View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Economic Quarterly— Volume 101, Number 2— Second Quarter 2015

Essays from our Annual
Reports, Part II
John A. Weinberg

This issue represents a second collection of essays originally published in the Richmond Fed’s Annual Report since 2007. The …rst issue
collected essays relating to the …nancial crisis and its aftermath. But
this was not all that was going on in the last eight years. In other
annual reports we have tried to address broad issues a¤ecting the economic well-being of U.S. households. The topics addressed in these
essays largely deal with longer-run trends in the economy— phenomena
that play out over longer intervals than the typical business cycle. As
such, these issues shape the backdrop to the Federal Reserve’s monetary policymaking.
The …rst of these was our 2007 essay on household savings, with
a particular focus on life-cycle aspects of savings— saving for retirement. One frequently hears concerns that many households approach
retirement age with savings inadequate to support a continuation of
their pre-retirement standard of living. These concerns are often motivated by the shift away over time from de…ned bene…t pensions in
the work place and by a declining personal savings rate in the U.S.
aggregate data. Looking carefully at the breadth of available empirical
and theoretical research, our 2007 essay found a more nuanced picture. Looking at household behavior through the lens of the life-cycle
theory of saving and consumption suggested that, while there was variation, most households were approaching retirement reasonably wellprepared. Two caveats to this …nding are important to note. First, the
essay looked entirely at evidence from before the deep recession that
began in late 2007 and severely disrupted household …nances. Second, for a large portion of the population, government transfers from
the Medicare and Social Security programs made up— and continue to
make up— a signi…cant portion of their retirement resources. And our
aging population means that these transfers will become an increasing
source of …scal strain for the federal government.

96

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

Budgetary issues more generally have been a topic of broad concern
in the United States in recent years. The recession of 2007–09 brought
with it a large increase in federal de…cits, and the polarized political
environment has led to near shut downs of the government on a number of occasions, as the Treasury has run up against its legislated debt
ceiling. In 2011, a year in which …scal policy and government borrowing was the subject of intense political debate (and gamesmanship), we
examined the notion of sustainability in government …nancial plans. In
our essay for that year, we explained that economic forces would put
an upper limit on how much debt a government could issue, although
identifying that limit, or how close we are to it at any point in time, is
di¢ cult. But …nancial market investors simply wouldn’t be willing to
hold— not without sharply higher yields— a level of debt so high that
future taxes would not be capable of paying it o¤. As a government
neared such a level, the public would come to expect some adjustment
to planned spending and taxes. But uncertainty about the shape that
such adjustments might take could itself have the e¤ect of dampening investment spending and thereby weaken growth. Further, …scal
policy stretching the limits of sustainability raises the risks that monetary policy will lose its ability to control the price level. Hence, the
possible consequences of continued political gridlock for the long-term
performance of the U.S. economy were (and are) signi…cant.
One of the de…ning characteristics of the recession of 2007–09 was
the dramatic increase in the share of the unemployed who were unemployed longer than 26 weeks. This episode was the worst economic
contraction in the United States since the Great Depression, with the
unemployment rate topping out at 10 percent. This peak was a little
below the peak in the 1982 recession. In that earlier period, however,
the long-term unemployed never accounted for more than about a quarter of all unemployed. By contrast, in the recent recession the share
of the long-term unemployed soared to more than 40 percent of overall
unemployment. Our 2010 Annual Report essay examined these facts,
together with the related phenomenon of “duration dependence”— the
tendency for unemployed with longer unemployment spells to have
lower probabilities of …nding a job. The essay argues that the distinct
patterns in the data for the Great Recession suggest that an unusually large number of workers with relatively low employability entered
unemployment in the contraction. This …nding is consistent with a
major source of the economic dislocation of the period coming from
structural changes in the economy that reduced the relative demand
for lower-skilled workers. While this is a topic that has continued to
attract considerable research attention, our 2010 essay’s early look at

J. A. Weinberg: Introduction

97

the period suggested that much of the labor market damage in the
Great Recession was beyond the ability of monetary policy to correct.
Perhaps related to structural changes that altered the relative demands for workers of varying skill levels, the period since the recession has seen varying rates of improvement for workers and households
across the income distribution. Indeed, inequality has increasingly become a topic of economic and political commentary. Our 2012 Annual
Report essay touched on this topic, but with a focus more on the dynamics of household economic standing, as opposed to the distribution
at a point in time. In particular, the essay surveys the evidence on intergenerational mobility— the frequency with which children born into
the lower parts of the income distribution are able to climb the economic ladder in their lifetimes. The fact that there is a fair amount
of persistence across generations is taken as evidence that people likely
face di¤erent levels of challenges in developing the human capital necessary for advancing one’s standard of living. And these disparities
in access to human capital investment likely begin very early in life—
pointing to a targeted approach to public early childhood education
investments as an avenue for improving the economic mobility of those
at the bottom of the distribution.
The broad trends discussed in these essays, as well as the public policy implications, fall mostly well outside the scope of monetary
policy. But by identifying forces shaping the real economy, they help
us understand the context in which the Federal Reserve pursues its
mandates for price stability and sustainable employment growth.

Economic Quarterly— Volume 101, Number 2— Second Quarter 2015— Pages 99–123

Are We Saving Enough?
Households and Retirement
Doug Campbell and John A. Weinberg

O

n October 15 of last year, a retired school teacher from Earleville, Maryland, sat down at a computer terminal and typed
responses to four “yes” or “no” questions, beginning with,
“Are you at least 61 years and 9 months old?” In answering a¢ rmatively, Kathleen Casey-Kirschling made history. Born one second after
midnight New Year’s Day, 1946, she was the …rst of the 78-millionmember baby boom generation to apply for Social Security bene…ts.
She became eligible to collect with the turn of 2008.
The reason Casey-Kirschling’s otherwise everyday act made news
is no mystery. In part because there are so many baby boomers relative to the overall population, Social Security payments to retirees
are projected to exceed payroll tax revenues in less than 10 years. By
2041, bene…ts will have to decline, or taxes or government borrowing
will have to increase. In the case of Medicare, the health care insurance system for the American elderly, similar changes are expected to
be necessary as early as 2019.
The baby boom generation’s retirement brings into focus perhaps
the most signi…cant demographic shift in United States history. Baby
boomers, the moniker for the generation born between 1946 and 1964,
comprise about 26 percent of the overall U.S. population. Their sheer
numbers assure that future growth in the labor force will slow by comparison to recent decades. The birth rate seems unlikely to ever spike
up to that experienced in the 1950s, and life expectancy continues to
increase.
In 1940, people who had already reached the age of 65 were expected
to live to be 77.7 years. By 2030, life expectancy for 65-year-olds
The views expressed are the authors’ and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve System.

100

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

is projected to reach 83.7 years. At the same time, birth rates are
falling: In 1955— the core of the baby boom— the average woman had
3.5 children in her lifetime; by 2005, the birth rate had leveled o¤ to
about 2 children per woman, a trend that is projected to hold steady
for the next 25 years.
These trends signify long-term rami…cations for the economic wellbeing of American households. First, the big picture: Population aging
presents a problem of consumption maintenance. If a growing number
of older people move into retirement, then there are fewer people working as a share of the population, increasing the so-called dependency
ratio shown in the …rst …gure in this article. So on a per-person basis, there would be relatively fewer goods and services being produced.
The upshot is that people could have less to consume than in the absence of population aging. This statement requires the economist’s
usual “other-things-being-equal”quali…cation, which means that other
factors in the economy a¤ect economic output per person. Most importantly, productivity growth resulting from technical change or improved
work force skills increases output per worker. But regardless of the status of such other factors, an aging population probably means lower
average consumption-per-person than would otherwise be possible.
Second, beyond the sustainability of national consumption, population aging threatens the sustainability of the nation’s entitlement
programs. Social Security and Medicare are pay-as-you-go programs,
meaning younger generations of workers …nance the retirements of older
generations. For Social Security, the present value of bene…ts promised
to older cohorts is $13.6 trillion greater than the present value of scheduled tax contributions to the system, according to the Treasury Department. As large numbers of baby boomers retire, they will drain
those promised bene…ts to the point where incoming tax revenue will
no longer be su¢ cient to keep the programs solvent. A similar issue exists at the state and local levels, where many public-employee pension
and retiree health care plans are less than fully funded. The growth of
public-sector obligations to retiring boomers could strain government
budgets at many levels.
Strains on entitlements are only one type of challenge facing today’s
workers. Employees also are adjusting to the predominance of a relatively new form of retirement saving— de…ned-contribution pensions,
most commonly in the form of employer-sponsored 401(k) plans, in
which workers are the main suppliers to their retirement plans. Under
such a plan, a household could potentially outlive its savings, unless it
was e¤ectively annuitized.
Fading away are de…ned-bene…t pensions, which provide guaranteed
income streams for retirees that they can’t outlive. At precisely the

D. Campbell and J. A. Weinberg: Households and Retirement

101

Figure 1 Longer Lives, Greater Dependency

Source: Annual Report of the Social Security and Medicare Boards of Trustees for
2007.
Notes: *Dependency Ratio per 100 workers; Population aged 65 and over, divided
by population aged 20–64; **Life expectancy at age 65.

time at which public transfer backstops that mitigate the problem of
longer lifespans are in trouble, responsibility for saving is being placed
upon the shoulders of individuals, as is the investment risk.
Despite the heightened importance of individual preparedness for
retirement, a puzzling observation is that Americans seem to be saving
less than ever. The personal saving rate, for example, has been declining. And there is no shortage of anecdotes about overboard consumer
spending and people entering their 60s with no nest eggs.
All of this adds up to quite a laundry list of concerns. To review, we have an aging population, which means problems in maintaining national consumption as well as maintaining entitlement programs
like Social Security and Medicare. Then we have the tricky transition
from guaranteed de…ned-bene…t pensions to employee-driven, de…nedcontribution 401(k) plans. And …nally we have economic statistics that
appear to show that Americans are saving at historically low rates. We
are left with a big question: Are U.S. households going to be …nancially
prepared for retirement?
In this essay, we initially aim to clear up some misconceptions
about Americans’saving habits. We look at the data on demographics,

102

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

pensions, and wealth, seeking to identify which trends merit concern
and action, and which may not.
Our emphasis is on households. Why households? In the popular
media, the cited statistics are almost always aggregate— they consider
the state of things across the board rather than by household. The popular press reports endless stories about perilously low saving rates; the
implication is that “the economy” is in trouble. But our interest isn’t
in the aggregate economy but in the economic well-being of individual households— people, couples, and families. In fact, when you look
at the data on individual households— that is, disaggregated data—
a surprisingly di¤erent picture emerges. Most households near retirement are saving adequately. Crucially, insofar as future policies are
concerned, their saving is as modern economic theory predicts: They
are mostly doing the best they can given their incomes.
Then we consider the future. The …nding that households are now
saving optimally assumes that the government will deliver on promised
Social Security and Medicare bene…ts. But the demographic shift will
stress the federal budget, imperiling those bene…ts. In addition, we
face the related problem that the demographic shift may reduce the
size of the overall pie that households can consume (relative to a world
in which no demographic change occurs). It might seem wise to …nd a
way to spread these burdens across generations so that future generations don’t take the biggest hit. Those ways might include saving more,
taxing more, or borrowing more. We will explore the e¤ects of these
di¤erent approaches, with particular attention to their unintended effects. Understanding the economic tradeo¤s inherent in each of these
strategies may help us choose well.

1.

MEASURING SAVINGS

It goes without saying that saving is important. Taking income from
present consumption and moving it to savings allows us to …nance
spending on both physical and human capital to increase the future
standard of living. The growth of future living standards depends on
how much income is set aside for savings, as well as growth in productivity.
Concern about Americans’readiness for retirement generally can be
traced to a single source— the personal saving rate. The most widely
cited measure of personal saving comes from the U.S. government’s
National Income and Products Accounts (NIPA). Boiled down, the
NIPA measure is disposable— or after-tax— income minus spending.
This measure held mostly steady between 7 percent and 10 percent
of disposable income from the 1950s through the early 1980s. It then

D. Campbell and J. A. Weinberg: Households and Retirement

103

Figure 2 Personal Saving Rate

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce.

began to fall, going south of 7 percent in 1990, to 4 percent in 1996, and
2.3 percent in 2001. In 2005, it went into negative territory. In 2006,
Americans saved an average of 0.4 percent of their disposable income,
and the saving rate has hovered around zero since then. It is impossible
to ignore the sharp downward movement that this rate has displayed
over the past two decades, and it has fallen more sharply than in most
other developed countries.
Why have savings trended so far south? Many assume the main
problem is self-control, or lack thereof. People may spend to satisfy
immediate needs or cravings, ignoring reality or hoping against all evidence that the future will bring more wealth. A related story is that
credit has become easy to obtain, leading households to take on more
debt— or at least saving less because they know they can borrow in an
emergency.
The components of the NIPA saving rate are worth a closer look.
C. Alan Garner, an economist with the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City, points out several potential shortcomings. The NIPA rate computes how much household income is put aside for other uses, such as
investments in homes or businesses. But it excludes capital gains and
losses on existing assets. Therefore, it doesn’t include potential changes
in wealth from assets ranging from stocks to home equity.
The 1990s and early 2000s saw signi…cant increases in both stocks
and housing values. Perhaps households, feeling wealthier, were

104

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

motivated to spend more. Indeed, some economists believe that there
is a “wealth e¤ect” on consumption; when household wealth rises or
falls, consumption will go in the same direction.
Measured savings is a consequence of households’consumption decisions and shows the di¤erence between measured income and the
resulting consumption. Consumption can grow with no corresponding
increase in measured income, which drives the saving rate lower but
this could be because actual income increased more rapidly than measured income. Meanwhile, those examining the NIPA rate don’t have
the same perspective as consumers, whose con…dence in their future
earnings or wealth isn’t directly observed. To observers, it may look
like some households are saving too little; for some of those households,
it may just be a case of spending now in anticipation of higher income
later.
For data on household wealth, the Federal Reserve’s Flow of Funds
Accounts provides some aggregate …gures. Overall, wealth has gone
up almost every year (it dropped in the 2001 recession), though the
growth has slowed in recent decades. It may seem surprising that the
saving rate has gone down while net household wealth has gone up.
But the two are not historically connected, as wealth changes are a
product mostly of changes in stock and real estate asset prices, which
are not taken into account by the standard measures of saving. By
itself, the NIPA rate doesn’t tell us whether Americans are likely to
reach retirement with su¢ cient wealth.
As with all national economic indicators, later revisions can change
initial results. Historically, the NIPA saving rate has mostly been revised upward, and sometimes by large amounts. Leonard Nakamura
and Tom Stark, economists with the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, …nd that initial estimates of personal savings from 1965 to 1999
on average were revised upward by 2.8 percentage points. For the
fourth quarter of 1981, for example, the revision was up 7.3 percentage
points. Nakamura and Stark attribute the di¤erences to new methodologies that take into account new sources of household income. New
data from Census revisions also may play a role in adjusting estimated
business sales, which in turn a¤ect personal consumption expenditures
captured in NIPA.
Finally, the saving rate is an aggregate measure. It gives no sense of
savings across the population’s distribution. How much are low-income
households saving compared with high-income households? The NIPA
saving rate, as generally cited, does not address this question.

D. Campbell and J. A. Weinberg: Households and Retirement
2.

105

A CLOSER LOOK AT WEALTH

Many studies have looked at more robust measures of household wealth.
Alicia Munnell and Mauricio Soto, economists at Boston College, analyzed the Health and Retirement Study (HRS), which provides panel
data from an initial 1992 sample of 7,600 households aged 51 to 61. It
provides a close-up look at where household savings are located at the
cusp of retirement.
Financial planners often rely on replacement rates to gauge whether
their clients are saving as much as they should. A replacement rate assesses the amount of spending a retired household’s savings can sustain
relative to its pre-retirement income. A typical rule of thumb is that
a retired household should plan to spend between 75 percent and 85
percent of annual income before retirement, because even though expenditures on things like health care might increase, living expenses
generally are lower for old people. Munnell and Soto calculate average
income replacement rates for households of adult couples with pensions
at 79 percent and those without pensions at 62 percent.
Clearly, households with replacement rates of 62 percent can expect
to experience declines in their living standards upon retirement. On the
other hand, these couples who lack pensions make up just 25 percent
of the sampled population.
Sizing up these …gures, Munnell and Soto conclude that: “The majority of households retiring today are in pretty good shape. Regardless of how retirement income and pre-retirement income are de…ned,
households with pensions appear to meet the threshold of adequacy.”
Importantly, Munnell and Soto found that for the mean of the middle 20 percent of soon-to-retire U.S. households, expected payments
from Social Security represent an average of 48 percent of their wealth.
Their prediction about the adequacy of household wealth assumes that
entitlement programs like Social Security will remain solvent.
Economists at Williams College and the Federal Reserve Board of
Governors take the next step by analyzing the HRS data for insights
into the distribution of savings across the population. David Love,
Paul Smith, and Lucy McNair develop a new measure they term “comprehensive wealth,” asking whether U.S. households are “adequately”
saving for retirement. The authors take one of the …rst looks at the
2004 wave of the HRS, which captures the “early baby boomers”born
between 1948 and 1953. They begin with …nancial net worth, which
they de…ne as the sum of stocks, checking accounts, and CDs, minus non-vehicle and non-housing debts. Also added are balances from
de…ned-contribution pension plans, typically 401(k)s, and IRA balances. Moreover they added present values of de…ned-bene…t pensions,

106

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

Social Security, and welfare, plus expected future labor income. And
they added employer matches to de…ned-contribution plans.
Their …ndings show that, “overall, households hold comprehensive
wealth that is several multiples”of the wealth level necessary to sustain
consumption at the o¢ cial poverty line. The median ratio of wealth
to the present value of future poverty lines is 3.56; the median annuity
value of wealth is $32,000. (These are, admittedly, not large nest eggs,
but since old people consume less than young people, they may well be
su¢ cient. A retirement annuity of $32,000 per person represents a 75
percent replacement rate for a worker earning $42,700 a year.) Still,
about 12 percent of households lack enough comprehensive wealth to
bring them over the poverty line, and 9 percent (with ratios between 1.0
and 1.5) are “near”the line. “Not surprisingly,”they write, “there is a
close correlation between lifetime earnings and the share of households
below or near the poverty line.”
Put another way, the working poor often don’t have enough savings
when older to lift them out of poverty in retirement. Poor households
in their working years remain poor in their retirement. “Overall, our
…ndings show a generally optimistic view of retirement savings adequacy among current older cohorts, though with a notable pocket of
inadequacy concentrated among those with the lowest lifetime earnings.” Like Munnell and Soto, these authors …nd that expected Social
Security payments represent a large share of retirement wealth for those
at or below the middle of the lifetime earnings distribution.

3.

A THEORY OF SAVING

The main reason that looking at aggregate statistics on saving can be
misleading is founded on two 50-year-old economic theories. In his 1957
book, A Theory of the Consumption Function, Milton Friedman found
that current income matters less in consumption than “permanent”
income, by which he meant a long-run average of anticipated income.
People tended to smooth their consumption throughout their lifetimes
based on how much they expected to earn.
Also in 1957, Albert Ando and Franco Modigliani tested the prediction that people’s natural inclination is to smooth their consumption
over their lifetimes. When younger and earning less income, people may
borrow more and save less. During middle age, when labor income is
typically at its peak, people will ratchet up their saving. In retirement, as income diminishes, people spend o¤ their savings. Overall,
households estimate the stream of resources over their lifetimes and
use that as their benchmark in deciding how much to spend at any
given period.

D. Campbell and J. A. Weinberg: Households and Retirement

107

It turns out that these theories, known as the permanent income
and life-cycle hypotheses, have matched up with the data fairly well
over time. One of the more recent studies on this front comes from
John Karl Scholz, Ananth Seshadri, and Surachai Khitatrakun. What
was most unique about their study was that it gained access to previously unavailable Social Security earnings data, providing more precise
measures of actual earnings and lifetime income than previously available. They developed optimal decision rules for consumption for each
household in the sample, with rules that di¤ered depending on household characteristics, and then plotted the distribution of optimal net
worth across households in the HRS.
It should be noted here that the “optimality” of saving as examined by Scholz, Seshadri, and Khitatrakun is related to a speci…c theory
of household behavior. While this theory is the standard approach of
economists studying saving and consumption, it necessarily abstracts
from many forces that might a¤ect behavior. Still, this idea of optimality is a useful notion that builds on the idea of “adequacy” by taking
into account the most important economic factors a¤ecting household
choices. Their two most important …ndings:
More than 80 percent of households in the observed HRS sample
have accumulated wealth above the targets implied by the model,
while 15.6 percent of surveyed households with a member nearing
retirement age fell short of wealth targets. But the authors note
that most of the people who are undersaving aren’t undersaving
by much.
At the same time, they …nd that “undersavers are concentrated
in the bottom half of the lifetime earnings distributions.” In the
lowest earnings decile (basically, people whose incomes are at or
below the poverty level), 30.4 percent of households are below the
optimal target; in the highest decile, 5.4 percent are below. (The
authors caution, however, that this result may be more strongly
related to whether a person is in a single or married household.)
What’s important about the Scholz, Seshadri, and Khitatrakun
model is that it con…rms the theoretical notion that households tend to
save the amount necessary to provide the maximum level of smoothed
consumption over their expected lifetimes. The model takes into account that each household experiences di¤erent ‡uctuations in earnings
and life expectancy. Though it may sound odd, viewed through this
lens, seemingly paltry levels of wealth may actually be quite consistent
with reasonably e¤ective saving behavior, given a household’s income
experience. At the aggregate level, it is impossible to identify this
household-level activity.

108

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

Figure 3 Optimal Savings

Source: Scholz, Seshadri, and Khitatrakun.

According to these economists and their high-quality data, most
people are doing precisely what economic theory says they should be
doing. Most people are doing the best they can given their situations.
(In fact, one of the authors’ main …ndings is that many people seem
to be oversaving.) Most households save enough to generate the highest level of smoothed consumption over their expected lifetimes. As
with Love, Smith, and McNair, these authors …nd that undersavers are
also the poorest, suggesting once again that America faces less of a
retirement savings problem than a poverty problem.
A downside to the optimality approach, some economists counter,
is that what’s “optimal” may still make a household “wealth poor” at
retirement. It might be the case that for one household, whose wage
earners lose jobs or get sick, entering retirement with only Social Security as a backstop is “optimal,” as it provides the smoothest possible
consumption over their lifetime. But some may consider relying on Social Security alone— with average monthly payments around $1,000 a
month at present— as simply inadequate. Of course, optimality should
not be confused with desirability. Morally or ethically, we might be
predisposed to wanting people to have more resources at retirement.
Additionally, models that generate optimal consumption paths rely
on assumptions that may not be correct, including mortality and risk
preferences.

