 53 18.27 18 57 20.38 6.25 6 48 7.19 7 47 8.46 1965 1966 1967 1968 19*69 70.43 82 22 83.42 88.45 99.52 27 24 32 21 32.22 35.51 40.54 43.19 50.01 51.20 52.94 58.99 25.41 3137 32.25 32.34 36.27 13.49 17.23 17.83 17.93 19.97 11.92 14 15 14.42 14.40 16.31 45.02 50.84 51.18 56.11 63.25 1.36 142 1.38 1.44 1.77 5.46 6.49 22.13 6.43 7.82 24.69 6.34 9.33 23.02 6.79 10.52 25.31 7.04 11.70 28.31 9.58 1049 11.11 12.06 14.43 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 105.61 108.53 120.25 137.70 156.98 44.24 46 60 49.35 56.66 64.29 61.36 61.93 70.89 81.04 92.69 36.99 33.60 35.42 42.37 53.21 19.80 16.78 18.22 22.75 27.44 17.19 68.62 16.82 74.93 17.20 84.82 19.62 95.33 25.76 103.78 2.02 2.67 2.88 3.31 4.62 6.95 5.93 6.72 7.41 8.23 13.03 14.70 16.26 17.97 19.83 29.77 34.20 40.00 45.53 47.79 16.85 17.43 18.96 21.12 23.30 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 157 71 65 21 171.45 7120 198 08 80 31 231.24 92.70 270.46 105.73 294.30 32613 92 50 100.25 117 77 138.54 164.73 54 92 59.95 69 22 79.72 98.68 26.33 28.47 34.04 40.43 51.07 28.59 31.47 3518 39.29 47.61 102 79 610 111.50 7.44 128 87 9 24 151.52 10.21 171.77 11.38 8.68 8.89 9.40 10.68 12.35 19 98 22.37 26 79 29.95 33.96 46 23 49.30 56 54 68.66 79.26 2180 23.51 26 90 32.02 34.83 11.98 34.62 82.28 12.96 37.64. 87.83 37.02 40.54 102.58 104.19 106.58 108.60 152.97 161.04 166.56 175.70 198033 1981 114.90 58.25 131.12 66.00 56.65 179.40 13.50 65.12 195.00 16.04 90.75 46.38 94.71 49.25 52.13 55.03 106.57 44.37 45.47 47.97 51.55 164.80 170.52 173.04 177.73 11.23 11.01 11.40 11.86 11.43 12.02 12.67 13.20 32.40 34.02 35.05 34.08 76.03 79.03 78.86 82.69 33.71 34.44 35.05 35.90 1980: 1 || Ill IV3 291.89 115.96 175.93 111.77 58.28 294.36 116.50 177.86 115.69 59.38 296.23 117 59 178.64 116.40 58.19 115.37 57.42 294.95 53.49 56.32 58.21 57.96 180.13 178.66 179.83 179.58 11.89 12.81 13.86 15.25 12.47 12.09 12.23 11.25 36.26 35.03 35.58 31.95 82.17 81.07 81.19 84.87 37.34 37.66 36.97 36.26 1981: I3 310.59 _ 1979; ti Ill IV. 255 55 265.24 273.15 284.30 aoo.n 39.48 11.50 36.78 84.09 122.69 60.23 62.46 187.90 16.07 40.01 11.60 36.21 87.43 130.57 65.36 65.21 193.27 18.02 :=: 1 Wholesale and retail trade; finance, insurance, and real estate; and personal, business, and professional services. 2 "Other" consists of construction; social services and membership organizations; and forestry, fisheries, and agricultural services. 3 Planned capital expenditures reported by business in late October-December 1980, corrected for biases. Note,—Revised series; for details, see Sumy of Current Business, October 1980. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. II*'ZZZZZZZ!!'..'ZZZZ 323.84 285 TABLE B-47.—Sales and inventories in manufacturing and trade, 1947-80 [Amounts in millions of dollars; monthly data seasonally adjusted] Total manufacturing and trade Year or month Sales' Inventories 2 Ratio 3 Merchant wholesalers Manufacturing Sales 1 Inventories 2 Ratio3 Sales' Retail trade Inventories 2 Ratio* Sales' Inven3 tories2 Ratio 35,260 33,788 52,507 49,497 1.42 1.53 15,513 17,316 16,126 25,897 28,543 26,321 1.58 1.57 1.75 6,808 6,514 7,957 7,706 1.13 1.19 10,200 11,135 11,149 14,241 16,007 15,470 1.26 1.39 1.41 38,596 43,356 44,840 47,987 46,443 59,822 70,242 72,377 76,122 73,175 1.36 1.55 1.58 1.58 1.60 18,634 21,714 22,529 24,843 23,355 31,078 39,306 41,136 43,948 41,612 1.48 1.66 1.78 1.76 1.81 7,695 8,597 8,782 9,052 8,993 9,284 9,886 10,210 10,686 10,637 1.07 1.16 1.12 1.17 1.18 12,268 13,046 13,529 14,091 14,095 19,460 21,050 21,031 21,488 20,926 1.38 1.64 1.52 1.53 1.51 51,694 54,063 55,879 54,201 59,729 79,516 87,304 89,052 87,093 92,129 1.47 1.55 1.59 1.60 1.50 26,480 27,740 28,736 27,247 30,286 45,069 50,642 51,871 50,241 52,945 1.62 1.73 1.80 1.84 1.70 9,893 10,513 10,475 10,257 11,491 11,678 13,260 12,730 12,739 13,879 1.13 1.19 1.23 1.24 1.15 15,321 15,811 16,667 16,696 17,951 22,769 23,402 24,451 24,113 25,305 1.43 1.47 1.44 1.43 1.40 60,827 61,159 65,662 68,995 73,682 94,713 95,594 101,063 105,480 111,503 1.56 1.54 1.50 1.49 1.47 30,879 30,923 33,357 35,058 37,331 53,780 54,885 58,186 60,046 63,409 1.75 1.74 1.70 1.69 1.64 11,656 11,988 12,674 13,382 14,529 14,120 14,488 14,936 16,048 17,000 1.22 18,294 1.20 18,249 1.16 19,630 1.15 20,556 1.14 21,823 26,813 26,221 27,941 29,386 31,094 1.45 1.43 1.38 1.39 1.40 80,283 87,187 90,348 98,143 105,042 120,907 136,790 145,335 156,166 169,841 1.45 1.47 1.56 1.54 1.55 40,995 44,870 46,487 50,268 53,540 68,185 77,952 84,659 90,617 98,210 1.60 1.62 1.76 1.74 1.77 15,611 16,987 19,448 20,846 22,609 18,317 20,765 25,377 26,604 29,114 1.15 1.15 1.25 1.25 1.23 23,677 25,330 24,413 27,030 28,893 34,405 38,073 35,299 38,945 42,517 1.39 1.44 1.43 1.38 1.41 107,475 178,337 116,035 188,563 130,049 203,161 152,237 234,163 175,741 285,519 1.62 1.58 1.50 1.43 1.47 52,832 55,925 63,042 72,954 84,821 101,667 102,677 108,296 124,672 157,915 1.90 1.83 1.67 1.58 1.65 23,943 26,257 29,584 36,822 45,836 32,803 35,823 39,786 46,254 56,537 1.29 30,700 1.30 33,853 1.27 37,422 1.17 42,461 1.12 45,083 43,867 50,063 55,079 63,237 71,067 1.41 1.41 1.40 1.40 1.48 180,263 285,035 202,001 310,736 224,786 337,432 254,297 380,643 288,388 426,796 1.58 86,617 158,178 1.48 98,810 170,156 1.44 110,842 180,224 1.41 124,714 198,334 1.41 141,000 228,258 1.83 1.66 1.59 1.52 1.52 44,633 53,509 62,842 73,551 55,113 61,307 67,998 80,771 89,676 1.24 49,013 71,744 1.21 54,784 79,273 1.21 60,435 89,210 1.19 66,741 101,538 1.17 73,837 108,862 1.44 1.38 1.39 1.43 1.45 274,091 274,844 283,741 276,406 286,413 283,772 385,379 389,312 392,630 398,307 401,945 406,720 1.41 1.42 1.38 1.44 1.40 1.43 135,213 135,718 141,039 134,398 141,783 139,050 201,143 203,819 205,752 209,175 210,881 213,942 1.49 1.50 1.46 1.56 1.49 1.54 67,585 67,860 70,657 70,402 72,338 72,629 81,498 82,700 83,558 84,632 84,904 85,406 1.21 1.22 1.18 1.20 1.17 1.18 71,293 71,266 72,045 71,606 72,292 72,093 102,738 102,793 103,320 104,500 106,160 107,372 1.44 1.44 1.43 1.46 1.47 1.49 289,994 293,167 296,760 298,452 298,949 302,117 413,581 417,130 418,461 422,710 425,952 426,796 1.43 142,094 1.42 142,708 1.41 143,614 1.42 145,547 1.43 144,326 1.41 146,289 216,120 218,669 221,341 223,476 226,483 228,258 1.52 1.53 1.54 1.54 1.57 1.56 74,778 75,588 76,480 77,322 78,203 78,678 87,662 88,280 88,372 88,819 89,676 1.17 73,121 1.17 74,871 1.16 76,666 1.15 75,583 1.14 76,421 1.14 77,150 109,799 110,181 108,748 110,415 110,383 108,862 1.50 1.47 1.42 1.46 1.44 1.41 312,458 310,181 305,165 294,998 292,478 294,203 431,420 435,155 439,114 445,170 445,801 447,031 1.38 152,088 1.40 152,889 1.44 150,081 1.51 143,596 1.52 141,515 1.52 141,573 232,294 235,096 238,522 242,540 243,402 243,630 1.53 1.54 1.59 1.69 1.72 1.72 80,906 79,299 78,550 76,391 76,376 76,629 90,690 91,342 91,497 92,378 92,562 93,633 1.12 79,464 108,436 1.15 77,993 108,717 1.17 76,534 109,095 1.21 75,011 110,252 1.21 74,587 109,837 1.22 76,001 109,768 1.36 1.39 1.43 1.47 1.47 1.44 304,154 308,019 318,321 325,838 329,140 449,510 451,951 454,566 456,532 458,235 1.48 1.47 1.43 1.40 1.39 145,678 146,643 152,764 156,697 158,386 244,105 243,517 243,615 242,876 244,186 1.68 1.66 1.59 1.55 1.54 80,189 82,606 85,470 88,532 88,821 94,619 97,111 98,111 99,275 99,879 1.18 78,287 110,786 1.18 78,770 111,323 1.15 80,087 112,840 1.12 80,609 114,381 1.12 81,933 114,170 80,830 1.42 1.41 1.41 1.42 1.39 1 Monthly average for year and total for month. Seasonally adjusted, end of period. Inventory/sales ratio. For annual periods, ratio of weighted average inventories to average monthly sales; for monthly data, ratio of inventories at end of month to sales for month. Note.—Earlier data are not strictly comparable with data beginning 1958 for manufacturing and beginning 1967 for wholesale and 2 3 The inventory figures in this table do not agree with the estimates of change in business inventories included in the gross national product since these figures cover only manufacturing and trade rather than all Dusiness, and show inventories in terms of current book value without adjustment for revaluation. Source: Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic Analysis and Bureau of the Census). 286 TABLE B-48.—Manufacturers' shipments and inventories, 1947-80 [Millions of dollars; monthly data seasonally adjusted] Shipments1 Year or month Total Inventories2 Nondurable goods indus- industries tries 1947 .. 1948.. 1949... 15,513 17,316 16,126 6,694 7,579 7,191 1950 .. 1951.. 1952 1953 . 1954 , 18,634 21,714 22,529 24,843 23,355 1955. 1956.. 1957.. 1958.. 1959 Nondurable goods industries Durable goods industries Durable Total Total 8,819 25,897 9,738 28,543 8,935 26,321 Materials and supplies Work m proc- Finished goods Total Materials and supplies Work in proc- Finished goods 13,061 14,662 13,060 12,836 13,881 13,261 8,845 10,493 11,313 13,349 11,828 9,789 31,078 15,539 11,221 39,306 20,991 11,216 41,136 23,731 11,494 43,948 25,878 11,527 41,612 23,710 15,539 18,315 17,405 6,206 18,070 6,040 17,902 8,317 8,167 2,472 2,440 7,409 7,415 26,480 27,740 28,736 27,247 30,286 14,071 14,715 15,237 13,563 15,609 12,409 13,025 13,499 13,684 14,677 45,069 50,642 51,871 50,241 52,945 26,405 30,447 31,728 30,258 32,077 19,194 10,417 10,608 10,032 10,776 10,756 12,317 12,837 12,387 13,063 6,348 7,565 8,125 7,839 8,239 18,664 20,195 20,143 19,983 20,868 8,556 8,971 8,775 8,662 9,080 2,571 2,721 2,864 2,828 2,944 7,666 8,622 8,624 8,491 8,845 I960 1961. 1962 . 1963 1964 . 30,879 30,923 33,357 35,058 37,331 15,883 15,616 17,262 18,280 19,637 14,996 15,307 16,095 16,778 17,694 53,780 54,885 58,186 60,046 63,409 32,371 32,544 34,632 35,866 38,506 10,353 10,279 10,810 11,068 11,970 12,772 13,203 14,159 14,871 16,191 9,245 9,063 9,662 9,925 10,344 21,409 22,341 23,554 24,180 24,903 9,082 9,493 9,813 9,978 10,131 2,946 3,110 3,296 3,406 3,511 9,380 9,738 10,444 10,796 11,261 1965 1966 1967 1968. 1969. 40,995 44,870 46,487 50,268 53,540 22,221 24,649 25,267 27,698 29,477 18,774 68,185 42,257 20,220 77,952 49,920 21,220 84,659 54,996 22,570 90,617 58,871 24,064 98,210 64,739 13,325 15,489 16,454 17,389 18,710 18,075 21,939 25,001 27,314 30,377 10,854 12,491 13,542 14,167 15,651 25,928 28,032 29,662 31,746 33,471 10,448 11,155 11,715 12,289 12,726 3,806 4,204 4,423 4,849 5,124 11,674 12,673 13,524 14,608 15,621 .. .. .. ... .. . 52,832 55,925 63,042 72,954 84,821 28,215 29,973 34,043 39,703 44,253 24,617 25,952 28,999 33,251 40,568 101,667 66,790 102,677 66,313 108,296 70,308 124,672 81,426 157,915 101,866 19,198 19,778 20,893 26,062 35,228 29,836 28,654 30,819 35,546 42,683 17,756 17,882 18,597 19,818 23,956 34,877 36,364 37,987 43,245 56,048 13,154 13,680 14,676 18,134 23,689 5,275 5,669 5,983 6,713 8,179 16,448 17,015 17,328 18,398 24,180 1975 1976 1977 1978 . 1979 86,617 98,810 110,842 124,714 141,000 43,678 50,697 58,010 66,505 73,981 42,939 48,113 52,832 58,210 67,019 158,178 170,156 180,224 198,334 228,258 101,766 109,095 115,751 129,456 151,689 33,629 36,562 38,785 41,480 48,857 42,923 44,843 47,030 55,523 66,837 25,214 27,690 29,937 32,454 35,994 56,412 61,061 64,472 68,878 76,569 23,199 8,692 25,056 9,576 25,316 10,152 26,719 10,729 30,257 11,774 24,521 26,429 29,005 31,430 34,538 Jan.. Feb. Mar... Apr.... May. June. 135,213 135,718 141,039 134,398 141,783 139,050 72,779 73,335 75,763 71,199 75,515 72,797 62,434 62,383 65,276 63,199 66,268 66,253 201,143 203,819 205,752 209,175 210,881 213,942 131,892 134,021 135,266 137,851 139,325 141,480 42,178 42,751 43,493 43,904 44,430 44,803 56,326 57,226 57,720 59,009 59,950 61,411 33,388 34,045 34,054 34,938 34,944 35,267 69,251 69,798 70,485 71,323 71,556 72,462 27,084 27,353 27,669 28,040 28,058 28,269 10,859 10,978 10,994 11,142 11,222 11,380 31,309 31,467 31,822 32,141 32,276 32,813 July . Aug... Sept.. Oct.. Nov Dec . 142,094 142,708 143,614 145,547 144,326 146,289 73,875 74,363 74,201 75,544 73,751 74,191 68,220 68,345 69,414 70,003 70,574 72,098 216,120 218,669 221,341 223,476 226,483 228,258 143,141 144,658 146,048 148,136 150,476 151,689 45,524 46,378 46,417 47,362 48,416 48,857 61,927 62,607 63,810 64,859 66,145 66,837 35,691 35,671 35,821 35,914 35,916 35,994 72,979 -28,527 11,522 74,011 29,109 11,621 75,293 29,353 11,888 75,340 29,644 11,860 76,007 30,084 11,894 76,569 30,257 11,774 32,930 33,281 34,052 33,836 34,027 34,538 152,088 152,889 150,081 143,596 141,515 141,573 77,948 79,159 75,925 72,207 69,443 69,056 74,140 73,730 74,156 71,389 72,07.2 72,517 232,294 235,096 238,522 242,540 243,402 243,630 154,043 155,314 157,127 159,877 160,607 160,404 49,627 50,248 50,347 51,086 50,665 50,177 67,951 68,397 69,585 70,594 71,411 71,891 36,465 36,669 37,195 38,197 38,531 38,336 78,251 79,782 81,395 82,663 82,795 83,226 30,873 31,418 31,967 32,322 32,406 32,338 12,065 12,269 12,687 12,774 12,708 12,611 35,313 36,095 36,741 37,567 37,681 38,277 June.. 145,678 72,544 73,134 244,105 160,875 50,032 July . 146,643 72,057 74,586 243,517 161,081 49,136 Aug . 152,764 76,571 76,193 243,615 160,691 49,007 Sept 156,697 79,497 77,200 242,876 160,137 48,722 Oct.. 158,386 80,268 78,118 244,186 160,865 48,796 Nov. 1 Monthly average for year and total for month. 2 Book value, seasonally adjusted, end of period. Note.—Data beginning 1958 are not strictly comparable with earlier data. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 72,126 73,113 73,209 73,037 73,693 38,717 38,832 38,475 38,378 38,376 83,230 82,436 82,924 82,739 83,321 32,314 31,461 31,918 32,139 32,278 12,634 12,620 12,725 12,551 12,790 38,282 38,355 38,281 38,049 38,253 1970 1971. 1972 1973 1974 8,966 10,720 7,894 9,721 1979: 1980: Jan Feb.. Mar. fc: 287 TABLE B-49.—Manufacturers' new and unfilled orders, 1947-80 [Amounts in millions of dollars; monthly data seasonally adjusted] Unfilled orders—shipments ratio 3 Unfilled orders2 New orders* industries Year or month Total Total NonCapital durable goods ;oods good indus* industi tries, nondefense Total Durable goods industries Nondurable Total industries NonDurable durable goods goods Industries industries 1947... 1948... 1949. 15,256 17,693 15,614 6,388 8,126 6,633 9,566 8,981 34,473 30,736 24,045 28,579 26,619 19,622 5,894 4,117 4,423 1950 1951.. 1952 1953 1954 . 20,110 23,907 23,204 23,586 22,335 10,165 12,841 12,061 12,147 10,768 9,945 11,066 11,143 11,439 11,566 41,456 67,266 75,857 61,178 48,266 35,435 63,394 72,680 58,637 45,250 6,021 3,872 3,177 2,541 3,016 3.42 4.12 0.96 1955. 1956.. 1957.. 1958. 1959. 27,465 28,368 27,559 27,002 30,724 14,996 15,365 14,111 13,290 16,003 12,469 13,003 13,448 13,712 14,720 60,004 67,375 53,183 47,370 52,732 56,241 63,880 50,352 44,559 49,373 3,763 3,495 2,831 2,811 3,359 3.63 3.87 3.35 3.09 3.01 4.27 4.55 4.00 3.69 3.54 1.12 1.04 .85 .86 ,94 1960. 1961 1962 1963.. 1964.. 30,235 31,104 33,436 35,524 38,357 15,303 15,759 17,374 18,709 20,652 14,932 15,345 16,061 16,815 17,705 45,080 47,407 48,577 54,327 66,882 42,514 44,375 45,965 51,270 63,691 2,566 3,032 2,612 3,057 3,191 2.78 2.63 2.69 2.80 3.10 3.37 3.13 3.24 3.37 3.72 .72 ,79 .68 .73 .72 1965 1966. 1967 . 1968 1969 42,100 46,402 47,062 50,684 53,967 23,278 26,177 25,831 28,113 29,887 7,070 7,746 18,823 20,225 21,231 22,571 24,079 80,071 98,401 105,030 109,912 115,142 76,298 94,575 101,058 105,935 110,969 3,773 3,826 3,972 3,977 4,173 3.33 3.81 3.71 3.84 3.74 3.95 4.55 4.42 4.64 4.48 .80 .76 .73 .69 .69 1970 1971 1972,. 1973 1974 52,068 55,990 64,162 76,183 87,157 27,418 30,004 35,059 42,853 46,740 6,800 7,517 8,803 11,089 12,737 24,650 25,986 29,104 33,330 40,417 105,916 106,772 120,395 159,468 187,574 101,323 101,744 114,059 152,089 182,037 4,593 5,028 6,336 7,379 5,537 3.64 3.37 3.29 3.87 4.12 4,38 4.04 3.89 4.58 4.94 .77 .77 .88 .93 .64 1975.. 1976... 1977. 1978 1979 85,082 99,184 112,451 128,488 144,335 41,957 51,047 59,562 70,145 77,215 10,772 12,501 15,084 18,308 21,643 43,125 169,126 48,137 173,646 52,889 193,561 58,344 239,321 67,120 279,710 161,286 165,509 184,708 228,819 267,879 7,840 8,137 8,852 10,502 11,831 3.69 3.20 3.16 3.35 3.67 4.42 3.83 3.77 3.92 4.35 .83 .74 .73 .80 .81 140,822 143,138 146,836 139,232 143,302 142,386 78,684 80,430 81,649 75,927 77,037 76,028 21,226 22,483 23,604 20,600 21,129 21,704 62,138 62,708 65,187 63,305 66,264 66,359 244,930 252,350 258,148 262,981 264,500 267,837 234,725 241,820 247,706 252,433 253,956 257,187 10,205 10,531 10,442 10,548 10,544 10,650 3.43 3.51 3.44 3.69 3.52 3.64 4.05 4.13 4.04 4.39 4.18 4.32 .76 .79 .75 .77 .74 .75 142,620 143,615 147,378 146,610 146,996 149,232 74,585 74,762 77,647 76,521 75,903 77,199 21,227 21,077 21,578 21,073 21,754 22,285 68,035 268,362 68,854 269,269 69,731 273,033 70,089 274,097 71,092 276,767 72,033 279,710 257,897 258,295 261,742 262,719 264,871 267,879 10,465 10,974 11,291 11,378 11,896 11,831 3.57 3.58 3.63 3.57 3.66 3.67 4.26 4.24 4.31 4.23 4.35 4.35 .71 .76 .78 .78 .81 .81 1980: Jan Feb.. . Mar. May" June. 155,588 154,603 152,065 143,313 138,920 138,582 81,467 81,021 77,546 72,416 67,328 66,454 23,859 21,480 22,590 22,162 19,589 19,954 74,121 73,582 74,519 70,897 71,592 72,128 283,211 284,924 286,907 286,629 284,033 281,044 271,399 273,263 274,884 275,098 272,981 270,383 11,812 11,661 12,023 11,531 11,052 10,661 3.53 3.53 3.62 3.75 3.83 3.82 4.20 4.17 4.30 4.50 4.61 4.60 .75 .77 .79 .76 .74 .71 July.. Aug.. Sept Ocl Nov *., 147,104 147,180 155,262 158,054 159,629 74,228 72,229 78,960 80,693 81,756 21,608 19,371 20,860 20,618 21,980 72,876 74,951 76,302 77,361 77,873 282,463 282,997 285,497 286,849 288,094 272,062 272,231 274,622 275,813 277,300 10,401 10,766 10,875 11,036 10,794 3.71 3.76 3.56 3.51 3.49 4.48 4.52 4.26 4.18 4.15 .68 .72 .69 .71 .69 1979: Jan Feb... Mar... fc.. June. July.., Aug . Sept Oct. Nov.. Dec 1 2 3 Monthly average for year and total for month. Seasonally adjusted, end of period. Ratio of unfilled orders at end of period to shipments for period; excludes industries with no unfilled orders. Annual figures relate to seasonally adjusted data for December. Note.—Data beginning 1958 are not strictly comparable with earlier data. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 288 PRICES TABLE B-50.—Consumer price indexes, major expenditure classes, 1929-80 [1967 = 100] Year or month All items Total > 1929 .. 1933 1939. . . Housing Food and beverages Food Total2 Rent, Home Fuel and other resi- ownerdential ship utilities3 Other Apparel TransEntergoods Medical and tainment and portation care upkeep services Energy1* 51.3 38.8 41.6 48.3 30 6 34.6 52Y 76.0 541 560 48.5 369 42.4 43.0 36.7 1940 . . 1941 .. .. 1942 1943. 1944 1945 1946. 1947 1948 1949. . 42.0 44.1 48.8 51.8 52.7 539 58.5 66 9 72.1 71.4 35.2 38.4 45.1 50.3 49.6 50.7 58.1 70.6 76.6 73.5 52.4 53.7 56.2 56.8 58.1 591 60.6 65.2 69.8 70.9 56.2 57.2 58.5 58.5 58.6 58.8 59.2 61.1 65.1 68.0 4^.8 44.8 52.3 54.6 58.5 61.5 67.5 78.2 83.3 80.1 42.7 44.2 48.1 47.9 47.9 47 8 50.3 55 5 61.8 66.4 36.8 37.0 38.0 39 9 411 421 44.4 481 51.1 52.7 1950 1951 1952.. .. 1953 1954. . .. 1955 1956 . .. . 1957 1958 1959 72.1 77.8 79.5 80.1 80.5 80.2 81.4 84 3 86.6 87.3 74.5 82.8 84.3 83.0 82.8 81.6 82.2 84.9 88.5 87.1 72.8 77.2 78.7 80.8 81.7 82.3 83.6 86.2 87.7 88.6 70.4 73.2 76.2 80.3 83.2 84.3 85.9 87.5 89.1 90.4 75.0 76.3 77.0 78.3 817 83.5 84.4 83.0 83.5 85.1 87.3 89.9 91.7 93.8 79.0 86.1 85.3 84.6 84.5 84.1 85.8 87.3 87.5 88.2 68 2 72.5 77.3 79.5 78.3 77.4 78.8 83.3 86.0 89.6 53.7 56.3 59.3 61.4 63.4 64 8 67 2 69.9 73.2 76.4 90.1 90.3 91.8 90.2 90.9 91.7 92.7 93.8 94 9 97.2 100.0 104 0 110.4 91.7 92.9 94.0 95.0 95.9 96 9 98.2 100.0 102.4 105.7 86.3 86.9 87.9 89.0 90.8 92 7 96.3 100.0 105.7 116.0 95.9 97.1 97.3 98.2 98.4 983 98.8 100.0 101.3 103.6 89.6 90.4 90.9 91.9 92.7 93 7 96.1 100.0 105.4 111.5 89.6 90.6 92.5 93.0 94.3 95 9 97.2 100.0 103.2 107.2 79.1 81.4 83.5 85.6 87.3 89 5 93.4 100.0 106.1 113.4 1960 196] 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 . . 1972 . 1973... „ 1974 . 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979. 1979: Jan. Feb Mar. .. Apr May . June July Aug. Sept Oct.. .. Nov Dec 1980. Jan. . Feb Mar . . Xv June July . Aug Sept Oct Nov . ..."""'. 1 88.7 89.6 90.6 91.7 92.9 94 5 97.2 100.0 104 2 109.8 103 6 108.8 88.0 89.1 89.9 91.2 92.4 94 4 99.1 100.0 103.6 108.9 111.0 110.4 94.2 94.4 94.7 95 0 94.6 963 978 100.0 101.5 104.2 116.3 121.3 125.3 133.1 147.7 161.2 170.5 1815 195.4 217.4 114.7 118.3 123.2 139.5 158.7 172.1 177.4 188.0 206.3 228.5 114.9 118.4 123.5 141.4 161.7 175.4 180.8 192.2 211.4 234.5 118.2 123.4 128.1 133.7 148.8 164.5 174.6 186 5 202.8 227.6 110.1 115.2 119.2 124.3 130.6 137.3 144.7 153.5 164.0 176.0 128.5 133.7 140.1 146.7 163.2 181.7 191.7 204 9 227.2 262.4 107.6 115.0 120.1 126.9 150.2 167.8 182.7 202 2 216.0 239.3 116.1 119.8 122.3 126.8 136.2 142.3 147.6 154.2 159.6 166.6 112.7 118.6 119.9 123.8 137.7 150.6 165.5 177 2 185.5 212.0 120.6 128.4 132.5 137.7 150.5 168.6 184.7 202 4 219.4 239.7 116.7 122.9 126.5 130.0 139.8 152.2 159.8 167.7 176.6 188.5 116.8 122.4 127.5 132.5 142.0 153.9 162.7 172.2 183.3 196.7 107.0 111.2 114.3 123.5 159.7 176.6 189.3 207.3 220.4 275.9 204.7 207.1 209.1 211.5 214.1 216.6 218.9 221.1 223.4 225.4 227 5 229.9 218.3 222.4 224.4 226.3 228.2 229.3 230.7 230.2 231.0 232.1 2331 235.5 223.9 228.2 230.4 232.3 234.3 235.4 236.9 236.3 237.1 238.2 239.1 241.7 213.1 215.6 217.6 219.8 222.4 225.5 228.4 231.5 234.6 237.7 240 8 243.6 170.3 171.0 171.3 172.0 173.8 174.7 175.9 177.5 179.0 181.4 1821 182.9 241.6 245.6 248.2 251.7 254.9 258.8 263.0 267.6 271.9 276.7 282 4 286.9 221.5 223.3 225.9 227.5 232.2 239.0 243.5 247.2 251.2 252.9 252 0 255.1 160.7 161.4 164.3 165.4 166.1 165.7 164.3 166.3 169.8 171.0 171.7 172.2 193.9 195.6 198.1 202.9 207.7 212.6 216.6 219.6 221.4 222.7 224 9 227.7 230.7 232.6 233.9 235.1 236.3 237.7 239.9 241.8 243.7 245.9 248.0 250.7 182.3 183.2 184.8 186.5 187.8 188.2 189.1 190.2 191.1 192.0 192.8 193.4 190.5 191.9 192.8 193.2 193.9 194.5 195.2 197.0 201.7 202.3 202.9 204.0 231.5 235.0 241.2 250.2 260.8 275.4 287.1 296.3 304.3 307.5 307.8 313.7 233.2 236.4 . 239.8 242.5 244.9 247.6 ... 247.8 249.4 251.7 253.9 256.2 237.5 238.6 241.0 242.8 244.1 245.7 248.3 252.0 254.2 255.5 257.4 243.8 244.9 247.3 249.1 250.4 252.0 254.8 258.7 261.1 262.4 264.5 247.3 250.5 254.5 257.9 261.7 266.7 265.1 265.8 267.7 271.1 273.8 184.1 185.6 186.6 187.0 188.9 191.1 192.1 193.2 195.1 197.1 198.3 292.5 296.3 302.0 307.7 312.9 320.4 315.4 315.4 317.6 323.8 329.4 258.6 263.8 268.0 270.5 275.9 282.2 285.5 286.8 288.2 287.6 285.7 171.0 171.9 176.0 177.3 177.5 177.2 176.2 178.6 182.2 183.9 184.8 233.5 239.6 243.7 246.8 249.0 249.7 251.0 252.7 254.7 256.1 259.0 253.9 257.9 260.2 262.0 263.4 264.7 266.6 268.4 270.6 272.8 274.5 195.3 197.8 200.6 202.5 204.0 205.3 206.6 208.0 209.8 210.9 211.2 206.3 208.1 208.9 209.8 211.2 212.5 213.5 214.5 220.6 221.5 222.8 327.9 344.6 355.0 358.8 363.2 367.8 370.4 370.7 370.1 368.0 366.1 . . 1 ib'6"6" ioo.o 105.7 105.2 Includes alcoholic beverages, not shown separately. Includes other items, not shown separately. Series beginning 1967 not comparable with series for earlier years. Fuel oil, coal, and bottled gas; gas (piped) and electricity; and other utilities and public services. 4 Fuel oil, coal, and bottled gas; gas (piped) and electricity; and gasoline, motor oil, coolant, etc. Note.—Data beginning 1978 are for all urban consumers; earlier data are for urban wage earners and clerical workers. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2 3 289 TABLE B-51.—Consumer price indexes, selected expenditure classes, 1939-80 [1967-100] Homeownership Food and beverage Fuel and other utilities Household fuels Food Year or month UAMA Total Total At home Away from nome Total hnmo nome purchase Financing, taxes, and insurance Maintenance and repair Total Total Fuel oil coal, and bottled gas Gas and electricity 1939 34 6 37.1 82.9 1940 . 1941... 1942 1943'" 1944 1945..! 1946 1947 1948 1949 35.2 38.4 45.1 49 6 50.7 58.1 70.6 76 6 73.5 38.2 40.5 43.1 45.2 47.1 48.0 51.3 58.4 68,6 70.3 82.1 81.4 81.0 80.6 80.3 79.6 77.4 77.1 79.1 81.0 1950 195ll* 1952 1953!!!!', 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 74 5 82.8 84 3 83.0 82.8 81.6 82.2 84,9 88,5 87.1 77 6 86.3 87 8 86.2 85.8 84.1 84.4 87.2 91.0 88.8 72 7 76.5 68.9 70.1 70.8 72.2 74.9 77.2 79.3 81.2 81.5 82.6 84.2 85.3 87.5 88.4 89.3 92.4 89.6 90.4 91.0 92.2 93.2 95.5 100.3 100.0 103.2 108.2 81.4 83.2 85.4 87.3 88.9 90.9 95.1 100.0 105.2 111.6 86.3 86.9 87.9 89.0 90.8 92.7 96.3 100.0 105.7 116.0 92 3 93.2 94 2 95,7 97.0 98.6 100.0 102.8 109.5 503 . *ni 79.8 76.7 780 75.0 ''' 86.5 87.1 76.3 87 3 77.0 87.6 78.3 90.0 817 91.3 83.5 84.4 913 71.2 72.4 74.1 77.2 80.5 81.8 83.2 83.0 83.5 85.1 87.3 89.9 8l!5 81.2 82.3 85.9 90.3 917 887 89.8 947 918 95.9 97.1 97.3 98.2 98.4 98.3 98.8 100.0 101.3 103.6 89.2 91.0 91.5 93.2 100.0 108.3 1237 84.6 85.9 86.5 87.7 89.5 91.3 95.2 100.0 106.1 115.0 101.4 103.4 94.6 97.0 100.0 103.1 105.6 98.6 99.4 99.4 99.4 99.4 99.4 99.6 100.0 100.9 102.8 93.8 Other utilities and public services 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964.... 1965.... 1966... 1967 1968!!!!!! 1969 100.0 103.6 108,8 88.0 89.1 89.9 91.2 92.4 94.4 99.1 100.0 103.6 108.9 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976!!!!!! 1977 1978 1979 114.7 118.3 123.2 139,5 1587 172.1 177.4 188.0 206.3 228.5 114.9 118.4 123.5 141.4 161.7 175.4 180.8 192.2 211.4 234.5 1137 116.4 121.6 141,4 162.4 175.8 179.5 190.2 210.2 232.9 119.9 126.1 131.1 141.4 159.4 174.3 186.1 200.3 218.4 242.9 128.5 133.7 140.1 146.7 163.2 181.7 191.7 204.9 227.2 262.4 118.3 124.8 130.0 1327 1427 160.3 168.4 179.5 196.7 223.1 142.3 143.5 150.8 160.6 181.1 201.9 212.8 227.2 257.8 308.9 124.0 1337 1407 151.0 171.6 187.6 199.6 214.7 233.0 256.4 107.6 115.0 120.1 126.9 150.2 167.8 182.7 202.2 216.0 239.3 107.9 115.3 120.1 128.4 1607 183.8 202.3 228.6 247.4 286.4 110.1 117.5 118.5 136.0 214.6 235.3 250.8 283.4 298.3 403.1 107.3 1147 120.5 126.4 145.8 169.6 189.0 213.4 232.6 257.8 107.4 1147 120.6 124.1 130.3 137.1 145.4 152,0 158.3 159.5 1979: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June 218.3 222.4 224.4 226.3 228.2 229.3 223.9 228.2 230.4 232.3 234.3 235.4 223.1 228.0 229.9 231,7 233.4 234.2 230.2 233.4 236.0 238.4 241.1 2427 241.6 245.6 248.2 2517 254.9 258.8 208.1 210.9 212.7 215.4 217.6 220.9 276.6 283.5 2877 292.1 297.2 302.2 245.2 245.9 247.5 250.6 252.4 255.5 221.5 223.3 225.9 227.5 232.2 239.0 256.3 259.3 264.0 266.8 274.6 286.2 316.4 326.1 339.5 349.8 364.3 391.2 239.5 241.2 244.0 245.3 251.6 259.9 159.0 159.0 158.8 158.8 159.0 159.2 230.7 230.2 231.0 232.1 233.1 235.5 236.9 236.3 237.1 238.2 239.1 2417 235.5 233.9 234.7 235.4 236.0 2387 244.9 246.5 247.6 249 6 251.3 253.4 263.0 267.6 271.9 276 7 282.4 286.9 224.0 226.9 229.8 233 4 237.3 239.9 308.6 316.4 323.0 330 5 340.1 348.3 257.9 259.7 262.5 264 7 266.4 268.3 243.5 247.2 251.2 252 9 252.0 255.1 293.8 2997 306.6 310 3 307.0 311.8 412.9 438.6 461.6 470 8 477.4 488.0 264.5 266.5 270.1 272 5 267.3 270.8 159.4 159.8 159.8 158 8 161.0 161.9 237.5 238.6 241.0 242.8 244.1 245.7 243.8 244.9 247.3 249.1 250.4 252.0 240.6 241.3 243.6 245.3 246.5 248.0 256.1 258.3 260.9 263.0 264.6 266.6 292.5 296.3 302.0 307.7 312.9 320.4 242.1 243.0 244.0 246.5 2497 252.6 359.8 3677 379.9 390.6 399.7 416.1 270.6 2737 278.8 282.9 284.9 285.9 258.6 263.8 268.0 270.5 275.9 282.2 318.0 327.1 333.9 337.8 346.4 355.8 514.0 539.1 553.4 556.4 556.0 5587 273.0 278.8 284.0 288.0 298.2 308.8 161.5 161.3 161.9 162.3 163.1 164.9 248.3 252.0 254.2 255.5 257.4 254.8 258.7 261.1 262.4 264.5 251.5 256.3 258.9 260.0 262.1 267.8 269.5 271.4 273.1 275.3 315.4 315.4 317.6 323.8 329.4 253.9 258.1 261.5 265.5 267.3 399.6 393.6 393.5 404.7 416.9 287.6 288.5 291.6 292.8 294.2 285.5 286.8 288.2 287.6 285.7 360.8 362.5 364.5 362.8 358.7 560.4 561.5 561.5 558.7 567.0 314,3 316.1 318.4 317.1 310.5 165.9 166.5 167.1 167.8 169.0 r July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 1980: Jan Feb Mar i/ay!!!!!!!!!! June July Aug Sept'!! Oct Nov See next page for continuation of table. 290 927 iod,'o 101.2 104.0 TABLE B-51.