View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

AUTOMATIC TRANSFERS FROM SAVINGS TO
CHECKING: PERSPECTIVE AND PROSPECTS*
Alfred Broaddus

On May 1, 1978, the Board of Governors
of the
Federal Reserve System amended its Regulation
Q
to allow member banks to transfer
funds from a
customer’s savings account to his checking account
automatically
under certain
stipulated
conditions.1
Such transfers
must be preauthorized
by the customer.
Specific arrangements
for the transfers
will
be the subject of an agreement
between a customer
and his bank and will presumably
vary from bank to
bank and from customer to customer.
In general,
however, once a customer
has contracted
for the
service, transfers will be triggered automatically
and
without any further authorization
whenever the customer’s checking balance falls below some agreed
minimum
level.2
The amendment
became effective
November 1,
1978.
The amendment is generally regarded as one of the
more important
developments
in retail banking
in
recent years.
While it is impossible at this time to
gauge the impact of the amendment
with a high
degree of certainty, it is safe to say that it has potentially significant implications
with respect to (1) the
relationship
between banks and their household customers, (2) competitive
relationships
between commercial banks and nonbank
depository
institutions,
(3) the earnings of banks and other financial institutions that offer the service, and (4) the conduct of
monetary
policy.
This article will show that the
authorization
of automatic
transfers is not a radical
*The
author thanks Bruce J. Summers
for very
comments
on an earlier draft of this article.

helpful

1 The FDIC has adopted a similar amendment.
Consequently,
the authority
to make automatic
transfers
has
been extended
to all insured
commercial
banks and all
mutual savings banks insured by the FDIC. A
lawsuit
challenging
the authority
of the agencies
to issue the
amendment
was denied by the U. S. District
Court for
the District
of Columbia,
United States League
of Savings Associations
v. Board of Governors
of the Federal
Reserve
System,
et al., Civil No. 78-0878 (D.D.C.,
filed
October
31, 1978).
2 Therefore,
the automatic
transfer
service
will differ
from such currently
permitted
services
as the payment
of regularly
recurring
bills from savings
accounts
and
services
where the customer
is able to order, by telephone, individually
specified
transfers
from his savings
account
to his checking
account
or to third parties.

regulatory development
but rather the latest event in
a longer run evolution affecting all depository institutions.
The article will describe this evolution and
indicate the relationship
of automatic transfers to it.
It also summarizes
the detailed provisions
of the
amendment,
and speculates on some of the amendment’s major potential implications.
I.

A BRIEF

PERSPECTIVE

To understand
where the automatic
transfer service stands in relation to other recent developments
in banking,
it is necessary
to recognize
its most
important
feature.
Specifically, the service will enable some depositors-the
exact number depending
on the terms under which the service is offered-to
reduce their demand balances. Therefore, the amendment authorizing
automatic
transfers
can be properly viewed as the latest in a series of events over the
last decade or so that have increased the extent to
which the public has been able to use interest-earning
deposits
for purposes
previously
requiring
noninterest-earning
demand balances.3
The important
events in this evolution are outlined in the Box. The
initial development
occurred in 1970 when the Federal Home Loan Bank Board authorized
federally
chartered savings and loan associations
to make preauthorized
non-negotiable
transfers
from savings
accounts to third parties for recurring
householdrelated expenditures.
Subsequent
developments
have
included
(1) the introduction
and extension
of negotiable order of withdrawal
(NOW)
accounts at
thrift institutions4
and commercial
banks in New
England
and more recently
New York,
(2) the
introduction
of share draft accounts
at federally
chartered credit unions, (3) the proliferation
of auto3 As

a result
of these developments,
some economists
now use the term “transaction
balances”
to designate
all
balances
in all types of accounts
that are held against
anticipated
current
expenditures
as opposed
to balances
held to meet longer term or emergency
contingencies.