D. Campbell and J. A. Weinberg: Households and Retirement

109

Having acknowledged these challenges, we can still agree that lifecycle theory seems to be generally squaring with the facts. Given the
resources that people acquire throughout their lifetimes, most are arranging for their nonworking years in retirement as best as they can.
Addressing poverty— where evidence of undersaving is greatest— is in
many ways a di¤erent problem.

4.

DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGE

The judgment that most Americans are saving reasonably well does not
mean we should be sanguine about the future. As the disaggregated
data show, Social Security accounts for a signi…cant portion of expected
retirement income for many households. But the aging of the U.S.
population will put strains on the ability of the government to make
good on its promised Social Security payments. On top of that, the
demographic shift could mean lower economic output and consumption
than in the absence of population aging.
We now face choices about how to prepare for these changes and
to make good on our promises to workers. Will we have to raise taxes
on current or future workers? Many analysts have postulated that
higher household saving rates are desirable because they could help
ease the burden of higher taxes or lower spending that might otherwise
be passed to future generations. To properly evaluate the choices, let’s
…rst consider the size of the shift and what it might seem to imply
about future consumption possibilities.
When we talk about population aging, it is important to take into
account both the larger share of old people and the smaller share of
children, because they can have opposite e¤ects on overall consumption
levels (with old people consuming more because of their medical needs,
and children, less). The declining birth rate means a lowered dependency burden, which ordinarily would be a good thing with regards to
per capita consumption. But in this case, it is swamped by the growing
number of old people per worker.
At face value, what these trends mean is that younger generations
of workers will support larger numbers of old people. Equally, it means
there could be fewer goods and services to go around compared with a
world in which there is no demographic change. This result is because,
in general, consumption per person depends on output per person. So
while productivity growth raises output per person, a growing share of
retirees in the population holds down those gains on a per-person basis.
To get a clearer understanding of the implications of population
aging on consumption, consider the ratio of working-age people (ages
20 to 64) to elderly people (older than 65). Currently, there are …ve

110

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

working-age adults for every person aged 65 and above. By 2030, there
will be three working-age adults for every elderly person. Overall, annual growth in the size of the labor force is expected to slow from 1
percent at present to 0.2 percent after 2020. (Obviously, these …gures
could change if, for example, more people stay in the labor force past
the usual retirement age of 65. Immigration of young workers could
also pick up some of the slack.)
Louise Sheiner, Daniel Sichel, and Lawrence Slifman, economists
with the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, argue that the best gauge
of the macroeconomic e¤ects of population aging is what they call a
“weighted support ratio.”This takes into account both the heightened
consumption needs of the elderly (primarily because of their greater
demand for health care) and the lower needs of children. Their weighted
support ratio is peaking now at about 0.64 (workers to old people and
children, with these populations’consumption needs weighted) as most
baby boomers remain in the work force. But it is projected to drop
sharply over the next decade, to 0.60 in 2020, then to 0.56 in 2040. That
seemingly small decline actually represents major changes in growth of
the U.S. labor force; it means the number of workers to dependent
population will be much lower than we’ve recently experienced, as well
as lower than the previous low point in the early 1960s. The weighted
support ratio falls farther than the simple support ratio, implying a
larger impact on the economy.
Now, it is a bit more complicated than that. A society’s potential level of consumption depends, among other things, on capital per
worker, technical advancement, and the return to capital. Given current trends, Sheiner, Sichel, and Slifman conclude that we will experience a signi…cant reduction in per capita consumption relative to a
baseline in which there is no demographic change. (These trends include assumptions about labor force participation among the elderly
and levels of immigration.) This is because the population bulge has
made our production bulge as well. We have, in short, experienced a
period of low dependency during which per capita output was high.
With fertility low relative to that of the baby boom generation, we received a temporary bene…t in the form of greater consumption available
per person.

5.

WHAT NOW?

The data presented earlier on household-level wealth holdings suggest
that older baby boomers are reasonably well-prepared for retirement.
On the other hand, dependency ratio calculations like those presented
in the previous section imply a real economic cost of the demographic

D. Campbell and J. A. Weinberg: Households and Retirement

111

bulge that will weigh on the consumption opportunities of future retirees, future workers, or both. How do we square these two facts? A
key assumption in the calculations of household wealth is that future
Social Security payments will be made according to current policy. This
assumption is important, since for many low- and moderate-income
households, expected Social Security payments represent a large fraction of retirement wealth. But as we discuss elsewhere, current Social
Security payment policy, together with current taxation policy, creates
large …scal de…cits. These will ultimately require changes either in
payments or in taxes (or both) and will ultimately a¤ect some people’s
consumption patterns.
People’s responses to the aggregate economic changes brought on
by the demographic trends will depend on the prices households face in
making consumption decisions and the returns households receive on
their labor time and savings. By prices, we mostly refer to wages and
interest rates. Does population aging somehow a¤ect prices in such a
way that individual households are hindered in their ability to prepare
for retirement? We now explain both how population aging could a¤ect
prices and then how it doesn’t have to.
Intuitively, the most obvious and simple plan might seem to be to
save our way out of demographic change— to put more money aside
now while we’ve got more people working. This would require people
to consume less, of course, but it would also help lower the burden on
future generations. With extra savings, we could add to the capital
stock and thus make future workers more productive.
If only it were as simple as that. The e¤ect of increasing the capital
stock may actually discourage saving. Federal Reserve Board economists Douglas W. Elmendorf (now with the Brookings Institution) and
Sheiner assume that current consumption and saving rates are close
to optimal (an assumption supported by other research cited in this
essay) to isolate the impact of population aging. They point out that
forcing greater saving on current workers is not an obviously bene…cial
approach to the looming demographic trends.
Here is why: Recall that the U.S. workforce is growing more slowly
now with the aging of the baby boomers. With fewer workers, we require less in the way of investment to provide new workers with capital.
So if we are trying to save our way out of uneven consumption, we increase the future capital-to-labor ratio (because we have less labor and
more capital than before). This means returns on capital are smaller
than before, and investment payo¤s are lower.
This is not to argue that we should simply kick the burden of
demographic change and supporting entitlement programs to future

112

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

generations. Rather, it is to explain the possible complications of that
approach. In fact, it’s fair to say that all approaches are imperfect.
A study by economists Laurence Kotliko¤, Kent Smetters, and Jan
Walliser considered how the combination of demographic change and
the burden of Social Security might play out. They conclude that
payroll taxes would have to jump by 77 percent, and that this increased
tax burden would swamp the extra capital to workers that ordinarily
would accompany an aging society. Alternatively, there is the research
of Nobel Prize-winning economist Edward C. Prescott and Arizona
State University’s Kathryn Birkeland: They argue that addressing the
solvency of entitlement programs while maintaining the overall welfare
of the U.S. population is as simple as having the government issue more
debt. Prescott and Birkeland’s point is that in the existing tax-andtransfer system, households may pare back their labor in the face of
high taxes. Despite the risks, issuing more government debt along with
a mandatory worker “saving-for-retirement system” would mean that
workers’ productive time is rewarded with a larger savings nest egg.
This results in a larger capital stock awaiting future generations.
By no means is this an endorsement of any of these approaches.
Our aim is to brie‡y point out what sort of consequences we can expect with each one. You can ask households to save more, but doing so
would tend to lower everybody’s rates of return. While there are many
other ways that economists approach the retirement/entitlement problem amid demographic change, the most useful are those that model
households as rational, forward-looking units that respond to incentives. If households face a pricing environment where saving makes
sense, they will do so.
While understanding the tradeo¤s involved with preparing for demographic change is important, it is also important to take action as
soon as possible. In their study, Sheiner, Sichel, and Slifman conclude
that if we made no changes to our saving habits, future generations
would see their per capita consumption fall 14 percent compared with
what it would have been without demographic change. By contrast,
if we alter saving rates now as a means to spread the burden equally
across generations, the relative decline in per capita consumption is
reduced to just 4 percent. While there is always uncertainty around
such projections, the desirability of a timely response to demographic
change is clear enough.

6.

CHANGES AHEAD

As the …rst retiring baby boomer, Kathleen Casey-Kirschling became
a symbol for America’s demographic transition. Her arrival on Social

D. Campbell and J. A. Weinberg: Households and Retirement

113

Security’s doorstep made long lingering questions more urgent: Do retirees have enough savings? Will her cohorts bankrupt our entitlement
programs? Will the sheer size of her generation cause living standards
to decline in the future?
We have shown that, contrary to popular opinion, most Americans
near retirement are saving largely as economic theory predicts they
should. Most of the nation’s undersavers are also the poorest. While
lack of savings isn’t exclusively a problem of the poor, that’s where the
problem is largest. Our chief concern should be for those who are poor
even before retirement.
The aging of the U.S. population is not a surprise. It is a predictable event that we can plan for. Research on household saving
behavior shows that most households plan reasonably well. But the
important caveat in this conclusion is that household planning appears
to be predicated on the assumption that Social Security and other retirement bene…ts will be paid according to current policy. The …scal
stresses that these policies face imply di¢ cult choices. Increasing taxes
to prop up entitlement programs would create additional problems.
Should the government take on more debt? Some economists believe
that approach is not as unwise as it …rst sounds— it could ease the
burden on current workers while allowing interest rates to remain high
enough to encourage household saving.
As we have described, an older society portends a time when the
growth of consumption per person might be held down, and saving
might become harder. The somewhat natural lengthening of time that
older workers stay in the labor force may cushion the demographic blow,
as might increased immigration. But in general, whichever approach
we take, our focus should be on making sure that households both
today and tomorrow are not impaired in their ability to save. If there
is no consensus about what to do next, there is agreement that to delay
action will exacerbate the problem for future generations. The earlier
we embark on this e¤ort, the more likely we are to achieve a desirable
outcome.

APPENDIX
The following sections appeared as sidebars in the original text.

114
1.

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

WHY AREN'T (SOME) PEOPLE SAVING MORE?

Though careful studies show that many people are saving enough, it’s
also clear that some people aren’t. Why not?
The …rst possible explanation is that …guring out how much to save
is complicated. Economic theory holds that people seek to smooth consumption over their lifetimes. But in the 21st century, this is not such
an easy calculation. Annamaria Lusardi and Olivia Mitchell explain
the di¢ culty this way: “The consumer must understand present discounted values, the di¤erence between nominal and real amounts, and
be able to project expected future labor income, pensions and Social
Security bene…ts, retirement ages, and survival probabilities, among
many other factors. These requirements are inherently complex and
demanding.”
Within the “it’s complicated”explanation fall several subcategories.
Some people, for example, may use simple rules of thumb in planning
for retirement. These rules might include aiming for certain replacement rates of income upon reaching retirement. But because of the
complex nature of investment decisions, this sort of planning may still
fall short, and retirees may have to shift down their consumption to adjust. (Some economists dispute the notion that consumers have to understand every detail to properly save for retirement. These economists
argue that most people make estimates that turn out to be accurate.)
A related explanation is that people may believe themselves to be
…nancially sophisticated when they really aren’t. However, some recent
research by Lusardi and Mitchell discounts this notion, …nding that
most people who classify themselves as …nancially literate indeed score
well on related testing.
A branch of economics is interested in the idea that undersaving
re‡ects a lack of self-control. Some surveys have shown that households
themselves cite “lack of willpower” for their low savings, while others
admit to procrastination. Behavioral economists use these examples in
support of their theories of why people deviate from standard economic
rules.
Though much of this kind of work is open to question, recent behavioral research on participation in 401(k) plans is striking. The research
has shown that if employers make “opt in” the default choice for such
plans, more people automatically end up saving than if “opt out” is
the default. This evidence runs contrary to traditional theory, which
holds that people ought to be making the same decision whether it is
the default or not.
Many studies point to a graver problem than the misperception
that most people aren’t saving enough— it’s that undersaving is most
widespread among the poor. A possible explanation is that because

D. Campbell and J. A. Weinberg: Households and Retirement

115

they have less to gain, poor people invest less in …nancial planning that
would help them save more. They may also face disincentives to saving
because of …nancial backstops like Social Security and welfare transfers.
Like a lot of research on savings, this …nding points to the need for
raising wealth for those with low incomes as much as for increasing
their savings.

2.

THE EFFECTIVENESS OF FINANCIAL
EDUCATION PROGRAMS

Of all the ways to encourage higher saving rates, perhaps none is more
popular than …nancial education. If only Americans were made aware
of the importance of retirement planning— and given some pointers
on how to get started— then changes in savings behavior would surely
follow.
That’s the conventional wisdom, at least. But despite the seemingly obvious link between knowledge and behavior, economists have
struggled to measure the degree to which …nancial literacy e¤orts actually work. It is well documented that some people have a poor grasp of
basic economic concepts, and that shortfalls of knowledge are particularly evident about Social Security and pensions. But the connection
between the e¤ect of being exposed to …nancial education and subsequent improvements in saving habits is tenuous.
The trick is distinguishing between causation and correlation. There
are de…nite correlations between wealth and retirement planning. Among
baby boomers who reported that they undertook even “a little”retirement planning, wealth holdings were twice as large as non-planners, according to economists Annamaria Lusardi and Olivia Mitchell. Meanwhile, many studies have documented that households that do little
…nancial planning tend to be the less educated and minorities. But
does that mean that planning can lift these households into more secure retirements?
Lusardi and Mitchell, who are two of the world’s leading researchers
on the topic, created a “…nancial literacy index” based on a survey of
Americans in their prime working years, with most respondents between 40 and 60, as well as the Health and Retirement Study. With
the index, the economists identify which traits and concepts are predictive of retirement planning. In general, they conclude that “…nancial
literacy is a key determinant of retirement planning”and that literacy
is highest among those exposed to economics in school and to those
who attended company-sponsored programs.
This supports some of their earlier research, which considered the
possibility that wealthier households planned more because they had

116

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

more to gain. They couldn’t …nd any e¤ect of wealth on planning,
however, and concluded that planning is more likely to cause wealth,
rather than vice-versa.
“Saving for retirement is becoming a more and more challenging
and a more important objective requiring ever-greater levels of …nancial
sophistication,” Lusardi and Mitchell wrote. “Clearly it is urgent to
target e¤ective programs to those who can put this necessary …nancial
knowledge to work.”
As it happens, the most e¤ective programs do not come cheap.
In a survey of the literature on …nancial education, Richmond Fed
economist Matthew Martin concludes that there are returns from such
programs, especially to low-income and lesser-educated households.
However, Martin …nds that one-size-…ts-all e¤orts may not succeed:
“Financial education programs are most e¤ective when they are tailored to the needs of the recipient and include face-to-face time, either
with a counselor or in a classroom setting.” As a result, the most effective programs also tend to be the most costly.

3.

DOES THE DECLINE OF DEFINED-BENEFIT
PENSIONS SIGNAL TROUBLE FOR
AMERICANS' RETIREMENT YEARS?

Retirement, as we know it today, is a relatively new concept. Back in
1880, eight in 10 men aged 65 and up still worked. When they stopped,
it usually was because they were physically unable to carry on. They
relied on family for …nancial support until their deaths. Self-…nanced
retirement was a luxury a¤ordable mainly to the rich.
Over time, workers came to rely on employer-sponsored pensions
(plus payments from Social Security, which launched in 1937). The
Pennsylvania Railroad Pension is touted as having kicked o¤ the private
pension era with its creation in 1900. Its “de…ned-bene…t” formula
generally has been followed ever since.
De…ned-bene…t pensions provide an annuity at retirement that workers can’t outlive. Bene…ts are a function of years of service and highest
salary. The assets of de…ned-bene…t pensions are professionally managed and the employer bears most of the investment risk. Employers
…rst started o¤ering de…ned-bene…t pensions in part to help with worker
loyalty and to ward o¤ strikes.
Today, de…ned-contribution plans, predominantly 401(k)s, have replaced de…ned-bene…t plans as the leading form of employer-provided
pension. This transition has raised concerns among some observers, in
part because de…ned-contribution pensions place more of the burden of
saving, not to mention the portfolio risk, on individuals. Participation

D. Campbell and J. A. Weinberg: Households and Retirement

117

in such plans is voluntary, meaning some will opt out of them, even if
it would not seem to be in their best interest to do so. And smaller
…rms don’t yet en masse o¤er 401(k) plans, whose big appeal is the
matching contributions that employers make.
Given current trends, what will household portfolios look like as
they reach retirement? In one study, economists with Williams College
and the Federal Reserve Board of Governors point out that though
personal retirement accounts (with de…ned-contribution plans being
the leading contributors) are small in size among people nearing retirement, this doesn’t necessarily suggest that Americans have inadequate
savings. Instead, it is mostly evidence that they are relatively new
vehicles for savings.
In the 2004 Health and Retirement Study, less than a third of households aged 75 and older had personal retirement accounts, compared
with about half of households aged 62 to 75 and 61 per cent of those
between 51 and 61. Despite this transition to de…ned-contribution coverage, “we do not …nd evidence of a steep deterioration in retirement
adequacy among the younger households in our sample.”
Growth in de…ned-contribution plans is widely evident. In 1985, assets in private de…ned-bene…t pensions almost doubled those in de…nedcontribution plans— $814 billion to $417 billion. In 2005, assets in
de…ned-contribution plans were on top, $3 trillion versus $2.2 trillion.
By 2040, 401(k) assets are projected to grow eightfold from their 2000
level.
By one study, the number of people covered by de…ned-bene…t pensions over the past 20 years fell by about 30 percent, while the number
covered only by a 401(k) plan grew 300 percent. The number of participants in de…ned-contribution plans grew from about 19 million in
1980 to more than 52 million in 2004.
Meanwhile, even though growth in 401(k) coverage has slowed in
recent years, participation rates are expected to climb well into the
future. Among those 60-year-olds in the 2nd earnings decile (i.e., people
whose earnings put them between the lowest 10th percentile and 20th
percentile of the total population), 401(k) participation in 2000 was 23
percent. By 2040, it’s expected to increase to 53 percent. It would
seem that even for the relatively poor, pension participation will rise.
Overall, participation rates at age 60 are expected to be much higher,
topping 80 percent, from the 70th earnings percentile on up.
Economists James Poterba, Steven Venti, and David Wise …nd
that the average 65-year-old in 2040 will have more than $450,000 in
personal retirement accounts (in 2000 dollars). Of course, there is
wide variance in accumulations. Those in the 2nd earnings decile are

118

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

Figure 4 Mean Projected 401(k) Assets for Cohorts Retiring
in 2000, 2020, and 2040

Source: Poterba, Venti, and Wise.

expected to have about $51,000 in mean projected 401(k) assets; those
in the 9th decile (90th percentile and up) about $1.1 million.
A lingering concern about 401(k) pensions is that so much of their
assets are in equities, which tend to be volatile. According to one
study, 61 percent of 401(k) assets in 2001 were in stocks. But this
extra risk has been shown to be o¤set by the portability of such plans.
Employees who take new jobs can take their 401(k) assets with them,
but de…ned-bene…t plans e¤ectively penalize workers who leave.
In general, these projections point to future retirement security for
most Americans, not the opposite. While the assets of low-income
households remain low in retirement, many economists are optimistic
that the transition away from de…ned-bene…t pensions is one that ultimately will lead to more wealth for U.S. households: “The advent of
personal account saving is projected to yield very large increases in the
…nancial assets of future retirees across the lifetime earnings spectrum,”
wrote Poterba, Venti, and Wise.

4.

THE FED'S ROLE

The Federal Reserve’s role in the coming demographic transition is
several-fold. First, the Fed can encourage households to make sound
…nancial decisions, supporting …nancial education e¤orts that inform
people about their choices and the importance of saving. In its

D. Campbell and J. A. Weinberg: Households and Retirement

119

regulation of …nancial institutions, the Fed ensures that consumers receive adequate disclosures. These roles will be increasingly important
as the United States begins its demographic shift.
Most importantly, the Fed abides by its two-part mission— to keep
prices stable and promote maximum sustainable economic growth. People decide whether and how much to save based principally on their
current and expected lifetime income and interest rates. By keeping
in‡ation low, the Federal Reserve helps keep a stable economic environment. In …ghting in‡ation, the Fed makes it easier for people to
save.

5.

NO EASY FIX FOR ENTITLEMENT PROGRAMS

The …nancial burden of paying for Social Security and Medicare is growing as the U.S. population ages. That’s hardly a revelatory statement,
but it bears repeating as the …rst baby boomers enter retirement and
begin to draw bene…ts from entitlement programs.
Both Social Security and Medicare are essentially “pay-as-you-go”
programs, with retiree bene…ts funded by current payroll taxes levied
on employers and employees. The 2007 Treasury Department report
calculates that, thanks to population aging, the present value of Social
Security’s scheduled bene…ts surpasses the present value of scheduled
tax receipts by $13.6 trillion— that’s the di¤erence between the amount
older cohorts put in to the program and the amount they plan to withdraw from it.
Meanwhile, Medicare expenses are expected to overtake income as
soon as 2010, with trust fund reserves depleted by 2019. The present
value of the unfunded liability for Medicare is close to $70 trillion over
an in…nite horizon. Federal spending to support the two programs is
expected to rise from 6 percent of GDP in 2005 to 20 percent in 2080.
Another way to look at it is to focus on the program revenues and
outlays as percentages of taxable payroll— income stays relatively ‡at
into the future while expenditures continue to climb.
How do we close these unsustainable …nancing gaps facing Social
Security and Medicare? There is no shortage of proposed reforms.
Broadly, they fall into four categories:
Keep more workers in the labor force, thereby reducing the growth
in the number of retired Americans receiving bene…ts to workers
paying taxes that fund those bene…ts.
Raise taxes on workers.
Reduce bene…ts.

120

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly
Allow greater numbers of young immigrants into the U.S. workforce.

