Full text of Economic Report of the President : 1969
The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT MM '" Transmitted to the Congress January 1969 Together With THE ANNUAL REPORT of the COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS Economic Report of the President Transmitted to the Congress January 1969 TOGETHER WITH THE ANNUAL REPORT OF THE COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS UNITED STATES GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE WASHINGTON : 1969 For sale by the Superintendent of Documents. U.S. Government Printing Office ^ 1. 50 CONTENTS Page ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT T H E RECORD OF ACHIEVEMENT 1 4 Contribution of Policy Gains in 5 years 4 5 DEVELOPMENTS IN 1968 6 T H E PROGRAM FOR 1969 7 The Budget Economic Outlook 7 9 TOWARD PRICE-COST STABILITY 9 The Roads to Avoid The Roads to Follow 10 10 REINFORCING THE FISCAL-MONETARY FRAMEWORK Budget Policy and Procedures Monetary Policy After Vietnam 12 12 13 14 T H E INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY 14 Balance-of-Payments Adjustment World Monetary System Trade Aid K E Y AREAS OF FEDERAL GOVERNMENT RESPONSIBILITY Quality of the Environment Community Development and Housing Education Consumer Protection Worker Protection Social Security 14 15 16 17 17 18 18 18 19 19 21 OUR COMMITMENT TO ELIMINATE POVERTY 21 Employment Opportunities Education, Health, and Nutrition Housing Income Support 21 22 22 22 CONCLUSION 23 in Page ANNUAL REPORT OF THE COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS* 25 CHAPTER 1. STRENGTHENING THE FOUNDATION OF PROSPERITY 33 CHAPTER 2. POLICIES FOR BALANCED EXPANSION 61 CHAPTER 3. PRICE STABILITY IN A HIGH EMPLOYMENT ECONOMY. . . 94 CHAPTER 4. T H E INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY 123 CHAPTER 5. COMBATING POVERTY IN A PROSPEROUS ECONOMY 151 REPORT TO THE PRESIDENT FROM THE CABINET COORDINATING COMMITTEE ON ECONOMIC PLANNING FOR THE END OF VIETNAM HOSTILITIES. . . . 181 APPENDIXES 213 APPENDIX A. REPORT TO THE PRESIDENT ON THE ACTIVITIES OF THE COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS DURING 1968 213 APPENDIX B. STATISTICAL TABLES RELATING TO INCOME, EMPLOYMENT, AND PRODUCTION 221 *For a detailed table of contents of the Council's Report, see page 29. IV ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT ECONOMIC REPORT OF THE PRESIDENT To the Congress of the United States: I regard achievement of the full potential of our resources— physical, human, and otherwise—to be the highest purpose of governmental policies next to the protection of those rights we regard as inalienable. I cited this as my philosophy in my first Economic Report in January 1964. I reaffirm it today. In the past 5 years, this Nation has made great strides toward realizing the full potential of our resources. Through fuller use and steady growth of our productive potential, our real output has risen nearly 30 percent. Most important of all are our human resources. Today the vast majority of our workers enjoy productive and rewarding employment opportunities. For those who lack skills, we have made pioneering efforts in training. We have improved education for the young to enhance their productivity and their wisdom as citizens of a great democracy. Our capital resources—plant and equipment—are being used intensively and have been continually expanded and modernized by a confident business community. This has all been accomplished in an environment that preserved—indeed, enlarged—the traditional freedom of our economic system. In today's prosperous economy, our people have more freedom of choice— among jobs, consumer goods and services, types of investments, places to live, and ways to enjoy leisure. I look upon the steady and strong growth of employment and production as our greatest economic success. In recent years, prosperity has become the normal state of the American economy. But it must not be taken for granted. It must be protected and extended —by adopting sound and prudent policies for this year and —by improving procedures for fiscal and monetary policymaking to meet our needs for the long run. I shall discuss these tasks in this Report. I shall also consider how we might deal with some of our key unsolved economic problems. • We must find a way of combining our prosperity with price stability. Reconciling these two objectives is the biggest remaining over-all economic challenge facing the Nation. • We must more fully secure the foundations of the world monetary system and of our own balance of payments. The international monetary system has undergone important evolutionary improvements, but we must seek more effective ways of coping with the stresses that can still develop. • We must fulfill our many unmet public needs such as good education, efficient transportation, clean air, and pure water. Quality as well as quantity is the key to a better life. • We must share more equitably the fruits of prosperity among all our citizens. A Nation as prosperous as ours can afford to open the doors of opportunity to all. Indeed, it cannot afford to leave any citizen in poverty. The achievements we have made and the lessons we have learned point the way for further progress. THE RECORD OF ACHIEVEMENT The Nation is now in its 95th month of continuous economic advance. Both in strength and length, this prosperity is without parallel in our history. We have steered clear of the business-cycle recessions which for generations derailed us repeatedly from the path of growth and progress. This record demonstrates the vitality of a free economy and its capacity for steady growth. No longer do we view our economic life as a relentless tide of ups and downs. No longer do we fear that automation and technical progress will rob workers of jobs rather than help us to achieve greater abundance. No longer do we consider poverty and unemployment permanent landmarks on our economic scene. CONTRIBUTION OF POLICY Our progress did not just happen. It was created by American labor and business in effective partnership with the Government. Ever since the historic passage of the Employment Act in 1946, economic policies have responded to the fire alarm of recession and boom. In the 1960's, we have adopted a new strategy aimed at fire prevention— sustaining prosperity and heading off recession or serious inflation before they could take hold. • In 1964 and 1965, tax reductions unleashed the vigor of private demand and brought the economy a giant step toward its full potential. • In 1966 and 1967, restrictive monetary and fiscal policies offset the strains of added defense spending. The adjustment was far from ideal, however, because of the delay in increasing taxes to pay the bills for the defense buildup and for continuing urgent civilian programs. • In 1968, our Nation's finances were finally adjusted to the needs of a defense emergency. The Revenue and Expenditure Control Act strengthened the foundation of prosperity. GAINS IN 5 YEARS Aided by these policies in the past 5 years, the Nation's total output of goods and services—our gross national product—has increased by more than $190 billion, after correcting for price changes. This is as large as the gain of the previous 11 years. The prosperity of the last 5 years has been accompanied by benefits that extend into every corner of our national life —more than 8J/2 million additional workers found jobs, —over-all unemployment declined from 5.7 percent of our labor force to 3.3 percent, —unemployment of nonwhite adult males dropped particularly dramatically, from 9.7 percent to 3.4 percent, —the number of persons in poverty declined by about I2/2 million—progress greater than in the entire preceding 13 years, —the average income of Americans (after taxes and after correction for price rises) increased by $535—more than one-fifth and again more than in the previous 13 years combined, —corporate profits rose by about 50 percent, —wages and salaries also went up by 50 percent, —net income per farm advanced 36 percent, —the net financial assets of American families increased $460 billion—more than 50 percent, and —Federal revenues grew by $70 billion, helping to finance key social advances. Meanwhile, a solid foundation has been built for continued growth in the years ahead. • Through Investment in Plant and Equipment. In the last 5 years, the stock of capital equipment has grown by nearly a third. Only 5 percent of manufacturing corporations report that their capacity is in excess of currently foreseen needs. • Through Investment in Manpower. More than a million Americans have acquired skills in special training institutions or on the job—as a result of new Federal efforts. • Through Investment in Education. College enrollment has risen by 2*4 million since 1963. Expenditures on all public education have increased at an average of 10 percent a year; Federal grants have almost quadrupled. • Through Investment in Our Neighborhoods. Our urban centers are beginning to be restored as decent places to live and initial steps have been taken to help ensure construction of 26 million new or rehabilitated housing units by 1978. DEVELOPMENTS IN 1968 Our economy had an exceptionally big year in 1968. • Our gross national product increased by $71 billion to $861 billion. Adjusted for price increases, the gain was 5 percent. • Payroll employment rose by more than two million persons. • Unemployment fell by 160,000. • The after-tax real income of the average person increased by 3 percent. • An estimated four million Americans escaped from poverty, the largest exodus ever recorded in a single year. • Our balance-of-payments results were the best in 11 years. In some ways, 1968 was too big a year. Even our amazingly productive economy could not meet all the demands placed upon it. Nearly half of the extra dollars spent in our markets added to prices rather than to production. The price-wage spiral turned rapidly. • Consumer prices rose by 4 percent and wholesale prices by 2*/2 percent. • Both union and nonunion wages increased about 7 percent— responding to higher costs of living and causing higher costs of production. • Some of the extra demands for goods were met out of foreign production, and imports soared 22 percent. The main source of the overheating was the excessive and inappropriate stimulus of the Federal budget in late 1967 and the first half of 1968. In January 1967, I pointed to the need for a tax increase. In the summer, when the upsurge was even more clearly foreseen, I urged im- mediate enactment of a 10-percent income tax surcharge. The subsequent delay in enactment resulted in a massive budget deficit of $25 billion for fiscal year 1968, which —accelerated the economy beyond safe speed limits, —weakened confidence in the dollar abroad, and —placed a heavy burden on credit markets at home, pushing interest rates sharply higher. Ultimate passage of the Revenue and Expenditure Control Act of 1968 at midyear brought a much needed swing to fiscal restraint. The budget now shows a surplus of $2.3 billion for fiscal 1969. Because of both greater revenues and reduced expenditures, this picture has changed dramatically since last January when we estimated a deficit of $8 billion. Just as the overly stimulative effects of the huge budget deficit of fiscal 1968 were unmistakable, so there can scarcely be doubt that the reverse swing—of even larger size—will improve balance in our economy. But just as inappropriate fiscal stimulus took a while to cause obvious problems, so needed fiscal restraint is taking time to work its full beneficial effects on the economy. By the time the surcharge was enacted, the forces of boom and inflation had developed great momentum. Our economy continued to advance too rapidly throughout 1968—but growth did slow from a hectic 6/2 percent rate early in the year to about 4 percent at yearend. The budget is now in harmony with the needs of the economy, and its welcome effects are gradually emerging. THE PROGRAM FOR 1969 The challenge to fiscal and monetary policies this year is difficult indeed. Enough restraint must be provided to permit a cooling off of the economy and a waning of inflationary forces. But the restraint must also be tempered to ensure continued economic growth. We must adopt a carefully balanced program that curbs inflation and preserves prosperity. T H E BUDGET My final budget is designed to meet this demanding assignment. It is a tight and prudent program for fiscal 1970. • It holds total Federal expenditures within the bounds of available revenues, yielding a surplus of $3.4 billion. • It finances our continued military efforts in Vietnam while we strive to bring about peace. 7 • It provides funds for our continuing national campaign against poverty, injustice, and inequality. • It limits increases in expenditures to programs of highest priority: the encouraging JOBS program and other manpower training, Model Cities and key housing programs, law enforcement, and education. • It trims lower priority programs wherever possible. The budget calls for the extension of the income tax surcharge at its current rate of 10 percent for 1 year from July 1, 1969 to June 30, 1970. My economic and financial advisers unanimously agree that this fiscal restraint is essential to safeguard the purchasing power of the dollar and its strength throughout the world. Indeed, the need for continued fiscal restraint is agreed upon by all informed opinion in both of our political parties. In today's economic and military environment, an immediate lowering of taxes would be irresponsible. The American people would be poorly served by a small short-run gain that would endanger their enormous long-term stake in a steady and stable prosperity. I hope and I believe that Members of the Congress of both parties will support timely action on taxes to continue on the course of fiscal responsibility which we have worked together to achieve. I asked for the surcharge as a temporary measure and that is the way I regard it. My proposal for a 1-year extension preserves the option of the new Administration and the Congress to eliminate the surcharge more rapidly if our quest for peace is successful in the near future. It is my conviction that the surcharge should be removed just as soon as that can be done without jeopardizing our economic health, our national security, our most urgent domestic programs, or international confidence in the dollar. Clearly, that time has not yet arrived. The extended surcharge will continue to take 1 percent of the income of the average American—less than half of the tax cut he received in 1964-65. In return, he will receive improved protection against the ravages of inflation, world financial crisis, and neglect or mismanagement of our priorities. It is the best investment in responsible fiscal management that the United States can make in 1969. Including this budget, I have been responsible for 6 years of fiscal planning. From fiscal 1965 to fiscal 1970, the Federal Government will have spent $969 billion on programs and received $936 billion in revenues. The total deficit for that period amounts to $33/ 2 billion. The bulk of that total deficit occurred in fiscal 1968, when action on taxes was long delayed. 8 By comparison, these six budgets —provided $35 billion of net tax reductions, even allowing for higher social security taxes, and —carried $109 billion of outlays to cover the special costs of the war in Vietnam. ECONOMIC OUTLOOK With this budget and appropriate monetary policy, our gross national product for 1969 should rise about $60 billion. • Increased expenditures on new plant and equipment will help expand and modernize our productive capacity. • State and local governments will continue to increase their spending rapidly to meet public needs. But Federal purchases will rise little. • Consumer spending and homebuilding activity should advance less than last year. • The over-all gains will not and should not be as large as those in 1968, but they will still make for a highly prosperous year. • For the fourth straight year, unemployment should be less than 4 percent of the labor force. Because fiscal policy is soundly planned, monetary policy should not be overburdened. It will need to support firmly the objective of moderating economic expansion. But homebuilding and other credit-sensitive areas need not be subjected to the sharp and uneven pressures of a credit squeeze. Monetary policy should be flexible and prepared to lessen restraint as the economy cools off. As pressures of demand moderate, our trade performance in world markets should improve. We should also see a gradually improving trend in prices and costs, although the wage-price spiral will continue to be troublesome. TOWARD PRICE-COST STABILITY The immediate task in 1969 is to make a decisive step toward price stability. This will be only the beginning of the journey. We cannot hope to reach in a single year the goal that has eluded every industrial country for generations—that of combining high employment with stable prices. There is no simple nor single formula for success. But this combination can and must be achieved—by the United States and within the next several years. Now that we have learned to sustain prosperity, we can surely not allow inflation to erode or erase that victory. T H E ROADS TO AVOID We stand at a critical turning point for national policy. We can meet the challenge, or we can try to evade it. Price stability could be restored unwisely by an overdose of fiscal and monetary restraint. This has been done before, and it would work again. But such a course would mean stumbling into recession and slack, losing precious billions of dollars of output, suffering rising unemployment, with growing distress and unrest. It would be a prescription for social disaster as well as for unconscionable waste. Or we could conceivably travel the route to mandatory controls on prices and wages. But the vital guiding mechanism of a free economy is lost when the Government fixes prices and wages. We did not impose such regulations on our businessmen and our workers during the recent years of military buildup and hostilities. We surely must not turn down this path—a dead end for economic freedom and progress. Or we could throw up our hands and allow the price-wage spiral to turn faster and faster. This counsel of despair would eventually undermine our prosperity and our financial system—wrecking the strong international position of the dollar and imposing unjust burdens on millions of our citizens. T H E ROADS TO FOLLOW Price stability in a prosperous economy must be pursued by a coordinated program involving a wide range of actions. The fiscal and monetary program I outlined earlier is our first line of defense against inflation. The Nation has surely learned that inflation will emerge unless responsible budget and credit policies keep demand within the bounds of the economy's productive capacity. Even then, advances in prices and wages at high employment can prove troublesome. No free economy can escape these tendencies entirely. But it can keep them from developing when unemployment is too high, and it can moderate the pressures that do emerge. To do so effectively requires reinforcing other important measures to reinforce fiscal and monetary policies. Productivity and Efficiency First, although the productive efficiency of our industries and of our workers is already the envy of the world, we must keep striving for further improvements. 10 Productivity can be raised even more rapidly and manpower can be employed more effectively through many methods in which Government can lend a hand—by training programs that better match skills to job requirements, by developing the potential of the disadvantaged, by using the wasted abilities of those who are out of work seasonally or intermittently, by providing better information about job opportunities, and by encouraging research and investment in better technology. Government, business, and labor can work together to improve industrial efficiency. We can strengthen our dedication to the competitive principles and practices that have made American industry preeminent. Impediments to efficiency must be identified and tackled, industry by industry, wherever they exist—as they do particularly in medical care and construction. The Government should look at its own programs and policies to ensure that they do not add an unnecessary penny to the costs of production. To fulfill this goal, public policies must be reviewed continually in many areas—procurement, regulation, international trade, commodity programs, and research and development. Voluntary Cooperation Second, both in their own interest and in the public interest, business and labor should exercise the utmost restraint in price and wage decisions. It is understandable that, with living costs rising sharply, labor cannot now accept wage agreements limited to the rise in productivity. It is also understandable that, with production costs increasing, business cannot now hold prices entirely stable. But the process of deceleration must take hold for both prices and wages. The demands for incomes by business and labor combined must be brought more closely into line with the amount of real income the economy can generate. A decisive step toward price stability in 1969 requires labor and business to accept some mutual sacrifices in the short run to preserve their enormous long-term interest in prosperity and a stable value of the dollar. In recent years, business, labor, and Government have been discussing the big economic issues—sometimes debating, but often agreeing. The dialogue should go forward and should explore new forms of labormanagement cooperation to ensure greater fulfillment of common interests. A year ago, I established the Cabinet Committee on Price Stability to coordinate efforts within the Administration to help improve efficiency, enlist voluntary restraint, and contribute to public education and dis- II cussion on the wage-price problem. In its recent Report, the Committee made many important recommendations which deserve the most serious consideration. The work of the Committee has proved its value, and should be continued in some appropriate form. The stakes are enormous in our efforts to combine high employment and price stability. We can sacrifice neither goal. The challenge can be met if we have the will. REINFORCING THE FISCAL-MONETARY FRAMEWORK The unparalleled economic expansion of the past 8 years testifies to the accomplishments of our fiscal and monetary policies. Yet the blemishes on that record show plainly that further improvements are needed. BUDGET POLICY AND PROCEDURES The budget is the keystone of Federal Government operations. It is a plan developed within the Executive Branch and a recommended program for action by the Congress. It is a blueprint for fiscal and economic policy. In my many years in Washington, I have worked intensively on the budget on both the legislative and executive sides. I know the difficulties of —coordinating a host of appropriation requests into a total program that accurately reflects national priorities, —making the dollar sum of the parts equal a whole that remains within prudent bounds, and —ensuring that decisions on tax revenues go hand in hand with those on expenditures. The Executive Branch coordinates its budgetary decisions through the Bureau of the Budget, with extensive cooperation from the Department of the Treasury and the Council of Economic Advisers. The Congress has no parallel process. I urge the Congress to review its procedures for acting on the annual budget and to consider ways that may improve the coordination of decisions among Federal programs and on Federal revenues in relation to expenditures. My experience has thoroughly convinced me of the fundamental wisdom of our system of checks and balances. The system works well because both the President and the Congress subject their own operations continually to careful scrutiny and review in light of experience. Costly delays in enacting recent tax legislation demonstrate the need 12 for a review of procedures in this area. Congress should ask: How can a prompt response to a Presidential request for tax action be assured? When such a recommendation takes a simple form (like the current income tax surcharge) and when it is made to head off a threat to prosperity, the Nation is entitled to a prompt verdict. To provide the fiscal flexibility needed in our modern economy, the Congress might be willing to give the President discretionary authority to initiate limited changes in tax rates, subject to Congressional veto. I believe that the President should have such authority. Alternatively, the Congress might choose to establish its own rules for ensuring a prompt vote—up or down—on a Presidential request for tax action. The Nation should never again be subjected to the threat of fiscal stalemate. MONETARY POLICY Our institutions allow monetary policy to adjust promptly and smoothly, and the value of this flexibility has become evident. When fiscal action has been delayed, monetary policy has been able to continue the battle against inflation. But tight credit, soaring interest rates, pressures on homebuilding, and nervous financial markets are the unhappy results of an overburdened monetary policy. Greater fiscal flexibility would help to ensure that monetary policy is not asked to carry an undue share of the load in restraining—or stimulating—the economy. The Administration and the Federal Reserve have learned to work together closely and to coordinate effectively, while preserving the appropriate independence of the Federal Reserve within the Government. Our monetary institutions are working well, and I see a need for only a few reforms to enhance their effectiveness. • The term of Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board should be appropriately geared to that of the President to provide further assurance of harmonious policy coordination. • The rigid requirement that no more than a single member of the Federal Reserve Board may be appointed from any one Federal Reserve District should be removed so that the President, with the advice and consent of the Senate, may choose the very best talent for the Board. • The Congress should review procedures for selecting the presidents of the 12 Reserve Banks to determine whether these positions should be subject to the same appointive process that applies to other posts with similarly important responsibilities for national policy. 323-166 O - 69 - 2 AFTER VIETNAM Despite some encouraging signs of progress toward peace, hostilities in Vietnam continue. In planning our budget, we must assume continuation of the war. But we must also be ready to adjust to peace whenever that welcome day arrives. Early in 1967, to ensure our readiness for peace, I established the Cabinet Coordinating Committee on Economic Planning for the End of Vietnam Hostilities. The Report of that Committee emphasizes the demanding task that will confront fiscal and monetary policies once a secure peace permits demobilization. The resources freed from war must not—and need not— be squandered in idleness. Rather, this manpower and material should be promptly enlisted in the service of peaceful progress. In addition to its immeasurable human benefits, peace will provide an economic dividend to the Nation and to the Federal budget. But that dividend is dwarfed by the urgent needs of our society. The Nation will have to weigh the priorities among attractive programs carefully and wisely to take full advantage of this dividend. High on the list of priorities is the commitment to provide equal and full economic opportunities for all our citizens. THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY BALANCE-OF-PAYMENTS ADJUSTMENT Our international accounts were in balance in 1968—for the first time since 1957. Much of the improvement came from the program I announced in an atmosphere of world financial crisis a year ago. The contrast today is striking and gratifying. The excellent results of last year were aided by temporary factors. Hence, we cannot relax our efforts to achieve fundamental improvement—especially in our disappointing trade performance. To strengthen our trade surplus and achieve a healthy balance of payments, we must —restore price stability at home, —encourage our farms and factories to become ever more competitive in quality and price so that they can export more, —intensify efforts to secure the removal of barriers to freer trade, —bring more foreign tourists to our shores to enjoy America with us, and —minimize the foreign exchange cost of our military commitments and economic aid overseas. 14 Our temporary programs to restrain capital outflows worked well in 1968. American businesses showed remarkable ingenuity and cooperation in pursuing their activities abroad while drastically cutting the drain on the Nation's balance of payments. These programs clearly aided in preserving the strength of the dollar. Capital restraints should never become permanent features of our economy. They should be ended as soon as possible. But the war continues and the movement toward noninflationary prosperity has just begun. We cannot now scrap our defenses against large capital outflows. For the present, we must —renew the Interest Equalization Tax before it expires on July 31, —maintain the direct investment control program in the more flexible form recently announced, and —continue the Federal Reserve program of voluntary restraint of foreign lending. To maintain our gains, ever closer international cooperation is needed among the highly interdependent nations of the world. Countries in deficit must meet their responsibilities. And countries in surplus must also pursue appropriate policies—striving especially for rapid economic expansion and giving world traders greater access to their markets. WORLD MONETARY SYSTEM The international monetary system was strengthened in 1968. An historic international agreement was reached, creating in the International Monetary Fund a new reserve asset—the Special Drawing Right. We spent 3 years studying, exploring, and negotiating with our commercial partners in order to reach this agreement. I eagerly await the day that actual distribution of SDR's will begin. They can meet the future needs of the world for international liquidity—in the proper amounts and in a usable form. I am proud that the United States acted so promptly to ratify this agreement with such overwhelming bipartisan support in the Congress. Some did not believe that such an agreement was possible, arguing that a rise in the official price of gold was the only way to increase international reserves. We and our trading partners rejected this futile course; it would have offered a ransom payment to speculators and would have failed to provide for the orderly growth of reserves. I have carried out my pledge that the United States would sell gold to official holders of dollars at $35 an ounce. There is clearly no need to change that price. Myths about gold die slowly. But progress can be made—as we have demonstrated. In 1968, the Congress ended the obsolete gold-backing requirement for our currency. Another major step in freeing the international monetary system from disturbances by gold speculators was taken in March, when the United States and the other active gold pool countries agreed to cease supplying gold to the private market. The resulting two-price system for gold is working successfully. The international economy has made major strides in the past. But we must recognize the problems that remain. The financial crises of 1968 stimulated constructive discussion of many proposals for further evolutionary improvements in the international economic system. These proposals are not an agenda for action in a week or a month or even a year. The issues posed cannot be resolved in a summit meeting or by a superplan. But they can be tackled effectively with the same kind of careful study and negotiation that led to the successful SDR plan. The United States should actively participate in such a procedure in order to strengthen the foundation of the world economy. TRADE World trade has continued to expand briskly—virtually unaffected by the sporadic crises in financial markets. Tariff barriers that once stifled international commerce have been substantially lowered—most notably by the Kennedy Round reductions which began in 1968 and will continue until 1973. We must reinforce this success by devoting equal energy to the removal of nontariff barriers. On our part, Congressional action to rescind the American Selling Price provision is essential for achieving reductions of nontariff barriers offered by several of our trading partners. Other nontariff barriers also need revision. • Agriculture has been the stepchild of trade negotiations, and deserves prompt and proper attention. • The international rules governing border tax adjustments should be revised so that they no longer give a special advantage to countries that rely heavily on excise and other indirect taxes. While we work to reduce trade barriers, we must not drop our guard against the advocates of protectionism at home and abroad. We will never neglect the legitimate concerns of any citizen. But the only real solutions are ones that improve our economy—not ones that erect new barriers that could provoke retaliation, or insulate producers from the 16 invigorating force of world competition. To provide the right kind of aid to those seriously hurt by import competition, present provisions for temporary adjustment assistance must be liberalized, as I have repeatedly recommended. AID Important economic progress is being made in the world's less developed countries. The beginnings of spectacular advances in world agriculture are now clearly evident. Family planning is gaining widespread support. The United States can and should help to promote further progress in world agriculture and family planning, and the achievement of more rapid economic growth in the less developed countries. Only if funds for foreign aid programs are restored to an adequate level can we do our part. The United States has long supported multilateral assistance as an equitable and efficient means of channeling aid from wealthy to poorer nations. We must reaffirm this support by promptly authorizing the U.S. contributions to the replenishment of the International Development Association and to the Special Funds of the Asian Development Bank. KEY AREAS OF FEDERAL GOVERNMENT RESPONSIBILITY The bountiful output of the American private enterprise system has made our high standard of living possible. Yet this same abundance has created a growing need for public action to improve the quality of life in our cities, towns, and countryside. The Federal Government must continue its partnership with the private sector and with State and local governments to provide better public services. Increased efforts are needed to —improve the environment by ensuring clean air, pure water, and the conservation of natural resources, —assist in community development and in education, —protect the consumer against unfair practices and unwholesome products, —ensure safe employment conditions, and —provide a more comprehensive social insurance system to protect against the financial impacts of retirement, unemployment, job accidents, and long-term illness of a breadwinner. l 7 QUALITY OF THE ENVIRONMENT More than ever, Americans realize that purposeful action is required to ensure an environment we can all enjoy. In the last 5 years, legislation has been enacted to abate air and water pollution and to control the disposal of solid wastes. Despite progress, many of our rivers still are open sewers, our atmosphere often unfit to breathe, and much of our land littered with discarded junk. We must —develop new methods for financing water treatment plants, —attack oil pollution of harbors and beaches, —strengthen laws for clean air and solid waste disposal, —stop the ravages of strip mining, and —preserve more parks and wilderness areas. COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT AND HOUSING Rapid population growth in our cities and rising living standards have created a backlog of community and housing needs. Local governments are finding it increasingly difficult to finance essential community facilities—schools, parks, hospitals, and transportation systems. The Federal Government must develop new ways to help communities raise capital for public facilities. The capacity of the housing industry must be enlarged and updated to meet the Nation's goal of adding 26 million decent homes and apartments over the next decade. To improve our communities and meet our housing needs, I recommend —an independent, federally established, Urban Development Bank to provide low-interest loans to State and local governments, —increased Federal research and development to improve construction technology, -—a Federal program to test housing materials and to improve building standards and practices, —the training of more construction workers through federally assisted manpower programs in cooperation with trade unions and contractors, and —an urban mass transportation trust fund, financed by a portion of the automobile excise tax. EDUCATION Providing good education is a national responsibility in which the Federal Government must do its part. Great progress has been made in 18 recent years toward our goal of providing every child all the education he wants and can absorb. But continued and expanded efforts will be needed. This Nation must strive to —provide every child with year-round opportunity for preschool education, —offer every teacher assistance for continuing education, —bring the cost of higher education within the means of every qualified student through expanded loans and grants, and —provide funds for higher education adequate to ensure instruction of finest quality. CONSUMER PROTECTION The confidence of consumers in the American marketplace is vital for a healthy economy. In the past 5 years, the Congress has ushered in a new era of consumer protection by enacting 20 major measures in this field. We have made great strides toward our goals of —ensuring that all products are safe and wholesome, —providing full and fair disclosure in the marketplace, and —eliminating fraud and deception by the few who prey on the unsuspecting, the elderly, and the poor. To carry on the work so well begun, legislation is needed to —prevent deceptive sales practices by giving new authority to the Federal Trade Commission, —reduce the likelihood of massive electric power failures which can paralyze our cities, —ensure that the small investor shares in the benefits of our thriving mutual fund industry, and —complete the circuit of Federal inspection for foods commonly served at the family dinner table. WORKER PROTECTION American workers are the most productive in the world and they have made our high standard of living possible. They and their families deserve a safe working place and adequate protection against the loss of income from on-the-job accidents, disability, and unemployment. Safety The human costs of accidents are immense—14,000 people killed on the job each year, 2.2 million workers injured. The monetary cost alone is a staggering $5 billion. Recent tragedies in our factories, mines, and other work places have dramatized once more the need for better safety practices. Must we wait for tragedy to strike again? The Congress failed to act last year on an urgently needed Occupational Safety and Health Bill and on the Coal Mine Safety Bill. We can delay no longer. This Nation must put an end to this senseless waste from job accidents—through comprehensive legislation that will ensure the best job safety and health practices in all American work places. Workmen's Compensation Workmen's compensation should ensure that no victim of a job-related accident lacks the funds to pay his medical bills and support his family. Currently, one employee in five has no workmen's compensation protection. Benefit levels are too often tragically low. The Federal Government should act now to ensure that the States provide adequate workmen's coverage and benefits. Disability Insurance Today disabled workers wait as long as 6 months before receiving benefits—and their disability must be expected to last more than 1 year. In addition, disabled workers are too often unable to pay for the medical care they need. To meet these shortcomings, I recommend that —the waiting period for benefits be reduced from 6 to 3 months, —the minimum duration of qualifying disability be reduced to 3 months, and —the totally and permanently disabled be eligible for Medicare. Unemployment Insurance Even in the height of prosperity during 1968, two million workers were out of work for a period of 15 weeks or longer. About a million workers spent at least half the year fruitlessly looking for work. Congress should strengthen the Federal-State Unemployment Insurance system by —extending coverage to five million more workers, —raising benefit levels, —lengthening payment periods, and —providing special federally financed benefits for the long-term unemployed, with recipients required to accept job training and other employment services under appropriate circumstances. 20 SOCIAL SECURITY Social security is one of the oldest and best social programs. Currently, 25 million people—one out of every eight Americans—receive a social security check every month. Largely because of social security, two-thirds of the beneficiaries—the elderly, widows, orphans, and the disabled— are above the poverty line. Yet we need to do more. I recommend an average increase in benefits of 13 percent, including —a rise of at least 10 percent for every beneficiary, —a 45 percent increase from $55 to $80 for the five million Americans receiving the minimum benefit, —a $100 monthly minimum benefit for those who have contributed to social security for 20 years or more, and —a liberalization of benefits for the elderly who choose to work. OUR COMMITMENT TO ELIMINATE POVERTY No achievement gives me greater pride than the advances in the war on poverty. No social challenge gives me greater concern than the elimination of poverty. Since the passage of the Economic Opportunity Act, which established the Nation's commitment to eliminate poverty, the number of poor Americans has been reduced by about 11 million. Still, 22 million Americans remain poor. The effective programs of the Office of Economic Opportunity must be preserved and strengthened. For this purpose, I am recommending a 2-year extension of the Economic Opportunity Act. EMPLOYMENT OPPORTUNITIES In recent years, our national prosperity has rapidly expanded job opportunities for the poor. To maintain progress, we must not retreat from high employment. The doors to opportunity are bound to be locked to the disadvantaged and to new workers if senior and skilled employees are being laid off. At the same time, we cannot count on normal economic growth to create as many jobs for the poor as were created when we moved out of a slack economy. We must therefore increase the emphasis on manpower programs in order to provide effective aid to the disadvantaged. In 1968, we launched a major new partnership with private industry—the National Alliance of Businessmen. Job Opportunities in 21 the Business Sector is a promising route for providing jobs and training for the hard-core unemployed. The JOBS program has reached its initial target 6 months ahead of schedule. My budget provides for major expansion of this program. The experience with JOBS encourages us to develop a similar program for employment in the rapidly growing public sector. EDUCATION, HEALTH, AND NUTRITION The poor are often handicapped by inferior education, ill health, and inadequate diets. Federal Government programs have begun to attack these roots of poverty. Head Start, Follow Through, and Title I of the Elementary and Secondary Education Act help in educating disadvantaged children. These should ultimately be expanded to meet the needs of all poor children. Medicaid has a high proportion of poor beneficiaries and should ultimately free the needy from the bonds of inadequate health care. Good health is essential for a good start in life. Expectant mothers and infants in poor families should be provided comprehensive health care. America, blessed with agricultural abundance, should not tolerate hunger among its people. The Food Stamp program should be expanded and a cooperative Federal-State effort launched to protect all Americans against hunger and malnutrition. HOUSING With the Housing and Urban Development Act of 1968 we set the goal of eliminating all substandard housing in the next decade. We must back that commitment with the needed resources—financial, technical, and human. First priority must be given to the needs of the poorest of the poor through the Model Cities program, rent supplements, home ownership, and public housing. And all families must be assured full and fair access to housing—with no discrimination. INCOME SUPPORT No matter how well we succeed in other efforts, cash assistance will be needed by many of the poor—the elderly, the disabled, and some mothers with sole responsibility for the care of young children. Although such funds do not directly remove the causes of poverty, they sustain life and 22 hope and help prevent poverty from being bequeathed from one generation to the next. Income support programs need a thorough review. The public discussion required to illuminate this area is well under way and will benefit from the report of the Commission on Income Maintenance, due at the end of this year. Americans will soon have to decide how best to help those who cannot earn enough to escape from poverty. Whatever strategies we choose, the effort to reduce poverty must be redoubled. Victory in the war on poverty can be won with only a modest share of the Nation's income gains. The total shortfall of income below the poverty line amounts to only 1 percent of our gross national product— one-fourth of our normal growth in a single year. A fully effective antipoverty program would initially cost more than that—but would not be out of range. Surely Americans will make the investment needed to eliminate poverty. CONCLUSION The American economy has been steadily on the march in the 1960's. It has shattered all records for progress toward the Employment Act's goals of "maximum employment, production, and purchasing power." It has bestowed great blessings of abundance on the vast majority of Americans in all walks of life. Economic growth has provided the resources for urgent defense needs and has still permitted a major expansion of civilian production—both public and private. It has allowed us to send a youngster to Headstart and a man to the moon. When our economy was less prosperous, many of our social problems were neglected—eclipsed by the struggle of families to make ends meet. The plight of the poor was fatalistically accepted when the majority of Americans were vulnerable to unemployment and deprivation. Our needs for improved schools, better cities, and a healthier environment were pushed into the background. As the average American's standard of living soared, we could afford to focus on new challenges. Facing these issues squarely has in itself been a great accomplishment. We have marshaled our determination to provide a good job, a decent standard of living, quality education, and a pleasing environment for everyone. We have begun to make progress toward these new aspirations. But we have only begun. And because we have so far to go, many of us are impatient. This feeling is in the great American tradition. High aspirations and impatience have constantly spurred us to greater achievements. And they will again. Our economy will not rest on the laurels of the 1960's. We will not relax to count or consolidate our gains. We will not retreat from the unprecedented prosperity we have achieved. This Nation will remain on the march. January 16, 1969. 24 THE ANNUAL REPORT OF THE COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS LETTER OF TRANSMITTAL COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS, Washington, D.C.January 10,1969. T H E PRESIDENT: SIR: The Council of Economic Advisers herewith submits its Annual Report, January 1969, in accordance with Section 4(c) (2) of the Employment Act of 1946. Respectfully, ARTHUR M. O K U N , Chairman. MERTON J. PECK. WARREN L. SMITH. CONTENTS Page 33 CHAPTER 1. STRENGTHENING THE FOUNDATION OF PROSPERITY Economic Gains in 1968 '......•• Production and Productivity .. Employment and Income . The Composition of Demand Economic Policy in 1968 Fiscal Policy Monetary Policy and Financial Developments Pattern of Activity During the Year Upsurge During the First Half of 1968. Expansion in the Second Half. Key Sectors in 1968 Retrospect .. Wages and Prices in 1968 Wages and Compensation Real Earnings and Unit Labor Costs Prices in 1968 Balance of Payments in 1968 Goods and Services Capital Account Economic Policy for 1969 Anti-Inflationary Strategy Fiscal Program for 1969 Monetary Policy Economic Outlook for 1969 Outlook by Sectors Price Outlook Outlook for the Balance of Payments .. . CHAPTER 2. POLICIES FOR BALANCED EXPANSION Realizing the Economy's Potential The Choice of a Target Potential Output Economic Gains of the Expansion •. The Problem of Economic Fluctuations . Short-Run Instability Automatic Stabilizers and Fiscal Drag . The Record of Policy Strategy for Expansion: 1961 to Mid-1965 Fiscal Problems of Defense and High Employment: 196568 Lessons of the Policy Record 29 34 34 34 36 37 38 39 40 40 41 42 45 45 46 47 48 49 50 52 53 53 54 55 55 56 58 59 61 61 62 64 67 70 70 72 74 74 75 77 2. POLICIES FOR BALANCED EXPANSION—Continued Formulating Fiscal Policy The Role of Economic Forecasting Preparing the Annual Budget Congressional Procedures . Adjusting to New Developments Some Issues of Monetary Policy The Conduct of Monetary Policy. Monetary Policy and the Money Supply Looking Ahead Page 78 78 80 82 84 85 85 89 93 CHAPTER CHAPTER 3. PRICE STABILITY IN A HIGH EMPLOYMENT ECONOMY. . . Prices, Wages, and Employment The Record in the Sixties The Task for Policy Improving Labor and Product Markets Improving Labor Mobility Efficient Use of Manpower Manpower Training Programs. Competition and Antitrust Policy Legal Restrictions on Competition Improving Consumer Information Regulated Industries Government Procurement Agriculture International Trade and Price Stability Voluntary Restraint in Prices and Wages Role of Private Decisions Standards for Decisions Application of Standards Future Role of Cooperation Conclusion .. . CHAPTER 4. T H E INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY Economic Growth and World Trade Trade and Trade Barriers Less Developed Countries The Bretton Woods System The Liquidity Problem Types of Reserves Special Drawing Rights The Need for Reserve Growth The Confidence Problem Private Shifting Among Currencies Private Demand for Gold Shifts Among Official Reserve Assets Proposals for Improving Reserve Management The Adjustment Problem Causes of Disturbances 3° 94 94 96 97 98 99 103 104 106 108 109 Ill 113 115 116 118 118 118 119 120 121 123 . 124 124 126 128 129 130 130 131 133 133 134 135 136 137 138 Page CHAPTER 4. THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY—Continued The Adjustment Problem—Continued Internal Adjustments Measures Directly Affecting International Transactions . . The Adjustment Problem of the United States Exchange Rate Adjustments Present System Proposals for Exchange Rate Flexibility Conclusion CHAPTER 5. COMBATING POVERTY IN A PROSPEROUS ECONOMY The Extent of Poverty Definition of Poverty Poverty Trends Strategies for Reducing Poverty Prosperity and the Reduction of Poverty Effects of Prosperity Prospects for Further Progress Income Distribution Education, Jobs, and Training Education and Poverty Hiring Standards Training and Job Access Improvements in Income Maintenance Welfare Programs Benefits in Kind Social Insurance Systems Major Reform Special Problems of Poverty Pockets Strategies for Attacking Ghetto Problems Strategies for Reducing Rural Poverty Fulfilling the National Commitment 151 151 . 152 153 155 155 156 158 160 161 162 162 . 163 164 165 166 168 170 172 173 176 178 List of Tables and Charts Tables 1. Gross Saving and Investment in Selected Years of Relatively High Employment, 1952-68 2. Changes in Various Measures From the National Income and Product Accounts Since Second Quarter 1967 3. Allocation of Disposable Personal Income in Selected Periods, 1956-68 4. Changes in Compensation, Productivity, Unit Labor Cost, and Output Price in the Private Economy Since 1947 5. Wage and Benefit Changes in Collective Bargaining Situations, 1963-68 6. United States Balance of Payments, 1963-68 31 138 140 142 145 145 146 149 36 41 43 46 47 50 Tables 7. Measures of Economic Activity During the Current Expansion. 8. Federal Fiscal Actions in T h r e e Periods Since Fourth Q u a r t e r 1960 9. N e t Funds Raised by Nonfinancial Sectors, 1961-68 10. Changes in Employment, 1961 to 1968 11. Changes in Hourly Earnings of Production a n d Nonsupervisory Workers on Private Nonagricultural Payrolls, 1961 to 1968 12. Growth of Gross National Product in Developed a n d Less Developed Countries, 1950-67 13. Growth of World Exports, 1952-67 14. Poverty a n d Near-Poverty Income Lines, 1967 15. N u m b e r of Poor Households a n d Incidence of Poverty, Selected Years, 1959-67 16. N u m b e r of Near-Poor Households a n d Incidence of NearPoverty by Age a n d Sex of H e a d of Household, 1959 a n d 1967 17. Selected Major Income Maintenance Programs, Fiscal Year 1969 18. Major Federal Income-in-Kind Programs Substantially Benefiting the Poor, Fiscal Year 1969 Charts 1. Changes in Gross National Product Since 1964 2. Wholesale Prices 3. Consumer Prices 4. U.S. Balance of International Payments 5. Gross National Product, Actual and Potential, and Unemployment Rate 6. Unemployment Rates 7. Selected Interest Rates 8. Price Performance and Unemployment 9. World Trade and Reserves 10. Number of Poor Persons and Incidence of Poverty 11. Taxes and Transfer Payments as Percent of Income (Excluding Transfers), by Income Class, 1965 Pag e 68 74 87 100 100 124 125 152 157 159 164 167 35 48 49 51 65 69 76 95 132 154 161 CHAPTER 1 Strengthening the Foundation of Prosperity HE AMERICAN ECONOMY achieved large gains in output and employment in 1968, as it continued to expand through an unprecedented eighth consecutive year. The value of the Nation's total output of goods and services—gross national product (GNP)—rose by $71 billion from 1967 to 1968; after adjusting for price increases, the gain amounted to 5 percent. Employment grew by I/2 million persons, and in December the unemployment rate was down to 3.3 percent, the lowest since the early 1950's. The number of persons below the poverty income line declined by 4 million, the largest such reduction in any year on record. Meanwhile, our over-all balance of international payments improved markedly. In part, however, this exuberance was too much of a good thing. The productive capability and adaptability of the American economic system were once more demonstrated; but the economy was severely tried by all of the demands placed upon it. The pressures of excessive demand pushed up the price level at the unacceptable rate of nearly 4 percent. Imports were drawn in from abroad at a very rapid pace, easing some domestic supply shortages but causing a sharp deterioration in the Nation's international trade surplus. And domestic financial markets came under renewed heavy pressure, producing sharp increases in interest rates. The excessive buoyancy reflected, in large part, the extended delay in enacting the 10 percent income tax surcharge which had been proposed by the President in August 1967. While the fiscal program was pending, restrictive monetary policy took some of the steam out of the economy. But by the time the appropriate fiscal restraint went into effect in mid-July, the underlying forces of expansion had attained great momentum—more than was realized at the time. As a result, the needed moderation in the pace of advance developed slowly. With inflationary pressures still strong, economic policy should continue to exert restraint in 1969. Total demand must be brought into better balance with the Nation's productive capacity to permit a slowing of price and cost increases. But the restrictiveness of policy should be tempered to preserve our basic prosperity; it should ensure that output continues to grow, although at a rate somewhat less than the growth of the economy's potential. The Administration's fiscal program is designed to meet these objectives. T 33 The remainder of this chapter reviews developments in 1968 in more detail, sets forth the Administration's fiscal program for 1969, and finally summarizes the outlook in 1969 for economic activity, prices and wages, and the balance of payments. The other four chapters of this Report review some of the lessons of economic policy derived from recent experience and discuss some of the challenges of the future. The evolving role of fiscal and monetary policies in the 1960's is discussed in Chapter 2. The challenge of achieving price stability in a high employment economy is the subject of Chapter 3. International economic progress and problems are dealt with in Chapter 4, while Chapter 5 is concerned with the reduction of poverty. This volume also contains a report on economic planning for the end of hostilities in Vietnam. ECONOMIC GAINS IN 1968 The record of 1968 reflects both sides of the performance of an overly buoyant economy: the benefit to most Americans from large gains in real income and output, and the substantial cost of inflationary pressures. PRODUCTION AND PRODUCTIVITY The 5 percent growth of real output achieved in 1968 was impressive in view of the already high level of resource utilization at the beginning of the year. But inflationary pressures were accentuated and, as shown in Chart 1, higher prices accounted for $31 J/i billion of the $71 billion rise in total GNP. The rise in total real output was accomplished in part by a strong recovery of productivity growth in the private sector over the previous year— 3.3 percent compared with 1.6 percent in 1967. In early 1967, many business firms had maintained high levels of employment in the expectation that the then emerging slowdown in production would prove temporary. Thus the diminished pace of the expansion was reflected in a slowing of productivity growth rather than a sharp rise in unemployment. Accordingly, with the resurgence of economic activity late in 1967 and in 1968, it was possible to meet some increased demand by fuller use of the existing work force. EMPLOYMENT AND INCOME As a result of the expansion, the unemployment rate fell to a 15-year low of 3.6 percent in 1963 compared with 3.8 percent in both 1966 and 1967, and the number of unemployed declined by 160,000. Workers on nonfarm payrolls increased by 2.1 million in 1968. The largest gains occurred in State and local government payrolls, which increased by nearly 565,000 workers, and in trade and private services, which together added 950,000 workers. Manufacturing employment rose a relatively moderate 300,000. The Federal Government's civilian work force remained practically unchanged from 1967, while 100,000 persons were added to the Armed Forces. 34 Chart 1 Changes in Gross National Product Since 1964 CHANGE IN BILLIONS OF DOLLARS +20 -20 +40 +60 1964 TO 1965 TOTAL GNP PERSONAL CONSUMPTION EXPENDITURES GOVERNMENT PURCHASES BUSINESS FIXED INVESTMENT OTHERi/ 1965 TO 1966 1966 TO 1967 1967 TO 1968 ^RESIDENTIAL STRUCTURES, CHANGE IN BUSINESS INVENTORIES, AND NET EXPORTS OF GOODS AND SERVICES. SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE. 35 +80 With higher employment and more rapid wage increases, total wages and salaries increased by $40 billion in 1968. A sharp $7 billion rise in transfer payments, plus gains in dividends, interest, and rental income, added further to household purchasing power. Thus over-all personal income registered a large increase of $57 billion over 1967. On an after-tax basis, and after correcting for price increases, income per capita increased by 3 percent in 1968—well above the average annual increase for the postwar years as a whole. Corporate profits also rebounded sharply from their decline in 1967. Before-tax profits increased by more than $10 billion. The 10 percent Federal income tax surcharge, enacted in June and made retroactive to January 1 for corporations, held the after-tax gain to $3 billion. Particularly large gains were recorded by the manufacturing sector. THE COMPOSITION OF DEMAND In contrast to the experience in many other years, the excessive expansion in 1968 was not attributable to any particular component of expenditures. Most components advanced, and they added up to a total of too much demand—what has been called a "well-balanced excess." Investment Sectors Residential construction outlays rose by $5 5/2 billion in 1968. As shown in Table 1, the proportion of total GNP accounted for by residential building TABLE 1.—Gross saving and investment in selected years of relatively high employment, 1952-68 Percent of gross national product Source or use of saving 1952 1956 1965 1966 1967 19681 Private sector: Gross investment Business fixed investment . . Residential structures Change in business inventories Net foreign investment Gross saving Personal saving Gross business saving Excess of private saving or investment (—) 14.9 17.1 16.4 16.5 14.7 14.8 9.1 5.0 10.4 10.4 10.9 10.6 10.5 .9 1.1 .4 1.4 .6 2.0 .3 .8 .2 16.2 16.5 16.7 16.9 16.1 5.2 10.2 4.9 11.3 4.1 12.4 4.4 12.3 5.1 11.8 4.7 11.3 .5 -.9 .1 .2 2.2 1.3 -1.1 1.4 -.2 .2 .1 -1.6 -.2 -.6 -1.1 1.2 .3 .2 -1.7 -.7 .6 -.3 -.5 -.4 -.4 -.5 -.1 15.4 5.2 4.0 3.3 3.1 3.5 .9 Government sector: Federal surplus or deficit (—) . State and local surplus or deficit (—) Government surplus or deficit (—) Statistical discrepancy 1 Preliminary. 2 Less than 0.05 percent. Sources: Department of Commerce and Council of Economic Advisers. -.1 recovered notably in 1968, although it remained far below the 4.3 percent average of the 1961-65 period. Business fixed investment increased ll/i percent, but was not a strong stimulative force in 1968. Its share of GNP fell slightly from 1967 to 1968, in contrast to its usual rise in a year of rapid expansion. Inventory accumulation played a relatively passive role in 1968, at least in comparison with the very sharp swings that were experienced in late 1966 and early 1967. Inventory-sales ratios were at a fairly normal level throughout much of the year. The net export balance declined to its lowest level since 1959. Exports of goods and services rose $5 billion. But imports of goods and services surged by $7 billion in response to the expansion of domestic demand. The increase in imports amounted to nearly 10 percent of the increase in GNP—about twice the normal share of total imports in GNP. Government The growth of Federal purchases for national defense slowed substantially. The $6/ 2 billion rise from 1967 to 1968 was far below the average of $11 billion a year between 1965 and 1967. Nondefense purchases of goods and services increased by $3 billion. Purchases of goods and services by State and local governments continued their rapid growth of recent years with a $9 billion increase. These expenditure increases were heavily concentrated in higher employee compensation payments, reflecting the growth of State and local employment. Personal Consumption Expenditures Consumer expenditures turned out to be an important expansionary force in the economy in 1968, in contrast to 1967. The over-all rise of $42 billion (8.6 percent) was marked by a strong $10 billion advance in durable goods purchases. Automobile sales rebounded from the mild decline of 1967, with total sales of 9.6 million new cars exceeding the previous 9.3 million record of 1965. The rate of consumer saving fell to 6.9 percent of disposable personal income from the unusually high 7.4 percent reached in 1967. ECONOMIC POLICY IN 1968 The buoyancy of public and private demand and the resulting buildup of inflationary pressures that developed after mid-1967 accentuated the urgent need for fiscal restraint. However, enactment of such restraint was long delayed, complicating the management of monetary policy and enabling inflationary tendencies to become entrenched. 37 FISCAL POLICY The economic background of fiscal policy in 1968 had its roots in developments in early 1967. Although over-all economic growth was proceeding only slowly at that time because of an inventory adjustment, it was apparent that underlying forces of expansion were strong. These were expected to become more dominant in the second half of the year, once the inventory adjustment had run its course. Accordingly, the President proposed, in his Budget Message of January 1967, a temporary 6 percent surcharge on individual and corporate income taxes, to take effect on July 1, 1967. By the second half of 1967, the prospect that excessive expansion was on the way became more apparent. Accordingly, in early August, the formal message requesting prompt enactment of the surcharge—revised to 10 percent—was sent to the Congress. However, the economy was not actually expanding at an excessive rate during the summer and early autumn, and the Congress was reluctant to take major action on the basis of a forecast of acceleration. No action was taken, and the fiscal impact remained strongly and inappropriately expansionary. The pace of economic expansion did in fact accelerate, and the President renewed the request for a 10 percent tax surcharge in January 1968. The evidence of excessive demand, rising prices, deteriorating trade performance, and growing financial pressures at home and abroad became compelling. An international financial crisis developed in March, and by mid-May accelerating credit demands had pushed interest rates to record high levels. Even after a rather general consensus on the need for fiscal restraint developed, there were further delays in reaching agreement on the form of restraint. Some legislators were prepared to vote for higher taxes only if accompanied by cutbacks in Federal spending; others only if a tax increase would serve as a means of avoiding such cutbacks. Congressional approval finally came with passage of the Revenue and Expenditure Control Act of 1968, signed into law by the President on June 28. The Act provided for the 10 percent surcharge as requested by the President in January, with effective dates made retroactive to January 1 for corporations and April 1 for individuals. Since the withholding rate under the personal income tax was raised on July 15, many individuals will receive reduced refunds or have to make additional final tax payments early this year to cover the retroactive portion of the tax. The Act also established specific limitations on Federal budget outlays for fiscal year 1969. Certain programs—support for Vietnam operations, interest on the public debt, veterans benefits and services, and social security benefits—were exempted from the limitations. Expenditures in the remaining categories were required to be reduced by $6 billion below the levels contained in the January Budget. 38 As a result of the enactment of this fiscal program, the Federal budget (as measured in the national income accounts) has shifted from a deficit of $11 billion in fiscal 1968 to one of only $1 billion (annual rate) in the second half of calendar 1968. The tax surcharge alone is currently withdrawing about $105/2 billion (annual rate) from the income stream. The enactment of the surcharge and expenditure cutbacks immediately strengthened international confidence in the dollar, and caused some relaxation in domestic financial markets. Economic activity continued to expand too strongly in the second half of 1968, but at a less feverish pace than in the first half. MONETARY POLICY AND FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENTS The Federal Reserve tightened credit in the first half of 1968 when little progress was made toward passage of the tax bill. In doing so, however, it attempted to steer a narrow course. There was hope for the enactment of fiscal restraint and hence good reason to avoid an extremely tight credit policy. On the other hand, it was necessary for monetary policy to help in cooling off the feverish economy in the short run and also to be ready to assume the full burden of restraint if the fiscal program should fail. Within these limitations, a series of actions did, in combination, achieve significant restraint. Two half-point increases brought the Federal Reserve discount rate to a modern high of 5 5/2 percent by late April. Regulation Q was also changed in April to raise the maximum allowable interest rates that banks could pay on time certificates of deposit. Open market operations brought pressures on bank reserve positions sufficient to slow bank credit growth to a 6/2 percent annual rate in the first half of the year, compared with an II/2 percent increase in 1967. In the first half of 1968, total funds raised in credit and equity markets were 17 percent below the volume of the last half of 1967. Interest rates in the open market moved sharply upward. By late May, the rate on 3-month Treasury bills reached 5.90 percent and highgrade corporate bonds commanded more than 7 percent—above the highs during the 1966 credit crunch. Interest rates fell for a time after the logjam on the tax bill broke in late May. The Federal Reserve followed this with some relaxation of its grip on bank reserve positions in June and July. In mid-August, the discount rate was reduced to 5*4 percent, largely in technical realignment to lower market rates. The initial easing of pressures on the banking system set off widespread expectations that monetary policy would soon be eased still further. The resulting increased demand for securities to capture potential capital gains drove interest rates sharply downward. Meanwhile, the demands for credit to finance security purchases were added to the already heavy credit demands from the Treasury and the private sector, with the result that growth of bank credit accelerated sharply after midyear. 39 Federal Reserve policy continued to accommodate a good part of the rising demands for credit, but not to the extent of preventing further increases in market interest rates. By early October, most rates had climbed more than half way back toward their May peaks. Then, in mid-December, the discount rate was restored to 5 5/2 percent. Toward yearend, the rate on 3-month Treasury bills was up to a new high of about 6.30 percent, a full percentage point above the level prevailing at the year's start, and most other market rates were at their highs for the year and for recent times. PATTERN OF ACTIVITY DURING THE YEAR The record of expansion during the year reflects substantial adjustments in the behavior of the various sectors of the economy. UPSURGE DURING THE FIRST HALF OF 1968 GNP increased by $42 billion (annual rate) between the fourth quarter of 1967 and the second quarter of 1968. As shown in Table 2, that surge was fueled by an extraordinary increase of $39^4 billion in final sales. This was in contrast to the last half of 1967, when an important stimulus had come with a rise in inventory investment from its very low rate earlier in the year. In the first half of 1968, increases in inventory investment contributed only $2 J/2 billion, much of which reflected a buildup of stocks in anticipation of a possible strike in the steel industry. Government expenditures were the most important expansionary force during the first half of 1968. Federal purchases of goods and services rose $65/2 billion (annual rate) from the fourth quarter of 1967 to the second quarter of 1968, reflecting a renewed acceleration in defense spending. State and local purchases increased more rapidly than usual, rising $5^2 billion over the period. A liberalization of Federal social security benefits took effect in March and contributed a major part of the $5 billion increase in transfer payments during the period. The Federal fiscal impact remained strongly expansionary, even though revenues rose sharply with the booming advance of economic activity. Most areas of private demand made relatively little contribution to the expansion. Business fixed investment rose $2 billion, barely keeping pace with price increases. After its strong advance during 1967, residential construction leveled off, reflecting a tight monetary policy. Net exports declined, as imports expanded rapidly. Personal consumption expenditures grew nearly in pace with disposable personal income between the fourth quarter of 1967 and the second quarter of 1968. Real GNP expanded at an annual rate of 6yi percent during these two quarters, far outpacing the rate of growth of about 4 percent in the economy's potential. Unemployment declined from 1967 levels and averaged 3.6 percent of the civilian labor force. In sharp contrast with 1965-66, the 40 vigor of expansion was not concentrated in industrial areas. Indeed, industrial production rose at a 5 / 2 percent annual rate during the first half of 1968, less than the pace of real GNP. EXPANSION IN THE SECOND HALF During the final two quarters of 1968, the growth of real GNP was 4 ^ percent, still above the rate of growth of potential although only by a narrow margin. In current prices, GNP rose $35 billion (Table 2). The growth in final sales decelerated, and inventory accumulation—after dipping in the third quarter—ended the year at a rate little different from the peak attained in the second quarter. TABLE 2.—Changes in various measures from the national income and product accounts since second quarter 1967 (Billions of dollars, seasonally adjusted annual rates] 1967 II •n 10 1967 IV •ft 10 1967 IV Item 1968 11 Gross national product.. 1968 II to 1968 IV i 30.8 41.9 34.9 6.0 24.7 2.5 39.4 — 8 35! 7 11.9 2.3 5.8 -1.7 25.7 2.0 1.0 -1.4 18.4 7.2 2.3 1.0 3.5 2.8 6.5 5.6 1.6 5.2 23.6 18.1 11.6 6.4 32.9 26.7 26.2 .6 30.1 16.2 18.8 -2.6 8.2 7.1 2 15.4 13.3 15.4 4.9 2.5 1.1 4.4 2.0 Other expenditures.. 3.6 6.8 Surplus or deficit ( — ) _ . . 1.1 2.0 Change in business inventories.. Final sales Personal consumption expenditures Business fixed investment _ Residential structures Net exports of goods and services Government purchases of goods and services: Federal State and local Consumer sector: Personal income Disposable personal income. Personal outlays Personal saving Federal Government sector: Receipts Expenditures. Purchases of goods and services: National defense Other. 1.0 .6 3.3 10.6 1 Preliminary. 2 Includes $3.6 billion of retroactive liability from corporate tax surcharge. Note.—Detail will not necessarily add to totals because of rounding. Sources: Department of Commerce and Council of Economic Advisers. In contrast to the first half of the year, the government sector did not propel the advance. Federal purchases of goods and services rose only $2 billion, and other Federal expenditures increased $3 billion. Meanwhile, the 10 percent surcharge on corporate and personal income taxes withdrew 41 over $10 billion (annual rate) from the private income stream. By the fourth quarter, the Federal budget was essentially in balance. Both homebuilding and business fixed investment, on the other hand, picked up steam in the second half and ended the year on a particularly strong note. Net exports made a modest recovery. Consumer expenditures advanced $18^2 billion between the second and fourth quarters, much less rapidly than in the first half of the year. The unemployment rate fell to a 15-year low of 3.4 percent in the fourth quarter, with exceptionally low rates for adult men. KEY SECTORS IN 1968 Two components of demand—consumer expenditures and residential construction—were subject to special influences in 1968 and therefore require further examination. Consumer Spending and Saving Consumer spending was important in determining the pattern of activity throughout the year. It was particularly stimulative in the third quarter, jumping $13 billion (annual rate) at a time when the surcharge was first affecting paychecks. Some delay in the adjustment of consumer spending patterns to the marked change in the growth of disposable personal income was expected. A lagged response was apparent, for example, in the behavior of consumption outlays following the tax reductions of 1964-65. The increase in withheld taxes stemming from the 1968 tax surcharge was expected to lead to a similar gradual response of consumption. Some decline in personal saving could be expected to absorb part of the tax for a while. In fact, saving declined far more than had been anticipated in the third quarter, falling $7 billion from the second quarter—more than could conceivably be attributed to the $6 billion of additional taxes from the surcharge. But this was immediately followed by an unusually small rise in consumer spending in the fourth quarter, with a consequent increase in the saving rate. During the second half of the year the saving rate averaged % of a percentage point lower than in the first half—nearly twice the decline that would have been consistent with both an unchanging basic strength of consumer demand and the anticipated lagged response to the tax increase. The third quarter surge in consumption continued to have a strong impact on economic activity through the end of the year as producers stepped up their rates of production in response to the increases in sales. With production proceeding vigorously, the moderation of consumer spending in the fourth quarter was translated into a substantial accumulation of inventories by yearend. The marked movements of consumer expenditures during 1968 continued the pattern of late 1966 and 1967. The ratios of consumer purchases 42 of various categories of goods and services and of consumer saving to disposable personal income for the past several years are shown in Table 3. During the 1959-66 period, consumer spending behavior maintained a fairly consistent relationship to disposable personal income. The saving rates in excess of 7 percent that prevailed in 1967 and the first half of 1968 represented an unusually large fraction of disposable income by comparison with 1959-66, although not with 1956-58. The saving rate has also been subject to substantial quarterly fluctuations about its recent high level. TABLE 3.—Allocation of disposable personal income in selected periods, 1956-68 [Percent] Category 1956-58 average Disposable personal income 1959-66 average 1968 1967 First half Second halfi 100.0 Saving 13.8 14.2 5.8 7.4 5.6 7.7 6.0 7.8 6.4 7.9 41.7 39.5 39.2 39.0 21.9 19.8 20.0 19.5 19.8 19.4 19.8 19.2 37.0 37.3 37.3 37.8 2.1 Interest paid and transfer payments to foreigners 13.3 34.3 Services 91.0 13.3 23.9 20.1 Food and beverages. Other nondurables... 100.0 90.2 44.0 Nondurable goods. 100.0 90.1 5.4 7.3 Autos and parts. Other durables.. 100.0 91.9 12.8 Durable goods 100.0 91.1 Personal consumption expenditures.. 2.4 2.5 2.4 2.4 5.7 7.4 7.3 6.6 6.9 i Preliminary. Note.—Detail will not necessarily add to totals because of rounding. Sources: Department of Commerce and Council of Economic Advisers. There is no clear explanation for the extra saving in the period from late 1966 to mid-1968. But the high saving did contribute to a sharp buildup in consumers' holdings of financial assets and to a slowing in the growth of consumer debt. Together, these developments meant that households had achieved relatively favorable financial positions, which permitted them to increase expenditures markedly whenever they chose to do so. Why they happened to pick the third quarter of 1968 to exercise this option cannot be adequately explained. Residential Construction As was the case in the preceding 2 years, monetary policy again had a significant impact on homebuilding activity in 1968. After rising sharply in the second half of 1967, outlays for residential construction remained essentially flat over the first 3 quarters of 1968, despite the fact that household formation and other factors were creating a tremendous underlying demand 43 foi> new houses. Only in the fourth quarter did such outlays show an appreciable rise. The factor that limited homebuilding was a curtailment in the availability of mortgage credit. The net flow of funds into mortgages fell by about 5 percent between the fourth quarter of 1967 and the second quarter of 1968. To some extent this reflected a slowdown of deposit inflows to major mortgage lenders as savers were attracted by the high interest rates available in the open market. But there was also a marked shift away from mortgage lending by mutual savings banks, which invested heavily in high-yielding corporate bonds. The effects of tight credit on residential construction were, however, far less severe in 1968 than during the 1966 credit squeeze and were also less than most observers had expected. Indeed, the number of new housing units started was at a depressed level in only 2 months—May and June— and then showed unexpected strength during the second half of the year. In part, of course, the stronger performance of homebuilding in 1968 reflected the fact that credit tightening early in the year was only shortlived and occurred against a background of continued hope for relief with the enactment of the tax surcharge. Builders and mortgage lenders thus tended to stretch a bit to keep operations going. Steps taken over the past few years to improve the mortgage market also helped to mitigate the effects of tight credit on homebuilding. As a result of 1966 legislation providing for improved coordination of the administrative ceilings applicable to interest rates that thrift institutions may pay on time and savings deposits, the severe competition among the various institutions for each other's deposits that occurred in 1966 was not repeated in 1968. Legislation passed in May 1968 suspended the statutory 6 percent interest ceiling on federally insured mortgages until October 1969, replacing it in the meantime with an administrative ceiling controlled by the Secretary of Housing and Urban Development. This administrative ceiling was raised to 6% percent, thereby increasing the availability of these types of mortgages. The legislation of May 1968 also provided for the appointment of a Commission to reexamine the interest rate ceiling and make recommendations for a permanent solution to the problem. There were also two important reforms affecting the operation of the Federal National Mortgage Association (FNMA) in 1968 that enabled it to support the mortgage market more effectively than in the past. In May, FNMA began auctioning commitments to purchase mortgages in the future, which builders and others could exercise at their option. By the year end, outstanding commitments under this program totaled $1.2 billion, bringing FNMA's total net participation in the mortgage market during the year to a record $4.2 billion. This increased volume of operations was in part due to the other reform, provided for in the 1968 Housing Act, which split the old FNMA into two corporations, one private (still designated FNMA) and the other a new 44 Government enterprise, the Government National Mortgage Association (GNMA). FNMA, which conducts the auctions mentioned above, has repaid the Government's investment, and its operations have accordingly been removed from the Federal budget. It is now free of the budgetary constraints that had sometimes limited the role of the old Government enterprise in the mortgage market. GNMA has powers—thus far unused—to help private lenders tap the capital market for additional funds that can flow into mortgages. RETROSPECT In retrospect, 1968 is seen as a year of excessively rapid expansion throughout. Yet, there was a noticeable difference between the pace of advance in the first half of the year and that in the second half. The growth rate of real GNP slowed markedly from 6J/2 percent early in the year to 4 percent by yearend. Still, a much more pronounced change of pace in activity was expected as well as desired. As of midyear, many Government and private economists expected that the advance of GNP in the second half of the year might be roughly half of the $42 billion gain for the first 2 quarters. The enactment of the fiscal program was one—but only one—of the elements underlying that expectation. Most of the slowdown was expected to result from a lessening of demand in the private sector—steel and other inventories and homebuilding. In point of fact, several elements of private demand showed unanticipated strength. The sluggishness of consumer buying in the early spring months proved to be temporary and misleading. Business fixed investment began to move up sharply from its previous plateau. Homebuilding rebounded very strongly and promptly following the easing of credit conditions. And, as noted earlier, the strength of consumer demand in the summer contributed to a stepup in production and ordering and subsequently to rising inventory accumulation. All of these elements taken together amounted to an unexpected buoyancy in private demand and production. While there is no clear way to tell how much the fiscal program moderated these forces, it is perfectly plausible that in the absence of fiscal restraint there would have been no deceleration whatsoever in the second half (unless, of course, the alternative of severe monetary restraint had been applied). WAGES AND PRICES IN 1968 As the economy resumed its vigorous advance in the last half of 1967, inflationary pressures reasserted themselves strongly and continued throughout 1968. 45 323-166 O—69 4 WAGES AND COMPENSATION Spurred by rising living costs and growing tightness in many labor markets, both union and nonunion wages turned up sharply. Average hourly earnings of production workers in private nonagricultural establishments rose 7 percent between December 1967 and December 1968, compared with 5 percent in the preceding 12 months. The hourly wage increases during the year for construction, manufacturing, and wholesale trade were all of about the same magnitude, while those in mining and retail trade were somewhat larger. Average hourly compensation in the private sector, including fringe benefits and employers' social security contributions, rose 7.4 percent from 1967 to 1968—as compared with 6.1 percent from 1966 to 1967 (Table 4). TABLE 4.—Changes in compensation, productivity, unit labor cost, and output price in the private economy since 1947 Percentage change per year Sector and item 1947 to 1966 1966 to 1967 1967 to 1968 i Total private economy: Average hourly compensation: * Current prices Constant prices a Output per man-hour Unit labor cost Implicit GNP price deflator. 5.2 3.1 3.5 1.7 2.0 6.1 3.2 1.6 4.4 3.1 7.4 3.3 3.3 3.9 3.6 4.9 2.8 2.9 1.9 2.2 6.0 3.1 1.1 4.8 3.5 7.2 3.2 3.4 3.7 3.6 5.1 3.0 3.2 1.8 2.0 5.3 2.4 .6 4.7 2.6 7.0 30 2.8 4.2 Private nonfarm: Average hourly compensation: 2 Current prices Constant prices' Output per man-hour Unit labor cost Implicit GNP price deflator Manufacturing: Average hourly compensation: 2 Current prices Constant prices 3 Output per man-hour Unit labor cost Implicit GNP price deflator * Preliminary. 2 Wages and salaries of all employees and supplements to wages and salaries such as employer contributions for social insurance and for private pension, health, unemployment, and welfare funds, compensation for injuries, pay of the military reserve, etc. Also includes an estimate of wages, salaries, and supplemental payment part of the income of the self-employed. 3 Adjusted for changes in the consumer price index. * Not available. Note.—Data for each sector relate to all persons. Sources: Department of Commerce, Department of Labor, and Council of Economic Advisers. Wage increases negotiated in all important collective bargaining situations covered five million workers—an unusually large number—in 1968. Multiyear settlements, covering 5,000 or more workers, had a median increase of 6.6 percent a year in wages and benefits weighted over the life of the contract (Table 5). In most cases, settlements were heavily "front loaded*'—that is, a disproportionate share of the increase was concentrated in the first year. The average first-year wage settlement was 7.5 percent, substantially above the 5.6 percent increase in 1967. This front-loading of new contracts may contribute to a substantial acceleration of economy-wide wage increases during periods of concentrated collective bargaining activity. Many of the 1968 settlements replaced contracts negotiated in 1965 or 1966, which had yielded very little gain in real hourly earnings because of the accelerating advance in prices. The unions naturally sought to restore their relative positions as quickly as possible, and hence insisted on concentrating a substantial part of the gains under new contracts in the first year. TABLE 5.—Wage and benefit changes in collective bargaining situations, 1963-68 Median percentage change negotiated or effective during Type of change 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 19681 Most important collective bargaining situations, annual rate of increase over life of contract: * Wage and benefit changes negotiated during specified year:3 Equal timing* Actual timing« Wage changes negotiated during specified year: 8 Equal timing Ail important collective bargaining situations:7 Manufacturing Nonmanufacturing. Wage adjustment effective during specified year, regardless of date of negotiations: * All industries Manufacturing Nonmanufacturing. 3.3 4.1 4.5 5.2 5.6 6.0 6.6 2.5 3.0 3.3 3.9 5.0 5.1 3.0 3.2 3.8 4.8 5.6 7.5 2.5 3.4 2.0 3.6 4.0 3.7 4.2 5.0 6.4 5.0 7.1 7.5 2.9 2.7 3.4 3.6 4.4 5.5 2.7 3.2 First-year wage adjustment negotiated during specified year: All industries 3.5 2.0 3.5 3.4 3.4 3.3 3.8 4.0 4.8 5.0 6.0 1 Based on preliminary data available in early January 1969. 2 Possible increases in wages resulting from cost-of-living escalator adjustments are omitted except for any part of the escalator increase guaranteed in the contract. • The 1964 estimate is based on 20 key contracts which affected 2.25 million workers in 11 major industries. The 1965 estimate covers most settlements affecting 10,000 workers or more in all industries excluding construction, services, finance, and government. Subsequent estimates cover all settlements affecting 5,000 workers or more in all industries except government. * Annual rate of increase assuming equal spacing of wage and benefit changes over life of contract. 5 Annual rate of increase taking account of actual effective dates of wage and benefit changes during contract period. 6 The estimates for 1963 to 1965 cover most settlements affecting 10,000 workers or more in all industries excluding construction, services, finance, and government. Subsequent estimates cover all settlements affecting 5,000 workers or more in all industries except government. ^ All contracts affecting 1,000 or more workers. From 1963 to 1965, construction, services, finance, and government are excluded. All industries except government are covered in subsequent estimates. 8 Includes changes in wage rates negotiated during specified year, plus increases decided upon in earlier years, costof-living escalator adjustments, and no wage changes. Source: Department of Labor. REAL EARNINGS AND UNIT LABOR COSTS The acceleration of money wages in 1968 was nearly matched by the acceleration of consumer prices so that the increase of 3.3 percent in real hourly compensation in the private economy was only slightly greater than the 1967 increase of 3.2 percent (Table 4). 47 Output per manhour in the private economy rose 3.3 percent in 1968, and this helped offset part of the cost to employers of the increase in hourly compensation. Nevertheless, unit labor costs still rose by 3.9 percent between 1967 and 1968. PRICES IN 1968 The general price level advanced sharply in 1968. Wholesale prices increased 2.8 percent in the 12 months ended December 1968, compared with only 0.8 percent during 1967 (Chart 2). Part of the spurt reflected the fact that farm prices rose 4.4 percent during 1968, reversing their decline during the 2 preceding years. However, industrial prices also rose on a broad front, advancing 2.6 percent during 1968 compared with 1.8 percent during 1967. Chart 2 Wholesale Prices 1957-59=100 120 ~ PROCESSED FOODS AND FEEDS 110 - V /••v./ ^ / -A COMMODITIES 100 A L L COMMODITIES \ - \ A \^ / / A ^ / NX FARM PRODUCTS 90 t tii ,, 1963 , 1964 ,. 1965 Ml I i i i i I i i i i i I . . 11 1 1 1 1 . i 1966 1967 I i,,,,, 1968 SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF LABOR. The consumer price index rose at an annual rate of 4.8 percent during the first 11 months of 1968 (Chart 3). This increase was led by a rise of 6.1 percent in consumer services, including a 7.2 percent jump in the cost of medical services. But prices of consumer commodities also moved up strongly. Partly because mortgage interest and homebuying costs rose particularly sharply, the deflator for personal consumption expenditures in the Chart 3 Consumer Prices 1957-59=100 140 / s 130 — SERVICES y y 120 ^ A L L ITEMS ^ ^ FOOD ^ ^ 110 ^—COMMODITIES LESS FOOD 100 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 11 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 i i I i1 i i 1 i i i i i 1 i i i i i 1 i i i i i 1 i i i i i 1 i i i i i 1 i i i i i 1 i i i i i 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF LABOR. GNP—which excludes these elements—increased considerably less rapidly than the consumer price index. It rose by 3.8 percent during the 4 quarters of 1968. The behavior of prices in 1968 represented a further intensification of the upward pressures that developed late in 1967. After rising 3.3 percent during 1966, consumer prices slowed to a 2^4 percent annual rate of increase during the first half of 1967, when economic activity moderated. But, with the resurgence of over-all demand—spurred by fiscal stimulus— late in 1967, the rate of price increase again accelerated. BALANCE OF PAYMENTS IN 1968 Although excessive economic growth generated a surge in imports and a sharp deterioration in the trade surplus in 1968, the overall balance of payments improved markedly. This primarily reflected a dramatic shift in the direction of capital flows. In 1967, the U.S. balance of payments as measured on the liquidity basis registered a deficit of $3.6 billion; the deficit was reduced to $1.1 billion at an annual rate during the first 3 quarters of 1968. (Table 6 and Chart 4). For the full year, preliminary estimates 49 TABLE 6.—United States balance of payments, 1963-68 [Billions of dollars] Type of transaction Balance on goods and servicesBalance on merchandise trade.. Balance on investment income.. Balance on other services Remittances and pensions 1963 58 . 5.1 3.3 -2.6 -.9 1968, first 3 quarters' 1965 84 . 6.6 3.9 -2.2 69 . 4.7 4.2 -2.0 51 . 48 . 2.4 3.6 4.2 -2.7 3.5 4.6 -3.3 .4 4.9 Q -1.0 -1.0 -1.3 __ 1966 1967 1964 -2.9 -1.1 Government grants and capital, net -3.6 -3.6 -3.4 -3.4 U.S. private capital, net -4.5 -2.0 -1.5 -.9 -6.6 -2.3 -2.5 -1.8 -3.8 -4.3 -4.2 -5.5 -3.5 .1 -.4 -3.6 .3 -.9 -3.0 -.5 -2.0 13 . .3 .6 .4 19 . -.1 1.6 .5 . 3 -.4 .1 .5 42 . .9 2.4 .9 -.2 -.9 -.3 -.2 34 . 1.0 1.5 .9 -.5 -2.0 -1.6 -1.3 . 3 -3.4 1.9 <5> .6 -2.7 1*.6 -2.8 .1 .1 .8 2.4 1.3 1.5 2.4 5.4 -1.3 -1.4 -3.6 -1.1 Direct investment U.S. bank claims Other U.S. private capital 2. Foreign private capital, net... U.S. securities (excluding Treasury issues). Foreign private liquid capital, net 3 Other foreign private capital* Errors and omissions BALANCE ON OFFICIAL RESERVE TRANSACTIONS BASIS. Plus: Increases in nonliquid liabilities to foreign monetary authorities Less: Foreign private liquid capital, net 3 BALANCE ON LIQUIDITY BASIS.. -4.3 -5.2 -3.3 .4 -2.3 10.4 3.7 5.4 1.3 -.3 1 2 3 4 Average of the first 3 quarters at seasonally adjusted annual rates. Includes redemptions of foreign securities. Includes changes in Treasury liabilities to international nonmonetary institutions. Includes certain Government transactions associated with special transactions. 5 Less than $50 million. Note.—Detail will not necessarily add to totals because of rounding. Source: Department of Commerce. show a liquidity surplus—for the first time since 1957. The balance on the official reserve transactions basis improved dramatically, achieving a surplus of $1.9 billion during the first 3 quarters of 1968, partly as a result of a marked shift in the holdings of liquid dollar assets abroad from foreign central banks to private investors. Such a shift improves the official settlements measure but does not affect the liquidity balance. The improvement in the balance of payments can be attributed to the President's program announced on January 1, 1968; to some special factors affecting primarily capital flows; and to the continuation of some longer term trends. GOODS AND SERVICES The merchandise trade surplus deteriorated markedly from $3.5 billion in 1967 to an annual rate of only $0.4 billion during the first 3 quarters of 1968. Imports rose about 22 percent above 1967. Exports, reflecting mainly the vigorous growth of income abroad, grew by 10 percent. The U.S. trade balance during 1968 was influenced by strikes in the copper and aluminum industries and a threatened strike in the steel industry, Chart 4 U.S. Balance of International Payments BILLIONS OF DOLLARS 50 — EXPORTS AND IMPORTS OF GOODS AND SERVICES - 40 EXPORTS - 30 — — ^ ^ ^ ^ ^ ^ IMPORTS — 20 o\ I I I I I 1964 1962 1960 \ I 1966 1968 J/ 10 NET CAPITAL FLOWS OTHER FOREIGN CAPITAL 7 U.S. PRIVATE J -10 1960 1962 I I 1964 I 1968 ^ 1966 10 BALANCE OFFICIAL RESERVE TRANSACTIONS BASIS s 0 LIQUIDITY BASIS 10 i i 1960 1 i 1962 1 1 1964 J/FIRST 3 QUARTERS AT SEASONALLY ADJUSTED ANNUAL RATES. i/SECURITIES OTHER THAN TREASURY ISSUES. SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE. 1 1 1966 1 1968^ all of which stimulated metal imports and reduced the trade surplus by perhaps $600 million. Nonagricultural goods accounted for the entire growth of merchandise exports during 1968, with exports to Western Europe and Latin America expanding especially rapidly. Agricultural exports, the most rapidly growing category between 1960 and 1966, declined rather abruptly in 1967 and remained depressed in 1968. While this decline was partially the result of a reduction of sales and donations to less developed countries, it also reflected a sharp decline in commercial exports to the European Economic Community, greatly influenced by EEC restrictions on agricultural imports. The service account in the balance of payments improved, reaching a surplus of $2.0 billion annual rate (during the first 3 quarters of 1968), as compared to $1.3 billion in 1967 (Table 6). The major gain came in net income from foreign investments, which continued its upward trend. Some improvement also occurred in the travel account in 1968, reflecting the reduced attractiveness of the Canadian exposition. CAPITAL ACCOUNT The capital account improved markedly, swinging from a net outflow on private account of $2.2 billion in 1967 to a net inflow of $5.2 billion in 1968 (first 3 quarters at annual rate). The new balance-of-payments programs had their major impact on the capital account. Mandatory controls on foreign direct investment, imposed January 1, 1968, greatly stimulated efforts by American firms to raise money abroad. During the first 9 months of 1968, $1.6 billion of new U.S. corporate securities were sold abroad to finance foreign investments, compared with less than $500 million during all of 1967. Firms also borrowed other funds totaling $0.7 billion, about twice the total for 1967. These borrowings permitted direct investment abroad to increase slightly, apparently proceeding in accordance with original intentions. Thus the target of $1 billion of balance-of-payments savings from the controls over direct investment was achieved without reducing American participation in the economies of other countries. Operating under new directives issued by the Federal Reserve Board, American banks reduced their claims on foreigners by $300 million during the first 9 months of 1968, compared with an increase of about $500 million during 1967. The swing of $800 million in bank lending exceeded the target of $500 million set in the January program. There were other improvements in the capital account that were not directly related to the balance-of-payments program. By the end of September, foreigners had already purchased $1.2 billion (net) of American securities in the open market (in addition to the $1.6 billion of new issues previously mentioned). In all of 1967, foreign purchases in the market amounted to only $0.6 billion, as a $450 million liquidation of holdings by the United Kingdom held down the total. The greater foreign interest in U.S. stocks and bonds during 1968 can be attributed to rising prices of U.S. equities and 52 high yields on U.S. bonds, as well as to political developments in France and Czechoslovakia that made European securities seem less attractive. Moreover, long-term forces continued to work, including the basic strength of the U.S. economy, the growing affluence of other countries, and the shortage of foreign corporate securities. A major inflow of liquid funds resulted from borrowings by American banks from their foreign branches. During 1968, these borrowings increased by $1.8 billion, compared with only $200 million in 1967. The major causes of this increase were the existence of relatively tight monetary conditions in the United States and fears about the stability of some European currencies. American banks also seem to be strengthening their ties to the European money market, giving them access to additional sources of funds. The U.S. Government increased its special financing arrangements during the year. In part, this increase resulted from greater efforts to obtain military offsets or neutralizations in line with the President's program. Some portion also resulted from a bilateral agreement with Canada whereby that country was exempted from the mandatory controls on direct investment. ECONOMIC POLICY FOR 1969 Although economic expansion is expected to moderate during the first half of 1969, a continuing policy of restraint is essential to curb inflationary pressures and to strengthen our international trade performance. ANTI-INFLATIONARY STRATEGY Checking inflationary forces that are deeply embedded in the structure of costs and prices is an extremely difficult and delicate process. One approach would be to adopt a drastically deflationary fiscal and monetary policy, involving a sharp reduction in Federal expenditures or a further increase in tax rates reinforced by extreme credit restraint. Such a policy could surely stop inflation in a reasonable period of time. But the cost would be intolerable—unemployment would rise substantially, and the United States could easily experience its first recession in nearly a decade. As the over-all unemployment rate rose, the rates for the disadvantaged—including nonwhites and teenagers—would rise even more rapidly. With heavy unemployment even among experienced workers, it would be extremely difficult to sustain recent initiatives to provide training and jobs for the unskilled and the disadvantaged. The danger of serious social unrest would be greatly increased. Moreover, the entire economy would suffer a huge loss of output, at a time when full production of goods and services is urgently needed to fulfill national goals. In any case, halting the current wage-price spiral is only the first step in the longer term task of maintaining reasonable price stability. Once a stable price performance had been achieved through a drastic policy of deflation, a decision would be required concerning the next step. If that choice should 53 be to prolong the slack performance of the economy, it would extend inequity and waste for years to come. If, on the other hand, there was a decision to shift to expansionary policy, there is no reason to believe that the period of deliberate deflation would have contributed to the longer run solution of the problem. Indeed, a rapid recovery to the economy's potential would probably involve more serious dangers of inflation than would a steadier movement that remained close to the path of potential output. In view of the intolerable costs of a drastic deflationary policy, a more moderate approach is required. The aim should be to slow down the growth of demand to a rate less than the growth of capacity while consistently maintaining forward motion. Once the rate of price increase has moderated, fiscal and monetary policy can be gradually adjusted toward stronger expansion. How soon that will prove appropriate cannot be foretold now. Nor can the proper target for utilization in the longer run be stated with assurance. If fiscal-monetary policy can succeed in avoiding spurts of expansion such as those experienced in 1965-66 and again in 1967-68, it should be possible to improve somewhat upon our recent price performance. But it is doubtful whether acceptable levels of unemployment and reasonable price stability can both be achieved without the successful implementation of structural anti-inflationary measures and of voluntary cooperation in wage and price decisions, along lines suggested in Chapter 3. In any case, it is clear that, for 1969, stabilization policy should be designed to hold the rate of expansion of real output below 4 percent but to keep it on a distinctly rising path. FISCAL PROGRAM FOR 1969 The President's Budget is designed to fulfill these objectives for economic activity in 1969. Federal expenditures are expected to rise by about $10 billion in 1969 compared with an increase of $19 billion in 1968. Defense purchases are expected to increase by about $2 billion, while nondefense purchases are scheduled to rise by about $1 billion. About half of these increases for the full year are accounted for by a pay increase at midyear for Federal civilian employees and the Armed Forces. This increase is designed to make Federal civilian pay scales comparable with those in private industry. Increases of $3 billion and $4 billion, respectively, are anticipated in Federal grants-in-aid to State and local governments and in domestic transfer payments. Most of the increases are either required by existing legislation or designed to help solve problems of highest national priority. To preserve the needed posture of fiscal restraint in the face of these minimal necessary increases in Federal expenditures, the President is asking the Congress to extend the 10 percent tax surcharge on personal and corporate income for 1 year beyond its present expiration date of June 30, 1969. In addition, the President is requesting a further extension at present levels of 54 the excise taxes on automobiles and telephone service which are now scheduled to decline on January 1, 1970. With these tax actions, it is estimated that the Federal budget (national income accounts basis) will show a surplus of about $5 billion during calendar 1969, compared with a deficit of $5 billion in 1968. The 10 percent tax surcharge was enacted as a temporary measure in June 1968 and is to be extended for 1 year as a temporary measure. Indeed, the President is urging the new Administration and the Congress to give serious consideration to coupling the extension of the surcharge with authority for the President to remove it entirely or partially, subject to Congressional veto, if warranted by developments in Vietnam, in the domestic economy, or in Federal outlays. MONETARY POLICY Monetary policy should remain flexible in 1969. In the environment prevailing at the start of the year, it is appropriate that monetary policy reinforce the effects of fiscal restraint to assure the needed moderation of pressures on the Nation's resources. The recent increase in the Federal Reserve discount rate and increased pressures on bank reserve positions are pursuing that objective. A slowing from the recent rapid growth of bank credit is appropriate in early 1969. But with fiscal restraint continuing through fiscal year 1970, monetary policy may gradually be able to shift to a less restrictive stance than presently prevails. Flexible and alert responses to a moderation of economic activity would permit a timely de-escalation of interest rates from their currently high levels and hence a more adequate flow of funds to savings institutions and the mortgage market. A decline from present peak levels of nominal interest rates would be desirable for the long run as well to avoid restricting capital formation and economic growth in general, and homebuilding in particular. The continuation of the surcharge through fiscal 1970 should permit a gradual movement toward a more desirable mix of monetary and fiscal policies; with fiscal policy better adjusted to the needs of economic stabilization, the need for restrictive monetary policy and relatively high interest rates should gradually abate. ECONOMIC OUTLOOK FOR 1969 The fiscal restraint contained in the Revenue and Expenditure Control Act of 1968 will have its major impact on the economy early in 1969. Assuming the fiscal program outlined above and appropriate monetary policy, GNP is expected to rise by $60 billion in 1969 from the $861 billion now estimated for 1968. This projection should not be viewed as an exact estimate, but rather as the midpoint of a range of possible outcomes. This forecast of an increase of approximately 7 percent in GNP means a continuation of prosperous conditions and economic expansion, though, as 55 desired, at a considerably more moderate rate than in 1968. The unemployment rate should remain below 4 percent. The expansion within 1969 is expected to be considerably less rapid than during 1968, and the increase in GNP from the fourth quarter of 1968 to the fourth quarter of 1969 should be about 6 percent—smaller than the yearover-year increase. The rise in real output during the four quarters of 1969 should be less than 3 percent while the rate of increase of over-all prices may be a little more than 3 percent. The first part of 1969 should see a slowing of economic expansion. Consumer spending should rise moderately, influenced by the continuing impact of tax withholding, extra final settlements of about $1^4 billion on 1968 taxes, and a $3 billion increase in social security taxes which became effective January 1. Federal Government purchases will change little while State and local government expenditures are expected to increase at a normal pace. Inventory investment should retreat from the high rate of the fourth quarter of 1968. On the other hand, a strong rise in business fixed investment is expected early in 1969, in line with recent surveys of business plans and new orders for machinery and equipment. All in all, a significant slowing in the pace of expansion is now likely. At mid-1969, a substantial pay increase for Federal Government employees is scheduled. Beyond that, only a slight increase in Federal purchases is anticipated. The tax burden on consumers will also be reduced at that time as final settlements on 1968 taxes are completed in the first half of the year, although consumer spending should continue to feel the lagged effects of the final settlements. These fiscal elements, together with a continuing increase in private investment, are expected to lead to slightly more rapid economic expansion in the second half of the year. Thus the year 1969 promises continued prosperity for the American economy. The slowing of the expansion should provide welcome relief from the excessive demand pressures of 1968 and offers the prospect of some deceleration in the upward movement of prices. OUTLOOK BY SECTORS A brief survey of the outlook for specific categories of expenditures will help to clarify the projection of over-all economic activity. Business Fixed Investment Private and public investment surveys compiled recently indicate a substantial rise in business fixed investment in 1969. The Commerce Department-SEC survey reports that businessmen plan to increase their plant and equipment spending by about 9 percent in the first half of 1969 above levels prevailing in 1968. Such a sharp increase in investment is already reflected in orders for durable equipment and in construction contracts. This marked prospective expansion of investment follows a year when industrial production has reached new peaks and when business cash flows 56 have been at record levels, but when there has been relatively little pressure on existing industrial capacity. The dimensions of the rise in investment are still difficult to evaluate in view of uncertainty about the possible impact of economic developments during the first half of the year and of monetary policy on business plans later in 1969. For the year as a whole, the increase in business fixed investment over 1968 is expected to be about $7 or $8 billion. Inventories At the end of 1968, ratios of inventories to sales were at normal levels, both for manufacturing and for retail and wholesale trade. Barring unforeseen changes in economic conditions over the year, inventory investment in 1969 may show a slight decline from the average rate of 1968. Homebuilding Demographic trends and the relatively low level of residential construction in recent years have created a very strong underlying demand for new homes. Housing starts rose sharply in the second half of 1968, and residential construction activity should advance further early in 1969. Because of the important role in the housing market of the availability of mortgage financing, considerable uncertainty attaches to estimates of home construction beyond the next few months. Given the prospective monetary policy for this year as outlined above, private nonfarm housing starts in 1969 may be expected to fall somewhat below their recent rate of approximately 1.6 million per year. Residential construction expenditures for the year may rise by approximately 10 percent over the average 1968 level, reflecting a larger number of new housing units and increased outlays per unit. But this would mean only a modest rise from the rate of activity at the end of 1968. Government For the year 1969 an increase of State and local government purchases of goods and services of about $10 billion can be anticipated in line with the growing needs for public services and facilities. This estimate assumes that monetary policy will not significantly curtail expenditures for public construction projects. Federal Government purchases are expected to remain at approximately their present levels during the first half of 1969, in accordance with expenditure restraint applied under the Revenue and Expenditure Control Act of 1968. However, an increase in Federal Government salaries will add $2.8 billion at annual rates to Federal Government expenditures beginning in the third quarter of 1969, and the Budget for fiscal 1970 in- 57 eludes other modest increases in purchases. For the calendar year 1969, Federal purchases of goods and services, including the pay increase, are expected to be approximately $3 billion higher than in 1968. Consumption Consumer spending in 1969 will be greatly influenced by the continuing adjustment of consumers to the changes in their disposable incomes resulting from the pace of advance in private and Government activity and from changes in their tax obligations. Consumer spending slowed in the closing months of 1968. Retail sales have not increased significantly since midsummer and the pace of automobile purchases has moderated. In the first half of 1969, increased tax burdens will further slow the growth of disposable personal income, although this may be reflected, in part, in a renewed decline of the saving rate. Consumer expenditures are thus expected to grow rather slowly during the first half of 1969. Surveys of consumer buying anticipations tend to confirm this prospect. Personal disposable income may grow somewhat more rapidly in the second half of 1969—in part because of the Federal pay increase and the completion by mid-year of final 1968 tax settlements. Thus, consumer spending may advance more strongly. For the year as a whole, it is anticipated that disposable personal income will increase nearly $35 billion and consumer expenditures should increase approximately the same amount reflecting a small decline in the saving rate. PRICE OUTLOOK The excessive rate of price and wage advance during 1968 will inevitably influence wages, costs, and prices during 1969. Unit labor costs will continue to increase, as will the costs of materials, supplies, and capital equipment. Financial costs are also likely to remain relatively high. Gradually, however, fiscal restraint coupled with restrictive monetary policy should moderate the excessive market pressures that prevailed during most of 1968. Present indications point to slightly lower farm prices during 1969, assuming normal weather conditions. Allowing for a continued increase in the costs of food processing and distribution, food prices at retail may remain approximately stable. Wage increases may have somewhat less impact in 1969 than they did in 1968. Second year increases in the union contracts negotiated in 1968 and the last half of 1967 will generally be less than for the first contract year. Collective bargaining activity will also be relatively light, since expiring major contracts up for wage negotiations cover only about half as many workers as in 1968. And finally, as restraint takes hold more firmly, lessened market pressures provide a prospect for some moderation in nonunion wages as well. 58 Wage-Price Policies for 1969 If substantial progress is to be made toward the restoration of price stability in 1969, restraint in private decisions is essential to complement responsible fiscal and monetary policies. Intensive consultations involving representatives of business, labor, and Government are required to explore practical and equitable ways in which such restraint might be achieved. Mutual shortterm sacrifices are needed to protect the great long-term interest of business, labor, and all Americans in noninflationary prosperity. It would be unrealistic to expect the full restoration of price stability in the immediate future. Given the recent history and the outlook for the cost of living, labor cannot be expected to accept wage increases in 1969 limited to the trend growth of productivity. Nor can businessmen be expected to absorb substantial cost increases without any adjustments in prices. Nevertheless, the process of price and wage deceleration must begin. In their own and in the public interest, business and labor should undertake a pattern of voluntary restraint that will carry the Nation a substantial distance back toward the goal of price stability in 1969. New wage agreements would move halfway back to the ultimate productivity standard next year if labor accepted wage settlements that would bring the average increase in money wage rates a little below 5 percent. Business would display comparable restraint in pricing if it intensified its efforts to offset rising costs through greater efficiency and if it absorbed a share of unavoidable increases in costs through acceptance of lower profit margins. This could be translated into a general rule that business agree to absorb increases of up to 1 percent in unit costs and accept as a guide in price decisions a profit target no higher than the average achieved in the years 1967-68. Responsible pricing requires that businessmen focus on margins before tax and not attempt to pass the temporary corporate tax surcharge on to consumers. It is also appropriate to ask those who depart from these standards to bear the obligation of demonstrating that special circumstances render the standards grossly unreasonable. These standards for price-wage restraint in 1969 were suggested by the Cabinet Committee on Price Stability in its December 1968 report to the President. Combined with responsible fiscal-monetary policy ajid continued efforts to improve the structure of the economy, acceptance of these standards for 1969 by key private decision-makers would carry the Nation a long way on the road to price stability. OUTLOOK FOR THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS With the anticipated slowing of economic growth, only a modest increase in imports is expected in 1969. The special strike situations which adversely affected trade in 1968 should not be repeated, although new problems of this kind could arise. Continuation of the rising trend in earnings on foreign 59 investment should be another source of improvement in our current account position. U.S. exports should increase in line with the expansion of foreign markets. The restrictive measures taken by France and the United Kingdom to safeguard their payments positions have reduced our export prospects, but these are likely to be offset by the German measures in the opposite direction. The capital account is unlikely to show improvement, and indeed may deteriorate. The restraint on bank lending cannot provide another large swing in net loans. Foreign purchases of U.S. securities can hardly be expected to continue at present rates. Even more important will be the state of financial markets at home and abroad. If European monetary conditions remain fairly relaxed relative to those prevailing in the United States, capital inflows can be expected—even if not on the same scale as in 1968. In view of the uncertain prospects for the balance of payments, the measures for controlling capital movements must be maintained for the present. The Interest Equalization Tax which expires at mid-year must be continued to assure against a major rise of new foreign security issues in the United States. Moreover, the program for controlling bank lending and the direct investment controls should be maintained. Both have been modified to make them more responsive to needs and more equitable. While further modifications will be possible as the balance of payments improves, the defenses provided by these programs cannot be lowered without risking the destabilizing effects of substantial refinancing of previous years' borrowings. Ultimate dismantling of the controls should proceed as soon as this can be accomplished without impairing the strength of the dollar. 