4Throughout
this article the term “thrift institution”
will
refer to nonbank
depository
institutions
such as mutual
savings banks, savings and loan associations,
and credit
unions.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

3

Box
RECENT

DEVELOPMENTS

PURPOSES

ENABLING

PREVIOUSLY

DEPOSITORS

REQUIRING

September
1970
The Federal
Home Loan Bank
Board
permitted
federally
chartered
savings
and
loan associations
to make preauthorized
nonnegotiable
transfers
from
savings
accounts
to third
parties for household-related
expenditures.
June 1972
State-chartered
mutual
savings
banks
in Massachusetts
began offering
NOW
accounts
following
a favorable
ruling of the Massachusetts
Supreme
Court.
NOW
accounts
are functionally
equivalent
to interest-bearing
checking
accounts.
September
1972
State-chartered
banks in New Hampshire
began
accounts.

mutual
offering

savings
NOW

January
1974
Federal
legislation
authorized
all
depository
institutions
except
credit
unions
in
Massachusetts
and New Hampshire
to offer NOW
accounts.
January
1974
First Federal
Savings
and Loan of
Lincoln, Nebraska,
installed
customer-bank
communications
terminals
in two supermarkets
enabling
customers
to withdraw
funds from
their
savings accounts
to pay for items purchased
from
the stores.
Early
1974
Money market
mutual funds became
These funds permit
shareholders
to
widespread.
redeem
shares
either by checks
drawn on designated commercial
bank accounts,
by wire transfer,
by telephone
or by mail.
August 1974
The National
Credit Union Administration
permitted
Federal
credit unions to issue
share drafts which, like NOW
accounts,
are functionally
equivalent
to interest-bearing
checking
accounts.

mated teller machines and similar facilities, (4) the
authorization
of banks to accept corporate
savings
accounts, and (5) the authorization
of banks to make
telephone-ordered
transfers
from savings accounts
to checking accounts.
Perhaps more interesting than the specific developments in the evolution are the underlying
forces propelling them.
These changes have occurred simultaneously with the flowering of the consumer movement, and it is probable that this coincidence accounts
in part for the political support accorded such innovations as NOW accounts.
The steady rise in market
interest
rates, which has increased
the opportunity
cost of holding non-interest-bearing
deposits, has also
Further,
some of the
undoubtedly
been a factor.
developments
have been a direct outgrowth
of technological advances associated with the emergence of
electronic funds transfer systems.
4

ECONOMIC

TO USE INTEREST-EARNING

NON-INTEREST-EARNING

REVIEW,

DEMAND

November 1974 Commercial
to accept
savings
deposits
governments.

BALANCES

FOR

BALANCES
banks
from

were authorized
state and local

April 1975
Commercial
banks were authorized
to
transfer funds from a savings deposit to a checking
account
upon receipt
of a depositor’s
telephone
order.
April 1975 The Federal
Home Loan Bank Board
extended
its 1970 action
by permitting
federally
chartered
savings
and loan associations
to make
preauthorized
transfers
from savings
accounts
to
third parties for any purpose.
September 1975 Commercial
banks were permitted
to make preauthorized
nonnegotiable
transfers
from
savings accounts
to third parties for any purpose.
November
1975 Commercial
banks were authorized
to accept savings
deposits
from partnerships
and
corporations
operated for profit, limited to $150,000
per customer
per bank.
In conjunction
with telephone-ordered
transfers,
this authority
made
it
possible
for small businesses
to earn interest
on
funds that can be readily used for transactions.
February
1976 Federal legislation
extended NOW
account
authority
to all New England
States.
October
account

1978
Federal
legislation
extended
authority
to New York State.

November
1978 Commercial
to offer automatic
transfers
to demand deposits.

NOW

banks were authorized
from savings deposits

Source:
Board of Governors
of the
serve System
[10, pp. 30-32].

Federal

Re-

In addition
to these factors, the evolution
also
appears to reflect important changes in the condition
of the thrift industry and in competitive relationships
between thrifts and commercial
banks over the last
10 to 12 years. In the immediate post-World-War
II
period and during the 1950’s housing demand was
strong due to wartime construction
postponements
and rising family formations.
As a result, thrift
institutions,
particularly
savings
and loan associations, grew rapidly throughout
the first two postwar
decades.5 Moreover, with a relatively steep upward5 According
to the Hunt
Commission
Report
[ll,
pp.
34-35], between 1945 and 1965 the total assets of savings
and loan associations
and mutual savings banks increased
at compound
annual rates exceeding
14 percent
and 6
percent,
respectively.
The rate for commercial
banks
was 4 percent.
During this same period the commercial
bank share of total assets held by all depository
institutions declined to 67 percent from 86 percent.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1978