Additionally, there are proposals to phase out the system in favor
of private accounts, such as the program that President Bush promoted unsuccessfully in 2005. And there is a school of thought that
argues that Social Security should be abolished because its existence
has a number of undesirable e¤ects, including that it discourages private savings that might otherwise supplement the program, and that
it encourages early exits from the labor force.
So what should be done? One thing that most economists agree
upon is that whatever reform is adopted, it will be easier to swallow—
as well as more evenly spread across generations — if it is taken sooner
rather than later. By government estimates, closing the 75-year unfunded liability of Social Security would require an immediate increase
in the payroll tax of about 2 percentage points; waiting until 2041
would require approximately a 4-percentage-point boost. Medicare
faces a similar scenario— it needs an immediate 3-percentage-point hike
to …x the liability, or waiting until 2020 would require a gradual 10percentage-point increase over the following 55 years. But this would
still not make the systems permanently solvent; it would merely put
them into balance for 75 years.
From a fairness perspective, this observation from the Treasury Department is worth considering: “Each time new legislation has ratcheted up taxes and real bene…ts, substantial windfalls have been conveyed to individuals in mid-to-late working life at the time of the
change, as these individuals face increased taxes for only a relatively
few years but are entitled to receive the full advantage of the bene…t
increases.”
The late Edward Gramlich, a former Federal Reserve Board governor, was one of the nation’s leading thinkers on the topic of reforming
Social Security and Medicare. His proposal consisted of two main parts:
First, he would eliminate the now $102,000 (but rising slowly each year)
cap on wages that are taxable for Social Security, thus bringing in more
revenue.
On the bene…t side, Gramlich wanted to raise both the early eligibility age and the normal retirement age for Social
Security, and then keep qualifying ages common across both Social
Security and Medicare. On balance, the changes would be su¢ cient to
permanently fund Social Security, but would still leave large holes in
parts of the Medicare system. And politically, Gramlich conceded, it
might be a tough sell. “The package of taxing all payrolls for Social
Security and advancing the normal retirement age is indeed strong
medicine,” he said in a 2005 speech.

D. Campbell and J. A. Weinberg: Households and Retirement

121

Figure 5 Social Security and Medicare Income and Cost
Rates

Source: Annual Report of the Social Security and Medicare Boards of Trustees for
2007.

REFERENCES
Aguiar, Mark, and Erik Hurst. 2005. “Consumption vs. Expenditure.”
Journal of Political Economy 113 (5): 919–48.
Bernheim, Douglas, Jonathan Skinner, and Steven Weinberg. 2001.
“What Accounts for the Variation in Retirement Wealth Among
U.S. Households?” American Economic Review 91 (4): 832–57.
Birkeland, Kathryn, and Edward C. Prescott. 2007. “On the Needed
Quantity of Government Debt.” Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis Quarterly Review 31 (1): 2–15.
Campbell, John. 2006. “Household Finance.” Journal of Finance 61
(4): 1,553–604.
Elmendorf, Douglas W., and Louise M. Sheiner. 2000. “Should
America Save for its Old Age? Fiscal Policy, Population Aging,
and National Saving.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 14 (3):
57–74.

122

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

Friedman, Milton. 1957. A Theory of the Consumption Function. (1st
ed.) Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Garner, C. Alan. 2006. “Should the Decline in the Personal Saving
Rate Be a Cause for Concern?” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City Economic Review, Second Quarter: 5–27.
Gramlich, Edward. 2005. “A First Step in Dealing with Growing
Retirement Costs.” Remarks at the Spring 2005 Banking and
Finance Lecture, Widener University, Chester, Penn., April 21,
2005.
Gramlich, Edward. 2006. “Another Attempt at Social Security
Reform.” University of Michigan Retirement Research Center
Policy Brief (February).
Kotliko¤, Laurence, Kent Smetters, and Jan Walliser. 2002. “Finding
a Way Out of America’s Demographic Dilemma.” National
Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 8258.
Lettau, Martin, and Sydney Ludvigson. 2004. “Understanding Trend
and Cycle in Asset Values: Reevaluating the Wealth E¤ect on
Consumption.” American Economic Review 94 (1): 276–300.
Love, David, Paul Smith, and Lucy McNair. 2007. “Do Households
Have Enough Wealth for Retirement?” Federal Reserve Board of
Governors Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2007-17.
Lusardi, Annamaria, and Olivia S. Mitchell. 2007. “Baby Boomers
Retirement Security: The Role of Planning, Financial Literacy,
and Housing Wealth.” Journal of Monetary Economics 54 (1):
205–24.
Lusardi, Annamaria, and Olivia S. Mitchell. 2007. “Financial Literacy
and Retirement Planning: New Evidence from the Rand American
Life Panel.” University of Michigan Retirement Research Center
Working Paper 2007-157.
Martin, Matthew. 2007. “A Literature Review on the E¤ectiveness of
Financial Education.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Working Paper 07-03.
Munnell, Alicia H., and Mauricio Soto. 2005. “What Replacement
Rates Do Households Actually Experience in Retirement?” Center
for Retirement Research at Boston College Working Paper
2005-10.
Nakamura, Leonard, and Tom Stark. 2005. “Benchmark Revisions
and the U.S. Personal Saving Rate.” Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia Working Paper 05-6.

D. Campbell and J. A. Weinberg: Households and Retirement

123

Poterba, James, Steven Venti, and David A. Wise. 2007. “Rise of
401(k) Plans, Lifetime Earnings, and Wealth Retirement.”
National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 13091.
Poterba, James, Steven Venti, and David A. Wise. 2007. “The
Changing Landscape of Pensions in the U.S.” National Bureau of
Economic Research Working Paper 13381.
Samwick, Andrew, and Jonathan Skinner. 2004. “How Will 401(k)
Plans A¤ect Retirement Income?” American Economic Review 94
(1): 329–43.
Scholz, John Karl, Ananth Seshadri, and Surachai Khitatrakun. 2006.
“Are Americans Saving ‘Optimally’for Retirement?” Journal of
Political Economy 114 (41): 607–43.
Sheiner, Louise, Daniel Sichel, and Lawrence Slifman. 2007. “A
Primer on the Macroeconomic Implications of Population Aging.”
Federal Reserve Board of Governors Finance and Economics
Discussion Series 2007-01.
“Social Security Reform: The Nature of the Problem.” U.S.
Department of the Treasury, Issue Brief No. 1 (undated).
Thaler, Richard H., and Shlomo Benartzi. 2004. “Save More
Tomorrow: Using Behavioral Economics to Increase Employee
Saving.” Journal of Political Economy 112 (1): S164–87.
“The 2007 Annual Report of the Board of Trustees of the Federal
Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Federal Disability Trust
Funds.” 2007. Social Security Administration, Washington, D.C.

Economic Quarterly— Volume 101, Number 2— Second Quarter 2015— Pages 125–149

The Rise in Long-Term
Unemployment: Potential
Causes and Implications
Andreas Hornstein and Thomas A. Lubik

T

he dramatic rise in long-term unemployment has been one of
the most striking features of the Great Recession of 2007–09.
The number of unemployed workers who have been out of a job
for more than half a year has reached heights that the U.S. economy
has not witnessed since the Great Depression.
The overall unemployment rate has been elevated for a substantial
period of time, although it has not reached its post–World War II peak
of 10.8 percent. Underlying this dire unemployment picture is the rise
in long-term unemployment and an overall lengthening of the duration
of unemployment spells, which are now far above their levels in previous
recessions.
The U.S. labor market historically has been characterized by relatively short unemployment durations for an average worker. The high
level of long-term unemployment we are currently seeing represents a
sharp break with previous experiences. In the past, most job losses led
to only short unemployment spells, as the labor market was able to
quickly absorb newly unemployed workers into employment relationships. Although some workers, in particular older ones, experienced
long periods of unemployment, the incidence of long-term unemployment in the United States was far less than in other OECD countries. Moreover, although recessions have always been characterized
by lengthening unemployment spells, a quick increase in hiring when
The authors would like to thank Marianna Kudlyak, Jessica Romero, Aaron
Steelman, John Weinberg, and Alexander Wolman for discussions and detailed comments and Nika Lazaryan for excellent research assistance. The views expressed are
those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.

126

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

coming out of a recession kept the incidence of long-term unemployment low. The Great Recession seems to be di¤erent in that respect.
The high level of unemployment, in combination with a high fraction of long-term unemployment, presents challenges for both monetary
and …scal policymakers. Many of the e¤orts of the Federal Reserve were
aimed at halting the decline in output and employment in the wake of
waves of adverse shocks. Arguably, the Fed’s policies were successful
in that respect. However, the U.S. economy has been operating under
extremely low nominal interest rates for such an extended period that
additional expansionary monetary actions, such as quantitative easing,
are possibly only marginally e¤ective.
In this article we discuss how long-term unemployment has become
such a dominant feature of the labor market during the Great Recession. We …rst summarize the data on aggregate unemployment and
the duration distribution of unemployment for the United States since
1960. We then show that, in terms of pure accounting, the composition of the unemployment pool is determined by the in‡ow and out‡ow
of workers, that is, by the rates at which workers lose and …nd jobs.
We begin from an aggregate perspective and argue that the increase in
long-term unemployment can largely be explained by a decline in the
exit rate from unemployment. The severity of the recession led to high
initial job losses, but the persistent and substantial increase in unemployment and unemployment duration is mainly due to a decline in job
…nding rates. In response to the increase in long-term unemployment,
Congress extended the maximum duration of unemployment bene…ts
from six months to close to two years. We discuss the e¤ects of this
extension on unemployment duration and argue that the e¤ects have
been limited.
We then proceed to a more disaggregate analysis and study how unemployment of di¤erent demographic groups was a¤ected by the Great
Recession. We show that unemployment rates and duration di¤er substantially across demographic groups, but that almost all groups were
equally a¤ected by the increase in unemployment rates and duration.
We then discuss how negative duration dependence, that is, the apparent decline in job …nding rates with the length of time unemployed,
a¤ects long-term unemployment. We …nd that accounting for duration
dependence allows us to better model long-term unemployment in the
U.S. labor market. This accounting framework also suggests that a signi…cant part of the increase in long-term unemployment is indeed due to
the in‡ow into unemployment of workers with relatively low job …nding
rates. We conclude by arguing that given the increased contribution to
overall unemployment of unemployed workers with inherently low job

A. Hornstein and T. A. Lubik: Long-Term Unemployment

127

…nding rates, monetary policymakers may want to exercise caution in
the use of policy to respond to the level of unemployment.

1.

A LOOK AT THE DATA

The standard measure of unemployment comes from the monthly Current Population Survey (CPS) conducted by the Census Bureau for the
Bureau of Labor Statistics. This survey, commonly known as the household survey, is a randomly selected sample of about 60,000 households
that report on their employment status and other characteristics.1
A respondent is classi…ed as employed, unemployed, or out of the
labor force. A respondent is classi…ed as unemployed if he or she reports not being employed but is actively searching for a job. The
labor force is de…ned as those respondents who are either employed or
unemployed, and respondents who are neither employed nor actively
searching for a job are classi…ed as being out of the labor force. The
unemployment rate is the ratio of the number of unemployed respondents to the number of workers in the labor force. Conditional on the
employment state, there are follow-up questions that further characterize the employment state. Employed respondents are asked about
the type of employment (part-time or full-time), their occupation, and
the industry of employment, among other questions. Unemployed respondents are asked about the length of the ongoing unemployment
spell and their previous occupation and industry. Basic demographic
information is also collected, such as the sex, age, race, and education
level of the respondent.2
There are two notable features to the pattern of the rise and fall
of unemployment over the business cycle. First, unemployment rises
1
The Bureau of Labor Statistics provides a detailed description of the CPS at
http://www.bls.gov/cps/.
2
We can look at the household survey as providing information on the supply of
labor. There are two other surveys that report on the state of the U.S. labor market
from the demand side for labor.
The Current Employment Statistics (CES) program, commonly known as the establishment survey, reports on the number of jobs from a sample of about 440,000 establishments in the U.S. nonfarm sector. By construction, the establishment survey provides
information on employment only, not unemployment. Furthermore, the establishment
survey provides information on jobs and not on household employment. For example, a
household survey respondent who works two jobs is counted as employed once, but the
establishment survey would count two jobs. Finally, the establishment survey does not
cover unincorporated self-employment.
Another recently introduced survey, the Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey
(JOLTS), tries to capture how establishments change their employment. JOLTS provides
monthly data on job openings, hires, quits, layo¤s, etc., for a sample of about 16,000
establishments.
More detailed descriptions of the CES and JOLTS are provided at
http://www.bls.gov/ces/home.htm and http://www.bls.gov/jlt/home.htm, respectively.

128

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

Figure 1 Long-Term Unemployment

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Haver Analytics, authors’ calculations.
Notes: The share of long-term unemployment (more than 26 weeks) as a percent
of total unemployment typically increases during recessions (the shaded areas).
But following the most recent recession, the share is nearly double the previous
peak after the 1981–82 recession.

rapidly at the onset of a recession, but it comes down only slowly over
the course of the recovery. Second, long-term unemployment increases
sharply with overall unemployment.
Figure 1 depicts the unemployment rate (dark orange line, left axis)
and the share of total unemployment that is long-term unemployment
(green line, right axis) for the U.S. economy from 1960 through 2010,
with recessions highlighted in grey.3 The average unemployment rate
for this period is about 6 percent, but unemployment increases substantially in recessions. For example, in the 1981–82 recession the unemployment rate increased by about three percentage points within
3
The recessions are dated using the business cycle peaks and troughs as announced
by the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). NBER business cycle dates are
a widely accepted de…nition of recessions in the United States. The NBER procedure to
date the beginning and end of a recession is supposed to re‡ect a widespread and signi…cant decline in economic activity. As such, the NBER procedure incorporates a large
number of measures of economic activity, including production, sales, income, and employment. Unemployment tends to lag the NBER recession dates, in the sense that the
unemployment rate peaks after the end of the recession. For more detailed information
on the NBER business cycle program, see http://www.nber.org/cycles/main.html.

A. Hornstein and T. A. Lubik: Long-Term Unemployment

129

one and a half years to reach a peak of 10.8 percent in October 1982.
In the expansion phase, the unemployment rate then usually declines
slowly from its peak. This pattern is especially noticeable for the 1990–
91 recession and the 2001 recession, and has given rise to the idea of a
“jobless recovery,”in which economic growth picks up, but employment
gains are small and unemployment declines only slowly. This pattern
seems to be repeating itself in the current recovery.
Long-term unemployment is de…ned as being unemployed for more
than 26 weeks. This is the conventional measure of long-term unemployment since unemployment bene…ts typically last for about half a
year. In Figure 1 we see that the average share of long-term unemployment is quite low, about 15 percent from 1960 to 2010, but in every
recession the share of long-term unemployment increases sharply with
the unemployment rate. A similar observation applies to the mean duration of unemployment for all those who report job search durations
in any month. From 1960 to 2010 the average mean duration of unemployment is about 14 weeks, but mean duration increases signi…cantly
in recessions.
The increase in unemployment during the Great Recession stands
out for its severity, especially the substantial increase in long-term unemployment. Unemployment peaked at 10.1 percent in October 2009,
about one quarter after the o¢ cial end of the recession according to
the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) dating scheme,
and stayed close to this level for almost one year. For the postwar period, this peak unemployment rate is second only to the 10.8 percent
unemployment rate after the 1981–82 recession. The share of long-term
unemployment peaked at 46 percent in the second quarter of 2010, and
averaged a bit more than 43 percent for all of 2010. This peak value
for the share of long-term unemployment is signi…cantly higher than
the previous peak of 26 percent that was attained following the 1981–
82 recession. Finally, mean duration of unemployment had increased
to about 35 weeks by the middle of 2010, again a substantial increase
over the previous peak for mean unemployment duration of 21 weeks
after the 1981–82 recession. Never before in the postwar period have
unemployed workers been unemployed for such a long time.

2.

ACCOUNTING FOR UNEMPLOYMENT

We now take a more systematic look at how total unemployment is
related to unemployment duration. For this purpose we study how
the in‡ows into unemployment and the out‡ows from unemployment
determine total unemployment. One can think of total unemployment
as the water level in a bathtub, which is determined by the in‡ow of

130

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

new water and the rate at which the water drains. The total number
of unemployed workers is determined by the rate at which workers
become newly unemployed and start looking for work (the entry rate)
and the rate at which current unemployed workers …nd work (the exit
rate).4 Other things being equal, the more workers who become newly
unemployed, that is, the higher the entry rate, then the higher the
total number of unemployed workers. Similarly, at a given in‡ow rate
of newly unemployed workers, the less likely it is that an unemployed
worker …nds a new job, then the higher the total number of unemployed
workers will be eventually. For a slightly more formal representation of
this model see Box 1.
While total unemployment depends on both the entry and exit
rates, the average duration of unemployment depends mainly on the
behavior of the exit rate. The lower the exit rate, that is, the lower the
chance that an unemployed worker becomes employed, then the longer
the average unemployment duration and the larger the share of workers
who have been unemployed for a long time.
Robert Shimer (2007) shows how one can recover measures of the
entry and exit rate from data on total unemployment and data on shortterm unemployment, that is, workers who have been unemployed for
fewer than …ve weeks.5 The maintained assumption of his accounting
exercise is that all unemployed workers are homogeneous in the sense
that they all have the same exit rate. This is a simplifying assumption
that provides some valuable …rst insight into the dynamics of unemployment and the interpretation of long-term unemployment. We will
relax that assumption below.
Since the increase in the unemployment rates during recessions is
usually accompanied by a substantial lengthening of unemployment
duration, a declining exit rate must be an important source of high
unemployment. In other words, it is hard to …nd a job during recessions. This observation also suggests that more long-term unemployment does not necessarily mean that the long-term unemployed are in
any way di¤erent from the short-term unemployed. Even if all unemployed workers face the same exit rate, a decline in the exit rate will
4
Given the de…nition of unemployment, workers may exit unemployment not only
because they …nd work, but also because they stop searching, that is, the workers drop
out of the labor force. Alternatively, they may enter unemployment not only because
they lose a job, but also because they decide to (re)enter the labor force and search for
a job. In the analysis we disregard the ‡ows in and out of the labor force. For most
purposes this is not a restrictive assumption (Shimer 2007).
5
Similar exercises have been performed by Elsby, Michaels, and Solon (2009) and
Fujita and Ramey (2009). An important debate in this literature concerns the relative importance of variations in the job …nding rates and the job separation rates in
accounting for variations of the unemployment rate.

A. Hornstein and T. A. Lubik: Long-Term Unemployment

131

Figure 2 Duration Dependence in Exit Rates

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Haver Analytics, authors’ calculations.
Notes: Workers who have been unemployed for fewer than …ve weeks have the
highest probability of exiting unemployment within the next month. The likelihood of exit typically declines for all workers during recessions (the shaded areas),
but it continued to decline well after the troughs of the last three recessions.

yield higher average unemployment duration and an increased share of
long-term unemployment.
We follow Shimer’s (2007) simple accounting framework and recover
entry and exit rates of homogeneous unemployed workers. In Figure
2 we display the implied exit rates of workers who have been unemployed for fewer than 5 weeks, fewer than 15 weeks, and fewer than
27 weeks. The green line displays the exit rate from unemployment
implied by data on short-term unemployment, that is, those workers
who have been unemployed for fewer than 5 weeks.6 Most of the time
unemployed workers …nd a job quite quickly: the average probability
that an unemployed worker …nds work within a month is about 40
percent, and at the peak of an expansion this job …nding probability
can be as high as 60 percent. As we also can see, the exit rate from
6
The exit rates displayed in Figure 2 are actually derived from the steady state relationship between unemployment duration shares and the exit rate as described in Box
1. We also calculate exit and entry rates using data on short-term unemployment while
not imposing the steady state condition as in Shimer (2007). With a few exceptions
the two procedures essentially yield the same series for the exit rate.

132

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

unemployment drops sharply in a recession, falling to about 35 percent in previous recessions. Furthermore, in the jobless recoveries after
the 1990–91 recession and the 2001 recession, the exit rate from unemployment declined signi…cantly even two years after the recessions’
troughs. The 2007–09 recession again stands out in terms of the speed
and magnitude of the decline in the exit rate from unemployment. One
year after the trough, the probability of …nding a job within a month
declined to about 20 percent, about half the average exit rate from
unemployment and substantially less than in previous recessions.
A model with homogeneous unemployment is consistent with the
qualitative features of long-term unemployment in recessions, but it
cannot account for the magnitude of long-term unemployment in recessions. Using the entry and exit rates from our unemployment accounting exercise, we can construct counterfactual duration distributions for
unemployment. By construction, the parameters of the simple model
exactly match total unemployment and the number of workers unemployed for fewer than 5 weeks. A model with homogeneous unemployed
workers is not a good match for medium- and long-term unemployment,
however. Consistent with the data on previous recessions, the model
does predict a sharp rise in medium- to long-term unemployment in
recessions. But the model signi…cantly understates the magnitude of
long-term unemployment: for almost all recessions the model predicts
only one-third of those workers who are unemployed for more than 26
weeks.

3.

THE EFFECTS OF UNEMPLOYMENT
INSURANCE ON UNEMPLOYMENT

We use the share of unemployed workers who have been unemployed for
more than 26 weeks as a measure of long-term unemployment. As noted
above, the particular cuto¤ duration for this conventional de…nition of
long-term unemployment is related to the maximum duration of unemployment bene…ts, usually 26 weeks. Unemployment compensation
programs are administered at the state level, and the amount and duration of bene…ts may vary across states. The duration of unemployment
compensation tends to increase in response to increased unemployment
following a cyclical downturn. These changes occur at the state and
federal level. In particular, in response to the increase in long-term
unemployment in 2008, in June of that year Congress authorized an
Emergency Unemployment Compensation (EUC) program that provided an additional 13 weeks of bene…ts for unemployed workers who
were eligible under state programs. After various additional authorizations, by early 2010 the maximum duration of unemployment bene…ts

A. Hornstein and T. A. Lubik: Long-Term Unemployment

133

was 99 weeks, with some variation across states. For a description of
the di¤erent programs, see Daniel Aaronson, Bhashkar Mazumder, and
Shani Schechter (2010).
The duration of unemployment bene…ts is extended in order to
lessen the negative impact of unemployment on long-term unemployed
workers. A side e¤ect of extended bene…ts can be to lengthen the average duration of unemployment. If we assume that unemployed workers
make choices about whether to accept or reject job o¤ers, then increasing or extending unemployment bene…ts will a¤ect how these choices
are made. On the one hand, unemployed workers who are currently eligible for unemployment bene…ts may be willing to hold out for longer
until they receive what they think is a more acceptable o¤er. This will
reduce the exit rate from unemployment for these workers and thereby
increase the average duration of unemployment. On the other hand,
not every unemployed worker quali…es for unemployment bene…ts. In
order to qualify, a worker must have had a job and must have been laid
o¤. If a worker does not qualify for unemployment bene…ts, lengthening the duration of unemployment bene…ts does not mean much for
the worker now, but it does make taking a job much more attractive
since the worker then quali…es for the extended unemployment bene…ts
should the worker become unemployed again. Thus one might expect
that unemployed workers who are ineligible for unemployment bene…ts
become more willing to accept job o¤ers if unemployment bene…ts are
extended.
There is a considerable amount of empirical work on the possible
e¤ects of extended unemployment bene…ts on unemployment duration.
Aaronson et al. (2010) and Michael Elsby, Bart Hobijn, and AyŞegül
Şahin (2010) survey that work and provide some estimates on how
the EUC program may have a¤ected the duration of unemployment.
They start with estimates that an extension of unemployment payments by one week tends to increase unemployment duration by 0.1
to 0.2 weeks. Considering that the duration of unemployment bene…ts
has been increased by up to 73 weeks, and that only about 50 percent
of unemployed workers are eligible for unemployment bene…ts, they
estimate that the EUC program may have lengthened the average duration of unemployment by between 2 and 6 weeks. This is a signi…cant
lengthening, but much less than the actual 18-week increase of average
unemployment duration from about 17 weeks in 2008 to 35 weeks in
the middle of 2010. Furthermore, as Aaronson et al. (2010) and Elsby
et al. (2010) point out, the lower bounds of their estimates are likely
to be more relevant than the upper bounds. Finally, using the simple bathtub model of unemployment, one can translate the estimated

134

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

increase in unemployment duration to an increase in the unemployment
rate of between one and three percentage points.7

4.