—Consumer price indexes, selected expenditure classes, 1939-80—Continued [1967=100] Transportatior Medical care Private Year or month Total Total New cars Used cars 1939 43.0 44.2 43.2 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 42.7 44.2 48.1 47.9 47.9 47.8 50.3 55.5 61.8 66.4 43 6 45.9 52 3 51.4 51.4 51.3 54.3 61.5 68.2 72.3 43,3 46.6 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 68.2 72.5 77.3 79.5 78.3 77.4 78.8 83.3 86.0 89.6 72.5 75 8 80.8 82.4 80.3 78 9 80.1 84 7 87.4 91.1 83.4 87 4 94 9 95.8 94.3 90.9 93.5 98.4 101.5 105,9 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 89.6 90.6 92.5 93.0 94.3 95.9 97.2 100.0 103.2 107.2 90.6 91.3 93.0 93.4 94.7 96.3 97.5 1000 103.0 106.5 104,5 104.5 104.1 103,5 103.2 100.9 99.1 100.0 102.8 104.4 83.6 86.9 94.8 96.0 100.1 99.4 97.0 1000 112.7 118.6 119.9 123.8 137.7 150 6 165.5 177.2 185.5 212.0 111.1 116.6 117.5 121.5 136.6 149 8 164.6 176.6 185.0 212.3 193.9 195.6 1981 202 9 207.7 212.6 216 6 219.6 . : : : v 221.4 222 7 224 9 227.7 233.5 239 6 243.7 246.8 249 0 249.7 251.0 252.7 254 7 2561 259.0 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1979: Jan Feb Mar Apr .... ... May::..:...:.::..:...:::::"..:. June July Aue sept:::::::::.: „• Nov Dec 1980: Jan . . . . Feb Mar Apr May June Julv Aug Sept Oct Nov . Gasoline AutoMedical Public mobile care Total mainte- Other transporcomtation nance modities and repair Medical care services 49.0 43.1 33.1 36.7 71.1 32.5 481 50.5 53 4 54.0 54.2 53.8 54.9 62.2 692 70.4 75.6 82.8 . ::: 72.3 43.0 44.9 48.8 49.4 50.0 50.4 52.0 56.4 59.6 61.1 331 33.1 33 3 33.4 33.5 33.5 34.4 36.0 40.7 45.2 36.8 37.0 38.0 39.9 41.1 42.1 44.4 48.1 51.1 52.7 70 8 71.4 73 0 73.5 74.3 74.8 76.2 81.8 86.1 87.4 32 5 32.7 33 7 35.4 36.9 37.9 40.1 43.5 46.4 48.1 71.8 73 9 75.8 80.3 82.5 83 6 86.5 90 0 88.8 89.9 62.3 67.0 68.6 72.3 74.8 76.5 79.5 82.4 83.7 85.5 48.9 54 0 57.5 61.3 65.5 67 4 70.0 72 7 76.1 78.3 53.7 56 3 59.3 61.4 63.4 64.8 67.2 69.9 73.2 76.4 88.5 910 91.8 92.6 93.7 94 7 96.7 99 3 102.8 104.4 49.2 51 7 55.0 57,0 58.7 60 4 62.8 65 5 68.7 72.0 103.1 92.5 91.4 91.9 91.8 91.4 94.9 97.0 100 0 101.4 104.7 87.2 89.3 90.4 91.6 92.8 94.5 96.2 100.0 105.5 112.2 103.4 109.7 81.0 84.6 87.4 88.5 90.1 91.9 95.2 100 0 104.6 112.7 79.1 81.4 83.5 85.6 87.3 89.5 93.4 100.0 106.1 113.4 104.5 103.3 101.7 100.8 100.5 100.2 100.5 100 0 100.2 101.3 74.9 77.7 80.2 82.6 84.6 87.3 92.0 100 0 107.3 116.0 107.6 112.0 111.0 111.1 117.5 127 6 135.7 142.9 153.8 166.0 104.3 110.2 110.5 117.6 122.6 146 4 167.9 182.8 186.5 201.0 105 6 106.3 107.6 118.1 159.9 170 8 177.9 188.2 196.3 265.6 120.6 129.2 135.1 142.2 156.8 176.6 189.7 203.7 220.6 242.6 119.2 128.4 129.1 127.8 132.4 141.2 163.1 177.3 184.6 198.6 128.5 137.7 143.4 144.8 148.0 158.6 174.2 182.4 187.8 200.3 120.6 128.4 132.5 137.7 150.5 168.6 184.7 202.4 219.4 239.7 103.6 105.4 105.6 105.9 109.6 118 8 126.0 134.1 143.5 153.8 124 2 133.3 138.2 144.3 159.1 1791 197.1 216.7 235.4 258.3 193.8 195 5 1981 203 2 208.1 213.3 217 4 220.4 222.0 2231 225 0 227.5 161.2 162.3 162 7 164 3 165.8 166.3 166 7 166.6 166.1 167.5 170 6 171.7 193.6 193 4 195 4 200 0 205.4 208.9 209 2 207.0 202.9 199 9 198 4 198.2 209.1 213 0 220 6 234 7 247.7 265.0 280 0 292.0 3010 303 8 306 9 313.9 231.3 233.9 236.3 238 2 240.1 242.0 244.0 245.7 247.1 249.1 250.8 252.6 191.4 192.5 193.4 194 8 196.4 297.3 198 5 200.5 201.7 203.7 205 5 207.5 190.0 230.7 190.7 232.6 1915 233.9 192 6 235.1 193.3 236.3 194.0 237.7 197 1 239.9 200.8 241.8 205.2 243.7 209.1 245.9 216.5 248.0 223.0 250.7 233 5 239 8 244.0 247 0 249 2 249.7 250.5 251.6 253 2 254 5 257.4 173 9 175 3 175.0 177.0 178 9 178.5 179.2 181.1 181.7 1819 184.3 197 2 195 3 195.2 196.7 199 3 200.7 203.4 206.4 214 6 222 7 230.8 334 6 357 6 370.9 374 7 375 4 376.2 376.7 375.9 373 0 370 5 370.5 255.1 209.8 258.2 212.6 260.9 . 216.5 264.3 223.3 266.1 224.5 267.3 225.0 269.0 224.5 271.1 224.7 273.8 226.0 276.0 226.5 278.4 228.8 89.2" 75.9 718 69.1 77 4 80.2 89.5 0) iod.6 226.8 229 5 232.1 235.9 239.5 242.2 250.5 261.5 271.0 273.6 277.0 253.9 257.9 260.2 262.0 263.4 264.7 266.6 268.4 270.6 272.8 274.5 148.8 248.3 150.1 250.4 150.7 251.8 151.6 253 1 152.4 254.4 153.3 255.9 154.1 258.5 155.0 260.6 155.8 262.8 156.6 265.3 157.8 267.6 159.2 270.7 160.5 162.1 163.5 164.9 166.4 167.9 169.1 170.2 171.3 172.5 173.8 274.4 279 0 281.5 283.4 284.7 285.9 288.0 289.8 292.3 294.8 296.6 1 Not available. Note.—Data beginning 1978 are for all urban consumers; earlier data are for urban wage earners and clerical workers. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of'Labor Statistics. 291 TABLE B-52.—Consumer price indexes by commodity and service groups, 1939-80 [1967=100] Services Commodities Special indexes Commodities less food Year or month All items All commodities Food All Alt Non- services Durable durable Rent Services less rent All items less food All itofnc uerns All items less Enerless food gy 1 energy and energy 1939 41.6 40.2 34.6 47.7 48.5 44.3 43.5 56.0 38.1 47.2 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 42.0 44.1 48.8 518 52.7 53.9 58.5 66.9 72.1 71.4 40.6 43.3 49.6 54.0 54.7 56.3 62.4 75.0 80.4 78.3 35.2 38.4 45.1 50.3 49.6 50.7 58.1 70.6 76.6 73.5 48.0 50.4 56.0 58.4 61.6 64.1 68.1 76.8 82.7 81.5 48.1 51.4 58.4 60.3 65.9 70.9 •74.1 80.3 86.2 87.4 44.7 46.7 51.6 53.8 56.6 58.6 62.9 72.2 77.8 76.3 43.6 44.2 45.6 46.4 47.5 48.2 49.1 51.1 54.3 56.9 56.2 57.2 58.5 58.5 58.6 58.8 59.2 61.1 65.1 68.0 38.1 38.6 40.3 42.1 44.2 45.1 46.7 49.0 51.9 54.5 47.3 48.7 52.1 53.6 55.7 56.9 59.4 64.9 69.6 70.3 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 721 77.8 79 5 80.1 80.5 80.2 81.4 84.3 86.6 87.3 788 85.9 87 0 86.7 85.9 85.1 85.9 88.6 90.6 90.7 74 5 82.8 84 3 83.0 82.8 81.6 82.2 84.9 88.5 87.1 81.4 87.5 88 3 88!5 87,5 86.9 87.8 90.5 91.5 92.7 88.4 95.1 96 4 95.7 93.3 91.5 91.5 94.4 95.9 97.3 76 2 82.0 82 4 83.1 83.5 83.5 85.3 87.6 88.2 89.3 58.7 61.8 64.5 67.3 69.5 70.9 72.7 75.6 78.5 80.8 704 73.2 76 2 80.3 83.2 84.3 85.9 87.5 89.1 90.4 56 0 59.3 62 2 64.8 66.7 68.2 70.1 73.3 76.4 79.0 71.1 75.7 77.5 79.0 79.5 79.7 81.1 ....._.„.. 83.8 "8X3" 85.7 86.3 85.2 87.3 87.0 87.0 88.7 89.6 90.6 917 92.9 94.5 97.2 100.0 104.2 109.8 91.5 92.0 92.8 93.6 ,94,6 / 95.7 98.2 100.0 103.7 108.4 88.0 89.1 89.9 912 92.4 94.4 99.1 100.0 103.6 108.9 93.1 93.4 94.1 94.8 95.6 96.2 97.5 100;0 103.7 108.1 96.7 96.6 97.6 97.9 98.8 98.4 98.5 100.0 103.1 107.0 90.7 91.2 91.8 92 7 93.5 94.8 97.0 100.0 104.1 108.8 83.5 85.2 86.8 88.5 90.2 92.2 95.8 100.0 105.2 112.5 91.7 92.9 94.0 95.0 95.9 96.9 98.2 100.0 102.4 105.7 81.9 83.9 85.5 87.3 89.2 91.5 95.3 100.0 105.7 113.8 88.8 89.7 90.8 92.0 93.2 94.5 96.7 100.0 104.4 110.1 88.3 88.3 94.2 89.3 89.3 94.4 90.4 90.5 94.7 91.6 916 95.0 92.9 93.0 94.6 94.3 94.3 96.3 97.3 96.6 97.8 100.0 1000 100.0 104.4 104.6 101.5 110.3 110.7 104.2 116.3 121.3 125.3 133.1 147.7 161.2 170.5 181.5 195 4 217.4 113.5 117.4 120.9 129.9 145.5 158.4 165.2 174.7 1871 208.4 114.9 118.4 123.5 141.4 161.7 175.4 180.8 192.2 2114 234.5 112.5 116.8 119.4 123.5 136.6 149.1 156.6 165.1 174 7 195.1 111.8 116.5 118.9 121.9 130.6 145.5 154.3 163.2 173 9 191.1 113.1 117.0 119.8 124.8 140.9 151.7 158.3 166.5 174 3 198.7 121:6 128.4 133.3 139.1 152.1 166.6 180.4 194.3 210 9 234^2 110.1 115.2 119.2 124.3 130.6 137.3 144.7 153.5 164 0 176.0 123.7 130.8 135.9 141.8 156.0 171.9 186.8 201.6 219 4 244.9 116.7 122.1 125.8 130.7 143.7 157.1 167.5 178.4 1912 2133 117.0 122.0 126.1 133.8 146.9 160.2 169.2 179.8 193 8 213]l 117.6 123.1 126.9 131.3 1412 155.3 165.5 175.8 188 7 2073 107.0 111.2 114.3 123.5 159.7 176.6 189.3 207.3 220.4 2753 iS&' "*:::::: June 204 7 207.1 209.1 211.5 214.1 216.6 195.8 198.3 200.5 203.3 205.8 208.4 223.9 228.2 230.4 232.3 234.3 235.4 181.9 183.7 185.9 188.9 191.6 194.7 182.0 183.6 184.9 187.2 189.2 191.1 1803 182.2 185.7 189.6 193.2 197.6 221.1 223.3 225.1 227.0 229.5 232.1 170.3 171.0 171.3 172.0 173.8 174.7 230 4 232.9 235.0 237.1 239.8 242.6 199.8201.8 203.8 206.3 208.9 211.8 202.9 205.2 206.9 208.8 210.7 212.2 197.0 198.8 200.4 202.3 204.1 205.8 231.5 235.0 241.2 250.2 260.8 275.4 July Aug Sept. .. Oct Nov Dec . 218.9 2211 223.4 225 4 227.5 229.9 210.5 212 2 214.1 215 6 217.4 219.4 236.9 236 3 237.1 238 2 239.1 241.7 197.0 199 5 201.8 203 4 2054 207.2 192.6 193 6 194.5 196 0 198.4 199.8 201.1 205 4 209.6 2113 2123 215.2 234.7 237 6 240J 243 6 246.2 249.3 175.9 177 5 179.0 181 4 182.1 182.9 245.6 248 8 252il 255 1 258.2 261.6 213.8 215 4 2173 219 2 224*. 1 221.4 266.4 223.6 207.3 209 4 211.5 213 6 216.1 218.1 287.1 296 3 3043 307 5 307* 313.7 233.2 236.4 239.8 242.5 244.9 247.6 222.4 225.2 228.0 229.9 231.4 232.8 243.8 244.9 247.3 249.1 250.4 252.0 210.4 213.8 216.7 218.6 220.2 221.4 201.3 202.1 203.0 204.9 207.1 208.6 220.5 227.3 232.6 234.6 235.5 236.3 253.1 256.8 261.3 265.3 269.2 274.2 184.1 185.6 186.6 187.0 188.9 191.1 266.1 270.2 275.4 280.0 284.4 290.0 229.9 233.5 237.1 239.9 242.6 245.5 225.9 228.0 230.8 233.4 235.7 238.3 220.6 222.8 225.7 228.5 231.0 233.7 327.9 344.6 355.0 358.8 363.2 367.8 247.8 249.4 251.7 253.9 256.2 234.1 236.7 239.0 240.7 242.5 254.8 258.7 261.1 262.4 264.5 222.2 224.2 226.6 228.3 230.0 209.8 212.4 215.3 218.1 220.6 236.6 237.8 239.3 239.6 240.5 272.4 272.5 274.8 277.9 280.9 192.1 193.2 195.1 197.1 198.3 287.6 287.4 289.8 293.2 296.4 245.1 246.3 248.6 250.9 253.2 238.3 240.0 242.5 245.1 247.7 233.1 234.3 236.9 239.7 242.4 370.4 370.7 370.1 368.0 366.1 1960 1961 1962.... 1963 1964.... 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 . . 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975.... 1976.... 1977 1978 1979 1979: Jan Feb Mar. 1980. Jan Feb Mar Apr . May June July Aug Sept Oct Nov .... ## 214.2 216 9 2193 2218 "g'ti.'i 90.3 91.8 1 Fuel oil, coal, and bottled gas; gas (piped) and electricity; and gasoline, motor oil, coolant, etc. Note.—Data beginning 1978 are for all urban consumers; earlier data are for urban wage earners and clerical workers. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 292 TABLE B-53.—Changes in consumer price indexes major groups, 1948-80 [Percent change] Year or month Services Commodities All items Dec. to Dec.2 Year to year 2.7 -1.8 Total Commodities less food Food Dec. to Dec.2 Energy » Year to year Dec. to Dec. 2 Year to year Dec. to Dec.2 Year to year Dec. to Dec.2 Year to year Dec. to Dec.2 Year to year 7.8 -1.0 1.7 -4.1 7.2 -2.6 -0.8 -3.7 8.5 -4.0 5.3 -4.8 77 -1.5 6.1 3.6 6.3 4.8 .... 5.8 5.9 .9 .6 -.5 1.0 7.9 2.2 .8 .5 7.7 5.9 —7 -.S -I A .6 9.0 1.3 -.3 -.9 9.6 7.4 -1.1 -1.3 -1.6 1.4 11.1 1.8 -1.5 -.2 5.7 4.6 -.5 2 -1.4 -.1 7.5 .9 .2 -1.1 3.6 5.2 4.6 4.2 1.9 3.2 5.3 4.4 4.3 .... 3.3 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 .4 2.9 3.0 1.8 1.5 -.4 1.5 3.6 2.7 .8 -.4 2.6 2.6 1.3 .6 -.9 .9 3.1 2.3 .1 — 9 -1.4 11 .7 2.8 3.3. 2.2 4.2 -.8 - 1 . 6 0 2.5 2.2 .8 1.5 -7 1.0 3.1 1.1 1.3 2.3 3.1 4.5 27 3.7 2.0 2.5 4.0 3.8 " - 0 7 2.9 4.3 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1.5 .7 1.2 1.6 1.2 1.6 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.1 0 1.0 1.4 .8 .9 .5 .9 .9 1.1 3.1 -.9 1.5 1.9 1.4 1.0 1.3 .9 1.4 1.3 -.3 .6 .7 1.2 .4 .4 .3 .7 7 .8 2.7 1.9 1.7 2.3 1.8 3.3 2.0 1.9 2.0 1.9 1.5 -1.1 2.1 -.8 -.2 -.4!a 1.9 3.4 3.0 4.7 6.1 1.7 2.9 2.9 4.2 5.4 1.6 2.5 2.5 3.8 5.5 1.2 2.6 1.8 3.7 4.5 3.4 3.9 1.2 4.3 7.2 2.2 5.0 .9 3.6 5.1 .7 1.9 3.1 3.7 4.5 .6 1.4 2.6 37 4.2 2.6 4.9 4.0 6.1 7.4 2.2 3.9 4.4 5.2 6.9 2.0 1.8 1.4 17 3.1 1.8 1.6 2.2 1.5 27 5.5 3.4 3.4 8.8 12.2 5.9 4.3 3.3 6.2 11.0 4.0 2.9 3.4 10.4 12.7 4.7 34 3.0 7.4 12.0 2.2 4.3 4.7 20.1 12.2 5.5 3.0 4.3 14.5 14.4 4.8 2.3 2.5 5.0 13.2 4.1 3.8 2.2 3.4 10.6 8.2 4.1 3.6 6.2 11.3 8.1 5.6 3.8 4.4 9.3 4.5 3.1 2.8 16.8 21.6 27 3.9 2.8 8.0 29.3 7.0 4.8 6.8 9.0 13.3 91 5.8 6.5 7.7 11.3 6.3 3.3 6.1 8.9 13.0 8.9 4.3 5.8 7.1 11.4 6.5 .6 8.0 11.8 10.2 8.5 3.1 6.3 10.0 10.9 6.2 5.1 4.9 7.7 14.3 9.2 5.0 5.4 5.8 117 8.1 7.3 7.9 9.3 13.7 9.5 8.3 77 8.5 11.0 11.6 6.9 7.2 8.0 37.4 10.6 7.2 9.5 6.3 25.2 1948 1949.. . . 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 .. . . ... 1965 1966 1967 .. . . 1968 1969 ... . 1970... 1971 .... 1972 1973 1974 .. . 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 02 17 2.6 .2 Change from preceding month SeaSeaSeaSeaSeaSeaUnad- sonally Unad- sonally Unad- sonally Unad- sonally Unad- sonally Unad- sonally justed ad* justed ad- justed adjusted adjusted ad- justed adjusted justed justed justed justed justed 1979: Jan Feb Mar f/ay. June Julv Aug Sept' Oct Nov Dec ' . . 1980: Jan Feb Mar Aor May June Aug. Sept .. ocf...:..... Nov 0.8 1.1 .8 .9 1.2 1.0 1.4 1.5 2.6 37 4.2 5.6 1.6 1.5 27 3.5 37 4.6 1.3 13 L3 .8 1.1 1.1 0.9 1.0 .8 .8 1.1 1.1 11 12 1.3 1.2 1.1 1.3 1.1 11 1.2 1.2 1.1 1.4 4.2 3.2 2.7 1.1 .1 1.9, 3.8 33 1.5 1.6 1.4 9 7 .5 2.0 17 1.3 .5 .4 .3 1.5 1.5 1.8 1.5 15 1.9 1.4 1.5 1.9 1.5 1.6 1.8 4.5 5.1 3.0 1.1 1.2 1.3 4.6 5.1 3.0 .9 .8 .3 .4 .9 11 .8 •7 .5 .9 11 ,S .9 _7 .0 8 1.1 1.1 -.8 -.1 7 1.2 1.0 7 .1 -2 2 -!s .3 0.9 1.2 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.2 0.9 1.1 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 0.8 1.3 1.1 1.4 1.2 1.3 1.0 1.2 1.1 1.0 .9 1.0 2.1 1.9 1.0 .8 .9 .5 1.4 1.4 1.0 .6 .6 .3 0.3 1.0 1.2 1.6 1.4 1.6 0.8 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.1 1.4 11 10 1.0 .9 .9 1.1 1.1 10 1.2 10 1.0 1.2 10 3 .9 .7 .8 .9 1.1 9 1.2 .8 1.0 1.1 .6 3 .4 1.1 .5 1 1.0 .8 L4 1.2 13 1.2 .8 1.0 .9 1.4 1.4 1.4 1.1 1.0 1.1 1.4 1.4 1.4 9 9 1.0 1.4 1.3 1.2 .8 7 .6 1.4 1.2 1.2 .5 .3 .9 .5 1.0 7 .5 0 -.0 1.0 .5 .3 .5 0 .6 1.1 1.0 .6 1.2 1.2 .8 1.0 1.1 1.5 .9 1.0 1.8 16 .8 1.1 .1 .6 9 .9 .9 10 1.0 1.0 7 1 c i\ 1.3 .9 2.3 .3 Fuel oil, coal, and bottled gas; gas (piped) and electricity; and gasoline, motor oil, coolant, etc. 2 Changes from December to December are based on unadjusted indexes. Note.—Data beginning 1978 are for all urban consumers; earlier data are for urban wage earners and clerical workers. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 293 TABLE B-54.—Changes in special consumer price indexes, 1958-80 [Percent change] Att items less food All items Year or month Dec. to Dec. 2 Year to Year Dec. to Dec. 2 Year to Year All items less energy Dec. to Dec* Year to Year At) items less food and energy Dec. to Dec. 2 Year to Year All items less home purchase and finance1 Dec. to Dec* Year to Year 1958 1959 1.8 1.5 2.7 .8 1.6 2.3 2.3 1.9 1.9 1.4 2.9 .8 1.8 2.2 2.3 2.1 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1.5 1*2 1.6 12 1.6 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.0 Ll 1.2 1.6 1.0 1.7 1.0 1.2 1.3 1.3 1.4 .8 1.2 1.8 1.3 1.5 Ll 1.2 1.3 1.4 .8 1.5 1.1 1.8 1.2 1.5 1.1 13 1.2 1.5 1965 1966 . 1967 .. 1968. . 1969 . 1.9 3.4 30 47 6.1 1.7 2.9 2.9 4.2 5.4 1.6 3.3 3.5 4.9 5.7 1.4 2.3 3.4 4.4 5.5 1.9 3.5 3.1 4.9 6.4 1.5 3.2 2.8 4.4 5.7 1.5 3.3 3.9 5.1 6.1 1.4 2.4 3.5 4.6 5.8 5^5 4.1 47 5.5 34 3.4 8.8 12.2 5.9 4.3 3.3 6.2 11.0 6.5 3.1 3.0 5.6 12.2 6.0 4.6 3.0 3.9 9.9 5.6 3.3 3.5 8.3 11.5 6.1 4.3 3.4 6.1 9.8 6.6 3.1 3.0 4.7 11.3 6.2 4.7 3.1 3.5 8.3 4.7 3.7 3.3 9.0 12.2 5.1 4.5 3.1 6.6 1L1 70 4.8 6.8 9.0 13.3 9.1 5.8 6.5 7.7 11.3 7.1 6.2 6.3 8.5 14.0 9.3 6.6 6.5 7.2 11.4 6.7 4.6 6.8 9.2 11.1 9.1 5.6 6.3 7.8 10.0 6.7 6.1 6.4 8.5 11.3 9.2 6.6 6.2 7.3 9.7 6.7 5.1 6.3 8.1 11.3 8.8 5.8 6.5 6.9 10.0 1970 . 1971 . 1972 1973 1974 . . . . 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 Change from preceding month Unadjusted Seasonally adjusted 0.9 12 10 1.1 1.2 1.2 1979: Jan Feb Mar ft. :.•••• • • June July Aug.. Sept.. Oct Nov Dec 1980: Jan Feb Mar Apr. fay June July Aug Sept Oct . . Nov Unadjusted Seasonally adjusted Unadjusted Seasonally adjusted Unadjusted Seasonally adjusted Unadjusted Seasonally adjusted 0.9 1.1 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 0.6 1.0 1.0 1.2 1.3 1.4 0.8 1.1 1.0 1.1 Ll 1.2 0.8 Ll .8 .9 .9 0.9 .9 .8 .7 .8 .6 0.5 .9 .8 .9 .9 .8 0.7 1.0 .8 .8 .8 .8 0.9 1.0 .9 1.1 1.2 1.1 1.0 8 .9 .9 1.0 .9 11 10 1.0 .9 .9 1.1 1.1 1.0 1.2 1.0 1.0 1.2 1.1 1.3 1.2 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.2 1.2 1.2 1.1 Ll 1.2 .8 .7 '.9 1.0 1.0 .8 .8 .9 .9 1.0 1.2 .7 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.2 .9 .8 1.0 .9 1.0 Ll 1.2 .9 .8 .8 .6 .6 .9 .9 .9 .9 .8 .8 1.0 1.4 14 14 11 1.0 1.1 1.4 1.4 1.4 .9 .9 1.0 1.5 1.6 1.5 1.2 1.1 1.2 1.8 1.6 1.5 Ll 1.0 Ll 1.0 .9 1.2 Ll 1.0 Ll 1.1 .7 1.2 1.0 .9 1.0 Ll 1.0 1.3 1.2 Ll 1.2 1.3 Ll 1.2 Ll 1.0 Ll 1.2 1.4 1.3 .9 1.3 1.2 1.3 -.2 .5 .9 .9 .9 -.2 A .9 1.0 .9 0 0 .7 1.0 1.1 Ll .8 1.0 1.2 Ll -.3 .5 Ll 1.2 1.1 '.$ 1.2 1.1 .1 .6 9 9 .9 0 LO 1.0 '.5 .6 .7 .8 1.0 .5 .6 1.0 1.1 .6 .9 'All items less home purchase and financing, taxes, and insurance. Changes from December to December are Based on unadjusted indexes. Note.—Data beginning 1978 are for all urban consumers; earlier data are for urban wage earners and clerical workers. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2 294 TABLE B-55.—Producer price indexes by stage of processing, 1947-80 [1967=100] Finished goods Consumer foods Year or month Total finished goods Finished goods excluding consumer foods Total Crude Total Total 1947 . 1948 . 1949. 1950 . 1951 . 1952. 1953.. 1954. 1955.. 1956... 1957 1958 1959 1960. 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 . . 1967 .. 1968. 1969. 1970 . 1971 ... 1972 .. 1973... 1974 1975. 1976 1977 . 1978 1979 1980 ».. 1979: Jan. Feb... Mar. Capital equipment Total finished consumer goods Consumer goods Proc- Durable 74.0 79.9 77.6 82.8 90.4 83.1 99.4 107.1 101.3 80.2 87.6 801 79.0 84.0 82.2 74.6 79.7 81.8 80.7 85.8 82.3 55.4 60.4 63.4 80.5 86.5 82.5 79.0 86.5 86.0 85.1 85.3 84.7 95.2 94.3 89.4 88.7 92.2 105.9 112.8 105.2 94.7 83.4 93.2 91.3 86.7 87.6 83.5 89.5 88.3 89.1 89.4 82.7 88.2 88.9 89.6 90.3 83.6 90.0 87.8 88.6 88.9 64.9 71.2 72.4 73.6 74.5 83.9 91.8 90.7 89.2 89.1 85.5 87.9 91.1 93.2 93.0 86.5 86.3 89.3 94.5 90.1 98.8 98.7 97.4 103.5 94.3 84.4 84.3 87.9 93.1 89.5 90.1 92.3 94.6 94.7 95.9 91.2 94.3 97.1 98.4 99.6 89.4 91.1 93.2 92.6 94.0 76.7 82.4 87.5 89.8 91.5 88.5 89.8 92.4 94.4 93.6 93.7 93.7 94.0 93.7 94.1 92.1 91.7 92.5 91.4 91.9 100.6 96.1 97.0 95.5 98.2 90.7 ,90.9 91.7 90.7 90.8 96.3 96.2 96.0 96.0 95.9 99.2 98.8 98.3 97.8 98.2 94.7 94.7 94.8 95.1 94.8 91.7 91.8 92.2 92.4 93.3 94.5 94.3 94.6 94.1 94.3 95J 98.8 100-0 102.8 106.6 95.4 101.6 100.0 103.6 110.0 98.6 104.8 100.0 107.5 116.0 94.9 101.0 100.0 103.0 108.9 100.0 102.6 105.4 96.6 98.1 100.0 102.1 104.6 97.9 98.5 100.0 102.2 104.0 95.9 97.8 100.0 102.2 105.0 94.4 96.8 100.0 103.5 106.9 96.1 99.4 100.0 102.7 106.6 110.3 113.7 117.2 127.9 147.5 113.5 115.3 121.7 146.4 166.9 116.3 115.8 121.2 160.7 180.8 113.1 115.1 121.7 143.9 164.6 109.1 113.1 115.4 120.1 139.3 107.7 111.4 113.5 118.6 138.6 106.9 110.8 113.3 115.4 125.9 108.3 111.7 113.6 120.5 146.8 112.0 116.6 119.5 123.5 141.0 109.9 112.9 116.6 129.2 149.3 163.4 170.3 180.6 194.6 216.1 181.0 180.2 189.2 206.7 226.3 181.2 194.8 201.8 215.5 231.4 181.3 177.4 186.4 204.1 223.8 156.2 165.5 176.2 188.9 210.8 153.1 161.8 172.1 183.7 208.2 138.2 144.4 152.2 165.8 181.9 163.0 173.3 185.4 195.4 225.9 162.5 173.2 184.5 199.1 216.7 163.6 169.0 178.9 192.6 215.7 244.7 238.0 234.1 236.1 244.4 248.5 204.9 278.2 239.5 246.7 205.4 207.7 209.1 211.4 212.7 213.7 220.2 225.1 226.3 227.8 226.6 223.6 236.7 257.2 244.6 241.8 226.7 227.1 216.9 220.5 222.8 224.6 224.4 221.3 198.8 200.2 201.7 204.2 206.3 208.5 193.4 194.9 196.7 199.3 202.1 205.2 175.2 176.2 176.8 178.4 179.5 180.4 205.4 207.2 209.8 213.1 217.1 221.7 209.3 210.8 211.7 214.0 215.1 215.8 203.7 206.3 207.9 210.2 211.6 212.7 216.2 217.3 220.7 224.2 226.3 228.1 224.9 223.5 228.1 226.7 230.5 232.1 224.9 231.7 214.0 215.5 228.1 227.9 222.8 220.7 227.0 225.5 228.6 230.3 211.4 213.2 216.2 221.3 222.8 224.6 208.9 212.3 216.3 221.4 223.1 225.3 181.6 181.1 182.9 189.0 190.0 191.8 227.1 233.4 239.0 243.3 245.5 247.9 217.2 216.5 217.8 222.8 223.9 225.3 215.6 217.5 221.7 224.7 227.1 229.1 June.. 232.4 235.7 238.5 240.5 241.6 243.0 231.4 231.6 233.1 228.9 230.0 231.0 226.0 220.1 230.9 222.3 226.1 223.6 229.7 230.4 231.1 227.2 228.1 229.4 230.5 234.6 237.8 241.7 242.8 244.3 232.3 238.3 242.3 246.2 247.6 249.5 199.1 202.1 200.3 201.2 201.0 203.5 254.7 262.7 270.9 276.9 279.6 281.0 229.3 230.5 232.2 236.2 236.6 237.7 233.5 237.6 240.8 242.1 243.4 245.0 July Aug Sept Oct Nov . . Dec... 247.1 249.1 248.9 252.2 253.2 254.7 239.7 244.9 245.8 245.9 246.9 247.2 233.8 240.8 253.2 231.3 248.2 252.6 238.0 243.0 242.9 244.8 244.5 244.5 246.9 248.0 247.4 251.7 252.7 254.5 251.9 252.8 252.3 255.0 255.9 257.6 206.6 207.0 204.9 211.0 210.6 211.7 283.0 284.2 284.7 284.9 287.0 289.1 240.5 241.8 241.3 248.2 249.1 251.1 249.6 251.9 251.8 253.6 254.7 255.9 fe. JuneJuly.... Aug... Sept.. Oct... Nov.. Dec... 1980: » Jan.... Feb.... Mar.. See next page for continuation of table. 295 TABLE B-55.—Producer price indexes by stage ofprocessing, 1947-80—Continued [1967=100] Crude materials for further processing Intermediate materials, supplies, and components Year or month Total Foods and feeds9 Processed Materials and components Other fitflle For manufacturing For construction and lubricants tainers Supplies Total Foodstuffs and feedstuffs Other Total Fuel Other 72.4 78.3 75.2 70.0 76.1 74.2 72.1 77.8 74.5 66.0 73.1 73.2 85.5 96.9 88.2 66.8 69.8 70.1 77.5 81.0 76.3 101.2 110.9 96.0 111.7 120.8 100.3 66.6 787 78.3 90.6 100.7 91.6 786 88.1 85 5 86.0 86.5 77.7 87.0 84 3 85.3 857 78.1 88.5 84.8 86.2 86.3 77.0 84.3 83.7 85.1 85.5 89.9 93.9 92.8 93.4 93.3 72.0 84.5 79.9 80.0 81.5 78.9 88.8 88.8 84.3 86.3 104.6 120.1 110.3 101.9 101.0 107.6 124.5 117.2 104.9 104.9 77.9 79.4 79.9 82.7 79.0 1047 1207 104.6 1O0.1 98.2 881 92.0 94.1 943 95.6 88.3 92.6 95.0 94.8 96.4 88.4 92.6 94.8 95.2 96.5 88.9 93.5 94.0 94.0 96.6 93.3 96.2 101.9 96.0 95.6 82.6 88.6 92.5 94.7 94.2 84.8 87.1 88.0 90.0 91.2 97.1 97.6 99.8 102.0 99.4 95.1 93.1 97.2 103.0 96.2 78.8 84.4 89.2 90.3 91.9 103.8 107.6 106.2 102.2 105.8 95.6 95.0 94 9 95.2 95.5 96.8 95.5 95.3 95.0 95.6 96.5 95.3 94.7 94.9 95,9 95.9 94.6 94.2 94.5 95.4 98.2 99.4 99.0 98.1 96.0 95.5 94.7 95.9 94.7 94.0 90.7 91.8 93.8 95.2 94.3 97.0 96.5 97.5 95.4 94.5 95.1 93.8 95.7 92.9 90.8 92.8 92.6 92.1 93.2 92.8 101.4 102.5 102.0 1007 102,4 96.8 99.2 100.0 102 3 105.8 97.4 99.3 100.0 1022 105.8 96.2 98.8 100.0 105 0 110.8 97.4 99.2 100.0 97 6 98.5 95.8 98.4 100.0 1024 106.3 95.2 99.4 100.0 1010 102.8 99.3 105.7 100.0 1016 108.4 97.1 105.9 100.0 1013 109.3 ""ioo.6" 102.7 96.9 98.9 100.0 102 5 106.1 102 2 106.8 93.5 96.3 100.0 1023 106.6 104.5 106.7 100.0 1021 106.9 109.9 114.1 118.7 131.6 162.9 109.1 111.7 118.5 168.4 200.2 109.9 114.3 118.9 128.1 159.5 110.0 112.8 117.0 127.7 162.2 112.6 119.7 126.2 136.7 161.6 105.0 115.2 118.9 131.5 199.1 111.4 116.6 121.9 129.2 152.2 108.0 111.0 115.6 140.6 154.5 112.3 115.1 127.6 174.0 196.1 112.0 114.2 127.5 180.0 189.4 112.7 117.0 128.0 162.5 208.9 122.6 139.0 1487 164.5 219.4 109.8 1107 121.9 161.5 205.4 180.0 189.3 201.7 215.5 242.8 195.3 186.6 191.0 201.0 223.2 178.6 189.5 202.4 216.4 244.0 178.7 185.6 195.5 208.3 234.1 176.4 188.0 202.9 224.4 246.9 233.0 250.9 283.8 296.4 360.9 171.4 181.4 193.1 212.5 235.3 168.1 179.2 188.0 196.9 217.6 196.9 205.1 214.3 240.1 282.2 191.8 190.1 190.9 215.3 247.2 206.9 233.6 258.4 2867 348.3 271.5 314.7 400.5 4637 568.2 188.3 210.2 217.3 235:4 284.5 279.6 252.3 281.3 265.4 268.2 4941 2634 2461 3161 258 9 424 5 710.2 3416 225.7 . 228.5 231.5 235.8 " " 238.2 240.3 214.3 218.2 218.9 220.7 219.3 223.0 226.5 229.1 232.3 236.7 239.3 241.3 218.6 221.6 224.5 229.0 230.9 232.1 236.1 239.0 241.3 244.5 245.2 245.6 302.0 304.8 312.9 323.9 336.8 349.5 223.9 224.3 229.3 231.8 234.5 234.9 207.4 209.6 211.1 212.8 213J 216.1 260.2 270.4 276.6 279.9 282.3 283.0 233.0 243.7 247.4 251.5 251.9 248.2 311.5 320.7 331.6 333.3 339.6 348.7 504,3 513.9 525.2 529.2 556.8 563.1 255.6 2647 275.5 276.5 276.6 286.6 July.. . . 244.6 Aug 247.5 Sept.... 251.0 Oct 255.0 Nov . . . 256.3 Dec. .. 258.7 231.0 223.1 226.6 226.0 226.9 229.8 245.4 249.0 252.5 256.8 258.1 260.5 236.0 238.0 240.7 244.3 245.5 247.8 247.4 249.2 252.5 254.7 254.0 253.7 364.8 384.6 399.4 410.6 416.5 424.6 235.4 237.6 237.9 242.6 243,8 247.1 219.6 219.6 221.2 224.9 226.4 229.2 287.1 281.7 288.3 289.5 290.8 296.2 254.1 2437 248.7 247.5 246.4 249.7 349.3 353.6 363.1 368.9 374.9 384.2 5707 586.2 604.0 612,9 617.4 634.5 285.2 286.1 293.3 298.1 304.6 311.6 265.9 271.6 273.7 275.1 276.4 278.2 224.8 237.5 232.4 227.3 239.7 242.1 268.4 273.7 276.2 278.0 278.6 280.5 255.5 259.8 259.5 260.3 262.2 264.1 257.7 262.1 265.5 265.6 265.7 267.1 444.0 464.0 481.0 486.9 488.8 493.0 250.9 251.6 253.8 262.6 263.8 265.5 232.5 239.0 240.8 241.7 241.8 243.2 296.8 308.4 303.5 297.0 300.7 299.6 243.0 252.6 245.9 235.5 242.9 242.5 398.9 414.3 412.7 413.9 410.5 407.9 636.3 664.8 664.1 678.9 690.3 695.6 330.1 341.7 339.8 337.0 329.3 324.4 281.0 283.8 284.1 286.3 288.0 291.2 251.0 264.4 267.1 282.2 288.7 269.9 282.9 285.0 285.2 286.6 288.0 292.6 265.4 268.6 268.4 271.8 273.1 275.5, 269.8 271.7 271.5 272.1 273.9 276.2 505.2 508.2 510.2 507.1 510.8 529.7 266.6 266.8 266.8 270.0 269.8 272.0 247.2 249.6 251.7 253.7 256.3 256.0 316.6 329.1 331.8 336,0 337.6 335.6 263.5 2767 276.7 279.1 277.3 271.3 417.1 424.4 436.3 444.1 452.0 457.8 710.5 725.4 740.5 756.1 776.1 783.3 331.9 342.2 348.1 353.5 357.9 363.3 1947.. . 1948 1949 1950 . 1951 . 1952 1953 1954 ... . 1955 1956 1957,. 1958 1959 1960 1961,. . 1962,. . 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969... . ; ;*. 1970 1971. 1972 1973,. . 1974.. . 1975. 1976 1977. 1978 1979.. . . 1980 1 1979: Jan . Feb . . Mar May. June 1980:l Jan Feb Mai . . . ... JR. •: . June July . . Aug . Sept Oct . . Nov . Dec .. 994 1 Data have been revised through August 1980 to reflect the availability of late reports and corrections by respondents. All data are subject to revision 4 months after original publication. 2 Intermediate materials for food manufacturing and feeds. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 296 TABLE B-56—Producer price indexes by stage of processing, special groups, 1974-80 [1967=100] Intermediate materials, supplies, and components Finished goods Crude materials for further processing Excluding food and energy Consumer Year or month Total Food Energy Capi- Total tal equip- ment goods FoodStuffs Foods Total and Energy Other Total feeds1 exclud- and Energy Other feedstuffs ing food and dHU energy 1974 147.5 166.9 215.2 133.3 141.0 129.1 162.9 200.2 188.7 156.7 196.1 1975 1976... 1977 1978 1979 163.4 170.3 180.6 194.6 216.1 181.0 180.2 189.2 206.7 226.3 252.4 274.5 305.0 318.1 438.1 148.5 156.7 166.1 178.6 194.4 162.5 173.2 184.5 199.1 216.7 141.0 148.0 156.1 167.4 182.4 180.0 189.3 201.7 215.5 242.8 195.3 186.6 191.0 201.0 223.2 220.8 237.3 268.3 281.2 344.6 174.7 184.9 196.0 210.1 234.1 196.9 191.8 205.1 190.1 214.3 190.9 240.1 215.3 282.2 247.2 266.9 291.0 344.9 390.7 479.4 19802 244.7 238.0 666.9 216.1 239.5 203.6 279.6 252.3 475.7 262.0 316.1 258.9 631.5 270.2 205.4 207.7 209.1 211.4 212.7 213.7 220.2 225.1 226.3 227.8 226.6 223.6 340.8 346.1 356.7 372.1 392.4 415.7 187.5 188.8 189.7 191.4 192.4 193.3 209.3 210.8 211.7 214.0 215.1 215.8 175.8 176.9 177.8 179.1 180.2 181.2 225.7 228.5 231.5 235.8 238.2 240.3 214.3 218.2 218.9 220.7 219.3 223.0 287.6 290.2 297.7 308.3 320.7 333.7 220.5 223.2 225.9 229.7 231.4 232.3 260.2 270.4 276.6 279.9 282.3 283.0 233.0 243.7 247.4 251.5 251.9 248.2 419.4 427.0 433.7 436.7 455.3 467.8 234.6 245.5 260.2 260.9 257.3 264.0 216.2 217.3 220.7 224.2 226.3 228.1 224.9 223.5 228.1 226.7 230.5 232.1 445.8 474.1 504.9 525.8 536.0 546.8 194.5 194.8 196.1 200.2 201.1 202.5 217.2 216.5 217.8 222.8 223.9 225.3 182.3 183.2 184.6 188.1 188.9 190.2 244.6 247.5 251.0 255.0 256.3 258.7 231.0 223.1 226.6 226.0 226.9 229.8 348.1 366.9 382.2 392.6 399.7 407.6 235.3 237.4 239.7 243.4 244.1 246.0 287.1 281.7 288.3 289.5 290.8 296.2 254.1 243.7 248.7 247.5 246.4 249.7 478.1 492.9 518.3 529.5 538.0 556.1 256.6 252.3 249.2 250.6 254.9 257.3 232.4 235.7 238.5 240.5 241.6 243.0 231.4 231.6 233.1 228.9 230.0 231.0 568.3 607.3 649.8 674.8 684.1 685.0 207.3 209.4 210.2 212.8 213.4 215.0 229.3 230.5 232.2 236.2 236.6 237.7 195.7 198.3 198.6 200.4 201.0 203.0 265.9 271.6 273.7 275.1 276.4 278.2 224.8 237.5 232.4 227.3 239.7 242.1 425.9 445.9 462.0 468.8 471.1 476.0 252.8 256.7 257.8 259.1 259.5 261.1 296.8 308.4 303.5 297.0 300.7 299.6 243.0 252.6 245.9 235.5 242.9 242.5 576.3 591.5 594.7 607.4 616.1 622.8 268.0 284.2 278.5 270.3 256.8 246.4 247.1 249.1 248.9 252.2 253.2 254.7 239.7 244.9 245.8 245.9 246.9 274.2 688.5 690.4 688.6 683.4 686.4 695.7 217.4 218.4 218.0 222.7 223.5 224.8 240.5 241.8 241.3 248.2 249.1 251.1 205.2 205.9 205.6 209.0 209.7 210.6 281.0 283.8 284.1 286.3 288.0 291.2 251.0 264.4 267.1 282.2 288.7 269.9 487.1 489.9 491.5 488.6 492.0 509.0 262.6 264.6 264.7 266.5 267.8 271.1 316.6 263.5 329.1 276.7 331.8 276.7 336.0 279.1 337.6 277.3 335.6 271.3 631.6 646.1 655.8 667.7 678.6 689.1 256.4 265.5 272.3 276.8 282.6 284.7 1979: Jan. Feb . .. Mar •ft'".!."' . June July Aug Sept Oct Nov.. Dec. 1980. 2 Jan Feb Mar Apr May. June . July Aug Sept Oct Nov . Dec .... 1 2 189.4 223.0 198.3 165.0 195.2 197.0 212.0 253.6 Intermediate materials for food manufacturing and feeds. Data have been revised through August 1980 to reflect the availability of late reports and corrections by respondents. All data are subject to revision 4 months after original publication. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 297 TABLE B-57.—Producer price indexes for major commodity groups, 1940-80 [1967=100] Farm products and processed foods and feeds Year or month Total 1940 . 1941 . 1942 1943. . 1944 1945 1946. 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 . . 1952 1953 . 1954 . 1955 1956 , 1957 .. 1958 1959 . . I960.. 1961. . 1962 1963 1964 1965 . 1966 1967 1968 . , 1969 . 1970 1971 ... 1972 1973 . 1974 1975 1976 . .. 1977.. 1978 1979 1980a 1979: Jan Feb Mar... Apr May"!"" .'... June.... . July... Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 1980: a Jan Feb Mar Processed foods and feeds Total Textile products and apparel Hides, skins, leather, and related products Fuels and related products, and powerl Chemicals and allied productsl 51.4 54.6 56.2 57.8 59.5 60.1 64.4 76.9 90.5 86.2 87.1 90.3 90.1 92.6 91.3 91.2 94.0 99.1 95.3 95.3 96.1 97.2 96.7 96.3 93.7 95.5 97.8 100.0 98.9 100.9 1062 115.2 118 6 134.3 208.3 245.1 265.6 302.2 322.5 408.1 573.4 52.4 57.0 63.3 64.1 64.8 65.2 70.5 93.7 95.9 87.6 88.9 101.7 96.5 97.7 98.9 98.5 99.1 101.2 102.0 101.6 101.8 100.7 99.1 97.9 98.3 99 0 99.4 100.0 99.8 99,9 102 2 104.1 104 2 110.0 146.8 181.3 187.2 192.8 198.8 222.3 260.2 82.9 88.7 80.6 83.4 92.7 91.6 87.4 88.9 85.0 84.9 87.4 91.8 89.4 89.5 91.0 91.9 92.5 92.3 95.5 101.2 100.0 102.2 107.3 1121 114.5 120.8 148.1 170.9 182.6 178.0 186.1 202.6 222.5 241.0 44.0 47 3 50.7 51.5 52.3 53.0 58.0 70.8 76.9 75.3 78.0 86.1 84.1 84.8 85.0 86.9 90.8 93.3 93.6 95.3 95.3 94.8 94.8 94.7 95.2 96.4 98.5 100.0 102.5 106.0 110 0 114.1 117.9 125.9 153.8 171.5 182.4 195.1 209.4 236.5 274.5 103.6 108.1 98.9 102.7 114.6 103.4 100.8 98.6 98.7 98.7 98.8 97.0 98.4 99.5 97.7 98.6 98.5 99.2 99.8 100.1 100.0 103.7 106.0 1071 109.0 113.6 123.8 139.1 137.9 148.2 154.0 159.8 168.7 183.4 45.2 48.4 52.8 52.7 52.2 52.9 61.1 83.3 84.2 79.9 86.3 99.1 80.1 81.3 77.6 77.3 81.9 82.0 82.9 94.2 90.8 91.7 92.7 90.0 90.3 94.3 103.4 100.0 103.2 108.9 1103 114.1 1313 143.1 145.1 148.5 167.8 179.3 200.0 252.4 348.6 93.5 93.7 93 7 94.7 93.8 93.2 97.1 103 5 .... 100.0 1024 108.0 .. 1117 ... 113.9 1224 ... . 1591 177.4 184 2 183.1 188.8 . . . 2066 229 8 244 6 41.4 50.3 64.8 75.0 75.5 78.5 90.9 109.4 117.5 101.6 106.7 124.2 117.2 106.2 104.7 98.2 96.9 99.5 103.9 97.5 97.2 96.3 98.0 96.0 94.6 98.7 105.9 100.0 102.5 109.1 1110 112.9 125.0 176.3 187.7 186.7 191.0 192.5 212.5 241.4 249.3 2211 227 2 229.0 231.2 230.8 229.0 232.2 227.5 231.8 230 6 232.3 234.6 230.4 2409 242.8 246.0 245.4 242.8 246.8 238.5 241.0 239 6 240.2 242.5 215.2 218 9 220.5 222.3 222.0 220.6 223.3 220.5 225.8 224 8 227*1 229.3 220.0 222 5 225.4 229.0 231.6 234.0 237.5 240.6 244.2 249 0 250^6 253.1 164.1 164 2 165.2 166.4 167.2 168.4 169.3 170.5 171.3 172 0 172i8 173.1 223.4 232 2 253.3 258.9 269.6 268.0 261.9 257.9 251.1 253 9 248^9 249.2 338.1 342 5 350.9 361.5 377.6 393.7 411.8 432.8 454.8 468 5 4763 487.9 205.0 207 3 209.9 215.1 218.0 219.2 225.0 228.5 230.8 234 2 236^0 238.2 231.9 237.0 234.9 229.3 233.8 234.3 246.6 255.1 256.3 258.8 260.1 256.5 236.4 242.3 239.3 228.9 233.5 233.4 254.3 263.8 266.6 263.4 264.9 265.3 228.5 233.1 231.6 228.6 233.1 233.9 241.5 249.4 249.8 2554 256.5 250.8 260.6 265.9 268.6 271.3 271.9 273.5 276.2 278.2 278.2 2812 282.7 286.1 175.2 176.5 179.3 181.2 182.0 183.0 184.7 185.6 186.2 187 8 189.3 190.2 255.7 250.9 246.8 243.5 240.7 240.9 245.1 251.3 247.8 3 508.0 532.7 553.5 566.6 572.1 576.5 585.5 590.6 593.0 592 5 597.6 611.7 246.0 248.7 252.8 259.8 262.5 262.8 263.3 264.4 263.2 264 6 266!9 267.9 . . . .. . .... 94.3 101.5 89.6 93 9 106,9 102 7 96 0 95 7 ... . 912 90.6 93.7 . 981 ," * * ." .... . . . tz . . June... July Aug... . Sept,. Oct Nov Dec Farm products Industrial commodities .. ... See next page for continuation of table. 298 . () 255.5 256.6 TABLE B-57.—Producer price indexes for major commodity groups, 1940*80—Continued [1967=100] Industrial commodities—Continued Pulp, paper, and allied products Metals and metal products Machinery and BQiiiprcicrii Furniture and household durables Nonmetallic mineral products Transportation equipment: Motor vehicles and equipment 4 41.4 42.1 42.8 42.4 42.1 42.2 46.4 53.7 58.2 61.0 53.8 57.2 61.8 61.4 63.1 63.2 67.1 77.0 81.6 82.9 49.1 50.2 52.3 52.4 53.5 55.7 59.3 66.3 71.6 73.5 40.4 43.2 47.2 47.2 47.5 48.3 56.0 64.1 70.8 75.7 73 5 76.5 78.0 Rubber and plastic products Lumber and wood products 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 57.1 61.5 71.6 736 72.7 70 5 70.8 70 5 72.8 70.5 27.4 32.7 35.6 37.7 40.6 41.2 47.2 73.4 84.0 77.7 72 5 75.7 72.4 37.8 38.5 39.1 39.0 39.0 39.6 44.3 54.9 62.5 63.0 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 85.9 105 4 95.5 89.1 90.4 102 4 103.8 103.4 103 3 102.9 89.3 97.2 94.4 94.3 92.6 971 98.5 93.5 92 4 98.8 74.3 88 0 85.7 85.5 85.5 87 8 93.6 95.4 96 4 97.3 66.3 73.8 73.9 76.3 76.9 82.1 89.2 91.0 90.4 92.3 63.1 70.5 70.6 72.2 73.4 75.7 81.8 87.6 89.4 91.3 84.7 91.8 90.1 91.9 92.9 93.3 95.8 98.3 99.1 99.3 75.4 80.1 80.1 83.3 85.1 87.5 91.3 94.8 95.8 97.0 75.3 79 4 84.0 83.6 83.8 86.3 91.2 95.1 981 100.3 79.2 83 9 83.4 85.6 86.4 86 5 87.6 90 2 92 0 92.2 I960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 103.1 99.2 96 3 96.8 95.5 95.9 97 8 100.0 103 4 105.3 95.3 91.0 916 93.5 95.4 95.9 100 2 100.0 113.3 125.3 98.1 95.2 96 3 95.6 95.4 96.2 98 8 100.0 1011 104.0 92.4 91.9 91.2 91.3 93.8 96.4 98.8 100.0 102.6 108.5 92.0 91.9 92.0 92.2 92.8 93.9 96.8 100.0 103.2 106.5 99.0 98.4 97.7 97.0 97.4 96.9 98.0 100.0 102.8 104.9 97.2 97.6 97.6 97.1 97.3 97.5 98.4 100.0 103.7 107.7 98.8 98.6 98.6 97.8 98.3 98.5 98.6 100.0 102.8 104.8 93.0 93.3 93 7 94.5 95.2 95.9 97 7 100.0 102 2 105.2 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 108.3 109.1 109.3 112 4 136 2 150.2 159.2 167 6 174.8 194.3 113.6 127.3 144.3 177.2 183 6 176.9 205.6 236.3 276.0 300.4 108.2 110.1 113.4 122.1 1517 170.4 179.4 186.4 195.6 219.0 116.6 118.7 123.5 132.8 171.9 185.6 195.9 209.0 227.1 259.3 111.4 115.5 117.9 121.7 139.4 161.4 171.0 181.7 196.1 213.9 107.5 110.0 111.4 115.2 127.9 139.7 145.6 151.5 160.4 171.3 112.9 122.4 126.1 130.2 153.2 174.0 186.3 200.5 222.8 248.6 108.7 114.9 118.0 119.2 129.2 144.6 153.8 163.7 176.0 190.5 109.9 112.9 114.6 119.7 1331 147.7 153.7 164.3 184.3 208.7 1980 2 217.3 288.8 249.3 286.2 239.6 187.3 282.8 208.7 258.7 1979: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June 180 8 183.2 185.9 188.8 190 8 193.1 290 2 293.9 300.5 304.9 302 8 299.8 207 0 208.8 212.3 215.0 216 2 216.6 2419 247.3 251.7 256.0 256 2 258.2 2051 206.5 207.9 209.8 2114 212.4 166 6 167.9 168.3 168.7 169.6 170.2 238.3 240.5 240.8 243.4 245.6 246.9 185 0 185.9 186.1 189.4 189.8 190.1 197 7 199.8 200.6 201.4 203.3 205.2 195.5 198 8 200.7 203.0 204.9 205.9 300.1 304 7 309.7 308.8 298.9 290.1 218.3 222 2 223.0 227.5 229.5 231.7 260.8 2618 263.7 269.6 271.1 273.6 214.8 216.0 217.7 220.0 221.3 223.4 170.7 171.5 172.7 175.1 176.4 177.9 249.5 249.9 254.6 256.2 257.4 259.6 190.8 187.8 188.6 197.1 197.4 198.2 207.0 208.9 213.1 218.9 221.4 227.4 207.8 210.7 212 7 214.1 215.0 217.3 290.0 294.7 294 9 275.6 272.1 279.8 237.4 239.2 242 6 247.8 249.2 251.1 284.6 288.9 286 8 284.4 281.8 281.9 227.6 230.2 232.5 236.4 237.6 239.2 183.4 185.6 185.7 184.4 185.4 186.5 268.4 274.0 276.5 283.7 284.0 283.4 200.7 200.1 200.7 205.4 204.5 205.2 242.9 262.9 2561 252.8 251.7 258.0 2188 220.5 2212 222 7 223 0 223.5 2892 296.1 2918 288 7 293 4 299.4 251 7 252.4 252 7 254 4 255 5 257.4 282 5 285.1 286.2 290 4 290 7 290.7 241.5 242.6 244.3 246.4 247.7 249.5 188.0 188.9 187.8 189.1 190.4 192.3 284.8 286.0 286.0 287.8 288.4 290.7 208.6 211.7 205.3 217.8 218.0 225.9 2617 260.1 264.4 265 0 263 8 265.4 Year or month . .. .. . July Aug ' Sept Oct Nov Dec 1980:2 Jan Feb Mar Apr NfayZ: June Julv Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec ... . ;.;:;;;:;;.;:;.;....T:. 1 Miscellaneous products Prices for some items in this grouping are lagged and refer to 1 month earlier than the index month. Data have been revised through August 1980 to reflect the availability of late reports and corrections by respondents. All data are subject to revision 4 months after original publication. 3 Not available 4 Index for total transportation equipment is not shown but is available beginning December 1968. 2 Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Digitized forSource: FRASER 299 TABLE B-58.—Changes in producer price indexes for finished goods, 1948-80 [Percent change] Finished consumer foods Total finished goods Year or month 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 I960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967. 1968 .. . 1969 1970 1971. 1972 ... 1973 1974 1975 . 1976. .. 1977 1978 1979 1980 a Year to year Dec. to Dec.1 Year to year 3.0 -4.6 10.4 2.9 -2.2 5 -.1 8.0 -2.9 1.8 9.5 -.6 -1.0 -2.4 -7.4 13.3 5.3 -5.9 -2.2 -1.9 -2.9 3.6 5.3 9.2 .......... -8.1 1.9 12.4 -.9 -5.2 -.8 -2 5 -2 3.5 5.8 -4.7 2.2 -4 .9 -1.2 .5 3.8 6.5 -1.6 3.6 2.4 3.4 6.2 4.3 3.2 2.1 1.6 2.1 5.6 6.6 20.3 21.2 14.0 8.4 7.2 5.5 l;o 6.6 9.2 8.3 9.5 14.4 13.3 5.2 3.3 2.2 16 3.1 4.8 2.2 3.2 3.8 11.8 18.3 6.6 3.3 6.6 9.2 12.6 11.7 2^ 3.6 2.3 .8 0 -37 5.2 -1.8 -.;3 - U 1.7 3.2 1.2 2.8 3.7 3.5 3.1 3.1 9.1 15.3 10.8 4.2 6.0 7.8 11.0 9.1 1.4 -.4 4.8 8.2 -2.5 5.9 8.0 22.5 13.0 5.5 -2.5 6.6 11.9 7.6 13.2 6.5 Consumer goods Total Dec. to Dec.1 1.2 4.2 3.2 .5 -.4 1.8 -.5 -'.2 5 Finished energy goods Finished goods excluding consumer foods Dec. to Dec.* Year to year Dec. to Dec > Year to year 4.0 -4.5 8.2 .9 -1.1 1.6 .3 1.7 2.5 17 6.3 -2.1 1.6 7.2 -1.3 .9 .3 .8 2.4 2.5 ,1 1.3 .4 -.1 -.2 0 -.1 .8 .4 -.3 ~;i ,1 12,1 6.0 6.5 7.2 11.6 .9 17 2.1 2.0 2.9 3.9 2.0 2.0 7.4 20.5 67 4.9 6.1 8.4 18.0 15.9 14.3 2.6 27 3.5 37 2.0 4.1 16.0 7 1.6 1.9 2.1 2.4 3.0 3.4 1.9 4.5 16.9 10.5 57 6.4 6.7 13.3 19.4 Capital equipment Year Dec. to to Dec.1 year Dec. to Dec. * Year to year Finished goods excluding food and energy Dec. to Dec. > Year to year 9.0 5.0 2.4 97 17 17 1.2 3.0 7.4 :...*.;. 6.2 2.6 1.9 .2 10.4 -.6 10.3 3.4 .8 2.3 1.1 5.6 8.3 4.3 1.3 1,0 .1 ;3 to ;9 1,5 3.9 3.1 3,0 4.6 4.9 2.4 2.0 5.3 22.6 8.2 6.4 7.2 8.0 8.8 11.5 1.2 2.5 3.3 3.5 3.3 4.8 4.1 2.5 3.3 14.2 15.2 6.6 6.5 7.9 8.8 10.5 ; ..." 16.4 5.4 9.1 8.0 627 27.2 17.3 8.8 11.1 4.3 377 52.2 .*;..;* 6.1 5.4 6.3 8.2 9.3 11.0 11.4 5.5 6.0 7.5 8.8 11.2 Percent change from preceding month Unadjusted Season- 17 Unadjusted 1.4 1.1 7 1.1 .6 .5 1.2 1.6 1.6 .9 .8 1980:2 Jan Feb Mar May"I ' June July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec '. 1.9 1.4 1.2 .8 '.6 1.7 .8 -.1 1.3 .4 .6 1.2 1.1 1.0 .8 .5 .6 1.2 1.1 1.5 1.1 1.2 .8 1.6 1.4 1.4 .6 .3 1.7 1.4 ~;8 .6 .6 a Unadjusted justed justed 1979: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug Sept Oc! Nov.... Dec Season- Season- S Unadjusted Season- 17 justed justed 1.5 1.4 1.3 -.4 -1.0 -1.0 .7 1.5 1.4 -.1 1.9 1.2 7 7 1.2 1.0 1.1 1.4 .9 1.4 2.4 .7 .8 1.1 1.0 .9 1.2 1.0 1.1 1.3 1.0 1.5 1.5 1.0 1.1 1.3 .8 .9 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.8 1.6 1.9 2.4 .8 1.0 1.1 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.4 1.4 17 1.7 1.9 1.8 1.1 1.2 -.3 .1 .6 -1.8 .5 .4 3.8 2.2 -.9 -.4 1.0 -2.8 .0 2.6 1.8 1.4 1.6 2.4 2.0 1.5 1.6 .4 7 1.1 3.1 2.6 1.7 1.6 .6 .8 2.9 2.8 1.8 1.5 ;o ";§ 2.0 2.2 7 -~U .6 .6 2.1 -.6 1.7 .7 .4 .1 3.9 4.3 ~;4 ;6 1.1 -1 17 .4 -1 Unadjusted .9 1.0 .4 -.2 1.1 ;9 7 Season$ justed 1.1 7 .4 1.1 1.0 .9 .6 1.1 ;3 .6 -.3 .6 2.3 .5 .6 7 .8 -.1 7 .9 1.8 1.6 7 17 .2 ;9 1.8 ;9 ;6 .8 .4 -.2 .6 -.2 2.9 T4 ;g '.8 .6 1.0 1.2 7 1.4 .7 Unadjusted Season- 3 Unadjusted 2.0 1.8 3.5 4.3 4.9 5.2 7.2 6.3 6.5 4.1 1.9 2.0 6.0 6.2 6.5 4.5 2.7 2.3 3.9 6.9 7.0 3.8 1.4 4.5 7.1 7.5 3.8 .8 -.6 -.7 .1 -.3 -.3 -.4 -.8 .4 1.3 1.4 . 1.6 .5 17 justed justed 1.4 1.6 3.1 4.3 5.5 5.9 Season- 1.2 7 .5 .9 ;5 .6 .2 .7 2.1 .4 7 2.4 1.0 .4 1.2 7 1.1 .5 -.2 2.2 .4 .6 1.0 .9 .6 .8 .6 .6 .8 .3 .8 1.1 .7 .9 2.0 1.2 L2 .3 .9 1.3 .6 -.1 1.1 .6 .8 1 Changes from December to December are based on unadjusted indexes. 2 Dataliave been revised through August 1980 to reflect the availability of late reports and corrections by respondents. All data are subject to revision 4 months after original publication. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 300 MONEY STOCK, CREDIT, AND FINANCE TABLE B-59.—Money stock measures and liquid assets, 1959-80 [Averages of daily figures; billions of dollars, seasonally adjusted] Ml-A Ml-B M2 M3 Ml-B plus overnight Currency Period plus demand deposits' December: 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 *. 1979: Jan. . Feb .... Mar t! June. . July ... Aug Sept.. Oct Nov... Dec. 1980 Jan... Feb Mar. .. June.. July.. Aug. . Sept.. Oct.. .. Nov. Dec. P. Ml-A plus other checkable deposits at banks and thrift institutions RPs and M2 plus Eurodollars, large time MMMF deposits and shares, and RPs at savings and term commercial smalltime banks and deposits at thrift commercial institutions banks and thrift institutions2 M3 plus other liquid assets 140.7 296.7 297.9 387.5 t41.6 146.1 148.8 154.2 161.3 311.2 333.9 361.1 391.4 422.8 313.3 337.9 368.2 402.3 438.0 402.5 429.1 464.5 501.8 538.3 168.8 172.9 184.2 198.5 204.7 457.2 478.5 523.6 566.2 587.6 478.5 502.2 555.7 605.3 610.4 582.3 613.9 667.2 730.9 761.2 215.3 229.2 250.5 264.1 275.3 215.4 229.4 250.6 264.4 275.7 625.2 709.6 801.6 858.1 906.2 671.7 769.7 877.8 976.1 1,058.6 812.5 898.7 1,017.7 1,137.2 1,242.8 287.9 305.0 328.4 351.6 369.7 289.0 307.7 332.5 359.9 386.4 1,022.4 1,166.7 1,294.1 1,401.5 1,525.5 1,161.0 1,299.7 1,460.3 1,623.6 1,775.5 1,369.6 1,523.5 1,715.5 1,927.7 2,141.1 385.4 411.0 1,669.7 1,954.0 350.1 350.0 351.9 356.1 355.5 359.4 360.0 360.7 363.9 369.6 369.2 373.9 1,407.5 1,413.8 1,426.6 1,441.2 1,449.5 1,465.9 1,631.9 1,642.3 1,654.8 1,669.1 1,679.2 1,695.2 1,939.4 1,954.8 1,978.3 2,000.7 2,021.1 2,048.7 362.0 364.0 365.9 366.6 368.0 369.7 377.4 379.9 382.2 382.9 384.2 386.4 1,478.3 1,491.8 1,502.9 1,510.1 1,516.4 1,525.5 1,709.2 1,725.8 1,745.5 1,757.8 1,765.4 1,775.5 2,063.8 2,081.3 2,110.0 2,120.4 2,126.4 2,141.1 370.8 373.7 373.1 367.6 367.8 371.3 388.1 391.3 391.2 386.6 386.2 390.9 1,534.5 1,546.7 1,553.1 1,549.9 1,562.1 1,585.7 1,786.9 1,804.5 1,811.1 1,811.1 1,824.2 1,844.5 2,155.2 2,175.9 2,190.1 2,200.7 2,216.6 2,229.1 373.7 379.7 383.7 386.7 388.9 385.4 394.5 401.6 406.9 410.8 414.0 411.0 1,609.7 1,629.2 1,640.9 1,652.9 1,667.2 1,669.7 1,865.2 1,886.3 1,900.7 1,917.1 1,940.8 1,954.0 2,243.4 2,268.2 2,295.1 2,310.1 140.7 141.6 146.1 148.8 154.2 161.2 168.7 172.8 184.2 198.4 204.6 1 Demand deposits at all commercial banks other than those due to domestic banks, the U.S. Government, and foreign banks and official institutions less cash items in the process of collection and Federal Reserve float. 2 Total M2 excludes demand deposits held by thrift institutions at commercial banks, not shown separately in components. Note.—See Table B-60 for components. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 33-540 0 - 8 1 - 2 0 : 301 QL 3 TABLE B-60.—Components of money stock measures and liquid assets, 1959-80 [Averages of daily figures; billions of dollars, seasonally adjusted, except as noted] OverMoney night Other repur- Over- market De- checknight mutual chase Cur- mand able fund agree- Eurorency depos- dedollars (MMMF) its' posits ments shares (RPs) }(net) notl NSA NSA NSA NSA Period Large SavSmall ings denomina- denominade- tion time tion time posits deposits2 deposits2 Term repurchase agreements {RPs) NSA NSA December: 1959 28.9 111.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 11.5 1.2 0.0 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 29.0 29.6 30.6 32,5 34.2 112.7 116.6 118.2 121.7 127.0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .1 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 157.8 173.9 193.1 212.6 233.3 12.6 14.8 20.2 25.7 29.3 2.0 4.0 10.9 15.3 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 36.3 38.3 40.4 43.5 46.1 132.4 134.5 143.7 154.9 158.6 .1 .0 .5 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 255.0 251.1 261.4 266.3 261.0 34,5 55.1 78.1 101.1 120.7 21.3 23.2 31.1 37.6 20.4 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 49.1 52.6 56.9 61.6 67.8 166.2 176.7 193.6 202.5 207.4 6.8 7.2 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 .0 256.7 .0 287.5 .0 317.0 153.0 191.8 232.6 266.4 288.9 45.1 57.6 73.0 110.9 144.0 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 73.8 80.7 88.7 97.6 106.3 214.1 224.4 239.7 253.9 263.4 1.1 7.5 .0 2.7 .0 1.0 8.3 16.7 13.6 17.6 21.9 21.7 2.0 3.6 10.3 476.1 43.6 416.7 340.4 396.6 454.9 533.8 656.5 129.6 118.0 145.2 194.7 219.4 15.0 21.0 27.3 30.5 1980"..... 116.5 268.9 25.6 25.5 4.6 75.8 395.5 760.5 250.6 33.7 June 98.2 98.9 99.6 100.2 100.9 101.8 251.9 251.1 252.3 255.9 254.7 257.6 9.9 10.8 12.0 13.6 13.6 14.6 21.2 21.9 23.1 23.9 25.9 26.3 2.3 2.6 2.8 2.8 2.8 2.9 12.1 14,5 16.8 19.2 21.8 24.6 468.1 460.7 457.0 452.3 448.6 449.8 546.3 555.9 565.6 576.1 583.9 591.0 197.4 200.9 200.0 198.6 198.2 196.8 July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 102.6 103.7 104.7 105.5 105.9 106.3 259.4 260.3 261.2 261.1 262.1 263.4 15.4 15.9 16.3 16.3 16.2 16.7 25.5 25.3 26.2 25.3 22.5 21.7 3.0 3.3 3.6 3.5 3.2 28.0 31.2 33.7 36.9 40.4 43.6 450.9 450.4 445.4 436.0 421.3 416.7 596.2 604.4 614.6 628.4 647.8 656.5 1980: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June 107.3 ^ 108.1 108.9 109.0 110.1 111.0 263.5 265.6 264.2 258.6 257.7 260.3 17.3 17.6 18.0 19.0 18.4 19.6 22.6 23.0 21.0 17.6 18.5 19.6 4.1 2.7 2.8 2.9 49.1 56.7 60.9 60.4 66.8 74,2 411.8 403.1 391.9 377.3 372.7 381.4 July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec" 112.0 113.4 113.9 115.1 15.9 116.5 261.6 266.3 269.8 271.6 273.1 268.9 20.8 21.9 23.2 24.1 25.1 25.6 23.0 25.2 26.4 25.5 25.6 25.5 3.6 3.7 3.7 4.4 4.7 4.6 80.6 80.7 78.2 77.4 77.0 75.8 393.8 403.9 407.9 410.1 405.2 395.5 1979: Jan Feb Mar Apr May '.1 1.1 1.6 .1 2.5 .1 .1 .1 2.5 3.1 .3 .4 4.1 1.4 3.6 4.1 3.6 0.0 145.2 .1 322.2 2.3 333.9 3.6 383.9 3.4 447.7 3.8 486.5 7.1 ShortTerm term Bankers' ComEuro- SavTreasaccep- mercial dollars ings ury tances paper (net) bonds securities .0 .5 1.0 1.5 0.7 46.1 38.7 0.5 3.6 36.8 37.1 39.9 40.7 38.5 .8 1.0 1.0 1.1 1.2 5.1 5.2 6.8 7.7 9.1 1.7 49.7 40.7 2.1 50.2 43.2 1.5 10.2 14.4 17.8 22.5 34.0 ,8 45.7 1.4 46.5 1.6 46.9 1.9 48.1 2.4 49.0 1.6 1.7 38.7 46.1 59.5 49.2 36.2 40.9 49.8 53.4 10.7 7.9 10.3 13.7 22.8 31.9 67.3 76.8 71.8 80.7 76.6 89.5 80.7 98.7 80.0 127.5 27.1 27.5 28.4 29.3 31.5 32.4 24.5 27,1 28.4 29.1 29.6 29.9 80.6 80.6 80.5 80.6 80.6 80.4 198.9 201.8 208.9 214.8 218.5 219.4 32.0 32.2 33.7 33.0 30.5 30.5 31.4 33.9 33.4 33.2 34.0 31.9 661.8 671.4 687.6 708.3 718.0 719,6 222.5 228.6 230.7 234.2 235.0 230.7 29.9 29.2 27.2 27.1 27.1 28.1 717.2 717.1 720.9 727.9 743.9 760.5 226.2 225.3 229.0 231.8 240.9 250.6 29.3 31.7 30.9 32.3 32.6 33.7 2.4 2.3 51.2 51.8 51.7 1.4 2.5 1.8 2.3 2.8 4.4 6.7 52.0 54.3 57.5 60.4 63.2 3.3 7.1 8.4 9.0 2.1 2.9 2.2 3.2 3.3 3.5 3.3 4.7 34.5 32.7 35.2 41.9 50.1 12.3 22.6 28.9 8.5 9.0 48.1 51.8 63.1 79.4 97.3 98.8 100.4 108.2 114.2 122.5 131.4 22.4 21.4 21.3 21.1 21.0 21.5 81.2 83.1 85.0 86.6 88.2 90.4 80.0 80.0 80.6 82.2 80.3 80.0 128.8 123.0 128.1 123.7 122.1 127.5 22.6 25.0 26.6 27.1 28.6 28.9 91.8 93.6 95.7 96.4 96.0 97.3 34.1 37.5 37.4 37.9 37.8 36.0 79.2 78.1 76.8 75.2 74.0 73.3 127.6 128.8 136.3 146.3 151.8 148.6 28.4 27.6 28.8 29.5 29.4 30.2 99.0 99.3 99.8 100.6 99.5 96.5 35.4 36.0 34.1 33.0 72.8 72.6 73.2 74.6 144.2 147.2 157.3 155.0 30.1 29.6 31.3 32.2 95.8 96.6 98.5 98.3 'Demand deposits at ail commercial banks other than those due to domestic banks, the U.S. Government, and foreign banks and official institutions less cash items in the process of collection and Federal Reserve float. "Small denomination and large denomination deposits are those issued in amounts of less than $100,000 and more than $100,000, respectively. Note.—NSA indicates data are not seasonally adjusted. See also Table B-59. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 302 TABLE B-61.—Commercial bank loans and investments, 1939-80 [Billions of dollars] Loans Total loans and investments Year and month End of month * 1939- Dec Total Investments Commercial and industrial US. Treasury securities Other securities 7.1 Loans plus loans sold to bank affiliates 40 7 17.2 16.3 43 9 50 7 67.4 85.1 105.5 124 0 114 0 116.3 114.2 18.8 21.7 19.2 19.1 21.6 261 31.1 38.1 42.4 17.8 218 41.4 59.8 77.6 90 6 74.8 69.2 62.6 1948- Dec 1949: Dec 113 0 118.7 * 41,5 42.0 62 3 66.4 92 10.3 1950- Dec 1951- Dec 1952- Dec 1953- Dec 1954* Dec 1955- Dec 1956- Dec 1957- Dec 1958- Dec 1959: Dec 124.7 130 2 139.1 1431 1531 157.6 1616 166.4 1812 188.7 51.1 56 5 62.8 66.2 691 80.6 88.1 91.5 95.6 110.5 39.4 61.1 60 4 62.2 62 2 67 6 60.3 57 2 56.9 651 57.7 12.4 13 4 14.2 14.7 16 4 16.8 16.3 17.9 20.5 20.5 110.5 I960: 196119621963196419651966: 196719681969- Dec Dec Dec Dec Dec Dec Dec Dec Dec Dec 197.4 212 8 231.2 250 2 272.3 3001 316.1 352.0 390.2 401.7 116.7 123.6 137.3 153 7 172.9 198.2 213.9 231.3 258.2 279.4 42.1 43 9 47.6 521 58.4 69.5 78.6 86.2 95.9 105.7 59.9 65 3 64.7 615 60.7 57.1 53.5 59.4 60.7 51.2 20.8 23.9 29.2 35.0 38.7 44.8 48.7 61.3 71.3 71.1 116.7 1236 137.3 153.7 172.9 198.2 213.9 231.3 258.2 283.3 1970- Dec 1971: Dec 1972- Dec 435 5 485.7 558.0 292 0 320.9 378.9 110 0 116.2 130.4 57 8 60.6 62.6 85.7 104.2 116.5 294 7 323.7 381.5 5661 647.8 713.6 744 6 804 3 8911 1,014.3 1,132.5 386 2 460.3 519.9 516.9 554 8 6321 747.8 847.2 136 3 165.6 197.3 189.8 1912 2112 246.5 290.5 641 58.7 53.7 82.1 100 6 99 5 93.4 93.8 115 8 128.8 140.0 145.7 149.0 159 6 173.1 191.5 388 8 464.6 524.7 521.3 558.5 636.9 751.6 850.0 Way';:.:;..;:v": :.;;:..::. :::::.. June 1,144.8 1,162 7 1165 2 11610 1,154.9 1,152.0 858.5 872 7 874 7 8716 860.6 853.5 295.6 301.1 302 8 3012 297.7 295.4 93.2 94 8 94 5 93 2 94.6 97.0 193.1 195.2 196.0 196.2 199.7 201.5 861.1 875.3 877.3 874.2 863.2 856.3 Julv Aug Sept Oct Nov 1160 0 1,177.2 1,191.0 1,204 5 1,221.2 855 0 865.8 876.4 886 2 899.4 296 2 301.4 306.0 312 0 318.4 100 9 104.4 106.6 107 9 109.3 204.2 207.0 208.0 210.3 212.5 857 8 868.7 879.3 889.0 902.1 1940194119421943: 19441945194619471948- Dec Dec Dec Dec Dec Dec Dec Dec Dec .... .. 7.4 72 6.r 6.1 6.3 73 8.1 9.0 9.2 Seasonally adjusted Average for month2 1972- Dec 1973- Dec 1974- Dec 1975- Dec 1976- Dec 1977- Dec 1978: Dec 1979- Dec 1980: Jan Feb Mai ADr •..:....:...."""".:.:.".: :;:;:;.: z 1 Data are for December 31 call dates. Data are prorated averages of Wednesday figures for domestically chartered banks and averages of current and previous month-end data for foreign-related institutions. Lease financing receivables are included in total loans and investments and in total loans. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 8 303 TABLE B-62.— Total funds raised in credit markets by nonftnancial sectors, 1972-80 [Billions of dollars] * Item Total funds raised by nonfinancial sectors.... U.S. Government 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 176.8 203.1 191.6 210.8 271.9 338.5 400.3 394.9 15.1 8.3 11.8 85.4 69.0 56.8 53.7 37.4 4.0 6.1 15.4 13.3 20.8 13.9 32.3 21.2 Foreign Private domestic nonfinancial sectors... 157.7 Corporate equities... Debt instruments.... Debt capital instruments.... State and local government obligations Corporate bonds Mortgages Home. Multi-family residential Commercial Farm 164.4 112.1 182.0 267.9 314.4 336.4 10.9 146.8 7.9 180.9 4.1 160.3 9.9 102.1 10,5 171.5 2.7 265.1 2.6 311.8 3.5 333.0 102.1 105.1 98.0 98.4 123.5 175.6 196.6 199.9 14.7 12.2 75.2 14.7 9.2 81.2 16.5 19.7 61.9 16.1 27.2 55.0 15.7 22.8 85.0 23.7 21.0 131.0 28.3 20.1 148.2 18.9 21.2 159.9 42.5 12.7 16.4 3.6 46.4 10.4 18.9 5.5 34.8 6.9 15.1 5.0 39.5 = .0 11.0 4.6 63.7 1.8 13.4 6.1 96.4 7.4 18.4 8.8 104.5 10.2 23.3 10.2 109.1 8.9 25.7 16.2 Other debt instruments.. 44.7 75.8 62.3 3.8 48.0 89.5 115.2 133.0 Consumer credit Bank loans n.e.c... Open-market paper. 19.8 17.1 .8 6.9 26.0 37.1 2.5 10.3 9.7 9.9 32.0 - 1 2 . 3 6.6 -2.6 13.7 9.0 25.6 4.0 4.0 14.4 40.6 27.0 2.9 19.0 50.6 37.3 5.2 22.2 44.2 50.6 10.9 27.3 By borrowing sector: Total 164.4 112.1 182.0 267.9 314.4 336.4 14.5 65.1 78.1 13.2 80.1 95.5 15.5 51.3 97.6 13.7 49.7 48.6 15.2 90.5 76.3 20.4 139.9 '.07.6 23.6 162.6 128.2 15.5 165.0 155.9 Farm Nonfarm noncorporate. Corporate 5.8 14.1 58.2 9.6 12.9 73.0 8.0 7.4 82.1 8.8 2.0 37.9 10.9 4.7 60.7 14.7 12.9 79.9 18.1 15.4 94.7 25.8 15.8 114.3 Debt instruments. Equities 47.2 10.9 65.2 7.9 78.0 4.1 28.0 9.9 50.2 10.5 77.2 2.7 92.2 2.6 110.8 3.5 176.8 203.1 191.6 210.8 271.9 338.5 400.3 394.9 157.7 State and local governments. Households Nonfinancial business Total funds supplied to nonfinancial sectors , Financed directly or indirectly by: Private domestic nonfinancial sectors.., Deposits Demand deposits and currency Time and savings deposits Money market funds and repurchase agreements Credit market instruments... Corporate equities 122.7 140.3 118.9 140.4 168.5 189.7 217.0 238.2 106.7 101.2 73.8 98.1 131.9 149.5 151.8 144.7 21.5 83.6 14.5 75.7 8.2 12.6 84.0 16.1 113.5 26.1 121.0 22.2 18.9 84.7 65.4 1.6 11.0 21.6 45.7 -5.6 -6.7 1.6 2.3 2.4 45.8 39.8 46.4 -3.5 -3.2 =6.1 6.4 At banks Credit and equity instruments.. U.S. Government-related loans, net U.S. Government cash balances Private insurance and pension reserves.. Other sources . 3.8 10.8 3.0 3.4 2.6 — 4 26.3 11.0 11.2 -1.5 30.7 16.1 See next page for continuation of table. 304 105.4 71.4 47.3 -11.9 -6.2 -2.2 14.6 41.0 14.4 .2 Foreign funds 115.2 2.1 13.4 43.2 22.1 10.3 11.7 -8.7 10.8 -4.6 17.9 1.2 42.0 46.5 6.3 40.1 26.3 -6.1 19.5 -4.6 33.4 2.4 24.9 2.8 39.7 .9 20.5 3.0 47.9 18.6 19.5 .9 58.7 26,5 30.5 3.7 70.6 32.0 664 34.3 20.3 35.4 TABLE B-62.—Total funds raised in credit markets by nonfinancial sectors, 1972-80—Continued [Billions of dollars] 1980 unadjusted quarterly flows Item 1 Total funds raised by nonfinancial sectors U S Government Foreign Private domestic nonfinancial sectors Corporate equities Debt instruments Debt capital instruments State and local government obligations Corporate bonds Mortgages . Home mortgages Multi-family residential Commercial ... .... ... Farm Other debt instruments Consumer credit Bank loans n.e.c... . Open-market paper Other By borrowing sector: Total State and local governments. Households. Nonfinancial business Farm Nonfarm noncorporate Corporate .... .... . ... Debt instruments.. Equities .. . . Total funds supplied to nonfinancial sectors II 1980 seasonally adjusted annual rates III 1 ii III 379 4 816 62 5 102 4 414 2 236 0 191 54 271 614 64 2 964 42 77 83 24 3 319 24 9 58.4 49 4 67 0 328 5 139 8 2581 2.0 56.4 1.2 48.2 1.2 65.3 8.0 320.5 4.7 135.2 4.9 253.2 38.5 41.9 50.4 198.0 138.2 177.7 1.6 5.0 6.6 11.4 239 20.8 23 2 154 0 14.8 43 3 319 8.4 84 33 6 801 23.4 33 6 1207 19.7 2.1 5.4 14.4 1.6 3.6 4.7 4.4 22.2 2.6 58 3.0 99.8 8.0 280 18.2 44.8 6.5 13.7 15.1 78.0 10.5 20 3 11.8 17 9 63 15 4 122 5 -31 75 5 -3.5 6.8 8.4 6.3 -8.1 2.2 6.0 6.2 39 13.0 -2.8 1.3 25 9 37.5 37.2 22.0 -44 2 -1.8 22.2 20.7 58.7 -10.2 20.9 58.4 49.4 67.0 328.5 139.8 258.1 1.4 23.1 33.9 5.8 13.3 7.8 27.1 303 20.2 1421 166 2 11.7 40.8 87 3 20.8 97.8 1394 23 9 18.4 123 8 23.2 -.1 643 18 6 18.8 102 0 59.6 47 971 49 236 0 379 4 321 5.4 7.9 48 2.2 26.3 .8 21.6 5.1 22 3 24.3 20.4 20 12 210 12 115 8 816 62 5 102 4 414 2 80 61 Financed directly or indirectly by: Private domestic nonfinancial sectors Deposits Demand deposits and currency Time and savings deposits..... Money market funds and repurchase agreements Credit market instruments Corporate equities Foreign funds At banks Credit and equity instruments U S Government-related loans net U S Government cash balances Private insurance and pension reserves Other sources .... Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 305 44 0 29 4 58 7 252 8 117 3 2571 19.3 40.1 43 4 151.5 165.9 174.6 -23.7 26.9 16.0 5.9 16.6 17.6 5.7 34.3 3.5 2.7 84.8 64.1 -2.9 98.4 70.4 40.8 119.9 14.0 27 6 114 17 8 118 7 -56 3 917 -2.9 .8 -2.5 -17.4 7.8 -9.2 73 -117 _7 27 8 -22 0 -33 7 7.2 .0 -16.2 4.5 -6.9 6.3 36.7 -9.0 -69.6 47.6 -51.6 17.9 6.2 -8.0 18.8 13.4 15.5 5.7 20.0 3.4 4.9 8.5 18.4 12.6 46.3 -6.8 73.0 42.9 -12.1 83.4 26.5 7.2 15.1 72.6 61.0 2 y TABLE B-63.—Federal Reserve Bank credit and member bank reserves, 1929-80 [Averages of daily figures; millions of dollars] Member bank reserves2 Reserve Bank credit outstanding Year and month Total U.S. Government and Federal agency securities Member bank borrowings Total Otherl Total Required Excess Seasonal 1929: Dec... 1933: Dec... 1939: Dec . 