60 Chapter 2 Policies for Balanced Expansion The Congress hereby declares that it is the continuing policy and responsibility of the Federal Government to use all practicable means consistent with its needs and obligations and other essential considerations of national policy . . . to promote maximum employment, production, and purchasing power. OR THE PAST 23 YEARS, these forthright marching orders in the Employment Act of .1946 have firmly committed the Federal Government to an active role in promoting high standards of over-all economic performance. Federal fiscal and monetary policies have contributed to a much improved record of stability and growth in the U.S. economy throughout the postwar era. In particular, during the past 8 years, national policy has been designed not merely to counter cyclical fluctuations but to promote steady expansion of economic activity in pace with productive potential. While fiscal and monetary policies have not always been appropriate to the needs of the day, their general success in fulfilling the lofty promises of the Employment Act is clearly demonstrated by the unparalleled prosperity achieved during the Kennedy and Johnson Administrations. Eight consecutive years of economic expansion, the longest and largest sustained advance in the annals of U.S. history, have dispelled the doubts that prevailed in the late 1950's about the vitality of the American economic system. The lessons of this experience are worth reviewing. Such a review, together with some suggestions for improvements in the formulation and implementation of stabilization policies, is the subject of this chapter. F REALIZING THE ECONOMY'S POTENTIAL How much the Nation's economy can produce—its supply capability— depends on the quantity and quality of its productive resources, including manpower, plant and equipment, and natural resources. The economy's aggregate demand is the total of spending for final output by all groups— consumers, businesses, government, and foreign buyers. When aggregate demand matches supply capability, resources are fully utilized and production equals the economy's potential. If aggregate demand should fall short of supply capability, part of the output that the economy is capable of turning out 6i 323-166 0—69——5 would not be produced, and some resources would be wasted in idleness. On the other hand, excessive demand—too much spending in relation to potential output—would generate inflationary pressures on prices and costs. The vbasic task of fiscal and monetary policies is to help ensure a match between demand and productive potential. These measures operate primarily by affecting the demand side of the balance. Government purchases of goods and services are directly a part of total demand; increases or decreases in such purchases change total spending in the same direction. In addition, other government expenditures indirectly influence total demand through their impact on private incomes. Social security benefits, for example, are "transfer payments" which add to the purchasing power of individuals, and thus encourage additional private spending, especially for consumer goods and services. Taxes, on the other hand, reduce the ability and willingness of families and business firms to spend, by drawing purchasing power out of private hands. By raising (or lowering) tax rates, the Federal Government can hold down (or add to) the flow of private spending. Monetary policies affect private spending primarily by changing the cost and availability of funds required to finance certain types of expenditures. If borrowing becomes expensive and difficult, expenditures for new homes, business machinery, and other things may be discouraged or postponed. The economy's potential output is continually expanding as a result of the growth of the labor force and increases in productivity. Economic policy must therefore aim at a moving target—helping demand to grow in pace so that an appropriate balance with potential is maintained. If demand does not expand or if it grows only sluggishly, men and machines become unemployed. THE CHOICE OF A TARGET Economic potential or capacity is not an absolute technical ceiling on output. It allows for some margin of unused human and physical resources. Even in the most extreme boom, there are always some people unemployed, some who could be attracted into the labor force, some who would be willing to "moonlight" or work overtime. Similarly, there are always some plants that could be operated more intensively or for longer hours. To operate the economy at its utmost technical capacity would require demands far in excess of supply in most markets, with resulting rampant inflation. The relevant concept of capacity, therefore, must allow for some margin of idle resources. The choice of a specific margin involves an appraisal of the behavior of prices and costs in a high-employment economy. But this appraisal involves more than a technical evaluation. If potential output is to be viewed as a target for policy, the choice of the ideal level of utilization is a social judgment that requires a balancing of national goals of high employment and reasonable price stability. 62 Balances of this sort are never simple. Both unemployment and inflation involve social and individual costs. The severe economic burden borne by those who have no jobs is obvious. At the bottom of the 1957-58 recession, there were more than five million workers out of jobs; and during 1958 more than 14 million workers experienced one or more spells of unemployment. Still others were forced to accept part-time employment or were relegated to jobs beneath their capacity. Some, in resignation, abandoned the search for jobs. The loss of income was tremendous. The costs in frustration, despair, and bitterness cannot be measured. Some of the costs of unemployment linger on because skills and supplies of labor are impaired. When over-all unemployment is excessive, employers have little incentive to provide job training programs for the unskilled or to upgrade workers to better paying jobs. Labor unions become increasingly concerned about the job security of existing members and often take measures that limit the supply of available labor for the longer run. Although the burden of a slack economy falls most heavily on the unemployed, the loss of production associated with underutilized resources imposes serious costs on nearly all groups. The incomes lost by the unemployed represent far less than half of the total shortfall of output and income. A slack economy sharply reduces the profits of large and small businesses and cuts government tax revenues. Moreover, part of the burden falls on future generations, because underutilization of capacity weakens investment incentives, slowing the rate of capital accumulation and limiting future productivity gains. It is difficult to balance the costs of inflation against those of an absolute loss of output and employment, because they are quantitatively and qualitatively different. Inflation has highly arbitrary and inequitable effects on the distribution of income and wealth. It benefits debtors at the expense of creditors; it hurts persons, such as some pensioners, whose incomes and asset values are fixed in money terms, and benefits those whose incomes and asset values increase more than in proportion to the over-all rise in prices. Since the impact of inflation on the welfare of an individual depends on the way in which both his income and the value of his wealth respond to the change in prices, its effects on broad classes of the population cannot be easily characterized. But there are many persons, in nearly all walks of life, who experience significant losses as a result of inflation. In general, financially sophisticated persons, who foresee the consequences of rising prices, can take steps to protect themselves, while the less sophisticated may lose. There is also a danger that inflation can set in motion speculative behavior that will cause further acceleration of price increases, with serious consequences for economic and social stability. There are even extreme examples in history of the breakdown of financial and economic systems as a result of galloping inflation. Finally, inflation may have adverse consequences for our balance of payments. If prices rise more rapidly in the United States than in other countries, our competitive position in world markets can be seriously undermined. As a collective social decision, the choice of an employment objective can and should be the subject of continuous reexamination. Chapter 3 suggests a number of structural measures that can help to lessen the conflict between high employment and price stability. When combined with an improved performance of fiscal and monetary policy along lines discussed in this chapter, these measures may make it possible to achieve progressively lower rates of unemployment with reasonable price stability. POTENTIAL OUTPUT In light of the considerations discussed above, a 4-percent unemployment rate was established as an "interim" target for national policy early in the Kennedy Administration. In each of its last seven Annual Reports, the Council of Economic Advisers has based its estimates of potential output on a 4-percent rate of unemployment. This Report continues to make use of this definition. The resulting estimated path of potential output for the period 1955 to 1968, together with the path of actual gross national product (GNP), is shown in Chart 5. Actual GNP was approximately equal to potential in 1955, but fell gradually below potential in the following years. The gap widened sharply in the 1957-58 recession, it failed to close fully in the ensuing expansion, and it widened again in the recession of 1960-61. In the first quarter of 1961, the gap amounted to about $60 billion (in 1968 prices), and the unemployment rate was 6.8 percent. From the first quarter of 1961 until the end of 1965, when the unemployment rate reached 4 percent, actual output was consistently below potential. But actual output grew more rapidly than potential, catching up and finally closing the gap. Since then, actual output has exceeded the calculated potential most of the time, as the unemployment rate has been below 4 percent. It is estimated that potential output grew about 3 / 2 percent a year from the mid-1950's to the early 1960's. After that, its growth appears to have speeded up gradually; for the last few years, it is estimated at 4 percent a year. Growth of potential output reflects the combined effects of expansion of available man-hours of labor and rising output per man-hour. Available Man-Hours Sustained growth of the labor force has resulted in a substantial rise in potentially available man-hours despite a gradually declining trend in average hours of work. Over the long run, the labor force has increased roughly in line with the working-age population (16 years old and over). This tendency has continued in the 1960's. The rising participation of women in the labor force has been roughly offset by the effects of a shift e4 Chart 5 Gross National Product, Actual and Potential, and Unemployment Rate BILLIONS OF DOLLARS (ratio scale)* 700 650 GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT IN 1958 PRICES - 600 yS POTENTIAL.!/ 550 y S / — \^^^ y^ — GAP yS 500 S^ / / \ / * " ^ ^ / ^ - ATA CU L / 450 - 1 400 1 1 1956 1 1958 1 1 1 1960 1 1962 1 1 1964 1 1 1966 1 1968 PERCENT PERCENT [] 12 GNP GAP AS PERCENT OF POTENTIAL (Left scale) •—• UNEMPLOYMENT RATE2/(Right scale) -6 J L 1956 J 1958 L 1960 J 1962 J L 1964 I 1966 I I 1968 •SEASONALLY ADJUSTED ANNUAL RATES. -I/TREND LINE OF 3'2% THROUGH MIDDLE OF 1955 TO 1962 IV, L\% FROM 1962 IV TO 1965 IV, AND 4% FROM 1965 IV TO 1968 IV. I/UNEMPLOYMENT AS PERCENT OF CIVILIAN LABOR FORCE; SEASONALLY ADJUSTED, SOURCES: DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE, DEPARTMENT OF LABOR, AND COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS. I 0 in the composition of the working-age population toward teenagers and older people, who have relatively low participation rates. Average hours worked per employed person have declined slowly over the long run, reflecting the secular trend toward more holidays, longer vacations, shortening of the workweek, and increasing participation of people who want to work only part time. Growth of the potential labor force has accelerated from 1*4 percent a year in the early 19605s to a present rate of about 1% percent—reflecting the upsurge in births immediately after World War II. This has been partially offset by the secular decline in hours worked of about l/± of 1 percent a year. The net result has been an acceleration of the growth of available man-hours from 1 to 11/2 percent a year over the period. Productivity Many factors contribute to growth in output per man-hour—the productivity of labor. These include increases in the stock of productive capital and improvements in its quality; better educated, better trained, and more experienced labor; and advances in technology, production methods, and management techniques. Since 1950, output per man-hour in the private economy has expanded at an average annual rate a little above 3 percent. For the entire economy, the calculated trend is somewhat lower, because improvements in the efficiency of Government workers are not measured statistically and are arbitrarily taken at zero. Thus the trend rate of increase in aggregate productivity— private and public—has been about 2*/2 percent a year. When added to the growth of available man-hours, this results in the 3 ]/2 percent annual growth of potential output for the late 1950's and the 4 percent current growth rate. Actual and Potential GNP Over the entire period from the recession trough in the first quarter of 1961 to the fourth quarter of 1968, actual GNP rose by $288 billion (in 1968 prices), reflecting the combined result of keeping up with the growth of potential GNP and of closing the gap. Potential GNP rose by $216 billion, an increase of 33 percent. Thus the Nation is presently earning a huge additional bonus of $72 billion a year in output as a result of having eliminated a great waste of idle resources. The unemployment rate in the first quarter of 1961 stood at 6.8 percent. At current levels of the labor force, the reduction of this rate to the 3.4 percent that prevailed in the fourth quarter of 1968—below the 4 percent rate that is used to define potential output—represents a gain in employment of 2.7 million. On the basis of current average productivity, this number of workers can be credited with a $31 billion contribution to output (annual rate). 66 However, the reduction of 3.4 percentage points in the unemployment rate accounts directly for only a portion of the gain in output associated with the closing of the gap. There were four other important factors involved: 1. In a slack economy, firms are often reluctant to lay off certain types of workers, particularly foremen, semi-professionals, and the highly skilled. The result is considerable on-the-job underemployment which depresses measured labor productivity. As the economy moves back toward potential, productivity increases more rapidly than the long-term trend. Since early 1961, output per man-hour has risen at an average annual rate of 3 percent, l /i of a percentage point more than trend. 2. Labor force participation has risen since 1961 as people who had not been looking for work responded to the greater availability of job opportunities. 3. The increased pace of economic activity slowed the secular decline in the length of the workweek. 4. The proportion of the labor force reporting involuntary part-time employment for economic reasons declined from 4.4 percent in early 1961 to 2.1 percent in the fourth quarter of 1968. Together, these four factors contributed an additional $41 billion to the output gain associated with the reduction of the unemployment rate. The $72 billion of extra GNP resulting from reducing the unemployment rate amounts to about 11 percent of potential output at the start of the period—that is, there was about a 3 percentage point bonus of annual production for each 1 percentage point reduction in the unemployment rate. ECONOMIC GAINS OF THE EXPANSION The chief over-all measures of the progress of the American economy during the past 8 years are presented in Table 7. The benefits of economic expansion have permeated nearly every corner of the economy and every aspect of our national life. From the recession trough in early 1961 to the end of 1968, the expansion of output created more than 10^4 million jobs. This was enough to provide work for the 8J/2 million net increase in the labor force while at the same time reducing the pool of unemployed workers by more than two million. Living standards have substantially increased. On an after-tax basis and after adjusting for price increases, total disposable personal income per capita—the purchasing power of households—has risen by 33 percent since early 1961. Personal consumption expenditures per person have risen in step. Meanwhile, net financial assets of households—the excess of their financial assets over their debts—have grown from $700 billion at the end of 1960 to an estimated $1,350 billion at the end of 1968. 67 TABLE 7.—Measures of economic activity during thecurrent Percentage change1 Amount Series expansion Unit or base Per year 1961 1 1968 IV i 482.6 719.1 49.0 5.3 316.2 44.9 20.9 97.6 454.8 79.4 24.0 151.0 43.8 76.8 14.8 54.7 4.8 7.6 52.2 45.4 79.4 71.6 52.1 57.7 5.6 6.1 1957-59=100 103.7 167.3 61.3 6.4 Billions of dollars 3.. do Dollars, 1958 prices3. 354.8 24.4 1,871 602.5 4 51.2 2,483 69.8 109.8 32.7 10.4 3.7 65.7 53.5 76.4 68.9 16.3 28.8 Total Production: Gross national product2 Personal consumption expenditures Business fixed investment Residential structures Government purchases Federal. . . State and local Industrial production Billions of dollars, 1958 prices.3 do do. . do- do do. _do 1.8 5.8 Income: Disposable personal income Corporate profits after tax Per capita disposable personal income 7.1 Employment: Civilian employment Nonagricultural payroll employment... Millions of persons do 2.0 3.3 1 Preliminary. 2 Total includes change in business inventories and net exports of goods and services not shown separately. 3 Annual rates. * 1968 IV not available; 1968 III used. Note.—All data are seasonally adjusted. Sources: Department of Commerce, Department of Labor, and Council of Economic Advisers. Corporate profits have more than doubled during the past 8 years, both before and after taxes. In addition to permitting sharply increased dividend payments to stockholders, these rising profits have provided the financing for a wholesale expansion and modernization of the Nation's productive capacity. Indeed, business has increased its real stock of capital goods by more than 40 percent since the end of 1960 and has progressively reduced the average age of existing capital. The decline in the over-all unemployment rate since early 1961 has been accompanied by equally impressive gains by specific categories of the labor force, as shown in Chart 6. In particular, the unemployment rate for white adult males had fallen to 1.8 percent by the fourth quarter of 1968, a level last achieved in 1953. For nonwhite adult males the decline in unemployment has been especially dramatic—from an intolerable 11.6 percent rate in early 1961 to 3.9 percent in late 1968. This represents a significant narrowing of the differential between white and nonwhite unemployment rates for men, from 6.4 percentage points at the beginning of the period to about 2 percentage points by the fourth quarter of 1968. On the other hand, there has been little progress in reducing the unemployment rates of teenagers, especially nonwhites. The progressive tightening of the over-all labor market during this period has made a substantial contribution to the elimination of employment barriers based on race and sex. While these are significant gains, the unemployment rates for some groups of workers still remain appallingly high. As Chapters 3 and 5 make clear, additional efforts are needed to 68 Chart 6 Unemployment Rates PERCENT (Seasonally adjusted)!/ 10 20 30 10 20 30 A L L CIVILIAN WORKERS NONWH1TE MEN WHITE WOMEN NONWHITE WOMEN WHITE TEENAGERS NONWHITE TEENAGERS I/PERCENT OF CIVILIAN LABOR FORCE IN EACH GROUP WHO ARE UNEMPLOYED, SOURCE: DEPARTMENT OF LABOR. assist such workers, who often suffer from such disadvantages as inadequate training and job discrimination. The strong advance in the economy has also permitted rapid progress in many social fields. As discussed more fully in Chapter 5, the number of Americans in poverty declined by 18 million during the past 8 years. Rates of infant and maternal mortality have been reduced, school enrollment and school completion rates have been raised, and millions of additional young people have been able to attend college. Many of these advances would have been impossible to achieve if rising tax revenues had not been generated by a vigorously expanding economy. Federal revenues expanded from $92/2 billion in fiscal 1960 to an estimated $186 billion in fiscal 1969, while State and local government revenues more than doubled. School construction, urban development, low-income housing, and many other programs at all levels of government have expanded correspondingly. THE PROBLEM OF ECONOMIC FLUCTUATIONS There is nothing inherent in the U.S. economy to ensure that total demand will grow consistently in pace with the economy's productive potential. The sum total of millions of decentralized spending decisions by households, businesses, and governments at all levels will not automatically and necessarily match potential output. The historical record is marked and marred by a pattern of fluctuations in which the economy often took two steps forward and then one step back. According to the National Bureau of Economic Research, the United States suffered 27 business-cycle contractions between 1854 and 1961, an average of one every 4 years. At other times, especially in periods of active hostilities, sharp surges in demand have strained the economy's potential, generating inflationary pressures. SHORT-RUN INSTABILITY All of the elements of demand have at times been sources of economic fluctuations. In the private sector, variations in the strength of demand have most often been concentrated in investment—inventory accumulation, business outlays for fixed capital, and residential construction expenditures. Elements of Demand Inventory stocks serve primarily as a buffer to ensure a smooth and efficient flow of material supplies and production and to guard against unforeseen increases in sales. Once inventory stock has been built up to a level adequate to cover a few months' production or sales, further accumulation is necessary only insofar as increases in sales are anticipated. Thus inventory investment can be sustained only by a steady expansion of sales. 70 Even relatively small variations in the rate of growth of sales can have sizable effects on inventory investment. An unexpected slowdown in demand, for example, will initially leave unsold goods on the shelves. Businessmen will wish to work off these excess inventories, and if they expect sales to continue at a slower pace, they will reduce their desired levels of future inventories. Cutbacks in production will then follow. As illustrated by the $17j/2 billion drop in the annual rate of inventory accumulation in early 1967, such fluctuations can be a major source of instability. Businessmen invest in new plant and equipment to increase and modernize their productive capacity. The rate of current capacity utilization, anticipated growth in demand, corporate cash flow, relative costs of capital and labor, and borrowing costs all influence investment decisions. Responses to changes in these factors are neither smooth nor readily predictable; and because of the long leadtimes generally involved in the production of capital goods, such responses may be spread out over a considerable period of time. But fluctuations in capital spending have often been an important source of instability. For example, real investment (constant prices) rose by 42 percent between 1963 and 1966, contributing to a strong expansion of aggregate demand, but then leveled out in 1967. The third component of investment, homebuilding, is dependent upon family formation and income, with the availability of mortgage funds often acting as a major constraint, particularly in the short run. Because credit conditions generally tighten when the economy is expanding rapidly and ease when growth slows down, residential construction has frequently moved opposite to the path of over-all economic activity, contracting when the rest of the economy has been booming. Consumer outlays normally follow the path of household incomes fairly closely. But such spending has also occasionally been an independent source of economic instability. Because consumption accounts for more than 60 percent of GNP, relatively small shifts in consumer demand have large impacts. The increase of 1 percentage point in the personal saving rate that occurred between 1966 and 1967, for example, directly reduced consumer expenditures by more than $5 billion. Fluctuations are particularly pronounced in consumer purchases of automobiles and other durable goods. The volatility of expenditures that makes for economic instability is by no means confined to private demand. Sudden changes in Federal spending have, on occasion, seriously disrupted the stability of the economy. Indeed, the rapid expansion of defense expenditures early in the Korean war, the rapid decline in 1953-54, and the upsurge of outlays for Vietnam in 196567 challenged economic policy as much as any change in the strength of private demand during the past 20 years. Multiplier Process An autonomous increase in demand and production in any sector can be expected to work through the economy by raising disposable income 71 and hence consumer expenditures, by encouraging greater inventory accumulation, and by creating incentives for additional investment in plant and equipment. This cumulative expansion is known as the "multiplier process." The results of this multiplier process are affected by the amount of unused resources available in the economy. At times of high unemployment and extensive unutilized capacity, an initial stimulus in demand is likely to be reflected primarily in a rise in real output with very little additional pressure on prices. But in an economy already operating at or above potential, where additional resources are not readily available, the main result may be upward pressure on prices with relatively little gain in real output. Developments in financial markets may influence the magnitude of the multiplier. Increases in demands for goods and services will tend to enlarge credit demands. Unless monetary policy permits supplies of funds to expand correspondingly, interest rates will rise and credit will become less readily available. In that event, some offsetting reduction is likely to take place in residential construction and other credit-sensitive expenditures. Generally this will be a partial offset, varying according to how much the supply of credit is permitted to expand. AUTOMATIC STABILIZERS AND FISCAL DRAG The potential sources of instability discussed above produced four recessions between 1948 and 1961. By prewar standards, these recessions were all relatively short and mild, though nevertheless costly. They were limited in intensity and duration by several elements built into the fiscal system which serve to moderate economic instability in an automatic and passive fashion. These so-called "automatic fiscal stabilizers" operate to bolster income flows to households and business firms in periods of declining output and, conversely, to slow down the growth of income in periods of expansion. Almost every tax—including State and local taxes—responds in some degree to changes in economic activity. Federal personal income tax collections are particularly responsive to such changes. They are the most important automatic fiscal stabilizer, cushioning take-home pay against fluctuations in the before-tax incomes of individuals. Another important stabilizer is the automatic expansion of unemployment compensation benefits when unemployment increases. The corporate income tax serves to reduce fluctuations in after-tax profits and hence in business investment outlays and dividend payments. By reducing the size of secondary effects on consumer and business outlays, these stabilizers reduce the severity of economic fluctuations. With the present tax system and schedules of unemployment compensation benefits, a decline in GNP automatically produces a reduction in government receipts and an increase in transfer payments. This limits the decline in private after-tax income—disposable personal income and retained corporate profits—to about 65 cents for each $1 of reduction in GNP. 72 During the postwar period, the automatic fiscal stabilizers have been a major factor in reducing economic instability. They go to work at once and avoid the delays inherent in discretionary action. But valuable as these automatic stabilizers are, they work only to limit—not prevent—swings in economic activity. For example, they become operative in a recession only after the decline has begun and cannot, by themselves, generate a recovery. If the factors causing a downturn are strong and persistent, automatic stabilizers may not be powerful enough to prevent a long and severe recession. The automatic stabilizers also operate without regard to the over-all level of economic activity. If the economy has fallen substantially below the path of potential output, the return to that path is made more difficult by the retarding effects of automatic fiscal stabilizers. The existence of the automatic stabilizers in such a situation means that a larger amount of fiscal or monetary stimulus—increased expenditures, reduced tax rates, or easing of credit conditions—will be required to achieve the needed increase in aggregate demand. In addition, automatic stabilizers work in a fashion that may inhibit the long-run expansion of demand. As the economy moves along the potential output path with reasonably stable prices, the Federal tax system generates an increase in revenues of about 6 percent a year. Unless this revenue growth is offset by reductions in taxes or by increases in expenditures, it acts as a "fiscal drag" by siphoning off income. Actions by the private sector can conceivably offset this effect if businesses increase investment expenditures faster than the growth of internal funds, or if households reduce their rate of saving. But under normal conditions, needed expansion may be prevented. In interpreting the economic impact of fiscal policy, it is essential to distinguish between the automatic changes in revenues and expenditures resulting from the operation of the automatic stabilizers, on the one hand, and discretionary changes brought about by changes in tax rates and expenditure programs, on the other. In order to measure the impact of discretionary fiscal policy, it is useful to prepare estimates of revenues and expenditures at a given—or "standardized"—level of income. When the difference between revenues and expenditures is estimated at the level of potential output, the result is sometimes referred to as the "full employment surplus." The full employment surplus was a particularly enlightening measure of fiscal policy in the early 1960's when the economy was far below its potential. Actual Federal budgets were then in deficit. But after taking account of the large shortfall in tax revenues associated with the gap between potential and actual output, there was a large full employment surplus. It meant that the economy could realize its potential only if private investment far exceeded private saving. By that standard, discretionary fiscal policy was highly restrictive. The vigorous and unbroken expansion of the last 8 years is in dramatic contrast to the 30-month average duration of previous expansions. No longer 73 THE RECORD OF POLICY is the performance of the American economy generally interpreted in terms of stages of the business cycle. No longer do we consider periodic recessions once every 3 or 4 years an inevitable fact of life. The forces making for economic fluctuations have been contained through the active use of fiscal and monetary policies to sustain expansion. The record of these policy actions is briefly surveyed in this section. A detailed review of the objectives and effects of monetary and fiscal actions from 1961 through 1967 was presented in last year's Annual Report. The discussion below summarizes some particularly pertinent aspects of the magnitude and scope of these actions. Subsequent sections discuss some of the problems of economic diagnosis and policy formulation in light of experience. STRATEGY FOR EXPANSION: 1961 TO MID-1965 A series of deliberately stimulative fiscal measures was undertaken from 1961 to mid-1965 to bring the economy up to full potential. The net magnitude of these actions is summarized in Table 8. The $37^4 billion total of expansionary actions—expenditure increases and net tax reductions— more than offset the $30yi billion estimated normal growth of revenues. Early actions on the expenditure side included an acceleration of a scheduled increase in social secu-rity benefits in 1961, liberalization of public assistance payments, and a step-up in defense purchases as part of a general TABLE 8.—Federal fiscal actions in three periods since fourth quarter 1960 [Billions of dollars, seasonally adjusted annual rates] 1960 IV to 1965 11 Item Federal expenditure increases2 1965 11 to 1967 IV 1967 IV to 1968 IV i 25.6 48.9 18.2 Defense purchases. Other purchases OASDHI3 benefitsAll other2 4 __. 3.4 7.4 5.0 9.8 25.4 2.8 10.0 10.7 5.4 2.6 5.2 5.0 Federal tax reductions 5_. 12.0 -6.0 5.5 Corporate Personal OASDHI s payroll taxes. Indirect business 8.5 -3.0 -3.5 -7.3 -2.2 1.0 Total expansionary actions8 37.6 Normal revenue growth at full employment- 30.5 Change in full employment surplus * -7.0 1 Preliminary. 2 Includes adjustment in unemployment insurance benefits for change in unemployment rate. Old-age, survivors, disability, and hospital and related insurance (OASDHI). « Consists of transfers other than OASDHI, grants, interest, and subsidies. 5 Minus sign indicates an increase in tax. 6 Sum of expenditure increases and tax reductions. 7 Normal revenue growth minus expansionary actions. Note.—Detail will not necessarily add to totals because of rounding. Sources: Department of Commerce and Council of Economic Advisers. 3 -8.5 2.5 -13.0 74 42.9 5.0 27.0 14.0 -16.0 9.0 realignment of our military forces. On the revenue side, stimulus to private investment was provided by a revision of depreciation guidelines and enactment of an investment tax credit of 7 percent on purchases of machinery and equipment in 1962. These measures were partially offset by increases in social security taxes in 1962 and 1963. The net stimulus from these actions worked in the right direction, but was inadequate to the major task of reaching potential output. In the middle of 1962, business investment demand proved disappointingly weak, and the pace of economic expansion slowed. In the absence of Congressional action on President Kennedy's tax reduction program in 1963, the budget again moved toward an unduly restrictive position. Tax reduction finally became a reality in the Revenue Act of 1964, which was President Johnson's first major legislative victory. This tax cut was unprecedented in many respects. When fully effective in 1965, it added more than $11 billion to private purchasing power—the largest stimulative fiscal action ever undertaken in peacetime. It was enacted while the Federal budget was in deficit and while expenditures were rising. It was designed explicitly to sustain and invigorate expansion up to potential output rather than to combat an existing or imminent recession. This major action was followed by the enactment of a phased reduction in excise taxes in the spring of 1965. Monetary policy also made an important contribution to the economic expansion by consistently accommodating growing credit demands at remarkably stable interest rates. A vigorously expansionary monetary policy which would have pushed interest rates to very low levels might, of course, have helped bring the economy to high employment more quickly. But such a decline in interest rates could have caused increased capital outflows from the United States, further impairing our balance-of-payments position. A series of actions by the Federal Reserve and the Treasury did actually raise U.S. short term interest rates during this period to bring them more into line with rates abroad. As shown in Chart 7, however, the upward pressure on short term rates did not spill over into long term markets. Decisions by the Federal Reserve at the beginning of 1962, in mid-1963, and in late 1964 to increase the maximum interest rates commercial banks could pay on time and savings deposits gave banks greater freedom to compete for funds. This enabled the banks to play an aggressive role throughout the period in tapping the market for liquid savings and rechanneling the funds into loans and investments. FISCAL PROBLEMS OF DEFENSE AND HIGH EMPLOYMENT: 1965-68 By mid-1965, the unemployment rate had been reduced to about 4 / 2 percent, and the gap between actual and potential output was being narrowed gradually and steadily. At this point, defense orders and expenditures 75 Chart 7 Selected Interest Rates PERCENT 8 - y —..A I n n i h i i i i li ii n i l ii i i I i ii i il M i n i 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 NOTE.-DATA PLOTTED ARE QUARTERLY THROUGH 1965, MONTHLY THEREAFTER. SOURCES: FEDERAL HOUSING ADMINISTRATION, BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM, MOODY'S INVESTORS SERVICE, AND TREASURY DEPARTMENT. began to build up rapidly, and the task of economic policy became considerably more complicated. The increase in defense activity reinforced a strong expansion of business spending on plant and equipment. The result was an excessively rapid growth of economic activity which generated inflationary pressures. Some fiscal action to restrain the economy was taken in 1966. A previously enacted rise in payroll taxes of $6 billion took effect at the start of the year. This was followed by prompt enactment of a series of tax measures proposed by the President in January—the reinstatement of some excise taxes that had been reduced, and the introduction of a system of graduated withholding of individual income taxes and of accelerated payments of corporate taxes. But even with these actions, fiscal policy remained strongly and inappropriately expansionary—in large part because defense spending continued to outrun expectations. As the President has recently made clear in reviewing the record, he discussed a recommended general rise in taxes privately with business and Congressional leaders early in 1966 and became convinced that a tax increase could not be enacted. In the fall, added fiscal restraint was provided by a temporary suspension of the investment tax credit and cutbacks in nondefense spending. In the absence of a full measure of timely fiscal restraint, an undue share of the burden of dampening the excessive expansion fell on monetary policy. In December 1965, the Federal Reserve raised the discount rate from 4 to 4J/2 percent and increased the maximum allowable interest rate on time deposits of commercial banks. As interest rates on bank time deposits and in the open market rose sharply, savings and loan associations and mutual savings banks experienced a sharp drop in their deposit inflows and thus had to cut back their lending to the homebuilding sector. These developments are described in more detail later in this chapter. The result of these actions was a marked slowing in the growth of final demand. But homebuilding bore a disproportionate share of the restrictive impact. Moreover, interest rates ratcheted sharply upward to the highest levels in several generations, and a near-crisis atmosphere developed in financial markets in August 1966. Because production continued to advance when final demand initially slowed, inventories increased rapidly late in 1966. The ensuing turn-around in inventory investment sharply accentuated an economic slowdown early in 1967, and the rate of price increase also slowed notably. Rising Government spending helped to maintain over-all expansion in the face of the large inventory adjustment in early 1967. And with easier credit stimulating homebuilding, strong expansionary forces reasserted themselves in the second half of that year. In August, President Johnson urged enactment of a 10-percent income tax surcharge. Delay in the passage of this measure intensified inflationary pressures and placed monetary policy in an awkward position as discussed in Chapter 1. LESSONS OF THE POLICY RECORD In most respects, the economy has performed extremely well in the last 8 years, and vigorous use of fiscal and monetary policy has contributed to this good performance. But the record could have been better, and it provides several lessons that should serve as guides for the future. First, the fiscal and monetary policy actions that were taken deliberately to influence economic activity generally worked in the right direction with effective results. Most of the shortcomings of the period were errors of omission rather than commission. This applies both to the delays in taking adequate stimulative action in 1961-63 and to the more recent delays in achieving fiscal restraint. Second, the experience of 1961-65 demonstrated that an effective fiscal policy to stimulate the economy could be carried out without adding unnecessarily to the size of the Federal budget. Since the aims of stabilization 77 323-166 0—69 6 policy can be implemented either through tax changes or expenditure changes, decisions regarding Federal expenditures can be properly based on the desired allocation of resources between the public and private sectors. Third, the record testifies to the effectiveness of a restrictive monetary policy in slowing down the economy, but also to its substantial undesirable side effects in bearing down on homebuilding and straining the financial system. The side effects point to the need for active fiscal policy to avoid placing a disproportionate share of the burden of economic stabilization on monetary policy. The major shortcomings of economic policy in recent years can be traced to difficulties in achieving prompt and appropriate adjustments in fiscal policy to offset variations in the strength of private demand and substantial changes in defense spending. The next section discusses some improvements that might be made in the formulation and implementation of fiscal policy. FORMULATING FISCAL POLICY The focus of fiscal policy in the United States is the annual Federal budget, which is presented in the Budget Message of the President in January. This budget covers the fiscal year starting 6 months later, on July 1. Any analysis of fiscal policy must begin with a consideration of the way in which this budget is formulated in the Executive Branch and the procedures by which the Congress acts on the President's recommendations. The requirements of economic stabilization are not always fully met, however, by the fiscal program incorporated in the annual budget, no matter how carefully this program is formulated. Conditions may change during the course of the year in such a way as to call for a significant policy response after the annual budget has been planned. Some degree of continuing flexibility is therefore necessary. One important forward step in budgetary practice was taken when the Federal budget for the fiscal year 1969 was presented. In accord with recommendations contained in the October 1967 Report of the President's Commission on Budget Concepts, a single unified budget was adopted, which covers in a comprehensive way all of the financial activities of the Federal Government. This unified budget provides a much improved statistical basis for formulating fiscal policy and evaluating its economic impact. THE ROLE OF ECONOMIC FORECASTING A certain amount of time is required for the economy to respond fully to changes in fiscal—and monetary—policies, and the actions taken at one point in time have effects that are felt over a considerable subsequent period. Whether a policy action will help or impair economic performance depends on the state of the economy in the period following the action. It cannot be judged adequately just by the facts of the economic situation at the time the decision is taken. It must be assessed in light of a forecast. 78 The responsibility within the Administration for projections of Federal revenues, expenditures, and economic activity rests jointly with the Department of the Treasury, the Bureau of the Budget, and the Council of Economic Advisers. Liaison is maintained with the Federal Reserve Board, which must also forecast economic activity as a basis for its decisions concerning monetary policy. These projections are particularly important in formulating the annual budget, and they are set forth regularly in the Council's Annual Report. But the evaluation of the economic situation and outlook must be kept up to date during the year. Thus the forecasts are revised for internal use as new information becomes available—indeed, the process of assessing the economic outlook is essentially a continuous one. The projections are frequently supplemented by quantitative estimates of the probable effects of alternative policy actions which might be taken. Quantitative evaluations of the outlook have been prepared for the President essentially on a quarterly schedule ever since 1961. This procedure assures a regular review by the President, with his chief economic and fiscal advisers, of the suitability of the budget program for the needs of the economy. The techniques used in preparing the Administration's economic projections have changed considerably over the years; but in general they depend on a set of quantitative relationships among economic magnitudes over time. The relationships that are relied upon may be based on formal statistical procedures, subjective expert judgment, or survey data. To a considerable extent, forecasting relies upon the timely availability of data relating to the economy's past performance which can be used as a basis for projecting its future behavior. Although there are still gaps in economic statistics, considerable progress has been made in recent years by the Department of Commerce, the Department of Labor, and other Federal Government agencies in increasing the quantity and improving the quality of statistical data available for assessing the performance of the economy. Government agencies also collect valuable information on the anticipated future behavior of some categories of expenditures. For example, the quarterly survey of investment anticipations provides a useful indication of the probable behavior of this highly volatile element of private demand. The Bureau of the Budget prepares up-to-date estimates of future Federal expenditures. Estimates of Federal tax revenues are prepared and kept current by the Treasury Department. Forecasting was notably successful in gauging in advance the rapid expansion of 1964 and the upsurge from late 1967 into 1968. On some occasions, however, difficulties have been encountered. The strength of the 1965-66 boom was not fully foreseen. Unexpected increases in the personal saving rate intensified the slowdown in economic activity that occurred in the first half of 1967. In the second half of 1968, private demand was 79 stronger than had been anticipated, as noted in Chapter 1. Nevertheless, the whole record makes clear that explicit quantitative projections are superior to extrapolations or hunches, which are the only alternative ways of guiding policy decisions that affect the future. The need for greater precision in both forecasting and policy formulation has increased greatly in recent years. Between 1961 and 1965, when actual output was consistently below potential, there was little threat of a serious rise in prices, and the risks of excessive expansion were small. Thus emphasis could be placed upon achieving a growth of actual output in excess of that of potential in order to close the gap. Since 1965, however, as actual output has remained relatively close to potential, the need to anticipate and to offset fluctuations in demand has correspondingly increased. PREPARING THE ANNUAL BUDGET The Federal budget should be formulated with two objectives in view. One is to provide the amount of fiscal stimulus or restraint needed to keep the economy moving along the potential output path—or to move it back toward that path if a departure has occurred. The other is to choose a level of Federal expenditures that provides the appropriate allocation of national resources between private and public uses. In principle, these two objectives can be pursued independently, since fiscal stimulus or restraint can be provided either by adjusting public expenditures or by adjusting tax rates to influence private spending. Determining the Extent of Expansionary Action In developing a budget that is appropriate in terms of fiscal impact, it is necessary at the outset to prepare an economic forecast for a period extending a year and a half beyond the time of budget presentation. The forecast covering the first 6 months of this period—for which the budget outlook has already been fairly well determined—provides the point of departure for viewing economic prospects in the ensuing fiscal year. From that point on, forecasts of private demand are used to determine the appropriate degree of fiscal stimulus or restraint to be provided by the budget. This determination takes account of the growth of Federal revenues when GNP grows in line with potential m a noninflationary environment at unchanged tax rates. When the economy is in reasonable balance on the path of potential output and private demand is expected neither to weaken nor to accelerate, the forecast will point to the need for expansionary fiscal action sufficient to offset the fiscal drag exerted by normal revenue growth. If the projection suggests that private demand will weaken or if the economy is operating below potential at the beginning of the year, expansionary fiscal action will be called for in an amount more than sufficient 8o to counteract the restraining effects of normal revenue growth. Conversely, if private demand is expected to strengthen or if the economy is operating above potential at the beginning of the year, an amount of expansionary fiscal action less than sufficient to offset the restraining effects of normal revenue growth will be required—or, in an extreme case, some additional restraint, beyond that provided by normal revenue growth, may be necessary. The desired amount of expansionary (or restrictive) fiscal action, as indicated by the forecast, can be provided either by increasing (reducing) Government expenditures, by reducing (increasing) tax rates, or by some combination of the two. A decision therefore has to be made whether to adjust taxes, or expenditures, or both. This decision involves difficult choices about the allocation of resources between public sector programs and the private sector. Public Expenditures and Tax Changes In order to make these choices intelligently, it is necessary to examine carefully the proposed Federal expenditures having the highest priorities— whether they be for the expansion of existing programs or for new initiatives—and judge whether the public needs that would be met by these programs are more or less urgent than the demands of the private sector that would be satisfied by tax reduction. Allowance ordinarily has to be made for a virtually unavoidable increase in expenditures sufficient to keep pace with rising costs and rising workloads under existing Federal programs. The decision would, however, still have to be made whether any needed restraint or additional stimulus over and above that provided by this built-in expenditure growth should come from changes in tax rates or in expenditures. All of this suggests that there is no reason to suppose that the proper allocation of resources between public sector and private sector activities would be achieved by keeping tax rates constant and adjusting Federal expenditures to meet the requirements of fiscal policy. It should be perfectly normal for the President to recommend a change in tax rates in his annual Budget Message. Such proposed changes have in fact been a feature of the last seven annual budgets. Indeed, consideration of the appropriateness of tax rates should be a normal part of the budget program—if no change is being proposed, the President should explain why existing tax rates are regarded as appropriate. If Government expenditures move ahead year by year at a rate about equal to the growth of tax revenues, changes in tax rates may not need to be made very often. However, it would be a remarkable coincidence if a steady growth in Government expenditures at that rate simultaneously satisfied the needs of economic stabilization and the Nation's wishes over the long run with respect to the proper allocation of resources between the public and private sectors of the economy. Sharp increases in defense spending pose special issues relating to the 81 allocation of resources between Federal nondefense programs and the private sector. A sharp increase in defense expenditures normally requires a compensating fiscal adjustment to prevent the budget from becoming undesirably stimulative. In principle, any needed adjustment can be accomplished either by increases in tax rates or reductions in Federal nondefense outlays. For a number of reasons, however, increases in tax rates should normally be the main instrument. First, sharp slashes in Federal nondefense programs are simply not administratively feasible in the short run. Second, social priorities for the nonmilitary public sector would be violated if these programs carried the major burden of fiscal adjustment. The overhead cost on society of increased defense requirements should be expected to be borne primarily by the 80 percent of GNP that represents private uses of output. It seems evident that the roughly 10 percent of GNP which Federal nondefense spending represents should not be expected to carry the major part of the load. This seems particularly compelling in a Nation which is affluent in general and yet beset by serious social problems. While it is entirely appropriate for some types of nondefense spending to be cut and stretched out in order to ease the fiscal problem, there are strong grounds for avoiding reductions in social programs that deal with the urgent problems of poverty and urban blight. CONGRESSIONAL PROCEDURES If fiscal policy, as embodied in the annual budget, is to make its maximum contribution to economic stabilization, some changes in Congressional procedures for reviewing and determining the budget would be desirable. General Budget Review One important problem lies in existing Congressional procedures for determining budget authority and hence Federal expenditures. In both the House and Senate, budget authority is essentially controlled by 13 separate appropriations subcommittees which determine budget authority for individual agencies and programs. Their individual decisions can lead to a total of budget authority and outlays that is not controlled nor determnied in a coordinated way. The Legislative Reorganization Act of 1946 called for a concurrent resolution on an expenditure total in advance of appropriations, but this limitation was not integrated into the appropriations procedures. Congress needs new machinery which ensures that the actions taken on authorizations and outlays for particular programs will add up to a total that achieves an appropriate allocation of resources between Federal programs and the private sector of the economy. This machinery should focus specific attention on the level of taxes required in conjunction with any given total of outlays in order to achieve an appropriate fiscal policy. In making its judgments on these matters, the Congress would presumably begin with the Administration's expenditure and tax recommendations as con- 82 tained in the January Budget. Then, assuming no major disagreement with, or change in, the basic economic outlook, any proposals to change the expenditure total substantially from that recommended in the Budget should be accompanied by a corresponding proposal for adjusting taxes. If such machinery could be satisfactorily introduced, it would help produce a more coordinated Congressional decision on both expenditures and taxes. Procedures for Tax Changes Procedures for a general review of the economy's fiscal needs along lines suggested above should expedite whatever specific action on taxes might be needed for fiscal policy purposes. In most circumstances, normal Congressional procedures for enacting the needed tax legislation would probably be satisfactory—especially if the Congress were to agree in advance on a form of tax adjustment that would be judged appropriate for this purpose. A proportional change in individual and corporate income taxes— like the current surcharge—might be a suitable form of adjustment. However, the experience of the 1960's, including the costly delays in the passage of the 1964 tax cut and the 1968 tax surcharge, suggests the desirability of some other standby arrangement for obtaining prompt adjustments in tax rates to achieve fiscal policy objectives in case of a delay in reaching a decision through normal Congressional procedures. As noted in Chapter 1, the Administration has requested that the Congress consider giving the President discretionary authority, subject to Congressional veto, to remove the current surcharge entirely or partially if warranted by developments. A more permanent arrangement to provide the desirable flexibility could take various forms, including: 1. Presidential discretion to propose temporary changes in personal income tax rates within certain specified limits—such as 5 percent in either direction—subject to veto by the Congress within (say) 30 days. This year's Budget Message contains such a proposal 2. A streamlined Congressional procedure for ensuring a prompt vote on Presidential proposals for changes in tax rates within certain specified limits. This would not shift any of the traditional powers of Congress to the President; the Congress would simply change its own rules. Since changes in tax rates required for fiscal policy objectives would probably take the form of simple modifications of the basic schedule of rates, it would be necessary also to ensure opportunities for a thoroughgoing review of the over-all structure of the revenue system, including the tax base and rates. A structural review of rates would be especially appropriate if rates should drift downward (or upward) consistently for a period of several years as a result of fiscal adjustments. It is important, however, that the issues of tax reform be treated and considered separately from the annual tax decisions related to fiscal policy. 83 ADJUSTING TO NEW DEVELOPMENTS Under the procedures outlined above, it would surely take several months for full legislative response to the President's January Budget. During that period, both the Congress and the Administration would be alert to any major unanticipated developments in the strength of private demand, in Federal defense needs, and in the desired mix of fiscal and monetary policy. Any such developments could and should be reflected in the implementation of the budget program. If the annual budget is carefully formulated and implemented, the need for a significant subsequent revision of the budget program later in the year should be the exception rather than the rule. Stabilization requirements could largely be met by reliance on automatic stabilizers and monetary policy. Much of the success of these stabilization efforts would depend upon the Federal Reserve's flexibility in adjusting monetary policy to circumstances as they unfold. In the development of the annual budget, there should be close consultation and coordination with the monetary authorities. A tentative projection of monetary and credit conditions should be prepared as part of the forecast underlying annual budget decisions. The fiscal program should minimize the risk of putting an excessive share of the burden of economic stabilization on monetary policy, as happened in 1966. But monetary policy should not be bound by the projections made at budget time—if conditions change, it should be adjusted accordingly. Indeed, given a reasonably appropriate fiscal policy, the further adjustments needed to keep the economy reasonably close to potential output should normally be within the capability of the Federal Reserve. It should be recognized, however, that major unforeseen developments may significantly modify the path of demand anticipated in the annual budget. As mentioned earlier, private demand has on occasion exhibited substantial unexpected strength or weakness. A major problem in recent years has stemmed from the uncertain path of increases in defense spending during the Vietnam buildup. While it is to be hoped that such a military buildup will not again be necessary, there can be no assurance in an insecure world that this will be the case. Accordingly, it is essential to be prepared to deal with such contingencies. Moreover, there could be similar and equally challenging problems of gauging the magnitude and timing of a demobilization—when peace is established. A special report to the President discussing the challenges and opportunities that will confront policymakers when peace comes in Vietnam is included in this volume. The path of defense orders and outlays is inherently difficult to predict in a period of military flux. Through intensified efforts of the Department of Defense, considerable progress has nevertheless been made in providing an improved flow of information relating to both the current and prospective economic impact of defense spending. Some of this information is now being made public by the Bureau of the Census in a monthly digest entitled Defense Indicators. Further efforts are needed, together with a full awareness of the importance of accurate information, especially at critical turning points in the trend of defense spending. SOME ISSUES OF MONETARY POLICY The record of the past 8 years demonstrates that flexible, discretionary monetary policy can make an effective contribution to economic stabilization. The economy's gradual return to full productive potential in the early 1960's was partly attributable to a monetary policy which kept ample supplies of credit readily available at generally stable interest rates. And in early 1967, the prompt recovery of homebuilding after the 1966 slowdown was the direct result of timely and aggressive easing of credit conditions by the Federal Reserve. The most dramatic demonstration of the effectiveness of monetary policy came in 1966, however, when a dangerously inflationary situation was curbed primarily by a drastic application of monetary restraint. Credit-financed expenditures at the end of that year appear to have been as much as $8 billion below what they might have been had monetary policy maintained the accommodative posture of the preceding 5 years. And there were substantial further "multiplier" effects on GNP as these initial impacts reduced income and consumption spending. THE CONDUCT OF MONETARY POLICY The primary guides for monetary policy are the various broad measures of economic performance, including the growth rate of total output, the relation of actual to potential ouput, employment and unemployment, the behavior of prices, and the Nation's balance-of-payments position. Extensive research, together with the experience of the last few years, has increased our knowledge of the complex process by which monetary policy influences these measures. While there are still major gaps in our knowledge of the precise chain of causation, some conclusions seem well established. Like fiscal policy, monetary policy affects economic activity only after some lag. Thus actions by the Federal Reserve must be forward-looking. In considering the prospects ahead, however, an assessment must be made of both the expected behavior of the private sector and of the likely future course of fiscal policy. As noted earlier, the inherent flexibility in the administration of monetary policy permits frequent policy adjustments to take account of unexpected developments in either the private or the public sector. Sectoral Impacts Monetary policy can affect spending through a number of channels. To some extent it works by changing the terms of lending, including interest rates, maturities of loans, downpayments, and the like, in such a way as to encourage or discourage expenditures on goods financed by credit. There 85 may also be market imperfections or legal constraints and institutional rigidities that change the "availability" of loans as monetary conditions change— that is, make it easier or more difficult for borrowers to obtain credit at given terms of lending. Under some circumstances, purchasers of goods and services may finance their expenditures by liquidating financial assets, and changes in the yields on these assets produced by a change in monetary policy may affect their willingness to engage in such transactions. Changes in monetary policy may also, on occasion, change the expectations of borrowers, lenders, and spenders in ways that affect economic conditions, although these expectational effects are rather complex and dependent upon the conditions existing at the time policy is changed. Monetary policy affects some types of expenditures more than others. The extent of the impact depends not only on the economic characteristics of the activity being financed but, in many instances, on the channels through which financing is obtained and the legal and institutional arrangements surrounding the financing procedures. Residential Construction. The sector of the economy most affected by monetary policy is residential construction. Although the demand for housing—and for mortgage credit—does not appear to be especially responsive to mortgage interest rates, the supply of mortgage funds is quite sensitive to several interest rate relationships. The experience of 1966 clearly demonstrated how rising interest rates can sharply affect flows of deposits to banks and other thrift institutions and thereby severely limit their ability to make new mortgage loans. In the first half of that year, the net deposit gain at savings and loan associations and mutual savings banks was only half as large as in the preceding 6 months. These institutions could not afford to raise the rates paid on savings capital to compete with the higher rates available to savers at banks and elsewhere because of their earnings situation—with their assets concentrated in mortgages that earned only the relatively low rates of return characteristic of several years earlier. Commercial banks experienced a similarly sharp slowing in growth of time deposits in the second half of the year, as the Federal Reserve's Regulation Q prevented them from competing effectively for liquid funds. This forced banks to make across-the-board cuts in lending operations. In addition, life insurance companies had a large portion of their loanable funds usurped by demands for policy loans, which individuals found attractive because of relatively low cost. High-yielding corporate securities also proved an attractive alternative for some institutional investments that might otherwise have gone into mortgages. Table 9 provides some indication of the extent of these various influences. As can be seen, savings and loan associations and mutual savings banks together supplied less than 10 percent of total funds borrowed in 1966, well below their 22 percent share in the preceding 5 years. This was the main 86 TABLE 9.—Net funds raised by nonfinancial sectors, 1961-68 1961-65 average Nonfinancial sector Total funds raised (billions of dollars) 1966 19681 1967 59.2 69.9 83.1 97.1 84.5 88.7 79.9 80.4 10.8 34.6 39.0 9.7 48.1 30.9 12.6 44.8 22.5 li.7 37.0 31.7 25.5 13.5 18.6 12.3 13.7 8.8 17.1 14.6 10.6 9.0 15.3 16.7 5.1 2.1 4.8 2.9 35.1 43.6 24.7 32.2 43.6 39.0 39.1 29.7 22.1 21.5 9.9 22.3 19.5 19.5 14.0 15.7 10.1 6.8 1.2 16.3 8.9 -2.0 11.2 9.4 3.9 12.9 15.3 -7.5 Percent of total raised by: Private domestic nonfinancial sectors State and local governments Nonfinancial business Households . Mortgages Other __ U.S. Government... _._ Rest of world. Percent of total supplied by: Commercial banks. Nonbank financial institutions _. Savings and loan associations and mutual savings banks Other Federal Reserve and U.S. Government State and local governments Foreign lenders Nonfinancial business Households, less net security credit 2.7 .5 4.6 .5 7.7 -.3 5.1 5.8 i Preliminary. Note.—Detail will not necessarily add to totals because of rounding. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. factor limiting the availability of household mortgage loans. The effect on homebuilding was quick and dramatic, as the seasonally adjusted volume of new housing units started fell by nearly half between December 1965 and October 1966. In 1967, as interest rates in the open market retreated from their 1966 highs, the thrift institutions were able to regain their competitive position in the savings market. A good part of their funds was fairly quickly channeled into the mortgage market. By fall, housing starts had recovered nearly to the level of late 1965. As noted in Chapter 1, many factors—including several significant institutional reforms, sharply improved liquidity positions, and the widespread expectation that monetary restraint was only temporary pending passage of the tax bill—helped to moderate the adverse effects of renewed monetary restraint on mortgage lending in 1968. But the thrift institutions again experienced some slowing of deposit inflows when market interest rates rose to new heights, and mutual savings banks switched a good part of their investments away from the mortgage market to high-yielding corporate bonds. State and Local Governments. State and local governments also felt the effects of monetary restraint in 1966. These governments cut back or postponed more than $2.9 billion, or nearly 25 percent, of their planned bond issues that year. It is difficult to determine precisely what caused these postponements. In 87 cases involving more than half the dollar volume, the reasons given related to the prevailing high level of interest rates. In some instances, the interest costs simply exceeded the legal ceiling governments were permitted to pay for borrowed funds. In other cases, finance officers decided to delay bond issues for a few months in the expectation that interest rates would decline. This sizable cutback in borrowings had a relatively small effect on State and local government expenditures. Larger governments apparently were able to continue most of their projects about as scheduled by drawing down liquid assets or borrowing temporarily at short term. Smaller governmental units, however, cut their contract awards by a total estimated at more than $400 million. Because of the problems State and local governments often face in raising funds, the Administration is proposing the establishment of an Urban Development Bank, which could borrow economically in the open market and then lend in the amounts needed to individual local governments. The Bank could lend at federally subsidized interest rates, with the Federal Government recovering the cost of the subsidy through taxation of the interest income earned by holders of the Bank's securities. Business and Consumer Spending. The 1966 credit squeeze undoubtedly also had some effects on business and consumer spending, though the amount of impact is not easily determinable. Most theoretical and empirical studies find that business firms in some way balance the cost of borrowed capital against the expected returns from their capital projects. Some small firms may also simply not be able to obtain funds during tight money periods. In 1966, bank lending to business did slow sharply during the second half of the year. Many of the larger firms shifted their demands to the open market—and paid record high interest rates for their funds—but some of the smaller ones probably were forced to postpone their projects. Household spending on durable goods—particularly automobiles—has been shown to be affected by changes in the cost and availability of consumer credit, as reflected in the interest rate, maturity, downpayment, and other terms. While it is difficult to sort out cause and effect, households borrowed only two-thirds as much through consumer credit in the second half of 1966 as in the preceding half year. Capital gains or losses on asset holdings accompanying changes in yields may also induce consumers to spend more or less on goods and services. Active and Passive Elements Monetary policy, like fiscal policy, has what might be termed active and passive components. Recognition of this distinction played an important role in formulating the accommodative policy of the early 1960's. In the 1950's, economic expansion had generally been accompanied by rising interest rates, which tended to produce an automatic stabilizing effect somewhat similar to the fiscal drag of the Federal tax system discussed earlier. The large amounts of underutilized resources available in the early 1960's made such restraint inappropriate, and credit was expanded sufficiently to prevent it from occurring. It is especially important to distinguish between these elements in monetary policy at cyclical turning points. If, for example, private demand weakens and causes a decline in economic activity, interest rates will generally fall as credit demands slacken, even without any positive action by the Federal Reserve to push rates down. This induced fall in interest rates can help to check the decline in economic activity but may not, by itself, induce recovery. Similarly, as the economy rises above potential, the induced rise in interest rates may only moderate the expansion but may not bring activity back into line with capacity. An active monetary policy during such periods requires positive effort by the Federal Reserve to produce further changes in interest rates and in availability of credit beyond those that would occur automatically. Since expectational responses may either accentuate or moderate the effects of the initial action, it is sometimes difficult to know in advance precisely how much of a policy change is needed. But the main point is clear—at such turning points, interest rate movements alone are not likely to provide an accurate reflection of the contribution of monetary policy to economic stabilization. Careful attention must also be paid to credit flows, particularly those to the private sector of the economy. MONETARY POLICY AND THE MONEY SUPPLY Examination of the linkages between monetary policy and various categories of expenditures suggests that, in the formulation of monetary policy, careful attention should be paid to interest rates and credit availability as influenced by and associated with the flows of deposits and credit to different types of financial institutions and spending units. Among the financial flows generally considered to be relevant are: the total of funds raised by nonfinancial sectors of the economy^ the credit supplied by commercial banks, the net amount of new mortgage credit, the net change in the public's holdings of liquid assets, changes in time deposits at banks and other thrift institutions, and changes in the money supply. Some consideration should be given to all of these financial flows as well as to related interest rates in formulating any comprehensive policy program or analysis of financial conditions. Much public attention has recently been focused on an alternative view, however, emphasizing the money supply as the most important— sometimes the only—link between monetary policy and economic activity. This emphasis has often been accompanied by the suggestion that the Federal Reserve can best contribute to economic stabilization by maintaining growth in the stock of money at a particular rate—or somewhat less rigidly, 89 by keeping variations in the rate of growth of the money stock within a fairly narrow band. There are, of course, numerous variants of the money view of monetary policy. The discussion below focuses only on the simple version that has captured most of the public attention. Money and Interest Rates In a purely theoretical world, abstracting from institutional rigidities that exist in our financial system and assuming that relationships among financial variables were unvarying and predictable, it would make little difference whether monetary policy was formulated in terms of interest rates or the money supply. The two variables are inversely related, and the alternative approaches would represent nothing more than different paths to precisely the same result. The monetary authorities could seek to control the money stock, with interest rates allowed to take on whatever values happen to result. Or alternatively, they could focus on achieving the interest rates that would facilitate the credit flows needed to finance the desired level of activity, allowing the quantity of money to be whatever it had to be. But financial rigidities do exist that often distort flows of credit in response to swings in interest rates. And financial relationships have changed steadily and significantly. Just since 1961, several important new financial instruments have been introduced and developed, including negotiable time certificates of deposit and Euro-dollar deposits. Attitudes of both investors and lenders have also undergone marked shifts, with sharp variations in the public's demand for liquidity superimposed on an underlying trend toward greater sensitivity to interest rates. There is, to be sure, enough of a link between money and interest rates at any given time to make it impossible for the Federal Reserve to regulate the two independently. But this linkage is hardly simple, and it varies considerably and unpredictably over time. The choice between controlling the stock of money solely and focusing interest rates, credit availability, and a number of credit flows can therefore make a difference. This choice should be based on a judgment—supported insofar as possible by empirical and analytical evidence—as to whether it is money holdings alone that influence the decisions of various categories of spending units. Money and Asset Portfolios The Federal Reserve conducts monetary policy primarily by expanding and contracting the supply of cash reserves available to the banking system. Such actions seek to induce an expansion or contraction in loans and investments at financial institutions, with corresponding changes in the public's holdings of currency and deposits of various kinds. The proportions in which the public chooses to hold alternative 9O types of financial assets depend upon a complex set of preferences, which, in turn, depend upon interest rate relationships. The process of expansion and contraction of money and credit stemming from Federal Reserve actions is fairly complex. But one aspect of it should be clearly understood: The money so created is not something given to the public for nothing as if it fell from heaven—that is, it is not a net addition to the public's wealth or net worth. There can be an immediate change in public wealth, but only to the extent that changes in interest rates generate capital gains or losses on existing assets. Any change in the money stock is associated with a change in the composition of the public's balance sheet, as people and institutions are induced to exchange—at a price—one asset for another or to increase (or decrease) both their assets and their liabilities by equal amounts. Since all the items in the public's balance sheet might be changed as a result of these compositional shifts, the change in the public's liquidity is not likely to be summarized adequately in terms of any single category of financial assets. It is, of course, possible that decisions to spend on goods and services are affected more by the presence of one type of financial asset than another in a spending unit's portfolio. But there is only scattered evidence of such behavior in various sectoral studies that have been undertaken to analyze the factors affecting the spending decisions of consumers, businesses, or State and local governments. Indeed, to the extent these studies do find spending decisions systematically affected by financial variables, it is often through changes in interest rates and availability of credit. Money and Income and a Monetary Rule One problem with the money supply as a guide to monetary policy is that there is no agreement concerning the appropriate definition of "money." One definition includes the total of currency outside commercial banks plus privately held demand deposits. A second also includes time deposits at commercial banks, and even more inclusive alternatives are sometimes used. On the other hand, there is a more limited definition, sometimes called "highpowered money" or "monetary base," which includes currency in circulation and member-bank reserve balances at the Federal Reserve banks. These different concepts of money do not always move in parallel with one another—even over fairly extended periods. Thus assertions that the money supply is expanding rapidly or slowly often depend critically on which definition is employed. In the first half of 1968, for example, there was a sharp acceleration in the growth of currency plus demand deposits, but growth of this total plus time deposits slowed considerably. On the other hand, relationships between movements in GNP and any of the money concepts have been close enough on the average—especially when processed through complex lags and other sophisticated statistical techniques—to be difficult to pass off lightly. 91 There is, of course, good reason to expect some fairly close relationship between money and income. This would be true even in a completely abstract situation in which it was assumed that the money supply per se had no direct influence on GNP, and that monetary policy worked entirely through interest rates. Since interest rates and the money supply are inversely related, any rise in GNP produced by a reduction in interest rates and increased credit availability would be accompanied by at least some increase in the money supply. The relationship also exists in a sort of "reverse causation" form—that is, as income goes up so does the demand for money, which the Federal Reserve then accommodates by allowing an increase in the actual money stock. This is precisely what happened during the 1961-65 period of accommodative policy, and it is always present to some extent as the Federal Reserve acts to meet the economy's changing credit needs. The problem of sorting out the extent of causation in the two directions still challenges economic researchers. A one-sided interpretation of these relationships is sometimes used to support the suggestion that the Federal Reserve conduct policy on the basis of some fixed, predetermined guideline for growth of the money supply (however defined). Given the complex role of interest rates in affecting various demand categories and the likely variations in so many other factors, any such simple policy guide could prove to be quite unreliable. The experience of the past several years illustrates the kinds of difficulties that might be encountered in using the money supply (defined here as currency plus demand deposits) as the exclusive guide for monetary policy. As described previously, high interest rates in 1966 began affecting the nonbank thrift institutions, the mortgage market, and the homebuilding industry soon after the start of the year. But during the first 4 months of that year, the money supply grew at an annual rate of nearly 6/ 2 percent, well above the long-term trend. Later that year, the financial situation of major mortgage lenders improved somewhat and housing eventually rebounded despite the fact that growth of money supply plus bank time deposits was proceeding at only a snail's pace. Growth of the money supply in the second quarter of 1968 was at an annual rate of 9 percent. The reasons for this acceleration—to a rate almost double the growth in the preceding quarter—are not fully apparent. The Federal Reserve could have resisted this sizable increase in the demand for money more than it did, but interest rates in the open market would then have risen well above the peaks that were in fact reached in May. Whether still higher rates would have been desirable is another issue, which cannot be settled merely by citing the rapid growth of the money supply. These illustrations suggest that any simple rigid rule related to the growth of the money supply (however defined) can unduly confine Federal Reserve policy. In formulating monetary policy, the Federal Reserve must be able to take account of all types of financial relationships currently prevailing and in prospect and be able to respond flexibly as changing 92 economic needs arise. In deciding on such responses, especially careful consideration must be given to likely changes in interest rates and credit availability, in view of the effects of these factors on particular sectors of the economy—especially the homebuilding industry. LOOKING AHEAD In the future as in the past 8 years, the maintenance of full prosperity deserves high priority among the Nation's goals because it contributes so much to so many of our other national objectives. Job opportunities provide the stepping stones out of poverty for many of the disadvantaged. As Chapter 5 makes clear, efforts to train the disadvantaged can hardly succeed in a sluggish economy. For those who have already obtained some minimum standard of living, prosperity offers a ladder to higher standards of comfort, civilization, and security. For those high on the income scale, prosperity provides the incentives and the funds for the growth of capital to strengthen our productive performance in the future. For the public sector, prosperity offers the revenues that can help to repair the accumulated decay of our cities, purify the environment, and improve education and transportation systems. Between 1968 and 1975, our civilian labor force will increase by 10J4 million persons, or an average of ll/2 million a year. If the new entrants are employed and productivity continues to grow at the recent trend rate, GNP will amount to about $1,150 billion (in 1968 prices) in 1975. The experience of the past 8 years should be of considerable benefit in the formulation of economic policies to ensure continued movement along the potential output path to reach this level of GNP in 1975. Economic policymakers can reasonably hope to maintain sustained growth in line with potential and to avoid the bumps of the business cycle and the unconscionable waste of a slack economy. A dynamic society should not, however, be satisfied merely with continuing along the present path of potential. Faster growth can be achieved if ways can be found to accelerate the growth of national productivity. Policies that aim at stimulating capital formation, education, and technological advance can play an important role. Additional gains in output and standards of living for all our citizens can be realized if ways can be found to achieve lower levels of unemployment and reasonably stable prices simultaneously. Chapter 3 discusses a number of measures that can help to make high employment and price stability more compatible. 93 323-166 < Chapter 3 Price Stability in a High Employment Economy T HE REMARKABLE ACHIEVEMENT of prosperity as the normal state of the American economy has been recorded in Chapter 2. Recent price performance has been far less satisfactory. Since 1965, prices have been rising too rapidly. The history of both the United States and other industrial nations shows that high employment is generally accompanied by inflationary tendencies, and that when prices are reasonably stable, this is at the cost of too many idle men and idle machines. The record of the past poses the critical challenge of the years ahead. Reconciling prosperity at high employment with price stability is the Nation's most important unsolved problem of over-all economic performance. Though the United States has done better than most industrial countries, its record is far from adequate. That record can and should be improved by measures discussed in this chapter. PRICES, WAGES, AND EMPLOYMENT The difficulties of combining price stability and high employment in the past 15 years are evident in Chart 8. It reveals a fairly close association of more rapid price increases with lower rates of unemployment. In 1956-57 and from 1966 to 1968, when the unemployment rate was between 3.6 and 4.3 percent, price increases ranged between 3.1 and 4.1 percent. In contrast, between 1958 and 1964 the unemployment rate consistently exceeded 5 percent, and price increases were uniformly less than 2 percent. The historical relationship has been neither mechanical nor precise. In some periods, the over-all price level has been affected by special and erratic factors such as crop failures, shifts in foreign demand, or bottlenecks arising from a spurt of demand in one sector of the economy. Moreover the price performance of any year is influenced by cost developments arising from conditions in prior years. Still, upward pressures on prices and wages are likely to be intensified when the economy is operating at high utilization of manpower and capital. In a slack economy, rising prices are rarely a problem. Even when demand begins to expand strongly, additional output is readily provided by increases in employment and fuller use of industrial capacity. If the expansion persists 94 Chart 8 Price Performance and Unemployment 1 1 I • 1956 4 • 1968 X # 1966 u s I 3h • 1957 - o • 1955 y 9 - • 1958 1964 a: ^ • 1965 • 1960 O • 1959 • 1963 i # - 3 1 4 1 5 • 1961 1962 6 1 7 UNEMPLOYMENT RATE-PERCENTl/ J/CHANGE DURING YEAR, CALCULATED FROM END OF YEAR DEFLATORS (DERIVED BY AVERAGING FOURTH QUARTER OF A GIVEN YEAR AND FIRST QUARTER OF SUBSEQUENT YEAR). 2/AVERAGE FOR THE YEAR. SOURCES: DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE, DEPARTMENT OF LABOR, AND COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS. at a rate exceeding the growth of the economy's productive capacity, however, demand will begin to press upon available capacity in some industries. As a result, increases in prices will become more frequent, there will be fewer offsetting decreases elsewhere, and living costs will begin to rise. Shortages of workers with particular skills or in certain localities may develop, and wages will accelerate for these groups. Because the balance of demand and supply differs among industries, these tendencies may emerge even while over-all unemployment and unused capacity are substantial. If demand continues to grow strongly, more industries and labor markets are strained and inflationary pressures become more pervasive. As unemployment declines, wages accelerate, since employers prefer to raise wages rather than jeopardize sales and profits through either strikes or inability to attract enough labor. The threat of losing markets through price 95 increases exercises much less discipline on the pricing policies of a firm when it (and its competitors) are operating close to capacity. Thus prices are readily marked up, both to reflect increased costs of labor and materials and to provide for higher profit margins. With living costs rising, wage increases are stepped up in most industries and generally exceed the economy-wide growth of productivity. Thus unit labor costs rise and in turn tend to be translated into higher prices. In this way, a buoyant economy can move from price stability into a rising spiral of wage and price adjustments. And once such a spiral starts, it becomes increasingly difficult to arrest, even after productive capacity has caught up with demand and the initial pressures have largely subsided. THE RECORD IN THE SIXTIES This sequence of events is illustrated by the performance of the U.S. economy in the 1960's. Price Stability: 1961-65 Between the first quarters of 1961 and 1965, rapid economic expansion took up much of the slack in the use of resources. The unemployment rate dropped from 6.8 percent to 4.8 percent (seasonally adjusted) during this 4-year period, and capacity utilization in manufacturing increased sharply. Yet the price and wage record was excellent. Average hourly compensation in the private nonfarm economy rose an average of 4.0 percent annually, but productivity increased at a rate of 3.9 percent, so that unit labor costs remained virtually unchanged. The average level of wholesale prices in January 1965 was the same as 4 years earlier. Consumer prices advanced at a moderate annual rate of 1.2 percent, largely reflecting gradual cost increases in distribution and services where productivity gains come slowly. The Price-Wage Upturn: 1965-68 The first significant break in relative price stability occurred early in 1965. Farm and food prices began a sharp upward climb, spurred by special and erratic factors affecting supply at home and abroad. More pervasive inflationary pressures started in the second half of 1965 when the military buildup in Vietnam began. The rise in prices of consumer services accelerated as firms found it increasingly difficult to recruit and keep workers in the traditionally lower paying service jobs. With consumer prices rising more rapidly and with stronger demand for labor, upward pressures on wages mounted. These developments show up clearly in the price and wage record. Between the second quarters of 1965 and 1966, consumer prices rose 2.7 percent. During the same period, average hourly compensation in the private 96 nonfarm economy jumped 6 percent, well above the growth of productivity; as a result, unit labor costs rose nearly 3 percent. Wage and price developments were influenced by the high level of utilization of the economy. In January 1966, unemployment fell below 4 percent of the labor force for the first time in nearly a decade, and the utilization of manufacturing capacity reached the highest rate since 1955. But price pressures were also intensified by the unusually rapid speed of the advance, as reflected in an annual rate of growth in the real gross national product (GNP) of more than 8 percent between the second quarter of 1965 and the first quarter of 1966. Had the economy approached the neighborhood of 4 percent unemployment more gradually, there would have been more time to train and upgrade labor and to introduce newer and more efficient equipment. When the rate of expansion slowed down late in 1966 and early in 1967, so did the upward movement of prices. Between August 1966 and April 1967, consumer prices continued to advance; but the annual rate of increase moderated to 2 percent, while average wholesale prices actually declined. An increase in supplies of farm products and other raw materials was especially helpful. As new facilities were completed, the pressures on manufacturing capacity decreased sharply, and price increases slowed down for a number of manufactured products. Nevertheless, higher costs had been built into the economy during 1965 and 1966, and when the economy picked up speed in the second half of 1967, prices and wages again accelerated. Union settlements, which had lagged in the initial stage of the advance, rose especially sharply in late 1967 and in 1968. As discussed in Chapter 1, the problems of rising prices and wages remain intense as 1969 begins. THE TASK FOR POLICY Because of the general relationship between prices and unemployment, decisions of fiscal and monetary policy present a serious dilemma. Achieving price stability by accepting high unemployment involves dreadful waste and tremendous social and human costs. But historically, unemployment rates of 4 percent or below have been associated with a price performance that most Americans consider unsatisfactory. As explained in Chapter 2, price increases at the rate recently experienced clearly impair our international trade performance, cause a haphazard redistribution of income and wealth, and may jeopardize sustained prosperity. The first line of defense against inflation must be fiscal and monetary policies that avoid excessive pressures of demand on productive capacity. By heading off sudden surges in demand and by promoting steady and smooth growth, these policies can also contribute to improved price performance at high employment. But fiscal and monetary policies alone cannot ensure the simultaneous achievement of low rates of unemployment and reasonable 97 price stability. The relationship between inflation and unemployment depends upon the workings of the Nation's institutions and markets. There is need for a wide ranging attack on inflation that will bring about pervasive improvements in the economy's price performance. To this end, the President established the Cabinet Committee on Price Stability early in 1968. The Committee has studied many aspects of the problem and has submitted its report, which covers many of the issues discussed below. IMPROVING LABOR AND PRODUCT MARKETS Our labor and product markets are among the most efficient and flexible in the world. Yet their further improvement is the key to making higher levels of employment consistent with price stability. These markets must be even more responsive to changing patterns of demand, and they must continuously increase the productivity of our resources. Measures to improve these markets are of two general but related kinds: those that facilitate the most productive use of our manpower resources, and those that improve the efficiency of our product markets. The efficiency of labor markets is reflected in the matching of job opportunities and available manpower. The fit is never perfect: while in some areas and for some skills "help wanted" signs prevail, there are simultaneously many unemployed persons whose skills or locations do not fit the needs of employers. Continued job vacancies tend to pull wages up and thereby attract labor. In areas of excess supply, however, wages are rarely subject to strong downward pressures. Thus unmanned jobs and jobless men do not offset each other in influencing average wages. The better the labor markets operate, the higher the level of employment and the lower the volume of job vacancies that can accompany any degree of upward pressure on average wages. There are a number of ways that a better and more flexible fit of available manpower and job opportunities can be achieved. Workers can move more easily between occupations and geographical locations if they are given improved information about job opportunities and if they are not confronted with barriers to entry into certain occupations. They can be aided by training programs which are more closely oriented toward skills that are in short supply. And the productivity of employed labor can be improved by the removal of restrictive work practices. Measures of these kinds can both alter the level of employment consistent with reasonable price stability and add significantly to the real output produced at a given level of employment. Product markets can also be made more efficient. The major thrust must be the strengthening of competition. Vigorous enforcement of antitrust policy is essential. Opportunities can be found to remove or reduce existing re- 98 straints on competition. Better information for the consumer can also strengthen competition. The continued pursuit of freer international trade can enhance the effectiveness of competition. Standards and policies in regulated industries, in agricultural programs, and in Government procurement should be kept under constant review, with price stability recognized as one of the goals of policy. The major measures discussed below should be viewed as elements of a comprehensive program to improve price-cost behavior. Other areas and other possible policy actions could be added to the list. The effects of the measures vary considerably in potential magnitude, and no single one can ensure a significant advance by itself. Yet if progress can be achieved on most of these fronts, the inflationary tendencies that accompany low unemployment should be reduced. Most of these measures may be expected to yield substantial gains in other directions. Some would increase employment opportunities for the disadvantaged. Others would enhance productivity and growth over the long run. It must also be recognized that many of these measures involve some social and financial costs that have to be assessed against the potential benefits. In fact, some of the present problems result from past public or private policies designed to promote such objectives as job security, public safety or health, and the protection of small businesses. Frequently these policies were aimed at conditions which prevailed years ago; they require reexamination in today's high employment economy. Structural improvements in our product and labor markets usually take time to institute and require time to show measurable effects. Most of the strategies cannot be counted upon to assist significantly in the immediate task of moving toward price stability in 1969. But early efforts are needed to make timely progress toward the long-run objective of combining high employment with reasonable price stability. IMPROVING LABOR MOBILITY Over the long term, there have been dramatic shifts in the pattern of demand for labor—from agriculture to manufacturing, from the production of goods to the supply of services, and from less to more highly skilled occupations. Agricultural workers represent only 5.0 percent of the civilian labor force as compared with 13.1 percent 20 years ago. The number of white collar workers has risen from one-third to nearly one-half of total employment since World War II, with an especially rapid rise in the number of professionals. The industry shifts in the past 7 years are shown in Table 10. The needed adjustments to both short- and long-run changes in the demand for labor have been largely accomplished by the normal operation of the market. Increases in earnings have been particularly large in those occupations for which demand has been rising rapidly. For example, increased 99 TABLE 10.—Changes in employment, 1961 to 1968 Millions of persons Percentage change per year, Industry group 1961 Total employment 1961 to 196812 1968 i Percentage distribution 2 19681 1961 Nonagriculture Nonagricultural payroll employment State and local government Services Retail trade Finance, insurance, and real estate Wholesale trade Manufacturing Production workers Nonproduction workers _. Federal Government Contract construction Transportation and public utilities.. Mining 65.7 75.9 2.1 100.0 100.0 5.2 60.5 ._ Agriculture 3.8 72.1 -4.3 2.5 7.9 92.1 5.0 95.0 54.0 68.1 3.4 100.0 100.0 6.3 7.7 8.3 2.7 3.0 16.3 9.5 10.5 10.4 3.4 3.7 19.7 5.9 4.6 3.3 3.0 2.9 2.7 11.7 14.2 15.4 5.1 5.5 30.2 13.9 15.4 15.3 4.9 5.4 29.0 12.1 4.2 14.5 5.3 2.6 3.1 22.4 7.9 21.3 7.7 2.3 2.8 3.9 .7 2.7 3.3 4.3 .6 2.6 2.1 1.5 -1.0 4.2 5.2 7.2 1.2 4.0 4.8 6.4 .9 1 Preliminary. 