DIFFERENT UNEMPLOYMENT EXPERIENCES

The previous discussion considers only the behavior of total unemployment in the economy. But the labor market experience in the United
States is not the same for all members of the labor force. Unemployment rates di¤er vastly across demographic groups. For instance, as
of December 2010 the unemployment rate among individuals who have
not completed high school was more than three times the unemployment rate of those with a college degree. It is therefore tempting to
hypothesize that some of the higher unemployment and the longer unemployment duration might be due to composition e¤ects. This term
describes the idea that during a recession the composition of newly
unemployed workers shifts toward demographic groups characterized
by lower exit rates and longer durations. In other words, the overall
unemployment picture hides deeper dynamics in the labor market that
a¤ect speci…c groups, occupations, or industries in markedly di¤erent
ways.
In Table 1 we show the average unemployment rate, mean duration
of unemployment, and share of long-term unemployment for several demographic groups for the available sample after 1960 and for the year
2010. Three things are apparent: First, unemployment rates and unemployment durations di¤er signi…cantly across demographic groups. Second, during the 2007–09 recession, unemployment tended to increase
more in some groups that in the past were less susceptible to job loss
in recessions. Third, for all demographic groups, unemployment rates,
mean durations of unemployment, and long-term unemployment shares
are signi…cantly higher than their sample averages prior to the recession. While the …rst two observations point to the possibility that
changes in the composition of unemployment in‡ows might contribute
to the overall increase in unemployment, the third observation suggests
that changes in composition cannot be a complete explanation for the
overall increase in unemployment.

7
This estimate is based on the relationship between mean unemployment duration
and the exit rate from unemployment described in Box 1. The calculations are conditional on an average monthly job separation rate of 3 percent per month (Shimer 2007).
A similar exercise is performed by Mazumder (2011).

24 and younger
25–54
55 and older
White
Black (1972–2010)
Asian (2000–2010)
Hispanic (1973–2010)

Age

Race

5.1
4.5
10.3
12.8

2.9
6.9
7.9

8.7
16.0
7.5
12.5

18.4
8.6
7.0

8.6
10.5

2.9

5.3
12.2
4.9
9.1

12.4
4.8
3.6

6.3
5.9

20.3

19.9
17.7

22.4

15.5
18.3
22.0
17.1

11.8
18.7
22.1

14.8
17.6

36.5

32.6
29.9

38.4

32.1
36.7
36.9
30.7

23.3
35.5
40.6

32.0
33.9

25.9

22.6
19.4

26.8

15.9
20.0
26.1
15.5

10.6
19.9
40.1

14.9
18.9

61.8

43.3
38.9

52.0

42.0
48.4
48.5
39.4

29.7
46.9
79.3

41.5
44.7

*Monthly observations from 1960 to 2010 unless otherwise noted. ** Data for unemployment duration and share
of long-term unemployment are not readily available. Unemployment rates and durations di¤er across demographic
groups. In the 2007–09 recession, unemployment nearly doubled in groups that traditionally have lower unemployment rates, such as college-educated workers and those in management, business, and …nancial operations.

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Haver Analytics, authors’ calculations.

Occupation
Management, business,
(2000–2010) and …nancial operations
Professional and
related occupations
Services
Production,
transportation,
and material moving

Female
Male

Gender

Total

Unemployment
Duration

Share of
Long-Term
Unemployment
Sample Avg.* 2010 Avg. Sample Avg. 2010 Avg. Sample Avg. 2010 Avg.
6.1
9.6
14.9
33.1
15.0
43.3

Unemployment
Rate

Table 1 Demographic Di erence in Unemployment
A. Hornstein and T. A. Lubik: Long-Term Unemployment
135

8.4
9.7
6.9
10.9
5.8
12.2

5.2
5.8
3.8
7.2
3.6
8.6
9.0
5.4
4.4
2.6

Education
Less than high school
(1992–2010)** High school completed
Some college
College completed

18.3
16.6

19.5

20.4
22.8
21.0

19.2

30.1
29.5

33.7

37.9
37.9
38.0

34.6

20.0
17.8

22.4

23.6
26.9
25.0

21.5

39.4
37.5

45.1

49.2
50.8
51.5

45.2

*Monthly observations from 1960 to 2010 unless otherwise noted. ** Data for unemployment duration and share
of long-term unemployment are not readily available. Unemployment rates and durations di¤er across demographic
groups. In the 2007–09 recession, unemployment nearly doubled in groups that traditionally have lower unemployment rates, such as college-educated workers and those in management, business, and …nancial operations.

Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Haver Analytics, authors’ calculations.

14.9
10.3
8.4
4.7

9.5

6.1

Construction
Manufacturing
Wholesale and retail
trade
Transportation and
utilities
Information
Financial activities
Professional and
business services
Education and health
services
Leisure and hospitality

Industry
(2000–2010)

Unemployment
Duration

Share of
Long-Term
Unemployment
Sample Avg.* 2010 Avg. Sample Avg. 2010 Avg. Sample Avg. 2010 Avg.
10.3
20.6
16.9
33.3
18.3
42.8
6.3
10.6
22.3
39.8
26.8
53.8

Unemployment
Rate

Table 1 (Continued) Demographic Di erence in Unemployment
136
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

A. Hornstein and T. A. Lubik: Long-Term Unemployment

137

The average unemployment rate in 2010 was more than 50 percent
higher than the average unemployment rate from 1960 through 2010.
Although the unemployment rate of males tends to be somewhat lower
than the unemployment rate of females, in 2010 the unemployment rate
of males increased relative to that of females. Across age groups, the
unemployment rate of younger workers (under 25) tends to be higher
than that of older workers (over 55), but in 2010 the unemployment rate
of older workers increased relative to that of younger workers.8 Overall, the unemployment rate of workers who have not completed high
school is about three times as high as that of workers with a college
degree, yet in 2010 the unemployment rate of college-educated workers increased slightly relative to that of workers without a high school
degree. Workers in managerial occupations related to business and …nancial operations have some of the lowest unemployment rates among
all occupations, certainly compared to service-oriented occupations and
occupations in the production sector, but in 2010 the unemployment
rate for managerial occupations increased somewhat relative to these
other occupations.9 Across industries, the average unemployment rate
in construction in 2010 was nearly three times the rate in …nancial activities, but in both industries the rate almost doubled over the sample
average. Since construction and …nancial services were at the heart of
the 2007–09 recession, it should not be too surprising that workers af…liated with both industries experienced some of the biggest increases
in unemployment rates.
The di¤erences in unemployment rates across demographic groups
are accompanied by similar di¤erences in mean unemployment duration and long-term unemployment shares, although the relationship
between these variables is not particularly tight. For example, on average the mean unemployment duration of older workers is more than
twice the mean duration of younger workers, yet the unemployment
rate of older workers is less than half that of younger workers. This observation highlights that there are two determinants of unemployment,
in‡ows and out‡ows, as discussed previously.10 The low unemployment
8
Across race groups, unemployment rates tend to be lower among whites, but relative to the whole sample unemployment rates among whites increased in 2010. One
should be careful when comparing the unemployment rate changes of di¤erent race
groups since the sample periods do not coincide.
9
The occupation and industry a¢ liation of an unemployed worker refer to the last
job held by that worker. It is not uncommon for workers to change occupations or
industries, even without an intervening unemployment spell. The classi…cation of an
unemployed worker by last known employment can be useful if it re‡ects on the human
capital that an unemployed worker has acquired and that a¤ects the job search decisions
of that worker.
10
See also the discussion of unemployment in OECD countries in Box 2.

138

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

rate for older workers, then, is mainly due to a very low in‡ow rate into
unemployment— in other words, a very low probability of losing a job.
On the other hand, once an older worker loses a job and becomes unemployed, the probability of …nding a new job is very low compared to
a younger worker. Nevertheless, it appears as if a general decline in job
…nding rates was an important driver of the increased unemployment
rate in the 2007–09 recession. Across all demographic groups, there are
comparable increases in mean unemployment duration and long-term
unemployment shares in 2010.
We have documented di¤erences in the way unemployment rates,
mean duration, and long-term unemployment changed for di¤erent demographic groups, but we do not want to overemphasize these di¤erences since essentially all groups experienced signi…cant increases in
unemployment. A more thorough analysis of the role of demographic
changes and their contributions to the average duration of unemployment is provided by Aaronson et al. (2010). They compare average unemployment duration in (1) the expansion phases following the
1981–82 and the 2001 recessions, and in (2) the …rst six months following the 1981–82 and the 2007–09 recessions. To a …rst approximation,
Aaronson et al. (2010) calculate the change in total unemployment
that is attributable to two di¤erent factors. First, they calculate the
change in unemployment duration that would have occurred given the
change in the demographic composition of the labor force, but assuming that the unemployment durations within demographic groups do
not change. Second, they calculate the change in unemployment duration that would have occurred assuming no change in the demographic
composition of the labor force, but allowing for the observed change of
unemployment durations within demographic groups.11 They …nd that
comparing the expansion phases after the 1981–82 and 2007–09 recessions, changes in the labor force composition account for less than half
of the trend change in unemployment duration. Furthermore, comparing the periods immediately after the 1981–82 and 2007–09 recessions,
changes in the labor force account for only one-…fth of the di¤erence in
unemployment duration.
11
There is also a third e¤ect, which captures any interactions between changes in
the relative size of demographic groups and changes in durations within demographic
groups.

A. Hornstein and T. A. Lubik: Long-Term Unemployment
5.

139

DURATION DEPENDENCE OF
UNEMPLOYMENT

People are di¤erent, and survey measures do not capture all the characteristics that are relevant to unemployment duration. Some characteristics that are relevant to the chances of an unemployed worker
…nding work can be quite persistent yet unobservable, and these characteristics might actually be related to the unemployment experience
itself. For example, consider two equal pools of unemployed workers
who at the beginning of the month share the same observable characteristics, except for the time that they have been unemployed already.
On average, at the end of the month relatively more workers from the
pool with the shorter unemployment duration will have found work. In
other words, the longer a worker has been unemployed already, the less
likely it is that he or she will …nd a job. This apparent decline in exit
rates with the length of time unemployed is called “negative duration
dependence.”12
Negative duration dependence is clearly inconsistent with the simple model of homogeneous unemployment that we discussed previously,
since that model assumes that in any given month all unemployed workers have the same chance of …nding work, independent of how long they
already have been unemployed. This observation may account for the
fact that the simple model understates the prevalence of long-term unemployment.
As noted previously, we can use the entry and exit rates from our
unemployment accounting exercise to construct counterfactual duration distributions for unemployment. When we account for unemployment in the previous section, we use the share of workers who were
unemployed for fewer than 5 weeks to calculate estimates of the exit
rate from unemployment. Suppose we were instead to use the share
of workers who were unemployed for fewer than 15 weeks to calculate
the exit rate from unemployment. The simple model imposes the same
exit rate on workers who were unemployed for fewer than 5 weeks and
on workers who were unemployed for between 5 and 15 weeks.
But if there is negative duration dependence, the exit rate we calculate when we use the share of workers who have been unemployed
for fewer than 15 weeks should be less than the exit rate we calculate when we use the share of workers who have been unemployed for
fewer than 5 weeks. In Figure 2 we display the exit rates from unemployment based on di¤erent segments of the duration distribution of
12
See Machin and Manning (1999) for a survey on the role of duration dependence
in the determination of long-term unemployment in Europe.

140

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

unemployment: the share of workers who have been unemployed for
fewer than 5 weeks, fewer than 15 weeks, and fewer than 27 weeks.
In fact, consistent with negative duration dependence, the implied exit
rates decline monotonically as unemployment duration increases.
Two explanations have been proposed for the observed negative
duration dependence of exit rates from unemployment. The …rst explanation simply assumes that for each unemployed worker, the exit
rate is a declining function of elapsed unemployment duration. Then
the exit rate from the unemployment pool declines with the duration
that the pool’s members have been unemployed. This approach is called
“true duration dependence.” An alternative explanation is to assume
that newly unemployed workers already di¤er according to their exit
rates from unemployment. Even if the exit rate for an individual worker
does not change over time, the composition of the pool will change over
time, which implies a change in the average exit rate from the pool.
In particular, over time workers with a high exit rate will make up a
smaller and smaller share of the remaining pool of workers who have
not yet found work, which implies a declining average exit rate from
the pool. This approach is called “unobserved heterogeneity.”
Various reasons can account for true duration dependence in exit
rates. For one, over time unemployed workers tend to lose skills associated with actual work experience and work-related training. This
decline in human capital implies that the average wage o¤er an unemployed worker could obtain probably also would decline over time.
If the bene…ts of staying unemployed remain constant over time,
for example via constant unemployment insurance payments, while the
average wage o¤er is declining, then the likelihood that an unemployed
worker accepts an o¤er probably also declines over time, and so would
the exit rate. Additionally, over time unemployed workers lose attachment to networks that may aid in …nding new jobs. Finally, potential
employers might interpret a prolonged unemployment spell as a signal
of ability, irrespective of the true, underlying characteristics of the unemployed worker. All of this means that exit rates from unemployment
would decline over time.13
Unobserved heterogeneity does not need any particular story. Clearly
surveys do not capture all the information that is relevant to the determination of exit rates from unemployment. For example, a worker who
loses a job for reasons that are idiosyncratic to the previous employer
13
See Ljungqvist and Sargent (1998) for an example that studies the implications
of duration dependence due to human capital depreciation. See Blanchard and Diamond
(1994) for an example of duration dependence due to employer screening of long-term
unemployed.

A. Hornstein and T. A. Lubik: Long-Term Unemployment

141

may have skills that are valued by a wide range of employers, and may
…nd work relatively quickly. On the other hand, if a worker loses a job
in an industry or occupation that is in secular decline, the skills of that
worker may not be easily transferable to a wide range of employers,
and this worker may stay unemployed for a long time.
The two explanations of duration dependence potentially have different policy implications. If true duration dependence is widespread
among unemployed workers, then current high levels of unemployment might imply high future unemployment because more unemployed
workers make the transition to long-term unemployment. In this case,
a reduction in current unemployment, if possible, would reduce future unemployment. On the other hand, if unobserved heterogeneity
accounts for duration dependence and the increase in unemployment,
and the duration of unemployment is mainly due to an in‡ux of workers with low exit rates, it might be a signal that unemployment is due
to a “mismatch” of skills. In this case, high unemployment may re‡ect structural change and may not be amenable to monetary policy
actions.
Preliminary work by one of the authors of this essay indicates that
a simple framework with two types of unemployed workers— short-term
unemployed with a relatively high exit rate from unemployment and
long-term unemployed with a relatively low exit rate— can account
quite well for the observed variation in the duration distribution of
unemployment (Hornstein 2011). This framework allows for two special cases. The …rst case consists only of true duration dependence: all
unemployed workers are initially short-term unemployed with a high
exit rate from unemployment, but during unemployment workers make
a random transition from short-term to long-term unemployment. The
second case consists only of unobserved heterogeneity: workers are from
the beginning either short-term or long-term unemployed, and they
never change types.
The two special cases of the framework provide di¤erent accounts
of unemployment volatility. In the true duration dependence case, almost all of the unemployment rate ‡uctuations are attributed to exit
rate ‡uctuations of the two types. Changes in entry rates of short-term
unemployed workers and transition rates from short-term to long-term
unemployment— that is, the true duration mechanism itself— have only
a limited e¤ect. In the unobserved heterogeneity case, on the other
hand, a substantial portion of the unemployment rate ‡uctuation is attributable to changes in the entry rate of long-term unemployed workers. In this case, ‡uctuations in entry and exit rates of long-term unemployed workers account for about two-thirds of unemployment rate

142

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

volatility. Of the two cases, the unobserved heterogeneity approach
provides a better match to the unemployment duration distribution.
The more general framework that allows for both true duration
dependence and unobserved heterogeneity yields results that are closer
to the special case of only unobserved heterogeneity. In the general
framework, unemployment volatility is about equally accounted for by
changes in the entry rate of long-term unemployed workers and the
exit rates of both types. Furthermore, it appears as if the observed
increase in unemployment in the 2007–09 recession is mainly driven by
the increased entry rate and reduced exit rate of long-term unemployed
workers.14 Given the above interpretation of long-term unemployment
due to unobserved heterogeneity, one could then argue that most of
the increase in unemployment in the 2007–09 recession represents an
increase in structural unemployment.

6.

LONG-TERM UNEMPLOYMENT AND
MONETARY POLICY

A simple view of the statistical relationship between unemployment
and in‡ation— the Phillips curve— suggests that the choices for monetary policymakers who want to promote employment and price stability are clear. Unemployment is high and in‡ation is low, therefore
monetary policy can and should be expansionary. Yet many modern
macroeconomists argue that movements in real quantities matter for
in‡ation dynamics only to the extent that they depart from their natural level. Furthermore, the best way to attain low unemployment
volatility in the long run is to follow policy rules that promote price
stability. 15 In this view, the labor market situation in the wake of the
Great Recession still presents a challenge to monetary policymakers.
Macroeconomic theory de…nes the natural rate of unemployment
as the hypothetical level of unemployment that would obtain in the
absence of any distortions, such as impediments to free adjustment
of nominal prices and wages. The di¤erence between actual and natural unemployment is often referred to as the “unemployment gap.”
It constitutes a measure of the degree of slack, or under-utilization
of resources, in the economy; a large and positive unemployment gap
may constrain in‡ationary pressures. With a large pool of unemployed
workers to hire from, wages are unlikely to increase, which therefore
14
According to the more general framework, the behavior of unemployment in
the 2007–09 recession is similar to its behavior in the 1981–82 recession. It is unlike
the 1973–75 and 1990–91 recessions, where the increase in the unemployment rate was
mainly driven by a general decline in exit rates.
15
For one exposition of this view, see Lacker and Weinberg (2006).

A. Hornstein and T. A. Lubik: Long-Term Unemployment

143

limits pricing pressures stemming from rising input costs. This scenario
seemingly describes the recent economic climate, with unemployment
persistently high and in‡ation trending gradually lower over the course
of the recession. How useful this argument is for policy decisions depends on how easy it is for policymakers to discern the level of the
natural rate. A main point of contention in the current policy debate
is whether the natural rate has substantially shifted upward over the
course of the Great Recession. The existence of very high long-term
unemployment has implications for this debate.
We have shown that the prevalence of long-term unemployment is
related to the fact that the exit rate out of unemployment declines with
the duration of unemployment. Since a high fraction of long-term unemployed workers …nd it di¢ cult to transition to employment, the pool
of workers who can reasonably expect to be hired may be e¤ectively
smaller than it appears from the raw unemployment numbers alone.
Thus the natural rate of unemployment would be higher, and the unemployment gap smaller, than what one might infer from the measured
level of unemployment. Furthermore, a preliminary account of unemployment during the Great Recession seems to indicate that overall
unemployment increased because of increased entry rates and reduced
exit rates of long-term unemployed workers, suggesting that structural
unemployment, and therefore the natural rate of unemployment, has
increased.
How, then, should monetary policymakers respond to the increase
in long-term unemployment? To the extent that the exceptionally
large share of long-term unemployment re‡ects structural change and
a higher natural rate of unemployment, policymakers should seriously
consider the possibility that a high unemployment rate does not necessarily equate to a large unemployment gap. Furthermore, if higher
long-term unemployment were to become a permanent feature of the
U.S. labor market, then the level of unemployment would be even less
likely to respond to short-term monetary stimulus. Any policy options
to deal with permanent long-term unemployment would likely have to
take the form of structural labor and product market reforms that increase the ability and willingness of the unemployed to …nd work, and
reduce the costs of generating and maintaining employment relationships. Reforms of this kind arguably reduced the incidence of long-term
unemployment in, for instance, the United Kingdom in the 1980s and
Germany during the past decade.

144

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

APPENDIX
The following sections appeared as Box 1 and Box 2 in the original
article.

1.

A SIMPLE FRAMEWORK FOR
UNEMPLOYMENT ACCOUNTING

We can formalize the bathtub model of unemployment described in
the text as follows. The labor force consists of a …xed number of L
workers who are either employed, E, or unemployed, U , and L = E +U .
For simplicity assume that employed workers become unemployed at
a constant rate and that unemployed workers become employed at
a constant rate . Then the rate of change of unemployment, U_ , is
simply the di¤erence between in‡ows and out‡ows,
U_ = E

U:

In‡ows and out‡ows and the change in unemployment are to be
interpreted as occurring instantaneously. The unemployment rate is
u. The rate of change
u = UL and the employment rate is e = E
L =1
of the unemployment rate is
u_ =

(1

u)

u:

In‡ow and out‡ow rates may change over time, but if these rates
remain constant, unemployment will converge to a rest point or steady
state, u*. If in‡ows exceed (fall short of) out‡ows, the unemployment
rate will increase (decline), u_ > 0(u_ < 0), toward the steady state.
In the steady state, in‡ows and out‡ows just balance such that the
unemployment rate remains constant, u_ = 0,
u =

:
+
If the exit rate from unemployment is large relative to the in‡ow
into unemployment, convergence to the steady state will be fast. In
this case, not much is lost in thinking about unemployment in any
given month as steady state unemployment corresponding to the in‡ow
and out‡ow rates for that month, and ignoring the convergence to the
steady state.
This simple model assumes that every unemployed worker faces
the same chance of exiting the unemployment pool. In particular, this

A. Hornstein and T. A. Lubik: Long-Term Unemployment

145

exit rate is independent of the time the worker has been unemployed.
Again, assuming that the in‡ow and out‡ow rates remain unchanged,
we can calculate the implied duration distribution of unemployment
in the steady state. The share of unemployed workers who have been
unemployed for no more than duration T is then given by
!T = 1

e

T

:

Entry and exit rates in U.S. unemployment are indeed quite high,
and we can interpret unemployment and the duration distribution of
unemployment as being close to their steady states. In the text we
use data on the duration distribution to recover estimates of the exit
rate from unemployment. Given an estimate of the exit rate, we then
use data on unemployment to obtain estimates of the entry rate into
unemployment.
Another way to relate the exit rate from unemployment to observables is to consider its implications for the average duration of
unemployment. Our description of the out‡ows from unemployment—
that an unemployed worker becomes employed at the instantaneous
rate independent of how long that worker has been unemployed—
corresponds to a particular stochastic process, namely a Poisson process.
For such a process the average duration that a worker is unemployed
is simply the inverse of the exit rate,
T =

1

:

The relationship between the exit rate from unemployment and the
average duration of unemployment allows us to obtain a back of the envelope calculation of the e¤ect of extended unemployment bene…ts on
the unemployment rate. Suppose that an extension of the length of unemployment bene…ts increases the average duration of unemployment
from T0 to T1 . That implies a reduction in the exit rate from unemployment from 0 = T10 to 1 = T11 . Everything else the same, that is,
with no change in the separation rate, the steady state unemployment
rate increases from u0 = ( +1=T0 ) to u1 = ( +1=T1 ) .