1,643 2,669 2,612 446 2,432 2,510 801 95 3 396 142 99 2,395 2,588 11,473 2,347 M,822 6,462 48 3 766 5,011 1940: Dec. 1941: Dec . 1942: Dec 1943: Dec . 1944-. Dec.. 1945: Dec . 1946: Dec . 1947: Dec 1948: Dec. 1949: Dec . 2,305 2,404 6,035 11,914 19,612 24,744 24,746 22,858 23,978 19,012 2,188 2,219 5,549 11,166 18,693 23,708 23,767 21,905 23,002 18,287 3 5 4 90 265 334 157 224 134 118 114 180 482 658 654 702 822 729 842 607 14,049 12,812 13,152 12,749 14,168 16,027 16,517 17,261 19,990 16,291 7,403 9,422 10,776 11,701 12,884 14,536 15,617 16,275 19,193 15,488 6,646 3,390 2,376 1,048 1,284 1,491 900 986 797 803 1950: 1951: 1952: 1953: 1954: 1955: 1956: 1957: 1958: 1959: Dec. Dec. Dec. Dec . Dec Dec Dec Dec. Dec. Dec 21,606 25,446 27,299 27,107 26,317 26,853 27,156 26,186 28,412 29,435 20,345 23,409 24,400 25,639 24,917 24,602 24,765 23,982 26,312 27,036 142 657 1,593 441 246 839 688 710 557 906 1,119 1,380 1,306 1,027 1,154 1,412 1,703 1,494 1,543 1,493 17,391 20,310 21,180 19,920 19,279 19,240 19,535 19,420 18,899 18,932 16,364 19,484 20,457 19,227 18,576 18,646 18,883 18,843 18,383 18,450 1,027 826 723 693 703 594 652 577 516 482 1960: Dec . 1961: Dec. 1962: Dec.. 1963: Dec 1964: Dec... 1965: Dec... 1966: Dec... 1967: Dec... 1968: Dec... 1969: Dec..., 29,060 31,217 33,218 36,610 39,873 43,853 46,864 51,268 56,610 64,100 27,248 29,098 30,546 33,729 37,126 40,885 43,760 48,891 52,529 57,500 87 149 304 327 243 454 557 238 765 1,086 1,725 1,970 2,368 2,554 2,504 2,514 2,547 2,139 3,316 5,514 19,283 20,118 20,040 20,746 21,609 22,719 23,830 25,260 27,221 28,031 18,514 19,550 19,468 20,210 21,198 22,267 23,438 24,915 26,766 27,774 769 568 572 536. 411 452 392 345 455 257 1970: Dec... 1971: Dec.., 1972: Dec... 1973: Dec..., 1974: Dec.., 1975: Dec.... 1976: Dec. 1977: Dec.., 1978: Dec.., 1979: Dec... 66,708 74,255 76,851 85,642 93,967 99,651 107,632 116,382 129,330 139,896 61,688 69,158 71,094 79,701 86,679 92,108 100,328 107,948 117,344 126,276 321 107 1,049 1,298 703 127 62 558 874 1,473 41 32 13 12 54 134 82 4,699 4,990 4,708 4,643 6,585 7,416 7,242 7,876 11,112 12,147 29,265 31,329 31,353 35,068 36,941 34,989 35,136 36,471 41,572 43,972 28,993 31,164 31,134 34,806 36,602 34,727 34,964 36,297 41,447 43,578 272 165 219 262 339 262 172 174 125 394 1980: Dec. r. 143,250 127,895 1,617 116 13,738 * 40,097 40,067 May*.' ., June 138,843 135,485 136,260 139,212 139,590 141,182 126,238 123,327 124,243 127,546 129,663 131,356 1,241 1,655 2,824 2,455 1,018 380 75 96 150 155 63 12 11,364 10,503 9,193 9,211 8,90< 9,446 45,170 43,156 43,097 44,877 43,968 43,479 44,928 42,966 42,911 44,683 43,785 43,268 242 190 186 194 183 211 July Aug.... Sept Oct. ... Nov Dec." 141,744 139,235 139,993 141,695 142,984 143,250 130,997 128,070 128,684 130,661 129,743 127,895 395 659 1,311 1,335 2,156 1,617 7 10 26 67 99 116 10,352 10,506 9,998 9,699 11,085 13,738 42,859 40,373 41,164 41,815 * 41,678 4 40,097 42,575 40,071 40,908 41,498 40,723 40,067 284 302 256 317 5 955 •30 1980: Jan Feb Mar 1 2 Mainly float. Beginning December 1959, part of currency and cash held by member banks allowed as reserves; beginning November 1960 all such currency and cash allowed. Beginning November 1972, includes reserve deficiencies on which Federal Reserve Banks were allowed to waive penalties for a transition period in connection with bank adaptation to Regulation J as amended effective November 9, 1972. Transition period ended after second quarter 1974. Effective November 1975, includes reserve deficiencies on which penalties are waived over a 24-month period when a nonmember bank merges into an existing member bank, or when a nonmember bank joins the Federal Reserve System. 3 Data are for licensed banks only. * Includes all reserve balances of depository institutions plus vault cash at institutions with required reserve balances plus vault cash equal to required reserves at other institutions. 8 Reserve balances with Federal Reserve Banks plus vault cash used to satisfy reserve requirements less required reserves. (This measure of excess reserves is comparable to the old excess reserve concept published historically.) Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 306 TABLE B-64.—Aggregate reserves and member bank deposits, 1959-80 [Averages of daily figures; billions of dollars, seasonally adjusted] Reserves of depository institutions1 Year and month Total 2 Nonborrowed Required Member bank deposits subject to reserve requirements Monetary base 3 Total Time and savings Private U.S. Government Adjusted for changes in reserve requirements4 institutions Total Nonborrowed sitory Required Monetary base 1959: Dec 18.61 17.67 18.10 48.3 157.8 54.4 98.6 4.8 16.12 15.18 15.61 45.8 I960: 1961: 1962: 1963: 1964: Dec Dec Dec Dec. Dec 18.91 19.76 19.72 20.39 21.27 18.84 19.63 19.46 20.06 21.01 18.17 19.18 19.14 19.90 20.87 48.7 50.2 51.2 53.8 56.5 162.2 175.4 189.1 203.7 219.1 58.9 67.8 80.1 92.4 104.1 98.8 102.7 103.3 105.9 109.1 4.6 4.9 5.7 5.4 5.9 16.35 16.91 17.36 17.85 18.50 16.27 16.77 17.10 17.52 18.24 15.60 16.32 16.79 17.36 18.10 46.1 47.3 48.8 51.3 53.8 1965: 1966: 1967: 1968: 1969: Dec Dec Dec Dec Dec 22.34 23.39 24.91 27.18 28.07 21.90 22.86 24.69 26.43 26.95 21.92 23.05 24.54 26.75 27.78 59.8 62.9 66.5 72.0 75.6 238.9 246.8 276.3 300.4 288.0 121.1 129.0 149.3 164.9 150.7 113.0 114.1 121.5 130.6 132.1 4.8 3.7 5.4 4.9 5.2 19.30 19.41 21.20 22.53 22.43 18.86 18.88 20.97 21.78 21.31 18.88 19.07 20.82 22.10 22.14 56.7 58.9 62.8 67.3 69.9 1970: 1971: 1972: 1973: 1974- Dec Dec Dec Dec Dec 29.22 31.28 31.40 34.98 36.66 28.89 31.15 30.35 33.68 35.94 28.97 31.09 31.11 34.68 36.41 79.8 85.5 90.2 98.6 106.8 321.7 361.1 402.8 443.4 487.2 179.4 211.4 242.4 280.4 323.3 136.1 143.8 154.4 158.2 160.6 6.2 5.8 6.1 4.8 3.3 23.98 25.63 28.53 30.25 32.15 23.65 25.50 27.48 28.95 31.42 23.73 25.44 28.25 29.94 3189 74,6 79.9 87.3 93.9 1021 1975: 1976: 1977: 1978: 1979: Dec. Dec Dec Dec . Dec 34.67 34.90 36.00 41.16 43.57 34.54 34.85 35.43 40.29 42.10 34.40 34.63 35.81 40.93 43.13 111.0 118.4 127.6 142.2 153.8 504.9 528.3 567.6 616.1 644.4 337.5 353.6 385.6 428.7 451.1 164.6 171.7 178.5 185.1 191.5 2.8 3.0 3.5 2.2 1.8 32.17 32.67 34.10 36.03 37.51 32.04 32.62 33.53 35.16 36.03 31.90 32.39 33.91 35.80 37.06 107.6 115.2 124.8 136.1 146.8 40.13 38.44 39.58 159.8 701.8 503.9 195.9 1.9 40.11 38.42 39.56 159.7 June 40 36 39,90 39 76 39.78 38.90 39.11 4115 40.66 40 59 40.52 40.53 40.31 143 2 143.4 143 9 144.6 145.1 145.9 619 0 617.5 615 4 618.7 616.0 614.7 431.2 432.9 432.3 431.8 429.8 427.6 185 8 182.7 1812 185.0 184.2 185.0 20 p..-::: 4136 40.87 4075 40.70 40.67 40.53 1.9 18 1.9 1.9 2.1 3619 35.71 35 60 35.57 35.59 35.56 3519 34.74 34 61 34.65 33.83 34.14 35 98 35.51 3544 35.40 35.45 35.34 137 1 137.3 137 9 138.5 139.2 140.1 July Aue Sept Oct Nov Dec 40:78 41.11 41.43 42.20 43.06 43.57 39.61 40.03 40.09 40.18 41.15 42.10 40.57 40.89 41.24 41.93 42.81 43.13 147.1 148.6 150.0 151.5 152.8 153.8 619.3 625.4 631.5 638.2 641.9 644.4 430.6 436.3 441.7 446.6 450.1 451.1 186.9 187.0 188.1 189.8 190.0 191.5 1.8 2.1 1.7 1.7 1.9 1.8 35.80 36.05 36.29 36.82 36.94 37.51 34.63 34.96 34.95 34.80 35.03 36.03 35.59 35.83 36.10 36.55 36.69 37.06 141.2 142.6 144.0 145.2 145.8 146.8 1980: Jan Feb... Mar Apr May June 43.44 43.35 43.67 44.85 44.45 43.96 42.20 41.70 40.85 42.39 43.43 43.58 43.19 43.14 43.48 44.65 44.27 43.76 154.7 155.6 156.6 157.9 158.5 158.9 643.7 647.2 649.1 655.4 656.8 658.0 451.9 454.4 457.9 464.2 467.7 467.9 189.5 190.9 189.4 188.7 187.3 188.4 2.3 1.9 1.8 2.4 1.8 1.7 37.48 37.40 37.48 37.52 37.49 37.46 36.23 35.75 34.65 35.06 36.47 37.08 37.22 37.19 37.29 37.32 37.31 37.26 147.8 148.7 149.5 149.7 150.7 151.5 42.78 40.75 41.52 41.73 41.23 40.13 42.39 40.09 40.21 40.42 39.17 38.44 42.50 40.45 41.26 41.52 40.73 39.58 158.8 158.2 159.5 160.9 160.6 159.8 658.5 667.8 678.2 684.7 694.5 701.8 467.0 474.2 482.0 486.7 494.2 503.9 189.1 191.5 194.5 195.6 198.2 195.9 2.5 2.1 1.8 2.4 2.2 1.9 37.57 38.05 38.73 38.89 M0.06 40.11 37.18 37.39 37.41 37.58 5 38.00 38.42 37.29 37.75 38.47 38.69 5 39.56 39.56 152.6 154.6 155.8 157.1 5 159.1 159.7 . 1980: Dec. P 1979: Jan Feb Mar Jutv Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec " 1 Reserves of depository institutions series reflect actual reserve requirement percentages with no adjustment to eliminate the effect of changes in Regulations D and M. Prior to November 13, 1980, the date of implementation of the Monetary Control Act, only the reserves of commercial banks that were members of the Federal Reserve System were included in the series. Since that date the series include the reserves of all depository institutions. In conjunction with the implementation of the act, required reserves of member banks were reduced about $4.3 billion and required reserves of other depository institutions were increased about $1.4 billion. Effective October 11, 1979, an 8 percentage point marginal reserve requirement was imposed on "managed liabilities". This action raised required reserves about $320 million. Effective March 12, 1980, the 8 percentage point marginal reserve requirement was raised to 10 percentage points. In addition the base upon which the marginal reserve requirement was calculated was reduced. This action increased required reserves about $1.7 billion in the week ending April 2, 1980. Effective May 29, 1980, the marginal reserve requirement was reduced from 10 to 5 percentage points and the base upon which the marginal reserve requirement was calculated was raised. This action reduced required reserves about $980 million in the week ending June 18, 1980. Effective July 24, 1980, the 5 percent marginal reserve requirement on managed liabilities and the 2 percent supplementary reserve requirement against large time deposits were removed. These actions reduced required reserves about $3.2 billion. 2 Reserve balances with Federal Reserve Banks plus vault cash at institutions with required reserve balances plus vault cash equal to required reserves at other institutions. 3 Includes reserve balances at Federal Reserve Banks in the current week plus vault cash held two weeks earlier used to satisfy reserve requirements at all depository institutions plus currency outside the U.S. Treasury, Federal Reserve Banks, the vaults of depository institutions, and surplus vault cash at depository institutions. 4 Reserve aggregates series have been adjusted to remove discontinuities associated with the implementation of the Monetary Control Act,5 marginal reserve requirements, the inclusions of Edge Act Corporation reserves, and other changes in Regulations D, K, and M. Reserve measures beginning November reflect increases in required reserves associated with the reduction of weekend avoidance activities of a few large banks. The reduction in these activities leads to essentially a one-time increase in the average level of required reserves that need to be held for a given level of deposits entering the money supply. In November, this increase in required reserves is estimated at $550 to $600 million. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 307 TABLE B-65.—Bond yields and interest rates, 1929-80 [Percent per annum] Corporate bonds (Moody's) U.I>. Treasury securities Bills (new issues)» Year or month 36month month Constant maturities2 3 years Aaa Baa 10 years Highgrade Prime Newhome mercial pal mortgage bonds yields 3 paper, (Stand- (FHLBB) months ard & Poor's) Prime rate charged by banks* Discount rate, Federal Reserve Bank of Federal funds rate* York4 4 73 5 90 4 27 5.85 5'/fe-6 5.16 1933 . 0 515 4.49 7.76 4.71 1.73 iy 2 -4 2.56 1939... 023 3.01 4.96 2.76 .59 1.50 1.00 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 .014 .103 326 .373 375 2.84 2.77 2 83 2.73 2.72 4.75 4.33 4 28 3,91 3.61 2 50 210 2 36 2 06 186 .56 .53 66 .69 .73 1.50 1.50 1.50 1.50 1.50 6 1.00 8 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 .375 .375 .594 1.040 1.102 2.62 2.53 2.61 2.82 2.66 3.29 3.05 3.24 3.47 3.42 167 164 2 01 2 40 2.21 .75 .81 1.03 1.44 1.49 1.50 1.50 lVfe-1% l%-2 2.00 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1.218 1.552 1766 1931 .953 2.47" * 2 85 2.40 1.63 2.62 2.86 2.96 3.20 2.90 3.24 3.41 3.52 3.74 3.51 1.98 2.00 2.19 2.72 2 37 1.45 2.16 2.33 2.52 1.58 2.07 2.56 3.00 3.17 3.05 1.59 1.75 1.75 1.99 1.60 1.753 2.658 3.267 1.839 3.405 3.832 2.47 3.19 3.98 2.84 4.46 2.82 3.18 3.65 3.32 4.33 3.06 3.36 3.89 3.79 4.38 3.53 3.88 4.71 4.73 5.05 2.53 2.93 3.60 3.56 3.95 2.18 3.31 3.81 2.46 3.97 3.16 3.77 4.20 3.83 4.48 1.89 2.77 3.12 2.15 3.36 1.78 2.73 3.11 1.57 3.30 2 928 2 378 2.778 3.157 3 549 3.247 2.605 2.908 3.253 3.686 3.98 3.54 3.47 3.67 4.03 4.12 3.88 3.95 4.00 4.19 4.41 4.35 4.33 4.26 4.40 5.19 5.08 5.02 4.86 4.83 3 73 3.46 3.18 3.23 3.22 5.89" 5.82 3.85 2.97 3.26 3.55 3.97 4.82 4.50 4.50 4.50 4.50 3.53 3.00 3.00 3.23 3.55 3.22 1.96 2.68 3.18 3.50 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 3 954 4.881 4.321 5 339 6 677 4.055 5.082 4.630 5.470 6.853 4.22 5.23 5.03 5.68 7.02 4.28 4.92 5.07 5.65 6.67 4.49 5.13 5.51 6.18 7.03 4.87 5.67 6.23 6.94 7.81 3.27 3.82 3.98 4.51 5.81 5.81 6.25 6.46 6.97 7.80 4.38 5.55 5.10 5.90 7.83 4.54 5.63 5.61 6.30 7.96 4.04 4.50 4.19 5.16 5.87 4.07 5.11 4.22 5.66 8.20 1970 1971 1972... 1973 1974 6.458 4 348 4.071 7 041 7.886 6.562 4.511 4.466 7.178 7.926 7.29 5.65 5.72 6.95 7.82 7.35 6.16 6.21 6.84 7.56 8.04 7.39 7.21 7,44 8.57 9.11 8.56 8.16 8.24 9.50 6.51 5.70 5.27 5,18 6.09 8.45 7.74 7.60 7.95 8.92 7,72 5.11 4.69 8.15 9.87 7.91 5.72 5.25 8.03 10.81 5.95 4.88 4.50 6.44 7.83 7.18 4.66 4.43 8.73 10.50 1975 1976 1977, . .! 1978 1979 5.838 6.122 4.989 5.266 5 265 5.510 7,221 7.572 10.041 10.017 7.49 6.77 6.69 8.29 9.71 7.99 7.61 7.42 8.41 9.44 8.83 8.43 8.02 8.73 9,63 10.61 9.75 8.97 9.49 10.69 6.89 6.49 5.56 5.90 6.39 9.01 8.99 9.01 9.54 10.77 6.33 5.35 5.60 7.99 7 10.91 7.86 6.84 6.83 9.06 12.67 6.25 5.50 5.46 7.46 10.28 5.82 5.05 5.54 7.93 11.19 1980 11.506 11.374 11.55 11.46 11.94 13.67 8.51 12.65 12.29 15.27 11.77 13.35 1929 . 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959... . .. 1960. . 1961 ... 1962... 1963 1964 . . . . . See next page for continuation of table. 308 1.00 1.00 1.00 M.00 6 1.00 •1.00 1.00 1.34 1.50 TABLE B-65.—Bond yields and interest rates, 1929-80—Continued [Percent per annum] Corporate bonds (Moody's) U.S. Treasury securities Year or month (new issues)' Constant maturities 2 Aaa Highgrade municipal bonds (Standard & Poor's) Prime commercial paper. Prime rate charged by banks* months month month 3 years 10 years 6.448 6.457 6.319 6.306 6.430 6.707 6.685 6.740 6.644 6.700 7.019 7.200 7.61 7.67 7.70 7.85 8.07 8.30 7.96 8.03 8.04 8.15 8.35 8.46 8.41 8.47 8.47 8.56 8.69 8.76 9.17 9.20 9.22 9.32 9.49 9.60 5.60 5.51 5.49 5.71 5.97 6.13 9.15 9.18 9.26 9.30 9.37 9.46 6.79 6.80 6.80 6.86 7.11 7.63 7% -8 8 -8 8 -8 8 -8 8 -8*4 8*4 -9 7.074 7.036 7.836 8.132 8.787 9.122 7.471 7.363 7.948 8.493 9.204 9.397 8.54 8.33 8.41 8.62 9.04 9.33 8.64 8.41 8.42 8.64 8.81 9.01 8.69 8.69 8.89 9.03 9.16 9.60 9.48 9.42 9.59 9.83 9.94 6.18 5.98 5.93 5.95 6.03 6.33 9.57 9.70 9.73 9.83 9.87 10.02 7.91 7.90 8.44 9.03 10.23 10.43 9 -9 9 -9% 9y 4 - 9 % 9%-ioy* 10*4-11*4 11*4-11% 9.351 9.265 9.457 9.493 9.579 9.045 9.501 9.349 9.458 9.498 9.531 9.062 9.50 9.29 9.38 9.43 9.42 8.95 9.10 9.10 9.12 9.18 9.25 8.91 9.25 9.26 9.37 9.38 9.50 9.29 10.13 10.08 10.26 10.33 10.47 10.38 6.25 6.19 6.16 6.14 6.10 5.99 10.18 10.20 10.30 10.36 10.47 10.66 10.32 10.01 9.96 9.87 9.98 9.71 9.262 9.450 10.182 11.472 11.868 12.071 9.190 9.450 10.125 11.339 11.856 11.847 8.94 9.14 9.69 10.95 11.18 10.71 8.95 9.03 9.33 10.30 10.65 10.39 9.20 9.23 9.44 10.13 10.76 10.74 10.29 10.35 10.54 11.40 11.99 12.06 6.05 6.10 6.40 6.98 7.19 7.09 10.78 11.01 11.02 11.21 11.37 11.64 9.82 10.39 11.60 13.23 7 13.26 12.80 Jan Feb.. Mar.. Apr. May .. June.. 12.036 12.814 15.526 14.003 9.150 6.995 11.851 12.721 15.100 13.618 9.149 7.218 10.88 12.84 14.05 12.02 9.44 8.91 10.80 12.41 12.75 11.47 10.18 9.78 11.09 12.38 12.96 12.04 10.99 10.58 12.42 13.57 14.45 14.19 13.17 12.71 7.21 8.04 9.09 8.40 7.37 7.60 11.87 11.93 12.62 13.03 13.68 12.66 12.66 13.60 16.50 14.93 9.29 8.03 July Aug 8.126 9.259 10.321 11.580 13.888 15.661 8.101 9.443 10.546 11.566 13.612 14.770 9.27 10.63 11.57 12.01 13.31 13.65 10.25 11.10 11.51 11.75 12.68 12.84 11.07 11.64 12.02 12.31 12.97 13.21 12.65 13.15 13.70 14.23 14.64 15.14 8.62 8.95 9.11 9.55 10.09 12.48 12.25 12.35 12.61 13.04 13.27 8.29 9.61 11.04 12.32 14.73 16.49 1978: Jan.. Feb.. Mar... t: June . July... Aug... Sept Oct.. Nov. Dec . 1979* Jan.. Feb. Mar.. t. June.. July... Aug.. Sept. Oct.. Nov... Dec... n%-u% im-n% n%-n% 3 H /4-ll% 11%-11% 11%-llH 11*4-11% 13*4-15 155 Discount rate, Federal Reserve Bank of New York 4 6 -6*4 SY2 -BV2 6% 6y 2 6y 2 7 -6*4 -6*4 -7 -7 7 -7y 4 1% - 7 % 7% -8 8 -8% 9 9 Federal funds rate* 6.70 6.78 6.79 6.89 7.36 7.60 7.81 8.04 8.45 8.96 9.76 10.03 -9*4 -9*4 -9*4 -9*4 9 Ms -9Y2 10.07 10.06 10.09 10.01 10.24 10.29 9*4-10 10 -10*4 10*4-11 U -12 12 -12 12 -12 10.47 10.94 11.43 13.77 13.18 13.78 12 12 13 13 13 12 -12 -13 -13 -13 -12 -11 13.82 14.13 17.19 17.61 10.98 9.47 11 10 10 11 11 12 -10 -10 -11 -11 -12 -13 9.03 9.61 10.87 12.81 15.85 18.90 9*4 9*4 9*4 9y* 1980: Oci SP-:Nov Dec 1 2 3 15%16% 16%-19*4 19*4-19*4 18*6-14 14 -12 12 -11 11 -11*4 U%-13 14*4-17% 17%-21*4 Rate on new issues within period; bank-discount basis. Yields on the more actively traded issues adjusted to constant maturities by the Treasury Department. Effective rate (in the primary market) on conventional mortgages, reflecting fees and charges as weft as contract rate and assuming on the average, repayment at end of 10 years. Rates beginning January 1973 not strictly comparable with prior rates. 4 Average effective rate for the year, except for prime rate for 1929-33 and 1947-48, which are ranges of the rate in effect during the5 period; opening and closing rate for the month. Since July 19, 1975, the daily effective rate is an average of the rates on a given day weighted by the volume of transactions at these rates. Prior to that date, the daily effective rate was the rate considered most representative of the day's transactions, usually the6 one at which most transactions occurred. From October 30, 1942, to April 24, 1946, a preferential rate of 0.50 percent was in effect for advances secured by Government securities maturing in 1 year or less. 7 Beginning November 1979, data are for 6-months paper. 8 On May I , range of 18*4-19 was in effect. Sources: Department of the Treasury, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Federal Home Loan Bank Board (FHLBB), Moody's Investors Service, and Standard & Poor's Corporation. 309 TABLE B-66—Consumer credit outstanding and net change, 1950-80 [Millions of dollars] Amount outstanding (end of month) Year and month 1950: Dec. 1951: Dec. 1952: Dec 1953: Dec. 1954: Dec 1955: Dec. 1956: Dec 1957: Dec.. 1958: Dec. 1959: Dec . I960: Dec 1961: Dec 1962: Dec 1963: Dec 1964: Dec 1965: Dec. 1966: Dec 1967: Dec . 1968: Dec 1969: Dec 1970: 1971: 1972: 1973: 1974: 1975: 1976: 1977: 1978: 1979: Dec Dec Dec . Dec. Dec , Dec. Dec. Dec... Dec... Dec. Installment credit > Total 25,641 27,268 32,551 36,736 38,192 45,348 49,268 52,191 52,702 60,741 65,104 67,635 73,917 82,805 92,591 103,207 109,749 115,430 126,949 137,742 143,113 157,795 177,639 203,077 213,427 223,140 248,916 289,133 337,713 380,528 Total Automobile Revolving 2 6,015 15,503 5,958 16,220 7,635 20,470 9,685 24,254 9,747 24,891 30,269 13,471 14,484 33,171 35,443 15,472 14,258 35,339 16,632 41,123 18,083 45,051 46,027 17,599 50,994 19,924 57,829 22,842 65,572 25,817 73,881 29,355 79,339 30,992 83,148 31,131 91,681 34,348 2,105 101,161 36,946 3,720 105,528 36,325 5,128 8,528 118,255 40,519 133,173 47.862 9,700 155,108 53,772 11,709 164,594 54,266 13,681 171,996 57,242 15,019 193,525 67,707 17,189 230,564 82,911 39,274 273,645 101,647 48,309 312,024 116,362 56,937 Mobile home 3 Other 2,461 7,226 9,526 13,580 14,642 14,434 14,573 14,945 15,235 16,838 9,488 10,262 12,835 14,569 15,144 16,798 18,687 19,971 21,081 24,491 26,968 28,428 31,070 34,987 39,755 44,526 48,347 52,017 55,228 60,495 61,614 61,982 66,085 76,047 82,005 85,301 94,056 93,434 108,454 121,887 Net change from preceding period Noninstallment credit * 10,138 11,048 12,081 12,482 13,301 15,079 16,097 16,748 17,363 19,618 20,053 21,608 22,923 24,976 27,019 29,326 30,410 32,282 35,268 36,581 37,585 39,540 44,466 47,969 48,833 51,144 55,391 58,569 64,068 68,504 Installment credit l Total Total Automobile Noninstallment credit * 3,271 717 4,250 1,677 3,784 2,050 637 62 5,378 3,724 2,902 1,013 2,272 988 - 1 0 4 -1,214 5,784 2,374 1,518 910 1,033 401 819 1,778 1,018 651 615 2,255 4,363 2,531 6,282 8,888 9,786 10,616 6,542 5,681 11,519 10,793 3,928 976 4,967 6,835 7,743 8,309 5,458 3,809 8,533 9,480 1,451 -484 2,325 2,918 2,975 3^38 1,637 139 3,217 2,598 435 1,555 1,315 2,053 2,043 2,307 1,084 1,872 2,986 1,313 5,371 14,682 19,844 25,438 10,350 9,713 25,776 40,217 48,580 42,815 4,367 12,727 14,918 21,935 9,486 7,402 21,529 37,039 43,081 38,379 -621 4,194 7,343 5,910 494 2,976 10,465 15,204 18,736 14,715 1,004 1,955 4,926 3,503 864 2,311 4,247 3,178 5,499 4,436 4,789 1,627 5,283 4,185 1,456 7,156 3,920 2,923 511 8,039 Seasonally adjusted 6 1979: Jan. Feb.. Mar... May. June. July.. Aug. Sept. Oct Nov Dec. 1980: Jan Feb Mar... ft June. July. Aug a.. Nov.. 337,603 338,995 342,678 346,864 352,096 356,241 359,020 364,224 368,545 371,644 375,268 380,528 273,863 274,770 277,321 281,191 285,717 289,928 293,151 298,006 301,978 304,370 307,336 312,024 102,419 47,800 103,511 47,068 105,456 46,770 107,188 47,245 109,279 47,855 111,121 48,545 112,187 48,918 113.685 50,304 115,190 51,230 115,668 51,928 116,102 53,270 116,362 56,937 15,401 15,601 15,855 15,925 16,107 16,236 16,318 16,487 16,584 16,718 16,793 16,838 108,243 108,594 109,240 110,833 112,476 114,026 115,728 117,530 118,974 120,056 121,171 121,887 63,740 64,221 65,357 65,673 66,379 66,313 65,869 66,218 66,567 67,274 67,932 68,504 5,602 5,897 5,383 5,288 3,748 2,322 4,214 4,220 3,350 3,809 3,166 2,611 2,031 1,681 1,579 1,388 1,140 3,118 3,524 5,234 4,705 3,410 2,608 2,816 2,731 4,008 3,033 2,694 2,033 816 871 1,713 954 794 1,014 1,226 1,672 716 575 378,277 377,046 376,334 374,491 371,732 370,018 371,917 374,172 375,526 376,151 311,012 310,149 309,127 307,831 305,788 304,399 303,853 305,763 306,926 307,222 308,051 116,719 117,202 117,642 117,502 117,058 116,456 116,125 116,868 116,781 116,657 116,517 16,832 16,875 16,944 16,974 16,912 16,988 17,004 17,068 17,113 17,276 17,293 121,205 120,803 120,272 119,665 118,593 117,913 117,688 118,056 118,626 118,691 118,937 67,265 66,897 67,207 66,660 65,944 65,619 1,959 2,517 1,277 -3,827 -4,102 -1,961 2,727 1,538 2,403 982 654 513 = 1,671 -^643 = 2,677 -1,041 -2,045 = 1,026 -=768 114 623 -2,156 -1,425 84 68,064 68,409 68,600 68,929 -544 835 1,009 524 -717 355 84 201 245 655 346 =46 = 178 56,256 55,269 54,269 53,690 53,225 53,042 53,036 53,771 54,406 54,598 55,304 1 -1,199 489 1,055 702 839 1,388 1,677 2,033 1,479 582 289 302 793 Installment credit covers most short- and intermediate-term credit extended to individuals through regular business channels, usually to finance the purchase of consumer goods and services or to refinance debts incurred for such purposes, and scheduled to be repaid (or with the option of repayment) in two or more installments. 2 Consists of credit cards at retailers, gasoline companies, and commercial banks, and check credit at commercial banks. Prior to 1968, included in "other," except gasoline companies, included in noninstallment credit prior to 1971. Beginning 1977, includes openend credit at retailers, previously included in ''other. Also beginning 1977, some retail credit was reclassified from commercial into consumer credit. Credit secured by real estate is generally excluded. 3 Not reported separately prior to July 1970. 4 Because of inconsistencies in the data and infrequent benchmarking, series on noninstallment credit is no longer published by the Federal Reserve Board on a regular basis. Data are shown here as a general indication of trends. 6 For installment credit, computed as the difference between extensions and liquidations (both seasonally adjusted); see also Table B 67, For noninstallment credit, computed as the change from one month to another in the seasonally adjusted amount outstanding. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 310 TABLE B-67—Consumer installment credit extended and liquidated, 1930-80 [Millions of dollars; monthly data seasonally adjusted] Total Year or month Liquidated Automobile Extended Liquidated 22,130 18,861 24,583 23,867 30,616 26,355 32,579 28,794 32,265 31,625 40,263 34,882 40,886 37,899 43,101 40,759 41,138 41,290 49,134 43,395 8,445 8,951 11,610 12,740 11,741 16,732 15,572 16,554 14,287 18,008 1960 1961 1962 1963 .. 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968. .. 1969 50,827 47,022 50,598 49,735 57,562 52,601 64,660 57,822 72,445 64,616 79,918 71,616 83,821 78,365 89,058 85,194 101,426 92,075 109,422 99,945 18,112 16,477 20,164 22,617 24,792 27,913 27,844 27,623 32,228 33,686 1970 . 1971 . 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 115,132 138,046 151,749 173,035 172.765 180,083 210,740 257,600 297,668 324777 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955. 1956 1957 1958 1959 1979: Jan Feb... Mar .. June. July . Aug... Sept... Oct .. Dec . . 1980: Jan Feb Mar iday" June. ... July Aug Sept Oct Extended Revolving» Extended Mobile home 2 Extended Liquidated Other Extended Liquidated 6,906 9,008 9,932 10,689 11,679 13,008 14,559 15,567 15,501 15,638 13,685 15,632 19,006 19,839 20,524 23,531 25,314 26,547 26,026 31,126 11,955 14,859 16,423 18,105 19,946 21,874 23,340 25,192 25,789 27,757 16,661 16,960 17,840 19,699 21,815 24,386 26,206 27,482 29,013 31,090 32,715 34,121 37,398 42,043 47,653 52,005 55,977 61,435 65,717 69,554 30,361 32,775 34,761 38,123 42,801 47,230 52,159 57,712 60,386 64,288 478 74,980 1,754 76,957 2,975 78,267 4,184 87,666 4,720 87,250 4,536 86,381 4,720 98,204 5,341 88,651 5,126 99,150 4,868 104,231 71,188 72,705 72,246 78,238 81,294 83,079 89,417 75,012 84,128 90,796 3,481 6,182 Liqui- 2,726 4,567 110,352 30,857 31,414 8,689 7,278 127,789 36,706 32,512 21,862 20,818 136,787 43,702 38,081 24,659 23,485 152,817 49,606 43,696 28,702 26,699 163,276 46,514 46,019 33,213 31,243 172,675 52,420 49,444 36,956 35,616 189,179 63,743 53,278 43,934 41,764 222,138 75,641 60,437 87,596 81,348 254,589 87,981 69,245 105,125 96,090 286,396 ,93,901 79,186 ll20,174 1111546 612 2,521 5,121 7,061 5,788 4,326 4,859 5,712 5,412 6,471 22,368 23,003 22,823 23,121 24,429 23,620 7,924 7,90S 7,789 7,955 8,100 7,427 5,893 6,224 6,210 6,567 6,960 6,439 9,553 9,871 9,533 9,724 9,941 9,919 8,716 8,989 8,877 8,891 9,164 9,326 613 675 615 496 609 498 323 399 414 431 424 430 8,492 8,772 8,236 8,755 8,945 8,387 7,436 7,391 7,322 7,232 7,881 7,425 27,108 24,292 27r593 24,862 28,109 24,101 27,712 24,679 26,895 24,201 26,638 24,605 7,586 7,802 8,380 7,814 7,470 7.735 6,770 9,949 6,931 10,303 6,667 10,356 6,860 10,439 6,676 10,500 6.721 10,146 9,442 9,494 9,610 9,579 9,781 9.745 492 527 507 531 488 453 430 413 411 405 398 368 9,081 8,961 8,866 8,928 8,437 8.304 7,650 8,024 7,413 7,835 7,346 7771 27,923 27,581 25,881 23,220 22,093 22,349 25,196 25,178 25,227 24,891 24,770 24,394 8,441 7,973 7,372 5,922 5,533 5,550 6,903 6,991 6,859 6,565 6,574 6,576 10,500 10,756 10,634 10,347 10,302 10,341 9,971 10,034 10,373 10,677 10,589 10,436 522 452 435 397 299 424 418 397 380 383 349 366 8,460 8,400 7,440 6,554 5,959 6,034 7,904 7,756 7,615 7,266 7,258 7,016 23,997 26,176 27,064 27,365 25,991 25,196 25,687 26,009 26,663 25,152 6,068 7,400 7,518 7,544 7,117 6,785 7,045 7,434 7,343 6,872 10,679 10,700 11,143 11,124 10,953 10,641 10,419 10,665 10,851 10,688 377 415 442 513 424 363 382 399 372 400 6,873 7,661 7,961 8,184 7,497 7,407 7,841 7511 8,097 7,192 26,582 27,223 26,173 26,930 27,595 26,231 1 Consists of credit cards at retailers, gasoline companies, and commercial banks, and check credit at commercial banks. Prior to 1968, included in "other," except gasoline companies included in noninstallment credit prior to 1971. Beginning 1977, includes openend credit at retailers, previously included in other. Also beginning 1977, some retail credit was reclassified from commercial into consumer credit. Credit secured by real estate is generally excluded. 2 Not reported separately prior to July 1970. Note.