2 Based on employment in thousands. Note.—Detail will not necessarily add to totals because of rounding. Source: Department of Labor. needs for workers in retail trade and service occupations have been reflected in wage gains larger than those in manufacturing (Table 11). Similarly, earnings in many professions have advanced rapidly. Although the labor force is highly mobile and able to adjust readily to substantial shifts in demand, there are still many costly barriers that workers must cross when moving among jobs and occupations. One remedy is to lower the barriers, allowing workers freer access to jobs. Another is to bring work to areas of high unemployment. The benefits and limitations of making jobs available to those living where few opportunities now exist are explored in Chapter 5. TABLE 11.—Changes in hourly earnings of production and nonsupervisory workers on private nonagricultural payrolls, 1961 to 1968 Average hourly earnings . Industry group Total private nonagricultural payrolls2 $2.14 1 Preliminary. Total includes certain industry groups not shown separately. Source: Department of Labor. 2 IOO $2.85 4.2 1.56 3.20 2.09 2.31 2.32 2.64 Retail trade Contract construction Finance, insurance, and real estate Wholesale trade Manufacturing Mining 1961 to 19681 19681 1961 Percentage change per year, 2.16 4.38 2.75 3.05 3.01 3.34 4.8 4.6 4.0 4.0 3.8 3.4 Information on Job Opportunities Rapid adaptation of the labor force to changing demands can be aided by timely information regarding job opportunities. The disadvantaged in particular are likely to lack such information. Recognizing this handicap, the Federal-State Employment Services in 1965 began seeking out disadvantaged workers for enrollment in training programs, for job referral, and for work counseling. The importance of improved job information was also recognized in the 1968 Amendments to the Manpower Development and Training Act (MDTA). This legislation authorized the development of a comprehensive system of labor market information, using electronic data processing and telecommunication systems for direct contact among recruitment, job training, and placement agencies. Relocation Assistance The cost of moving can make it difficult for low-income workers to respond to job opportunities. The 1965 Amendments to the MDTA authorized an experimental program of relocation assistance to test the value of helping disadvantaged workers in depressed areas move to places of better employment opportunity. Thus far, 13,000 workers and their families have received assistance under the program. The experience from this pilot program suggests that the benefits far outweigh the $750 average cost of relocation. Vesting and Portability of Pension Rights By 1980, private retirement plans will cover some 40 million workers— about three-fifths of all private nonfarm employees. Nonvested plans, in which the worker loses his pension rights if his employment terminates, not only operate inequitably against many long-service employees but also discourage mobility. Vesting would enable the worker to retain his financial stake in his pension when he changes employers. To encourage more vesting, the Department of Labor has proposed a Pension Benefit Security Act. It would require full vesting after 10 years of service, to become fully effective 12 years after passage. At present, only about 20 percent of all workers are in retirement plans which fulfill this requirement. Another way to overcome the restrictive effect of pension plans on mobility would be to increase the ability of employees to transfer pension credits among employers in a particular industry. This type of portability, largely found in multi-employer collective bargaining contracts, enhances mobility within industries but not across industry boundaries. In construction, multiemployer pension plans are common but generally limited to a particular city IOI or metropolitan area. Greater reciprocity among these plans would enhance mobility in this important sector. Licensing State licensing provisions affecting some skilled trades and many professions restrict mobility to the extent that there is not full reciprocity among States. Electricians, plumbers, barbers, and beauticians are examples of the licensed tradesmen; physicians, dentists, lawyers, accountants, and teachers are examples of the professionals. In some cases, notably physicians, there is relatively full reciprocity. But in others, those who have licenses in one State are required to pass new examinations or to meet different special qualifications if they want to move to other States. In principle, these requirements are imposed to protect public health or safety, or the quality of service. Yet they may serve to restrict competition, particularly in localities or States where pay scales are relatively high. Mobility could be enhanced by universal reciprocity at generally acceptable standards. Discrimination in Employment One of the most widespread barriers to the full use of our labor force is discrimination against women and members of minority groups. Great progress has been made in reducing these and other categoric barriers to employment; Federal legislation now outlaws discrimination on the basis of race, religion, national origin, sex, or age. While the policy is now clear, a very large job of enforcement remains. In addition, arbitrary barriers to employment may still be imposed by employers who maintain unnecessarily restrictive hiring standards as described in Chapter 5. Some unions also impose unreasonable restrictions on membership. Minimum Wages Minimum wage laws protect the worker against the imperfections of the labor market which lead to substandard wages. Such laws may also encourage the more efficient use of labor. Although increases in the minimum wage are likely to be reflected in higher prices, society should be willing to pay the cost if this is the best way to help low-wage workers. Yet excessively rapid and general increases in the minimum can hurt these workers by curtailing their employment opportunities. Since 1956, the Federal minimum has gone up about in line wTith average hourly compensation, while coverage has progressively expanded to cover low-wage industries. In considering the future rate of increase for minimum wages, careful scrutiny should be made of the possibility of adverse employ- 102 ment effects. The benefits of higher minimums should be weighed against alternative ways of helping low-wage workers. EFFICIENT USE OF MANPOWER Responding to the expanding employment opportunities of our economy, American workers generally have accepted—and even welcomed—technological change. But there are exceptions; unions have secured management acceptance of restrictive work rules in such industries as railroads, printing, longshoring, and construction. These rules reflect a legitimate concern for job security. But where technological change does adversely affect job security, it would be preferable to avoid restrictive practices and develop solutions specifically to meet that problem. Workers can be largely compensated for the loss of particular positions and of seniority protection through such provisions as severance pay, attrition plans, and the option of early retirement for older workers. The trend of collective bargaining agreements is in this direction, but the exceptions are still costly to the economy. Legal Restrictions Legal restrictions designed to protect health and safety may, in some cases, impose unnecessary barriers to the efficient use of labor. For example, local building codes sometimes prevent the use of construction labor as efficiently as technology allows, according to a report of the National Commission on Urban Problems. The Commission also found that an unnecessary diversity among codes inhibits large-scale operations by contractors and manufacturers. It recommended that private and public bodies develop standards that could be accepted and applied throughout the Nation. Another example is railroad full-crew laws affecting freight and road service in seven States. These laws reflect an approach that dates back to the era of the steam engine. Despite dieselization and modern improvements in communication, the laws remain. Seasonality Instability of work leads to inefficient use of manpower, throwing persons able and willing to work into unemployment. Seasonal variations are a major source of such waste, particularly in construction. More than one-fourth of all wage and salaried workers in contract construction experience some unemployment during the year. This is about double the proportion in manufacturing and other nonagricultural industries. Besides the waste of valuable manpower, seasonality leads to labor shortages during peaks of activity in particular occupations and geographical areas. A number of studies have indicated that, for most types of construction, the added costs of winter work are small and might be offset by just the savings in unemployment compensation for construction workers. More 103 stable employment might also moderate the sharp upward trend in hourly wages for construction workers, at the same time improving their annual incomes. In light of these considerations, the President recently instructed Government agencies to explore the possibility of scheduling more construction in winter months. Progress in this direction by the Federal Government could serve as an example to State and local governments and to private industry. MANPOWER TRAINING PROGRAMS Training programs must be oriented toward two main objectives. The first, and probably most important in both its economic and social implications, is to assist the disadvantaged and the unemployed to acquire new skills. Such efforts present special and highly important problems, which are discussed in Chapter 5 in the context of the problem of poverty. The second objective is to help increase the supply of skilled workers and professionals to keep up with rapidly rising demand. Skilled Workers Federal and federally assisted training programs can make an important contribution to meet the rising demand for skilled workers in periods of high employment. The Vocational Education Act of 1963 authorized a large expansion of vocational training programs. Post-secondary day school vocational enrollments increased from 171,000 in 1964 to 501,000 in 1967, and enrollments of adults in part-time programs rose from 2.3 to 2.9 million. The total number of persons in trade and industrial programs rose from 1.1 to 1.4 million between 1964 and 1967. Establishing and operating flexible, expanding training programs pose some difficult problems. Ideally, the pattern of training should be related to forecasts of changing demand for workers in different occupations, thus meshing the training with emerging needs. In practice, this is not easy to accomplish. There is also danger that vocational programs, once established, may continue unchanged despite radical shifts in the demand for skills. For example, high school enrollments in vocational agriculture remained almost constant from 1964 to 1967, despite the sharp and persistent drop in agricultural work opportunities and the movement of many rural youths to other jobs. The scope of vocational education should be broadened to meet the future manpower needs of the economy. The 5 percent of total enrollees in vocational classes preparing for health and technical occupations is much too small. More training should be provided in new occupations such as automatic data processing and electronics. In addition, skilled workers will be needed in such traditional trades as construction. There is every indication that the demand for construction in the 1970's will be of unprecedented magnitude. Success in meeting the 104 national target for housing recently adopted by the Congress will depend upon the availability of enough skilled workers. Professions The demand for professionals has increased sharply. Although their number has grown at an annual rate of 4.2 percent in 1961-68, as compared with only a 2.6 percent increase in the number of production workers in manufacturing, supply has not kept pace with demand. As a result, earnings in many professions have risen at a substantially higher rate than those of manufacturing production workers. The rise in demand for professional and technical personnel reflects numerous factors. In health care, the general rise in affluence has contributed significantly, along with Medicare, Medicaid, and the rapid increase in the elderly population. Total spending on health care rose from $26 billion in fiscal 1960 to $53 billion in fiscal 1968. The great technological advances of the past decade have vastly increased the demand for such professionals as physicists, chemists, mathematicians, and engineers. Expenditures for research and development have grown rapidly. Between fiscal 1961 and 1966, the dominant factor in the expansion was Government spending for research and development, which rose at the rate of 11.5 percent a year, before slowing markedly in 1966-68. For the National Aeronautics and Space Administration program alone, the number of scientists and engineers directly involved increased from less than 11,000 in 1960 to a peak of nearly 92,000 in mid-1966. Private spending on research and development also increased at a rapid rate, growing at 8.8 percent annually between 1961 and 1967. Newly instituted Federal programs have helped to meet the expanding demand for professional personnel. The Education Professions Development Act of 1967 gave the Office of Education authority to assist in the training of school personnel at all levels and in various occupations. Under the Health Professions Educational Assistance Amendments of 1965, about 13,500 scholarships have been awarded in medicine, dentistry, and pharmacy. A variety of fellowship, training, and grant programs is providing assistance to more than 43,000 students in 1968-69, as compared with 10,500 in 1962-63. Despite these advances, the present programs are not adequate to meet the growing needs for trained professionals. Adjusting Job Requirements In light of the high and growing demand for fully qualified professional personnel, the more routine or subprofessional tasks should be performed by such paraprofessionals as teacher's aides, nurse's aides, dental technicians, and engineering technicians. 105 The New Careers Program, administered by the Department of Labor, is helping to prepare disadvantaged adults for jobs in public and private nonprofit agencies in the fields of health, education, welfare, neighborhood redevelopment, and public service. As of mid-1968, about 5,000 persons were enrolled under this program. Cooperating institutions have agreed to revise job requirements and to develop new career opportunities for subprofessional workers. Future Directions for Manpower Policy Training programs under the MDTA have the potential for making a great contribution to price stability and high employment. Accomplishments thus far have been limited, mainly because the programs have been small relative to need. Only an average of 173,000 persons yearly have been enrolled from 1963 to 1968. In 1968, 272,000 were enrolled, equal to three-tenths of 1 percent of the Nation's labor force. Moreover, only 18 percent of the total were trained in critical skills. The creation of a new system of adult job training proved complex. Difficulties were inherent and experimentation necessary. But after 5 years of experience, it is evident that MDTA training and assistance can help the economy make more efficient use of manpower. The Federal Government has greatly increased its support of college students and institutions of higher education. The total funds available in both grants and loans rose from an estimated $1.5 billion in 1962 to $4.4 billion in 1968. Federal funds for student loans increased from an estimated $75 million in 1962 to $251 million in 1968. Nevertheless, there remains a need for additional support. When properly designed, loans are a particularly suitable form of aid for college students, although many youths from low-income families may require special assistance through direct grants. Federal aid can also be useful in underwriting the costs of expanding the capacity of professional schools where training facilities are most critically short, as in medical education. And better planning of Government programs can lessen the pressure on the limited pool of professional manpower. The Federal Government directly and indirectly pays the salaries of 10 to 15 percent of all professionals. Because the supply of professionals cannot be expanded quickly, adding significantly to demand can affect salaries throughout the economy for many years. COMPETITION AND ANTITRUST POLICY The prevalence of strong competitive forces in most markets of the U.S. economy reflects its vast size, the ability and willingness of businessmen to respond to new opportunities, and a long-standing commitment of public policy to promote competition—most importantly exemplified in the antitrust laws. 106 Antitrust Laws and Prices While antitrust action is an effective weapon against collusive price agreements, violations still occur and continuous vigilance is necessary. For example, since 1965, there have been price-fixing convictions in such diverse industries as plumbing fixtures, steel, and pharmaceuticals. Antitrust also has a major role to play in reducing concentration. In highly concentrated industries—those in which a few firms control a large proportion of sales—price competition is likely to be less intense than it is elsewhere in the economy. Numerous studies have shown a significant relationship between high concentration and high profit rates—an indication of weak competitive pressures. Moreover, the high profits sometimes earned by firms in the less competitive industries are understandably a tempting target for large wage demands, which sometimes spread to other industries. Furthermore, concentrated industries often maintain prices in the face of declining demand, reducing output instead. As demand fluctuates among products over time, prices may rise where demand increases, but fail to decline where demand decreases. This results in an inflationary bias, which might be substantially reduced by greater competition. Vigorous antitrust enforcement helps to hold down prices by breaking up price conspiracies and reducing concentration. A continuing program of antitrust actions can increase competition and contribute to improved over-all price performance at high employment. Mergers and Concentration The present levels of concentration in many industries are in large part the result of peaks of merger activity at the turn of the century and during the 1920's. Although the number of mergers in recent years has reached gargantuan proportions—1,496 major mergers of manufacturing and mining concerns in 1967 as compared to 219 in 1950—most of them involved firms in different industries rather than in the same industry. In part, this reflects the Celler-Kefauver amendment to the Clayton Act which has severely restricted combinations that might lessen competition. In 1967, 83 percent of the larger mergers consisted of purchases of firms in unrelated industries; in comparison, less than 60 percent of larger mergers between 1948 and 1953 were of this conglomerate type. Reducing Concentration In a few major industries, concentration has been very high for many years. New approaches to reducing concentration in these industries should be examined. Competitive forces can be enhanced by modifying existing industry patterns or by promoting entry of additional competitors. One approach would be to seek court decrees to promote competition by such measures as altering distribution and patent licensing practices. In 107 industries of critical economic importance, the appropriate remedy may be the divestiture of parts of the operations of the largest firms to create new competitors. A second approach is to adopt measures to channel merger activity in directions that would increase competition. Mergers could have a healthy impact on concentration if acquiring firms of very large size were barred from purchasing the leading firms in other concentrated industries. The major route for entry into a concentrated industry by a very large firm then would be to build new capacity or to buy an existing smaller firm. When a very large firm buys a small firm in a concentrated industry, it has the resources to expand that firm's capacity and to try to increase its share of the market. Such a merger can infuse new vigor and ideas into that market. There is also need to review certain provisions of the tax laws which provide incentives for mergers. Consideration should be given to modifying the statutes so as to make the tax laws more consistent with the objectives of antitrust policy. An effective program to deal with very high levels of concentration may require new legislation, carefully drafted to avoid either penalizing economic efficiency or placing unnecessary restrictions on the freedom to respond to competitive opportunities. With these two limitations, measures to strengthen competitive pressures in a number of highly concentrated industries could further increase the contribution of antitrust policy to price stability. LEGAL RESTRICTIONS ON COMPETITION In spite of the Government's commitment to the strengthening of competitive markets, some existing laws may weaken competition. Most of these laws were adopted during the 1930's to relieve the especially serious impact of the depression on small firms in the distributive trades. Resale Price Maintenance Major examples of these depression-born laws are the resale price maintenance statutes still in effect in 22 States. These "Fair Trade" acts permit a manufacturer to require that all the retailers in a State observe a minimum resale price for that manufacturer's trademarked products. Since these products generally move in interstate commerce, the practice rests on exemptions from Federal antitrust laws granted under the provisions of the MillerTydings Act (1937) and the Maguire amendment (1952). Resale price maintenance contracts are used mostly in the sale of drugs, cosmetics, appliances, and liquors. A survey by the Department of Justice in 1956 showed that prices were 19 to 27 percent higher on fair-traded items in States with resale price maintenance laws than in other States. Some estimates place the annual cost to the consumer of resale price maintenance at $1.5 billion. 108 One effect of resale price maintenance is to shift the focus of competition into less desirable forms. Retailers compete by providing more extensive consumer services, thereby increasing business costs. Manufacturers often set resale prices at levels providing generous markups to retailers, in order to induce them to favor the sale of their products. The principal objective of resale price maintenance is to protect smaller concerns from their larger competitors. The prohibition of predatory practices is a valid objective of public policy. In practice, however, lower prices reflecting greater efficiency and lower costs cannot be called predatory. Moreover, there is no evidence that the efficient small retailer needs such special protection, which can freeze an inefficient market structure. For these reasons, the Administration has consistently opposed legislation designed to extend resale price maintenance. Indeed, it is hard to see a continuing justification for the existing laws in today's prosperous economy. Robinson-Patman Act The Robinson-Patman Act is another important Federal law intended to protect the small from the large. The Act attempts to prevent chains, mail-order houses, and other huge buyers from extorting preferential price concessions from suppliers. Although public policy should be concerned with preventing improper use of the advantages conferred by sheer size, some evidence indicates that the Act has had the unintended effect of accentuating price rigidities in some markets. A seller may refuse to bargain on price with an individual customer by contending that under the law any concession granted to one buyer would have to be made uniformly available to all others. The law may conflict with the development of more efficient methods of distribution, such as integrating wholesale and retail functions or dispensing with independent brokers. By requiring proportionally equal treatment in certain promotional practices, the Act has discouraged experimentation with marketing techniques. It has been interpreted to prevent sellers from charging different prices in widely separated geographic markets. A careful reappraisal of the Act might suggest ways to focus its application more sharply on those particular forms of price discrimination that constitute a truly serious threat to competition. IMPROVING CONSUMER INFORMATION The effectiveness of price competition in consumer markets depends partly on the purchasing skill of the consumer. Dependable product and price information are needed to allow consumers to evaluate and compare the relative costs and merits of the enormous variety of goods and services offered for sale. 109 323-166 0—69 8 Legislative Achievements and Proposals In the last two Congresses, 20 bills protecting the consumer were enacted. Two of the most important were the Truth-in-Packaging and the Truthin-Lending Acts. The Truth-in-Packaging Act, signed in November 1966, recognizes that the bewildering multiplicity of package sizes for common household products makes price comparison difficult. While the enforcement provisions are weak, the Act takes important steps toward remedying the situation. One provision encourages interested industry groups, with the aid of consumers and government agencies, to develop voluntary standards to limit the number of package sizes. Another provision requires standardization of the location and form of the quantity statements on packages. The 1968 Truth-in-Lending Act requires that the finance charge on consumer credit transactions be expressed in terms of a simple annual rate. At present such charges are often stated in ways that make it difficult for the consumer to know the true cost of credit. Among the legislative proposals remaining from the previous Congress are those relating to deceptive sales techniques, which in the home improvement field alone are estimated to cost the consumer over $500 million annually. The Deceptive Sales Act, passed by the Senate but not the House in 1968, would give the Federal Trade Commission authority to obtain court orders to stop fraudulent and deceptive practices promptly. Other proposals would permit cancellation without penalty for 3 business days after the signing of a door-to-door sales contract and would authorize a Federal Trade Commission study of the home improvement industry. Sometimes selling practices themselves may restrict consumer choice and lead to higher prices. Often when a promotional practice is introduced by one seller, the response from competitors is not to lower prices but to introduce the same type of promotion. Trading stamps illustrate the contagious nature of sales techniques. Although many buyers can choose readily between stores that offer stamps and those that do not, other buyers can do so only at substantial inconvenience. In fact, almost half of all food sales in 1963 were made by merchants offering trading stamps. Therefore consideration should be given to legislation that assures consumers a choice between stamps and an equivalent cash discount. Product Testing Steps can also be taken to provide more complete and reliable product information. Advertising is a major source of consumer information, but it needs to be supplemented. The purpose of advertising is to stress the desirable qualities of particular items, not to set forth an objective appraisal of the relative merits of competing products. A few independent groups now test products and publicize their results, but their ability to do so is limited partly because their financial resources are not large. These activities could be supplemented by making available HO to the public the test data which various agencies of the Federal Government have accumulated in connection with their procurement activities. As a beginning, the Department of Health, Education, and Welfare and the Veterans Administration have recently announced that they will release the results of future product tests. REGULATED INDUSTRIES Electric power, most communications, natural gas, banking, securities markets, insurance, and most public transportation are subject to detailed regulation by Federal, State, or local agencies. The economic importance of these sectors is great. They account for about 9 percent of national income, and their prices and services affect many production and investment decisions throughout the economy. Problems naturally develop in regulated areas where technology and demand have changed rapidly. Existing regulatory practices need continuing review to determine whether established measures and institutions are efficiently responding to changing technology. Moreover, regulatory issues increasingly span the jurisdictions of several Federal agencies or cut across the authority of Federal-State-local agencies. Some of the areas where careful review might be most rewarding are identified below. Utilities Public utilities, especially electric and telephone companies, have made impressive economic gains through high rates of productivity and declining relative prices. Notwithstanding these gains, utilities might contribute more to price stability if productivity improvement or cost savings were more promptly translated into lower rates, with due regard to preserving the incentives for increased efficiency and the ability of the companies to raise new capital. Electric Power* The two major characteristics of the electric power industry in the last decade have been its rapid growth, now at 7 percent a year, and the lower unit costs made possible by advances in technology, increased interstate system coordination, and economies of scale. These complementary trends have permitted significant reductions in rates charged consumers, despite increases in many costs to the industry. These trends should continue in the next decade; the National Power Survey estimated that cost savings of as much as $11 billion annually (measured in 1962 dollars) are possible by 1980, if full advantage is taken of technological progress and market potential, and if closer coordination of planning and operations among the diverse ownership segments of the industry is achieved. Regulatory programs must be reevaluated periodically and new programs designed to ensure that these potential cost savings are fully realized and promptly reflected in rates. ill Natural Gas. This important fuel has almost tripled its share of the energy market in the last 3 decades and now supplies about one-third of the Nation's energy requirements. Natural gas is subject to comprehensive Federal, State, and local regulation. The Federal Government regulates entry into interstate markets, wholesale rates, and conditions of service and safety. In the 1960's, Federal regulation has resulted in relatively stable rates, in contrast to the steep price increases that marked the preceding decade. The new concept of setting a common price schedule for natural gas sales in each producing area offers the expectation of an improved regulatory procedure. Recently, rising costs—particularly taxes and bond interest rates—have caused natural gas companies to file a rash of applications for rate increases. Some applications also assert that higher rates are necessary to stimulate exploration for, and development of, future reserves. These contentions must be recognized and dealt with expeditiously. Specifically, careful scrutiny must be given to costing formulas, evolving technology, and to the future adequacy of supply. Securities Markets A careful review of securities markets revealed several problems in the thriving mutual funds industry. In particular, a provision of the Investment Company Act prohibits dealers from reducing sales charges fixed by the mutual fund underwriter. Many mutual funds have commission charges considerably higher than those on most other security transactions. In addition, stock exchange rules prescribe uniform minimum brokerage commissions. The Securities and Exchange Commission is currently investigating this practice to see whether such limits on price competition can be eliminated or modified without damage to security markets. Transportation The sector that appears to offer the broadest opportunities for further regulatory improvement is transportation. Regulation was originally imposed on railroads about 80 years ago, when competition from other modes was minimal, to protect shippers and travelers from discriminatory treatment. With the development of new modes of transportation such as pipelines, trucking, and air carriers, the general pattern of railroad regulation has been extended to cover them. But technological change, rising consumer incomes, and extensive public investment in transport facilities have led to greatly increased competition among different forms of transportation. In the past two decades, some regulatory decisions have insulated existing carriers and their patterns of service and rates from that invigorating competition. Competition. Statutory exemptions from regulation in water and motor transport cover about 87 percent of the ton-miles moved on inland waterways 112 and 64 percent of intercity ton-miles moved by truck. Free market decisions involving rates and the amount and quality of service have worked satisfactorily in these exempted areas over a long period. Current antitrust laws protect against improper carrier conduct. Reliance on competition permits carriers to adjust rates freely. Regulators, in contrast, have often required firms to keep rates up to the level of "fully distributed costs," which reflect an arbitrary allocation of overhead. Air, truck, and inland water carriers do not have the large indivisible inputs characteristic of railroads and pipelines, such as rights-of-way and terminals. Thus railroads have relatively high fixed costs, and if overhead must be allocated to each traffic unit on a rigid basis, the calculated average costs and rate schedules may differ markedly from the variable expenses of additional traffic. Minimum rates based on these average costs can divert traffic from railroads even when they could offer the least costly mode of transportation. A recent specific case illustrates this problem. The Interstate Commerce Commission denied a request by the railroads to reduce their rate for handling ingot molds to a level lower than that charged by the competing bargetruck service. The proposed rate was below the railroads' fully distributed costs, but above their marginal costs. On appeal, the Supreme Court held that the Commission had the authority to determine which cost base to use. The decision thus left it to the Commission to base its rulings on marginal cost criteria when it thought appropriate. To the extent that minimum rate regulation is continued, marginal costs rather than fully distributed costs would most closely approximate the pattern which a competitive market would produce. This principle, if generally applied, would result in a much more efficient distribution of transportation resources and in lower costs to users of transportation services. Entry. A better use of our potential transportation resources can also be achieved by lessening regulatory barriers to entry—particularly for trucks. A motor carrier now requires a specific grant of operating authority, a procedure instituted in an earlier period of overcapacity. The problem today is to serve a growing volume of traffic, which has expanded since 1961 at an annual rate of 4 percent as measured by intercity ton-miles. The Interstate Commerce Commission has issued over 100,000 grants of operating rights to motor carriers, mostly at the time regulation was instituted. At present, securing new rights is difficult; moreover, some existing rights are restricted to specific commodities, routes, direction of movement, and territory. GOVERNMENT PROCUREMENT The Federal Government, the largest single buyer in our economy, purchased $54.7 billion of goods and services from the private sector in 1967. Consequently, the manner and care with which the Government carries out its purchases have a significant impact not only on the prices it pays but on other prices throughout the economy. Competitive Procurement Because competition normally works to improve quality and keep prices in line with costs, the Government has long relied on competitive bidding whenever possible. In fiscal 1968, about three-quarters of the dollars spent by the General Services Administration, the chief purchaser of general supplies for the Government, involved formal bidding; another fifth involved other procurement methods that stressed price competition. Currently 82 percent of all Government purchases are made by the Department of Defense. Since many of these expenditures involve the development and production of sophisticated weapon systems, they are less suited to conventional price competition. In fiscal 1968, only 38 percent of defense outlays—up from 33 percent in fiscal 1961—utilized formal bidding or other methods stressing price competition. However, varying degrees of competition existed for a substantial portion of the remainder of defense procurement. Negotiated Procurement Competitive procurement is most difficult to achieve for specially built hardware, such as major defense systems, for which the Federal Government is the only buyer. When competition cannot be relied upon to hold down costs, contracts providing incentives for cost reduction are desirable. Fixed-price type contracts, in which the contractor shares in any cost reduction or cost escalation, have increased from 58 percent of all defense purchases in fiscal 1961 to 78 percent in fiscal 1968. Cost-plus-fixed-fee contracts, which provide less incentive for cost reduction, have dropped from 37 percent of the dollar volume to 11 percent over the same period. Total Package Procurement, a major procurement innovation of the 1960ss, has extended competition and permitted more fixed price contracts. It requires a binding commitment from the contractor on as much of the production program as is feasible at the time of the initial award. This is a significant departure from the earlier practice of conducting design competitions for development followed by cost reimbursement production contracts with the developer. The new approach emphasizes the use of performance specifications and provides tightened control over design and contract changes, thereby reducing expensive modifications. Since the contractor is committed to cost and performance figures for production units before detailed design begins, he has a strong motive to design for economical production, reliability, and simplicity of maintenance. Single Source Procurement Unfortunately, it is not possible to introduce price competition into all purchasing. For example, Total Package Procurement is unsuited for pro- 114 grams where needs or technology are changing rapidly, since technical uncertainties cannot be identified in detail before major work starts. From the point of view of price stability, the least desirable situation is the case of a "sole source" supplier, operating under a cost reimbursement (rather than fixed price) contract. In fiscal 1968, 14 percent of the dollar volume of defense procurement was in this category. Such awards often reflect the special experience of one firm as well as the uncertainties of technology. For example, only one particular firm is considered to have the capability to develop the Sentinel antiballistic-missile system. Therefore, the Department of Defense will of necessity procure from one source for this multibillion dollar program for some time. A large number of subcontractors are involved, however; and as soon as possible, major items will be broken out and procured separately under competitive conditions. Great progress has been made in recent years in improving procurement methods, but further progress is essential for improved price performance. Efforts to encourage competition and to develop new methods of procurement must be maintained. AGRICULTURE Three main problems continue to confront agricultural policymakers. Returns to the labor of some farmers and their workers are low, particularly on smaller farms. Price fluctuations are severe as a result of weather, livestock production cycles, and international developments. And price instability is compounded by excess capacity and a consequent chronic tendency to produce more of certain major crops than the market can readily absorb at reasonable prices. Achievements of Agricultural Policies In broad perspective, past agricultural programs have been successful for commercial farmers. They have made it possible to eliminate the burdensome surpluses of 1960. They have provided higher and more stable prices than would have existed otherwise and thereby helped moderate fluctuations in farm income. They have reduced risks associated with farm planning, permitted more efficient business management, and encouraged a substantial increase in the capital investment per worker. These factors in turn have made possible gains in labor productivity of 175 percent since 1950. Changing Farm Structure Profound changes have occurred in the structure of the farm economy in the 35 years since major farm price legislation was first introduced. The number of farms has been halved. Total farm output and average farm size have more than doubled. Differences in output per farm have become pro- nounced. Fifteen percent of the farmers—those grossing $20,000 or more annually—marketed two-thirds of the value of the 1967 farm output. More than half of the farmers accounted for less than 7 percent of the total. Farm income is a progressively less important part of the total income of many operators of smaller farms. In 1967, farmers selling less than $2,500 in farm products received net farm incomes averaging only $1,018 but had average off-farm incomes of $5,681. Nevertheless, there are many farm families without such off-farm income whose total incomes fall below the poverty line. New Directions for Policy In light of the changing structure of U.S. agriculture, proposals have been advanced to modify price support programs. A reasonable limit on the amount any one farmer could receive from Government payments might provide annual savings approaching $200 million. Any such program, however, would have to be carefully designed to avoid major administrative difficulties and to preserve the incentives for acreage limitations. A Department of Agriculture study indicates that, in recent years, farmers with gross annual incomes at or above $20,000 earned more for their labor and capital than they would have with the same resources in the nonfarm sector. This suggests that these highly efficient farmers have a lessening need for economic aid. On the other hand, those with small farms derive less than 20 percent of their income, on the average, from farm sales. Hence some gradual restructuring of farm price supports to bring market demand and supply into closer balance would have little effect on their income, and payment limitations would not apply to them. A better balance of equity among large farms, small farms, and consumers would be achieved if more market-oriented price supports were accompanied by: an expansion of the 1965 Cropland Adjustment Program (providing for voluntary land retirement) ; more job training programs in rural areas; continued emphasis on community resource development; and more effective income maintenance programs for farm families in poverty (see Chapter 5). A restructuring of farm programs along these lines could encourage large farmers to continue to increase their investments and make full use of the opportunities constantly being opened by new technology. They would also have freedom to exercise the option of conserving land resources until market competition made profitable cultivation possible. INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND PRICE STABILITY Price competition is enhanced by the availability of imported products. During periods of high employment, increased import competition helps to offset the decline in the intensity of competitive behavior among domestic producers which accompanies high over-all demand. Rising imports also help to avoid the development of bottlenecks and shortages when demand is n6 straining domestic capacity. They thus make a vital contribution toward the moderation of inflationary tendencies. There is no doubt that prices in industries subject to strong import competition would have risen faster if such competition had been restricted. For example, steel prices increased by 35 percent between 1953 and 1961 when imports were small, but only 7^2 percent between 1961 and the end of 1968 when growing world capacity led to an expansion of imports. There is clear evidence that steel producers have been especially wary about raising prices for product lines subject to heavy import competition, such as wire and wire products, or hot rolled sheet. To the extent that less expensive imported items enter into further processing or manufacture, they reduce costs and permit lower prices for final products. Thus the availability of imported yarn and fabrics, by reducing the costs of our apparel manufacturers, permits them to compete more effectively against apparel imports. The competitiveness of our machinery manufacturers in export markets is similarly enhanced by their ability to obtain steel—imported or domestic—at prices lower than they would have to pay if imports were restricted. Impact on Domestic Industries The increased flow of imports entails certain costs that must be weighed against the benefits. It has cut into the markets of some important industries (notably steel, textiles, and footwear) and a few agricultural sectors. This has resulted in pressures for import restrictions, usually in the form of quota limitations. An international arrangement controlling imports has been in effect for cotton products since 1962, and a current issue is whether to extend this type of arrangement to textiles made from wool and synthetics. Quotas have been imposed on agricultural imports, usually to prevent the growth of Government stockpiles. For a number of products, informal arrangements limiting imports are in force or are being considered as a more flexible and less onerous instrument than formal quotas. While imports are an important factor in a number of domestic markets, they have not prevented expansion of the industries most affected. Steel, textile, and apparel output has increased since 1960, and after-tax profits have risen in all three industries. The rate of return on equity for these industries has also improved considerably, although it remains below the average for all manufacturing—as it has for many years. It is important to emphasize that increased imports in these and other industries reflect, in part, long-run changes in trade patterns resulting from the natural development of the industrial structures of the United States and its trading partners. The dynamic U.S. economy need not and should not be insulated from these changes. The crucial issue is not whether barriers to imports would increase employment and sales in the industries affected, but rather whether our economy is offering ample employment and investment opportunities, at the same or better conditions, in other 117 pursuits. If these interindustry shifts impose transitional costs, such burdens should be shared and alleviated by Federal adjustment assistance. Furthermore, fundamental shifts in efficiency should be carefully distinguished from special situations such as dumping practices and export incentives given by other nations. Some of these situations, as well as adjustment assistance, are discussed in Chapter 4 along with other measures to ensure the two-way nature of trade by keeping world markets open and fair. National Security and Trade A valid case for protecting a key industry can be made if national security would be seriously threatened by a sharp increase in imports. The national security rationale underpins the mandatory oil import program, which imposes limits on petroleum imports. It may be desirable to reexamine the security rationale to determine if the present administration of the program best meets the objective. Some changes may be possible which, while preserving essential security objectives, would permit greater flexibility and ensure an economical supply of petroleum feedstocks for the petrochemical industry. VOLUNTARY RESTRAINT IN PRICES AND WAGES The forces exerting upward pressures on wages and prices in a high employment economy are broad and impersonal. The responses of wages and prices to these pressures, however, are expressed through a multitude of separate decisions by employees and employers, by sellers and buyers. ROLE OF PRIVATE DECISIONS These decisions must be made within the constraints imposed by the market, constraints which operate on even the largest businesses and the strongest unions. Nevertheless, major companies in highly concentrated industries have substantial discretion in their price and wage decisions, as do many unions in the determination of wages. The way this discretion is exercised by the majority of business executives and labor leaders can have a substantial impact on the trends of prices and wages, even though no single business or union can by itself have a decisive influence. This imposes a grave responsibility on decisionmakers who have discretionary market power. Since the economic consequences of private price and wage decisions bear so importantly on the public welfare, it is appropriate for Government to point the way in which these individual decisions can best serve the public interest. STANDARDS FOR DECISIONS The Government has worked to evoke a general awareness of the importance of price and wage restraint among business, labor, and the public. These efforts date back to the Economic Reports of President Eisenhower 118 in the late 1950's. A more explicit formulation was proposed in the Council's 1962 Annual Report in the form of the wage-price guideposts. In subsequent Reports, these guideposts evolved gradually—a process described in detail in the Council's 1967 Annual Report. As initially set forth in 1962, the guideposts stated: The general guide for noninflationary wage behavior is that the rate of increase in wage rates (including fringe benefits) in each industry be equal to the trend rate of over-all productivity increase. . . . The general guide for noninflationary price behavior calls for price reduction if the industry's rate of productivity increase exceeds the over-all rate—for this would mean declining unit labor costs; it calls for an appropriate increase in price if the opposite relationship prevails; and it calls for stable prices if the two rates of productivity increase are equal. The guideposts were never intended to apply in highly competitive sectors where market forces determine prices and wages in an impersonal fashion. They are applicable to markets in which discretionary power exists. Even in these markets, short-run exceptions have always been recognized when changes in relative prices and wages are necessary to facilitate shifts in the use of labor and capital, or where substandard wages exist. APPLICATION OF STANDARDS Between 1961 and 1965, decisionmakers with discretionary power generally conformed to the pattern envisaged by the guideposts. There were occasional departures, however. In particular, some industries with higherthan-average productivity gains did not reduce prices as unit labor costs fell. The extent to which the satisfactory performance was enhanced by the efforts of the Administration to urge the observance of the guideposts cannot be precisely assessed. But the history of key wage and price decisions during this period indicates that these efforts did exert a distinct and significant influence. The blemished price-wage record of the past 3 years reflects primarily an excessive growth of demand. Indeed, the initial departures from the path of price and cost stability were concentrated in farm products, raw materials, and services where guideposts have little, if any, applicability. The same forces also influenced price and wage decisions in areas of discretionary market power. Once consumer prices started to move up sharply, increases in compensation no larger than the productivity trend would not have led to any improvement in real income. Workers could not be expected to accept such a result, particularly in view of the previous rapid and consistent rise in corporate profits. Recognizing this situation, the Council, in its 1967 and 1968 Reports, did not suggest that wage increases should be limited to the trend growth of productivity. It did, however, continue to urge maximum possible restraint in both wage settlements and price adjustments, and it continued to maintain the validity of the basic productivity principle for long-run price stability. With wage increases substantially in excess of productivity, it was also recognized that production costs in many industries would rise and that some price adjustments were inevitable. At the same time, with profits generally at a high level, many industries were in a position to absorb increases in labor costs either wholly or in considerable part. The Administration therefore continued to urge business executives to avoid or minimize price increases. This stress on the economy-wide consequences of discretionary price and wage decisions has served an important educational role in addition to its direct effects on prices and wages. The discussion of standards for prices and wages has focused the attention of business, labor, and the public on the inflationary results of individual actions that add up to demands for income in excess of what the economy can produce. Awareness of this proposition has spread among key decisionmakers in both the business and labor communities in recent years. FUTURE ROLE OF COOPERATION The cooperation of labor and business in the observance of voluntary standards of price and wage behavior is an essential part of a full program to combine high employment and reasonable price stability. Such cooperation must be viewed as a supplement to appropriate fiscal and monetary policy and to measures for improving the efficiency of the economy. The task immediately ahead is to make significant progress toward restoring price stability during 1969. The public and private policies essential to this end are discussed in Chapter 1. Once this has been achieved, however, the essential task for the longer run will still remain. Mandatory price and wage controls are no answer. Such controls freeze the market mechanism which guides the economy in responding to the changing pattern and volume of demand; they distort decisions on production and employment; they require a huge and cumbersome bureaucracy; they impose a heavy and costly burden on business; they perpetrate inevitable injustices. They are incompatible with a free enterprise economy and must be regarded as a last resort appropriate only in an extreme emergency such as all-out war. Better ways must be devised of establishing standards for voluntary restraint, and for eliciting cooperation from those who enjoy discretionary market power. But if voluntary restraint is to be effective, better means must be found of focusing the attention and eliciting the cooperation of all private groups concerned—business, labor, the public—in dealing with the 120 issue of maintaining reasonable price stability at high employment. The task will not be easy since it requires that each group accept some sacrifice of its apparent short-run interest in order to serve its own and the public's longrun interests. In the past, neither labor nor business played a major role in the development of the guidepost approach. In the future, effective cooperation is much more likely if those to whom the standards will apply participate in their development. Persuasion can be helped by representation. In view of such considerations, the President instructed the Cabinet Committee on Price Stability to: "Work with representatives of business, labor, and the public to enlist cooperation toward responsible wage and price behavior . . ." The institutional arrangements for increased business and labor participation can take many forms. This past year, the Labor-Management Advisory Committee has begun the dialogue necessary to develop standards that business and labor leaders might be willing to accept jointly. The development of standards by such a cooperative effort would strengthen the educational role of voluntary restraint and increase its effectiveness. It is essential that the system remain on a voluntary basis. The principal sanction consistent with voluntary restraint is the force of public opinion. This means that decisions which significantly threaten the public interest must be spotlighted. Since many wage and price decisions are complicated and difficult to analyze, some competent authority must call attention to flagrant departures from standards of responsible decisionmaking. Unpleasant as such a task may be, it is inescapable. The precise way in which this task is carried out is less important than public acceptance of the necessity, equity, and reasonableness of the procedures used to review price and wage decisions. CONCLUSION This chapter has reviewed some of the programs which may improve the ability of the economy to maintain reasonably stable prices at high levels of employment. It has also reviewed the contribution that can be made by voluntary cooperation toward price and wage decisions consistent with the public interest. Some conclusions emerge clearly. It is not inevitable that pressures on labor supply should begin to appear when unemployment falls below 4 percent. It is not inevitable that wage increases should substantially exceed productivity gains, and that prices should begin to rise rapidly, as the economy reaches high employment. It is not inevitable that price stability should be restored only through the wasteful remedy of repeated doses of economic stagnation and high unemployment. But to meet the challenge, the Nation must move ahead vigorously and imaginatively on many fronts. Both labor and product markets require nu- 121 merous structural improvements, and voluntary restraint must make an even greater contribution than in the past. The task of reconciling price stability with high employment cannot be accomplished by Government alone, or by business alone, or by labor alone. It requires clear comprehension by all groups of the overwhelming importance of this goal. And it requires an awareness of the bleakness of the alternatives: either achieving stability by sacrificing high employment or realizing high employment by acquiescing in persistent inflation. We cannot, and need not, accept either of these alternatives. 122 Chapter 4 The International Economy I N THE PAST TWO DECADES, enormous progress has been made in building a closely knit international economy. Remarkable growth in the volume of international commerce has gone hand in hand with sustained world prosperity; each has contributed to the other. At times, deep and obvious strains in the international monetary system have imperiled this progress, but these financial difficulties have been weathered without a serious setback in economic growth or world trade. The world economy emerged from the Second World War in a gravely weakened state, with many countries suffering severely from war damage. International trade was disrupted, and exchange controls and bilateral trad' ing arrangements were the order of the day. However, the recuperative strength of the European nations, assisted by U.S. aid, resulted in rapid economic recovery. During the 1950's, the increasingly prosperous countries of western Europe liberalized trade and capital movements substantially. Meanwhile U.S. capital exports promoted economic growth abroad, and our balance-of-payments deficits contributed to a desirable expansion of world monetary reserves. However, by the end of the 1950's, U.S. deficits were beginning to cause concern. A nagging question was raised: Did the international monetary system require continuous U.S. deficits and an intolerable, persistent weakening of the reserve position of the United States if serious reserve inadequacies for other countries were to be avoided? The growth of world trade and income has continued—indeed, has accelerated—during the 1960's. But there have been periodic monetary disturbances associated with expected or feared realignments of exchange rates. While financial officials have shown wisdom and ingenuity in modifying and strengthening the international monetary system, important problems remain. Recent major financial disturbances have emphasized the need for further evolution to insure that the system can continue to support growing wrorld trade and income. This chapter briefly reviews the growth of world trade and output and some of the key policy issues regarding our trade relationships with the developed and less developed countries. The review is followed by discussion of international financial problems and by analysis of several current proposals designed to strengthen the international monetary system. 123 ECONOMIC GROWTH AND WORLD TRADE In the years since the Second World War growth has come to be accepted as a normal feature of the world economy. It is easy to forget that this was not the case in earlier periods. The depression years of the 1930's present a particularly sharp contrast. But by any historical comparison, the economic progress of the last 20 years is unprecedented. World income has more than doubled since 1950. In the fifties, growth was especially rapid in the western European countries, while in recent years the United States has grown more vigorously (Table 12). Japan has experienced rapid and sustained growth throughout the period. With their more rapid population growth, the less developed countries, taken together, have experienced a slower growth of per capita income than have the developed countries, even though total income has grown at about the same rate in both groups of countries. Growth of per capita income has varied widely among the less developed countries, in recent years ranging from high rates for Iran, Korea, Taiwan, and Thailand to virtual stagnation or even decline for some parts of Asia and Latin America. TRADE AND TRADE BARRIERS The rapid growth of recent decades has contributed much to the increase in world trade (Table 13). A continuing reduction in trade barriers has TABLE 12.—Growth of gross national product in developed and less developed countries, 1950-67 [Percentage change per year] Total real GNP Per capita real GNP Region and country 1950 to 1955 1955 to 1960 1960 to 1967 1950 to 1955 1955 to 1960 1960 to 1967 4.7 3.4 4.9 3.5 2.2 3.7 United States Europe1 EEC2 Other countries3 Japan .4.3 5.0 6.3 6.2 4 7.7 2.2 4.4 5.3 6.1 9.8 4.7 4.2 4.6 7.7 2.6 4.3 5.5 4.4 * 6.2 .5 3.6 4.4 4.6 8.8 3.3 3.2 3.6 6.3 9.3 Less developed countries5 4.7 4.5 2.8 2.2 2.5 5.1 5.0 5.9 4.2 3.8 2.3 2.1 3.4 2.1 1.2 1.7 3.9 1.9 2.5 1.3 Developed countries Latin America Near East6 South Asia East Asia Africa o 3.4 o o o 10.4 5.0 46 6.4 4.3 5.2 3.6 °1.3 8 O * Excludes Spain, Greece, and Turkey. 2 European Economic Community (EEC) consists of Belgium, Luxembourg, France, Germany (Federal Republic and West Berlin), Italy, and Netherlands. 3 Consists of Canada, Australia, New Zealand, South Africa, and Japan. i Change from 1952 to 1955. 5 Estimates based on countries for which data are available. 6 Includes Greece and Turkey. 7 Not available. Note.—Data exclude U.S.S.R., other East European countries, Mainland China, and Cuba. Source: Agency for International Development. 124 TABLE 13.—Growth of world exports, 1952-67 [Percentage change per year] 1952-53 1959-60 to Region and country to 1959-60 World total.. 1966-67 1952-53 to 1966-67 5.7 8.1 6.9 Developed countries. _ Industrialized countries * Other developed countries 2. 6.2 6.5 3.7 8.8 8.9 8.0 7.5 7.7 5.8 Less developed countries... 4.1 5.9 5.0 Latin America Other Western Hemisphere... Middle East Asia excluding Japan Africa excluding South Africa. Other countries 2.3 3.1 9.4 4.2 3.4 7.3 5.1 3.5 8.3 4.0 7.8 6.1 3.7 3.3 8.8 4.1 5.6 6.7 By type of export: Selected exporters of manufactures 3. Selected oil exporters * Other less developed countries 5.3 9.7 3.0 15.7 8.2 4.6 10.4 8.9 3.8 1 Includes United States, United Kingdom, industrial Europe, Canada, and Japan. 2 Includes other Europe, Australia, New Zealand, and South Africa. 3 Includes Israel, Hong Kong, Korea, and Taiwan. * Includes Iran, Libya, Saudi Arabia, Venezuela, and Kuwait. Note: Data include Yugoslavia, but exclude U.S.S.R., other East European countries, Mainland China, and Cuba. Source: International Monetary Fund. also stimulated trade. As a result of six multilateral trade negotiations within the framework of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), levels of protection have been repeatedly lowered during the past 20 years. As the staged tariff reductions negotiated during the recent Kennedy Round are completed during the next 3 years, this downward trend will continue. Even after these reductions, tariffs will remain a significant barrier to trade and further efforts will be required to reduce them. Nontariff Barriers As tariffs have been reduced, other barriers to trade have increased in relative importance. Nontariff barriers have been adopted for a variety of reasons. For example, some import quotas are surviving remnants of supposedly temporary restrictions imposed by certain countries during periods of balance-of-payments difficulties, as permitted under the rules of the GATT. Other barriers result from domestic laws aimed at protecting consumers, such as sanitary and health regulations. Government procurement policies discriminating in favor of domestic producers are another form of nontariff barrier and are at times a serious impediment to international competition for government contracts. While protection on industrial goods has been reduced in recent years, restrictions on agricultural trade, including tariffs, have risen. These barriers are of particular concern to the United States because they have proven to be a major hindrance to U.S. agricultural exports. 125 323-166 O—69- The GATT rules are interpreted as permitting a country to exempt exports from indirect taxes and to impose on imports a charge equivalent to these indirect taxes. Countries such as the United States that rely heavily on income or other direct taxes may suffer a disadvantage, since similar "border adjustments" are not permitted for direct taxes. This urgent problem is under intensive discussion with our trading partners. Work on other nontariff barriers is going forward in the GATT. Continuing and concerted efforts are necessary both for the United States and for its trading partners. Meaningful negotiations require that the United States as well as foreign countries be prepared to make concessions. The barrier maintained by the United States that is of greatest concern to our trading partners is the "American Selling Price" provision. Under this practice, applicable to certain benzenoid chemicals and a few other goods, tariffs are based on the prices of domestic products rather than actual prices of imports. During the Kennedy Round, conditional agreement was reached for the United States to eliminate this provision, in return for commitments by others to undertake additional reductions in tariffs on chemicals. In addition, Belgium, France, Italy, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom agreed, as part of the package, to modify certain of their nontariff barriers. Legislation to eliminate the American Selling Price provision would permit this significant agreement to be carried out. Adjustment Assistance The Trade Expansion Act of 1962 provided for adjustment assistance to those injured by tariff reductions. It recognized that, because the gains from trade are widely distributed to the consuming public, the Nation as a whole should share the costs of adjustment associated with trade liberalization. In practice, however, the criteria of the Act have proved too rigorous. In no actual case has it been possible to demonstrate, as required, both that tariff reductions have been the major cause of an increase in imports and that the increase in imports has been the major cause of serious injury to an industry, firm, or group of workers. Legislative modification of these criteria is required in order to establish an effective program of adjustment assistance. LESS DEVELOPED COUNTRIES International trade and capital transfers have made important contributions to the growth of many less developed countries during the postwar period, and they will have a major role to play in the future. As shown in Table 13, less developed countries have not shared fully in the growth of world trade. Apart from a few countries which export manufactured goods or petroleum, exports of the less developed countries 126 have grown only about half as rapidly since 1952 as those of developed nations. Most of the less developed countries depend heavily on export earnings from the sale of primary products. These products are subject to marked year-to-year price fluctuations and in some cases to declining price trends, making them a highly unreliable source of foreign exchange. Some experts have proposed formal international commodity agreements aimed at changing market price behavior. While some commodity agreements are already in existence, they have not provided a complete solution, and few additional commodities appear suited to such agreements. Additional borrowing arrangements to compensate for shortfalls in export earnings, similar to the facility established by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) in 1963, have also been suggested. The staffs of the IMF and the World Bank have been studying the problem of volatile export receipts and are expected to report soon on the additional part these two institutions might play in arrangements to increase the stability of foreign exchange inflows to primary producers. Tariff Preferences In the long run, dependence of the less developed countries on primary products can be lessened through increased exports of manufactured goods. The advanced countries can assist in this process by removing some of their current restrictions on imports of those manufactured and semimanufactured goods of particular interest to less developed countries. Since further general tariff reductions seem unlikely in the immediate future, the granting of tariff preferences to less developed countries may represent a way of achieving a more rapid reduction of these barriers. The 1968 United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) unanimously endorsed the early establishment of a system of generalized nonreciprocal tariff preferences for less developed countries. The United States and other developed nations are now engaged in discussions to determine whether a mutually acceptable system can be devised. A generalized tariff preference system would help the less developed countries, but it wrould be only a modest step toward meeting their total foreign exchange needs. The developed countries are likely to insist on excluding certain products from the preference scheme, and trade in other commodities will continue to be restricted by quotas and other nontariff barriers. Furthermore, the initial benefits of the preference scheme would go largely to the minority of less developed countries that have already begun to export manufactured goods. Foreign Aid The experience of the 1950's and the 1960's has demonstrated the value of foreign assistance in promoting economic development. Foreign capital and 127 technical assistance from both public and private sources have been significant factors in the highly successful development efforts of such countries as Greece, Israel, Korea, Mexico, Pakistan, and Taiwan. While the total volume of foreign assistance has been growing during the 1960's, it has not kept pace with the rising ability of the less developed countries to make efficient use of such funds. Foreign assistance expenditures by the United States rose sharply in fiscal 1962 but have not increased significantly since then. Unless the recent declining trend in appropriations is reversed, expenditures must ultimately fall. The International Development Association, an affiliate of the World Bank, was established in 1960 to make credits available to developing countries on liberal terms. It has been an effective channel of multilateral assistance, of which the United States has been a major proponent. However, its resources have been largely exhausted and replenishment is essential. It is important that the United States authorize its contribution promptly, because the contributions of other countries depend on the U.S. decision. THE BRETTON WOODS SYSTEM The rapid growth in the world economy in the post war period has been built on a greatly improved financial base. At the 1944 Bretton Woods Conference, the major industrial countries created through the IMF an international monetary system based on pegged exchange rates. The system has been strengthened by the great strides in cooperation in the IMF and in other institutions such as the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) and the Bank for International Settlements (BIS). This cooperation has paid handsome dividends in times of crisis. International understanding, carefully nurtured during periods of calm, has permitted the multilateral assessment of problems and the determination of mutually acceptable solutions. This was well illustrated in March 1968, when decisions taken with respect to the private gold market ended the immediate threat to stability and basically strengthened the system. At times of severe strain, such as the British devaluation in 1967, international cooperation has contained crises and prevented chain reactions. To be sure, the international monetary system has had its problems. Crises have occurred all too frequently. Yet the system has consistently been able to meet the needs of the day, it has evolved and adapted, and it can be strengthened further to meet the remaining strains. While conserving proven arrangements, governments seem increasingly ready to consider additional improvements. Proposed evolutionary changes require careful study and deliberation, based on widespread official and public discussions. It is particularly important that these involve the bankers and traders who would be directly affected. The following discussion is intended to contribute to such a dialogue, rather than to make specific recommendations. 128 International monetary disturbances have centered around three interrelated problems: adjustment, confidence, and liquidity. "Adjustment" is the process of reestablishing balance-of-payments equilibrium when a country is substantially out of balance. An adjustment problem exists when the relevant forces and policies are either too weak to reestablish equilibrium within a reasonable period or involve domestic or international effects that are inordinately costly. "Confidence" refers to the willingness to hold monetary assets. A problem arises when holders either become dissatisfied with the safety of some of these assets or see the possibility of profit in switching them abruptly into a different form. This problem is related to adjustment: dissatisfaction with a currency often reflects a lack of faith in the ability of the issuing country to eliminate its balance-of-payments difficulty without resort to a change in its exchange parity. "Liquidity" relates to international monetary reserves which are held by countries to finance temporary balance-of-payments deficits. If world reserves are too low or too high, or if their rate of growth is inadequate or excessive, a liquidity problem exists. Liquidity needs are closely related to adjustment: the less rapidly and effectively the adjustment process works, the higher the level of reserves needed to finance temporary balance-of-payments deficits, and the less likely it is that any given level of reserves will be adequate. THE LIQUIDITY PROBLEM A country incurs a balance-of-payments deficit when its payments to other countries exceed its receipts from them, apart from "settlement items" required to square accounts. The immediate consequence of a deficit is that the foreign exchange market becomes unbalanced. More of the deficit country's currency is supplied than demanded at the existing price of the currency, and this will depress the price—the exchange rate. Because of their commitment to a fixed exchange rate, however, central banks intervene to limit the fall in the rate. The floor on the exchange rate is within 1 percent of the official parity established by the country in agreement with the IMF. In order to prevent the exchange rate from dropping below this floor, a country in deficit must use its foreign exchange reserves to buy the excess supply of its own currency. If the country has ample reserves, it will have sufficient breathing space to restore equilibrium—without resort to policies of excessive domestic restraint or direct intervention in external transactions. If reserves are scanty, however, pressures will develop to deal immediately with the deficit, even through undesirable means. If a general shortage of reserves should occur, economic growth could be retarded by widespread deflationary policies, and international trade and investment could be burdened by restrictions. On the other hand, excessive amounts of reserves could unduly weaken the incentives of deficit countries to adjust, thereby encouraging worldwide inflation. 129 TYPES OF RESERVES Existing stocks of world reserves include gold, foreign exchange, and IMF reserve positions. Gold is the largest component of reserves, but gold holdings have expanded very little for many years; most recently, they have declined. As was discussed in the Council's 1968 Annual Report, nonmonetary demand for gold seems to be absorbing a substantial and increasing share of current new production at existing prices. The value of official gold reserves would be increased if the official price of gold were raised. This action is explicitly rejected for compelling reasons. Although it would immediately increase world reserves, it could not provide the orderly growth of reserves needed by the world economy. It would grant unearned windfall gains to private speculators, to gold producers, and to countries holding their reserves mainly in gold; it would encourage speculation; and it would divert scarce resources into the production of a metal already adequately supplied for nonmonetary uses. The foreign exchange component of reserves grows only if the major reserve currency countries, the United States and the United Kingdom, incur balance-of-payments deficits; and if surplus countries are willing to hold more dollars and sterling. Thus, as the foreign exchange component of world reserves is expanded, the liquidity position of the reserve currency countries may be undermined. It is generally recognized that the United States should not run large deficits, and policies have been formulated and implemented for reaching an acceptable payments position. The United Kingdom also is determined not to run deficits and has in fact designed its economic policy to yield balance-of-payments surpluses in order to retire external debt. To some extent, such debt repayments will actually contract world reserves. Thus world reserves cannot be expected to grow substantially through expansion of official holdings of either gold or foreign exchange. Some limited expansion through normal IMF lending is to be expected. Reserve positions in the Fund are expanded, however, only when countries draw on the Fund beyond their "gold tranche" or automatic drawing rights. In so doing, they accept obligations to repay. The natural reluctance of countries to become overcommitted to the Fund or to other countries through borrowings sharply limits the probable expansion of reserves in this form. SPECIAL DRAWING RIGHTS In order to deal with the liquidity problem, steps have been taken to create a new international reserve asset, the Special Drawing Right (SDR), as discussed in the Council's 1968 Annual Report. SDR's will be allocated by the IMF to member countries. They will be a form of owned reserves, usable for balance-of-payments needs without an obligation of repayment. Their use is subject only to the reconstitution provision, which requires that dur- 130 ing the initial 5-year period a country's average holdings of SDR's should be at least 30 percent of its average net cumulative allocation over this period. A draft outline of the proposed arrangements for issuing SDR's was approved at the 1967 meetings of the IMF in Rio de Janiero and subsequently translated into legal form by the Executive Directors of the Fund. In March 1968, at a meeting in Stockholm of Ministers and Central Bank Governors of the major industrial countries, a consensus was reached on an amendment to the IMF Articles of Agreement. The amendment was subsequently approved by an overwhelming majority of the Board of Governors of the Fund. The amendment was then submitted to member countries for ratification, which requires acceptance by 67 member countries (total membership is 111) having 80 percent of the voting power in the IMF. By January 1, 1969, the amendment had been accepted by 27 countries representing 47 percent of the voting power. Seven countries have taken the further required step of depositing with the IMF instruments of participation indicating that they are prepared to carry out their obligations under the proposed amendment. The United States, acting with overwhelming bipartisan support in the Congress, was the first country to complete both of these steps. When participation has been certified by member countries having 75 percent of total IMF quotas, the new facility will be established in the Fund. Resolving the world liquidity problem requires actual creation of SDR's— a major step beyond legal establishment of the facility. The basic decisions lie ahead—namely when to activate the facility and in what amounts. These decisions will require collective judgment concerning the desired growth of world reserves and the portion of that growth which should take the form of Special Drawing Rights. THE NEED FOR RESERVE GROWTH The problem of estimating reserve needs has attracted much interest among economists and government officials in the last few years. The needed volume of reserves depends in part on the probable size of temporary balance-of-payments deficits which must be financed, because this affects the judgment of monetary authorities as to the amounts of reserves they need to hold. According to findings by the staff of the IMF, the magnitude of deficits requiring financing has tended to increase at the same rate as the volume of world transactions. This suggests that the prospective growth of world transactions might be a helpful guide to the required growth in reserves. Since trade in commodities makes up the largest portion of international transactions and is the one most reliably reported in statistics, it is useful as an indicator of trends. The historical relation between the growth of reserves and the growth of trade (measured by imports) is depicted in Chart 9. Between 1950 and 1968 imports increased 7.6 percent a year, while reserves grew at only 2.5 percent a year. Thus, in the aggregate, reserves declined quite substantially Chart 9 World Trade and Reserves BILLIONS OF DOLLARS (ratio scale) 200 ~ 150 WORLD TRADE (ANNUAL IMPORTS) 100 " 20 1950 52 54 56 58 60 62 64 66 68- .I/ESTIMATES BASED ON DATA FOR FIRST 3 QUARTERS. NOTE.-TRADE DURING YEAR, RESERVES AT END OF YEAR. DATA INCLUDE YUGOSLAVIA, BUT EXCLUDE U.S.S.R., OTHER EAST EUROPEAN COUNTRIES, MAINLAND CHINA, AND CUBA. SOURCE: INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND. in relation to imports, and probably in relation to the average size of deficits. These over-all results are, however, heavily influenced by the large net decline in reserves of the United States, the world's largest holder. The United States was able to give up these reserves because of its excess holdings at the beginning of the period. But this loss cannot continue. No other country now appears to have excess reserves sufficient to replace the United States as a willing and able net loser of reserves. The relationship between growth of reserves and growth of imports is significantly altered when the United States is excluded from world totals. Between 1950 and 1968, reserves of countries other than the United States grew 5.6 percent a year, on the average, while their imports grew at 7.8 percent. Some have suggested that reserves in the future should grow at essentially the same rate as world transactions—about 8 percent a year—to avoid any further decline in the ratio of average reserves to potential deficits. However, the world economy has been able to adapt to reductions in this ratio in the past. And a moderate further decline may be appropriate, both because countries should have increasing access to borrowed reserves and because 132 possible improvements in the adjustment process may reduce the need for reserves. Some guidance might be derived from the 5.6 percent growth rate of reserves experienced between 1950 and 1968 by countries other than the United States. In any case, a major increase from the very slow growth of the past 2 years is needed. Whatever the desired rate of growth of reserves, its achievement will depend mainly on the creation of Special Drawing Rights, since other components of total reserves, as noted above, are unlikely to expand significantly. While it is still too early to make a decision about the proper size of the initial issue of SDR's, amounts of $1 billion or $2 billion a year—which have been used as illustrative examples of SDR creation—appear to be inadequate. These amounts imply a rate of reserve growth of only about 1.4 to 2.8 percent. With such slow growth, the SDR facility might fail to achieve its objective of avoiding a destructive competition for reserves. THE CONFIDENCE PROBLEM Shifts in confidence can be reflected in two ways: through actions initiated in the private economy and through actions by governments. Private holders of liquid assets constantly adjust the composition of their holdings. When they decide to shift from the financial assets of one country to those of another—a process described for simplicity as shifting from one currency to another—either exchange rates or official reserve holdings or both are affected. In addition, shifts by private holders between currencies and gold can have an impact on monetary stability, although the significance of such shifts has been substantially altered by the gold accord reached in Washington in March 1968. PRIVATE SHIFTING AMONG CURRENCIES Some shifts by private holders out of one currency into another are merely responses to differentials in short term interest rates. Other shifts among currencies may be induced by the expectation of, or anxiety about, a change in exchange rates—and thus can be viewed as reflecting changes in confidence. Such speculative movements occur when the payments and reserve positions of some countries create significant uncertainties that exchange parities will remain fixed. Speculative capital flows can result from direct sales of the suspect currency for stronger ones, or through the operation of the so-called "leads and lags" mechanism, under which normal commercial disbursements denominated in foreign currency are accelerated while receipts denominated in domestic currency are delayed. (This was an important element in the 1968 French crisis.) A crisis of confidence can severely deplete the monetary reserves of a nation. Flows of this kind can be very large—up to $1 billion in a single day. Crises resulting from shifts of confidence have occurred from time to time. At different times in 1968, the Canadian dollar, the British pound, and the French franc were under downward pressures, and the German mark was subjected to upward pressures. As international businesses and financial institutions have matured, additional currencies have been brought into wide international use. Thus the number of currencies potentially subject to such crises has increased. It is quite appropriate that countries should borrow reserves, if necessary, to deal with temporary emergencies of this kind. The "swap network" has traditionally provided lines of credit among central banks for this purpose; it was expanded and enlarged during 1968. Further improvements could be made in central bank borrowing procedures through a proposal whereby speculative funds would be immediately "recycled"—returned to countries suffering losses from countries experiencing gains. Even if generous lines of short term credit are available, they leave countries vulnerable, because crises may be long lasting. Lenders or borrowers may be reluctant to renew loans, fearing overcommitment. Fortunately, in recent years, improvements in cooperation among the central banks and in the procedures of the IMF have reduced such fears. However generous borrowing facilities may be, they cannot deal fully with a crisis of private confidence that arises from a major disequilibrium in the underlying balance-of-payments position of a country. In such circumstances, prompt and decisive measures to achieve a basic adjustment are the key to the restoration of confidence. But the requirements for adequate adjustment are aggravated when a loss of confidence imposes a heavy drain on reserves. PRIVATE DEMAND FOR GOLD Private asset holders may respond to a loss of confidence in a currency by buying gold rather than other currencies, particularly when the choice of a "safe" foreign currency is not obvious. Gold speculation is rather common in many countries, although not in the United States where it is illegal. Private imports of gold can be an important channel for currency flight and thus become a claim on a country's reserves. Furthermore, because the price of gold in the private market is sometimes used by speculators as a barometer of confidence in currencies, increases in that price can intensify currency runs. While governments still retain some concern over private demands for gold, they are now much less directly involved than prior to March 1968. For the preceding 7 years, countries participating actively in the "gold pool" had stabilized the price of gold in the private market in London by buying and selling near the official price of $35 an ounce. In March 1968, these countries agreed to discontinue their activities. Prior to 1966, the pool was a net purchaser of gold, and the resulting additions of gold to monetary reserves strengthened the international monetary system. Subsequently, however, the pool became a substantial net 134 seller, parting with gold out of monetary stocks to keep the price from rising. Following British devaluation in late 1967, and in the early months of 1968, the volume of net gold sales became a serious drain on international monetary reserves. Moreover, the market took on a highly speculative tone. Several large and irregular waves of gold purchases had destabilizing domestic monetary effects in certain countries and transmitted speculative fever to foreign exchange markets. In March, the active gold pool countries agreed to cease selling gold in the private market, and agreed that purchases of gold from the private market were no longer necessary. They obtained the cooperation of other central banks in this decision. As a result, the international monetary system has been substantially insulated from the destabilizing effects of changes in the private demand for gold, and gold can no longer be drained from monetary stocks into private uses. SHIFTS AMONG OFFICIAL RESERVE ASSETS Problems may arise if monetary authorities decide to shift their holdings abruptly among the various reserve assets. They may shift for political or other reasons, but they are often motivated by changes in the relative degrees of confidence attaching to the future values of these assets. For example, if official holders, fearing a sterling devaluation, were to shift into dollars, the United Kingdom would be forced to give up some of its international reserves. Likewise, if official holders of dollars decided to convert them into gold, the United States would lose some of its reserves. Crises of confidence may feed on themselves; for example, a significant decline in U.K. reserves could further weaken the confidence of both official and private holders of sterling. Shifts out of officially held sterling by sterling area countries became a serious problem following the British devaluation of November 1967. The great majority of the sterling area countries did not devalue along with the British; thus the purchasing power of the reserves of sterling holders was reduced in terms of their own currencies as well as in dollars. This loss led to a movement toward reserve diversification which became particularly pronounced in the spring of 1968. In recognition that the burden of such reserve diversification should not be borne by the British alone, 12 industrial countries, including the United States, together with the Bank for International Settlements, set up a new $2 billion loan facility in September 1968. It was designed to provide finance to Britain to replace reserves lost as a result of the decline of sterling balances within the sterling area. The BIS will act as an intermediary and will obtain the required funds by borrowing in international markets, by accepting reserve deposits from central banks of the sterling area, and by calling upon standby lines of credit provided by the cooperating countries. The United Kingdom has given a dollar-value guarantee to the sterling area on eligible official sterling reserves, and the sterling-area countries in return have undertaken to maintain an agreed proportion of their reserves in sterling. The new facility should go far toward moderating the sterling diversification problem. Some observers have pointed to the possibility of large-scale conversions of dollars into gold by central banks. The likelihood of such an abrupt shift of preferences must, however, be viewed in perspective. There are several reasons why countries choose to hold dollars. Dollars are useful because they can be readily employed in exchange markets and are more easily put to use in emergencies than gold. Countries recognize that they can convert dollars to gold as they see fit, although they may at times refrain from gold conversions through a cooperative desire not to weaken the international monetary system by reducing total world reserves. Dollars—unlike gold— earn interest, and the efficient American money and capital markets make investment easy. Thus there is and should continue to be a strong demand for dollars by central banks. Some central banks have a preference—arising mainly from tradition—in favor of gold as a reserve asset. They often appear unconcerned about earning interest on reserves, perhaps because their income is usually turned over to their national treasuries. When dollars are acquired by countries with a preference for gold from countries with a preference for currencies as reserves, conversions into gold may occur. This could happen even with no increase in total dollars held abroad and no shift in general sentiment toward gold or away from the dollar. Furthermore, as world reserves grow, there would be a demand for added gold if countries attempted to maintain their "traditional" ratios of gold to total reserves. However, countries recognize that gold will decline as a proportion of total world reserves. And as the SDR agreement indicated, they seem prepared collectively to adjust the composition of their reserve holdings. Preferences that now exist among sterling, dollars, and gold could become more complicated as SDR's are added, thereby creating further possibilities for shifts in the composition of reserves. Certain safeguards, however, were provided in the plan: the power given the IMF to direct SDR's to various holders was designed to prevent inadvertent destabilizing shifts from SDR's into other types of reserves. Furthermore, additional SDR's could be created to offset world reserve losses arising from shifts among reserve assets. PROPOSALS FOR IMPROVING RESERVE MANAGEMENT It has been suggested that agreement on mutually acceptable rules of reserve management might help to avoid destabilizing changes in reserve composition. If deficit countries used each of their reserve assets in proportion to its share in their total holdings, and if surplus countries were 136 willing to accept and hold different types of reserves in the exact proportions made available, the system would be internally consistent. Before such rules could be endorsed, their workings would need to be examined and agreed upon in detail. A more sweeping suggested reform would be to eliminate the differences among reserve assets. Countries could combine all their reserves by depositing them in a joint account, which would be drawn upon when reserves were used. Such a scheme was discussed in the September 1968 Report of the Subcommittee on International Exchange and Payments, of the Joint Economic Committee (JEC) of the Congress. In an examination of proposals of this kind, many questions arise which would require careful study: What would be the role of the United States? Would participation be voluntary or compulsory? Would countries be permitted to withdraw from the pool? In view of the progress already made in dealing with world liquidity and in strengthening international cooperation, how urgent is such a major reform? THE ADJUSTMENT PROBLEM The Bretton Woods system was designed to correct the weaknesses in the international monetary system that were apparent in the interwar years. Faced with domestic economic collapse during the 1930's, some countries attempted, by deliberately undervaluing their currencies, to stimulate exports, retard imports, and thus add to employment. But one country's gain was another country's loss. Competitive devaluations, and restrictions on exchange and trade, imposed a heavy toll on international commerce. The postwar economy was built upon the general understanding that full employment would be the target of national economic policies, and that this goal would be sought primarily through domestic monetary and fiscal policies. It was also expected that excessive price increases would normally be avoided. In the absence of both chronic deflation and chronic inflation, continuous balance-of-payments problems were viewed as unlikely. The IMF was to help in the adjustment process by granting credit to allow countries time to adjust without parity changes. Provisions were included to put pressure on surplus countries to take an appropriate part in the adjustment process—for example, the "scarce currency" clause, which permits discrimination in trade against persistent surplus countries whose currencies are formally declared to be scarce. Under these conditions, a system of stable exchange rates was expected to operate successfully and to stimulate international trade and capital movements, while removing the temptation for governments to solve domestic problems by external means. Although pegged parities were made the normal operating rule of the system, provision was also made for changing parities to correct fundamental disequilibria. The meaning of "fundamental disequilibrium" was not fully clarified, but the expectation at the time was that changes in parities would not be unusual. Actually, parity changes for developed countries have been 137 rare. In part, this is because major countries have been reasonably successful in avoiding excesses of inflation and deflation; but it also reflects concern about the serious economic and political consequences of changes in the parities of major currencies, including the possibility of a worldwide chain reaction. Furthermore, greater freedom for international capital transactions has complicated the process of changing parities. CAUSES OF DISTURBANCES Despite the real accomplishments of stabilization policies, the international economy has been subject to disturbances. Some have been caused by the relatively mild cyclical fluctuations that have occurred, and others by differences among countries in long term trends of prices, economic growth, technological advance, and import demand. Countries differ with respect to the maximum rate of price increase—or the maximum volume of idle resources—that they view as tolerable. In general, a country incurring price increases greater than the average of other countries will find its exports becoming less competitive and its domestic market more accessible to imports. Countries which grow particularly rapidly tend to experience stronger increases in imports (although they may simultaneously improve the competitive position of their exports). Or a country may experience long term deterioration in its external position if its demand for imports is more responsive to income growth than is the demand for its exports. These factors, singly and in combination, have led to some serious imbalances. Adjustment problems may also reflect, in part, an insufficient growth of global reserves. When over-all reserves are growing only slowly, there can be acute pressures on deficit countries to adjust. At the same time, surplus countries may find that their reserves are not accumulating too rapidly; hence they may have little incentive to correct their imbalances. A world shortage of reserves could particularly complicate the adjustment problem of the United States, subjecting it to intense pressures from other countries in weak payments positions or from countries not satisfied with their reserve holdings. The United States might literally be prevented from correcting its balance-of-payments deficit, because every improvement in the U.S. position would cause some other countries to take protective actions to counter any weakening of their own positions. There are a number of means open to a country for correcting balanceof-payments disequilibria without altering its exchange rate. These means differ in speed, in effectiveness, and in their side effects. They include internal measures such as fiscal and monetary policies, together with supporting incomes, manpower, and regional policies; and direct measures affecting international movements of goods, services, or capital. INTERNAL ADJUSTMENTS Often the domestic policies which would contribute to balance-of-payments adjustments are also desirable for domestic reasons. Thus if a country 138 faces a balance-of-payments deficit and rapidly rising prices, it should follow tighter monetary and fiscal measures, supported by incomes policy to help restrain wages and prices, both to improve its trade balance and to curb inflation. Indeed, one argument sometimes made in favor of a system of fixed exchange rates is that balance-of-payments deficits stiffen the resolve of governments to achieve price stability. Conversely, if high levels of unemployment are accompanied by payments surpluses, expansionary domestic policies are clearly indicated. However, a country may face a balance-of-payments deficit at a time when domestic demand is not excessive. It will then be understandably reluctant to attack its payments problem by restrictive monetary and fiscal policies. The opposite problem may arise if a payments surplus occurs when the domestic situation calls for anti-inflationary policies. While the situations of surplus and deficit countries are symmetrical, incentives to adjust may not be equally strong in the two cases. There is no definite limit on the accumulation of reserves, so surplus countries often are under little pressure to restore equilibrium. But for deficit countries whose freedom of action is constrained by a limited supply of reserves, pressures to take corrective action may become inexorable. If real progress is to be made in achieving a better balance of world payments, it is crucial that surplus countries participate in the adjustment process, as was indicated in the 1966 Report on the Balance of Payments Adjustment Process by Working Party No. 3 of OECD. Changes in the Policy Mix There are some opportunities to mitigate conflicts between international and domestic goals by altering the mix of monetary and fiscal policies. By influencing interest rates, monetary policies have direct effects on capital flows as well as on domestic demand. If a country has a balance-of-payments deficit and a satisfactory or inadequate level of domestic demand, fiscal policy may be eased and monetary policy simultaneously tightened. This combination can, in principle, avoid any reduction of internal demand, and capture the benefits of tighter money in reducing capital outflows or attracting foreign capital. Thus it may be possible to improve the balance of payments without adding to unemployment. The reverse combination of policies may be used by countries facing the surplus-inflation dilemma. While changes in the mix of monetary and fiscal policy have significant possibilities, and they can be reinforced by appropriate incomes and manpower policies, such adjustments cannot always be relied upon as an escape from major conflicts in objectives. Some of the balance-of-payments gains resulting from interest rate adjustments may be temporary. A change in interest rates may initially cause investors to make large adjustments in the composition of their existing portfolios of financial assets. Once this initial stock adjustment is completed, however, further gains from this source may be quite small. 