2.

THE PERSISTENCE OF LONG-TERM
UNEMPLOYMENT: AN INTERNATIONAL
COMPARISON

Many European economies experienced high rates of unemployment
associated with signi…cant long-term unemployment throughout the

146

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

1980s and 1990s.16 This high European unemployment has been attributed to the interaction of labor market institutions with structural
and monetary shocks. For example, one of the authors of this essay
(Hornstein), together with Per Krusell and Giovanni Violante (2007),
argues that in response to a common acceleration of embodied technological change, di¤erent labor market institutions in continental Europe
and the United States led to a di¤erential response of unemployment
and wage inequality in these countries. On the other hand, Laurence
Ball (1997) sees the original common shock in a series of disin‡ations
induced by monetary policy around 1980, but also argues that the impact on unemployment di¤ered depending on the countries’labor market institutions. European unemployment rates eventually declined, in
some countries arguably due to structural reforms in product and labor
markets in the wake of the European Monetary Union.
In the following discussion we provide a short summary of the determinants of unemployment in OECD countries based on the data set
provided by Michael Elsby, Bart Hobijn, and AyŞegül Şahin (2011). In
our analysis of cyclical long-term unemployment in the United States,
we have suggested that a general decline in exit rates from unemployment is an important source of increased long-term unemployment following a recession. The cross-sectional data for the OECD countries,
on the other hand, suggest that both entry rates and exit rates are important drivers of unemployment in the long run. Based on the analysis
of the simple model in Box 1, we construct job …nding rates using the
fraction of workers who have been unemployed for fewer than three
months.17 Using this exit rate from unemployment and the unemployment rate, we construct job separation rates. We construct job …nding
and job separation rates for each country for each available year. In
Figure 3 we display the average job …nding and job separation rates
for each country. We express these rates as the probability that in
any month an employed (unemployed) worker will become unemployed
(employed).
16

For a survey, see Machin and Manning (1999).
Our procedure assumes (1) that the country data for unemployment rates and
duration distributions re‡ect steady states, and (2) that there is no duration dependence
in exit rates from unemployment. The steady state assumption is a good approximation
for labor markets with relatively high job …nding rates, such as the U.S. labor market.
Since the job …nding rates are much smaller for almost all other OECD countries, our
procedure is potentially less reliable for these countries. It turns out that our estimates
from the simple steady-state-based procedure are not that di¤erent from the estimates
one obtains if transition dynamics are taken into account. Elsby et al. (2011) argue
that for most of the continental European countries, there is no signi…cant evidence for
duration dependence in exit rates, but that there is evidence for duration dependence
in most of the other countries.
17

A. Hornstein and T. A. Lubik: Long-Term Unemployment

147

Figure 3 Labor Market Turnover in Selected OECD
Countries

Sources: Elsby, Hobijn, and Şahin (2011), OECD, authors’ calculations.
Notes: The number to the right of each country name is the average unemployment rate from 1968–2006. U.S. workers on average are more likely to become
unemployed than in other OECD countries, but they also …nd new work more
quickly. In countries with low job turnover, such as Italy and Spain, the average
unemployment rate is much higher than in the United States. The number to the
right of each country is the country’s average unemployment rate from 1968–2006.

The ‡uidity of the U.S. labor market stands out when compared
to the labor markets of almost all other countries. This is especially
true when compared to several continental European countries that
have high unemployment rates. In the United States, the average unemployed worker has a more than 35 percent chance of …nding work
within a month, while at the same time there is a less than 3 percent
chance that a worker becomes unemployed within a month. The high
job …nding rate more than counteracts the high job separation rate,
such that at 6 percent the average U.S. unemployment rate is quite low
compared to most other countries. The Italian labor market, on the
other hand, displays very low turnover. Workers rarely become unemployed and unemployed workers take a very long time to …nd work; job

148

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

separation and job …nding probabilities are one-tenth of those in the
United States. In Italy this extremely sclerotic labor market results in
an unemployment rate that is almost twice that of the United States.
Looking at the cross-section of countries in Figure 3, it appears
that the less turnover there is in a country’s labor market, the higher
the unemployment rate. Most of the continental European countries
with high average unemployment rates are concentrated in the lower
left hand corner of Figure 3, with low job …nding and job separation
probabilities. One should be careful not to draw too many conclusions
from this observation about the causality between transition rates and
the level of unemployment, but there is evidence that low separation
rates due to rigid labor market laws can lead to low job …nding rates.
(For example, see Giuseppe Bertola and Andrea Ichino [1995].) Finally,
comparing Figures 2 and 3 we can see that the U.S. job …nding rate,
even at an extreme cyclical trough like the one after the 2007–09 recession, is still higher than the average job …nding rate in most other
OECD countries.

REFERENCES
Aaronson, Daniel, Bhashkar Mazumder, and Shani Schechter. 2010.
“What Is Behind the Rise in Long-Term Unemployment?”Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago Economic Perspectives 34 (2): 28–51.
Ball, Laurence M. 1997. “Disin‡ation and the NAIRU.” In Reducing
In‡ation: Motivation and Strategy, edited by Christina Romer and
David Romer, 167–94. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Bertola, Giuseppe, and Andrea Ichino. 1995. “Wage Inequality and
Unemployment: United States versus Europe.” In NBER
Macroeconomics Annual, edited by Ben S. Bernanke and Julio J.
Rotemberg, 13–66. Boston: MIT Press.
Blanchard, Olivier Jean, and Peter A. Diamond. 1994. “Ranking,
Unemployment Duration, and Wages.” Review of Economic
Studies 61 (3): 417–34.
Elsby, Michael W. L., Bart Hobijn, and AyŞegül Şahin. 2010. “The
Labor Market in the Great Recession.” Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity Spring: 1–48.

A. Hornstein and T. A. Lubik: Long-Term Unemployment

149

Elsby, Michael W. L., Bart Hobijn, and AyŞegül Şahin. 2011.
“Unemployment Dynamics in the OECD.” Federal Reserve Bank
of San Francisco Working Paper 2009–04.
Elsby, Michael W. L., Ryan Michaels, and Gary Solon. 2009. “The Ins
and Outs of Cyclical Unemployment.” American Economic
Journal: Macroeconomics 1 (1): 84–110.
Fujita, Shigeru, and Garey Ramey. 2009. “The Cyclicality of
Separation and Job Finding Rates.” International Economic
Review 50 (2): 415–30.
Hornstein, Andreas. 2011. “Accounting for Unemployment: The Short
and Long of It.” Mimeo, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.
Hornstein, Andreas, Per Krusell, and Giovanni L. Violante. 2007.
“Technology-Policy Interaction in Frictional Labour-Markets.”
Review of Economic Studies 74 (4): 1,089–124.
Lacker, Je¤rey M., and John A. Weinberg. 2006. “In‡ation and
Unemployment: A Layperson’s Guide to the Phillips Curve.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond 2006 Annual Report, 4–26.
Ljungqvist, Lars, and Thomas J. Sargent. 1998. “The European
Unemployment Dilemma.” Journal of Political Economy 106 (3):
514–50.
Machin, Stephen, and Alan Manning. 1999. “The Causes and
Consequences of Longterm Unemployment in Europe.” In
Handbook of Labor Economics Vol. 3, edited by Orley Ashenfelter
and David Card, 3,085–139. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Mazumder, Bhashkar. 2011. “How Did Unemployment Insurance
Extensions A¤ect the Unemployment Rate in 2008–10?” Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago Chicago Fed Letter no. 285.
Shimer, Robert. 2007. “Reassessing the Ins and Outs of
Unemployment.” Mimeo, University of Chicago.

Economic Quarterly— Volume 101, Number 2— Second Quarter 2015— Pages 151–167

Unsustainable Fiscal Policy:
Implications for Monetary
Policy
Renee Haltom and John A. Weinberg

T

he debt of the United States government that is held by the
public reached its highest point since World War II in 2011, at
67.7 percent of gross domestic product (GDP).1 Annual de…cits
surpassed 10 percent of GDP in 2009, the highest level since 1945,
dipping to 8.7 percent of GDP in 2011. The early-to-mid 1980s was
the only other point in the postwar period in which de…cits exceeded 5
percent of GDP.
Recent numbers are high by historical comparison, but more important than the current size of the de…cit and debt is the path they are
likely to follow in the future. Federal debt held by the public was actually higher after World War II than it is today— 109 percent of GDP in
1946, the highest level on record— but a key di¤erence was that large
de…cits then were almost entirely associated with the temporary war
e¤ort. The same cannot be said today; several factors point to large
demands on …scal resources for most of the foreseeable future. Most
The authors would like to thank Andreas Hornstein, Thomas A. Lubik, Aaron
Steelman, and Alexander Wolman for discussions and detailed comments. The views
expressed are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
1
There are two common ways to measure the government’s debt burden. Debt held
by the public, used in this essay, re‡ects government borrowing from private …nancial
markets. Total federal debt, the second common measure, comprises debt held by the
public (private investors, including the Federal Reserve) and debt held by government
accounts. The two measures have di¤erent implications. Debt held by the public can
a¤ect the current economy by crowding out private borrowing. In contrast, debt held by
government accounts re‡ects internal transactions that are not traded in capital markets.
However, that debt is nonetheless a legal liability of the federal government and a burden
on taxpayers, which is why total debt is also used as a measure of the government’s
overall debt burden. We focus on debt held by the public because that is the measure
for which long-term projections are readily available.

152

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

prevalent is the aging population. The …rst baby boomers reached retirement age in 2011, and the fraction of the population aged 65 or older
will surpass 20 percent by 2035, compared to 13 percent today. For the
past 30 years, there have been roughly …ve working people in the United
States for every person of retirement age; that number will drop to 2.8
after 2035. This “dependency ratio” is a rough approximation of the
number of working individuals in the economy that support, through
taxes and Social Security contributions, the people drawing age-related
bene…ts from the government. The aging population will impose significant demands on federal resources through Social Security, Medicare,
and Medicaid. These programs are written into law, which means their
spending is not determined annually by the federal budgets created
by the U.S. president and Congress, but instead can only be reduced
through major overhauls to law.2
The nonpartisan Congressional Budget O¢ ce (CBO) projects the
federal government’s long-term budget outlook under two scenarios:
a “baseline” scenario that holds current laws constant and an “alternative” scenario that incorporates the e¤ects of laws the CBO deems
likely to pass. (The budget outlooks under both scenarios are displayed
in Figure 1.) The baseline scenario re‡ecting current laws presents the
more optimistic view of the future path of …scal policy. Tax revenues are
projected to reach much higher levels than in recent history, while each
category of spending except that on Social Security, health care entitlements, and interest payments on debt is projected to fall to its lowest
level since World War II. Still, the increase in revenues and decline in
other spending would be slightly more than o¤set by increased spending on Social Security, Medicaid, and Medicare as the population ages.
Therefore, de…cits would remain positive, causing debt levels to grow
slowly over time. Under the baseline scenario, debt held by the public
would rise to 84 percent of GDP by 2035, staying in that ballpark for
the remaining decades of the forecast. (See Figure 2.)
The alternative scenario— the one the CBO considers more likely—
presents a more alarming picture of the growth in federal debt. In
2
The aging population may not be the only source of coming strains on government budgets. Additional, though less certain, liabilities stem from the government’s
implicit support of other sectors of the economy. This is the support that market participants may assume the federal government will provide to certain markets in the event
of trouble, including contingent support to the housing agencies Fannie Mae and Freddie
Mac, as well as private pension funds. Whether the government ever will provide this
implicit support is highly uncertain, but John Walter and Nadezhda Malysheva (2010)
estimated that more than half the private …nancial sector— potentially $25 trillion in
liabilities, far greater than the size of the economy— was likely to enjoy some explicit
or implicit federal backing at the end of 2009. Not included in their analysis were public sector pensions, which are underfunded by more than $3 trillion, more than triple
states’ outstanding debts, according to the most pessimistic estimates.

R. Haltom and J. A. Weinberg: Unsustainable Fiscal Policy

153

Figure 1 Projected Budget Gaps (as a Percent of GDP)

Source: Congressional Budget O¢ ce’s 2011 Long-Term Budget Outlook.
Notes: The Congressional Budget O¢ ce produces two long-term budget projections: the “baseline” scenario, based on current laws, and the “alternative” scenario, based on laws expected to pass. *Projections begin with the 2012 budget.

that scenario, revenues do not rise much from where they are today,
yet spending grows rapidly. This is because of law changes the CBO
deems likely to take place, including an extension of the tax cuts that
were enacted since 2001 and extended in 2010. The CBO also assumes that tax laws will be changed to keep tax revenues close to their
long-run average of 18.4 percent of GDP, rather than rising to historically large levels as they do in the baseline scenario. In addition,

154

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

Figure 2 Federal Debt Held by the Public (as a Percent of
GDP)

Source: Congressional Budget O¢ ce’s 2011 Long-Term Budget Outlook.
Federal debt held by the public consists primarily of U.S. Treasury securities, including those held by the Federal Reserve. It does not include debt held in federal
government accounts or securities issued by Fannie Mae or Freddie Mac. *Projections begin with the 2012 debt level.

Medicare payments are not assumed to decrease as current law dictates,
health care spending under the major reform bill passed in 2010 is not
assumed to decrease after 2021 as current law prescribes, and spending
on non-entitlement programs is not assumed to fall as rapidly as in
the baseline scenario. Under these conditions, federal debt held by the
public would rise sharply after 2011, exceeding its historical record of
109 percent of GDP as early as 2023. It would surpass 200 percent of
GDP— far more than double today’s share of GDP— by the late 2030s.
The two scenarios represent optimistic and pessimistic alternatives
from a range of possible outcomes. The exercise shows that the evolution of the federal government’s …scal position depends largely on
policy decisions that have yet to be made. Given the demands on …scal
resources coming from the aging population under existing laws, achieving a path toward …scal balance will involve very di¢ cult tradeo¤s for
…scal policymakers.

R. Haltom and J. A. Weinberg: Unsustainable Fiscal Policy
1.

155

UNSUSTAINABLE FISCAL POLICY

Economists use the word “unsustainable” to describe debt levels projected by the CBO’s alternative scenario, a characterization re‡ecting
the likelihood that …nancial markets would force a painful adjustment
in …scal policy before such debt levels could be reached. That notion
is based on a simple framework called the government’s intertemporal
budget constraint. “Intertemporal”simply means “over time,”while a
budget constraint is a basic accounting identity that says an entity must
pay for everything that it purchases. The government’s intertemporal
budget constraint says that the value of the government’s outstanding
debt must equal the present value of its expected future surpluses—
that is, what …nancial markets believe surpluses will be, calculated in
today’s dollars.
The intertemporal budget constraint suggests that any time the
real debt increases by even a small amount— a budget de…cit is run in
a single year— the expectation of future taxes or spending must adjust
to put the equation in balance. However, the equation says only that
surpluses must eventually rise; it provides no guidance on when that
must occur. Historical experience doesn’t provide a great deal more
insight. For example, the U.S. government ran moderate de…cits, averaging roughly 3 percent of GDP every year, from 1970 to 1997, with no
obvious concern from …nancial market participants about the sources
of future surpluses. That experience would imply that governments
can sustain moderate de…cits seemingly inde…nitely.
That is less likely to be true when the imbalance between outstanding debt and future surpluses is very large. The larger the debt grows,
the larger future surpluses— revenues in excess of spending— must be
to satisfy the equation. However, there are limits to future surpluses.
Spending cannot drop to zero; to the contrary, spending is expected
to rise to historically high levels as a percent of GDP even under the
CBO’s most optimistic scenario, and tax revenues have an upper limit.
As tax rates grow higher, they distort incentives to work and produce,
and at very high rates would shrink the revenue collected by the government. There are likely to be political limits to tax revenues even
before that point is reached, a reality re‡ected in the CBO’s alternative scenario assumption that tax revenues will revert to their historical
average of 18.4 percent of GDP within a decade. With debt levels predicted to grow much larger than GDP within two decades, it is clear
that many years of higher taxes would be required to produce enough
surpluses to resolve the resulting imbalance. There is some level of
debt that is high enough— although how high is di¢ cult to predict—
that generating the amount of future surpluses required would simply
be infeasible.

156

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

That point is what economists have called the “…scal limit.” At
the …scal limit, the government cannot borrow further, and the government’s existing spending promises therefore cannot be funded. At
least one of two events must occur at the …scal limit: the government
would reduce its debt levels by defaulting, or real debt levels would be
reduced through actions taken by the central bank.
There are two main ways in which central banks can improve governments’…scal positions. The …rst is through “seigniorage,” the revenue that governments e¤ectively receive when central banks create
money. In the United States, it comes from the interest the Fed earns
on the Treasury securities it purchases to expand the money supply.
The Fed retains only the interest revenue that it requires to fund operations, and turns the rest over to the Treasury each …scal year.3 The
level of seigniorage remitted annually does not signi…cantly a¤ect debt:
it amounts to slightly more than 1 percent of revenues in most years.4
The governments of most developed nations do not regularly rely on
seigniorage as a funding strategy because overreliance on seigniorage—
that is, on money creation— will inevitably lead to rising in‡ation. Perhaps the most famous example of printing money to fund government
operations is Germany in the early 1920s, when the price level doubled
every two days. This action is sometimes called “monetizing” government debt: if the market grows unwilling to purchase government debt
at low rates, the central bank can step in to purchase that debt directly
from the government. Stanley Fischer, Ratna Sahay, and Carlos Vegh
(2002) estimate how much government revenue can be created through
seigniorage from a sample of 24 countries in the post-World War II
period. Those nations created enough money to push annual in‡ation
above 100 percent. During those episodes, seigniorage amounted to
just 4 percent of GDP on average— not enough to cover their average
de…cits of just below 5 percent of GDP. By comparison, de…cits under
3
This revenue for the Treasury e¤ectively is a tax on the public’s holdings of noninterest-bearing money— the currency and bank reserves issued by the Fed— since the
public would have otherwise earned interest from holding those treasuries.
4
Since 2009, the Fed has produced a larger than average amount of seigniorage
because the Fed has earned greater interest revenue due to the large expansion of the
Fed’s balance sheet to treat the …nancial crisis. From 2001 through 2008, the Fed turned
an average of $26 billion over to the Treasury each …scal year, averaging 1.1 percent of
gross …scal receipts. From 2009 through 2011, the Fed turned an average of $67.9 billion
over to the Treasury each year, or roughly 2.7 percent of gross …scal receipts. Data for
the Fed’s annual remissions to the Treasury can be found in the annual reports of the
Federal Reserve Board of Governors, available on its website. Though the seigniorage
revenue remitted to the Treasury has been larger in recent years due to the Fed’s increased interest income, partially o¤setting that increased income is the fact that the
Fed, as of 2008, pays banks interest for the reserves they hold. The Federal Reserve
System paid $3.8 billion to banks in 2011 in interest on reserves and term deposits.

R. Haltom and J. A. Weinberg: Unsustainable Fiscal Policy

157

the CBO’s alternative scenario are projected to grow from a low of 5.6
percent of GDP in 2014 to more than 57 percent of GDP by 2085.
Aside from seigniorage, a central bank can reduce the government’s
debt burden by creating in‡ation that was not anticipated by …nancial
markets. In‡ation allows all borrowers, the government included, to
repay loans issued in nominal terms with cheaper dollars than the ones
they borrowed. In the United States, in‡ation tends to be low and predictable from year to year. In‡ation that is higher than expected, and
therefore not priced into the contract interest rate, tends to produce
only a small transfer of wealth from lenders to borrowers. (Indeed, this
is one strong rationale behind the Fed’s price stability objective for
monetary policy.) However, roughly 90 percent of the federal government’s debt is issued in nominal terms at prices that re‡ect the market’s
expectations for in‡ation over the life of the loan. A signi…cant deviation from those expectations would produce a larger transfer of wealth
from lenders to borrowers. Historically, some central banks— though
never the Federal Reserve— have even produced in‡ation for the sole
purpose of eroding the value of the government’s debt.
Today, the central banks of most developed nations operate independently of …scal policy considerations, and none that the authors are
aware of produce in‡ation for the explicit purpose of reducing government debt levels. Between low, stable in‡ation and minimal seigniorage
revenue, the Federal Reserve’s policies generally have little direct impact on the government’s debt burden. (See Box 1 for an overview of
other ways in which …scal and monetary policies interact.) This could
change, however, if …nancial markets began to view hitting the …scal
limit as a possibility. That situation would inevitably invite monetary
policymakers to intervene since in‡ation presents one possible source
of revenue. (See the Appendix for a discussion of ways in which this
pressure could arise in a crisis.)
In fact, economic research suggests that high debt levels ultimately
could overwhelm a central bank’s e¤orts to keep prices stable. The remainder of this essay will argue that these outcomes should be avoided
in the United States by putting …scal policy on a sustainable path.

2.