—Installment credit covers most short- and intermediate-term credit extended to individuals through regular business channels, usually to finance the purchase of consumer goods and services or to refinance debts incurred for such purposes, and scheduled to be repaid (or with the option of repayment) in two or more installments. Liquidated credit includes repayments, chargeoffs, and other credit. See also Table B-66. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 311 TABLE B-68.—Mortgage debt outstanding by type of property and of financing, 1939-80 [Billions of dollars] Nonfarm properties by type of mortgage Nonfarm properties End of year or quarter All properties Conventional3 Government underwritten properties Total Multi- Com1- to 4- family family prop- mercial proper- Total2 houses erties ties' 1- to 4-family houses Total VA FKA guarinsured anteed Total 1-to 4family houses 1939 35.5 6.6 28.9 16.3 5.6 7.0 1.8 1.8 1.8 27.1 14.5 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 36.5 37.6 36.7 35 3 34.7 6.5 6.4 6.0 54 4.9 30.0 31.2 30.8 299 29.7 17.4 18.4 18.2 17 8 17.9 5.7 5.9 5.8 58 5.6 6.9 7.0 6.7 6.3 6.2 2.3 3.0 3.7 4.1 4.2 2.3 3.0 3.7 4.1 4.2 2.3 3.0 3.7 41 4.2 27.7 28.2 27.1 25.8 25.5 15.1 15.4 14.5 13.7 13.7 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 35.5 41.8 48.9 56.2 62.7 4.8 49 5.1 5.3 5.6 30.8 36.9 43.9 50.9 57.1 18.6 230 28.2 33.3 37.6 5.7 61 6.6 7.5 8.6 4.3 6.3 9.8 13.6 17.1 4.3 6.1 9.3 12.5 15.0 4.1 3.7 3.8 5.3 6.9 0.2 2.4 5.5 7.2 8.1 72.8 82.3 91.4 101.3 113.7 6.1 6.7 7.2 7.7 8.2 66.7 75.6 84.2 93.6 105.4 45.2 51.7 58.5 66.1 75.7 10.1 11.5 12.3 12.9 1.3.5 22.1 26.6 29.3 32.1 36.2 18.9 22.9 25.4 28.1 32.1 8.6 9.7 10.8 12.0 12.8 10.3 13.2 14.6 16.1 19.3 26.5 30.6 34.1 37.3 40.0 44.6 49.0 54.9 61.5 69.2 14.3 16.9 18.9 20.8 22.6 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 6.4 7.7 9.1 10.2 10.8 11.5 12.5 13.4 14.5 16.3 26.3 28.8 33.1 38.0 43.6 1955 1956 1957 1958.. . 1959. . 129.9 144.5 156.5 171.8 190.8 120.9 134.6 1461 160.7 1787 88.2 99.0 107 6 117.7 1309 14.3 14.9 153 16.8 18 7 18.3 20.7 23.2 26.1 29.2 42.9 47,8 516 55.1 593 38.9 43.9 47 2 50.1 538 14.3 15.5 165 19.7 23 8 24.6 28.4 30 7 30.4 30 0 78.0 86.8 94.6 105.5 119.4 49.3 55.1 604 67.6 77 0 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 207.5 228.0 251.4 278.5 305.9 9.0 9.8 10.4 11.1 121 12.8 13.9 15.2 16.8 18.9 194.7 214.1 236.2 261.7 287.0 141.9 154.7 169.3 186.4 203.4 20.3 23.0 25.8 29.0 33.6 32.4 36.4 41.1 46.2 50.0 62.3 65.6 69.4 73.4 77.2 56.4 59.1 62.2 65.9 69.2 26.7 29.5 32.3 35.0 38.3 29.7 29.6 29.9 30.9 30.9 132.3 148.5 166.9 188.2 209.8 85.5 95.6 107,1 120.5 134.1 1965 1966 1967.. .. 1968.. 1969 333.3 356.5 381.2 410.9 441.4 21.2 23.1 25.1 27.4 29.2 312.1 333.4 356.1 383.5 412.2 220.5 232.9 247.3 264.8 282.8 37.2 40.3 43.9 47.3 52.3 54.5 60.1 64.8 71.4 77.1 81.2 84.1 88.2 93.4 100.2 73.1 76.1 79.9 84.4 90.2 42.0 44.8 47.4 50.6 54.5 31.1 31.3 32.5 33.8 35.7 231.0 249.3 267.9 290.1 312.0 147.4 156.9 167.4 180.4 192.7 1970 1971.. 1972.. 1973 1974 474.2 526.5 603.4 682.3 742.5 30.3 32.2 35.8 41.3 46.3 443.8 494.3 567.7 641.1 696.2 298.1 328.3 372.2 416.2 449.4 60.1 70.1 82.8 93.1 100.0 85.6 95.9 112.7 131.7 146.9 109.2 120.7 131.1 135.0 140.2 97.3 105.2 113.0 116.2 121.3 59.9 65.7 68.2 66.2 65.1 37.3 39.5 44.7 50.0 56.2 334.6 373.5 436.5 506.0 556.0 200.8 223.1 259.2 300.0 328.1 801.5 889.2 1,023.5 1,172.8 1,333,6 50.9 57.0 65.8 76.2 92.4 750.7 832.2 957.7 1,096.6 1.241.2 490.8 556.5 656.6 761.8 872.1 100.6 104.5 111.8 122.0 130.7 159.3 171.2 189.3 212.7 238.4 147.0 154.1 161.7 176.4 199.0 127.7 133.5 141.6 153.4 172.9 66.1 66.5 68.0 71.4 81.0 603.7 61.6 678.0 67.0 795.9 73.6 920.2 82.0 92.0 1,042.2 363.0 422.9 515.0 608.5 699.1 1,051.7 1,092.2 1,133.5 1,172.8 68.1 70.9 73.8 76.2 983.7 1,021.4 1,059.7 1,096.6 676.4 706.3 734.8 761.8 113.7 116.4 119.4 122.0 193.6 198.7 205.6 212.7 165.3 167.4 174.7 176.4 144.7 146.7 150.7 153.4 68.6 69.2 69.9 71.4 76.1 77.6 80.8 82.0 818.4 853.9 885.1 920.2 531.7 559.6 584.0 608.5 III III... IV 1,206.2 1,252.4 1,295.9 1,333.6 80.2 85.1 89.2 92.4 1,126.0 1,167.4 1,206.8 1,241.2 784.5 817.0 846.3 872.1 124.0 125.9 128.3 130.7 217.5 224.5 232.2 238.4 183.0 187.1 194.3 199.0 158.4 162.2 168.2 172.9 73.9 76.4 79.1 81.0 84.5 943.1 85.8 980.3 89.2 1,012.5 92.0 1,042.2 626.2 654.7 678.1 699.1 1980: 1 II.... III... 1,363.8 1,386.3 1,149.2 97.0 101.4 104.3 1,266.8 1,285.0 1,314.9 891.2 904.2 926.2 132.1 133.6 136.0 243.5 247.1 252.7 207.5 210.8 180.8 184.1 86.0 87.4 99.4 94.8 1,059.2 96.7 1,074.1 710.3 720.1 1975 1976.. 1977.. 1978.. 1979.. . . 1978: III™ IV... 1979: "' . 1 2 3 Includes negligible amount of farm loans held by savings and loan associations. Includes FHA insured multifamily properties, not shown separately. Derived figures. Total includes multifamily and commercial properties, not shown separately. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, based on data from various Government and private organizations. 312 TABLE B-69-—Mortgage debt outstanding by bolder, 1939-80 [Billions of dollars] Major financial institutions End of year or quarter Total Total Savings and loan associations Mutual savings banks Other holders Commercial banks1 Life insurance companies Federal and related agen-2 cies Individuals and others 1939 35.5 18.6 3.8 4.8 4.3 5.7 5.0 11.9 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 36.5 37.6 36.7 353 347 19.5 20.7 20.7 20 2 20.2 4.1 4.6 4.6 46 4.8 4.9 4.8 4.6 4.4 4.3 4.6 4.9 4.7 4.5 4.4 6.0 6.4 6.7 67 6.7 4.9 4.7 4.3 3.6 3.0 12.0 12.2 117 115 11.5 1945 1946 1947 1948. 1949 35.5 41.8 48.9 56.2 62.7 21.0 26.0 31.8 37.8 42.9 5.4 7.1 8.9 10.3 11.6 4.2 4.4 4.9 5.8 6.7 4.8 7.2 9.4 10.9 11.6 6.6 7.2 87 10.8 12.9 2.4 2.0 1.8 1.8 2.3 12.1 13.8 15.3 16.6 17.5 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 72.8 82 3 91.4 101.3 113.7 51.7 59 5 66.9 75.1 85.7 13.7 156 18.4 22.0 26.1 8.3 9.9 11.4 12.9 15.0 13.7 14 7 15.9 16.9 18.6 16.1 19.3 21.3 23.3 26.0 2.8 3.5 4.1 4.6 4.8 18.4 19 3 20.4 217 23.2 1955 1956 .... . 1957 1958. 1959 . 129.9 144.5 156.5 171.8 190.8 99.3 111.2 119.7 131.5 145.5 31.4 35.7 40.0 45.6 53.1 17.5 19.7 21.2 23.3 25.0 21.0 22.7 23.3 25.5 28.1 29.4 33.0 35.2 37.1 39.2 5.3 6.2 77 8.0 10.2 25.3 27.1 29.1 32.3 35.1 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 207.5 228.0 251.4 278.5 305.9 157.6 172.6 192.5 217.1 241.0 60.1 68.8 78.8 90.9 101.3 26.9 29.1 32.3 36.2 40.6 28.8 30.4 34.5 39.4 44.0 41.8 44.2 46.9 50.5 55.2 11.5 12.2 12.6 11.8 12.2 38.4 43.1 46.3 49.5 527 1965 . . . 1966 1967 1968 1969 . . 333.3 356.5 381.2 410.9 441.4 264.6 280.8 298.8 319.9 339.1 110.3 114.4 121.8 130.8 140.2 44.6 47.3 50.5 53.5 56.1 49.7 54.4 59.0 65.7 70.7 60.0 64.6 67.5 70.0 72.0 13.5 17.5 20.9 25.1 31.1 55.2 58.2 61.4 65.9 71.2 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 474.2 526.5 603.4 682.3 742.5 355.9 394.2 450.0 505.4 542.6 150.3 174.3 206.2 231.7 249.3 57.9 62.0 67.6 73.2 74.9 73.3 82.5 99.3 119.1 132.1 74.4 75.5 76.9 81.4 86.2 38.3 46.4 54.6 64.8 82.1 79.9 85.9 98.9 112.2 117.8 801.5 889 2 1,023.5 1,172.8 1,333.6 581.2 647 5 745.0 848.1 939.5 278.6 323 0 381.2 432.8 475.8 77.2 816 881 95.2 98.9 136.2 1513 179.0 214.0 246.0 89.2 916 96.8 106.2 118.8 101.0 116 6 140.3 170.5 216.6 119.3 1251 138.2 154.2 177.5 I! Ill IV. 1,051.7 1,092.2 1,133.5 1,172.8 764.6 793.8 822.0 848.1 392.4 407.9 420.9 432.8 89.8 91.5 93.4 95.2 184.4 194.5 205.4 214.0 97.9 99.9 102.2 106.2 146.0 152.6 161.4 170.5 141.2 145.8 150.2 154.2 1979: | II . . Ill IV 1,206.2 1,252.4 1,295.9 1,333.6 866.0 894.4 920.2 939.5 441.4 456.5 468.3 475.8 96.1 97.2 97.9 98.9 220.1 229.6 239.6 246.0 108.4 111.1 114.4 118.8 181.2 192.4 203.8 216.6 159.0 1657 171.9 177.5 1,363.8 1,386.3 1,419.2 951.9 958.9 977.5 479.1 481.2 492.1 99.2 99.2 99.3 251.2 253.1 258.0 122.5 125.5 128.1 228.8 238.4 246.1 183.2 189.1 1957 1975 1976 1977 1978 .. 1979 1978. 19801 . 1! Ill ... 1 Includes loans held by nondeposit trust companies, but not by bank trust departments. "Includes Includes former Federal National Mortgage M o g a g e Association Assciation (FNMA) ( N M A ) and new Govement Government National Mortgage Association Associaton (GNMA), as well F d l Housing H i A dmiitti V t a Administration, Adiitati Pbli H i A d m i i t t i o Farmers F H d m i i t t i o n and d iin earlier li Administration, Veterans Public Housing Administration, Home A Administration, as Federal yyea r s Reconstruction Finance Corporation, Homeowners Loan Corporation, and Federal Farm Mortgage Corporation. Also includes GNMA Pools and U.S.-sponsored agencies such as new FNMA, Federal Land Banks, and Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation. Other U.S. agencies (amounts small or current separate data not readily available) included with "individuals and others. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, based on data from various Government and private organizations. 313 GOVERNMENT FINANCE TABLE B-70.—Federal budget receipts, outlays, and debt,fiscalyears 1971-82 [Millions of dollars; fiscal years] Actual Description 1971 Transition quarter 1972 1973 1974 1975 208,649 232,225 264,932 280,997 300,005 81,773 . 148,846 161,357 92,193 72,959 -13,156 -21,325 181,219 104,846 -21,133 187,505 118,590 -25,098 201,099 133,695 -34,789 54,085 32,071 =4,383 1976 BUDGET RECEIPTS AND OUTLAYS: Total receipts Federal funds Trust funds Interfund transactions... Total outlays Federal funds Trust funds Total Interfund surplus ortransactions... deficit ( - ) Federal funds Trust funds 188,392 133,785 66,193 -11,586 211,425 232,021 247,074 269,620 326,151 366,418 94,728 163,651 59,360 -11,586 178,110 67,067 -13,156 186,951 81,448 -21,325 199,918 90,835 -21,133 240,081 111,168 -25,098 269,921 131,286 -34,789 65,088 34,023 -4,383 -23,033 -23,373 -14,849 -4,688 -45,154 -66,413 »12,956 -29,866 6,833 -29,264 5,892 -25,594 10,745 -18,699 14,011 -52,576 7^22 -68,822 2,409 -11,004 = 1,952 OUTSTANDING DEBT, END OF PERIOD: Gross Federal debt 409,467 437,329 468,426 486,247 544,131 631,866 646,379 Held by Government agencies Held by the public 105,140 304,328 113,559 323,770 140,194 346,053 147,225 396,906 151,566 480,300 148,052 498,327 Federal Reserve System 65,518 238,810 71,426 252,344 125,381 343,045 75,181 267,863 80,648 265,405 84,993 311,913 94,714 385,586 96,702 401,625 188,392 208,649 232,225 264,932 280,997 300,005 81,773 86,230 26,785 48,578 16,614 3,735 2,591 94,737 32,166 53,914 15,477 5,436 3,287 103,246 36,153 64,542 16,260 4,917 3,188 118,952 38,620 76,780 16,844 5,035 3,334 122,386 40,621 86,441 16,551 4,611 3,676 131,603 41,409 92,714 16,963 5,216 4,074 38,801 8,460 25,760 4,473 1,455 1,212 3,533 325 3,252 381 3,495 426 4,845 524 5,777 934 5,451 2,575 1,500 112 211,425 232,021 247,074 269,620 326,151 366,418 94,728 75,808 4,097 4,180 1,031 3,909 4,288 2,358 8,050 2,916 76,550 4,693 4,173 1,270 4,235 5,280 2,216 8,388 3,422 74,541 4,066 4,030 1,179 4,763 4,852 924 9,065 4,595 77,781 5,681 3,977 837 5,670 2,227 3,925 9,172 4,134 85,552 6,922 3,989 2,169 7,336 1,659 5,607 10,388 3,738 89,430 5,552 4,370 3,127 8,124 2,504 3,792 13,435 4,767 22,307 2,193 1,161 794 2,532 581 1,392 3,304 1,340 9,839 14,716 55,426 9,776 1,299 2,020 535 19,602 12,519 17,467 63,913 10,730 1,650 2,415 673 20,563 12,735 18,832 72,965 12,013 2,131 2,568 7,351 22,782 12,344 22,073 84,437 13,386 2 462 3,243 6,890 28,032 15,870 27,648 108,576 16,597 2,942 3,133 7,187 30,911 18,737 33,448 127,390 18,432 3,320 2,948 7,235 34,511 5,162 8,721 32,797 3,962 859 883 2,092 7,216 -8,427 -8,137 -12,318 -16,651 -14,075 -14,704 -2,567 -2,611 - 4,765 -2,768 -5,089 -279 -2,927 -5,436 -3,956 -3,319 -6,583 -6,748 -3,980 -7,667 -4,242 -7,800 -985 -270 -2,428 -2,662 -1,311 Other BUDGET RECEIPTS Individual income taxes, Corporation income taxes Social insurance taxes and contributions Excise taxes Estate and gift taxes Customs duties.. Miscellaneous receipts: Deposits of earnings by Federal Reserve System .... Allother BUDGET OUTLAYS National defense International affairs General science, space, and technology Energy.. Natural resources and environment. Agriculture Commerce and housing credit... Transportation Community and regional development. Education, training, employment, and social services Health Income security Veterans benefits and services Administration of justice. . . General government. ... General purpose fiscal assistance. Interest Allowances Undistributed offsetting receipts Composition of undistributed offsetting receipts: Employer share, employee retirement, Interest received by trust funds. ... Rents and royalties on the Outer Continental Shelf 1,051 See next page for continuation of table. 314 TABLE B-70.—Federal budget receipts, outlays, and debt,fiscalyears 1971-82—Continued [Millions of dollars; fiscal years] Actual Description Estimate 1978 1979 357,762 401,997 465,940 520,050 607,525 711,780 241,312 152,763 -36,313 270,484 168,012 -36,498 316,351 189,641 -40,052 350,849 213,875 -44,674 415,239 242,545 -50,259 484,105 286,113 -58,437 402,710 450,804 493,635 579,613 662,740 739,296 295,756 143,267 -36,313 331,985 155,318 -36,498 362,381 171,305 -40,052 419,214 205,074 -44,674 474,932 238,068 -50,259 530,817 266,916 -58,437 -44,948 -48,807 -27,694 -59,563 -55,215 -27,516 -54,444 9,496 -61,804 12,694 -46,030 18,335 -68,364 8,801 -59,693 4,477 -46,712 19,196 709,138 780,425 833,751 914,317 992,398 1,057,664 157,295 551,843 169,477 610,948 115,480 495,468 199,212 715,105 120,846 594,259 205,293 787,105 105,004 446,839 189,162 644,589 115,594 528,996 357,762 401,997 465,940 520,050 607,525 711,780 157,626 54,892 108,688 17,548 7,327 5,150 180,988 59,952 123,410 18,376 5,285 6,573 217,841 65,677 141,591 18,745 5,411 7,439 244,069 64,600 160,747 24,329 6,389 7474 284,013 66,009 184,824 44,393 6,909 331,677 64,648 214,664 69,633 7,668 7,800 5,908 622 6,641 772 8,327 910 11,767 975 13,069 899 14,710 402,710 450,804 493,635 579,613 662,740 739,296 97,501 4,813 4,677 4,172 10,000 5,532 98 14,636 6,348 20,985 38,785 137,900 18,038 3,600 3,169 9,499 38,009 105,186 5,922 4,742 5,861 10,925 7,731 3,324 15,445 11,070 26,463 43,676 146,181 18,974 3,802 3,706 9,601 43,966 117,681 6,091 5,041 6,856 12,091 6,238 2,565 17,459 9,542 29,685 49,614 160,159 19,928 4,153 4,093 8,372 52,556 135,856 10,733 5,722 6,313 13,812 4,762 7,782 21,120 10,068 30,767 58,165 193,100 21,183 4,570 4,505 8,584 64,504 161,088 11,314 6,258 8,739 14,110 1,112 3,456 24,054 11,144 31,773 66,032 231,650 22,591 4,786 5,170 6,854 80,405 -15,053 -15,772 -18,488 -21,933 -27,796 184,399 12,152 7,590 11,973 14,039 4,803 8,058 21,551 9,084 34,511 74,636 255,006 24,462 4,882 5,246 6,902 89,946 1,920 -31,863 -4,548 -8,131 -2,374 -4,983 -8,530 -2,259 -5,271 -9,950 -3,267 -5,787 -12,045 -4,101 -6,561 -13,435 -7,800 -6,798 -15,165 -9,900 1977 1980 1981 1982 BUDGET RECEIPTS AND OUTLAYS; Total receipts Federal funds Trust funds Interfund transactions. Total outlays.. Federal funds Trust funds Interfund transactions Total surplus or deficit ( - ) . . Federal funds... Trust funds OUTSTANDING DEBT, END OF PERIOD: Gross Federal debt Held by Government agencies Held by the public Federal Reserve System., Other ' BUDGET RECEIPTS.... Individual income taxes Corporation income taxes Social insurance taxes and contributions Excise taxes Estate and gift taxes Customs duties Miscellaneous receipts: Deposits of earnings by Federal Reserve System.. Another .. BUDGET OUTLAYS... National defense International affairs General science, space, and technology Energy Natural resources and environment Agriculture Commerce and housing credit Transportation Community and regional development Education, training, employment, and social services.. Health Income security Veterans benefits and services Administration of justice General government General purpose fiscal assistance Interest Allowances \ Undistributed offsetting receipts Composition of undistributed offsetting receipts: Employer share, employee retirement Interest received by trust funds Rents and royalties on the Outer Continental Shelf.. .J.439 225,559 832,105 Note.—Under provisions of the Congressional Budget Act of 1974, the fiscal year for the Federal Government shifted beginning with fiscal year 1977. Through fiscal year 1976, the fiscal year was on a July 1-June 30 basis. Beginning October 1976 (fiscal year 1977), the fiscal year is on an October 1-September 30 basis. The period July 1,1976 through September 30,1976 is a separate fiscal period known as the transition quarter. Refunds of receipts are excluded from receipts and outlays. See "Budget of the United States Government, Fiscal Year 1982" for additional information. Sources: Department of the Treasury and Office of Management and Budget. 315 TABLE B-l\.—Federal budget receipts and outlays, fiscal years 1929-82 [Millions of dollars] Fiscal year Receipts Outlays Surplus or deficit ( - ) 1929 3,862 3,127 734 1933 1,997 4,598 -2,602 1939. 4,979 8,841 -3,862 1940 1941.. . 1942 ... 1943. 1944... 6,361 8,621 14,350 23,649 44,276 9,456 13,634 35,114 78,533 91,280 -3,095 -5,013 -20,764 -54,884 =-47,004 1945 . . 1946 . 1947 . 1948. . 1949 1950. .. 1951. 1952. 1953 1954 . .. 45,216 39,327 38,394 41,774 39,437 92,690 55,183 34,532 29,773 38,834 -47,474 -15,856 3,862 12,001 603 39,485 51,646 66,204 69,574 69,719 42,597 45,546 67,721 76,107 70,890 -3,112 6,100 -1,517 -6,533 = 1,170 1955 .. 1956 . 1957 1958.. 1959. 65,469 74,547 79,990 79,636 79,249 68,509 70,460 76,741 82,575 92,104 -3,041 4,087 3,249 -2,939 -12,855 1960 1961 . 1962 1963 . 1964 . 92,492 94,389 99,676 106,560 112,662 92,223 97,795 106,813 111,311 118,584 269 -3,406 -7,137 -4,751 -5,922 1965 1966 1967. .. 1968 1969... 116,833 130,856 149,552 153,671 187,784 118,430 134,652 158,254 178,833 184,548 -1,596 -3,796 -8,702 -25,161 3,236 1970 1971. .. 1972 1973 1974 193,743 188,392 208,649 232,225 264,932 196,588 211,425 232,021 247,074 269,620 -2,845 -23,033 -23,373 =-14,849 -4,688 1975 1976 Transition quarter. 1977 .. 1978 1979 280,997 300,005 81,773 357,762 401,997 465,940 326,151 366,418 94,728 402,710 450,804 493,635 -45,154 -66,413 -12,956 -44,948 1980. 1981' 1982» 520,050 607,525 711,780 579,613 662,740 739,296 . . - 48,807 - 27,694 -59,563 -55,215 -27,516 1 Estimates. Note.—Under provisions of the Congressional Budget Act of 1974, the fiscal year for the Federal Government shifted beginning with fiscal year 1977. Through fiscal year 1976, the fiscal year was on a July 1-June 30 basis; beginning October 1976 (fiscal year 1977), the fiscal year is on an October 1-September 30 basis. The 3-month period from July 1, 1976 through September 30, 1976 is a Oata for 1929-39 are according to the administrative budget and those beginning 1940 according to the unified budget. Refunds of receipts are excluded from receipts and outlays. See "Budget of the United States Government, Fiscal Year 1982" for additional information. Sources: Department of the Treasury and Office of Management and Budget. 316 TABLE B-72.—Relation of Federal Government receipts and expenditures in the national income and product accounts to the unified budget,fiscalyears 1980-82 [Billions of dollars; fiscal years] Estimate Receipts and expenditures 1980 1981 1982 520.0 607.5 711.8 8.6 4.0 -4.4 -1.2 9.7 6.4 10.3 -8.0 -1.5 .3 .2 527.3 614.4 728.2 RECEIPTS Total budget receipts.... Government contribution for employee retirement (grossing) Other netting and grossing Adjustment to accruals Geographic exclusions Other Federal sector, national income and product accounts, receipts 6.3 1.1 -1.5 EXPENDITURES Total budget outlays 579.6 662.7 739.3 Lending and financial transactions Government contribution for employee retirement (grossing). ... Other netting and grossing Defense timing adjustment Bonuses on Outer Continental Shelf land leases Geographic exclusions Other..... -10.3 8.6 4.0 -6.1 -6.8 10.3 Federal sector, national income and product accounts, expenditures.. -2.3 -4.5 -.8 9.7 6.4 -.9 5.2 -4.9 -1.1 -5.3 -1.3 578.2 671.0 746.3 22 6.3 6.1 Note.—See Note, Table B-71. See Special Analysis B, "Special Analyses, Budget of the United States Government, Fiscal Year 1982" for description of these categories. Sources: Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic Analysis), Department of the Treasury, and Office of Management and Budget: 317 TABLE B-73.—Government receipts and expenditures, national income and product accounts, 1929-80 [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Calendar year or quarter Receipts Expenditures State and local government Federal Government Total government Surplus or deficit (-). national income and product accounts Receipts Expenditures Surplus or deficit <-), national Receipts income and product accounts Surplus or deficit Expenditures national income and product accounts 1929 11.3 10.3 1.0 3.8 2.6 1.2 7.6 7.8 =0.2 1933 9.3 10.7 -1.4 2.7 4.0 -1.3 7.2 7.2 =.1 1939 15.4 17.6 -2.2 6.7 8.9 -2.2 9.6 9.6 .0 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 .. . 1947 1948 1949 17.7 25.0 32 6 49.2 51.2 53.2 510 56.9 58.9 55.9 18.4 28.8 64.0 93.3 103.0 92.7 45.6 42.5 50.5 59.3 -.7 = 3.8 =31.4 =44.1 -51.8 =39.5 5.4 14.4 8.4 =3.4 8.6 15.4 22 9 39.3 410 42.5 391 43.2 43.2 38.7 10.0 20.5 56.1 85.8 95.5 84.6 35.6 29.8 34.9 41.3 = 1.3 = 5.1 -33.1 -46.6 -54.5 42.1 3.5 13.4 8.3 =2.6 10.0 10.4 10.6 10.9 11.1 11.6 13.0 15.4 17.7 19.5 9.3 9.1 88 8.4 8.5 9.0 11.1 14.4 17.6 20.2 .6 1.3 1.8 2.5 2.7 2.6 1.9 1.0 .1 = .7 1950 1951 1952 1953 . . . . 1954 1955 , 1956 1957 1958 ... 1959 69.0 85 2 90.1 94.6 89.9 101.1 109 7 116.2 115.0 129.4 61.0 79.2 93.9 101.6 97.0 98.0 104 5 115.3 127.6 131.0 8.0 61 =3.8 =6.9 -7.1 3.1 52 .9 = 12 6 = 1.6 50.0 64 3 67.3 70 0 63.7 72.6 78 0 81.9 78 7 89.8 40.8 57.8 71.1 77.1 69.8 68.1 71.9 79.6 88.9 91.0 9.2 6.5 -3.7 -7.1 -6.0 4.4 61 2.3 = 10 3 = 1.1 21.3 23.4 25.4 27.4 29.0 31.7 35.0 38.5 42.0 46.4 22.5 23 9 25.5 27.3 30.2 32.9 35 9 , 39.8 44 3 46.9 = 1.2 = .4 -.0 ,1 = 1.1 -1.3 g -1.4 -2.4 -.4 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 139.5 144.8 156.7 168.5 174.0 188.3 212.3 228.2 263.1 296.7 136.4 149.1 160.5 167.8 176.3 187.8 213.6 242.4 269.1 286.8 3.1 -4.3 -3.8 .7 -2.3 .5 = 13 -14.2 -6.0 9.9 96.1 98.1 106.2 114.4 114.9 124.3 1418 150.5 174.4 196.9 93.1 101.9 110.4 114.2 118.2 123.8 143.6 163.7 180.5 188.4 3.0 = 3.9 =4.2 -13 .5 -18 = 13.2 =6.0 8.4 49.9 54.0 58.5 63.2 69.5 75.1 84.8 93.6 107.3 120.2 49.8 54.4 58.0 62.8 68.5 75.1 84 3 94.7 107.2 118.7 .1 -.4 .5 .5 1.0 --.0 .5 -1.1 .1 1.5 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 .. 1979 302.8 322.6 368.3 413.1 455.2 470.5 538.4 605 7 6816 765.2 313.4 342.0 371.6 405.3 460.0 534.3 574.9 624.0 681.9 753.2 -10.6 = 19.4 = 33 7.8 -4.7 -63.8 -36.5 = 18 3 - 2 11.9 191.9 198.6 227 5 258.6 287.8 287.3 331.8 3751 4315 494.4 204.3 220.6 244 3 264.2 299.3 356.6 384.8 421.5 460 7 509.2 -12.4 -22.0 -16 8 = 5.6 -11.5 = 69.3 = 53.1 =46.4 —29 2 = 14.8 135.4 153.0 178 3 195.0 211.4 237.7 267.8 298.0 327 4 351.2 133.5 150.4 164 8 181.6 204.6 232.2 251.2 270.0 298 4 324.4 1.9 2.6 13.5 13.4 6.8 5.5 16.6 28.1 29 0 26.7 1980" 834.2 869.0 = 34.8 538.9 601.2 = 62.3 382.6 355.0 27.6 1978: I H Ill IV 640.7 674.2 691.2 720.5 658.4 669.3 690.0 709.7 -17.7 49 1.1 10.8 398.6 423 6 440.9 462.7 447.4 451 1 463.7 480.6 =48.8 -27 4 =22.8 -17.9 316.9 328 0 327.2 337.7 285.8 295 7 303.3 309.0 31.1 32 3 23.9 28.7 1979: I II lit IV 739.7 750.9 775.3 794.7 721.7 737.0 764.0 790.3 18.1 13.9 11.3 4.4 477.0 485.9 500.6 514.0 488.4 494.0 515.8 538.6 -11.5 =8.1 -=15.2 -24.5 340.9 342.7 355.4 365.6 311.4 320.8 328.9 336.7 29.5 21.9 26.5 28.9 1980: I || Ill 815.0 807.6 839.9 824.6 850.2 885.6 =9 6 -42.5 =45.6 528 4 520.9 540.8 564 7 587.3 615.0 36 3 66.5 -74.2 3721 373.9 386.8 345 4 350.0 358.2 26 6 23.9 28.5 ... .. . Note.—Federal grants-in-aid to State and local governments are reflected in Federal expenditures and State and local receipts. Total government receipts and expenditures have been adjusted to eliminate this duplication. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 318 TABLE B-74.—Federal Government receipts and expenditures, national income and product accounts, 1958-82 [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Expenditures Receipts Transfer payments Year or quarter Fiscal year: 2 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 . . 1968 . . 1969 . . 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 3 1981 . . 1982 V Calendar year: 1958 1959. I960.. 1961 1962 1963 1964 J965 1966 ..„ 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 .. . 1972 1973 1974 1975 .. .. 1976 1977 1978. . 1979.... 1980* 1979: I II Ill IV 1980: I II*""" Tota! Indirect Personal Corporate business tax and profits tax and nontax nontax tax receipts accruals accruals SubsiGrantsdies PurContriin-aid less chases butions to Net current of for State 1 intersurplus To and est of social Total goods and To local paid governinsurserv- persons foreigners government ance ices ments enterprises 52.6 58.9 71.5 84.2 91.9 101.0 116.2 133.4 152.7 171.3 194.8 226.3 82.8 91.2 91.3 98.1 106.2 111.7 117.2 118.5 132.7 154.9 172.2 184.6 195.5 212.9 232.7 255.7 278.2 328.8 370.7 411.7 450.5 494.7 578.2 671.0 746.3 51.1 54.8 52.9 55.8 61.0 63.7 65.9 64.6 72.4 86.0 95.0 98.0 97.1 94.9 100.6 101.1 104.5 117.9 125.1 140.3 1507 163.4 190.2 218.5 248.7 40.4 12.4 14.9 17.6 18.3 20.5 23.1 24.0 25.0 33.1 36.7 40.7 46.7 49.3 54.4 62.7 79.5 89.8 94.1 106.5 118.5 137.2 159.0 172.2 88.9 91.0 93.1. 101.9* 110.4 114.2 118.2 123.8 143.6 163.7 180.5 188.4 204.3 220.6 244.3 264.2 299.3 356.6 384.8 421.5 460.7 509.2 601.2 53.9 53.9 53.7 57.4 63.7 64.6 65.2 67.3 78.8 90.9 98.0 97.6 957 96.2 101.7 102.0 111.0 122.7 129.2 143.9 153.4 167.9 198.9 75.3 73.5 75.3 74.3 29.4 29.4 29.3 29.6 155.5 157.4 159.9 163.0 494.0 515.8 538.6 164.8 163.6 165.1 178.1 80.5 60.9 66.7 31.9 38.7 42.9 169.2 169.3 171.8 564.7 587.3 615.0 190.0 1987 194.9 78.1 85.4 94.8 95.0 104.0 110.0 115.6 120.0 132.7 146.0 159.9 189.8 194.8 192.4 213.4 240.7 271.6 283.4 314.9 365.9 414.2 480.7 527.3 614.4 728.2 36.3 38.2 42.5 43.6 47.3 49.6 50.7 51.4 57.5 64.4 71.4 90.2 94.0 87.9 100.5 107.4 122.7 127.5 137.2 166.4 186.4 223.1 249.7 290.5 339.3 17.9 21.4 22.3 20.0 22.7 23.3 25.7 27.1 30.8 30.3 33.1 36,8 32.9 31.9 34.2 41.2 43.4 41.8 52.5 58,8 67.2 75.8 70.6 67.9 78.8 11.6 12.0 13.2 13.3 14.2 15.0 15.6 16.9 15.5 15.8 17.1 18.6 19.2 20.0 19.9 20.7 21.4 22.2 24.4 24.5 27.2 29.1 35.7 61.2 83.8 78.7 89.8 96.1 98.1 106.2 114.4 114.9 124.3 141.8 150.5 174.4 196.9 191.9 198.6 227.5 258.6 287.8 287.3 331.8 375.1 431.5 494.4 538.9 36.8 39.9 43.6 44.7 48.6 51.5 48.6 53.9 61.7 67.5 79.7 95.1 92.6 90.3 108.2 1147 131.3 125.8 147.3 170.1 194.9 231.4 11.5 12.5 13.4 13.6 14.6 15.3 16.2 16.5 15.6 16.3 18.0 19.0 19.3 20.4 20.0 21.2 21.7 23.9 23.4 25.0 28.1 29.4 258.0 18.0 22.5 21.4 21.5 22.5 24.6 26.1 28.9 31.4 30.0 36.1 36.1 30.6 33.5 36.6 43.3 45.1 43.6 54.6 61.6 71.2 74.6 68.3 477.0 485.9 500.6 514.0 216.7 225.7 236.2 247.1 528.4 520.9 540.8 246.9 252.0 259.4 12.3 13.9 16.7 18.1 19.9 22.1 23.6 24.5 28.9 35.5 38.3 44.2 48.8 1 2 4.7 6.2 6.9 6.9 7.6 8.3 9.8 10.9 12.7 14.8 17.8 19.2 22.6 26.8 32.6 40.4 41.6 101.8 131.4 153.8 166.6 178.7 197.8 2347 276.8 308.7 1.7 1.8 1.8 2.1 2.1 2.1 2.2 2.2 2.3 2.2 2.1 2.2 2.0 2.3 2.8 27 3.0 3.1 3.0 3.2 3.5 4.0 4.6 4.7 5.2 66.3 74.7 79.1 867 90.3 94.6 19.6 20.1 21.6 25.0 25.6 27.0 27.9 30.3 33.5 40.1 46.0 50.6 61.3 727 80.5 93.3 114.5 146.3 158.8 169.6 181.8 204.9 1.8 1.8 1.9 2.1 2.2 2.2 2.2 2.2 2.3 2.2 2.1 2.1 2.2 2.6 2.7 2.6 3.2 3.1 3.2 3.2 3.8 4.2 5.6 6.8 6.5 7.2 8.0 9.1 10.4 11.1 14.4 15.9 18.6 20.3 24.4 29.0 37.5 40.6 43.9 54.6 61.1 67.5 77.3 80.4 245.2 4.5 17.8 19.9 20.6 23.6 25.1 26.5 27.4 28.4 31.8 37.2 42.7 487 55.0 67.7 76.1 87.2 48.4 57.5 5.4 5.6 6.8 6.4 6.4 7.1 77 8.2 87 9.6 10.4 11.9 13.5 14.0 14.0 157 19.6 217 25.2 28.4 33.5 40.6 51.2 67.3 75.1 2.4 2.5 2.4 3.3 4.1 4.0 4.1 4.3 4.8 5.2 4.1 4.7 5.5 7.0 6.5 9.2 7.6 6.0 6.2 7.0 9.6 9.8 10.8 13.4 14.0 87.3 29.1 35.2 42.3 53.4 2.8 2.1 2.6 4.0 4.2 3.9 4.5 4.6 5.5 47 4.5 5.2 6.5 6.3 7.9 7.8 5.5 6.9 5.8 8.2 9.3 9.4 12.1 192.5 197.5 212.8 216.8 78.2 77.8 80.8 84.9 40.0 42.0 42.9 44.4 8.5 9.2 10.5 9.5 224.4 232.2 260.4 85.5 87.2 87.7 50.3 54.4 53.5 10.1 11.0 137 5.2 6.2 6.8 6.2 6.8 7.3 8.0 8.4 9.2 9.8 11.3 12.7 14.1 13.8 14.4 18.0 20.7 23.1 26.8 Includes an item for the difference between wage accruals and disbursements, not shown separately. Under provisions of the Congressional Budget Act of 1974, the fiscal year for the Federal Government shifted beginning with fiscal: year 1977. Through fiscal year 1976, the fiscal year was on a July 1-June 30 basis; beginning October 1976 [fiscal year 1977), the fiscal year is on an October 1-September 30 basis. The 3-month period from July 1, 1976 through September 30, 1976 is a separate fiscal period known as the transition quarter. 