139 There are limits on the willingness of countries to alter the mix of monetary and fiscal policies. A deficit country may hesitate to raise interest rates, fearing that such a move would deter capital formation and thereby curtail the improvement in productivity that may be a basic solution to its balance-of-payments difficulties. Or high interest rates may be objectionable because of their uneven impact on the domestic economy. Or a growing level of foreign indebtedness may be undesirable because it will increase the burden of service payments. Finally, increases in domestic interest rates may lead to higher interest rates abroad. In that event, the differentials between foreign and domestic rates may diminish, weakening the impact on capital flows. In the absence of international coordination of monetary policies, efforts by deficit countries to tighten credit may lead to a worldwide escalation of interest rates. This may not only impede the immediate objectives of the deficit countries but may also dampen world economic growth. Clearly, the adjustment mechanism could benefit from a continued strengthening of international cooperation in this area of policy. Thus there are often important limitations on the practical scope for adjustments in the monetary-fiscal mix as a means of reconciling domestic and international objectives. One important principle stands out. In a country with a serious balance-of-payments problem, the use of monetary policy for expansionary domestic purposes may be severely constrained; and primary reliance may therefore have to be placed on fiscal policy to pursue stabilization objectives. In the United States and in many other countries, this implies the need for greater speed and flexibility in the implementation of fiscal measures. MEASURES DIRECTLY AFFECTING INTERNATIONAL TRANSACTIONS In the OECD Adjustment Process report, it was recognized that fiscal and monetary policies, no matter how skillfully combined, cannot always be relied upon as the exclusive means of balance-of-payments adjustment. Given the many goals of economic policy, numerous instruments are needed. Under some circumstances, the report suggests the use of measures directly affecting international transactions. Most countries do make use of specific measures affecting trade or capital movements as part of their adjustment. These policies may help to reconcile domestic and international objectives. Such measures as import duties or quotas, export subsidies, changes in border taxes, and taxes and prohibitions on international capital movements offer opportunities for improving the payments balance while avoiding major effects on the domestic economy. Some of these measures, such as special tariffs and export subsidies, are prohibited by the GATT, but their use has at times been sanctioned, implicitly or explicitly, so long as they were considered temporary. Likewise, exchange controls on current transactions are generally discouraged for 140 countries accepting the full obligations of convertibility in the IMF, but specific authorizations have been granted under emergency conditions. Trade Measures The only trade measure explicitly condoned by the GATT for safeguarding the balance of payments is the use of temporary quantitative restrictions. Quotas on imports can be a very powerful instrument. But they can be very disruptive of normal commercial arrangements, troublesome to impose and administer, and difficult to abandon. Over the last few years, developed countries have shown a growing preference for the use of import surcharges, export subsidies, or combinations of the two. At times, countries change their normal pattern of tax adjustments at the border in an attempt to promote balance-of-payments equilibrium. When a deficit country is taking only partial advantage of its opportunity under the GATT to make border adjustments for domestic indirect taxes, it can help itself by moving to full compensation. However, such action by a surplus country conflicts with the policies that should be followed for balance-of-payments adjustment. For example, on January 1 and July 1, 1968, in conjunction with an internal tax reform, the German government raised its rate of border adjustment. This tended to increase the German merchandise surplus—much as a small devaluation of the mark would have done—and at a time when Germany's balance-of-payments position was very strong indeed. Another example of a change in a domestic tax which permitted an increase in border adjustments was the action taken by the French government in November 1968. A rise in value-added taxes, which are eligible under the GATT for border adjustments, was substituted for the existing payroll tax, which was not eligible. In this case, the aim of the increase in border adjustments was to help restore over-all payments equilibrium. Also in November, the German government reduced by 4 percentage points its border charge on most imports and its tax rebate on most exports, without any corresponding domestic tax changes. This measure was taken deliberately to reduce the large German trade surplus and had effects somewhat similar to an upward valuation of the mark. When countries resort to trade measures to affect their balance-of-payments positions, efforts should be made to minimize distortions. General import charges imposed by themselves favor production for the domestic market, thus shrinking the volume of international trade, while general export grants alone unduly favor production for export. When general import charges are combined with general export grants at the same rate, these two tendencies offset each other, with no more distortion of merchandise trade than would result from a devaluation. Even such a uniform and general combination of import charges and export grants would distort the choice between merchandise transactions and other international flows, such as tourism. Furthermore, serious misalloca141 323-166 0—69 10 tions could occur if exemptions were given individual industries or classes of products. Finally, even under the best of circumstances, temporary trade measures may in practice become embedded and thus should be used with great caution. Nevertheless, this approach may be useful under some conditions. It should be explored further to determine whether proper safeguards can be established to ensure that equal use is made by surplus and deficit countries, and that the goals of liberal commercial policy are maintained. Capital Account Measures All major countries take actions at times to influence international capital flows. The techniques employed range from special incentives for domestic investment to exchange controls and capital issues committees. There is some rationale for concentrating on the capital account, since fewer basic adjustments in the allocation of real resources are required by shifts in financial flows than by changes in trade. And measures to influence the capital account are generally more easily reversed in response to shifting balanceof-payments fortunes. Sometimes, however, restraints on capital movements develop into a patchwork of controls that involve major administrative difficulties, bear down unevenly and inefficiently on different types of capital flows, and create a search for loopholes. The distortions can be reduced to the extent that restraints can be applied more equally among categories of capital flows and interference can be minimized within any particular category. There may be opportunities to make greater use of the price system by applying variable taxes to capital flows or by auctioning permits to export capital. While the allocation of capital might be improved and administrative burdens eased by innovations in the techniques of controlling capital flows, any system of major restraints is bound to be far from ideal. The possible need for temporary direct measures on the capital account must be recognized, but so should the long term benefits of greater freedom in capital flows among nations. THE ADJUSTMENT PROBLEM OF THE UNITED STATES The difficulties of balance-of-payments adjustment for deficit countries are evident from the recent experience of the United States. In the early 1960's, the United States was faced with a payments deficit at a time when its economy was operating far below capacity. The causes of the deficit were numerous. The United States was shouldering an extraordinarily large share of the burden of providing for the security of the Free World and of supplying aid to less developed countries. The United States possessed the only large and sophisticated capital market in which foreigners could borrow freely, and the European countries had advanced to the point where they desired capital and could attract it. Moreover, because of Europe's general economic progress and the formation of the EEC and the European Free Trade Association, American companies 142 had developed an intense interest in making direct investments there. Finally, the U.S. competitive position had deteriorated during the 1950's. The Over-All Strategy In the early 1960's, U.S. domestic needs called for expansionary policies, while traditional balance-of-payments remedies would have required greater restraint on demand. To reconcile this conflict, a mixed strategy was followed. It emphasized those elements in the domestic expansion which tended to improve international competitiveness, together with specific measures of a temporary nature to influence the external position. The selection of balance-of-payments measures reflected several concerns: the determination to maintain, as far as possible, liberal policies with respect to international trade and capital flows; the desire not to shift problems to countries in a weak balance-of-payments position; and the need to maintain the stability of the international monetary system, which was so crucially dependent on the dollar. Further difficulties in designing appropriate balance-of-payments measures arose from uncertainty over how much correction was needed, from the unpredictability of the immediate quantitative impact of particular actions, and from the large and uncertain "feedback" effects inherent in the large size of the United States. Some policies were clearly desirable on all counts, such as improving knowledge with respect to export prospects, trimming unnecessary government expenditures abroad, encouraging other industrial countries to give larger amounts of aid to less developed countries, pressing for a more equitable sharing of military burdens, and removing a tax penalty on foreigners trading in American securities. Reducing the Impact of Government Activities A further group of measures to reduce the foreign exchange costs of U.S. military and foreign aid required more difficult decisions. In principle, savings of foreign exchange in the military area could have been pursued through three alternative strategies: (1) reducing the level of security, (2) obtaining increased contributions of military forces from other countries, or (3) reducing, offsetting, or neutralizing the foreign exchange costs of a maintained level of U.S. military effort. The first alternative was ruled out. The second was pursued but with little immediate prospect of success. Thus the third became the approach emphasized in the short run. Domestic producers were given a preference over foreigners in supplying defense needs, at some added cost to the Federal budget. Foreign governments were urged to purchase more of their military equipment in the United States. In recent years, special U.S. Treasury bonds have been sold to countries to neutralize their balance-of-payments inflows from U.S. military expenditures. Reducing the foreign exchange costs of U.S. aid presented an equally difficult choice. Either the amount of foreign aid had to be reduced, or a 143 method had to be found to ensure that more of the money provided by the United States was spent in this country. The second alternative—aid-tying— was chosen. This tended to reduce the effectiveness of a given dollar amount of aid, but the alternative of slashing the volume of aid would have been even more costly to recipient countries. Restraining Capital Outflows While gains were obtained through these measures in the early sixties, the over-all payments problem was intensified by a major increase in private capital outflows. Faced with an apparently insatiable demand for capital abroad, the United States had the choice of raising domestic interest rates enough to price foreigners out of our market, of taxing foreign loans specifically, or of using direct controls to stop capital outflows. The first alternative was inconsistent with domestic needs for economic expansion. The second alternative was chosen when the Interest Equalization Tax (IET) was proposed in 1963. It substantially reduced foreign portfolio investments by Americans, except new security issues from Canada and investments in less developed countries, which were exempted. But demand for capital shifted to American banks, so the IET was extended to longer term loans of banks. Other types of bank loans and direct investment were not covered by the tax, and these forms of capital outflow kept expanding. In response to a large outflow of capital at the end of 1964, voluntary programs were initiated in February 1965 to cover the major remaining capital flows. The American corporations which were large direct investors were asked to help by reducing their capital expenditures abroad, by relying on foreign financing for a greater share of their investments, or by expanding reflows of dividends to the United States. Banks and other financial institutions were meanwhile asked to follow guidelines established by the Federal Reserve Board which suggested quantitative limits on foreign lending. Most, if not all, of these measures have been successful in achieving the objectives for which they were designed. The basic balance-of-payments position improved through 1964 and 1965, and the liquidity deficit was sharply reduced. Further progress was interrupted in 1966 by the mounting foreign exchange costs associated with the war in Vietnam and by the reduced trade surplus resulting from overly rapid domestic expansion. Because the U.S. external position deteriorated sharply late in 1967 and the stability of the international monetary system seemed in serious danger, a new set of measures was proposed by the President on January 1, 1968. This program included mandatory restrictions on foreign direct investment, further tightening of the guidelines on lending by banks and other financial institutions, and various other steps to reduce the deficit. The program was successful. As noted in Chapter 1, the balance of payments has improved. In particular, American direct investors have managed to finance a 144 much greater proportion of their investments abroad by foreign borrowing, and there has been a net reduction in U.S. bank credit to the rest of the world. With the exception of more timely action to assure adequate domestic restraint in recent years, it is hard to see, even in retrospect, any preferable strategies in U.S. policies to correct the deficit. The eclectic, ad hoc measures that were taken involved certain costs. But they maintained the strength of the dollar and the health of the world economy. More basic improvements lie ahead—pending peace and the restoration of price stability. EXCHANGE RATE ADJUSTMENTS An efficient international adjustment mechanism should permit countries to choose their own domestic economic targets for growth, employment, and price-cost performance. Policies that restore balance at home should not lead to pressures on the international accounts—in the form of either excessive accumulation or rapid depletion of reserves. Suggestions have been put forward for amending the adjustment mechanism to lessen the conflict between domestic and balance-of-payments objectives. It is claimed by some that greater reliance on changes in exchange rates would work in this direction. PRESENT SYSTEM Present IMF rules provide for adjustments of exchange parities as a means of correcting a fundamental disequilibrium. In practice, however, the process of exchange rate adjustment may involve major difficulties; and in consequence, there is often extreme reluctance to change exchange rates even when balance-of-payments difficulties are severe. To illustrate, the currency of a country with a large and persistent deficit will become widely recognized as a candidate for devaluation and this may touch off a crisis in private confidence, as discussed above. Speculation based on the prospect of devaluation will aggravate the initial balance-of-payments difficulties and increase the outflow of reserves. To discourage such speculation, governments tend to make categorical assertions that devaluation is not being considered; once such assertions have been made, it becomes a matter of national pride and political reputation to maintain the parity. Furthermore, an actual adjustment in an exchange rate may generate the expectation of a further change; once an exchange parity has been adjusted, a second adjustment seems less unthinkable. Fear of such a perverse reaction may cause a country to depreciate by an excessive amount in the first instance. This may lead other countries to devalue also, thus reducing the potential balance-of-payments gain of the initiating country. Such a chain reaction can severely disrupt foreign exchange markets. Thus the difficulties *45 associated with parity adjustments have at times driven countries to commit themselves to existing parities in all but the most extreme situations. PROPOSALS FOR EXCHANGE RATE FLEXIBILITY A number of suggestions—ranging from minor adjustments to far-reaching changes—have been made for altering the current exchange rate arrangements of the IMF. The most sweeping change, advocated primarily by some academic economists, would be to abandon the pegged exchange system in favor of "floating rates," completely free to fluctuate in response to market forces. In contrast, other proposals call for a modest widening of the existing 1 percent limit on fluctuations of rates on either side of parity. Still another type of proposal would provide for small but frequent changes in parities. Each of the proposals is intended to make adjustments in exchange rates a more acceptable and effective means of correcting payments imbalances, and to reduce the speculative disturbances that sometimes develop under the present system. Opinions differ widely over the probable effects of the various proposals; intensive study would be required before serious consideration could be given to the adoption of any of them. The dramatic advances in world trade and prosperity achieved under the present system provide a strong case for conservatism in considering innovations; at the same time, the recurrence of financial strains has aroused widespread interest in possible amendments to the system. In general, the wider the latitude for changes in exchange rates, the greater would be the amount of adjustment provided; but also the greater would be the uncertainty of those engaged in international commerce and the possibility of a disturbance to trade and investment relationships. Floating Rates While a system of floating exchange rates would ensure essentially automatic adjustment to balance-of-payments disturbances, serious questions arise about its operation. Advocates of flexible exchange rates are divided on whether official intervention in exchange markets should be permitted. A complete ban on official intervention would be a very radical change, obviating any need for central banks to hold international reserves. Exchange rates might fluctuate quite widely, causing substantial uncertainty. If, on the other hand, official intervention were permitted under a system of floating rates, it might smooth out transitory fluctuations in exchange rates, but it would open up the danger of exchange rate manipulation. For example, a government might wish to drive down the price of its currency in order to strengthen the competitive position of its exports. It is difficult to devise rules which would permit desirable smoothing and yet ban manipulation. 146 In general, fluctuating exchange rates would require shifts of resources among industries that export, those that compete with imports, and others, as relative prices in world markets reflected changes in exchange rates. Moreover, uncertainty about future exchange rates would concern international traders and investors. They could obtain some insurance by entering forward exchange markets, buying or selling foreign currencies at definite prices for delivery at some specified future date. But such forward transactions might be quite expensive and thus add to the costs of world trade. Furthermore, international investors might not be able to satisfy their needs for protection in forward exchange markets, given the long time horizon of many capital transactions. Advocates of floating exchange rates believe that the benefits outweigh the costs of these uncertainties. They point out that uncertainty about exchange rates is not unique to a system of floating rates. Indeed, no feasible international system can guarantee against exchange rate adjustments. Moreover, they emphasize that international businessmen live with many uncertainties, both political and commercial. Finally, it is their contention—not universally accepted—that, under floating rates, there would be an easing of pressures for exchange controls and trade barriers. The adoption of floating exchange rates would constitute a drastic change in the international monetary system. If the present system were functioning very badly and if no other possibility of reform were available, there might be a compelling argument for adopting this one; but such is not the case. Wider Bands Under present arrangements, day-to-day market pressures can be reflected in small fluctuations of each exchange rate within a narrow band. Central banks of countries other than the United States intervene in the market by buying and selling foreign exchange to keep the dollar prices of their currencies within 1 percent or less of established parities. The United States rounds out the system by selling and buying gold in dealings with central banks at $35 an ounce. Proposals have been made by the JEC Subcommittee on International Payments and by others to introduce greater flexibility of rates by widening the permissible band of fluctuation around the par value. With a band of 2 percent on either side of parity, the exchange rate between two nondollar currencies could change by as much as 8 percent. Suggestions for a wider band, like other proposals for greater flexibility in exchange rates, are not directed at the official price of gold. The latter is not an exchange rate. There is no need whatsoever for it to be altered to accommodate greater flexibility of exchange rates. A widening of exchange rate bands could contribute to the adjustment process. The currency of a country with an incipient deficit would fall in price, thus making imports more expensive and lowering the cost of exports 147 to buyers in world markets. Imports would be discouraged and exports stimulated, strengthening the balance of payments. If the exchange rate approached the floor with its future course expected to be upward, the stimulus might be particularly strong; there would be an incentive to take advantage of the temporary low price of the country's exports. Advocates of a wider band believe that it might deter speculative runs in two ways. First, the additional adjustment permitted by the wider band might make discrete changes in parities appear less likely, thus reducing uncertainty. Second, a wider band would increase the potential loss on a "wrong bet" against a currency. Under the present narrow band, the speculator has relatively little to lose if he bets against a currency and it is not in fact devalued. With a wider band, the risk of loss would be increased, because a currency that was initially under pressure could experience a larger rebound in price. There is, however, no concrete basis for estimating the extent to which these features would deter speculation. The wider the band is made, the greater the potential uncertainty about the course of exchange rates, but also the greater the amount of balance-ofpayments adjustment which may take place within the band. In an evaluation of a wider band, these conflicting considerations would have to be weighed in determining its optimum width. A very wide band comes close to a floating exchange rate and thus shares the shortcomings of this drastic reform. A small widening of the band, on the other hand, might not markedly reduce the need for, and the expectation of, discrete changes in parity. Gradual Adjustment of Parities The evolution toward greater exchange rate flexibility could involve a gradual, limited adjustment of exchange parties. Two forms of the so-called "crawling peg" have been proposed, one discretionary and one automatic. Under the discretionary variant, a country in disequilibrium would no longer make one substantial change in its parity, but rather would announce a rate of increase (or decrease) in its parity of some specified small percentage per month, until further notice. Once the desired effect had been attained, the country would halt the process. This might make the transition to an equilibrium parity easier, and perhaps curb speculation. Its effect on the political obstacles to changes in parities is not entirely clear; governments might find it just as painful to announce a parity change in a series of small steps as in a single abrupt one. The discretionary crawling peg might therefore be used no more frequently than the present "adjustable peg." The automatic form of gradual adjustment would remove parities from the direct control of individual countries. Under one variant, the parity on any business day would be the average of the actual exchange rates over the preceding 12 months (or some other suitable period). The actual exchange rate would be within a band around the parity prevailing on that 148 day, with official intervention permitted only at the floor or ceiling. For a period of 1 year and a band of 1 percent, the largest possible change in the parity—attained only if a currency were continuously at its floor or ceiling—would be 2 percent a year. Larger or smaller potential changes could be permitted by adopting a different period for calculating the moving average, or by altering the width of the band. Again an optimum choice would depend upon the importance of certainty about future exchange rates, on the one hand, and on the speed of balance-of-payments adjustment to be permitted through the crawling peg, on the other. Unlike fully flexible rates, the crawling peg would not be intended to offset all cyclical and random fluctuations in international transactions; but, unlike a widening of the band, it would permit sizable changes in exchange rates over the long run. Thus it could cope with the problem of modest trends in the equilibrium values of currencies resulting from divergent national trends of prices, economic growth, export supply, import demand, or investment flows. It might seem that, if a currency showed fundamental weakness and was therefore expected to move downward for an extended period, speculation would become a problem because of the predictability of the exchange rate movement. This kind of speculation could, in principle, be avoided by raising interest rates above the otherwise prevailing level by an amount equal to the anticipated rate of downward crawl of the currency. The exchange gain from moving out of the currency would then be offset by the loss of interest. Such changes in interest rates might, however, necessitate offsetting adjustments in fiscal policy and, as discussed earlier, marked changes in the policy mix are sometimes difficult to achieve. Limits on tolerable interest rate changes would thus be one constraint on the speed of parity adjustment which could be permitted in such a system. The various proposed modifications in the exchange rate system raise many difficult technical issues, and clearly a proper evaluation of these proposals must be preceded by a great deal of careful study. CONCLUSION By far the most important attribute of the postwar international economy has been steady and rapid growth. The spectacular nature of recent international monetary disturbances should not obscure the mighty contribution that the international economic system has made to world prosperity. Worldwide flows of goods and investments have been the cornerstones on which the prosperity of many nations has rested; at the same time, the growth of national economies has made possible the tremendous increases in world trade and international investment. Trade is the center of the international economic system, and it cannot prosper in the face of highly restrictive national policies. Only a continuous 149 chipping away at tariffs and other trade barriers can provide assurance against backsliding. Pressures for protection must be successfully resisted. The fruits of unprecedented prosperity are still not being fully shared by many nations in Africa, Asia, the Middle East, and Latin America. The future growth of these nations must be built primarily on the skills, intelligence, and labor of their citizens. But the developed countries must facilitate the process by providing technical assistance, capital resources, and access to markets. The international monetary system established at Bretton Woods and developed through the years has made a major contribution to international economic growth. This system has served the world well, but it has increasingly been subject to serious strains. To ensure the continuing smooth operation of the monetary system, work must go forward on the problems of liquidity, confidence, and adjustment. Great progress has been made in recent years as exemplified by the agreement creating Special Drawing Rights. This achievement required careful study and long negotiations. Similar extensive efforts will be needed in the future if progress is to be maintained, but the prospects for eventual success are bright. 150 Chapter 5 Combating Poverty in a Prosperous Economy . . . the policy of the United States [is] to eliminate the paradox of poverty in the midst of plenty in this Nation by opening to everyone the opportunity for education and training, the opportunity to work, and the opportunity to live in decency and dignity. F OR OVER 4 YEARS the United States has had an explicit national commitment to eliminate poverty in our society, a commitment enunciated by the President in the State of the Union Message of 1964 and confirmed by the Congress in the above words later that year in the Fconomic Opportunity Act. Americans are increasingly prosperous. Median family income in the United States (in constant 1967 prices) rose from $6,210 in 1959 to $7,974 in 1967, a gain of 28 percent in 8 years. Yet many families are still not able to attain minimum living standards. A preliminary estimate indicates that in 1968 about 22 million people lived in households with incomes below the "poverty line." While this is far fewer than in the past— more than 40 million were similarly situated in 1960—too many Americans remain poor. This chapter examines the recent progress in reducing poverty, the nature of the task that remains, and the strategies available for eliminating poverty. THE EXTENT OF POVERTY A family is "poor" if its income is insufficient to buy enough food, clothing, shelter, and health services to meet minimum requirements. Universally acceptable standards for determining these minimum needs are impossible to formulate since the line between physical necessities and amenities is imprecise. The social and psychological aspects of poverty further complicate efforts to measure poverty. As average incomes rise, society amends its assessment of basic needs. Individuals who cannot afford more than a small fraction of the items enjoyed by the majority are likely to feel deprived. Consequently, an absolute standard that seems appropriate today will inevitably be rejected tomorrow, just as we now reject poverty definitions appropriate a century ago. DEFINITION OF POVERTY Even a rough measure of progress in reducing poverty requires an explicit definition, although the line drawn is unavoidably arbitrary. In its 1964 Annual Report, the Council used a poverty line of $3,000 annual family income. Since 1965, the Council has employed the more refined definition of poverty developed by the Social Security Administration (SSA). The SSA poverty lines reflect the differing consumption requirements of families based on their size and composition, the age of members, and whether their residence is farm or nonfarm. The calculations center around the U.S. Department of Agriculture's Economy Food Plan, which in December 1967 added up to a per capita weekly food outlay of $4.90. For families of three or more, the SSA measure assumes all other family needs can be obtained for an amount equal to twice the family's food requirement. In 1967, the nonfarm poverty threshold for an average four-person family was $3,335 as compared to a median income, for families of that size, of $8,995. Poverty lines for different types of households are shown in Table 14. The problems of low-income families neither begin nor end at any arbitrary poverty line. A sharp decline in poverty may be a misleading indicator TABLE 14.—Poverty and near-poverty income lines, 1967 Poverty income line Household characteristic^ Near-poverty income line Nonfarm households: 1 member. . . $1,635 $1,985 1,565 1,685 1,890 2,045 2,115 2,855 1,970 2,185 2,655 2,945 . -.. 2,600 3,335 3 930 4,410 5,430 3 425 4,345 5 080 5,700 6,945 1,145 1,390 . 1,095 1,195 1,330 1,450 1,475 1,990 1,380 1,535 1,870 2,075 1,815 2,345 2,755 3,090 3,790 2,400 3,060 3,565 3,995 4,850 65 years and over Under 65 years 2 members... Head 65 years and over Head under 65 years . 3 4 5 6 7 . . . members members... members members . members or more . Farm households: 1 member 65 years and over . Under 65 years . . . . . . . . . 2 members Head 65 years and over Head under 65 years 3 4 5 6 7 members members members members members or more 1 -.. Households are defined here as the total of families and unrelated individuals. Note.—Poverty and near-poverty income standards are defined by the Social Security Administration; they take into account family size, composition, and place of residence. Income lines are adjusted to take account of price changes during the year. Source: Department of Health, Education, and Welfare. of progress if a large number of families are raised just above the poverty line. Accordingly, the SSA has also developed a "near poor" standard averaging about one-third higher than the poverty line but still less than one-half of median income for many types of families. Near-poor income standards are shown in Table 14. The SSA poverty definitions have some limitations. Since they are multiples of food costs, the poverty lines change only when food prices change, and these prices do not necessarily parallel the prices of other essentials. Regional differences in living costs are not reflected in the poverty line. The income data take no account of income in kind such as health care, subsidized housing, and foodstuffs (except for food grown on farms). No adjustment is made for either net assets or fluctuating incomes, and yet families with savings or temporary income interruptions have different problems than the chronically poor. These problems are currently under study in an effort to refine the poverty concept. A different threshold could affect the distribution of measured poverty among various groups but would probably show much the same trend in total poverty over the long run. POVERTY TRENDS With the general rise in family incomes in the postwar period, the incidence of poverty—the percentage of persons in poor households relative to the total population—has declined sharply from 30 to less than 12 percent (see Chart 10). The number of persons in poverty declined about 20 million over the past 20 years, including a drop of 12 million since 1963—an estimated 4 million in 1968 alone. Along with the reduction in the number of poor households, the "poverty gap"—the difference between the actual incomes of the poor and the incomes necessary to place them above the poverty line—has been reduced. The poverty gap fell from $13.7 billion in 1959 to $9.7 billion in 1967, measured in current dollars. Distribution by Community Type The incidence of poverty is highest—23 percent—in those rural areas not in metropolitan counties, with the heaviest concentrations in the South and Appalachia. The incidence is also quite high—19 percent—in the smaller cities and towns outside of major metropolitan areas. In the central cities, the incidence is 16 percent and in their suburbs about 9 percent. Racial and Ethnic Distribution Most of the poor are white. In 1967 (the latest year for which detailed data on the poor are available), 71 percent of all poor families and 83 percent of all poor unrelated individuals were white. The incidence of poverty Chart 10 Number of Poor Persons and Incidence of Poverty MILLIONS OF PERSONS PERCENT 50 - 50 V NUMBER OF POOR PERSONS 40 - 40 30 - 30 • \ _ _ 7 20 - 20 INCIDENCE OF POVERTY J / (Right scale) ^ 10 - - I 0 1948 50 I I 52 I 54 I I 56 I I I 58 I 60 I I I 62 I 64 I I I 66 10 I 68 -I/POOR PERSONS AS PERCENT OF TOTAL NONINSTITUTIONAL POPULATION. N0TE._P0VERTY IS DEFINED BY THE SOCIAL SECURITY ADMINISTRATION POVERTY-INCOME STANDARD. SOURCES: DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE, DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH, EDUCATION, AND WELFARE, OFFICE OF ECONOMIC OPPORTUNITY, AND COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS. is far higher among nonwhites: about one household in three compared with about one in seven among whites. Of the 2.4 million nonwhite households in poverty, 2.3 million are Negroes; the remainder are mostly the original Americans—Indians and Eskimos. A 1964 survey revealed that 74 percent of the 55,000 families living on Indian and Eskimo reservations had incomes under $3,000. Only recently has the reduction of poverty among nonwhites matched the reduction among whites. Between 1959 and 1962, the number of whites in poverty declined 2.8 million, but during the same period the number of poor nonwhites rose by 0.9 million. Between 1962 and 1967, white poverty was reduced another 7 million or about 28 percent, while poverty among nonwhites fell by 3.2 million—also about 28 percent. The relative position of nonwhite families, after deteriorating in the late 1950's, has improved since 1961. (See Appendix Table B-20.) Only since 1966 has nonwhite median family income as a fraction of white median family income surpassed its previous peak of 57 percent in 1952. Unemployment among nonwhite men age 25 to 54 has recently fallen below 1951-53 levels, but unemployment rates for nonwhite women and nonwhite teenage males are much higher than during the early 1950's. 154 Most poor white families in the United States are not members of identifiable ethnic groups; however, two groups—Mexican-Americans, living largely in southwestern States, and Puerto Ricans, concentrated in New York City—exhibit disproportionately high incidences of poverty. In 1966, unemployment rates among Mexican-Americans in southwestern cities ranged between 8 percent and 13 percent, two to three times the national average. Subemployment—the sum of unemployment, employment producing earnings too low to provide an escape from poverty, and nonparticipation in the labor force by individuals who have given up hope of finding work— ranged from 42 to 47 percent in the Mexican-American sections of southwestern cities. And while Puerto Ricans constitute only about 8 percent of the New York City population, they have been estimated to represent over one-third of the recipients of welfare and about one-third of all occupants of substandard housing. STRATEGIES FOR REDUCING POVERTY A program for reducing poverty has four principal economic dimensions. First, sustained high employment and economic growth—key objectives of economic policy for a wide variety of reasons—are prime essentials. Second, education, training, medical assistance, and access to well-paying jobs are needed by many of the poor to escape from chronic unemployment and low-paying dead end jobs. Third, three-fifths of the heads of poor households cannot easily enter the labor force because of age or disability, or because they are mothers with sole responsibility for the care of young children. Some workers with large families are not likely—even with training and other types of employment assistance—to earn an income sufficient to pull their families out of poverty. Because increased employment opportunities will not eliminate poverty among these groups, some form of income maintenance is required. Fourth, poverty is concentrated in "pockets"—city "ghettos" and certain rural areas. The numbers of poor in poverty pockets can be reduced by promoting public and private investment in these communities and by providing relocation assistance to those with employment opportunities elsewhere. In addition to economic policies, social and psychological strategies have an important role to play. These include information about family planning for those who request it, legal assistance, and the encouragement of self-help organizations. Such programs lie outside the purview of this Report. PROSPERITY AND THE REDUCTION OF POVERTY Virtually all the progress in reducing poverty over the past 20 years has occurred during periods of general prosperity. In three periods of sustained economic expansion—1949-53, 1954-56, and 1961 to the present— 155 the annual decline in the number of individuals in poverty averaged two million or more a year. In contrast, during recessions the number of poor people has increased. The brief recession of 1954 wiped ou,t half of the gains of the preceding 4-year expansion, and several successive years of sluggish economic performance in the late 1950's increased the number of persons in poverty to about the level of 7 years earlier. (See Chart 10.) EFFECTS OF PROSPERITY Poor families are affected unequally by economic growth and high employment, depending upon their ability to take advantage of expanded employment opportunities. Recent trends in poverty reduction for different groups are shown in Table 15. Households with Heads of Working Age Economic expansion has caused significant reductions in poverty among households headed by a working-age man. Tightening labor markets raise wages for the poor who are employed, and provide better employment opportunities for the unemployed and for those with very low-paying or part-time jobs. Furthermore, when prosperity pushes unemployment rates to low levels among skilled workers, business is more inclined to train poorly qualified workers for skilled jobs. From 1964 to 1966, the number of poor households headed by a working-age man with work experience fell 400,000 a year; in contrast, there had been no decline from 1959 to 1961. The number of poor households headed by a working-age woman with job experience has not changed during the 1960's. The decline in the incidence of poverty among this group reflected a rise in the total number of households headed by working-age women. Prosperity is less effective in reducing poverty among households headed by women for several reasons. Women are far less likely to be employed than men; only about three-fifths of the women who head families have some job experience, compared to about 90 percent for male family heads. Many women who head families, being the adult solely responsible for young children, are unable to accept full-time employment unless day care is provided for their children. Furthermore, women are far less likely to escape poverty even if they do work, because their employment is less steady and they earn lower wages. Nonwhite families are more than twice as likely— and white families are more than three times as likely—to be poor if headed by a woman than if headed by a man. Elderly Households During the 1960's, the number of poor elderly households fell slightly, while the incidence of poverty among this group decreased substantially. High employment has some immediate effect on poverty among the aged 156 TABLE 15.—Number of poor households and incidence of poverty, selected years, 1959-67 19661 Characteristic of head of household 1959 1961 1964 Originally published 1967 Revised Millions Number of poor households:2 13.4 Unrelated individualsFamilies 3 11.9 10.9 10.7 10.2 3.9 3.8 3.9 4.0 3.8 2.5 1.4 Head 65 years and over.. 13.0 3.9 Total 2.5 1.3 2.8 1.1 2.7 1.2 2.7 1.2 2.7 1.1 9.4 9.1 8.0 7.0 6.8 6.4 Unrelated individuals. 2.6 2.4 2.3 2.1 2.1 2.2 White Male___ Female. 1.9 .6 1.3 1.8 .6 1.2 1.8 .6 1.2 1.6 ill 1.6 .6 1.0 1.6 .5 1.1 Nonwhite... Male... Female. .7 .3 .4 .7 .3 .4 .5 .2 .3 .5 .2 .3 .5 .2 .3 .5 .2 .3 Head under 65 years 6.8 6.7 5.7 4.9 4.7 4.2 White Male... Female. 4.9 3.8 1.1 4.7 3.7 1.0 4.0 3.0 1.0 3.3 2.3 1.0 3.1 2.2 .9 2.8 2.0 .8 Nonwhite... Male—. Female. 1.9 1.3 .6 2.0 1.3 .7 1.7 1.1 .6 1.6 .9 .7 1.5 .9 .7 1.4 .7 .7 Families« Percent Incidence of poverty: 5 Total households2.. 24.0 17.8 17.5 16.2 43.8 40.0 38.5 38.9 36.3 68.1 32.5 Unrelated individualsFamilies 3 19.9 48.6 Head 65 years and over.. 22.6 64.4 27.2 59.9 21.6 55.3 23.0 56.3 23.1 53.4 20.3 19.8 18.8 16.0 13.7 13.3 12.2 36.8 33.9 31.0 28.3 28.7 27.0 White Male... Female. 32.9 24.6 39.1 29.7 22.8 35.2 28.3 22.0 33.0 25.8 20.1 30.0 25.5 21.0 28.8 24.4 18.0 29.0 Nonwhite__. Male... Female. 54.8 47.1 63.5 55.0 45.5 66.8 45.1 34.6 58.1 41.7 29.1 54.1 45.3 35.5 55.1 40.1 29.4 51.7 Head under 65 years Unrelated individuals.. 16.8 16.1 13.3 11.2 10.6 9.5 White Male... Female. 13.4 11.4 35.9 12.6 10.7 33.9 10.4 8.5 31.2 8.4 6.5 29.1 7.9 6.1 27.9 7.1 5.4 25.3 Nonwhite... Male... Female. 48.6 42.1 71.3 47.8 40.2 72.8 27.8 32.3 62.4 34.3 25.9 61.2 33.4 25.1 60.3 29.9 20.9 54.9 Families *_ 1 The revised estimates differ slightly from those originally published because of the use of a somewhat different estimating procedure. For an explanation of the two methods, see "Current Populat.on Reports Series P-60, No. 54." 2 Households are defined here as the total of families and unrelated individuals. 3 Consists only of two-person families whose head is 65 years or over. All other families included in "head under 65 years." * All families other than two-person families whose head is 65 years or over. s Poor households as percent of total households in the category. Note.—Poverty is defined by the Social Security Administration poverty-income standard; it takes into account family size, composition, and place of residence. Poverty-income lines are adjusted to take account of price changes during the period. Detail will not necessarily add to totals because of rounding. Sources: Department of Commerce and Department of Health, Education, and Welfare. 157 323-166 0—69- -11 by providing more jobs for elderly individuals wishing to continue work. This opportunity is particularly important for those with retirement income below the poverty line. Over the longer run, prosperity permits more workers to accumulate assets and to achieve higher pension rights prior to retirement. At present, an individual earning the minimum wage and working full-time in a job covered by social security is entitled to old-age benefits of approximately $120 a month upon retirement—only about $10 a month below the poverty line. Reflecting both the higher lifetime earnings of the aged and statutory improvements, social security retirement benefits have increased greatly and have been the most important factor in reducing poverty among the elderly. Since 1961, legislation has increased social security retirement benefits 21 percent across the board,—substantially greater than the increase in consumer prices. The minimum benefit increased 37 percent. The Disabled The ill and disabled have benefited least from recent prosperity and other efforts to alleviate poverty. Although the incidence of poverty among households whose heads are under 65 and not working for health reasons fell from 1959 to 1967, the number actually rose. Some disabled can be retrained, and these individuals can obtain jobs more readily when unemployment is low. But many who are ill or disabled cannot take advantage of job opportunities. The Near-Poor Table 16 shows the number of households and the number of persons who were in the near-poor category in 1959 and 1967. The compositions of the poor and the near-poor categories differ considerably. Most striking is the difference in the proportion of nonelderly households headed by a working-age woman. These households account for 46 percent of all nonelderly poor households; among the near-poor, they account for 22 percent. Except for the elderly, most near-poor families are headed by men who are employed, but at low wages. The number of near-poor showed a considerable decline between 1959 and 1967. Many who rose from poverty were added to the near-poor, but at the same time an even larger number of the former near-poor moved to a higher income level. PROSPECTS FOR FURTHER PROGRESS As indicated above, prosperity has played a key role in reducing poverty and is essential to further progress. But sustained growth and high employment—in the absence of other more direct efforts to help the poor—cannot maintain the recent rate of decline in poverty. 158 TABLE 16.—Number of near-poor households and incidence of near-poverty and sex of head of household, 1959 and 1967 by age Incidence of near-poverty (percent) * Number (millions) Age and sex of head of household 1959 Near-poor households2 1967 1959 1967 4.3 3.7 7.7 5.9 3.8 2.9 8.3 5.8 Head 65 years and overs Head under 65 years4 .7 3.1 .8 2.1 15.2 7.6 14.0 4.8 Male head Female head 3.4 .4 2.4 .5 8.4 8.2 5.5 8.7 Unrelated individuals .5 .8 5.1 6.0 .2 .3 .5 .3 6.1 4.6 9.1 4.0 .2 .3 .3 .5 5.5 4.9 5.8 6.1 15.8 12.0 9.0 6.1 Families Head 65 years and over Head under 65 years Male head Female head._ . . . . Addendum: Near-poor persons * Near-poor households as percent of total number of households in the category; near-poor persons as percent of total persons. 2 Households are defined here as the total of families and unrelated individuals. 3 Consists only of two-person families whose head is 65 years or over. All other families included in "head under 65 years." 4 All families other than two-person families whose head is 65 years or over. Note.—Near-poverty is defined by the Social Security Administration near-poverty-income standards; it takes into account family size, composition, and place of residence. Near-poverty-income lines are adjusted to take account of price changes during the period. Detail will not necessarily add to totals because of rounding. Sources: Department of Commerce and Department of Health, Education, and Welfare. If the 1961-68 reductions in the number of poor persons could be continued, poverty would be eliminated entirely in about 10 years. If the record of 1968 could be continued, poverty would be eliminated in about 5^2 years. Maintenance of these rapid reductions will become increasingly difficult because, as poverty declines, an increasing fraction of the remaining poor are members of households whose economic status is least affected by prosperity. Households headed by women with children, disabled persons, or elderly persons accounted for 6.0 million or 59 percent of all poor households in 1967. Much of the progress in the 1960's has been due to the lowering of the unemployment rate. As that rate fell, further declines were increasingly effective. The hard-core unemployed, the educationally disadvantaged, and the victims of discrimination are the last to be hired during a return to high employment and the first to be fired during a slowdown. Upgrading the unskilled and uneducated to fill shortages in skilled labor takes time. Consequently, if high employment is maintained, these adjustments will continue to reduce poverty, but their effects will gradually diminish. In the absence of increased direct assistance to the poor or further reductions in unemployment, present annual declines in poverty must be expected to become smaller. The elimination of poverty will be long in coming if the incomes of the 159 poor grow only at the same pace as the incomes of other households. If the real income (including transfer payments) of each poor household were to grow at 3 percent a year—approximately the average gain for all households during normal conditions of economic growth—eliminating only half of poverty would take 12 years for poor families and 17 years for unrelated individuals. To shorten substantially the period needed to reduce poverty, the incomes of the poor must grow faster than average income—some redistribution to the poor must be made from the benefits of growth. INCOME DISTRIBUTION Only a relatively small redistribution of the benefits of growth is needed to speed greatly the reduction in poverty. If the approximately 85 percent of households that are not poor and receive about 95 percent of total income are willing to make only a small sacrifice of the estimated 3 percent yearly growth in their real income per capita, the prospects for poverty reduction can be greatly transformed. If the increase in real income for the nonpoor is lowered merely from 3 percent to 2*/2 percent a year and if that differential of about $2.8 billion annually is effectively transferred to those in poverty, then family incomes for those now poor can grow about 12 percent annually. This redistribution would eliminate the 1967 "poverty gap" of $9.7 billion in less than 4 years. Since any program of redistribution would be likely to reach some of the near-poor and might raise some poor families substantially above the poverty line before others are affected, perhaps a better projection of the time required would be 6 to 8 years. The rapid reductions in poverty during the 1960's paralleled a significant rise in the share of total family income going to the lowest income groups. In part, this shift in distribution has been accomplished by increased employment of poor adults at higher wages. The combined effect of the tax and transfer payment systems at all levels of Government also operates to redistribute income to the poor. The net gain or burden from the public sector for any group depends on the difference between all the benefits received from government expenditures and all the taxes paid. Many programs—like national defense—have benefits that are difficult to allocate by groups; however, the benefits of transfer payments—such as social security benefits, welfare payments, and unemployment compensation—can be allocated and compared with the tax burden. The impact of Federal, State, and local taxes and of transfer payments on the distribution of income in 1965 is shown in Chart 11. The tax system by itself redistributes income away from the poor. As a share of income, higher taxes are paid by households in the lower income classes than by those with incomes between $6,000 and $15,000. This reflects the heavy tax burden on low-income families from State and local taxes—primarily sales, excise, and property taxes. Federal taxes also contribute to this burden through the social security payroll tax. The poor receive nearly as much from transfer payments as from all other 160 Chart 11 Taxes and Transfer Payments as Percent of Income (Excluding Transfers), by Income Class,1965 PERCENT 60 - 40 _ DERAL TAXES ' 20 - TAXES AS PERCE NIT OF INCOME - / STATE AND LOCAL TAXES — / ///A 0 ///A V ///) '///At YAAA 60 TAXES LESS TRANSFER F AYMENTS AS PERCENT OF INCOME 40 20 0 20 - - 40 - - 60 - - 80 Under 2,000 2,0003,999 4,0005,999 6,0007,999 8,0009,999 10,00014,999 15,000 & Over INCOME CLAS (DOLLARS) S SOURCE: COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS, BASED ON DATA FROM A VARIETY OF SOURCES. DESCRIPTION AVAILABLE ON REQUEST. sources. While these payments do not go exclusively to the poor, they do have a powerful redistributive impact. The ratio of receipts to household income (excluding transfers) is very high in the lowest income classes. As household incomes rise, the proportion of transfers to other income falls sharply. When government transfer payments and taxes are combined, the concentration of transfer payments in the lower income groups much more than offsets their tax burden. But since average transfer payments fall rapidly as income rises, the excess of taxes over transfer payments as a fraction of income rises much more sharply from $0 to $4,000 than in higher income classes. EDUCATION, JOBS, AND TRAINING Education and training measures can improve job opportunities for the poor and their children. 161 EDUCATION AND POVERTY Education can help prevent the children of the poor from remaining poor when they grow up. They are already better schooled than their parents. About three-fourths of poor youths between 16 and 21 either are attending school or are high school graduates, whereas more than half of their parents had no high school education. Yet these youths still have less schooling than their more fortunate contemporaries, 90 percent of whom are in school or are high school graduates. Although most poor children of all ages are now in school, inferior facilities and poorly qualified teachers lower the value of the education many of them receive. Even schools equivalent to those of the prosperous would not yield equal education. Poverty imposes handicaps that children of more prosperous families do not have. Children of the poor are less likely to receive good health care and good nutrition, both of which affect success in school. They are also less likely to receive the verbal and intellectual stimulation in their early years that prepares them to master school work. They start school somewhat behind other youngsters, and they receive less parental assistance. Since school does not meet the challenge of helping them catch up, it becomes a place of defeat, leading many to drop out. Poor children from minority groups suffer another handicap, segregation. More than 60 percent of all Negro pupils in the first grade attend elementary schools in which at least 90 percent of the students are Negro. Not only are facilities and instruction inferior in many of these schools, but studies of educational performance suggests that segregation itself has an adverse effect on school performance. If poor children are to have equal opportunity to compete successfully for good jobs, they need special help in the preschool years. They also need compensatory education, with expenditures exceeding those made on other pupils. Finally, they need financial help and other encouragement to stay in school and continue their education. Major efforts have been made to upgrade education provided children of the poor in programs such as the Elementary and Secondary Education Act, the Economic Opportunity Act, and the Vocational Education Amendments of 1968. Head Start, Title I of the Elementary Education Act, and Follow Through are comprehensive programs, combining health care, nutrition, and the involvement of the child's family, as well as education. Most of these special Federal efforts have been in operation for 3 years or less. While too little experience has been gained to allow a full evaluation, enough positive results are evident to justify continuing the programs. HIRING STANDARDS Poverty is perpetuated by hiring standards that arbitrarily discriminate against the disadvantaged. 162 Racial Discrimination The persistence of racial discrimination in hiring frustrates the efforts of nonwhites to realize full returns from schooling and discourages the young from remaining in school. For example, a larger portion of white male dropouts 16 to 21 years of age secure skilled and semiskilled jobs than nonwhite males who graduate from high school, and the average earnings of nonwhite high school graduates are lower than those of white dropouts. Attacks are being made on discrimination in higher level occupations, although most of the initial progress is in clerical jobs. The public sector has a better record than the private sector in eliminating discrimination in hiring. For example, 20 percent of the Federal and municipal white collar workers in metropolitan New York City are Negro. In contrast, Negroes hold only 6 percent of the white collar jobs in large private firms in New York City. Restrictive Hiring Practices Arbitrary hiring standards and customary employment practices, as well as outright racial discrimination, curtail work opportunities. During World War II, industry successfully adjusted standards and restructured work patterns to fit jobs to the level of workers' skills. All too often, recruitment and testing procedures currently used by Government and business do not take sufficient account of innate intelligence and aptitude. TRAINING AND JOB ACCESS On-the-job training is an important route to employment. Consequently, the Government increased the number of on-the-job trainees financed under the Manpower Development and Training Act from 11,000 in fiscal 1965 to 125,000 in fiscal 1968. By the end of 1968, half the trainees had less than 4 years of high school, and 53 percent were from families with incomes below the poverty line. Through the Job Opportunities in the Business Sector (JOBS) program sponsored by the National Alliance of Businessmen, nearly 12,000 cooperating business firms have helped disadvantaged workers find employment. The premise of the program is that the best job training is a job. JOBS encourages waiving of some hiring standards and provides counseling and training to raise the productivity of the trainees. The interim goal of employers pledging to place 100,000 disadvantaged persons by June 1969 has already been met far ahead of schedule. JOBS contracts have been issued to about 800 employers who are reimbursed an average of $3,000 per trainee for the extra costs. 163 The rapidly growing public sector has no counterpart to the JOBS program. Such a program would usefully supplement the present expansion of job opportunities in the private sector. Two other major programs are designed for young workers. The Job Corps helps the most severely disadvantaged youths without job prospects. As of mid-1968, the program had provided health care, food, and job training for 195,000 enrollees since 1965. From 1965 to 1968 the Neighborhood Youth Corps provided jobs for over 1.3 million youngsters from lowincome areas. While the part-time and summer work is too low skilled to provide useful job training, the modest pay helps youths from low-income families stay in school. IMPROVEMENTS IN INCOME MAINTENANCE The United States now has a substantial commitment to income maintenance, spending about $60 billion in fiscal 1968 (Table 17). Each program serves the special needs of a particular group, and many are not designed specifically to help the poor. Individuals who can normally earn an adequate living are served by social insurance systems which protect against loss of income through death, disability, and unemployment, and which provide retirement income. Individuals with inadequate earning TABLE 17.—Selected major income maintenance programs,fiscalyear 1969 Beneficiaries * Total outlays (millions of dollars) Program Number (thousands) Percent in households with income less than $3,300 2 100 58,679 All programs3 Aid to families with dependent children 3,206 6,146 Unemployment insurance: Federal-State unemployment compensation.. Federal employees and ex-servicemen Railroad. 2,300 111 52 5,196 49 8 92 Disability programs: Workmen's compensation Federal employees Veterans'compensation _ Railroad ._ Social security Ajd to the blind Aid to the permanently and totally disabled * 1,686 57 2,611 77 2,691 92 726 40 2,390 4 1 2,278 84 71 2 Assistance to those 65 years and over: Social security retirement and survivors' benefits. Old-age assistance Military retirement Civil service retirement Railroad retirement Veterans' pensions 24,681 1,833 2,265 2,364 1,542 2,127 21,931 2,123 681 918 99 6 2,252 3 1 10 0 32 700 100 General assistance _ Assistance-in-kind« () * () * 15 24 <) * 10,226 * Estimated. 2 income including cash benefits. 3 Data exclude State and local government retirement systems and all private retirement and charitable programs. * Not available. 5 Estimate by Council of Economic Advisers. 6 Federal outlays only. See Table 18. Source: Bureau of the Budget (except as noted). 164 20 10 39 10 0 10 0 34 80 ability may be assisted by welfare, veterans pensions, in-kind payments (such as food stamps or public housing), and manpower training allowances. Despite recent improvements, existing income maintenance progams provide neither adequate coverage nor sufficient benefits to prevent poverty. Rarely are able-bodied working-age individuals, or families headed by healthy, nonelderly men, eligible for existing cash benefit programs yet, these groups make up two-thirds of poor nonelderly households. Even among some of the groups for which programs are available, coverage is much less than complete. Benefits are rarely adequate to raise households above the poverty line. The average Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) payment in mid-1968 was just over $2,000 a year per family; in five States, it was less than $1,000 a year. Average benefits in mid-1968 for a retired couple under old-age insurance were about $1,800—below the poverty line for such families by about $200. WELFARE PROGRAMS Important improvements in public assistance have been made. The courts have overturned the controversial "man in the house" rule, which had denied AFDG benefits to children when a man not legally responsible for their care lived with the family. Courts have also declared invalid some State residency requirements for public assistance. States have recently been instructed to determine income need by affidavit, rather than personal investigation, a change to a more efficient and less demeaning method. The work incentive principle was introduced in the 1967 Social Security Amendments, which call for welfare benefits for AFDC mothers to be reduced by less than the full amount of earnings. Finally, the average AFDC benefit rose $17 per family (11 percent) between mid-1967 and mid-1968. These improvements have led to the paradox of growing welfare rolls and costs amidst a general reduction in poverty. Not only have welfare applications increased, but between 1960 and 1967, the fraction of applicants declared eligible for benefits rose dramatically. Reform of eligibility rules and increased awareness of welfare programs by the poor have probably been responsible for the substantial rise in applications. The Freeze on AFDC Rolls While the welfare system generally has been improved in recent years, the enactment of a sharp limitation on the number of AFDC beneficiaries, now scheduled to take effect July 1, 1969, was a major step backward. The "freeze" forbids Federal financing for any increase in a State's ratio of deserted or illegitimate children receiving AFDC assistance to the total child population. In all States, the freeze places a very tight limit on the expansion of welfare rolls; in some it will even cause a decline, unless the States are willing to assume the Federal share of the costs. Eligibility for federally aided 165 public assistance should not be determined on the basis of the place of a family in the waiting line at the welfare agency, but upon the need of the family. Repeal of the AFDC freeze is the most urgently required step toward a more humane and rational welfare system. Raising and Equalizing Welfare Benefits In federally assisted welfare programs—AFDC, old-age assistance, aid to the blind, and aid for the disabled—benefits vary widely among States but are well below the poverty line nearly everywhere. For example, the monthly AFDC benefits for a family of four range among the States from a low of $40 to a high of $290 but exceed the poverty threshold in only one State. Establishing minimum welfare benefits—wholly financed by the Federal Government—could raise the lowest benefits significantly. This minimum could be modest initially and then increased until benefits are adequate in all States. Since poverty is a national problem which happens to be geographically concentrated, federalization of most of the cost of welfare expenditures, perhaps including even administrative costs, would be desirable over the long run. Federal administration would reduce the difficulties arising from major differences in local standards of benefits, eligibility, and administration. Improving Work Incentives in AFDC Currently, if a State elects, mothers receiving AFDC may earn up to $30 a month without having their welfare benefits reduced. Beyond $30, benefits are reduced by two-thirds of additional earnings. By July 1, 1969, all States must adopt this work incentive formula. While these new provisions are an important advance, work incentives are still too small and do not extend to other welfare categories. If child-care facilities are available, welfare mothers may be required to work or to accept training in order to receive benefits. At present, shortages of child-care facilities and training assignments limit the impact of this provision. Nevertheless the rule raises fundamental social issues: whether children are better off in a child-care center or at home with their mothers, and whether a mother should be required to work while also performing household tasks for her family. These issues are not easily resolved. Nevertheless an equitable system should not penalize those who work and should provide adequate benefits to those who cannot work. BENEFITS IN KIND Many assistance programs provide goods and services rather than cash. In-kind assistance is often designed to promote those types of consumption 166 by the poor that also benefit other members of society. For example, society may subsidize housing or health care because eliminating poor housing and ill health benefits the community as a whole. Some in-kind programs, such as school lunches, provide specific goods and services especially important to the young. In-kind benefits often reflect the standards, tastes, and values of the majority and their desire to influence the consumption patterns of recipients. The well-being of the poor is raised by such programs, but the poor would probably consider themselves better off if they had equivalent amounts in cash and the accompanying freedom of choice. Present Programs Outlays in fiscal 1969 for the major in-kind programs which directly benefit the poor are summarized in Table 18. Health. Medicare and Medicaid account for 84 percent of in-kind expenditures. Medicaid benefits go primarily to the poor, and one-third of Medicare beneficiaries are poor. Because of high maternal and infant mortality rates among the poor, expansion of comprehensive health care for mothers and babies in poor families is especially desirable. Food. The next largest in-kind program is food assistance, which includes food stamps, school lunches, and the distribution of commodities from surplus stocks. Food programs reach a significant number of the poor but as few as 20 percent in some concentrated poverty areas. The coverage TABLE 18.—Major Federal income-in-kind programs substantially benefiting the poor, fiscal year 1969 Beneficiaries1 Federal outlays (millions of dollars) Program Total programs 10,226 Food programs... 665 11.3 36 . 39 . . 2 36 . 29 . 100 100 100 10 0 28 . . 1 36 . 57 67 9,077 6,222 2,384 193 Food stamps Child nutrition Special supplemental r Other direct distribution 9.5 9.5 3 3.2 36 75 70 273 128 9 255 Housing programs.. 484 Public housing Rent supplements.. 456 28 Health service programsMedicare Medicaid Maternity and infant care Public Health Service medical programs: Indians, seamen, etc Neighborhood health centers 175 103 1 Estimated. 2 Income including cash benefits. 3 1 ncludes children and mothers benefiting from more than one service of the Children's Bureau. Source: Bureau of the Budget. Percent in households with income less than $3,3002 Number (millions) 167 .6 55 75 of the food stamp program will expand from 2.8 to 3.6 million persons by the middle of 1969, largely as a result of expansion into new areas and lower stamp charges. The child nutrition program, providing free or low-cost school lunches, is now being expanded. Housing. Two programs to be expanded significantly under the Housing Act of 1968 are directed toward low-income groups—rent supplements and public housing. By midyear, 19,000 families—nearly all poor—will be receiving rent supplements. In fiscal 1969, the number of public housing units available will increase by 75,000, bringing the total to 780,000. Roughly half the occupants are poor. The average monthly rental in public housing is about $50, more than many poor families can afford. In the North, the lowest income families in public housing spend more than 30 percent of their income on rent. In contrast, occupants with incomes over $5,000 pay about one-sixth of their income in rent. Only in the South are the majority of nonelderly public housing tenants below the poverty line. Public housing could be made more accessible to the very poor in a number of ways. First, higher welfare benefits would help recipients pay present rents. Second, rents could be lowered if the Federal Government subsidized a larger share of public housing costs. Third, rents for the poorest families could be reduced if rents for all tenants were more closely tied to income. SOCIAL INSURANCE SYSTEMS For the vast majority of Americans, social insurance guards against a fall in income due to retirement, disability, survivorship, or unemployment. These programs prevent much of the poverty that in the past resulted from interruptions in wage income. They make remaining poverty problems more manageable. Retirement The largest American income maintenance program is social security. About 22 million Americans now receive about $25 billion in annual benefits from Old Age and Survivors Insurance. The goal of providing every elderly American citizen with a decent retirement income is becoming a reality. Similarly, more and more widows with young children and disabled individuals are being supported above the poverty line. Rising prices should not be permitted to erode the purchasing power of the retired. Social security benefits should now be increased 10 percent across the board, in line with changes in the cost of living since benefits were last raised and to allow for additional improvement. A revised method of computing benefits, effective in fiscal 1971, would provide another increase. Many individuals receiving low social security benefits have little if any other income. Increasing the monthly minimum benefit from $55 to $80— 168 and to $100 for workers with 20 years of coverage—would reduce poverty by more than half a million persons. The earnings test should be liberalized. At present every dollar earned in excess of $1,680 a year reduces benefits by 50 cents; earnings over $2,880 reduce benefits dollar for dollar. Because earnings are subject to other taxes, additional earnings above $2,880 actually reduce total after-tax income. The tax-free earnings allowance should be raised to $1,800. Fifty percent of earnings beyond $1,800 up to $3,000 and 75 percent of earnings thereafter would be deducted from benefits. Virtually all workers are now covered either by social security or similar retirement programs. Regular employment will provide retirement benefits above the poverty line for all but the very lowest-paid workers. Most future recipients of low social security benefits will be either individuals covered by other retirement programs or housewives with only a few years of work experience. Neither group will constitute an extensive poverty problem. The most efficient mechanism for assisting the elderly poor is either expansion of Old Age Assistance or establishment of an income-related social security minimum—perhaps financed out of general revenues—far above the standard minimum. Under the latter proposal, social security benefits could be high enough, together with other income, to bring all the elderly above the poverty line. Disability The number of poor households headed by the disabled has not declined since 1959. Better Disability Insurance under social security can improve this record. At present, to qualify for benefits, workers must be disabled 6 months, and the disablement must be expected to last another 6 months or to result in death. To remove this hardship, the waiting period for benefit eligibility should be reduced from 6 to 3 months, and eligibility should not be limited to disabilities which last more than 1 year. The burden of unusually high medical expenses could be lifted by extending Medicare to the permanently and totally disabled. The other major disability income program is workmen's compensation, intended to pay medical expenses and provide income for workers (and their survivors) disabled through work-related accidents and diseases. Workmen's compensation is governed by State laws which require employers to obtain insurance from private companies or a State fund, or to establish self insurance. The present weaknesses of workmen's compensation are inadequate benefits and the exclusion of large groups of workers. In 1966 the maximum cash benefit (including dependents' allowances) under workmen's compensation was below the poverty line for a fourperson family in 39 States; over half the States have maximum benefits less than 50 percent of income prior to disability. About 11 million workers— 169 mostly domestics, agricultural employees, and employees of small businesses—currently are not covered at all by workmen's compensation. Improvements in workmen's compensation ought to come through State laws. To provide an incentive for such action and to protect workers in its absence, Federal action may be required. Consideration should be given to legislation requiring States to extend coverage and to improve benefits. If States fail to act, the law might require employers to purchase insurance providing additional coverage and higher benefits. Unemployment Insurance Unemployment insurance contributes significantly to the prevention of poverty by providing income to regular members of the labor force during periods of involuntary unemployment. Yet more than a fifth of the employed labor force are excluded, a large number of whom are in low-wage occupations such as domestic service and farm work. The original aim of unemployment insurance was to restore at least half of wages lost. Average weekly benefits—about $42 in 1966—are roughly a third of weekly earnings in covered industries. Most States now pay benefits for a maximum of 26 weeks in a single year; over one-fifth of the recipients exhaust their benefits, even in periods of high employment. For a fair and modern unemployment insurance system, legislation is needed to broaden protection, ensure higher and more uniform benefits, provide special training, and eliminate abuses. MAJOR REFORM Proposals for more fundamental reforms of the income maintenance system merit consideration along with the more evolutionary suggestions outlined above. Major reform can be undertaken in two ways. First, the categorical approach can be expanded and improved by reforming eligibility requirements, raising benefit levels, and—in particular—adding programs for poor families headed by a working man and for other groups not now covered. Alternatively, present welfare programs could be replaced by a single universal Federal program—supplemented by social insurance—having no eligibility requirements other than low income. Benefits for Poor Families Headed by Working-Age Men The largest omission from the present income maintenance system is a program to assist families headed by able-bodied working males who are not eligible for unemployment insurance or who have exhausted its benefits. Unconditional cash benefits to working-age men are often opposed on the grounds of possible adverse effects on work incentives. Whatever society's attitude toward fathers in poverty, failure to assist their children makes the children likely candidates for a new generation of poor. Further- 170 more, under the present system a father can often increase the income of his family by deserting them to make them eligible for welfare. Children's Allowances. Children's allowances are systematic payments by the Government to families with children. The United States is the only Western industrialized nation without a children's allowance. The program has been adopted in some nations as a vehicle for both providing income to the poor and promoting population growth. Children's allowances can take several forms. To channel aid effectively to the poor, the allowances have to be related to family income. If children's allowances are not income-related but go to all families, they are an exceedingly inefficient way to help the poor. An income-related children's allowance is one method of attacking poverty among two categories of poor households—those with moderate incomes and large families and those with low incomes and average-size families. Guaranteed Work. A program of guaranteed work opportunity for poor, employable fathers is especially attractive because it offers a workable compromise between those who favor income maintenance and those who favor expanded employment as a vehicle for ending poverty among these families. Fathers suffering from long term unemployment would certainly be eligible for the program. Eventually others with very low incomes might be included. Each enrollee would receive cash benefits and would be required to participate in steps—including acceptance of placement services or training— leading to private employment paying at least minimum wages. Those for whom private employment could not be found would be given meaningful public service jobs at minimum wages that provide opportunities for advancement. The guaranteed work program could ultimately allow any man to earn the minimum wage, which at present would bring families of 4 or fewer near the poverty line. By itself, this would not solve the problem of poverty for large families. Nevertheless, the largest gap in the present income maintenance system would be closed in a manner consistent with the traditional American attitude toward welfare for able-bodied fathers. The Negative Income Tax. The negative income tax would provide a minimum-income guarantee to all individuals. Benefits would be reduced by a fraction of income, as is currently the practice for AFDC mothers and individuals receiving social security. A minimum-income guarantee would end society's attempts to distinguish between the "deserving" and ' 'undeserving" poor, establishing the principle of social responsibility to aid those in need without questioning whether the fault was individual or social. As a substitute for other income maintenance programs, the negative income tax is bound to be expensive. If the guaranteed income is set at or near the poverty line—and if the proportion of earnings by which benefits are reduced is low enough to provide adequate work incentives—substantial 171 benefits must be provided to middle-income families, swelling the cost. To illustrate, suppose the minimum-income guarantee for a family of four is $3,300—about the income required to escape poverty in 1967. Suppose that every dollar earned reduces benefits' by 50 cents—a reduction that probably approaches the maximum consistent with providing work incentives. Under this plan, a family earning $5,000 a year would have benefits reduced by one-half of $5,000 (or $2,500), leaving the family eligible for $800. All families of four with less than a $6,600 income would receive some assistance. Adoption of this particular plan now would cost about $20 billion over and above present income maintenance outlays; roughly half would go to families not now in poverty. The cost can be reduced by increasing the rate at which benefits go down as income increases. But this approach would reduce work incentives. The cost could also be reduced by setting the guaranteed minimum income well below the poverty line; however, if a low-income guarantee were adopted, poverty would not be eliminated. To deal with this problem, the income guarantee could be supplemented by State—or even Federal—welfare programs for particular categories. But then attempts to distinguish between the "deserving" and "undeserving" poor would not have been eliminated. Another way of dealing with the problem of different categories of the poor within the framework of the negative income tax is to establish separate minimum-income guarantees and benefit-rate reductions for various types of households. Again such modification would introduce complexities and reduce the appeal of the plan as simple and universal. Nevertheless, a minimum-income plan may be acceptable both in terms of cost and of the beneficiaries served. If the guaranteed minimum income is at or close to the poverty line, and if the rate of benefit reduction is low enough to limit adverse incentive effects, the plan would meet the tests of a good income maintenance system. The Commission on Income Maintenance has been asked to study in detail the appropriate long-run direction of policy in this area. The Commission will report at the end of this year. SPECIAL PROBLEMS OF POVERTY POCKETS Poverty in the United States is unevenly distributed, both racially and geographically. Two particularly visible concentrations of poverty are big city ghettos and declining rural areas. Many difficulties faced by residents of poverty pockets are simply virulent local outcroppings of national problems. Others are peculiar to the community in which the concentrations of poor occur. The discussion below separates the elements of poverty problems in ghettos and rural communities into those amenable to general, national solutions and those that require special programs aimed at the areas in question. 172 STRATEGIES FOR ATTACKING GHETTO PROBLEMS The most visible—and certainly most explosive—concentration of poverty is in the ghettos of large cities. Here deteriorating physical facilities, inadequate public services, low income, and high unemployment combine with high population density to create a dehumanizing, hostile environment. The ghetto contains a concentration of people whose health, age, family status, and limited training are obstacles to full-time employment in wellpaying jobs. It has vastly inferior educational and health services. These are national problems, and strategies discussed elsewhere in this chapter could produce significant rewards in the ghetto. Other ghetto problems—and the programs required to deal with them— are unique. First, unemployment is extremely high. The Department of Labor reported that in the fall of 1966 the unemployment rate in the lowincome neighborhoods of eight large cities was 9.3 percent. More striking, subemployment was an additional 23 percent. The second problem of ghetto areas is extensive deterioration of the physical environment—housing, commercial buildings, even open spaces. Restoration of the cities will be expensive, whether publicly or privately financed, but a large-scale facelifting of urban America offers the opportunity for a rational, coherent attack on the problems of the ghetto. Fiscal Disparities Within Metropolitan Areas Roughly an eighth of welfare benefit costs, half of elementary and secondary education expenditures, and virtually all police, fire protection, and sanitation costs are borne by local government. Central cities, with their large concentrations of poor, have difficulty meeting these costs. The property tax base per capita is substantially higher in the suburbs than in the central cities, but suburbs collect less total tax revenue per capita and spend far less per capita on social services—health care, welfare, police, fire protection, recreation, and sanitation. Suburbs spend far more per capita (and per student) on education than does the central city. Responding to lower taxes and better educational systems, a stream of middle income families flows from the central city to suburban communities. Central cities must then cut back on services or raise taxes even higher, in either case increasing incentives to leave the city. The heavy burden of providing services to the poor thus threatens the viability of the central city. Access to Employment The residential patterns of the poor affect their opportunities for employment. Because few lower income families can afford automobiles, their mobility is severely limited. Jobs, shopping, health care, and social contacts must all be within walking distance or accessible through inexpensive public transportation. 173 323-166 Total Employment. Most jobs are in the central cities. Even in sectors such as manufacturing, wholesale and retail trade, nonprofessional business services, entertainment, and government, with relatively more jobs in lower skill occupations, the ratio of employment to population is over 40 percent higher in the cities than their suburbs. Employment in the city is also less physically dispersed than in the suburbs, and public transportation is more readily available. For the foreseeable future, most ghetto residents will continue to have a greater chance of finding a job in the central city. Job vacancies created by normal attrition are far more numerous than those created by entirely new positions, and consequently the number of job openings is greater in the city with its much larger total employment. Some big city ghettos— such as Watts—are isolated from the areas of greatest employment density, but Harlem and Bedford-Stuyvesant are only a few minutes on the subway from the most dense center of employment in the world. Job problems in such areas are not explained by physical isolation from sites of employment. Job Growth. Most of the growth in employment is occurring in the suburbs, and job opportunities for low-income people will continue to grow there. Many ghetto residents already hold suburban jobs. A recent study of commuting patterns in Pittsburgh indicated that employed, low-income Negroes, on balance, traveled away from the central city to reach their jobs, while whites in the same employment class traveled toward the central city— and traveled fewer miles. Access for ghetto residents to the growing number of suburban jobs can be improved by both better transportation and less discrimination in suburban housing. The transportation requirements for those taking better paying suburban jobs are greatest in the first few months of employment. After that, workers tend to buy their own cars or form car pools. Transportation needs of domestics and other low-paid workers are not so easily solved. Suburban housing is already becoming more available to ghetto residents. Between 1966 and 1968, the number of Negroes residing in the suburbs grew by half a million, although Negroes continued to account for only about 5 percent of the suburban population. Access to suburban housing should continue to improve as the fair housing provisions of the Civil Rights Act of 1968 become effective. Living Costs for the Poor The central city ghetto is an expensive place to live. Ghetto residents often pay higher prices for comparable merchandise and are frequently sold inferior goods. To some extent, these higher prices reflect higher selling costs resulting from smaller average purchases, increased pilferage, slower turnover of perishable items, and higher insurance rates. Easy credit, along with high-pressure salesmanship and door-to-door selling techniques, also adds 174 to the costs of ghetto retailers. A Federal Trade Commission study of Washington, D.C., furniture and appliance stores revealed that prices in ghetto stores averaged $255 for each of $100 of wholesale cost, compared to $159 in the rest of the city. Even so, net return on investment was considerably lower than for retailers elsewhere. If ghetto residents had greater access to general market retailers, they would pay significantly lower prices. This access requires improved transportation facilities in some cities and education—educating general retailers that low-income families can carry moderate amounts of installment credit, and educating low-income shoppers about price differentials. The Role of Private Enterprise in Ghetto Development Reconstruction of the cities will require deeper involvement of private enterprise. The major asset of private business is its efficiency in accomplishing specific tasks at minimum cost. The Federal Government has recognized the contribution business can make. For example, local housing authorities are now permitted to turn over much of the planning, site acquisition, and supervision of construction of public housing to private developers. This "Turnkey" policy has reduced costs and greatly cut the time required to produce public housing. Without government inducements, profits are low in ghetto areas—a deterrent to private investment. Despite higher prices, retail business has difficulty thriving in the ghetto. Investing in new housing for low-income families—particularly in big cities—is usually a losing proposition. Indeed, the most profitable investment is often one that demolishes the homes of lowincome families to make room for businesses and higher income families. Much of the blemished reputation of early urban renewal programs came from pursuing the most profitable development of renewal areas. Many business leaders are willing to sacrifice some profits in order to invest in the ghetto, but they cannot be expected to shoulder the major part of a financial burden that is properly the responsibility of all society. Participation by the private sector is also limited by the large scale normally needed to make a ghetto project economically viable. Costs are far lower and prospects for permanent improvement far greater if redevelopment of an entire neighborhood is undertaken in a relatively short period. Only the largest corporations are likely to be able to afford efficient renewal efforts. Government aid to provide profit opportunities will be needed to induce significant participation by the private sector. The Federal Government can provide such aid by direct subsidies to firms willing to build under its program specifications. Alternatively, a tax credit or a deduction from taxable income could be given for a broad class of ghetto development expenditures. 175 Three considerations bear on the choice of the proper techniques for attracting private enterprise into ghetto reconstruction. First, the efficiency of Federal assistance is reduced if subsidies are paid for activities that would have been undertaken anyway. Tax incentives automatically apply to all investment in the subsidized category. Even in the most depressed urban areas, some investments are still being made without subsidies. Second, a dollar of direct expenditure and a dollar of tax incentive have identical effects upon the budget, requiring either a reduction in other Federal programs or an increase in taxes. One technique adds to Federal expenditures; the other lowers Federal tax receipts. Finally, tax incentives are not effective for encouraging indigenous businesses. Large corporations, earning profits in other operations, benefit from tax incentives, but firms operating only in the ghetto—where profits are low—receive less benefit. New firms often receive no benefits from tax incentives since fledgling enterprises typically earn low profits. Since support of new, ghetto-owned businesses is a particularly promising vehicle for promoting ghetto development, a more direct form of assistance for these firms is necessary. Such firms need loans and management assistance as well as the subsidies that would be provided to established businesses through tax incentives. The Federal Government has moved to assist indigenous businesses. Projects in Model Cities areas must, where possible, be constructed by labor and businesses from the "model neighborhood." The Small Business Administration, through federally guaranteed loans and technical assistance, aided 2,300 minority-owned businesses in fiscal 1968. It plans to raise this number to 6,500 new firms in fiscal 1969 and 14,000 in fiscal 1970. The Federal Government can also assist in establishing other social institutions. Community Action Agencies, supported by the Office of Economic Opportunity, provide a fulcrum for involving the residents of lowincome areas in the revitalization of their neighborhoods. These agencies also provide a single, knowledgeable source of information on the programs available to assist the poor, as well as supplying many of these services themselves. STRATEGIES FOR REDUCING RURAL POVERTY Over two-fifths of America's poor live in rural communities, even though only about one-fourth of the population is rural. Rural poverty, though not as visible as urban poverty, is a major national concern. Rural communities face two special problems. First, average family incomes in these areas are often low. Rural communities have difficulty making sufficient investments in public facilities and schools. Expansion of Federal support for income maintenance, education, and other social services for the poor would relieve rural communities of some of the burden of caring for their relatively large dependent population. The second special problem stems from the persistent outmigration of the past half century. Migration to the city occurs largely because of declines in the principal sources of rural job opportunities—agriculture, mining, and foresty. Most migrants improved their living conditions by moving. In areas where jobs were limited and migration took place, those who stayed obtained more employment at better wages than if migration had not occurred. A reduced rural population creates serious problems of public finance. Those who leave tend to be more employable, more highly skilled, better educated, and younger than those who remain. Some rural communities are thus left with a skilled labor force too small to support new industries. In many areas, excess capacity has developed in public facilities built for larger populations than currently exist. The cost of maintaining these facilities limits the ability of local governments to finance other public services. Other rural communities are growing vigorously. Manufacturing employment is increasing more rapidly in the less urbanized States than in those containing large urban centers. Furthermore, from 1962 to 1966 nonfarm employment grew most rapidly in the counties with the smallest population centers. Net migration out of most rural counties is continuing, but at a slower pace than in the 1950's, particularly in the rural South and Midwest. For example, of the 100 nonmetropolitan counties in Kansas, only 7 gained in population through migration in the 1950Js; 32 have done so since 1960. Annual net migration from nonmetropolitan counties in the South has fallen from 400,000 between 1950 and 1960 to 50,000 since 1960. These trends indicate that a selective rural development policy, concentrating on those counties which have begun to grow in the 1960's can produce substantial economic progress in much of rural and smalltown America. The Federal Role In Rural Communities Federal aid for education, planning, and public facilities overcomes barriers to future development arising from the low income of rural communities. Title I of the Elementary and Secondary Education Act provides funds to defray part of the costs of education in areas with high concentrations of poverty. About 30 percent of these funds go to rural areas. The Federal Government has also taken an active role in promoting areawide planning in rural areas. Forty million Americans reside in seven areas served by Regional Action Planning Commissions established under the provisions of the Public Works and Economic Development Act. These agencies help to plan over-all regional economic development and to coordinate Federal, State, and local community assistance. The Department of Agriculture provides technical assistance to private and public groups in rural areas undertaking coordinated planning and de- 177 velopment activities. Loans, grants, and technical aid to low-income rural areas from the major Federal Departments amounted to over $1 billion in fiscal 1968. Diversification of the Rural Economy Since economic development programs are more effective if some growth has already taken place, Federal rural development assistance should be oriented toward more densely settled "growth centers," such as smaller growing cities or small metropolitan areas. With a population of viable size, a community can diversify its economy and cushion itself against employment fluctuations in one industry. As more firms settle in an area, they interact with mutual benefit by forming a sufficient market for the growth of business services and of cheaper communications and transportation—increasing the attractiveness of the community for further business development. This strategy has largely been adopted by the Department of Agriculture and the Economic Development Administration in aiding depressed, nonmetropolitan regions. In addition, Federal agencies should give explicit consideration to the development effects of Federal installations. Military bases and scientific installations, for example, have a profound effect on the community in which they locate. Some rural communities, suited only for traditional resource-based industries, will continue to decline. The Federal Government should ensure that the remaining population is not required to carry the whole burden of declines in the industries many rural communities have depended upon. Adequate income maintenance, support for education, and federalization of other costs associated with economic and population decline are the most equitable steps that can be taken to assist these areas. Federal support for the costs of moving low-income individuals to employment opportunities elsewhere is also desirable in certain situations. Job training and job location services are also needed to help both migrants and those who remain. These last two measures are discussed in Chapter 3. FULFILLING THE NATIONAL COMMITMENT With a "poverty gap" of slightly more than 1 percent of GNP, the United States can—if it will—rapidly reduce poverty. This effort will require that the incomes of the poor grow faster than average income. Otherwise, conquering poverty will take a long time indeed. The long-run objective should be to reduce dependency, as well as poverty. To this end, education and training will be required so that all Americans can qualify for a decent job. In addition, programs are needed to expand employment opportunities in poverty pockets. But many of these efforts will take years to become fully effective. To meet the most pressing income needs of the poor promptly, expansion of income maintenance is required. Welfare and social insurance programs have brought us a long way in combating poverty among the covered groups; further benefit increases can close the poverty gap among those covered. The most difficult policy issues pertain to families headed by an ablebodied man, for whom no major income support programs now exist. Most of these men now work but with insufficient earnings to take their families— particularly large families—out of poverty. Maintaining high employment is essential to eliminating poverty among families headed by a working man. Continued prosperity will raise the incomes of some of these men above the poverty line. For the rest, a desirable policy could be compounded out of job training, placement, income support, and public employment. The poverty gap in 1967 for these families—containing 10.7 million persons—was $2.7 billion. The actual costs of a program to assist this group would exceed this amount. Supplementary employment services and, for reasons of equity and work incentive, some benefits for the near-poor, would have to be provided. Federalization of more of the costs of providing the poor with welfare, education, health care, training, and public facilities would spread the costs of combating poverty more equitably. Caring for the poor now places a severe financial burden on communities with concentrated poverty. The choice as to how poverty will be eliminated has begun to enter into public discussion and debate. A number of good alternatives are available. After appropriate and intensive deliberation, the American public must find mechanisms for effectively attacking poverty—mechanisms and programs that can command widespread support. The success of any program is jeopardized if assistance is handed out begrudgingly and becomes demeaning to the recipients. Beyond this, the most essential requirement is a program of a scale adequate to guarantee rapid progress toward ending poverty. Fulfilling the Nation's commitment is far more important than the details of the precise tactics used. 179 REPORT TO THE PRESIDENT FROM THE CABINET COORDINATING COMMITTEE ON ECONOMIC PLANNING FOR THE END OF VIETNAM HOSTILITIES 181 LETTER OF TRANSMITTAL WASHINGTON, D.C., December 31, 1968. THE PRESIDENT: SIR: The Cabinet Coordinating Committee on Economic Planning for the End of Vietnam Hostilities herewith submits its report on the studies you requested in your memorandum of March 1, 1967. Respectfully, JOSEPH W. BARR Secretary of the Treasury. CLARK M. CLIFFORD Secretary of Defense. C. R. SMITI Secretary of Commerce. WlLLARD WlRTZ ^ Secretary of Labor. IARLES J. ZWIGK Director, Bureau of the Budget. ARTHUR M. OKUN Chairman, Council of Economic Advisers. 183 CONTENTS Page SUMMARY OF FINDINGS 189 FISCAL-MONETARY POLICIES DURING DEMOBILIZATION RESOURCES AND PRIORITIES POLICIES T O ASSIST PARTICULAR COMMUNITIES AND INDIVIDUALS . 189 189 190 LOOKING FORWARD TO PEACE 191 FISCAL-MONETARY POLICIES DURING DEMOBILIZATION 191 DEMOBILIZATION SCENARIO ECONOMIC IMPACT 191 193 FISCAL-MONETARY ADJUSTMENT 195 RESOURCES AND PRIORITIES 198 PROJECTIONS OF THE PRIVATE ECONOMY 198 BASELINE FEDERAL EXPENDITURES 199 T H E PEACE-AND-GROWTH DIVIDEND 200 ALTERNATIVE USES OF THE DIVIDEND 201 POLICIES T O ASSIST PARTICULAR COMMUNITIES AND INDIVIDUALS 207 T H E MAGNITUDE OF THE READJUSTMENT 207 READJUSTMENT OPERATIONS COMMITTEE 208 FUNDING READJUSTMENT PROGRAMS 209 ASSISTING DEFENSE-DEPENDENT AREAS 210 ASSISTING DISPLACED INDIVIDUALS 210 List of Tables and Charts Tables 1. Illustrative Projections for Fiscal Year 1972 and Recent Experience 2. Estimated Gap Between Amounts Currently Authorized and Funded 3. Illustrative New Programs or Major Expansions of existing Federal Civilian Programs, Fiscal Year 1972 (derived from Proposals of Task Forces and Study Groups) 4. Estimated First Year Cost of Readjustment Programs Charts 1. Federal Purchases for National Defense 2. Illustrative Reduction in Defense Spending with a Vietnam Demobilization 3. Illustrative Paths of Defense Spending With and Without a Vietnam Demobilization 199 202 204 209 188 192 194 Report to the President FROM THE CABINET COORDINATING COMMITTEE ON ECONOMIC PLANNING FOR THE END OF VIETNAM HOSTILITIES I N MARCH 1967 you asked the Secretaries of Treasury, Defense, Commerce, and Labor; the Director of the Bureau of the Budget; and the Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers to form a committee to coordinate the economic planning for the end of hostilities in Vietnam. As initial terms of reference, you instructed the Committee to —consider possibilities and priorities for tax adjustment —prepare, with the Federal Reserve Board, plans for quick adjustments of monetary and financial policies —determine which high priority programs can be quickly expanded —determine priorities for the longer range expansion of programs to meet the needs of the American people, both through new and existing programs —study and evaluate the future direction of Federal financial support to our States and local governments —examine ways in which the transition to peace can be smoothed for the workers, companies, and communities now engaged in supplying our defense needs, and for the men released from our armed forces. Vietnam hostilities first became a significant economic influence in the summer of 1965, at a time when the economy was remarkably well-balanced and was in the midst of the longest peacetime expansion in history. The increase in the military budget required for Vietnam (evident in Chart 1) complicated the tasks of fiscal-monetary policies. The economy was subjected to inflationary strains. Although the American economic system demonstrated the strength and adaptability necessary to carry the extra load without major disruption and without jeopardizing its fundamental health, the cost of war has been a load for the economy to carry—not a supporting "prop." Prosperity has not depended on the defense buildup and will not need high military spending to support it in peacetime. On the contrary, peace will provide the Nation with welcome opportunities to channel into civilian use manpower and material resources now being devoted to war. 187 Chart 1 Federal Purchases for National Defense BILLIONS OF DOLLARS LEVEL 80 * i i 60 - i *7 i 1968 PRICES-1-7 / / i t # — . \ # / 40 # / # / # / # / — IN CURRENT PRICES — 20 0 i i 1950 I 1 52 1 1 54 1 1 56 1 1 58 1 1 60 1 1 62 1 I 64 1 1 66 68 PERCENT AS PERCENT OF G N P ^ 7 15 - 10 5 0 - ' I 1950 I I 52 I I 54 I I 56 I I 58 I I 60 I I 62 I I 64 I I 66 I/CURRENT PRICES DIVIDED BY IMPLICIT PRICE DEFLATOR FOR TOTAL FEDERAL PURCHASES. 2/BASED ON CURRENT PRICES. NOTE: DATA RELATE TO PURCHASES OF GOODS AND SERVICES. SOURCES: DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE AND COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS. 188 I 68 SUMMARY OF FINDINGS A self-contained summary of the findings of the Committee is presented initially under three major headings. It is followed by more detailed discussion of each major section. FISCAL-MONETARY POLICIES DURING DEMOBILIZATION Sustaining prosperity during the demobilization and seizing the welcome opportunities of peacetime will depend upon the careful and forward-looking management of fiscal and monetary policies. If demobilization should produce a major and rapid decline in defense spending, and if policies were not adjusted, the Federal budget would have an excessively restrictive effect on the economy. An illustrative pattern of demobilization was developed on the assumption that, within 6 months after cessation of hostilities, a genuine peace would be secured and a full withdrawal of troops could be initiated. In such a rapid demobilization, the use of real resources for defense purposes would drop by $16 billion (annual rate in 1968 prices) below the previously planned path over a period of six quarters following the truce and, ultimately, by $19 billion at the end of 10 quarters. If there were no compensating fiscalmonetary policy actions, the Nation could be threatened with a recession similar to that at the end of Korean hostilities. The magnitude and the timing of the policy adjustment best suited to promote steady and healthy economic growth will depend on the strength of private demand at the time peace arrives and on the specific profile of the defense cutback. The best possible projections of these elements will be needed in order to guide fiscal-monetary policy. A number of possible compensating measures can be foreseen now. If the current 10 percent income tax surcharge is still in effect when hostilities end, its early expiration (or phasing out) could provide a major offsetting element. A detailed plan to speed up expenditures on established high priority projects should be available for the President's consideration. If further stimulus is appropriate, new program initiatives could be launched. The objectives of the compensating fiscal action should receive the support of monetary policy, but credit conditions probably should not be pushed into a posture of aggressive ease. Meanwhile, the objectives of an improved price-cost performance and balance-of-payments equilibrium should be pursued intensively. RESOURCES AND PRIORITIES The choices among alternative fiscal adjustments during the demobilization period should be guided by longer run priorities. Such priorities should be weighed in advance so that the Nation will be ready to take full advantage of any opportunities to launch important new programs, to strengthen high-priority existing programs, or to reduce taxes. 189 323-166 0—69 13 As revenues expand in a growing peacetime economy, the elbow room in the budget increases. But about one-half of the growth in revenues is preempted by essentially built-in commitments of existing expenditure programs to meet the needs of a growing population and an expanding economy. These commitments are reflected in the estimated "baseline" budget for both defense and nondefense expenditures in fiscal 1972. These estimates assume that the transition to peace is essentially completed by 1972, and that the current 10 percent income tax surcharge and certain excise taxes have expired by that time. According to the illustrative calculations, the "peace-and-growth dividend"—available for Federal programs above the baseline or for tax reduction—would amount to $22 billion by fiscal 1972, and would increase $7 to $8 billion a year thereafter. The peace-and-growth dividend must be used in order to maintain healthy economic growth, and it can be used constructively. Some possible uses of the dividend are set forth to illustrate the considerable pressures, demands, and opportunities for Federal efforts in the years ahead. Some liberalization of social insurance and other cash benefits—in part, to keep up with the cost of living—is viewed as a significant claim on the dividend. In addition, the full funding of existing civilian programs to authorized levels would cost $6 billion a year. Beyond that, a variety of major expansions in existing programs and of new programs are highly eligible claimants. A selection of such items, based largely on proposals which have been made by experts or study groups, adds up to $40 billion a year. And other more ambitious, new proposals, which are currently receiving widespread public discussion must also be recognized. Furthermore, tax reduction merits consideration as an effective way to share part of the dividend broadly among Americans. It is clear that the Nation cannot carry out all these activities—funding existing programs, undertaking new program initiatives, and reducing taxes—in the next few years from the peace-and-growth dividend; difficult choices based on a careful determination of priorities will be necessary. But for those objectives placed at the top of society's priority list, progress can be made in a peaceful environment of prosperity and reasonable price stability. As noted above, our calculations allow for expiration of temporary taxes now in effect. In view of the urgent needs of the public sector, the Committee would not recommend further large-scale Federal tax reductions in the years immediately following the end of Vietnam hostilities. POLICIES TO ASSIST PARTICULAR COMMUNITIES AND INDIVIDUALS The economic impact of the war has been broadly diffused among all States and most industries. Only a relatively small number of areas and industries are likely to be specially affected by the demobilization or to encounter significant transitional problems. The Committee recommends 190 certain measures to aid people in those areas and industries, including: community redevelopment assistance, homeowner assistance, and—most importantly—the strengthening of job placement and training. We also recorrimend the early establishment of a coordinating group, which might be called the Readjustment Operations Committee, to assume responsibility for detailed planning of Federal readjustment assistance, to work with State and local authorities responsible for demobilization planning, and to coordinate Federal readjustment programs during demobilization. The steps we propose for readjustment assistance are limited and relatively inexpensive, reflecting our conviction that the maintenance of general prosperity is far and away the major part of the economic problem of the transition. In our dynamic and flexible free market economy, most areas and industries should be able to make a prompt and healthy adjustment so long as the Federal Government promotes noninflationary prosperity. LOOKING FORWARD TO PEACE We also wish to stress the importance of a responsible and responsive fiscal policy during the remaining period of hostilities. Only in recent months, through the enactment of the 1968 program of fiscal restraint, have our Nation's finances become adequately adjusted to the defense emergency situation. Maintenance of appropriate fiscal and monetary policy is absolutely essential both to preserve prosperity and to minimize the problem of transition at the end of hostilities. FISCAL-MONETARY POLICIES DURING DEMOBILIZATION Peace may "break out" in any number of ways. For example, hostilities may decline gradually, accompanied by reduced expenditures on armament and manpower. Alternatively, there could be a lengthy armed truce which would permit no significant reduction in our forces in Southeast Asia. DEMOBILIZATION SCENARIO In the calculations underlying this report, defense activities in Vietnam are assumed to continue at essentially present levels until hostilities cease. It is furthermore assumed that, within 6 months after a truce, there will be a genuine assurance of peace and hence the beginnings of a full withdrawal of troops from Vietnam with accompanying cutbacks in other outlays. An illustrative demobilization scenario developed by the Department of Defense points to the reductions in manpower, materials, and outlays described below. These are the amounts by which defense activities would fall short of the path that they would have followed had hostilities continued. 1. The armed services would decline by about 800,000 persons, averaging 200,000 a quarter starting in the third quarter following the truce and terminating after the sixth quarter. 2. Civilian personnel in the Department of Defense would be reduced by 170,000, also declining smoothly between the third and sixth quarters. 3. As a result of the manpower reduction, military and civilian compensation would be reduced by $7 billion (annual rate) at 1968 pay rates by the end of the sixth quarter. 4. Other operating expenditures (annual rate in 1968 prices) would decline by $4 billion over a slightly longer period. 5. Expenditures for procurement would be reduced by $8 billion over an interval of 10 quarters. This reduction would take longer in order to rebuild inventories held by the Department of Defense. 6. Total real defense spending (annual rate in 1968 prices) would thus be reduced by $8 billion at the end of four quarters, $16 billion at the end of six quarters, and $19 billion at the end of 10 quarters. The time profile of the assumed reduction in real expenditures is shown in Chart 2. Chart 2 Illustrative Reduction in Defense Spending With a Vietnam Demobilization BILLIONS O F DOLLARS, 1 9 6 8 PRICES (ANNUAL RATES) 20 TOTAL REDUCTION IN DEFENSE SPENDING 15 M - iiii ~ ^PROCUREMENT^X^^^^^^g 10 - 5 •" PERSONNEL COMPENSATION 1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 1 7 I 8 } 9 QUARTERS FOLLOWING TRUCE NOTE—DATA RELATE TO FEDERAL PURCHASES OF GOODS AND SERVICES FOR NATIONAL DEFENSE. SOURCE: COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS BASED ON ESTIMATES OF DEPARTMENT OF DEFENSE. 