sloping yield curve in place during this period, the
juxtaposition
of generally long-term mortgage-dominated asset portfolios and predominantly
short-term
time and savings deposit liabilities on thrift balance
sheets produced no significant
structural
difficulties.
On the contrary, thrift operations were highly profitable.
Conditions
changed rather dramatically,
however,
in the late 1960’s. Spreads between short- and longterm interest
rates were narrower
on the average
during this period than in earlier years, reflected in a
flatter and sometimes downward-sloping
yield curve.
Given the maturity
structure
of thrift assets and
liabilities,
this development
squeezed thrift profit
margins.
These difficulties
were compounded
by
stronger
competition
from commercial
banks
for
household
time and savings deposits.6
Moreover,
virtually all thrifts suffered sharp reductions
in deposit growth during the periods of restrictive
monetary policy in 1966 and 1969-1970.
This change in the fortunes of the thrifts troubled
the industry
itself, its regulators,
and others concerned about the politically sensitive longer run prospects for housing finance.
The Hunt Commission
Report, issued in 1971, addressed this problem among
others.
One of its major recommendations
was that
thrifts be allowed a broader range of activities
in
order that they might break out of the bind imposed
by the structure of their balance sheets.7 The Commission
proposed
that the lending
and investing
powers of savings and loan associations
and mutual
savings banks be extended and that these institutions
be allowed to offer third-party
payment
services,
including ordinary checking accounts, to nonbusiness
customers.
The Hunt Commission Report has led to the introduction of several comprehensive
legislative programs
in the Congress to “reform”
depository
institutions
The sweeping
and markets and their regulators.
6 In testimony
during the hearings
on the FINE
“Disthe National
Association
of Mutual
cussion Principles,”
Savings
Banks
presented
data drawn from the Federal
Reserve
flow of funds accounts
indicating
that the savings and loan association
share of the growth of household time and savings deposits declined from 46.9 percent
in the 1946-1956 period to 34.1 percent
in the 1966-1974
period.
The mutual savings
bank share declined
from
23.2 percent
to 11.9 percent, while the commercial
bank
share increased
from 29.9 percent to 54.0 percent.
U. S.
Congress,
House, Committee
on Banking,
Currency
and
Housing,
Financial
Institutions
and the Nation’s
Economy
(FINE)
“Discussion
Principles,”
Hearings,
before
a subcommittee
of the Committee
on Banking,
Currency
and Housing,
House of Representatives,
94th Cong., 1st
and 2nd sess., 1975, p. 865.
7 For general background
on the Hunt Commission
prepared by the co-directors
of the Commission’s
professional staff, see [6, pp. 9-20].
FEDERAL

R&SERVE

scope of these proposals has produced to date enough
anxiety in all quarters
to prevent
passage of the
Commission’s
principal
recommendations.
Faced
with political inertia at the national level, some elements within the thrift industry
have sought to expand their powers by other means.
Of specific relevance to this article, some thrifts, particularly
the
mutual
savings
banks in the Northeast
and the
emerging credit unions, have worked vigorously
to
gain and promote
third-party
payment
services in
order to compete more effectively with commercial
banks.8
Several of the most important
innovations
listed in the accompanying
Box were initiated
by
thrifts, including
NOW accounts, credit union share
drafts, and the installation
of point-of-sale
terminals
in supermarkets.
Among the various initiatives
of the thrifts to expand their deposit service powers, the most important
in terms of its potential
longer run effects on all
depository institutions
was probably the introduction
of NOW accounts in Massachusetts
and New Hampshire in 1972 at the instigation
of the Consumer
Savings Bank of Worcester,
Massachusetts,
a mutual
savings bank.9
At that time, savings banks in the
New England States did not have the power to offer
ordinary demand deposits, and earlier efforts to obtain that authority by state legislation in Connecticut,
New Hampshire,
and Massachusetts
had failed. The
NOW
innovation
circumvented
this restriction
by
tying third-party
payment
powers to savings accounts, which the savings banks were empowered to
offer.
But this action introduced
a new and highly
significant
element into the picture, because NOW
accounts, although legally a form of savings account,
are for all practical purposes equivalent to a checking
account that bears explicit interest.
The growth of
the NOW instrument
in New England and the subsequent introduction
of the similar share draft account by credit unions elsewhere has forced an extensive reconsideration
of the 45-year-old prohibition
of
interest payments
on demand deposits in the Congress, regulatory agencies, and the banking and thrift

8 The

savings and loan industry
has been generally
less
interested
in obtaining
third-party
payment
powers than
the mutual savings banks and credit unions, fearing such
powers would result in loss of the interest
rate ceiling
differential
on time and savings
deposits.
The Federal
Home Loan Bank Board, however, which regulates
federally chartered
associations,
has strongly
favored
the
extension
of full third-party
payment
powers
to thrifts.
See Federal Home Loan Bank Board, A Financial
Institution
for the Future,
(Washington,
D. C.: Office
of
Economic
Research,
Federal
Home Loan Bank Board,
1975), pp. 27-33.