3 Estimates. Sources: Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic Analysis) and Office of Management and Budget. 319 TABLE B-75.—State and local government receipts and expenditures, national income and product accounts, 1946-80 [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Expenditures Receipts Calendar year or quarter Total Personal tax and nontax receipts Corpo- Indirect Contribubusiness rate tions for tax and profits social nontax tax insurance accruals accruals Federal grantsin-aid Totall Surplus or Subsideficit dies TransNet Purless national fer interest chases current income paypaid of surplus and ments less goods of product to diviand govern- accounts perdends services sons received ment enterprises 1946 1947 1948 1949... 13 0 15.4 177 19.5 1.5 17 2.1 2.4 0.5 .6 7 .6 9.3 107 12.2 13.3 0.6 !8 .9 1.1 17 2.0 2.2 11.1 14.4 17.6 20.2 9.9 12.8 15.3 18.0 1.7 2.3 3.0 3.0 0.2 .1 .1 .1 -0.7 -.8 -.8 =.9 1.9 1.0 .1 -7 1950 1951 1952 1953... 1954 21.3 23.4 25.4 27.4 29.0 2.5 2.8 3.0 3.2 3.5 .8 .9 .8 .8 .8 14.6 15.9 17.4 18.8 19.9 1.1 1.4 1.6 1.7 2.0 2.3 2.5 2.6 2.8 2.9 22.5 23.9 25.5 27.3 30.2 19.8 21.8 23.2 25.0 27.8 3.6 3.1 3.3 3.5 3.6 .1 .0 .0 .0 .1 -.9 -1.0 -1.1 -1.2 -1.3 -1.2 -.4 ~!l -1.1 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959.... 31.7 35.0 38.5 42.0 46.4 3.9 4.5 5.0 5.4 6.1 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.2 21.6 23.8 25.7 27.2 29.3 2.1 2.3 2.6 2.8 3.1 3.1 3.3 4.2 5.6 6.8 32.9 35.9 39.8 44.3 46.9 30.6 33.5 37.1 41.1 43.7 3.8 3.9 4.3 4.8 5.1 .1 .1 .1 .1 .1 = 1.5 -1.6 -1.7 -17 -2.0 -1.3 =.9 -1.4 = 2.4 = .4 1960 1961 1962 1963. 1964 49.9 54.0 58.5 63 2 69.5 6.7 7.4 8.2 88 10.0 1.2 1.3 1.5 17 U 32.0 34.4 37.0 39 4 42.6 3.4 3.7 3.9 4.2 4.7 6.5 7.2 8.0 91 10.4 49.8 54.4 58.0 62 8 68.5 46.5 50.8 54.3 59 0 64.6 5.4 5.8 6.0 6.4 6.9 .1 .1 .1 .1 -2.2 -2.3 -2.5 -2 8 -2.8 .1 „_ 4 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 75.1 84 8 93.6 107.3 120.2 10.9 12 8 U.S 17.5 20.6 2.0 22 2.5 3.1 3.4 46.1 49 7 54.0 60.9 67.6 5.0 57 6.7 7.2 8.3 11.1 14 4 15.9 18.6 20.3 75.1 84 3 94.7 107.2 118.7 71.1 79 8 89.3 101.0 111.2 7.3 81 9.4 10.5 12.2 -.3 _7 -.9 -1.1 -1.4 =3.0 =3 0 -3.1 -3.2 =•3.3 -.0 5 -1.1 .1 1.5 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 135.4 153.0 178,3 195.0 211.4 23.2 26.4 32.8 36.0 39.0 3.5 4.1 5.0 5.8 6.5 75.0 83.3 91.5 99.7 107.4 9.2 10.2 11.5 13.0 14.6 24.4 29.0 37.5 40.6 43.9 133.5 150.4 164.8 181.6 204.6 124.4 138.7 151.4 168.5 193.1 147 17.3 19.3 207 20.9 -2.0 -1.7 -1.9 -3.3 -5.0 -3.6 -3.7 -4.2 -4.3 —4.4 1.9 2.6 13.5 13.4 6.8 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 237 7 267.8 298.0 327.4 351.2 431 49.6 56.4 63.9 70.6 71 9.3 11.0 117 13.0 116 2 128.3 141.0 149.9 159.0 16 8 19.5 22.1 24.6 28.1 54 6 61.1 67.5 77.3 80.4 232 2 251.2 270.0 298.4 324.4 217 2 232.9 250.6 279.2 305.9 24 6 27.6 29.7 32.8 35.0 = 51 =4.5 -5.2 -7.7 -10.3 —45 -4.8 -5.1 -5.7 -6.3 55 16.6 28.1 29.0 26.7 1980 * 382.6 807 11.9 171.2 31.5 87.3 355.0 335.9 38.9 -12.4 -7.4 27.6 1978: 1 II Ill IV 316.9 328.0 327.2 337.7 60.6 63.0 64.9 67.1 10.2 118 12.0 13.0 147.7 1516 148.5 152.0 23.5 24 1 24^9 25.8 74.8 77 5 76.9 79.9 285.8 295 7 303.3 309.0 266.2 276 0 284.2 290.6 317 32 7 33.3 33.5 -6.6 =7 3 -8.0 -8.7 -5.5 57 -5.8 -5.9 31.1 32 3 23^9 28.7 Ill IV 340.9 342.7 355.4 365.6 67.7 67.8 72.3 747 13.2 12.9 13.1 12.9 155.1 156.4 160.6 163.9 26.8 27.9 28.6 29.2 78.2 77.8 80.8 84.9 311.4 320.8 328.9 336.7 293.4 301.6 310.4 318.3 33.8 34.5 35.4 36.4 -9.4 =9.9 -10.6 -11.2 =6.0 -6.2 -6.5 -67 29.5 21.9 26.5 28.9 1980: | II Ill 372.1 373 9 386.8 76.2 78.3 82.1 137 106 117 167.0 167 7 173.0 29.6 302 32.3 85.5 87 2 87.7 345.4 350 0 358.2 326.8 3313 338.6 37.2 381 39.7 -11.8 — 12 2 -127 =7.0 -72 -7.5 26.6 23 9 28.6 is .5 1.0 1979: nil. .. 1 Includes an item for the difference between wage accruals and disbursements, not shown separately. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 320 TABLE B-76.—State and local government revenues and expenditures, selected fiscal years, 1927-79 [Millions of dollars] General expenditures by function 2 Genera) revenues by source2 Fiscal year 1 Total Property taxes Sales and Individgross ual reincome ceipts taxes taxes Corpo- Revenue ration from All net Federal income Govern- others taxes ment Total Education Highways Public welfare All other 4 1927 7,271 4,730 470 70 92 116 1,793 7,210 2,235 1,809 151 3,015 1932 1934 1936 1938 7,267 7,678 8,395 9,228 4,487 4,076 4,093 4,440 752 1,008 1,484 1,794 74 80 153 218 79 49 113 165 232 1,016 948 800 1,643 1,449 1,604 1,811 7,765 7,181 7,644 8,757 2,311 1,831 2,177 2,491 1,741 1,509 1,425 1,650 444 889 827 1,069 3,269 2,952 3,215 3,547 1940 1942 1944 1946 1948 9,609 10,418 10,908 12,356 17,250 4,430 4,537 4,604 4,986 6,126 1,982 2,351 2,289 2,986 4,442 224 276 342 422 543 156 272 451 447 592 945 858 954 855 1,861 1,872 2,123 2,269 2,661 3,685 9,229 9,190 8,863 11,028 17,684 2,638 2,586 2,793 3,356 5,379 1,573 1,490 1,200 1,672 3,036 1,156 1F225 1,133 1,409 2,099 3,862 3,889 3,737 4,591 7,170 1950 1952 1953 1954 20,911 25,181 27,307 29,012 7,349 8,652 9,375 9,967 5,154 6,357 6,927 7,276 788 998 1,065 1,127 593 846 817 778 2,486 2,566 2,870 2,966 4,541 5,763 6,252 6,897 22,787 26,098 27,910 30,701 7,177 8,318 9,390 10,557 3,803 4,650 4,987 5,527 2,940 2,788 2,914 3,060 8,867 10,342 10,619 11,557 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 31,073 34,667 38,164 41,219 45,306 10,735 11,749 12,864 14,047 14,983 7,643 8,691 9,467 9,829 10,437 1,237 1,538 1,754 1,759 1,994 744 890 984 1,018 1,001 3,131 7,584 3,335 8,465 3,843 9,250 4,865 9,699 6,377 10,516 33,724 36,711 40,375 44,851 48,887 11,907 13,220 14,134 15,919 17,283 6,452 6,953 7,816 8t567 9,592 3,168 3,139 3,485 3,818 4,136 12,197 13,399 14,940 16,547 17,876 1960 1961 1962 1963 50,505 54,037 58,252 62,890 16,405 18,002 19,054 20,089 11,849 12,463 13,494 14,456 2,463 2,613 3,037 3,269 1,180 1,266 1,308 1,505 6,974 7,131 7,871 8,722 11,634 12,563 13,489 14,850 51,876 56,201 60,206 64,816 18,719 20,574 22,216 23,776 9,428 9,844 10,357 11,136 4,404 4,720 5,084 5,481 19,325 21,063 22,549 24,423 1962-63 5 1963-64« 1964-65 6 62,269 68,443 74,000 19,833 21,241 22,583 14,446 15,762 17,118 3,267 3,791 4,090 1,505 1,695 1,929 8,663 14,556 10,002 15,951 11,029 17,250 63,977 69,302 74,546 23,729 26,286 28,563 11,150 11,664 12,221 5,420 5,766 6,315 23,678 25,586 27,447 1965-66* 1966-67 5 1967-68 5 1968-69 5 1969-708 83,036 91,197 101,264 114,550 130,756 24,670 26,047 27,747 30,673 34,054 19,085 20,530 22,911 26,519 30,322 4,760 5,826 7,308 8,908 10,812 2,038 2,227 2,518 3,180 3,738 13,214 15,370 17,181 19,153 21,857 19,269 21,197 23,598 26,118 29,971 82,843 93,350 102,411 116,728 131,332 33,287 37,919 41,158 47,238 52,718 12,770 6,757 13,932 8,218 14,481 9,857 15,417 12,110 16,427 14,679 30,029 33,281 36,915 41,963 47,508 1970-718 1971-72* 1972-73= 1973-74« 1974-75° 144,927 166,352 190,214 207,670 228,171 37,852 42,133 45,283 47,705 51,491 33,233 11,900 37/488 15,237 42,047 17,994 46,098 19,491 49,815 21,454 3,424 4,416 5,425 6,015 6,642 26,146 31,253 39,256 41,820 47;034 32,374 35,826 40,210 46,541 51,735 150,674 166,873 181,227 198,959 230,721 59,413 64,886 69,714 75,833 87,858 18,095 19,010 18,615 19,946 22,528 18,226 21,070 23,582 25,085 28,155 54,940 61,907 69,316 78,096 92,180 1975-76^ 1976-77* 1977-78 5 1978-79* 256,176 285,796 315,960 343,278 57,001 62,535 66,422 64,944 54,547 60,595 67,596 74,247 24,575 29,245 33,176 36,932 7,273 9,174 10,738 12,128 55,589 62,575 69,592 75,164 57,191 61,673 68,436 79,864 256,731 97,216 274,388 102,805 296,983 110,758 327,517 119,448 23,907 23,105 24,609 28,440 32,604 35,941 39,140 41,898 103,004 112,537 122,476 137,731 1 2 Fiscal years not the same for all governments. See footnote 5. Excludes revenues or expenditures of publicly owned utilities and liquor stores, and of insurance-trust activities. Intergovernmental receipts and payments between State and local governments are also excluded. 3 Includes1 licenses and other taxes and charges and miscellaneous revenues. 4 Includes expenditures for health, hospitals, police, local fire protection, natural resources, sanitation, housing and urban renewal, local parks and recreation, general control, financial administration, interest on general debt, and unallocable expenditures. . 5 Data for fiscal year ending in the 12-month period through June 30. Data for 1963 and earlier years include local government amounts grouped in terms of fiscal years ended during the particular calendar year. Note.—Data are not available for intervening years. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 321 TABLE B-77,—Interest-bearing public debt securities by kind of obligation, 1967-80 [Millions of dollars] End of year or month public debt securities Fiscal year: 1967.. 1968 . 1969 322,286 344,401 351,729 1970 1971. 1972.. 1973.. 1974. 369,026 396,289 425,360 456,353 473,238 1975.. 1976.. 1977.. 1978 1979. 532,122 619,254 697,629 766,971 819,007 1980... 906,402 1979: June 789,502 791,249 792,344 795,434 803,816 799,863 July Aug Sept. Oct. Nov... Dec ... 806,508 812,095 819,007 825,736 832,730 843,960 Jan Feb Mar 1980: Jan. . Feb, Mar Apr. . May June.. July Aug Sept. Oct.... Nov.. 846,517 853,366 862,211 868,866 873,529 876,275 880,395 888,733 906,402 906,948 909,371 Nonmarketable Marketable Total interestTotal Bills * 210,672 226,592 226,107 58,535 64,440 68,356 76,154 86,677 94,648 100,061 105,019 128,569 161,198 156,091 160,936 161,378 49,108 71,073 78,946 93,489 104,807 113,419 117,840 128,419 150,257 191,758 241,692 267,865 274,242 232,599 245,473 257,202 262,971 266,575 315,606 392,581 443,508 485,155 506,693 594,506 199,832 310,903 496,529 497,976 500,400 504,585 506,867 499,343 506,994 509,187 506,693 515,033 519,573 530,731 159,938 160,489 161,378 161,692 165,100 172,644 535,658 540,636 557,493 564,869 567,560 566,735 175,522 177,422 190,780 195,296 195,387 184,684 576,145 583,419 594,506 599,406 605,381 191,491 199,306 199,832 202,309 208,721 162,286 162,416 165,459 163,730 163,076 159,890 Total Foreign GovernU.S. government savings ment and account bonds public series series 2 36,779 39,626 45,724 56,355 71,073 83,772 111,614 117,808 125,623 136,426 150,816 168,158 193,382 206,663 216,516 226,673 254,121 281,816 312,314 311,896 51,213 1,514 56,155 51,712 3,741 59,526 51,711 4,070 66,790 51,281 4,755 76,323 53,003 9,270 82,784 55,921 18,985 89,598 59,418 28,524 101,738 61,921 25,011 115,442 65,482 23,216 124,173 69,733 21,500 130,557 75,411 21,799 140,113 79,798 21,680 153,271 80,440 28,115 176,360 72,727 25,158 189,848 24,164 Treasury TreasuryI bonds notes 97,418 91,079 78,805 62,956 53,989 49,135 45,071 33,137 Other* 2,731 2,828 3,051 4,068 5,759 3,654 3,701 4,289 3,644 4,883 16,797 27,067 27,400 272,807 271,372 270,803 275,311 276,123 272,066 278,257 277,582 274,242 280,832 279,723 283,379 61,436 64,189 64,139 65,544 67,668 67,387 292,973 293,273 291,944 290,849 296,949 300,520 80,414 80,459 80,417 80,426 80,430 80,460 30,257 28,150 28,161 25,416 25,158 26,807 155,237 157,637 153,765 158,178 164,552 166,274 27,065 27,027 29,601 26,829 26,809 26,981 68,799 71,116 71,073 72,510 74,751 74,708 299,514 302,909 312,314 310,703 313,157 313,229 80,524 80,503 80,440 80,178 79,669 79,517 28,015 27,688 28,115 28,010 29,164 28,820 163,882 167,301 176,360 175,267 176,992 177,460 27,094 27,418 27,400 27,247 27,331 27,434 283,990 286,814 290,390 291,831 291,532 301,455 302,626 300,251 310,903 311,927 311,119 76,147 76,400 76,323 77,741 80,641 80,596 82,027 83,861 83,772 85,170 85,541 310,859 312,730 304,718 303,997 305,968 309,539 304,250 305,314 311,896 307,542 303,989 78,247 77,338 75,643 73,889 73,247 73,072 72,968 72,853 72,727 72,669 72,524 30,045 29,643 26,901 26,250 25,925 25,460 174,904 178,415 175,451 179,652 182,642 186,842 181,479 182,447 189,848 185,665 182,447 27,664 27,336 26,722 24,207 24,156 24,165 25,779 25,845 25,158 24,805 24,501 24,022 24,170 24,164 24,404 24,518 1 2 Includes Treasury bonds and minor amounts of Panama. Canal and postal savings bonds. Nonmarketable certificates of indebtedness, notes, bonds, and bills in the Treasury foreign series of dollar-denominated and foreigncurrency denominated issues. 3 Includes depository bonds, retirement plan bonds, Rural Electrification Administration bonds, State and local bonds, and special issues held only by U.S. Government agencies and trust funds and the Federal home loan banks. 4 Includes $5,610 million in certificates not shown separately. Note.—Through fiscal year 1976, the fiscal year was on a July 1 June 30 basis; beginning October 1976 (fiscal year 1977) the fiscal year is on an October 1-September 30 basis. Source: Department of the Treasury. 322 TABLE B-78.—Estimated ownership ofpublic debt securities, 1967-80 [Par values;' billions of dollars] Total public debt securities Held by private investors End of year or month Total^ Fiscal year: 1967 1968 1969 Held by Held by Govern- Federal Reserve Total 3 ment accounts Banks Mutual savings State and banks ComCorporalocal and mercial 6 govern-6 insurtions 4 banks ments ance companies MiscelIndilaneous viduals7 investors 3 - 8 322.9 345.4 352.9 71.8 76.1 84.8 46.7 52.2 54.1 204.4 217.0 214.0 55.5 59.7 55.3 13.2 12.5 11.6 11.0 12.0 11.1 23.6 25.1 26.4 70.4 74.2 77.3 30.7 33.4 32.3 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 370.1 397.3 426.4 457.3 474.2 95.2 102.9 111.5 123.4 138.2 57.7 65.5 71.4 75.0 80.5 217.2 228.9 243.6 258.9 255.6 52.6 61.0 60.9 58.8 53.2 10.4 10.3 10.2 9.6 8.5 8.5 7.4 9.3 9.8 10.8 29.0 25.9 26.9 28.8 28.3 81.8 754 73.2 75.9 807 35.0 491 63.2 76.0 74.2 1975 1976 . . . 1977 . 1978.. . 1979 1980 533.2 620.4 698.8 771.5 826.5 907.7 145.3 149.6 155.5 167.9 1877 197.7 84.7 94.4 104.7 115.3 115 5 1207 303.2 376.4 438.6 488.3 523.4 589.2 69.0 92.5 99.8 94.4 90.1 100.9 10.6 16.0 20.5 20.3 194 197 13.8 24.7 23.4 19.4 24.0 25.5 317 39.3 48.2 63.8 67.1 73.4 86.8 96.2 106.5. 113.9 115 5 123.0 91.3 1077 140.2 176.5 207 3 2467 790.5 792.2 796.8 796.4 804.8 804.9 167 7 170.1 166.3 170.7 177.0 178.5 1013 103.5 110.9 108.6 106.2 109.7 521.4 518.6 519.6 517.1 521.5 516.6 89.9 91.1 92.5 92.0 94.2 93.5 19.9 20.0 20.0 19.7 19.6 19.3 22.0 22.7 23.5 24.4 25.2 26.1 64.0 63.9 65.5 65.9 66.2 66.6 115 2 116.2 116.1 116.0 117.0 113.0 2104 204.7 202 0 199.1 199.3 198.1 807.5 813.1 826.5 826.8 833.8 845.1 176 2 178.6 187.7 185.7 187.1 187.1 1114 113.0 115.5 114.6 118.1 117.5 519.8 521.5 523.4 526.5 528.6 540.5 89 8 89.0 90.1 90.4 91.5 91.5 19 5 19.6 197 19.7 19.5 19.4 25.4 24.7 24.0 24.3 24.6 24.9 66.5 66.6 66.5 67.1 67.2 67.4 1141 114.6 115.5 116.0 115.4 116.1 204 5 207.0 207.5 209.0 210.4 221.2 847.7 854.6 863.5 870.0 877.9 877.6 184.5 187.8 186 3 188.2 190.7 194.9 116.3 115.2 1167 118.8 124.3 124.5 546.9 551.6 560.5 563.0 562.9 558.2 92.1 92.9 92.4 90.3 92.0 93.6 19.0 19.2 19 9 19.8 18.3 18.3 26.5 28.1 21.8 257 25.0 22.8 67.8 72.9 68.1 67.3 67.6 67.4 117.0 113.8 124 8 125.3 124.3 120.1 224.4 224.7 233 5 234.6 235.7 236.0 881.7 893.4 907.7 908.2 189.2 189.8 197.7 193.4 119.6 119.8 120.7 121.5 572.9 583.8 589.2 593.3 94.4 98.1 100.9 103.4 19.1 19.1 19.7 20.8 25.3 24.6 25.5 25.3 68.9 707 73.4 73.1 121.2 124.1 123.0 122.9 244.0 247.2 246.7 247.8 1979 Jan Feb Mar Apr May June .... ... ... .. July Aug. .... . .. SP - • . Nov Dec 1980: Jan Feb Mar £_:::•: :....:. .:;. June July Aug Sept Oct 1 U.S savings bonds, series A-F and J, and U.S. savings notes are included at current redemption value. 2 As of July 31, 1974, public debt outstanding has been adjusted to exclude the notes of the International Monetary Fund to conform with the Budget presentation. This adjustment applies to the 1967-79 data in this table. 3 For comparability with 1975-79 published data, published data for 1967-74 have been adjusted to exclude notes of the International Monetary fund, these adjustments amounted to $3.3 billion in 1967, $2.2 billion in 1968, and $0.8 billion in each year 1969 through 1974. These adjustments were necessary in order to add to the total public debt figures as published by the Department of 4the Treasury. Includes commercial banks, trust companies, and stock savings banks in the United States and Territories and island possessions; figures exclude securities held in trust departments. * Exclusive of banks and insurance companies. 6 Includes trust, sinking, and investment funds of State and local governments and their agencies, and of Territories and 7 8 Includes partnerships and personal trust accounts. Includes savings and loan associations, nonprofit institutions, corporate pension trust funds, dealers and brokers, certain government deposit accounts and government-sponsored agencies, and investments of foreign balances and international accounts in the United States. Note.—Through fiscal year 1976, the fiscal year was on a July 1—June 30 basis; beginning October 1976 (fiscal year 1977), the fiscal year is on an October 1—September 30 basis. Source: Department of the Treasury. 323 TABLE B-79-—Maturity distribution and average length of marketable interest-bearing public debt securities held by private investors, 1967-80 End of year or month Amount outstanding, privately held Maturity class Average length Within lyear Ito5 years 5 to 10 years 10 to 20 years 20 years and over Millions of dollars Fiscal year: 1967 1968 . 1969. .. 150,321 159,671 156,008 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 157,910 161,863 165,978 167,869 164,862 1975 1976.. 1977.. 1978 1979... 210,382 279,782 326,674 356,501 380,530 1980,... 463,717 1979: Jan Feb.. . Mar., Apr .... May. June. 382,556 381,797 380,060 383,315 388,001 377,649 July ... Aug. Sept.. Oct.... Nov... Dec,.. 1980 Jan,. .. Feb.... Mar.. 383,102 384,771 380,530 389,074 390,439 402,226 June.. July....... Aug... Sept... Oct. Nov 408,300 414,647 430,036 435,283 433,175 431,893 446,255 454,063 463,717 467,845 475,365 Years 56,561 66,746 69,311 76,443 74,803 79,509 84,041 87,150 115,677 151,723 161,329 163,819 181,883 220,084 53,584 52,295 50,182 57,035 58,557 57,157 54,139 50,103 65,852 89,151 113,319 132,993 127,574 156,244 21,057 21,850 18,078 8,286 14,503 16,033 16,385 14,197 15,385 24,169 33,067 33,500 32,279 38,809 6,153 6,110 6,097 7,876 6,357 6,358 8,741 9,930 8,857 8,087 8,428 11,383 18,489 25,901 184,277 185,602 186,967 185,725 188,018 184,113 183,277 182,891 181,883 182,297 180,676 190,403 192,829 195,694 208,542 207,942 209,899 198,365 210,106 218,977 220,084 222,346 230,987 133,992 132,434 129,454 132,538 130,576 124,443 129,462 130,607 127,574 134,205 133,276 133,173 135,132 137,442 137,514 142,011 140,835 147,756 149,215 150,764 156,244 156,712 154,434 33,690 31,299 31,245 31,235 33,572 33,359 33,555 32,392 32,279 32,325 34,319 36,592 36,793 37,593 40,151 40,111 36,317 39,715 39,426 35,652 38,809 38,747 38,021 15,282 15,195 15,141 16,578 17,326 17,271 18,617 18,548 18,489 19,938 19,866 19,796 21,247 21,794 21,725 23,140 22,270 22,229 23,682 25,948 25,901 27,338 27,266 Months 12,968 12,670 12,337 8,272 7,645 6,922 4,564 3,481 6 3 11 4,611 6,652 10,531 14,805 20,304 7 11 7 22,679 15,315 17,267 17,254 17,239 18,508 18,462 18,390 20,334 20,304 20,309 22,302 22,262 22,299 22,124 22,104 22,079 23,854 23,828 23,826 22,722 22,679 22,702 24,657 10 9 9 10 8 10 10 9 10 9 9 10 Note,- All issues classified to final maturity. Through fiscal year 1976, the fiscal year was on a July 1—June 30 basis; beginning October 1976 (fiscal year 1977), the fiscal year is on an October 1—September 30 basis. Source: Department of the Treasury: 324 CORPORATE PROFITS AND FINANCE 4. ABLE B-80.—Corporate profits with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments, 1946-80 [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Profits after tax with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments Corporate profits with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments Corporate profits tax liability 1946 . 1947 1948 1949 16.6 22.3 29.4 27.1 9.1 113 12.4 10.2 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 33.9 38.7 36.1 36.3 35.2 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 Dividends Undistributed profits with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments 7.5 11.0 17.0 16.9 5.6 63 7.0 7.2 1.9 47 10.0 9.7 17.9 22.6 19.4 20.3 17.6 16.0 16.1 16.7 16.0 17.5 8.8 8.5 8.5 8.8 9.1 7.2 7.6 8.2 7.2 8.4 45.5 43.7 43.3 38.5 49.6 22.0 22.0 21.4 19.0 23.6 23.4 21.8 21.8 19.5 26.0 10.3 11.1 11.5 11.3 12.2 13.1 10.7 10.3 8.2 13.8 47.6 48.6 56.6 62.1 69.2 22.7 22.8 24.0 26.2 28.0 24.9 25.8 32.6 35.9 41.2 12.9 13.3 14.4 15.5 17.3 12.1 12.5 18.2 20.4 23.9 80.0 85.1 82.4 89.1 85.1 30.9 33.7 32.5 39.2 39.5 49.1 51.4 49.9 50.0 45.6 19.1 19.4 20.2 22.0 22.5 30.0 32.0 29.7 27.9 23,1 71.4 83.2 96.6 108.3 94.9 34.2 37.5 41.6 49.0 51.6 37.2 45.7 55.0 59.3 43.3 22 5 22.9 24.4 27.0 29.9 14.8 22.8 30.5 32.3 13.4 110.5 138.1 164.7 185.5 196.8 50.6 63 8 72.6 83.0 87.6 59.9 74 3 92.2 102.5 109.2 30.8 37 4 39.9 44.6 50.2 29.1 36 9 52.3 57.9 59.1 181.7 80.1 101.6 56.0 45.6 | 11 Ill IV 163.6 185.2 190.5 202.7 71.2 83 3 85.0 92.3 92.4 1019 105.4 110.4 42.3 43 5 45.4 47.3 50.1 58 4 60.0 63.1 || III IV 201.9 196.6 199.5 189.4 88.5 86.4 88.4 87.2 113.3 110.2 111.1 102.2 49.0 49.8 50.2 51.6 64.3 60.5 60.9 50.6 I II III 200.2 169.3 177.9 94 2 715 78.5 106.0 97 8 99.5 53 9 55 7 56.7 52 1 421 42.8 Year or quarter 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 . . .. 1965 1966 1967 . 1968 1969 . . . . .. .. . . 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 .... 1980 * 1978: Total 1979: 1980: Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 325 T A B L E B-81.—Corporate profits by industry, 1929-80 [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Corporate profits with inventory valuation adjustment and without capital consumption adjustment Domestic industries Financial1 rear or quarter Total Nonfinancial Total Federal Reserve banks Other Total Total Manufacturing2 Daet KcSl Wholesale and retail trade Utilities 3 1.0 1.8 of the world Other 1929 10.5 10.2 1.3 0.0 1.3 8.9 1933 = 1.2 -1.2 .3 .0 .3 -1.5 1939 6.5 6.1 .8 .0 .8 5.3 3.3 .7 1.0 .3 .3 1940 1941 1942 . 1943... 1944 ... 1945 . 1946 1947 1948 1949 . 9.8 9.6 1.0 15.0 20.1 24.1 23.5 18.9 18.9 24.9 32.2 29.9 11 1.2 1.3 1.6 1.7 2.1 1.7 2.6 3.1 .9 1.0 1.2 1.3 1.6 1.6 2.0 1.6 2.3 2.9 8.6 15.4 20.5 24.5 24.0 19.3 19.6 25.9 33.4 31.1 .0 .0 .0 .0 .1 .1 .1 .1 .2 .2 14.0 18.9 22.8 21.9 17.3 16.8 23.2 29.6 26.8 5.5 9.5 13.6 17.6 16.2 1>2 1.4 2.2 3.0 3.2 3.3 3.8 4.6 5.5 4.5 1.3 2.0 3.4 4.4 3.9 2.7 1.8 2.2 3.0 3.0 .6 1.1 1.5 1.6 1.6 1.5 2.1 2.9 3.6 3.1 .3 ,4 .4 .4 .4 .3 .7 1.0 1.3 1.1 3.1 36 4.0 4.5 4.6 4.8 5.0 5.2 5.7 6.8 .2 3 .4 .4 .3 .3 .5 .6 .6 .7 3.0 3.3 3.7 4.1 4.3 4.5 4.5 4.6 5.1 6.0 33.5 37 9 34.7 33.9 31.8 40.3 39.1 38.3 33.5 42.9 20.9 24 6 21.7 22.0 19.9 26.0 24.7 24.0 19.4 26.4 5.0 50 4.8 3.8 3.8 5.0 4.5 4.0 46 4.9 5.0 4.7 5.6 5.9 5.8 5.9 7.0 3.6 37 3.3 3.1 3.4 3.6 4.1 4.0 3.6 3.6 1.3 17 1.9 1.8 2.0 2.4 2.8 3,1 2.5 2.7 7.2 7.0 7.3 6.8 6.9 7.5 8.5 9.0 1.0 .8 .9 1.0 1.1 1.4 1.7 2.0 2.5 3.1 6.2 6.3 6.4 5.8 5.8 6.2 6.8 7.0 7.9 8.0 39.5 39.8 44.2 49.0 54.9 64.0 68.2 64.8 69.3 63.5 23.6 23.3 26.0 29.3 32.3 39.3 41.9 38.5 41.2 36.6 7.4 7.8 8.4 9.3 10.4 10.5 10.0 11.0 11.8 10.7 10.8 10.3 3.6 3.7 3.9 4.4 5.1 5.6 6.3 6.5 6.9 6.1 3.0 3.2 3.6 3.9 4.2 4.5 4.2 4.4 5.2 6.1 8.6 26.6 34.1 40.7 45.5 39.0 52.6 69.2 76.2 85.3 88.9 11.7 13.4 13.9 12.5 21.3 22.4 27.0 24.5 23.0 8.2 8.5 9.0 8.7 6.1 10.0 14.5 17.8 20.7 18.0 5.9 6.5 6.9 8.0 7.9 6.5 7.1 8.6 9.3 6.2 50.2 60.8 70.0 76.0 65.4 95.8 120.3 137.7 150.0 150.8 11.9 14.2 16.7 19.5 20.8 13.7 16.3 13.0 14.3 15.5 19.7 30.3 . 1950 1951 1952 .. 1953 1954 . 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 36.7 5.2 -.4 -.5 11.8 13.8 13.2 9.7 9.0 .0 0.9 -.7 0.2 .0 37.9 43 3 40.6 40.2 38.4 47.5 46.9 46.6 41.6 52.3 38.7 38.4 36.4 45.1 44.1 43.5 39.1 49.6 49.7 50.0 55.1 59.7 66.0 76.0 80.9 78.1 84.9 80.8 46.7 46.8 51.5 55.8 61.8 71.5 76.7 73.7 79.7 74.6 10.4 11.1 1979 68.9 82.0 94.0 105.6 96.7 120.6 151.6 176.7 199.0 212.7 62.4 74.9 85.3 92.0 80.4 107.6 137.4 161.2 179.3 182.4 12.1 14.1 15.3 15.9 15.0 11.8 17.1 23.5 29.3 31.6 9.6 11.1 17.3 21.6 22.0 1980" 199.2 167.5 30.0 11.7 18.3 137.5 73.6 20.5 19.6 23.7 31.7 174.9 197.4 205.4 218.3 155.9 181.0 186.1 194.3 27.0 28.6 30.1 31.6 7.0 7.4 8.0 8.6 20.0 21.2 22.1 23.0 128.9 152.4 156.0 162.8 73.0 86.4 88.3 93.6 22.0 25.3 25.6 25.2 17.0 21.0 22.1 22,6 17.0 19.7 20.0 21.4 19.0 16.5 19.3 24.0 217.8 213.0 215.6 204.5 191.7 184.4 180.5 172.9 31.3 31.0 31.5 32.6 8.8 9.2 9.7 10.5 22.5 21.8 21.7 22.1 160.4 153.4 149.0 140.3 99.4 91.5 84.4 80.2 21.0 22.9 25.6 22.6 20.8 19.2 17.1 14.9 19.1 19.7 22.0 22.6 26.0 28.5 35.1 31.7 215.6 186.9 195.9 179.0 157.5 165.0 33.3 30.1 28.7 11.9 12.7 11.3 21.4 17.4 17.4 145.7 127.5 136.2 92.1 61.3 68.5 14.8 25.9 20.4 16.1 16.6 22.5 23.7 24.8 111 36.6 29.3 30.9 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969. . . .. .. 1970 1971 . 1972.. 1973 .... 1974 1975 1976. . 1977 . 1978 . . . ... . 415 3.6 3.3 3.4 4.5 5.7 5.7 6.0 6.2 7.7 10.7 11.9 11.4 • 4.4 4.6 5.9 4.9 5.0 5.8 5.9 7.5 8.1 8.2 9.1 9.5 1978. IL . '.'".. Ill IV 1979: j IL . Ill . . . IV . . . 19801 II.. Ill . . 1 Consists of the following industries: Banking; credit agencies other than banks; security and commodity brokers, dealers, and services; insurance carriers; regulated investment companies; small business investment companies; and real estate investment trusts. 2 See Table B-82 for industry detail. 3 Consists of transportation, communication, and electric, gas, and sanitary services. Note.—The industry classification is on a company basis and is based on the 1972 Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) beginning 1948, and on the 1942 SIC prior to 1948. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 326 TABLE B-82.—Corporate profits of manufacturing industries, 1929-80 [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates} Corporate profits with inventory valuation adjustment and without capital consumption adjustment Durable goods Nondurable goods Year or quarter 1929 1933.. . . Total manufacturing Total 5.2 2.6 Food and kindred products Chemicals and allied products Petroleum and coal products Other Total Primary metal industries Fabricated metal products Machinery, except electrical Electric and electronic equipment 0.3 .4 0.5 1.1 1.2 1.3 0.6 .7 1.1 1.4 2.1 1.6 2.3 2.3 1.9 1.7 1.7 2.1 2.0 1.4 2.1 1.2 1.3 1.5 1.4 1.2 1.1 1.2 1.5 1.3 1.7 3.1 2.4 2.4 2.6 2.1 4.1 2.2 2.6 .9 3.0 Motor vehicles and equipment 2.6 _ 4 -.4 1939. . 3.3 1.7 1.7 1940... 1941. 1942. . 1943 . . 1944... 1945... 1946.... 1947... 1948 . 1949. . 5.5 9.5 11.8 13.8 13.2 9.7 9.0 13.6 17.6 16.2 2.4 3.1 4.6 5.7 5.9 5.2 6.6 7.8 10.0 8.0 1.4 1.3 1.9 1.6 1.2 1.4 1.7 1.8 .9 1.5 2.8 1.9 3.1 3.6 3.7 2.8 3.1 6.4 7.2 8.1 7.4 4.5 2.4 5.8 7.5 8.1 0.8 1.5 1.6 1.5 1950. 1951... 1952. 1953... 1954... 1955.. 1956.. 1957... 1958... 1959.... 20.9 24.6 21.7 22.0 19.9 26.0 24.7 24.0 19.4 26.4 8.9 11.4 9.9 10.1 9.4 11.8 11.9 10.7 10.0 12.7 1.6 1.4 1.7 1.8 1.6 2.2 1.8 1.8 2.1 2.4 2.3 2.8 2.3 2.2 2.2 3.0 2.8 2.8 2.5 3.5 2.3 2.7 2.3 2.B 2.7 3.0 3.3 2.6 2.1 2.5 2.7 4.4 3.6 3.3 2.9 3.6 4.1 3.6 3.3 4.3 12.0 13.2 11.7 11.9 10.5 14.3 12.8 13.3 9.3 13.7 2.3 3.1 1.9 2.5 1.7 2.9 3.0 3.0 1.9 2.3 I960.. 1961.. 1962.. 1963... 1964.... 1965 1966 1967. . 1968... 1969... 23.6 23.3 26.0 29.3 32.3 39.3 41.9 38.5 41.2 36.6 12.0 11.9 12.0 13.1 14.4 16.3 18.1 17.6 19.1 17.7 2.2 2.3 2.3 2.7 2.7 2.8 3.2 3.2 3.2 3.0 3.1 3.2 3.2 3.6 4.0 4.6 4.9 4.3 5.2 4.5 2.5 2.2 2.2 2.1 2.4 2.9 3.2 3.9 3.7 3.2 4.2 4.1 4.3 4.6 5.3 6.0 6.8 6.3 7.0 6.9 11.6 11.4 14.0 16.3 17.9 23.0 23.8 20.9 22.2 18.9 2.0 1.6 1.6 2.0 2.5 3.1 3.6 2.7 1.9 1.4 1.0 1.1 1.3 1.4 2.0 2.4 2.4 2.3 2.0 1.8 1.9 2.3 2.5 3.3 3.9 4.5 4.1 4.1 3.7 1.3 1.3 1.5 1.6 1.7 2.7 3.0 2.9 2.8 2.3 3.0 2.5 4.0 4.9 4.7 6.2 5.1 3.9 5.5 4.7 1970 1971. 1972. 1973 1974 1975.... 1976... 1977 1978. 1979.. 26.6 34.1 40.7 45.5 39.0 52.6 69.2 76.2 85.3 16.5 17.8 18.3 21.2 25.8 33.6 38.8 40.2 42.3 49.4 3.2 3.5 2.9 2.4 2.8 8.6 6.9 6.7 5.9 6.9 3.9 4.4 5.2 6.0 5.6 6.5 8.3 8.0 8.3 8.2 3.5 3.5 3.0 5.0 10.5 9.6 12.6 11.8 12.6 18.3 5.9 6.4 7.2 7.8 6.8 8.9 11.0 13.7 15.4 16.0 10.2 16.3 22.4 24.3 13.2 18.9 30.4 36.0 43.0 39.5 .7 1.6 2.2 5.4 2.9 2.1 1.3 3.2 4.2 1.1 1.5 2.1 2.5 1.6 3.0 3.8 4.5 4.8 5.0 2.9 2.9 4.3 4.6 2.9 4.7 6.3 7.6 8.9 8.8 1.2 1.9 2.8 3.0 .4 2.1 3.4 5.4 6.3 6.3 1.2 5.0 5.9 5.7 l'.9 7.2 9.2 8.9 4.3 1980*... 