192 1 10 t 11 12 This is a rapid demobilization—probably the most rapid that could realistically be assumed. Demobilization may in fact turn out to be smaller or more gradual as a result of any one of at least three developments: 1. A gradual decline in military activity prior to the truce, 2. A long period of uncertainty between the attainment of the truce and the decision for redeployment, or 3. The need to maintain significant residual forces in Vietnam, even in peacetime. The rapid pattern of demobilization is assumed because it represents the sharpest test of the Nation's ability to adapt to peace—not because it appears most probable. If the Nation is ready to meet the challenge of rapid demobilization, the lesser challenge of a more gradual transition can surely be handled. The estimated decline in defense expenditures is significantly less than the $29 billion a year currently estimated as the cost of the war. Of resources currently used for Vietnam, $10 billion would be required in other military uses in peacetime. The reduction in Vietnam outlays during the demobilization will appear as a shortfall from an otherwise increasing path of defense spending. If hostilities were to continue with undiminished intensity, the total defense budget would probably continue to rise at least enough to cover increases in military pay scales and gradual advances in prices paid for defense goods. A hypothetical example is presented in Chart 3 to illustrate the relationship between the paths of defense spending with and without the demobilization. In this illustration, defense purchases are assumed to be $80 billion initially and to be rising at the rate of $1 billion a quarter to cover price and pay increases and to provide for a very modest real growth. In the absence of peace, defense purchases would reach $86 billion after six quarters and $90 billion after 10 quarters. The demobilization scenario above implies that defense purchases would be pulled below this rising path by about $16 billion six quarters after the cessation of hostilities, and by about $19 billion after 10 quarters. The absolute decline from the initial level of $80 billion would be considerably less, reaching $10 billion at the end of six quarters. ECONOMIC IMPACT The economic impact of the demobilization (and the required fiscalmonetary adjustment) can be most readily appraised by supposing that the fiscal program had been appropriately designed initially, under the assumption of continuing hostilities, to promote a balance between aggregate demand and the economy's supply capabilities. In this situation, a major policy adjustment would be required to offset the shortfall resulting from demobilization. The impact of demobilization on the balance between aggregate demand and the economy's productive capacity has three aspects. X 93 Chart 3 Illustrative Paths of Defense Spending With and Without a Vietnam Demobilization BILLIONS OF DOLLARS (ANNUAL RATES) DEFENSE SPENDING 90 UNDER HYPOTHETICAL CONTINUATION OF HOSTILITIES 85 80 75 UNDER DEMOBILIZATION 70 65 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 QUARTERS FOLLOWING TRUCE N0TE._DATA RELATE TO FEDERAL PURCHASES OF GOODS AND SERVICES FOR NATIONAL DEFENSE. SOURCE: COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS BASED ON ESTIMATES OF DEPARTMENT OF DEFENSE. 1. The reduced use of resources by the Federal Government, reflected in the decline of defense spending described above. 2. The short-run downward adjustments of inventories by defense suppliers as their production is adjusted to declining orders and falls below deliveries to the Government. The economic impact would occur even before Federal expenditures declined, and would remain significant for only about four quarters after the truce. 3. An increase in the Nation's potential output resulting from the potential additional employment of released military personnel in civilian jobs, where productivity is substantially greater. Some women will withdraw from the labor force when their husbands return to civilian life, and some veterans will return to school before entering the civilian labor force. After allowing for these elements, the cumulative net induced increase in the private labor force is estimated at about 600,000 after six quarters. This shift toward higher productivity would add about $4 or $5 billion to potential GNP. To absorb this increment, action would be required to add nearly $2 billion directly to total demand. The resulting additional 194 incomes could be expected to generate the necessary additional $2 to $3 billion increment in demand. With no policy offset whatsoever, the direct shortfall of demand by the sixth quarter following the truce could amount to $18 billion: $16 billion for the real decline in military spending and $2 billion for the direct increment in demand needed to make use of the addition to potential output. Shifts in the strength of private demand might either reduce or add to this gap, but they would be unlikely to change the picture dramatically. Without compensatory stabilization action, the gap would be multiplied through induced further cutbacks in demand that spread through the private sector. Eight quarters after the truce, the total multiplied shortfall below the potential output of the economy could reach $40 billion. Inaction would thus threaten a recession similar to the 1953-54 experience following the Korean hostilities. FISCAL-MONETARY ADJUSTMENT The instruments of fiscal and monetary policy must be available for prompt and decisive use to promote noninflationary prosperity and economic growth. These instruments are clearly capable, in principle, of offsetting the restrictive fiscal impact of demobilization. Indeed, an excessive or premature stimulative fiscal-monetary program could overdo the job and generate an inflationary boom. A major challenge will be to determine and carry out a policy adjustment of proper size and timing. Determining the Magnitude The above projections merely suggest the general magnitude of the policy requirements during a rapid demobilization. The specific dimensions can only be appraised when peace comes and much more is known about the prospects for private demand, the budget, and the time-path of the military cutback. Nevertheless, some important guides can be provided to the problems and procedures involved in determining the magnitude of the compensating actions. 1. When peace comes, the President and the Congress will need advice based on detailed projections of the GNP, prices, unemployment, and the balance of international payments. Despite the inherent limitations of projections, prudent reliance on quantitative forecasts—carefully weighed and interpreted—is preferable to a policy of wait-and-see, a resort to predetermined rules of policy adjustment, or a simple extrapolation of existing economic conditions. 2. Efforts should begin now to strengthen the quality of statistical information about the economy's performance—such as those improvements recommended in the budget program for fiscal 1969. Information of this type may be critical in determining the appropriateness of policy during the demobilization. 3. For the same reasons, the Department of Defense should continue intensive efforts to improve projections of military orders and outlays so as to aid economic policy during demobilization. Assessing the time-path of the military cutback will be subject to uncertainties similar to those that were encountered in appraising the initial defense buildup in Vietnam. 4. Flexibility of fiscal and monetary policy decisions will be important to the success of adjustment. Even with the best efforts, gauging private demand and defense outlays will be difficult. During the demobilization, prediction of private spending will be complicated by the substantial psychological impacts of peace on private decisionmakers. It is a safe judgment that Americans will be delighted by peace, but it does not follow that they will therefore spend more, or alternatively that they will save more. Hence a successful transition program—marked by steadiness and stability in the growth, employment, and price performance of the Nation—may require continuing adjustments in the budgetary balance and in the behavior of monetary and credit flows. 5. Fiscal-monetary policies for the transition should take into account the initial economic situation. If the economy is advancing too rapidly when peace comes, the restrictive effect of demobilization should not be entirely offset. If the economy is initially sluggish, the adjustment of stabilization policies should more than compensate for the impact of demobilization. Types of Compensatory Action In the event of a rapid demobilization, the required policy adjustment may be large. This extraordinary "dividend" would be fully available to provide for "controllable" expenditures or tax reductions, unlike the normal fiscal dividend from growing tax revenues which must, in part, finance the built-in growth of Federal expenditures. The various types of action which might be undertaken should be considered in advance. 1. If the cessation of hostilities occurs while the income tax surcharge is still in effect, its early expiration (or phasing out) could provide a major element in the required fiscal offset. Acceleration of the currently scheduled reductions in excise taxes on automobiles and telephone service could serve as another element in the fiscal adjustment. 2. There should be available, for the President's consideration, a program of accelerated expenditures that could be initiated on short notice following the cessation of hostilities. These should be confined to highpriority public expenditures which, in any event, would be made in the near future. It is currently estimated that such a program could add to Federal expenditures (at annual rates) by as much as $3 billion in 6 months and $7.5 billion in 12 months following its activation. 3. Decisions on Federal expenditures, as part of the program of fiscal adjustment, should be made in light of the promptness with which various types of outlays will add to total demand. For example, according to our staff studies, some—although not all—Federal grant programs to States 196 and localities involve a significant lag between the expenditure of the funds by the Federal Government and their translation into additional purchases by the recipients. Programs with long lags are not ideal for supporting demand during the transition. In contrast, other Federal programs generate orders or contracts to the private sector which would increase employment and economic activity promptly even before expenditures are incurred by the Federal Government. 4. While the precise assignment of responsibilities between fiscal and monetary policies should be made in full light of the circumstances associated with peace, monetary policy should be expected to play a supportive role to the fiscal program. Credit policies can undoubtedly help significantly to ensure an adequate supply of mortgage credit to meet the needs for additional housing. But placing a heavy readjustment burden on monetary policy would be inadvisable; it probably should not shift toward extreme ease to provide a maximum economic stimulant. For one thing, balanceof-payments considerations are likely to limit, to some degree, the easing of credit. Also, the flexibility inherent in monetary policy makes it a useful instrument to hold in reserve as a means of compensating for deficiencies or excesses that might develop in the fiscal program or for unforeseen developments in private demand. 5. In general, fiscal policy adjustments during the transition should advance longer range national objectives. One basic choice will concern the relative importance in the fiscal program of tax reduction and of increased Federal expenditures. This decision should not be governed by considerations of economic stabilization; various mixes of increased spending and reduced taxes can be equally satisfactory from that standpoint. Rather the choice should depend upon the extent to which the Nation wishes to channel resources from defense uses into the other areas of the public sector. Given the allocation between tax cuts and increased civilian programs, further choices will be required to set priorities among various existing programs and possible new programs. These priorities should be established in advance. 6. In the event that the Administration plans to initiate, during the transition, any new programs which would require major legislation, such legislation might be submitted to the Congress in the near future for discussion and debate and perhaps even for enactment on a standby basis. Thus these programs could be ready when needed. Other Objectives In addition to the objective of steady and sustainable growth at high employment, policies during the transition should be directed at the price performance of the economy and the balance of payments. 1. During the transition period, efforts should be redoubled to combat the troublesome inflationary tendencies of a high-employment economy. The efforts could include various measures which have been explored recently by the Cabinet Committee on Price Stability: to strengthen manpower programs, to improve the price performance of particularly troublesome sectors such as construction and medical care, to increase the efficiency of the private economy generally, to minimize any inflationary effects of the Federal Government's own activities, and to achieve, through cooperative efforts, patterns of collective bargaining and of business price determination that are consistent with over-all price stability. 2. Intensive efforts should be made to take full advantage of the opportunities that peace may bring for improvement in the U.S. balance of payments. The direct foreign exchange cost of our military presence in Southeast Asia is now about $1.6 billion a year higher than in 1965. Reduction in this outflow could be reinforced by other measures to yield a more comprehensive solution to our lingering international payments problem. RESOURCES AND PRIORITIES Many of the choices that will have to be made during transition should be guided by a longer range view. To build the best bridge to peacetime prosperity, we should know in advance where we want to go when we cross that bridge. The following projections are intended to provide an indication of the resources that will become available in the next few years, and to serve as an aid in making critical choices about the uses of these resources. The projections are focused on fiscal 1972. They are based on the assumption that the transition will be essentially completed by that time, an assumption that is reasonably consistent with the demobilization scenario if a truce occurs during calendar 1969. PROJECTIONS OF THE PRIVATE ECONOMY Underlying the post-demobilization outlook are some fairly detailed economic projections prepared by our staff. While these projections are surely not to be regarded as precise forecasts of economic conditions, they provide useful rough indications, on the basis of reasonable assumptions, of what the economic situation might be. The economic framework was based on an unemployment rate of 3.8 percent and an over-all rate of price increase which gradually declines to about 2 percent a year by 1972. These assumptions represent neither a forecast nor a judgment that these rates will necessarily be feasible or appropriate. Lower unemployment would result in a higher GNP and increased budgetary resources. Greater price stability would also be highly desirable. What combination of price stability and high employment will prove feasible depends upon the success of measures to help reconcile these two objectives. The time-path of real GNP was estimated, using labor force, employment, and productivity projections supplied by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. On the basis of the projected path of the over-all price index of GNP, the estimated GNP (in current dollars) for fiscal 1972 is $1,100 billion (Table 1). 198 TABLE 1.—Illustrative projections for fiscal year 1972 and recent experience [Billions of dollars] Calendar year Item 1968, Gross national product Federal receipts.._ second half * 879 _ _. 185 Federal expenditures and dividend. 186 Baseline expenditures _. 186 80 106 Defense purchases.. Other expenditures. Peace-and-growth dividend. Federal surplus or deficit ( - ) . _ _ -1 Fiscal year 1972 projected 1,100 226 222 200 73 127 22 4 i Seasonally adjusted annual rates; preliminary. Note.—Federal receipts, expenditures, and surplus or deficit are the concepts used in the Federal Government sector of the national income and product accounts. Detail will not necessarily add to totals because of rounding. Sources: Department of Commerce and Council of Economic Advisers. This GNP estimate served as the basis for projecting anticipated Federal revenue in 1972, in line with the assumed growth of incomes. Projected revenues are augmented by scheduled increases in social security taxes, and reduced by the assumed expiration of the current 10 percent income tax surcharge and of excise taxes on telephone service and automobiles. The net result of these calculations is an estimate of Federal receipts in fiscal 1972 of $226 billion. Next the various components of private demand were projected, allowing for the effect of tax payments on private incomes and assuming that the indicated GNP was in fact achieved. Specific allowances for the impact of the Housing Act of 1968 were incorporated into the projection of residential construction activity. Additional estimates were also made for anticipated State and local government expenditures. BASELINE FEDERAL EXPENDITURES A baseline level of Federal expenditures was then projected. Defense Baseline defense expenditures for fiscal 1972 are calculated on the assumption that non-Vietnam programs now funded or approved will be carried out on schedule with no stretchout or cancellation. No allowance is made for possible new defense programs. These baseline defense expenditures are consistent with the demobilization scenario outlined earlier. The estimate for defense purchases is $73 billion in fiscal 1972, compared to $80 billion in the second half of calendar 1968. The $7 billion decline is the result of the reduction in spending associated with Vietnam (which amounts to $19 bil- 199 lion at 1968 prices, as shown in Chart 2), offset in part by allowances for higher pay scales, some upcreep in prices paid for defense items, and program adjustments following the end of the war. In constant prices, the baseline estimate for fiscal 1972 is nearly 20 percent below current real defense outlays. Compared with the pre-Vietnam average level of 1960-64, real baseline expenditures for fiscal year 1972 are roughly 15 percent higher. The calculations of cost increases are necessarily imprecise because the character of defense equipment and programs changes markedly over time. After 1972, baseline defense expenditures would move up slowly, mainly to keep pace with rising costs. Nondefense Baseline Federal nondefense expenditures rise over time for several reasons. Some gradual increases must be expected in the prices of the things the Government buys, and the pay of civilian Government employees must be raised about in pace with wages and salaries elsewhere. More veterans become eligible for pensions; more Government employees qualify for retirement benefits; a growing population increases the workload of many Government agencies, such as the Post Office Department and the National Park Service; and so on. Social security benefits rise even with an unchanged benefit formula, as more persons become eligible for benefits and as the average past income of applicants rises. As a result, baseline nondefense expenditures will rise nearly $7 billion per year to reach $127 billion in fiscal 1972. THE PEACE-AND-GROWTH DIVIDEND The peace-and-growth dividend may be defined as the additional total demand—over and above normal private demand and baseline Federal expenditures—needed to achieve the specified GNP target. Estimated total demand for goods and services—including that in the baseline Federal budget—adds up to $1,078 billion for fiscal 1972. The difference of $22 billion between the target GNP of $1,100 billion and estimated total demand is the peace-and-growth dividend. It represents the additional total demand that would have to be forthcoming to achieve the GNP target. For the years following 1972, the annual peace-and-growth dividend may be expected to grow $7 or $8 billion a year, as annual Federal revenues expand by roughly $15 billion and baseline expenditures absorb about half of that growth. The peace-and-growth dividend can be viewed in another way. Between now and fiscal 1972, the $19 billion decline in defense expenditures resulting from peace in combination with normal revenue growth provides sufficient Federal budgetary resources to cover built-in defense and nondefense commitments, to permit removal of the surcharge, and to allow for a further $22 billion addition to total demand through expansionary policy actions. 2OO The peace-and-growth dividend is thus a rough measure of the resources available for expansionary action. A dollar of this dividend may be "used up" either by a dollar of increased Federal purchases or by a dollar of additional private purchases. The latter could be induced by a reduction in taxes, an increase in Federal transfer payments, or an easing of monetary policy. An increase in transfer payments or a reduction in taxes of one dollar will generally not increase private spending by a full dollar; to the extent that these instruments are used, the total of expansionary fiscal action can be somewhat greater than the peace-and-growth dividend. The projections implicitly assume certain monetary conditions and interest rates. The appropriate Federal Reserve policy may be either more restrictive or more stimulative than assumed, thus affecting fiscal policy requirements. The appropriate budget deficit or surplus in any given year is determined by the fiscal action needed to support private demand in light of monetary conditions. The above calculations imply a $4 billion surplus (national income accounts basis) in fiscal 1972. Private demand may be either weaker or stronger than assumed, thereby calling for a different budgetary policy. If private demand is weaker, smaller surpluses (or possibly deficits) will be needed, and the peace-and-growth dividend in fiscal 1972 will be larger than $22 billion. Conversely, if private demand is stronger, larger surpluses will be needed and the dividend will be smaller. ALTERNATIVE USES OF THE DIVIDEND The peace-and-growth dividend must be used in some fashion if the growth and employment targets are to be achieved. And it surely can be used productively by strengthening valuable Federal programs, enacting tax reductions, and easing monetary policy. Indeed, the problem will be to choose among many worthy alternatives. There is no limit to the portion of the peace-and-growth dividend that could, in principle, take the form of a lighter tax burden on individuals and businesses. This use of the dividend would contribute effectively to achieving the growth and employment targets. Our national experience from 1962 to 1965 demonstrates the effectiveness of the stimulus from a markedly lightened Federal tax burden. But the use of the dividend to reduce Federal taxes must compete with compelling needs for strengthened and new public expenditure programs. The ultimate national decisions on priorities must focus on the allocation of the dividend between these two basic routes. Some of the possible increases in Federal expenditures are spelled out below. Two areas of expenditure that would appear to have a significant claim are: increases in benefits needed to maintain standards under social security and related Federal programs, and the full funding of existing programs which are currently operating below authorized levels. 201 Maintaining Standards Under Cash Benefit Programs The baseline expenditure projections allow for growth in social security and other transfer benefits resulting from an increased number of recipients and an increase in the lifetime earnings of recipients under the present benefit formula. But they make no allowance for statutory liberalization of benefit formulas under Old Age and Survivor's Insurance, unemployment insurance, Federal retirement, railroad retirement, veterans benefits, and public assistance programs. If, in fact, there were no legislative liberalization, social insurance trust funds would accumulate a substantial surplus, while benefits would shrink in terms of purchasing power. A legislated increase of $4 billion by fiscal 1972 in these benefit formulas would ensure that benefits at least keep pace with assumed increases in the cost of living. Full Funding of Existing Programs Several Federal programs, particularly ones adopted recently, are operating below levels authorized by the Congress. To fund these programs fully, thus making appropriations match authorizations, would cost about $6 billion a year as distributed in Table 2. These programs are already making important contributions to the solution of major social and environmental problems, and increasing their appropriations to authorized levels would probably command high priority. Nevertheless, in establishing priorities, the relative value of each of these programs should be weighed against those of new or expanded programs and of tax reduction. TABLE 2.—Estimated gap between amounts currently authorized and funded Billions of dollars per year Program 6.0 Total full cost.. 2.0 1.3 .6 .5 .2 Elementary and secondary education ., Higher education Housing and community development Water and air pollution control Crime control and prevention Area redevelopment _._ Health training and research, etc __. Agricultural conservation and adjustment. '.A .5 Source: Bureau of the Budget. New Efforts in Civilian Programs A variety of new efforts—entirely new programs or major expansions of existing civilian programs—are also eligible claimants for a share of the peace-and-growth dividend. A review of recent recommendations by task forces or study groups indicates the possible desirability of new domestic programs in the fields of education, health, job and manpower training, social insurance, welfare, urban development, crime prevention, 202 air and water pollution control, natural resource development, transportation, space technology, and science. Table 3 contains a list of programs that have been prominently and generally discussed recently as desirable to meet the needs of the Nation during the next several years. The table is presented for illustrative purposes only and does not indicate any program priorities. It sets forth quantitative estimates of the expenditures that might take place in each of these programs during fiscal 1972. In many instances, the dollar amounts shown in the table are considerably below the recommendations of recent task forces or study groups. By many standards, the list is incomplete and inadequate. Yet, it totals $40 billion—nearly double the entire estimated peace-and-growth dividend for that year. The clear lesson emerging from this table—and the reason for its inclusion in this report—is that some very difficult choices will have to be made. New Defense Programs Depending upon international developments affecting our national security and upon technological changes in weapon systems, added expenditures on new defense programs may be needed. If these are essential to our national security, they must be given a top priority claim on the peaceand-growth dividend. At the same time, it is clear that the possibilities for expansion in the defense area are virtually unlimited, and that utmost efficiency will continue to be needed in budgeting for defense. For illustrative purposes, the staff of the Department of Defense has assembled a package of $6j/i billion (annual rate) of expenditures on new DOD programs which may come up for consideration in the next few years. The major elements in the package are expenditures of $2 billion for aircraft development and modernization in connection with major new programs, $0.8 billion for the construction of defense installations and family housing projects, $0.7 billion for shipbuilding and modernization of naval forces, and $2 billion for advanced strategic and general purpose weapon systems. Major New Initiatives The proposals listed in Table 3 essentially expand or build upon existing programs. More elaborate proposals have also been advanced as alternatives to this piecemeal approach. A comprehensive income maintenance plan, such as the "negative income tax," has been widely discussed as a simple and equitable device to assist the poor. A negative income tax that succeeded in making major inroads on poverty while preserving work incentives might cost as much as $15 to $20 billion a year. Such a program would protect people against the ravages of poverty, but it would still need to be reinforced by efforts in housing, health, education, and job training aimed at the long-run sources and causes of poverty. 203 TABLE 3.—Illustrative new programs or major expansions of existing Federal civilian programs, fiscal year 1972 {derived from proposals of task forces and study groups) Hypothetical expenditures (billions of dollars) Program Total expenditures.. 39.7 Education Preschool Elementary and secondary.. Higher.. Vocational 7.0 1.0 2.5 3.0 Health Kiddie-care Medicare for disabled Comprehensive health centers Hospital construction and modernization.. 3.8 .5 1.8 1.0 Nutrition 1.0 .8 Community service programs. Jobs and manpower Public jobs Manpower Development Training Act. Employment service 2.5 1.8 .5 .2 Social security and income support Unemployment insurance Public assistance Social security improvements 9.5 2.0 4.0 3.5 .3 Veterans Economic, area, and other special development programs.. Entrepreneurial aid Area redevelopment Rural development Indian assistance 2.2 Crime, delinquency, and riots Violence and riot prevention Safe streets programs — Rehabilitation of offenders and delinquents 1.0 .1 .3 .3 .3 L0 — Prevention of delinquency and crime by special measures for delinquency-prone youthQuality of environment Air pollution prevention and control Public water supply construction programs Water pollution control and sewage treatment Solid waste disposal Natural beautification, environmental protection, and recreational development Natural resource development and utilization Land and forest conservation... Water resources and related programs Mineral and energy (excluding hydroelectric) development Natural environmental development _ ___ !3 1.0 .1 .2 1.4 !5 .2 .5 5.5 Urban development _ _ ___. New cities Land acquisition and financial planning (suburban).. Urban mass transportation Model cities _ Other urban facilities and renewal Transportation _ Airway and airport modernization _ Rapid interurban ground transit.. _ Modernization of merchant marine Motor vehicle and transportation safety research and safety grants 1.7 .5 .5 2.0 2.0 1.0 .4 .1 ._ .3 Science and space exploration Post-Apollo space program _ Scientific research in oceanography, communications, social and behavioral sciences, and natural sciences _ 1.0 Foreign economic aid 1.0 See Notes at end of table. 204 .5 TABLE 3.—Illustrative new programs or major expansions of existing Federal civilian programs, fiscal year 1972 (derived from proposals of task forces and study groups)—Continued NOTES Education. The preschool program, an extension of Head Start, would provide full-time preschool education for about 500,000 children.The elementary and secondary education funds would about double the Federal support in that area. The funds proposed for higher education would more than double current Federal support.The vocational education funds would raise Federal support about halfway toward the recommendation of the 1968 Advisory Council on Vocational Education. Health. The "kiddie-care" proposal would provide health care for needy mothers and infants. Medicare offered to beneficiaries of social security disability insurance on a contributory basis would potentially reach 2.2 million persons in 1972. About 350 additional comprehensive neighborhood health care centers a year could be established for the amount shown. The added funds for health facilities would enable the Federal Government to double the rate of output of such facilities, in line with estimates of national needs. Nutrition. Nutritional supplements for needy pregnant women, nursing mothers, and small infants account for about $200 million, while the remainder would allow a doubling of existing food assistance programs. Community service programs. This would provide for expanded daycare centers for children of needy working mothers and for expansion of coordinated services through neighborhood centers. Jobs and manpower. The funds for jobs in the public sector would permit expansion of about 500,000 jobs to provide public service employment for the chronically disadvantaged; this program would reinforce expansion in education, health services, and urban and area redevelopment. The increase in MDTA training would support expansion of the JOBS program and would reinforce efforts to lower unemployment while improving the Nation's price performance. It would also provide trained manpower for construction. The growth in employment service operations envisions strengthening, decentralizing, and computerizing manpower activities; developing a rural manpower service; and enlarging services to the disadvantaged. Social security and income support. The unemployment insurance funds would provide for higher benefits, extended benefits during recessions, and aid to the unemployed through retraining and mobility assistance. The public assistance funds could permit revision of benefit standards and extended coverage, or the adoption of a modest new program of income aid with objective standards. The added expenditure could fill as much as 40 percent of the current poverty income gap. Expansion of the WIN program would provide more job and training opportunities for welfare recipients. The social security expenditure couid provide a higher minimum benefit for those dependent on social insurance benefits as the main source of income, and liberalization of eligibility requirements for disability insurance, as well as some general improvement in benefit levels. Veterans. The higher priority recommendations made by the Veterans' Advisory Commission in March 1968 could be instituted with these funds. Economic, area, and other special development programs. The entrepreneurial assistance program could help minority groups—so-called "black capitalism." Area redevelopment programs would assist growth centers in less populated areas, while rural redevelopment programs would concentrate on small communities, providing community facility development, special housing, and family farm assistance. Crime, delinquency, and riots. Federal aid to State and local governments could be provided to help prevent violence and riots and permit a higher degree of Federal readiness to cope with such emergencies. The safe streets program funds would be used to work towards the objectives of the National Crime Commission with respect to strengthening the police and courts. Rehabilitation of offenders and delinquents would be pursued by intensive retraining and other services. Quality of environment. Federal funds for pollution abatement may be required to enforce standards, investigate claims, or abate pollution caused by government or not readily attributable to particular private individuals. Assistance in expanding the Nation's water supply system would provide a small fraction of the $2.5 billion annual requirement over the next 10 years. Provision of more recreational areas near population centers would be made possible. Natural resource development and utilization. Department of the Interior, Corps of Engineers, and Department of Agriculture programs relating to land, mineral, energy, forest, recreational, and other fields have large backlogs of useful projects, many already planned and authorized but held back for budgetary reasons. Urban development. Metropolitan development assistance would support improved planning and coordinated advance land acquisition. Each of these programs emphasizes these requirements, whether in new communities, suburbs, or older central cities. The allowances represent only a fractional contribution to the reconstruction and development of the cities. Transportation. Such expanded investments in the improvement of the principal elements of the Nation's transportation system would serve the objectives of economic development, safety, and national defense. Science and space exploration. The allowances would permit the science and space agenices to fund some of the research opportunities not covered in the stringent budgets of recent years. Foreign economic aid. This additional amount would help to meet growth targets in Southeast Asia and under the Alliance for Progress as well as to cover other aid requirements. Even this increase would leave our foreign assistance program below levels of a few years back. Source: Bureau of the Budget. 205 323-166 0—69 14 An alternative major program initiative would provide guaranteed employment opportunities for persons willing and able to work but unable to find jobs. Depending on eligibility criteria and the techniques of implementation, such a program might cost $2 to $10 billion a year. Another area of mounting public concern is the financial pressure on State and local governments. As a means of reducing the relative importance of the more onerous State and local taxes, the Federal Government might adopt some general scheme of revenue sharing—such as a return of some personal tax revenues to the States (or localities) or a Federal tax credit for State income taxes. Some suggested plans would cost $5 to $10 billion a year. A specific but more limited proposal along these lines would be the establishment of a trust fund to finance a generalized Model Cities program. Another major proposal that has much support is the establishment of an Urban Development Bank, which would raise its funds in the private capital market. This institution would lend to State and local governments at reduced cost, thereby relieving the pressure on the market for tax-exempt securities. It would place only a minimal burden on the Federal budget since the interest subsidies would be offset, at least in part, by increased Treasury receipts from reduced use of the tax exemption. But the charge against national resources—and therefore against the peace-andgrowth dividend—would be substantial, depending upon the extent to which the Bank finances projects that would not otherwise have been undertaken. There have also been proposals for replacing the present military draft with a more equitable and efficient method of obtaining the manpower needed for national defense. One such proposal, which might cost $5 to $10 billion a year, would be the adoption of a fully volunteer army. Another would be the establishment of a National Service Corps, in which every young person would be expected to give at least 2 years of service to the Nation either as a member of the Armed Forces or in a civilian assignment that would contribute to the solution of important national problems. Conclusion The problems of poverty, human resource development, and the pressing need to improve our physical environment will impose very heavy demands on the Federal budget in the years ahead. The end of the struggle in Vietnam, together with increased tax revenues resulting from economic growth, will make a sizable volume of real resources available to deal with these problems. But, for years and years ahead, the peace-and-growth dividend is dwarfed by the magnitude of the needs. Difficult choices must be made— choices between increased expenditures and tax reductions, between defense spending and nondefense programs, and among competing civilian programs. The above calculations allow for tax reduction from present rate levels through the expiration of the 10 percent surcharge and certain excise taxes. These funds would permit the private sector to engage in extra private 206 consumption or investment above the normal growth of private demand, But in view of the vast and urgent needs for services that can best be supplied through the public sector, we would not recommend further largescale Federal tax reductions in the years immediately following the end of Vietnam hostilities. POLICIES TO ASSIST PARTICULAR COMMUNITIES AND INDIVIDUALS Demobilization will require some shifts in employment patterns—from the Armed Forces to civilian jobs, from defense industries to those producing civilian goods and services, and from one community or area to another. Shifts in the composition of activity will not be new or unusual. They are a regular feature of the highly mobile and dynamic U.S. economy. As technology and the pattern of demand evolve, the free choices of businesses, workers, and consumers operate through markets to shift resources among industries and geographic areas. These movements are largely self-adjusting and do not usually pose major problems either to workers or communities. When support is needed, various Federal agencies stand ready to assist through community development activities, job information, and manpower training. The Office of Economic Adjustment in the Department of Defense has been dealing since 1961 with the specific economic impact associated with closings of defense installations and other major changes in military outlays. The experience of these activities provides a guide for policies to assist in the adjustment problems of those communities and individuals likely to be severely affected by demobilization. Measures to assist in specific adjustments can complement fiscal-monetary policy in producing a smooth, noninflationary transition. THE MAGNITUDE OF THE READJUSTMENT Under the particularly rapid demobilization scenario assumed above, an estimated 600,000 persons would be added to the private labor force during the six quarters following the truce. In addition, as many as 750,000 civilian employees could be required to shift jobs as defense purchases from private businesses decline. Altogether, an additional 1.3 million workers may seek new civilian employment over a period of six quarters—an average of about 75,000 job shifts a month over and above those normally taking place. The shifts would be unevenly spaced during the period and might exceed 100,000 in some months. This is a significant—but not enormous—addition to the normal amount of job shifting. To provide perspective, in 1966-67 the average number of layoffs per month in manufacturing alone was about 250,000, and voluntary 207 separations averaged about 470,000 a month, while manufacturing workers were hired at an average monthly rate of 730,000 in 1966 and 640,000 in 1967. While no comparable data exist for nonmanufacturing sectors, layoffs and hirings for the total economy must be far larger. The figures indicate the dynamism and the normal adaptations of the labor market. While specific problems of dislocation in certain areas will occur, the figures do indicate that the magnitude of the demobilization problem should be manageable if fiscal-monetary policies ensure that overall demand remains strong. Particular measures to facilitate the structural transitions of demobilization should include community redevelopment assistance, homeowner assistance, and, most importantly, the strengthening of job placement and job training. Efficient planning and implementation of these measures will require the establishment of a coordinating committee. READJUSTMENT OPERATIONS COMMITTEE A Readjustment Operations Committee should be established in the near future to assume responsibility for detailed planning of Federal readjustment assistance and to work closely with State and local authorities. The Committee should include the Secretaries of Defense, Commerce, and Labor; the Director of the Bureau of the Budget; the Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers; and the Director of the Office of Emergency Preparedness. Prior to demobilization, the Committee should be responsible for: 1. Planning for demobilization, including frequent updating of the estimated expenditures required for adjustment assistance, 2. Undertaking and supporting research on characteristics of individual communities likely to require special readjustment assistance and in particular developing a system of "early warning," 3. Providing technical advice and information for State and local government demobilization planning authorities, and 4. Coordinating an inventory by the Departments of Defense, Commerce, and Labor of the skills and training of defense industry workers and armed services personnel, and of the skill requirements of potential sources of employment in defense-dependent areas. During the demobilization period, the Readjustment Operations Committee should be responsible for: (1) Coordinating Federal assistance programs to communities and individuals with severe readjustment problems, (2) Identifying areas experiencing, or likely to experience, high unemployment during demobilization, through advance notification by the Department of Defense of impending contract cancellations and military base closings, and through a careful monitoring of economic developments in key areas by the Departments of Labor and Commerce, and (3) De- 208 termining, in cooperation with State and local governments, the appropriate size and mix of Federal assistance programs, and recommending specific programs and budget allocations for dealing with the problems of severely disrupted areas. FUNDING READJUSTMENT PROGRAMS The activities to assist a smooth transition will rely mainly on existing programs designed to aid communities faced with structural adjustments or to help workers gain new skills. How much these programs must be expanded will depend upon many factors which cannot be estimated precisely, but the approximate initial size of the programs is shown in Table 4. TABLE 4.—Estimated first year cost of readjustment programs [Millions of dollars] Estimated first year cost Program High Low 120 EDA community development assistance SBA loans HUD homeowner emergency loans _ MDTA training Employment service Relocation assistance Veterans assistance- . ... ?88 20 Total cost 50 10 1 53 7 4 30 14C ?n 15 50 Note.—Abbreviations used in this table represent the following: EDA (Economic Development Administration), SBA (Small Business Administration), HUD (Department of Housing and Urban Development), and MDTA (Manpower Development and Training Act). Source: Bureau of the Budget. Once hostilities cease or prospects for demobilization appear, supplemental appropriations for readjustment purposes should be sought promptly. All expenditures from special appropriations should be coordinated by the Readjustment Operations Committee. When demobilization plans are definitely known, more exact program expenditures should be determined by the Readjustment Operations Committee. Initial appropriations should be at the low end of the estimated range with the understanding that additional funds may be needed. These program supplements should be reserved for uses directly related to the post-Vietnam transition. In addition, funds should be requested to provide returning servicemen with veterans benefits under existing programs and to assist State unemployment insurance programs in cases of high localized unemployment. Even before demobilization, important permanent improvements should be made in some existing institutions to make them more effective both in the transition to peace and in the long run. The Unemployment Insurance program should be strengthened by increasing coverage, raising benefits, lengthening the possible duration of payments, and improving the 209 financial base of the system. And minimum standards of vesting of private pension plans should be established, so that as the economy shifts to a peacetime footing, workers can change jobs without losing their benefits. ASSISTING DEFENSE-DEPENDENT AREAS One major measure to be coordinated by the Readjustment Operations Committee is Federal assistance for communities that will experience a major decline in employment opportunities due to the closing or curtailment of a defense plant or military base. The possible scope of this task is suggested by the growth in defense employment during the buildup for Vietnam. From 1965 to 1967, 38 local areas experienced increases in defense employment exceeding 5 percent of their total work force. A few of these localities are moderately large metropolitan areas, but some are predominantly rural counties with no urban center exceeding 12,000 population; these rural areas may be especially vulnerable to defense cutbacks during demobilization. The Federal Government can assist severely affected communities with redevelopment potential to reorient their economies through programs of the Economic Development Administration and the Small Business Administration. Initial-year funds required for these specific purposes might range from $20 to $50 million for the Economic Development Administration and from $5 to $10 million for the Small Business Administration. These agencies would help defense-dependent communities modernize public facilities, develop industrial sites, convert defense installations to other uses, and otherwise make themselves attractive to new industry. ASSISTING DISPLACED INDIVIDUALS While most of the individuals who lose defense jobs or who are released from military service will be readily employable, some will not possess the required skills, while others will be geographically isolated from job opportunities. Federal programs should be undertaken to ease the impact of demobilization upon the most seriously affected individuals. Strengthening the Federal Employment Service Demobilization will greatly enlarge demands on the resources of the Federal-State Employment Service. Prior to demobilization, plans should be made for expanding the staff of the Employment Service offices: to ensure their capacity for handling veterans and laid-off defense workers, to improve the flow of information about job opportunities outside the local labor market, and to station staff temporarily at locations convenient to military personnel about to be discharged. The Employment Service may require $7 to $20 million in the first year to provide these activities. 2IO Expanding Manpower Training Some individuals dislocated from defense employment will need retraining. The preliminary estimate is that $53 million will be needed to prepare about 26,000 servicemen for civilian employment through Project Transition and to train about 20,000 enrollees in other MDTA programs. Further appropriations of up to $140 million may be required for the two programs. Providing Relocation Assistance A relocation assistance fund should be established to help low- and middleincome workers move out of defense-dependent communities with inadequate reemployment opportunities. The program should be administered by the Department of Labor, which should develop general policy on relocation assistance—including eligibility criteria—in cooperation with the Readjustment Operations Committee. The program should provide full grant assistance for workers taking low-income jobs, and a mix of loans and grants for those obtaining higher paying jobs. Relocation assistance should be available only to individuals directly affected by cutbacks in specified defense-dependent communities. The number assisted could range between 10,000 and 30,000 families, requiring expenditures between $4 and $15 million. Funding Veterans Assistance Current programs available to veterans are generally adequate to cover the needs of returning servicemen; however, the accelerated separations associated with demobilization will require additional appropriations for these programs—especially employment consultation services and the educational assistance program. Adequate financing of veterans programs may cost $30 to $50 million a year during demobilization. Providing Homeowner Assistance The Federal Government should undertake to prevent a widespread loss of homes in areas suffering temporary unemployment during demobilization. The Department of Housing and Urban Development should establish a program to encourage private lenders to declare moratoria on mortgage payments on homes owned and occupied by individuals dislocated by a defense cutback. When an extension of mortgage payments cannot be obtained, the Department of Housing and Urban Development should be authorized to lend the homeowner funds at a reasonable interest rate to cover mortgage payments. Expenditures of about $2 million should be ample for this program. 211 Appendix A REPORT TO THE PRESIDENT ON THE ACTIVITIES OF THE COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS DURING 1968 213 LETTER OF TRANSMITTAL COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS, Washington, D.C., December 31, 1968. T H E PRESIDENT. SIR : The Council of Economic Advisers submits this report on its activities during the calendar year 1968 in accordance with the requirements of the Congress, as set forth in section 4 (d) of the Employment Act of 1946. Respectfully, Arthur M. Okun, Chairman. Merton J. Peck. Warren L. Smith. 215 Report to the President on the Activities of the Council of Economic Advisers During 1968 During the year 1968, the activities of the Council of Economic Advisers were dominated by the urgent need to preserve the enormous benefits of prosperity and to head off the threats of serious inflation and international monetary instability. It was clear, as the year began, that the delay in enacting your fiscal proposals was contributing to inflationary pressures and jeopardizing the foundations of prosperity. The Council devoted much of its energy during the first half of the year toward the enactment of the Revenue and Expenditure Control Act, which you signed on June 28. The Council's efforts in the area of fiscal policy continued to be carried out with the closest coordination and cooperation of the Treasury Department and the Bureau of the Budget. The uncertain fiscal situation created a major problem for monetary policy, and the Council engaged in frequent consultations and exchanges of information with the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Much of the Council's work to meet the challenge of price stability focused on the fundamental long-run aspect of inflationary tendencies in a high employment economy. The newly established Cabinet Committee on Price Stability and its staff studied inflationary tendencies in individual sectors of the economy and ways these could be modified by the structural improvement of freely operating markets. The Cabinet Committee also proved to be an excellent institution for intensifying, coordinating, and broadening the base of the Administration's efforts to improve price performance—both by structural efforts and by enlisting cooperation for voluntary restraint in price and wage decisions. Particularly in the second half of the year, after an appropriate fiscal policy was implemented, the Council and the other agencies of the Committee intensified these efforts, both publicly and privately. The progress and the strains in the international financial system during 1968 placed a high premium on studies in this area. The Council conducted analyses and evaluations of a variety of proposals which have been advanced as ways LU strengthen the system. Throughout the year, the Council continued to conduct studies and evaluate programs and proposals on a wide range of economic and social issues. The most important of these efforts were centered on the challenge of reducing poverty and drawing disadvantaged groups into the mainstream of economic life. 217 Another significant activity was the study of preparations for achieving a smooth economic transition to peace after hostilities cease in Vietnam. Other important efforts dealt with the analysis of domestic financial markets, industrial markets, housing, collective bargaining, agricultural policy, manpower training and development, and various social insurance and income maintenance programs. COUNCIL MEMBERSHIP On February 15, 1968, Merton J. Peck from Yale University joined the Council, replacing Gardner Ackley, who became Ambassador to Italy; and Arthur M. Okun, who had served as a Member since November 16, 1964, was designated to succeed to the Chairmanship previously held by Mr. Ackley. On July 1, Warren L. Smith from the University of Michigan replaced James Duesenberry, who returned to his duties at Harvard University. Following is a list of all past Council members and their dates of service: Name Position Edwin G. Nourse Leon H. Keyserling John D. Clark.... Roy Blough Robert C. Turner Arthur F. Burns... NeilH.Jacoby Walter W. Stewart Joseph S. Davis Raymond J. Saulnier Paul W. McCracken Karl Brandt Henry C. Wallich James Tobin Kermit Gordon Walter W. Heller Gardner Ackley John P. Lewis Otto Eckstein James S. Duesenberry _ Chairman Vice Chairman Acting Chairman Chairman Member Vice Chairman _ Member Member Chairman. Member Member Member Member _ Chairman. Member... Member Member Member Member... Chairman... Member Chairman Member Member _ Member Oath of office date Augusts 1 9 4 6 . - . August 9,1946 November 2,1949 May 10,1950 Augusts 1946 May 10,1950 June 29,1950 September 8,1952. March 19,1953 September 15,1953 December 2,1953 May 2,1955 April 4,1955. December 3,1956 December 3,1956 November 1,1958. May 7, 1959 January 29,1961 _ January 29,1961 January 29,1961 August 3,1962 November 16,1964 May 17,1963 September 2,1964 February 2,1966 Separation date November 1,1949. January 20,1953. ... February 11,1953. August 20,1952. January 20,1953. December 1,1956. February 9,1955. April 29,1955. October 31,1958. January 20,1961. January 31,1959. January 20,1961. January 20,1961. July 31,1962. December 27,1962. November 15,1964. February 15,1968. August 31,1964. February 1,1966. June 30,1968. COUNCIL STAFF At the end of 1968, members of the Council's professional staff were Susan R. Ackerman, F. Gerard Adams, Barry P. Bosworth, Frederick W. Deming, Marten S. Estey, Catherine H. Furlong, Frances M. James, Lawrence B. Krause, James W. Kuhn, David W. Lusher, Thomas G. Moore, Saul Nelson, Roger G. Noll, David J. Ott, Courtenay M. Slater, Luther T. Wallace, Charles B. Warden, Jr., and G. Paul Wonnacott. Each year a number of staff members who have joined the Council on a temporary basis return to their posts in private life or in Government. Those leaving the Council in 1968 were John F. Burton, Jack W. Carlson, Christopher K. Clague, Thomas F. Dernburg, Peter P. Dorner, Raymond W. Goldsmith, Hendrik S. Houthakker, Saul H. Hymans, Carey P. Modlin, Joseph D. Mooney, and Frank W. Schiff. 218 Continuing its practice of asking leading members of the economics profession to assist in the analysis of economic problems, the Council in 1968 called on the following consultants: Henry J. Aaron, James T. Bonnen, William H. Branson, William Capron, Richard N. Cooper, John T. Dunlop, Otto Eckstein, Stephen M. Goldfeld, Kermit Gordon, Walter W. Heller, Allen H. Lerman, Paul MacAvoy, Edwin S. Mills, Joseph Pechman, George L. Perry, Paul Samuelson, Charles A. Taff, James Tobin, and Lloyd Ulman. The Council continued its graduate student intern program, which was started in 1961. Those working with the Council for various periods in 1968 were Robert E. Anderson, Lucy A. Cardwell, Albert J. Eckstein, Morris Goldstein, Stephen P. Magee, Richard W. Nelson, David M. Nienhaus, David F. J. Piachaud, Charles G. Plourde, Craig E. Swan, C. Daniel Vencill, and William D. Watson, Jr. Research assistants included Rosanna M. Coffey, Katherine Champe, Charles E. Kurlansky, Rosemary D. Marcuss, Roselee N. Roberts, Joanne C. Turner, and Carolyn T. Welch. As in the past, the Council received loyal and energetic assistance from its nonprofessional staff. Members of this staff at the end of 1968 were Teresa D. Bradburn, Judson A. Byrd, II, Gladys R. Durkin, Mary C. Fibich, James W. Gatling, Elizabeth F. Gray, Laura B. Hoffman, Christine L. Johnson, Roberta R. Kirk, Helen H. Knox, Bessie M. Lafakis, Betty Lu Lowry, V. Madge McMahon, Eleanor A. McStay, A. Keith Miles, Joyce A. Pilkerton, Dorothy L. Reid, Earnestine Reid, Lucille F. Saverino, Bettye T. Siegel, Nancy F. Skidmore, Barbara E. Skolnik, Margaret L. Snyder, and Elizabeth A. Zea. In preparing its Annual Report, the Council relied upon the editorial skills of Robin Elliott. COUNCIL ACTIVITIES The Council of Economic Advisers was established as an agency of the Federal Government nearly 22 years ago by the Employment Act of 1946. Under the Act the Council is charged with the responsibility of analyzing and interpreting economic developments and of recommending economic policies that will promote the goals of "maximum employment, production, and purchasing power." The Council's chief responsibility is to keep the President fully informed of economic developments and emerging problems which may affect the Nation's economy. To meet this responsibility, the Council continuously reviews economic conditions, undertakes special studies of particular problem areas, and makes recommendations concerning Government programs and policies. The Council confers regularly with all major Government agencies having responsibilities in the economic field. The Secretary of the Treasury, the Director of the Bureau of the Budget, and the Chairman of the Council and their respective staffs (the "Troika") 219 provide the President with a continuous joint assessment of the economic and budgetary outlook for the current and subsequent fiscal years. The heads of the "Troika" agencies and their associates, together with the Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, meet as the "Quadriad" with the President to discuss domestic and international monetary problems. In addition to its regular and informal consultations with other Government agencies, the Council and its staff in 1968 participated with other agencies in a large variety of more formal committees, task forces, and studies. The Council and its staff represent the United States in a number of important international conferences. The Council Chairman heads the U.S. delegation to the meetings of the Economic Policy Committee of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), and members of the Council and its staff this year participated in many other international meetings under the auspices of the OECD. The Chairman also met with the Chairman and staff of the Economic Council of Canada in Ottawa, and the Council was involved in activities of the United Nations Economic Commission for Europe. An important responsibility of the Council is to explain and clarify the Administration's economic policies, both within the Government and to the public at large. This is done through numerous speeches, articles, press briefings, statements, Congressional testimony, its Annual Report, and by assisting the President in the preparation of his Economic Report. The Council meets frequently and informally with many individuals and groups, both from the United States and abroad, including businessmen, bankers, labor leaders, government officials, university scholars and students, members of the press corps, and interested private citizens, and more formally with a number of advisory groups, including the President's Advisory Committee on Labor-Management Policy and the Business Council's Liaison Committee with the Council of Economic Advisers. The Council prepares two documents for publication. One is the Economic Report of the President, together with the Annual Report of the Council of Economic Advisers. Over 66,000 copies of the 1968 Report were distributed to Members of the Congress, Government officials, the press, and depository libraries, or sold to the public by the Superintendent of Documents. The second is the monthly Economic Indicators. This important compilation of current economic statistics has been prepared since 1948 at the Council under the direction of Miss Frances M. James, and is published by the Joint Economic Committee of the Congress. More than 12,000 copies are furnished to Members of the Congress and depository libraries or sold to the public every month. 220 Appendix B STATISTICAL TABLES RELATING TO INCOME, EMPLOYMENT, AND PRODUCTION 221 323-166 0—69 15 CONTENTS National income or expenditure: B-l. Gross national product or expenditure, 1929-68 B-2. Gross national product or expenditure, in 1958 prices, 1929-68 B-3. Implicit price deflators for gross national product, 1929-68 B-4. Gross national product by major type of product, 1929-68 B-5. Gross national product by major type of product, in 1958 prices, 1929-68 B-6. Gross national product: Receipts and expenditures by major economic groups, 1929-68 B-7. Gross national product by sector, 1929-68 B-8. Gross national product by sector, in 1958 prices, 1929-68 B-9. Gross national product by industry, in 1958 prices, 1947-67 B-10. Personal consumption expenditures, 1929-68 B-l 1. Gross private domestic investment, 1929-68 B-12. National income by type of income, 1929-68 B-l 3. Relation of gross national product and national income, 1929-68. . . . B-14. Relation of national income and personal income, 1929-68 B-l 5. Disposition of personal income, 1929-68 B-l6. Total and per capita disposable personal income and personal consumption expenditures, in current and 1958 prices, 1929-68 B-l 7. Sources of personal income, 1929-68 B-18. Sources and uses of gross saving, 1929-68 B-19. Saving by individuals, 1946-68 B-20. Number and money income (in 1967 prices) of families and unrelated individuals, by color of head, 1947-67 Population, employment, wages, and productivity: B-21. Population by age groups: Estimates, 1929-68, and projections, 1970-85 B-22. Noninstitutional population and the labor force, 1929-68 B-23. Civilian employment and unemployment, by sex and age, 1947-68. . B-24. Selected unemployment rates, 1948-68 B-25. Unemployment by duration, 1947-68 B-26. Unemployment insurance programs, selected data, 1940-68 B-27. Wage and salary workers in nonagricultural establishments, 1929-68. B-28. Average weekly hours of work in selected nonagricultural industries, 1929-68 B-29. Average gross hourly earnings in selected industries, 1929-68 B-30. Average gross weekly earnings in selected nonagricultural industries, 1929-68 B—31. Average weekly hours and hourly earnings, gross and excluding overtime, in manufacturing industries, 1939-68 B-32. Average weekly earnings, gross and spendable, total private nonagricultural industries, in current and 1957-59 prices, 1947-68. . . B-33. Average weekly earnings, gross and spendable, in manufacturing industries, in current and 1957-59 prices, 1939-68 B-34. Indexes of output per man-hour and related data, private economy, 1947-63 223 227 228 230 232 233 234 236 237 238 239 240 241 242 243 244 245 246 248 249 250 251 252 254 255 256 257 258 260 261 262 263 264 265 266 Production and business activity: B-35. Industrial production indexes, major industry divisions, 1929-68. . . . B—36. Industrial production indexes, market groupings, 1947—68 B-37. Industrial production indexes, selected manufactures, 1947-68 B-38. Manufacturing output, capacity, and utilization rate, 1948-68 B-39. Business expenditures for new plant and equipment, 1939 and 194569 B-40. New construction activity, 1929-68 B-41. New housing starts and applications for financing, 1929-68 B-42. Sales and inventories in manufacturing and trade, 1947-68 B-43. Manufacturers' shipments and inventories, 1947-68 B-44. Manufacturers' new and unfilled orders, 1947-68 Prices: B-45. B-46. B-47. B-48. B-49. Consumer Consumer Consumer Wholesale Wholesale price price price price price indexes, indexes, indexes, indexes, indexes, by major groups, 1929-68 by special groups, 1935-68 selected commodities and services, 1935-68. by major commodity groups, 1929-68 by stage of processing, 1947-68 Money supply, credit, and finance: B-50. Money supply, 1947-68 B-51. Bank loans and investments, 1929-68 B-52. Selected liquid assets held by the public, 1946-68 B-53. Federal Reserve Bank credit and member bank reserves, 1929-68. . . B-54. Bond yields and interest rates, 1929-68 B-55. Short- and intermediate-term consumer credit outstanding, 1929-68. B-56. Instalment credit extended and repaid, 1946-68 B-57. Mortgage debt outstanding, by type of property and of financing, 1939-68 B-58. Mortgage debt outstanding, by lender, 1939-68 B-59. Net public and private debt, 1929-68 Government finance: B-60. Federal budget receipts and outlays, 1929-70 B-61. Federal budget receipts, outlays, financing, and debt, 1959-70 B-62. Relation of the Federal Budget to the Federal sector of the national income and product accounts, 1967-70 B-63. Receipts and expenditures of the Federal Government sector of the national income and product accounts, 1946-70 B-64. Public debt securities, by kind of obligation, 1929-68 B-65. Estimated ownership of public debt securities, 1939-68 B-66. Average length and maturity distribution of marketable interest-bearing public debt, 1946-68 B-67. Receipts and expenditures of the government sector of the national income and product accounts, 1929-68 B-68. Receipts and expenditures of the State and local government sector of the national income and product accounts, 1946-68- • •• B-69. State and local government revenues and expenditures, selected fiscal years, 1927-67 224 Page 267 268 269 270 271 272 274 276 277 278 279 280 281 282 284 286 287 288 289 290 292 293 294 295 296 297 298 300 301 302 303 304 305 306 307 Corporate profits and finance: B-70. Profits before and after taxes, all private corporations, 1929-68 B-71. Sales, profits, and stockholders' equity, all manufacturing corporations (except newspapers), 1947-68 B-72. Relation of profits after taxes to stockholders' equity and to sales, all manufacturing corporations (except newspapers), by industry group, 1947-68 B-73. Sources and uses of funds, nonfarm nonfinancial corporate business, 1957-68 B-74. Current assets and liabilities of United States corporations, 1939-68. B-75. State and municipal and corporate securities offered, 1934-68 B-76. Common stock prices, earnings, and yields, and stock market credit, 1939-68 B-77. Business formation and business failures, 1929-68 Agriculture: B-78. Income from agriculture, 1929-68 B-79. Farm production indexes, 1929-68 B-80. Farm population, employment, and productivity, 1929-68 B-81. Indexes of prices received and prices paid by farmers, and parity ratio, 1929-68 B-82. Selected measures of farm resources and inputs, 1929-68 B-83. Comparative balance sheet of agriculture, 1929-69 International statistics: B-84. United States balance of payments, 1946-68 B-85. United States merchandise exports and imports, by commodity groups, 1958-68 B-86. United States merchandise exports and imports, by area, 1962-68. . B-87. United States overseas loans and grants, by type and area, fiscal years 1962-68 B-88. International reserves, 1949, 1953, and 1963-68. B-89. United States reserve assets: Gold stock, holdings of convertible foreign currencies, and reserve position in the International Monetary Fund, 1946-68 B-90. Price changes in international trade, 1960-68 B-91. Consumer price indexes in the United States and other major industrial countries, 1957-68 General Notes Detail in these tables will not necessarily add to totals because of rounding. Unless otherwise noted, all dollar figures are in current prices. Symbols used: " Preliminary. __ Not available (also, not applicable). * Amount insignificant in terms of the particular unit (e.g., less than $50 million where unit is billions of dollars). 225 Page 308 309 310 312 313 314 315 316 317 318 319 320 322 323 324 326 327 328 329 330 331 332 NATIONAL INCOME OR EXPENDITURE TABLE B-l.—Gross national product or expenditure, 1929-68 [Billions of dollars] Year or quarter Total gross national product Personal sumption expenditures^ Government purchases of goods and services Gross private domestic investment2 Net exports of goods and services 3 Federal* Total Total National defense5 Other State and local 1929.. 103.1 77.2 16.2 1.1 8.5 1.3 1.3 7.2 1930.. 1931.. 1932.. 19331934.. 1935.. 1936.. 1937.. 1938.. 1939.. 90.4 75,8 58.0 55.6 65.1 72.2 82.5 90.4 84.7 90.5 69.9 60.5 48.6 45.8 51.3 55.7 61.9 66.5 63.9 66.8 10.3 5.6 1.0 1.4 3.3 6.4 8.5 11.8 6.5 9.3 1.0 9.2 9.2 8.1 8.0 9.8 10.0 12.0 11.9 13.0 13.3 1.4 1.5 1.5 2.0 3.0 2.9 4.9 4.7 5.4 5.1 1.4 1.5 1.5 2.0 3.0 2.9 4.9 4.7 5.4 1.2 3.9 7.8 7.7 6.6 6.0 6.8 7.1 7.0 7.2 7.6 8.2 1940.. 1941.. 1942.. 19431944.. 19451946.. 1947.. 1948.. 1949- 99.7 124.5 157.9 191.6 210.1 211.9 208.5 231.3 257.6 256.5 70.8 80.6 88.5 99.3 108.3 119.7 143.4 160.7 173.6 176.8 13.1 17.9 9.8 5.7 7.1 10.6 30.6 34.0 46.0 35.7 -2.0 -1.8 -.6 7.5 11.5 6.4 6.1 14.0 24.8 59.6 88.6 96.5 82.3 27.0 25.1 31.6 37.8 6.0 16.9 51.9 81.1 89.0 74.2 17.2 12.5 16.5 20.1 2.2 13.8 49.4 79.7 87.4 73.5 14.7 9.1 10.7 13.3 3.8 3.1 2.5 1.4 1.6 .7 2.5 3.5 5.8 6.8 8.0 7.9 7.7 7.4 7.5 8.1 9.8 12.6 15.0 17.7 1950.. 1951.. 1952.. 1953.. 1954.. 1955.. 1956.. 1957.. 1958.. 1959.. 284.8 328.4 345.5 364.6 364.8 398.0 419.2 441.1 447.3 483.7 191.0 206.3 216.7 230.0 236.5 254.4 266.7 281.4 290.1 311.2 54.1 59.3 51.9 52.6 51.7 67.4 70.0 67.8 60.9 75.3 1.8 3.7 2.2 .4 1.8 2.0 4.0 5.7 2.2 .1 37.9 59.1 74.7 81.6 74.8 74.2 78.6 86.1 94.2 97.0 18.4 37.7 51.8 57.0 47.4 44.1 45.6 49.5 53.6 53.7 14.1 33.6 45.9 48.7 41.2 38.6 40.3 44.2 45.9 46.0 4.3 4.1 5.9 8.4 6.2 5.5 5.3 5.3 7.7 7.6 19.5 21.5 22.9 24.6 27.4 30.1 33.0 36.6 40.6 43.3 1960.. 19611962.. 19631964.. 1965.. 1966.. 1967.. 1968 p. 503.7 520.1 560.3 590.5 632.4 684.9 747.6 789.7 860.7 325.2 335.2 355.1 375.0 401.2 432.8 465.5 492.2 533.7 74.8 71.7 83.0 87.1 94.0 108.1 120.8 114.3 127.5 4.0 5.6 5.1 5.9 8.5 6.9 5.1 4.8 2.4 99.6 107.6 117.1 122.5 128.7 137.0 156.2 178.4 197.1 53.5 57.4 63.4 64.2 65.2 66.9 77.4 90.6 100.0 44.9 47.8 51.6 50.8 50.0 50.1 60.6 72.4 78.9 8.6 9.6 11.8 13.5 15.2 16.8 16.8 18.2 21.1 46.1 50.2 53.7 58.2 63.5 70.1 78.8 87.8 97.1 ]4 .4 .6 !l .3 1.3 1.1 1.7 1.3 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1966: L . IIIII. IV. 728.4 740.4 753.3 768.2 457.8 461.1 469.3 473.7 116.8 121.0 119.9 125.7 6.0 5.2 4.5 4.5 147.8 153.1 159.5 164.3 72.5 75.6 79.9 81.5 55.3 58.6 63.0 65.4 17.2 17.0 16.9 16.1 75.3 77.4 79.7 82.7 1967: I. 772.2 780.2 795.3 811.0 480.9 490.3 495.5 502.2 113.0 107.6 114.7 121.8 5.2 5.1 5.4 3.4 173.1 177.3 179.6 183.5 87.4 90.0 91.3 93.5 70.0 72.1 72.9 74.6 17.4 17.9 18.4 19.0 85.8 87.2 88.4 90.0 831.2 852.9 871.0 887.8 519.4 527.9 541.1 546.3 119.7 127.3 127.1 136.1 1.5 2.0 3.3 3.0 190.5 195.7 199.6 202.5 97.1 100.0 101.2 101.6 76.8 79.0 79.6 80.0 20.3 21.0 21.5 21.6 93.4 95.6 98.4 100.8 III. IV.. 1968: I.... II... III... IV P.. i See Table B-10 for detailed components. 2See Table B-ll for detailed components. 3 See Table B-6 for exports and imports separately. * Net of Government sales. 5 This category corresponds closely to the national defense classification in the "Budget of the United States Government for the Fiscal Year ending June 30,1970." Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 227 TABLE B-2.—Gross national product or expenditure, in 1958 prices, 1929-68 [Billions of dollars, 1958 prices] Persona! consumption expenditures Year or quarter Total gross national product Gross private domestic investment Fixed investment Total Durable goods Nondurable goods Nonresidential Serv- Total Total Structures Producers' durable equipment Total Residential structures Change in businessinventories 1929.. 203.6 139.6 16.3 69.3 54.0 40.4 36.9 26.5 13.9 12.6 10.4 3.5 1930.. 1931.. 1932.. 1933.. 1934.. 1935.. 1936.. 1937.. 1938.. 1939.. 183.5 169.3 144.2 141.5 154.3 169.5 193.0 203.2 192.9 209.4 130.4 126.1 114.8 112.8 118.1 125.5 138.4 143.1 140.2 148.2 12.9 11.2 8.4 8.3 9.4 11.7 14.5 15.1 12.2 14.5 65.9 65.6 60.4 58.6 62.5 65.9 73.4 76.0 77.1 81.2 51.5 49.4 45.9 46.0 46.1 47.9 50.5 52.0 50.9 52.5 27.4 16.8 4.7 5.3 9.4 18.0 24.0 29.9 17.0 24.7 28.0 19.2 10.9 9.7 12. i 15.6 20.9 24.5 19.4 23.5 21.7 14.1 8.2 7.6 9.2 11.5 15.8 18.8 13.7 15.3 11.8 7.5 4.4 3.3 3.6 4.0 5.4 7.1 5.6 5.9 9.9 6.6 3.8 4.3 5.6 7.5 10.3 11.8 8.1 9.4 6.3 5.1 2.7 2.1 2.9 4.0 5.1 5.6 5.7 8.2 -.6 -2.4 -6.2 -4.3 -2.7 2.4 3.1 5.5 -2.4 1.2 1940.. 1941.. 1942.. 1943.. 1944.. 1945.. 1946.. 1947.. 1948.. 1949.. 227.2 263.7 297.8 337.1 361.3 355.2 312.6 309.9 323.7 324.1 155.7 165.4 161.4 165.8 171.4 183.0 203.5 206.3 210.8 216.5 16.7 19.1 11.7 10.2 9.4 10.6 20.5 24.7 26.3 28.4 84.6 89.9 91.3 93.7 97.3 104.7 110.8 108.3 108.7 110.5 54.4 56.3 58.5 61.8 64.7 67.7 72.1 73.4 75.8 77.6 33.0 41.6 21.4 12.7 14.0 19.6 52.3 51.5 60.4 48.0 28.1 32.0 17.3 12.9 15.9 22.6 42.3 51.7 55.9 51.9 18.9 22.2 12.5 10.0 13.4 19.8 30.2 36.2 38.0 34.5 6.8 8.1 4.6 2.9 3.8 5.7 12.5 11.6 12.3 11.9 12.1 14.2 7.9 7.2 9.6 14.1 17.7 24.6 25.7 22.6 9.2 9.8 4.9 2.9 2.5 2.8 12.1 15.4 17.9 17.4 4.9 9.6 4.0 -.2 -1.9 -2.9 10.0 -.2 4.6 -3.9 1950.. 1951.. 1952.. 1953.. 1954.. 1955.. 1956.. 1957.. 1958.. 1959. 355.3 383.4 395.1 412.8 407.0 438.0 446.1 452.5 447.3 475.9 230.5 232.8 239.4 250.8 255.7 274.2 281.4 288.2 290.1 307.3 34.7 31.5 30.8 35.3 35.4 43.2 41.0 41.5 37.9 43.7 114.0 116.5 120.8 124.4 125.5 131.7 136.2 138.7 140.2 146.8 81.8 84.8 87.8 91.1 94.8 99.3 104.1 108.0 112.0 116.8 69.3 70.0 60.5 61.2 59.4 75.4 74.3 68.8 60.9 73.6 61.0 59.0 57.2 60.2 61.4 69.0 69.5 67.6 62.4 68.8 37.5 39.6 38.3 40.7 39.6 43.9 47.3 47.4 41.6 44.1 12.7 14.1 13.7 14.9 15.2 16.2 18.5 18.2 16.6 16.2 24.8 25.5 24.6 25.8 24.5 27.7 28.8 29.1 25.0 27.9 23.5 19.5 18.9 19.6 21.7 25.1 22.2 20.2 20.8 24.7 8.3 10.9 3.3 .9 -2.0 6.4 A. 8 1.2 -1.5 4.8 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965. 1966 1967 1968 v 487.7 497.2 529.8 551.0 581.1 617.8 657.1 673.1 706.9 316.1 322.5 338.4 353.3 373.7 397.7 417.8 430.5 450.7 44.9 43.9 49.2 53.7 59.0 66.6 71.3 72.4 80.0 149.6 153.0 158.2 162.2 170.3 178.6 186.9 191.1 197.0 121.6 72.4 125.6 69.0 131.1 79.4 137.4 82.5 144.4 87.8 152.5 99.2 159.5 108.8 167.0 99.5 173.8 106.8 68.9 67.0 73.4 76.7 81.9 90.1 94.9 93.6 99.8 47.1 45.5 49.7 51.9 57.8 66.3 73.8 73.7 76.7 17.4 17.4 17.9 17.9 19.1 22.3 23.9 22.6 22.5 29.6 28.1 31.7 34.0 38.7 44.0 49.9 51.1 54.3 21.9 21.6 23.8 24.8 24.2 23.8 21.1 19.9 23.1 3.5 2.0 6.0 5.8 5.8 9.0 13.9 5.9 6.9 Seasonally adjusted annual rates IV... 648.6 653.3 659.5 667.1 415.7 414.8 420.0 420.6 72.9 69.2 71.8 71.4 185.5 186.9 187.8 187.5 157.3 158.7 160.4 161.7 106.1 109.5 107.4 112.3 95.8 94.7 95.5 93.7 72.2 72.7 74.8 75.4 24.4 23.8 24.1 23.4 47.8 48.9 50.7 52.1 23.6 22.0 20.7 18.2 10.3 14.7 12.0 18.6 1967: I . . . . II III... IV... 665.7 669.2 675.6 681.8 424.8 431.2 431.8 434.1 70.1 73.7 72.6 73.0 190.3 191.6 191.1 191.6 164.4 99.8 165.9 94.2 168.1 99.3 169.5 104.7 91.8 92.0 94.0 96.7 74.2 73.3 73.2 74.0 23.8 22.1 22.2 22.1 50.3 51.1 51.0 52.0 17.6 18.7 20.8 22.7 8.0 2.3 5.2 8.0 1968: I . . . . II... III.. IV p. 692.7 703.4 712.3 719.1 444.9 447.5 455.7 454.8 77.3 78.9 82.5 81.4 196.5 196.1 198.5 196.8 171.0 172.6 174.8 176.6 101.5 99.5 107.3 97.4 105.8 99.0 112.5 103.4 76.5 74.5 76.6 79.4 23.4 22.1 21.9 22.5 53.0 52.4 54.7 57.0 23.0 22.9 22.4 24.0 2.0 9.9 6.8 9.1 1966: I . . . . See footnotes at end of table. 228 TABLE B-2.—Gross national product or expenditure, in 1958 prices, 1929-68—Continued [Billions of dollars, 1958 prices] Net exports of goods and services Government purchases of goods and services Year or quarter Net exports Exports Imports Total Federal State and local 1929 1.5 11.8 10.3 22.0 3.5 18.5 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 1.4 .9 .6 * .3 -1.0 -1.2 -.7 1.9 1.3 10.4 8.9 7.1 7.1 7.3 7.7 8.2 9.8 9.9 10.0 9.0 7.9 6.6 7.1 7.1 8.7 9.3 10.5 8.0 8.7 24.3 25.4 24.2 23.3 26.6 27.0 31.8 30.8 33.9 35.2 4.0 4.3 4.6 6.0 8.0 7.9 12.2 11.5 13.3 12.5 20.2 21.1 19.6 17.3 18.6 19.2 19 6 19 4 20.6 22.7 2.1 .4 —2.1 -5.9 -5.8 -3.8 8.4 12.3 6.1 6.4 11.0 11.2 7.8 6.8 7.6 10.2 19.6 22.6 18.1 18.1 8.9 10.8 9.9 12.6 13.4 13.9 11.2 10.3 12.0 11.7 36.4 56.3 117.1 164.4 181.7 156.4 48.4 39.9 46.3 53.3 15.0 36.2 98.9 147.8 165.4 139.7 30.1 19.1 23.7 27.6 21.4 20.1 18 3 16.6 16.3 16.7 18 4 20.8 22.7 25.7 1950. 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956. . 1957. 1958 1959 2.7 5.3 3.0 1 l 3.0 3.2 5.0 6.2 2.2 16.3 19.3 18.2 17.8 18.8 20.9 24.2 26.2 23.1 23.8 13.6 14.1 15.2 16.7 15.8 17.7 19.1 19.9 20.9 23.5 52.8 75.4 92.1 99.8 88.9 85.2 85.3 89.3 94.2 94.7 25.3 47.4 63.8 70.0 56.8 50.7 49.7 51.7 53.6 52.5 27.5 27.9 28.4 29.7 32.1 34.4 35.6 37.6 40.6 42.2 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 v 4.3 51 4.5 5.6 8.3 6.2 4.0 2.4 .2 27.3 28.0 30.0 32.1 36.5 37.4 40.1 41.8 45.9 23.0 22.9 25.5 26.6 28.2 31.2 36.1 39.3 45.7 94.9 100.5 107.5 109.6 111.2 114.7 126.5 140.7 149.2 51.4 54.6 60.0 59.5 58.1 57.9 65.2 74.8 79.3 43.5 45.9 47.5 50.1 53.2 56.8 61.3 65.9 69.9 - . 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 . . . . . Seasonally adjusted annual rates 5.3 4.3 3.6 2.9 39.9 39.7 40.4 40.4 34.5 35.4 36.8 37.5 121.5 124.7 128.5 131.3 61.8 64.0 66.9 67.9 59.6 60.7 61.6 63.4 1967- 1 II Ill IV 3.0 2.8 3.1 1.0 41.4 41.7 42.1 41.9 38.5 38.9 39.1 40.9 138.1 141.0 141.4 142.0 72.7 75.1 75.6 75.6 65.4 66.0 65.8 66.4 1968: 1 II Ill IV v -.1 -.6 44.0 44.7 47.6 47.1 44.1 45.4 46.9 46.5 146.5 149.2 150.1 151.0 78.1 80.1 79.5 79.4 68.4 69.1 70.6 71.6 1966- 1 II HI IV . .7 1 Net of Government sales. Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 229 TABLE B-3.—Implicit price deflators for gross national product, 1929-68 [Index numbers, 1958=100] Gross private domestic investmentl Personal consumptior expenditures Fixed investment Total gross national Year or quarter Nonresident nrnri ucti Total Durable goods Nondurable goods Services Total Total Structures ResiProdential ducers' strucdurable tures equipment 1929 50.6 55.3 56.4 54.5 56.1 39.4 39.9 35.7 44.6 38 1 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934.. 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 49.3 44.8 40.2 39.3 42.2 42.6 42.7 44.5 43.9 43.2 53.6 47.9 42.3 40.6 43.5 44.4 44.7 46.5 45.6 45.1 55.3 49.1 43.2 41.9 44.7 43.7 43.6 45.8 46.7 46.0 51.6 44.1 37.7 38.0 42.7 44.5 44.8 46.4 44.0 43.2 55.7 52.7 48.3 43.6 44.3 44.4 45.0 46.8 47.7 47.7 37.9 35.2 31.6 30.6 33.7 34.3 34.6 37.8 38.2 37.7 38.1 35.8 32.9 31.6 34.9 35.9 35.6 38.8 39.3 38.7 34.0 31.1 27.6 27.9 28.9 30.6 30.2 34.4 33.9 33.1 43.0 41 1 39.1 34.5 38.8 38.7 38.5 41.4 43.0 42.2 37.1 33 6 27 3 27.1 30.1 29.8 31.3 34.3 35.5 35.7 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 43.9 47.2 53.0 56.8 58.2 59.7 66.7 74.6 79.6 79.1 45.5 48.7 54.8 59.9 63.2 65.4 70.5 77.9 82.3 81.7 46.5 50.4 59.3 64.2 71.5 75.9 76.8 82.7 86.3 86.8 43.8 47.7 55.6 62.5 66.2 68.7 74.3 83.6 88.5 85.6 47.9 49.8 52.7 55.3 57.5 58.7 62.7 67.9 72.1 74.3 39.0 42.0 46.5 49.3 51.1 51.5 58.5 66.7 73.9 74.7 40.0 42.7 47.8 49.9 51.0 51.0 56.3 64.5 70.7 72.8 33.9 36.4 41 3 46 8 48.6 49.2 54.4 64.4 71.5 71.2 43.4 46.3 51 5 51.1 51.9 51.7 57.5 64.6 70.3 73.6 36.9 40.3 43 3 47 0 51.6 54.9 59.7 71.7 80.8 78.5 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 80.2 85.6 87.5 88.3 89.6 90.9 94.0 97.5 100.0 101.6 82.9 88 6 90.5 91.7 92.5 92 8 94.8 97 7 100.0 101.3 87.8 94 2 95.4 94.3 92.9 91 9 94.9 98.4 100.0 101.4 86.0 93 3 94.3 93.9 94.2 93.6 94.9 97.7 100.0 99.9 76.3 80.0 83.6 87.7 90.0 92.0 94.6 97.3 100.0 103.0 77.5 83.1 85.3 86.6 86.8 89.0 94.0 98.5 100.0 102.6 74.4 80.4 82.6 84.0 84.8 86.7 92.4 97 9 100.0 102.2 72.9 79 3 83.2 84.9 86.0 88.1 93.4 98 6 1Q0.0 102.7 75.2 80 9 82.2 83.5 84.0 85.9 91.8 97.5 100.0 102.0 82.5 88 6 90.8 91.9 90.4 92.9 97.4 99.8 100.0 103.1 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 * » 103.3 104.6 105.8 107.2 108.8 110.9 113.8 117.3 121.8 102.9 103.9 104.9 106.1 107.4 108.8 111.4 114.3 118.4 100.9 100.6 100.8 100.4 100.4 99.6 98.8 100.4 103.1 101.2 101.9 102.8 104.0 104.9 106.9 110.6 112.9 116.9 105.8 107.6 109.0 110.9 113.1 115.1 118.1 122.1 127.2 103.4 103.9 104.9 106.0 107.6 109.3 111.8 115.6 120.2 102.9 103.4 104.1 104.5 105.7 107.5 110.2 113.5 117.2 104.0 105.6 107.1 108.9 111.1 114.7 119.0 123.6 129.7 102.2 102.1 102.3 102.3 103.0 103.9 106.0 109.1 112.0 104.5 105.0 106.7 108.9 112.3 114.2 117.4 123.1 129.9 1966: 1 112.3 113.3 114.2 115.2 110.1 111.2 111.7 112.6 98.1 98.5 98.8 99.6 109.3 110.4 111.0 111.7 116.6 117.6 118.4 119.5 110.6 111.4 112.1 113.0 108.9 109.8 110.4 111.6 117.1 118.4 119.8 120.7 104.7 105.6 106.0 107.5 115.9 117.0 118.2 119.0 1967- 1 116.0 116.6 117.7 118.9 113.2 113.7 114.7 115.7 99.6 99.6 100:7 101.7 111.9 112.4 113.3 114.0 120.5 121.5 122.5 123.7 113.9 114.6 116.2 117.4 112.5 112.9 113.8 114.9 121.7 122.7 124.6 125.5 108.2 108.6 109.1 110.3 119.7 121.4 124.8 125.6 120.0 121.2 122.3 123.5 116.8 118.0 118.7 120.1 102.2 102.7 103.1 104.2 115.2 116.4 117.2 118.6 125.1 126.7 127.8 129.1 118.3 119.6 120.8 121.9 115.8 116.7 117.6 118.6 126.3 128.8 131.3 132.6 111.2 111.7 112.1 113.1 126.3 128.9 131.7 132.7 . — II III IV II III IV 1968: 1 || III . . IV v See footnotes at end of table. 230 TABLE B-3.—Implicit price deflators for gross national product, 1929-68—Continued [Index numbers, 1958=100] Exports and imports 1 of goods and services Government purchases of goods and services Gross national product by sector Year or quarter Exports Imports Total Federal State and local Private 2 General government 1929 59.5 57.3 38.6 36.0 39.1 51.7 34.1 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 52.3 41.0 34.7 33.7 40.6 42.3 43.4 46.5 43 8 44.1 49.0 39.3 31.5 28.8 33.6 36.0 36.7 40.7 37.9 38.6 37.9 36.3 33.4 34.5 36.8 37.0 37.6 38.4 38 3 37.9 34.1 34.5 31.9 33.1 37.4 37.0 40.5 40.7 40 5 40.8 38.7 36.6 33.8 35.0 36.6 37.0 35.9 37.1 36 8 36.3 50.4 45.7 40.9 39.9 43.0 43.5 43.4 45.3 44 6 43.9 34.1 34.5 33.7 33.5 34.8 34.7 36.5 36.5 37.4 36.8 1940 1941. 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 48.6 53.0 61.5 65.2 69 9 71.3 75.4 87.3 92.7 87.0 40.8 43.0 48.3 51.2 53.2 56.4 64.9 79.4 86.4 82.2 38.5 44,0 50.9 53.9 53 1 52.6 55.8 62.9 68.1 71.0 40.2 46.6 52.5 54.9 53 8 53 1 57.3 65.6 69 8 73.0 37.3 39.2 42.3 44.6 46.1 48.6 53.2 60.4 66.4 68.9 44.7 48.7 55.5 60.9 62.0 62.6 68.2 76.3 81.4 80.6 36.0 34.7 37.3 39.7 43.3 48.3 55.4 58.5 60.8 64.7 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 84.9 97.0 98.8 95.2 94.3 94.9 97.5 101.3 100.0 98.8 88.7 107.2 103.6 99.1 100.8 100.6 102.5 104.0 100.0 99.3 71.8 78.5 81.0 81.8 84.1 87.1 92.1 96.4 100.0 102.4 72.9 79.4 81.2 81.4 83.5 86.9 91.7 95.8 100.0 102 2 70.8 76.9 80.6 82.8 85.3 87.5 92.7 97.3 100.0 102.6 81.4 87.4 89.0 89.6 90.8 91.6 94.5 97.9 100.0 101.4 67.1 70.5 74.4 76.6 79.5 84.0 88.7 93.3 100.0 104.2 I960.. 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968* 99.9 101.9 100.8 100.6 101.5 104.7 107.6 109.5 110.4 101.0 100.1 98.5 99.5 101.5 103.4 105.5 104.2 105.4 105.0 107.1 109.0 111.8 115.7 119.4 123.5 126.8 132.1 104.2 105 2 105.6 108 0 112.2 115.5 118.8 121.2 126.1 105.9 109.4 113.2 116.3 119.5 123.5 128.4 133.3 138.8 102.8 103.7 104.7 105.8 107.0 108.8 111.4 114.8 118.9 108.6 113.6 116.6 121.5 128.4 133.5 139.1 143.7 152.1 105.6 107.1 108.0 109.5 104.5 105.4 106.2 105.9 121.7 122.7 124.2 125.1 117.3 118.2 119.4 120.1 126.2 127.5 129.3 130.5 110.1 111.1 111.8 112.8 137.4 138.0 139.9 141.0 109.8 109.2 109.3 109.7 104.8 103.9 104.0 104.1 125.3 125.7 127.0 129.2 120.2 120.0 120.7 123.7 131.0 132.2 134.3 135.5 113.6 114.1 115.2 116.2 141.5 142.4 143.4 147.6 107.9 111.6 110.6 111.2 104.3 105.6 105.2 106.5 130.1 131.1 133.0 134.1 124.4 124.9 127.2 128.0 136.6 138.4 139.4 140.8 117.2 118.4 119.3 120.4 149.1 150.5 153.4 155.1 . . . 1966- 1 II. Ill IV . ... 1967- 1 II III IV 1968: l III IV p . . . . .. 1 Separate deflators are not available for total gross private domestic investment, change in business inventories, and net exports of goods and services. 2 Gross national product less compensation of general government employees. See also Tables B-7 and B-8. Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 23I TABLE B-4-.—Gross national product by major type of product, 1929-68 [Billions of dollars] Goods output Year or quarter Total gross national prod- Nondurable goods Serv- Strucices tures 3 oo | | I! Total Final goods sales uct 1929 Durable goods Total Final sales Final Total sales 2 = Final Total sales 103.1 101.4 1.7 56.1 54.3 1.7 17.5 16.1 1.4 38.5 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936.— 1937.. 1938.... 1939 90.4 75.8 58.0 55.6 65.1 72.2 82.5 90.4 84.7 90.5 90.7 77.0 60.5 57.2 65.8 71.2 81.2 87.9 85.6 90.1 -.4 -1.1 -2.5 -1.6 -.7 1.1 1.3 2.5 -.9 .4 46.9 37.4 26.7 27.0 34.4 39.9 45.8 51.5 45.3 49.0 47.3 38.6 29. 28.6 35.1 38.8 44.5 48.9 46.2 48.6 -.4 -1. -2.5 -1.6 -.7 1.1 1.3 2.5 -.9 .4 11.4 7.7 3.6 4.9 7.4 9.3 12.2 13.9 9.9 12.7 12.5 - 1 . 0 9.0 - 1 . 2 5.7 - 2 . 0 5.4 - . 5 7.3 .1 8.9 .3 11.2 13.1 10.8 - . 9 12.4 .3 35.5 29.7 23.1 22.1 27.0 30.6 33.6 37.6 35.4 36.3 1940.... 1941.... 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 99.7 124.5 157.9 191.6 210.1 211.9 208.5 231.3 257.6 256.5 97.5 2.2 120.1 4.5 156.2 1.8 192.2 - . 6 211.1 - 1 . 0 213.0 - 1 . 0 202.1 6.4 231.8 - . 5 252.9 4.7 259.6 - 3 . 1 56.0 72.5 93.6 120.4 132.3 128.9 124.9 139.7 154.2 147.5 53.8 2.2 68.0 4.5 91.9 1.8 121.0 - . 6 133.3 - 1 . 0 129.9 - 1 . 0 118.5 6.4 140.1 - . 5 149.4 4.7 150.5 - 3 . 16.6 26.8 35.5 54.2 57.9 48.9 36.9 46.0 48.7 47.8 15.4 1.2 39.3 38.4 23.8 3.0 45.6 44.2 34.5 1.0 58.1 57.4 66.2 66.8 54.2 58.5 - . 6 74.4 74.8 50.2 - 1 . 3 80.0 79.7 31.6 5.3 88.0 86.9 44.3 1.7 93.7 95.9 105.5 101.5 48.0 49.9 - 2 . 1 99.7 100.6 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 284.8 328.4 345.5 364.6 364.8 398.0 419.2 441.1 447.3 483.7 278.0 6.8 318.1 10.3 342.4 3.1 364.1 .4 366.4 - 1 . 5 392.0 6.0 414.5 4.7 439.8 1.3 448.8 - 1 . 5 478.9 4.8 162.4 189.7 195.6 204.1 197.1 216.4 225.4 234.6 230.8 249.1 155.6 179.4 192.5 203.7 198.6 210.4 220.7 233.3 232.3 244.4 60.4 73.7 74.6 79.4 72.1 85.7 90.3 94.4 83.6 95.6 56.3 4.1 66.8 6.9 73.5 1.1 78.5 .9 74.6 - 2 . 5 82.7 3.0 87.5 2.8 93.1 1.3 86.4 -2.8 93.2 2.3 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 v 503.7 520.1 560.3 590.5 632.4 684.9 747.6 789.7 860.7 500.2 3.6 259.6 256.0 3.6 99.5 97.4 2.1 160.1 158.6 163.7 518.1 2.0 262.3 260.2 2.0 96.5 96.6 - . 1 165. 554.3 6.0 284.5 278.5 6.0 109.0 106.2 2.8 175.5 172.2 584.6 5.9 298.6 292.7 5.9 116.1 113.3 2.8 182.5 179.4 626.6 5.8 319.4 313.6 5.8 127.0 122.8 4.2 192.4 190.7 675.3 9.6 347.2 337.6 9.6 139.6 133.0 6.7 207.6 204.7 732.8 14.7 382.2 367.5 14.7 156.0 145.7 10.2 226.3 221.8 783.6 6.1 396.9 390.8 6.1 159.3 156.4 3.0 237.6 234.5 853.1 7.6 430.9 423.3 7.6 176.7 172.2 4.5 254.2 251.1 102.0 116.0 121.0 124.8 125.0 130.7 135.1 140.2 147.2 153.6 38.2 34.8 29.6 23.6 23.2 27.8 29.9 33.3 35.8 35.4 36.2 Gross auto product 1" 0.3 35.6 11.4 34.2 .1 31.7 — 4 27.5 -1.1 25.7 - . 9 27.1 . 7 28.3 31.0 * 32.3 33. .1 34.0 9.2 6.7 3.8 2.9 3.5 4.0 5.6 6.7 6.2 7.5 1.0 1.4 .7 -.6 -.3 .2 1.1 -2.2 4.0 -1.0 35.4 40.3 50.3 62.5 71.8 76.5 68.0 70.2 75.7 80.8 8.3 11.8 14.0 8.7 6.1 6.5 15.6 21.4 27.7 28.3 7.2 8.8 11.9 99.3 2.7 87.0 112.6 3.4 101.2 119.1 2.0 110.8 125.2 - . 5 118.8 124.1 1.0 123.5 127.7 2.9 132.6 133.2 1.9 142.3 140.2 154.2 145.9 1.3 163.4 151.1 2.4 176.2 35.4 37.5 39.1 41.7 44.2 49.0 51.5 52.3 53.1 58.3 15.4 13.5 12.0 16.3 14.6 21.2 16.9 19.5 14.5 19.1 1.5 2.1 3.2 3.1 1.6 3.0 4.5 3l l| 3.1 187.3 199.5 213.3 226.2 244.2 262.9 288.0 314! 8 342.8 56.8 58.3 62.6 65.7 68.8 74.8 77.3 77.9 87.1 21.4 17.9 22.5 25.1 25.8 31.8 30.3 29.0 35.6 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1966: I—. II... ML. IV.. 728.4 740.4 753.3 768.2 717.5 725.0 740.4 748.4 10.9 15.4 12.8 19.8 371.4 378.0 383.8 395.1 360.5 362.6 371.0 375.3 10.9 15.4 12.8 19.8 150.8 152.1 157.7 163.7 143.3 7.6 220.6 142.2 9.9 225.9 147.3 10.5 226.1 150.2 13.6 231.4 217.3 220.4 223.7 225.1 3.3 5.5 2.4 6.3 277.5 284.7 292.3 298.1 79.5 77.7 77.2 74.9 32.7 29.4 28.4 30.6 1967: IV.. 772.2 780.2 795.3 811.0 763.8 778.0 789.9 802.7 8.4 2.3 5.3 8.3 389.9 394.1 398.9 404.8 381.5 391.8 393.6 396.5 8.4 2.3 5.3 8.3 154.5 157.7 161.1 164.1 151.1 157.1 157.3 159.9 3.3 .6 3.8 4.2 235.4 236.4 237.8 240.7 230.4 234.7 236.2 236.6 5.0 1.7 1.6 4.1 306.3 310.9 317.5 324.7 76.1 75.3 78.8 81.5 26.2 29.2 29.3 31.3 L... II... ML. IV v. 831.2 852.9 871.0 887.8 829.1 2.1 414.9 412.8 2.1 168.2 166.7 842.1 10.8 428.4 417.6 10.8 175.3 169.1 863.5 7.5 436.9 429.5 7.5 180.0 175.1 877.8 10.0 443.3 433.2 10.0 183.1 177.9 1.5 6.2 4.9 5.2 246.7 253.1 256.9 260.2 246.1 248.5 254.4 255.3 .6 4.6 2.5 4.9 330.4 339.2 347.6 354.0 85.8 85.4 86.4 90.6 33.7 36.1 36.1 36.7 1968: I.... Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 232 TABLE B-5.—Gross national product by major type of product, in 1958 prices, 1929-68 (Billions of dollars, 1958 prices] Goods output Final sales Total Total Final goods sales Total Final sales II )ods Nondurable goods l Total Final sales Gross Serv- Struc- auto prod>>« ices tures uct 3.5 33.6 30.9 2.7 70.4 69.5 0.8 69.3 30.3 90.5 91.1 - . 6 83.2 85.7 - 2 . 4 68.7 74.9 - 6 . 2 68.8 73.2 - 4 . 3 77.9 80.5 - 2 . 7 88.6 86.2 2.4 102.2 99.1 3.1 110.2 104.8 5.5 100.5 102.9 - 2 . 4 110.7 109.5 1.2 22.4 16.3 8.3 11.7 16.9 21.5 28.7 31.0 21.1 27.6 24.5 19.2 13.4 13.4 16.7 20.6 26.3 29. 23.4 27.0 -2.1 -3.0 -5.1 -1.7 .2 .9 2.4 1.9 -2.3 .6 68.0 67.0 60.4 57.1 61.0 67.1 73.5 79.2 79.4 83.0 66.5 66.5 61.5 59.8 63.8 65.6 72.8 75.7 79.5 82.5 1.5 .5 -1.1 -2.7 -2.8 1.5 .7 3.6 -.1 .6 67.7 65.8 61.9 63.0 65.3 68.1 73.3 73.9 74.8 76.9 25.3 20.2 13.7 9.8 11.1 12.8 17.5 19.1 17.7 21.8 124.0 143.4 158.1 187.4 204.8 198.0 172.1 172.2 178.4 174.2 119.0 133.8 154.1 187.6 206.7 201.0 162.1 172.4 173.8 178.1 4.9 9.6 4.0 -.2 -1.9 -2.9 10.0 -.2 4.6 -3.9 35.6 50.0 57.2 85.6 95.9 84.3 54.7 60.1 61.3 58.0 32.8 2.7 88.4 86.2 2.2 80.0 43.5 6.6 93.4 90.3 3.1 89.8 54.4 2.9 100.9 99.7 1.2 107.7 85.2 .4 101.7 102.4 - . 6 131.8 97.4 -1.5 108. 109.3 - . 4 144.0 87.4 -3.1 113.7 113.6 .2 144.3 46.1 8.6 117.4 116.0 1.4 113.3 58.6 1.5 112.2 113.8 - 1 . 7 106.5 60.0 1.2 117.1 113.8 3.3 109.3 61.0 - 3 . 0 116.2 117.1 - . 9 112.4 23.2 30.5 31.9 17.9 12.4 12.9 27.2 31.2 36.1 37.5 10.3 11.4 14.8 347.0 8.3 372.5 10.9 391.8 3.3 411.8 .9 409.0 - 2 . 0 431.6 6.4 441.2 4.8 451.2 1.2 448.8 - 1 . 5 471.1 4.8 192.6 208.4 214.0 225.4 215.1 236.1 239.0 239.8 230.8 247.7 184.3 8.3 197.5 10.9 210.7 3.3 224.5 .9 217.1 - 2 . 0 229.7 6.4 234.2 4.8 238.5 1.2 232.3 - 1 . 5 242.9 4.8 73.4 84.1 84.6 91.0 81.9 96.5 96.5 96.2 83.6 94.0 68.3 5.2 119.1 116.0 3.1 117.5 76.1 8.0 124.3 121.4 2.9 130.5 83.2 1.5 129.4 127.6 1.8 136.3 89.9 1.2 134.4 134.6 - . 2 140.3 84.8 - 3 . 0 133.2 132.3 .9 141.8 93.0 3.4 139.7 136.7 3.0 147.5 93.5 3.0 142.5 140.7 1.8 153.0 95.0 1.2 143.6 143.6 * 160.1 86.4 -2.8 147.2 145.9 1.3 163.4 91.6 2.4 153.7 151.2 2.5 171.2 45.2 44.4 44.7 47.0 50.2 54.3 54.0 52.6 53.1 57.0 19.1 15.9 13.5 18.7 17.1 24.6 18.6 20.2 14.5 18.5 484.2 495.2 523.8 545.2 575.2 608.8 643.2 667.2 699.9 256.0 257.3 277.3 289.7 308.6 330.7 355.9 361.0 380.3 252.6 3.5 97.8 95.9 255.3 2.0 94.9 94.9 271.3 6.0 107.0 104.1 283.9 5.8 114.2 111.4 302.! 5.8 124.6 120.4 321.7 9.0 136.5 130.1 342.0 13.9 151.1 141.5 355.1 5.9 150.3 147.6 373.4 6.9 162.1 158.1 1929 203.6 200.1 3.5 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 183.5 169.3 144.2 141.5 154.3 169.5 193.0 203.2 192.9 209.4 184.1 171.7 150.5 145.9 157.0 167.1 189.9 197.8 195.3 208.2 -.6 -2.4 -6.2 -4.3 -2.7 2.4 3.1 5.5 -2.4 1.2 1940 1941 1942 1943 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 227.2 263.7 297.8 337.1 361.3 355.2 312.6 309.9 323.7 324.1 222.3 4.9 254.1 9.6 293.8 4.0 337.3 - . 2 363.2 - 1 . 9 358.2 - 2 . 9 302.6 10.0 310.1 - . 2 319.1 4.6 328.1 - 3 . 9 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956.. 1957 1958 1959 355.3 383.4 395.1 412.8 407.0 438.0 446.1 452.5 447.3 475.9 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 v 487.7 497.2 529.8 551.0 581.1 617.8 657.1 673.1 706.9 1944 Durable goods f1 Inventc chan Year or quarter Total gross national product 3.5 2.0 6.0 5.8 5.8 9.0 13.9 5.9 6.9 103.9 100.4 2.0 * 2.8 2.8 4.1 6.5 9.6 2.7 4.0 158.2 162.3 170.3 175.6 184.1 194.2 204.8 210.7 218.2 156.7 160.3 167.2 172.5 182.3 191.6 200.5 207.5 215.3 1.5 2.0 3.1 3.1 1.7 2.6 4.3 3.2 3.0 176.6 184.0 193.7 200.9 210.8 221.9 236.4 249.6 260.1 55.0 55.8 58.8 60.4 61.6 65.2 64.8 62.5 66.4 21.0 17.5 22.0 24.7 25.5 31.8 30.9 29.0 34.8 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1966: I.... II... 339.8 338.4 344.6 345.4 10.3 14.7 12.0 18.6 147.8 147.7 152.6 156.4 140.7 7.1 138.4 9.3 142.9 9.7 143.9 12.5 202.3 205.4 203.9 207.5 199.1 200.0 201.6 201.5 3.2 5.4 2.3 6.1 230.7 234.7 238.9 241.3 67.9 65.5 64.1 61.8 33.5 30.0 29.0 31.0 657.7 666.9 670.4 673.8 8.0 357.2 349.2 2.3 360.3 358.1 5.2 361.9 356.7 8.0 364.4 356.4 8.0 2.3 5.2 8.0 146.7 149.9 151.6 152.8 143.8 149.3 148.2 149.0 3.0 .6 3.4 3.8 210.5 210.5 210.2 211.6 205.5 208.8 2C8.5 207.5 5.0 1.7 1.8 4.1 246.1 247.8 251.2 253.2 62.3 61.1 62.5 64.2 26.6 29.6 29.2 30.7 690.7 693.5 705.5 710.0 2.0 9.9 6.8 9.1 368.4 369.3 378.0 377.7 2.0 9.9 6.8 9.1 155.9 161.2 164.9 166.3 154.5 155.6 160.5 161.7 1.4 5.6 4.4 4.6 214.5 218.0 219.8 220.5 213.9 213.7 217.4 216.0 .6 4.3 2.4 4.6 255.1 258.7 262.3 264.5 67.2 65.5 65.2 67.7 33.0 35.4 35.2 35.4 648.6 653.3 659.5 IV.... 667.1 638.3 638.5 647.6 648.5 665.7 669.2 675.6 681.8 692.7 703.4 III..,- 712.3 IV P . . 719.1 1967: I. III... IV... 1968: I . . . . . 10.3 14.7 12.0 18.6 350.1 353.1 356.5 363.9 370.4 379.2 384.7 386.8 Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 233 TABLE B-6.—Gross national product: Receipts and expenditures by major economic groups. 1929-68 (Billions of dollars] Government Persons Disposable personal income Year or quarter Net receipts PerPersonal sonal Equals: consaving Total sumpor exclud- tion disexing inpendi- saving terest tures and Less: Interest paid and Total i transfer payments transfers to foreigners Expenditures Surplus or deficit Tax Less: Less: Equals: (-), naand TransTransPurfers, nonfers, Equals: Total chases tional inintertax interNet of excome est, goods reest, rependiand and and ceipts and ceipts tures prodsubservor ac- subuct acsidies s ices cruals sidies 2 counts 1929 83.3 1.9 81.4 77.2 4.2 11.3 1.8 9.5 10.3 1.8 8.5 1930 1931 1932 1933— 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938. 1939.. 74.5 64.0 48.7 45.5 52.4 58.5 66.3 71.2 65.5 70.3 1.2 .9 ^8 .9 .8 .9 73.3 63.1 48.0 44.9 51.7 57.8 65.5 70.3 64.6 69.4 69.9 60.5 48.6 45.8 51.3 55.7 61.9 66.5 63.9 66.8 3.4 2.6 -.6 -.9 .4 2.1 3.6 3.8 .7 2.6 10.8 9.5 8.9 9.3 10.5 11.4 12.9 15.4 15.0 15.4 1.9 3.1 2.6 2.7 3.1 3.4 4.1 3.2 3.8 4.2 8.9 6.3 6.3 6.7 7.4 8.0 8.8 12.2 11.2 11.2 11.1 12.4 10.6 10.7 12.9 13.4 16.1 15.0 16.8 17.6 1.9 3.1 2.6 2.7 3.1 3.4 4.1 3.2 3.8 4.2 9.2 9.2 8.1 8.0 9.8 10.0 12.0 11.9 13.0 13.3 1940 1941 . . 1942 1943 1944... 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 75.7 92.7 116.9 133.5 146.3 150.2 160.0 169.8 189.1 188.6 1.0 1.1 .8 .8 .8 1.0 1.4 1.8 2.2 2.4 74.7 91.6 116.1 132.7 145.5 149.3 158.6 168.0 186.9 186.2 70.8 80.6 88.5 99.3 108.3 119.7 143.4 160.7 173.6 176.8 3.8 11.0 27.6 33.4 37.3 29.6 15.2 7.3 13.4 9.4 17.7 25.0 32.6 49.2 51.2 53.2 50.9 56.8 58.9 56.0 4.4 4.0 4.4 4.7 6.5 10.4 18.5 17.3 18.8 21.3 13.3 21.0 28.2 44.4 44.7 42.8 32.4 39.5 40.1 34.7 18.4 28.8 64.0 93.3 103.0 92.7 45.5 42.4 50.3 59.1 4.4 4.0 4.4 4.7 6.5 10.4 18.5 17.3 18.8 21.3 14.0 24.8 59.6 88.6 96.5 82.3 27.0 25.1 31.6 37.8 -.7 -3.8 -31.4 -44.1 -51.8 -39.5 5.4 14.4 8.5 -3.2 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 206.9 226.6 238.3 252.6 257.4 275.3 293.2 308.5 318.8 337.3 2.9 3.1 3.5 4.3 4.6 5.1 5.9 6.4 6.5 7.1 204.1 223.5 234.8 248.3 252.9 270.2 287.2 302.2 312.3 330.3 191.0 206.3 216.7 230.0 236.5 254.4 266.7 281.4 290.1 311.2 13.1 17.3 18.1 18.3 16.4 15.8 20.6 20.7 22.3 19.1 68.7 84.8 89.8 94.3 89.7 100.4 109.0 115.6 114.7 128.9 22.9 19.9 19.0 19.5 21.9 23.4 25.5 28.7 33.0 34.0 45.8 64.9 70.8 74.8 67.8 76.9 83.5 86.8 81.6 95.0 60.8 79.0 93.7 101.2 96.7 97.6 104.1 114.9 127.2 131.0 22.9 19.9 19.0 19.5 21.9 23.4 25.5 28.7 33.0 34.0 37.9 59.1 74.7 81.6 74.8 74.2 78.6 86.1 94.2 97.0 7.8 5.8 -3.8 -6 9 -7.0 2.7 4.9 .7 -12.5 -2.1 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 v 350.0 364.4 385.3 404.6 438.1 473.2 511.6 546.3 589.0 7.8 8.1 8.6 9.7 10.7 12.0 13.1 13.9 14.4 342.3 356.3 376.6 394.9 427.4 461.3 498.4 532.4 574.5 325.2 335.2 355.1 375.0 401.2 432.8 465.5 492.2 533.7 17.0 21.2 21.6 19.9 26.2 28.4 32.9 40.2 40.8 139.8 144.6 157.0 168.8 174.1 189.1 213.2 227.4 260.9 36.5 41.3 42.8 44.4 46.7 49.9 55.3 62.9 70.2 103.3 103.3 114.2 124.3 127.3 139.2 157.9 164.6 190.7 136.1 149.0 159.9 166.9 175.4 186.9 211.5 241.3 267.3 36.5 41.3 42.8 44.4 46.7 49.9 55.3 62.9 70.2 99.6 107.6 117.1 122.5 128.7 137.0 156.2 178.4 197.1 3.7 -4.3 -2.9 1.8 —1.4 2.2 1.7 -13.8 -6.4 .7 .6 1 0 -2!s -1.8 -1.4 -2.4 -2.0 -3.1 -1.8 -2.2 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1966: I.... II... III... IV... 500.0 505.5 515.4 525.4 12.7 13.1 13.2 13.5 487.3 492.5 502.2 511.8 457.8 461.1 469.3 473.7 29.5 31.4 32.9 38.1 204.3 211.5 216.5 220.5 53.6 53.1 55.8 58.8 150.8 158.4 160.8 161.7 201.3 206.2 215.3 223.1 53.6 53.1 55.8 58.8 147.8 153.1 159.5 164.3 3.0 5.3 1.2 -2.6 1967: 1.... 11... III... IV... 534.2 541.5 550.0 559.6 13.7 14.2 14.0 13.9 520.6 527.3 536.1 545.7 480.9 490.3 495.5 502.2 39.7 37.0 40.5 43.4 222.2 223.6 229.0 234.8 62.0 62.2 63.4 63.8 160.2 161.4 165.7 171.0 235.2 239.5 243.0 247.4 62.0 62.2 63.4 63.8 173.1 177.3 179.6 183.5 -12.9 -15.9 -14.0 -12.5 1968: I.... II... III... IV p.. 574.4 586.3 592.7 602.5 14.1 14.4 14.5 14.7 560.3 571.9 578.2 587.7 519.4 527.9 541.1 546.3 40.8 44.0 37.1 41.4 246.6 254.2 267.2 66.4 69.8 71.8 72 9 180.3 184.4 195.4 256.9 265.5 271.3 275.4 66.4 69.8 71.8 72.9 190.5 195.7 199.6 202.5 -10.3 -11.3 -4.1 See footnotes at end of table. 234 T A B L E B—6.—Gross national product: Receipts and expenditures by major economic groups, 1929-68— Continued [Billions of dollars] International Business Year or quarter 1929 1930 19311932 1933 1934 19351936 1937 1938 1939. 1940 1941 1942 1943 . 1944 1945 1946 1947.. 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 . 1957 1958 1959 I960.. 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 v TransNet exports of goods Excess fers to and services of forGross transpriGross Excess eigners fers revate of in- by peror tained domes- vestsons Less: Equals: of net earn- tic in- ment and ExNet Imexings 3 vestGovports ports exports ernment < ports ment 11.2 8.6 5.3 3.2 3.2 5.2 6.4 6.7 7.7 8.0 8.4 10.5 11.4 14.5 16.3 17.1 15.1 14.5 20.2 28.0 29.7 29.4 33.1 35.1 36.1 39.2 46.3 47.3 49.8 49.4 56.8 56.8 58.7 66.3 68.8 76.2 84.7 91.6 93 1 97.5 16.2 10.3 5.6 1.0 1.4 3.3 6.4 8.5 11.8 6.5 9,3 13.1 17.9 9.8 5.7 7.1 10.6 30.6 34.0 46.0 35.7 54.1 59.3 51.9 52.6 51.7 67 4 70.0 67.8 60.9 75.3 74.8 71.7 83.0 87.1 94.0 108.1 120 8 114 3 127.5 -5.1 -1.6 -.3 2.2 1.8 1.9 * -1.8 -4.0 1.6 -.9 -2.7 -6.5 4.6 10.6 10.0 4.6 -16.1 -13.8 -18.0 -6.0 -24.7 -26.2 -16.8 -16.5 -12.5 -21.1 -22.8 -18.1 -11.5 -18.5 -18.0 -13.0 -16 8 -18.4 -17.8 -23.4 —29 2 -21 1 -30.0 0.4 .3 .3 .2 .2 .2 '.2 .2 .2 .2 .2 .2 .2 .2 .3 .8 2.9 2.6 4.5 5.6 4.0 3.5 2.5 2.5 2.3 25 2.4 2.3 24 2.4 2.4 2.6 2.7 2.8 2.8 2.8 29 31 2.7 7.0 5.4 3.6 2.5 2.4 3.0 3.3 3.5 4.6 4.3 4.4 5.4 5.9 4.8 4.4 5.3 7.2 14.7 19.7 16.8 15.8 13.8 18.7 18.0 16.9 17.8 19.8 23.6 26.5 23.1 23.5 27.2 28.6 30.3 32.3 37.1 39 2 43.1 45.8 50.6 5.9 4.4 3.1 2.1 2.0 2.4 3.1 3.4 4.3 3.0 3.4 3.6 4.6 4.8 6.5 7.1 7.9 7.2 8.2 10.3 9.6 12.0 15.1 15.8 16.6 15.9 17.8 19.6 20.8 20.9 23.3 23.2 23.0 25.1 26.4 28.6 32.3 38 1 41 0 48.2 1.1 1.0 .4 .4 .6 .'l .3 1.3 1.1 1.7 1.3 * -1.8 -2.0 -.6 7.5 11.5 6.4 6.1 1.8 3.7 2.2 .4 1.8 20 4.0 5.7 2.2 .1 4.0 5.6 5.1 5.9 8.5 6.9 51 48 2.4 -0.8 —.7 -.2 -.2 -.2 -.4 .1 .1 —l -1.1 -.9 -1.5 -1.1 .2 2.2 2.1 1.4 -4.6 -8.9 -1.9 -.5 2.2 -.2 .3 2.1 .5 .5 -1.5 -3.4 .2 2.3 -1.7 -3.0 -2.5 -3.1 -5.7 -4.1 -2.2 -1.7 .3 Gross naTotal Statis- tional income tical prodor re- disuct ceipts crep- or exancy penditure 102.4 91.2 75.1 57.7 55.0 64.5 72.5 81.3 90 5 84.1 89.2 98.7 124.1 159.0 193.6 207.6 208.0 208.4 230.4 259.5 256.2 283.3 325.1 343.3 361.6 362.1 395.9 420.4 441.1 445.8 484.5 504.8 520.8 559.8 590.8 633.7 688.0 750 9 793 2 865.7 1.6 -.8 -1.0 -.8 .5 -.3 -1.3 -3.1 —3 3 -3 5 -4.7 103.1 90 4 75 8 58.0 55.6 65 1 72.2 82.5 90 4 84 7 90.5 99.7 124.5 157.9 191 6 210.1 211.9 208 5 231.3 257.6 256.5 284.8 328.4 345 5 364.6 364.8 398 0 419.2 441.1 447 3 483.7 503.7 520.1 560 3 590.5 632 4 684.9 747 6 789 7 860.7 0.7 - 8 .7 .3 .6 .5 -.2 1.2 * .6 1.3 1.0 .4 -1.1 -2.0 2.5 3.9 1 .9 -2.0 .3 1.5 3.3 2.2 3.0 2.7 21 -1.1 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1966: 1 II III IV..- 88.9 90.4 91.9 95.3 116.8 121.0 119.9 125.7 -27.9 -30.5 -28.0 -30.4 3.4 2.9 2.8 2.6 42.1 42.6 43.6 44.2 36.1 37.3 39.1 39.7 6.0 5.2 4.5 4.5 -2.7 -2.3 -1.7 -1.9 730.3 744.2 757.7 771.3 -1.9 -3.9 -4.4 -3.1 728.4 740 4 753 3 768.2 1967: 1 91.3 91.9 93.5 95.9 113.0 107.6 114.7 121.8 -21.7 -15.7 -21.2 -25.9 2.9 3.4 3.4 2.6 45.5 45.5 46.1 46.0 40.3 40.4 40.6 42.6 5.2 5.1 5.4 3.4 -2.3 -1.6 -2.1 -.8 775.0 784.0 798.6 815.2 -2.8 -3.8 -3.4 -4.2 772.2 780 2 795.3 811.0 92.8 97.4 99.9 119.7 127.3 127.1 136.1 -26.9 -29.9 -27.2 2.6 2.8 2.8 2.8 47.5 49.9 52.6 52.4 46.0 47.9 49.4 49.5 1.5 2.0 3.3 3.0 1.1 .8 835.9 856.5 876.3 -4.7 -3.6 -5 3 831.2 852.9 871 0 887.8 III— IV 1968: 1 II III IV v 1 -.2 Personal income less personal tax and nontax payments (fines, penalties, etc.). 2 Government transfer payments to persons, foreign net transfers by government, net interest paid by government, and subsidies less current surplus of government enterprises. 2 Undistributed corporate profits, corporate inventory valuation adjustment, capital consumption allowances, and wage accruals less disbursements. * Private business investment, purchases of capital goods by private nonprofit institutions, and residential housing. See Table B - l l . • Net foreign investment with sign changed. Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 235 TABLE B-7.—Gross national product by sector, 1929-68 [Billions of dollars] Gross private product1 Total gross national product Year or quarter Business Total loiai Nonfarm2 Total Farm Households Rest of the world Gross government product^ 1929.. 103.1 98.8 95.1 85.4 9.7 2.9 0.8 4.3 1930.. 1931.. 1932.. 1933.. 1934.. 1935.. 1936.. 1937.. 1938.. 1939.. 90.4 75.8 58.0 55.6 65.1 72.2 82.5 90.4 84.7 90.5 85.8 71.2 53.6 50.9 59.5 66.3 75.2 83.5 77.0 82.9 82.4 68.3 51.3 48.9 57.4 64.1 72.9 81.0 74.5 80.3 74.8 62.0 46.8 44.3 52.7 57.1 66.5 72.7 67.9 74.0 7.7 6.3 4.5 4.6 4.7 7.0 6.4 8.3 6.6 6.3 2.7 2.3 1.9 1.7 1.8 1.9 2.0 2.3 2.2 2.3 .7 .5 .4 .3 .3 .4 .3 .3 .4 .3 4.5 4.7 4.4 4.7 5.6 5.9 7.3 6.9 7.6 7.6 1940.. 1941.. 1942.. 1943.. 1944.. 1945.. 1946.. 1947.. 1948.. 1949.. 99.7 124.5 157.9 191.6 210.1 211.9 208.5 231.3 257.6 256.5 91.9 115.1 142.8 166.0 177.9 176.8 187.7 214.6 240.1 237.0 89.1 112.2 139.5 162.4 173.8 172.3 182.7 208.6 233.5 230.1 82.6 103.3 126.5 147.2 158.5 156.4 163.9 188.5 210.2 211.4 6.5 8.9 13.0 15.3 15.3 15.9 18.8 20.2 23.3 18.8 2.4 2.5 2.9 3.2 3.7 4.1 4.5 5.1 5.6 5.9 .4 .4 .4 .4 .4 .4 .6 .8 1.0 1.0 7.8 9.4 15.1 25.6 32.2 35.2 20.8 16.7 17.4 19.4 1950.. 1951.. 1952.. 1953.. 1954.. 1955.. 1956.. 1957.. 1958.. 1959.. 284.8 328.4 345.5 364.6 364.8 398.0 419.2 441.1 447.3 483.7 263.9 301.0 314.3 332.7 332.4 363.8 382.6 402.0 405.2 439.4 256.3 292.8 305.8 323.6 322.7 352.9 370.8 389.3 391.7 425.0 236.3 269.9 283.7 303.3 303.1 334.1 352.2 370.9 370.9 405.3 20.0 22.9 22.2 20.3 19.6 18.8 18.6 18.4 20.8 19.6 6.4 6.9 7.2 7.8 8.1 9.1 9.8 10.5 11.4 12.2 1.2 1.3 1.3 1.3 1.6 1.8 2.1 2.2 2.0 2.2 20.9 27.4 31.2 31.9 32.5 34.2 36.6 39.1 42.1 44.3 I960.. 1961.. 1962.. 1963.. 1964.. 1965.. 1966.. 1967.. 1968 P. 503.7 520.1 560.3 590.5 632.4 684.9 747.6 789.7 860.7 456.3 469.2 505.7 532.4 569.4 617.1 671.1 704.8 766.4 440.7 452.3 487.4 513.0 548.2 594.4 646.7 677.9 737.4 420.2 431.4 466.2 491.5 527.6 570.8 622.0 653.7 712.4 20.5 20.9 21.2 21.5 20.6 23.7 24.7 24.2 25.0 13.2 14.0 15.0 16.0 17.3 18.5 20.2 22.3 24.0 2.4 2.9 3.3 3.4 4.0 4.2 4.2 4.6 5.0 47.5 50.9 54.7 58.1 63.0 67.8 76.5 84.8 94.3 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1966: L II IIL. IV 728.4 740.4 753.3 768.2 655.4 665.3 675.4 688.2 631.5 641.3 650.8 663.1 605.9 616.5 626.5 639.0 25.6 24.8 24.2 24.2 19.9 19.7 20.4 20.7 4.0 4.2 4.1 4.4 73.0 75.1 77.9 80.0 1967: I . — II III IV 772.2 780.2 795.3 811.0 690.4 696.7 709.8 722.3 664.5 670.7 682.4 694.1 640.7 646.7 658.0 669.4 23.8 24.0 24.4 24.8 21.8 22.1 22.5 22.9 4.1 4.0 5.0 5.3 81.8 83.5 85.4 88.6 1968: L — 831.2 852.9 871.0 887.8 740.3 759.9 775.0 790.3 712.4 730.8 745.6 760.7 688.1 706.1 720.2 735.2 24.3 24.7 25.5 25.5 23.5 24.2 24.2 24.2 4.4 4.9 5.2 5.4 90.8 93.0 96.0 97.6 III V 1 * Gross national product less compensation of general government employees. 2 Includes compensation of employees in government enterprises. Government enterprises are those agencies of government whose operating costs are to a substantial extent covered by the sale of goods and services, in contrast to the general activities of government, which are financed mainly by tax revenues and debt creation. The Post Office and public power systems are examples of government enterprises; on the other hand, State universities and public parks are part of general government activities. 3 Compensation of general government employees. Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 236 TABLE B-8.—Gross national product by sector, in 1958 prices, 1929-68 [Billions of dollars, 1958 prices) Gross private productl Total gross national product Year or quarter Business Households Tntal 1 Oldl Nonfarm2 Total Rest of the world Gross government products Farm 1929 203.6 190.9 182.1 165.1 17.0 7.4 1.4 12.7 1930 1931 1932 1933.... 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 183.5 169.3 144.2 141.5 154.3 169.5 193.0 203.2 192.9 209.4 170.1 155.8 131.0 127.5 138.3 152.4 173.1 184.3 172.6 188.7 161.4 147.7 123.8 120.6 131.1 144.9 165.4 176.4 164.6 180.7 145.4 129.2 105.8 103.0 116.6 128.4 150.5 158.5 146.8 162.5 16.1 18.5 18.0 17.5 14.6 16.5 14.9 17.9 17.8 18.2 7.1 6.6 6.0 5.7 6.2 6.4 6.8 7.1 6.8 7.1 1.6 1.4 1.3 1.2 1.0 1.1 1.0 .8 1.1 .9 13.3 13.5 13.2 14.0 16.0 17.1 19.9 18.9 20.4 20.6 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 227.2 263.7 297.8 337.1 361.3 355.2 312.6 309.9 323.7 324.1 205.6 236.6 257.3 272.8 286.9 282.5 275.1 281.4 295.0 294.1 197.1 228.1 248.7 264.9 278.9 274.6 267.0 272.8 286.0 284.7 179.6 209.3 228.0 245.3 259.5 256.5 248.6 255.8 267.0 266.2 17.5 18.8 20.6 19.6 19.4 18.1 18.5 17.0 19.0 18.4 7.6 7.5 7.8 7.2 7.1 7.1 7.1 7.5 7.9 8.2 1.0 .9 .8 .8 .9 .8 .9 1.1 1.2 1.2 21.6 27.2 40.5 64.3 74.4 72.8 37.5 28.6 28.7 30.1 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 355.3 383.4 395.1 412.8 407.0 438.0 446.1 452.5 447.3 475.9 324.2 344.6 353.2 371.1 366.2 397.2 404.8 410.5 405.2 433.4 314.2 334.5 343.2 360.7 355.4 385.4 392.2 397.5 391.7 419.4 294.9 316.2 324.2 340.7 335.0 364.4 371.4 377.2 370.9 398.3 19.4 18.4 19.0 20.0 20.4 20.9 20.8 20.3 20.8 21.1 8.7 8.8 8.8 9.1 9.2 10.1 10.6 10.9 11.4 11.7 1.3 1.2 1.2 1.3 1.6 1.8 2.0 2.1 2.0 2.2 31.1 38.8 4U8 41.7 40.9 40.7 41.3 41.9 42.1 42.5 487.7 497.2 529.8 551.0 581.1 617.8 657.1 673.1 706.9 444.0 452.3 482.9 503.2 532.0 567.0 602.1 614.0 644.8 429.5 436.9 466.7 486.6 514.4 548.9 583.4 594.0 623.8 407.6 414.8 444.6 463.8 492.1 525.2 561.1 569.9 599.9 21.9 22.2 22.1 22.8 22.3 23.7 22.2 24.1 23.9 12.2 12.4 12.9 13.2 13.7 14.0 14.8 15.5 16.1 2.3 2.9 3.4 3.4 3.9 4.1 4.0 4.5 4.9 43.7 44.8 46.9 47 8 49.1 50.8 55.0 59.0 62.0 * 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968* Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1966: I II III IV 648.6 653.3 659.5 667.1 595.5 598.9 603.8 610.3 577.0 580.3 585.0 591.1 554.3 557.4 563.6 569.3 22.7 22.9 21.4 21.9 14.7 14.5 14.9 15.0 3.8 4.0 3.9 4.2 53.1 54.4 55.7 56.8 1967: I II III IV 665.7 669.2 675.6 681.8 607.9 610.6 616.0 621.7 588.5 591.2 595.6 600.8 564.8 567.5 571.2 576.3 23.7 23.7 24.4 24.5 15.3 15.5 15.6 15.7 4.1 3.9 4.9 5.2 57.8 58.6 59.6 60.1 1968: I II III IV P 692.7 703.4 712.3 719.1 631.8 641.6 649.7 656.2 611.4 620.5 628.5 634.9 587.8 596.2 604.5 610.9 23.6 24.3 24.0 24.0 16.1 16.3 16.2 16.0 4.3 4.8 5.1 5.3 60.9 61.8 62.6 62.9 1 Gross national product less compensation of general government employees. 2 Includes compensation of employees in government enterprises. Government enterprises are those agencies of government whose operating costs are to a substantial extent covered by the sale of goods and services, in contrast to the general activities of government which are financed mainly by tax revenues and debt creation. The Post Office and public power systems are e xamplesof government enterprises; on the other hand, State universities and public parks are part of general government activities. 3 Compensation of general government employees. SouFCe: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 237 323-166 0—69 -16 TABLE B-9.—Gross national product by industry, in 1958 prices, 1947-67 [Billions of dollars, 1958 prices] Manufacturing Year AgriTotal culture, Congross fores- tract nacontry, tional strucand product fishtion eries Total TransGovporta- Whole- Finance, erntion, insurment sale saie All comance, Servand Non- muniDurand and ices govern- other i able durable cation, retail real ment goods goods trade estate enterindus- indus- and prises tries tries utilities 1947. 