SOURCES OF FISCAL INFLATION

Even without direct political pressures on the central bank to create
in‡ation, unsustainable …scal policy may be able to force that outcome.
In‡ation is commonly argued to be “always and everywhere a monetary
phenomenon,”a statement re‡ecting the monetarist notion that in the
long run, in‡ation can be created only by the central bank’s actions to
increase the money supply. However, economists Thomas Sargent and

158

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

Neil Wallace (1981) show that the central bank may not have control
over in‡ation in times of …scal crisis. This stems from the idea that the
public has a limited demand, based on its private portfolio preferences,
to hold government debt as a percent of GDP. Sargent and Wallace
model a scenario in which the government has reached that limit on
debt, yet continues to run budget de…cits. If the government is to
avoid default, the central bank has no choice but to produce in‡ation
to reduce debt levels and satisfy the intertemporal budget constraint.
In this scenario, monetary policymakers uncharacteristically focus on
stabilizing debt, while in‡ation is determined by de…cit policy.5
Does this scenario resemble the way monetary and …scal policies are
conducted in the United States? In the Sargent and Wallace framework,
…scal authorities “move …rst”by choosing levels of debt and surpluses,
leaving monetary policymakers to make up for any imbalance. However, the central bank may be able to constrain the actions of …scal
authorities by making the …rst move; that is, by …rmly establishing the
expectation among both …scal authorities and market participants that
it will not step in to reduce debt levels with in‡ation.6 One could argue
that this is the way monetary policy is conducted in the United States,
such that the in‡ationary outcome that Sargent and Wallace describe
need not be a concern. Since the early 1980s, American monetary policy has tended to adjust interest rates fairly predictably in response to
the performance of in‡ation and unemployment.
As a result of this consistent stance in opposition to in‡ation, …nancial markets view the Fed’s in‡ation objectives as highly credible, as
evidenced by anchored in‡ation expectations. The same is true for the
central banks of many other developed nations. Some central banks
even face legally binding price stability mandates, such as the Bank
of England, which must explain its failures to the Chancellor of the
Exchequer, as well as the actions that are being taken to correct them.
The credibility that these central banks have earned is bolstered by
the operational independence most of them have been granted by their
5
Sargent and Wallace label this outcome the “unpleasant monetarist arithmetic”
of chronic …scal de…cits. Variations of this model are presented by Eric Leeper (1991),
Christopher Sims (1994), John Cochrane (1999), and Michael Woodford (2001), among
others.
6
Eric Leeper (1991) describes this as an “active monetary policy/passive …scal policy” framework. An active policy is one that chooses its objectives— surplus or de…cit
levels for …scal policy, or money supply growth for monetary policy— as it sees …t, leaving the “passive” entity to stabilize debt. If monetary policy is “active,” it generally
follows a policy that adjusts interest rates in response to in‡ation. When …scal policy is
active, it pursues the spending and tax policies it desires without necessarily stabilizing
debt. If it chooses large debt levels, it will ultimately determine in‡ation as a result of
Sargent and Wallace’s “unpleasant arithmetic.”

R. Haltom and J. A. Weinberg: Unsustainable Fiscal Policy

159

governments, which insulates monetary policy from pressure to set
aside price stability to temporarily boost the economy.
In practice, however, a central bank’s credibility cannot constrain
…scal policy in any meaningful sense: it cannot stop …scal policymakers
from running budget de…cits that continually expand the debt. As a
result, whether high debt levels would lead to in‡ation depends critically on whether the public believes …scal authorities will balance the
intertemporal budget constraint, or instead leave …scal imbalances to
be addressed by in‡ation. Unfortunately, neither theory nor experience
provides a good rule of thumb for when those expectations might begin
to change, potentially unleashing a …scal crisis, though it is reasonable
to expect that such a shift becomes more likely as projected debt levels
grow ever larger. For example, Eric Leeper (2010) imagines a scenario
in which the federal government is almost at its …scal limit, but …scal
authorities still have some ability to adjust …scal policy to stabilize debt
levels. Being near the …scal limit is enough to enable an equilibrium in
which markets expect the central bank to accommodate the debt with
in‡ation in the future. The public’s expectation of higher in‡ation can
push actual in‡ation higher before the central bank decides to create a
single dollar.7
To emphasize the power of expectations in creating in‡ation, it is
worth noting that a change in expectations also could bring an in‡ationary episode to a quick end. Sargent (1981) looked at the hyperin‡ations experienced by Austria, Hungary, Germany, and Poland after
World War I. Each country …nanced massive government de…cits and
war reparations through sales of government debt to the central bank,
resulting in hyperin‡ation. In each case, hyperin‡ation was brought to
a sudden end through drastic regime changes in both …scal and monetary policies: each nation established an independent central bank that
was legally prohibited from extending credit to the government and
established rules that limited …scal policy to …nancing debt through
private markets. In each case, the regime change credibly convinced
market participants that the central bank would no longer …nance …scal
policy.
The lesson from this literature is that when the public expects …scal authorities to take action to satisfy the budget constraint while
they still can, in‡ation need not rise. This is perhaps the situation
in the United States today: debt projections under the CBO’s more
7
This e¤ect presents an outcome similar to the “unpleasant monetarist
arithmetic”— that chronic …scal de…cits can lead to in‡ation— except that here
in‡ation can arise even without monetary accommodation provided by the central
bank. Accordingly, this branch of literature is called “the …scal theory of the price
level.” Several of the references provided in footnote …ve follow this line of thinking.

160

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

likely scenario exceed historical records for most developed countries,
yet markets appear perfectly willing to purchase government debt at
low interest rates, indicating that in‡ation expectations remain low.
Apparently markets believe …scal imbalances will be resolved through
…scal policy rather than through in‡ation. However, as long as there
is uncertainty over the feasibility of generating su¢ cient future surpluses, policymakers cannot be sure that market expectations will not
shift unexpectedly and produce in‡ation. Leeper (2010) argues that a
way to reduce that uncertainty would be to establish clear rules that
govern …scal policy in times of …scal strain to avoid long-term imbalances, a topic discussed at the end of this essay. In the meantime,
since uncertainty remains over how current …scal imbalances would be
resolved, it is useful to consider the options facing the central bank in
an environment of …scal crisis.

3.

ENCOURAGING SUSTAINABLE POLICY

Credible monetary policy may help postpone the spike in in‡ation expectations that the above literature describes by convincing the public
that the central bank will not quickly or easily agree to erode the debt
through in‡ation. In many developing countries, central banks have a
history of creating large amounts of in‡ation to help governments …nance spending. For countries with that history, …scal imbalances may
more easily lead to a spike in in‡ation. Fortunately, the United States
has no such history. The Fed can preserve its credibility by continuing
to meet its price stability objectives, a task made more complicated in
times of economic turbulence. In the past few years, weak economic
conditions have greatly in‡uenced the policies of the Fed and many
other central banks, while in‡ation has perhaps been less of an immediate concern. It is useful to remember that the Fed’s credibility helps
make policies aimed at supporting real economic growth more e¤ective.
For example, markets remained con…dent in 2008 that the Fed would
act to constrain any in‡ation pressures that emerged, even as the Fed
added extraordinary liquidity to the banking system.
There are additional steps that can be taken to bolster the Fed’s
credibility. Elected leaders could rea¢ rm the central bank’s independence to reassure markets that the Fed will not face political pressure
to erode the debt through in‡ation, similar in spirit to the formal accord struck between the Fed and the Treasury Department in 1951.
(See Appendix.) A formal target for in‡ation, like the one adopted
by the Fed in early 2012, may strengthen the central bank’s perceived
commitment to avoiding in‡ation.

R. Haltom and J. A. Weinberg: Unsustainable Fiscal Policy

161

However, these steps may not be su¢ cient. As research by Sargent
and Wallace and others describes, …scal policy that does not contain
the debt may lead to in‡ation even if monetary policymakers have the
best intentions. This is due to the incontrovertible nature of the government’s intertemporal budget constraint. When the expected path
for …scal policy does not by itself achieve balance in the constraint over
time, the price level is the only other factor that can adjust to provide
it.
It is useful to consider how much in‡ation would be required to
adequately reduce current debt levels. The opening paragraphs of this
essay noted that the historical peak of the U.S. debt-to-GDP ratio was
reached after World War II. Counting only the portion of that debt
that could easily be bought and sold in public markets, George Hall
and Sargent (2011) estimate that it took 30 years for debt to fall from
97.2 to 16.9 as a percent of GDP. They estimate that about 20 percent
of that debt reduction came from in‡ation. (Annual in‡ation, measured
by the Personal Consumption Expenditures Price Index, averaged 3.2
percent over that time period.) To consider how much in‡ation would
be required today to address current debt imbalances, Michael Krause
and Stéphane Moyen (2011) estimate that a moderate rise in in‡ation to
4 percent annually sustained for at least 10 years— in e¤ect a permanent
doubling of the Fed’s in‡ation objective— would reduce the value of
the additional debt that accrued during the 2008–09 …nancial crisis,
not the total debt, by just 25 percent. If the rise in in‡ation lasted
only two or three years, a 16 percentage point increase— from roughly
2 percent in‡ation today to 18 percent— would be required to reduce
that additional debt by just 3 percent to 8 percent. Such in‡ation
rates were not reached even in the worst days of the in‡ationary 1970s.
The reason in‡ation has such a minimal impact on debt in Krause and
Moyen’s estimates is that while in‡ation erodes the value of existing
nominal debt, it increases the …nancing costs for newly issued debt
because investors must be compensated to be willing to hold bonds
that will be subject to higher in‡ation. This e¤ect would be greater
for governments such as the United States that have a short average
maturity of government debt and therefore need to reissue it often.
With these estimates in mind, it is worth recalling the CBO’s projection that debt held by the public may triple as a percent of GDP
within 25 years. The estimates cited above suggest that in‡ation is
simply not a viable strategy for reducing such debt levels. In addition,
it is important to remember that in‡ation is costly on many levels.
In‡ation high enough to signi…cantly erode the debt would in‡ict considerable damage on the economy and would require costly policies
for the Fed to regain its credibility after the fact. In‡ation that was

162

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

engineered speci…cally to erode debt would provide a signi…cant source
of …scal revenue without approval via the democratic process, and so
would raise questions about the role of the central bank as opposed to
the roles of Congress and the executive branch in raising …scal revenues.
Ultimately, the solution to high debt levels must come from …scal authorities. Decades of monetary policy research suggests that
rules and institutions can help ensure that central bankers take a longrun view of their policy objectives, even when doing so entails di¢ cult or unpopular policy choices in the short term. Monetary policymakers have increasingly adopted transparent and consistent practices
that make their policy rules credible and reduce uncertainty over their
priorities.
The same rules-based institutions do not currently exist for …scal
policy. To a degree, this is a matter of necessity: the distributional nature of …scal policy ought to be subject to the approval of the general
public via the political process. However, it may be possible to create better rules for the more objective aspects of …scal policy, a point
argued by Leeper (2010). Just as Congress has agreed to set longrun objectives for the Fed while leaving day-to-day policy choices to
independent monetary policymakers, …scal policymakers could adopt
objective long-run goals for …scal policy— such as appropriate long-run
targets for the ratio of debt to economic growth, guidelines for when
unusual circumstances justify a large increase in debt, and how quickly
…scal imbalances should be resolved in that situation— while leaving
the distributional details to the democratic process.
With that said, guaranteeing that policymakers will remain committed to those rules is di¢ cult in practice.
The recent …scal crisis in Europe provides telling proof. As a precondition to joining the European monetary union, 17 nations agreed
to the Stability and Growth Pact, an agreement obligating each nation
to maintain annual de…cits of less than 3 percent of GDP and overall
debt levels of less than 60 percent of GDP. Even the threat of sanctions
for breaching this agreement was not enough to bind the …scal policies
of many European nations, including ones that have been the focus
of the recent debt crisis and ones currently in relative …scal health. If
everyone knows that there are circumstances under which the rules will
be violated— such as a demographic shift or an unprecedented …nancial
crisis that calls upon national resources— then those rules will fail to
anchor expectations. Though rules may be helpful, they may not be
enough without some mechanism for enforcing them.
Despite the di¢ culties of establishing …scal rules to reduce uncertainty over how …scal imbalances would be resolved, there are encouraging examples from within the United States of …scal policymakers

R. Haltom and J. A. Weinberg: Unsustainable Fiscal Policy

163

adopting a longer-term perspective. Before the Constitution was created, the federal government had no power to levy taxes without unanimous approval from the states. After a period in which both federal and
state debt became signi…cantly devalued, the …scal regime was changed
in 1790 by creating new powers for federal taxation and, as a quid pro
quo, nationalizing state debt. This policy established an unfortunate
precedent for relieving local governments of their debt burdens. Nearly
50 years later, the states again had incurred heavy debts and defaulted
after the recession of the late 1830s. Creditors again looked to the
federal government, but Congress rejected proposals to take on state
debt, arguing that states had entered into debt of their own accord
to …nance local projects. The decision was costly to the federal government. Its reputation su¤ered because international creditors did
not distinguish between state and federal debt, yet the decision forced
states to rewrite their treatment of debt in their constitutions. Many
adopted the balanced-budget amendments they retain today. Sargent
(2011) describes this episode as an example of how …scal crises can lead
to positive institutional changes.
Ultimately, the solution to current …scal imbalances will require
our elected authorities to make di¢ cult decisions. The Fed’s best contribution to this process is to maintain its commitment to monetary
policy objectives, including low and stable in‡ation. For the time being, markets appear to believe that …scal policymakers will put future
debt, spending, and tax levels on a more sustainable path. If they are
correct, our nation will not have to experience the signi…cant economic
challenges of a world in which those expectations have changed.

APPENDIX
The following sections appeared as sidebars in the original article.

1.

THE INTERACTION BETWEEN FISCAL POLICY
AND MONETARY POLICY

Several of the everyday interactions between …scal policy and monetary
policy do not have a large e¤ect on their respective goals to support a
strong economy.
The most direct interaction in the United States is that monetary
policy is conducted in the secondary market for U.S. Treasury securities. The Fed buys treasuries to put money into the banking system

164

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

when it wants to accommodate economic growth, and sells them to remove money and suppress in‡ation. The Fed does not exchange securities directly with the U.S. Treasury, but instead conducts transactions
with private …nancial market participants, which avoids con‡icts of interest that could otherwise arise from this relationship. The Fed also
a¤ects the government’s borrowing costs when it raises interest rates in
times of strong economic growth. Today the Fed’s independence avoids
pressure to make borrowing cheaper for the government, but this was
not always the case.
More fundamentally, both …scal policy and monetary policy a¤ect
the broader economy through the spending and investment decisions
of households and businesses— though neither has a perfect ability to
manage the economy in this way— and as a result their policies can
a¤ect each other’s goals. (This, too, has led to political pressures
throughout the Fed’s history, as discussed in the sidebar.) So the Fed
must consider the e¤ects of current …scal policy when it sets monetary
policy to pursue its goals of price stability and healthy employment.
For example, the Fed must consider how …scal actions are likely to
a¤ect private demand based on how and when people expect those actions to be paid for by increased taxes or future expenditure reductions.
Another possible e¤ect of debt-…nanced …scal stimulus— and another
way in which …scal and monetary policy interact— is that it could put
upward pressure on interest rates in the economy as government borrowing rises.
Finally, as the main essay discusses, …scal policy can have costly
implications for monetary policy in times of …scal crisis.

2.

COULD THE FED'S MONETARY POLICY
INDEPENDENCE WITHSTAND A FISCAL
CRISIS?

On March 4, 1951, the Federal Reserve and the Treasury Department
publicly agreed that the Fed would end its nine-year program in support
of …scal policy. Soon after the United States entered World War II, the
Fed had committed to regularly purchasing enough Treasury debt to
keep the government’s …nancing costs low. The agreement to end that
program became known as the Fed-Treasury accord, and it marked the
end of an era of strong Treasury in‡uence over monetary policy decisions, helping to usher in a new era of Fed independence. The accord
asserted the Fed’s authority to independently determine the size of the
money supply to reach its congressionally established goals, which today include stable prices and healthy employment. This separation

R. Haltom and J. A. Weinberg: Unsustainable Fiscal Policy

165

of authority has been essential to keeping the Fed accountable while
shielding monetary policy from short-term political in‡uence.
The 1951 accord has not completely insulated the Fed from political
intervention, however. Pressures on the Fed often have been motivated
by a short-term interest in economic stimulus, but the Fed also has experienced pressures to place greater weight on price stability, including
recently. Since the 1980s, despite occasional pressures, appreciation
has grown both inside and outside of central banks for monetary policy
independence as the best way to achieve both objectives.
The main essay points to research suggesting that …scal imbalances
can lead to in‡ation. This could occur most directly through explicit
pressure from elected leaders to create in‡ation, but it also could stem
from the central bank’s desire to soothe an economy su¤ering from
…scal crisis.
It is useful to consider the conditions that likely would arise in
…scal crisis. The federal government would face two extreme choices:
defaulting on its debt or enacting some combination of painful spending
cuts and tax increases. The prospect of the …rst option would wreak
havoc in …nancial markets as investors become concerned about the
growing risk associated with U.S. Treasury securities. This e¤ect has
been demonstrated by the unfolding sovereign debt crisis in Europe. In
early 2010, markets began to demand higher yields to hold debt issued
by European governments that sustained large projected debt levels.
The debt of some nations was downgraded by credit rating agencies,
damaging the …nancial position of the many
European banks that hold large amounts of sovereign debt because
the banks were then forced to raise more capital. A similar e¤ect would
arise in a U.S. …scal crisis since Treasury securities are widely held by
…nancial institutions and play an important role in many private market transactions as well. The European Central Bank responded by
purchasing sovereign debt and also accepting that debt as collateral
in loan agreements to banks. (The ECB’s purchases were “sterilized,”
meaning that an equal amount in liquidity was removed from the …nancial system so that the purchases would not add to the overall money
supply.)
The second option facing governments, a combination of sudden
tax increases and broad cuts to services, could cause economic weakness in the short run. Independent of the possible short-run e¤ects
of …scal “austerity,” rational households and businesses are likely to
hold back spending in anticipation of …scal retrenchments even before
such decisions are announced, particularly if there is uncertainty over
the speci…c forms those adjustments would take. Without knowing
whether payroll taxes will be higher in …ve years, a planned government

166

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

investment project will come to fruition, or employer health care costs
will change abruptly, …rms may delay a broad spectrum of spending,
hiring, and investment decisions until those various sources of uncertainty have been resolved. In Europe, too, the uncertain resolution
of …scal imbalances has dampened spending and economic activity.
Though monetary policy cannot resolve this type of uncertainty, it is
clear that both default and extreme …scal retrenchment may threaten
the central bank’s economic objectives.
That is why the dynamics of …scal crisis can create di¢ cult shortterm tradeo¤s for the central bank: the economic pain associated with
…scal crisis versus the longer-term costs of central bank intervention
to reduce debt levels— including the risk of in‡ation, damaged central
bank credibility, and a precedent for rescuing the government from its
debt. At the same time, even the most conservative central banker
might feel compelled to intervene in hopes of limiting a panic before
it could grow more severe, despite the known costs of doing so. (A
related discussion is presented by Je¤rey Lacker, 2011.)
Averting …scal crisis entails making people believe that di¢ cult
…scal policy choices will be made before they are forced by …nancial
markets. Thus, creating that expectation may require …scal constraint
before it seems strictly necessary. Yet because of the di¢ cult and unpopular tradeo¤s required to achieve …scal balance, it may be tempting
for elected o¢ cials to delay action in hopes that monetary policy will
relieve imbalances.
Experience since the 1951 accord and the prospects for how a …scal
crisis could unfold make clear the conditional nature of monetary policy independence. Extreme conditions could stress both the consensus
in support of independence and the central bank’s ability to act independently. While formal agreements like the accord can make overt
political intervention in monetary policy more di¢ cult, such “rules”
cannot ensure that the central bank would escape di¢ cult choices in
times of crisis.

REFERENCES

Cochrane, John H. 1999. “A Frictionless View of U.S. In‡ation.” In
NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1998, edited by Ben S. Bernanke
and Julio J. Rotemberg. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

R. Haltom and J. A. Weinberg: Unsustainable Fiscal Policy

167

Congressional Budget O¢ ce. 2011. “2011 Long-Term Budget
Outlook.”
Fischer, Stanley, Ratna Sahay, and Carlos A. Vegh. 2002. “Modern
Hyper- and High In‡ations.” Journal of Economic Literature 40
(3): 837–80.
Hall, George J., and Thomas J. Sargent. 2011. “Interest Rate Risk
and Other Determinants of Post-WWII US Government
Debt/GDP Dynamics.” American Economic Journal :
Macroeconomics 3 (July): 192–214.
Krause, Michael U., and Stéphane Moyen. 2011. “Public Debt and
Changing In‡ation Targets.” Deutsche Bundesbank (April 29).
Lacker, Je¤rey M. 2011. “Understanding the Interventionist Impulse
of the Modern Central Bank.” Speech to the CATO Institute 29th
Annual Monetary Conference, Washington, D.C. (November 16).
Leeper, Eric M. 1991. “Equilibria Under ‘Active’and ‘Passive’
Monetary and Fiscal Policies.” Journal of Monetary Economics
27: 129–47.
Leeper, Eric M. 2010. “Monetary Science, Fiscal Alchemy.” Paper
presented at the Kansas City Fed Economic Policy Symposium at
Jackson Hole (August).
Malysheva, Nadezhda, and John R. Walter. 2010. “How Large Has
the Federal Financial Safety Net Become?” Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond Economic Quarterly 96 (Third Quarter): 273–90.
Sargent, Thomas J. 1981. “The Ends of Four Big In‡ations.” Federal
Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Working Paper No. 158 (May).
Sargent, Thomas J. 2011. “United States Then, Europe Now.” Nobel
Prize Lecture (December 8).
Sargent, Thomas J., and Neil Wallace. 1981. “Some Unpleasant
Monetarist Arithmetic.” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Quarterly Review 5 (Fall).
Sims, Christopher A. 1994. “A Simple Model for Study of the
Determination of the Price Level and the Interaction of Monetary
and Fiscal Policy.” Economic Theory 4 (3): 381–399.
Woodford, Michael. January 2001. “Fiscal Requirements for Price
Stability.” NBER Working Paper No. 8072.

Economic Quarterly— Volume 101, Number 2— Second Quarter 2015— Pages 169–191

Land of Opportunity:
Economic Mobility in the
United States
Kartik Athreya and Jessie Romero

T

he gap between people in the highest percentiles of earnings
and wealth distributions and the rest of society has grown signi…cantly during the past several decades, a fact that has led to
considerable public discussion about the nature of opportunities available in the United States. Often overlooked in this debate, however, is
the importance of economic mobility— the extent to which people are
able to move up and down the income ladder— in determining what
inequality implies for opportunity. If mobility is high, for example, the
level of inequality at any point in time is not necessarily cause for concern, since it’s possible that today’s poor will be tomorrow’s rich. The
potential for such upward mobility is the foundation of the American
dream that has lured generations of immigrants to the United States.
The dream endures today. Nearly half of Americans aged 18–29
believe they will become rich at some point in their lifetimes, according
to a 2012 Gallup Poll. But the odds are against them: In 2010 (the most
recent year for which the Internal Revenue Service has published data),
only about 5 percent of U.S. households earned more than $150,000 per
year, and about 1 percent earned more than $350,000 per year. (See
Figure 1). Most of those people, moreover, were not born to poor
parents— especially not in recent years.
Understanding economic mobility is essential to understanding how
observed levels and patterns of economic inequality relate to the implicit promise of American life. But this is complicated. Mobility and
The authors would like to thank Huberto Ennis, Arantxa Jarque, Marianna
Kudlyak, Karl Rhodes, and Aaron Steelman for valuable discussions and insights.
The views expressed are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.