9 For a summary
see

[4].

BANK OF RICHMOND

of the early

history

of NOW

accounts

5

industries.
Indeed, legislation
that would have extended NOW account authority
nationwide,
a development that would have substantially
reduced the
force of the prohibition,
was introduced
and debated
although
not passed by Congress
in 1977.10 The
reconsideration
has received
added impetus
from
technological
developments
such as automated
teller
machines and similar devices that have made it much
easier and less costly for individual
depositors
to
transfer funds from savings to checking.
It is against this background
that the amendment
permitting
automatic transfers from savings accounts
to checking accounts must be evaluated.
Far from
an isolated regulatory
development,
the amendment
is a natural step in what increasingly
appears to be
an inexorable
sequence of events, driven by technological developments
and changing competitive forces
affecting depository
institutions,
that is steadily increasing
the ability of households
to use interestearning accounts for many of the purposes for which
non-interest-earning
balances
were previously
required.

II.

THE

PROVISIONS

OF THE

AMENDMENT

qualitatively.
The number of responses received by
the Board set a record for proposals of this nature.
The proposal
had received some attention
in the
general press, which may account for the large number of letters-many
of them handwritten-sent
by
individuals.
A majority,
approximately
52 percent,
of the responses favored adoption.
The amendment
finally enacted by the Board reflects the second round of public comments and therefore itself differs from the revised proposal.
The
amendment
has seven major provisions:12
(1) In offering the automatic
transfer
service
banks may either agree to make the transfers
necessary to maintain some prearranged
minimum
nonzero
balance in the depositor’s
checking account, or they may agree to maintain a zero checking balance, i.e., to transfer funds continuously
as
required to cover checks as they are written.
(2) Banks offering the service will not be required to impose either an interest forfeiture or a
(They are free to
service charge on transfers.
impose either if they so choose.)
This provision
constitutes
the major departure
from the Board’s
revised proposal.
In commenting
on the revised
proposal a large number of financial
institutions
had suggested
that the required
interest penalty
be eliminated.

The amendment
authorizing
automatic
transfers
was originally
proposed by the Board of Governors
in March 1976.
This initial proposal elicited little
response from the general public and largely negative
comments from banks and other financial institutions.
In retrospect
this lack of interest is understandable
since the terms of the proposal were quite restrictive.
Depositors
would have been required
to forfeit 30
days’ interest
on amounts transferred,
and transfers
would have had to be made in $100 units.
To the
extent they were aware of the proposal,
potential
users of the service apparently did not find these conditions attractive, and banks evidently concluded they
could not offer the service profitably subject to these
restrictions.
In the light of this reaction, the Board
did not implement
this initial proposal.

(5) The service is entirely voluntary
both for
banks and bank customers and can be made only
with the prior consent of the customer.
(Consent
in the case of automatic transfers,
of course, is to
the service, not to individual
transfers.)

The proposal was revived in early 1978, but with
important
revisions.
The interest forfeiture penalty
was softened,11 and the $100 unit requirement
for
transfers was dropped.
The response to this second
proposal was quite different, both quantitatively
and

(6) A bank offering the service must “disclose
prominently
and call to the attention of depositors”
that it reserves the right to require not less than
30 days’ advance notice of withdrawals
from savings accounts
subject to transfer
just as it has

(3)
only.

The

service

may be offered

to individuals

(4) The service may be offered beginning
November 1, 1978, six months after the date of the
amendment’s
adoption.
The delay was provided
to allow ample start-up time to banks planning to
offer the service.13

10 Ironically,
the legislation’s
defeat was due largely
to
thrift opposition
arising from fear that Congress
would
couple the extension
with the abolition
of the interest
rate ceiling differential.

provisions
listed here paraphrase
those set forth
in the Board’s formal announcement
of the amendment’s
adoption
in the May 1978 Federal Reserve Bulletin, pp.
424-425.