1948. 1949. 1950. 1951. 1952. 1953. 1954. 1955. 1956. 1957. 1958. 1959. 309.9 323.7 324.1 17.9 20.0 19.4 12.9 14.1 14.7 91.8 96.3 90.9 52.3 55.0 50.5 39.4 41.3 40.4 29.6 30.4 28.7 52.7 54.2 55.2 35.6 36.5 37.8 30.6 31.9 32.1 32.4 33.2 34.7 6.7 7.1 10.6 355.3 383.4 395.1 412.8 407.0 20.4 19.5 20.2 21.2 21.6 16.2 18.2 18.3 18.9 19.3 105.5 116.2 118.7 128.6 119.5 60.8 69.0 71.5 79.1 71.2 44.7 47.2 47.3 49.5 48.3 30.8 34.3 34.6 35.7 36.4 60.4 61.4 62.9 64.9 65.5 41.0 42.9 44.7 46.8 49.8 33.1 34.0 34.5 35.3 35.4 35.9 43.9 47.2 47.1 46.1 12.1 13.0 14.0 14.3 13.5 438.0 446.1 452.5 447.3 475.9 22.1 22.0 21.5 22.0 22.3 20.8 21.8 21.1 20.7 22.0 133.6 134.1 134.6 123.7 138.9 80.7 79.4 79.6 69.6 79.9 52.9 54.6 54.9 54.0 59.0 38.6 40.5 41.3 40.6 43.3 71.6 73.8 75.1 75.1 80.8 52.7 54.8 57.0 59.2 61.4 38.2 40.2 41.8 42.9 45.1 46.0 46.2 46.9 47.3 47.9 14.4 12.7 13.1 16.0 14.1 1960. 1961. 1962. 1963 1964. 487.7 497.2 529.8 551.0 581.1 23.1 23.4 23.3 24.0 23.6 21.7 21.4 21.7 21.9 23.3 140.9 140.4 154.6 162.4 173.7 81.0 79.7 90.0 95.6 102.4 59.9 60.7 64.7 66.8 71.3 44.9 46.0 48.9 51.9 54.7 82.3 83.5 88.9 92.8 98.9 64.1 67.1 71.2 74.4 78.3 46.7 48.3 50.8 52.2 54.7 49.2 50.6 52.6 53.9 56.1 14.7 16.3 17.9 17.4 17.8 1965 1966 1967 617.8 657.1 673.1 25.0 23.5 25.4 23.5 24.4 23.6 190.5 205.7 206.5 114.8 124.9 124.3 75.7 80.8 82.2 59.2 64.4 68.0 104.8 111.7 113.6 83.1 87.2 90.1 57.7 60.5 62.7 58.0 62.2 66.9 15.8 17.4 16.3 i Mining, rest of world, and residual (the difference between gross national product measured as sum of final products and gross national product measured as sum of gross product by industries). Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 238 TABLE B-10.—Personal consumption expenditures, 1929-68 [Billions of dollars] Durable goods c o "S. n • 8- ex. 3 XJ Is 1 Other Total Housi Trans Other 77. 2 9.2 3.2 4.8 1. 2 37.7 19.5 9.4 1.8 7. 0 30.3 11.5 4. 0 2. 6 12.2 1930 1931 1932—. 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 69. 9 60. 5 48. 6 45. 8 51. 3 55. 7 61. 9 66. 5 63. 9 66. 8 7.2 5.5 3.6 3.5 4.2 5.1 6.3 6.9 5.7 6.7 2.2 1.6 .9 1.1 1.4 1.9 2.3 2.4 1.6 2.2 3.9 3.1 2.1 1.9 2.2 2.6 3.2 3.6 3.1 3.5 1. 1 9 6 5 6 7 8 l! 0 9 l! 0 34.0 29.0 22.7 22.3 26.7 29.3 32.9 35.2 34.0 35.1 18.0 14.7 11.4 10.9 12.2 13.6 15.3 16.5 15.6 15.7 8.0 6.9 5.1 4.6 5.7 6.0 6.6 6.8 6.8 7.1 1.7 1.5 1.5 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.9 2.1 2.1 2.2 6. 3 5. 7 4. 8 5. 3 7. 2 7. 9 9. 1 9. 8 9. 5 10.1 28.7 26. 0 22. 2 20.1 20. 4 21. 3 22. 8 24. 4 24. 3 25.0 11.0 10.3 9.0 7.9 7.6 7.7 8.0 8.5 8.9 9.1 3. 9 3. 5 3. 0 2. 8 3. 0 3. 2 3. 4 3. 7 3. 6 3. 8 2. 2 1.9 1. 6 1. 5 1. 6 1. 7 1. 9 2. 0 1. 9 2. 0 11.5 10.3 8.6 7.9 8.2 8.7 9.5 10.2 9.9 10.1 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945.... 1946—. 1947.... 1948.... 1949 70. 8 80. 6 88. 5 99. 3 08. 3 19. 7 43. 4 60. 7 73. 6 7.8 9.6 6.9 6.6 6.7 8.0 15.8 20.4 22.7 24.6 2.7 3.4 .7 .8 .8 1.0 4.0 6.2 7.5 9.9 3.9 4.9 4.7 3.9 3.8 4.6 8.6 10.9 11.9 11.6 1. 1 1. 4 1. 6 1. 9 2. 2 2. 5 3. 2 3. 3 3. 4 3.2 37.0 42.9 50.8 58.6 64.3 71.9 82.4 90.5 96.2 94.5 16.6 19.2 23.3 27.4 29.9 33.2 39.0 43.7 46.3 44.8 7.4 8.8 11.0 13.4 14.4 16.5 18.2 18.8 20.1 19.3 2.3 2.6 2.1 1.3 1.6 1.8 3.0 3.6 4.4 5.0 10. 7 12.2 14. 4 16.5 18.4 20.5 22. 1 24.4 25. 4 25. 4 26. 0 28. 1 30.8 34. 2 37. 2 39. 8 45.3 49.8 54.7 57. 6 9.4 10.2 11.0 11.5 12.0 12.5 13.9 15.7 17.5 19.3 4. 0 4. 3 4.8 5.2 5.9 6.4 6. 8 7. 5 8.1 8. 5 2. 1 2. 4 7 4 3. 7 4. 0 5.0 5.3 5. 8 5. 9 10.4 11.2 12.3 14.0 15.6 16.8 19.7 21.4 23.3 23.9 1950 1951 1952.... 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 91. 0 206. 3 216. 7 30.5 29.6 29.3 230.0 33.2 236. 5 32.8 254. 4 39.6 266.7 38.9 281. 4 40.8 290. 1 37.9 311. 2 44.3 13.1 11.6 11.1 14.2 13.6 18.4 16.4 18.3 15.4 19.5 14.1 14.4 14.3 14.9 15.0 16.6 17.5 17.3 17.1 18.9 3. 3 3.6 3.9 4. 1 4.2 4. 6 5. 0 5. 2 5. 4 5.9 98.1 108.8 114.0 116.8 118.3 123.3 129.3 135.6 140.2 146.6 46.0 52.1 54.7 55.5 56.5 58.1 60.4 63.9 66.6 68.4 19.6 21.2 21.9 22.1 22.1 23.1 24.1 24.3 24.7 26.4 5.4 6.1 6.8 7.7 8.2 9.0 9.8 10.6 11.0 11.6 27. 1 29. 3 30. 5 31. 6 31. 5 33. 1 34. 9 36. 7 37 9 40. 2 62.4 21.3 67. 9 23.9 73. 4 26.5 79. 9 29.3 85. 4 31.7 91. 4 33.7 98.5 36.0 105.0 38.5 112. 0 41.1 120. 3 43.7 9. 5 10. 4 11. 1 12.0 12. 6 14.0 15. 2 16. 2 17. 3 18. 5 6. 2 6. 7 7. 1 7. 8 7. 9 8.2 8.6 9. 0 9 3 10 1 25.4 26.9 28.7 30.8 33.2 35.5 38.6 41.3 44.3 48.0 45.3 44.2 49.5 53.9 59.2 66.3 70.5 72.6 82.5 20.1 18.4 22.0 24.3 25.8 30.3 30.4 30.4 36.5 18.9 19.3 20.5 22.2 25.0 26.9 29.8 31.4 34.3 6. 3 151.3 6 5 155.9 6 9 162.6 7. 5 168.6 70.1 72.1 74.4 76.5 80.5 85.8 92.7 94.9 101.3 27.3 27.9 29.6 30.6 33.5 35.9 39.8 42.1 45.8 12.3 12.4 12.9 13.5 14.0 15.3 16.6 18.1 19.8 41. 6 128. 7 43 5 135 1 45 7 143 0 46.3 48.7 52.0 55.4 59.3 63.5 67.3 70.9 76.2 20. 0 20. 8 22. 0 10 8 10.6 11 0 25.6 27.1 29. 0 31. 2 6 15.0 16.6 51.6 54.9 58.0 62.5 68.1 73.8 80.4 88.9 97.0 '5 1 oo c o •I I Housi T3 Gasol ine an Cloth ing an -a 1 | Total perso i' 03 Other 1929 quarter Furnit u r e a hoid equ Food, exclu dm hoi ic bev era; s Total ooaa Autor nobile 5 3 \ Total or 1 = ion Year Services Nondurable goods 76.8 325.2 1960 335. 2 1961 1962.... 355. 1 1963.-.. 375. 0 1964..-. 401. 2 432. 8 1965 1966 465. 5 492 2 1967 1968 p . - 533. 7 8. 5 9 1 10 3 10 9 11 7 178.7 191.1 206.7 215.8 230.2 48. 0 152 4 50.6 163 3 54 1 175 5 57. 5 188 3 60 6 203.8 63. 3 221 o 23. 1 24. 3 i 11 11 12 13 4 6 6 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1 9 6 6 : 1 . . . 457 8 II . 461 1 III. 469 3 IV. 473 7 71.6 68.2 71.0 71.1 31.8 28.9 30.3 30.5 29.3 29.0 30.4 30.4 10 5 202.8 10 3 206.3 10. 3 208.3 10.2 209.3 91.4 93.1 93.3 93.2 39.2 39.4 40.5 40.3 16.0 16.4 16.7 17.1 56.2 57 4 57 8 58 7 183 186 190 193 4 7 0 3 66.0 66.8 67.6 68.8 26 26 27 27 1 9 6 7 : 1 . . . 480 .9 II- 490.3 III. 495 .5 IV. 502 .2 69.8 73.4 73.1 74.2 28.1 31.2 31.0 31.4 31.1 31.2 31.4 31.8 10.6 11.0 10.8 11.1 212.9 215.3 216.4 218.4 94.4 94.4 94.7 96.2 40.9 42.4 42.8 42.3 17.7 17.8 18.3 18.6 59 9 60 7 60.6 61 3 198 201 205 209 2 6 9 6 69.7 70.4 71.2 72.2 519 .4 527 .9 541 .1 546 .3 79.0 81.0 85.1 84.8 33.3 33.9 35.4 34.4 11.1 11.7 11.5 12.3 226.5 98.6 228.2 101.0 232.7 102.2 233.5 103.1 44.6 44.8 47.2 46.5 19.7 19.4 20.0 20.2 63 63 63 63 6 213 9 0 218 7 74.0 75.4 76.9 78.6 1968:L. II. III IV 34.6 35.4 38.1 38.0 1 3 223.4 6 228.0 Quarterly data are estimates by Council of Economic Advisers. 2 Includes standard clothing issued to military personnel. s Includes imputed rental value of owner-occupied dwellings. Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics (except as noted). 239 13 3 13 6 13 6 13 8 77.9 79.4 81.3 82.9 28.1 28 7 29 2 29 9 14 14 15 15 7 8 1 5 85.7 87.7 90.4 92.0 30.3 31 0 31 5 31 9 16 2 16.3 16 8 17 1 93.3 95.9 98.2 100.5 2 9 5 8 TABLE B-1I.—Gross private domestic investment, 1929-68 [Billions of dollars] Change in business inventories Fixed investment Year or quarter Total gross private domestic investment Nonresidential Structures Total Residential structures Producers' durable equipment Total Total Total Total Nonfarm Total Nonfarm 0.2 Nonfarm Farm Nonfarm 1929.. 16.2 14.5 10.6 5.0 4.8 5.6 4.9 4.0 3.8 1930.. 19311932.. 1933.. 1934.. 1935.. 1936.. 1937.. 1938... 1939... 10.3 5.6 1.0 1.4 3.3 6.4 8.5 11.8 6.5 9.3 10.6 6.8 3.4 3.0 4.1 5.3 7.2 9.2 7.4 8.9 8.3 5.0 2.7 2.4 3.2 4.1 5.6 7.3 5.4 5.9 4.0 2.3 1.2 .9 1.0 1.2 1.6 2.4 1.9 2.0 3.9 2.3 1.2 .9 1.0 1.2 1.6 2.4 1.8 1.9 4.3 2.7 1.5 1.5 2.2 2.9 4.0 4.9 3.5 4.0 3.7 2.4 1.3 1.3 1.8 2.4 3.3 4.1 2.9 3.4 2.3 1.7 .7 .6 .9 2.2 1.6 1.2 1.6 1.9 2.0 2.9 1940... 1941.. 1942... 1943... 1944... 1945... 1946... 1947... 1948... 1949... 13.1 17.9 9.8 5.7 7.1 10.6 30.6 34.0 46.0 35.7 11.0 13.4 8.1 6.4 8.1 11.6 24.2 34.4 41.3 38.8 7.5 9.5 6.0 5.0 6.8 10.1 17.0 23.4 26.9 25.1 2.3 2.9 1.9 1.3 1.8 2.8 6.8 7.5 8.8 8.5 2.2 2.8 1.8 1.2 1.7 2.7 6.1 6.7 8.0 7.7 5.3 6.6 4.1 3.7 5.0 7.3 10.2 15.9 18.1 16.6 4.6 5.6 3.5 3.2 4.2 6.3 9.2 14.0 15.5 13.7 1950... 1951... 1952... 1953... 1954... 1955... 1956... 1957... 1958... 1959... 54.1 59.3 51.9 52.6 51.7 67.4 70.0 67.8 60.9 75.3 47.3 49.0 48.8 52.1 53.3 61.4 65.3 66.5 62.4 70.5 27.9 31.8 31.6 34.2 33.6 38.1 43.7 46.4 41.6 45.1 9.2 11.2 11.4 12.7 13.1 14.3 17.2 18.0 16.6 16.7 8.5 10.4 10.5 11.9 12.3 13.6 16.5 17.2 15.8 15.9 18.7 20.7 20.2 21.5 20.6 23.8 26.5 28.4 25.0 28.4 1960... 1961... 1962... 1963— 1964... 1965— 1966... 1967... 1968*.. 74.8 71.7 83.0 87.1 94.0 108.1 120.8 114.3 127.5 71.3 69.7 77.0 81.3 88.2 98.5 106.1 108.2 120.0 48.4 47.0 51.7 54.3 61.1 71.3 81.3 83.6 90.0 18.1 18.4 19.2 19.5 21.2 25.5 28.5 27.9 29.2 17.4 17.7 18.5 18.8 20.5 24.9 27.8 27.1 28.4 30.3 28.6 32.5 34.8 39.9 45.8 52.8 55.7 60.8 1.7 1.8 '.S .8 1.1 1.5 1.8 1.9 2.8 -.4 -1.1 -2.5 -1.6 -.7 1.1 1.3 2.5 -.9 .4 -.1 -1.6 -2.6 -1.4 .2 .4 2.1 1.7 -1.0 .3 3.4 3.9 2.1 1.4 1.3 1.5 7.2 11.1 14.4 13.7 3.2 3.7 1.9 1.2 1.1 1.4 6.7 10.4 13.6 12.8 2.2 4.5 1.8 -.6 -1.0 -1.0 6.4 -.5 4.7 -3.1 1.9 4.0 .7 -.6 -.6 -.6 6.4 1.3 3.0 -2.2 15.7 17.7 17.6 18.6 18.0 21.2 24.2 25.9 22.0 25.4 19.4 17.2 17.2 18.0 19.7 23.3 21.6 20.2 20.8 25.5 18.6 16.4 16.4 17.2 19.0 22.7 20.9 19.5 20.1 24.8 6.8 10.3 3.1 -L5 6.0 4.7 1.3 -1.5 4.8 6.0 9.1 2.1 1.1 -2.1 5.5 5.1 .8 -2.3 4.8 27.7 25.8 29.4 31.2 36.3 41.6 48.1 51.0 55.8 22.8 22.6 25.3 27.0 27.1 27.2 24.8 24.6 30.0 22.2 22.0 24.8 26.4 26.6 26.7 24.3 24.0 29.4 3.6 2.0 6.0 5.9 5.8 9.6 14.7 6.1 7.6 3.3 1.7 5.3 5.1 6.4 8.6 14.9 5.6 7.2 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 116.8 121.0 119.9 125.7 105.9 105.6 107.0 105.9 78.6 79.8 82.6 84.2 28.6 28.1 28.9 28.2 27.9 27.4 28.2 27.5 50.0 51.7 53.7 55.9 45.5 47.2 49.3 50.4 27.3 25.8 24.4 21.7 26.8 25.2 23.9 21.1 0.5 .5 .6 .6 10.9 15.4 12.8 19.8 10.7 15.4 13.3 20.2 II Ill IV..... 113.0 107.6 114.7 121.8 104.6 105.4 109.3 113.5 83.5 82.7 83.3 85.0 29.0 27.2 27.7 27.7 28.3 26.4 27.0 26.9 54.5 55.5 55.6 57.3 49.8 50.7 50.9 52.6 21.1 22.7 26.0 28.5 20.5 22.1 25.4 27.9 .6 .6 .6 .6 8.4 2.3 5.3 8.3 8.3 2.2 4.8 7.1 1968: I II III..... 119.7 127.3 127.1 136.1 117.6 116.5 119.6 126.0 88.6 87.0 90.1 94.2 29.6 28.5 28.8 29.8 28.8 27.7 28,0 29.0 59.0 58.5. 61.3 64.4 54.3 53.6 56.4 59.0 29.1 29.5 29.5 31.8 28.5 28.9 28.9 31.2 .6 .6 .6 .6 2.1 10.8 7.5 10.0 1.6 10.4 7.3 9.2 1966: II III IV..... 1967: I Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 24O TABLE B-12.—National income by type of income, 1929-68 [Billions of dollars] Compensation of employees Year or quarter Total national income1 Total Corporate profits and inventory valuation adjustment Business and professional income Income Rental inof InSupNet come Inven- farm come pleof Corpo- Inven- interproof Wages ments tory tory est perrate prieunin- valuand to valusala- wages Total corpo- ation tors 3 sons Total profits ation before adjustrated adjustries and taxes • ment enter- ment salaprises ries 2 1929 86.8 51.1 50.4 0.7 9.0 8.8 0.1 6.2 5.4 10.5 10.0 0.5 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 75.4 59.7 42.8 40.3 49.5 57.2 65.0 73.6 67.4 72.6 46.8 39.8 31.1 29.5 34.3 37.3 42.9 47.9 45.0 48.1 46.2 39.1 30.5 29.0 33.7 36.7 41.9 46.1 43.0 45.9 .7 .6 .6 .5 .6 .6 1.0 1.8 2.0 2.2 7.6 5.8 3.6 3.3 4.7 5.5 6.7 7.2 6.9 7.4 6.8 5.1 3.3 3.9 4.8 5.5 6.8 7.2 6.7 7.6 4.3 3.4 2.1 2.6 3.0 5.3 4.3 6.0 4.4 4.4 4.8 7.0 3.8 2.0 2.7 - 1 . 3 2.0 - 1 . 2 1.7 1.7 1.7 3.4 1.8 5.6 2.1 6.8 2.6 4.9 2.7 6.3 3.7 -.4 -2.3 1.0 2.3 3.6 6.3 6.8 4.0 7.0 3.3 2.4 1.0 -2.1 -.6 -.2 -.7 1.0 -.7 49 5.0 4.6 4.1 4.1 4.1 3 8 3.7 3.6 3.5 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 81.1 104.2 137.1 170.3 182.6 181.5 181.9 199.0 224.2 217.5 52.1 64.8 85.3 109.5 121.2 123.1 117.9 128.9 141.1 141.0 49.8 62.1 82.1 105.8 116.7 117.5 112.0 123.0 135.4 134.5 2.3 2.7 3.2 3.8 4.5 5.6 5.9 5.9 5.8 6.5 8.6 11.1 14.0 17.0 18.2 19.2 21.6 20.3 22.7 22.6 8.6 11.7 14.4 17.1 18.3 19.3 23.3 21.8 23.1 22.2 .8 .6 .3 -.5 -.1 * - . 1* .2 -.2 * -.6 -.4 -.2 9.8 15.2 20.3 24.4 23.8 19.2 19.3 25.6 33.0 30.8 10.0 17.7 21.5 25.1 24.1 19.7 24.6 31.5 35.2 28.9 -.2 -2.5 -1.2 -.8 -.3 -.6 -5.3 -5.9 -2.2 1.9 3.3 3.2 3.1 2 7 2.3 2.2 1.5 1.9 1.8 1.9 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 241.1 278.0 291.4 304.7 303.1 331.0 350.8 366.1 367.8 400.0 154.6 180.7 195.3 209.1 208.0 224.5 243.1 256.0 257.8 279.1 146.8 171.1 185.1 198.3 196.5 211.3 227.8 238.7 239.9 258.2 7.8 9.6 10.2 10.9 11.5 13.2 15.2 17.3 17.9 20.9 24.0 26.1 27.1 27.5 27.6 30.3 31.3 32.8 33.2 35.1 25.1 26.5 26.9 27.6 27.6 30.5 31.8 33.1 33.2 35.3 37.7 42.7 39.9 39.6 38.0 46.9 46.1 45.6 41.1 51.7 42.6 43.9 38.9 40.6 38.3 48.6 48.8 47.2 41.4 52.1 -5.0 -1.2 1.0 -1.0 -.3 -1.7 -2.7 -1.5 -.3 -.5 2.0 2.3 2.6 2.8 3.6 4.1 4.6 5.6 6.8 7.1 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 v 414.5 427.3 457.7 481.9 518.1 564.3 620.8 652.9 712.8 294.2 302.6 323.6 341.0 365.7 393.8 435.6 468.2 513.6 270.8 278.1 296.1 311.1 333.7 358.9 394.6 423.4 463.5 23.4 24.6 27.5 29.9 32.0 35.0 41.1 44.8 50.1 34.2 35.6 37.1 37.9 40.2 42.4 44.8 46.3 47.8 34.3 35.6 37.1 37.9 40.3 42.8 45.1 46.6 48.4 .2 -.1 .3 -.5 -A -1.7 -1.5 -.4 .5 -1.1 -.3 .2 -.2 -.2 -.5 -.3 -.1 -.1 * * * * -.1 -.4 -.3 -.3 -.6 4.5 6.4 9.8 11.7 11.6 12.2 14.9 15.2 17.5 12.7 2.9 3.5 4.5 5.1 5.4 5.6 6.6 s!o IK 4.7 13.5 15.8 15.0 13.0 12.4 11.4 11.4 11.3 13.4 11.4 8.4 9.4 10.3 11.5 12.7 13.6 13.9 14.3 14.8 15.4 15.6 12.0 12.8 13.0 13.1 12.1 14.8 15.9 14.4 15.1 15.8 16.0 16.7 17.1 18.0 19.0 19.8 20.3 21.0 49.9 50.3 55.7 58.9 66.3 76.1 83.9 80.4 89.2 49.7 50.3 55.4 59.4 66.8 77.8 85.6 81.6 92.3 -L7 -1.7 -1.2 -3.1 8.4 10.0 11.6 13.8 15.8 18.2 20.8 23.3 26.3 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1966: 1 . . . || III . IV.. 604.0 615.1 626.7 637.3 420.6 430 8 441.4 449.7 381.0 390 2 399.8 407.2 39.6 40 5 41.5 42.5 44.5 44 7 44.7 45.2 16.9 16.1 15.5 15.1 19.5 19.7 19.9 20.0 82.7 83.4 84.2 85.3 85.2 85.6 86.7 85.0 -2.6 -2.2 -2.5 .3 19.8 20.4 21.1 22.0 1967: L__ II... III IV.. 638.6 645.1 656 9 670.9 456.7 461.8 471.5 482.7 413.3 417.6 426 3 436.4 43.4 44.2 45 2 46.2 45.7 46.1 46 6 46.8 14.4 14.4 14.6 14.3 20.1 20.2 20.4 20.5 79.5 79.6 80.2 82.3 79.9 80.3 80.8 85.4 -.4 -.7 -.6 -3.1 22.2 22.9 23.6 24.3 688 1 1968' 1 IL.. 705.4 722.5 Ill IV P. ^96 8 507.1 519.7 530.7 448 3 457.6 469.0 479.0 48 4 49.4 50.7 51.7 47 2 47.8 48.0 48.2 14.6 14.8 15.4 15 5 20.7 20.9 21.0 21 2 83.8 89.2 91.6 88.9 91.8 92.7 -5.1 -2.7 -1.0 -3.7 25.0 25.8 26.7 27.6 1 National income is the total net income earned in production. It differs from gross national product mainly in that it excludes depreciation charges and other allowances for business and institutional consumption of durable capital goods, and indirect business taxes. See Table B-13. 2 Employer contributions for social insurance and to private pension, health, and welfare funds; compensation for injuries; directors' fees; pay of the military reserve; and a few other minor items. 3 Includes change in inventories. * See Table B-70 for corporate tax liability and profits after taxes. Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 241 T A B L E B—13/—Relation of gross national product and national income, 1929—68 [Billions of dollars] Year or quarter Gross national product Less: Capital consumption allowances Plus: Subsidies Equals: less Net current national surplus of govprodernuct ment enterprises Less: Indirect business taxes Total Federal State and local Business transfer payments Statistical discrepancy 0.7 Equals: National income 1929- 103.1 7.9 95.2 -0.1 7.0 1.2 5.8 0.6 1930.. 1931.. 1932.. 1933.. 1934.. 1935.. 1936.. 1937.. 19381939.. 90.4 75.8 58.0 55.6 65.1 72.2 .5 82.4 68.0 50.7 48.6 58.2 65.4 75.4 83.3 77.4 83.2 -.1 .1 .2 .5 7.2 6.9 6.8 7.1 7.8 8.2 8.7 9.2 9.2 9.4 1.0 .9 .9 1.6 2.2 2.2 2.3 2.4 2.2 2.3 6.1 6.0 5.8 5.4 5.6 6.0 6.4 6.8 6.9 7.0 .5 .6 90.4 84.7 90.5 8.0 7.9 7.4 7.0 6.8 6.9 7.0 7.2 7.3 7.3 1940.. 1941.. 1942.. 1943.. 1944.. 1945.. 1946.. 1947.. 1948.. 1949.. 99.7 124.5 157.9 191.6 210.1 211.9 208.5 231.3 257.6 256.5 7.5 8.2 9.8 10.2 11.0 11.3 9.9 12.2 14.5 16.6 92.2 116.3 148.1 181.3 199.1 200.7 198.6 219.1 243.1 239.9 .4 .1 .2 .2 .7 .8 .9 -.2 -.1 -.1 10.0 11.3 11.8 12.7 14.1 15.5 17.1 18.4 20.1 21.3 2.6 3.6 4.0 4.9 6.2 7.1 7.8 7.8 8.0 8.0 7.4 7.7 7.7 7.8 8.0 8.4 9.3 10.6 12.1 13.3 .4 .5 .5 .5 .5 .5 .5 .6 .7 1950.. 1951.. 1952.. 1953.. 1954.. 1955. 1956. 1957. 1958. 1959. 284.8 328.4 345.5 364.6 364.8 398.0 419.2 441.1 447.3 483.7 18.3 21.2 23.2 25.7 28.2 31.5 34.1 37.1 38.9 41.4 266.4 307.2 322.3 338.9 336.6 366.5 385.2 404.0 408.4 442.3 .2 .2 -. 1 -.4 -.2 -. 1 .8 .9 .9 23.3 25.2 27.6 29.6 29.4 32.1 34.9 37.3 38.5 41.5 8.9 9.4 10.3 10.9 9.7 10.7 11.2 11.8 11.5 12.5 14.5 15.8 17.3 18.7 19.7 21.4 23.6 25.5 27.0 28.9 .9 1.0 1.2 1.1 1.2 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1960. 1961. 1962. 1963. 1964. 1965. 1966. 1967. 1968 * 503.7 520.1 560.3 590.5 632.4 684.9 747.6 789.7 860.7 43.4 45.2 50.0 52.6 56.1 59.8 64.1 69.2 74.3 460.3 474.9 510.4 537.9 576.3 625.1 683.5 720.5 786.4 45.2 47.7 51.5 54.7 58.4 62.5 65.3 69.6 75.8 13.5 13.6 14.6 15.3 16.1 16.5 15.8 16.2 17.6 31.7 34.1 36.9 39.4 42.3 45.9 49.5 53.4 58.2 1.9 2.0 2.1 2.3 2.5 2.7 3.0 3.1 3.3 -1.0 -.8 .5 -.3 -1.3 -3.1 -3.3 -3.5 -4.7 414.5 427.3 457.7 481.9 518.1 564.3 620.8 652.9 712.8 .3 .4 * .1 .2 1.4 1.4 .8 1.3 1.3 2.3 1.6 'j .6 .6 .6 .6 .4 .5 .7 .3 .6 .5 -.2 1.2 * .6 1.3 1.0 .4 -1.1 -2.0 2.5 3.9 .1 .9 -2.0 .3 1.5 3.3 2.2 3.0 2.7 2.1 -1.1 1.6 86.8 75.4 59.7 42.8 40.3 49.5 57.2 65.0 73.6 67.4 72.6 81.1 104.2 137.1 170.3 182.6 181.5 181.9 199.0 224.2 217.5 241.1 278.0 291.4 304.7 303.1 331.0 350.8 366.1 367.8 400.0 Seasonally adjusted annual rate 728.4 740.4 753.3 768.2 62.3 63.5 64.7 65.9 666.1 676.9 688.6 702.4 1.9 2.2 2.8 2.3 62.9 64.9 66.0 67.5 15.2 15.9 16.0 16.1 47.8 49.0 50.0 51.4 2.9 3.0 3.0 3.0 -1.9 -3.9 -4.4 -3.1 604.0 615.1 626.7 637.3 1967: 1 II III. IV 772.2 780.2 795.3 811.0 67.1 68.4 70.0 71.1 705.1 711.8 725.3 739.8 1.8 1,6 1.5 1.3 68.0 69.0 70.1 71.2 15.9 16.1 16.3 16.4 52.1 52.8 53.8 54.7 3.1 3.1 3.2 3.2 -2.8 -3.8 -3.4 -4.2 638.6 645.1 656.9 670.9 1968: 1 II 111 831.2 852.9 871.0 887.8 72.3 73.7 74.9 76.2 758.8 779.1 796.1 811.6 .5 .7 1.0 .7 72.8 74.8 76.7 79.0 17.0 17.5 17.8 18.1 55.8 57.3 58.9 60.9 3.2 3.3 3.3 3.3 -4.7 -3.6 -5.3 688.1 705.4 722.5 1966: 1 II Ill IV . IVP Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 242 TABLE B-14.—Relation of national income and personal income, 1929-68 [Billions of dollars] Less: Year or quarter National income Corporate profits and inventory valuation adjustment Plus: Wage GovContributions accruals ernment for less transfer dispayments social insurburseto perments sons ance Interest paid by government (net) and by consumers Equals: Dividends Business transfer payments Personal income 10.5 0.2 0.9 2.5 5.8 0.6 85.9 75.4 59.7 42.8 40.3 49.5 57.2 65.0 73.6 67.4 72.6 7.0 2.0 -1.3 -1.2 1.7 3.4 5.6 6.8 4.9 6.3 .3 .3 .3 .3 .3 .3 .6 1.8 2.0 2.1 1.0 2.1 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.8 2.9 1.9 2.4 2.5 1.8 1.8 1.7 1.6 1.7 1.7 1.7 1.9 1.9 1.9 5.5 4.1 2.5 2.0 2.6 2.8 4.5 4.7 3.2 3.8 .5 .6 77.0 65.9 50.2 47.0 54.0 60.4 68.6 74.1 68.3 72.8 81.1 104.2 137.1 170.3 182.6 181.5 181.9 199.0 224.2 217.5 9.8 15.2 20.3 24.4 23.8 19.2 19.3 25.6 33.0 30.8 2.3 2.8 3.5 4.5 5.2 6.1 6.0 5.7 5.2 5.7 2.7 2.6 2.6 2.5 3.1 5.6 10.8 11.1 10.5 11.6 2.1 2.2 2.2 2.6 3.3 4.2 5.2 5.5 6.1 6.5 4.0 4.4 4.3 4.4 4.6 4.6 5.6 6.3 7.0 7.2 .4 .5 .5 .5 .5 .5 .5 .6 .7 78.3 96.0 122.9 151.3 165.3 171.1 178.7 191.3 210.2 207.2 241.1 278.0 291.4 304.7 303.1 331.0 350.8 366.1 367.8 400.0 37.7 42.7 39.9 39.6 38.0 46.9 46.1 45.6 41.1 51.7 6.9 8.2 8.7 8.8 9.8 11.1 12.6 14.5 14.8 17.6 14.3 11.5 12.0 12.8 14.9 16.1 17.1 19.9 24.1 24.9 7.2 7.6 8.1 9.0 9.5 10.1 11.2 12.0 12.1 13.6 8.8 8.6 8.6 8.9 9.3 10.5 11.3 11.7 11.6 12.6 .8 .9 1.0 1.2 1.1 1.2 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 227.6 255.6 272.5 288.2 290.1 310.9 333.0 351.1 361.2 383.5 414.5 427.3 457.7 481.9 518.1 564.3 620.8 652.9 712.8 49.9 50.3 55.7 58.9 66.3 76.1 83.9 80.4 89.2 20.7 21.4 24.0 26.9 27.9 29.6 38.0 41.9 46.9 26.6 30.4 31.2 33.0 34.2 37.2 41.0 48.6 55.3 15.1 15.0 16.1 17.6 19,1 20.5 22.3 23.6 25.9 13.4 13.8 15.2 16.5 17.8 19.8 21.7 22.9 24.6 1.9 2.0 2.1 2.3 2.5 2.7 3.0 3.1 3.3 401.0 416.8 442.6 465.5 497.5 538.9 586.8 628.8 685.8 0.2 -.2 \l .6 .6 .6 .6 .4 .5 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1966: I . . . II.. III. IV.. 604.0 615.1 626.7 637.3 82.7 83.4 84.2 85.3 36.5 37.3 38.7 39.4 39.5 39.0 41.0 44.3 21.5 22.1 22.4 23.1 21. 6 21. 9 21. 9 21. 6 2.9 3.0 3.0 3.0 570.4 580.3 592.1 604.5 1967: I . . . II.. III. IV.. 638.6 645.1 656.9 670.9 79.5 79.6 80.2 82.3 40.9 41.6 42.1 43.0 47.5 48.3 48.9 49.7 23.4 23.2 23.5 24.2 22. 5 23. 2 23. 5 22. 5 3.1 3.1 3.2 3.2 614.8 621.6 633.7 645.2 1968: I. 688.1 705.4 722.5 83.8 89.2 91.6 45.8 46.5 47.4 47.8 52.5 55.0 56.3 57.5 24.9 25.7 26.2 26.7 23.6 24. 4 25. 2 25. 4 3.2 3.3 3.3 3.3 662.7 678.1 694.3 708. 2 III. Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 243 TABLE B-15.—Disposition of personal income, 1929-68 Percent of disposable personal income Less: Personal outlays Year or quarter Personal income Less: Personal tax and nontax payments Equals: Disposable personal income Total PerPerEquals: sonal Interest sonal Percontransfer sonal sump- paid by paysaving contion ments expend- sumers to foreigners itures Personal outlays Consumption expenditures Total Billions of dollars Personal saving Percent 1929.. 85.9 2.6 83.3 79.1 77.2 1.5 0.3 4.2 95.0 92.7 5.0 1930.. 1931.. 1932.. 1933.. 1934.. 1935.. 1936.. 1937.. 1938.. 1939.. 77.0 65.9 50.2 47.0 54.0 60.4 68.6 74.1 68.3 72.8 2.5 1.9 1.5 1.5 1.6 1.9 2.3 2.9 2.9 2.4 74.5 64.0 48.7 45.5 52.4 58.5 66.3 71.2 65.5 70.3 71.1 61.4 49.3 46.5 52.0 56.4 62.7 67.4 64.8 67.7 69.9 60.5 48.6 45.8 51.3 55.7 61.9 66.5 63.9 66.8 .9 .7 .5 .5 .5 .5 .6 .7 .7 .7 .3 .3 .2 .2 .2 .2 .2 .2 .2 .2 3.4 2.6 -.6 -.9 .4 2.1 3.6 3.8 .7 2.6 95. 4 95. 9 101. 3 102. 0 99. 3 96. 3 94. 6 94. 7 98. 9 96. 3 93.8 94.4 99.8 100.6 98.0 95.2 93.3 93.4 97.6 95.0 4.6 4.1 -1.3 -2.0 1940.. 1941.. 1942.. 1943.. 1944.. 1945.. 1946.. 1947.. 1948.. 1949.. 78.3 96.0 122.9 151.3 165.3 171.1 178.7 191.3 210.2 207.2 2.6 3.3 6.0 17.8 18.9 20.9 18.7 21.4 21.1 18.6 75.7 92.7 116.9 133.5 146.3 150.2 160.0 169.8 189.1 188.6 71.8 81.7 89.3 100.1 109.1 120.7 144.8 162.5 175.8 179.2 70.8 80.6 88.5 99.3 108.3 119.7 143.4 160.7 173.6 176.8 .8 .9 .7 .5 .5 .5 .8 1.1 1.5 1.9 .2 .2 .1 .2 .4 .5 .7 .7 .7 .5 3.8 11.0 27.6 33.4 37.3 29.6 15.2 7.3 13.4 9.4 94.9 88.2 76.4 75.0 74. 5 80.3 90. 5 95. 7 92. 9 95. 0 93.6 86.9 75.7 74.4 74.0 79.7 89.6 94.6 91.8 93.8 5.1 11.8 23.6 25.0 25.5 19.7 9.5 4.3 7.1 5.0 1950.. 1951.. 1952.. 1953.. 1954.. 1955.. 1956.. 1957.. 1958.. 1959.. 227.6 255.6 272.5 288.2 290.1 310.9 333.0 351.1 361.2 383.5 20.7 29.0 34.1 35.6 32.7 35.5 39.8 42.6 42.3 46.2 206.9 226.6 238.3 252.6 257.4 275.3 293.2 308.5 318.8 337.3 193.9 209.3 220.2 234.3 241.0 259.5 272.6 287.8 296.6 318.3 191.0 206.3 216.7 230.0 236.5 254.4 266.7 281.4 290.1 311.2 2.4 2.7 3.0 3.8 4.0 4.7 5.4 5.8 5.9 6.5 .5 .4 .4 .5 .5 .5 .8 .6 .6 .6 13.1 17.3 18.1 18,3 16.4 15.8 20.6 20.7 22.3 19.1 93.7 92. 4 92. 4 92. 8 93. 6 94. 3 93. 0 93. 3 93. 0 94. 4 92.3 91.0 90.9 91.1 91.9 92.4 91.0 91.2 91.0 92.3 6.3 7.6 7.6 7.2 6.4 5.7 7.0 6.7 7.0 5.6 I960.. 1961.. 1962.. 1963.. 1964.. 1965.. 1966.. 1967.. 1968i 401.0 416.8 442.6 465.5 497.5 538.9 586.8 628.8 685.8 50.9 52.4 57.4 60.9 59.4 65.7 75.3 82.5 96.9 350.0 364.4 385.3 404.6 438.1 473.2 511.6 546.3 589.0 333.0 343.3 363.7 384.7 411.9 444.8 478.6 506.2 548.1 325.2 335.2 355.1 375.0 401.2 432.8 465.5 492.2 533.7 7.3 7.6 8.1 9.1 10.1 11.3 12.5 13.1 13.7 .5 .5 .5 .6 .6 .7 .6 .8 .7 17.0 21.2 21.6 19.9 26.2 28.4 32.9 40.2 40.8 95.1 94. 2 94.4 95. 1 94. 0 94. 0 93. 6 92. 6 93 1 92.9 92.0 92.2 92.7 91.6 91.5 91.0 90.1 90.6 4.9 5.8 5.6 4.9 6.0 6.0 6.4 7.4 6.9 3^7 5.4 5.3 1.1 3.7 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1966: I . . . III. IV. 1967: I . . II.. IV.. 1968: I . . II. 570.4 580.3 592.1 604.5 70.4 74.7 76.8 79.2 500.0 505.5 515.4 525.4 470.5 474.2 482.5 487.3 457.8 461.1 469.3 473.7 12.1 12.4 12.6 12.9 0.6 .7 .6 .6 29.5 31.4 32.9 38.1 94 93 93 92 1 8 6 7 91.6 91.2 91.1 90.2 5.9 6.2 6.4 7.3 614.8 621.6 633.7 645.2 80.5 80.1 83.6 85.6 534.2 541.5 550.0 559.6 494.6 504.5 509.5 516.1 480.9 490.3 495.5 502.2 13.0 13.1 13.2 13.3 .7 1.2 .8 .7 39.7 37.0 40.5 43.4 92 6 93 2 92.6 92.2 90.0 90.5 90.1 89.7 7.4 6.8 7.4 7.8 662.7 678.1 694.3 708.2 88.3 91.9 101.6 105.7 574.4 586.3 592.7 602.5 533.5 542.3 555.6 561.1 519.4 527.9 541.1 546.3 13.4 13.6 13.8 14.0 7 '.8 .7 40.8 44.0 37.1 41.4 92 9 92 5 93 7 93.1 90.4 90.0 91.3 90.7 7.1 7.5 6.3 6.9 Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 244 • 7 TABLE B-16.— Total and per capita disposable personal income and personal consumption expenditures, in current and 1958 prices, 1929-68 Disposable personal income Year or quarter Total (billions of dollars) Personal consumption expenditures Per capita (dollars) Total (billions of dollars) Current prices 77.2 139.6 634 1,145 121,875 69.9 60.5 48.6 45.8 51.3 55.7 61.9 66.5 63.9 66.8 130.4 126.1 114.8 112.8 118.1 125.5 138.4 143.1 140.2 148.2 567 487 389 364 406 437 483 516 492 510 1,059 1,016 919 897 934 985 1,080 1,110 1,079 1,131 123,188 124,149 124,949 125,690 126,485 127,362 128,181 128,961 129,969 131,028 70.8 80.6 88.5 99.3 108.3 119.7 143.4 160.7 173.6 176.8 155.7 165.4 161.4 165.8 171.4 183.0 203.5 206.3 210.8 216.5 536 604 656 726 782 855 1,014 1,115 1,184 1,185 1,178 1,240 1,197 1,213 1,238 1,308 1,439 1,431 1,438 1,451 132,122 133,402 134,860 136,739 138,397 139,928 141,389 144,126 146,631 149,188 1,646 1,657 1,678 1,726 1,714 1,795 1,839 1,844 1,831 1,881 191.0 206.3 216.7 230.0 236.5 254.4 266.7 281.4 290.1 311.2 230.5 232.8 239.4 250.8 255.7 274.2 281.4 288.2 290.1 307.3 1,259 1,337 1,381 1,441 1,456 1,539 1,585 1,643 1,666 1,758 1,520 1,509 1,525 1,572 1,575 1,659 1,673 1,683 1,666 1,735 151,684 154,287 156,954 159,565 162,391 165,275 168,221 171,274 174,141 177,073 1,883 1,909 1,968 2,013 2,123 2,235 2,332 2,401 2,473 325.2 335.2 355.1 375.0 401.2 432.8 465.5 492.2 533.7 316.1 322.5 338.4 353.3 373.7 397.7 417.8 430.5 450.7 1,800 1,824 1,902 1,980 2,088 2,224 2,364 2,472 2,653 1,749 1,755 1,813 1,865 1,945 2,044 2,122 2,162 2,240 180,684 183,756 186,656 189,417 192.120 194,592 196,920 199.118 201,166 1958 prices Current prices 1958 prices 1929. 83.3 150.6 683 1,236 1930. 1931. 1932. 1933. 1934. 1935. 1936. 1937. 1938. 1939. 74.5 64.0 48.7 45.5 52.4 58.5 66.3 71.2 65.5 70.3 139.0 133.7 115.1 112.2 120.4 131.8 148.4 153.1 143.6 155.9 605 516 390 362 414 459 518 552 504 537 1,128 1,077 921 893 952 1,035 1,158 1,187 1,105 1,190 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 75.7 92.7 116.9 133.5 146.3 150.2 160.0 169.8 189.1 188.6 166.3 190.3 213.4 222.8 231.6 229.7 227.0 218.0 229.8 230.8 573 695 867 976 1,057 1,074 1,132 1,178 1,290 1,264 1,259 1,427 1,582 1,629 1,673 1,642 1,606 1,513 1,567 1,547 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 206.9 226.6 238.3 252.6 257.4 275.3 293.2 308.5 318.8 337.3 249.6 255.7 263.3 275.4 278.3 296.7 309.3 315.8 318.8 333.0 1,364 1,469 1,518 1,583 1,585 1,666 1,743 1,801 1,^31 1,905 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 350.0 364.4 385.3 404.6 438.1 473.2 511.6 546.3 589.0 340.2 350.7 367.3 381.3 407.9 435.0 459.2 478.0 497.4 1,937 1,983 2,064 2,136 2,280 2,432 2,598 2,744 2,928 1958 prices Population (thousands) * 1958 prices Current prices Current prices Per capita (dollars) Seasonally adjusted annual rates 500.0 505.5 515.4 525.4 454.1 454.6 461.4 466.6 2,550 2,571 2,613 2,656 2,316 2,312 2,340 2,359 457.8 461.1 469.3 473.7 415.7 414.8 420.0 420.6 2,335 2,345 2,380 2,394 2,120 2,110 2,130 2,126 196,096 196,629 197,216 197,834 1967: I... IIIll IV. 534.2 541.5 550.0 559.6 471.9 476.3 479.5 483.7 2,693 2,723 2,758 2,798 2,379 2,395 2,404 2,418 480.9 490.3 495.5 502.2 424.8 431.2 431.8 434.1 2,424 2,466 2,485 2,511 2,142 2,168 2,165 2,170 198,356 198,852 199,425 200,006 1968: I... 574.4 586.3 592.7 602.5 491.8 497.1 499.2 501.6 2,866 2,918 2,942 2,982 2,454 2,474 2,478 2,483 519.4 527.9 541.1 546.3 444.9 447.5 455.7 454.8 2,591 2,628 2,686 2,704 2,220 2,227 2,262 2,251 200,433 200,911 201,462 202,025 1966: I. III. IV. IV p. 1 Population of the United States including Armed Forces overseas. Annual data are for July 1; quarterly data are for middle of period, interpolated from monthly data. Sources: Department of Commerce (Office of Business Economics and Bureau of the Census) and Council of Economic Advisers. 245 TABLE B-17.—Sources of personal income, 1929-68 [Billions of dollars] Wage and salary disbursements * Year or quarter Total personal ncome Propru inco CommoditypiUUUUHIg industries lotai Total Manufacturing Distrib- Service utive indus- industries tries ernment Gov- Other labor income 1 Business and professional 1929.. 85.9 50.4 21.5 16.1 15.6 8.4 4.9 0.6 9.0 1930.. 1931.. 1932.. 1933.. 1934.. 1935.. 1936.. 1937.. 1938.. 1939.. 77.0 65.9 50.2 47.0 54.0 60.4 68.6 74.1 68.3 72.8 46.2 39.1 30.5 29.0 33.7 36.7 41.9 46.1 43.0 45.9 18.5 14.3 9.9 9.8 12.1 13.5 15.8 18.4 15.3 17.4 13.8 10.8 7.7 7.8 9.6 10.8 12.4 14.6 11.8 13.6 14.5 12.5 9.8 8.8 9.9 10.7 11.8 13.2 12.6 13,3 8.0 7.1 5.8 5.2 5.7 5.9 6.5 7.1 6.8 7.1 5.2 5.3 5.0 5.1 6.1 6.5 7.9 7.5 8.2 8.2 .6 .5 .5 .4 .4 .5 .6 .6 .6 .6 7.6 5.8 3.6 3.3 4.7 5.5 6.7 7.2 6.9 7.4 1940.. 1941.. 1942. 1943.. 1944. 1945.. 1946.. 1947.. 1948. 1949. 78.3 96.0 122.9 151.3 165.3 171.1 178.7 191.3 210.2 207.2 49.8 62.1 82.1 105.6 116.9 117.5 112.0 123.0 135.3 134.6 19.7 27.5 39.1 48.9 50.3 45.8 46.0 54.3 61.0 57.7 15.6 21.7 30.9 40.9 42.9 38.2 36.5 42.5 47.2 44.7 14.2 16.3 18.0 20.1 22.7 24.8 31.0 35.2 37.6 37.7 7.5 8.1 9.0 9.9 10.9 12.0 14.4 16.1 17.9 18.6 8.4 10.2 16.0 26.6 33.0 34.9 20.7 17.4 18.9 20.6 .7 .7 .9 1.1 1.5 1.8 1.9 2.3 2.7 3.0 8.6 11.1 14.0 17.0 18.2 19.2 21.6 20.3 22.7 22.6 1950. 1951. 1952. 1953. 1954. 1955. 1956. 1957. 1958. 1959. 227.6 255.6 272.5 288.2 290.1 310.9 333.0 35L1 361.2 383.5 146.7 171.0 185.1 198.3 196.5 211.3 227.8 238.7 239.9 258.2 64.6 76.1 81.8 89.4 85.4 92.8 100.2 103.8 99.7 109.1 50.3 59.4 64.2 71.2 67.6 73.9 79.5 82.5 78.7 86.9 39.9 44.3 46.9 49.8 50.2 53.4 57.7 60.5 60.8 64.8 19.9 21.7 23.3 25.1 26.4 28.9 31.6 33.9 35.9 38.7 22.4 28.9 33,1 34.1 34.6 36.2 38.3 40.4 43.5 45.6 3.8 4.8 5.3 6.0 6.3 7.3 8.4 9.5 9.9 11.3 24.0 26.1 27.1 27.5 27.6 30.3 31.3 32.8 33.2 35.1 1960. 1961. 1962. 1963. 1964. 1965. 1966. 1967. 1968 v 401.0 416.8 442.6 465.5 497.5 538.9 586.8 628.8 685.8 270.8 278.1 296.1 311.1 333.7 358.9 394.6 423.4 463.5 112.5 112.8 120.8 125.7 134.1 144.5 159.4 166.6 180.5 89.7 89.8 96.7 100.6 107.2 115.6 128.0 134.1 145.4 68.1 69.1 72.5 76.0 81.2 86.9 93.9 100.5 109.4 41.5 44.0 46.8 49.9 54.1 58.3 63.6 70.0 77.2 48.7 52.2 56.0 59.5 64.3 69.3 77.7 86.3 96.3 12.0 12.7 13.9 14.9 16.6 18.7 20.8 23.3 26.1 34.2 35.6 37.1 37.9 40.2 42.4 44.8 46.3 47.8 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1966: I IL. III. IV.. 570.4 580.3 592.1 604.5 381.0 390.2 399.8 407.2 154.2 158.2 161.1 163.9 123.2 127.0 129.7 132.2 91.0 92.9 95.0 96.5 61.5 62.9 64.7 65.6 74.3 76.2 79.1 81.2 20.0 20.5 21.1 21.7 44.5 44.7 44.7 45.2 1967: I. 614.8 621.6 633.7 645.2 413.3 417.6 426.3 436.4 164.7 164.1 167.1 170.5 132.5 132.3 134.6 137.1 98.1 99.6 101.4 103.1 67.5 69.1 70.8 72.4 83.1 84.7 86.9 90.4 22.3 22.9 23.7 24.2 45.7 46.1 46.6 46.8 1968: I.. II. 662.7 678.1 694.3 708.2 448.3 457.6 469.0 479.0 175.6 178.6 181.6 186.1 141.2 143.8 146.7 149.7 105.6 108.0 111.1 113.1 74.5 76.2 78.2 79.9 92.6 94.8 98.1 99.9 25.0 25.7 26.5 27.3 47.2 47.8 48.0 48.2 See footnotes at end of table. 246 Farm 2 TABLE B-17.—Sources of personal income, 1929-68—Continued [Billions of dollars] Transfer payments Year or quarter Rental nit#i ncome UIVIof per- dends sons Personal interest income Old-age, survivors, disability, Total and health insurance benefits State unemployment insurance benefits Veterans' benefits Less: Personal contributions Other for social insurance Nonagricultural personal income3 1929.. 5.4 5.8 7.2 1.5 0.6 0.9 0.1 77.6 1930.. 1931.. 1932.. 1933.. 1934.. 1935.. 1936.. 1937.. 1938.. 1939.. 4.8 3.8 2.7 2.0 1.7 1.7 1.8 2.1 2.6 2.7 5.5 4.1 2.5 2.0 2.6 2.8 4.5 4.7 3.2 3.8 6.8 6.7 6.3 5.7 5.8 5.7 5.5 5.6 5.5 5.5 1.5 2.7 2.2 2.1 2.2 2.4 3.5 2.4 2.8 3.0 * 0.4 .4 .9 L.I L.4 L.6 L.8 1.9 L.6 1.8 1.9 2.0 .1 .2 .2 .2 .2 .2 .2 .6 .6 .6 70.8 60.8 46.7 43.2 49.8 53.9 63.0 66.7 62.6 66.9 1940.. 1941.. 1942.. 1943.. 1944.. 1945.. 1946.. 1947.. 1948.. 1949.. 2.9 3.5 4.5 5.1 5.4 5.6 6.6 7.1 8.0 8.4 4.0 4.4 4.3 4.4 4.6 4.6 5.6 6.3 7.0 7.2 5.4 5.5 5.3 5.3 5.6 6.3 6.8 7.5 7.9 8.5 3.1 3.1 3.1 3.0 3.6 6.2 11.3 11.7 11.2 12.4 * * 0.1 .1 .2 .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .6 1.6 .8 .5 .4 .5 1.9 .6 .5 .5 .5 .3 .3 .1 .1 .4 1.1 .8 .8 1.7 .5 .5 .5 .5 .9 2.8 6.7 6.7 5.8 5.1 2.0 2.2 2.2 2.2 2.4 2.7 3.1 3.7 4.1 4.9 .7 .8 1.2 1.8 2.2 2.3 2.0 2.1 2.2 2.2 72.3 87.8 111.0 137.3 151.2 156.4 161.0 173.0 189.4 191.3 1950.. 1951.. 1952.. 1953.. 1954.. 1955.. 1956.. 1957.. 1958.. 1959.. 9.4 10.3 11.5 12.7 13.6 13.9 14.3 14.8 15.4 15.6 8.8 8.6 8.6 8.9 9.3 10.5 11.3 11.7 11.6 12.6 9.2 9.9 10.6 11.8 13.1 14.2 15.7 17.6 18.9 20.7 15.1 12.5 13.0 14.0 16.0 17.3 18.5 21.4 25.7 26.6 1.0 1.9 2.2 3.0 3.6 4.9 5.7 7.3 8.5 10.2 1.4 .8 1.0 1.0 2.0 1.4 1.4 1.8 3.9 2.5 4.9 3.9 3.9 3.7 3.9 4.3 4.3 4.4 4.6 4.6 7.9 5.9 6.0 6.3 6.5 6.8 7.2 7.9 8.7 9.4 2.9 3.4 3.8 4.0 4.6 5.2 5.8 6.7 6.9 7.9 210.9 236.4 254.1 271.9 274.7 296.4 318.5 336.6 344.3 368.5 I960.. 1961.. 1962.. 1963.. 1964.. 1965.. 1966.. 1967.. 1968 p. 15.8 16.0 16.7 17.1 18.0 19.0 19.8 20.3 21.0 13.4 13.8 15.2 16.5 17.8 19.8 21.7 22.9 24.6 23.4 25.0 27.7 31.4 34.9 38.7 43.1 46.8 52.1 28.5 32.4 33.3 35.3 36.7 39.9 43.9 51.7 58.6 11.1 12.6 14.3 15.2 16.0 18.1 20.8 25.7 30.3 2.8 4.0 2.9 2.8 2.6 2.2 1.8 2.1 2.0 4.6 4.8 4.8 5.0 5.3 5.6 5.7 6.6 7.2 10.0 10.9 11.2 12.2 12.9 14.0 15.6 17.3 19.1 9.3 9.6 10.3 11.8 12.5 13.4 17.8 20.4 22.9 385.2 400.0 425.5 448.1 480.9 519.5 566.1 609.3 665.4 * Seasonally adjusted annual rates IILIIII IV 1967: 1 II 111 IV 1968: 1 Ill IV x > 19.5 19.7 19.9 20.0 21.6 21.9 21.9 21.6 41.3 42.4 43.4 45.1 42.4 42.0 44.0 47.3 19.4 19.6 21.0 23.2 2.0 1.6 1.8 1.8 5.9 5.4 5.3 6.3 15.2 15.4 15.8 16.0 16.9 17.3 18.3 18.6 548.8 559.4 571.8 584.5 20.1 20.2 20.4 20.5 22.5 23.2 23.5 22.5 45.6 46.1 47.2 48.5 50.5 51.4 52.1 52.9 24.5 25.8 26.0 26.4 2.1 2.1 2.2 2.0 6.5 6.6 6.5 6.8 17.5 16.9 17.3 17.7 19.7 20.3 20.6 20.9 595.3 602.3 614.0 625.7 20.7 20.9 21.0 21.2 23.6 24.4 25.2 25.4 49.8 51.4 52.9 54.3 55.7 58.3 59.5 60.8 28.2 30.5 30.9 31.6 2.2 1.9 2.1 2.0 7.0 7.1 7.2 7.4 18.4 18.8 19.3 19.8 22.3 22.8 23.2 23.4 642.7 658.0 673.5 687.2 1 The total of wage and salary disbursements and other labor income differs from compensation of employees in Table B-12 in that it excludes employer contributions for social insurance and the excess of wage accruals over wage disbursements. 2 Includes change in inventories. 3 Nonagricultural income is personal income exclusive of net income of unincorporated farm enterprises, farm wages, agricultural net interest, and net dividends paid by agricultural corporations. Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 247 TABLE B-18.—Sources and uses of gross saving, 1929-68 [Billions of dollars] Gross private saving and government surplus or deficit, national income and product accounts Government surplus or deficit ( - ) Private saving Year or quarter Total Gross investment Total Personal saving Gross business saving Total Federal State and local -0.2 Total Gross private domestic investment Net foreign investment 1 Statistical discrepancy 1929 16.3 15.3 4.2 11.2 1.0 1.2 17.0 16.2 08 07 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 11.8 5.1 .8 .9 3.2 6.6 7.2 11.9 7.0 8.8 12.1 8.0 2.5 2.3 5.6 8.6 10.3 11.5 8.7 11.0 3.4 2.6 -.6 -.9 .4 2.1 3.6 3.8 .7 2.6 8.6 5.3 3.2 3.2 5.2 6.4 6.7 7.7 8.0 8.4 —.3 -2.9 -1.8 -1.4 -2.4 -2.0 -3.1 .3 -1.8 -2.2 .3 -2.1 -1.5 -1.3 -2.9 -2.6 -3.6 -.4 -2.1 -2.2 -.6 -.8 — 3 -.1 .5 .6 .5 .7 .4 (2) 11 0 58 1.1 1.6 3.8 64 8.4 11.8 7.6 10.2 10 3 5 6 1.0 1.4 3.3 64 8.5 11.8 6.5 9.3 7 .2 .2 —.1 -.1 .1 1.1 .9 — 8 7 3 .6 .5 _ 2 1.2 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 . . 1949 13.6 18.6 10.7 5.5 2.5 5.2 35.1 42.0 49.9 35.9 14.3 22.4 42.0 49.7 54.3 44.7 29.7 27.5 41.4 39.0 3.8 11.0 27.6 33.4 37.3 29.6 15.2 7.3 13.4 9.4 10.5 11.4 14.5 16.3 17.1 15 1 14.5 20.2 28.0 29.7 -.7 -3.8 -31.4 -44.1 -51.8 -39.5 5.4 14.4 8.5 -3.2 -1.3 -5.1 -33.1 -46.6 -54.5 -42.1 3.5 13.4 8.4 -2.4 .6 1.3 1.8 2.5 2.7 2.6 1.9 1.0 .1 -.7 14.6 19.0 9.6 3.5 5.0 9.1 35.2 42.9 47.9 36.2 13.1 17.9 9.8 5.7 7.1 10.6 30.6 34.0 46.0 35.7 1.5 1.1 2 -2.2 -2.1 -1.4 4.6 8.9 1.9 .5 1.0 .4 -1.1 -2.0 2.5 3 9 50.4 56.1 49.5 47.5 48.5 64.8 72.7 71.2 59.2 73.8 42.5 50.3 53 3 54.4 55.6 62.1 67.8 70.5 71.7 75.9 13.1 17.3 18.1 18.3 16.4 15.8 20.6 20.7 22.3 19.1 29.4 7.8 9.1 6.2 5.8 33.1 35 1 - 3 . 8 - 3 . 8 36.1 - 6 . 9 - 7 . 0 39.2 - 7 . 0 - 5 . 9 46.3 2.7 4.0 47.3 4.9 5.7 .7 2.1 49.8 49.4 - 1 2 . 5 - 1 0 . 2 56.8 - 2 . 1 - 1 . 2 -1.2 -.4 1 -1.1 -1.3 -.9 -1.4 -2.3 -.8 51.8 59.5 51.6 50.5 51.3 66.9 71.6 71.2 60.7 73.0 54.1 59.3 51.9 52.6 51.7 67.4 70.0 67.8 60.9 75.3 -2.2 .2 -.3 -2.1 -.5 1.5 3.4 -.2 -2.3 1.5 3.3 2.2 3.0 2.7 2.1 -1.1 * 1.6 -.8 77.5 75.5 85.0 90.5 101.0 115.3 126.3 119.5 132.0 73.9 79.8 87.9 88.7 102.4 113.1 124.6 133.3 138.4 17.0 21.2 21.6 19.9 26.2 28.4 32.9 40.2 40.8 3.5 56.8 3.7 58.7 - 4 . 3 - 3 . 8 66.3 - 2 . 9 - 3 . 8 68.8 1.8 .7 76.2 - 1 . 4 - 3 . 0 84.7 2.2 1.2 91.6 1.7 .7 93.1 - 1 3 . 8 - 1 2 . 4 97.5 - 6 . 4 - 5 . 3 .2 -.5 .9 1.2 1.7 1.0 1.1 -1.4 -1.1 76.5 74.7 85.5 90.3 99.7 112.2 123.0 116.0 127.2 74.8 71.7 83.0 87.1 94.0 108.1 120.8 114.3 127.5 1.7 3.0 2.5 3.1 5.7 4.1 2.2 1.7 -.3 -1.0 -.8 .5 -.3 -1.3 -3.1 -3.3 -3.5 -4.7 . . 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 I960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968* (3) 'A .6 1.3 .1 .9 -2.0 .3 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1966: 1. II Ill IV 121.4 127.1 126.0 130.7 118.4 121.8 124.8 133.3 29.5 31.4 32.9 38.1 88.9 90.4 91.9 95.3 3.0 5.3 1.2 -2.6 2.0 3.7 -.3 -2.8 1.0 1.6 1.5 .2 119.4 123.3 121.6 127.6 116.8 121.0 119.9 125.7 2.7 2.3 1.7 1.9 -1.9 -3.9 -4.4 -3.1 1967: 1 II III IV 118.0 113.0 120.1 126.8 130.9 128.9 134.1 139.4 39.7 37.0 40.5 43.4 91.3 91.9 93.5 95.9 -12.9 -15.9 -14.0 -12.5 -11.2 -13.3 -12.9 -12.2 -1.7 -2.6 -1.1 -.4 115.2 109.3 116.7 122.6 113.0 107.6 114.7 121.8 2.3 1.6 2.1 .8 -2.8 -3.8 -3.4 -4.2 1968: 1 . . . II Ill 123.4 130.1 132.9 133.6 141.4 137.0 40.8 44.0 37.1 41.4 92.8 - 1 0 . 3 - 8 . 6 97.4 - 1 1 . 3 - 1 0 . 2 99.9 - 4 . 1 - 2 . 8 -1.7 -1.1 -1.3 118.7 126.5 127.5 136.3 119.7 127.3 127.1 136.1 -1.1 -.8 .5 .2 -4.7 -3.6 -5.3 IVP * Net exports of goods and services less net transfers to foreigners. 2 Surplus of $32 million. 3 Deficit of $41 million. Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 248 TABLE B-19.—Saving by individuals, 7946-68 l [Billions of dollars] Increase in financial assets Year or quarter Currency and Total 2 demand deposits Tota Securitie > nsurance Mortand SavCon- Other gage Corpopen- Non- sumer tanings debt Con- Other Govrate Corpo- sion acfarm on sumer debts dugible and re- homes rables assets7 non- credit ounts ernrate ment for- stock s serves farm bonds* eign homes bonds 1946 1947 1948 1949 24. 4 20. 23. 3 18 7 17.5 12.6 8.6 9.3 4.8 -1.1 -1.1 -1.5 6.3 3.4 2.3 2.6 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 ?fi 8 ?9 8 24. 8 12.9 17.2 20 5 20.6 19.4 25.0 26 7 27.0 29.7 31.4 1.8 4.4 1.7 2.5 4.5 7.7 .4 1.8 .8 8.3 9.2 8.8 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 23. 9 28. 0 33 8 1966' 1 14 6 28 n 28.2 24.6 30.1 32 1 31 7 29. 9 ?8 8 34 6 41 9 47 4 48 6 54 9 III.. IV.. 11 7 19 7 1.2 -.5 3.3 .2 24.6 31.9 38.0 43.2 51.1 55.0 51.6 63.5 -1.6 .9 2.8 12.0 10.3 13.3 16.1 -2 4 -1.5 1.1 4.7 4.1 6.6 7.2 1.9 12.5 1967: 1... II... III.. IV.. 15.0 5.7 13.5 20.8 13.0 11.1 17.4 22.0 1.9 1.7 2.7 6.2 1968: 1... II... III.. 14 9 8 1 13.6 12.0 16.4 18.5 -4.1 3.6 4.7 Less Increase in debt Net investment in 9.5 12.1 14.0 11.4 12.4 17.4 23 4 23.0 23.9 26.5 19.2 32.4 -1.5 -0.9 2.2 -.8 1. 2 - . 2 1. 6 - . 5 1. 1 1 1 1. 0 7 5.4 5.5 5.4 5.6 4. 8 7 9 11. 2 10. 1 5.8 7.5 7.1 7.0 2.7 2 2 6. 7 1 4 4.1 4 7 4.9 4 2 2.7 3 2 2.8 2 9 -0.4 2 3 2.5 2 1 -.9 -.2 7 16 15 6.9 6.3 7.4 15 ? 13 9 13. 4 10.2 49 4? 19 7.5 6.8 7.0 4 1 14.0 14.8 18.4 6.4 4.9 9.9 5 9 1.2 4.8 4.9 3.0 2.9 1. 1 1. 6 ? 7 7.6 9.0 12.3 11 0 8 8 9 5 13.0 3.9 1.1 6 4 3 5 2 6 2.4 6.0 7.2 4 3 5 0 6 8 6 4 8.5 10.9 11.3 12 9 15 0 15.8 16.1 11 4 10.9 4.5 1.7 5 5 7 3 8.0 9.4 6 9 4.4 7.0 8.6 10 1 13 8 13.7 15.7 15 0 18.6 8 3 0 1.6 3.1 1 8 9 9 3.4 -.4 1 6 8 2 0 6 4 ? 2 2 -1 6 7 0 7 7 -.2 -.4 .9 .7 .8 .9 * 9 r 71 2. 7.5 7.5 8.1 9.4 1. n 9.3 8 1 5 10.2 7 11.2 4 1 5 0 10 ? * 3 -.4 4 - . 7 -1 8 -1.0 -2 6 1 -.8 - . 3 -1 7 1.2 8 1.6 - 4 1 11.3 12.0 12.5 14.1 15.5 16.5 17.9 19.0 12 6 8 4? 16. 7 14. 14. 1 5.5 3.6 18.2 4.9 .6 5.5 1 17 8 14 15. 7 14 2 15. 8 5.1 2.9 6 7 8.9 8 6 18 2 1 16.2 15.8 14.1 11.2 14.8 14.9 12.1 1 0 3 1 1 9 16. 3 12 5 8 2 5 7 5.0 37 11 .7 .4 4 4 4.3 4.5 34 3 2 6 3.4 5.1 3 0 2 5 1.0 -.9 2 -1 5 4.3 4.6 4 0 3 3 2.6 6.0 5 4 3 3 3 2 2.6 2.5 c 6 -.*3 - 2 1.9 8 .4 7 .1 1 1 1.2 - 1 1 .8 - 1 1 4.4 5.2 4.7 5.0 2.1 2.3 3.8 4.3 .8 3.7 2.2 5.4 2 7 1 3 1.9 - 2 . 3 1.9 2.3 3.3 1.1 3.8 3.3 1.6 8.0 5.6 3.5 4.8 5.5 4.5 3 8 4 0 4 6 1.6 4.7 4.1 1 10 3.7 - 1 . 4 3.6 3.6 4.2 3.3 .3 10.8 5.7 9.0 - 1 7 9.9 - 3 8 7 7.8 4 0 5.6 8.1 5.0 6.2 19 1 7 2 6 o 3.8 1 4 - 1 Individuals' saving, in addition to personal holdings, covers saving of unincorporated business, trust funds, and nonprofit institutions in the forms specified. 2 Includes miscellaneous financial assets, not shown separately. 3 Includes shares in savings and loan associations and credit unions and time deposits at banks. 4 U.S. Government and State and local obligations. s Includes investment company shares. 6 Private insurance reserves, private insured and noninsured pension reserves, and government insurance and pension reserves. 7 Noncorporate business investments. s Security credit, policy loans, and noncorporate business debt. Note.—In addition to the concept of saving shown above, there are other concepts of individuals' saving, with varying degrees of coverage, currently in use. The personal saving estimates of the Department of Commerce are dehved as the difference between personal i ncome (after taxes) and personal outlays. For a reconciliation of the two series, see Securities and Exchange Commission "Statistical Bulletin," August 1968, and "Survey of Current Business," July 1968. These estimates are compatible with the flow-of-funds system of accounts of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. A reconciliation of these estimates with the flow-of-funds accounts will be available in the near future. Source: Securities and Exchange Commission. 249 TABLE B-20.—Number and money income {in 1967 prices) of families and unrelated individuals, by color of head, 1947-67 Total Year White With incomes Total under $3,000 number Median Num(mil- income ber Perlions) (mil- cent lions) Families:» 1947 1948 1949 37.2 38.6 39.3 $4,531 4,418 4,348 10.2 11.0 11.8 27.4 28.5 29.9 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 . 1957 1958 1959 . 39.9 40.6 40.8 41.2 42.0 42.9 43.5 43.7 44.2 45.1 4,611 4,767 4,893 5,314 5,188 5,531 5,882 5,889 5,871 6,210 11.1 10.4 10.0 9.5 10.3 9.4 8.7 8.9 9.0 8.6 27.8 25.7 24.5 23.0 24.5 22.0 20.0 20.4 20.4 19.1 1960 1961 .. 1962 1963 1964 1965 . 1966 45.5 46.3 47.0 47.4 47.8 48.3 48.9 6,350 6,418 6,587 6,822 7,073 7,357 7,651 8.6 8.7 8.3 7.9 7.5 7.1 6.7 1966 2 1967 2 49.1 49.8 7,716 7,974 6.6 6.2 Total number Median (mil- income lions) 34.1 35.3 4,796 4,960 5,183 5,520 5,415 5,766 6,145 6,130 6,122 6,473 18.9 18.7 17.7 16.7 15.7 14.8 13.7 41.1 41.9 42.4 42.7 43.1 43.5 44.0 13.4 12.5 44.1 44.8 With incomes under $1,500 Total number Median Num(mil- income ber Perlions) (mil- cent lions) 8.2 8.4 9 0 $1,467 1,423 1,482 4.2 4.4 4.5 50.8 52.3 50.5 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957... 1958 1959 9 4 91 9.7 95 97 99 9.8 10.4 10.9 10 9 1.472 I 535 U 787 756 ,519 1,655 1,766 1,818 ,777 I 821 4.8 45 4.3 4 4 4.8 4.7 4.4 4.6 4.9 4.8 50.8 49 6 44.8 46 2 49.6 47.1 45.2 44.2 45.0 44.0 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965. _ 1966 11 1 11.2 11.0 11.2 12.1 12.1 12.4 I 954 1,963 1.946 l! 969 2,144 2,289 2,340 47 4.6 4.5 4.5 4.7 4.3 4.4 13.1 2,391 4.5 1967 2 8.3 9.0 24.1 25.4 26 9 8.4 7.5 6.8 7.0 7.1 6.7 25.0 22.6 21.3 20.5 21.8 19.4 17.3 17.6 17.6 16.4 6,601 6,701 6,887 7,146 7,388 7,670 7,944 6.8 6.8 6.5 6.0 5.8 5.5 5.3 8,018 8,274 5.1 4.8 3.1 3.3 $2,418 2,453 2 315 1.9 2.0 62.4 60.5 63 1 3.8 3.9 4.0 4.0 4.0 4.2 2,591 2,61b 2,941 3,093 3,003 3,185 3,241 3,278 3,134 3,336 1.9 1.9 1.9 1.9 1.9 1.9 57.7 57.0 51.1 48.5 50.1 47.5 46.5 46.7 48 3 45.6 16.4 16.2 15.3 14.3 13.7 12.8 11.9 4.3 4.5 4.6 4.8 4.8 4.8 4.9 3,644 3, 563 3,680 3,797 4,133 4,256 4,749 1.8 1.9 1.8 1.9 1.7 1.6 1.4 42.0 42.8 40.0 39.2 34.4 33.0 29.2 11.6 10.8 5.0 5.0 4,778 5,141 1.5 1.4 29.2 27.1 Nonwhite White Total Unrelated individuals:3 1947 1948 1949 With incomes With incomes under $3,000 Total under $3,000 number Median NumNumPer- (mil- income ber ber Per(mil- cent lions) (mil- cent lions) lions) $4,720 4,597 4,527 38.2 39.0 39.5 39.7 40.2 40.9 Nonwhite With incomes With incomes under $1,500 Total under $1,500 Total numnumber Median Number Median Num(mil- income ber Per- (mil- income ber Perlions) (mil- cent lions) (mil- cent lions) lions) 7.2 7.3 $1,546 1,474 J,589 3.6 3.7 49.3 50.7 48.6 1.0 1.1 $1,119 1,107 1,165 .9 .8 .7 .8 .9 .9 1^769 1,781 .8 .9 .8 .8 .8 .8 .7 56.6 55 6 53.7 52.5 48.7 44.8 44.9 1,834 .8 43.7 3.9 3.9 3.7 3.8 4.0 3.9 15 1.4 1.3 1.5 1.6 1.6 2,098 2,113 2,083 2,071 2,261 2,383 2,430 3.9 3.7 3.7 3.7 3.9 3.5 3.7 40.1 39.1 33.4 38.2 37.1 34.2 34.0 1.5 1.6 1.5 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.6 ,?7fi 1,316 391 ,416 2,431 3.7 33.2 1.8 8 2 8.5 8.5 8.9 9.2 9.3 42.3 41.4 40.6 40.1 38.8 35.7 35.3 9.6 9.6 9.5 9.7 10.4 10.5 10.8 34.6 11.3 61.6 63.2 61.3 60.1 55 9 55.3 51.2 60.8 58.7 52.2 55 9 56. 7 55.6 49.4 48 4 43.0 45 1 47.6 45.2 44.3 42.3 43.3 42.1 1,546 1,618 1,922 1,854 1,643 1,769 1,819 1,918 1,877 1,924 0.6 .7 1,147 1,256 1,335 J.460 ,133 l|414 1,307 ?93 ,?97 !The term "family" refers to a group of two or more persons related by blood, marriage, or adoption and residing together; all such persons are considered members of the same family. 2 Based on revised methodology. 3 The term "unrelated individuals" refers to persons 14 years of age and over (other than inmates of institutions) who are not living with any relatives. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 25O POPULATION, EMPLOYMENT, WAGES, AND PRODUCTIVITY TABLE B-21.—Population by age groups: Estimates, 1929-68, and projections, 1970-85 [Thousands of persons] Age (years) July 1 Total Under 5 5-13 20-24 14-19 25-44 45-64 65 and over Estimates: 1929.. 121,767 11,734 22,131 13,796 10,694 35,862 21,076 6,474 1930.. 1931.. 1932.. 1933.. 1934.. 123,077 124,040 124,840 125,579 126,374 11,372 11,179 10,903 10,612 10,331 22,266 22,263 22,238 22,129 21,964 13,937 13,980 14,015 14,070 14,163 10,915 11,003 11,077 11,152 11,238 36,309 36,654 36,988 37,319 37,662 21,573 22,031 22,473 22,933 23,435 6,705 6,928 7,147 7,363 7,582 1935.. 1936.. 1937.. 1938.. 1939.. 127,250 128,053 128,825 129,825 130,880 10,170 10,044 10,009 10,176 10,418 21,730 21,434 21,082 20,668 20,253 14,296 14,442 14,558 14,680 14,748 11,317 11,375 11,411 11,453 11,519 37,987 38,288 38,589 38,954 39,354 23,947 24,444 24,917 25,387 25,823 7,804 8,027 8,258 8,508 8,764 1940.. 1941.. 1942.. 1943.. 1944.. 132,122 133,402 134,860 136,739 138,397 10,579 10,850 11,301 12,016 12,524 19,936 19,674 19,427 19,319 19,246 14,770 14,682 14,534 14,381 14.264 11,690 11,807 11,955 12,064 12,062 39,868 40,383 40,861 41,420 42,016 26,249 26,718 27,196 27,671 28,138 9,031 9,288 9,584 9,867 10,147 1945.. 1946.. 1947.. 1948.. 1949.. 139,928 141,389 144,126 146,631 149,188 12,979 13,244 14,406 14,919 15,607 19,326 19,625 20,118 20,990 21,634 13,942 13,597 13,447 13,171 13,006 12,036 12,004 11,814 11,794 11,700 42,521 43,027 43,657 44,288 44,916 28,630 29,064 29,498 29,931 30,405 10,494 10,828 11,185 11,538 11,921 1950.. 1951.. 1952. 1953. 1954. 152,271 154,878 157,553 160,184 163,026 16,410 17,333 17,312 17,638 18,057 22,423 22,998 24,501 25,701 26,886 12,839 12,727 12,807 12,986 13,230 11,680 11,552 11,350 11,062 10,832 45,672 46,103 46,495 46,786 47,001 30,849 31,362 31,884 32,394 32,942 12,397 12,803 13,203 13,617 14,076 1955. 1956. 1957. 1958. 1959. 165,931 168,903 171,984 174,882 177,830 18,566 19,003 19,494 19,887 20,175 27,925 28,929 29,673 30,651 31,767 13,501 13,981 14,795 15,337 15,816 10,714 10,616 10,603 10,756 10,969 47,194 47,379 47,440 47,337 47,192 33,506 34,057 34,591 35,109 35,663 14,525 14,938 15,388 15,806 16,248 1960. 1961. 1962. 1963. 1964. 180,684 183,756 186,656 189,417 192,120 20,364 20,657 20,746 20,750 20,670 32,985 33,296 33,943 34,606 35,301 16,217 17,565 18,484 19,075 19,812 11,116 11,408 11,889 12,620 13,154 47,134 47,061 46,968 46,932 46,881 36,208 36,756 37,316 37,869 38,438 16,659 17,013 17,311 17,565 17,863 1965. 1966. 1967. 1968. 194,592 196,920 199,118 201,166 20,404 19,811 19,191 18,521 35,889 36,544 36,965 37,239 20,637 21,582 21,697 22,106 13,679 14,063 15,197 15,788 46,807 46,855 47,077 47,614 39,015 39,601 40,194 40,768 18,162 18,464 18,798 19,129 Projections:» 1970: Series C. Series D. 206,039 204,923 18,740 17,625 } 37,224 } 23,136 } 17,261 } 48,276 j} 41,817 19,585 1975: Series C. Series D. 219,366 215,367 21,211 18,323 35,319 34,209 1980: Series C. Series D_ 235,212 227,665 24,298 20,736 36,680 32,695 1985: Series C. Series D. 252,871 241,731 26,645 23,030 41,875 35,933 132 } 19,299 | ! }24,621 }20,997 | 53,881 } 43,364 23,282 ; 21,699 I 1n 068 i 1 fR ' } 62,374 || 43,180 } | 72,083 I) 42,940 21,159 23,063 24,978 i Two of four series projected by the cohort method and based on different assumptions with regard to completed fertility, which moves gradually toward a level of 2,775 children per 1,000 women for Series C and 2,450 children per 1,000 women for Series D. For further explanation of method of projection and for additional data, see "Population Estimates, Current Population Reports, Series P-25, No. 381," December 1967. Note.—Data for Armed Forces overseas included beginning 1940 Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 251 TABLE B-22.—Noninstitutional population and the labor force, 1929-68 Civilian labor force Year or month Noninstitutional population Total labor force (including armed forces) Employment Armed forces Total Total Agricultural Nonagricultural Unemployment Total Unemlabor force as ploypercent ment of non- as percent of institu- civilian tional labor popuforce lation Percent Thousands of persons 14 years of age and over 1929 49,440 260 49,180 47,630 10,450 37,180 1,550 3.2 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 50,080 50,680 51,250 51,840 52,490 260 260 250 250 260 49,820 50,420 51,000 51,590 52,230 45,480 42,400 38,940 38,760 40,890 10,340 10,290 10,170 10,090 9,900 35,140 32,110 28,770 28,670 30,990 4,340 8,020 12,060 12,830 11,340 8.7 15.9 23.6 24.9 21.7 1935 1936_ 1937 1938 1939 53,140 53,740 54,320 54,950 55,600 270 300 320 340 370 52,870 53,440 54,000 54,610 55,230 42,260 44,410 46,300 44,220 45,750 10,110 10,000 9,820 9,690 9,610 32,150 34,410 36,480 34,530 36,140 10,610 9,030 7,700 10,390 9,480 20.1 16.9 14.3 19.0 17.2 1940. 1941 1942 1943 1944 100,380 101,520 102,610 103,660 104,630 56,180 57,530 60,380 64,560 66,040 540 1,620 3,970 9,020 11,410 55,640 55,910 56,410 55,540 54,630 47,520 50,350 53,750 54,470 53,960 9,540 9,100 9,250 9,080 8,950 37,980 41,250 44,500 45,390 45,010 8,120 5,560 2,660 1,070 670 56.0 56.7 58.8 62.3 63.1 14.6 9.9 4.7 1.9 1.2 1945 1946 1947 105,530 106,520 107,608 65,300 60,970 61,758 11,440 3,450 1,590 53,860 57,520 60,168 52,820 55,250 57,812 8,580 8,320 8,256 44,240 46,930 49,557 1,040 2,270 2,356 61.9 57.2 57.4 1.9 3.9 3.9 Percent Thousands of persons 16 years of age and over 1947 1948 1949 103,418 104,527 105,611 60,941 62,080 62,903 1,591 1,459 1,617 59,350 60,621 61,286 57,039 58,344 57,649 7,891 7,629 7,656 49,148 50,713 49,990 2,311 2,276 3,637 58.9 59.4 59.6 3.9 3.8 5.9 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954. 106,645 107,721 108,823 110,601 111,671 63,858 65,117 65,730 66,560 66,993 1,650 3,100 3,592 3,545 3,350 62,208 62,017 62,138 63,015 63,643 58,920 59,962 60,254 61,181 60,110 7,160 6,726 6,501 6,261 6,206 51,760 53,239 53,753 54,922 53,903 3,288 2,055 1,883 1,834 3,532 59.9 60.4 60.4 60.2 60.0 5.3 3.3 3.0 2.9 5.5 1955 1956 . 1957 1958 . . 1959 112,732 113,811 115,065 116,363 117,881 68,072 69,409 69,729 70,275 70,921 3,049 2,857 2,800 2,636 2,552 65,023 66,552 66,929 67,639 68,369 62,171 63,802 64,071 63,036 64,630 6,449 6,283 5,947 5,586 5,565 55,724 57,517 58,123 57,450 59,065 2,852 2,750 2,859 4,602 3,740 60.4 61.0 60.6 60.4 60.2 4.4 4.1 4.3 6.8 5.5 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 119,759 121,343 122,981 125,154 127,224 72,142 73,031 73,442 74,571 75,830 2,514 2,572 2,828 2,738 2,739 69,628 70,459 70,614 71,833 73,091 65,778 65,746 66,702 67,762 69,305 5,458 5,200 4,944 4,687 4,523 60,318 60,546 61,759 63,076 64,782 3,852 4,714 3,911 4,070 3,786 60.2 60.2 59.7 59.6 59.6 5.5 6.7 5.5 5.7 5.2 1965 1966 1967 1968 129,236 131,180 133,319 135,562 77,178 78,893 80,793 82,272 2,723 3,123 3,446 3,535 74,455 75,770 77,347 78,737 71,088 72,895 74,372 75,920 4,361 3,979 3,844 3,817 66,726 68,915 70,527 72,103 3,366 2,875 2,975 2,817 59.7 60.1 60.6 60.7 4.5 3.8 3.8 3.6 See footnotes at end of table. 252 TABLE B-22.—Noninstitutional population and the labor force, 1929-68—Continued Civilian labor force Year or month Noninstitutional population Total labor force (including armed forces) Employment Armed forces Total Total Agricultural Nonagricultural Unemployment Thousands of persons 16 years of age and over Total labor force as percent of noninstitutional population Unemployment as percent of civilian labor force Percent 1967: Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May. June 132,295 132,448 132,627 132,795 132,969 133,168 78,706 79,107 78,949 79,560 79,551 82,464 3,386 3,418 3,436 3,449 3,456 3,444 75,320 75,689 75,513 76,111 76,095 79,020 72,160 72,506 72,560 73,445 73,637 75,391 3,335 3,281 3,410 3,721 3,825 4,395 68,826 69,225 69,149 69,724 69,812 70,996 3,160 3,183 2,954 2,666 2,457 3,628 59.5 59.7 59.5 59.9 59.8 61.9 4.2 4.2 3.9 3.5 3.2 4.6 July. Aug. Sept. Oct.. Nov. Dec. 133,366 133,645 133,847 134,045 134,224 134,405 82,920 82,571 80,982 81,595 81,582 81,527 3.449 3,459 3,456 3,463 3,469 3,470 79,471 79,112 77,526 78,132 78,113 78,057 76,221 76,170 74,631 75,181 75,218 75,338 4,516 4,378 3,931 4,033 3,759 3,545 71,705 71,792 70,700 71,148 71,460 71,793 3,250 2,942 2,895 2,951 2,894 2,719 62.2 61.8 60.5 60.9 60.8 60.7 4.1 3.7 3.7 3.8 3.7 3.5 1968:Jan.. Feb.. Mar. Apr.. May. June. 134,576 134,744 134.904 135,059 135,249 135,440 79,811 80,869 80,938 81,141 81,770 84,454 3,464 3,467 3,491 3,507 3,536 3,567 76,347 77,402 77,447 77,634 78,234 80,887 73,273 74,114 74,517 75,143 75,931 77,273 3,366 3,462 3,537 3,851 3,996 4,516 69,908 70,653 70,980 71,292 71,935 72,757 3,074 3,288 2,929 2,491 2,303 3,614 59.3 60.0 60.0 60.1 60.5 62.4 4.0 4.2 3.8 3.2 2.9 4.5 July. Aug. Sept. Oct__ Nov. Dec. 135,639 135,839 136,036 136,221 136,420 136,619 84,550 83,792 82,137 82,477 82,702 82,618 3,586 3,589 3,591 3,603 3,517 3,500 80,964 80,203 78,546 78,874 79,185 79,118 77,746 77,432 75,939 76,364 76,609 76,700 4,476 4,107 3,836 3.767 3,607 3,279 73,270 73,325 72,103 72,596 73,001 73,421 3,217 2,772 2,606 2,511 2,577 2,419 62.3 61.7 60.4 60.5 60.6 60.5 4.0 3.5 3.3 3.2 3.3 3.1 Seasonally adjusted 1967:Jan... Feb_.. Mar.. Apr... May.. June.. 80,319 80,339 80,112 80,263 79,958 80,658 76,933 76,921 76,676 76,814 76,502 77,214 74,094 74,063 73,822 73,939 73,550 74,169 3,990 3,876 3.858 3,843 3,728 3,739 70,104 70,187 69,964 70,096 69,822 70,430 2,839 2,858 2,854 2,875 2,952 3,045 3.7 3.7 3.7 3.7 3.9 3.9 July.. Aug.. Sept.. Oct.. Nov.. Dec. 80,944 81,057 81,263 81,535 81,459 81,942 77,495 77,598 77,807 78,072 77,989 78,473 74,478 74,664 74,638 74,735 75,005 75,577 3,847 3,956 3,697 3,718 3,839 4,216 70,631 70,708 70,941 71,017 71,166 71,361 3,017 2,934 3,169 3,337 2,984 2,896 3.9 3.8 4.1 4.3 3.8 3.7 1968:Jan... FebMar_. Apr... May.. June.. 81,386 82,138 82,150 81,849 82,149 82,585 77,923 78,672 78,658 78,343 78,613 79,018 75,167 75,731 75,802 75,636 75,829 76,048 4,003 4,127 4,014 3,980 3,893 3,851 71,164 71,604 71,788 71,656 71,936 72,197 2,756 2,941 2,856 2,707 2,784 2,970 3.5 3.7 3.6 3.5 3.5 3.8 July.. Aug.. Sept.. Oct... Nov.. Dec. 82,572 82,279 82,422 82,407 82,549 82,956 78,985 78,690 78,831 78,804 79,032 79,456 76,038 75,929 75,957 75,952 76,389 76,867 3,836 3,733 3,602 3,481 3,676 3,874 72,202 72,196 72,355 72,471 72,713 72,993 2,947 2,761 2,874 2,852 2,643 2,589 3.7 3.5 3.6 3.6 3.3 3.3 Note.—Labor force data in Tables B-22 through B-25 are based on household interviews and relate to calendar week including the 12th of the month. For definitions of terms, area samples used, historical comparability of the data, comparability with other series, etc., see "Employment and Earnings and Monthly Report on the Labor Force." Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 253 323-166 O—69 17 TABLE B—23.—Civilian employment and unemployment, by sex and age, 1947—68 [Thousands of persons 16 years of age and over] Unemployment Employment Males Year or month Total 20 Total 16-19 years years and over Total Females Males Females 20 16-19 years years and over Total Total 20 16-19 years years and over Total 20 16-19 years years and over 1947 1948 1949 57,039 40,994 2,218 38,776 16,045 1,691 14,354 2,311 1,692 58,344 41 1,726 2,345 39,382 16,618 1,683 14,937 2,276 1,559 57,649 40, 0,926 2,124 38,803 16,723 1,588 15,137 3,637 2,572 270 1,422 619 717 255 1,305 352 2,219 1,065 144 152 223 475 564 841 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954. 58,920 41 ,580 59,962 41 ,780 60,254 41 ,684 61,181 42,431 60,'" 41 1,110 "",620 2,186 2,156 2,106 2,135 39,394 17 ,340 39,626 18,182 18,570 39,578 18i 40,296 18,750 2,239 1,221 1,185 1,202 2,344 318 191 205 184 310 1,922 1,049 1,029 834 698 980 632 1,019 2,035 1,188 195 145 140 123 191 854 689 559 510 .997 1955 1956. 1957. 1958. 1959. 62,171 42,621 63,802 43,380 :, 802 43, 64,071 43,357 63,036 42 423 "!, 64,630 43; 1,466 2,095 2,164 2,117 2,012 2,198 40,526 1 19,550 41,216 20;"0,422 41,239 20,, 1,714 40,411 20,613 . 41,267 21,164 1,548 1,654 1,663 1,570 1,640 18, 002 18,767 19,052 19,043 19,524 2,852 2,750 2,859 4,602 3,740 1,854 1,711 1,841 3,098 2,420 274 269 299 416 398 1,580 1,442 1,541 2,681 2,022 1960. 1961. 1962. 1963. 1964. 65,778 43, 1,904 65,746 43, 1,656 66,702 44, 67,762 44, i,657 69,305 45, .,474 ;, 71,088 46, 340 i, 72,895 46, 919 74,372 47,,479 75,920 48, 1,114 2,360 2,314 2,362 2,406 2,587 41,543 21 ,874 1,769 41,342 22!,090 1,793 41,815 22! 525 1,833 , 42,251 23,105 1,849 42,886 23; "1,831 1,929 20,105 20,296 20,693 21,257 21,903 3,852 4,714 3,911 4,070 3,786 2,486 2,997 2,423 2,472 2,205 425 479 407 500 487 2,060 1,366 2,518 1,717 2,016 ",488 1,971 ,598 1,718 ,581 22,630 23,507 24,397 25,281 3,366 2,875 2,975 2,817 1,914 1,551 1,508 1,419 479 1,435 432 1,119 448 1,060 427 993 ,452 ,324 ,468 ,397 1,405 1,407 1,402 1,381 1,409 1,445 \,m 1965. 1966. 1967. 1968. 1,517 15,824 3,288 1,611 16,570 2,055 1,612 16,958 1,883 1,584 17,164 1,834 1,985 39,634 18,490 1,490 17,000 3,532 2,918 43,422 24, 748 t, 3,252 43,667 25, 976 i, 3,186 44,293 26, 1,893 3,254 44,859 27,,807 2,118 2,469 2,496 2,525 998 1,039 1,018 1,504 1,320 823 176 832 209 821 197 262 1,242 256 1,063 286 349 313 383 386 1,080 1,368 1,175 1,216 1,195 395 1,056 404 919 390 1,078 412 985 Seasonally adjusted 1967: Jan Feb.... Mar.... Apr.... May.... June... 74,094 47,,437 74,063 47;,417 73,822 47,,339 73,939 47,,256 73,550 47,,147 74,169 47,,419 3,294 3,241 3,314 3,204 3,158 3,245 44,143 26,657 44,176 26,646 , ., 44,025 26, ' 025 26,483 44, 052 26,683 43, 989 26,403 44, 174 26,750 2,590 24, 1,067' 2,594 24, i,052 2, 1,924 1,061 2,503 23i 1,900 2,582 24, •,168 2,839' 2,858 2,854 2,875 2,952 3,045 1,434 1,451 1,452; 1,494 1,543 1,600 4091 1,025 446 1,005 407 1,045 4371 1,057 443 1,100 465 1,135 July.... Aug Sept.... Oct Nov.... Dec... 74,478 47, ,537 74,664 47,1 ',630 74,638 47, i ',603 74,735 47, ',532 75; 005 47,553 75,577 47,885 3,191 3,209 3,135 3,072 3,047 3,110 44,346 26,941 44,42127,034 44,468 27,035 44,460 27,203 44,506 27,452 44,775 27,692 2,505 2,457 2,395 2,392 2,416 2,419 24,436 24,577 24,640 24,811 25,036 25,273 3,017 2,934 3,169 3,3371 2,984 2,896 1,521 1,514 1,469 1,671 1,570 1,431 437 446 431 533 498 423 1968: Jan Feb.... Mar.... Apr Apr. Vlay. May.... June 75,167 47,790 75,731 48,056 7 5 , 802 48,059 "" 75,636 48,083 75,829 48,,017 :, 76,048 48, 111 3, 050 44,740 3, 214 44,842 3, 276 44,783 3, 325 44,758 3,275 44t, 742 3,253 44; 858 ^ 2,575 2,639 2,615 2,584 2,580 2,622 24,802 25,036 25,128 24,969 25,232 25,315 2,756 2,941 2,856 2,707 2,784 2,970 1,433 1,505 1,446 1,344 1,355 1,545 403 438 437 386 384 480 1,160 3,239 44,92127,878 2,514 25,364 2,947 76,038 48, i, 75,929 48, 216 " 309 44,907 27,713 2,528 25,185 2,761 75,957 48,079 244 44,835 27,878 2,475 25,403 2,874 75,952 48',,002 249 44,753 27,950 2,448 25,502 2,852 76,389 48,145 28,244 2,447 25,797 2,643 76,867 48,622 309 45; 313 28,245 2,378 25,867 2,589 1,452 1,377 1,400 1,487 1,361 1,256 July.. Aug.. Sept.. Oct... Nov.. Dec... 27,377 27,675 27,743 27,553 27,812 27,937 Note.-See Note, Table B-22. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 254 328' 395 381 360 383 383 1,077 1,012 1,021 1,021 1,026 1,062 1,084 1,496 1,068 1,420 1,038 1,700 1,138 1,666 1,072 1,414 1,008 1,465 403 425 422 414 382 390 1,093 995 1,278 1,252 1,032 1,075 1,030 1,067 1,009 958 971 1,065 1,323 1,436 1,410 1,363 1,429 1,425 315 1,008 402 1,034 444 966 414 949 462 967 443 982 442 1,010 1,495 989 1,384 388 390 1,010 1,474 455 1,032 1,365 935 1.282 426 824 1,333 432 466 1,029 977 407 431 1,043 994 371 917 365 947 386 TABLE B-24.—Selected unemployment rates, 1948-68 [Percent] By sex and age Year or month All workers Both sexes, 16-19 years By cclor By selected groups White Nonwhite Experienced wage and salary workers Married men* Fulltime workers 2 Bluecollar workers 3 3.6 5.3 3.5 5.6 5.9 8.9 3.7 6.2 3.5 5.4 4.2 8.0 5.1 4.0 3.2 2.9 5.5 4.9 3.1 2.8 2.7 5.0 9.0 5.3 5.4 4.5 9.9 5.6 3.2 2.9 2.6 6.2 4.6 1.5 1.4 1.7 4.0 5.0 2.6 2.5 3.8 3.7 4.0 7.2 Men, 20 years and over Women, 20 years and over 1948.. 1949.. 3.8 5.9 9.2 13.4 1950.. 1951. 1952. 1953. 1954. 5.3 3.3 3.0 2.9 5.5 12.2 8.2 8.5 7.6 12.6 3.2 5.4 4.7 2.5 2.4 2.5 4.9 1955. 1956. 1957. 1958. 1959. 4.4 4.1 4.3 6.8 5.5 11.0 11.1 11.6 15.9 14.6 3.8 3.4 3.6 6.2 4.7 4.4 4.2 4.1 6.1 5.2 3.9 3.6 3.8 6.1 4.8 8.7 8.3 7.9 12.6 10.7 4.8 4.4 4.6 7.2 5.7 2.6 2.3 2.8 5.1 3.6 1960. 1961. 1962. 1963. 1964. 5.5 6.7 5.5 5.7 5.2 14.7 16.8 14.7 17.2 16.2 4.7 5.7 4.6 4.5 3.9 5.1 6.3 5.4 5.4 5.2 4.9 6.0 4.9 5.0 4.6 10.2 12.4 10.9 10.8 9.6 5.7 6.8 5.6 5.5 5.0 3.7 4.6 3.6 3.4 2.8 1965. 1966. 1967. 1968- 4.5 3.8 3.8 3.6 14.8 12.7 12.9 12.7 3.2 2.5 2.3 2.2 4.5 3.8 4.2 3.8 4.1 3.3 3.4 3.2 8.1 7.3 7.4 6.7 4.3 3.5 3.6 3.4 5.2 Labor force time lost * 7.2 3.9 3.6 3.4 7.2 5.8 5.1 6.2 10.2 7.6 5.1 5.3 8.1 6.6 5.5 4.9 7.8 9.2 7.4 7.3 6.3 6.7 8.0 6.7 6.4 5.8 2.4 1.9 1.8 1.6 4.3 3.4 3.5 3.1 5.3 4.2 4.4 4.1 5.0 4.2 4.2 4.0 6.7 Seasonally adjusted 1967: Jan.. Feb. Mar. Apr. May. June. 3.7 3.7 3.7 3.7 3.9 3.9 11.1 12.6 11.8 12.0 12.7 12.7 2.3 2.2 2.3 2.3 2.4 2.5 4.3 4.0 4.1 4.1 4.1 4.2 3.3 3.3 3.2 3.3 3.4 3.5 6.7 7.2 7.4 7.2 7.7 7.7 3.5 3.4 3.4 3.4 3.6 3.8 1.7 1.7 1.8 1.9 1.9 1.9 3.2 3.2 3.3 3.4 3.5 3.6 4.2 4.2 4.2 4.6 4.6 4.6 4.1 4.1 4.1 4.0 3.8 4.4 July. Aug.. Sept. Oct.. Nov. Dec. 3.9 3.8 4.1 4.3 3.8 3.7 12.9 13.3 13.4 14.8 13.9 12.8 2.4 2.3 2.3 2.5 2.4 2.2 4.3 3.9 4.9 4.8 4.0 4.1 3.5 3.4 3.6 3.7 3.4 3.3 7.3 6.8 8.0 8.8 7.3 6.9 3.7 3.6 3.9 4.1 3.7 3.5 1.8 1.9 1.8 1.9 1.7 1.7 3.6 3.6 3.6 3.8 3.5 3.3 4.6 4.4 4.6 4.9 4.4 4.3 4.2 4.3 4.6 4.7 4.2 4.1 1968: Jan.. Feb_ Mar. Apr. May. June. 3.5 3.7 3.6 3.5 3.5 3.8 11.3 12.6 13.0 11.9 12.6 13.6 2.3 2.3 2.2 2.1 2.1 2.3 3.9 4.0 3.7 3.7 3.7 3.7 3.2 3.3 3.2 3.1 3.2 3.3 6.4 7.2 6.9 6.7 6.4 7.2 3.3 3.5 3.4 3.2 3.1 3.6 1.6 1.7 1.7 1.5 1.6 1.7 3.3 3.4 3.2 3.1 3.2 3.3 4.3 4.3 4.4 3.9 3.7 4.2 4.0 4.2 4.0 3.7 3.6 4.3 July. Aug. Sept. Oct.. Nov. Dec. 3.7 3.5 3.6 3.6 3.3 3.3 13.6 12.0 12.6 12.7 12.2 12.6 2.2 2.2 2.2 2.3 2.0 1.8 3.9 3.7 3.9 3.8 3.4 3.5 3.3 3.2 3.2 3.2 3.0 2.9 6.9 6.2 6.7 7.4 6.5 6.0 3.6 3.4 3.4 3.4 3.2 3.0 1.6 1.6 1.6 1.7 1.6 1.4 3.3 3.3 3.2 3.2 3.0 2.7 4.3 4.2 4.1 4.1 3.8 3.6 4.3 4.0 4.0 3.9 3.7 3.6 1 Married men living with their wives. Data for 1949 and 1951-54 are for April; 1950, for March. 2 Data for 1949-61 are for May. 3 Includes craftsmen, operatives, and nonfarm laborers. Data for 1948-57 are based on data for January, April, July, and October. * Man-hours lost by the unemployed and persons on part time for economic reasons as a percent of potentially available labor force man-hours. Note.-See Note, Table B-22. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 255 TABLE B-25.— Unemployment by duration, 1947-68 Duration of unemployment Total unemployment Year or month Less than 5 weeks 5-14 weeks 15-26 weeks 27 weeks and over Thousands of persons 16 years of age and over 704 234 164 669 1,194 193 428 116 256 1,450 1,177 1,135 1,142 1,605 1,055 574 516 425 166 148 132 j 495 357 137 84 317 2,852 2,750 2,859 4,602 3,740 1,335 1,412 1,408 1,753 1,585 815 366 336 1,396 1,114 301 321 785 469 1960 1961. 1962. 1963 1964 3,852 4,714 3,911 4,070 3,786 1,719 1,806 1,659 1,751 1,697 1,176 1,376 1,134 1,231 1,117 503 728 534 535 491 454 804 585 553 482 1965. 19fifi 1967 1968. 3,366 2,875 2,975 2,817 1,628 1,535 1,635 1,594 983 404 804 893 810 295 ! 271 i 256 ; 351 241 177 156 1947 1948 1949 2,311 2,276 3,637 1,210 1,300 1,756 1950 1951 1952. 1953 1954 3,288 2,055 1,883 1,834 3,532 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 482 1,116 805 891 78 232 239 667 571 Seasonally adjusted 2,839 2,858 2,854 2,875 2,952 3,045 1967: Jan Feb.. Mar... . Apr May.. June . . ... July Aug Sept Oct . .. .... Dec .. . . Nov ... .... ... Mar Apr May . . June.. . . July Aug Sept .. Oct Nov Dec. . .. . . .... 1968 Jan Feb . . . . 1,496 1,606 1,628 1,618 1,704 1,713 794 789 833 871 871 909 276 257 256 250 291 291 200 190 180 184 142 150 3,017 2,934 3,169 3,337 2,984 2,896 1,662 1,572 1,783 1,789 1,609 1,418 895 934 937 930 968 266 234 111 305 307 259 170 211 163 170 178 186 2,756 2,941 2,856 2,707 2,784 2,970 1,360 1,721 1,689 1,507 1,696 1,753 840 776 755 830 718 841 302 286 268 241 283 260 2,947 2,761 2,874 2,852 2,643 2,589 1,656 1,629 1,647 1,557 1,527 1,352 860 767 819 915 791 841 275 237 235 260 226 171 186 169 180 157 127 163 178 161 134 128 128 152 Note.-See Note, Table B-22. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 256 1,105 TABLE B-26.— Unemployment insurance programs, selected data, 1940-68 State programs All programs Year or month Covered employment i Insured unemployment (weekly average) 23 Total benefits Insured paid unem(milploylions ments of dollars) 2 * Initial claims Exhaustions s Unadjusted Weekly average, thousands Thousands Insured unemployment as percent of covered employment Seasonally adjusted Benefits paid Total (millions of dollars)* Average weekly check (dollars) e Percent 1940 1941_. 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 24,291 28,136 30,819 32,419 31,714 30,087 31,856 33,876 34,646 33,098 1,331 842 661 149 111 720 2,804 1,793 1,446 2,474 534.7 358.8 350,4 80.5 67.2 574.9 2,878.5 1,785.5 1,328.7 2,269.8 1,282 814 649 147 105 589 1,295 997 980 1,973 214 164 122 36 29 116 189 187 200 340 5.6 3.0 2.2 .5 .4 2.1 4.3 3.1 3.0 6.2 518.7 344.3 344.1 79.6 62.4 445.9 1,094.9 775.1 789.9 1,736.0 10.56 11.06 12.66 13.84 15.90 18.77 18.50 17.83 19.03 20.48 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 . 1956 1957... 1958 1959 . . . . 34,308 36,334 37,006 38,072 36,622 40,018 42,751 43,436 44,411 45,728 1,605 1,467.6 1,000 862.9 1,069 1,043.5 1,067 1,050.6 2,051 2,291.8 1,399 1,560.2 1,323 1,540.6 1,571 1,913.0 3,269 4,290.6 2,099 2,854.3 1,513 969 1,044 990 1,870 1,265 1,215 1,446 2,526 1,684 236 208 215 218 304 226 227 270 369 277 4.6 2.8 2.9 2.8 5.2 3.5 3.2 3.6 6.4 4.4 1,373.1 840.4 998.2 962.2 2,026.9 1,350.3 1,380.7 1,733.9 3,512.7 2,279.0 20.76 21.09 22.79 23.58 24.93 25.04 27.02 28.17 30.58 30.41 1960 1961 1962 . 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 v 46,334 46,266 47,776 48,434 49,637 51,580 54,739 56,341 2,071 2,994 1,946 M,973 1,753 1,450 1,129 1,270 1,180 3.022.8 4,358.1 3.145.1 3.025.9 2,749.2 2,360.4 1,890.9 2,220.0 2.213.2 1,908 2,290 1,783 1,806 1,605 1,328 1,061 1,205 1,110 331 350 302 7 297 268 232 203 226 200 4.8 5.6 4.4 4.3 3.8 3.0 2,3 2.5 2.2 2,726.7 3,422.7 2,675.4 2,774.7 2,522.1 2,166.0 1,771.3 2,101.0 2,060. 0 32.87 33.80 34.56 35.27 35.92 37.19 39.75 41.25 43.25 54,769 54,667 55, 094 *>55,581 1,631 1,654 1,603 1,423 1,197 1,071 235.8 230.9 270.1 210.5 193.1 165.4 1,558 1,582 1,532 1,360 1,142 1,019 300 267 239 244 188 186 3.3 3.4 3.3 2.9 2.4 2.1 2.3 2.5 2.6 2.6 2.7 2.6 224.8 219.5 257.5 200.6 183.6 156.1 41.70 41.97 42.07 41.81 40.99 40.00 1,247 1,123 956 953 1,068 1,339 155.3 184.0 132.3 133.0 146.6 171.8 1,184 1,059 894 889 997 1,259 288 187 158 180 208 278 2.4 2.2 1.8 1.8 2.0 2.6 2.8 2.6 2.5 2.4 2.3 2.3 147.3 172.8 122.6 122.1 135.0 159.2 40.10 41.08 40.10 40.70 41.19 41.85 1,719 1,653 1,480 1,216 1,026 944 264.8 259.4 247.5 207.2 170.2 139.3 1,624 1,556 1,390 1,142 964 883 316 227 183 183 156 157 3.3 3.2 2.8 2.3 2.0 1.8 2.4 2.3 2.3 2.1 2.2 2.2 248.5 243.7 231.1 195.1 159.1 129.1 42.60 43.58 43.64 43.12 42.42 42.26 1,058 1,024 868 861 985 1,245 156.9 162.8 133.4 138.7 134.9 174.3 991 955 802 794 913 1,170 240 174 141 154 189 261 2.0 1.9 1.6 1.6 1.8 2.3 2.3 2.3 2.2 2.1 2.1 2.2 145.6 150.0 121.8 126.0 122.5 163.8 42.39 43.73 43.78 44.37 44.72 45.50 . 1967: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec P55,977 *57,004 *56,933 P57,354 . . P57,199 *56,818 *57,117 8 57,577 1968: Jan Feb Mar Apr . . May June. ._ July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec p .. 1 includes persons under the State, UCFE (Federal employee, effective January 1955), and RRB (Railroad Retirement Board) programs. Beginning October 1958, also includes the UCX program (unemployment compensation for ex-servicemen). 2 Includes State, UCFE, RR, UCX, UCV (unemployment compensation for veterans, October 1952-January I960), and SRA (Servicemen's Readjustment Act, September 1944-September 1951) programs. Also includes Federal and State programs for temporary extension of benefits from June 1958 through June 1962, expiration date of program. 3 Covered workers who have completed at least 1 week of unemployment. * Includes benefits paid under extended duration provisions of State laws, beginning June 1958. Annual data are net amounts and monthly data are gross amounts. 6 Individuals receiving final payments in benefit year. * For total unemployment only. 7 Programs include Puerto Rican sugarcane workers for initial claims and insured unemployment beginning July 1963. 8 Preliminary; December 1967 is latest month for which data are available for all programs combined. Workers covered by State programs account for about 88 percent of the total. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Employment Security. 257 TABLE B-27.—Wage and salary workers in nonagricultural establishments, 1929-68 [All employees; thousands of persons] Total wage and salary workers Year or month Manufacturing Total Durable goods Nondurable goods (government Mining Contract construction Transportation and public utilities Wholesale and retail trade Finance, insurance, and real estate Services : 1ederal State and local 1929 31,339 10, 702 1,087 1,497 3,916 6,123 1,509 3, 440 533 2,532 1930 1931 1932 1933.. 1934 29,424 26,649 23 628 23,711 25,953 9, 562 8, 170 6 7,397 8,501 1,009 873 731 744 883 1,372 1,214 970 809 862 3,685 3,254 2 816 2,672 2,750 5,797 5,284 4 683 4,755 5,281 1,475 1,407 1 341 1,295 1,319 3, 376 3, 183 931 2, 873 3, 058 526 560 559 565 652 2,622 2,704 2 666 2,601 2,647 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 27,053 29,082 31,026 29.209 30,618 9,069 9,827 10,794 9 440 10,278 4, 715 5, 564 897 946 1,015 891 854 912 1,145 1,112 1 055 1,150 2,786 2,973 3,134 2 863 2,936 5,431 5,809 6,265 6 179 6,426 1 335 ,388 1,432 L 425 1,462 3, 142 3, 326 3, 518 473 3, 517 753 826 833 829 905 2,728 2,842 2,923 3,054 3,090 1940 1941 . 1942 1943 1944 32,376 36,554 40 125 42,452 41,883 10,985 13,192 15 280 17, 602 17, 328 363 6, 968 8 11, 084 10, 856 6?? 6, 225 6 458 6,518 6,472 925 957 992 925 892 1,294 1,790 2 170 1,567 1,094 3,038 3,274 3,460 3,647 3,829 6,750 7, 210 7, 118 6, 982 7, 058 1,502 1,549 1,538 L.502 1,476 681 i 921 084 996 1,340 4, 148 4, 163 2^905 2,928 3,206 3,320 3,270 3,174 3,116 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949.. 40,394 41,674 43,881 44,891 . . . . 43,778 15, 524 14 703 15, 545 15, 582 14 441 9, 074 7 74? 8, 385 8 326 7 489 6,450 6,962 7, 159 7, 256 6, 953 836 862 955 994 930 1,132 1,661 1,982 2,169 2,165 3,906 4,061 4,166 4,189 4,001 7, 314 8 376 8, 955 9, 272 9, 264 1,497 1,697 1,754 1,829 1,857 4, 241 4 719 5, 050 5, 206 5, 264 2,808 ?54 1,892 1,863 1,908 3,137 3,341 3,582 3,787 3,948 8 094 9 089 9 349 10 110 9,129 7, 147 7 304 7 ?84 7 438 7 185 901 929 898 866 791 2,333 2,603 2,634 2,623 2,612 4,034 4,226 4,248 4,290 4,084 9, 386 9, 742 10, 004 10,247 10 ?35 1,919 1,991 2,069 2,146 2,234 5, 382 5, 576 5 730 5 867 6 002 1,928 2,302 4?0 ? 305 188 4,098 4,087 4,188 4,340 4,563 . . 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 45,222 47,849 48,825 50,232 49,022 15 16 16 17 16 241 393 63? 549 314 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 50,675 52,408 52,894 51,363 53,313 16 17 17 15 16 88? 243 174 945 675 9 9 q 8 9 541 834 856 830 373 7 7 7 7 7 340 409 319 116 303 792 822 828 751 732 2,802 2,999 2,923 2,778 2,960 4,141 4,244 4,241 3,976 4,011 10 535 10, 858 10 886 10 750 11 127 2,335 2,429 2,477 2,519 2,594 6 ?74 6, 536 6 749 6 806 7 130 ? 191 2,233 4,727 5,069 5,399 5,648 5,850 54,234 54,042 55, 596 ! 56,702 58,332 16 16 16 16 17 796 3?6 853 995 ?74 q 9 q 9 q 459 070 480 616 816 7 7 7 7 7 336 ?f>6 373 380 458 712 672 650 635 634 2,885 2,816 2,902 2,963 3,050 4,004 3,903 3,906 3,903 3,951 11 11 11 11 1? 391 337 566 778 160 2,669 2,731 2,800 2,877 2,957 7 7 8 8 8 664 0?8 3?5 709 770 ?79 7 340 ,358 / 348 6,083 6,315 6,550 6,868 7,249 7 656 7 930 8 01? 8,160 632 627 616 625 3,186 3,275 3,203 3,256 4,036 4,151 4,271 4,346 1? 13 13 14 716 ?45 613 115 3,023 9 087 3,100 9 551 3.217 10.060 3,357 10 504 / ,378 / ,564 / 719 ',736 7,714 8,307 8,897 9,462 1960 1961 . 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968P ... 60,832 64,034 66,030 68,134 18.062 19 214 19 434 19,734 10 406 ii ?84 ii 4?? n ,574 See footnotes at end of table. 258 187 2,209 TABLE B-27.—Wage and salary workers in nonagricultural establishments, 1929-68— Continued [All employees; thousands of persons) Manufacturing Year or month Total wage and salary workers Total Durable goods Nondurable goods Mining Contract construction Transporta- Wholetion sale and and pubretail lic trade utilities Government Finance, insurance, and real estate Services Federal State and local Seasonally adjusted 1966: Jan... Feb... Mar.. AprMay.. June.. 62,535 62,884 63,253 63,456 63,714 64,141 18,641 18,818 18,928 19,046 19,143 19,272 10,852 10,976 11,059 11,149 11,226 11,305 7,789 7,842 7,869 7,897 7,917 7,967 633 630 633 593 627 629 3,308 3,316 3,366 3,321 3,262 3,299 4,091 4,109 4,122 4,126 4,142 4,160 13,016 13,047 13,094 13,156 13,195 13,267 3,066 3,067 3,080 3,083 3,091 3,101 9,329 9,371 9,412 9,441 9,486 9,535 2,428 2,453 2,477 2,498 2,523 2,575 8,023 8,073 8,141 8,192 8,245 8,303 July.. Aug.. Sept.. Oct... Nov.. Dec— 64,273 64,438 64,539 64,779 65,000 65,272 19,289 19,404 19,409 19,491 19,544 19,585 11,334 11,423 11,463 11,521 11,536 11,558 7,955 7,981 7,946 7,970 8,008 8,027 632 634 630 628 625 625 3,292 3,257 3,240 3,218 3,200 3,251 4,136 4,119 4,183 4,195 4,215 4,221 13,309 13,326 13,339 13,366 13,394 13,403 3,110 3,111 3,115 3,116 3,124 3,138 9,572 9,620 9,634 9,682 9,747 9,800 2,582 2,592 2,597 2,620 2,624 2,650 8,351 8,375 8,392 8,463 8,527 8,599 1967: Jan... Feb... Mar.. AprMay.. June- 65,524 65,646 65,672 65,619 65,677 65,821 19,628 19,573 19,517 19,425 19,346 19,356 11,576 11,554 11,511 11.418 11,389 11,369 8,052 8,019 8,006 8,007 7,957 7,987 627 626 626 623 622 621 3,262 3,307 3,227 3,204 3,159 3,131 4,247 4,254 4,255 4,216 4,273 4,276 13,444 13,461 13,495 13,529 13,564 13,573 3,146 9,849 3,159 9,898 3,172 9,956 3,186 9,970 3,199 9,996 3,214 10,032 2,667 2,676 2,688 2,688 2,701 2,747 8,654 8,692 8,736 8,778 8,817 8,871 Jury.. Aug_. Sept.. Oct... Nov.. Dec... 65,920 66,186 66,123 66,286 66,778 67,060 19,288 19,407 19,285 19,302 19,518 19,593 11,335 11,433 11,272 11,264 11,463 11,498 7,953 7,974 8,013 8,038 8,055 8,095 626 610 606 603 603 603 3,168 3,165 3,182 3,184 3,214 3,275 4,296 4,288 4,278 4,267 4,297 4,302 13,610 13,648 13,684 13,729 13,791 13,793 3,223 3,241 3,251 3,261 3,273 3,289 10,056 10,110 10,139 10,171 10,270 10,316 2,743 2,740 2,718 2,718 2,692 2,709 8,910 8,977 8,980 9,051 9,120 9,180 1968: Jan... Feb.. Mar_. Apr... May.. June.. 67,058 67,600 67,656 67,755 67,792 68,039 19,612 19,612 19,607 19,657 19.693 19,777 11,541 11,514 11,495 11,533 11,545 11,571 8,071 8,098 8,112 8,124 8,148 8,206 604 608 609 632 631 632 3,107 3,388 3,330 3,313 3,245 3,174 4,317 4,342 4,332 4,331 4,281 4,336 13,818 13,920 13,999 14,009 14,049 14,086 3,291 3,304 3,311 3,323 3,334 3,335 10,331 10,405 10,415 10,402 10,425 10,467 2,721 2,721 2,718 2,717 2,721 2,795 9,257 9,300 9,335 9,371 9,413 9,437 68,170 68,314 68,382 68,701 NOVP. 68,920 Dec p. 69,186 19,776 19,748 19,755 19,807 19,854 19,918 11,619 11,563 11,577 11,603 11,647 11,685 8,157 8,185 8,178 8,204 8,207 8,233 638 638 639 591 635 638 3,189 3,195 3,252 3,285 3,273 3,353 4,346 4,358 4,365 4,374 4,394 4,369 14,117 14,181 14,222 14,298 14,331 14,310 3,350 3,376 3,387 3,411 3,425 3,441 10,498 10,548 10,545 10,610 10,695 10,758 2,788 2,751 2,716 2,705 2,696 2,697 9,468 9,519 9,501 9,620 9,617 9,702 Juiy_. Aug.. Sept.. Oct... Note.—Data in Tables B-27 through B-33 are based on reports from empli ing establishments and relate to full- and part-time wage and salary workers in nonagricultural establishments who woi ;ed during, or received pay for, any part of the pay period which includes the 12th ot the month. Not comparable with labor force data (Tables B-22 through B - 2 5 ) , which include proprietors, self-employed persons, domestic servants, and unpaid family workers, and which count persons as employed when they are not at work because of industrial disputes, bad weather, etc. For description and details of the various establishment data, see "Employment and Earnings and Monthly Report on the Labor Force." Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 259 TABLE B—28.—Average joeekly hours of work i n selected nonagricultural Total nonagricultural private i Year or month .. . 40.3 40.0 39.4 39.8 39.9 39.9 39.6 39.1 39.6 39.3 38.8 38.5 39.0 38.6 38.6 38.7 38.8 38.7 38.8 38.6 38.0 37.8 32.5 34.7 33.8 37.2 40.9 39.9 34.9 37.9 39.2 42.0 45.0 46.5 46.5 44.0 40.4 40.5 40.4 39.4 41.1 41.5 41.5 41.2 40.1 41.3 41.0 40.3 39.5 40.7 40.1 40.3 40.9 41.1 41.4 42.0 42.1 41.2 41.4 38.4 38.0 38.0 37.9 37.9 37.9 38.0 38.0 38.1 37.9 38.0 37.8 37.6 37.9 37.8 37.6 37.8 37.9 37.9 37 9 38.0 37 7 37.5 37.6 41.0 40.3 40.4 40.5 40.5 40.4 40.5 40.6 40.9 40.7 40.7 40.7 40.2 40.8 40.7 40.1 40.9 40.9 40.9 40.7 41.1 41 0 40.8 40.7 41.6 40.9 41.1 41.0 41.0 41.0 41.1 41.1 41.4 41.2 41.2 41.3 40.9 41.4 41.4 40.7 41.5 41.7 41.5 41 1 41.7 41 6 41.6 41.4 ... . .. . Total NonDurable durable goods goods 44.2 42.1 40.5 38.3 38.1 34.6 36.6 39.2 38.6 35.6 37.7 38.1 40.6 43.1 45.0 45.2 43.5 40.3 40.4 40.0 39.1 40.5 40.6 40.7 40.5 39.6 40.7 40.4 39.8 39.2 40.3 39.7 39.8 40.4 40.5 40.7 41.2 41.3 40.6 40.7 1929... 1930 1931 . 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939... 1940. . . 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 . . 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961... 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 v Manufacturing Contract construction Retail trade Wholesale trade industries, Bituminous coal mining Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug Sept Oct Nov.. Dec 1968: Jan . . Feb Mar Apr MayJune July Aug Sept Oct Nov p Dec p Class 1 railroads Telephone communication 38.1 41.9 40.0 35.1 36.1 37.7 37.4 36.1 37.4 37.0 38.9 40.3 42.5 43.1 42.3 40.5 40.2 39.6 38.9 39.7 39.5 39.7 39.6 39.0 39.9 39.6 39.2 38.8 39.7 39.2 39.3 39.6 39.6 39.7 40.1 40.2 39.7 39.8 38.2 38.1 37.7 37.4 38.1 38.9 37.9 37.2 37.1 37.5 37.0 36 8 37.0 36.7 36.9 37.0 37.3 37.2 37.4 37.6 37.7 37.3 43.4 43.2 42.8 41.8 40.9 41.0 40.9 41.3 3 40.3 40.2 40.4 40.4 40.4 39.8 39.1 39.2 39.0 38.6 38.1 38.1 38.2 38.0 37.6 37.4 37.3 37.0 36.6 35.9 35.3 34.7 41.6 42.9 43 1 42.3 41.8 41.3 41.1 41.4 42.3 43.0 42.8 41.6 41.1 41.0 40.8 40.7 40.8 40.7 40.6 40.5 40.7 40.5 40.3 40.2 40.6 40.5 40.5 40.6 40.6 40.6 40.8 40.7 40.3 40.0 35.5 35.3 35.4 35.3 35.2 35.4 35.4 35.4 35.3 35.1 35.2 35.1 34.8 34.9 34.7 34.8 34.6 34.9 34.9 34 9 34.7 34 5 34.4 34.3 40.6 40.5 40.4 40.4 40.2 40.3 40.3 40.3 40.3 40.2 40.2 40.1 40.0 40.0 39.9 39.9 39.8 40.3 40.1 40 3 40.2 40 1 40.0 39.8 33 3 28.1 27.0 29.3 26 8 26.2 28.5 27 7 23.3 26.8 27.8 30 7 32.4 36.3 43.0 42.0 41 3 40.3 37.7 32.3 34.7 34.9 33.8 34.1 32.3 37.3 37.5 36.3 33.3 35.8 35.8 35.9 «37.0 < 38.9 *39.2 *40.2 M0. 8 M0.8 «39.5 40.0 39.5 39.5 39.7 39.5 39.6 39.6 39.7 40.0 39.7 39.9 39.9 39.2 40.0 39.8 39.2 39.8 40.0 39.9 39.9 40.1 39 9 39.7 39.9 38.3 37.6 37.4 37.4 36.8 37.4 37.4 37.4 38.0 37.2 39.4 37.2 36.0 37.9 36.8 37.8 37.2 37.6 37.3 37.5 37.9 37 5 36.0 37.9 43.7 44.3 45 8 47.0 48.7 48 9 48.5 46 0 46.4 46.2 43.7 40.8 41.0 40.6 40.6 40.8 41.9 41.7 41.7 41.6 41.9 41.7 42.3 42.6 42.9 43.5 43.6 43.9 43.2 38 8 38 9 39.1 39.5 40 1 40.5 41.9 42 3 2 41.7 39 4 37.4 39.2 38.5 38.9 39.1 38.5 38.7 38.9 39.6 39.5 39.0 38.4 39.2 39.6 39.4 39.9 40.0 40.2 40.4 40.6 39.3 39.8 Unadjusted Seasonally adjusted 1967: Jan 1929-68 41.1 40.0 39.7 40.1 40.5 41.7 41.1 40.6 40.3 41.8 41.3 40.7 40.6 41.0 40.4 40.5 41.5 40.9 40.6 29.9 39.3 43.1 44.1 43.7 41.9 44.1 43.9 41.4 44.0 42.7 43.1 43.8 42.6 44.3 44.0 42.7 44.3 45.0 43.0 44.7 39.5 39.8 38.8 39.1 38.9 39.4 39.6 39.0 39.7 39.7 39.4 39.3 39.2 39.1 39.1 38.6 38.1 39.9 40.2 39.9 40.6 40.6 41.1 Mn addition to industries shown separately, total includes other mining; other transportation and public utilities; finance, insurance, and real estate; and services. 2 Nine-month average, April through December, because of new series started in April 1945. 3 Beginning 1947, data include eating and drinking places. Comparable figure excluding eating and drinking places is 41.0 hours for 1947. 4 Eleven-month average; excludes data for July. Note.—Hours and earnings data in Tables B-28 through B-33 relate to production workers in manufacturing and mining, to construction workers in contract construction, and generally, to nonsupervisory employees in other industries. See Table B 31 for unadjusted weekly hours in manufacturing. See also Note, Table B 27. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 260 TABLE B-29.—Average gross hourly earnings in selected industries, 1929-68 Total nonYear or month agricultural private ! Manufacturing Total NonDurable durable goods goods Contract construction Retail trade Wholesale trade Bituminous coal mining Class I railroads Telephone communication Agricultures 1929._ $0.560 $0.659 $0.241 1930.. 1931.. 1932.. 19331934.. 1935.. 1936.. 1937.. 1938.. 1939.. .546 .509 .441 .437 .526 .544 .550 .617 .620 .627 $0.492 .467 .550 .571 .580 .667 .679 .691 $0,412 .419 .505 .520 .519 .566 .572 .571 .662 .626 .503 $0.484 19401941.. 1942.. 1943.. 1944.. 1945. 1946.. 1947.. 1948.. 1949.. $1,131 1.225 1.275 .655 .726 .851 .957 1.011 1.016 .075 .217 .328 .378 .716 .799 .937 1.048 1.105 1.099 1.144 1.278 1.395 1.453 .590 .627 .709 .787 .844 .886 .995 1.145 1.250 1.295 $1,541 1.713 1.792 .494 .518 .559 .606 .653 .699 .797 4.838 .901 .951 1950.. 19511952.. 1953.. 1954.. 1955. 19561957.. 1958. 1959. 1.335 1.45 1.52 1.61 1.65 1.71 1.80 1.89 1.95 2.02 .440 .56 .65 .74 .78 1.86 1.95 2.05 2.11 2.19 1.519 1.65 1.75 1.86 1.90 1.99 2.08 2.19 2.26 2.36 1.347 1.44 1.51 1.58 1.62 1.67 1.77 1.85 1.91 1.98 1.863 2.02 2.13 2.28 2.39 2.45 2.57 2.71 2.82 2.93 .983 1.06 1.09 1.16 1.20 1.25 1.30 1.37 1.42 1.47 1960... 1961 — 1962... 1963— 1964... 1965-__ 1966... 1967... 1968 p. 2.09 2.14 2.22 2.28 2.36 2.45 2.56 2.68 2.85 2.26 2.32 2.39 2.46 2.53 2.61 2.72 2.83 3.01 2.43 2.49 2.56 2.63 2.71 2.79 2.90 3.00 3.19 2.05 2.11 2.17 2.22 2.29 2.36 2.45 2.57 2.74 3.08 3.20 3.31 3.41 3.55 3.70 3.89 4.11 4.38 1967:Jan Feb.... Mar..__ Apr May.... June 2.62 2.63 2.63 2.64 2.66 2.67 2.78 2.79 2.79 2.80 2.81 2.82 2.96 2.96 2.96 2.97 2.99 2.99 2.51 2.53 2.54 2.55 2.55 2.56 July Aug Sept.... Oct Nov_.__ Dec 2.69 2.69 2.72 2.72 2.73 2.73 2.82 2.82 2.85 2.85 2.88 2.91 3.00 3.00 3.03 3.03 3.05 3.09 1968:Jan Feb.... Mar... Apr MayJune 2.76 2.78 2.79 2.80 2.83 2.85 2.94 2.94 2.96 2.97 2.99 3.00 2.86 2.86 2.91 2.92 2.92 2.93 3.00 2.99 3.05 3.06 3.08 3.10 July Aug Sept Oct..._ NOVP.. .485 .651 .720 .768 .828 .849 .858 $0.730 $0.774 .816 .822 .226 .172 .129 .115 .129 .142 .152 .172 .166 .166 .711 .763 .828 .898 .948 .990 1.107 1.220 1.308 1.360 .854 .960 1.030 1.101 1.147 1.199 1.357 1.582 1.835 1.877 .733 .743 .837 .852 .948 .955 1.087 1.186 1.301 1.427 .827 .820 .843 .870 .911 3.962 1.124 1.197 1.248 1.345 .169 .206 .268 .353 .423 .472 .515 .547 .580 .559 1.427 1.52 1.61 1.70 1.76 1.83 1.94 2.02 2.09 2.18 1.944 2.14 2.22 2.40 2.40 2.47 2.72 2.92 2.93 3.11 1.572 1.73 1.83 1.398 1.49 1.59 1.68 1.76 1.82 1.86 1.95 2.05 2.18 .561 .625 .661 .672 .661 .675 .705 .728 .757 .798 1.52 1.56 1.63 1.68 1.75 1.82 1.91 2.01 2.16 2.24 2.31 2.37 2.45 2.52 2.61 2.73 2.88 3.05 3.14 3.12 5 3.12 5 3.15 5 3.30 5 3.49 5 3.66 5 3.75 5 3.84 2.61 2.67 2.72 2.76 2.80 3.00 3.09 3.24 2.26 2.37 2.48 2.56 2.62 2.70 2.79 2.88 3.03 .818 .834 .856 .880 .904 .951 1.03 1.12 1.21 4.03 4.02 4.00 4.00 4.04 4.03 1.97 L98 1.98 1.99 2.00 2.01 2.81 2.83 2.84 2.86 2.86 2.87 3.79 3.71 3.72 3.77 3.73 3.75 3.19 3.26 3.17 3.23 3.19 3.21 2.86 2.88 2.87 2.87 2.88 2.89 2.57 2.57 2.61 2.61 2.62 2.64 4.10 4.11 4.20 4.22 4.22 4.25 2.01 2.00 2.03 2.04 2.05 2.04 2.88 2.87 2.91 2.91 2.93 2.95 3.74 3.76 3.75 3.73 3.79 3.25 3.22 3.27 3.26 3.31 3.33 2.88 2.87 2.90 2.90 2.89 2.91 3.13 3.12 3.14 3.15 3.18 3.18 2.67 2.68 2.69 2.70 2.72 2.73 4,34 4.27 4.28 4.27 4.32 4.29 2.09 2.11 2.12 2.13 2.14 2.16 2.96 3.00 3.01 3.02 3.04 3.05 3.81 3.77 3.77 3.76 3.76 3.80 3.33 3.38 3.35 3.35 3.34 3.40 2.90 2.90 2.91 2.89 2.96 3.05 1.24 3.18 3.17 3.23 3.25 3.27 3.29 2.75 2.75 2.78 2.79 2.80 2.82 4.34 4.38 4.47 4.50 4.52 4.52 2.16 2.16 2.19 2.20 2.21 2.20 3.04 3.05 3.10 3.09 3.12 3.15 3,46 3.04 3.06 1.18 3.76 3.78 3.75 4.09 $0.610 .628 .658 .674 1.88 1.93 1.96 2.12 2.26 2.44 2.54 3.14 3.16 3.18 1.14 "."998 1.10 "i.'iif i."07~ 1.27 * For coverage, see footnote 1, Table B-28. 2 Weighted average of all farm wage rates on a per hour basis. s Nine-month average, April through December, because of new series started in April 1945. 4 Beginning 1947, data include eating and drinking places. Comparable figure excluding eating and drinking places is $0,901 for 1947. s Eleven-month average; excludes data for July. Note—See Note, Tables B-27 and B-28. Sources: Department of Labor (Bureau of Labor Statistics) and Department of Agriculture. 26l TABLE B-30.—Average Year or month Total nonagricultural private* gross weekly earnings i n selected nonagricultural industries, Manufacturing Total Durable goods Nondurable goods 1929 $24.76 $26.84 23.00 20.64 16.89 16.65 18.20 19.91 21 56 23.82 22.07 23.64 24.42 20.98 15.99 16.20 18.59 21.24 23 72 26.61 23.70 26.19 21.40 20.09 17.26 16.76 17 73 18.77 19 57 21 17 20.65 21.36 $45. 58 49.00 50.24 24.96 29.48 36.68 43 07 45.70 44 20 43 32 49.17 53.12 53.88 28.07 33.56 42.17 48.73 51.38 48 36 46.22 51.76 56.36 57.25 21.83 24.39 28.57 33 45 36.38 37 48 40 30 46.03 49.50 50.38 53.13 57.86 60.65 63.76 64.52 67.72 70.74 73.33 75.08 78.78 58.32 63.34 67.16 70.47 70.49 75.70 78.78 81.59 82.71 88.26 62.43 68.48 72.63 76.63 76.19 82.19 85.28 88.26 89.27 96.05 80.67 82.60 85.91 88.46 91.33 95.06 98.82 101.84 107.73 89.72 92.34 96.56 99.63 102.97 107. 53 112.34 114.90 122.51 1967: Jan Feb Mar Apr May . . . June 99.82 99.15 99.41 99.26 100. 55 101 73 July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 1968: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June Retail trade Wholesale trade $22.47 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 Contract construction 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 p TIT: July Aug Sept Oct v Nov Dec v Telephone communication $25.11 $21.01 $26.75 25.19 25 44 25.38 26 96 28.36 28.51 28.76 22.04 17 59 13.58 14.21 17 45 18.86 21 89 22.94 19.78 22.99 $31.90 $30 03 31.74 32.14 $58.87 65.27 67.56 21.34 22.17 23.37 24 79 26.77 28 59 32.92 3 33.77 36.22 38.42 29.36 31.36 34.28 37.99 40.76 42 37 46 05 50.14 53.63 55.49 23.74 29.47 33.37 39.97 49.32 50 36 56.04 63.75 69.18 60.63 32.47 34.03 39.34 41.49 46.36 46 32 50.00 55.03 60.11 62.36 32.67 32.88 34.14 36.45 38.54 2 40 12 44 29 44.77 48.92 51.78 53.48 56.88 59.95 62.57 63.18 66.63 70.09 72.52 74.11 78.61 69.68 76.96 82.86 86.41 88.91 90.90 96.38 100.27 103.78 108.41 39.71 42.82 43.38 45.36 47.04 48.75 50.18 52.20 54.10 56.15 58.08 62.02 65.53 69.02 71.28 74.48 78.57 81.41 84.02 88.51 67.46 74.69 75.04 81.84 77.52 92.13 102.00 106. 00 97.57 111.34 64.14 70.93 74.30 76.33 78.74 82.12 88.40 94.24 101. 50 106.43 54.38 58.26 61.22 65.02 68.46 72.07 73.47 76.05 78.72 85.46 97.44 100.35 104.70 108.09 112.19 117.18 122.09 123.60 132.07 80.36 82.92 85.93 87.91 90.91 94.64 98.49 102.03 109. 05 113.04 118.08 122.47 127.19 132.06 138.38 146. 26 154.95 163. 37 57.76 58.66 60.96 62.66 64.75 66.61 68.57 70.95 74.95 90.72 93.56 96.22 99.47 102.31 106.49 111.11 116.06 122. 00 112.41 112.01 114.46 121.43 128.91 140.26 149.74 153. 00 151.68 108.84 112.94 115.87 118.40 121.80 130. 80 135.65 139.97 89.50 93.38 98.95 102.40 105.32 109.08 113.27 113.18 120.59 113.42 111.88 112.44 112.56 113.81 114 49 122.84 120.47 121.36 121.18 122.89 122 89 99.65 99.18 100.08 100. 22 100.73 101 63 149.92 144. 32 147.20 147.60 150.29 153.95 69.15 69.10 69.30 69.45 69.80 71 56 113.81 114.05 114.45 114.97 114.97 115 66 155. 77 148.40 147.68 151.18 151.07 156 38 137.49 143.77 138. 53 135. 34 140.68 140.92 112.97 114.62 111.36 112.22 112.03 113.87 103 03 103.30 103 90 103.36 103.74 103. 74 113.65 114.49 116 85 116.28 117.50 119.60 122.40 123.30 125 75 125.44 125.66 129.16 102. 03 102.80 104.92 104.14 105.06 105. 86 158.67 159.06 162.96 160.78 161.63 155.13 72.96 72.60 71.66 71.20 71.34 72.22 116.93 115.95 117.27 116.98 117.79 119.18 157.00 153.71 152.66 151.13 155.91 156. 53 134.55 141.68 139.63 140. 51 144.98 141.86 114.05 111.93 115.13 115.13 113.87 114.36 102.95 104 53 104.90 104. 44 106.69 108 59 117.60 119 36 120.18 118.21 122.29 123 30 127.70 128. 54 129.68 127.58 132.29 132.92 103.86 106.40 106.79 104.76 108. 26 109.47 151.90 154.57 154.94 159.27 162.43 164.74 72.11 72.80 72.93 73.49 73.40 75.82 118.10 119.40 119.80 119.89 120.99 122.92 155.07 153.06 154. 57 151.90 152.28 157.70 147.52 148.72 143.05 148.41 150.30 146.20 113.68 113.39 113.78 111.55 112.78 121.70 109.25 109 54 110 87 110 38 109 50 110.75 122.10 121 69 125 66 125 77 125 97 127.41 131.02 130.29 135.01 135 85 136 03 137.85 110.00 110 55 112.03 111 88 111 72 113.08 167.52 169.94 172.99 172 80 158.20 168.14 77.33 77.33 75.99 75 46 75.14 76.12 122.82 123.22 124.62 123.91 124.80 126. 32 157.29 153.78 153.47 112 13 160.74 154.66 122.21 122.09 127.48 128.35 130.70 . ... . Bitumi- Class 1 nous railcoal mining roads 1929-68 1 For coverage, see footnote 1, Table B-28. 2 Nine-month average, April through December, because of new series started in April 1945. 3 Beginning 1947, data include eating and drinking places. Comparable figure excluding eating and drinking places is $36.94 for 1947. Note.-See Note, Tables B-27 and B-28. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 262 T A B L E B-31.—Average weekly hours and hourly earnings, gross and excluding overtime, in manufacturing industries, 1939—68 Durable goods manufacturing industries Ai manufacturing I industries Average weekly hours Average weekly hours Average hourly earnings Average hourly earnings Nondurable goods manufacturing industries Average weekly hours Average hourly earnings Year or month ExcludGross ing overtime Gross $0 627 1939 37.7 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 38.1 40.6 43.1 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 40 5 1.440 1.56 40.6 40.7 1.65 1.74 40.5 1.78 39 6 1.86 40 7 40.4 37.6 1.95 39.8 37.5 2.05 39.2 37.2 2.11 40.3 37.6 2.19 39.7 39.8 40.4 40 5 40.7 41 2 41.3 40.6 40.7 37.3 37.4 37.6 37.7 37.6 37 6 37.4 37.2 37.1 40.8 40.1 40.3 40.2 40 5 40.6 37.4 36.9 37.1 40.3 40.6 41.0 40.8 40.8 41.1 37.9 Gross Excluding overtime $0.691 39.2 42.0 Gross Excluding overtime 37.4 Gross Excluding overtime $0.571 37.0 57.8 63.2 66.1 45.0 46.5 46.5 44.0 40.4 40.5 40.4 39.4 .716 .799 $0.762 .937 .872 1.048 .966 1.105 1.019 1.099 3 1.031 1.144 1.111 1.278 1.24 1.395 1.35 1.453 1.42 1.39 1.51 1.59 1.68 1.73 1.79 1.89 1.99 2.05 2.12 68.2 73.6 77.4 81.6 84.3 86.9 91.5 96.2 100.2 103.4 41.1 41.5 41.5 41.2 40.1 41.3 41.0 40.3 39.5 40.7 38.0 37.9 37.6 38.0 1.519 1.65 1.75 1.86 1.90 i.99 2.08 2.19 2.26 2.36 1.46 1.59 1.68 1.79 1.84 1.91 2.01 2.12 2.21 2.28 39.7 1.347 39.5 1.44 1.51 39.7 1.58 39.6 1.62 39.0 1.67 39.9 39 6 37.2 1.77 39,2 37.0 1.85 38.8 36.6 1.91 39.7 37.0 1.98 1.31 1.40 1.46 1.53 1.58 1.62 1.72 2.26 2.32 2.39 2.46 2.53 2.61 2.72 2.83 3.01 2.20 2.25 2.31 2.37 2.44 2.51 2.59 2.72 2.88 106.8 109.9 112.7 115.5 118.4 121.5 125.6 131.5 139.5 40.1 40.3 40.9 41.1 41.4 42.0 42.1 41.2 41.4 37.7 38.0 38.1 38.2 38.1 38.1 37.8 37,7 37.6 2.43 2.49 2.56 2.63 2.71 2.79 2,90 3.00 3.19 2.36 2.42 2.48 2.54 2.60 2.67 2.76 2.88 3.05 39.2 39.3 39.6 39.6 39.7 40 1 40.2 39.7 39.8 36.7 36.8 36.9 36.9 36.8 36 9 2.05 2.11 2.17 2.22 2.29 2 36 36.8 2.45 36.6 2.57 36.5 2.74 1.99 2.05 2.09 2.15 2.21 2.27 2.35 2.47 2.63 2.78 2.79 2.79 37.1 2.80 37 3 2.81 37.3 2.82 2.67 2.68 2.69 2.70 2.70 2.71 128.9 129.5 129.8 130.4 130.6 131.0 41.5 40.7 41.0 40.8 41.1 41.1 37.8 37.3 37.6 37.6 37.8 37.7 2.96 2.96 2.96 2.97 2.99 2.99 2.84 2.84 2.85 2.86 2 87 2.88 39.7 39.2 39 4 39 3 39 5 39.7 36.7 36.3 36 5 36.4 36 5 36.6 2.51 2.53 2 54 2 55 2.56 2.42 2.44 2.45 2.46 2.46 2.46 37.1 37.2 37.3 37.3 37.4 37.5 2.82 2.82 2.85 2.85 2.88 2.91 2.71 2.71 2.73 2.73 2.76 2.79 131.4 131.7 132.6 133.0 133.9 134.7 40.8 41.1 41.5 41.4 41.2 41.8 37.5 37.6 37.6 37.7 37.7 38.0 3.00 3.00 3.03 3.03 3.05 3.09 2.88 2.88 2.89 2.90 2.93 2.96 39.7 40.0 40.2 39.9 40.1 40.1 36.6 36.7 36.6 36.5 36.8 36.8 2.57 2.57 2.61 2.61 2.62 2.64 2.47 2.47 2.50 2.50 2.52 2.54 40.0 40.6 40.6 39.8 40.9 41.1 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 ' - - 1967: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 1968: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug Sept Nov 32.2 36.7 37.3 37.3 36.9 37.3 37.4 2.94 2.94 2.96 2.97 2.99 3.00 2.83 2.83 2.85 2.86 2.87 2.87 136.1 136.9 137.5 138.2 138.6 138.8 40.8 41.2 41.3 40.5 41.6 41.8 37.3 37.8 37.8 37.5 37.8 37.9 3.13 3.12 3.14 3.15 3.18 3.18 3.00 3.00 3.02 3.03 3.04 3.04 38.9 39.7 39.7 38.8 39.8 40.1 35.9 36.7 36.6 36.1 36.6 36.7 2.67 2.68 2.69 2.70 2.72 2.73 2.57 2.58 2.59 2.61 2.62 2.62 40.7 40.7 41.2 41.1 40.9 37.2 37.1 37.2 37.2 37.1 37.2 3.00 2.99 3.05 3.06 3.08 2.88 2 87 2.90 2.92 2.94 2.96 139.1 139.8 141.2 141.7 142.5 143.4 41.2 41.1 41.8 41.8 41.6 41.9 37.6 37 4 37.6 37.6 37.5 3.18 3.17 3.23 3.25 3.27 40.0 40 2 40.3 40.1 39 9 37.7 3.29 3.05 3 03 3.08 3.09 3.12 3.13 36.6 36 7 36.5 36.6 36 4 36.7 2.75 2 75 2.78 2.79 2 80 2.82 2.63 2.64 2.66 2.67 2.69 2.70 .655 .726 $0.691 .851 793 .881 .957 1.011 .933 1.016 3.949 1.075 1.035 1.217 1.18 1.328 1.29 1.378 1.34 45.0 45.2 43.5 40.3 40.4 40.0 39.1 Oct Ex- Adjusted Exclud- hourly cludearnings, ing Gross ing (1957overover59= time time 100)i p Dec *_ 41.1 3.10 2 2 2 2 2 2 33.4 37.5 40.8 43.7 45.5 50.4 1 43.1 42.3 40.5 40.2 39.6 38.9 40.1 - Earnings in current prices, adjusted to exclude the effects of overtime and interindustry shifts. Annual average not available; April used. 3 Eleven-month average; August 1945 excluded because of VJ Day holiday period. 2 Note.—See Note, Tables B-27 and B-28. See Table B-28 for seasonally adjusted average gross weekly hours. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 263 .590 .627 $0,613 .684 .709 .748 .787 .844 .798 .886 3.841 .995 .962 1.145 1.11 1.250 1.21 1.295 1.26 38.9 40 3 42.5 2 55 1.80 1.86 1.92 TABLE B—32.—Average weekly earnings, gross and spendable, total private nonagricultural industries, in current and 1957-59 prices, 1947-68 Average spendable weekly earnings2 Average gross weekly earnings Year or month Current prices 1947 1948 1949 1957-59 prices i Workers with no dependents Current prices 1957-59 prices * Workers with three dependents Current prices 1957-59 prices * $45.58 49.00 50.24 $58. 59 58.47 60.53 $39.16 43.11 44.15 $50.33 51.44 53.19 $44.64 48.51 49.74 $57.38 57.89 59.93 1950 1951 1952 1953... 1954 1955 1956 1957 .. 1958 1959 53.13 57.86 60.65 63.76 64.52 67.72 70.74 73.33 75.08 78.78 63.40 63.93 65.57 68.41 68.93 72.58 74.70 74.83 74.56 77.62 46.02 48.68 50.07 52.45 53.76 56.27 58.63 60.47 61.83 64.52 54.92 53.79 54.13 56.28 57.44 60.31 61.91 61.70 61.40 63.57 52.04 55.79 57.87 60.31 60.85 63.41 65.82 67.71 69.11 71.86 62.10 61.65 62.56 64 71 65.01 67.96 69.50 69.09 68.63 70.80 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965. 1966 1967 __ 1968 v 80.67 82.60 85.91 88.46 91.33 95.06 98.82 101.84 107. 73 78.24 79.27 81.55 82.91 84.49 86.50 87.37 87.57 3 89.11 65.59 67.08 69.56 71.05 75.04 78.99 81.29 83.38 86.71 63.62 64.38 66.00 66.59 69.42 71.87 71.87 71.69 3 71.72 72.96 74.48 76.99 78.56 82.57 86.30 88.66 90.86 95.28 70.77 71.48 73.05 73.63 76.38 78.53 78.39 78.13 3 78. 81 99.82 99.15 99.41 99.26 100. 55 101.73 87.03 86.37 86.44 86.09 86.98 87.70 81.85 81.35 81.54 81.43 82.41 83.30 71.36 70.86 70.90 70.62 71.29 71.81 89.26 88.72 88.93 88.81 89.84 90.78 77 82 77.28 77.33 77.03 77.72 78.26 103.03 103.30 103.90 103.36 103.74 103.74 88.44 88.37 88.73 87.97 88.06 87.77 84.29 84.49 84.95 84.54 84.82 84.82 72.35 72.28 72.54 71.95 72.00 71.76 91.81 92.03 92.50 92.07 92.38 92.38 78.81 78.73 78.99 78.36 78.42 78.16 102.95 104. 53 104.90 104.44 106.69 108. 59 86.80 87.84 87.78 87.11 88.69 89.82 84.23 85.42 85.70 83.91 85.57 86.97 71.02 71.78 71.72 69.98 71.13 71.94 91.75 93.01 93.30 92.68 94.40 95.85 77.36 78.16 78.08 77.30 78.47 79.28 109. 25 109. 54 110.87 110.38 109. 50 110.75 89.92 89.86 90.73 89.81 88.74 87.46 87.67 88.65 88.29 87.64 88.57 71.98 71.92 72.55 71.84 71.02 96.36 96.58 97.59 97.22 96.55 97.50 79.31 79.23 79.86 79.10 78.24 .. 1967- Jan Feb Mar. Apr... May June .. .. . .. July Aug... . Sept Oct Nov Dec. . ... . . 1968: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July.. . Aug Sept . . Oct Nov p Dec p .. .. * Earnings in current prices divided by the consumer price index. 2 Average gross weekly earnings less social security and income taxes. 3 Estimates based on 11-month average of the consumer price index. Note.—"Total private" consists of manufacturing; contract construction; retail and wholesale trade; mining; transportation and public utilities; finance, insurance, and real estate; and services. See also Note, Tables B-27 and B-28. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 264 TABLE B—33.—Average weekly earnings, gross and spendable, in manufacturing industries, in current and 1957-59 prices, 1939-68 Average spendable weekly earnings2 Average gross weekly earnings Year or month Current prices 1957-59 prices 1 Worker with no dependents Current prices 1957-59 prices 1 Worker with three dependents Current prices 1957-59 prices l 1939 $23.64 $48.84 $23.37 $48.29 $23.40 $48.35 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 24.96 29.48 36.68 43.07 45.70 44.20 43.32 49.17 53.12 53.88 51.15 57.47 64.58 71.43 74.55 70.49 63.71 63.20 63.39 64.92 24.46 27.96 31.80 35.95 37.99 36.82 37.31 42.10 46.57 47.21 50.12 54.50 55.99 59.62 61.97 58.72 54.87 54.11 55.57 56.88 24.71 29.19 36.31 41.33 43.76 42.59 42.79 47.58 52.31 52.95 50.64 56.90 63.93 68.54 71.39 67.93 62.93 61.16 62.42 63.80 58.32 63.34 67.16 70.47 70.49 75.70 78.78 81.59 82.71 88.26 69.59 69.99 72.61 75 61 75.31 81.14 83.19 83.26 82.14 86.96 50.26 52.97 55.04 57.59 58,45 62.51 64.92 66.93 67.82 71.89 59.98 58.53 59.50 61.79 62.45 67.00 68.55 68.30 67.35 70.83 56.36 60.18 62.98 65.60 65.65 69.79 72.25 74.31 75.23 79.40 67.26 65.50 68.09 70.39 70.14 74.80 76.29 75.83 74.71 78.23 89.72 92.34 96.56 99.63 102.97 107. 53 112.34 114.90 122.51 87.02 88.62 91.61 93.37 95.25 97.84 99.33 98.80 3 101.33 72.57 74.60 77.86 79.82 84.40 89.08 91.57 93.28 97.70 70.39 71.59 73.87 74.81 78.08 81.06 80.96 80.21 3 80. 81 80.11 82.18 85.53 87.58 92.18 96.78 99.45 101.26 106.75 77.70 78.87 81.15 82.08 85.27 88.06 87.93 87.07 3 88.30 113.42 111.88 112.44 112.56 113.81 114.49 98.88 97.46 97.77 97.62 98.45 98.70 92.16 91.00 91.42 91.51 92.46 92.97 80 35 79.27 79.50 79.37 79.98 80.15 100.08 98.86 99,30 99.40 100.39 100.93 87.25 86.11 86.35 86.21 86.84 87.01 113.65 114.49 116.85 116.28 117.50 119.60 97.55 97.94 99.79 98.96 99.75 101.18 92.34 92.97 94 76 94.33 95.26 96.85 79.26 79.53 80 92 80.28 80.87 81.94 100.27 100.93 102 83 102.37 103.35 105.04 86.07 86.34 87.81 87.12 87.73 88.87 1968: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June 117.60 119.36 120.18 118.21 112.29 123.30 99.16 100.30 100.57 98.59 101.65 101.99 95.33 96.66 97.29 94.07 97.08 97.83 80 38 81.23 81.41 78.46 80 70 80.92 103.43 104.85 105.50 103.23 106.38 107.16 87.21 88.11 88.28 86.10 88.43 88.64 July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 122.10 121.69 125.66 125.77 125.97 127.41 100.49 99.83 102.83 102.34 102.08 96.94 96.64 99.57 99.65 99.80 100. 86 79.79 79.28 81.48 81.08 80.88 106 23 105.91 108.98 109.06 109.22 110.33 87.43 86.88 89.18 88.74 88.51 . . 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 . 1967 1968 v 1967* Jan Feb Mar Apr May. June . . ... July . . .. Aug Sept Oct.:::.:;::::::::::::::: Nov Dec * Earnings in current prices divided by the consumer price index. 2 Average gross weekly earnings less social security and income taxes. Estimates based on 11-month average of the consumer price index. Note.—See Note, Tables B-27 and B-28. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 3 265 TABLE B-34.—Indexes of output per man-hour and related data, private economy, 1947-6 11957-59=100) Output per man-hour Output^ Nonfarm industries Year Total private Farm Total Manufacturing Nonmanufacturing Man-hours 2 Nonfarm industries Total private Farm Total Manufacturing Nonmanufacturing Nonfarm industries Total private Farm Total Establishment basis 3 1947... 69.0 1948... 72.0 1949... 74.2 49.8 58.0 56.5 74.1 76.5 79.5 72.3 76.4 79.3 75.1 76.3 79.6 67.6 70.8 70.6 82.1 91.8 88.9 66.8 69.8 69.7 69.3 72.7 68.7 65.6 68.3 70.2 1950... 1951... 1952... 1953... 1954... 64.4 64.7 70.3 79.6 83.7 84.4 86.3 87.0 89.6 91.6 85.0 86.9 87.3 90.2 91.8 84.1 85.6 86.7 88.8 91.5 77.9 82.8 84.8 89.1 87.9 93.7 88.9 91.8 96.6 98.6 77.0 82.5 84.5 88.8 87.4 79.7 87.8 89.7 97.1 90.3 75.7 79.8 81.9 84.5 86.0 1955... 1956— 1957... 1958... 1959— 93.9 84.4 95.7 97.2 94.7 94.1 88.0 95.2 96.2 94.3 96.9 93.3 97.2 98.2 96.7 99.8 103.0 99.7 98.1 100.6 103.4 104.8 103.1 103.7 102.9 95.4 97.2 98.6 97.3 104.1 101.0 95.1 100.5 97.1 98.1 98.6 100.5 97.2 101.9 104.2 1960... 1961... 1962___ 1963... 1964... 105.0 108.6 113.8 117.9 122.5 110.7 119.4 122.2 133.1 135.5 104.4 107.4 112.3 115.7 120.0 105.5 107.9 114.3 118.9 124.7 103.9 107.4 111.5 114.3 118.0 106.6 108.6 116.0 120.8 127.8 105.8 107.2 106.8 110.1 107.7 1965... 1966... 1967... 1968 p. 126.6 131.4 133.5 137.9 148.1 152.9 171.7 172.1 123.6 127.7 129.0 133.4 129.8 131.6 132.5 136.2 120.5 125.4 127.1 131.9 136.2 144.6 147.5 154.9 114.5 107.2 116.4 114.9 80.3 82.7 84.3 87.8 89.9 95.8 95.1 86.6 87.4 89.5 88.2 91.2 93.8 95.6 101.0 97.1 102.7 99.1 107.7 95.4 98.4 90.0 93.2 94.5 95.2 94.0 100.9 92.2 101.3 94.9 101.7 97.1 93.4 99.1 104.9 103.9 101.6 119.6 99.4 103.8 103.3 114.2 102.0 105.3 101.8 105.1 101.4 103.6 97.5 97.6 97.5 95.2 100.7 97.2 101.1 101.2 97.4 100.6 100.4 98.5 101.0 106.7 108.7 116.5 121.4 128.8 106.4 106.0 116.8 122.7 131.2 106.8 110.1 116.3 120.8 127.7 101.5 100.0 101.9 102.5 104.3 95.6 89.8 87.4 82.7 79.5 102.2 101.2 103.7 104.9 107.3 100.9 98.2 102.2 103.2 105.2 102.8 102.5 104.3 105.7 108.2 137.3 146.6 149.1 157.0 143.9 155.3 156.0 163.0 134.0 142.2 145.7 154.0 107.5 110.1 110.5 112.3 77.3 70.1 67.8 66.8 111.1 114.8 115.6 117.7 110.9 118.0 117.7 119.7 111.2 113.4 114.6 116.8 98.0 164.8 98.4 158.4 95.1 157.3 97.0 100.1 100.6 101.5 97.8 145.6 137.5 130.6 121.4 117.8 90.1 91.3 87.7 Labor force basis * 1947... 67.9 1948... 70.2 1949... 71.9 49.8 58.0 56.1 72.9 74.5 76.8 67.6 70.8 70.6 82.1 91.8 88.9 66.8 69.8 69.7 99.6 164.8 100.8 158.2 98.2 158.6 91.6 93.7 90.8 1950... 1951... 1952... 1953... 1954... 64.1 64.3 69.9 79.1 83.3 82.4 85.7 87.5 90.4 92.8 77.9 82.8 84.8 89.1 87.9 93.7 88.9 8 96.6 98.6 77.0 82.5 84.5 99.2 100.9 100.4 100.8 96.8 93.4 96.3 96.6 98.2 94.2 1955... 1956... 1957... 1958... 1959... 78.5 82.1 84.5 88.4 90.8 94.7 84.0 96.7 94.6 87.5 95.9 97.2 93.3 97.7 99.4 103.1 99.2 103.4 104.7 103.1 87.4 146.2 138.3 1131.3 122.1 118.3 95.4 101.0 95.1 97.2 100.5 97.1 98.1 98. 97.3 100.5 97.2 104.1 101.9 104.2 100.7 120.3 98.3 102.7 114.9 101.2 101.4 105.2 100.9 97.9 97.5 98.0 100.7 97.3 101.1 1960. 104.5 1961 107.3 1962. 113.0 1963 116.7 1964... 121.0 110.7 119.9 |122.3 133.5 135.8 103.1 105.9 111.4 114.4 118.4 106.6 108.6 116.0 120.8 127.8 105.8 107.2 106.8 110.1 107.7 106.7 108.7 116.5 121.4 128.8 102.0 101.2 102.7 103.5 105.6 95.6 89.4 87.3 82.5 79.3 102.8 102.6 104.6 106.1 108. 1965.. 125.0 1966. 130.4 1967. 132.7 1968 v_ 138.2 148.3 152.7 171.4 174.0 121.8 126.4 128.1 133.3 136.2 144.6 147.5 154.9 114.5 107.2 116.4 114.9 137.3 146.6 149.1 157.0 108.9 110.9 111.1 112.1 77.2 70.2 67.9 66.1 112.8 115.9 116.4 117.7 1 2 Output refers to gross national product in 1958 prices. Hours worked by all persons in private industry engaged in production, including man-hours of proprietors and unpaid family workers. 3 Man-hours estimates based primarily on establishment data. 4 Man-hours estimates based primarily on labor force data. Note.—For information on sources, methodology, trends, and underlying factors influencing the measures, see Bureau of Labor Statistics, Department of Labor, Bulletin No. 1249 "Trends in Output per Man-Hour in the Private Economy, 1909-58," December 1959. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 266 PRODUCTION AND BUSINESS ACTIVITY TABLE B—35.—Industrial production indexes, major industry divisions, 1929-68 [1957-59=100] Year or month Total industrial production Manufacturing Mining Total Durable Utilities Nondurable 1929.. 38.4 38.6 38.2 38.3 54.2 12.7 1930.. 1931.. 1932.. 1933.. 1934.. 1935.. 1936.. 1937.. 1938.. 1939.. 32.0 26.5 20.7 24.4 26.6 30.7 36.3 39.7 31.4 38.3 31.7 25.9 19.9 23.7 26.0 30.6 36.4 39.7 30.5 37.9 28.4 19.5 11.9 15.5 18.8 24.1 31.2 35.2 22.6 31.4 34.8 32.8 28.9 32.8 33.8 37.4 41.6 44.1 39.1 44.9 47.0 40.3 33.6 38.5 40.3 43.7 50.3 56.7 49.0 53.8 13.1 12.5 11.7 11.5 12.2 13.2 14.9 16.4 16.5 18.3 1940.. 1941.. 1942.. 1943.. 1944.. 1945.. 1946.. 1947.. 1948.. 1949.. 43.9 56.4 69.3 82.9 81.7 70.5 59.5 65.7 68.4 64.7 43.8 58.3 73.1 88.7 86.3 73.0 60.0 66.4 68.9 65.1 40.0 57.7 79.9 102.9 100.9 78.2 54.7 64.3 67.0 60.9 47.3 57.6 63.7 70.7 68.2 65.6 64.8 67.2 69.5 68.3 60.1 64.8 67.0 69.0 74.2 73.0 72.2 79.9 84.0 74.5 20.3 22.8 25.6 28.3 30.1 30.6 31.8 36.5 40.8 43.4 1950. 1951.. 1952.. 1953.. 1954.. 1955.. 1956.. 1957.. 1958.. 1959.. 74.9 81.3 84.3 91.3 85.8 96.6 99.9 100.7 93.7 105.6 75.8 81.9 85.2 92.7 86.3 97.3 100.2 100.8 93.2 106.0 74.1 83.5 88.5 99.9 88.4 101.9 104.0 104.0 90.3 105.6 76.0 78.5 80.0 83.6 83.6 91.6 95.4 96.7 96.8 106.5 812 91.3 90.5 92.9 90.2 99.2 104.8 104.6 95.6 99.7 49.5 58.4 61.2 66.8 71.8 80.2 87.9 93.9 98.1 108.0 I960.. 1961.. 1962.. 1963.. 1964.. 1965.. 1966.. 1967.. 1968*. 108.7 109.7 118.3 124.3 132.3 143.4 156.3 158.1 165.3 108.9 109.6 118.7 124.9 133.1 145.0 158.6 159.7 166.8 108.5 107.0 117.9 124.5 133.5 148.4 164.8 163.7 169.9 109.5 112.9 119.8 125.3 132.6 140.8 150.8 154.6 162.8 101.6 102.6 105.0 107.9 111.5 114.8 120.5 123.8 126.3 115.6 122.3 131.4 140.0 151.3 160.9 173.9 184.9 202.1 Seasonally adjusted 1967: Jan.. Feb.. Mar. Apr. May. June. 158.3 156.7 156.6 156.7 155.6 155.7 160.2 158.5 158.3 158.3 157.2 157.1 165.5 162.9 162.6 162.5 162.2 161.4 153.5 153.0 153. 0 153.0 151.0 151.6 123.9 123.1 121.9 122.5 120.8 123.6 180.2 180.2 181.8 183.0 183.2 183.9 July. Aug. Sept. Oct.. Nov. Dec. 156.4 158.3 156.8 157.2 159.8 162.1 157.4 159.5 158.1 158.5 161.3 164.1 162.3 163.6 161.0 160.7 164.1 168.1 151.3 154.4 154.5 155.8 157.7 159.0 127.7 128.2 124.5 122.8 124.1 122.8 184.6 185.4 185.6 188.7 191.5 192.6 1968: Jan.. Feb.. Mar. Apr.. May. June. 161.2 162.0 163.0 162.5 164.2 165.8 162.7 163.6 164.6 163.7 165.8 167.3 167.2 167.6 168.2 167.2 169.8 171.0 157.1 158.6 160.0 159.5 160.8 162.7 121.6 123.9 126.2 127.1 126.9 129.2 196.7 199.0 198.0 196.5 196.1 197.9 July. Aug. Sept. Oct.. Nov. Dec i 166.0 164.6 165.1 165.7 167.4 168.9 167.4 165.7 166.3 167.0 168.7 170.1 170.8 167.8 168.7 169.3 171.4 172.6 163.0 163.0 163.3 165.0 165.3 167.0 130.0 129.4 127.0 120.7 126.5 127.1 199.3 202.1 204.8 208.4 210.0 212.5 Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 267 T A B L E B—36.—Industrial production indexes, market groupings, 1947—68 [1957-59=1001 Materials Final products Year or month Total industrial production Consumer goods * Total Total Equipment Automotive products Home goods Total, including defense Business Total Durable goods Nondurable goods 1947 1948 1949 65.7 68.4 64.7 64.2 66.6 64.5 67.1 69.2 68.8 69.4 72.6 72.0 68.8 71.7 66.3 55.4 58.3 52.0 69.9 72.6 63.5 67.0 70.2 64.8 68.2 71.0 64.2 64.9 68.2 64.2 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954. . 74.9 81.3 84.3 91.3 85.8 72.8 78.6 84.3 89.9 85.7 78.6 77.8 79.5 85.0 84.3 90.6 80.1 72.1 91.3 85.0 91.4 78.7 78.8 90.2 86.0 56.4 78.4 94.1 100.5 88.9 68.0 83.1 94.1 96.6 85.1 76.9 83.8 84.3 92.6 85.9 79.5 87.8 88.9 100.7 88.4 73.3 78.8 79.0 84.1 83.3 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959.. 96.6 99.9 100.7 93.7 105.6 93.9 98.1 99.4 94.8 105.7 93.3 95.5 97.0 96.4 106.6 118.3 97.8 105.2 86.7 108.1 97.3 100.9 96.6 92.8 110.7 95.0 103.7 104.6 91.3 104.1 91.9 104.7 105.3 89.8 104.9 99.0 101.6 101.9 92.7 105.4 104.7 105.3 104.8 90.0 105.1 93.0 97.7 98.9 95.4 105.7 1960 1961 1962.... 1963 1964 108.7 109.7 118.3 124.3 132.3 109.9 111.2 119.7 124.9 131.8 111.0 112.6 119.7 125.2 131.7 123.2 111.8 131.1 141.2 145.1 110.8 112.2 122.2 129.6 141.1 107.6 108.3 119.6 124.2 132.0 110.2 110.1 122.1 128.3 139.1 107.6 108.4 117.0 123.7 132.8 106.6 104.8 114.1 121.2 131.2 108.7 112.2 120.0 126.3 134.4 1965 1966 1967 1968 P 143.4 156.3 158.1 165.3 142.5 155.5 158.3 165.0 140.3 147.5 148.5 156.6 167.2 163.0 149.1 174.2 154.8 168.9 166.0 175.5 147.0 172.6 179.4 182.9 156.7 181.2 182.8 184.9 144.2 157.0 157.8 165.7 144.3 156.9 151.9 157.8 144.1 157.2 163.9 173.8 Seasonally adjusted 158.3 156.7 156.6 156.7 155.6 155.7 158.3 157.0 157.2 157.6 156.4 156.8 148.3 146.2 146.8 147.6 146.1 147.0 147.0 135.7 144.6 151.3 145.8 151.2 168.0 164.1 162.7 158.9 158.5 156.6 179.9 180.3 179.6 179.1 178.4 177.9 186.9 186.6 184.4 183.5 182.1 181.3 158.4 156.2 155.4 155.9 154.6 155.2 155.4 151.8 151.1 151.0 149.7 149.1 161.6 160.8 159.8 161. C 159.7 161.4 July Aug SeDt Oct Nov Dec 156.4 158.3 156.8 157.2 159.8 162.1 156.8 158.6 156.9 157.0 160.1 162.1 146.9 149.1 147.0 148.2 150.2 153.0 155.2 161,1 142.1 145.2 152.4 170.0 157.3 163.6 164.4 166.4 170.8 168.3 178.2 179.1 178.1 176.0 181.5 181.5 180.8 181.4 179.8 176.9 183.5 183.4 155.9 158.1 157.1 157.7 160.1 162.0 149.3 151.8 148.6 148.6 152.4 155.1 162.7 164.6 166. C 167.0 168.1 169.2 1968- Jan Feb Mar Apr May June 161.2 162.0 163.0 162.5 164.2 165.8 160.8 162.0 163.5 161.7 163.0 165.2 151.3 152.9 155.0 153.5 154.6 156.8 164.2 162.7 173.4 168.7 178.1 180.7 169.1 171.5 172.9 170.1 170.4 173.4 181.4 181.6 181.8 179.4 181.1 183.2 183.3 182.9 183.3 180.9 182.5 184.3 161.7 161.8 162.8 163.1 165.2 166.7 154.9 155.4 156.7 157.1 159.4 160.4 168.7 168.3 169.1 169.3 171.2 173.9 166.0 164.6 165.1 165.7 167.4 168.9 164.7 164.8 165.7 166.4 167.4 168.2 156.4 156.8 157.3 158.5 158.9 159.4 180.4 177.1 175.6 178.9 180.2 177.3 171.5 174.6 175.9 176.7 178.4 182.6 181.9 183.6 183.3 185.7 187.1 183.4 182.4 185.2 187.1 190.0 192 167.4 164.2 165.1 165.5 167.5 169.6 159.8 153.3 153.3 155.3 158.0 160 175.3 175.5 177.2 176.0 178.3 180 1967: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June . . . July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec P * Also includes apparel and consumer staples, not shown separately. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 268 TABLE B—37.