170

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

Figure 1 Thresholds for Selected Income Percentiles

Source: Internal Revenue Service.
Notes: An “income percentile threshold” is the lowest amount earned by a household in that percentile. Income is “adjusted gross income,” which is income minus
certain deductions. Amounts are in current dollars.

inequality are determined jointly by random chance, by policy, and—
most confounding of all for social scientists— by the deliberate actions
of individuals or their parents. Regarding the latter determinant, it is
clear that people di¤er according to their aptitude for various tasks,
their appetite for risk, and their preferences for work versus leisure,
among other characteristics. Both mobility and inequality thus will
arise at least in part because di¤erent people make di¤erent choices.
(See Appendix.)
This reality creates a challenge for economists seeking to understand the sources of observed levels of mobility and inequality, and for
policymakers who hope to in‡uence those levels. If everyone has the
same opportunities for movement, then di¤erences in income, wealth,
or education must at least partially re‡ect deliberate choices and not
market structure. This is not a setting in which many people would …nd
e¤orts to alter outcomes via policy compelling. In contrast, to the extent that inequality continues across generations because people do not
have the same chances, then inequality and immobility can be partially
chalked up to market structure. From a normative standpoint, there

K. Athreya and J. Romero: Economic Mobility in the U.S.

171

thus might be support for policy interventions that seek to equalize
opportunities, rather than those that would equalize outcomes.
One such intervention is greater investment in early education.
High-quality early-childhood education equips children with the skills
they need to succeed at each subsequent stage of life, yet in the United
States, access to such education appears to strongly depend on parents’income. Children of poor parents are thus at a disadvantage from
the very beginning— a disadvantage from which it is very di¢ cult to
recover. But these children are not the only ones who are a¤ected; all
else equal, a more skilled workforce increases the productivity of society
as a whole. Enhancing early education opportunities for the initially
disadvantaged could therefore lead to better economic outcomes for
everyone.
This essay will review both recent and longer-run features of U.S.
economic mobility, with a focus on how those trends a¤ect the interpretation of data on income inequality. It then will discuss some of the
challenges and choices facing policymakers seeking to alter observed
outcomes.

1.

INEQUALITY IN THE UNITED STATES

By nearly any measure, income inequality in the United States is increasing.1 In particular, today’s rich are both richer than their counterparts in the past and richer relative to those around them. In 1979,
the top 1 percent of households took home 7.4 percent of total aftertax income in the United States. By 2007, the share had more than
doubled to 16.7 percent (Congressional Budget O¢ ce 2011).2 At the
same time, the share of income earned by households at all levels of
the remaining distribution stayed ‡at or declined. Those in the middle
three quintiles (…fths), for example, saw their share decrease from 51
percent to 43.9 percent. The picture looks the same for pretax income;
the share accruing to the top 1 percent rose from 8.9 percent to 18.7
1
Economists also study consumption inequality, or di¤erences in the amounts of
goods and services that households purchase. Consumption inequality might di¤er from
income inequality because of savings, taxes, or in-kind bene…ts such as food stamps.
Some recent research suggests consumption inequality is much less pronounced than income inequality (e.g., Meyer and Sullivan [2013]), although other research …nds that
the trends in income and consumption inequality are very similar (e.g., Aguiar and Bils
[2011]).
2
The CBO de…nes after-tax income as market income (labor income, business income, capital gains, capital income, and other income) plus government transfers (such
as Social Security payments, unemployment bene…ts, or in-kind transfers such as food
stamps) minus taxes paid.

172

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

Figure 2 Income Distribution by Quintiles

Source: Congressional Budget O¢ ce.
Notes: Quintiles are displayed on the left scale; the top 1 percent is displayed
on the right scale. After-tax income is de…ned as market income (labor income,
business income, capital gains, capital income, and other income) net of transfer
payments and taxes.

percent (Congressional Budget O¢ ce 2011).3 These changes are a result both of increasing concentration of all types of income at the top
of the distribution and a shift in the composition of income toward
business income and capital gains (Congressional Budget O¢ ce 2011).
This compositional change also makes incomes at the top of the distribution more volatile, but the trend is clearly one of growing inequality.
(See Figure 2.)
Other research shows similar trends. Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez (2003) …nd that after remaining ‡at throughout the 1950s
and 1960s, the share of pretax income earned by the top 10 percent
of households increased from 31.5 percent in 1970 to 41.4 percent in
1998.4 As in the CBO’s analysis, this increase was largely driven by
those at the very top of the distribution. While the income share for
those in the 90th through 99th percentiles increased from 23.7 percent
to 26.9 percent, the share for those in the very top percentile nearly
doubled, from 7.8 percent to 14.6 percent.5
3
Data
are
from
the
supplemental
data
tables
posted
at
www.cbo.gov/publication/43373.
4
In Piketty and Saez (2003), the unit of analysis is a tax unit, de…ned as two
married people living together (with or without dependents) or a single adult (with or
without dependents). Their income measure excludes capital gains.
5
Updated data are available at elsa.berkeley.edu/~saez/TabFig2011prel.xls.

K. Athreya and J. Romero: Economic Mobility in the U.S.

173

The trend continued after the 2007–09 recession. Although average
real income for the top 1 percent fell about three times more than for
the remaining 99 percent, the decline was almost entirely due to the
stock market crash. As markets recovered in 2010, incomes for the top
1 percent increased 11.6 percent, compared to only 0.2 percent for all
other households (Saez 2013).
Income shares for the 90th–99th percentiles and the top 1 percent
continued to increase, to 29.1 percent and 17.4 percent, respectively, in
2011 (Piketty and Saez 2003, updated data).
These data have garnered a great deal of attention from economists,
policymakers, and the public, but do they shed light on what is actually
happening to individuals or households?

2.

MOBILITY: A CENTRAL FORCE BEHIND
INEQUALITY

An observation of inequality at any point in time is only a snapshot;
it does not shed light on how that snapshot developed. For example,
imagine three di¤erent worlds: In the …rst world, the …rst inhabitants
‡ip coins to determine not only their income, but also the income of
all future generations; each descendant earns either $1,000 or $100,000
per year, depending on his ancestor’s original coin toss. In the second
world, the members of each new generation ‡ip coins, but they do
so just once at birth to determine whether they will earn $1,000 or
$100,000 per year during their lifetimes. In the third world, individuals
get to ‡ip a coin each year to determine their income for that year.
The people in these worlds face very di¤erent lifetime risks. The
…rst world, which is akin to a caste system, is very risky from the
perspective of the …rst ancestor, who is determining outcomes for an
entire dynasty. The second world also is risky since the die is cast for
one person’s entire life, but each of her descendants gets a chance to
‡ip the coin, making it unlikely that bad luck will persist across many
generations. The third environment is the least risky since it is very
unlikely that an individual’s average annual income over his lifetime
would be signi…cantly di¤erent than $50,500, the average annual income
he can expect over many years.
Despite these di¤erences, snapshots of these economies in any given
year look the same. In each, about half the population earns $1,000
per year, while the other half earns $100,000. Clearly, then, inequality
data alone do not reveal the underlying prospects of individuals. For
this, one must study economic mobility.

174

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

3.

TRENDS IN ECONOMIC MOBILITY

Economists and policymakers generally are interested in two types of
mobility: intragenerational and intergenerational. Intragenerational
mobility describes how a given person’s economic status changes over
the course of his lifetime. Intergenerational mobility re‡ects the degree to which a person’s economic status as an adult di¤ers from that
of her parents or ancestors. Status is usually measured by earnings
(wage income), income (all sources of income, including wages), or less
frequently wealth (the value of assets minus liabilities). Most research
focuses on relative intra- and intergenerational mobility, or how a person’s status changes in comparison to others. But it is also important
to recognize that a person might experience absolute mobility even in
the absence of relative mobility. She might occupy the same place in
the earnings distribution as her parents, remaining in the same position
relative to the rest of society, but still have a higher standard of living
than her parents did, depending on the rate of economic growth.6

Intragenerational Earnings Mobility
Does the top of the income distribution comprise the same people year
in and year out, or do individuals ‡ow in and out of the highest percentiles over their lifetimes? If intragenerational mobility is high, then
any snapshot of inequality will overstate the actual long-term inequality among individuals. For example, it is possible that the large gap
in recent years between those in the top percentile and the rest of the
distribution re‡ects an increase in the variation of annual earnings due
to stock options and large bonuses. If that were the case, short-term inequality might be high, but long-term inequality could be much lower,
re‡ecting high mobility.
In addition, in most modern societies, there is a clear life-cycle pattern to earnings and income. Imagine an extreme case where half the
population earns $1,000 during the …rst half of their lives and $100,000
during the second half, while the other half of the population earns
$100,000 early in life and $1,000 later. Income inequality would be
high at a point in time, but everybody has the same lifetime income.
Assuming that individuals could save and borrow to smooth their consumption over time, the snapshot of income inequality might not accurately re‡ect people’s well-being since consumption inequality— a truer,
and harder to measure, barometer— would be relatively low.
6

For example, see Easterlin (2000).

K. Athreya and J. Romero: Economic Mobility in the U.S.

175

Anthony Shorrocks (1978) formalized these ideas by developing an
index in which mobility is de…ned as the extent to which income inequality decreases over a given timeframe. Wojciech Kopczuk, Emmanuel Saez, and Jae Song (2010) calculate Shorrocks indices comparing inequality in annual earnings and in earnings averaged over …ve
years for workers between 1937 and 2004. They …nd that short-term
(…ve-year) mobility has not changed over the period, which implies that
greater volatility of short-term earnings is not the source of observed
higher inequality. Instead, higher inequality is likely the result of increased variation in lifetime earnings, including higher earnings at the
top of the distribution. The authors conclude that mobility has not
been su¢ cient to o¤set the rise in inequality, and thus that short-term
inequality likely re‡ects lifetime inequality.
Kopczuk, Saez, and Song (2010) also …nd that long-term income
mobility, from the beginning to the end of working life, actually increased signi…cantly for all workers between 1942 and 1999. There is
signi…cant heterogeneity among groups of workers, however. Although
on average men are more upwardly mobile than women, men’s mobility
was stable or declining during the sample period. Women’s mobility,
however, has increased greatly since the 1960s, as more women have
moved into higher-paying professions. Thus, the increase in mobility for
all workers has been driven by the labor market experiences of women.
Heterogeneity in intragenerational mobility also is apparent across
the income distribution. Gerald Auten, Geo¤rey Gee, and Nicholas
Turner (2013) …nd that about 75 percent of taxpayers aged 35–40 who
were in the second, third, or fourth quintile in 1987 were in a di¤erent
quintile in 2007. (About 60 percent of those who changed position
moved up or down a single quintile.) But they …nd greater persistence
at the top and bottom of the distribution: 43 percent of taxpayers in
the bottom quintile were still there 20 years later, and 46 percent of
taxpayers in the top quintile maintained their positions. The authors
also …nd that the very top earners tended to remain top earners: From
1992 through 2006, between 60 percent and 70 percent of the top 1
percent in a given year were in the top 1 percent in the following year.

Intergenerational Mobility
A commonly used measure of intergenerational mobility is the intergenerational elasticity of earnings (IGE). The IGE describes in percentage
terms how much of the di¤erence between the earnings of families in
one generation persists into the next generation, typically by comparing the correlation of the earnings of fathers and sons. For example, an
IGE of 0.5 means that a 10 percent di¤erence between the income of

176

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

two fathers translates into a 5 percent di¤erence in the income of their
sons. The smaller the IGE, the greater the amount of mobility.
Important early studies of the United States and other developed
countries found a high degree of mobility, with an IGE of 0.2 or less
(Becker and Tomes 1986). Later research, however, found that data
used in this work featured biases that would lead to arti…cially low
measurements of the true level of earnings persistence. (See Stokey
[1996] for a review of this research.)
New and better data suggest that mobility in the United States has
been historically lower than initial estimates implied, and that it has
declined even further in recent decades. Daniel Aaronson and Bhashkar
Mazumder (2008) construct a time series of intergenerational elasticity
from 1950 to 2000. They …nd that mobility increased between 1950 and
1980— the IGE decreased from 0.40 to 0.32— but decreased signi…cantly
during the 1980s and 1990s, with the IGE reaching 0.58 by 2000.
Although exact international comparisons are not possible, most
research suggests that people in the United States are somewhat less
mobile than people in Canada, Denmark, Finland, and Norway, where
the IGE is about 0.15 to 0.2. In Germany and Switzerland, the IGE
is about 0.3, and people in the United Kingdom and France also are
relatively immobile, with IGEs of about 0.4 to 0.5 (Corak 2006).
While the IGE is a widely used statistic in work on intergenerational
mobility, it only re‡ects average mobility across the entire distribution
of individuals; it does not reveal anything about the direction of mobility or how it varies across di¤erent groups. To learn more about such
mobility, Mazumder (2008) calculates transition rates, the likelihood
of moving from one point in the distribution to another, across generations. He …nds that, as with intragenerational measures, the amount of
mobility varies signi…cantly according to income. For example, there is
a great deal of “stickiness” at the top and bottom of the distribution;
people whose parents are in the bottom quintile of income are more
likely to be in the bottom quintile themselves, and those whose parents
are in the top quintile are likely to remain there. More than 60 percent
of children whose parents are in the bottom quintile will end up in the
bottom or second quintile, compared to 23.3 percent of those whose
parents are in the top quintile. Only 7.4 percent of people who reach
the top quintile are from families in the bottom quintile. (See Figure 3.)
There also are stark di¤erences between black people and white people
and between men and women. Whites appear to be more upwardly mobile and less downwardly mobile than blacks. Mazumder (2008) …nds
that about 24.9 percent of whites remain in the bottom quintile, compared to 43.7 percent of blacks. And 38.9 percent of whites remain in
the top quintile, compared to 21.3 percent of blacks. In addition, more

K. Athreya and J. Romero: Economic Mobility in the U.S.

177

Figure 3 Intergenerational Income Quintile Transition Rates

Source: Mazumder (2008).
Notes: The …gure shows what percentages of adolescents from families in a given
income quintile remained in that quintile or transitioned to a di¤erent quintile
as adults. For example, 33.5 percent of adolescents from families in the bottom
quintile remained in the bottom quintile, while 26.9 percent moved to the second
quintile. Income data were gathered from 1979 through 1980 and again from 1997
through 2003.

than twice as many whites as blacks experience the “rags-to-riches”
scenario of moving from the bottom quintile to the top quintile, 10.6
percent compared to 4.1 percent. Mazumder also …nds a large gender
gap. While 40.5 percent of women from families in the lowest quintile
remain there, only 27.2 percent of men do. Conversely, 43.0 percent of
men from families in the top quintile remain in that quintile, compared
to 31.9 percent of women. Men are thus more upwardly mobile and
less downwardly mobile than women. The gender gap is trumped by
the race gap, however: Both black men and black women tend to be
the most likely to remain in the bottom quintile and the most likely to
fall out of the top quintile.7
7

Isaacs (2008) …nds similar di¤erences in black and white mobility.

178

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

Mobility of Immigrants
For centuries, the American dream has drawn immigrants to the United
States, from the waves of German and Irish immigrants in the late 1800s
to the nearly 12 million Mexican immigrants who arrived during the
past four decades.8 But how likely is it that the dream becomes a
reality?
Decennial census data indicate that immigrants’earnings increase
rapidly after they arrive in the United States; the earnings gap between
them and their native-born peers appears to shrink substantially over
time. Comparing natives and immigrants with similar work experience,
Darren Lubotsky (2007) …nds that the positive earnings gap between
natives and the cohort of immigrants who came to the United States
between 1965 and 1969 fell from 38 percent in the 1970 Census to 16
percent in the 1980 Census, and vanished by the 1990 Census. The
gap between natives and immigrants who arrived in the late 1980s
fell from 55 percent to 36 percent between the 1990 and 2000 censuses. This mobility might be spurious, however. Up to one-third of
immigrants eventually return to their home countries; if these immigrants tend to be those with lower earnings, then the apparent earnings
growth actually re‡ects fewer low earners in the data pool. Lubotsky
(2007) corrects for this “selective out-migration” by studying longitudinal rather than cross-sectional data, and …nds that earnings growth
is signi…cantly lower. In the cross-sectional data, immigrants’relative
earnings increase 20 percent during their …rst decade in the United
States and an additional 10 percent to 20 percent in each following
decade. In the longitudinal data, however, immigrants’earnings grow
between 12 percent and 15 percent during their …rst 15 years in the
country and then stagnate.
The mobility of the second generation also appears to be decreasing. Throughout the 20th century, the children of immigrants not only
earned more than their parents, but they also earned more on average
than the rest of the non-immigrant population, perhaps re‡ecting some
of the selection e¤ects Lubotsky (2007) observed. But that advantage
is shrinking. In 1940, the second generation earned 17.8 percent more
than non-immigrants on average. In 1970, the di¤erence was 14.6 percent, and by 2000, the di¤erence had fallen to 6.3 percent (Borjas 2006).
The reason might be a shift in the composition of immigrants. There
has long been signi…cant heterogeneity in earnings among immigrant
8
The number includes undocumented immigrants. Since the 2007–09 recession, net
migration from Mexico has fallen to virtually zero. Between 2007 and 2011, the number
of undocumented Mexican immigrants in the United States declined by about 1 million
(Passel, Cohn, and Gonzalez-Barrera 2012).

K. Athreya and J. Romero: Economic Mobility in the U.S.

179

groups, and in recent times, immigrants from developed countries tend
to earn more than those from developing countries. Immigrants from
Germany earned 24.9 percent more than non-immigrants in 1970 and
their children earned 19.5 percent more in 2000, for example, while
those from Mexico earned 31.6 percent less in 1970 and their children
earned 14.6 percent less in 2000 (Borjas 2006).9 While wages in the
second generation tend to regress toward the mean, overall earnings
show signi…cant persistence into the second generation. Borjas (2006)
…nds that across all immigrant groups, the intergenerational elasticity
over the period 1970 to 2000 is 0.43. As the composition of immigrants increasingly shifts toward people from less-developed countries,
who tend to have lower skills and levels of education, the wage gap is
likely to persist through successive generations of immigrants (Haskins 2008).10 Irrespective of how quickly immigrants’earnings approach
the earnings of natives, many immigrants still improve their economic
status signi…cantly by immigrating to the United States. In this sense,
the move to the United States is a powerful form of economic mobility,
and the United States’absorption of both legal and illegal immigrants
makes it an engine of global mobility.
This last point must be part of any meaningful assessment of the
mobility o¤ered by a society. Even a calci…ed society, in which intergenerational or intragenerational mobility of natives is low, may be a
source of mobility for the world’s residents via its openness to immigrants. Conversely, societies that promote intergenerational mobility of
natives through intensive early intervention and generous social safety
nets but limit entry of immigrants— perhaps out of fear that they will
exploit the generous safety nets— might hinder equality of opportunity
in a global sense.11

4.

WHAT GENERATES PERSISTENCE?

The preceding discussion has highlighted empirical …ndings on the persistence of economic outcomes both within and across generations.
But these …ndings do not explain why persistence across generations
9
Because the ‡ow of immigrants from Mexico has been substantially greater than
the ‡ow from developed countries, the average wage of …rst-generation immigrants is
still lower than the average wage of their native-born peers.
10
Immigrant mobility matters not only for the prospects of the immigrants themselves, but also for measured inequality in society as a whole. Imagine a room in which
everyone is six feet tall. If a group of shorter people enter the room, measured inequality in height will increase. In the context of immigration, the arrival of a group with
wealth, skills, or education signi…cantly di¤erent from those of natives can mechanically
increase inequality at a point in time.
11
See, for example, Pritchett (2006).

180

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

exists in the …rst place or why it might have increased.
As
Aaronson and Mazumder (2008) note, intergenerational elasticities do
not re‡ect causality. Instead, measures like the IGE are simply omnibus
measures of everything correlated with parents’income and children’s
future earnings— factors ranging from the neighborhood where a child
grew up to the availability of health care, among many others.
Intuitively, parents’decisions to invest in developing their children’s
skills, or “human capital,” are important. Their willingness to make
such investments stems in large part from altruistic concern for their
children.12 One model that incorporates this dynamic was created by
Gary Solon (2004). He relates this investment decision to the rate
of return to human capital and to the progressivity of public investment in children’s human capital, such as government provision of education and health care. Solon’s model suggests several things: that
higher-income parents invest more in their children’s human capital,
that more progressive public investment in children’s human capital
partially crowds out parents’investment, and that parents are likely to
invest more when the returns to human capital increase. The model
predicts that intergenerational mobility will decrease during a period
of increasing returns to human capital because rich parents are able to
invest more than poor parents, and that mobility will increase during
a period of more progressive public investment.
Recent trends in intergenerational mobility do correspond to Solon’s
predictions (Mazumder 2012). The returns to college education dropped
during the 1940s, remained steady for several decades, and then began
rising around 1980. These turning points in the returns to college education match the turning points in intergenerational elasticity observed
in Aaronson and Mazumder (2008), as well as in other studies of mobility trends.
In Solon’s (2004) model, the degree of progressivity of public education is exogenous— that is, determined outside the model. Andrea
Ichino, Loukas Karabarbounis, and Enrico Moretti (2011) develop a
model in which the degree of progressivity is the outcome of sociopolitical forces. In their model, public education is an insurance system
that increases the future income of children without much innate talent
at the expense of the future income of children with high innate talent.
Public education thus increases mobility. But currently rich dynasties
prefer low mobility for their descendants (as will be discussed in more
detail in the following section), so in countries where rich dynasties are
more politically active, spending on public education will be lower.
12

For a thorough treatment, see Mulligan (1997).