11 Only the interest actually accrued on the funds transferred during the 30 days prior to the transfer would have
had to be forfeited.

13 A request

6

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

12 The

of the Independent
Bankers
Association
of
New York to delay the beginning
date still further was
denied by the Board on September
13, 1978.
NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1978

reserved this right
in the past.

for ordinary

savings

accounts

(7) Banks may arrange with thrift institutions
to offer jointly automatic
transfers
from savings
accounts at thrifts to checking accounts at banks.
These provisions
are subject to change as experiIn its
ence with automatic
transfers
accumulates.
announcement
the Board stated that it will monitor
the effects of the amendment
on competitive
conditions and flows of funds in depository
markets in
order to make whatever modifications
seem appropriate.
As presently written, the amendment’s
central feature is the high degree of flexibility it offers to banks
in packaging the service and to customers in using it.
Banks can set whatever conditions
they wish with
respect to such details as the frequency and amounts
of transfers,
minimum
balance
requirements,
and
account maintenance
fees and other charges.
Presuming there is at least moderate
variety in bank
offerings in a given local market, an individual
customer might be able to use the service to avoid overdrafts and overdraft charges, to maintain a specified
minimum
checking balance to avoid ordinary checking account service charges, or to maintain
a zero
checking balance, in accordance
with his characteristics and needs.
III.

SOME

POTENTIAL

ment for banks and bank customers with the aid of
Table I. The latter part will speculate on some of the
broader and more permanent
effects.14
Appeal to Depositors
Sections
I and II of
Table I present information
that might help determine the appeal of automatic transfers to depositors
at a typical medium-sized
or large bank in an urban
or suburban
area.
Section I lists the assumptions
underlying
the analysis.
Lines I.B and I.C show the
various assumed charges and interest rates faced by
the depositor
before and after the introduction
of
In both cases an
automatic
transfers,
respectively.
attempt was made to specify what might be regarded
as median or “typical” service charges.15 As anyone
familiar with the banking industry knows, however,
there is extraordinary
variation in both the form and
level of such charges across banks.
Therefore,
the
assumptions
are a rough approximation
at best.
Banks will apparently
offer automatic transfers in
two basic forms : (1) as overdraft
protection
and
(2) as what might be called “interest maximization”
accounts.16
The latter appear to be the more important and are the only type considered in the remainder of this article.
These accounts will generally
involve a linked checking account and savings account.
The bank will agree to maintain a very low
balance
(for many banks zero)
in the checking
account, transferring
any surplus funds to savings

IMPLICATIONS

This section will speculate on some of the potential
repercussions
of automatic transfers.
The service has
important
potential implications,
ranging from transitory effects on banks and their depositors to more
lasting effects on the functioning
of the nation’s payments system. It must be emphasized, however, that
while it is important
for both banks and the general
public to be aware of the potential impact of automatic transfers,
it is not possible to predict either
the magnitude
or the timing of these effects with high
confidence.
Apart from the possibility of future modification
of
the amendment,
the significance
of automatic
transfers-especially
during the first year following their
promulgation-will
depend largely on how aggressively banks promote the service and how favorably
the service is received by the public.
Neither factor
can be foreseen with much certainty.
For these reasons, what follows should not be regarded as a set
of predictions
but rather as illustrations
of what
might occur under certain specific hypothetical
conditions.
The first part of the section will discuss
some of the immediate
implications
of the amend-

14 On October 16, 1978, when this article was in the late
stages of preparation,
Congress
unexpectedly
extended
the authority
to offer NOW
accounts
to all federally
chartered
commercial
banks and thrifts
in New York
State.
Prior to the passage of this legislation,
banks and
thrifts in the State had been preparing
to offer automatic
transfers.
Since NOW accounts
and the most important
forms of automatic
transfer accounts are in some respects
substitutes
from the standpoints
of both offering institutions and depositors.
the legislation
renders the effects of
the automatic
transfer
amendment
even less certain
in
New York than elsewhere.
This article does not attempt
to take account of this late development.
The legalization
of NOW’s
in New York increases
the
probability
that NOW account authority
will be extended
nationwide
at an early date.
In that event automatic
transfers
would probably
serve as a transition
step to
NOW’S
Even
so, automatic
transfers
may not be
hastily
abandoned
because
larger
banks
have already
invested sizable sums in preparing
the operational
mechanisms and promotional
programs
to support transfers.
Support
requirements
for NOW
accounts
are different.
15By mid-October
1978, a sizable
number
of larger
banks had announced
preliminary
prices for automatic
transfer
services.
Many of these announcements
were
reported
in the American Banker newspaper
in August,
September,
and October.
16The main difference between the two forms of service
Overrelates to the anticipated
frequency
of transfers.
draft protection
accounts
are designed
to accommodate
relatively
infrequent
transfers,
whereas
interest
maximization accounts
are intended
to handle more frequent
transfers.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