—Industrial production indexes, selected manufactures, 1947—68 [1957-59=100] Nondurable manufactures Durable manufactures Year or month 1947 1948 1949 Fabricated Primary metal metals products Machinery Transportation equipment Instruments and related products Clay, glass, and lumber Textile, Furni- apparel, ture Paper and and and miscel- leather printing prodlaneous ucts Chemical, petroleum, and rubber products Foods, beverages, and tobacco 90.7 94.3 79.4 75.9 77.2 69.8 65.3 66.5 59.0 42.9 46.9 47.1 53.7 55.2 49.2 75.8 79.7 72.3 73.5 77.4 71.6 81.0 84.5 80.6 66.7 69.4 69.3 47.5 50.8 49.4 80.7 80.0 80.8 99.9 108.7 99.3 112.5 91.3 85.4 91.2 89.0 100.3 90.2 72.7 83.0 92.1 100.5 87.7 56.4 62.9 73.1 91.7 83.8 57.3 65.7 78.1 85.3 82.9 87.7 92.0 89.3 92.7 89.6 83.7 80.2 82.4 89.7 86.8 89.1 87.4 89.5 90.7 86.9 76.7 79.4 77.7 82.6 85.0 60.7 67.4 69.9 75.2 74.7 83.6 85.4 87.3 88.2 89.8 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 118.4 116.4 112.2 87.5 100.4 98.3 98.8 101.5 92.9 105.5 96.5 107.1 104.2 88.8 107.1 102.0 97.4 106.4 89.5 104.0 88.7 95.4 98.0 92.1 109.9 100.7 102.0 97.5 94.1 108.5 97.9 101.0 97.6 93.3 109.0 95.5 98.0 96.9 95.0 108.1 92.5 97.1 97.8 97.0 105.2 86.8 91.4 95.6 95.5 108.9 93.1 96.6 96.7 99.4 103.9 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 101.3 98.9 104.6 113.3 129.1 107.6 106.5 117.1 123.4 132.7 110.8 110.4 123.5 129.2 141.4 108.2 103.6 118.3 127.0 130.7 116.5 115.8 123.0 130.2 136.4 105.7 104.5 109.3 114.4 121.1 113.3 114.1 124.5 129.1 138.4 107.5 108.4 115.1 118.5 125.2 109.0 112.4 116.7 120.1 127.5 113.9 118.9 131.2 141.8 152.5 106.6 110.2 113.3 116.8 120.8 1965 1966 1967 1968 v 137.6 142.7 132.5 137.1 147.8 163.0 161.9 168.2 160.5 183.8 183.4 184.5 149.2 166.9 165.7 179.6 151.4 176.5 184.8 184.2 127.6 132.9 130.7 137.1 151.8 165.0 162.6 169.8 135.8 141.6 139.4 145.2 135.3 146.4 149.6 155.4 164.6 181.9 190.0 207.2 123.4 128.1 131.7 134.1 1950 1951 1952.. 1953 1954 . Seasonally adjusted 1967: Jan Feb.... Mar Apr May.... June 132.6 131.9 129.2 129.0 128.9 129.0 166.7 165.0 162.9 161.0 160.7 160.8 190.3 186.8 184.5 182.1 180.5 177.5 162.6 157.5 162.6 165.7 167.5 169.3 186.2 183.4 185.8 187.6 185.3 184.1 128.6 128.9 128.3 129.7 127.9 126.8 166.3 163.9 162.4 162.9 162.3 161.5 140.6 137.7 136.9 135.7 135.5 134.7 148.4 148.7 149.5 149.9 149.1 149.4 186.6 187.0 186.9 186.5 182.2 184.1 131.5 131.1 131.3 132.9 131.0 131.3 July.... Aug Sept.... Oct..... Nov Dec 128.7 129.5 129.0 131.7 134.9 140.9 159.8 159.1 158.1 158.2 159.8 162.4 180.0 182.9 182.2 179.6 183.2 182.2 170.8 171.9 159.2 159.2 165.6 177.5 182.9 183.2 183.1 183.2 185.4 186.3 127.4 127.0 129.6 131.4 132.4 137.0 159.1 159.9 161.4 160.9 161.5 163.3 134.9 137.2 138.8 140.1 142.8 146.0 148.6 150.3 148.5 148.6 149.9 149.7 184.7 191.7 192.9 195.3 197.6 199.5 130.0 131.0 130.1 131.4 132.1 133.4 1968: Jan Feb.... Mar Apr.. . May.... June 136.3 139.3 140.2 143.3 148.5 148.6 163.9 165.7 166.6 161.4 165.0 166.1 183.4 183.2 183.3 179.4 179.9 181.7 175.6 175.1 177.6 175.3 180.4 182.6 186.7 184.7 183.8 181.4 181.2 181.3 132.5 130.7 128.8 138.0 137.7 137.1 165.2 166.9 166.9 166.5 169.8 169.5 141.0 141.9 143.9 142.9 144.1 145.2 148.6 150.6 152.0 151.6 154.5 155.2 197.7 200.2 201.6 200.9 203.1 206.6 132.0 133.1 133.7 133.6 132.9 134.5 July.... Aug Sept Oct Nov.... Dec p . . . 145.8 122.8 120.6 123.0 129.6 136 166.2 166.3 167.6 172.2 173.6 175 182.7 183.8 186.4 186.1 188.4 189 183.2 181.7 180.5 180.4 179.9 179 179.2 182.6 184.3 185.8 188.3 190 136.2 135.5 138.8 139.7 140.0 142 169.5 170.1 170.9 171.3 171.7 172 144.2 144.1 144.8 146.2 147.2 148 155.6 156.5 156.8 157.6 158.6 160 208.2 207.6 207.9 211.7 212.5 215 134.2 134.4 134.5 134.7 133.4 135 Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 269 323-166 O—69 -18 TABLE B-38.—Manufacturing output, capacity, and utilization rate, 1948-68 Utilization rate 2 Output Capacity» Period Total Advanced products 1957-59 output=100 Primary products Percent 1948. 1949. 68.9 65.1 76.8 81.1 89.7 80.2 87.9 80.3 92.2 80.0 1950. 1951. 1952. 1953. 1954. 75.8 81.9 85.2 92.7 86.3 84.3 87.4 92.7 98.4 103.3 90.4 94.0 91.3 94.2 83.5 87.3 91.0 91.9 94.1 83.8 94.8 98.1 90.4 94.4 83.0 1955. 1956. 1957. 1958. 1959. 97.3 100.2 100.8 93.2 106.0 108.4 114.3 120.7 125.8 130.1 90.0 87.7 83.6 74.0 81.5 87.8 86.0 82.3 73.6 81.0 93.2 90.1 85.3 74.6 82.1 I960. 1961. 1962. 1963. 1964. 10a.9 10!). 6 118.7 124.9 133.1 134.9 139.6 144.4 149.8 155.6 80.6 78.5 82.1 83.3 85.7 81.1 78.9 82.5 83.1 84.4 80.0 78.1 81.6 83.6 87.4 1965. 1966. 1967. 1968 145.0 158.6 159.7 166.8 164.0 175.0 186.1 196.8 88.5 90.5 85.3 84.4 87.6 90.5 85.9 83.7 89.7 90.5 84.6 85.5 Seasonally adjusted 116.6 118.6 119.7 119.9 142.4 143.7 145.1 146.4 82.0 82.4 82.4 81.8 81.4 82.8 83.3 82.5 82.7 81.9 81.1 80.7 1963: I—- II— III.. IV... 121.3 124.9 126.0 127.2 147.8 149.1 150.5 151.8 82.0 83.9 83.7 83.7 82.2 82.9 83.6 83.7 81.7 85.2 83.9 83.8 1964: I . . . . II... III.. IV... 129.4 132.5 134.7 135.9 153.3 154.9 156.4 158.0 84.5 85.7 86.3 86.2 83.8 84.7 84.9 84.4 85.5 87.1 88.3 88.8 1965: I . . . . II... III.. IV... 141.4 143.5 146.1 148.9 160.1 162.7 165.3 167.9 88.5 88.4 88.5 88.6 87.2 87.1 87.4 88.7 90.2 90.1 90.1 88.5 1966: I - . . II... III.. IV... 154.5 157.7 159.9 161.7 170.7 173.6 176.5 179.3 90.5 90.8 90.6 90.0 90.2 90.4 90.6 90.6 90.9 91.4 90.6 89.1 1967: I . . . II... III.. IV... 159.0 157.5 158.3 161.3 182.1 184.8 187.5 190.1 87.1 85.0 84.3 84.8 87.8 86.2 85.1 84.3 86.2 83.4 83.2 85.6 1968: I v... II *.. III*. IV p. 163.6 165.6 166.5 168.7 192.8 195.5 198.2 200.9 84.9 84.8 84.0 84.1 84.4 83.6 83.5 83.2 85.5 86.5 84.6 85.3 1962: l.._II — III IV » For description and source of data see "A Revised Index of Manufacturing Capacity," Frank de Leeuw, Frank E. Hopkins, and Michael D. Sherman, "Federal Reserve Bulletin," November 1966, pp. 1605-1615. See also McGraw-Hill surveys on "Business Plans for New Plants and Equipment" for data on capacity and operating rates. 2 Output as percent of capacity; based on unrounded data. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (output) and sources in footnote 1 (capacity and utilization rate). 270 TABLE B-39.—Business expenditures for new plant and equipment, 1939 and 1945-69 [Billions of dollars] Manufacturing Year or quarter Total i Total Durable goods Transportation Nondurable goods Mining Railroad Other Public utilities Commercial and other ^ 1939 5.51 1.94 0.76 1.19 0.33 0.28 0.36 0.52 2.08 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 8.69 14.85 20.61 22.06 19.28 3.98 6.79 8.70 9.13 7.15 1.59 3.11 3.41 3.48 2.59 2.39 3.68 5.30 5.65 4.56 .38 .43 .69 .88 .79 .55 .58 .89 1.32 1.35 .57 .92 1.30 1.28 .89 .50 .79 1.54 2.54 3.12 2.70 5.33 7.49 6.90 5.98 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 20 60 25.64 26.49 28.32 26.83 7 49 10 85 11.63 11.91 11.04 3 14 5.17 5.61 5.65 5.09 4 36 5.68 6.02 6.26 5.95 .71 .93 .98 .99 .98 1 11 1.47 1.40 1.31 .85 1 21 1 49 1.50 1.56 1.51 3.31 3.66 3.89 4.55 4.22 6 78 7.24 7.09 8.00 8.23 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 28.70 35.08 36.96 30.53 32.54 11.44 14.95 15.96 11.43 12.07 5.44 7.62 8.02 5.47 5.77 6.00 7.33 7.94 5.96 6.29 .96 1.24 1.24 .94 .99 .92 1.23 1.40 .75 .92 1.60 1.71 1.77 1.50 2.02 4.31 4.90 6.20 6.09 5.67 9.47 11.05 10.40 9.81 10.88 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 35.68 34.37 37.31 39.22 44.90 14.48 13.68 14 68 15.69 18.58 7.18 6.27 7 03 7.85 9.43 7.30 7.40 7.65 7.84 9.16 .99 .98 1.08 1.04 1.19 1.03 .67 .85 1.10 1.41 1.94 1.85 2.07 1.92 2.38 5.68 5.52 5.48 5.65 6.22 11.57 11.68 13.15 13.82 15.13 51.96 60.63 61.66 64.53 22.45 26.99 26.69 26.78 11.05 13.00 13.00 13.19 1.30 1.47 1.42 1.49 1.73 1.98 1.53 1.51 2.81 3.44 3.88 4.46 6.94 8.41 9.88 11.38 16.73 18.36 18.25 18.91 . . . 1965 1966 1967 19683 . . 11.40 13.99 13.70 13.58 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 58.00 60.10 61.25 62.80 1967: 1 III IV 1968: 1 II III IV3 1969: |3 11 3 _ 13.15 13.85 14.35 14.50 12.45 12.95 13.20 13.25 1.40 1.55 1.45 1.45 1.75 2.00 1.85 2.35 3.30 3.50 3.40 3.50 8.25 8.30 8.55 8.50 17.70 17.95 18.45 19.25 27.85 27.00 26.15 26.00 14.20 13 75 13.50 13.50 13.70 13.25 12.65 12.55 1.40 1.30 1.45 1.50 1.80 1.55 1.40 1.40 3.05 3.90 4.10 4.45 9.20 9.70 9.80 10.65 18.30 18.05 17.95 18.70 64.75 62.65 63.45 67.25 III IV 25.60 26.80 27.55 27.75 61.65 61.50 60.90 62.70 1966' 1 26.35 25.80 26.65 28.10 13.65 12.80 13.65 14.15 12.70 13.00 13.05 13.90 1.55 1.40 1.35 1.60 1.65 1.45 1.40 1.50 4.35 3.65 4.60 5.35 11.60 11.65 10.90 11.45 19.20 18.70 18.50 19.25 71.15 69.80 29.60 29.70 15.10 15.40 14.50 14.30 1.55 1.80 4.30 13.20 20.65 40^10 1 Excludes agriculture. 2 Commercial and other includes trade, service, finance, communications, and construction. ' Estimates based on anticipated capital expenditures reported by business in late October and November 1968. The quarterly anticipations include adjustments, when necessary, for systematic tendencies in anticipatory data. Note.—Annual total is the sum of unadjusted expenditures; it does not necessarily coincide with the average of seasonally adjusted figures. These figures do not agree precisely with plant and equipment expenditures included in the gross national product estimates of the Department of Commerce. The main difference lies in the inclusion in the gross national product of investment by farmers, professionals, institutions, and real estate firms, and of certain outlays charged to current account. These series are not available for years prior to 1939 and for 1940 to 1944. Sources: Department of Commerce (Office of Business Economics) and Securities and Exchange Commission. 271 TABLE B-40,—New construction activity, 1929-68 [Value put in place, millions of dollars] Private construction Public construction i Total new construction Year or month Residential building (nonfarm) Nonresidential building and other construction Total Total Total* New housing units Total Commercial 2 Industrial Federally owned State and locally owned * Others 1929 . . 10,793 8,307 3,625 3,040 4,682 1,135 949 2,598 2,486 155 2,331 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 8,741 6,427 3,538 2,879 3,720 4,232 6,497 6,999 6,980 8,198 5,883 3,768 1,676 1,231 1,509 1,999 2,981 3,903 3,560 4,389 2,075 1,565 1,570 1,320 893 532 1,010 1,565 1,875 1,990 2,680 485 290 380 710 1,210 1,475 1,620 2,270 1,416 2,028 1,570 1,709 221 74 176 191 158 266 492 232 254 2,858 2,659 1,862 1,648 2,211 2,233 3,516 3,096 3,420 3,809 209 454 223 130 173 211 290 387 285 292 2,383 1,528 630 470 625 3,808 2,203 1,046 2,649 2,388 1,529 1,132 1,585 1,419 2,719 2,320 2,703 3,050 8,682 11,957 14,075 8,301 5,259 5,809 12,627 5,054 6,206 3,415 1,979 2,186 3,411 10,396 2,985 3,510 1,715 2,560 3,040 1,440 1,276 4,752 348 409 155 33 56 203 442 801 346 156 208 642 3 ; 300 2,069 2,696 1,700 1,094 1,371 2,135 5,644 1,153 14,308 20,041 . 26,078 26,722 12,077 16,722 21,374 20,453 6,247 9,850 13,128 12,428 4,795 7,765 10, 506 10,043 5,830 6,872 8,246 8,025 1,153 33,575 35,435 36,828 39,136 41,380 46,519 47,601 49,139 50,153 55,305 26,709 26,180 26,049 27,894 29,668 34,804 34,869 35,080 34,696 39,235 18,126 15,881 15,803 16,594 18,187 21,877 20,178 19, 006 19,789 24,251 15, 551 13,207 12,851 13,411 14,931 18,242 16,143 14,736 15,445 19,233 1960 1961 1962 1963 53,941 55,447 59,576 62,755 38,078 38,299 41,707 43,859 21,706 21,680 24,292 25,843 New series « 1962 1963 1964 .... 1965 1966 1967 1968 7 59,667 63,423 66,200 72,319 75,120 76,160 84,167 41,798 44,057 45,810 50,253 51,120 50,587 56,611 24,292 26,187 26,258 26,268 23,971 23,736 28,422 ... .. 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 Mew series 5 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 . . ... 885 815 761 884 989 1,149 1,053 1,163 1,689 1,107 1,290 2,802 3,628 5,751 10,660 6,322 3,073 2,398 2,231 1,397 1,182 1,689 1,702 1,397 972 2,988 4,213 5,452 5,871 2,231 3,319 4,704 6,269 8,583 10,299 10,246 11,300 11,481 12,927 14,691 16, 074 14,907 14,984 1,415 1,498 1,137 1,791 2,212 3,218 3,631 3,564 3,589 3,930 1,062 2,117 2,320 2,229 2,030 2,399 3,084 3,557 2,382 2,106 6,106 6,684 6,789 7,280 7,239 7,310 7,976 8,953 8,936 8,948 16,410 16,189 18,638 20,064 16,372 16,619 17,415 18,016 4,180 4,674 4,955 5,200 2,851 2,780 2,949 2,962 18,638 20,385 20,354 20,351 17,964 17,885 22,374 17,506 17,870 19, 552 23,985 27,149 26,851 28,189 5,144 4,995 5,396 6,739 6,879 6,982 8,297 2,842 2,906 3,565 5,118 6,679 6,131 5,649 710 570 720 See footnotes at end of table. 749 455 520 620 860 272 957 1,279 1,486 1,199 905 271 333 516 626 814 797 776 717 759 1,182 3,751 9,313 5,609 2,505 1,737 2,446 2,000 1,347 713 568 661 865 1,366 865 840 1,177 1,488 1,366 2.479 3,527 4,781 6,866 9,255 10,779 11,242 11,712 11,715 12,732 14,059 15,457 16,070 1,624 2,981 4,185 4,139 3,428 2,769 2,726 2,974 3,387 3,724 5,242 6,274 6,594 7,103 8,284 8,946 10,006 11,085 12,070 12,346 9,341 9,165 9,511 9,854 15,863 17,148 17,869 18,896 3,622 3,879 3,913 3,970 12,241 13,269 13,956 14,926 9,520 9,969 10,591 12,128 13,591 13,738 14,243 17,869 19,366 20,390 22,066 24,000 25,573 27,556 3,913 4,010 3,905 4,018 3,957 3,512 3,415 13,956 15,356 16,485 18,048 20,042 22,061 24,141 TABLE B-40.—New construction activity, 1929-68—Continued [Value put in place, millions of dollars] Private construction Residential building (nonfarm) Total Year or month new construction Public construction Nonresidential building and other construction Total Total New Total* housing units Total Commercial 2 Industrial Federally owned Others State and locally owned 4 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1967: Jan Feb.... Mar.... Apr May.... June... 74,561 74,525 73,382 72,801 73,655 73,774 48,777 48,277 47, 557 47,023 48,076 48,737 19,873 20,148 20,652 20,924 21,638 22,631 14,203 14,531 15,070 15,514 16,298 17,042 28,904 28,129 26,905 26,099 26,438 26,106 7,804 7,525 7,198 7,000 7,062 6,779 7,218 6,962 6,098 5,737 5,850 5,807 13,882 13,642 13,609 13,362 13,526 13,520 25,784 26,248 25,825 25,778 25, 579 25,037 3,739 3,473 3,512 3,227 3,409 3,272 22,045 22,775 22,313 22, 551 22,170 21,765 July.... Aug Sept.... Oct..... Nov.... Dec 75,738 76,741 78,253 78,883 79,609 81,207 50,380 51,641 52,841 53,520 53,946 53,965 23,850 25,015 25,770 26,427 27,222 27,635 17,760 18,688 19,523 20,406 21,286 21,757 26,530 26,626 27,071 27,093 26,724 26,330 6,782 6,576 6,732 6,996 7,018 6,688 6,133 6,061 6,395 6,173 5,681 5,822 13,615 13,989 13,944 13,924 14,025 13,820 25,358 25,100 25,412 25,363 25,663 27,242 3,704 3,566 3,528 3,486 3,603 3,655 21,654 21,534 21,884 21,877 22,060 23,587 1968: Jan Feb.... Mar.... Apr May.... June... 82,873 83,884 83,572 85,299 85,707 82,050 55,316 55,380 56,055 57,403 57,260 54,981 26,988 26,754 27,698 29,320 29,628 28,187 21,226 21,282 21,677 22,300 22,312 21,450 28,328 28,626 28,357 28,083 27,632 26,794 7,721 8,328 8,258 8,512 8,111 8,122 6,330 5,740 5,528 5,484 5,275 4,852 14,277 14,558 14,571 14,087 14,246 13,820 27,557 28, 504 27,517 27,896 28,447 27,069 3,528 3,692 3,561 3,381 3,436 3,287 24,029 24,812 23,956 24,515 25,011 23,782 July.... Aug Sept.... Oct..... Nov *>.._ Dec 7.... 81,328 83,551 84,504 87,151 86,730 87,600 54,658 56,497 57,242 59,455 58,878 59,600 27,440 28,140 29,148 30,019 30,363 31,050 21,248 21,919 22,771 23,562 23,898 24,550 27,218 28,357 28,094 29,436 28,515 28,500 8,272 8,641 8,534 8,939 7,962 7,950 4,752 5,575 5,492 6,096 6,398 6,400 14,194 14,141 14,068 14,401 14,155 14,150 26,670 27,054 27,262 27,696 27,852 28,000 3,052 3,384 3,340 3,539 3,458 3,400 23,618 23,670 23,922 24,157 24,394 24,650 1 Total includes additions and alterations and nonhousekeeping units not shown separately. 2 Office buildings, warehouses, stores, restaurants, and garages. 3 Farm, institutional, public utilities, and all other private. 4 Includes Federal grants-in-aid for State and locally owned projects. * New series in 1946 reflects differences due to the new higher level series of housing starts and farm construction expenditures and the reduced level value in place series for public utilities. See "Construction Report C30-61 ( S u p p l e m e n t ) " for a description of the differences. 6 New series differs from old in that it reflects differences in 1962 due to the introduction of new series for private nonresidential buildings and differences in 1963 due to the introduction of new series for State and locally owned public construction. See "Construction Report C30-65S" for a description of the differences. 7 Preliminary estimates by Council of Economic Advisers. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, except as noted. 273 TABLE B-41.—New housing starts and applications for financing, 1929-68 [Thousands of units] Housing starts Private and public i Private i Total (farm and nonfarm) Year or month Total (farm and nonfarm) Proposed home construction s Nonfarm Type of structure2 Nonfarm Government home programs New private housing units authorized < Total Total One family Two or more families FHA3 V A AppliRecations quests for for FHA VA comappraismitals ments 3 1929 509.0 509.0 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 330.0 254.0 134.0 93.0 126.0 221.0 319.0 336.0 406.0 515.0 330 0 254.0 134.0 93.0 126.0 215.7 304.2 332.4 399.3 458.4 13.2 48.8 57.0 106.8 144.7 6 20 6 47 8 49 8 131 1 179.8 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 602.6 706.1 356.0 191.0 141.8 529.6 619.5 301.2 183.7 138.7 176.6 217.1 160 2 126.1 83.6 231.2 288 5 238.5 144 4 62.9 326.1 1,023.2 1,268.5 1,362.1 1,466.1 324.9 1,015.2 1,265.1 1,344.0 1,429.8 38.9 67.1 178.3 216.4 252.6 7 8.8 91.8 160.3 71.1 90.8 56.6 121.7 286.4 293.2 327.0 1,908.1 1,419.8 1,445.4 1,402.1 1,531.8 1,626.6 1,324.9 1,174.8 1,314.2 282.7 1,494.6 328.2 186.9 229.1 216.5 250.9 268.7 183.4 150.1 270.3 307.0 191.2 148.6 141.3 156.5 307.0 392.9 270.7 128.3 102.1 109.3 1,208.3 397.7 192.8 267.9 253.7 338.6 306.2 197.7 198.8 341.7 369.7 164.4 226.3 251.4 535.4 620.8 401.5 159.4 234.2 234.0 257.4 338.6 471.4 589.6 557.8 509.1 386.5 447.7 1,230.1 1,284.8 1,439.0 1,582.9 1,502.3 1,450.6 1,141.5 1,268.4 225.7 198.8 197.3 166.2 154.0 159.9 1?9.1 141.9 998.0 1,064.2 1,186.6 1,334.7 1,285.8 1,239.8 971.9 1,141.0 242.4 243.8 221.1 190.2 182.1 188.9 153.0 167.2 142.9 177.8 171.2 139.3 113.6 102.1 99.2 124.3 414.7 1,189.3 562.3 1,382.8 132.7 137.2 . .- New series 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 . 1,951.9 1,491.0 1,503.9 1,437.6 1,550. 5 1,646.0 1,349.1 1,223.9 1,382. 0 1,553.5 1,531.3 1,516.8 1,234.1 1,296.0 1960 1,365.0 1961 1,492.4 1962 1,642.0 1963 1,561.6 1964 _ 1,509.6 1965 1,196.2 1966 1,321.9 1967 First 11 months: 1967 1,238.8 1968 v 1,442.7 1,274.0 1,336.8 1,468.7 1,614.8 1,534.7 1,487.5 1,172.8 1,298.8 1,252.1 994.7 1,313.0 974.4 1,462.7 991.3 1,610.3 1,020.7 1,529.3 971.5 1,472.9 963.8 1,165.0 778.5 1,291.6 843.9 1,216.7 1,211.5 1,419.5 1,406.0 796. 8 843.7 74.6 83.3 77.8 71.0 59.2 49.4 36.8 52.5 1,055.9 8 56.0 1,234.6 s 168. 5 8131.7 Monthly totals, unadjusted 1967:Jan Feb.... Mar.... Apr May June July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 61.7 63.2 92.9 115.9 134.2 131.6 60.4 62.0 90.7 114.2 131.9 129.6 59.1 61.4 91.5 113.7 132.0 125.4 40.2 40.3 66.6 79.8 87.3 87.6 18.9 21.1 24.9 33.9 44.7 37.8 57.7 60.2 89.2 112.0 129.7 123.4 8.6 8.3 11.1 11.0 14.8 14.3 3.1 2.9 3.9 4.1 4.7 5.2 58.5 57.0 91.4 99.5 111.2 115.5 10.1 10.7 16.6 14.8 16.0 16.3 7.1 7.7 10.3 11.0 10.9 12.8 126.1 130.2 125.8 137.0 120.2 83.1 124.9 126.5 123.4 134.6 118.6 82.1 125.3 127.4 121.9 135.4 118.4 80.1 82.3 83.7 78.2 81.7 69.1 47.0 43.0 43.7 43.7 53.7 49.3 33.1 124.0 123.6 119.5 133.1 116.8 79.1 12.3 13.9 12.6 14.1 11.7 9.4 4.8 5.6 4.8 5.3 4.5 3.6 97.1 110.6 103.4 111.8 99.8 85.2 12.7 17.1 14.6 15.3 12.9 10.2 12.2 11.6 10.8 12.5 9.5 7.9 See footnotes at end of table. 274 TABLE B-41.—New housing starts and applications for financing, 1929-68—Continued [Thousands of units] Housing starts Private and public^ Year or month Proposed Private Total (farm and nonfarm) Total (farm and nonfarm) Nonfarm struction5 1 Nonfarm Type of structure 2 Government home programs Total Total One family Two or more families FHA3 V A New private housing AppliReunits author- cations quests for for ized* FHA VA comapmitpraisments 3 als Monthly totals, unadjusted 82.7 87.2 128.6 165.2 145.1 142.9 82.0 85.3 126.0 162.2 143.3 141.1 80.5 84.6 126.6 162.0 140.9 137.9 45.2 55.4 79.3 98.0 86.8 81.4 35.3 29.2 47.3 64.0 54.1 56.5 79.8 82.8 123.9 159.1 139.0 136.0 9.7 10.6 12.0 14.3 13.8 12.3 3.4 4.1 4.5 5.4 5.5 5.0 73.4 88.8 115.5 132.4 130.5 113.9 11.2 12.4 15.9 14.7 15.7 13.7 8.4 10.6 11.6 12.4 11.0 10.4 142.5 July 141.0 Aug Sept.... 139.8 Oct p . . . 142.5 Nov p . . . 125.0 140.0 138.9 138.0 139.8 123.0 139.8 136.6 134.3 140.0 122.7 86.4 82.5 80.2 85.1 63.3 53.4 54.1 54.1 54.9 59.4 137.3 134.5 132.4 137.3 120.7 12.9 13.6 12.1 14.5 11.4 4.9 4.8 4.6 5.3 4.2 4.3 118.0 113.7 116.3 127.6 101.2 13.2 15.1 13.9 17.1 13.5 12.0 12.5 11.5 10.4 12.7 11.4 9.0 1968: Jan Feb Mar.... Apr May.... June... Dec p Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1967' Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug Sept Oct Nov . . Dec 1968: Jan.. Feb Mar Apr. May.... June July .Aug Sept.. . Oct p NOVP . . 1,111 1 149 1,094 1,116 1,274 1,233 806 802 774 759 839 849 305 347 320 357 435 384 1,079 1,132 1,067 1,099 1,254 1,214 146 134 126 125 143 144 50 47 49 50 49 51 1,010 946 985 1,089 1,093 1,174 153 137 151 159 162 169 109 107 103 122 109 135 1 369 1,407 1 445 1 496 1,590 1,250 862 875 923 913 952 797 507 532 522 583 638 453 1 356 1,381 1 415 1,478 1,567 1,235 140 141 150 155 154 149 53 57 56 58 54 55 1,159 1,189 1 223 1,253 1,222 1,390 155 180 176 185 189 162 1,456 1,537 1,511 1,591 1,364 1,365 912 1,075 920 922 838 790 544 462 591 669 526 575 1,430 1,499 1,479 1,562 1,345 1,348 157 164 149 147 133 137 52 63 63 59 57 54 1,148 1,394 1,416 1,340 1,280 1,281 163 152 160 144 161 157 146 122 131 151 136 125 122 141 127 126 110 120 1,531 1,518 1,592 1,562 1,677 904 867 944 960 885 627 651 648 602 792 1,507 1,496 1,570 1,533 1,649 134 144 145 153 158 49 51 54 55 53 64 1,289 1,290 1,393 1,378 1,390 146 167 168 198 211 184 135 127 125 147 172 135 Dec p 1 Military housing starts, including those financed with mortgages insured by FHA under Section 803 of the National Housing Act, are included in publicly financed starts but excluded from total private starts and from FHA starts. 2 Not available prior to 1959 except for nonfarm for 1929-44. 3 Units are for 1-4 family housing. < Data beginning 1967 cover approximately 13,000 permit-issuing places. Data for 1963-66 are based on 12,000 places and 1959-62,10,000 places. The addition of approximately 1,000 permit-issuing places contributed an increase of 3 percent in 8 total permit authorizations. Units in mortgage applications or appraisal requests for new home construction. 6 FHA program approved in June 1934: all 1934 activity included in 1935. 7 Monthly estimates for September 1945-May 1950 were prepared by Housing and Home Finance Agency. 8 January-December average. Sources: Department of Commerce (Bureau of the Census), Department of Housing and Urban Development, Federal Housing Administration (FHA), and Veterans Administration (VA), except as noted. 275 TABLE B-42.—Sales and inventories in manufacturing and trade, 1947—68 [Amounts in millions of dollars] Total manufacturing and trade Manufacturing Merchant wholesalers Retail trade Year or month Sales i InvenRatio 3 Sales i tories 2 Inventories 2 Ratio 3 Sales i Inven- tories2 Ratio 3 Sales i Inventories 2 Ratio 3 1947.. 1948.. 1949- 35,260 33,788 52,507 49,497 1.42 1.53 15,513 25,897 17,316 28,543 16,126 26,321 1.58 1.57 1.75 6,! 6,514 7,957 7,706 1.13 1.19 10,200 14,241 11,135 16,007 11,149 15,470 1.26 1.39 1.41 1950.. 195U. 1952.. 19531954.. 38,596 43,356 44, 840 47,987 46,443 59,822 70,242 72,377 76,122 73,175 1.36 1.55 1.58 1.58 1.60 18,634 21,714 22,529 24,843 23,355 1.48 1.66 1.78 1.76 1.81 7,695 9,284 8,597 9,886 8,782 10,210 9,052 10,686 8,993 10,637 1.07 1.16 1,12 1.17 1.18 12,268 13,046 13,529 14,091 14,095 19,460 21,050 21,031 21,488 20,926 1.38 1.64 1.52 1.53 1.51 1955.. 1956.. 1957.. 1958.. 1959.. 51,694 54,063 55,879 54,233 59,661 79,516 87,304 89,052 86,922 91,891 1.47 1.55 1.59 .-, .60 .50 26,480 45,069 27,740 50,642 28,736 _-,.--, 51,871 27,280 50,070 30,219 52,707 I960.. 1961.. 1962.. 1963.. 1964.. 60,746 61,133 65,417 68,969 73,685 94,747 95,728 101,149 105, 525 111,548 .56 .54 .51 1.49 1.47 30,796 30,896 33,113 35,032 37,335 53,814 54,943 58,212 60,027 63,370 1.79 1.74 1.72 1.69 1.64 1965... 1966... 1967_.. 1968 4. 80,276 87,184 88,962 97,127 121,140 ,184 137; 143,772 153,193 1.45 1.48 1.58 1.53 41,003 44,876 45,712 50,447 68,179 78,125 82,819 88,182 1.60 15,595 18,274 1.62 16,979 20,691 1.77 17,099 21,635 1.70 18,338 22,523 31,078 39,306 41,136 43,948 41,612 1.62 9,893 1.73 10,513 1.80 10,475 1.84 10,257 1.70 11,491 11,678 13,260 12,730 12,739 13,879 1.13 15,321 22,769 1.19 15,811 23,402 1.23 16,667 24,451 1.24 16,696 24,113 1.15 17,951 25,305 1.43 1.47 1.44 1.43 1.40 11,656 11,988 12,674 13,382 14, 527 14,120 14,488 14.936 16,048 16,977 1.22 18,294 26,813 1.20 18,249 26,297 1.16 19,630 28,001 1.15 20, 556 29,450 1.13 21,822 31,201 1.45 1.44 1.38 1.39 1.40 1.14 1.14 1.22 1.20. 23,677 34,687 25.330 38,368 26,151 39,318 28,342 42,488 1.40 1.44 1.47 1.44 Seasonally adjusted 1967: Jan Feb.... Mar... Apr.— May-.. June— 87,987 87,365 87,664 87,684 87,998 89,292 138,251 138,729 139,149 139,681 139,924 139,866 1.57 1.59 1.59 1.59 1.59 1.57 45,011 44,948 45,021 44,744 45,281 45,579 79,084 79,730 80,128 80,612 81,203 81,119 1.76 1.77 1.78 1.80 1.79 1.78 17,239 16,897 16,853 16,972 16,769 17,117 20,780 20,742 20,859 20,785 20,587 20,599 1.21 1.23 1.24 1.22 1.23 1.20 25,737 25,520 25,790 25,968 25,948 26, 596 38,387 38,257 38,162 38,284 38,134 38,148 1.49 1.50 1.48 1.47 1.47 1.43 July... Aug--_ Sept..Oct.... Nov... Dec.— 88,679 90,135 89,987 89,043 90,759 91,970 140,336 140,895 141,246 141,461 142,554 143,772 1.58 1.56 1.57 1.59 1.57 1.56 45,038 46,471 45,884 45,748; 46,955 47,961 81,478 81,853 81,719 81,968 82,389 82,819 1.81 1.76 1.78 1.79 1.75 1.73 17,145 17.198 17,330 17,195 17,419 17,641 20,511 20,789 20,810 20,945 21,061 21.635 .20 .21 .20 .22 .21 1.23 26,496 26,466 26,773 26,100 26,385 26,368 38,347 38,253 38,717 38,548 39,104 39,318 1.45 1.45 1.45 1.48 1.48 1.49 1.56 1.54 1.53 1.55 1.54 1.52 48,447 48, 356 48,446 48,755 50,014 50,729 82,890 83,408 83,759 84,382 85,278 85, 582 1.71 1.72 1.73 1.73 1.71 1.69 17,694 17,953 18,021 18,006 17,897 18,374 21,641 21,623 21,618 21,863 21,924 22,098 1.22 1.20 1.20 1.21 1.22 1.20 26,936 27,512 28,145 27,675 28,132 28,451 39,575 39,788 39,776 40,242 40,606 40,842 1.47 1.45 1.41 1.45 1.44 1.44 149- 063 1.51 1.54 149,923 1.52 150,725 1.53 152,122 153,193 -..1.53 51,425 49, 825 51,441 52,560 52,685 85,829 86,713 87,109 87,566 88,182 1.67 1.74 1.69 1.67 1.67 18,269 18,498 18, 792 18,418 18,866 22,169 22,200 22,192 22,336 22,523 1.21 1.20 1.18 1.21 1.19 28,802 29,037 28, 863 28,706 28,891 28,273 41,065 41,010 41,424 42,220 42,488 1.43 1.41 1.44 1.47 1.47 1968: Jan._-_ Feb.... Mar... Apr.... May... June... July... Aug... Sept--. Oct.... Nov *._ Dec p... 93,077 144,106 93,821 144,819 94,612 145,153 94,436 146,487 96,043 147,808 97, 554 148, 522 98,496 97,360 99,096 99,684 100,442 T 1 Monthly average for year and total for month. 2 Seasonally adjusted, end of period. 3 Inventory/sales ratio. For annual periods, ratio of weighted average inventories to average monthly sales; for monthly data, ratio of inventories at end of month to sales for month. < Where December data not available, data for year calculated on basis of no change from November. Note.—The inventory figures in this table do not agree with the estimates of change in business inventories included in the gross national product since these figures cover only manufacturing and trade rather than all business, and show inventories in terms of current book value without adjustment for revaluation. Source: Department of Commerce (Office of Business Economics and Bureau of the Census). 276 TABLE B-4r3.—Manufacturers' shipments and inventories, 1947-68 [Millions of dollars] Shipmentsl Inventories 2 Durable goods industries Year or month Total DuraNonble durable goods goods indus- industries tries Materials Work Finand in ished sup- process goods plies Total Total 8,819 25,897 13,061 9,738 28,543 14,662 8,935 26,321 13,060 Nondurable goods industries Total Materials Work Finand in ished sup- process goods plies 1947 1948 1949 15,513 17,316 16,126 6,694 7,579 7,191 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 18,634 21,714 22,529 24,843 23,355 8,845 10,493 11,313 13,349 11,828 9,789 11,221 11,216 11,494 11,527 31,078 39,306 41,136 43,948 41,612 15,539 20,991 23,731 25,878 23,710 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 26,480 27,740 28,736 27,280 30,219 14,071 14,715 15,237 13,572 15,544 12,409 13,025 13,499 13,708 14,675 45,069 50,642 51,871 50,070 52,707 26,405 9,194 10,756 30,447 10,417 12,317 31,728 10,608 12,837 30,095 9,847 12,294 31,839 10,585 12,952 1960 1961 1962 . . 1963 1964 30,796 30,896 33,113 35,032 37,335 15,817 15,544 17,103 18,247 19,634 14,979 15,352 16,010 16,786 17,701 53,814 54,943 58,212 60,027 63,370 32,360 32,518 34,609 35,807 38,433 10,286 10,241 10,803 10,997 11,928 12,780 9,190 13,221 9,056 14,210 9,596 15,000 9,810 16,254 10,251 21,454 9,113 22,425 9,463 23,603 9,837 24,220 9,999 24,937 10,179 2,935 9,353 3,192 9,770 3,303 10,463 3,412 10,809 3,519 11,239 ___. 41,003 22,216 18,788 20,240 20,739 22,753 68,179 78,125 82,819 88,182 42,204 49,797 53,540 57,124 13,285 15,484 15, 592 16,695 18,144 21,976 24,675 26,198 10,775 12,337 13,273 14,231 25,975 28,328 29,279 31, 058 10,478 11,266 11,247 11,557 3,823 4 255 4,496 4,854 11,674 12,807 13,536 14,647 12, 505 12,650 12,778 12,942 13,080 13,105 28,546 28,680 28,788 28,966 29,125 29,084 1965 1966 1967 1968 3 44,876 24,635 - - 45,712 24,973 50,447 27,694 12,836 13,881 13,261 8,966 10,720 7,894 9,721 15,539 18,315 17,405 6,206 18,070 6,040 17,902 8,317 8,167 2,472 2,440 7,409 7,415 18,664 20,195 20,143 19,975 20,868 8,556 8,971 8,775 8,671 9,089 2,571 2,721 2,864 2,800 2,928 7,666 8,622 8,624 8,498 8,857 6,348 7,565 8,125 7,749 8,143 Seasonally adjusted 45,011 44,948 45,021 44,744 45,281 45,579 24,575 24,485 24,516 24,207 24,655 24,979 20,436 20,463 20,505 20,537 20,626 20,600 79,084 79,730 80,128 80,612 81,203 81,119 50, 538 51,050 51,340 51,646 52,078 52,035 15,643 15,667 15,643 15,544 15,460 15,377 22,390 22,733 22,919 23,160 23,538 23,553 11,324 11,337 11,414 11,376 11,427 11,435 4,293 4,309 4,329 4,353 4,364 4,393 12,929 13,034 13,045 13,237 13,334 13,256 Sept__Oct— Nov Dec 45,038 46,471 45,884 45,748 46,955 47,961 24,417 25,759 25,171 24,802 25, 538 26,610 20,621 20,712 20,713 20,946 21,417 21,351 81,478 81,853 81,719 81,968 82,389 82,819 52,461 52,801 52,582 52,867 53,283 53,540 15,479 15,510 15,369 15,446 15,532 15,592 4,371 4,393 4,369 4,396 4,444 4,496 13,200 13,228 13,376 13,385 13,382 13, 536 1968: Jan Feb Mar Apr May.... June 48,447 48,356 48,446 48,755 50,014 50,729 26,925 26,711 26,844 26,888 27,509 27,633 21,522 21,645 21,602 21,867 22,505 23,096 82,890 83,408 83,759 84,382 85,278 85,582 53,525 54,009 54,295 54,724 55,234 55,442 15,489 15,648 15,840 16,071 16,379 16,498 4,482 4,497 4,508 4,522 4,604 4,619 13,577 13,653 13,829 13,909 14,128 14,188 July Aug Sept.... Oct Nov ".— 51,425 49,825 51,441 52,560 52,685 28,211 26,837 27,985 28,960 28,917 23,214 22,988 23,456 23,600 23,768 85,829 86,713 87,109 87, 566 88,182 55,461 56,069 56,458 56,657 57,124 16,753 16,781 16,704 16,763 16,695 23,755 13,227 29,017 11,446 23,905 13,386 29,052 11,431 23,954 13,259 29,137 11,392 24,173 29,101 11,320 24,428 29,106 11,280 24,675 29,279 11,247 13,273 24,641 13,395 29,365 11,306 24,926 13,435 29,399 11,249 25,078 13,377 29,464 11,128 25,214 13,439 29,658 11,228 25,392 13,463 30,044 11,312 25,490 13,454 30,140 11,333 25,237 13,471 30,368 11,366 25,544 13,744 30,644 11,508 25,772 13,982 30,651 11,511 25,825 14,069 30,909 11,609 26,198 14,231 31,058 11,557 4,682 4,729 4,679 4,724 4,854 14,320 14,407 14,461 14,576 14,647 1967: Jan Feb Mar Apr..... May June July Aug $3 1 Monthly average for year and total for month. Book value, seasonally adjusted, end of period. Where December data not available, data for year calculated on basis of no change from November. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 2 3 277 TABLE B-44.—Manufacturers* new and unfilled orders, 1947-68 [Amounts in millions of dollars] New orders1 Unfilled orders 2 Durable goods industries Year or month Nondurable goods industries Total Total Machinery and equipment Total Durable goods industries Nondurable goods industries Unfilled orders-shipments ratio 3 Total Durable goods industries Nondurable goods industries 1947 1948 1949 15,256 17,692 15,614 6,388 8,126 6,633 8,868 9,566 8,981 34,415 30,717 24,506 28,532 26,601 20,018 5,883 4,116 4,488 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 20,110 23,907 23,203 23,533 22,313 10,165 12,841 12,061 12,105 10,743 2,084 1,770 9,945 11,066 11,142 11,428 11,570 43,055 69,785 75,649 61,178 43,266 36,838 65,835 72,480 58,637 45,250 6,217 3,950 3,169 2,541 3,016 3.42 4.12 0.96 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 27,423 28,383 27,514 26,901 30,679 14,954 15,381 14,073 13,170 15,951 2,499 2,870 2,566 2,354 2,878 12,469 13,002 13,441 13,731 14,728 60,004 67,375 53,183 48,882 54,494 56,241 63,880 50,352 45,739 50,654 3,763 3,495 2,831 3,143 3,840 3.63 3.87 3.35 2.60 2.85 4.27 4.55 4.00 3.49 3.44 1.12 1.04 .85 .55 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 30,115 31,085 33,005 35,322 37,952 15,223 15,698 17,026 18,522 20,258 2,791 2,854 3,090 3,412 3,935 14,892 15,387 15,979 16,800 17,694 46,133 48,485 47,351 50,960 58,536 43,401 45,336 44,531 47,980 55,652 2,732 3,149 2,820 2,980 2,884 2.58 2.52 2.46 2.41 2.50 3.21 3.02 2.96 2.89 2.99 .63 .75 .68 .65 .59 41,803 45,938 45,928 50,672 22,986 25,710 25,189 27,924 4,435 5,268 5,250 5,822 18,817 20,228 20,739 22,748 68,208 81,072 83,686 85,684 64,980 77,987 80,578 82,607 3,228 3,085 3,108 3,077 2.63 2.92 2.83 3.13 3.50 3.39 .62 .56 .53 1965... 1966.. 1967 1968* -.- I Seasonally adjusted 1967: Jan.. Feb.. Mar.. Apr_. MayJune. 44.362 44,526 43,966 44,553 45,876 46,332 23,945 24,148 23,540 24,039 25,301 25,768 5,072 5,022 4,982 5,081 5,090 5,376 20,417 20,378 20,426 20,514 20,575 20,564 80,423 80,001 78,946 78,755 79,350 80,103 77,357 77,020 76,044 75,876 76,522 77,311 3,066 2,981 2,902 2,879 2,828 2,792 2.92 2.92 2.88 2.92 2.90 2.90 3.51 3.50 3.46 3.53 3.50 3.48 0.56 .55 .54 .53 .52 .51 July.. Aug.. Sept. Oct.. Nov_. Dec. 45,606 46,654 45,942 46,655 47,320 49,463 24,921 25,879 25,177 25,679 25,852 28,056 5,376 5,471 5,350 5,314 5,372 5,495 20,685 20,775 20,765 20,976 21,468 21,407 80,671 80,854 80,912 81,819 82,184 83,686 77,815 77,935 77,941 78,818 79,132 80,578 2,856 2,919 2,971 3,001 3,052 3,108 2.94 2.84 2.90 2.94 2.86 2.83 3.54 3.40 3.48 3.54 3.44 3.39 .52 .53 .54 .53 .53 .53 1968: Jan.. Feb.. Mar.. Apr.. May.. June. 48,353 48,453 49,566 49,237 49,650 49,850 26,837 26,814 28,005 27,373 27,172 26,701 5,466 5,380 5,382 5,492 5,447 5,968 21,516 21,639 21,561 21,864 22,478 23,149 83,592 83,689 84,809 85,291 84,927 84,048 80,490 80, 593 81,754 82,239 81,902 80,970 3,102 3,096 3,055 3,052 3,025 3,078 2.80 2.79 2.82 2.83 2.78 2.72 3.37 3.36 3.39 3.41 3.36 3.28 .52 .52 .52 .50 .49 .50 50,181 50,201 51,877 53,931 53,384 26,925 27,329 28,381 30,280 29,635 5,714 6,027 5,916 6,550 6,263 23,256 22,872 23,496 23,651 23,749 82,806 83,184 83,617 84,991 85,684 79,684 80,177 80,572 81,894 82,607 3,122 3,007 3,045 3,097 3,077 2.64 2.79 2.67 2.64 2.66 3.17 3.38 3.24 3.19 3.21 .50 .50 .48 .48 .48 July... Aug... Sept.. Oct... Nov *>- 1 Monthly average for year and total for month. 2 Seasonally adjusted, end of period. 3 Ratio of unfilled orders at end of period to shipments for period. Annual figures relate to seasonally adjusted data for December. * Where December data not available, data for year calculated on basis of no change from November. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 278 PRICES TABLE B^-5.—Consumer price indexes, by major groups, 1929-68 For city wage earners and clerical workers [1957-59 = 100) Housing Year or month All ems Food Total Rent Apparel and upkeep Transportation Medical care 'ersonal care Reading Other and goods recreaand tion services 1929.. 59.7 55.6 85.4 55.3 1930.. 1931.. 1932.. 1933.. 1934.. 1935.. 1936.. 1937.. 1938.. 1939.. 58.2 53.0 47.6 45.1 46.6 47.8 48.3 50.0 49.1 48.4 52.9 43.6 36.3 35.3 39.3 42.1 42.5 44.2 41.0 39.9 56.3 57.1 59.1 60.1 59.7 83.1 78.7 70.6 60.8 57.0 56.9 58.3 60.9 62.9 63.0 54.1 49.2 43.6 42.1 46.1 46.5 46.9 49.3 49.0 48.3 49.4 49.8 50.6 51.0 49.8 49.4 49.6 50.0 50.2 50.2 42.6 43.2 45.7 46.7 46.5 50.2 51.0 52.5 54.3 54.4 52.7 52.6 54.0 54.5 55.4 1940.. 1941.. 1942.. 1943.. 1944.. 1945, 1946-. 1947. 1948. 1949- 48.8 51.3 56.8 60.3 61.3 62.7 68.0 77.8 83.8 83.0 40.5 44.2 51.9 57.9 57.1 58.4 66.9 81.3 88.2 84.7 59.9 61.4 64.2 64.9 66.4 67.5 69.3 74.5 79.8 81.0 63.2 64.3 65.7 65.7 65.9 66.1 66.5 68.7 73.2 76.4 48.8 51.1 59.6 62.2 66.7 70.1 76.9 89.2 95.0 91.3 49.5 51.2 55.7 55.5 55.5 55.4 58.3 64.3 71.6 77.0 50.3 50.6 52.0 54.5 56.2 57.5 60.7 65.7 69.8 72.0 46.4 47.6 52.2 57.6 61.7 63.6 68.2 76.2 79.1 78.9 55.4 57.3 60.0 65.0 72.0 75.0 77.5 82.5 86.7 89.9 57.1 58.2 59.9 63.0 64.7 67.3 69. r 75.4 78.9 81.2 1950. 1951. 1952, 1953. 1954, 1955. 1956. 1957. 1958. 1959. 83.8 90.5 92.5 93.2 93.6 93.3 94.7 98.0 100.7 101.5 85.8 95.4 97.1 95.6 95.4 94.0 94.7 97.8 101.9 100.3 83.2 88.2 89.9 92.3 93.4 94.1 95.5 98.5 100.2 101.3 79.1 82.3 85.7 90.3 93.5 94.8 96.5 98.3 100.1 101.6 90.1 98.2 97.2 96.5 96.3 95.9 97.8 99.5 99.8 100.6 79.0 84.0 89.6 92.1 90.8 89.7 91.3 96.5 99.7 103.8 73.4 76.9 81.1 83.9 86.6 88.6 91.8 95.5 100.1 104.4 78.9 86.3 87.3 88.1 88.5 90.0 93.7 97.1 100.4 102.4 89.3 92.0 92.4 93.3 92.4 92.1 93.4 96.9 100.8 102.4 82.6 86.1 90.6 92.8 94.3 94.3 95.8 98.5 99.8 101.8 1960--. 1961... 1962... 1963.-. 1964... 1965... 1966.. 1967-.. 1968 1.. 103.1 104.2 105.4 106.7 108.1 109.9 113.1 116.3 120.9 101.4 102.6 103.6 105.1 106.4 108.8 114.2 115.2 119.2 103.1 103.9 104.8 106.0 107.2 108.5 111.1 114.3 118.8 103.1 104.4 105.7 106.8 107.8 108.9 110.4 112.4 114.9 102.2 103.0 103.6 104.8 105.7 106.8 109.6 114.0 119.8 103.8 105.0 107.2 107.8 109.3 111.1 112.7 115.9 119.6 108.1 111.3 114.2 117.0 119.4 122.3 127.7 136.7 144.6 104.1 104.6 106.5 107.9 109.2 109.9 112.2 115.5 120.0 104.9 107.2 109.6 111.5 114.1 115.2 117.1 120.1 125.5 103.8 104.6 105.3 107.1 108.8 111.4 114.9 118.2 123.5 1967: Jan.. Feb.. Mar.. Apr.. May.. June. 114.7 114.8 115.0 115.3 115.6 116.0 114.7 114.2 114.2 113.7 113.9 115.1 113.1 113.3 113.3 113.6 113.9 114.1 111.4 111.7 111.8 111.9 112.1 112.2 111.3 111.9 112.6 113.0 113.8 113.9 113.4 113.8 114.2 115.1 115.5 115.7 132.9 133.6 134.6 135.1 135.7 136.3 113.8 114.1 114.4 114.9 115.0 115.3 118.5 118.6 118.9 119.4 119.6 119.7 116.2 116.3 116.4 116.6 116.7 116.9 July.. Aug.. Sept.. Oct... Nov.. Dec. 116.5 116.9 117.1 117.5 117.8 118.2 116.0 116.6 115.9 115.7 115.6 116.2 114.3 114.7 115.0 115.3 115.5 116.0 112.4 112.6 112.8 113.0 113.2 113.5 113.7 113.8 115.1 116.0 116.6 116.8 116.2 116.4 116.8 117.7 118.3 117.9 136.9 137.5 138.5 139.0 139.7 140.4 115.5 116.1 116.4 116.5 116.9 117.2 119.8 120.0 120.5 121.4 122.0 122.2 117.8 118.8 119.7 120.3 121.0 121.4 Jan.. Feb.. Mar.. Apr_. May__ JuneJuly.. Aug.. Sept. Oct.. Nov.. 118.6 119.0 119.5 119.9 120.3 120.9 117.0 117.4 117.9 118.3 118.8 119.1 116.4 116.9 117.2 117.5 117.8 118.7 113.7 113.9 114.2 114.4 114.6 114.9 115.9 116.6 117.6 118.4 119.5 119.9 118.7 118.6 119.0 119.0 119.1 119.7 141.2 141.9 142.9 143.5 144.0 144.4 117.6 117.6 118.4 119.0 119.6 120.1 122.7 123.0 124.2 124.9 125.3 125.6 121.9 122.1 122.4 122.5 122.6 123.5 121.5 121.9 122.2 122.9 123.4 120.0 120.5 120.4 120.9 120.5 119.5 120.1 120.4 120.9 121.7 115.1 115.4 115.7 116.0 116.3 119.7 120.3 122.2 123.3 124.0 119.8 120.0 119.5 120.6 121.2 145.1 145.5 146.4 147.4 148.2 120.4 120.9 121.5 122.1 122.8 125.9 126.3 126.7 127.5 128.0 123.9 124.2 124.4 125.1 125.4 1968: i January-November average. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 279 TABLE B-46.—Consumer price indexes, by special groups, 1935-68 For city wage earners and clerical workers [1957-59=100] Commodities Year or month All items All items less food All items less shelter Services Commodities less food All commodities Food Ail Durable Nondurable Total nondurable All ;ervices Rent Ail services less rent 47.8 48.3 50.0 49.1 48.4 52.5 53.0 54.9 55.5 55.1 46.1 46.7 48.2 46.8 46.0 45.0 45.6 47.4 45.6 44.7 42.1 42.5 44.2 41.0 39.9 50.2 50.8 53.0 53.0 52.1 47.1 47.8 50.8 51.7 50.6 48.8 49.2 51.2 50.9 50.1 44.5 45.1 46.8 44.7 43.8 52.2 52.8 54.4 55.4 55.5 56.9 58.3 60.9 62.9 63.0 49.3 49.0 49.5 49.9 49.9 48.8 51.3 56.8 60.3 61.3 62.7 68.0 77.8 83.8 83.0 55.3 56.9 60.9 62.6 65.0 66.5 69.4 75.8 81.3 82.1 46.3 49.1 55.3 59.5 60.5 62.1 68.4 79.4 85.6 84.1 45.1 48.2 55.2 60.1 60.8 62.6 69.4 83.4 89.4 87.1 40.5 44.2 51.9 57.9 57.1 58.4 66.9 81.3 88.2 84.7 52.4 55.0 61.2 63.8 67.3 70.0 74.4 83.9 90.3 89.0 50.2 53.6 60.9 62.9 68.7 73.9 77.3 83.8 89.9 91.2 50.6 52.8 58.4 60.9 64.0 66.3 71.1 81.7 88.0 86.3 44.3 47.4 54.3 59.0 59.5 61.2 68.0 82.0 88.0 85.4 55.7 56.4 58.2 59.3 60.7 61.5 62.7 65.3 69.4 72.6 63.2 64.3 65.7 65.7 65.9 66.1 66.5 68.7 73.2 76.4 50.0 50.6 52.8 55.2 57.9 59.1 61.2 64.3 68.0 71.4 83,8 90.5 92.5 93.2 93.6 93.3 94.7 98.0 100.7 101.5 83.1 88.4 90.5 92.3 92.8 93.1 94.7 97.9 100.1 102.0 84.7 91.8 93.6 93.9 93.9 93.4 94.7 97.8 100.7 101.5 87.6 95.5 96.7 96.4 95.5 94.6 95.5 98.5 100.8 100.9 85.8 95.4 97.1 95.6 95.4 94.0 94.7 97.8 101.9 100.3 88.9 95.6 96.4 96.6 95.6 94.9 95.9 98.8 99.9 101.2 92.2 99.2 100.5 99.8 97.3 95.4 95.4 98.5 100.0 101.5 86.2 92.7 93.2 94.0 94.4 94.4 96.5 99.1 99.8 101.0 85.9 94.0 95.1 94.9 94.8 94.1 95.4 98.4 101.0 100.6 75.0 78.9 82.4 86.0 88.7 90.5 92.8 96.6 100.3 103.2 79.1 82.3 85.7 90.3 93.5 94.8 96.5 98.3 100.1 101.6 73.4 77.8 81.5 84.9 87.4 89.4 91.9 96.1 100.2 103.6 103.1 104.2 105.4 106.7 108.1 109.9 113.1 116.3 120.9 103.7 104.8 106.1 107.4 108.9 110.4 113.0 116.8 121.7 103,0 104.2 105.4 106.7 108.0 109.6 112.9 115.9 120.4 101.7 102.3 103.2 104.1 105.2 106.4 109.2 111.2 115.1 101.4 102.6 103.6 105.1 106.4 108.8 114.2 115.2 119.2 101.7 102. 0 102.8 103.5 104.4 105.1 106.5 109.2 113.0 100.9 100.8 101.8 102.1 103.0 102.6 102.7 104.3 107.4 102.6 103.2 103.8 104.8 105.7 107.2 109.7 113.1 117.5 101.9 102.8 103.6 104.9 106.0 107.9 111.8 114.0 118.2 106.6 108.8 110.9 113.0 115.2 117.8 122.3 127.7 134.0 103.1 104.4 105.7 106.8 107.8 108.9 110.4 112.4 114.9 107.4 110.0 112.1 114.5 117.0 120.0 125.0 131.1 138.2 114.7 114.8 115.0 115.3 115.6 116.0 114.8 115.2 115.4 115.9 116.3 116.5 114.2 114.3 114.6 114.8 115.1 115.6 109.9 109.9 110.0 110.2 110.5 111.0 114.7 114.2 114.2 113.7 113.9 115.1 107.3 107.6 107.8 108.4 108.7 108.9 102.7 102.8 102.9 103.4 103.9 104.1 111.0 111.5 111.8 112.4 112.7 112.7 112.7 112.7 112.9 113.0 113.2 113.8 125.5 125.9 126.3 126.6 127.0 127.4 111.4 111.7 111.8 111.9 112.1 112.2 128.8 129.2 129.5 130.0 130.4 130.8 116.5 116.9 117.1 117.5 117.8 118.2 116.8 117.1 117.7 118.2 118.7 118.9 116.1 116.5 116.7 117.1 117.5 117.7 111.5 111.9 112.0 112.4 112.6 112.9 116.0 116.6 115.9 115.7 115.6 116.2 109.1 109.4 110.0 110.6 111.1 111.1 104.4 104.7 104.8 105.7 106.0 106.1 112.8 113.2 114.1 114.5 115.2 115.2 114.3 114.8 114.9 115.1 115.3 115.6 127.7 128.2 128.7 129.1 129.6 130.1 112.4 112.6 112.8 113.0 113.2 113.5 131.2 131.7 132.3 132.7 133.2 133.8 118.6 119.0 119.5 119.9 , 120.3 | 120.9 119.3 119.7 120.2 120.6 121.0 121.6 118.2 118.5 119.1 119.6 120.0 120.4 113.2 113.5 113.9 114.3 114.7 115.1 117.0 117.4 117.9 118.3 118.8 119.1 111.2 111.5 111.9 112.2 112.5 113.0 106.3 106.4 106.6 106.9 106.9 107.4 115.1 115.6 116.1 116.4 117.0 117.5 116.0 116.4 116.9 117.3 117.8 118.2 130.8 131.3 132.1 132.5 133.0 133.9 113.7 113.9 114.2 114.4 114=6 114.9 134.6 135.2 136.1 136.6 137.1 138.1 121.5 121.9 122.2 122.9 123.4 122.1 122.6 123.0 123.8 124.4 120.8 121.2 121.5 122.2 122.5 115.5 115.9 116.1 116.8 117.1 120.0 120.5 120.4 120.9 120.5 113.2 113.5 113.9 114.7 115.3 107.6 107.7 107.6 108.5 109.3 117.6 118.1 118.9 119.7 120.2 118.7 119.2 119.6 120.2 120.3 134.9 135.5 136.0 136.6 137.4 115.1 115.4 115.7 116.0 116.3 139.3 140.0 140.5 141.2 142.0 1 January-November average. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 28O TABLE B-47.—Consumer price indexes, selected commodities and services, 1935-68 For city wage earners and clerical workers (1957-59 = 100) Nondurable commodities less food Durable commodities Year or month Services less rent NonHouse- Trans- MedHouse- House Apparel durahold porta- ical bles Used hold furcomcare Other* tion less Total services cars dura- nish- Total modserv- servfood less ings bles ities ices ices and rent apparel Total i New cars 1935 1936 . . . 1937 1938 1939 . . . 47.1 47.8 50.8 51.7 50.6 40.3 40.6 41 4 43.4 42.4 51.2 52.1 56 7 56 7 55.6 48.0 48.8 52 8 52 4 51.3 48.8 49.2 51 2 50.9 50.1 46.7 47.2 49 8 49 4 48.6 51.4 51.9 53 2 53.1 52.4 49.3 49.0 49 5 49.9 49.9 46.6 46.2 45.9 46.2 46.4 46.3 46.5 47.1 47.2 47.3 1940 1941 . . . 1942 1943 1944 . 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 50.2 53.6 60.9 62.9 68.7 73.9 77.3 83.8 89.9 91.2 42.5 45.7 67.9 74.2 81.2 54.9 58.7 65.7 68.2 74.6 80.3 84.9 93.9 99.9 97.2 50.9 54 4 61.9 63.6 69.1 73.9 80.6 93 4 99.1 95.7 50.6 52.8 58.4 60.9 64.0 66.3 71.1 81.7 88.0 86.3 49.2 51.7 60.4 63.2 67 6 71.2 78.5 90 9 96.5 92.7 52.9 54.7 57.8 60.2 61.9 63.1 65.8 74.9 81.8 81.9 50.0 50.6 52.8 55.2 57.9 59.1 61.2 64.3 68.0 71.4 46.3 46.6 49 1 49.1 49.0 49.1 50 1 51.7 57.7 64.2 47.3 47.6 49.0 51.6 53.7 55.2 58.4 63.3 67.6 70.1 1950 1951 . 1952 1953 1954 . . 1955 1956 1957 . 1958 1959 92.2 81.8 99.2 85.7 100.5 93.1 99.8 94.0 108.4 97.3 92.5 92.2 95.4 89.2 87.2 95.4 91.7 83.9 98.5 96.5 94.0 100.0 99.6 97.4 101.5 103.9 108.8 98.4 107 8 105.0 103.8 101.0 98.3 97.9 99.6 100.3 100.2 96.3 86.2 106 8 92.7 104.2 93.2 103.7 94.0 101.9 94.4 100.0 94.4 98.9 96.5 100.5 99.1 99.8 99.8 99.8 101.0 91.6 100 2 99.1 98.0 97.5 97.0 98.6 99.7 99.7 100.6 82.5 73.4 87 6 77.8 89.3 81.5 91.6 84.9 92.5 87.4 92.8 89.4 95.1 91.9 98.8 96.1 99.9 100.2 101.3 103.6 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 . . . 1965 1966 . 1967 1968 3 100.9 100.8 101.8 102.1 103.0 102.6 102.7 104.3 107.4 102.5 102.5 102.1 101.5 101.2 99.0 97.2 98.1 100.6 101.6 105.6 115.2 116.6 121.6 120.8 117.8 121.5 100.1 98.9 98.8 98.5 98 4 96.9 96.8 98.2 101.2 100.1 99.5 98.9 98.5 98 4 97.9 98.8 100.8 104.6 102.6 103.2 103.8 104.8 105.7 107.2 109.7 113.1 117.5 102.0 102.6 103.0 104.0 104 9 105.8 108.5 113.0 118.9 102.8 103.3 104.2 105.3 106.2 108.0 110.3 113.1 116.6 1967: Jan___ Feb... Mar.._ Apr__. May... June.. 102.7 102.8 102.9 103.4 103.9 104.1 97.6 97.3 97.2 97.0 96.9 96.8 113.0 114.0 115.9 118.8 121.4 122.4 97.6 97.7 97.8 98.0 98.1 98.0 99.7 100.0 100.3 100.6 100.6 100.7 111.0 111.5 111.8 112.4 112.7 112.7 110.1 110.7 111.5 111.9 112.7 112.8 104.4 97.0 124.8 104.7 96.9 125.2 104.8 96.1 126.2 105.7 101.1 126.0 106.0 101.4 125.6 106.1 101.3 124.8 98.1 98.2 98.4 98.7 98.8 99.1 100.8 100.8 101.2 101.5 101.8 102.1 112.8 113.2 114.1 114.5 115.2 115.2 99.6 99.9 100.4 126." 3" 100.8 126.7 101.1 101.3 102.6 103.1 103.8 104.2 104.4 104.7 107.6 99.8 101.5 107.7 99.1 101.6 107.6 98.4 126.7" 102.0 108.5 102.8 102.3 109.3 103.8 102.8 104.8 104.9 105.4 105.9 106.5 July... Aug... Sept.. Oct... Nov... Dec.. 1968: J a n . . . Feb... Mar... Apr... May... June.. July... Aug... Sept.. Oct... Nov... 106.3 106.4 106.6 106.9 106.9 107.4 101.0 100.8 100.6 100.3 100.3 100.1 125.8 123.6 90.4 95.7 100.8 103.6 68.4 71.7 74.8 75.3 80.1 80.1 85 2 83.0 88.9 85.5 89 1 88.0 90.5 91.4 94.8 95.3 100.8 100.0 104.3 104.8 93.5 97.2 100.2 102.6 107.4 110.0 112.1 114.5 117.0 120.0 125.0 131.1 138.2 108.0 109.2 110.6 113.0 114.8 117.0 121.5 127.0 134.0 107.0 109.5 111.2 112.4 115.0 119.3 124.3 128.4 133.2 109.1 113.1 116.8 120.3 123.2 127.1 133.9 145.6 155.8 106.2 109.7 112.6 115.3 118.5 121.8 126.5 131.5 138.5 111.6 111.9 112.0 112.7 112.6 112.7 128.8 129.2 129.5 130.0 130.4 130.8 125.1 125.5 125.6 126.0 126.5 126.7 126.9 127.2 127.4 127.6 127.7 128.1 140.6 141.6 142.9 143.6 144.4 145.2 129.1 129.4 129.7 130.3 130.8 131.3 112.6 112.7 114.1 115.1 115.7 115.9 113.0 113.4 114.1 114.2 114.8 114.7 131.2 131.7 132.3 132.7 133.2 133.8 127.0 127.5 128.1 128.4 128.6 129.1 128.3 128.8 128.9 129.2 130.0 130.4 146.0 146.7 148.0 148.7 149.6 150.4 131.6 131.9 132.4 133.1 133.9 134.3 115.1 115.6 116.1 116.4 117.0 117.5 114.8 115.6 116.6 117.6 118.7 119.1 115.3 115.5 115.8 115.8 116.0 116.6 134.6 135.2 136.1 136.6 137.1 138.1 129.9 130.6 131.1 131.5 132.1 133.7 131.5 131.9 132.4 132.7 132,9 133.3 151.4 152.3 153.6 154.3 155.0 155.5 134.8 135.3 137.0 137.6 138.3 138.9 117.6 118.1 118.9 119.7 120.2 118.9 119.5 121.5 122.7 123.4 116.9 117.3 117.4 117.9 118.3 139.3 140.0 140.5 141.2 142.0 135.6 136.7 137.0 137.6 138.5 133.5 133,6 133.8 134.6 135.2 156.6 157.1 158.2 159.4 160.3 139.2 139.7 140.3 140.9 141.5 '1ncludes certain items not shown separately. 3 Includes the services components of apparel, personal care, reading and recreation, and other goods and services. ' January-November average. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 28l TABLE B-48.— Wholesale price indexes, by major commodity groups, 1929-68 [1957-59 = 100] Industrial commodities All commodities Year or month Farm products Processed foods and feeds Total Textile products and apparel Hides, skins, leather, and related products Fuels and related products, and power Chemicals and allied products 1929 52.1 63.9 51 7 56.6 61.5 1930 1931 - - _ . 1932 1933 1934 1935 . . 1936 1937 1938 1939 . . . . . . . 47.3 39.9 35.6 36.1 41.0 43.8 44.2 47.2 43.0 42.2 54.0 39.6 29.4 31.3 39 9 48.0 49.4 52.7 41 9 39.9 48.1 42.4 39.7 40 2 44 2 44.0 44.9 48.1 46 1 46.0 52.0 44 7 38.0 42.0 44 9 46 5 49.5 54.3 48 2 49.6 58.2 50 0 52.1 49.3 54 3 54 5 56.5 57.5 56 6 54.2 46.6 48 8 50 9 51.2 53.6 51 0 50.7 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 43.0 47.8 54.0 56.5 56.9 57.9 66.1 81.2 87.9 83.5 41.3 50 1 64.6 74.8 75 3 78.3 90.6 109.1 117.1 101.3 92.6 99.1 90.0 46.8 50 3 53.9 54.7 55 6 56.3 61.7 75.3 81.7 80.0 105.7 110.3 100.9 52.3 56 1 61 1 61.0 60 5 61 3 70.7 96.5 97.5 92.5 53.2 56 6 58 2 59.9 61 6 62 3 66.7 79.7 93.8 89.3 51.6 56 1 62 3 63.1 63 8 64 2 69.4 92.2 94.4 86.2 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 86.8 96.7 94.0 92.7 92.9 93.2 96.2 99.0 100.4 100.6 106.4 123.8 116.8 105.9 104.4 97.9 96.6 99.2 103.6 97.2 93.2 103.5 102.3 97.6 99.3 95.0 94.8 97.6 102.5 99.9 82.9 91.5 89.4 90.1 90.4 92.4 96.5 99.2 99.5 101.3 104.8 116.9 105.5 102.8 100.6 100.7 100 7 100.8 98.9 100.4 99.9 114.8 92.8 94.1 89.9 89.5 94 8 94.9 96.0 109.1 90.2 93.5 93.3 95.9 94.6 94.5 97 4 102.7 98.7 98.7 87.5 100.1 95.0 96.1 97.3 96.9 97.5 99.6 100.4 100.0 100.7 100.3 100.6 100.3 100.5 102.5 105.9 106.1 108.7 96.9 96.0 97.7 95.7 94.3 98.4 105.6 99 7 102.2 100.0 101.6 102.7 103.3 103.1 106.7 113.0 111.7 114.1 101.3 100.8 100.8 100.7 101.2 102.5 104.7 106 3 109.0 101.5 99.7 100 6 100.5 101.2 101.8 102.1 102 1 105.5 105.2 106.2 107 4 104.2 104.6 109.2 119.7 115 8 119.2 99.6 100.7 100.2 99.8 97.1 98.9 101.3 103 6 102.5 100.2 99.1 97.5 96.3 96.7 97.4 97.8 98.4 98.2 106.2 106.0 105.7 105.3 105.8 106.3 102.6 101.0 99.6 97.6 100.7 102.4 112.8 111.7 110.6 110.0 110.7 112.6 105.8 106.0 106.0 106.0 106.0 106.0 102.0 102.0 101.8 101.8 101.6 101.6 117.9 118.0 116.9 115.7 115.2 115.6 102.6 103.4 103.7 103.3 104.4 104.0 98.4 98.5 98.5 98.8 98.8 98.5 106.5 106.1 106.2 106.1 106.2 106.8 102.8 99.2 98.4 97.1 96.4 98.9 113.1 112.1 112.7 111.7 110.9 111.5 106.0 106.3 106.5 106.8 107.1 107.4 101.5 101.7 102.0 102 2 103.0 103.8 115.2 114.4 114.4 114 8 115.4 116.0 103.9 104.7 104.5 103.0 102.8 102.6 98.3 98.0 97.9 98.2 98.2 98.4 107.2 108.0 108.2 108.3 108.5 108.7 99.0 101.3 102.1 102.1 103.6 102.5 112.4 113.3 112.9 112.8 113.6 114.6 107.8 108.3 108.6 108.8 108.6 108.8 104.3 104.6 104.6 104.7 104.8 105.2 116.5 116.7 117.9 118.3 118.8 118.7 101.8 102.5 102.0 102.4 102.4 103.7 98.2 98.1 98.6 98.8 98.7 98.5 109.1 108.7 109.1 109.1 109.6 109.8 103.9 101.4 102.8 101.2 103.1 103.3 115.9 114.9 115.3 114.4 114.7 114.7 108.8 103.9 109.2 109.7 109.9 110.2 105.8 106.0 106.5 107.0 107.2 119.5 119.5 120.7 122.3 122.4 103.3 102.6 102.5 101.9 102.0 98.2 98.1 97.9 97.8 97.8 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 2 . .. . . . .. .. 1967: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July.. Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 1968: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June ._ July Aug_ . . . Sept Oct . Nov Dec P. See footnotes at end of table. 282 TABLE B-48.— Wholesale price indexes, by major commodity groups, 1929-68—Continued [1957-59=1001 Industrial commodities—Continued Year or month Pulp, paper, and allied products Furnitureand household durables Transportation equipment: Motor vehicles and equipment 1 Rubber and rubber products Lumber and wood products 1929 57.6 26.4 44.1 56.4 53.4 42.8 1930 1931 1932. 1933 1934 1935 1936.. 1937 1938 1939 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960. 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 2 50.4 42.8 37.1 39.0 45.5 45.8 49.4 58.1 57.1 59.3 55.3 59.6 69.4 71.3 70.4 68.3 68.6 68.3 70.5 68.3 24.1 19.6 16.9 20.0 23.5 22.6 23.6 27.9 25.4 26.1 28.9 34.5 37.5 39.7 42.8 43.4 49.7 77.4 88.5 81.9 94.1 102.5 99.5 99.4 97.6 102.3 103.8 98.5 97.4 104.1 100.4 95.9 96.5 98.6 100.6 101.1 105.6 105.4 118.0 102.6 103.6 103.6 104.1 104.2 104.7 105.3 106.1 108.7 107.3 106.7 107.6 39.7 35.7 32. 33.6 37.1 37.0 37.8 43.2 41.6 41.2 41.4 42.2 42.8 42.7 42.7 43.4 48.5 60.2 68.5 69.0 72.7 80.9 81.0 83.6 84.3 90.0 97.8 99.7 99.1 101.2 101.3 100.7 100.0 100.1 102.8 105.7 108.3 109.6 112.3 55.5 51.1 45.0 45.1 49.0 48.6 49.3 54.7 53.4 53.2 54.4 57.8 62.5 62.1 63.8 63.9 67.8 77.8 82.5 83.8 85.6 92.8 91.1 92.9 93.9 94.3 96.9 99.4 100.2 100.4 100.1 99.5 98.8 98.1 98.5 98.0 99.1 101.0 104.0 53.2 49.7 46.5 49.2 52.6 52.6 52.7 53.9 52.2 51.2 51.2 52.4 54.5 54.7 55.8 58.1 61.8 69.1 74.7 76.7 78.6 83.5 83.5 86.9 88.8 91.3 95.2 98.9 99.9 101.2 101.4 101.8 101.8 101.3 101.5 101.7 102.6 104.3 108.0 40.3 38.3 37.3 35.6 37.5 36.0 35.7 38.2 40.8 40.0 41.3 44.2 48.2 48.2 48.5 49.4 57.2 65.5 72.4 77.4 100.4 100.4 100.6 100.6 100.8 100.8 83.2 102.1 92.5 86.3 87.6 99.2 100.6 100.2 100.1 99.7 99.9 96.1 93.3 93.8 92.5 92.9 94.8 97.0 100.2 1967: Jan... Feb... Mar.. Apr... May.. June.. July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 1968: Jan... Feb... Mar.. Apr... May.. June. July.. Aug.. Sept.. Oct... Nov.. Dec p. 95.6 95.8 95.9 95.9 95.8 95.8 95.8 97.8 98.2 98.8 99.1 99.2 99.5 99.5 99.7 99.7 99.8 99.9 100.7 100.6 100.7 101.0 101.1 75.3 78.6 75.2 108.6 111.6 113.9 115.8 117.0 117.2 77.1 91.3 89.0 88.7 88.8 91.1 97.2 99.0 100.1 101.0 101.8 98.8 100.0 99.2 99.0 99.9 102.6 104.0 105.2 103.1 103.3 103.6 103.9 103.9 103.9 104.1 104.0 104.1 104.3 104.6 104.8 105.2 105.7 105.2 105.2 105.5 104.7 119.2 120.5 122.6 124.9 126.8 104.9 104.9 105.1 105.2 105.2 Metals and metal products Machinery and equipment 109.4 109.6 109.4 109.1 108.9 108.8 46.3 47.1 47.8 47.4 47.1 47.2 51.9 60.0 65.1 68.2 70.5 78.8 78.9 80.7 82.1 84.6 91.5 97.9 100.0 102.1 102.9 102.9 102.9 103.1 103.8 105.0 108.2 111.8 115.1 108.9 109.2 109.5 109.9 111.0 111.4 112.2 113.3 113.8 113.3 111.7 111.7 111.1 111.2 111.5 111.6 111.6 111.6 111.6 111.8 111.9 112.2 112.6 113.2 100.9 101.0 101.2 101.7 102.0 102.1 113.9 114.1 114.3 114.8 115.0 115.0 103.0 103.3 103.6 103.8 104.0 103.9 103.6 103.7 103.8 103.9 103.8 103.9 104.2 104.5 104.7 104.9 105.1 105.3 106.0 106.9 107.3 107.4 107.8 108.3 111.4 111.3 112.2 112.5 112.4 115.2 115.4 115.8 116.1 116.6 104.1 104.2 104.4 104.5 104.7 108.4 108.7 108.7 108.9 109.2 1 Index tor total transportation equipment not available. 2 Where December data not available, January-November average. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 46.2 Nonmetallic mineral products 283 77.0 81.1 85.8 85.4 85.6 88.2 93.2 97.2 100.3 102.5 101.0 100.8 100.8 100.0 100.5 100.7 100.8 102.1 104.7 101.6 101.6 101.6 101.6 101.6 101.4 101.3 101.3 101.5 103.7 104.0 104.0 104.3 104.3 104.3 104.3 104.2 104.5 104.2 104.4 104.1 106.5 106.6 Miscellaneous products 80.3 83.6 85.2 86.6 91.7 91.2 93.6 94.4 94.5 95.8 98.6 100.6 100.8 101.7 102.0 102.4 103.3 104.1 104.8 106.8 109.2 111.7 107.9 108.0 107.7 108.0 108.0 109.6 109.7 110.0 110.2 110.5 110.6 110. 7 111.0 111.3 111.5 111.8 111.8 111.8 111.5 111.6 111.9 112.0 112.5 TABLE B-49.—Wholesale price indexes, by stage of processing, 1947-68 [1957-59=100) Intermediate materials, supplies, and componentsl Crude materials Year or month Ail commodities Materials and components for manufacturing .1 Total Foodstuffs and feedstuffs Nonfood materials, except fuel Fuel Total Materials for food Total manufacturing Materials for nondurable manufacturing Materials for durable manufacturing Materials and Com- components ponents for for conmanu- strucfactur- tion ing 1947 . 1948 1949 81.2 87.9 83.5 100.8 110.5 95.6 113.0 122.2 101.5 86.5 96.2 87.5 73.6 87.0 86.5 76.5 82.7 79.4 75.5 81.5 78.0 102.6 105.8 91.0 94.0 99.5 90.7 58.8 66.4 68.2 63.0 68.0 69.3 69.6 77.0 77.2 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 86.8 96.7 94.0 92.7 92.9 104.2 119.6 109.9 101.5 100.6 108.9 126.0 118.6 106.2 106.2 100.0 115.3 99.9 95.6 93.8 86.1 87.7 88.3 91.4 87.3 83.0 93.0 90.3 90.8 91.3 81.8 92.7 88.8 90.2 90.4 94.7 105.5 101.4 101.6 100.7 95.2 110.3 99.3 98.5 96.9 72.1 80.1 80.3 83.9 85.7 71.9 81.6 81.8 83.3 83.7 81.2 88.8 88.2 89.7 90.1 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 93.2 96.2 99.0 100.4 100.6 96.7 97.2 99.4 101.6 99.0 96.2 94.2 98.4 104.2 97.4 99.1 102.8 101.4 97.6 101.0 87.1 93.3 98.6 99.8 101.6 93.0 97.1 99.4 99.6 101.0 92.6 96.9 99.3 99.7 101.0 97.5 97.9 99.7 102.0 98.3 97.3 98.8 100.1 99.1 100.8 90.0 95.7 98.8 99.5 101.8 87.4 95.4 99.1 99.9 101.1 93.7 98.5 99.1 99.1 101.8 1960 1961 1962 1963— 1964 100.7 100.3 100.6 100.3 100.5 96.6 96.1 97.1 95.0 94.1 96.2 94.9 96.8 94.0 91.9 96.8 97.9 97.4 96.2 97.8 102.5 102.3 101.8 103.0 102.5 101.0 100.3 100.2 100.5 100.9 101.0 99.8 99.2 99.4 100.4 99.5 102.6 100.5 105.5 104.0 100.8 98.6 98.0 97.1 97.8 101.9 100.5 100.4 100.5 102.5 100.6 99.6 98.8 98.8 99.7 101.1 99.7 99.3 99.6 100.6 1965_. 1966 1967 19684 _ _. 102.5 105.9 106.1 _ _ 108.7 98.9 105.3 99.6 101.1 98.3 107.2 101.2 102.5 99.8 101.9 95.5 97.5 103.3 106.4 110.3 112.5 102.2 104.8 105.6 107.9 102.0 104.0 104.8 107.0 106.6 111.3 109.2 110.6 98.7 99.5 99.0 100.1 104.6 106.6 108.1 111.6 101.3 104.9 107.9 110.4 101.4 104.1 105.4 110.3 1967: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June 106.2 106.0 105.7 105.3 105.8 106.3 101.9 100.8 99.7 98.0 100.6 101.4 104.2 102.7 101.3 99.2 103.1 104.2 97.0 96.5 95.7 94.6 94.7 95.1 109.4 109.3 109.4 110.2 110.3 109.8 105.6 105.5 105.5 105.5 105.3 105.4 104.7 104.8 104.6 104.6 104.4 104.4 110.1 109.0 108.7 108.1 109.1 110.2 99.3 99.3 99.1 99.1 98.9 98.6 107.6 107.9 107.7 107.6 107.4 107.4 107.5 107.6 107.9 107.9 107.6 107.5 104.4 104.7 104.8 104.9 104.8 104.9 July Aug Sept Oct_ Nov Dec 106.5 106.1 106.2 106.1 106.2 106.8 101.7 99.5 98.5 97.9 96.5 98.6 104.7 101.4 99.9 99.1 96.1 98.3 94 6 94.5 94.3 94.2 95.9 98.4 110.2 110.3 111.0 110.9 111.3 111.5 105.4 105.4 105.7 105.7 106.1 106.5 104.4 104.5 104.7 104.8 105.4 105.8 110.2 109.9 110.0 108.6 108.0 108.1 98 4 98.4 98.4 98.8 99.3 99.8 107 5 107.7 108.1 108.4 109.5 109,9 107 5 107.9 108.0 108.1 108.6 109.1 105.2 105.5 106.3 106.2 106.3 106.8 1968: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June 107.2 108.0 108.2 108.3 108.5 108.7 99.1 100. S 101.6 101.4 102.0 101.4 99.1 101.8 102.6 102.9 104.1 103.2 98.2 98.4 98.9 97.6 96.6 96.7 111.4 111.7 112.2 112.3 112.4 112.2 106.9 107.6 107.7 107.9 107.7 107.8 106.3 108.9 107.1 107.2 105.9 106.8 108.7 109.9 109.6 109.7 110.6 111.3 99.8 100.1 99.9 100.0 100.3 100.0 110.9 112.0 112.7 112.3 110.9 110.9 109.4 109.9 110.0 110.6 110,5 110.3 107.4 108.5 109.3 109.9 109.8 110.0 109.1 108.7 109.1 109.1 109.6 109.8 102.6 100.8 100.9 100.2 101.5 104.9 102.0 102.1 101.2 103.2 96.8 97.4 97.7 97.0 96.8 112.5 112.4 112.6 113.2 114.3 107.9 107.9 108.3 108.5 108.6 106.9 106.8 107.3 107.4 107.6 112.0 111.3 111.6 110.6 111.3 100.0 100.1 100.4 100.4 100.5 110.9 110.9 111.9 112.2 112.1 110.4 110.5 110.6 111.0 111.3 110.4 110.9 111.7 112.4 112.9 July Aug Sept Oct Nov Deep See footnotes at end of table. 284 TABLE B-49.—Wholesale price indexes, by stage of processing, 1947-68—Continued 11957-59=100] Special groups of industrial products Finished goods Consumer finished goods Year or month Total Total Foods Other nondurable goods Durable goods Producer finished goods Crude materials 2 InterConmediate sumer materials, finished supplies, goods exand com- cluding ponents s foods 1947 1948 1949 80.1 86.4 84.0 86.1 92.6 88.3 90.7 99.0 91.0 86.5 92.0 88.2 75.9 81.1 83.2 61.8 67.4 70.7 79.2 92.5 84.0 73.4 79.8 77.8 83.1 88.4 86.5 1950 . _. 1951 1952 1953 _ 1954 85.5 93.6 93.0 92.1 92.3 89.8 98.2 97.0 95.4 95.3 92.8 104.2 103.3 97.9 97.1 89.6 96.5 94.1 95.0 95.3 84.1 89.7 90.4 91.1 91.8 72.4 79.5 80.8 82.1 83.1 93.6 102.9 93.1 92.4 88.0 81.4 91.2 88.3 89.4 89.8 87.8 94.2 92.9 93.7 94.1 92.5 95.1 98.6 100.8 100.6 94.7 96.1 98.9 101.0 100.1 94.7 94.5 97.8 103.5 98.7 95.8 97.7 99.9 99.3 100.8 92.8 95.9 98.7 100.1 101.3 85.6 92.0 97.7 100.2 102.1 96.6 102.3 100.9 96.9 102.3 92.5 97.0 99.6 99.4 101.0 94.8 97.1 99.5 99.6 100.9 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 101.4 101.4 101.7 101.4 101.8 101.1 100.9 101. 2 100.7 100.9 100.8 100.4 101.3 100.1 100.6 101.5 101.5 101. 6 101.9 101.6 100.9 100.5 100.0 99.5 99.9 102.3 102.5 102.9 103.1 104.1 98.3 97.2 95.6 94.3 97.1 101.4 100.1 99.9 99.6 100.2 101.3 101.2 101.0 101.0 100.9 1965 1966 . 1967 19684 103.6 106.9 108.2 111,2 102.8 106.4 107.0 109.8 104.5 111.2 109.5 113.3 102.8 104.8 107.2 109.3 99.6 100. 2 101.7 103.8 105.4 108.0 111.5 115.2 100.9 104.5 100.0 101.7 101.5 103.6 104.8 107.4 101.6 103.2 105.2 107. 3 1967: Jan Feb.. Mar Apr May June 107.7 107.6 107.2 107.0 107.6 108.4 106.6 106.5 106.0 105.7 106.4 107.4 110.3 109.3 107.9 106.9 108.5 110.9 105.8 106.3 106.4 106.4 106.9 107.2 101.3 101.3 101.3 101.3 101.3 101.0 110.5 110.6 110.7 110.8 111.1 111.2 101.4 101.1 100.2 99.3 99.4 99.4 104.4 104.6 104.6 104.7 104.5 104.4 104.2 104.5 104.5 104.6 104.8 104.9 108.7 108.3 108.7 108.6 108.9 109.3 107.7 107.2 107.6 107.2 107.5 107.9 • 111.5 109.6 110.5 108.8 109.1 110.1 107.4 108.0 108.0 107.8 107.9 108.0 101.1 101.2 101.4 102.8 103.0 103. 0 111.2 111.4 111.6 112.6 113.0 113.4 99.0 99.0 99.5 99.4 100.6 101.3 104.5 104.6 104.9 105.0 105.5 105.9 105.1 105.5 105.6 106.0 106.1 106.2 109.7 110 2 110.4 110.5 110.9 111.3 108.2 108.9 109.0 109.0 109.5 110.0 110.6 112.0 111.9 111.7 113.0 113.6 108. 0 108.4 108.6 109.0 109.1 109.8 103.5 103.5 103.6 103.5 103.5 103.5 114.0 114.2 114.4 114.8 114.9 115.1 101.4 102.4 103.1 101.7 100.5 100.6 106.3 107.0 107.3 107.5 107.3 107.2 106.4 106.7 106.8 107.0 107.0 107.5 111.9 111.4 112.0 112.0 112.5 110.7 110.0 110.7 110.6 111.0 115.3 113.7 115.6 113.9 114.8 110.0 109.7 103.9 110.0 110.2 103.3 103.6 103.4 104.9 105.0 115.2 115.4 115.7 116.4 116.9 100.9 101.0 101.5 102.2 103.0 107.3 107.4 107.8 108.1 108.2 107.5 107.5 107. 5 108.2 108.4 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 . July Aug . Sept Oct. Nov Dec 1968: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug Sept Oct Nov Deep . . _ . .. - . 1 Includes, in addition to subgroups shown, processed fuels and lubricants, containers, and supplies. 2 Excludes crude foodstuffs and feedstuffs, plant and animal fibers, oilseeds, and leaf tobacco. Excludes intermediate materials for food manufacturing and manufactured animal feeds. Where December data not available, January-November average. Note.—For a listing of the commodities included in each sector, see monthly report "Wholesale Prices and Price Indexes," January-February 1967. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 3 4 285 MONEY SUPPLY, CREDIT, AND FINANCE TABLE B-50.—Money supply, 1947-68 [Averages of daily figures, billions of dollars] Money supply — DeCurrency mand com- deposil component 1 ponent Year and month 1947: Dec. 1948: Dec. 1949: Dec. 148.5 147.6 147.6 152.9 160.8 168.6 173.3 180.6 116.2 122.7 127.4 128.8 132.3 151. 0 150.0 150.0 115.9 114. 3 113.9 26.8 26.2 25.5 89. 1 88. 1 88.4 35.1 ! 35.7 36.1 1.0 1.8 2.8 155. 6 163. 8 171. 7 176. 4 183. 6 119. 2 125. 8 130.8 132. 1 135. 6 25.4 26.6 27.8 28.2 27.9 93. 8 99 2 103 0 103.9 107 7 36.4 38.0 40.9 44.2 48.0 2.4 2.7 4.9 3.8 5.0 107.4 108.7 107.6 112.6 113.1 188. 2 191. 7 196. 0 209. 3 212. 2 138. 6 140. 3 139. 3 144. 7 145. 6 28.4 28.8 28.9 29.2 29.5 110 2 111 5 110.4 115.5 116.1 49.6 51.4 56.7 64.6 66.6 3.4 3.4 3.5 3.9 4.9 112.1 72.9 115.9 82.7 116.8 97.8 120.5 112.2 125.1 126.6 216. 8 231. 2 248. 2 268. 2 289. 2 144. 7 149. 4 151. 6 157. 3 164 0 29.6 30.2 31.2 33.1 35.0 115.2 72.1 119.2 81.8 120.3 96.7 124.1 111.0 129.1 125.2 4.7 4.9 5.6 5.1 5.5 130.5 132.1 140.9 149.6 317. 332. 369. 401 3 7 1 7 172 0 175.8 187 1 199 2 37.1 39.1 41.2 44.3 134.9 136.7 145.9 154.8 145.2 1156.9 182.0 J202.5 4.6 3.4 5.0 4.7 131.8 133.0 134.3 133.5 135.3 136.7 335 334 338 342 341 347 9 5 6 3 8 2 175 3 170 6 171 9 173 6 171 0 174.2 38.5 38.3 38.5 38.6 38.8 39.2 136.8 132.2 133.4 134.9 132.2 135.0 160.6 164.0 166.7 168.8 170.8 173.0 4.2 5.1 4.9 4.8 6.6 4.0 350 353 357 360 363 369 9 5 3 9 7 1 175 7 175 8 178.3 180 5 182 4 187 .1 39.6 39.6 39.7 40.0 40.4 41.2 136.2 136.2 138.5 140.5 141.9 145.9 175.2 177.8 179.0 180.4 181.3 182.0 5.7 4.3 5.0 6.3 5.3 5.0 35.4 36.0 36.4 113.1 111.5 111.2 1950: 1951: 1952: 1953: 1954: U.S. Government demand deposits* Unadjusted Seasonally adjusted Dec. Dec. Dec. Dec. Dec. Time 25.0 26.1 27.3 27.7 27.4 1955: 1956: 1957: 1958: 1959: Dec. Dec. Dec. Dec. Dec 185.2 188.8 193.3 206.6 209.3 135.2 136.9 135.9 141.1 141.9 1960: 1961: 1962: 1963: 1964: Dec Dec. Dec Dec Dec 213.9 228.1 245.2 265.2 285.9 141.1 145.4 147.4 153.0 159.3 1965: Dec... 1966: Dec... 1967: Dec. 1968: Dec p. 313.4 328 6 364.8 397.3 166.8 170.4 181.3 193.0 1967: J a n . . Feb.. Mar . Apr.. May.. JuneJuly.. Aug.. Sept. Oct_. Nov_. Dec. 331.3 335.2 339.1 340.6 344.5 348.6 170.3 171.8 173.2 172.5 174.4 176.0 38.5 38.7 38.9 39.0 39.1 39.3 352.6 356.2 358.5 360.8 363.0 364.8 177.8 178.9 179.1 180.2 181.0 181.3 39.4 39.5 39.7 39.9 40.1 40.4 1968: J a n . . Feb.Mar._ Apr . May.. JuneJuly.. Aug.. Sept. Oct.. Nov.. Dec p 366.4 367.9 370.1 371.4 373.7 375.6 182.3 182.7 183.4 184.3 186.1 187.4 40.6 40.7 41.1 41.4 41.6 42.0 184.1 185.2 186.7 187.1 187.6 188.2 371 4 367 1 369.6 373.5 370.9 374.1 187 .6 181.4 182.0 185.6 182.5 185.6 40.5 40.3 40.7 41.1 41.3 41.9 147.1 141.1 141.2 144.5 141.1 143.6 183.7 185.8 187.7 187.9 "^8.4 188. 6 5.0 7.2 6.6 4.2 6.4 5.4 379.8 384.0 386.0 389.8 393.9 397.3 189. 4 42. 2 190.3 42.6 189. 5 42. 7 190.2 42.8 192.0 43.2 193.0 43.4 190.4 193.8 1196.6 199.5 201.9 204.3 378.0 381.3 384.8 389.7 394.1 401.7 187.2 186.9 188.6 190.6 193.4 199.2 42.4 42.7 42.7 42.9 43.7 44.3 144.8 144.2 145.8 147.7 149.7 154.8 190. 8 194. 4 196. 2 199.1 200. 7 202. 5 5.7 5.5 5.9 6.1 4.2 4.7 28.9 29.6 30.6 32.5 34.2 1 Currency outside the Treasury, the Federal Reserve System, and the vaults of all commercial banks. 2 Demand deposits at all commercial banks, other than those due to domestic commercial banks and the U S Governbank' ™*h ' t e m S ' " p r o c e s s o f c o l l e c t i o n a n d Federal Reserve float, plus foreign demand balances at Federal Reserve !AL m ( l, d o P 2 s i t s a d i u s t e d a r e t i m e deposits at all commercial banks other than those due to domestic commercial banks and the U.S. Government. * Deposits at all commercial banks. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 286 TABLE B-51.—Bank loans and investments, 1929-68 [Billions of dollars] Weekly reporting large commercial banks 3 All commercial banks End of year or month ! Total loans and investments 2 1929 5. 1930 5. 1931 5. 1932 ». 1933 5. 1934 5. 1935... 1936__. 1937._ 1938.. 1939.. 1940... 1941._. 1942.. 1943.. 1944.. 1945.. 1946.. 1947.. 1948.. 49.4 48.9 44.9 36.1 30.4 32.7 36.1 39.6 38.4 38.7 40.7 43.9 50.7 67.4 85.1 105.5 124.0 114.0 116.3 114.2 1948. 1949. 1950. 1951. 1952. 1953. 1954. 1955. 1956_ 1957. 1958. 1959. 1960. 1961. 1962' 1963' 1964. 1965. 1966. 1967. 1968 < 1967: Jan Feb Mar..... Apr May..... June July..... Aug Sept.... Oct Nov ..... Dec 1968: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug Sept p... Oct p.... Nov p.... Decs.... Investments Loans 2 113.0 118.7 124.7 130.2 139.1 143.1 153.1 157.6 161.6 166.4 181.2 185.9 194.5 209.6 227.9 246.2 267.2 294.4 310.5 346.5 384.8 314.3 317.7 321.5 322.9 324.7 326.2 332.5 336.6 339.1 342.0 344.3 346.5 349.9 353.9 352.5 355.2 357.3 357.8 365.9 370.4 374.8 379.6 381.6 384.8 U.S. Government securities 35.7 34.5 29.2 21.8 16.3 15.7 15.2 16.4 17.2 16.4 17.2 18.8 21.7 19.2 19.1 21.6 26.1 31.1 38.1 42.4 Seasonally 41.5 42.0 51.1 56.5 62.8 66.2 69.1 80.6 88.1 91.5 95.6 107.8 113.8 120.4 134.0 149.6 167.7 192.6 7 208.2 225.4 252.8 210.2 210.8 211.9 212.9 213.4 214.1 216.5 218.0 219.9 221.4 222.7 225.4 227.5 229.2 229.0 231.4 232.6 233.5 238.4 241.1 243.8 246.9 250.4 252.8 4.9 5.0 6.0 6.2 7.5 10.3 13.8 15.3 14.2 15.1 16.3 17.8 21.8 41.4 59.8 77.6 90.6 74.8 69.2 62.6 Other securities Business loans 4 8.7 9.4 9.7 8.1 6.5 6.7 7.1 7.9 7.0 7.2 7.1 7.4 7.2 6.8 6.1 6.3 7.3 8.1 9.0 9.2 5.1 4.2 4.7 5.3 7.1 6.3 6.4 6.5 7.3 11.3 14.7 15.6 9.2 10.3 12.4 13.4 14.2 14.7 16.4 16.8 16.3 17.9 20.5 20.5 20.8 23.9 29.2 35.0 38.7 44.8 7 48.7 61.4 71.0 49.9 51.1 52.4 53.7 54.9 56.2 56.5 57.3 57.7 58.6 60.4 61.4 62.4 62.7 63.6 63.4 63.6 63.9 64.4 65.5 67.0 68.5 70.2 71.0 15.6 13.9 17.9 21.6 23.4 23.4 22.4 26.7 30.8 31.8 31.7 30.7 32.2 32.9 35.2 38.8 42.1 3 53.1 60.7 65.8 74.0 60.4 60.4 62.0 62.3 61.8 63.8 63.7 62.2 63.4 63.1 63.7 65.8 65.0 65.1 66.5 67.6 67.1 69.2 69.2 68.1 69.4 69.7 71.2 74.0 adjusted 62.3 66.4 61.1 60.4 62.2 62.2 67.6 60.3 57.2 56.9 65.1 57.7 59.8 65.3 64.6 61.7 60.7 57.1 53.6 59.7 61.0 54.1 55.8 57.3 56.3 56.4 55.9 59.4 61.3 61.4 61.9 61.2 59.7 60.0 62.0 59.9 60.3 61.0 60.4 63.1 63.9 64.0 64.2 61.0 61.0 1 Data are for last Wednesday of month (except June 30 and December 31 call dates used for all commercial banks). 2 Adjusted to exclude interbank loans beginning 1948. 3 Loans by weekly reporting large commercial banks beginning 1965 and formerly weekly reporting member banks. See "Federal Reserve Bulletin," March 1967. * Commercial and industrial loans and prior to 1956, agricultural loans. Beginning July 1959, loans to financial institutions excluded. Prior to 1943, published data adjusted to include open market paper. 5 June data used because complete end-of-year data not available. 6 Commercial bank data are estimates for December 3 1 . 7 Effective June 1966, balances accumulated for payment of personal loans (about $1.1 billion) are excluded from loans at all commercial banks, and certain certificates of CCC and Export-Import Bank totaling about $1 billion are included in other securities rather than in loans. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 287 TABLE B-52.—Selected liquid assets held by the public, 1946-68 i [Billions of dollars, seasonally adjusted] Time deposits End of year or month | Demand deposits and currency2 Total Commercial banks3 Postal savings system Mutual savings banks 1946.. 1947. 1948. 1949. 239.1 246.2 254.1 262.1 108. 5 I 112.4 110.5 I 1950. 1951. 1952. 1953. 1954. 271.4 281.0 296.0 311.5 320.3 1955. 1956. 1957. 1958. 1959. 332.5 343.2 356.0 373.1 393.9 133.3 134.6 133.5 138.8 139.7 1960. 1961. 1962. 1963. 1964. 399.2 424.6 459.0 495.4 530.5 138.4 ! 142.6 ! 144.8 j 149.6 156.7 73.1 82.5 98.1 i 112.9 | 127.1 | 36.2 38.3 1965. 1966 5 1967. 1968 6 573.1 601.5 650.5 164.1 168.6 180.7 147.1 159.3 183.1 52.6 55.2 60.3 64.3 1967: Jan... Feb.. Mar.. Apr.. May.. June. 605.2 604.8 615.2 613.2 619.8 620.8 167.0 165.9 171.0 168.7 173.0 173.7 163.6 165.3 167.6 168.6 170.7 172.4 July.. Aug.. Sept.. OcL.. Nov.. Dec. 623.1 630.3 635.7 638.1 645.9 650.5 172.0 174.2 176.3 175.8 177.9 180.7 1968: Jan... Feb._ Mar.. Apr.. May.. June. 655.9 658.7 665.7 664.6 667.9 670.9 July p.. Aug p.. Sept p.. Octp... Nov P.. 676.6 679.7 684.5 692.6 697.9 Savings and loan shares U.S. Government savings bonds * U.S. Government securities maturing within 1 year * 110.4 I 16.9 17.8 18.4 19.3 3.3 3.4 3.3 3.2 8.5 9.7 11.0 12.5 48.6 50.9 53.4 55.0 19.4 16.6 21.6 25.5 115.5 120.9 125.5 127.3 130.2 36.6 38.2 41.2 44.6 48.2 20.1 20.9 22.6 24.4 26.3 j 2.9 2.7 2.5 2.4 2.1 14.0 16.1 19.2 22.8 27.2 55.8 55.4 55.7 55.6 55.6 26.4 26.8 29.3 34.4 30.6 49.7 52.0 57.5 65.4 67.4 28.1 30.0 31.6 33.9 34.9 1.9 , 1.6 I 1.3 1.1 .9 32.0 37.0 41.7 47.7 54.3 55.9 54.8 51.6 50.5 47.9 31.6 33.2 38.8 35.6 48.8 .6 .5 .5 .4 61.8 70.5 79.8 90.9 101.4 47.0 47.4 47.6 49.0 49.9 41.9 42.6 46.8 48.1 46.1 109.8 113.4 123.9 130.8 50.5 50.9 51.9 52.5 48.6 53.9 50.5 58.5 55.5 55.9 56.3 56.8 57.4 58.0 113.7 114.8 116.3 117.1 118.0 118.9 51.0 50.9 51.0 51.1 51.1 51.2 54.2 51.7 52.9 50.9 49.5 46.5 174.7 177.2 178.1 180.1 183.8 183.1 58.4 58.7 ; ! 59.1 59.5 i 59.9 60.3 j 119.9 121.0 122.5 123.0 123.7 123.9 51.3 51.3 51.4 51.4 51.5 51.9 46.7 47.8 48.2 48.3 49.1 50.5 179.6 178.3 181.8 181.1 183.9 I 186.8 | I 33.9 35.3 35.9 36.3 186.5 187.6 187.9 187.6 187.7 187.9 60.6 61.1 61.4 ! 61.7 ' 62.1 j 62.6 123.6 124.6 125.9 126.0 126.5 126.8 51.9 51.8 51.8 51.8 51.8 51.9 53.6 55.4 57.0 56.5 55.9 54.9 186.2 186.0 186.3 187.6 189.4 191.5 194.0 195.9 200.0 204.4 62.8 63.0 ! 63.4 63.8 64.3 64.3 127.2 128.1 129.5 130.0 130.8 130.8 51.9 52.0 52.0 52.0 52.1 52.5 56.9 56.6 57.4 59.2 57.0 58.5 | i ! | ! I 41.4 ! 44.5 49.0 .3 .1 1 Excludes holdings of the U.S. Government, Government agencies and trust funds, domestic commercial banks, and Federal Reserve banks. Adjusted wherever possible to avoid double counting. 2 Agrees in concept with the money supply, Table B-50, except for deduction of demand deposits held by mutual savings banks and savings and loan associations. Data are for last Wednesday of month. 3 Time deposits at all commercial banks other than those due to domestic commercial banks and the U.S. Government (same concept as in Table B-50). Data are for last Wednesday of month, except that June 30, and December 31 call data are used where available. 4 Excludes holdings of Government agencies and trust funds, domestic commercial and mutual savings banks, Federal Reserve banks, and beginning February 1960, savings and loan associations. 5 Effective June 1966, balances accumulated for the payment of personal loans (about $1.1 billion) are excluded from time deposits at all commercial banks and from total liquid assets. 6 Estimates by Council of Economic Advisers. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (except as noted). 288 TABLE B-53.—Federal Reserve Bank credit and member bank reserves, 1929-63 [Averages of daily figures, millions of dollars] Member bank reserves Reserve Bank credit outstanding Year and month Total U.S. Government securities Member bank borrowings All other, mainly float ; Required Total i Excess Member bank free reserves (excess reserves less borrowings) 1929: Dec 1,643 446 801 396 2,395 2,347 48 1930: Dec 1931: D e c . 1932: Dec. 1933: Dec 1934: Dec 1935: D e c . 1936: Dec 1937: Dec 1938: D e c 1939: D e c . 1,273 1,950 2,192 2,669 2,472 2,494 2,498 2,628 2,618 2,612 644 777 1,854 2,432 2,430 2,430 2,434 2,565 2,564 2,510 337 763 281 95 10 6 7 16 7 3 292 410 57 142 32 58 57 47 47 99 2,415 2,069 2,435 2,588 4,037 5,716 6,665 6,879 8,745 11,473 2,342 2,010 1,909 il,822 2,290 2,733 4,619 5,808 5,520 6,462 73 60 526 1766 1,748 2,983 2,046 1,071 3,226 5,011 -264 -703 245 671 1,738 2,977 2,039 1,055 3,219 5,008 2,305 2,404 6,035 11,914 19,612 24,744 24,746 22,858 23,978 19,012 2,188 2,219 5,549 11,166 18,693 23,708 23,767 21,905 23,002 18,287 3 4 90 265 334 157 224 134 118 114 180 482 658 654 702 822 729 842 607 14,049 12,812 13,152 12,749 14,168 16,027 16,517 17,261 19,990 16,291 7,403 9,422 10,776 11,701 12,884 14,536 15,617 16,275 19,193 15,488 6,646 3,390 2,376 1,048 1,284 1,491 900 986 797 803 6,643 3,385 2,372 958 1,019 1,157 743 762 663 685 21,606 25,446 27,299 27,107 26,317 26,853 27,156 26,186 28,412 29,435 20,345 23,409 24,400 25,639 24,917 24,602 24,765 23,982 26,312 27,036 142 657 1,593 441 246 839 688 710 557 906 1,119 1,380 1,306 1,027 1,154 1,412 1,703 1,494 1,543 1,493 17,391 20,310 21,180 19,920 19,279 19,240 19,535 19,420 18,899 2 18,932 16,364 19,484 20,457 19,227 18,576 18,646 18,883 18,843 18,383 18,450 1,027 826 723 693 703 594 652 577 516 482 885 169 -870 252 457 -245 -36 -133 -41 -424 29,060 31,217 33,218 36,610 39,873 43,853 46,864 51,268 56, 501 27,248 29,098 30, 546 33,729 37,126 40,885 43,760 48,891 52, 529 87 149 304 327 243 454 557 238 765 1,725 1,970 2,368 2,554 2,504 2,514 2,547 2,139 3,207 19,283 20,118 20,040 20,746 21,609 22,719 23,830 25,260 27,165 18,527 19,550 19,468 20,210 21,198 22,267 23,438 24,915 26,766 756 568 572 536 411 452 392 345 399 669 419 268 209 168 -2 -165 107 -366 46,802 46,587 46,524 46,902 47,323 47,547 44,066 44,215 44,620 45,082 45,699 45,844 389 362 199 134 101 123 1 2,347 2,010 1,705 1,686 1,523 1,580 24,075 23,709 23,405 23,362 23,284 23,518 23,702 23,351 22,970 23,053 22,914 23,098 373 358 435 309 370 420 -16 -4 236 175 269 297 48,590 48,210 48,147 48,993 49,752 51,268 46,807 46,612 46,398 47,367 48,010 48, 891 87 89 90 126 133 238 1,696 1,509 1,659 1,500 1,609 2,139 23,907 23,791 24,200 24,608 24,740 25,260 23,548 23,404 23,842 24,322 24,337 i 24,915 ; 359 387 358 286 403 345 272 298 268 160 270 107 51,287 50,873 ! 51,863 52, 509 52,998 53,813 49,046 48,930 49,511 50, 090 i 50,581 51,306 237 ; 361 671 683 746 692 i 2,004 1,582 i 1,681 1,736 1,671 1,815 25,834 25,610 25, 580 25, 546 ! 25, 505 ! 25,713 ! 25,453 25,211 ! 25,224 ! 25,276 25,085 ! 25,362 381 399 356 270 420 351 j 144 38 -315 -413 -326 -341 54, 573 ! 55.048 i 54,769 55,741 56,158 56, 501 52,090 52,646 i 52,222 i 53,300 53.388 52,529 525 565 515 i 427 1 569 765 ! 1,958 1,837 2,032 2,014 2,201 3,207 26,001 26,069 26,077 26,653 26,760 27,165 • 25,702 25,694 25.694 26,393 26,472 ! 26,766 299 375 383 i 260 288 399 -226 -190 -132 -167 -281 -366 1940: 1941: 1942: 1943: 1944: 1945: 1946: 1947: 1948: 1949: Dec Dec Dec. Dec Dec Dec Dec. Dec Dec Dec 1950: 1951: 1952: 1953: 1954: 1955: 1956: 1957: 1958: 1959: Dec. Dec Dec Dec Dec. Dec Dec Dec Dec. Dec 1960: 1961: 1962: 1963: 1964: 1965: 1966: 1967: 1968: Dec Dec... Dec Dec Dec... Dec Dec Dec Dec p . . . . . . . . 1967: Jan Feb Mar Apr. May June July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 1968: J a n . . . . Feb Mar Apr. May.. June July.. Aug Sept. Oct... Nov p Dec p .. ! 1 1 .. , : ! i 1 Data from March 1933 through April 1934 are for licensed banks only. 2 Beginning December 1959, total reserves held include vault cash allowed. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 289 i ! i ! -753 TABLE B-54.—Bond yields and interest rates, 1929-68 [Percent per annum] Corporate bonds (Moody's) U.S Government securities Year or month 3-month Treasury bills i 9-12 3-5 month year Taxable 4 issues 2 issues 3 bonds Aaa Baa Average High- rate on Prime Fedgrade shortFHA comeral term municnew mer- Reserve home bank ipal cial Bank loans bonds mortdis(Stand- to busi- paper, gage 4-6 count yields» ard & n e s s rate Poor's) selected months cities 0) 5.85 5.16 8 3.59 2 64 2.73 1.73 1.02 3.04 2 11 2.82 2 56 1.54 2.1 .75 .75 .94 .81 .59 1.50 1.50 1.33 1.00 1.00 2.1 2.0 2.2 2.6 2.4 .56 .53 .66 .69 .73 1.00 1 00 8 1.00 8 1.00 8 1.00 1.67 1 64 2.01 2.40 2.21 2.2 2 1 2.1 2.5 2.68 .75 81 1.03 1.44 1.49 8 1.00 8 1 00 1.00 1.34 1.50 3.24 3.41 3.52 3.74 3.51 1.98 2.00 2.19 2.72 2.37 2.69 3.11 3.49 3.69 3.61 1.45 2.16 2.33 2.52 1.58 1.59 1.75 1.75 1.99 1.60 4.21 4.29 4.61 4.62 3.06 3.36 3.89 3.79 4.38 3.53 3.88 4.71 4.73 5.05 2.53 2.93 3.60 3.56 3.95 3.70 4.20 4.62 4.34 9 5.00 2.18 3.31 3.81 2.46 3.97 1.89 2.77 3.12 2.16 3.36 4.64 4.79 5.42 5.49 5.71 4.02 3.90 3.95 4.00 4.15 4.41 4.35 4.33 4.26 4.40 5.19 5.08 5.02 4.86 4.83 3.73 3.46 3.18 3.23 3.22 5.16 4.97 5.00 5.01 4.99 3.85 2.97 3.26 3.55 3.97 3.53 3.00 3.00 3.23 3.55 6.18 5.80 5.61 5.47 5.45 4.22 5.16 5.07 5.59 4.21 4.65 4.85 5.26 4.49 5.13 5.51 6.18 4.87 5.67 6.23 6.94 3.27 3.82 3.96 4.51 5.06 6.00 io 6.00 6.68 4.38 5.55 5.10 5.90 4.04 4.50 4.19 5.17 5.46 6.29 6.55 7.13 4.89 5.02 4.94 4.86 4.94 5.01 4.43 4.61 4.63 4.55 4.57 4.63 4.74 4.78 4.92 4.96 4.98 5.07 5.06 5.12 5.32 5.41 5.48 5.58 3.52 3.63 3.72 3.59 3.68 3.77 4.82 4.88 5.21 5.38 5.39 5.51 4.50 4.50 4.50 4.50 4.50 4.50 5.62 5.70 5.55 5.63 5.85 5.89 6.00 6.00 6.00 4.50 4.50 4.50 4.50 4.50 4.50 1929 (6) 4.73 5.90 4.27 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 (6) 1 402 .879 .515 .256 2.66 2.12 4.55 4 58 5.01 4.49 4.00 5.90 7 62 9.30 7.76 6.32 4.07 4 01 4.65 4.71 4.03 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 .137 .143 447 .053 .023 1.29 1.11 1 40 83 .59 3.60 3.24 3.26 3.19 3.01 5.75 4.77 5.03 5.80 4.96 3 41 3.07 3.10 2.91 2.76 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 014 .103 .326 .373 .375 0.75 .79 50 73 1 46 1.34 1.33 2 46 2.47 2.48 2.84 2.77 2. S3 2.73 2.72 4.75 4.33 4.28 3.91 3.61 2.50 2 10 2.36 2.06 1.86 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 .375 375 594 1.040 1.102 .81 82 88 1.14 1.14 1.18 1 16 1.32 1.62 1.43 2.37 2 19 2 25 2.44 2.31 2.62 2.53 2.61 2.82 2.66 3.29 3 05 3.24 3.47 3.42 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1.218 1.552 1.766 1.931 .953 1.26 1.73 1 81 2.07 .92 1.50 1.93 2.13 2.56 1.82 2.32 2.57 2.68 2.94 2.55 2.62 2.86 2.96 3.20 2.90 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1.753 2.658 3.267 1.839 3.405 1.89 2.83 3.53 2.09 4.11 2.50 3.12 3.62 2.90 4.33 2.84 3.08 3.47 3.43 4.08 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 2.928 2.378 2.778 3.157 3.549 3.55 2.91 3.02 3.28 3.76 3.99 3.60 3.57 3.72 4.06 1965 1966 1967 1988 . _ - 3.954 4.881 4.321 5.339 4.09 5.17 4.84 5.62 4.596 4.670 4.626 4.611 4.642 4.539 4.83 4.92 4.96 4.87 4.90 4.94 1966' Jan Feb Mar Apr May June Juiy Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec -. . 4.855 4.932 5.356 5.387 5.344 5.007 5.17 5.52 5.80 5 57 5.45 5.10 5.22 5.58 5.62 5.38 5.43 5.07 4.75 4.80 4.79 4.70 4.74 4.65 5.16 5.31 5.49 5.41 5.35 5.39 See footnotes at end of table. 290 5.68 5.83 6.09 6.10 6.13 6.18 3.94 4.17 4.11 3.97 3.93 3.83 o (7) (7) 5.82 6.30 6.31 4.34 4.17 6.00 6.32 6.45 6.51 6.58 6.63 6.81 TABLE B-54.—Bond yields and interest rates, 1929-68—Continued [Percent per annum] Corporate bonds (Moody's) U.S. Government securities Year or month 3-month Treasury bills i 9-12 3-5 Taxable year month issues 2 issues 3 bonds* Aaa Baa Average rate on HighPrime shortgrade comterm municmerbank ipal cial loans bonds paper, (Stand- to busi4 6 — nessard & Poor's) selected months cities Jan Feb Mar Apr May June 4.759 4.554 4.288 3.852 3.640 3.480 4.71 4.64 4.35 4.03 4.09 4.40 4.71 4.73 4.52 4.46 4.68 4.96 4.40 4.47 4.45 4.51 4.76 4.86 5.20 5.03 5.13 5.11 5.24 5.44 5.97 5.82 5.85 5.83 5.96 6.15 3.58 3.56 3.60 3.66 3.92 3.99 July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 4.308 4.275 4.451 4.588 4.762 5.012 4.98 5.10 5.21 5.32 5.55 5.69 5.17 5.28 5.40 5.52 5.73 5.72 4.86 4.95 4.99 5.19 5.44 5.36 5.58 5.62 5.65 5.82 6.07 6.19 6.26 6.33 6.40 6.52 6.72 6.93 4.05 4.03 4.15 4.31 4.36 4.49 1968: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June 5.081 4.969 5.144 5.365 5.621 5.544 5.39 5.37 5.55 5.63 6.06 6.01 5.53 5.59 5.77 5.69 5.95 5.71 5.18 5.16 5.39 5.28 5.40 5.23 6.17 6.10 6.11 6.21 6.27 6.28 6.84 6.80 6.85 6.97 7.03 7.07 4.34 4.39 4.56 4.41 4.56 4.56 July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 5.382 5.095 5.202 5.334 5.492 5.916 5.68 5.41 5.40 5.44 5.56 6.00 5.44 5.32 5.30 5.42 5.47 5.99 5.09 5.04 5.09 5.24 5.36 5.66 6.24 6.02 5.97 6.09 6.19 6.45 6.98 6.82 6.79 6.84 7.01 7.23 4.36 4.31 4.47 4.56 4.68 4.91 1967: « 6.13 5.95 5.95 5.96 6.36 6.84 6.89 6.61 Federal Reserve Bank discount rate FHA new home mortgage yields » 5.73 5.38 5.24 4.83 4.67 4.65 4.50 4.50 4.50 4.10 4.00 4.00 6.77 6.62 6.46 6.35 6.29 6.44 4.92 5.00 5.00 5.07 5.28 5.56 4.00 4.00 4.00 4.00 4.18 4.50 6.51 6.53 6.60 6.63 6.65 6.77 5.60 5.50 5.64 5.81 6.18 6.25 4.50 4.50 4.66 5.20 5.50 5.50 6.81 6.81 6.78 6.83 6.94 6.19 5.88 5.82 5.80 5.92 6.17 5.50 5.48 5.25 5.25 5.25 5.36 7.52 7.42 7.35 7.28 7.29 7.36 1 Rate on new issues within period. Issues were tax exempt prior to March 1,1941, and fully taxable thereafter. For the period 1934-37, series includes issues with maturities of more than 3 months. 2 Certificates of indebtedness and selected note and bond issues (fully taxable). 3 Selected note and bond issues. Issues were partially tax exempt prior to 1941, and fully taxable thereafter. 4 First issued in 1941. Series includes bonds which are neither due nor callable before a given number of years as follows: April 1953 to date, 10 years; April 1952-March 1953, 12 years; October 1941-March 1952, 15 years. « Data for first of the month, based on the maximum permissable interest rate (6% percent beginning early May 1968) and, thru July 1961, 25-year mortgages paid in 12 years and, thereafter, 30-year mortgages paid in 15 years. • Treasury bills were first issued in December 1929 and were issued irregularly in 1930. 7 Not available on same basis as for 1939 and subsequent years. s From October 30, 1942, to April 24, 1946, a preferential rate of 0.50 percent was in effect for advances secured by, Government securities maturing in 1 year or less. c Beginning 1959, series revised to exclude loans to nonbank financial institutions. 10 Beginning February 1967, series revised to incorporate changes in coverage, in the sample of reporting banks, and in the reporting period (shifted to the middle month of the quarter). Note.—Yields and rates computed for New York City except for short-term bank loans. Sources: Treasury Department, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Moody's Investors Service, Standard & Poor's Corporation, and Federal Housing Administration. 291 TABLE B-55.—Short- and intermediate-term consumer credit outstanding, 1929-68 [Millions of dollars] Instalment credit End of year or month Total Noninstalment credit Repair and modernization loans i Total 1929 7,116 . 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 4 1967- Jan Feb Mar Apr May June_. July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 1968: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug._ Sept Oct. Nov Dec 4 6,351 5,315 4,026 3,885 4,218 5,190 6,375 6,948 6,370 7,222 8,338 9,172 5,983 4,901 5,111 5,665 8,384 11,598 14,447 17,364 21,471 22,712 27,520 31,393 32,464 38,830 42,334 44,971 45,129 51,544 56,141 57,982 63,821 71,739 80,268 90,314 97,543 102,132 112 850 96,407 95,271 95,231 95,725 96,427 97,341 97,632 . - . 98,324 98 625 98,870 99,648 . . . 102,132 101,260 . . . 100,771 100,981 102,257 103,411 104,620 105,680 107,090 107,636 108,643 110,035 112,850 Automobile paper Other consumer goods paper 3,524 1,384 1,544 27 986 684 356 493 1,432 1,214 834 799 25 22 18 15 889 37 459 992 1,372 1,494 1,099 1,497 2,071 2,458 1,000 1,290 1,505 1,442 1,620 1,827 1,929 1,195 253 364 572 721 3,022 2,463 1,672 1,723 1,999 2,817 3,747 4,118 3,686 4,503 5,514 6,085 3,166 2,136 2,176 2,462 4,172 6,695 8,996 11,590 14,703 15,294 19,403 23,005 23, 568 28,906 31,720 33,868 33,642 39,247 42,968 43,891 48,720 55,486 62,692 71,324 77,539 80,926 89 750 76,855 76,221 76,183 76,360 76,784 77,519 77,860 78,551 78,765 79,006 79,485 80,926 80,379 80,233 80,474 81,328 82,312 83,433 84,448 85,684 86,184 87,058 87,953 89,750 614 742 355 397 455 981 1,924 3,018 4,555 6,074 5,972 7,733 9,835 9,809 13,460 14,420 15,340 14,152 16,420 17,658 17,135 19,381 22,254 24,934 28,619 30,556 30,724 34 150 30,304 30.062 30,056 30,138 30,321 30,626 30,792 30,932 30 741 30,711 30,718 30,724 30,579 30,682 30,942 31,331 31,818 32,364 32,874 33,325 33,336 33,698 33,925 34,150 819 791 816 1,290 2,143 2,901 3,706 4,799 4,880 6,174 6,779 6,751 7,641 8,606 8,844 9,028 10,631 11,545 11,862 12,627 14,177 16,333 18,565 20,978 22,395 24 750 20,744 20,398 20,274 20 200 20,238 20,395 20,442 20 634 20 878 21,055 21,323 22,395 22,117 21,767 21,644 21,841 22,011 22,248 22,452 22,777 22,988 23,248 23,668 24,750 Personal loans Total Charge accounts Other 2 569 3,592 1,996 1,596 2,379 579 3,329 2,852 2,354 2,162 2,219 2,373 2,628 2,830 2,684 2,719 2,824 3,087 2,817 2,765 2,935 3,203 4,212 4,903 5,451 5,774 6,768 7,418 8,117 8,388 8,896 9,924 10,614 11,103 11,487 12,297 1,833 1,635 1,374 1,286 1,306 1,354 1,428 1,504 1,403 1,414 1,471 1,645 1,444 1,440 1,517 1,612 2,076 2,381 2,722 2,854 3,367 3,700 4,130 4,274 4,485 4,795 4,995 5,146 5,060 5,104 1,496 1,217 980 876 2 807 3,369 3,806 3 769 3 658 3,540 3,411 3 399 3 389 3,248 3,091 2,919 2,683 2,373 2,134 1,962 1,894 1,937 2,057 2,240 2,413 2,590 2,713 2,914 3,127 3,290 3,519 3,869 4,188 4,618 13,173 14,091 15,101 16,253 17,576 18,990 20,004 21,206 23 100 19,552 19,050 19,048 19,365 19,643 19,822 19,772 19,773 19,860 19,864 20,163 21,206 20,881 20, 538 20,507 20,929 21,099 21,187 21,232 21,406 21,452 21,585 22,082 23,100 5,329 5,324 5,684 5,903 6,195 6,430 6,686 6,968 7,800 543 464 416 219 218 900 927 298 371 376 1,088 1,245 1,322 255 130 119 182 405 718 853 898 974 832 869 1,016 1,085 1,385 1,610 1,616 1,693 1,905 2,101 2,346 2,809 3,148 3,221 3,298 3,437 3,577 3,728 3,818 3,789 3 950 3,772 3] 737 3,722 3,713 3,752 3,780 3,789 3,817 3,814 3,810 3,810 3,789 3,734 3,708 3,688 3,697 3,746 3,769 3,808 3,857 3,881 3,910 3,931 3,950 Addendum: Policy loans by life insurance companies 3 1,009 1,496 1,910 2,224 2,431 2,814 3,357 4,111 4,781 5,392 6,112 6,789 7,582 8,116 9,386 10,617 11,673 13,414 15,618 17,848 20,412 22,187 24,018 26 900 22,035 22,024 22,131 22,309 22,473 22,718 22,837 23,168 23,332 23,430 23,634 24,018 23,949 24,076 24,200 24,459 24,737 25,052 25,314 25,725 25,979 26,202 26,429 26,900 6,031 5,366 5,320 5,513 5,761 5,948 5,922 5,930 5,956 5,995 6,146 6,968 6,424 5,859 5,710 6,026 6,276 6,368 6,457 6,574 6,550 6,692 6,964 7,800 913 1,019 1,200 1,326 1,281 1,305 1,353 1,442 1,373 1,325 1,418 1,591 2,136 2,522 2,729 2,920 3,401 3,718 3,987 4,114 4,411 5,129 5,619 5,957 6,427 7,193 7,844 8,767 9,417 10,350 11,381 12,560 13,318 14,238 15,300 13,521 13,684 13,728 13,852 13,882 13,874 13,850 13,843 13,904 13,869 14,017 14,238 14,457 14,679 14,797 14,903 14,823 14,819 14,775 14,832 14,902 14,893 15,118 15,300 5,231 5,733 6,234 6,655 7,140 7,678 9,117 10,059 9,222 9,303 9,397 9,499 9,582 9,671 9,734 9,805 9,861 9,933 9,996 10,080 10,167 10,258 10,362 10,474 10,599 10,729 10,813 10,925 11,026 11,117 * Holdings of financial institutions only; holdings of retail outlets are included in "other consumer goods paper." 2 Single-payment loans and service credit. 3 Year-end figures are annual statement asset values; month-end figures are book value of ledger assets. These loans are not included in consumer credit series. * Preliminary; December by Council of Economic Advisers. Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and Institute of Life Insurance (except as noted). 292 T A B L E B—56.—Instalment credit extended and repaid, 1946—68 [Millions of dollars] Other consumer goods paper Repair and modernization loans Extended Automobile paper Total Extended Personal loans Year or month Extended Repaid Extended Repaid Repaid Repaid Extended Repaid 1946.. 1947.. 1948.. 1949.. 8,495 6,785 12,713 10,190 15, 585 13,284 18,108 15,514 1,969 3,692 5,217 6,967 1,443 2,749 4,123 5,430 3,077 4,498 5,383 5,865 2,603 3,645 4,625 5,060 423 704 714 734 200 391 579 689 3,026 3,819 4,271 4,542 2,53d 3,405 3,957 4,335 1950.. 1951.. 1952.. 1953.. 1954.. 21,558 23,576 29,514 31,558 31,051 18,445 22,985 25,405 27,956 30,488 8,530 8,956 11,764 12,981 11,807 7,011 9,058 10,003 10,879 11,833 7,150 7,485 9,186 9,227 9,117 6,057 7,404 7,892 8,622 9,145 835 841 1,217 1,344 1,261 717 772 917 1,119 1,255 5,043 6,294 7,347 8,006 8,866 4,660 5,751 6,593 7,336 8,255 1955.. 1956.. 1957. 1958.. 1959. 38,972 39,866 42,019 40,110 48,048 33,634 37,056 39,870 40,339 42,603 16,734 15,515 16,465 14,226 17,779 13,082 14,555 15,545 15,415 15,579 10,642 11,721 11,810 11,738 13,981 9,752 10.758 11,574 11,557 12,402 1,393 1,582 1,674 1,871 2,222 1,316 1,370 1,477 1,626 1,765 10,203 11,051 12,069 12,275 14,070 9,484 10,373 11,276 11,741 12,857 1960. 1961. 1962. 1963. 1964. 49,793 49,048 56,191 63,591 70,670 46,073 48,124 51,360 56.825 63,470 17,657 16,029 19,694 22,126 24,046 16,419 16,552 17,447 19,254 21,369 14,525 14,551 15,701 17,920 20,821 13,613 14,235 14,935 16,369 18,666 2,215 2,092 2,084 2,186 2,225 1,876 2,015 2,010 2,046 2,086 15,396 16,377 18,710 21,359 23,578 14,165 15,319 16,969 19,156 21,349 1965. 1966. 1967. 19681. 78,586 82,335 84,693 96,450 69,957 76,120 81,306 87,650 27,227 27,341 26,667 31,300 23,543 25,404 26,499 27,950 22,750 25,591 26,952 30,400 20,518 23,178 25,535 28,000 2,266 2,200 2,113 2,300 2,116 2,110 2,142 2,150 26,343 27,203 28,961 32,450 23,780 25,428 27,130 29,550 Seasonally adjusted 1967: J a n . . Feb.. Mar . Apr... May.. JuneJuly.. Aug.. Sept.. Oct.. NovDec... 6,792 6,735 6,803 6,856 6,744 7,114 6,590 6,617 6,566 6,766 6,554 6,794 2,162 2,146 2,170 2,184 2,173 2,277 2,158 2,219 2,156 2,248 2,168 2,235 2,196 2,144 2,134 2,176 2,113 2,213 2,069 2,034 2,053 2,123 2,055 2,097 168 179 180 179 188 193 173 181 176 185 180 185 2,266 2,266 2,319 2,317 2,270 2,431 2,190 2,183 2,181 2,210 2,151 2,277 7,059 7,272 7,278 7,250 7,304 7,360 6,802 6,874 6,965 6,934 6,913 7,001 2,228 2,259 2,297 2,253 2,262 2,233 2,196 2,215 2,280 2,244 2,190 2,205 2,248 2,320 2,339 2,307 2,303 2,383 2,145 2,172 2,188 2,193 2,193 2,255 169 172 169 169 174 170 179 176 180 176 178 171 2,414 2,521 2,473 2,521 2,565 2,574 2,282 2,311 2,317 2,321 2.352 2,370 1968: J a n . . Feb... Mar.. Apr... May.. June.. 7,453 7,847 7,903 7,863 8,033 8,003 7,054 7,111 7,281 7,222 7,301 7,287 2,385 2,559 2,605 2,509 2,590 2,570 2,254 2,275 2,316 2,297 2,327 2,289 2,339 2,458 2,531 2,597 2,535 2,536 2,223 2,269 2,372 2,340 2,312 2,324 169 184 183 189 197 179 182 173 185 176 184 175 2,560 2,646 2,584 2,568 2,711 2,718 2,395 2,394 2,408 2,409 2,478 2,499 8,247 8,187 8,416' 8,533 8,288 8,200 7,390 7,253 7,701 7,586 7,454 7,400 2,673 2,684 2,783 2,782 2,681 2,600 2,352 2,327 2,482 2,391 2,363 2,300 2,622 2,483 2,560 2,645 2,640 2,600 2,374 2,209 2,428 2,451 2,388 2,400 195 185 196 202 191 200 181 170 179 177 175 200 2,757 2,835 2,877 2,904 2,776 2,800 2,483 2,547 2,612 2,567 2,528 2,500 July.. Aug.. Sept.. Oct_. Nov.. Dec*. i Preliminary; December by Council of Economic Advisers. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (except as noted). 293 TABLE B-57.—Mortgage debt outstanding, by type of property and of financing, 1939-68 [Billions of dollars] Nonfarm properties Nonfarm properties by type of mortgage Conventional2 FHA-VA underwritten End of year or quarter All properties Farm properties Total 1- to 4family houses Multifamily Commercial properties i 1- to 4-family houses Total Total Total FHA insured VA guaranteed 1- to 4family houses 1939.. 35.5 6.6 28.9 16.3 5.6 7.0 1.8 1.8 1.8 27.1 14.5 1940.. 1941.. 1942.. 1943.. 1944.. 36.5 37.6 36.7 35.3 34.7 6.5 6.4 6.0 5.4 4.9 30.0 31.2 30.8 29.9 29.7 17.4 18.4 18.2 17.8 17.9 5.7 5.9 5.8 5.8 5.6 6.9 7.0 6.7 6.3 6.2 2.3 3.0 3.7 4.1 4.2 2.3 3.0 3.7 4.1 4.2 2.3 3.0 3.7 4.1 4.2 27.7 28.2 27.0 25.8 25.5 15.1 15.4 14.5 13.7 13.7 1945.. 1946.. 1947.. 1948.. 1949.. 35.5 41.8 48.9 56.2 62.7 4.8 4.9 5.1 5.3 5.6 30.8 36.9 43.9 50.9 57.1 18.6 23.0 28.2 33.3 37.6 5.7 6.1 6.6 7.5 8.6 6.4 7.7 9.1 10.2 10.8 4.3 6.3 9.8 13.6 18.1 4.3 6.1 9.3 12.5 15.0 4.1 3.7 3.8 5.3 6.9 0.2 2.4 5.5 7.2 8.1 26.5 30.5 34.1 37.3 39.0 14.3 16.9 18.9 20.8 22.6 1950.. 1951.. 1952.. 1953.. 1954.. 72.8 82.3 91.4 101.3 113.7 6.1 6.7 7.2 7.7 8.2 66.7 75.6 84.2 93.6 105.4 45.2 51.7 58.5 66.1 75.7 10.1 11.5 12.3 12.9 13.5 11.5 12.5 13.4 14.5 16.3 22.1 26.6 29.3 32.1 36.2 18.9 22.9 25.4 28.1 32.1 8.6 9.7 10.8 12.0 12.8 10.3 13.2 14.6 16.1 19.3 44.6 49.0 54.9 61.5 69.2 26.3 28.8 33.1 38.0 43.6 1955. 1956. 1957. 1958. 1959. 129.9 144.5 156.5 171.8 190.8 9.0 9.8 10.4 11.1 12.1 120.9 134.6 146.1 160.7 178.7 88.2 99.0 107.6 117.7 130.9 14.3 14.9 15.3 16.8 18.7 18.3 20.7 23.2 26.1 29.2 42.9 47.8 51.6 55.2 59.2 38.9 43.9 47.2 50.1 53.8 14.3 15.5 16.5 19.7 23.8 24.6 28.4 30.7 30.4 30.0 78.0 86.8 94.5 105.5 119.4 49.3 55.1 60.4 67.6 77.0 1960. 1961. 1962. 1963. 1964. 206.8 226.3 248.6 274.3 300.1 12.8 13.9 15.2 16.8 18.9 194.0 212.4 233.4 257.4 281.2 141.3 153.1 166.5 182.2 197.6 20.3 23.0 25.8 29.0 33.6 32.4 36.4 41.1 46.2 50.0 62.3 65.5 69.4 73.4 77.2 56.4 59.1 62.2 65.9 69.2 26.7 29.5 32.3 35.0 38.3 29.7 29.6 29.9 30.9 30.9 131.7 146.9 164.1 184.0 204.0 84.8 93.9 104.3 116.3 128.3 1965 1966 v 1967 v 1968 v 325.8 347.0 369.8 396.6 21.2 23.3 25.5 27.8 304.6 323.6 344.3 368.8 212.9 223.6 236.1 251.3 37.2 40.1 43.7 47.2 54.5 59.9 64.5 70.3 81.2 84.1 88.2 73.1 76.1 79.9 42.0 44.8 47.4 31.1 31.3 32.5 223.4 239.5 256.1 139.8 147.5 156.1 1965: L... II.... l IV... 305.2 312.3 319.2 325.8 19.5 20.2 20.7 21.2 285.7 292.1 298.5 304.6 200.6 204.8 209.0 212.9 34.3 35.2 36.2 37.2 50.8 52.0 53.2 54.5 77.9 78.7 80.0 81.2 70.0 70.7 72.0 73.1 39.0 39.7 40.9 42.0 31.0 31.0 31.1 31.1 207.8 213.4 218.5 223.4 130.5 134.1 137.0 139.8 1966: II p . . III p . IV p.. 331.9 338.6 343.3 347.0 21.8 22.5 23.0 23.3 310.2 316.1 320.3 323.6 216.2 219.6 221.9 223.6 38.2 39.0 39.6 40.1 55.8 57.5 58.9 59.9 82.1 82.6 83.4 84.1 74.1 74.6 75.4 76.1 43.0 43.7 44.4 44.8 31.1 30.9 31.0 31.3 228.1 233.5 236.9 239.5 142.1 145.0 146.5 147.5 1967: \v,_. II p.. III p . IV p.. 350.1 355.8 362.8 369.8 23.7 24.3 24.9 25.5 326.3 331.4 337.9 344.3 224.9 227.8 232.0 236.1 40.8 41.7 42.6 43.7 60.6 61.9 63.2 64.5 84.4 85.3 86.4 88.2 76.4 77.3 78.3 79.9 45.2 45.7 46.6 47.4 31.2 31.5 31.7 32.5 241.9 246.1 251.5 256.1 148.4 150.6 153.7 156.1 1968: I p__. II p_III p. IV p 375.3 382.5 389.4 396.6 26.0 26.8 27.3 27.8 349.3 355.8 362.1 368.8 239.3 243.3 247.3 251.3 44.2 45.2 46.1 47.2 65.8 67.2 68.8 70.3 89.4 90.7 92.0 81.0 82.1 83.2 48.1 48.7 49.6 32.9 33.4 33.6 259.9 265.0 270.1 158.3 161.2 164.1 1 Includes negligible amount of farm loans held by savings and loan associations. 2 Derived figures. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, estimated and compiled from data supplied by various Government and private organizations. 294 TABLE B-58.—Mortgage debt outstanding, by lender, 1939-68 (Billions of dollars] Selected financial institutions Total End of year or quarter Total Savings and loan associations Mutual savings banks Other lenders Commercial banks i Life insurance U.S. comagencies 2 panies Individuals and others 1939 35.5 18.6 3.8 4.8 4.3 5.7 5.0 11.9 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 36.5 37.6 36.7 35.3 34.7 19.5 20.7 20.7 20.2 20.2 4.1 4.6 4.6 4.6 4.8 4.9 4.8 4.6 4.4 4.3 4.6 4.7 4.7 4.5 4.4 6.0 6.4 6.7 6.7 6.7 4.9 4.7 4.3 3.6 3.0 12.0 12.2 11.7 11.5 11.5 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 35.5 41.8 48.9 56.2 62.7 21.0 26.0 31.8 37.8 42.9 5.4 7.1 8.9 10.3 11.6 4.2 4.4 4.9 5.8 6.7 4.8 7.2 9.4 10.9 11.6 6.6 7.2 8.7 10.8 12.9 2.4 2.0 1 8 1.9 2.4 12.1 13.8 15 3 16.5 17.4 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 72.8 82.3 91.4 101.3 113.7 51.7 59.5 66.9 75.1 85.7 13.7 15.6 18.4 22.0 26.1 8.3 9.9 11.4 12.9 15.0 13.7 14.7 15.9 16.9 18.6 16.1 19.3 21.3 23.3 26.0 2.7 3.4 40 4.4 4.6 18.4 19.4 20 5 21.8 23.4 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 129.9 144.5 156.5 171.8 190.8 99.3 111.2 119.7 131.5 145.5 31.4 35.7 40.0 45.6 53.1 17.5 19.7 21.2 23.3 25.0 21.0 22.7 23.3 25.5 28.1 29.4 33.0 35.2 37.1 39.2 5.2 60 7.4 7.8 10.0 25.4 27.3 29.3 32.5 35.4 206.8 226.3 248.6 274.3 300.1 157.6 172.6 192.5 217.1 241.0 60.1 68.8 78.8 90.9 101.3 26.9 29.1 32.3 36.2 40.6 28.8 30.4 34.5 39.4 44.0 41.8 44.2 46.9 50.5 55.2 11.2 11.8 12.2 11.2 11.4 38.0 41.9 44.0 45.9 47.7 325.8 347.0 369.8 396.6 264.6 280.8 298.9 319.3 110.3 114.4 121.9 130.7 44.6 47.3 50.5 53.4 49.7 54.4 59.0 65.6 60.0 64.6 67.5 69.8 12.4 15.8 18.4 21.8 48.7 50.4 52.4 55.3 IV 305.2 312.3 319.2 325.8 245.8 252.3 258.7 264.6 103.2 105.9 108.4 110.3 41.5 42.5 43.5 44.6 44.8 46.5 48.4 49.7 56.3 57.3 58.4 60.0 11.6 11.7 11 9 12.4 47.8 48.2 48.6 48.7 1966: 1 v II v III v . . IV v 331.9 338.6 343.3 347.0 269.6 274.7 278.2 280.8 112.3 114.0 114.4 114.4 45.4 45.9 46.6 47.3 50.7 52.3 53.6 54.4 61.2 62.5 63.6 64.6 13.5 14.4 15.2 15.8 48.8 49.4 50.0 50.4 1967: 1 v II v III p IV v 350.1 355.8 362.8 369.8 282.9 287.7 293.4 298.9 114.8 116.9 119.5 121.9 48.1 48.9 49.7 50.5 54.5 55.7 57.5 59.0 65.5 66.1 66.6 67.5 16 4 16.7 17.5 18.4 50 8 51.4 52.0 52.4 1968: 1 v II * III v \\v 375.3 382.5 389.4 396.6 302.7 308.2 313.6 319.3 123.4 126.0 128.4 130.7 51.2 51.8 52.5 53.4 60.1 62.0 63.8 65.6 68.0 68.4 68.9 69.8 19.6 20.6 21. 1 21.8 53.0 53.8 54.7 55.3 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 . . . _ . 1965 1966 v 1967 *. 1968 P .__. 1965: 1 II III 1 Includes loans held by nondeposit trust companies, but not bank trust departments. 2 Includes former FNMA and new GNMA, as well as FHA, VA, PHA, Farmers' Home Administration and in earlier years RFC, HOLC and FFMC. Also includes U.S.-sponsored agencies such as new FNMA and Federal land banks. Other U.S. agencies (amounts small or current separate data not readily available) included with "individuals and others." Sources: Board'of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, based on data from related Government and private organizations, including Federal Home Loan Bank Board, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Institute of Life Insurance, Federal National Mortgage Association, Government National Mortgage Association, and Department of Commerce. 295 TABLE B-59.—Net public and private debt, 1929-68 * [Billions of dollars] Public Private Individual and noncorporate End of year Total Federal FedState Goveral and ern- finan- local ment cial 3 govand agency ernagency2 ment Nonfarm Total Corporate Total Total Mortgage Commercial and financial* Farm * Consumer 1929 191.9 16.5 13.6 161.8 88.9 72.9 12.2 60.7 31.2 22.4 7.1 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 192.3 182.9 175 0 168.5 171.6 16.5 18.5 21 3 24.3 30.4 14.7 16.0 16 6 16.3 15.9 161.1 148.4 137.1 127.9 125.3 89.3 83.5 80.0 76.9 75.5 71.8 64.9 57.1 51.0 49.8 11.8 11.1 10.1 9.1 8.9 60.0 53.8 47.0 41.9 40.9 32.0 30.9 29 0 26.3 25.5 21.6 17.6 14 0 11.7 11.2 6.4 5.3 4.0 3.9 4.2 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 175.0 180.6 182.2 179.9 183.3 34.4 37.7 39.2 40.5 42.6 16.1 16.2 16.1 16.1 16.4 124.5 126.7 126.9 123.3 124.3 74.8 76.1 75.8 73.3 73.5 49.7 50.6 51.1 50.0 50.8 8.9 8.6 8.6 9.0 8.8 40.8 42.0 42.5 41.0 42.0 24.8 24.4 24.3 24.5 25.0 10.8 11.2 11.3 10.1 9.8 5.2 6.4 6.9 6.4 7.2 1940 1941 1942 1343 1944 189 8 44 8 211.4 56.3 258.6 101.7 154.4 313.2 370.6 211.9 16 4 16.1 15.4 14.5 13.9 128.6 139.0 141.5 144.3 144.8 75.6 83.4 91.6 95.5 94.1 53.0 55.6 49.9 48.8 50.7 9.1 9.3 9.0 8.2 7.7 43.9 46.3 40.9 40.5 42.9 26.1 27.1 26.8 26.1 26.0 95 10.0 8.1 9.5 11.8 8.3 9.2 6.0 4.9 5.1 1945 1946 1947.. 1948 1949 405.9 396.6 415.7 431.3 445.8 252.5 229.5 221.7 215.3 217.6 0.7 .6 .7 13.4 13.7 15.0 17.0 19.1 140.0 153.4 178.3 198.4 208.4 85.3 93.5 108.9 117.8 118.0 54.7 59.9 69.4 80.6 90.4 7.3 7.6 8.6 10.8 12.0 47.4 52.3 60.7 69.7 78.4 27.0 31.8 37.2 42.4 47.1 14.7 12.1 11.9 12.9 13.9 5.7 8.4 11.6 14.4 17.4 1950 1951 1952 19531954 486.1 518.9 549.7 581.1 605.2 217.4 216.9 221.5 226.8 229.1 .7 1.3 1.3 1.4 1.3 21.7 24.2 27.0 30.7 35.5 246.3 276.5 299.9 322.2 339.3 142.1 162.5 171.0 179.5 182.8 104.2 114.0 128.9 142.7 156.5 12.3 13.7 15.2 16.8 17.5 92.0 100.3 113.7 126.0 139.0 54.7 61.4 68.4 76.2 85.7 15.8 16.2 17.8 18.4 20.8 21.5 22.7 27.5 31.4 32.5 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 664.3 697.6 727.4 768.2 830.7 229.6 224.3 223.0 231.0 241.4 2.9 2.4 2.4 2.5 3.7 40.2 44.4 48.6 53.2 58.0 391.6 426.5 453.4 481.5 527.6 212.1 231.7 246.7 259.5 283.3 179.5 194.8 206.7 222.0 244.3 18.7 19.4 20.2 23.2 23.8 160.9 175.4 186.5 198.8 220.5 98.1 108.7 117.2 127.2 140.3 24.0 24.4 24.3 26.5 28.7 38.8 42.3 45.0 45.1 51.5 1960 1961 — 1962 1963 1964 872.0 929.4 997.0 1,071.2 1,154.0 239.8 246.7 253.6 257.5 264.0 3.5 4.0 5.3 7.2 7.5 63.0 70.0 78.1 84.7 92.4 565.7 608.7 660.0 721.8 790.1 302.8 324.3 348.2 376.1 409.9 262.9 284.4 311.8 345.7 380.2 25.1 27.5 30.2 33.2 36.0 237.8 256.9 281.6 312.5 344.2 150.9 164.1 180.2 198.5 218.5 30.8 34.8 37.6 42.3 45.4 56,1 58.0 63 J 71.7 80.3 1965 1966 1967 1,243.8 1,335.7 1,424.8 1,547.4 266.4 271.8 286.5 292.5 8.9 11.2 9.0 21.6 99.9 868.6 107.1 945.6 117.9 1,011.4 129.5 1,103.8 452.3 498.3 534.4 586.0 416.3 447.3 477.0 517.8 39.3 42.0 46.0 50.0 377.0 405.3 431.0 467.8 236.4 251.6 265.5 283.5 50.3 56.2 63.4 71.5 90.3 97.5 102.1 112.8 1968<> 1 Net public and private debt is a comprehensive aggregate of the indebtedness of borrowers after eliminating certain types of duplicating governmental and corporate debt. For a further explanation of the concept, see "Survey of Current Business," October 1950. 2 Net Federal Government and agency debt is the outstanding debt held by the public, as defined in the "Budget of the United States Government, for the Fiscal Year ending June 30,1970." Figures shown here are subject to revision. s This comprises the debt of Federally-sponsored agencies, in which there is no longer any Federal proprietary interest. The obligations of the Federal Land Banks are included here beginning in 1947; the debt of the Feieral Home Loan Banks is included beginning in 1951; and the debt of the Federal National Mortgage Association—Secondary Market Operations is 4included beginning with 1968. Farm mortgages and farm production loans. Farmers' financial and consumer debt is included in the nonfarm categories. 5 Financial debt is debt owed to banks for purchasing or carrying securities, customers' debt to brokers, and debt owed to6life insurance companies by policyholders. Estimates. Sources: Department of Commerce (Office of Business Economics), Treasury Department, Department of Agriculture. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Federal Home Loan Bank Board, Federal Land Banks, and Federal National Mortgage Association. 296 GOVERNMENT FINANCE TABLE B-60.—Federal budget receipts and outlays, 1929-70 [Millions of dollars] Fiscal year Receipts Administrative budget: 1929 1930.. 1931 1932.. 1933... 1934 1935.. Outlays Surplus or deficit ( - ) 3,861 4,058 . 3,116 1,924 1,997 3,015 3,706 . . . 1936 19371938 1939 Consolidated cash statement: 1940 734 738 3,577 4,659 4,598 6,645 6,497 -462 -2,735 -2,602 -3,630 -2,791 3,997 4,956 5,588 4,979 . 3 127 3,320 8,422 7,733 6,765 8,841 -4,425 -2,777 -1,177 -3,862 6,879 9,589 -2,710 9,202 15,104 25,097 47,818 50,162 13,980 34,500 78,909 93,956 95,184 -4,778 -19,396 -53,812 -46,138 -45,022 43,537 43,531 45,357 41,576 40,940 61,738 36,931 36,493 40,570 43,147 -18,201 6,600 8,864 1,006 -2,207 53,390 68,011 71,495 45,797 67,962 76,769 7,593 49 -5,274 69,920 65,462 71,138 68,503 -1,218 -3,041 74,581 79,958 79,621 79,179 92,470 70,461 76,748 82,575 92,111 92,230 4,121 3,210 -2,954 -12,932 240 1961— 1962 1963... 1964... 1965 94,378 99,657 106,572 112,669 116,813 97,802 106,830 111,314 118,585 118,431 -3,424 -7,174 -4,742 -5,916 -1,618 1966 1967 1968 19691 1970 i 130,864 149,562 153,676 186,092 198,686 134,654 158,352 178,862 183,701 195,272 -3,790 -8,790 -25,187 2,391 3,414 1941 1942 1943 1944... 1945 . 1946... 1947.... 1948 1949— 1950 1951 1952 1953 . Unified budget: 1954 1955... 1956 1957 1958 1959.-. 1960 . . . .. 1 Estimate. Note.—Certain interfund transactions are excluded from receipts and outlays starting in 1932. For years prior to 1932 the amounts of such transactions are not significant. Refunds of receipts are excluded from receipts and outlays starting in 1913; comparable data are not available for prior years. Source: Bureau of the Budget. 297 TABLE B-61.—Federal budget receipts, outlays,financing,and debt, 1959-70 [Millions of dollars; fiscal years] Actual Description 1959 1960 1961 79,179 89,453 92,470 90,348 94,378 96,604 99,657 104,480 106, 572 111,459 112,669 118,041 -10,274 2,122 -2,226 -4,823 -4,887 -5,372 Loan account: Loan disbursements. Loan repayments 7,859 5,201 8,310 6,427 7,869 6,671 9,621 7,271 9,646 9,791 10,237 9,693 Net lending. 2,659 1,882 1,198 2,351 -145 545 79,179 92,111 92,470 92,230 94,378 97,802 99,657 106,830 106,572 111,314 112,669 118,585 RECEIPTS, EXPENDITURES, AND NET LENDING : Expenditure account: Receipts Expenditures (excludes net lending)... Expenditure account surplus or deficit(-) Total budget: Receipts Outlays (expenditures and net lending). 1962 1963 1964 -12,932 240 -3,424 -7,174 -4,742 -5,916 BUDGET FINANCING: Borrowing from the public. Other means of financing... 8,665 4,267 2,142 -2,382 1,465 1,959 9,734 -2,560 6,120 -1,378 3,089 2,827 Total budget financing... 12,932 -240 3,424 7,174 4,742 5,916 287,739 234,970 290,799 237,112 292,869 238,577 303,227 248,311 310,775 254,431 316,728 257,520 Budget surplus or deficit (—) OUTSTANDING DEBT, END OF YEAR: Gross Federal debt Held by the public 79,179 Individual income taxes Corporation income taxes Employment taxes and contributions Unemployment insurance 2 ,„ Contributions for other insurance and retirement Excise taxes... Estate and gift taxes Customs duties Miscellaneous receipts3 MEMORANDUM: Federal funds.. Trust funds BUDGET OUTLAYS (EXPENDITURES NET LENDING) 94,378 99,657 106,572 112,669 40,715 21,494 11,248 2,667 41,338 20,954 12,680 2,902 45,571 20,523 12,835 3,337 47,588 21,579 14,747 4,112 48,697 23,493 16,959 4,045 769 10, 578 1,333 925 594 766 11,676 1,606 1,105 1,193 855 11,860 1,896 982 910 873 12,534 2,016 1,142 826 944 13,194 2,167 1,205 1,036 1,006 13,731 2,394 1,252 1,093 75, 563 16,907 75,118 19,260 79,635 20,022 83,463 23,109 87,111 25,558 92,111 92,230 97,802 106,830 111,314 118,585 46,617 3,267 145 5,365 1,209 4,451 851 1,081 17,690 5,428 7,070 1,173 45,908 3,054 401 3,322 1,019 4,774 971 1,282 18,734 5,426 8,299 1,334 47,383 3,357 744 3,340 1,568 5,048 191 1,480 21,847 5,688 8,108 1,543 51,097 4,492 1,257 4,131 1,686 5,410 589 1,703 23,374 5,625 8,321 1,703 52,257 4,115 2,552 5,139 1,505 5,745 -880 1,706 25,274 5,520 9,215 1,841 53,591 4,117 4,170 5,186 1,972 6,482 -185 1,998 26,598 5,681 9,810 2,103 -2,238 -2,296 -2,495 - 2 , 558 -2,674 -2,939 77,111 17,323 -2,322 74,869 19,986 -2,626 79,339 21,774 -3,311 86,599 23,394 -3,163 90,135 23,898 -2,719 95,761 25,941 -3,118 AND National defense International affairs and finance Space research and technology Agriculture and agricultural resources NaturaI resources Commerce and transportation Community development and housing Education and manpower Health and welfare Veterans benefits and services Interest General government Allowances. T — Undistributed intragovernmental transactions . MEMORANDUM: Federal funds Trust funds Intragovernmental transactions. 92,470 36,719 17,309 8,821 2,131 65,679 13,500 BUDGET RECEIPTS. See footnotes at end of table. 298 TABLE B-61.—Federal budget receipts, outlays,financing,and debt, 1959-70—Continued [Millions of dollars; fiscal years] Estimate Actual Description 1969 1965 RECEIPTS, EXPENDITURES, AND NET LENDING: Expenditure account: Receipts Expenditures (excludes net lending) Expenditure account deficit ( - ) surplus 1966 1967 1968 116,813 117,182 130,864 130,822 149,562 153,299 153,676 172,830 186,092 182,315 198,686 194,356 1970 or -369 42 -3,736 -19,153 3,777 4,330 Loan account: Loan disbursements. Loan repayments 10,911 9,662 14,628 10,796 17,676 12,623 20,422 14,389 12,478 11,092 8,113 7,197 Net lending. 1,249 3,832 5,053 6,032 1,386 916 116,813 118,431 130,864 134,654 149,562 158,352 153,676 178,862 186,092 183,701 198,686 195,272 Total budget: Receipts Outlays (expenditures and net lending). Budget surplus or deficit ( - ) -1,618 -3,790 -8,790 -25,187 2,391 3,414 BUDGET FINANCING; Borrowing from the public. Other means of financing... 4,037 -2,419 3,080 710 2,854 5,936 23,095 2,092 -3,091 700 - 4 , 000 586 Total budget financing.._ 1,618 3,790 8,790 25,187 1-2,391 -3,414 OUTSTANDING DEBT, END OF YEAR: Gross Federal debt Held by the public 323,096 261,557 329,419 264,637 341,309 267,491 369,724 290,586 365,159 276,586 371,482 272,586 BUDGET RECEIPTS.. 116,813 130,864 149,562 153,676 186,092 198,686 48,792 25,461 17,359 3,819 55,446 30,073 20,662 3,777 61,526 33,971 27,822 3,659 68,726 28,665 29,223 3,346 84,400 38,100 34,842 3,300 90,400 37,900 39,863 3,575 1,079 14,570 2,716 1,442 1,576 1,127 13,062 3,066 1,767 1,885 1,866 13,719 2,978 1,901 2,120 2,050 14,079 3,051 2,038 2,498 2,366 14,800 3,200 2,300 2,784 2,431 15, 700 3,400 2,300 3,117 90,863 25,950 101,344 29,520 111,732 37,829 114,627 39, 049 141,050 45,042 147,795 50,891 118,431 134,654 158,352 178,862 183,701 195,272 49,578 4,340 5,091 4,807 2,063 7,364 288 2,509 27,209 5,722 10,357 2,276 56,785 4,490 5,933 3,679 2,035 7,135 2,644 4,496 31,320 5,920 11,285 2,360 70,081 4,547 5,423 4,376 1,860 7,652 2,616 6,135 37,605 6,897 12, 588 2,584 80,516 4,619 4,721 5,944 1,702 8,076 4,076 7,012 43,508 6,882 13,744 2,632 80,999 3,938 4,247 5,448 1,898 8,048 2,313 7,165 48,839 7,692 15,171 2,948 100 81,542 3,755 3,947 5,181 1,891 8,969 2,772 7,887 54,966 7,724 15,958 3,275 3,150 -3,174 -3,431 - 4 , 009 - 4 , 570 -5,105 - 5 , 745 94,807 27,081 --3,457 106,513 31,809 -3,668 126,780 36,932 -5,360 143,105 41,529 -5,771 148,160 43,037 -7,496 154,722 48,431 -7,881 Individua! income taxes ^.. Corporation income taxes Employment taxes and contributions Unemployment insurance2 Contributions for other insurance and reti re m e nt Excise taxes Estate and gift taxes Customs duties Miscellaneous receipts3 MEMORANDUM: Federal funds.. Trust funds... BUDGET OUTLAYS (EXPENDITURES NET LENDING) AND National defense International affairs and finance Space research and technology Agriculture and agricultural resources Natural resources Commerce and transportation Community development and housing Education and manpower Health and welfare Veterans benefits and services Interest General government Allowances Undistributed intragovernmental transactions MEMORANDUM: Federal funds Trust funds Intragovernmental transactions. 1 2 3 Excludes $10,803 million of net credits for conversion of mixed-ownership enterprises to private ownership. Includes Federal funds of $321 million in 1959 and $339 million in 1960. Includes both Federal funds and trust funds. Source: Bureau of the Budget. 