K. Athreya and J. Romero: Economic Mobility in the U.S.

181

In the United States, spending on public education mostly begins
with kindergarten. But children face di¤erences even before they begin school that may determine their future success. Mazumder (2008)
…nds that educational attainment alone is not enough to explain different mobility rates among black and white children. Black and white
people who have completed the same number of years of school still
have di¤erent intergenerational mobility rates, particularly at the level
of high school completion and below. Other research also has found
that educational attainment can explain less than half of the intergenerational transmission of earnings (Bowles, Gintis, and Groves 2008).
What this research implies is that human capital embodies more
than the number of years spent in school. For example, adolescents
who score higher on the Armed Forces Qualifying Test (AFQT) are
more likely to move out of the bottom income quintile, and di¤erences
in AFQT scores can explain nearly all of the black/white mobility gap
(Mazumder 2008).13 These test scores, however, capture much more
than innate intelligence or academic achievment; non-cognitive skills
such as work ethic, the ability to follow instructions, motivation, and
patience also are essential to success on such standardized tests (Bowles,
Gintis, and Groves 2008; Heckman 2008). In fact, these non-cognitive
skills may be just as important as cognitive skills in determining future
success in the labor market. For example, the General Educational
Development (GED) credential is supposed to demonstrate cognitive
equivalence between people who have graduated from high school and
people who have dropped out and taken the GED exam instead. But
GED holders have much poorer labor market outcomes than high school
graduates despite obtaining equivalent knowledge. The reason, James
Heckman and other economists have concluded, is that many students
who earn a GED lack the non-cognitive skills that would have enabled
them to complete high school— the same skills that would help them
succeed in the labor market (Heckman, Humphries, and Mader 2010).
Recognizing the importance of non-cognitive skills begs an important question: How do children acquire these skills? A consensus now
exists that the foundation is laid very early in life, even from infancy.
Skill development is hierarchical; the early mastery of basic emotional,
social, and other non-cognitive skills makes it easier to learn more complex cognitive skills throughout life. And children who fall behind early
have di¢ culty catching up. Gaps in cognitive skills that are important
13
The AFQT is administered by the military to determine quali…cation for enlistment. AFQT scores have been widely used by economists as a measure of pre-labor
market skills.

182

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

for adult outcomes are present as early as age 5 and tend to persist
into adulthood (Heckman 2008).
The data suggest that poor and minority children are much more
likely to fall behind. A recent report from the Brookings Institution
(Sawhill, Winship, and Grannis 2012) examines the likelihood of achieving certain social and economic milestones on the path to the middle
class, de…ned in the report as having a family income at least 300 percent of the poverty level, or about $70,000 for a married couple with
two children. Only 48 percent of children from families in the bottom
income quintile are ready for school at age 5, compared to 78 percent
of children from families in the top quintile.14 There also is a large
disparity in early childhood outcomes according to race. Sixty-eight
percent of white children are ready for school at age 5, versus only 56
percent of black children and 61 percent of Hispanic children. The gap
between white and black widens throughout the lifespan. By age 11,
73 percent of white children versus 52 percent of black children have
basic reading and math skills. By age 29, only 33 percent of black people have successfully transitioned to adulthood (de…ned by the authors
as living independently and having either a college degree or a family
income at least 250 percent of the poverty level), while 68 percent of
white people reach this milestone. Hispanic people fare somewhat better; 66 percent achieve the age-11 milestone, and 47 percent reach the
age-29 milestone.

5.

CHALLENGES FOR POLICYMAKERS

What is the role for public policy, if any, in addressing economic inequality and mobility? Answering this question requires asking several
others: What would policy try to achieve, and in particular, whose
well-being would it attempt to enhance? Would the goal be to improve
opportunities for current cohorts or for future generations? Would policy treat individuals at di¤erent moments in time as discrete units,
irrespective of their ancestors, or would it emphasize dynasties by taking into account how family members invest in descendants?
From a policymaker’s point of view, mobility might be inadequate
as a measure of what a good society should provide its members. First
of all, there is a tradeo¤ between mobility and predictability. Recall
the imaginary world resembling a caste system described earlier. This
setting is utterly immobile and risky for each dynasty’s …rst member.
But it is perfectly safe for the members of each successive generation
14
The authors de…ne “school-ready” as having acceptable pre-reading and math
skills and behavior that is generally school-appropriate.

K. Athreya and J. Romero: Economic Mobility in the U.S.

183

since income is completely stable. In fact, for a person whose ancestor
‡ipped the $100,000 coin, this world is not only safe, but also quite
comfortable. On the macro level, it is possible that the costs of large
‡uctuations and risky income patterns outweigh the bene…ts of high
mobility and reduced inequality. Peter Gottschalk and Enrico Spolaore (2002) study a model in which there are large welfare gains from
greater mobility if aversion to inequality is the only consideration. But
if aversion to income ‡uctuations is considered, those gains disappear.
Of course, this might not be of great consolation to a person whose
ancestor ‡ipped the $1,000 coin.
In addition, a world in which mobility is high is one where parents
are of little consequence, despite their desire or ability to position their
children and grandchildren for future success. Few parents would want
to live in a world where their investments in their children have no
in‡uence beyond their lifetimes. The ‡ip side is that descendants of
people who were not altruistic or who made poor decisions would not
be as constrained by their ancestors’actions.
Viewed in this light, what most people might agree on is trying
to promote individual productivity while limiting downward mobility.
Broadly speaking, the former goal involves ensuring preparedness at labor market entry, while the latter involves insuring households against
low innate abilities, poor health, or job loss. Knowing the extent to
which these forces matter is crucial for policy interventions to be effective. For example, if workers were similarly prepared at the time
of entry into the labor market, and shocks in working life were important, the question would be how, if at all, to better insure workers,
and not how to alter educational investment decisions. Conversely, if
preparedness di¤ered and shocks during working life were unimportant,
further insuring workers would yield little bene…t. Instead, changes to
the educational system would be more e¤ective.
Both factors are important, according to a recent line of work exempli…ed by Mark Huggett, Gustavo Ventura, and Amir Yaron (2011).
They …nd that about 60 percent of the observed disparity in lifetime
earnings is due to individual di¤erences that exist before people enter the labor market, and the remainder is due to shocks that bu¤et
them as they work, such as job losses. Their research stresses that the
observed evolution of earnings inequality over lifetimes is consistent
with a simple setting in which all workers accumulate skills through
experience and e¤ort, but do so at substantially di¤erent rates that re‡ect their initial “learning” ability. At the same time, their estimates
clearly indicate that a substantial portion of inequality is generated
during working life. This suggests that shocks to earnings are essential
to a successful theory of earnings dispersion in the economy.

184

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

A critical point here is that the disparity in learning ability likely
arises not only from di¤erences in innate ability, but also from forces
such as the quality of K-12 education and parental and cultural in‡uences. These forces are very di¤erent for children from poor versus rich
families— a dynamic that is magni…ed by a labor market that demands
increasing levels of skill.

6.

INVESTING IN HUMAN CAPITAL

For most people— all but a lucky few— labor is what they can sell to
generate income. They can increase the value of their labor by acquiring
greater skills, but the value of their labor is only partially under their
control. It also depends on the supply and demand for their skills in
the marketplace.
The industrial revolution, for example, created factories that made
workers more productive and more valuable without substantially increasing their skills. But the information revolution has created a
marketplace that rewards personally acquired skills, such as computer
programming or mathematical analysis. In this new environment, an
individual’s innate ability and early life education become critical because they largely determine the levels of skills each person can develop
to “rent” to the marketplace.
Given the large earnings gap between workers with and without
college degrees, many policies aim to increase college access, for example by increasing federal subsidies for student loans. But it’s not
clear that college is the best focus for policymakers. The observed disparity between high school and college graduates applies to students
who have graduated from college already; those students who have not
yet enrolled might not necessarily receive the same bene…t, perhaps
because they are not as well prepared. For example, Lutz Hendricks
and Oksana Leukhina (2012) …nd in preliminary work that about 70
percent of the lifetime earnings gap between high school and college
graduates results from ability selection rather than from attaining the
college degree per se. In other words, the college graduates were likely
to be better earners even before entering college.
Intervening well before college could yield much higher returns. As
noted above, the skills learned early in life prepare children to obtain
more complex skills later in life. Heckman and many other researchers
have found that the return on a dollar invested in human capital is
highest when the investment occurs at age 3, and that children who
receive high quality early education fare much better on a variety of
socioeconomic measures (Heckman 2008).

K. Athreya and J. Romero: Economic Mobility in the U.S.

185

The most cost-e¤ective policy for increasing equality of opportunity
is thus likely to be one that shifts funding away from universal college
subsidies and toward early childhood interventions. Elizabeth Caucutt
and Krishna Kumar (2003) …nd that a large increase in college subsidies
with the goal of reducing the “enrollment gap”leads to very ine¢ cient
use of education resources, with little or no welfare gain, because more
poorly prepared students enroll and the dropout rate increases. In a
model of human capital transmission in which parents invest in their
children, Diego Restuccia and Carlos Urrutia (2004) …nd that subsidies
for investment in early education are much more e¤ective at mitigating
persistence in earnings than subsidies for college.
Investments in early childhood education can be viewed as a form of
insurance against the risk of being born to poor parents, among other
things. And while the public provision of such insurance could yield a
big “bang for the buck”by enabling current generations to invest more
in the education of future generations, one must also acknowledge the
potential for moral hazard. A public system that equalizes the educational opportunities (or far more ambitiously, the home environments)
of poor and rich children could reduce the incentives of all parents to
invest in children.15
Greater public investment in early childhood education cannot replace the advantages that some parents are able to bestow upon their
children, nor can it guarantee that all children will grow up to be
prosperous. But such investments could give more children the necessary foundation for future acquisition of skills, and ensure that large
amounts of human capital are not foregone simply because many children are born to poor families. This foregone human capital is a loss
not only for the child, but also for society as a whole. According to an
in‡uential line of research, long-run economic growth depends on the
amount of human capital in a society.16 Unlike physical capital, which
exhibits decreasing returns to scale, human capital might well exhibit
increasing returns. Knowledge leads to new ideas and new technologies, which lead to higher productivity, thus raising per capita income
and living standards for society as a whole.
As this essay has discussed, economic inequality has increased signi…cantly in the United States in recent years. At the same time,
data suggest that economic mobility also has decreased, particularly
for those born at the top and the bottom of the income distribution.
15
See Chang and Kim (2012) and Seshadri and Yuki (2004) for more on the “price
of egalitarianism.”
16
In‡uential papers on “endogenous growth theory” include Romer (1986) and
Lucas (1988).

186

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

Many factors contribute to the attainment and persistence of economic
status, including innate ability, preferences for present versus future
rewards, aversion to risk, and quite a bit of luck. But for nearly all
people, advancement depends critically on opportunities to obtain human capital— and those opportunities are not the same for children
born to poor versus rich families. Policies that aim to equalize these
opportunities, particularly very early in life, appear to yield a very high
return on investment, although much remains to be learned about the
feasibility of implementing such interventions on a large scale. Nonetheless, such e¤orts have the potential to help the United States achieve a
more inclusive prosperity.

APPENDIX
The following section appeared as a sidebar in the original article.

1.

THE ROLE OF CHOICE

Inequality and immobility partially re‡ect deliberate choices related to
the fact that people di¤er in their tolerance for risk or in their willingness to defer grati…cation (what economists call “time discounting”).
But these di¤erences cannot be directly observed. Instead, economists
must make inferences based on actual outcomes, such as occupational
choice, savings, and consumption.
Risk tolerance has a large impact on occupational choice, and thus
on income and wealth. Beginning with Frank Knight’s Risk, Uncertainty, and Pro…t (1921) and continuing in modern work since Richard
Kihlstrom and Jean-Jacques La¤ont (1979), economists have modeled
entrepreneurs as less risk averse than other people and therefore more
likely to undertake high-risk/high-return enterprises. To the extent
that people genuinely vary in risk aversion, this model suggests that
the rich and the poor disproportionately will be those with high risk
tolerance, while those in the middle will be more risk averse. This
is consistent with data that show a disproportionate number of selfemployed people at both ends of the earnings and wealth spectrums.
They also …gure more prominently among households in …nancial distress (Sullivan, Warren, and Westbrook 2000).
Additional evidence for the role of risk tolerance in personal economic outcomes comes from Sam Schulhofer-Wohl (2011), who …nds
that risk-tolerant workers tend to have jobs more exposed to

K. Athreya and J. Romero: Economic Mobility in the U.S.

187

economy-wide or “aggregate” risk. Movements in these workers’ incomes thus tend to be more volatile even when they have insured
themselves against individual-level, or “idiosyncratic,” risks, such as
job loss or illness. As a result, volatility in their consumption of goods
and services is not necessarily evidence of poor insurance possibilities
in the marketplace. Indeed, Schulhofer-Wohl (2012) …nds that after
correcting for this bias, U.S. households do not appear to be bearing
any signi…cant uninsurable risk. (A variety of other research, however,
has found that certain types of shocks, such as a long-term disability,
are clearly not fully insured.)
Observed inequality also might re‡ect di¤erent preferences for consumption in the present versus the future. Per Krusell and Anthony
Smith (1998) show, for example, that a model that includes variation in
“impatience,”or the willingness of households to borrow against future
earnings, successfully matches observed wealth inequality in the U.S.
population. Emily Lawrance (1991) and Marco Cagetti (2003) also
…nd that data on consumption and wealth suggest the presence of signi…cant di¤erences in preferences, especially in risk-aversion and time
discounting. They …nd that less-skilled and less-wealthy individuals
generally are less patient— meaning they place a higher value on current versus future consumption— than their more-skilled and wealthier
counterparts. More recently, Lutz Hendricks (2007) has measured the
extent of di¤erences in households’ discount factor by noticing that
households vary a great deal in their wealth even though they have
and can expect to have very similar lifetime incomes.
Taken as a whole, economists’work suggests that many of the observed di¤erences in the way households make decisions can be understood as arising from di¤erences in risk tolerance or time discounting.
A caveat, however, is that a variety of di¢ cult-to-model environmental forces might play a large role in generating these di¤erences. In a
society with low life expectancy or a high violent crime rate, for example, individuals might not be “choosing” to be impatient so much as
making a rational decision to value current over future consumption.
Likewise, not attending college might indicate an individual with a high
discount factor who chose not to invest in K-12 education— or it might
indicate a person facing strong institutional barriers to attending college. It is important to keep such environmental factors in mind when
interpreting any model that includes heterogeneity in preferences.

188

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

REFERENCES
Aaronson, Daniel, and Bhashkar Mazumder. Winter 2008.
“Intergenerational Economic Mobility in the United States, 1940
to 2000.” Journal of Human Resources 43 (1): 139–72.
Aguiar, Mark A., and Mark Bils. February 2011. “Has Consumption
Inequality Mirrored Income Inequality?” National Bureau of
Economic Research Working Paper No. 16807.
Auten, Gerald, Geo¤rey Gee, and Nicholas Turner. January 4, 2013.
“Income Inequality, Mobility and Turnover at the Top in the
United States, 1987–2010.” Paper presented at the Allied Social
Science Associations Annual Meeting, San Diego.
Becker, Gary S., and Nigel Tomes. July 1986. “Human Capital and
the Rise and Fall of Families.” Journal of Labor Economics 4 (3)
Part 2: S1–39.
Borjas, George J. Fall 2006. “Making It in America: Social Mobility in
the Immigrant Population.” Future of Children 16 (2): 55–71.
Bowles, Samuel, Herbert Gintis, and Melissa Osborne Groves. 2008.
“Intergenerational Inequality Matters.” In Unequal Chances,
edited by Samuel Bowles, Herbert Gintis and Melissa Osborne
Groves, 1–22. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Cagetti, Marco. July 2003. “Wealth Accumulation Over the Life
Cycle and Precautionary Savings.” Journal of Business and
Economic Statistics 21 (3): 339–53.
Caucutt, Elizabeth M., and Krishna B. Kumar. 2003. “Higher
Education Subsidies and Heterogeneity: A Dynamic Analysis.”
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 27: 1,459–502.
Chang, Yongsung, and Sun-Bin Kim. January 2012. “The Price of
Egalitarianism.” B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics 11 (1).
Congressional Budget O¢ ce. July 2012. “The Distribution of
Household Income and Federal Taxes, 2008 and 2009.”
Congressional Budget O¢ ce. October 2011. “Trends in the
Distribution of Household Income Between 1979 and 2007.”
Corak, Miles. 2006. “Do Poor Children Become Poor Adults? Lessons
from a Cross-Country Comparison of Generational Earnings
Mobility.” In Research on Economic Inequality, Vol. 13, edited by
John Creedy and Guyonne Kalb, 143–88. Bingley, U.K.: Emerald
Group Publishing.

K. Athreya and J. Romero: Economic Mobility in the U.S.

189

Easterlin, Richard A. Winter 2000. “The Worldwide Standard of
Living since 1800.”Journal of Economic Perspectives 14 (1): 7–26.
Gottschalk, Peter, and Enrico Spolaore. 2002. “On the Evaluation of
Economic Mobility.” Review of Economic Studies 69 (1): 191–208.
Haskins, Ron. 2008. “Immigration: Wages, Education, and Mobility.”
In Getting Ahead or Losing Ground: Economic Mobility in
America, edited by Julia B. Isaacs, Isabel V. Sawhill, and Ron
Haskins, 81–90. Washington, D.C.: The Pew Charitable Trusts.
Heckman, James J. July 2008. “Schools, Skills, and Synapses.”
Economic Inquiry 46 (3): 289–324.
Heckman, James J., Lance J. Lochner, and Petra E. Todd. February
2008. “Earnings Functions and Rates of Return.”National Bureau
of Economic Research Working Paper No. 13780.
Heckman, James J., John Eric Humphries, and Nicholas S. Mader.
June 2010. “The GED.” National Bureau of Economic Research
Working Paper No. 16064.
Hendricks, Lutz. September 2007. “How Important Is Discount Rate
Heterogeneity for Wealth Inequality?” Journal of Economic
Dynamics & Control 31(9): 3,042–68.
Hendricks, Lutz, and Oksana Leukhina. May 2012. “The Return to
College: Selection Bias and Dropout Risk.”Manuscript, University
of North Carolina, Chapel Hill, and University of Washington.
Huggett, Mark, Gustavo Ventura, and Amir Yaron. December 2011.
“Sources of Lifetime Inequality.” American Economic Review 101
(7): 2,923–54.
Ichino, Andrea, Loukas Karabarbounis, and Enrico Moretti. January
2011. “The Political Economy of Intergenerational Income
Mobility.” Economic Inquiry 49 (1): 47–69.
Isaacs, Julia B. 2008. “Economic Mobility of Black and White
Families.” In Getting Ahead or Losing Ground: Economic Mobility
in America, edited by Julia B. Isaacs, Isabel V. Sawhill and Ron
Haskins, 71–80. Washington, D.C.: The Pew Charitable Trusts.
Kihlstrom, Richard E., and Jean-Jacques La¤ont. August 1979. “A
General Equilibrium Entrpreneurial Theory of Firm Formation
Based on Risk Aversion.” Journal of Political Economy 87 (4):
719–48.
Knight, Frank H. 1921. Risk, Uncertainty, and Pro…t. Hart, Scha¤ner,
and Marx Prize Essays, no. 31. Boston: Houghton Mi- in.

190

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly

Kopczuk, Wojciech, Emmanuel Saez, and Jae Song. February 2010.
“Earnings Inequality and Mobility in the United States: Evidence
from Social Security Data since 1937.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 125 (1): 91–128.
Krusell, Per, and Anthony A. Smith, Jr. October 1998. “Income and
Wealth Heterogeneity in the Macroeconomy.” Journal of Political
Economy 106 (5): 867–96.
Lawrance, Emily C. February 1991. “Poverty and the Rate of Time
Preference: Evidence from Panel Data.” Journal of Political
Economy 99 (1): 54–77.
Lubotsky, Darren H. October 2007. “Chutes or Ladders? A
Longitudinal Analysis of Immigrant Earnings.” Journal of
Political Economy 115 (5): 820–67.
Lucas, Robert E. Jr. July 1988. “On the Mechanics of Economic
Development.” Journal of Monetary Economics 22 (1): 3–42.
Mazumder, Bhashkar. May 2008. “Upward Intergenerational
Economic Mobility in the United States.” Economic Mobility
Project, The Pew Charitable Trusts.
Mazumder, Bhashkar. April 2012. “Is Intergenerational Mobility
Lower Now than in the Past?” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Chicago Fed Letter, no. 297.
Meyer, Bruce D., and James X. Sullivan. January 4, 2013.
“Consumption and Income Inequality in the U.S. since the
1960s.” Paper presented at the Allied Social Science Associations
Annual Meeting, San Diego.
Mulligan, Casey B. 1997. Parental Priorities and Economic
Inequality. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Passel, Je¤rey, D’Vera Cohn, and Ana Gonzalez-Barrera. April 2012.
“Net Migration from Mexico Falls to Zero— and Perhaps Less.”
Pew Research Hispanic Center.
Piketty, Thomas, and Emmanuel Saez. February 2003. “Income
Inequality in the United States, 1913–1998.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 118 (1): 1–39.
Pritchett, Lant. 2006. Let Their People Come: Breaking the Gridlock
on Global Labor Mobility. Washington, D.C.: Center for Global
Development.
Restuccia, Diego, and Carlos Urrutia. December 2004.
“Intergenerational Persistence of Earnings: The Role of Early and
College Education.” American Economic Review 94 (5): 1,354–78.

K. Athreya and J. Romero: Economic Mobility in the U.S.

191

Romer, Paul M. October 1986. “Increasing Returns and Long-Run
Growth.” Journal of Political Economy 94 (5): 1,002–37.
Saez, Emmanuel. January 2013. “Striking It Richer: The Evolution of
Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2011
Estimates).” Manuscript.
Sawhill, Isabel V., Scott Winship, and Kerry Searle Grannis.
September 2012. “Pathways to the Middle Class: Balancing
Personal and Public Responsibilities.” Brookings Institution
Center on Children and Families.
Schulhofer-Wohl, Sam. October 2011. “Heterogeneity and Tests of
Risk Sharing.” Journal of Political Economy 119 (5): 925–58.
Seshadri, Ananth, and Kazuhiro Yuki. October 2004. “Equity and
E¢ ciency E¤ects of Redistributive Policies.” Journal of Monetary
Economics 51 (7): 1,415–47.
Shorrocks, Anthony. December 1978. “Income Inequality and Income
Mobility.” Journal of Economic Theory 19 (2): 376–93.
Solon, Gary. 2004. “A Model of Intergenerational Mobility Variation
over Time and Place.” In Generational Income Mobility in North
American and Europe, edited by Miles Corak, 38–47. Cambridge,
England: Cambridge University Press.
Stokey, Nancy L. 1996. “Shirtsleeves to Shirtsleeves: The Economics
of Social Mobility.” In Frontiers of Research in Economic Theory:
The Nancy L. Schwartz Memorial Lectures, 1983-1997, edited by
Donald P. Jacobs, Ehud Kalai and Morton I. Kamien, 210–41.
Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press.
Sullivan, Teresa A., Elizabeth Warren, and Jay Lawrence Westbrook.
2000. The Fragile Middle Class: Americans in Debt. New Haven
and London: Yale University Press.