73.6 53.7 6.6 7.3 25.4 14.5 19.9 2.6 3.7 6.4 5.4 -5.1 1978: I. . II.. til. . IV.... 73.0 86.4 88.3 93.6 38.2 42.4 42.6 45.9 5.8 5.6 5.6 6.7 7.7 8.1 8.2 9.4 9.9 12.8 13.7 13.9 14.9 15.9 15.0 15.9 34.7 44.0 45.7 47.7 1.2 3.7 3.6 4.2 4.1 4.8 5.0 5.4 7.0 10.3 7.8 10.3 5.9 5.9 7.3 6.0 7.6 8.9 10.0 9.1 1979: I ... II ... . III.. . IV. . 99.4 91.5 84.4 80.2 48.5 48.5 49.6 50.9 6.6 7.5 6.7 6.7 9.4 15.0 16.9 17.7 23.7 17.4 15.4 17.4 13.8 50.9 43.0 34.8 29.3 4.8 4.7 4.5 2.8 5.5 5.3 4,6 4.8 9.3 8.8 9.2 8.0 92.1 61.3 68.5 64.0 51.2 49.1 8.2 6.7 5.7 31.0 25.3 22.2 16.0 13.2 14.2 28.1 10.1 19.4 5.9 2.0 1980: I .. II . . Other 7.8 6.6 11.8 6.6 -.3 6.6 3.8 5.5 -2.9 -8.8 -4.8 Mote.—The industry classification is on a company basis and is based on the 1972 Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) beginning 1948, and on the 1942 SIC prior to 1948. Source.- Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 327 TABLE B-83.—Sales, profits, and stockholders1 equity, all manufacturing corporations, 1950-80 [Billions of dollars] 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 Sales (nat\ (net) . . .. . . . 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 . . . . 1965 1966. . . . 1967. . . 1968. 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 . . 1973: IV ... Profits Profits Profits Year or quarter Stock- Nondurable goods industries Durable goods industries All manufacturing corporations Before After holders' income1 income equity2 taxes taxes Sales /nof \ (net; C+nnL MOCK- Before After holders'2 income income equity taxes' taxes 1819 245.0 250.2 265.9 248.5 23.2 27.4 22.9 24.4 20.9 12 9 11.9 10.7 11.3 11.2 83.3 98.3 103.7 108.2 113.1 86 8 116.8 122.0 137.9 122.8 12.9 15.4 12.9 14.0 11.4 278.4 307.3 320.0 305.3 338.0 28.6 29.8 28.2 22.7 29.7 15.1 16.2 15.4 12.7 16.3 120.1 131.6 141.1 147.4 157.1 142.1 159.5 166.0 148.6 169.4 16.5 16.5 15.8 11.4 15.8 345.7 356.4 389.9 412.7 443.1 27.5 27.5 31.9 34.9 39.6 15.2 15.3 17.7 19.5 23.2 165.4 172.6 181.4 189.7 199.8 173.9 175.2 195.5 209.0 226.3 14.0 13.6 16.7 18.5 21.2 492.2 554.2 575.4 631.9 694.6 46.5 51.8 47.8 55.4 58.1 27.5 30.9 29.0 32.1 33.2 211.7 230.3 247.6 265.9 289.9 257.0 291.7 300.6 335.5 366.5 708.8 751.4 849.5 1,017.2 48.1 53.2 63.2 81.4 28.6 31.3 36.5 48.1 306.8 320.9 343.4 374.1 275.1 21.4 13.0 386.4 6.7 6.1 5.5 5.8 5.6 8.1 8.3 7.9 5.8 8.1 7.0 6.9 8.6 9.5 Sales (nat\ (nei; Qtnr\t MOCK- Before After income income taxes l taxes hotders'2 equity 6.1 5.7 5.2 5.5 5.6 7.0 7.8 7.5 6.9 8.3 8.2 8.5 9.2 43.5 51.1 53.9 55.7 58.2 39.9 47.2 49.8 52.4 54.9 95.1 128.1 128.0 128.0 125.7 10.3 12.1 10.0 58.8 65.2 70.5 72.8 77.9 136.3 147.8 154.1 156.7 168.5 12.1 13.2 11.6 82.3 84.9 89.1 93.3 98.5 171.8 181.2 1944 203.6 216.8 13.5 13.9 15.1 16.4 18.3 26.2 29.2 25.7 30.6 31.5 14.5 16.4 14.6 16.5 16.9 105.4 115.2 125.0 135.6 147.6 235.2 2624 274.8 296.4 328.1 20.3 22.6 22.0 24.8 26.6 15.5 16.4 144 106.3 115.1 122.6 130.3 142.3 363.1 382.5 435.8 527.3 23.0 26.5 33.6 43.6 12.9 14.5 18.4 24.8 155.1 160.6 1714 188.7 345.7 368.9 413.7 489.9 25.2 26.7 29.6 37.8 15.7 16.7 18.0 23.3 151.7 160.3 172.0 185.4 140.1 10.8 6.3 194.7 135.0 10.6 6.7 191.7 104 9.6 124 11.3 13.9 10.0 11.6 13.0 14.6 61.3 664 70.6 74.6 79.2 83.1 87.7 92.3 96.3 101.3 New series: 236.6 20.6 13.2 368.0 122.7 10.1 6.2 185.8 113.9 10.5 7.0 182.1 1974 1,060.6 92.1 58.7 395.0 529.0 41.1 24.7 196.0 531.6 51.0 34.1 199.0 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1977 1,065.2 1,203.2 1,328.1 1,496.4 1,741.8 79.9 104.9 115.1 132.5 154.2 49.1 64.5 70.4 81.1 98.7 423.4 462.7 496.7 539.4 600.5 521.1 589.6 657.3 760.7 865.7 35.3 50.7 57.9 69.6 72.4 21.4 30.8 34.8 41.8 45.2 208.1 224.3 239.9 261.5 292.5 544.1 613.7 67Q.8 735.7 876.1 44.6 54.3 57.2 62.9 81.8 27.7 33.7 35.5 39.3 53.5 215.3 238.4 256.8 277.9 308.0 311.5 338.6 331 7 346^2 25.6 32.4 27 3 29^9 15.6 19.7 16 7 479.8 492.9 5024 5117 151.2 169.5 163 8 172J 12.5 16.9 13 0 15^5 7.5 10.2 78 160.3 169.1 167 9 1715 13.0 15.5 8.1 9.5 94 230.8 2384 243 1 24L5 249.1 254.5 ocq 0 CD 3,3 340.3 377 5 376^9 401.8 26.9 36 0 33.4 36.3 16.0 170.1 195 0 189.7 205.9 13.6 19 8 17.0 19.1 7.9 250.3 170.3 20'.4 22.6 518.7 531 8 5463 560.8 406.6 436.4 437.5 461.2 36.5 42.6 38.2 36.8 22.7 26.8 24.7 24.5 576.2 592.5 609.2 624.0 207.5 222.6 213.6 221.9 18.8 21.6 16.4 15.7 465 0 465.7 463.7 39 4 35.9 33.1 24 7 22.4 21.0 640 0 654.2 666.6 219 9 21B.B 212.8 15 8 13!5 11.9 1973: IV ii'...'. . ... . . Ill IV 1978 1 II III. . . IV 1979- 1 ii"... ! "" in IV . . . 19801 II Ill 184 221 •\OO A 14 1 m.o 14.3 13.3 89 9^0 2684 10.1 11.0 281.1 287.8 11.2 13.5 144 294.3 303.2 312.6 321.9 15 0 332 5 342^0 349.9 I.C.M fcJ/.O lot.** ifi 7 1D.& 10.3 11.6 265.2 272.9 187,2 195.9 164 17.1 114 281.9 289.3 296.5 302.1 199.1 213.8 223.9 239.3 17.7 21.1 21.9 21.2 14.4 97 307 5 31Z1 316.8 245 1 ZA6.9 250.9 23 6 22^3 21.2 13.7 13.3 10.3 10.1 8^2 7.3 264.2 8.1 in 1 Rl £./**,£, 1 In the old series, "income taxes" refers to Federal income taxes only, as State and local income taxes had already been deducted. In 2the new series, no income taxes have been deducted. Annual data are average equity for the year (using four end-of-quarter figures). Note.—Data are not necessarily comparable from one period to another due to changes in accounting procedures, industry classifications, sampling procedures, etc. For explanato™ notes concerning compilation of the series, see "Quarterly Financial Report for Manufacturing, Mining, and Trade Corporations, Federal Trade Commission. Source: Federal Trade Commission. 328 TABLE B-84.—Relation of profits after taxes to stockholders' equity and to sales, all manufacturing corporations, 1947-80 Ratio of profits after income taxes (annual rate) to stockholders' equity—percent1 Year or quarter Profits after income taxes per dollar of sales—cents All manufacturing corporations Durable goods industries Nondurable goods industries All manufacturing corporations Durable goods industries Nondurable goods industries 1947 1948 1949 15.6 16.0 11.6 14.4 15.7 12.1 16.6 16.2 11.2 6.7 7.0 5.8 6.7 7.1 6.4 6.7 6.8 54 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 15.4 121 10.3 10 5 9.9 16.9 13 0 11.1 11.1 10.3 14.1 11.2 9.7 9.9 9.6 7.1 4.8 4.3 4.3 4.5 7.7 5.3 4.5 4.2 4.6 6.5 45 4.1 43 4.4 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 12 6 12 3 10.9 86 10.4 13 8 12.8 11.3 8.0 10.4 114 11.8 10.6 9.2 10.4 5.4 5.3 4.8 4.2 4.8 57 5.2 4.8 3.9 4.8 51 5.3 4.9 4.4 4.9 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 92 8.9 9.8 103 11.6 85 8.1 9.6 10.1 11.7 98 9.6 9.9 10.4 11.5 4.4 4.3 4.5 4.7 5,2 40 3.9 4.4 4.5 5.1 48 4.7 4.7 49 5.4 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 13.0 13 4 11.7 121 11.5 13.8 14 2 11.7 12.2 11.4 12.2 12.7 11.8 11.9 11.5 5.6 5.6 5.0 5.1 4.8 5.7 56 4.8 4.9 4.6 5.5 5.6 5.3 5.2 5.0 1970 1971 1972 1973 9.3 97 10.6 12.8 8.3 90 10.8 13.1 10.3 10.3 10.5 12.6 4.0 4.1 4.3 4.7 3.5 38 4.2 4.7 4.5 45 4.4 4.8 1973- IV 13.4 12.9 14.0 4.7 4.5 5.0 ., .. New series: 1973-IV 14.3 13.3 15.3 5.6 5.0 6.1 1974 14.9 12.6 17.1 5.5 4.7 6.4 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 11.6 13.9 14.2 15.0 16.4 10.3 13 7 14.5 16.0 15.4 12.9 14.2 13.8 14.2 17.4 4.6 5.4 5.3 5.4 5.7 4.1 52 5.3 5.5 5.2 5.1 55 5.3 5.3 6.1 1977: I II III IV 13.0 16.0 13.3 14.4 13.0 17.1 12.9 15.1 13.0 15.0 13.7 13.7 5.0 5.8 5.0 5.3 5.0 6.0 4.8 5.4 5.0 5.6 5.3 5.2 1978: 1 II HI IV 12.4 16 7 14.9 16.1 12.7 18 7 15.5 17.0 12.1 14 8 14.4 15.3 4.7 5.9 5.4 5.6 4.7 62 5.4 5.6 4.8 56 5.4 5.6 1979: I II Ill IV 15.7 18.1 16.3 15.7 16.2 18.4 14.0 13.4 15.3 17.8 18.4 17.9 5.6 6.1 5.7 5.3 5.5 6.0 4.8 4.6 5.6 6.3 6.4 6.0 1980: I || 111 15.4 13.7 12.6 12.6 10.6 9.2 18.1 16.5 15.7 5.3 4.8 4.5 4.4 3.8 3.4 6.1 5.7 5.5 .'.'. * *..] 1 Annual ratios based on average equity for the year (using four end-of-quarter figures). Quarterly ratios based on equity at end of quarter only. Note.—Based on data in millions of dollars. See Note, Table 8-83. Source: Federal Trade Commission. 329 TABLE B-85.—Relation of profits after taxes to stockholders' equity and to sales, all manufacturing corporations, by industry group, 1979-80 Profits after income taxes per dollar of sales—cents Ratio of profits after income taxes (annual rate) to stockholders' equity—percentl Industry 1980 1979 III 1979 IV 1 II III III 1980 IV 1 II III 16.3 15.7 15.4 13.7 12.6 5.7 5.3 5.3 4.8 4.5 14 0 13 4 12 6 10 6 92 48 4.6 44 3.8 34 19.4 13.3 13.9 5.7 5.9 16.8 11.5 11.8 14.4 5,6 5.2 1.9 2.5 5.4 4.6 4.2 5.4 2.1 11.7 15.8 -2.3 18.2 12.8 22.9 3.4 8.7 -.7 67 3.9 7.9 2.7 6.7 1.2 3.6 Fabricated metal products .. Machinery, except electrical. ., Electrical and electronic equipment Transportation equipment2 15.8 16.0 16.4 5.2 15.4 17.2 16.6 14.1 8.2 17.1 13.3 15.6 6.8 4.4 3.7 6.0 12.3 13.9 4.5 6.8 4.4 7.2 5.0 6.0 4.0 6.6 3.8 6.3 17.6 7.9 16.0 3.8 14.8 -3.6 14.2 -6.2 5.3 1.7 5.5 2.5 5.1 1.2 4.8 -1,2 4.8 -2.1 Motor vehicles and equipment Aircraft, guided missiles, and parts..., -.5 3.5 -2.2 -14.1 ^18.1 -.2 1.2 -.8 -5.2 -6.9 17.9 18.3 16.5 16.5 15.4 5.1 5.0 4.5 4.3 43 Alt manufacturing corporations Durable goods industries Stone, clay, and glass products.. Primary metals industries Iron and steel Nonferrous metals Instruments and related products Other durable manufacturing products ..... 16.2 17.0 16.2 17.3 17.6 8.4 8.7 8.5 8.9 9.1 19.7 15.7 12.5 9.0 12.2 5.2 4.1 3.6 2.7 3.6 18.4 17.9 18.1 16.5 15.7 6.4 6.0 6.1 5.7 5.5 Food and kindred products Tobacco manufactures Textile mill products Paper and allied products Printing and publishing Chemicals and allied products2.. 17.2 21.6 13.4 20.5 20.1 15.9 13.8 184 12.5 13.4 16.8 15.3 12.8 212 10.9 13.3 15.0 18.0 13.4 20 2 7.9 13.1 16.5 15.3 15.1 22 3 6.7 10.8 17.3 15.0 3.9 131 3.7 8.2 6.8 7.2 3.1 10.8 3.2 5.4 5.5 7.0 3.0 131 2.8 5.4 5.2 8.0 3.1 121 2.0 5.5 5.6 7.1 3.4 13 0 1.8 4.6 5.8 7.1 Industrial chemicals and synthetics Drugs 13.3 18.4 13.6 17.9 16.1 21.6 12.3 18.3 9.6 22.6 5.9 12.4 6.1 11.9 6.8 14.0 4.7 15.1 21.1 24.6 24.3 21.5 18.2 9.0 9.5 9.0 5.7 12.4 8.4 8.8 5.6 7.7 5.6 6.2 2.7 1.7 2.4 1.8 2.0 19.0 14.3 10.5 10.3 16.0 3.7 2.8 2.2 2,2 3.1 Nondurable goods industries Petroleum and coal products Rubber and miscellaneous plastics products Other nondurable manufacturing products 1 Ratios based on equity at end of quarter. 2 Includes other industries not shown separately. Source: Federal Trade Commission. 330 7.2 TABLE B-86.—Determinants of business fixed investment, 1955-80 [Percent, except as noted] Nonfinancial corporations Real investment as percent of real GNP Capacity utilization rate in manufacturing J Cash flow as percent of GNP a Rate of return on depreciable assets 3 Rate of return on stockholders'4 equity Ratio of market value to replacement cost of net assets B 9.3 9.7 9.7 8.7 8.8 87.1 86.4 83.7 75.2 81.9 9.3 8.9 8.9 8.6 9.3 14.3 12.2 11.1 9.5 12.2 6.2 5.5 5.0 3.9 4.9 0.855 .837 .775 .810 .977 9.1 8.8 9.0 9.0 9.4 80.2 77.4 81.6 83.5 85.6 8.9 8.8 9.5 9.7 10.1 11.1 11.2 12.9 13.8 14.7 5.0 4.4 5.9 6.4 7.6 .954 1.055 .998 1.096 1.174 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 10.5 11.0 10.4 10.3 10.7 89.6 91.1 86.9 87.1 86.2 10.6 10.4 10.0 9.4 8.6 16.1 15.8 14.0 13.8 12.1 9.3 9.1 8.0 7.8 7.2 1.247 1.126 1.138 1.174 1.053 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974.. 10.5 10.0 10.2 11.0 10.9 79.3 78.4 83.5 87.6 83.8 7.8 8.3 8.6 8.0 7.0 9.5 10.1 10.7 10.6 8.1 4.6 5.4 6.7 9.3 8.7 .861 .939 1.011 .932 .666 9.7 9.7 10.3 10.7 11.0 72.9 79.5 81.9 84.4 85.7 9.0 9.3 9.6 9.3 8.9 8.8 9.6 10.1 9.9 9.0 5.4 4.9 6.3 7.1 7.8 .658 .743 .656 .606 .561 10.7 (6) 8.7 (6) (6) (6) Year 1955 1956.. 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 . 1963 1964 . 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 p 1 2 3 Federal Reserve Board index. Cash flow calculated as after-tax profits plus capital consumption allowance plus inventory valuation adjustment. Profits before taxes plus capital consumption adjustment and inventory valuation adjustment plus net interest paid divided by the stock of depreciable assets valued at current replacement cost. Data for the inventory component of depreciable assets do not reflect national income and product accounts benchmark revisions. 4 After-tax profits corrected for inflation effects divided by net worth {physical capital component valued at current replacement cost). Data do not reflect national income and product accounts benchmark revisions. 5 Equity plus interest-bearing debt divided by current replacement cost of net assets. Data for the inventory component of depreciable assets do not reflect national income and product accounts benchmark revisions. * Not available. Sources: Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic Analysis), Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, and Council of Economic Advisers. 331 TABLE B-87.—Sources and uses of funds, nonfarm nonfinancial corporate business, 1946-80 [Billions of dollars; quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Sources Uses External Year or quarter Credit market funds Total Internal ! Total Total Securities and mortgages Loans and shortterm paper 3.3 3.0 Others Total Discrepancy Purchase Increase (sources of in physical3 financial less uses) assets assets 3.7 5.8 3.3 -2.7 17.1 25.3 24.9 17.9 18.5 17.0 19.9 14.4 -1.4 8.4 5.0 3.5 1.3 1.4 3.6 1.9 3.9 4.1 1.5 15.9 5.7 -1.5 .5 39.9 37.2 29.1 27.7 27.7 23.6 29.8 24.5 25.4 22.8 16.4 7.4 4.6 2.3 4.9 1.9 -1.3 .1 !'4 6.4 7.5 10.4 10.5 8.1 3.7 5.3 1.9 -.0 4.1 13.1 2.5 -.4 1.2 7.9 49.2 41.1 39.4 38J 51.7 32.7 37.1 35.2 27.9 37.5 16.5 4.0 4.2 10.8 14.2 2.8 2.9 2.9 2.5 3.5 11.9 12.5 12.8 12.2 14.8 7.5 10.8 9.4 8.4 4.5 1.8 3.5 3.8 5.9 1.0 6.7 4.3 9.3 7.7 40.6 50.4 54.9 59.1 64.1 38.0 37.2 43.8 44.9 50.7 2.7 13.2 11.1 14.2 13.4 7.0 4.1 3.9 6.9 8.5 35.1 36.3 32.7 52.2 57.0 20.6 25.4 29.8 31.8 38.6 9.3 15.9 21.6 18.8 20.7 11.4 9.5 8.2 13.0 17.9 14.4 10.9 2.9 20.4 18.4 82.2 90.5 87.5 105.3 113.1 62.0 75.7 73.0 77.2 84.3 20.2 14.8 14.5 28.2 28.8 9.0 6.3 6.4 9.2 5.6 58.9 68.6 80.8 83.8 75.7 45.5 59.3 80.8 116.2 115.6 40.7 45.2 58.2 73.0 82.1 32.1 41.1 40.6 37.0 39.1 8.5 4.1 17.6 36.1 43.0 4.9 14.1 22.6 43.1 33.4 95.9 119.6 145.8 185.6 179.0 80.3 86.0 100.3 123.3 134.7 15.6 33.5 45.6 62.3 44.4 8.5 8.2 15.8 14.4 12.2 150.0 209.7 242.3 295.7 341.3 106.8 125.3 139.9 148.8 158.3 43.2 84.4 102.3 146.9 183.0 37.9 60.7 79.9 94.7 114.3 49.3 48.8 46.1 49.2 52.4 -11.4 11.9 33.8 45.6 61.9 5.3 23.8 22.4 52.2 68.7 133.0 183.3 216.8 274.3 319.4 99.9 139.0 169.9 195.9 221.3 33.2 44.3 46.9 78.3 98.2 16.9 26.4 25.5 21.4 21.9 259.6 297.7 303.5 322.1 135.0 150.5 153.8 155.9 124.5 147.2 149.7 166.2 94.7 92.7 90.4 101.1 31.9 54.8 55.1 55.0 62.8 38.0 35.3 46.2 29.8 54.5 59.3 65.1 232.5 281.3 284.4 298.9 177.0 203.2 199.9 203.6 55.5 78.1 84.4 95.2 27.0 16.4 19.1 23.2 350.2 323.3 377.3 314.9 154.4 159.0 161.6 158.2 195.8 164.3 215.7 156.7 113.4 123.9 126.7 93.0 48.9 55.2 56.2 49.2 64.5 68.7 70.5 43.8 82.4 40.4 89.0 63.7 324.8 294.6 360.5 298.3 213.0 228.6 226.6 216.9 111.8 66.1 133.9 81.4 25.5 28.7 16.8 16.6 315.4 204.9 258.7 153.7 160.1 165.7 161.7 44.9 93.1 123.8 64.3 102.0 56.2 59.1 61.8 67.7 5.2 40.3 37.9 -19.4 -9.0 294.9 190.0 240.7 226.0 220.0 209.1 68.9 -=30.0 31.6 20.6 14.9 18.0 1946.... 1947.... 1948... 1949.... 18.4 26.7 28.5 19.7 7.8 12.6 18.8 19.3 10.6 14.1 9.8 6.9 8.3 6.5 3.1 3.6 5.4 6.7 4.9 1950.,. 1951... 1952... 1953.. 1954.... 41.8 35.9 29.2 27.3 29.1 17.8 19.7 21,2 21.1 23.5 24.0 16.2 8.0 6.1 5.6 8.1 10.5 9.5 5.6 6.5 4.2 6.4 8.0 6.0 6.7 1955.. 1956... 1957... 1958 . 1959 52.0 44.0 42.2 41.3 55.2 28.8 28.7 30.4 29.6 35.0 23.2 15.3 11.8 11.7 20.1 10.2 12.8 12.2 10.5 12.2 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 47.6 54.5 58.8 66.0 72.6 34.7 35.3 41.6 44.5 50.1 12.9 19.2 17.2 21.5 22.5 1965 1966. 1967... 1968 .. 1969 91.1 96.8 93.9 114.6 118.6 56.1 60.5 61.3 62.3 61.7 1970., 1971 . 1972 .. 1973 . 1974 104.4 127.8 161.6 200.0 191.3 1975.. 1976 1977 1978 1979 -"u 1978: II . ' III IV 1979- II 1980. I.. .. II. 1 Undistributed profits (after inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments), capital consumption allowances, and foreign branch profits. 2 Consists of tax liabilities, trade debt, and miscellaneous liabilities. a Plant and equipment, residential structures, inventory investment, and mineral rights from U.S. Government. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 332 TABLE B-88.—Current assets and liabilities of U.S. corporations, 1939-80 [Billions of dollars] Current assets End of year or quarter Total Cash 1 U.S. Government 2 securities Current liabilities Notes Other and accounts Invencurrent receiv- tories assets able Total Net Notes Other Current and current working ratio 3 capital accounts liabilities payable All corporations SEC series:5 1939 54.5 10.8 2.2 22.1 18.0 1.4 30.0 21.9 8.1 24.5 1.817 1940 .. 1941.... 1942 . . 1943.. .. 1944.. 1945 .. . 1946 . 1947, .. 1948 . 1949. . 60.3 72.9 83.6 93.8 97.2 97.4 108.1 123.6 133.0 133.1 13.1 13.9 17.6 21.6 21.6 21.7 22.8 25.0 25.3 26.5 2.0 4.0 19.8 25.6 27.3 27.6 26.8 26.3 37.6 44.6 48.9 45.3 1.5 32.8 40.7 47.3 51.6 51.7 45.8 51.9 61.5 64.4 60.7 23.2 26.4 26.0 26.3 26.8 25.7 31.6 37.6 39.3 37.5 9.6 10.1 16.4 20.9 21.1 15.3 14.1 14.8 16.8 24.0 28.0 27.3 26.9 26.5 25.9 30.7 38.3 42.4 43.0 14.3 21.3 25.3 24.9 20.1 20.3 23.9 25.0 23.3 27.5 32.3 36.3 42.1 45.6 51.6 56.2 62.1 68.6 72.4 1.838 1.791 1.767 1.818 1.880 2.127 2.083 2.010 2.065 2.193 1950... 1951 . . 1952 1953 ..., 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958. .. 1959.... 161.5 179.1 186.2 190.6 194.6 224.0 237.9 244.7 255.3 277.3 28.1 30.0 30,8 31.1 33.4 34.6 34.8 34.9 37,4 36.3 19.7 20.7 19.9 21.5 19.2 23.5 19.1 18.6 18.8 22.8 56.8 61.5 67.4 68.5 73.6 88.9 97.7 102.2 109.7 120.6 55.1 64.9 65.8 67.2 65.3 72.8 80.4 82.2 81.9 88.4 1.7 2.1 2.4 2.4 3.1 4.2 5.9 48.3 54.9 59.3 59.5 6L7 9.1 79.8 92.6 96.1 98.9 99.7 121.0 130.5 133.1 136.6 153.1 76.1 83.9 86.6 90.4 101.0 31.6 37.8 36.8 39.4 38.0 45.0 46.6 46.5 46.2 52.0 81.6 86.5 90.1 91.8 94.9 103.0 107.4 111.6 118.7 124.2 2.024 1.934 1,938 1.927 1.952 1.851 1.823 1.838 1.869 1.811 I960.. . 1961 289.0 306.8 37.2 41.1 20.1 20.0 129.2 139.2 91.8 95.2 10.6 11.4 160.4 171.2 106.8 U4.6 53.6 56.6 128.6 135.6 1.802 1.792 1.4 1.3 1.3 1.4 2.4 1.7 1.6 1.6 1.4 6.7 7.5 Nonfinancial corporations6 5 SEC series: 1961 1962 1963 . 1964 . 1965 . . 1966 .. . 1967 . . 1968 .. 1969 1970 1971 1972 . 1973.. 1974 95.0 100.5 106.8 14.4 13.0 10.3 11.5 10.6 97.9 103.2 110.5 119.9 134.1 146.6 155.3 173.9 197.0 50.2 53.3 59.0 66.3 71.1 7.7 U.O 10.6 12.8 12.3 735.4 759.0 826.8 902.1 1,030.0 1,200.9 73,2 82,1 88,2 95.8 104.5 116.1 1,081.0 1,108.2 1,169.5 1,200.9 102J 1,235.2 1,233.8 126.6 142.8 153.1 166.0 186.4 10.5 12.1 14.4 16.3 18.1 19.7 22.0 26.9 31.6 123.7 132.4 145.5 156.6 178.8 199.4 211.3 244.1 287.8 84.4 88.7 97.0 104.9 121.5 137.5 147.1 168.8 199.2 39.3 43.7 48.5 51.7 57.3 61.9 64.2 75.3 88.6 131.0 137.3 142.7 149.0 157.2 164.6 174.9 182.4 185.7 2.059 2.037 1.981 1.951 1.879 1.825 1.828 1.747 1.646 206.1 221.1 248.2 288.5 322.1 193.3 200.4 225.7 263.9 313.6 35.0 43.8 55.8 66.4 71.7 304.9 326.0 375.6 450.9 530.4 211.3 220.5 282.9 340.3 402.3 93.6 105.5 92.7 110.7 128.1 187.4 203.6 223.7 246.9 260.3 1.615 1.625 1.595 1.548 1.491 11.1 19.0 23.4 17.6 16.3 15.6 265.8 272.1 292.8 324.7 383.8 456.8 319.5 315.9 342.4 374.8 426.9 501.7 65.9 69.9 80.1 89.2 98.5 110.8 453.4 451.6 494.7 549.4 665.5 809.1 269.8 264.2 281.9 313.2 373.7 456.3 183.6 187.4 212.8 236.2 291.7 352.8 282.0 307.4 332.2 352.7 364.6 391.8 1.622 1.681 1.672 1.642 1.548 1,484 100.1 103.7 116.1 17.4 18.6 15.8 15.6 408.1 421.1 453.0 456.8 451.4 465.2 489.4 501.7 101.4 103.2 107.7 110.8 705.4 724.7 777.8 809.1 391.3 406.4 438.8 456.3 314.1 318.3 339.0 352.8 375.6 383.5 391.7 391.8 1.532 1.529 1.504 1.484 110.2 111.4 15.1 13.9 471.2 464.2 519.5 525.7 119.3 318.7 838.3 828.1 467.9 463.1 370.4 364.9 397.0 405,7 1.474 1.490 254.7 269.7 288.2 305.6 336.0 364.0 386.2 426.5 473.6 34.8 37,1 39.8 40.5 42.8 41,9 45,5 48.2 47,9 492.3 529.6 599.3 697.8 790.7 16.5 16.8 16.7 15.8 U3.1 FTC-FRB series:1 1974 1975. 1976.. . 1977. ... 1978.... 1979.. . 1979: I. II. II! IV. 1980: I. 1 2 3 4 5 6 Includes time certificates of deposit. Includes Federal agency issues. Total current assets divided by total current liabilities. Excludes banks, savings and loan associations, and insurance companies. Based on data from "Statistics of Income," Department of the Treasury. Excludes banks, savings and loan associations, insurance companies, investment companies, finance companies (personal and commercial), real estate companies, and security and commodity brokers, dealers, and exchanges. 7 Based on data from "Quarterly Financial Report for Manufacturing, Mining, and Trade Corporations," Federal Trade Commission. See "Federal Reserve Bulletin," July 1978, for details regarding the series. Note.-SEC series not available after 1974. Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Federal Trade Commission, and Securities and Exchange Commission. 333 TABLE B-89-—State and municipal and corporate securities offered, 1934-80 [Millions of dollars] Year or quarter Corporate securities offered for cash State and municipal Type of corporate security Industry of corporate issuer securities offered Total for cash corporate Common Preferred Bonds Manufac- Electric, Transpor- Communigas, and (princi- offerings and tation a cation stock stock turing l water 2 pal notes amounts) Other 939 397 372 67 133 176 1939... 1,128 2,164 87 98 1,979 604 1,271 186 103 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1,238 956 524 435 661 2,677 2,667 1,062 1,170 3,202 108 110 34 56 163 183 167 112 124 369 2,386 2,389 917 990 2,670 992 848 539 510 1,061 1,203 1,357 472 477 1,422 324 366 48 161 609 159 96 4 21 109 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 795 1,157 2,324 2,690 2,907 6,011 6,900 6,577 7,078 6,052 397 891 779 614 736 758 1,127 782 492 425 4,855 4,882 5,036 5,973 4,890 2,026 3,701 2,742 2,226 1,414 2,319 2,158 3,257 2,187 2,320 1,454 711 286 755 800 902 571 211 329 293 1,008 946 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 3,532 3,189 4,401 5,558 6,969 6,362 7,741 9,534 8,898 9,516 811 1,212 1,369 1,326 1,213 631 838 564 489 816 4,920 5,691 7,601 7,083 7,488 1,200 3,122 4,039 2,254 2,268 2,649 2,455 2,675 3,029 3,713 813 494 992 595 778 399 612 760 882 720 1,300 1,058 1,068 2,138 2,037 1955 1956.. , 1957 1958 1959 5,977 5,446 6,958 7,449 7,681 10,240 10,939 12,884 11,558 9,748 2,185 2,301 2,516 1,334 2,027 635 636 411 571 531 7,420 8,002 9,957 9,653 7,190 2,994 3,647 4,234 3,515 2,073 2,464 2,529 3,938 3,804 3,258 893 724 824 824 967 1,132 1,419 1,462 1,424 717 2,757 2,619 2,426 1,991 2,733 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 7,230 8,360 8,558 10,107 10,544 10,154 13,165 10,705 12,211 13,957 1,664 3,294 1,314 1,011 2,679 409 8,081 450 9,420 422 8,969 343 10,856 412 10,865 2,152 4,077 3,249 3,514 3,046 2,851 3,032 2,825 2,677 2,760 718 694 567 957 982 1,050 1,834 1,303 1,105 2,189 3,383 3,527 2,761 3,957 4,980 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 11,148 11,089 14,288 16,374 11,460 14,782 17,385 24,014 21,261 25,997 1,473 1,901 1,927 3,885 7,640 724 580 881 636 691 12,585 14,904 21,206 16,740 17,666 5,414 7,056 11,069 6,958 6,346 2,934 3,666 4,935 5,293 6,715 702 1,494 1,639 1,564 1,779 945 2,003 1,975 1,775 2,172 4,787 3,167 4,396 5,671 8,985 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 17,762 24,370 22,941 22,953 22,824 37,451 43,229 39,705 31,680 37,820 7,037 9,485 10,707 7,642 4,050 1,390 3,683 3.371 3,341 2,273 29,023 30,061 25,628 20,700 31,497 10,647 11,651 6,398 4,832 10,511 11,009 11,721 11,314 10,269 12,836 1,253 1,148 860 811 1,005 5,291 9,252 5,840 12,867 4,836 16,298 4,872 10,897 3,932 9,632 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 29,326 33,845 45,060 46,215 42,261 53,632 53,314 54,229 48,212 53,015 7,414 8,305 8,047 7,937 8,709 3,459 2,803 3,916 2,832 3,525 42,759 42,206 42,266 37,443 40,781 18,652 15,496 13,757 11,062 11,552 15,893 14,418 13,704 12,253 13,687 3,637 4,649 3,218 2,696 3,294 4,466 3,562 4,443 3,640 4,694 1980: First 3 quarters 36,089 61,602 12,670 2,614 46,318 19,709 12,860 2,884 5,431 20,719 1979: I || IN IV 9,722 10,526 9,872 12,142 12,038 15,104 13,662 12,211 1,910 1,447 2,250 3,102 556 9,572 611 13,046 1,438 9,974 920 8,189 2,096 3,300 3,659 2,497 3,287 3,346 3,057 3,997 720 895 899 780 7,836 15,361 12,892 17,721 25,097 18,784 5,354 3,462 3,854 910 11,457 807 20,828 897 14,033 6,548 7,110 6,051 4,716 4,176 3,968 890 840 1,154 1934 1980: 1 2 3 1,569 779 1,103 1,243 10,983 15,194 19,113 18,565 19,797 4,365 6,788 4,946 3,697 1,278 4,289 2,142 10,830 2,011 5,600 Prior to 1948, also includes extractive, radio broadcasting, airline companies, commercial, and miscellaneous company issues. Prior to 1948, also includes telephone, street railway, and bus company issues. Prior to 1948, includes railroad issues only. Note.=Covers substantially all new issues of State, municipal, and corporate securities offered for cash sale in the United States in amounts over $100,000 and with terms to maturity of more than 1 year; excludes notes issued exclusively to commercial banks, intercorporate transactions, and issues to be sold over an extended period, such as employee-purchase plans. Closed-end investment company issues are included beginning 1973. Sources: Securities and Exchange Commission, "The Commercial and Financial Chronicle" and "The Bond Buyer." 334 TABLE B-90.—Common stock prices and yields, 1949-80 Common stock prices * New York Stock Exchange indexes (Dec. 31, 1965=50) 2 Year or month Composite Industrial Transportation Utility Finance Common stock yields (percent) s DowJones industrial average3 Standard & Poor's composite index (194143=10)4 Dividendprice ratio 6 Earningsprice ratio 7 1949 9.02 179.48 15.23 6.59 15.48 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 10.87 13 08 13.81 13.67 1619 21.54 24.40 23.67 24.56 30.73 216.31 257.64 270.76 275.97 333.94 442.72 493.01 475.71 491.66 632.12 18.40 22.34 24.50 24.73 29.69 40.49 46.62 44.38 46.24 57.38 6.57 6.13 5.80 5.80 4 95 4.08 4.09 4.35 3.97 3.23 13.99 11.82 9.47 10.26 8.57 7.95 7.55 7.89 6.23 5.78 30.01 35.37 33.49 37.51 43.76 47.39 46.15 50.77 55.37 54.67 46.18 51.97 58.00 57.44 ' 50.26 53.51 50.58 46.96 ' 45.41 45.43 44.19 42.80 44.45 ' 49.82 65.85 70.49 618.04 691.55 639.76 714.81 834.05 910.88 873.60 879.12 906.00 876.72 55.85 66.27 62.38 69.87 81.37 88.17 85.26 91.93 98.70 97.84 3.47 2.98 3.37 3.17 3.01 3.00 3.40 3.20 3.07 3.24 5.90 4.62 5.82 5.50 5.32 5.59 6.63 5.73 5.67 6.08 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 45.72 54.22 60 29 57.42 43.84 45.73 54.46 53.69 53.70 58.32 48.03 57.92 65 73 63.08 48.08 50.52 60.44 57.86 58.23 64.76 32.14 44.35 50.17 37.74 31.89 31.10 39.57 41.09 43.50 47.34 37.24 39.53 38.48 37.69 29.79 31.50 36.97 40.92 39.22 38.21 60.00 70.38 78.35 70.12 49.67 47.14 52.94 55.25 56.65 61.42 753.19 884.76 950.71 923.88 759.37 802.49 974.92 894.63 820.23 844.40 83.22 98.29 109 20 107.43 82.85 86.16 102.01 98.20 96.02 103.01 3.83 3.14 2 84 3.06 4.47 4.31 3.77 4.62 5,28 5.47 6.45 5.41 5 50 7.12 11.59 9.15 8.90 10.79 12.03 13.46 1980 68.10 78.70 60.61 37.35 64.25 891.41 118.78 5.26 55.77 55.08 56.19 57.50 56.21 57.61 61.31 60.37 61.89 63.63 62.21 63.57 43.69 42.27 43.22 45.92 45.60 47.54 38.83 39.21 38.94 38.63 37.48 38.44 57.59 56.09 57.65 59.50 58.80 61.87 837.39 825.18 847.84 864.96 837.41 838.65 99.71 98.23 100.11 102.07 99.73 101.73 5.33 5.48 5,41 5.35 5.58 5.53 Nov Dec 58.38 61.19 61.89 59.27 59.02 61.75 64.24 67.71 69.17 66.68 66.45 69.82 48.85 52.48 52.21 48.09 47.61 50.59 38.88 39.26 38.39 36.58 36.55 37.29 64.43 68.40 67.21 61.64 60.64 63.21 836.95 873.55 878.50 840.39 815.78 836.14 102.71 107.36 108.60 104.47 103.66 107.78 5.50 5.30 5.31 5.56 5.71 5.53 1980: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June 63 74 66.06 59.52 58 47 61.38 65.43 72 67 76.42 68.71 66 31 69.39 74.47 52 61 57.92 51.77 48.62 51.07 54.04 37 08 36.22 33.38 35.29 37.31 38.53 64 22 61.84 54.71 57.32 61.47 65.16 860 74 878.22 803.56 786.33 828.19 869.86 110 87 115.34 104.69 102.97 107.69 114.55 5 41 5.24 5.87 6.05 5.77 5.39 68.56 70.87 73.12 75.17 78.15 76.69 78.67 82.15 84.92 88.00 92.32 90.37 59.14 62.48 65.89 70.76 77.23 75.74 38.77 38.18 38.77 38.44 38.35 37.84 66.76 67.22 69.33 68.29 67.21 67.46 909.79 947.33 946.67 949.17 971.08 945.96 119.83 123.50 126.51 130.22 135.65 133.48 5.20 5.06 4.90 4.80 4.63 4.74 . . . . 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964. . 1965 1966 1967.. 1968 1969 . . . . . .. 1979: Jan Feb Mar May' June ."..' July... . Aug S1- ... . . • •.-.:•: .. J""y Aug Sept Oct . Nov . Dec . ... 