299 TABLE B-62.—Relation of the Federal Budget to the Federal sector of the national income and product accounts, 1967-70 [Billions of dollars; fiscal years] Actual Estimate Receipts and Expenditures 1967 1968 1970 1969 RECEIPTS 149.6 198.7 2.1 1.4 -.'l 2.2 1.3 .2 -.1 161.1 190.0 202.3 158.4 178.9 183.7 195.3 -5.1 1.7 1.2 -.4 -1.6 -.8 1.1 -6.0 1.9 1.1 -2.1 -1.6 -.7 .9 -1.4 2.1 1.4 1.8 -1.1 -.4 1.1 -.9 2.2 1.3 1.8 -1.0 -.3 1.2 154.4 Federal sector, national income and product accounts, receipts 186.1 1.9 1.1 4.6 -.2 147.7 Employer share, employee retirement.. Other netting and grossing Adjustment to accruals Other 153.7 1.7 1.2 -4.7 -.2 Total receipts, budget. 172.4 187.3 199.6 EXPENDITURES Total outlays, budget. Loan account Employer share, employee retirement Other netting and grossing Defense timing adjustment.. Lending inthe expenditure account _ Dollar expenditures to finance agricultural exports. Other Federal sector, national income and product accounts, expenditures _ Note.—See Special Analysis A, "Budget of the United States Government for the Fiscal Year Ending June 30, 1970," for description of these categories. Sources: Bureau of the Budget and Department of Commerce (Office of Business Economics). 300 TABLE B-63.—Receipts and expenditures of the Federal Government sector of the national income and product accounts, 1946-70 [Billions of dollars] Receipts Year or quarter Fiscal year: 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955.. 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 19691 19701 Calendar year: 1946 1947.. 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 v Total Expenditures Indirect Personal Cor- busipo- | ness tax rate tax and non- profits and tax nontax actax receipts cruals accruals Transfer payments Contributions for social insurance Total Purchases of goods and services To persons To foreigners (net) Grantsin-aid to State and local governments Net interest paid Subsidies less current surplus of government enterprises Surplus or deficit national income and product accounts 38.4 42.7 43.6 40.0 42.0 60.8 65.1 69.3 65.8 67.2 75.8 80.7 77.9 85.4 94.8 95.3 104.2 110.2 115.5 120.5 133.0 147.7 161.1 190.0 202.3 16.9 18.8 20.0 16.3 16.5 23.2 28.8 31.4 30.3 29.7 33.6 36.7 36.3 38.2 42.5 43.6 47.3 49.6 50.7 51.3 57.6 64.5 71.6 88.6 94.0 8.3 10.6 11.2 11.0 11.9 21.5 19.3 19.7 17.3 18.7 21.1 20.6 17.8 21.5 22.3 20.3 22.9 23.5 25.7 27.7 31.2 31.4 34.5 39.3 40.2 7.4 7.9 7.9 8.0 8.2 9.5 9.7 10.7 10.4 10.0 10.8 11.7 11.6 11.9 13.2 13.3 14.2 15.0 15.6 16.9 15.7 16.0 17.1 18.1 19.2 5.8 5.5 4.6 4.8 5.5 6.6 7.3 7.5 7.8 8.7 10.2 11.7 12.2 13.8 16.7 18.1 19.9 22.1 23.5 24.6 28.5 35.8 37.9 44.0 48.9 55.5 29.5 30.9 39.6 42.4 44.6 66.0 75.8 74.2 67.3 69.8 76.0 83.1 90.9 91.3 98.0 106.4 111.4 116.9 118.5 131.9 154.4 172.4 187.3 199.6 40.1 13.0 13.2 19.3 19.0 25.1 46.6 56.1 53.2 43.9 45.2 47.7 50.7 54.7 52.7 55.5 60.9 63.4 65.7 64.4 71.7 84.9 95.6 101.5 105.6 8.3 8.7 8.1 11.3 8.1 8.5 9.3 10.5 12.1 12.8 14.4 17.8 19.8 20.6 23.6 25.1 26.4 27.3 28.3 31.8 37.3 42.4 48.0 52.8 1.8 2.6 5.0 4.3 3.1 2.6 2.1 1.7 2.1 1.8 1.9 1.7 1.8 1.8 2.1 2.1 2.1 2.2 2.2 2.3 2.2 2.1 2.1 2.1 0.9 1.5 1.8 2.1 2.4 2.4 2.5 2.8 2.9 3.0 3.2 3.7 4.7 6.2 6.8 6.9 7.6 8.4 9.8 10.9 12.7 14.8 17.4 19.6 23.0 3.7 4.2 4.2 4.3 4.4 4.6 4.8 4.8 5.0 4.9 5.1 5.5 5.7 5.9 7.0 6.8 6.8 7.5 8.1 8.5 9.0 9.9 10.8 12.0 12.2 2.1 -17.1 .7 13.2 .5 12.7 .8 .4 1.0 -.5 1.3 16.2 1.1 - 1 . 0 .9 - 6 . 5 1.0 -8.5 1.3 -.1 6.0 1.7 2.8 4.7 2.5 - 5 . 1 2.4 - 5 . 5 2.3 3.5 3.2 - 2 . 7 3.8 - 2 . 1 3.6 - 1 . 2 3.8 - 1 . 4 4.1 2.0 4.5 1.0 5.3 - 6 . 7 4.1 -11.3 2.7 4.1 2.7 3.9 39.1 43.2 43.3 38.9 49.9 64.0 67.2 70.0 63.8 72.1 77.6 81.6 78.7 89.7 96.5 98.3 106.4 114.5 115.0 124.7 143.0 151.2 176.9 17.2 8.6 19.6 10.7 19.0 11.8 16.1 9.8 18.1 17.0 26.1 21.5 31.0 18.5 32.2 19.5 29.0 17.0 31.4 20,6 35.2 20.6 37.4 20.2 36.8 18.0 39.9 22.5 43.6 21.7 44.7 21.8 48.6 22.7 51.5 24.6 48.6 26.4 53.8 29.3 61.7 32.4 67.3 I 30.9 79.4 i 38.4 7.8 7.8 8.0 8.0 8.9 9.4 10.3 10.9 9.7 10.7 11.2 11.8 11.5 12.5 13.5 13.6 14.6 15.3 16.1 16.5 15.8 16.2 17.6 5.5 5.1 4.5 4.9 5.9 7.1 7.4 7.4 8.1 9.3 10.6 12.2 12.4 14.8 17.7 18.2 20.5 23.1 23.8 25.1 33.1 36.8 41.5 35.6 29.8 34.9 41.3 40.8 57.8 71.0 77.0 69.7 68.1 71.9 79.6 88.9 91.0 93.0 102.1 110.3 113.9 118.1 123.5 142.4 163.6 182.2 17.2 9.2 12.5 8.8 16.5 7.6 20.1 8.7 18.4 10.8 37.7 8.5 51.8 8.8 57.0 9.5 47.4 11.5 44.1 12.4 45.6 13.4 49.5 15.7 53.6 19.5 53.7 20.1 53.5 21.5 57.4 24.9 63.4 25.5 64.2 27.0 65.2 27.8 66.9 30.3 77.4 33.4 90.6 40.1 100.0 I 45.7 2.2 1.9 3.8 5.1 3.6 3.1 2.1 2.0 1.8 2.0 1.9 1.8 1.8 1.8 1.9 2.1 2.2 2.2 2.2 2.2 2.3 2.2 2.1 1.1 1.7 2.0 2.2 2.3 2.5 2.6 2.8 2.9 3.1 3.3 4.2 5.6 6.8 6.5 7.2 8.0 9.1 10.4 11.1 14.4 15.7 18.4 4.2 4.2 4.3 4.4 4.5 4.7 4.7 4.9 5.0 4.9 5.3 5.7 5.6 6.4 7.1 6.6 7.2 7.7 8.3 8.7 9.5 10.3 11.9 3.5 1.6 13.4 .6 8.4 .7 .8 - 2 . 4 1.2 9.1 1.3 6.2 1.0 - 3 . 8 .8 - 7 . 0 1.1 -5.9 1.5 4.0 2.4 5.7 2.6 2.1 2.7 -10.2 2.1 - 1 . 2 2.5 3.5 3.8 - 3 . 8 4.0 - 3 . 8 3.6 4.2 -3.0 4.3 1.2 5.4 .7 4.8 -12.4 4.2 - 5 . 3 57.6 61.3 62.9 64.9 66.0 65.1 68.2 69.7 72.0 74.9 83.7 86.8 15.2 15.9 16.0 16.1 15.9 16.1 16.3 16.4 17.0 17.5 17.8 18.1 31.8 32.5 33.8 34.5 35.9 36.5 37.0 37.9 40.5 41.2 42.0 42.4 13.3 14.2 14.9 15.1 15.1 14.6 15.9 17.0 17.7 18.3 18.5 19.2 9.1 9.3 9.5 10.0 10.2 9.9 10.2 10.7 11.3 11.8 12.1 12.2 5.0 5.3 5.9 5.5 5.1 4.8 4.8 4.6 3.9 4.1 4.4 4.2 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 136.8 142.1 145.5 147.7 148.1 148.2 152.2 I V . . . 156.4 1968: I . . . . 166.6 I I . . . . 171.8 I I I . . . 182.1 IV v_ 1966: l . _ . . II... III... IV.. 1967: I . . . . 32.2 32.4 32.8 32.2 30.3 30.5 30.6 32.4 37.0 38.2 38.6 134.8 138.4 145.8 150.5 159.3 161.5 165.1 168.6 175.1 181.9 184.9 186.8 72.5 75.6 79.9 81.5 87.4 90.0 91.3 93.5 97.1 100.0 101.2 101.6 32.2 31.6 33.4 36.4 39.3 39.9 40.3 40.8 43.2 45.6 46.6 47.4 2.7 2.3 2.2 1.9 2.2 2.3 2.6 1.9 1.9 2.1 2.1 2.1 2.0 3.7 -2.8 -11.2 -13.3 -12.9 -12.2 -8.6 -10.2 -2.8 i Estimates. Note.—Includes the transactions of the trust accounts and excludes certain financial transactions. Corporate profits taxes are included in receipts on an accrual basis; expenditures are timed with the delivery; and CCC guaranteed pricesupport crop loans are counted as expenditures when the loans are made, not when CCC redeems them. Sources: Department of Commerce (Office of Business Economics) and Bureau of the Budget. 301 323-166 0—69 TABLE B-64.—Public debt securities by kind of obligation, 1929-68 [Billions of dollars] Interest-bearing public debt Total public debt securities i End of year or month 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 I960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1967- Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 1968: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec . . . . . ... . . .. . - - _ . ... -.- _ _ . _ - Marketable public issues Shortterm issues 2 16 3 16.0 17.8 20.8 23 6 28.5 30.6 34.4 37.3 39.4 41.9 45.0 57.9 108 2 165.9 230.6 278.1 259.1 256.9 252.8 257.1 256.7 259.4 267.4 275.2 2/8. 7 280.8 276.6 274.9 282.9 290.8 290.2 296.2 303.5 309.3 317.9 320.9 329.3 344.7 358.0 328.9 329.6 330.9 327.8 330.9 326.2 330.6 335.8 335.9 340.5 345.1 344.7 346.3 351.6 349.5 347.0 352.3 347.6 351.1 354.4 354.7 357.2 356.9 358.0 3.3 2.9 2.8 5.9 7.5 11.1 14.2 12.5 12.5 9.8 7.7 7.5 8.0 27.0 47.1 69.9 78.2 57.1 47.7 45.9 50.2 58.3 65.6 68.7 77.3 76.0 81.3 79.5 82.1 92.2 103.5 109.2 120.5 124.6 121.2 115.5 110.4 118.9 131.2 151.5 119.7 120.2 120.9 118.1 118.8 113.3 117.6 120.9 121.3 126.0 130.8 131.2 134.1 139.6 138 0 135.1 140.7 135.5 139.9 144.8 145.2 148.3 149.5 151.5 Treasury bonds 11.3 11.3 13.5 13.4 14.7 15.4 14.3 19.5 20.5 24.0 26.9 28.0 33.4 49.3 67.9 91.6 120.4 119.3 117.9 111.4 104.8 94.0 76.9 79.8 77.2 81.8 81.9 80.8 82.1 83.4 84.8 79.8 75.5 78.4 86.4 97.0 104.2 99.2 95 2 85.3 99.1 99.1 99.0 99.0 97.9 97.4 97.4 97.4 97.3 97.3 95.3 95.2 95.2 93.6 93 6 93.6 91.1 91.1 91.0 88 4 88.3 88.3 86.2 85.3 Nonmarketable public issues United States savings bonds 3 0.2 .5 1.0 1.4 2.2 3.2 6.1 15.0 27.4 40.4 48.2 49.8 52.1 55.1 56.7 58.0 57.6 57.9 57.7 57.7 57.9 56.3 52.5 51.2 48.2 47.2 47.5 47.5 48.8 49.7 50.3 50.8 51 7 52.3 50.8 50.9 51.0 51.1 51.1 51.2 51.3 51.4 51 4 51.6 51.7 51.7 51.7 51.7 51 8 51.8 51.9 51.9 52.0 52 0 52.1 52.2 52.3 52.3 Investment bonds * Special issues« 0.6 .8 .4 .4 4 .6 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 13.0 13.4 12.9 12.7 12.3 11.6 10.3 9.0 7.6 6.2 5.1 4.4 3.7 3.4 2.8 2.7 2.6 2.5 2.7 2.6 2.6 2.6 2.6 2.6 2.6 2.6 2.6 2.6 2.6 2.6 2.6 2.6 2 5 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.5 .6 2.2 3.2 4.2 5.4 7.0 9.0 12.7 16.3 20.0 24.6 29.0 31.7 33.9 33.7 35.9 39.1 41.2 42.6 43.9 45.6 45.8 44.8 43.5 44.3 43.5 43.4 43.7 46.1 46.3 52.0 57.2 59.1 51.3 51.5 52.1 51.6 55.2 56.2 56.2 58.3 57.7 57.2 57.4 57.2 55.9 57.2 56.7 57.0 59.2 59.5 58.9 60.1 59.7 58.8 59.0 59.1 1 Total includes non-interest-bearing debt, Postal Savings bonds, prewar bonds, adjusted service bonds, depositary bonds, Armed Forces leave bonds, Rural Electrification Administration series bonds, foreign series certificates and notes, foreign currency certificates, notes and bonds, Treasury certificates, U.S. retirement plan bonds and U.S. savings notes not shown separately. Not all of total shown is subject to statutory debt limitation. 2 Bills, certificates of indebtedness, and notes. 3 Includes sales of U.S. savings notes beginning May 1967. * Series A bonds through September 1965 and, beginning April 1951, series B convertible bonds. 5 Issued to U.S. Government accounts. These accounts also held $17.3 billion of public marketable and nonmarketable issues on December 31, 1968. Source: Treasury Department. 302 TABLE B-65.- -Estimated ownership of public debt securities, 1939—68 [Par values,* billions of dollars] Total public debt securities 2 Held by private investors End of year or month Total Held Held by by Govern- Federal ment Reserve accounts banks Total Mutual State savings Misceland Combanks Other Indi- laneous mercial and in- corpo- 4 local viduals6 inves3 banks surance rations governtors 7 ments 5 companies 0.4 9.4 0.9 8.4 1939 ._.. 2.0 41.9 2.5 33.8 12.7 5.6 .5 10.0 .8 1940_ 45.0 36.2 2.0 6.7 2.2 13.7 9.2 .7 1941 13.0 57.9 47.1 4.0 1.3 85 17.1 11 0 23 3.5 1942 ._ . 1.0 108.2 91.5 15.4 23.3 10.5 38.2 6.2 10.1 6.0 2.1 37.2 165.9 16.4 1943 14.5 139.8 57.3 20.8 11.5 9.3 1944 21.4 4.3 53.1 192.8 76.7 28.0 230.6 19.0 18.8 1945. . . 11.8 6.5 64.0 230.0 90.8 22.2 278.1 34.7 23.9 24.3 11.5 6.3 64.1 208.4 74.5 1946 259.1 15.3 27.4 36.7 23.3 7.3 11.9 1947 65.7 203.6 68.7 35.9 14.1 256.9 30.8 22.6 12.5 7.9 65.5 1948. 195.8 62.4 32.7 14.8 252.8 33.7 23.3 12.9 66.3 202.4 66.8 31.5 8.1 1949 35.9 16.8 257.1 18.9 13.7 1950 _. 256.7 8.8 61.8 66.3 199.9 29.6 19.7 36.0 20.8 1951 259.4 61.5 9.6 64.6 13.6 39 3 196.3 26.3 20 7 23 8 14.7 63.4 1952. . 267.4 25.5 11.1 65.2 199.8 19.9 42.9 24.7 12.7 16.0 25.1 1953 45.4 63.7 21.5 64.8 275.2 203.8 25.9 1954 278.7 69.2 24.0 14.4 63.5 16.9 207.1 46.7 24 9 19 1 15.4 1955 18.3 207.0 62.0 23.2 65.0 23.1 280.8 49.0 24.8 16.3 59.5 18.9 1956 200.5 21.2 18.7 65.9 276.6 51.2 24.9 1957 274.9 59.5 20.1 17.7 16.6 64.9 19.0 24 2 197.8 52.8 16.5 67.5 18.9 1958 . . 204.5 19.8 63.7 52.1 282.9 26.3 18.1 18.0 19.4 24.2 1959 69.4 60.3 21.4 212.7 290.8 51.4 26.6 26.3 I960.. 62.1 66.1 290.2 210.0 18.1 18.7 27.4 52.8 18.7 17.4 1961 67.2 65.9 26.8 296 2 52 5 214.8 18 5 28 9 19 0 30.2 67.1 17.4 1962 66.0 219.4 303.5 18.6 53.2 30.8 20.1 31.5 16.8 220.5 64.2 68.2 1963 309.3 55.3 18.7 33.6 21.1 33.0 222.5 16.5 1964 69.8 58.4 63.9 317.9 18.2 37.0 21.1 33.2 60.7 72.1 220.4 15.7 1965 15.8 320.9 59.7 40.8 22.9 33.2 219.1 57.4 74.6 14.1 1966- . 329.3 44.3 14.9 65.9 24.9 222.4 34.7 63.8 74.0 1967 344.7 49.1 12.6 12.2 73.1 25.1 358.0 76.5 65.4 11.5 75.1 35.1 1968 $ 52.9 228.6 14.6 26.9 34.7 43.5 14.7 74.9 1967: Jan 328.9 64.8 220.6 13.9 57.7 24.7 Feb 329.6 44.0 219.7 57.3 13.7 14.7 74.6 34.5 66.0 24 9 34.7 58.0 13.5 74.0 330.9 44.9 219.3 14.1 Mar... . 66.8 25.0 57.2 72.7 34.7 Apr 327.8 45 5 215.7 13.1 12 9 66.6 25 1 34.6 56.4 71.9 May 214.5 330.9 13.0 70.3 13.6 46.1 25 0 32.6 70.9 55.5 326.2 46.7 207.7 12.7 June . . 71.9 11.1 24.9 33.7 70.8 212.0 58.3 12.7 July... 71.8 46.8 11.9 330.6 24.6 71.4 215.5 60.2 12.4 33.7 Aug. 12.8 335.8 73.8 46.6 25.0 46.9 215.7 12.8 72.5 33.8 Sept 335.9 73.3 61.1 10.7 24 8 34.7 73.2 Oct 340.5 47.4 220.2 63.5 12.7 72.9 11.6 24 5 73.2 48.9 222.9 63.4 12.7 13.0 24.4 73.9 35.5 345.1 Nov Dec 344.7 73.1 49.1 222.4 63.8 12.6 12.2 25.1 74.0 34.7 36.5 1968: Jan 49 1 225.3 62.8 12.5 25 6 71.9 13.4 74.5 346.3 36.6 229.2 63.7 75.2 73.4 12.5 Feb.. . 49.0 14.8 26.4 351.6 62.0 75.2 72.9 226.8 35.8 Mar 349 5 49 7 12.6 14 1 27 1 35.6 75.2 50.5 223.3 59.8 Apr . 347.0 73.2 12.2 13.6 26.9 75.4 60.8 12.4 34.9 May 75.8 352.3 50 6 225.9 15 6 26 8 33.6 74.2 76.2 219.2 59.8 12.0 52.2 13.0 June 347.6 26.6 34.2 61.2 74.7 July.. 52.4 223.0 26.7 351.1 75.6 14.3 11.9 354.4 224.4 62.1 14.5 74.9 34.1 Aug 76.9 53 0 11.9 26.9 34.7 63.5 75.2 76.6 224.9 26.7 Sept 354.7 53.3 11.9 12.9 65.3 75.0 357.2 76.2 227.7 11.7 14.0 26.8 34.9 Oct 53.3 34.9 75.0 53.4 26.7 356.9 76.6 226.9 63.9 Nov 14.8 11.6 35.1 75.1 Decs... 358.0 65.4 76.5 52.9 228.6 11.5 14.6 26.9 1 United States savings bonds, series A-F and J, and U.S. savings notes are included at current redemption value. 2 Not all of total shown is subject to statutory debt limitation. 3 Includes commercial banks, trust companies, and stock savings banks in the United States and Territories and island possessions; figures exclude securities held in trust departments. Since the estimates in this table are on the basis of par values and include holdings of banks in United States Territories and possessions, they do not agree with the estimates in 4 Table B-51, which are bas id on book values and relate only to banks within the United States. Exclusive of banks and insurance companies. 8 Includes trust, sinking, and investment funds of State and local governments and their agencies, and of Territories and possessions. 6 Includes partnerships and personal trust accounts. 7 Includes savings and loan associations, nonprofit institutions, corporate pension trust funds, dealers and brokers Federal oriented agencies not included in Government accounts, and investments of foreign balances and international accounts in this country. Beginning with December 1946, the international accounts include investments by the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, the International Monetary Fund, the International Development Association, the Inter-American Development Bank, and various United Nations' funds, in special non-interest-bearing notes and bonds issued by the U.S. Government. s Preliminary estimates by Council of Economic Advisers. Source: Treasury Department (except as noted). 3°3 TABLE B-66.—Average length and maturity distribution of marketable interest-bearing public debt, 1946-68 Maturity class End of year or month Amount outstanding Within 1 year 5 to 10 years 1 to 5 years 10 to 20 years Average length 20 years and over Millions of dollars Fiscal year: 1946 1947 1948 1949 Years Months 189,606 168,702 160,346 155,147 61,974 51,211 48,742 48,130 24,763 21,851 21,630 32,562 41,807 35,562 32,264 16,746 17,461 18, 597 16,229 22,821 43, 599 41,481 41,481 34,888 1 5 2 9 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 155,310 137,917 140,407 147,335 150,354 42,338 43,908 46,367 65,270 62,734 51,292 46,526 47,814 36,161 29,866 7,792 8,707 13,933 15,651 27,515 28,035 29,979 25,700 28,662 28,634 25,853 8,797 6,594 1,592 1,606 2 7 8 4 6 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 155,206 154,953 155,705 166,675 178,027 49,703 58,714 71,952 67,782 72,958 39,107 34,401 40,669 42, 557 58,304 34,253 28,908 12,328 21,476 17,052 28,613 28, 578 26,407 27,652 21,625 3,530 4,351 4,349 7,208 10 4 9 3 7 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 183,845 187,148 196,072 203, 508 206,489 70,467 81,120 88,442 85,294 81,424 72,844 58,400 57,041 58,026 65,453 20,246 26,435 26,049 37,385 34,929 12,630 10,233 9,319 8,360 8,355 7,658 10,960 15,221 14,444 16,328 4 6 11 1 0 1965 1966 1967 1968 208,695 209,127 210,672 226,592 87,637 89,136 89,648 106,407 56,198 60,933 71,424 64,470 39,169 33,596 24,378 30,754 8,449 8,439 8,425 8,407 17,241 17,023 16,797 16,553 4 11 7 2 1967: Jan Feb Mar Apr May.... June 218,796 219,245 219,914 217,127 216,650 210,672 106,021 101,549 102,242 99,670 95, 524 89,648 59,434 66,717 66,722 66, 541 70,238 71,424 28,002 25,655 25,650 25,645 25,641 24,378 8,432 8,431 8,430 8,428 8,426 8,425 16,908 16,893 16,870 16,843 16,819 16,797 6 6 5 5 6 7 July Aug Sept Oct..... Nov Dec 214,968 218,253 218,637 223,271 226,081 226,476 93,957 95, 040 95,442 100,208 102,158 104,363 71,433 76,244 78,198 78, 088 77,320 78,159 24,376 21,793 19,840 19,837 21,487 18,859 8,423 8,422 8,421 8,419 8,418 8,417 16,780 16,758 16,737 16,719 16,697 16,679 5 5 4 1968: Jan Feb Mar.... Apr May..... June 229,285 233,273 231,651 228,718 231,761 226,592 107,199 116,253 114,646 111,783 109,012 106,407 78.157 67,967 67,969 67,922 67,017 64,470 18,859 24,005 24,006 24,006 30,752 30,754 8,416 8,414 8,413 8,411 8,409 8,407 16,654 16,635 16,617 16,596 16,571 16,553 0 0 1 2 230,977 233,167 233,556 236,651 235,653 236,812 110,824 106,121 106,534 116,040 104,938 108,611 64,469 64,996 64,997 58,606 70,751 68,260 30,754 37,143 37,143 37,142 35,130 35,130 8,406 8,402 8,401 8,400 8,398 8,396 16,525 16,504 16,482 16,464 16,436 16,415 0 2 1 0 1 0 July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 2 1 0 Note.—All issues classified to final maturity except partially tax-exempt bonds, which were classified to earliest call date (the last of these bonds were called on August 14,1962, for redemption on December 15, 1962). Source: Treasury Department. 304 T A B L E B—67.—Receipts and expenditures of the government sector of the national income and product accounts, 1929-68 [Billions of dollars] Total government Surplus or deficit Calendar year or quarter Receipts Expenditures State and local government Federal Government * Surplus or deficit national income and product accounts Receipts Expenditures national income and product accounts Surplus or deficit Receipts Expenditures national income and product accounts 1929 11.3 10.3 1.0 3.8 2.6 1.2 7.6 7.8 -0.2 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 10.8 9.5 8.9 9.3 10.5 11.4 12.9 15.4 15.0 15.4 11.1 12 4 10.6 10 7 12 9 13.4 16 1 15.0 16.8 17.6 -.3 -2.9 -1.8 -1 4 -2.4 -2.0 -3.1 .3 -1.8 -2.2 3.0 2.0 1.7 2.7 2.8 4.2 3.2 4.0 7.8 7.7 7.3 7 2 8.4 8 5 7.6 7 2 -.6 - 8 8.6 8.1 .5 4.0 5.0 7.0 6.5 6.7 6.5 8.7 7.4 8.6 8.9 .3 -2.1 -1.5 -1 3 -2.9 -2.6 -3 6 -.4 -2.1 -2.2 9.1 8 6 9.1 9.3 9.6 8.6 8 1 8.4 9.0 9.6 .6 5 .7 .4 17.7 25.0 32.6 49.2 51.2 53.2 50.9 56.8 58.9 56.0 18 4 28.8 64.0 93 3 103.0 92 7 45.5 42.4 50 3 59.1 -.7 -3.8 -31.4 -44.1 -51.8 -39.5 5.4 14.4 8.5 -3.2 8.6 15.4 22.9 39.3 41.0 42.5 39.1 43.2 43.3 38.9 10.0 20.5 56.1 85.8 95.5 84.6 35.6 29.8 34.9 41.3 -^•1 3 -5.1 -33.1 -46 6 -54.5 -42 1 3.5 13.4 8 4 -2.4 10 0 10.4 10.6 10 9 11.1 11 6 12.9 15.3 17 6 19.3 9.3 9.1 8.8 8.4 8.5 9 0 11.0 14.3 17 4 20.0 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 68.7 84.8 89 8 94.3 89.7 100 4 109.0 115 6 114.7 128.9 60.8 79.0 93 7 101 2 96.7 97 6 104.1 114 9 127.2 131.0 7.8 5.8 -3.8 -6.9 -7.0 2.7 4.9 .7 -12.5 -2.1 49.9 64.0 67.2 70.0 63.8 72.1 77.6 81.6 78.7 89.7 40.8 57.8 71.0 77.0 69.7 68.1 71.9 79.6 88.9 91.0 9.1 6.2 -3 8 -7.0 -5.9 4.0 5.7 2 1 -10.2 -1.2 21.1 23.3 25 2 27.2 28.8 31.4 34.7 38 2 41.6 46.0 22.3 23.7 25 3 27.0 29.9 32.7 35.6 39.5 44.0 46.8 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968* 139.8 144.6 157.0 168 8 174.1 189 1 213.2 227.4 260.9 136.1 149.0 159.9 166 9 175.4 186 9 211.5 241.3 267.3 3.7 -4.3 -2.9 1.8 -1.4 2.2 96.5 98.3 106.4 114.5 115.0 124.7 143.0 151.2 176.9 93.0 102.1 110.3 113.9 118.1 123.5 142.4 163.6 182.2 3.5 -3 8 -3.8 49.9 53.6 58.6 63.4 69.5 75 5 84.6 91.9 102.4 49.6 54.1 57.6 62.2 67.8 74 5 83.5 93.3 103.5 -1.4 -1.1 204.3 211.5 216.5 220.5 201.3 206 2 215.3 223.1 222.2 223.6 229.0 234.8 235 2 239.5 243.0 247 4 246.6 254.2 267.2 256.9 265 5 271 3 275.4 . 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 . . . 3.5 1.7 -13.8 -6.4 6.4 -3.0 1 2 7 -12.4 -5.3 -.3 0) 6 1.3 1.8 2.5 2.7 2 6 1.9 1.0 -.7 -1.2 -.4 (3) .1 -1.3 -.9 -1.4 -2.3 -.8 .2 -.5 .9 1.2 1.7 1 0 1.1 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1966: 1 III IV 1967- 1 II Ill . . . . . . . I V 1968: 1 . . . II III 3.0 5.3 1.2 -2.6- 136.8 142.1 145.5 147.7 134.8 138.4 145.8 150.5 2.0 3 7 -.3 -2.8 80.8 83.6 86.0 87.9 79.8 82.0 84.4 87.7 1.0 1.6 1.5 .2 -12.9 -15.9 -14.0 -12.5 148.1 148.2 152.2 156.4 159.3 161.5 165.1 168.6 -11.2 -13.3 -12.9 -12.2 89.3 90.0 92.7 95.5 91.0 92.6 93.8 95.8 -1.7 -2.6 -1.1 - 4 -10.3 -11.3 -4.1 166.6 171.8 182.1 175.1 181.9 184.9 186.8 -8.6 -10.2 -2.8 97.8 100.8 103.6 99.5 101.9 104.9 107.8 -1.7 -1 1 -1.3 1 See Note, Table B-S3. 2 Surplus of $32 million. 3 Deficit of $41 million. Note.—Federal grants-in-aid to State and local governments are reflected in Federal expenditures and State and local receipts and expenditures. Total government receipts and expenditures have been adjusted to eliminate this duplication. Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 305 T A B L E B-68.—Receipts and expenditures of the State and local government sector of the national income and product accounts, 1946-68 [Billions of dollars; calendar years] Receipts Year or quarter Total Indirect PerbusiCorsonal porate ness tax profits tax and tax and nontax accruals nontax receipts accruals Expenditures Contributions Fedfor eral social grantsinsur- in-aid ance Total Surplus or deficit Less: PurTransCurrent <-), chases fer surplus national of payNet income goods ments interest of ern-gov- and and to paid ment prodservperenter- uct acices sons prises counts 1946 1947 1948 1949 12.9 15.3 17.6 19.3 1.5 1.8 2.1 2.4 0.5 .6 .7 .6 9.3 10.6 12.1 13.3 0.5 .6 .7 .8 1.1 1.7 2.0 2.2 17.4 20.0 9.8 12.6 15.0 17.7 1.7 2.3 2.9 2.9 0.3 .3 .3 .3 0.7 .8 .8 .9 1.9 1.0 .1 -.7 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 21.1 23.3 25.2 27.2 28.8 2.6 2.9 3.1 3.4 3.7 .8 .9 .8 .8 .8 14.5 15.8 17.3 18.7 19.7 1.0 1.2 1.3 1.5 1.7 2.3 2.5 2.6 2.8 2.9 22.3 23.7 25.3 27.0 29.9 19.5 21.5 22.9 24.6 27.4 3.5 3.0 3.2 3.3 3.4 .3 .3 .3 .3 .4 .9 1.1 1.1 1.2 1.4 -1.2 -.4 -1.1 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 31.4 34.7 38.2 41.6 46.0 4.1 4.7 5.2 5.6 6.3 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.0 1.2 21.4 23.6 25.5 27.0 28.9 1.8 2.0 2.3 2.5 2.7 3.1 3.3 4.2 5.6 6.8 32.7 35.6 39.5 44.0 46.8 30.1 33.0 36.6 40.6 43.3 3.7 3.8 4.2 4.6 4.8 .5 .5 .5 .6 .7 1.6 1.7 1.8 1.8 2.0 -1.3 -.9 -1.4 -2.3 -.8 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 49.9 53.6 58.6 63.4 69.5 7.3 7.7 8.7 9.4 10.8 1.3 1.4 1.4 1.7 1.9 31.7 34.1 36.9 39.4 42.3 3.0 3.2 3.5 3.8 4.1 6.5 7.2 8.0 9.1 10.4 49.6 54.1 57.6 62.2 67.8 46.1 50.2 53.7 58.2 63.5 5.1 5.5 5.7 6.0 6.5 .7 .8 .8 .8 .7 2.2 2.3 2.6 2.8 2.9 1965 1966 1967 1968 75.5 84.6 91.9 102.4 11.8 13.6 15.2 17.5 2.1 2.2 2.6 2.9 45.9 49.5 53.4 58.2 4.5 4.8 5.1 5.3 11.1 14.4 15.7 18.4 74.5 83.5 93.3 103.5 70.1 78.8 87.8 97.1 6.9 7.5 8.5 9.6 .5 .3 .2 .3 3.0 3.1 3.3 3.4 11.0 14.3 .2 -.5 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1966: I-.-II... III.. IV— 80.8 83.6 86.0 87.9 12.8 13.4 13.9 14.2 2.2 2.2 2.3 2.2 47.8 49.0 50.0 51.4 4.7 4.8 4.9 5.0 13.3 14.2 14.9 15.1 79.8 82.0 84.4 87.7 75.3 77.4 79.7 82.7 7.3 7.4 7.6 7.9 0.4 .3 .3 .3 3.1 3.1 3.2 3.2 1.0 1.6 1.5 .2 1967: 89.3 90.0 92.7 95.5 14.6 15.0 15.4 15.8 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.7 52.1 52.8 53.8 54.7 5.0 5.1 5.1 5.1 15.1 14.6 15.9 17.0 91.0 92.6 93.8 95.8 85.8 87.2 88.4 90.0 8.2 8.4 8.6 9.0 .3 .2 .2 .2 3.2 3.3 3.3 3.3 -1.7 -2.6 -1.1 1968: I.... 97.8 II — 100.8 III.. 103.6 IV p. 16.3 17.0 17.9 18.9 2.8 2.9 2.9 55.8 57.3 58.9 60.9 5.2 5.3 5.4 5.5 17.7 18.3 18.5 19.2 99.5 101.9 104.9 107.8 93.4 95.6 98.4 100.8 9.2 9.4 9.6 10.1 .2 .3 .3 .4 3.4 3.4 3.4 3.5 -1.7 -1.1 -1.3 l.._II... III — IV... i Deficit of $41 million. Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 306 TABLE B-69.—State and local government revenues and expenditures, selectedfiscalyears 1927-67 [Millions of dollars] General revenues by source Fiscal year 1 Total Property taxes Sales and gross receipts taxes Individual income taxes 2 General expenditures by function ReveCorponue ration from net Federal income Governtaxes ment All other revenue 3 Total Education Highways Public welfare 2 AM other< 1927 7,271 4,730 470 70 92 116 1,793 7,210 2,235 1,809 151 3,015 1932 1934 1936 1938 7,267 7,678 8,395 9,228 4,487 4,076 4,093 4,440 752 1,008 1,484 1,794 74 80 153 218 79 49 113 165 232 1,016 948 800 1,643 1,449 1,604 1,811 7,765 7,181 7,644 8,757 2,311 1,831 2,177 2,491 1,741 1,509 1,425 1,650 444 889 827 1,069 3,269 2,952 3,215 3,547 1940 1942 1944 1946 1948 9,609 10,418 10,908 12,356 17,250 4,430 4,537 4,604 4,986 6,126 1,982 2,351 2,289 2,986 4,442 224 276 342 422 543 156 272 451 447 592 945 858 954 855 1,861 1,872 9,229 2,123 9,190 2,269 8,863 2,661 11,028 3,685 17,684 2,638 2,586 2,793 3,356 5,379 1,573 1,490 1,200 1,672 3,036 1,156 1,225 1,133 1,409 2,099 3,862 3,889 3,737 4,591 7,170 1950 1952 1953 1954 20,911 25,181 27,307 29, 012 7,349 8,652 9,375 9,967 5,154 6,357 6,927 7,276 788 998 1,065 1,127 593 846 817 778 2,486 2,566 2,870 2,966 4,541 5,763 6,252 6,897 22,787 7,177 26,098 8,318 27,910 9,390 30,701 10,557 3,803 4,650 4,987 5,527 2,940 8,867 2,788 10,342 2,914 10,619 3,060 11,557 1955.... 1956 1957 1958 1959 31,073 34,667 38,164 41,219 45,306 10,735 7,643 11,749 8,691 12,864 9,467 14,047 9,829 14,983 10,437 1,237 1,538 1,754 1,759 1,994 744 890 984 1,018 1,001 7,584 3,131 3,335 8,465 3,843 9,250 4,865 9,699 6,377 10,516 33,724 36,711 40,375 44,851 48,887 11,907 13,220 14,134 15,919 17,283 6,452 6,953 7,816 8,567 9,592 3,168 3,139 3,485 3,818 4,136 12,197 13,399 14,940 16,547 17,876 1960 1961 1962 1963 50,505 54,037 58,252 62,890 16,405 18,002 19,054 20,089 11,849 12,463 13,494 14,456 2,463 2,613 3,037 3,269 1,180 1,266 1,308 1,505 6,974 7,131 7,871 8,722 11,634 12,563 13,489 14,850 51,876 56,201 60,206 64,816 18,719 9,428 20,574 9,844 22,216 10,357 23,776 11,136 4,404 4,720 5,084 5,481 19,325 21,063 22,549 24,423 1962-63 5 1963-64 5 1964-65 5 1965-66 5 1966-67» 62,269 68,443 74,000 83,036 91,626 19,833 21,241 22,583 24,670 26,280 14,446 15,762 17,118 19,085 20,554 3,267 3,791 4,090 4,760 5,835 1,505 1,695 1,929 2,038 2,227 8,663 10,002 11,029 13,214 15,505 14,556 15,951 17,250 19,269 21,227 63,977 69,302 74, 546 82,843 93,770 23,729 26,286 28,563 33,287 38,233 11,150 11,664 12,221 12,770 13,956 5,420 5,766 6,315 6,757 8,249 23,678 25,586 27,447 30,029 33,332 1 Fiscal years not the same for all governments. See footnote 5. 2 Excludes revenues or expenditures of publicly owned utilities and liquor stores, and of insurance-trust activities. Intergovernmental receipts and payments between State and local governments are also excluded. 3 Includes licenses and other taxes and charges and miscellaneous revenues. * Includes expenditures for health, hospitals, police, local fire protection, natural resources, sanitation, housing and urban renewal, local parks and recreation, general control, financial administration, interest on general debt, and other unallocable expenditures. 5 Data for fiscal year ending in the 12-month period through June 30. Data for 1963 and earlier years include local government amounts grouped in terms of fiscal years ended during the particular calendar year. Note.—Data are not available for intervening years. See Table B-59 for net debt of State and local governments. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. 3°7 CORPORATE PROFITS AND FINANCE TABLE B-70.—Profits before and after taxes, all private corporations, 1929-68 [Billions of dollars] Corporate profits (before taxes) and inventory valuation adjustment Manufacturing Year or quarter All dustries Total 2.6 5.2 1.5 3.9 1.3 -.5 -1 0 4 3 .9 2.1 1.7 3.2 1.7 3.8 .8 2.3 1.7 3.3 1940... 1941... 1942... 1943... 1944... 1945... 1946-.. 1947... 1948... 1949... 10.5 7.0 2.0 -1.3 -1.2 1.7 3.4 5.6 6.8 4.9 6.3 9.8 15.2 20.3 24.4 23.8 19.2 19.3 25.6 33.0 30.8 5.5 9.5 11.8 13.8 13.2 9.7 9.0 13.6 17.6 16.2 1950... 1951... 1952... 1953.1954... 1955... 1956-.. 1957-.. 1958... 1959... 1960... 1961..1962-1963... 1964-.. 1965... 1966... 1967... 1968 »_. 37.7 42.7 39.9 39.6 38.0 46.9 46.1 45.6 41.1 51.7 49.9 50.3 55.7 58.9 66.3 76.1 83.9 80.4 89.2 1966: I... II.. III.. IV.. 1967: 1929... 1930___ 1931... 1932... 1933.1934... 1935... 1936.._ 1937.1938... 1939... Transportation, NonDurcomdurable muniable goods goods cation, inand induspublic tries dus- utilities tries 2.6 2.4 1.3 .5 1.8 1.2 .5 .2 *. .4 .4 All other industries Corporate profits after taxes Corporate profits before taxes Corporate tax liability i DiviTotal dend payments 3.4 10.0 1.9 3.7 .2 - . 4 - . 9 -2.3 1.0 -.8 2.3 .3 3.6 .9 6.3 1.7 6.8 2.2 4.0 2.1 7.0 2.0 3.0 10.0 3.7 17.7 5.1 21.5 6.2 25.1 6.7 24.1 6.7 19.7 8.5 24.6 9.9 31.5 12.5 35.2 11.6 28.9 8.6 1.4 2.9 .8 .5 - . 9 .4 - 2 . 7 .5 .4 .7 1.6 1.0 2.6 1.4 4.9 1.5 5.3 1.0 2.9 1.4 5.6 7.2 2.8 7.6 10.1 11.4 10.1 14.1 11.1 12.9 11.2 10.7 9.0 9.1 15.5 11.3 20.2 12.5 22.7 10.4 18.5 12.7 13.5 13.3 12.6 13.4 15.2 15.6 15.8 15.9 18.4 17.9 19.1 20.5 20.6 23.5 25.6 29.0 29.4 32.1 17.8 22.3 19.4 20.3 17.7 21.6 21.7 21.2 19.0 23.7 23.0 23.1 24.2 26.3 28.3 31.3 34.6 33.5 41.3 Undistributed profits Corporate capital consumption allow-2 ances 4.2 4.3 4.3 4.0 3.8 3.6 3.6 3.6 3.6 3.7 3.7 4.0 4.4 4.3 4.4 4.6 4.6 5.6 6.3 7.0 7.2 2.8 -2.6 -4.9 -5.2 -1.6 -1.0 -.2 .4 .6 -.2 1.8 3.2 5.7 5.9 6.6 6.5 4.4 9.9 13.9 15.6 11.3 8.8 8.6 8.6 8.9 9.3 10.5 11.3 11.7 11.6 12.6 13.4 13.8 15.2 16.5 17.8 19.8 21.7 22.9 24.6 16.0 13.0 11.0 11.5 11.3 16.5 15.9 14.2 10.8 15.9 13.2 13.5 16.0 16.6 20.6 26.7 29.3 25.2 26.4 Profits plus capital consumption allowances 3 8.8 10.3 11.5 13.2 15.0 17.4 18.9 20.8 22.0 23.5 24.9 26.2 30.1 31.8 33.9 36.4 39.7 43.4 47.1 5.8 5.5 4.1 2.5 2.0 2.6 2.8 4.5 4.7 3.2 3.8 3.1 6.4 7.2 8.1 7.4 4.5 2.4 5.8 7.5 8.1 1.1 1.5 2.1 1.6 1.7 2.4 3.1 4.6 5.7 5.9 5.2 6.6 7.8 10.0 8.1 1.3 2.0 3.4 4.4 3.9 2.7 1.8 2.2 3.0 3.0 20.9 24.6 21.6 22.0 19.9 26.0 24.7 24.0 19.3 26.3 24.4 23.3 26.6 28.8 32.7 39.3 42.8 39.2 44.3 12.0 13.2 11.7 11.9 10.5 14.3 12.8 13.3 9.3 13.6 12.0 11.4 14.1 15.8 17.8 22.8 24.1 21.2 24.4 8.9 11.4 9.9 10.1 9.4 11.8 11.9 10.7 10.0 12.7 12.4 11.9 12.5 13.0 14.9 16.6 18.8 18.0 19.9 4.0 4.6 4.9 5.0 4.7 5.6 5.9 5.8 5.9 7.0 7.5 7.9 8.5 9.5 10.1 11.1 12.0 11.8 12.8 82.7 83.4 84.2 85.3 42.9 42.6 42.7 43.3 24.4 23.8 23.6 24.5 18.5 18.8 19.0 18.8 11.8 12.1 12.1 12.0 28.0 28.7 29.4 30.1 85.2 85.6 86.7 85.0 34.5 34.6 35.0 34.4 50.8 51.0 51.6 50.7 21.6 21.9 21.9 21.6 29.1 29.1 29.7 29.1 38.4 39.3 40.1 41.0 79.5 79.6 80.2 82.3 39.3 39.1 38.5 39.9 21.0 21.2 20.6 21.9 18.3 17.9 17.9 18.0 11.7 11.8 12.0 11.9 28.4 28.8 29.7 30.6 79.9 80.3 80.8 85.4 32.8 33.0 33.2 35.1 47.1 47.3 47.6 50.3 22.5 23.2 23.5 22.5 24.6 24.1 24.1 27.9 41.9 42.9 44.1 44.9 83.8 89.2 91.6 41.3 44.9 45.3 22.3 25.2 25.0 19.0 19.7 20.3 12.5 12.5 13.0 30.0 31.8 33.3 88.9 91.8 92.7 39.8 41.1 41.5 49.1 50.7 51.2 23.6 24.4 25.2 25.4 25.5 26.3 26.0 45.7 46.7 47.6 48.5 !8 .5 1.0 42.6 43.9 38.9 40.6 38.3 48.6 48.8 47.2 41.4 52.1 49.7 50.3 55.4 59.4 66.8 77.8 85.6 81.6 92.3 24.9 21.6 19.6 20.4 20.6 27.0 27.2 26.0 22.3 28.5 26.7 27.2 31.2 33.1 38.4 46.5 51.0 48.1 51.0 3.8 4.2 5.0 5.4 6.1 6.4 4.7 5.8 7.0 7.9 Seasonally adjusted annual rates II.. III. IV.. 1968: I — III IV p.. 1 Federal and State corporate income and excess profits taxes. 2 Includes depreciation and accidental damages. 3 Corporate profits after taxes plus corporate capital consumption allowances. Note.—Beginning 1962 data reflect the new depreciation guidelines issued by the Treasury Department July 11,1962' and the investment tax credit provided in the Revenue Act of 1962. Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 3 o8 TABLE B—71.—Sales, profits, and stockholders1 equity, all manufacturing corporations (except newspapers), 1947—68 [Billions of dollars] All manufacturing corporations Year or quarter Profits Sales (net) Nondurable goods industries Durable goods industries Profits Profits Before taxes After taxes Stockholders' Sales equityi (net) Before taxes After taxes StockSales holders' (net) equity l Before taxes After taxes Stockholders' equity» 1947.. 1948.. 1949- 150.7 165.6 154.9 16.6 18.4 14.4 10.1 11.5 9.0 65.1 72.2 77.6 66.6 75.3 70.3 7.6 8.9 7.5 4.5 5.4 4.5 31.1 34.1 37.0 84.1 90.4 84.6 9.0 9.5 7.0 5.6 6.2 4.6 34.0 38.1 40.6 19501951.. 1952.. 1953.. 1954.. 181.9 245.0 250.2 265.9 248.5 23.2 27.4 22.9 24.4 20.9 12.9 11.9 10.7 11.3 11.2 83.3 98.3 103.7 108.2 113.1 86.8 116.8 122.0 137.9 122.8 12.9 15.4 12.9 14.0 11.4 6.7 6.1 5.5 5.8 5.6 39.9 47.2 49.8 52.4 54.9 95.1 128.1 128.0 128.0 125.7 10.3 12.1 10.0 10.4 9.6 6.1 5.7 5.2 5.5 5.6 43.5 51.1 53.9 55.7 58.2 1955.. 1956.. 1957.. 1958.. 1959.. 278.4 307.3 320.0 305.3 338.0 28.6 29.8 28.2 22.7 29.7 15.1 16.2 15.4 12.7 16.3 120.1 131.6 141.1 147.4 157.1 142.1 159.5 166.0 148.6 169.4 16.5 16.5 15.8 11.4 15.8 8.1 8.3 7.9 5.8 8.1 58.8 65.2 70.5 72.8 77.9 136. 3 147.8 154.1 156.7 168.5 12.1 13.2 12.4 11.3 13.9 7.0 7.8 7.5 6.9 8.3 61.3 66.4 70.6 74.6 79.2 I960.. 19611962.. 1963.. 1964.. 345.7 356.4 389.9 412.7 443.1 27.5 27.5 31.9 34.9 39.6 15.2 15.3 17.7 19.5 23.2 165.4 172.6 181.4 189.7 199.8 173.9 175.2 195.5 209.0 226.3 14.0 13.6 16.7 18.5 21.2 7.0 6.9 8.6 9.5 11.6 82.3 84.9 89.1 93.3 98.5 171.8 181-.2 194.4 203.6 216.8 13.5 13.9 15.1 16.4 18.3 8.2 8.5 9.2 10.0 11.6 83.1 87.7 92.3 96.3 101.3 1965.. 1966. 1967. 492.2 554.2 575.4 46.5 51.8 47.8 27.5 30.9 29.0 211.7 257.0 230.3 291.7 247.6 300.6 26.2 29.2 25.7 14.5 16.4 14.6 105.4 235.2 115.2 262.4 125.0 274.8 20.3 22.6 22.0 13.0 14.6 14.4 106.3 115.1 122.6 1966: I II III.... IV.... 129.9 141.0 137.8 145.5 12.4 14.0 12.3 13.1 7.2 8.4 7.4 7.9 222.4 228.6 233.4 236.8 68.0 75.4 71.1 77.3 7.0 8.2 6.5 7.5 3.8 4.6 3.7 4.2 110.0 114.2 117.1 119.3 61.9 65.6 66.7 68.2 5.4 5.8 5.8 5.6 3.4 3.7 3.7 3.7 112.4 114.3 116.3 117.5 1967: I II III.... IV.... 137.0 145.1 141.5 151.8 11.4 12.6 11.0 12.8 6.7 7.6 6.7 7.9 240.9 245.6 249.7 254.3 71.1 77.0 72.6 80.0 6.2 7.2 5.4 7.0 3.4 4.1 3.1 4.0 121.6 123.7 126.0 128.6 65.9 68.2 68.9 71.8 5.2 5.4 5.6 5.9 3.3 3.5 3.6 3.9 119.3 121.8 123.6 125.7 1968: I II III.... 148.9 158.9 155.7 12.5 14.8 13.2 7.4 8.3 7.6 258.6 263.4 268.4 78.8 86.0 81.0 6.7 8.6 6.8 3.7 4.5 3.7 130.9 134.1 137.2 70.1 72.9 74.8 5.8 6.2 6.4 3.7 3.8 4.0 127.7 129.4 131.2 * Annual data are average equity for the year (using four end-of-quarter figures). Note.—For explanatory notes concerning compilation of the series, see "Quarterly Financial Report for Manufacturing Corporations," Federal Trade Commission and Securities and Exchange Commission. Data are not necessarily comparable from one period to another due to changes in accounting procedures, industry classifications, sampling procedures, etc. Specific information about the effects of the more significant changes and revisions is contained in the following issues of the "Quarterly Financial Report": third quarter 1953, third quarter 1956, first quarter 1959, and first quarter 1965. Sources: Federal Trade Commission and Securities and Exchange Commission. 309 T A B L E B—72.—Relation of profits after taxes to stockholders* equity and to sales, all manufacturing corporations {except newspapers), by industry group, 1947—68 Ail manufacturmg corMoporator tions Total vehi(ex- dur- cles cept able^ and equipnewsment papers) Year or quarter Durable goods industries Aircraft and parts Electrical machinery, equipment, and supplies p.: PriMa Stone, Fab- mary riclay, iron for ery cated and and (ex- metal steel motal glass prodinelec- prod- dusucts trical) ucts tries dusines Fur -nri fjY Lumber and wood products (except furniture) Instruments and related products Miscellaneous manufacturmg (including ordnance) Ratio of profits after Federal taxes (annual rate) to stockholders equity —percent2 1947. . 1948 1949 1950 1951 . 1952 1953 1954 1955 . 1956 1957 1958 1959 . . 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 . . . 1967: 1 II III IV 1968: 1. II 111 15.6 16.0 11.6 15.4 12.1 10 3 10.5 9.9 12.6 12.3 10.9 8.6 10.4 9.2 8.9 9.8 10.3 11.6 13.0 13.4 11.7 11.2 12.4 10.8 12.5 11.5 12.6 11.4 14.4 15.7 12.1 16.9 13.0 11 1 11.1 10.3 13.8 12 8 11.3 8.0 10.4 8.5 8.1 9.6 10.1 11.7 13.8 14.2 11.7 11.2 13.2 9.8 12.5 11.3 13.4 10.7 16.4 19.9 22.1 25.3 14.3 13.9 13.9 14.1 21.7 13 1 14.2 8.2 14.5 13.5 11.4 16.3 16.7 16.9 19.5 15.9 11.7 12.5 16.4 3.8 14.0 16.5 17.9 7.4 17.7 13 2 8.1 7.3 9.8 12.7 11.3 12.2 15.2 14.4 12.9 11.7 12.5 12.4 14.7 13.6 14.4 14.3 19.0 16.1 13.6 20 9 14.0 13 7 13.1 12 4 12.3 11 4 12l5 10 2 12 5 9 5 8.9 10.0 10.1 11.2 13.5 14.8 12.8 12.2 12.8 11.9 14.1 11.8 11.4 11.5 15.7 16.3 11.6 14 1 13 0 11 3 9.8 86 10 3 12 6 10.7 69 9.7 75 7.8 9.1 9.6 12.5 14.1 15.0 12.9 12.3 15.2 12.2 12.0 11.1 13.6 12.3 17.6 17.0 10.4 16 0 13 4 10 1 9.8 76 10 0 10 7 9.3 73 80 56 5.9 7.9 8.3 10.1 13.2 14 7 12.7 12.7 14.2 11.7 12.1 10.0 12.5 12.1 12.0 12.4 14.7 14.2 10.0 8.1 14 3 15 1 12 3 13 8 8 5 11 6 10.7 11.1 8 1 10 4 13.5 15 5 12 7 16 4 11.4 9.3 72 60 8.0 7.9 72 7.1 7.1 6.1 5.4 7.5 7.0 7.6 8.8 9.8 9.8 11.9 10.2 14.8 7.7 10.9 7.9 13.7 7.9 12.8 6.0 7.8 9.1 9.5 8.6 10.5 4.5 8.9 11.5 9.9 14 0 15.0 13.1 17 7 14 2 11 7 11.8 12 5 15 6 14 9 12.4 10 2 12 7 9.9 8.9 8.9 8.7 9.6 10.3 9.9 8.2 3.3 9.4 10.4 9.5 18.0 15.9 8.1 15 2 11 3 86 8.2 60 92 11 6 8.5 6 3 8.9 6.5 4.9 7.9 8.3 10.1 13.4 14.2 12.1 10.6 12.0 12.4 13.3 3.9 9.1 11.7 12.0 12.8 12.5 22 9 19.2 9.1 17 5 11 9 85 7.1 6 3 11.1 87 4.7 5.7 9.4 3.6 4.1 5.6 8.2 9.9 10.1 10.0 8.6 5.5 8.6 10.5 9.6 10.9 16.1 16.3 6.0 5.5 3.3 5.1 3.4 2.7 2.6 2.1 2.9 3.4 2.6 2.0 2.7 2.1 1.6 2.3 2.4 2.9 3.7 3.9 3.5 3.2 3.5 3.6 3.8 2.8 3.6 3.5 11.4 9.9 5.9 9.4 5.5 4.1 3.5 3.4 5.4 3.9 2.3 2.8 4.2 1.7 1.9 2.5 3.3 3.9 4.0 3.8 3.4 2.4 3.4 4.0 3.7 4.4 5.7 5.8 14.4 14.0 12.1 16 7 13 2 11 6 11.4 12 3 12.5 12 4 12.0 10.6 13.1 11.6 10.6 12.0 12.1 14.4 17.5 20.9 18.0 15.7 16.9 18.7 20.3 14.1 15.5 18.0 14.0 12.2 7.2 12 3 97 70 8.2 7.5 8.5 11 6 7.7 8.2 9.3 9.2 9.9 9,4 8.8 9.5 10.7 15.4 13.1 12.8 12.5 13.2 13.9 12.6 9.6 12.2 7.7 7.8 7.1 8.6 6.1 4.8 4.6 5.5 6.0 5.8 5.7 5.4 6.5 5.9 5.4 5.9 6.0 7.2 8.6 9.5 8.5 8.0 7.9 8.8 9.1 7.4 7.6 8.7 6.3 5.6 3.6 56 3.7 2.7 2.9 2.8 3.1 3.6 ?.5 3.0 3.5 3.5 3.6 3.4 3.3 3.6 3.8 4,9 4.2 4.2 4.1 4.2 4.1 4.2 3.1 4.0 Profits after taxes per dollar of sales—cents 1947 1948 ._ . 1949 1950 . 1951 1952 . . 1953 1954 1955... . 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 . 1962 1963 1964. 1965 1966 1967 1967: 1 II III.— IV 1968: 1 II lll..__ 67 7.0 5.8 7.1 4 8 4.3 4.3 4.5 5.4 5.3 4.8 4.2 4.8 4.4 4.3 4.5 4.7 5.2 5.6 5.6 5.0 4.9 5.2 4.7 5.2 5.0 5.2 4.9 67 7.1 6.4 7.7 53 4.5 4.2 46 5.7 5.2 4.8 3.9 4.8 4.0 3.9 4.4 4.5 5.1 5.7 5.6 4.8 4.8 5.3 4.3 5.0 4.7 5.2 4.5 6.0 6.9 7.9 8.3 4.7 4.7 3.9 5.1 6.9 5.2 5.4 4.0 6.3 5.9 5.5 6.9 6.9 7.0 7.2 6.2 4.9 5.3 6.3 1.9 5.4 6.1 6.2 3.4 2.9 2.4 1.6 1.4 1.8 2.4 2.3 2.6 3.3 3.0 2.7 2.6 2.5 2.6 2.9 2.9 3.2 3.4 6.3 5.9 5.7 7.2 50 4.5 4.1 4.5 4.4 3.8 4.2 3.8 4.4 3.5 3.5 3.7 3.8 4.2 4.8 4.8 4.4 4.2 4.4 4.2 4.8 4.2 4.1 4.1 7.2 7.3 6.4 7.3 5.5 4.8 4.2 4.4 5.1 5.4 4.8 3.7 4.8 3.9 4.1 4.5 4.7 5.8 6.2 6.4 5.7 5.7 6.3 5.5 5.3 5.1 5.7 5.6 7.4 7.1 5.1 6.8 5.0 4.0 3.6 3.1 3.8 4.0 3.6 3.1 3.2 2.4 2.5 3.1 3.2 3.7 4.5 4.9 4.5 4.6 4.9 4.2 4.2 3.6 4.4 4.2 See footnotes at end of table. 310 6.6 7.6 6.5 7.9 5.8 4.7 5.3 5.3 7.2 6.7 6.6 5.4 5.4 5.1 4.6 3.9 4 R 5.6 5.7 5.8 4.8 4.8 4.8 3.9 5.7 5.1 5.5 2.9 8.9 9.0 6.9 10.2 7.8 6.7 6.3 6.6 8.3 9.3 6.6 4.7 5.8 5.4 5.3 5.5 5.3 6.5 7.3 8.2 6.8 8.1 7.7 5.3 6.0 5.4 6.4 5.9 7.9 8.6 8.6 10.1 7.1 6.6 6.5 7.4 8.6 8.2 7.5 6.8 7.9 6.6 5.8 5.6 5.3 5.6 5.9 5.6 4.8 2.3 5.4 5.7 5.4 2.6 6.4 6.3 TABLE B—72.—Relation of profits after taxes to stockholders'' equity and to sales, all manufacturing corporations {except newspapers), by industry group, 1947—68—Continued Nondurable goods industries Year or quarter Total nondurable i Food and kindred products Tobacco manufactures Textile mill products Apparel and related products Paper and allied products Printing and publishing (except newspapers) Chemicals and allied products Petroleum refining Rubber and miscellaneous plastic products Leather and leather products Ratio of profits after Federal taxes (annual rate) to stockholders ' equity—percent2 1947 . 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 . . . 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1967: I.. IL III IV. 1968: I.. IL III 16.6 16.2 11.2 14.1 11.2 9.7 9.9 9.6 11.4 11.8 10.6 9.2 10.4 9.8 9.6 9.9 10.4 11.5 12.2 12.7 11.8 11.2 11.6 11.7 12.5 11.7 11.7 12.1 17.6 12.8 11.8 12.3 8.1 7.6 8.1 8.1 8.9 9.3 8.7 8.7 9.3 8.7 8.9 8.8 9.0 10.0 10.7 11.2 10.8 9.4 10.3 11.7 11.8 9.9 10.2 11.4 10.1 13.6 12.6 11.5 9.5 8.4 9.4 10.2 11.4 11.7 12.5 13.5 13.4 13.4 13.6 13.1 13.4 13.4 13.5 14.1 14.4 12.1 14.7 15.8 15.0 13.5 13.6 15.9 6.7 6.8 5.4 6.5 4.5 4.1 4.3 4.4 5.1 5.3 4.9 4.4 4.9 4.8 4.7 4.7 4.9 5.4 5.5 5.6 5.3 5.1 5.2 5.2 5.5 5.3 5.2 5.3 4.2 3.3 3.3 3.4 2.0 1.9 2.0 2.1 2.3 2.4 2.2 2.2 2.4 2.3 2.3 2.3 2.4 2.7 2.7 2.7 2.6 2.3 2.5 2.8 2.8 2.5 2.5 2.7 4.1 5.2 5.1 4.9 3.8 3.2 3.7 4.2 4.8 5.0 5.2 5.4 5.4 5.5 5.7 5.7 5.9 5.9 5.9 5.9 5.9 5.1 5.8 6.4 6.2 5.7 5.5 6.0 19.5 18.7 7.6 12.7 8.2 4.2 4.6 1.8 5.7 5.8 4.2 3.5 7.5 5.8 5.0 6.2 6.1 8.5 10.9 10.1 7.6 5.9 7.1 7.8 9.5 7.1 9.1 9.5 18.9 12.1 7.5 10.1 2.9 4.4 5.1 4.5 6.1 8.1 6.3 4.9 8.6 7.7 7.2 9.3 7.7 11.7 12.7 13.3 12.0 9.6 8.6 14.4 15.1 12.0 9.3 15.0 22.0 16.4 10.7 16.2 13.9 10.5 10.1 9.9 11.5 11.6 8.9 8.1 9.5 8.5 7.9 8.1 8.1 9.3 9.4 10.6 9.1 9.0 9.5 8.6 9.3 8.5 10.5 9.2 17.2 14.7 11.4 11.5 10.3 9.1 9.4 9.2 10.2 13.0 11.7 9.0 11.4 10.6 8.5 10.3 9.2 12.6 14.2 15.6 13.0 12.1 13.5 14.1 12.2 10.9 10.7 14.8 15.9 15.8 13.2 17.8 12.2 10.9 10.7 11.6 14.7 14.2 13.3 11.4 13.7 12.2 11.8 12.4 12.9 14.4 15.2 15.1 13.1 13.0 13.7 12.2 13.3 13.4 13.6 12.8 15.2 13.3 13.4 12.7 13.4 13.9 12.5 10.0 9.8 10.1 10.3 10.1 11.3 11.4 11.8 12.4 12.5 12.6 12.3 12.1 13.1 12.9 11.9 12.1 12.4 12.3 8.7 16.9 14.8 11.1 11.3 10.6 13.2 12.2 11.1 9.1 11.0 9.1 9.3 9.6 9.2 10.6 11.7 12.2 10.3 9.3 9.0 9.2 13.7 10.8 13.5 11.8 14.0 10.4 6.2 10.9 2.1 5.8 6.0 5.9 8.5 7.2 7.0 5.7 8.5 6.3 4.4 6.9 6.9 10.5 11.6 12.9 11.9 12.8 7.9 12.1 14.6 13.3 12.0 12.4 11.1 10.1 10.4 10.6 11.1 11.6 10.6 9.5 9.5 9.9 10.3 9.7 10.8 10.9 11.1 11.2 11.0 11.2 10.9 10.7 11.2 11.2 10.6 10.7 4.4 4.7 3.8 5.8 4.5 3.6 3.8 4.0 4.4 4.4 4.2 3.5 4.0 3.6 3.8 3.7 3.6 4.1 4.3 4.4 3.9 3.7 3.4 3.6 5.1 4.2 4.8 4.5 4.3 3.3 2.2 3.7 .6 1.8 1.8 1.9 2.5 2.1 2.0 1.7 2.2 1.6 1.1 1.8 1.8 2.6 2.8 3.G 3.0 3.2 2.1 3.0 3.4 3.3 3.1 3.3 Profits after taxes per dollar of sales—cents 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958........ 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1967: I IL... Ill — IV.... 1968: I ML-I 8.2 8.3 4.1 5.8 3.4 1.9 2.2 1.0 2.6 2.6 1.9 1.6 3.0 2.5 2.1 2.4 2.3 3.1 3.8 3.6 2.9 2.4 2.7 2.9 3.4 2.7 3.2 3.4 4.6 3.1 2.1 2.8 .6 1.0 1.2 1.1 1.3 1.6 1.3 1.0 1.5 1.4 1.3 1.6 1.4 2.1 2.3 2.4 2.3 1.8 1.7 2.8 2.9 2.5 1.9 2.7 10.7 8.5 6.5 8.8 6.6 5.7 5.4 5.6 6.1 6.1 5.0 4.7 5.2 5.0 4.7 4.6 4.5 5.1 4.9 5.4 4.7 4.8 4.9 4.5 4.7 4.4 5.1 4.5 6.1 5.2 4.5 4.5 3.7 3.3 3.4 3.4 3.6 4.2 3.7 3.1 4.0 3.6 2.8 3.4 3.2 4.3 4.8 5.1 4.4 4.3 4.6 4.9 3.9 3.8 3.6 4.8 8.8 8.8 8.2 10.3 6.5 6.1 6.1 6.8 8.3 8.0 7.6 7.0 7.9 7.5 7.3 7.4 7.5 7.9 7.9 7.8 6.9 6.9 7.0 6.5 7.0 7.0 6.9 6.6 1 Includes certain industries not shown separately. 2 Annual ratios based on average equity for the year (using four end-of-quarter figures). Quarterly ratios based on equity at end of quarter only. Note.—Ratios based on data in millions of dollars. For explanatory notes concerning compilation of the series, see "Quarterly Financial Report for Manufacturing Corporations," Federal Trade Commission and Securities and Exchange Commission. See also Note, Table B-71. Sources: Federal Trade Commission and Securities and Exchange Commission. 311 T A B L E B—73.—Sources and uses of funds, nonfarm nonfinancial corporate business, 1957—68 [Billions of dollars] Source or use of funds 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 42.0 42.2 55.5 47.3 54.7 63.3 65.9 70.2 89.3 99.1 94.0 109.1 30.6 29.5 35.0 34.4 35.6 41.8 43.9 50.5 56.6 61.1 61.5 63.8 Undistributed profits 1 .. 11.8 Corporate inventory valuation adjustment. -1.5 Capital consumption allowances 1 ... 20.3 8.3 12.6 10.0 10.2 12.4 13.6 -.3 -.5 .2 -.1 .3 -.5 18.3 23.1 24.4 20.7 5 -1.7 -1.7 -1.2 -3.1 21.4 22.9 24.2 25.4 29.2 30.8 32.8 35.2 38.4 42.0 45.6 12.7 20.5 12.9 19.1 21.5 22.0 19.7 32.7 38.0 32.5 45.3 2.5 4.6 1.8 .1 .3 6.6 1.2 1.9 .6 4.6 2.9 2.5 .7 4.4 1.1 4.7 -.3 3.9 3.5 2.9 .5 6.0 1.5 4.0 1.4 4.0 3.3 3.6 1.3 3.4 .9 1.8 5.4 3.1 9.2 1.3 7.4 1.9 4.3 1.2 2.3 10.2 15.1 2.7 3.8 6.9 5.2 2.5 1.7 7.8 3.1 .2 -3.8 6.6 5.1 .2 13.4 2.9 5.5 4.3 11.1 2.1 5.8 88.2 Sources, total 1 Internal sources . External sources Stocks.. Bonds Mortgages Bank loans, n.e.c... Other loans Trade debt Profits tax liability. Other liabilities.... 11.4 2.1 2.4 6.3 5.7 .4 1.2 1.1 -.6 .7 .2 .5 4.3 -2.1 -2.6 2.2 2.4 Uses, total. 40.0 42.1 Purchases of physical assets. 34.7 27.3 Nonresidential fixed investment Residential structures... Change in business inventories 33.4 .7 28.4 1.4 Increase in financial assets 2 .. Liquid assets Demand deposits and currency Time deposits U.S. Government securities Open-market paper Consumer credit Trade credit Other financial assets Discrepancy (uses less sources). 2.2 1.6 3.0 3.5 1.2 .7 3.0 1.3 .3 1.0 4.9 3.1 2.4 - 2 . 2 3.6 4.0 54.4 45.2 36.9 39.2 31.1 1.7 34.9 1.3 55.0 61.7 65.8 66.9 37.0 44.7 46.7 53.5 33.2 2.2 37.0 3.0 38.6 3.7 44.0 3.6 21.3 96.7 90.6 105.2 64.9 79.8 74.1 81.3 53.2 3.8 63.0 2.8 64.9 3.7 70.1 3.9 .6 -2.5 41 . 3.0 15 . 4.7 4.3 5.9 7.9 14.1 5.5 7.4 5.3 14.8 17.4 6.1 18.0 16.9 19.1 13.4 23.3 16.9 16.5 24.9 -.1 * * 2.5 4.3 .6 .8 1.0 .9 7.4 -.4 .3 5 6 -3.9 . 3.5 41 . 1.5 -1.0 .9 * 66 . .1 -.5 1.3 1.7 1.9 -.9 3.7 -5.4 .7 -.2 .1 .5 .9 .1 10.0 4.6 .9 8.2 4.1 .2 2.6 2.5 7^9 3.4 .8 7.2 3.3 .2 6.3 3.7 -1.9 -i -1.1 -2.0 1 .3 -1.6 -.8 -2.5 -1.8 3.2 3.9 3.9 .7 -1.7 4.1 -.7 .3 2.0 .5 -1.4 -2.1 -1.2 -3.0 1.4 .7 1.4 .8 2.3 .8 3.6 8] 5 4.8 -i 1.0 9.1 2.5 1.0 8.7 5.3 1.6 13.8 2.2 -3.3 -1.1 -2.3 -3.4 -2.9 1.2 12.8 7.9 1.1 10.8 3.3 The figures shown here for "internal sources," "undistributed profits," and "capital consumption allowances" differ from those shown for "cash flow, net of dividends," "undistributed profits" and "capital consumption allowances" in the gross corporate product table in the national income and product accounts of the Department of Commerce for the following reasons: (1) these figures include, and the statistics in the gross corporate product table exclude, branch profits remitted from foreigners net of corresponding U.S. remittances to foreigners; and (2) these figures exclude, and the gross corporate product figures include, the internal funds of corporations whose major activity is farming. 3 Includes some categories not shown separately. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System 312 TABLE B—74.—Current assets and liabilities of United States corporations^ 1939-68 [Billions of dollars] Current assets Current liabilities Ad- End of year or quarter vances ReNet Fedand Cash U.S. ceiv- Notes Notes Other workeral Other preon and and ing Gov- ables curincurInpayfrom acacernrent capiTotal hand venand U.S. counts tories rent Total ments, counts come tal ment liaastax U.S. in securi- Gov- receivPaysets 2 liabili- biliable Govbanks ties ern- 1 able ties ties ernment 1 ment . 54.5 10.8 2.2 22.1 18.0 1.4 30.0 21.9 1.2 6.9 24.5 60.3 72.9 83.6 93.8 97.2 13.1 13.9 17.6 21.6 21.6 2.0 4.0 10.1 16.4 20.9 0.1 .6 4.0 5.0 4.7 23.9 27.4 23.3 21.9 21.8 19.8 25.6 27.3 27.6 26.8 1.5 1.4 1.3 1.3 1.4 32.8 40.7 47.3 51.6 51.7 0.6 .8 2.0 2.2 1.8 22.6 25.6 24.0 24.1 25.0 2.5 7.1 12.6 16.6 15.5 7.1 7.2 8.7 8.7 9.4 27.5 32.3 36.3 42.1 45.6 1945.-. 1946 97.4 108.1 21.7 22.8 21.1 15.3 2.7 .7 23.2 30.0 26.3 37.6 2.4 1.7 45.8 51.9 .9 24.8 31.5 10.4 8.5 9.7 11.8 51.6 56.2 1947 1948 1949 123.6 133.0 133.1 25.0 25.3 26.5 14.1 14.8 16.8 44.6 48.9 45.3 1.6 1.6 1.4 61.5 64.4 60.7 10.7 11.5 9.3 13.2 13.5 14.0 62.1 68.6 72.4 1950 1951 1952 . 1953 1954 161.5 179.1 186.2 190.6 194.6 28.1 30.0 30.8 31.1 33.4 19.7 20.7 19.9 21.5 19.2 1.1 2.7 2.8 2.6 2.4 55.7 58.8 64.6 65.9 71.2 55.1 64.9 65.8 67.2 65.3 1.7 2.1 2.4 2.4 3.1 79.8 92.6 96.1 98.9 99.7 .4 1.3 2.3 2.2 2.4 47.9 53.6 57.0 57.3 59.3 16.7 21.3 18.1 18.7 15.5 14.9 16.5 18.7 20.7 22.5 81.6 86.5 90.1 91.8 94.9 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 224.0 237.9 244.7 255.3 277.3 34.6 34.8 34.9 37.4 36.3 23.5 19.1 18.6 18.8 22.8 2.3 2.6 2.8 2.8 2.9 86.6 95.1 99.4 106.9 117.7 72.8 80.4 82.2 81.9 88.4 4.2 5.9 6.7 7.5 9.1 121.0 130.5 133.1 136.6 153.1 2.3 2.4 1.7 73.8 81.5 84.3 88.7 99.3 19.3 17.6 15.4 12.9 15.0 25.7 29.0 31.1 33.3 37.0 103.0 107.4 111.6 118.7 124.2 1960 1961 289.0 306.8 37.2 41.1 20.1 20.0 3.1 3.4 126.1 135.8 91.8 95.2 10.6 160.4 11.4 171.2 1.8 1.8 105.0 112.8 13.5 14.1 40.1 42.5 128.6 135.6 New series 3 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 304.6 326.5 351.7 372.2 410.2 40.7 43.7 46.5 47.3 49.9 19.2 19.6 20.2 18.6 17.0 3.4 3.7 3.6 3.4 3.9 133.3 144.2 156.8 169.9 190.2 95.2 100.7 107.0 113.5 126.9 12.9 14.7 17.8 19.6 22.3 155.8 170.9 188.2 202.2 229.6 1.8 2.0 2.5 110.0 119.1 130.4 140.3 160.4 14.2 15.2 16.5 17.0 19.1 29.8 34.5 38.7 42.2 46.9 148.8 155.6 163.5 170.0 180.7 1966 1967 443.4 464.0 50.1 52.3 15.7 12.4 4.5 5.1 205.1 144.5 23.6 253.2 25.9 262.9 4.4 5.8 176.2 183.6 19.1 15.2 53.6 58.3 190.2 201.1 Ill IV 415.7 425.7 433.4 443.4 47.5 48.4 47.6 50.1 17.2 15.5 14.8 15.7 3.9 4.0 4.2 4.5 193.2 199.2 203.5 205.1 130.4 134.6 139.5 144.5 23.6 24.0 23.8 23.6 232.2 237.5 244.4 253.2 3.3 3.5 4.0 4.4 160.6 166.4 170.2 176.2 19.1 16.7 18.0 19.1 49.1 51.0 52.3 53.6 183.6 188.2 189.0 190.2 1967: 1 II Ill IV 443.9 444.9 452.7 464.0 47.3 47.7 49.1 52.3 14.4 11.5 10.8 12.4 4.4 4.6 4.7 5.1 205.1 207.5 211.5 214.5 148.1 149.2 151.2 153.8 24.8 24.3 25.4 25.9 251.4 251.1 255.4 262.9 4.9 5.7 5.8 173.5 177.0 178.6 183.6 18.6 12.7 13.5 15.2 54.3 55.9 57.6 58.3 192.6 193.8 197.2 201.1 1968: 1 II — III 471.4 481.9 492.2 50.1 51.4 52.8 14.6 13.3 12.9 4.8 4.7 4.8 216.6 156.6 223.6 159.9 229.5 163.7 28.7 265.4 29.1 272.1 28.6 281.3 6.1 6.2 6.3 181.9 188.0 193.8 17.3 15.4 15.6 60.2 62.5 65.5 206.0 209.8 210.9 1939 . . 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1966: 1... 38.3 42 .4 4C .0 214.5 153.8 21.6 39 . 3 31 . 5 2.3 1.7 2.7 3.1 5.4 1 Receivables from and payables to U.S. Government do not include amounts offset against each other on corporations' books or amounts arising from subcontracting which are not directly due from or to the U.S. Government. Wherever possible, adjustments have been made to include U.S. Government advances offset against inventories on corporations' books. 2 Includes marketable securities other than U.S. Government. 3 Generally reflects definitions and classifications used in "Statistics of Income" for 1961. Note.—Data relate to all United States corporations, excluding banks, savings and loan associations, insurance companies, and beginning with the new series for 1961, investment companies. Year-end data through 1965 are based on "Statistics of Income" (Treasury Department), covering virtually all corporations in the United States. "Statistics of Income" data may not be strictly comparable from year to year because of changes in the tax laws, basis for filing returns, and processing of data for compilation purposes. All other figures shown are estimates based on data compiled from many different sources, Including data on corporations registered with the Securities and Exchange Commission. Source: Securities and Exchange Commission. 313 TABLE B-75.—State and municipal and corporate securities offered, 1934-68 l [Millions of dollars] Corporate securities offered for cash 2 Year or quarter State and municipal securities offered for cash (principal amounts) Gross proceeds 3 Proposed uses of net proceeds * New money Total Common stock Preferred stock Bonds and notes Total Total Plant and equipment Working capital Retirement of securities Other purposes 1934.. 939 397 371 384 32 26 231 95 1935.. 1936.. 1937.. 1938.. 1939.. 1,232 1,121 908 1,108 1,128 2,332 4,572 2,310 2,155 2,164 22 272 285 25 87 86 271 406 86 98 2,225 4,029 1,618 2,044 1,980 2,266 4,431 2,239 2,110 2,115 208 858 991 681 325 111 380 574 504 170 96 478 417 177 155 1,865 3,368 1,100 1,206 1,695 193 204 148 222 95 1940.. 1941.. 1942.. 1943.. 1944.. 1,238 956 524 435 661 2,677 2,667 1,062 1,170 3,202 108 110 34 56 163 183 167 112 124 369 2,386 2,390 917 990 2,669 2,615 2,623 1,043 1,147 3,142 569 868 474 308 657 424 661 287 141 252 145 207 187 167 405 1,854 1,583 396 739 2,389 192 172 173 100 96 1945.. 1946.. 1947.. 1948.. 1949.. 795 1,157 2,324 2,690 2,907 6,011 6,900 6,577 7,078 6,052 397 891 779 614 736 758 127 762 492 425 4,855 4,882 5,036 5,973 4,890 5,902 6,757 6,466 6,959 5,959 1,080 3,279 4,591 5,929 4,606 638 2,115 3,409 4,221 3,724 442 1,164 1,182 1,708 882 4,555 2,868 1,352 307 401 267 610 524 722 952 1950.. 1951.. 1952.. 1953.. 1954.. 3,532 3,189 4,401 5,558 6,969 811 6,361 7,741 1,212 9,534 ,369 8,898 ,326 9,516 1,213 631 838 564 489 816 4,920 5,691 7,601 7,083 7,488 6,261 7,607 9,380 8,755 9,365 4,006 6,531 8,180 7,960 6,780 2,966 5,110 6,312 5,647 5,110 1,041 1,421 1,868 2,313 1,670 1,271 486 664 260 1,875 984 589 537 535 709 1955. 1956. 1957. 1958. 1959. 5,977 5,446 6,958 7,449 7,681 10,240 10,939 12,884 11,558 9,748 2,185 2,301 2,516 1,334 2,027 635 636 411 571 531 7,420 8,002 9,957 9,653 7,190 10, 049 7,957 10,749 9,663 12,661 11,784 11,372 9,907 9,527 8,578 5,333 6,709 9,040 7,792 6,084 2,624 2,954 2,744 2,115 2,494 1,227 364 214 549 135 864 721 663 915 814 1960. 1961. 1962. 1963. 1964. 7,230 8,360 8,558 10,107 10,544 10,154 13,165 10,705 12,211 13,957 1,664 3,294 1,314 1,012 2,679 409 450 422 343 412 8,081 9,420 8,969 10,856 10,865 9,924 8,758 12,885 10,715 10,501 8,240 12,049 8,898 13,792 11,233 5,662 7,413 5,652 5,340 7,003 3,097 3,303 2,588 3,558 4,230 271 868 754 1,526 754 895 1,302 1,507 1,625 1,805 1965... 1966... 1967.-. 1968 P.. 11,148 11,089 14,288 16,295 15,992 18, 074 24,798 22,400 1,547 1,939 1,959 3,860 725 574 885 640 13,720 15,801 13,063 15,561 17,841 15,806 21,954 24,409 22,230 17,900 7,712 12,430 16,154 5,352 3,376 6,076 996 241 312 1,741 1,795 1,867 IIIII. IV.. 2,870 3,177 2,434 2,609 5,094 5,115 4,197 3,669 519 975 171 274 215 115 143 101 4,359 4,025 3,883 3,294 5,036 5,046 4,143 3,617 4,320 4,644 3,663 3,179 3,258 3,668 2,907 2,597 1,062 976 756 582 51 72 52 67 665 331 428 371 IIIII. IV.. 4.046 3,799 3,038 3,404 5,464 6,208 6,832 6,294 298 518 447 696 92 208 231 354 5,074 5,482 6,154 5,244 5,403 6,109 6,716 6,181 5,076 5,672 5,943 5,538 3,808 4,265 4,329 3,752 1,268 1,407 1,614 1,787 39 51 133 89 287 386 640 554 3,658 3,771 4,574 4,295 5,178 740 5,705 832 5,280 980 6,235 1,305 249 124 180 85 4,189 4,749 4,120 4,845 5,081 5,594 5,170 4,627 4,802 4,610 3,591 3,262 2,880 1,036 1,540 1,730 67 50 30 387 742 530 1966: 1967: 1968: I . III... IV p . . 1 These data cover substantially all new issues of State, municipal, and corporate securities offered for cash sale in the United States in amounts over $100,000 and with terms to maturity of more than 1 year. 2 Excludes notes issued exclusively to commercial banks, intercorporate transactions, sales of investment company issues, and issues to be sold over an extended period, such as offerings under employee-purchase plans. 3 Number of units multiplied by offering price. * Net proceeds represents the amount received by the issuer after payment of compensation to distributors and other costs of flotation. Sources: Securities and Exchange Commission, "The Commercial and Financial Chronicle," and "The Bond Buyer." TABLE B-76.—Common stock prices, earnings, and yields, and stock market credit, 1939-68 Standard & Poor's common stock data Price index1 Year or month Totai (500 stocks) Industrials (425 stocks) Public utilities (50 stocks) Railroads (25 stocks) Dividend yield > (percent) Stock market credit Price/ earnings ratio 3 Customer credit (excluding U.S. Government securities) Total 1941-43=10 1939 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1967 Jan... Feb... Mar... Apr... May... June.. July... Aug... Sept.. Oct... Nov... Dec... 1968: Jan... Feb... Mar... Apr... May... June.. July... Aug... Sept.. Oct... Nov... Dec p.. 12.06 11.02 9.82 8.67 11.50 12.47 15.16 17.08 15.17 15.53 15.23 18.40 22.34 24.50 24.73 29.69 40.49, 46.62 44.38 46.24 57.38 55.85 66.27 62.38 69.87 81.37 88.17 85.26 91.93 98.70 84.45 87.36 89.42 90.96 92.59 91.43 93.01 94.49 95.81 95.66 92.66 95.30 95.04 90.75 89.09 95.67 97.87 100.53 100.30 98.11 101.34 103.76 105.40 106.48 11.77 10.69 9.72 8.78 11.49 12.34 14.72 16.48 14.85 15.34 15.00 18.33 22.68 24.78 24.84 30.25 42.40 49.80 47.63 49.36 61.45 59.43 69.99 65.54 73.39 86.19 93.48 91.09 99.18 107.49 89.88 93.35 95.86 97.54 99.59 98.61 100.38 102.11 103.84 104.16 100.90 103.91 103.11 98.33 96.77 104.42 107.02 109.73 109.16 106.77 110.53 113.29 114.77 116.01 16.34 15.05 10.93 7.74 11.34 12.81 16.84 20.76 18.01 16.77 17.87 19.96 20.59 22.86 24.03 27.57 31.37 32.25 32.19 37.22 44.15 46.86 60.20 59.16 64.99 69.91 76.08 68.21 68.10 66.42 70.63 70.45 70.03 71.70 70.70 67.39 67.77 68.03 67.45 64.93 63.48 64.61 68.02 65.61 62.62 63.66 62.92 65.21 67.55 66.60 66.77 66.93 70.59 70.54 Net debit balances* Bank loans to 'others"* Bank loans to brokers and dealers0 Millions of dollars 9.82 9.41 9.39 8.81 11.81 13.47 18.21 19.09 14.02 15.27 12.83 15.53 19.91 22.49 22.60 23.96 32.94 33.65 28.11 27.05 35.09 30.31 32.83 30.56 37.58 45.46 45.78 46.34 46.72 48.84 44.48 46.13 46.78 45.80 47.00 48.19 49.91 50.43 49.27 46.28 42.95 43.46 43.38 42.35 41.68 44.79 48.00 51.72 51.01 48.80 51.11 54.26 53.74 55.19 4.05 5.59 6.82 7.24 4.93 4.86 4.17 3.85 4.93 5.54 6.59 6.57 6.13 5.80 5.80 4.95 4.08 4.09 4.35 3.97 3.23 3.47 2.98 3.37 3.17 3.01 3.00 3.40 3.20 3.07 3.51 3.36 3.29 3.24 3.19 3.19 3.15 3.11 3.07 3.07 3.18 3.09 3.13 3.28 3.34 3.12 3.07 3.00 3.00 3.09 3.01 2.94 2.92 2.93 13.80 10.24 8.26 8.80 12.84 13.66 16.33 17.69 9.36 6.90 6.64 6.63 9.27 10.47 9.69 11.25 11.50 14.05 12.89 16.64 17.05 17.09 21.06 16.68 17.62 18.08 17.08 14.92 17.52 942 473 517 499 821 1,237 1,253 1,332 1,665 2,388 2,791 2,823 2,482 3,285 3,280 3,222 4,259 4,125 5,515 5,079 5,521 5,329 7,883 7,345 7,415 17.86 1,374 976 1,032 968 1,249 1,798 1,826 1,980 2,445 3,436 4,030 3,984 3,576 4,537 4,461 4,415 5,602 5,494 7,242 7,053 7,705 7,443 10,347 5,290 5,349 5,718 5,819 5,926 6,166 6,603 6,607 6,825 7,010 7,053 7,883 7,797 7,419 7,248 7,701 8,268 8,728 8,861 8,489 8,724 8,859 8,994 7,808 7,969 8,085 8,333 8,800 8,869 17.81 9,162 9,433 9,495 17.41 10,347 10,229 9,840 9,622 16.40 10,047 10,625 "17.'23' 11,138 11,277 10,976 11,238 11,336 11,575 17.01 353 432 503 515 469 428 561 573 648 780 1,048 1,239 1,161 1,094 1,252 1,181 1,193 1,343 1,369 1,727 1,974 «2,184 2,115 2,464 2,674 2,055 2,066 2,090 2,150 2,159 2,167 2,197 2,262 2,337 2,423 2,442 2,464 2,432 2,421 2,374 2,346 2,357 2,410 2,416 2,487 2,515 2,557 2,631 2,674 715 584 535 850 1,328 2,137 2,782 1,471 784 1,331 1,608 1,742 1,419 2,002 2,248 2,688 2,852 2,214 2,190 2,569 2,584 2,614 3,398 4,352 4,754 4,631 M,277 4,501 5,082 5,798 4,672 4,045 4,484 4,385 4,075 3,813 4,195 4,685 4,814 4,670 4,296 5,082 5,823 5,052 4,305 4,376 4,282 4,585 6,327 6,156 6,452 5,650 4,960 5,798 * Annual data are averages of monthly figures and monthly data are averages of daily figures. 2 Aggregate cash dividends (based on latest known annual rate) divided by the aggregate monthly market value of the stocks in the group. Annual yields are averages of monthly data. 3 Ratio of quarterly earnings (seasonally adjusted annual rate) to price index for last day in quarter. Annual ratios are averages of quarterly data. * As reported by member firms of the New York Stock Exchange carrying margin accounts. Includes net debit balances of all customers (other than general partners in the reporting firm and member firms of national exchanges) whose combined accounts net to a debit. Balances secured by U.S. Government obligations are excluded through 1967 and included thereafter. Data are for end of period. s Loans by weekly reporting member banks (weekly reporting large commercial banks beginning 1965) to others than brokers and dealers for purchasing or carrying securities except U.S. Government obligations. Data are for last Wednesday 'Loans'by weekly reporting member banks (weekly reporting large commercial banks beginning 1965) for purchasing or carrying securities, including U.S. Government obligations. Data are for last Wednesday of period. toUIWV. BowA O\fcOMttWt*Ot VE» f *tett\ tasww System, Standard & Poor's Corporation, and New York Stock Exchange. 3*5 TABLE B—77.—Business formation and business failures, 1929-68 Business failures * Year or month index of net business formation (1957-59 = 100) 1929 . . . 1930 1931 1932 1933 3 1934 1935 . _ 1936 1937 1938 1939 3_ . . . 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 . 1948 1949 1950 1951. 1952 . 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1 ... 1961 1962 . 1963 . 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 123.1 96.7 102.3 102.8 108.0 103.5 99.8 107.6 103.2 98.3 97.1 104.6 99.8 95.4 98.0 100.6 104.5 106.0 105.5 107.7 New business incorporations (number) 132,916 112,638 96,101 85,491 92,925 83,649 92,819 102,545 117,164 139,915 141,163 137,112 150,781 193,067 182,713 181,535 182,057 186,404 197,724 203,797 200,010 206,569 Amount of current liabilities (millions of dollars) Number of failures Business failure rate 2 Liability size class Total Under $100,000 and $100,000 over Liability size class Total Under $100,000 and $100,000 over 103.9 121.6 133.4 154.1 100.3 61.1 61.7 47.8 45.9 61.1 69.6 63.0 54.5 44.6 16.4 6.5 4.2 5.2 14.3 20.4 34.4 34.3 30.7 28.7 33.2 42.0 41.6 48.0 51.7 55.9 51.8 57.0 64.4 60.8 56.3 53.2 53.3 51.6 49.0 38.6 22,909 26,355 28,285 31,822 19,859 12,091 12,244 9,607 9,490 12,836 14,768 13,619 11,848 9,405 3,221 1,222 809 1,129 3,474 5,250 9,246 9,162 8,058 7,611 8,862 11,086 10,969 12,686 13,739 14,964 14,053 15,445 17,075 15,782 14,374 13,501 13,514 13,061 12,364 9,636 22,165 25,408 27,230 30,197 18,880 11,421 11,691 9,285 9,203 12,553 14,541 13,400 11,685 9,282 3,155 1,176 759 1,002 3,103 4,853 8,708 8,746 7,626 7,081 8,075 10,226 10,113 11,615 12,547 13,499 12,707 13,650 15,006 13,772 12,192 11,346 11,340 10,833 10,144 7,829 744 947 1,055 1 625 979 670 553 322 287 283 227 219 163 123 66 46 50 127 371 337 538 416 432 530 787 860 856 1,071 1,192 1,465 1,346 1,795 2,069 2,010 2,182 2 155 2,174 2,228 2,220 1,807 483.3 668.3 736.3 928.3 457.5 334.0 310.6 203.2 183.3 246.5 182.5 166.7 136.1 100.8 45.3 31.7 30.2 67.3 204.6 234.6 308.1 248.3 259.5 283.3 394.2 462.6 449.4 562.7 615.3 728.3 692.8 938.6 1,090.1 1,213.6 1,352.6 1,329.2 1,321.7 1,385.7 1,265.2 941.0 261.5 303.5 354.2 432.6 215.5 138.5 135.5 102.8 101.9 140.1 132.9 119.9 100.7 80.3 30.2 14.5 11.4 15.7 63.7 93.9 161.4 151.2 131.6 131.9 167.5 211.4 206.4 239.8 267.1 297.6 278.9 327.2 370.1 346.5 321.0 313.6 321.7 321.5 297.9 241.1 221.8 364.8 382.2 495.7 242.0 195.4 175.1 100.4 81.4 106.4 49.7 46.8 35.4 20.5 15.1 17.1 18.8 51.6 140.9 140.7 146.7 97.1 128.0 151.4 226.6 251.2 243.0 322.9 348.2 430.7 413.9 611.4 720.0 867.1 1,031.6 1,015.6 1,000.0 1,064.1 967.3 699.9 54.9 57.1 49.7 52.1 48.6 48.6 43.2 49.3 49.1 47.4 42.2 43.2 38.2 37.5 44.3 43.5 40.9 36.9 41.0 36.5 40.3 37.5 35.7 29.9 1,191 1,216 1,216 1,160 1,100 1,047 843 1,017 913 949 881 831 844 832 1,021 1,003 909 751 810 734 705 768 696 563 1,003 995 981 966 917 850 708 793 758 782 718 673 651 682 839 833 707 616 646 607 598 614 569 467 188 221 235 194 183 197 135 224 155 167 163 158 193 150 182 170 202 135 164 127 107 154 127 96 108.2 113.5 119.3 103,8 93.4 104.6 72.6 108.9 93.9 81.6 70.0 195.4 104.5 79.6 88.6 80.1 91.4 74.7 90.3 65.8 58.7 65.4 58.7 83.4 30.2 29.3 28.7 27.8 27.1 24.7 20.8 23.7 22.2 22.5 21.3 19.6 20.4 21.4 26.1 24.8 21.9 18.6 19.2 18.3 19.1 18.6 17.9 14.8 77.9 84.1 90.6 76.1 66.3 80.0 51.7 85.2 71.8 59.1 48.7 175.8 84.1 58.2 62.5 55,3 69.5 56. C 71.1 47.5 39.5 46.8 40.8 68.6 Seasonally adjusted 1967: Jan.... Feb Mar Apr May June July Aug Sept Oct Nov Dec 1968: Jan Feb Mar Apr May June.., July Aug Sept oct.:.: Nov Dec 102.2 103.2 103.3 103.7 105.0 108.1 108.4 110.7 110.3 110.6 112.7 113.8 113.5 114.5 113.6 113.9 115.1 116.2 119.1 119.7 122.1 125.2 124.6 16,703 15,987 16,244 16,760 17,627 17,799 16,300 17,674 18,118 18,000 18,403 18,168 17,223 18,014 17,974 18,659 18,796 19,197 19,530 20,053 21,237 21,721 20,850 1 Commercial and industrial failures only. Excludes failures of banks and railroads and, beginning 1933, of real estate, insurance, holding, and financial companies, steamship lines, travel agencies, etc. 2 Failure rate per 10,000 listed enterprises. 3 Series revised; not strictly comparable with earlier data. Sources: Department of Commerce (Bureau of the Census) and Dun & Bradstreet, Inc. 3l6 AGRICULTURE T A B L E B—78.—Income from agriculture, 1929-68 Income received from farming Personal income received by total farm population Net to farm operators Realized gross Year or quarter From From From nonTotals farm 1 farm all sources sources sources2 ProducCash tion ex- Exclud- Includreceipts penses ing net ing net from inven- invenmarkettory tory ings change change4 Billions of dollars Net income per farm, including net inventory cha nge Current prices 1968 prices8 Dollars __ 13.9 11.3 7.7 6.3 6.2 945 2,054 ... 1929 9.1 6.4 4.7 5.3 6.4 7.1 8.4 8.9 7.7 7.9 6.9 5.5 4.5 4.4 4.7 5.1 5.6 6.2 5.9 6.3 4.5 2.9 1.9 2.7 3.9 4.6 5.1 5.2 4.2 4.3 4.3 3.3 2.0 2.6 2.9 5.3 4.3 6.0 4.4 4.4 651 506 304 379 431 775 639 905 668 685 1,514 1,368 950 1,184 1,197 2,095 1,727 2,382 1,856 1,903 5.4 7.7 7.2 9.0 7.2 7.4 3.2 5.4 4.6 6.2 4.7 4.8 2.2 2.3 2.6 2.7 2.5 2.6 11.5 8.4 6.4 7.1 8.6 9.7 10.8 11.4 10.1 10.6 1946 1947 1948. 1949 7.6 10.1 14.1 16.5 16.6 17.2 20.0 21.1 23.8 19.5 4.8 6.8 10.1 12.1 12.2 12.8 15.5 15.8 18.0 13.3 2.8 3.3 3.9 4.4 4.4 4.4 4.6 5.3 5.8 6.2 11.1 13.9 18.8 23.4 24.4 25.8 29.5 34.1 34.7 31.6 8.4 11.1 15.6 19.6 20.5 21.7 24.8 29.6 30.2 27.8 6.9 7.8 10.0 11.6 12.3 13.1 14.5 17.0 18.8 18.0 4.2 6.1 8.8 11.8 12.1 12.8 15.0 17.1 15.9 13.6 4.5 6.5 9.9 11.7 11.7 12.3 15.1 15.4 17.7 12.8 706 1,031 1,588 1,927 1,950 2,063 2,543 2,615 3,044 2,233 1,961 2,644 3,609 3,854 3,750 3,820 4,238 3,683 4,059 3,059 1950 1951. 1952. 1953 1954. 1955 1956 1957. 1958 1959. 20.4 22.7 22.1 19.8 18.4 17.6 17.8 17.7 19.5 18.1 14.1 16.2 15.4. 13.4 12.5 11.4 11.2 11.0 12.8 11.0 6.3 6.5 6.7 6.4 5.9 6.2 6.6 6.6 6.7 7.0 32.3 37.1 36.8 35.0 33.6 33.1 34.3 34.0 37.9 37.5 28.5 32.9 32.5 31.0 29.8 29.5 30.4 29.7 33.5 33.5 19.4 22.3 22.6 21.3 21.6 21.9 22.4 23.3 25.2 26.1 12.9 14.8 14.1 13.7 12.0 11.2 11.9 10.7 12.7 11.4 13.7 16.0 15.1 13.1 12.5 11.5 11.4 11.3 13.5 11.5 2,421 2,946 2,896 2,626 2,606 2,463 2,535 2,590 3,189 2,795 3,316 3,682 3,575 3,282 3,217 3,041 3,091 3,083 3,708 3,250 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964. 1965 1966. 1967 1968 » 18.7 19.7 20.4 20.6 20.6 23.6 24.8 23.7 24.4 11.5 12.2 12.3 12.1 11.3 13.5 14.3 13.0 13.5 7.2 7.5 8.2 8.5 9.3 10.0 10.5 10.7 10.9 38.1 39.8 41.3 42.3 42.6 44.9 49.6 49.1 50.8 34.2 35.1 36.4 37.4 37.2 39.3 43.2 42.8 44.1 26.4 27.1 28.6 29.7 29.5 30.9 33.4 34.8 35.9 11.7 12.6 12.6 12.6 13.1 14.0 16.2 14.2 14.9 12.1 13.0 13.2 13.2 12.3 15.0 16.1 14.6 15.4 3,049 3,399 3,586 3,708 3,564 4 487 4,967 4,654 5,035 3,505 3,907 4,075 4,166 3,960 4,931 5,284 4,848 5,035 1930 . 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 . 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944. _.__ Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1967: 1 ________ II III IV 48.9 49.3 49.2 48.9 42.5 43.0 43.0 42.7 34.4 34.9 35.0 35.0 14.5 14.4 14.2 13.9 14.6 14.7 14.8 14.5 4,640 4,670 4,700 4,610 4,880 4,860 4,900 4,750 1968: 1 II III IV v 49.8 50.7 51.6 51.1 43.2 44.0 44.9 44.3 35.4 35.9 36.2 36.3 14 4 14.8 15.4 14.8 14.8 15.1 15.7 15.8 4,840 4,940 5,130 5,170 4,940 4,940 5,080 5,120 1 Net income to farm operators including net inventory change, less net income of nonresident operators, plus wages and salaries and other labor income of farm resident workers, less contributions of farm resident operators and workers to 2social insurance. Consists of income received by farm residents from nonfarm sources, such as wages and salaries from nonfarm employment, nonfarm business and professional income, rents from nonfarm real estate, dividends, interest, royalties, unemployment compensation, and social security payments. 3 Cash receipts from marketings, Government payments, and nonmoney income furnished by farms. 4 Includes net change in inventory of crops and livestock valued at the average price for the year. 5 Income in current prices divided by the index of prices paid by farmers for family living Items on a 1968 base. Source: Department of Agriculture. 323-166 O—69 -21 317 TABLE B-79.—Farm production indexes, 1929-68 [1957-59=1001 Livestock and products Crops Year Farm output^ Meat ToOil Vege- Fruits Feed Hay Total 2 grains and Food tables and Cot- bacco crops Total 3 animals nuts ton orage rains 1929... 62 73 62 79 68 1930.., 1931 1932 1933 1934... 1935 1936 . 1937... 1938... 1939... 1940... 1941... 1942... 1943... 1944... 1945... 1946... 1947... 1948.. 1949.. 1950.. 1951.. 1952.. 1953.. 1954.. 1955.. 1956.. 1957.. 1958.. 1959.. I960.. 19611962.. 1963.. 1964.. 1965.. 1966.. 1967.. 1968 v. 61 66 64 59 51 61 55 69 67 68 70 73 82 80 83 81 84 81 88 87 86 89 92 93 93 96 97 95 102 103 106 107 108 112 111 114 113 118 120 69 77 73 65 54 70 59 81 76 75 78 79 89 83 88 85 89 85 97 92 89 91 95 94 93 96 95 93 104 103 108 106 107 111 108 115 111 117 119 56 63 73 56 33 60 38 67 65 65 66 71 81 74 78 75 82 63 9i 80 81 75 79 77 81 86 85 93 101 106 109 99 100 108 95 111 110 124 118 66 72 74 69 64 82 66 75 81 75 86 86 93 91 90 93 87 84 84 83 89 92 90 92 92 98 94 101 102 97 103 102 106 106 107 112 110 115 114 74 79 63 47 45 55 54 74 77 63 69 79 83 72 88 92 95 111 107 92 86 85 109 100 88 83 87 82 121 97 115 106 98 102 114 117 118 134 141 73 74 75 76 73 80 81 75 82 81 81 83 84 89 97 92 94 105 91 97 94 96 89 90 95 93 96 102 98 102 100 102 108 106 106 101 108 109 110 113 75 120 88 73 92 75 76 71 90 70 93 84 96 93 99 98 84 98 89 106 101 92 98 98 100 97 98 99 99 103 94 102 104 98 102 103 100 101 106 108 116 109 113 138 105 105 78 86 101 154 97 96 102 88 105 93 100 74 71 97 122 131 82 124 124 134 111 120 108 89 93 118 116 116 121 125 124 121 78 61 88 95 89 58 80 63 76 68 91 80 110 84 73 81 81 113 114 134 122 115 114 117 135 130 119 130 127 126 96 100 104 112 119 134 135 129 107 109 114 99 13 14 14 13 11 13 21 16 18 22 29 34 37 56 60 50 54 52 55 67 61 71 65 63 63 71 78 92 91 111 98 104 121 122 128 128 153 164 171 188 63 64 65 66 67 61 59 63 62 65 70 71 75 84 91 86 86 83 82 80 85 88 92 92 93 96 99 99 97 99 104 102 107 108 111 114 111 114 117 118 Dairy Poults prod- and ucts eggs 62 75 44 63 66 67 70 59 53 60 58 63 71 72 76 87 97 88 84 82 81 79 83 89 95 95 94 98 103 100 96 98 106 103 107 109 114 117 111 116 120 123 76 78 79 79 78 78 79 79 81 82 84 89 92 91 92 95 94 93 90 93 93 92 92 97 98 99 101 101 100 99 101 103 104 103 105 103 100 100 99 45 44 44 44 41 41 44 44 45 48 49 54 62 71 71 74 69 68 67 74 78 81 82 84 87 86 94 95 101 104 104 112 112 115 119 124 132 138 134 » Farm output measures the annual volume of farm production available for eventual human use through sales from farms or consumption in farm households. Total excludes production of seeds and of feed for horses and mules. 2 Includes production of seeds and of feed for horses and mules and certain items not shown separately. 3 Includes certain items not shown separately. Source: Department of Agriculture. 318 TABLE B-80.—Farm population, employment, and productivity, 1929-68 Farm population (April l ) ^ Year Number (thousands) As percent of total populations Farm employment (thousands)* Farm output Per man-hour Total Family Hired workers workers Per unit of total input Total Crops Livestock and products Crop production per acre4 Livestock production per breedunit Index, 1957-59=100 1929.. 30,580 25.1 12,763 9,360 3,403 63 28 28 48 69 68 1930.. 1931.. 1932.. 1933.. 1934.. 30,529 30,845 31,388 32,393 32,305 24.8 24.8 25.1 25.8 25.5 12,497 12,745 12,816 12,739 12,627 9,307 9,642 9,922 9,874 9,765 3,190 3,103 2,894 2,865 2,862 63 69 69 65 59 28 30 30 28 27 27 30 30 27 27 47 47 47 46 43 64 72 68 61 51 70 70 69 68 62 1935.. 1936.. 1937.. 1938.. 1939.. 32,161 31,737 31,266 30,980 30,840 25.3 24.8 24.2 23.8 23.5 12,733 12,331 11,978 11,622 11,338 9,855 9,350 9,054 8,815 8,611 2,878 2,981 2,924 2,807 2,727 69 62 73 74 72 31 29 33 35 35 31 28 33 35 34 44 46 46 48 50 66 56 76 73 74 69 70 71 75 75 1940.. 1941.. 1942.. 1943.. 1944.. 30,547 30,118 28,914 26,186 24,815 23.1 22.6 21.4 19.2 17.9 10,979 10,669 10,504 10,446 10,219 8,300 8,017 7,949 8,010 7,988 2,679 2,652 2,555 2,436 2,231 1Z 75 82 79 82 36 39 42 42 44 37 39 43 41 44 50 51 56 58 56 76 77 86 78 83 75 80 81 78 75 1945.. 1946.. 1947.. 1948.. 1949.. 24,420 25,403 25,829 24,383 24,194 17.5 18.0 17.9 16.6 16.2 10,000 10,295 10,382 10,363 9,964 7,881 8,106 8,115 8,026 7,712 2,119 2,189 2,267 2,337 2,252 82 85 82 88 86 46 49 50 56 57 46 50 50 57 57 58 59 61 62 66 82 86 82 92 85 79 78 79 1950. 1951.. 1952. 1953. 1954.. 23,048 21,890 21,748 19,874 19,019 15.2 14.2 13.9 12.5 11.7 9,926 9,546 9,149 8,864 8,651 7,597 7,310 7,005 6,775 6,570 2,329 2,236 2,144 2,089 2,081 85 86 89 90 91 61 f2 68 71 74 63 61 67 69 73 68 72 74 76 80 84 85 90 89 88 86 89 89 93 92 1955. 1956. 1957. 1958.. 1959. 19,078 18,712 17,656 17,128 16,592 11.5 11.1 10.3 9.8 9.4 8,381 7,853 7,600 7,503 7,342 6,345 5,900 5,660 5 521 5,390 2,036 1,953 1,940 1,982 1,952 94 96 96 103 11 0 80 86 91 103 106 77 83 90 105 105 85 89 92 100 108 91 92 93 105 102 93 95 96 100 104 I960.. 1961. 1962. 1963. 1964. 15,635 14,803 14,313 13,367 12,954 8.7 8.1 7.7 7.1 6.7 7,057 6,919 6,700 6,518 6,110 5,172 5,029 4,873 4,738 4,506 1,885 1,890 1,827 1,780 1,604 105 106 107 108 107 115 120 127 137 142 114 116 122 129 132 113 123 130 140 152 109 112 115 118 115 105 109 108 110 113 1965.... 1966.... 1967 1968 P . 12,363 11,595 10,817 10,500 6.4 5.9 5.4 5.2 5,610 5,214 4,903 4,745 4,128 3,854 3,650 3,550 1,482 1,360 1,253 1,195 no 106 108 107 154 159 169 176 146 150 155 165 159 170 183 187 122 119 122 127 111 118 119 1 Farm population as defined by Department of Agriculture and Department of Commerce, i.e., civilian population living on farms, regardless of occupation. 2 Total population of United States as of July 1 including Armed Forces abroad. 3 Includes persons doing farmwork on all farms. These data, published by the Department of Agriculture, Statistical Reporting Service, differ from those on agricultural employment by the Department of Labor (see Table B-22) because of differences in the method of approach, in concepts of employment, and in time of month for which the data are collected. See monthly report on "Farm Labor." * Computed from variable weights for individual crops produced each year. Sources: Department of Agriculture and Department of Commerce (Bureau of the Census). 319 T A B L E B—81.—Indexes of prices received and prices paid by farmers, and parity ratio, 1929—68 [1957-59=1001 Prices received by farmers Crops Year or month All farm prodAll ucts^ crops Food grains Feed grains and hay Total Feed grains Livestock and products Cotton Tobacco Oilbearing crops All livestock and products^ Meat animals Dairy Poultry prod- and ucts eggs 61 55 74 77 57 35 62 50 65 102 1930.. 1931.. 1932.. 1933.. 1934_. 1935.. 1936.. 1937.. 1938.. 1939.. 52 36 27 29 37 45 47 51 40 39 52 34 26 32 44 46 49 53 36 37 44 27 21 31 43 46 51 57 35 34 67 46 31 36 60 68 65 79 45 46 68 44 28 36 60 70 68 84 45 44 40 24 19 26 39 38 38 36 27 28 29 20 18 22 32 35 33 41 36 31 52 38 28 27 32 44 46 49 43 41 43 30 20 19 22 38 38 42 37 36 55 43 33 34 40 45 49 51 45 43 81 62 51 47 56 74 73 70 69 61 1940.. 1941.. 1942.. 19431944.. 1945.. 1946.. 1947.. 1948.. 1949.. 42 51 66 «80 «82 6 86 6 98 114 119 103 41 48 65 84 89 91 102 118 114 100 40 46 57 70 78 81 95 128 118 103 54 58 72 96 108 106 127 161 162 112 54 58 73 97 109 104 131 171 170 109 32 43 60 64 66 69 91 105 104 94 28 32 51 66 72 74 78 77 78 82 97 100 114 158 153 106 42 53 66 77 76 82 94 111 122 106 35 47 46 55 60 63 66 •77 62 6 86 «67 «89 « 81 6 104 107 106 117 117 101 62 77 96 121 112 126 127 141 153 140 1950.. 1951.. 1952.. 1953. 1954.. 1955. 1956. 1957.. 1958.. 1959. 107 125 119 105 102 96 95 97 104 99 104 119 120 108 108 104 105 101 100 99 106 115 116 111 110 107 106 106 98 96 122 143 147 130 128 116 115 105 97 123 147 150 132 130 116 116 105 97 98 108 129 119 102 105 104 103 101 97 102 83 90 89 89 91 90 93 96 100 104 120 148 129 122 133 109 111 106 98 96 108 130 119 104 97 90 88 94 106 100 110 133 115 94 92 80 76 89 109 102 97 112 118 104 96 96 99 101 99 100 118 144 130 140 113 121 112 102 108 90 1960. 1961. 1962.. 1963.. 1964. 1965. 1966. 1967. 1968. 99 99 101 100 98 103 110 104 107 100 102 104 107 107 104 106 100 102 96 99 107 106 90 77 87 84 76 96 95 98 104 105 110 114 110 100 94 94 96 102 103 108 112 108 97 97 100 104 104 100 94 82 73 72 103 109 109 102 101 106 114 114 117 93 112 108 113 112 116 128 121 115 98 98 99 95 91 101 113 107 112 96 97 101 94 88 104 116 109 112 101 101 99 99 100 102 115 119 124 101 92 92 92 90 92 102 84 89 Febl5. Mar 15 Apr 15 May 15 June 15 106 104 103 102 104 105 100 99 100 100 99 102 117 116 117 115 115 116 115 114 115 114 114 115 64 65 66 66 64 66 115 116 116 115 115 115 128 125 126 125 124 125 109 107 106 103 108 108 108 107 105 104 114 115 122 120 117 114 113 111 97 90 91 82 80 78 July 15 Augl5 Sept 15 Octl5. Novl5 Dec 15 106 105 105 104 104 105 99 99 98 101 102 103 113 105 104 101 97 101 112 104 103 97 94 97 68 71 69 88 98 89 115 114 112 111 115 114 122 117 116 113 114 115 110 110 110 107 105 105 116 115 111 108 103 103 114 117 122 125 125 124 84 81 84 77 78 82 1968: Jan 15.. Feb 15.. Mar 15.. Apr 15. May 15. June 15 105 106 107 107 108 107 103 102 103 104 105 103 102 104 104 103 104 103 99 101 101 101 102 101 72 64 63 64 69 67 115 116 116 116 116 116 117 119 118 118 118 118 107 109 109 109 109 111 105 111 112 113 113 115 124 122 120 119 119 117 84 83 84 80 78 85 July 15.. Aug 15_. Sept 15. Oct 1 5 . . Nov 15.. Dec 15_. 108 108 110 108 108 108 99 101 103 102 102 99 99 93 95 93 98 100 97 90 92 90 96 97 65 84 85 86 78 70 116 119 119 118 118 120 117 117 111 109 111 112 114 113 116 113 113 115 118 115 114 110 109 111 120 123 128 131 132 131 90 91 104 94 97 103 1929.. 1967: Jan 15 See footnotes at end of table. 320 > TABLE B-81.—Indexes of prices received and prices paid by farmers, and par it ratio, 1929-68— Continued [1957-59=100] Prices paid by farmers Year or month 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963—. 1964 1965 1966— 1967 1968 1967: Jan 15... Febl5... Mar 15. . Apr 15... May 15.. June 15.. July 15... Aug 15... Septl5_. Octl5__. Novl5... Dec 15... 1968: Jan 15... Feb 15... Mar 15... Apr 15... May 15.. June 15.. July 15.. Aug 15.. Sept 15.. Octl5... Nov 15... Dec 15... All items, interest, taxes, and wage rates (parity index) 55 52 44 38 37 41 42 42 45 42 42 42 45 52 58 62 65 71 82 89 86 87 96 98 95 95 94 95 98 100 102 102 103 105 107 107 110 114 116 121 116 115 116 116 116 117 117 117 117 117 117 117 118 119 120 121 121 121 121 121 121 122 123 123 Commodities and services Production items FamAll All items living items production items i 55 51 44 38 38 43 45 45 48 45 44 45 48 55 61 64 66 72 85 92 88 90 100 100 96 96 95 96 98 101 101 101 101 103 104 104 106 109 111 114 110 110 110 110 HI 111 111 111 111 111 111 111 112 113 113 114 114 114 114 114 114 115 115 116 54 50 43 37 38 43 43 43 45 43 42 42 45 52 58 61 64 71 83 88 85 86 94 95 94 94 95 96 99 100 101 102 102 103 104 105 107 110 113 117 112 112 112 111 112 112 113 113 113 114 114 114 115 115 116 117 117 117 118 118 118 119 119 119 56 52 43 38 38 44 46 46 50 47 46 47 50 57 63 66 67 73 85 95 91 94 104 104 97 97 96 95 98 100 102 101 101 103 104 103 105 108 109 111 109 109 109 109 109 110 110 109 109 109 109 109 110 111 111 111 112 112 112 111 111 111 112 113 Feed 68 61 43 32 37 52 53 55 62 47 47 50 54 66 78 87 86 100 118 125 103 105 118 126 114 113 106 103 101 99 100 98 98 100 104 103 104 109 106 102 110 109 109 108 107 107 106 104 104 103 102 103 104 104 103 103 103 102 101 99 100 99 101 101 Motor vehicles Farm machinery 36 35 35 34 34 36 37 38 39 42 40 40 42 45 47 51 53 55 63 71 78 78 83 87 86 86 87 89 96 100 104 102 102 105 109 111 113 117 121 128 43 43 42 40 39 40 41 42 43 44 43 43 43 46 48 49 49 51 58 67 76 78 83 86 87 87 87 92 96 100 104 107 110 111 113 116 119 124 129 136 119 127 121 121 130 1 122 124 124 124 132 126 133 129 129 136 128 138 130 132 Interest 2 Wage Taxes 3 rates* Parity ratio s Fertilizer 85 83 75 66 61 69 68 64 67 67 66 64 64 71 76 77 79 79 88 96 98 94 100 102 103 102 101 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 99 100 100 100 98 100 100 100 101 101 101 101 101 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 98 98 4 98* 98 98 96 96 96 96 116 113 108 101 90 80 74 68 64 60 58 56 54 51 46 43 41 40 42 43 45 49 54 59 63 68 74 83 91 100 109 120 131 145 162 182 206 231 253 273 253 253 253 253 253 253 253 253 253 253 253 253 273 273 273 273 273 273 273 273 273 273 273 273 56 57 56 51 44 38 36 36 36 38 37 38 38 38 37 37 39 43 48 56 60 65 68 71 74 77 81 87 93 100 107 117 125 132 139 147 156 170 181 193 181 181 181 181 181 181 181 181 181 181 181 181 193 193 193 193 193 193 193 193 193 193 193 193 92 83 67 58 64 75 88 92 93 78 77 81 93 105 113 108 109 113 115 110 100 101 107 100 92 92 96 99 105 109 110 114 116 119 125 135 146 158 137 137 137 146 146 146 148 148 148 152 152 152 150 150 150 157 157 157 159 159 159 166 166 166 (66) (80) (95) (95) (97) (83) (85) (88) (98) (109) (116) (110) (111) (115) (116) (111) (100) (102) (108) (101) (93) 80 86) 74 (79) 74 (79) 76 (81) 75 (80) 74 (79) 72 (77) 74 (79) 75 (80) 74 (80) 75 (80) 74 (79) 73 (78) 73 (78) 74 (79) (79) (80) 79) 79) 79) 79) (79) (79) -- (81) 73 (79) 73 (79) 73 (78) Includes items not shown separately. 2 Interest payable per acre on farm real estate debt. 3 Farm real estate taxes payable per acre (levied in preceding year). 4 Monthly data are seasonally adjusted. s Percentage ratio of prices received for all farm products to parity index, on a 1910-14=100 base. The adjusted parity ratio (shown in parentheses in the table) reflects Government payments made directly to farmers. 6 Includes wartime subsidy payments. Source: Department of Agriculture. 321 TABLE B-82.—Selected measures offarm resources and inputs, 1929-68 Crops harvested (millions of acres) i Year Total Exclusive of use for feed for horses and mules Index numbers of inputs (1957-59 = 100) Livestock breeding units (195759 = 100)2 Manhours of farm work (billions) Total _ harm labor Farm real estate3 MeFeed, chaniFertiseed, cl a lizer and power and liveand liming stock ma- materials pur- 4 chinery chases Miscellaneous 1929.. 365 298 92 23.2 218 92 38 21 27 76 1930.. 1931.. 1932.. 1933.. 1934.. 369 365 371 340 304 304 303 311 281 247 92 93 95 98 98 22.9 23.4 22.6 22.6 20.2 216 220 213 212 190 91 89 86 87 86 40 38 35 32 32 21 16 11 12 1 4 26 23 24 24 24 76 78 79 76 69 1935.. 1936.. 1937.. 1938.. 1939.. 345 323 347 349 331 289 269 295 301 286 86 90 87 87 93 21.1 20.4 22.1 20.6 20.7 89 94 91 94 198 192 208 193 194 88 89 90 91 92 33 35 38 40 40" 17 20 24 23 24 23 31 29 30 37 66 68 68 70 72 1940.. 1941.. 1942.. 1943.. 1944.. 341 344 348 357 362 298 304 309 320 326 95 94 104 117 114 20.5 20.0 20.6 20.3 20.2 97 97 100 101 101 192 188 194 191 190 92 92 91 89 88 42 44 48 50 51 28 30 34 38 43 45 46 57 63 64 73 74 75 76 76 1945.. 1946.. 1947.. 1948.. 1949.. 354 352 355 356 360 322 323 329 332 338 109 107 104 98 99 18.8 18.1 17.2 16.8 16.2 99 99 99 100 101 177 170 162 158 152 88 91 92 95 95 54 58 64 72 80 45 53 56 57 61 72 69 73 72 69 76 77 78 74 82 1950.. 1951.. 1952.. 1953.. 1954.. 345 344 349 348 346 326 326 334 335 335 102 103 103 100 104 15.1 15.2 14.5 14.0 13.3 101 104 103 103 102 142 143 136 131 125 97 98 99 99 100 86 92 96 97 98 68 73 80 83 88 72 80 81 80 82 85 91 91 1955.. 1956. 1957.. 1958.. 1959. 340 324 324 324 324 330 315 316 317 318 106 104 101 99 100 12.8 12.0 11.1 10.5 10.3 102 101 99 99 102 120 113 104 99 97 100 99 100 100 100 99 99 100 99 101 90 91 94 97 109 86 91 93 101 106 94 98 95 100 105 1960. 1961. 1962. 1963. 1964. 324 303 295 300 301 319 299 291 296 297 97 98 100 101 101 9.8 9.4 9.1 8.8 8.3 101 101 101 104 104 92 89 85 82 78 101 101 103 104 106 104 101 100 104 102 111 117 125 141 155 109 111 117 123 126 106 109 113 117 120 1965 1966.... 1967 1968 v 298 295 308 301 294 291 304 100 97 98 7.9 7.5 7.4 7.2 104 107 109 112 74 71 70 68 106 107 106 106 105 110 112 116 162 182 205 221 127 136 140 149 120 123 120 130 1 3 Acreage harvested (excluding duplication) plus acreages in fruits, tree nuts, and farm gardens. Animal units of breeding livestock, excluding horses and mules. ' Includes service buildings and improvements on land. < Nonfarm inputs associated with farmers' purchases. Source: Department of Agriculture. 322 TABLE B-83.—Comparative balance sheet of agriculture, 1929-69 [Billions of dollars] Assets Claims Financial assets Other physical assets Beginning of year MaHousechinhold Real DeTotal estate ery equip- posits Live- and 2 and stock i motor Crops ment and curvehifurnish- rency cles ings ProReal Invest- Total estate Other prie; tors U.S. ment debt equidebt savings in coties bonds operatives 48.0 6.6 3.2 47.9 43.7 37.2 30.8 32.2 6.5 4.9 3.6 3.0 3.2 3.4 3.3 3.0 2.5 2.2 33.3 34.3 35.2 35.2 34.1 3.5 5.2 5.1 5.0 5.1 2.2 2.4 2.6 3.0 3.2 52.9 55.0 62.9 . 73.7 84.6 33.6 34.4 37.5 41.6 48.2 5.1 5.3 7.1 9.6 9.7 3.1 3.3 4.0 4.9 5.4 2.7 3.0 3.8 5.1 6.1 4 2 4.2 4.9 5.0 5.3 3.2 3.5 4.2 5.4 6.6 0.2 .4 .5 1.1 2.2 .8 .9 .9 1.0 1.1 52.9 55.0 62.9 73.7 84.6 94.2 . _ 103.5 116.4 127.9 134.9 53.9 61.0 68.5 73.7 76.6 9.0 9.7 11.9 13.3 14.4 6.5 5.4 5.3 7.4 10.1 6.7 6.3 7.1 9.0 8.6 5.6 6.1 7.7 8.5 9.1 7.9 9.4 10.2 9.9 9.6 3.4 4.2 4.2 4.4 4.6 1.2 1.4 1.5 1.7 1.9 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 132.5 151.5 167.0 164.3 161.2 75.3 86.6 95.1 96.5 95.0 12.9 17.1 19.5 14.8 11.7 12.2 14.1 16.7 17.4 18.4 7.6 7.9 8,8 9.0 9.2 8.6 9.7 10.3 9.9 9.9 9.1 9.1 9.4 9.4 9.4 4.7 4.7 4.7 4.6 4.7 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 165.1 169.6 178.0 185.8 202.2 98.2 102.9 110.4 115.9 124.4 11.2 10.6 11.0 13.9 17.7 18.6 19.3 20.3 20.2 21.8 9.6 8.3 8.3 7.6 9.3 10.0 10.5 10.0 9.9 9.8 9.4 9.5 9.4 9.5 10.0 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 203.1 204.0 212.9 221.0 229.8 130.2 131.7 138.0 143.8 152.1 15.2 15.6 16.4 17.3 15.8 22.2 21.8 22.3 22.7 24.1 7.7 8.0 8.8 9.3 9.8 9.6 8.9 9.1 9.0 8.9 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 v 238.5 256.0 269.8 283.5 297.9 160.9 172.5 182.5 193.7 202.7 14.5 17.5 18.9 18.7 25.5 9.2 27.1 9.7 28.9 10.0 31.0 9.5 72.4 8.6 8.6 8.4 8.5 1929 ... . 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 68.5 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948.. 1949 .. 9.8 2.5 4.0 3.6 0.6 68 5 9.6 9.4 9.1 8.5 7.7 5.0 53.9 6.6 6.5 6.4 6.0 5.4 34 3.9 4.1 4.0 3.5 42 9 44.6 52.4 63.7 75.7 94.2 103.5 116.4 127.9 134.9 4.9 4.8 4.9 5.1 5.3 3.4 3.2 3.6 4.2 6.1 85.9 95.5 107.9 118.6 123.5 2.1 2.3 2.5 2.7 2.9 132.5 151.5 167.0 164.3 161.2 5.6 6.1 6.7 7.2 7.7 6.8 7.0 8.0 8.9 9.2 120.1 138.4 152.3 148.2 144.3 5.0 5.2 5.1 5.1 5.2 3.1 3.3 3.5 3.7 4.0 165.1 169.6 178.0 185.8 202.2 8.2 9.0 9.8 10.4 11.1 9.4 9.8 9.6 10 0 12.5 147.5 150.8 158.6 165.4 178.6 9.2 8.7 8.8 9.2 9.2 4.7 4.6 4.5 4.4 4.2 4.3 4.7 5.0 5.3 5.7 203.1 204.0 212.9 221.0 229.8 12.1 12.8 13.9 15.2 16.8 12.7 13.4 14.8 16.5 18.1 178.3 177.8 184.2 189.3 194.9 9.6 10.0 10.3 10.9 4.2 4.1 3,9 3.8 22.8 6.0 6.5 6.9 7.4 238.5 256.0 269.8 283.5 297.9 18.9 21.2 23.3 25.5 27.8 18.7 20 4 22.4 24.9 27.6 200.9 214 4 224.1 233.1 242.5 7.6 7.4 7.2 7.0 68 1 2 Beginning with 1961, horses and mules are excluded. Includes all crops held on farms and crops held off farms by farmers as security for Commodity Credit Corporation loans. The latter on January 1,1968, totaled $487 million. Source: Department of Agriculture. 323 INTERNATIONAL STATISTICS TABLE B-84.—United States balance of payments, 1946-68 [Millions of dollars] Exports of goods and services Imports of goods and services Income on investments Year or quarter Total Merchan' dise i Military sales Private Government Total Other services Merchandise1 Military expenditures -5,073 -5,979 -7,563 -6,879 -493 -455 -799 -621 1946 1947 1948 1949 14,735 19,737 16,789 15,770 11,707 16,015 13,193 12,149 751 1,036 1,238 1,297 2,226 -6,991 -8,208 -10,349 -9,621 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 13,807 18,744 17,992 16,947 17,759 10,117 14,123 13,319 12,281 12,799 1,484 1,684 1,624 2 1,658 182 1,955 109 198 204 252 272 2,097 2,739 2,845 2,564 2,551 -12,028 -15,073 -15,766 -16,561 -15,931 -9,108 -11,202 -10,838 -10,990 -10,354 1955 1956 1957 19581959 19,804 23,595 26,481 _ 23,067 23,489 14,280 17,379 19,390 16,264 16,295 200 161 375 300 302 2,170 2,468 2,612 2,538 2,694 274 194 205 307 349 2,880 3,393 3,899 3,658 3,849 -17,795 -19,628 -20,752 -20,861 -23,342 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 27,325 28,609 30,343 32,432 37,098 19,487 19,944 20,606 22,071 25,297 335 402 656 657 747 3,001 3,561 3,948 4,151 4,930 348 381 471 498 456 4,155 4,320 4,661 5,055 5,668 -23,355 -23,151 -25,358 -26,620 -28,688 1965 1966 1967 19681° 39,196 43,142 45,756 50,219 26,244 830 5,384 29,176 829 5,659 30,468 1,240 6,235 33,452 1,431 6,819 21 2,256 66 2,620 102 2,256 Other services Balance on goods and services Remittances and pensions -1,425 7,744 -1,774 11,529 -1,987 6,440 -2,121 6,149 -648 -728 -631 -641 -576 -1,270 -2,054 -2,615 -2,642 -2,344 -2,601 -2,874 -2,956 -2,935 1,779 3,671 2,226 386 1,828 -533 -480 -571 -644 -633 -11,527 -12,804 -13,291 -12,952 -15,310 -2,901 -2,949 -3,216 -3,435 -3,107 -3,367 -3,875 -4,245 -4,474 -4,925 2,009 3,967 5,729 2,206 147 -597 -690 -729 -745 -815 -14,744 -14,522 -16,219 -17,014 -18,648 -3,087 -2,998 -3,105 -2,961 -2,876 -5,523 -5,631 -6,035 -6,645 -7,164 3,970 5,458 4,985 5,812 8,409 -697 -724 -779 -891 -896 -2,945 -7,834 -3,735 -8,787 -4,340 -9,658 -4,511 -10,293 6,901 5,080 4,768 2,395 -1,027 -1,015 -1,276 -1,136 509 6,229 -32,295 -21,516 593 6; 885 -38,063 -25,541 624 7,189 -40,989 -26,991 835 7,683 -47,824 -33,020 Seasonally adjusted annual rates 1966: I II III IV... 42,112 42,580 43,648 44,236 1967: I 45,484 II 145,508 III :46,052 IV.... 45,984 5,316 5,552 5,768 5,996 596 596 588 596 6,648 6,840 6,996 7,064 -36,080 -37,344 -39,112 -39,716 -24,144 -25,052 -26,268 -26,700 -3,488 -3,692 -3,848 -3,916 -8,448 -8,600 -8,996 -9,100 30,644 1,340 5,772 30,812 1,344 5,564 30,504 980 6,684 29,912 1,292 6,916 604 660 624 612 7,124 7,128 7,260 7,252 -40,312 -40,432 -40,616 -42, 592 -26,744 -26,420 -26,164 -28,636 -4,288 -4,260 -4,392 -4,416 -9,280 -9,752 -10,060 -9,540 1,048 1,568 1,432 1,052 792 7,552 -46,136 -31,468 -4,440 -10,228 884 7,680 -47,860 -33,280 -4,492 -10,088 828 7,816 —49,476 -34,312 -4,600 -10,564 1,064 1,144 1,200 28,752 28,716 29,476 29,760 800 876 820 820 47,440 31,696 1,224 6,176 1968: I 50,228 33,300 1,448 6,916 II III *__ 52,988 35,360 1,620 7,364 See footnotes at end of table. 324 TABLE B-84.—United States balance of payments, 1946-68— Continued [Millions of dollars] Year or quarter U.S. Government grants and capital, net 2 U.S. private capital, net Direct investment Other longterm Shortterm Balance Foreign capital, net 2 Errors and Offiunrecial corded l reserve transactions qu'dity3 transbasis actions basis * Changes in selected liabilities (decrease ( - ) ) « To foreign official holders Liquid Nonliquid Changes in gold, convertible currencies, and To IMF other gold foreign tranche holders 7 position (increase ( ) ) 1946.... 1947.... 1948.... 1949.... -5,293 -6,121 -4,918 -5,649 -230 -749 -721 -660 127 -49 -69 -310 -189 -116 187 -615 -432 -361 44 218 949 1,193 786 993 4,210 817 136 -623 -3,315 -1,736 -266 1950.... 1951.... 1952.... 1953.... 1954.... -3,640 -3,191 -2,380 -2,055 -1,554 -621 -508 -852 -735 -667 -495 -437 -214 185 -320 -149 -103 -94 167 -635 181 540 52 146 249 -11 500 627 366 191 -3,489 1,758 -33 -415 1,256 480 1955.... 1956.... 1957.... 1958.... 1959-... -2,211 -2,362 -2,574 -2, 587 -1,986 -241 -823 -1,951 - 6 0 3 -2,442 - 8 5 9 -1,181 -1,444 -1,372 - 9 2 6 -191 -517 -276 -311 -77 297 615 545 186 736 1960 1961 1962 1963.... 1964—. -2,768 -2,779 -3,013 -3,578 -3,564 -1,674 -1,598 -1,654 -1,976 -2,328 - 8 5 5 -1,349 -1,025 -1,556 -1,227 -546 -1,698 - 7 8 5 -2,103 -2,147 364 702 1,026 690 689 -892 -847 -997 -244 -860 -3,901 - 3 , 4 0 3 -2,371 j-1,347 -2,204-2,702 -2,670 - 2 , 0 1 1 -2,800-1,564 9 1,448 9 681 9 457 1,673 1,075 250 -39 318 308 1,084 214 620 1,554 2,145 606 1,533 377 171 1965.... 1966.... 1967-.. 196810.. -3,370 -3,444 -4,211 -4,252 -3,468 -1,079 753 -3,623 - 2 5 6 -418 -3,020 -1,270 -1,214 -3,348 - 6 0 3 -1,280 270 2,531 3,185 7,448 -315 -210 -532 -304 -1,335 - 1 , 2 8 9 -1,357 266 -3,571 - 3 , 4 0 5 -1,080 1,888 -18 -1,595 2,062 85 761 1,291 131 2,384 1,457 1,222 568 52 -l,206L -2,184. -1,541 182 -869 -1,165 2,292 1,035 515 - 1 , 2 4 2 568 - 9 7 3 1,184 578 511 - 3 , 3 6 5 423 - 3 , 8 7 0 Seasonally adjusted annual rates Quarterly totals unadjusted - 7 9 2 1 - - 2 , 5 2 0 - -1,636 -580 -372 -464 924 - -1,204 2,768 - 4 0 8 - -1,332 396 -852 54 -598 -199 34 247 90 390 475 27 1,211 61 7 424 68 82 -6 -4,704 -2,612 -696 - 5 9 2 -4,156-2,604 -724 -1,088! —3,952—3,608 -2,024 -1,520 -4,032-3,260 -1,636 -1,656 3,460 - 1 , 0 0 0 - -2,020 -7,056 4 , r " -1,832 - -2,088 -3,224 988 828 - -3,208! 3,064 - 6 , 9 6 8 - -4,328 1,412 -80 544 21 8 1,317 332 580 19 1 260 -709 95 1,306 765 1,027 -419 -375 -181 -800 -532 - 2 2 8 -1,424 - 7 8 0 -1,884| 5,468 -2,748'- -2,224 9,916 —972 - 6 5 6 6,112 6,960 -1,716 164 1,776 1,776 1,363 2,198 -44 369 772 524 718 2,263 1,065 904 -137 -571 1966: I — II.. III.. IV. -3,864' -2,780 -3,936-4,008 -2,992 -3,488 -2,988-4,216 1967: I.. II... ML. IV.. 1968: I . . . -4,656-1,496 II... -4,288 -4,140 -3,812 -4,408 -988 -256 -28 244 -276 -192 -524 -680 1,112 4,340 1,500 3,184 jj * Adjusted from customs data for differences in timing and coverage. 2 Includes certain special Government transactions. s, 3 Equals changes in liquid liabilities to foreign official holders, other foreign holders, and changes in official reserve assets < consisting of gold, convertible currencies, and the U.S. gold tranche position in the IMF. * Equals changes in liquid and nonliquid liabilities to foreign official holders and changes in official reserve assets consisting of gold, convertible currencies, and the U.S. gold tranche position in the IMF. * Includes short-term official and banking liabilities, foreign holdings of U.S. Government bonds and notes, and certain nonliquid liabilities to foreign official holders. * Central banks, governments, and U.S. liabilities to the IMF arising from reversible gold sales to, and gold deposits with the United States. * Private holders; includes banks and international and regional organizations, excludes IMF. 8 Not reported separately. 9 Includes change in Treasury liabilities to certain foreign military agencies; excluding these changes, data ($ millions) are 1,258 (1960), 741 (1961), 918 (1962). 10 Average for the first 3 quarters on a seasonally adjusted annual rates basis. Note.—Data exclude military grant-aid and U.S. subscriptions to International Monetary Fund. Source: Department of Commerce, Office of Business Economics. 325 TABLE B—85.—United States merchandise exports and imports, by commodity groups, 1958—68 [Millions of dollars] Merchandise exports * Total, including reexports 2 Merchandise imports Domestic exports General imports s Year or quarter Seasonally Unad- Total 2 4 adjusted justed Total* Food, Crude Food, Crude bever- mate- Manbever- mateufacages, rials Seaages, rials tured and to- and and to- and 6 sonally Unadbacco fuels s goods adjusted bacco fuels s justed Gross merchandise trade surplus, seaManufac- sonally adtured goods e justed ^ 1958 1959 16,373 16,208 16,418 16,234 2,688 2,852 3,051 11,546 2,996 11,171 13,262 15,629 3,550 3,580 4,062 4,580 5,283 7,090 3,111 789 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 19,635 20,190 20,973 22,427 25,690 19,434 19,944 20,703 22,143 25,338 3,167 3,466 3,743 4,188 4,637 3,942 3,863 3,355 3,774 4,336 12,559 12,748 13,655 14,259 16,388 15,019 14,716 16,392 17,140 18,684 3,392 3,455 3,674 3,863 4,022 4,380 4,303 4,640 4,692 4,976 6,847 6,523 7,626 8,066 9,096 4,616 5,474 4,581 5,287 7,006 26,699 29,379 30,934 34,000 26,356 28,944 30,550 33,600 4,520 5,186 4,710 4,600 4,274 4,403 4,722 4,800 17,388 19,108 20,752 23,800 21,366 25,542 26,812 33,000 4,013 4,589 4,701 5,400 5,385 5,674 5,334 6,000 11,238 14,413 15,712 20,400 5,333 3,837 4,122 1,000 ;;E 1965 1966 1967 1968 s 1966* 1 II III IV 7,194 7,257 7,439 7,500 7,078 7,435 7,025 7,841 6,978 7,305 6,919 7,742 1,252 1,257 1,310 1,367 1,024 1,086 1,027 1,266 4,644 4,888 4,530 5,046 6,021 6,335 6,59? 6,661 5,894 6,334 6,5 5 6,769 1,112 1,165 1,112 1,200 1,410 1,438 1,456 1,370 3,184 3,517 3,765 3,947 1,173 921 847 839 1967- 1 II III IV 7,770 7,777 7,772 7,688 7,680 7,967 7,273 8,014 7,584 7,867 7,176 7,923 1,127 1,157 1,131 1,295 1,158 1,208 1,123 1,233 5,196 5,431 4,829 5,296 6,684 6,590 6,542 7,105 6,616 6,579 6,405 7,212 1,212 1,125 1,100 1,264 1,385 1,336 1,254 1,359 3,806 3,844 3,779 4,283 1,086 1,187 1,230 583 1968- 1 II III IV8 8,012 8,368 8,965 8,600 7,980 8,570 8,369 9,100 7,882 8,463 8,262 9,000 1,196 1,091 1,122 1,200 1,176 1,204 1,166 1,300 5,428 6,061 5,900 6,400 7,823 8,232 8,455 8,300 7,735 8,219 8,420 8,600 1,257 1,308 1,431 1,400 1,437 1,452 1,554 1,600 4,786 5,155 5,123 5,300 189 136 510 300 1 Beginning 1960, data have been adjusted for comparability with the revised commodity classifications effective in 1965 2 Totals exclude Department of Defense shipments of grant-aid military supplies and equipment under the Military Assistance Program. 3 Total arrivals of imported goods other than intransit shipments. 4 Total includes commodities and transactions not classified according to kind. 6 Includes fats and oils. 6 Includes machinery, transportation equipment, chemicals, metals, and other manufactures. Export data for these items include military grant-aid shipments. 7 Exports, excluding military grant-aid, less general imports; quarterly data seasonally adjusted. 8Totals based on data for October, November, and estimates for December. Note.—Data are as reported by the Bureau of the Census. Export statistics cover all merchandise shipped from the U.S. customs area, except supplies for U.S. Armed Forces. Export values are f.a.s. port of export and include shipments under Agency for International Development and Food for Peace programs as well as other private relief shipments. I m p o r t values are defined generally as the market value in the foreign country, excluding the U.S. import duty and transportation costs such as ocean freight and marine insurance. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of International Commerce. 326 TABLE B-86.—United States merchandise exports and imports, by area, 1962-68 [Millions of dollars] Area 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 January-November 1967 Exports (including reexports and special category shipments): Total Developed countries Developing countries Canada Other Western HemisphereWestern Europe i Eastern Europe. Asia Australia and Oceania Africa .. General imports: Total Developed countries Developing countries Canada Other Western Hemisphere.. Western Europe1 Eastern Europe Asia Australia and Oceania Africa Unidentified countries2 1968 21,700 23,347 26,508 27,478 30,320 31,526 28,655 31,282 13,985 7,589 15,124 8,056 17,202 8,966 18,315 9,023 20,010 10,112 21,371 9,960 19,390 9,084 21,272 9,820 4,045 3,679 7,633 125 4,676 519 1,023 4,251 3,692 8,171 167 5,448 565 1,053 4,915 4,292 9,096 340 5,802 804 1,259 5,643 4,274 9,224 140 6,012 956 1,229 6,661 4,769 9,805 198 6,733 805 1,349 7,165 4,718 10,103 195 7,146 1,017 1,182 6,547 4,302 9,174 181 6,504 853 1,094 7,296 4,828 9,967 190 6,877 949 1,175 16,392 17,140 18,684 21,366 25, 542 26,812 24,381 30,093 10,250 6,035 10,807 6,242 11,894 6,676 14,067 7,145 17, 590 7,762 18,943 7,681 17,210 6,999 21,843 8,056 3,660 3,931 4,544 79 2,960 440 754 24 3,829 4,021 4,731 81 3,192 502 777 7 4,239 4,151 5,208 99 3,620 440 917 10 4,832 4,371 6,155 137 4,528 453 878 12 6,125 4,704 7,678 179 5,276 594 979 7 7,107 4,635 8,050 177 5,348 581 906 8 6,438 4,229 7,287 162 4,910 522 825 8 8,042 4,637 9,240 182 6,298 658 1,027 9 1 Includes Finland, Yugoslavia, Greece, and Turkey. 2 Consists of certain low-valued shipments and some uranium imports, not identified by country. Note.—Developed countries include Canada, Western Europe, Japan, Australia, New Zealand, and the Republic of South Africa. Developing countries include rest of the world except Communist areas in Eastern Europe and Asia and unidentified countries. Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of International Commerce. 327 TABLE B-87.—United States overseas loans and grants, by type and area, fiscal years 1962-68 [Millions of dollars] Type of program and fiscal period Total Near East and South Asia East Asia Other and nonregional Latin America Vietnam 516 189 327 397 168 229 274 228 46 459 29 430 562 248 313 337 200 137 162 145 17 604 70 534 Africa Europe Total economic loans and grants (net obligations and loan authorizations): 1 1962-67 average Loans Grants 4,730 2,535 2,195 1,576 1,167 409 1,163 754 409 1968 4,749 2,604 2,145 1,279 1,066 212 1,362 874 488 347 * 347 444 * 444 4,538 4,445 1,576 1,279 1,163 1,362 347 444 446 468 397 337 167 21 442 534 678 976 245 348 273 393 11 4 53 64 27 48 60 113 8 7 2,297 1,891 764 440 557 496 278 304 226 230 209 116 2 * 261 304 196 270 108 148 20 50 11 3 21 26 16 25 17 18 3 1 376 570 80 174 178 301 26 28 27 49 65 18 365 490 71 89 235 307 25 26 8 18 26 49 1,388 1,398 720 652 151 228 69 140 157 185 139 148 101 3 95 178 62 103 10 15 1 4 9 2 3 18 46 Loans Grants _ Economic loans and grants to less developed countries, by program: 2 Net obligations and loan authorizations: 1962-67 average 1968 Repayments and interest: 1962-67 average.. 1968 Agency for International Development: Net obligations and loan authorizations: 1962-67 average 1968 Repayments and interest: 1962-67 average 1968 Export-Import Bank long-term loans: Loan authorizations: 1962-67 average... 1968 ---Repayments and interest: 1962-67 average 1968 Food for Freedom: Obligations: 1962-67 average 1968 Repayments and interest: 1962—67 average 1968 Contributions and Subscriptions to International Lending Organizations: 3 Obligations: 1962-67 average 1968 Peace Corps and other: 4 Obligations: 1962-67 average 1968 Repayments and interest: 1962—67 average 1968 241 424 51 42 79 124 162 300 236 162 12 13 115 36 37 25 22 24 50 64 22 39 5 8 9 21 3 3 1 1 6 6 *Some data are preliminary. Countries have been classified "less developed" on the basis of the standard list of less developed countries used by the Development Assistance Committee of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. On this basis, "less developed" countries include all countries receiving U.S. loans or grants except the following which are considered "developed": Japan, Australia, New Zealand, Republic of South Africa, Canada, and all of Europe except Malta, Spain and Yugoslavia. 3 Includes capital subscriptions and contributions to the Inter-American Development Bank, the International Development Association and the Asian Development Bank. 4 Data for certain programs from Department of Commerce (Office of Business Economics). Source: Agency for International Development (except as noted). 328 TABLE B-88.—International reserves, 1949, 1953, and 1963-68 [Millions of dollars; end of period] 1968 Area and country 1949 1953 1964 1963 1965 1966 1967 September December All countries. 45,635 51,890 66,370 68,670 70,430 71,895 73,510 73,440 Developed a r e a s . . . 37,245 41,390 56,820 58,945 59,445 60,235 61,055 59,850 26,024 23,458 16,843 16,672 15,450 14,882 14,830 14,634 15,710 United Kingdom 1,752 2,670 3,147 2,316 3,004 3,100 2,695 2,717 2,422 Other Western Europe Austria Belgium.. France... Germany Italy Netherlands Scandinavian countries (Denmark, Finland, Norway, and Sweden) Spain Switzerland... Othera. 6,457 92 978 580 196 10,515 325 1,144 829 1,773 768 1,232 29,413 1,229 1,970 4,908 7,650 3,619 2,102 32,279 1,317 2,222 5,724 7,882 3,824 2,349 33,583 1,311 2,334 6,343 7,429 4,800 2,416 34,950 1,333 2,350 6,733 8,028 4,910 2,448 1,026 150 1,768 1,500 1,875 1,147 3,074 1,839 2,380 1,513 3,120 1,948 2,324 1,409 3,244 1,973 2,340 1,205 3,324 2,278 2,236 1,049 3,555 2,306 2,451 1,120 2,932 2,394 1,902 2,603 2,881 3,027 2,693 2,709 2,727 892 2,058 2,019 2,152 2,119 2,030 2,380 United States- ( 537 & 1,222 Canada- 1,197 Japan... Australia, New Zealand, and South Africa Less developed areas * Latin America. Middle E a s t . . . Other Asia Other A f r i c a . . . 36,448 34,469 1 484 1,538 2,590 2,416 6,994 4,374 8,152 9,189 5,463 5,584 2,619 2,471 1,510 2,187 4,201 2,463 2,320 3,932 2,906 (0 1,582 8,390 2,775 1,475 3,395 <290 1,952 2,756 2,777 2,228 2,494 2,341 2,921 10,500 9,550 9,725 10,985 11,660 12,455 13,590 3,400 1,200 3,840 1,800 2,725 2,255 3,085 1,405 2,855 2,320 3,070 1,415 3,280 2,675 3,395 1; 575 3,180 2,845 3,845 1,730 3,460 3,195 3,975 1,750 3,660 3,345 4,240 2,145 i Not available separately. 3 In addition to other Western European countries, includes unpublished gold reserves of Greece and an estimate of gold to be distributed by the Tripartite Commission for the Restitution of Monetary Gold. 3 Includes unpublished gold holdings not allocable by area. < Estimate. Note.—Includes gold holdings, reserve positions in the International Monetary Fund, and foreign exchange of all countries except U.S.S.R., other Eastern European countries, Communist China and Cuba (after 1960). Beginning 1959, when most of the major currencies of the world became convertible, data exclude known holdings of inconvertible currencies, balances under payments agreements, and the bilateral claims arising from liquidation of the European Payments Union. Source: International Monetary Fund, "International Financial Statistics." 329 TABLE B-89.—United States reserve assets: Gold stock, holdings of convertible foreign currencies, and reserve position in the International Monetary Fund, 1946-68 [Millions of dollars] Gold stock i End of year or month Total reserve assets Total* Treasury Convertible foreign currencies3 Reserve position in International Monetary Fund4 1946 1947 1948 1949 20,706 24,021 25,758 26,024 20,706 22,868 24,399 24,563 20,529 22,754 24,244 24,427 1,153 1,359 1,461 1950 1951 _ 1952 1953 1954 24,265 24,299 24.714 23,458 22 978 22,820 22,873 23,252 22,091 21 793 22,706 22,695 23,187 22,030 21 713 1,445 1,426 1,462 1,367 1 185 22,797 23,666 24,832 22,540 21,504 21,753 22 058 22,857 20,582 19,507 21,690 21,949 22,781 20,534 19,456 1,044 1,608 1,975 1,958 1,997 19,359 18,753 17,220 16,843 16,672 17,804 16,947 16,057 15,596 15,471 17,767 16,889 15,978 15,513 15,388 99 212 432 15,450 14,882 14,830 15,710 s 13,806 13 235 12,065 10,892 13,733 13,159 11,982 10,367 781 1 321 2,345 3,528 14,196 13,998 13,855 13,906 13,943 14,274 13,202 13,161 13,184 13,234 13;214 13,169 13,157 13,107 13,107 13,109 13,109 13,110 645 14,224 14,605 14,649 14,927 15,438 14,830 13,136 13,075 13,077 13,039 12,965 12,065 14,620 14,790 13,926 13,840 14,348 14,063 14,366 14,427 14,634 14,427 15,660 15,710 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 . ... 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 . . . . . 1967: Jan... Feb Mar Apr _ May June July Aug Sept Oct . Nov Dec 1968: Jan.... Feb Mar. Apr May June July Aug. Sept Oct . Nov Dec 116 1,555 1,690 1,064 1,035 769 5 863 326 420 1,290 480 349 357 314 315 357 357 363 366 738 367 13,108 13,008 13,006 12,905 12,908 11,982 719 1,162 1,200 1,509 2,092 2,345 369 368 12,003 11,900 10,703 10,547 10,468 10,681 11,984 11,882 10,484 10,484 10,384 10,367 2,176 2,235 2,746 2,804 3,386 2,479 441 655 477 489 494 903 10,676 10,681 10,755 10,788 10,897 10,892 10,367 10,367 10,367 10,367 10,367 10,367 2,773 2,817 2,953 2,703 3,655 3,528 917 929 926 936 372 379 381 420 1,108 1,290 1 Includes gold sold to the United States by the International Monetary Fund with the right of repurchase which amounted to $800 million on December 31, 1968. Beginning September 1965 also includes gold deposited by the IMF to mitigate the impact on the U.S. gold stock of purchases by foreign countries for gold subscriptions on increased IMF quotas. Amount outstanding was $230 million on December 31,1968. The United States has a corresponding gold liability to 2the IMF. Includes gold in Exchange Stabilization Fund. 3 Includes holdings of Treasury and Federal Reserve System. 4 In accordance with Fund policies the United States has the right to draw foreign currencies equivalent to its reserve position in the Fund virtually automatically if needed. Under appropriate conditions the United States could draw additional amounts equal to the United States quota. 5 Reserve position includes, and gold stock excludes, $259 million gold subscription to the Fund in June 1965 for a U.S. quota increase which became effective on February 23, 1966. In figures published by the Fund from June 1965 through January 1966, this gold subscription was included in the U.S. gold stock and excluded from the reserve position. Mote.—Gold held under earmark at Federal Reserve Banks for foreign and international accounts is not included in the gold stock of the United States. Sources: Treasury Department and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 330 TABLE B-90.—Price changes in international trade, 1960-68 11958=100] 1968 Area or commodity class 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1960 Third quarter Unit value indexes by area Developed areas Total: 100 103 101 104 101 105 102 104 103 104 104 104 106 104 106 105 105 105 101 101 103 105 102 107 102 105 103 104 106 106 107 105 112 108 113 108 99 95 97 93 95 95 97 97 97 97 97 99 97 98 97 98 97 93 95 Exports Terms of trade i . 91 93 94 97 101 103 101 102 103 103 101 100 3 102 3 99 104 104 101 102 102 102 103 100 104 100 106 103 99 99 3 99 3 100 11 0 100 98 97 99 96 84 107 81 109 81 106 98 97 16 0 155 108 178 97 101 98 71 95 104 19 0 13 6 91 101 93 71 96 110 15 0 105 106 115 99 97 110 United States » Exports Terms of trade 1. Developing areas Total: Exports Terms of trade 1. Latin America Exports Terms of trade 1. Southern and Eastern Asia < 111 109 Exports Terms of traded World export price indexes « Foodstuffs Coffee, tea, and cocoaCereals Other agricultural commodities * Fats, oils, and oilseeds.. Textile fibers Wool Rubber Minerals Metal ores.. 8 Manufactured goods: Total ... Nonferrous base metals 8_. 100 13 0 100 90 94 90 13 0 72 98 70 103 99 80 101 107 94 104 108 141 13 0 97 105 107 107 99 73 102 13 0 95 112 127 95 16 0 87 105 105 104 92 100 12 0 110 98 116 131 91 94 104 104 15 3 108 105 110 93 93 Primary commodities: Total. 97 95 91 77 96 101 114 89 101 106 102 92 99 12 0 19 0 92 96 13 0 110 1 Terms of trade indexes are unit value indexes of exports divided by unit value indexes of imports. 2 Includes foreign trade of Alaska, Hawaii, and Puerto Rico. 3 Data are for second quarter 1968. * Excludes Japan. « Data for manufactured goods are unit value indexes, e Includes nonfood fish and forest products. Note.—Data exclude trade of Communist areas in Eastern Europe (except Yugoslavia) and Asia. Sources: United Nations and Department of Commerce (Bureau of International Commerce). 331 95 104 109 162 TABLE B-91.—Consumer price indexes in the United States and other major industrial countries 1957-68 11963==100] United States Period Canada Japan France Germany Netherlands Italy United Kingdom 1957 1958.. 1959 91.8 94.4 95.1 91.7 94.1 95.1 79.3 78.9 79.8 69.6 80.1 85.0 88.1 90.0 90.9 83.2 85.5 85.1 88 90 91 86.9 89 5 90.0 1960 . 1961 1962 1963-_ 1964 96.6 97.7 98.8 100.0 101.3 96.2 97.1 98.3 100.0 101.8 82.6 87.0 93.0 100.0 103.9 88.1 91.0 95.4 100.0 103.4 92.1 94.3 97.1 100.0 102.3 87.1 88.9 93.1 100.0 105.9 94 95 97 100 106 90.9 94.0 98.0 100.0 103.3 103.0 106.0 109.0 113.3 104.3 108.2 112.0 116.3 110.7 116.4 121.0 127.0 106.0 108.9 111.8 116.4 105.8 109.5 111.1 112.5 110.7 113.3 116.9 118.4 111 118 121 125 108 2 112.4 115.2 120.1 1965: 1. II. _ III . . IV 102 1 102.8 103.2 103.7 103 1 103.9 104.8 105.3 108.6 110.8 110.8 112.9 105.0 106.1 106.3 106.9 104.1 105.4 106.5 107.1 109.5 110.1 111.2 111.9 108 113 112 112 105 8 108.5 108.9 109.6 1966: L II ._ Ill IV 104 5 105.6 106.6 107.4 106 7 107.9 108.9 109.5 114 9 116.4 116.5 117.6 107 7 108.5 109.2 109.8 108.5 109.8 109.6 110.1 112.7 113.0 113.3 114.2 116 120 118 118 110-4 112.5 112.9 113.8 1967: 1 II III IV 107.6 108.4 109.5 110.4 109.9 111.5 113.2 113.6 119.8 119.7 120.2 124.1 110.8 111.2 111.9 113.5 110.9 111.5 111.2 110.8 115.9 116.6 117.5 117.9 119 123 122 122 114.4 115.4 114.8 116.2 1968: 1 II Ill IV 2 111.6 112.8 114.2 115.5 114.9 116.0 117.3 117.9 126.2 126.4 127.4 129.8 115.1 115.8 117.2 119.2 112.3 112.5 112.5 112.9 118.2 118.5 118.3 118.5 124 125 126 117.8 120.6 121.3 122.0 1965 1966 1967 1968 ! ... _ 1 Averages for January-November for the United States; January-September for the Netherlands; and January-October for all other countries. 2 October-November average for the United States and October data for ail other countries. Sources: Department of Labor and Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. 332 U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE: 1969 O—323-166