1 13.09 13.58 13.38 13.77 14.98 13.08 Averages of daily closing prices, except New York Stock Exchange data through May 1964 are averages of weekly closing prices. Includes alt the stocks (more than 1,500) listed on the New York Stock Exchange. Includes 30 stocks. * Includes 500 stocks. 5 Standard & Poor's series, based on 500 stocks in the composite index. 6 Aggregate cash dividends {based on latest known annual rate) divided by aggregate market value based on Wednesday closing prices. Monthly data are averages of weekly figures; annual data are averages of monthly figures. 7 Ratio of quarterly earnings after taxes (seasonally adjusted annual rate) to price index for last day of quarter. Annual ratios are averages of quarterly ratios. 2 3 Note.—All data relate to stocks listed on the New York Stock Exchange. Sources: New York Stock Exchange, Dow-Jones & Co., Inc., and Standard & Poor's Corporation. 335 TABLE B-91.—Business formation and business failures, 1929-80 Business failures1 Year or month Index fit nat or net business formation (1967= 100) Amount of current liabilities (millions of dollars) Number of failures New business incorporations (number) Business failure rate2 103.9 100 3 69.6 63.0 54.4 44.6 16.4 6.5 4.2 52 14.3 20.4 34.4 Liability size class Total Under $100,000 $100,000 and over 22,909 19,859 14,768 13,619 11,848 9,405 3,221 1,222 809 1,129 3,474 5,250 9,246 22,165 18,880 14,541 13,400 11,685 9,282 3,155 1,176 759 1,003 3,103 4,853 8,708 744 979 111 219 163 123 66 46 50 126 371 397 538 Liability size class Total Under $100,000 $100,000 and over 483.3 457.5 182.5 166.7 136.1 100.8 45.3 31.7 30.2 67.3 204.6 234.6 308.1 261.5 215.5 132.9 119.9 100.7 80.3 30.2 14.5 11.4 15.7 63.7 93.9 161.4 221.8 242.0 49.7 46.8 35.4 20.5 15.1 17.1 18.8 51.6 140.9 140.7 146.7 1929 1933 n 1939 3 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949, 104.8 " 86.4 132 916 112,897 96,346 85,640 1950.. 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 90.8 90.1 94.5 92.4 90.8 98.2 95.4 91.4 91.1 98.1 93.092 83,778 92,946 102,706 117,411 139,915 141,163 137,112 150 781 193,067 34.3 30.7 28.7 33,2 42.0 41.6 48.0 51.7 55 9 51.8 9,162 8,058 7,611 8,862 11,086 10,969 12,686 13,739 14,964 14,053 8,746 7,626 7,081 8,075 10,226 10,113 11,615 12,547 13,499 12,707 416 432 530 787 860 856 1,071 1,192 1,465 1.346 248.3 259.5 283.3 394.2 462.6 449.4 562.7 615.3 728.3 692.8 151.2 131.6 131.9 167.5 211.4 206.4 239.8 267.1 297.6 278.9 97.1 128.0 151.4 226.6 251.2 243.0 322.9 348.2 430.7 413.9 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 94.5 91.1 92.8 94.7 98.0 99.5 98.9 100.0 107.6 113.5 182,713 181,535 182,057 186,404 197,724 203,897 200,010 206,569 233,635 274,267 57.0 64.4 60.8 56.3 53.2 53.3 51.6 49.0 38.6 37.3 15,445 17,075 15,782 14,374 13,501 13,514 13,061 12,364 9,636 9,154 13,650 15,006 13,772 12,192 11,346 11,340 10,833 10,144 7,829 7,192 1,795 2,069 2,010 2,182 2,155 2,174 2,228 2,220 1,807 1,962 938.6 1,090.1 1,213.6 1,352.6 1,329.2 1,321.7 1,385.7 1,265.2 941.0 1,142.1 327.2 370.1 346.5 321.0 313.6 321.7 321.5 297.9 241.1 231.3 611.4 720.0 867.1 1,031.6 1,015.6 1,000.0 1,064.1 967.3 699.9 910.8 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 107.1 109.5 115.5 115.5 111.2 108.8 117.2 126.5 132.9 131.7 264,209 287,577 316,601 329,358 319,149 326,345 375,766 432,172 478,019 524,565 43.8 41.7 38.3 36.4 38.4 42.6 34.8 28.4 23.9 27.8 10,748 10,326 9,566 9,345 9,915 11,432 9,628 7,919 6,619 7,564 8,019 7,611 7,040 6,627 6,733 7,504 6,176 4,861 3,712 3,930 2,729 2,715 2,526 2,718 3,182 3,928 3,452 3,058 2,907 3,634 1,887.8 1,916.9 2,000.2 2,298.6 3,053.1 4,380.2 3,011.3 3,095.3 2,656.0 2,667.4 269.3 271.3 258.8 235.6 256.9 298.6 257.8 208.3 164.7 179.9 1,618.4 1,645.6 1,741.5 2,063.0 2,796.3 4,081.6 2,753.4 2,887.0 2,491.3 2,487.5 5easonally adjusted 1979: Jan Feb.".. Apr May June 131.3 132.1 132.5 130.9 130.5 130.9 42,410 42,302 42,761 43 034 43 895 43,044 27.4 24.4 27.9 30 8 291 26.2 642 545 732 734 708 602 355 291 379 397 380 307 287 254 353 337 328 295 182.2 177.1 187.8 242.8 200 4 273.2 15.1 12.8 18.0 16,8 16.8 13.8 167.1 164.3 169.8 226.0 183.7 259.4 Julv Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 1318 130.3 132.5 131.9 131.4 133.9 44 655 42,911 44,687 46,478 44,811 43,579 27 5 32.9 26.1 33.6 23.1 24,9 565 736 505 767 519 509 285 412 248 374 260 242 280 324 257 393 259 267 212 2 287.4 186.2 395.8 184.3 138.0 139 18.0 11.4 17.5 13.7 12.2 198 3 269.4 174.8 378.3 170.6 125.8 June ft ...v . 131.0 129.8 125.8 120.5 117.8 114.8 44,447 44,583 42,615 42,461 41,974 39,746 30.9 27.5 36.2 42.2 39.3 48.7 729 677 925 1,068 975 1,094 363 330 452 525 452 522 366 347 473 543 523 572 243.1 190.8 274.2 428.2 381.1 436.7 17.0 15.5 21.7 24.4 22.0 25.2 226.2 175.3 252.5 403.8 359.2 411.5 July Aug Sept Oct 115.3 117.7 120.6 117.6 44,058 43,266 46,488 47,225 52.0 45.4 45.0 1,141 1,009 926 1,340 531 486 465 610 523 461 445.7 345.4 1,002.9 26.3 23.2 22.2 419.4 322.2 980.7 Mar .. 1980: Jan, Feb.. . Mar . . 1 Commercial and industrial failures only. Excludes failures of banks and railroads and, beginning 1933, of real estate, insurance, holding, and financial companies, steamship lines, travel agencies, etc. 2 Failure rate per 10,000 listed enterprises. " Series revised; not strictly comparable with earlier data. Sources: Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic Analysis) and Dun & Bradstreet, Inc. 336 AGRICULTURE TABLE B-92.—Farm income 1929-80 [Billions of dollars; Quarterly data at seasonally adjusted annual rates] Income of farm operators from farming Net farm income Gross farm income Produc- Cash marketing receipts Year or quarter Total1 Total Livestock and products Crops Value of inventory changes 2 expenses Current dollars 1967 dollars3 7.7 44 6.3 6.2 26 4.4 66 106 10.7 5.3 7.9 6.2 28 4.5 5.1 25 3.3 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 11.3 14.3 19.9 23.3 24.0 25.4 29.6 32.4 36.5 30.8 8.4 4.9 3.5 .3 6.9 4.5 11.1 15.6 19.6 20.5 21.7 24.8 29.6 '30.2 27.8 6.5 9.0 11.5 11.4 12.0 13.8 16.5 17.1 15.4 4.6 6.5 8,1 9.2 9.7 11.0 13.1 13.1 12.4 .4 1.1 -.1 -.4 -.4 .0 -1.8 1.7 -.9 7.8 10.0 11.6 12.3 13.1 14.5 17.0 18.8 18.0 6.5 9.9 11.7 11.7 12.3 15.1 15.4 177 12.8 10.7 14.7 20 2 22.7 22 2 22.8 25.8 23.0 24.5 17.9 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 331 38 3 37.8 34 4 34.2 33 5 34.0 34 8 39.0 37.9 28.5 32.9 32.5 31.0 29.8 29.5 30.4 29.7 33.5 33.6 16.1 19 6 18.2 16.9 16.3 160 16.4 17 4 19.2 18.9 12.4 13.2 14.3 14.1 13.6 13 5 14.0 12 3 14.2 14.7 .8 -.5 6 .8 .0 19.5 22.3 22.8 21.5 21.8 22.2 22.7 23.7 25.8 27.2 13.6 15 9 15.0 13 0 12.4 113 11.3 111 13.2 10.7 18.9 20 5 18.8 16 2 15.4 141 13.8 131 15.2 12.3 I960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 389 40.5 42 3 43.4 42 3 46.5 50 5 50.5 518 56.4 34.2 35.2 36.5 37.5 37.3 39.4 43.4 42.8 44.2 48.2 19.0 19.5 20.2 20.0 19.9 21.9 25.0 24.4 25.5 28.6 15.3 15.7 16.3 17.4 17 2 17.5 18.4 18.4 18.7 19.6 .4 .3 .6 .6 _ 8 1.0 _ 1 .7 .1 .1 27.4 28.6 30.3 31.6 31.8 33.7 36.5 38.2 39.5 42.1 11.5 12.0 12.1 11.8 10.5 12.9 14.0 12.3 12.3 14.3 13 0 12.3 13 3 12.8 113 13.7 14.4 12.3 118 13.0 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 58 6 62 0 71.0 98.9 98.3 100 3 1018 108.1 126.9 149.6 50.5 52 9 61.2 87.1 92.4 88.2 94 8 95.8 112.5 131.5 29 6 30 6 35.7 45.9 41.4 43 0 0 47.4 59.0 68.6 210 22 3 25.5 41.1 51.1 451 48 7 48.3 53.5 62.8 .9 3.4 -1.6 34 -2 4 .6 .4 4.1 44.4 47 4 52.3 65.6 72.2 75.9 83.1 90.3 100.8 118.6 14.2 14 6 18.7 33.3 26.1 24.5 18 7 17.8 26.1 31.0 III IV 119.7 123.5 126.3 138.0 105.5 109.8 112.7 122.2 53.0 58.0 60.6 64.6 52.5 51.8 52.1 57.6 .5 .3 .4 .4 97.4 98.8 100.1 106.9 22.3 24.7 26.2 31.1 11.8 12.8 13.2 15.4 1979: I || Ill IV 145.5 149.1 149.9 154.1 128.9 130.9 130.6 135.4 69.7 68.2 66.9 69.7 59.2 62.7 63.7 65.7 3.2 3.9 5.4 3.9 114.2 116.3 119.6 124.2 31.3 32.8 30.3 29.9 15.1 15.3 13.7 13.1 1521 1518 158.6 137.2 136.4 142.8 67.9 69.2 70 8 1.0 70.5 72.3 -3.9 127.2 129.9 132.9 25.9 23.4 21.8 10.9 656 1929 1933 1939 13.8 .... . . . . 69 11.3 461 -0.1 2 .1 12 .9 - 6 2 14 12.0 12 2 121 14.9 25.1 17.7 15 2 110 9.8 13.3 14.2 1978: j || 1980: I || , ... Ill 15 96 8.8 'Cash marketing receipts and inventory changes plus Government payments, other farm cash income, and nonmoney income furnished by farms. 2 Physical changes in end-of-period inventory of crop and livestock commodities valued at average prices during the period. 3 Income in current dollars divided by the consumer price index (Department of Labor). Source: Department of Agriculture, except as noted. 337 TABLE B-93.—Farm output ami productivity indexes, 1929-80 11967 «100] Farm output Productivity indicators Crops2 Year Total' 1929. .. Total:! Feed grains Food grains Oil crops Livestock and products11 Farm output Crop per prounit duction per of acre 4 total input Farm output per hour of farm work Total 53 53 1933 , Crops Livestock and products 16 26 15 25 1939 ... . 25 20 27 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944... 29 29 40 41 36 20 21 24 24 24 21 23 25 24 25 27 28 30 31 30 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 36 34 39 47 45 26 27 28 31 32 27 29 29 33 33 31 32 33 34 35 1950 1951 1952.... 1953. 1954 46 47 46 47 49 34 35 38 39 42 36 35 39 40 42 37 39 40 41 43 1955... . 1956 1957 1958... 1959... 53 60 58 69 64 44 47 51 57 59 45 48 53 61 61 46 48 50 54 58 1960 1961 1962.... 1963 1964 87 87 68 77 78 81 81 87 91 92 95 97 90 91 92 96 95 92 95 97 95 65 67 71 77 81 66 68 72 77 79 62 66 71 77 82 88 100 106 98 95 97 100 114 116 95 97 100 100 101 100 97 100 102 103 100 97 100 105 106 89 92 100 106 110 90 94 100 106 108 86 93 100 105 112 89 116 112 115 93 91 107 102 114 120 117 121 131 155 127 105 106 107 105 106 102 110 110 111 105 104 112 115 116 104 115 128 136 130 136 111 126 135 138 128 121 128 137 144 156 121 121 129 131 144 114 120 126 135 145 142 141 132 125 143 153 132 175 182 219 101 105 106 106 110 115 115 114 116 119 112 111 117 121 130 152 162 173 183 184 142 146 158 166 171 160 178 189 204 195 129 119 157 168 112 115 113 189 166 224 91 91 92 96 95 93 91 92 96 94 1965.. .. 1966 1967 ., 1968. . 1969.... 98 95 100 102 102 99 95 100 103 104 89 100 95 99 1970 1971 .. 1972 1973 . . 1974.... 101 110 110 112 106 100 112 113 119 110 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 114 117 119 122 129 1980" 123 1 Farm output measures the annual volume of net farm production available for eventual human use through sales from farms or consumption in farm households. a Gross production. :| Includes items not included in groups shown. 4 Computed from variable weights for individual crops produced each year. Source: Department of Agriculture. 338 TABLE B-94.—Farm input use, selected inputs, 1929-80 Farm population (April I ) 1 Year Number (thousands) As percent of total population 2 Farm employment (thousands) 3 Total Selected indexes of input use (1967 = 100) Fam- Hired ily work- work- Crops harvested (millions of acres) 4 Total Farm labor Farm real tate Mechanical power and machinery Agricultural chemicals 5 Feed, seed, and livestock purchases6 10 31 1929 30,580 25.1 12,763 9,360 3,403 365 102 329 103 1933 32,393 25.8 12,739 9,874 2,865 340 96 321 97 28 1939 . 30,840 23.5 11,338 8,611 2,727 331 294 102 41 1940 . 1941. 1942 . 1943 1944 30,547 30,118 28,914 26,186 24,815 23.1 22.6 21.4 19.2 17.9 10,979 10,669 10,504 10,446 10,219 8,300 8.017 7,949 8,010 7,988 2,679 2,652 2,555 2,436 2,231 341 344 348 357 362 100 100 103 104 105 293 288 296 292 289 103 102 100 98 98 13 14 15 17 20 42 45 48 52 52 1945 . 1946. 1947.. 1948 .. 1949 . 24,420 25,403 25,829 24,383 24,194 17.5 18.0 17.9 16.6 16.2 10,000 10,295 10,382 10,363 9,964 7,881 8,106 8,115 8,026 7,712 2,119 2,189 2,267 2,337 2,252 354 352 355 356 360 103 101 101 103 105 271 260 246 240 231 98 102 103 103 104 20 21 23 25 27 54 53 55 56 61 1950.. 1951. 1952 1953 1954 . 23,048 21,890 21;748 19,874 19,019 15.2 14.2 13.9 12.5 11.7 9,926 9,546 9,149 8,864 8,651 7,597 7,310 7,005 6,775 6,570 2,329 2,236 2,144 2,089 2,081 345 344 349 348 346 104 107 107 106 105 217 218 208 200 192 105 105 105 105 105 84 90 94 96 96 29 32 35 36 37 63 67 69 69 71 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 19,078 18,712 17,656 17,128 16,592 11.5 11.1 10.3 9.8 9.4 8,381 7,852 7,600 7,503 7,342 6,345 2,036 5,900 1,952 5,660 1,940 5,521 1,982 5,390 1,952 340 324 324 324 324 105 103 101 100 102 185 174 162 156 151 105 102 102 100 101 97 98 97 97 98 39 41 41 43 49 72 75 74 79 84 1960 1961 1962 1963. 1964 15,635 14,803 14,313 13,367 12,954 8.7 8.1 7.7 7.1 6.8 7,057 6,919 6,700 6,518 6,110 5,172 5,029 4,873 4,738 4,506 1,885 1,890 1,827 1,780 1,604 324 302 295 298 298 101 100 100 100 100 145 139 133 129 122 100 100 100 100 100 97 94 94 93 93 49 53 58 65 71 84 88 90 90 92 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 12,363 11,595 10,875 10,454 10,307 6.4 5.9 5.5 5.2 5.1 5,610 5,214 4,903 4,749 4,596 4,128 1,482 3,854 1,360 3,650 1,253 3,535 1,213 3,419 1,176 298 294 306 300 290 98 98 100 100 99 110 103 100 97 93 99 99 100 99 98 94 96 100 101 101 75 85 100 105 111 93 97 100 97 101 9,712 9,425 9,610 9,472 9,264 4.7 4.6 4.6 4.5 4.4 4,523 4,436 4,373 4,337 4,389 3,348 1,175 3,275 1,161 3,228 1,146 3,169 1,168 3,075 1,314 293 305 294 321 328 100 100 100 101 100 101 99 98 97 95 100 102 101 105 109 115 124 131 136 140 104 111 113 116 107 8,864 8,253 6,194 6,501 6,241 4.2 3.8 '2.9 7 3.0 7 2.8 4,342 4,374 4,155 3,957 3,774 3,026 2,997 2,859 2,689 2,501 1,317 1,377 1,296 1,267 1,273 336 337 344 337 348 100 103 105 105 108 96 97 99 97 96 113 116 120 125 129 127 145 154 160 182 101 110 112 115 120 6,100 7 3,790 2,485 1,305 97 125 183 121 1970 1971 1972 . 1973 1974. 1975 1976 1977 1978 . 1979 1980 " 7 7 7 7 2.7 107 65 'Farm population as defined by Department of Agriculture and Department of Commerce, i.e., civilian population living on farms, regardless of occupation. See also footnote 7. 2 Total population of United States as of July 1, including Armed Forces overseas. Data from 1980 census not yet available. 3 Includes persons doing farmwork on atf farms. These data, published by the Department of Agriculture, differ from those on agricultural employment by the Department of Labor (see Table 8-29) because of differences in the method of approach in concepts of employment, and in time of month for which the data are collected. See quarterly report on "Farm Labor," 4 Acreage harvested plus acreages in fruits, tree nuts, and farm gardens, s Fertilizer, lime, and pesticides. e Nonfarm constant dollar value of feed, seed, and livestock purchases. 7 Based on new definition of a farm. Under old definition of a farm, farm population (in thousands and as percent of total population) for 1977, 1978, and 1979 is 7,806 and 3.6; 8,005 and 3.7; and 7,553 and 3.4, respectively. Sources: Department of Agriculture and Department of Commerce (Bureau of the Census). 339 TABLE B-95.—Indexes ofprices received and prices paid by farmers, 1940-80 [1967^=1003 Prices paid by farmers Prices received by farmers All farm products . . June July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec Livestock and products Production items Total2 Tractors and selfpropelled machinery Fertilizer Fuels and energy Wage rates3 103 107 106 103 106 100 100 97 100 108 114 175 224 201 197 192 203 223 239 40 50 62 72 71 77 88 105 115 99 102 122 111 97 90 85 82 89 99 93 92 91 93 89 86 94 106 100 104 117 118 118 136 183 165 172 177 175 217 257 251 36 39 44 50 53 56 61 70 76 73 75 82 84 81 81 81 81 84 86 87 88 88 90 91 92 94 99 100 103 108 112 118 125 144 164 180 192 202 219 250 280 43 45 52 57 60 61 67 78 87 83 86 95 95 89 89 87 87 90 92 93 92 93 94 95 94 96 100 100 100 104 108 113 121 146 166 182 193 200 217 248 275 92 96 100 104 111 116 122 128 137 161 195 217 238 259 289 323 103 102 100 94 87 88 91 94 102 167 217 185 181 180 196 243 98 98 100 101 102 104 107 108 116 159 177 187 202 212 276 380 15 18 23 31 38 42 46 49 52 51 50 55 59 61 60 61 63 66 68 72 74 76 78 80 82 86 93 100 108 119 128 134 142 155 178 192 210 226 242 265 286 233 242 246 245 246 244 244 238 240 236 238 239 209 216 214 213 220 234 238 236 226 224 226 222 253 265 274 274 270 255 249 242 254 247 251 255 235 239 244 247 249 249 252 251 255 257 258 260 231 236 244 247 248 248 251 249 254 256 256 258 272 111 280 280 280 293 293 293 302 302 302 302 179 179 187 187 194 194 194 194 194 211 211 222 226 229 235 246 256 270 285 298 308 314 318 324 257 257 257 269 269 269 266 266 266 269 269 269 236 238 234 224 227 232 247 256 261 260 264 261 220 220 220 217 223 226 242 250 259 259 270 266 252 255 247 232 232 237 252 262 263 263 260 258 269 271 274 274 275 278 280 283 286 288 290 291 263 266 270 268 268 270 273 278 282 284 287 287 302 302 317 317 317 325 325 325 337 337 337 337 222 222 244 244 248 248 248 248 248 246 246 247 345 365 378 384 385 387 388 385 385 383 386 390 284 284 284 284 284 284 288 288 289 288 288 288 40 48 64 83 88 90 102 117 113 100 103 118 119 107 108 103 104 100 99 to 40 49 64 77 79 83 94 110 115 100 103 121 115 102 98 93 92 94 100 96 95 96 98 97 95 98 106 100 102 107 110 113 125 179 192 185 186 183 210 241 245 — CO OO 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945.. . 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951... . 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971.. 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1979: Jan Feb Mar Apr . May June .... July, Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 1980: Jan Feb Mar Crops 5to Year or month All commodities, services, interest, taxes, and wage rates • 1 Addendum: Average farm real estate value per acre4 19 19 21 23 26 29 32 36 39 41 40 46 51 52 51 53 55 58 61 66 68 69 73 77 82 86 93 100 107 113 117 122 132 150 187 213 242 283 308 351 404 '351 379 404 —-• Includes items used for family living, not shown separately. Includes other items not shown separately. Seasonal^ adjusted; annual data are averages of seasonally adjusted data. Average for 48 States. Annual data are for March 1 of each year through 1975 and for February 1 beginning 1976. Monthly data are for first of month. Source: Department of Agriculture. 2 :> 4 340 TABLE B-96.—U.S. exports and imports of agricultural commodities, 2940-80 [Billions of dollars] Imports Exports Year Total 1 Food Feed grains grains 2 Oilseeds and products 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 o.r 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 2.3 3.1 4.0 3.5 3.6 SI .4 .1 .3 .4 .7 1.4 1.5 1.1 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 2.9 4.0 3.4 28 3.1 .2 .3 .3 3 .2 .6 1.1 1.1 7 .5 .2 .3 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 3.2 4.2 4.5 3.9 4.0 .3 .4 .3 .5 .6 .6 1.0 1.0 .8 .9 4.8 5.0 5.0 5.6 6.3 .5 .5 .8 .8 .9 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 6.2 6.9 6.4 6.3 6.0 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 '4 4 4 4 4 Cotton Tobacco 0.2 .1 .1 .2 .1 El Animals and products Total 1 .1 0.1 .3 .8 1,2 1.3 1.3 1.7 1.3 1.5 1.8 .3 .5 .4 .5 .9 .2 A .3 .2 .3 .9 .9 .7 .5 .4 1.7 2.3 2,8 3.1 2.9 1.0 1.1 .9 5 .8 .3 .3 .3 .5 .3 .4 .5 4.0 5.2 4.5 4.2 4.0 A .5 .5 .4 .6 .5 .7 1.0 .7 .4 .4 .3 .4 .4 .3 .6 .7 .7 .5 .6 1.2 1.4 1.3 1.5 1.7 .6 .6 .7 .8 1.0 1.0 .9 .5 .6 .7 .4 .4 .4 A A 1.1 1.3 1.1 .9 .9 1.4 1.8 1.5 1.4 1.2 1.2 1.2 1.3 1.3 1.3 .5 .4 .5 A .5 '.3 !e 7.3 7.7 9.4 17.7 22.0 1.1 1.0 15 3.5 4.6 1.4 1.3 1.8 4.7 5.4 1.9 2.2 2.4 4.3 5.7 A .6 .5 .9 1.3 .5 .5 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 21.9 23.0 23.6 29.4 34.7 5.2 6.0 4.9 5.9 7.7 6.2 4.7 3.6 5.5 6.3 4.5 5.1 6.6 8.2 8.9 Jan-Oci: 1979 1980 27.3 33.2 6.1 7.7 5.1 6,3 6.8 7.5 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 .7 1.2 2.1 2.1 .. . $ .'3 .2 Crops, fruits, and vegetabfes" Animals and products El 0.2 .3 '1 A .3 Coffee AgriCocoa cultural beans trade and prod- balance ucts 0.1 .2 .2 .3 .3 -0.8 -1.0 .3 .4 .4 .4 .6 .3 .5 .6 .7 .8 El .2 .2 .2 .7 1.1 .2 .2 .2 .5 1.1 1.4 1.4 15 1.5 4.0 4.0 4.0 3.9 4.1 .2 .5 .4 .5 .2 .2 .2 .2 '.B 1.4 1.4 1.4 1.2 1.1 -.8 2 .2 _ i .6 .6 .6 .7 .8 3.8 3.7 3.9 4.0 4.1 .2 .2 .2 .3 .3 .6 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.2 .2 .9 .9 .8 1.0 1.3 1.2 1.6 2.3 .8 .7 .7 .7 .8 4.1 4.5 4.5 5.0 5.0 .3 .4 .4 .5 .9 1.2 1.1 1.3 1.4 1.1 1.1 1.0 1.2 .9 5.8 5.8 6.5 8.4 10.2 .5 .6 .8 .8 1.6 1.5 1.8 2.6 2.2 1.2 1.2 1.3 1.7 1.6 .2 .3 .9 .9 1.0 1.1 1.6 1.8 1.5 1.9 2.9 9.3 11.8 1.0 1.0 1.5 1.7 2.2 .9 .9 1.1 1.4 1.2 1.7 2.4 2.7 3.0 3.8 9.3 11.0 13.4 14.8 16.7 .8 .9 1.2 1.5 1.7 1.8 2.3 2.3 19 1.7 2.9 4.2 4.0 4.2 .5 .6 1.0 1.4 1.2 12.6 12.0 10.2 14.6 18.0 1.7 2.5 .8 1.0 3.1 3.1 13.6 14.3 1.4 1.4 3.1 3.0 3.2 3.6 1.0 .8 13.7 18.8 1 Total 2 Rice, 3 .2 .1 ll .2 .2 .2 .1 ',2 2 '.2 .1 2 .2 .3 .5 8 1.2 .3 .7 -1.1 -1.1 -1.1 -13 -.9 i 2.1 2.4 1.9 1.3 1.1 includes items not shown separately. wheat, and wheat flour. includes nuts, fruits, and vegetable preparations. Hess than $50 million. Note.—Data derived from official estimates released by the Bureau of the Census, Department of Commerce. Agricultural commodities are defined as (1) nonmarine food products and (2) .other products o1 agriculture which have not passed through complex processes of manufacture. Export value, at U.S. port of exportation, is based on the selling price and includes inland freight, insurance, and other charges to the port. Import value, defined generally as the market value in the foreign country, excludes import duties, ocean freight, and marine insurance. Source: Department of Agriculture. 341 TABLE B-97.—Balance sheet of the farming sector, 1929-81 [Billions of dollars] Assets Claims Other physical assets Beginning of year Total Real estate live- Machinstock 1 ery and Crops2 motor vehicles Household equipment and furnishings Financial assets Deposits U.S. and savings curbonds rency Investments in cooperatives Total x Real estate debt Other debt Proprietors' equities 48.0 6.6 3.2 30.8 3.0 2.5 8.5 34,1 5.1 3.2 6.8 53.0 54.8 62.9 73.6 84.0 33.6 34.4 37.5 41.6 48.2 5.1 5.3 7.1 9.6 9.7 3.1 3.3 4.0 4.9 5.4 2.7 3.0 3.9 5.1 6.1 4.2 4.1 4.8 4.8 4.7 3.2 3.5 4.2 5.5 6.6 0.3 .3 .5 1.1 2.2 0.8 .9 .9 1.0 1.1 53.0 54.8 62.9 73.6 84.0 6.6 6.5 6.4 5.9 5.4 3.4 3.9 4.1 4.0 3.5 43.0 44.4 52.4 63.7 75.1 1945 1946 1947. 1948 . ... 1949.. . . 93.8 102 9 115.9 127.4 134.6 53.9 610 68.5 73.7 76.6 9.0 97 11.9 13.2 14.4 6.5 54 5.3 7.4 10.1 6.7 63 7.1 9.0 8.5 5.2 55 7.2 8.1 8.9 7.9 94 10.2 9.9 9.6 3.4 42 4.2 4.4 4.6 1.2 14 1.5 1.7 1.9 93.8 102 9 115.9 127.4 134.6 4.9 47 4.9 5,1 5.3 3.4 32 3.6 4.2 6.1 85.5 95 0 107.4 118.1 123.2 1950 1951 . . 1952 1953 1954 134.5 154.3 170.1 167.6 164.6 77.6 89.5 98.4 100.1 98.7 12.9 17.1 19.5 14.8 11.8 12.2 14.1 16.7 17,4 18.4 7.6 7.9 8.8 9.0 9.2 8.4 9.6 10.1 9.6 9.5 9.1 9.1 9.4 9.4 9.4 4.7 4.7 4.7 4.6 4.7 2.0 2.3 2.5 2.7 2.9 134.5 154.3 170.1 167.6 164.6 5.6 6.1 6.7 7.2 7.7 6.8 6.9 8.0 8.9 9.2 122.1 141.3 155.4 151.5 147,7 168.8 173.6 182.8 191.3 208.4 102.2 107.5 115.7 121.8 131.1 11.2 10.6 11.0 13.9 17.7 18.6 19.3 20.2 20.1 21.8 9.6 8.3 8.3 7.6 9.3 9.7 10.0 9.6 9.6 9.4 9.4 9.5 9.4 9.5 10.0 5.0 5.2 5.1 5.1 5.2 3.1 3.2 3.5 3.7 3.9 168.8 173.6 182.8 191.3 208.4 8.2 9.0 9.8 10.4 U.l 9.4 9.8 9.5 10.0 12.5 151.2 154.8 163.5 170.9 184.8 1960 . . . . 1961 1962 1963 1964 210.2 210.8 219.3 227.7 235.8 137.2 138.5 144.5 150.2 158.6 15.3 15.6 16.4 17.3 15.9 22.7 22.2 22.5 23.5 23.9 7.7 8.0 8.8 9.3 9.8 9.2 8.7 8.9 8.8 8.8 9.2 8.7 8.8 9.2 9.2 4.7 4.6 4.5 4.4 4.2 4.2 4.5 4.9 5.0 5.4 210.2 210.8 219.3 227.7 235.8 12.0 12.8 13.8 15.1 16.8 12.8 13.4 14.7 16.3 17.6 185.4 184.6 190.8 196.3 201.4 1965. 1966.. 1967 1968 1969 243.8 260,8 274 2 288.0 302.8 167.5 179.2 1891 199.7 209.2 14.5 17.6 19 0 18.9 20.2 24.8 26.0 27 4 29.8 31.3 9.2 9.7 10 0 9.6 10.6 8.4 8.4 83 8.8 9.4 9.6 10.0 10 3 10.9 11.5 4.2 4.0 39 3.8 3.8 5.6 5.9 62 6^5 6.8 243.8 260.8 274 2 288*0 302.8 18.9 21.2 23 l 25.1 27.4 17.9 19.5 210 22^3 23.1 207.0 220.1 230 1 240^6 252.3 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 314.9 326.0 351.8 394.8 478.5 215.8 223.2 239.6 267.3 327.7 23.5 23.7 27.3 34.1 42.4 32.3 34.4 36.6 39.3 44.2 10.9 10.7 11.8 14.5 22.1 9.6 10.0 10.8 11.9 12.3 11.9 12.4 13.2 14.0 14.9 3.7 3.6 3.7 4.0 4.1 7.2 8.0 8.8 9.7 10.8 314.9 326.0 351.8 394.8 478.5 29.2 30.3 32.2 35.7 41.3 23.8 24.2 269 29.6 32.8 261.9 271.5 292.7 329.5 404.4 1975 1976 517.6 580.2 368.5 416.9 24.6 29.5 55.7 65.0 23.3 21.3 14.0 14.2 15.1 15.6 4.3 4.4 13.3 517.6 580.2 46.3 51.1 35.5 39.7 435.8 489.4 1977 3. . 1978.. 1979. . .. 641.4 697.4 804.4 472.9 513.7 586.1 29.0 31.9 51.2 71.0 77.0 85.1 22.0 24.9 27.4 13.7 15.5 18.0 14.8 15.2 15.5 3.8 3.9 4.2 14.1 15.3 16.8 641.4 697.4 804.4 56.6 63.6 70.8 46.1 55.6 65.2 538.7 578.1 668.3 1980 . . 1981 918.9 999.3 671.2 730,3 61.2 69.9 94.3 98.0 33.1 38.3 20.5 22.5 15.9 16.2 4.0 3.6 18.6 20.5 918.9 999.3 82.1 96.1 75.2 84.4 761.6 818.8 1929. 1933. . 1939.. 1940... 1941. . 1942 1943 .. . . 1944 . . . . 1955 1956 . 1957 1958 1959 . . 9.8 1 Beginning with 1961, horses and mules are excluded. Includes all crops hetd on farms and crops held off farms by farmers as security for Commodity Credit Corporation loans. The latter on January 1, 1981 totaled approximately $1.0 billion. 3 Beginning 1977, data are for farms included in the new farm definition, that is, places with sales of $1,000 or more annually. Note.—Beginning 1960, data include Alaska and Hawaii. Source: Department of Agriculture. 2 342 INTERNATIONAL STATISTICS T A B L E B-98—Exchange rates, 2973-80 [Cents per unit of foreign currency, except as noted] Belgian franc Year and month Canadian dollar French franc German mark Italian lira Japanese yen 2.5377 100.333 22.191 35.548 0.17600 0.38190 2.5040 2.6366 2.5364 2.7158 102.877 103.481 101.384 101.192 20.742 20.408 20.831 22.109 38.211 39.603 37.580 40.816 .15687 .15379 .15103 .15179 .35454 .35340 .33439 .33288 2.9083 2.8603 2.5485 2.5311 99.954 97.426 97.437 98.627 23.804 24,971 22.367 22.428 43.120 42.726 38.191 38.144 .15842 .15982 .14740 .14645 .34731 .34077 .33345 .32715 2.5480 2.5220 2.6046 2.7483 101.431 102.712 102.557 98.204 21.657 21.109 20.334 20.055 39.064 38.797 40.169 41.965 .12113 .11780 .11837 .11521 .33276 .33424 .34800 .33933 2.7258 2.7713 2.7910 2.9608 95.125 94.549 93.168 91.132 20.075 20.240 20.314 20.844 41.812 42.453 43.034 46.499 .11276 .11295 .11318 ,11416 .35687 .36652 .37486 .41491 3.1589 3.0590 3.2207 3.3637 88.823 89.143 85.739 84.763 21.256 21.841 22.909 23.178 49.181 47.984 50.778 53.217 .11692 .11634 .12050 .11863 .43148 .46744 .52656 .51038 Mar June Sept 3.3971 3.3048 3.4684 3.5423 85.187 85.296 85.814 85.471 23.328 22.914 23.826 24.614 53.754 53.084 55.758 57.671 .11888 .11828 .12326 .12329 .48470 .45750 .44963 .41613 1980: Mar June Sept Dec 3.3395 3.5335 3.4844 3.1543 85.255 86.836 85.861 83.560 23.188 24.310 24.056 21.925 54.039 56.584 55.883 50.769 .11635 .11973 .11742 .10704 .40246 .45894 ,46644 .47747 March 1973 1974: Mar June Sept Dec 1975Mar June Sept Dec 1976. Mar June Seot Dec 1977: Mar June Sept Dec 1978: Mar June Sept Dec •":::. 1979: . . : : ; 7.'.:.. De? Netherlands guilder March 1973 1974: Mar June Sept Dec 1975Mar June Sept Dec 1976. Mar June. Sept Dec 1977. Mar June Sept Dec 1978: Mar June Sept Dec 1979: Mar June Sept Dec 1980Mar June Sept . . ... . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Dec Swedish Krona United States dollar {March 1973=100) Multilateral trade-weighted average Bilateral tradeweighted average 34.834 22.582 31.084 247.24 100.0 100.0 36.354 37.757 36.870 39.331 21.915 22.885 22.333 23,897 32.490 33.449 33.371 38.442 234.06 239.02 231.65 232.94 101.6 100.0 102.9 98.6 100.9 99.9 103.0 101.0 42.124 41.502 37.229 37.234 25.481 25.532 22.501 22.685 40.273 40.086 36.905 37.970 241.80 228.03 208.35 202.21 93.9 94.8 103.0 103.5 98.5 100.0 104.9 105.0 37.149 36.524 38.390 40.240 22.702 22.475 22.998 24.051 38.980 40.484 40.431 40.823 194.28 176.40 172.72 167.84 105.1 107.1 105.7 105.3 104.6 105.2 104.0 105.8 40.079 40.326 40.604 42.955 23.726 22.625 20.602 21.044 39.209 40.170 42.115 48.168 171.74 171.91 174.31 185.46 105.2 104.4 103.8 98.4 106.2 105.6 105.4 101.9 45.994 44.716 46.733 49.120 21.693 21.690 22.592 22.808 52.693 53.046 63.765 59.703 190.55 183.72 195.95 198.61 94.8 94.7 89.5 88.5 100.3 99.2 96.0 96.3 49.801 48.374 50.635 52.092 22.901 23.028 23.860 23.935 59.473 58.884 62.087 62.542 203.78 211.19 219.66 220.07 88.4 89.6 86.7 86.3 96.7 98.0 96.5 97.5 49.270 51.578 51.398 46.730 23.008 23.995 24.072 22.722 56.710 61.207 61.012 56.022 220.45 233.59 240.12 234.60 90.3 85.3 85.5 91.0 100.1 94.9 95.1 98.7 Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Swiss franc United Kingdom pound 343 TABLE B-99— U.S. international transactions, 1946-80 [Millions of dollars; quarterly data seasonally adjusted] Merchandise12 Investment income3 Year or q