7

8

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1978

on a regular basis.
Checks will then be covered by
transfers from the savings account, typically for the
exact amount of the check. A majority of the banks
intend to impose a fixed monthly maintenance
charge
for this service and an additional fee per check.
A
number of banks also plan to offer the service without
charge to depositors
who maintain
minimum
combined balances exceeding
some specified amount.17
The prices assumed in Lines I.C2 and I.C3 appear
to lie somewhere between the relatively liberal terms
announced by several large West Coast banks and the
more stringent terms likely to prevail in the East.

characteristics.
Column (6) of the upper table presents the net increase in service charges for accounts
at several different activity levels.18 In general, the
increase is a rising function of activity.
Column 2
of the lower table shows the approximate
gross
interest on funds transferred
to savings at various
checking balance levels.
Together
the two tables
indicate that depositors who normally write 15 to 20
checks a month would have to be currently
holding
an average checking account balance in the $1500$2000 range to gain from the service, and even at
this level the gain would be nominal.19

Section II of the table attempts to suggest what
kinds of households,
as indexed by their checking
and savings account balances and account activity
levels, might find this “typical” automatic
transfer
offer attractive.
Since it is assumed the service will
be offered free to depositors
who maintain
a minimum balance exceeding $3500, all households holding
minimum
combined checking and savings balances
over this level before the introduction
of automatic
transfers would benefit from the service. The amount
of the gain for these depositors would increase with
the depositor’s average checking balance and his account’s activity (the latter because he is assumed to
be paying $.10 currently
for each check written).
Although all depositors in this class would gain from
the service, it is unlikely that all would use it even
Depositors
where it were conveniently
available.
with relatively small and inactive checking accounts
before automatic
transfers
might not consider
the
small gain worth the trouble of opening new accounts.
Further,
surveys of consumer
attitudes
toward the
service have suggested that many potential users fear
it might compromise
the integrity
of the savings
account by making ii easier to indulge in unintended
spending out of funds originally
set aside as longer
term savings.
Depositors
with a combined
minimum
balance
below $3500 in this example would be charged.
Section II.B of the table attempts to indicate the conditions under which depositors
in this class might
find automatic
transfer accounts advantageous.
As
indicated,
this determination
would require a comparison of (1) the gain from interest paid on funds
formerly held idle in a non-interest-bearing
checking
account that could now be held in an interest-bearing
savings account and (2) the net increase in service
charges.
The data in the two numerical tables permit
such a calculation for a variety of account behavior

If the various terms assumed are at all representative, it is obvious that the service will appeal mainly
to the minority of depositors who maintain relatively
high balances in their checking account.
Many of
the larger banks are planning to emphasize this point
as candidly as possible in promoting
the service.

17 In the case of zero checking
balance
arrangements,
the minimum
combined
balance
by definition
refers
to
the minimum
balance in the savings account.

Effects on Bank Profits During the Transition
It is probable
that the introduction
of automatic
transfers will have some effect on commercial
bank
profits.
It is even more likely that the magnitude
and timing of this effect will vary widely from bank to
bank, reflecting differences in the competitive
conditions faced by individual
banks.
Section III of Table I presents a simplified example of the possible effect of automatic transfers on
the before-tax earnings of a Federal Reserve member
bank with total deposits in the $600-700 million
range during the first year the service is offered. The
analysis is based on a set of specific, hypothetical
assumptions
regarding
such factors as (1) the percentage of eligible household demand deposit balances
shifted to savings accounts subject to transfer and
(2) service charge policy before and after the inauguration
of automatic
transfers.
Most of the data
on which the analysis is based were taken from the

18 For

simplicity,
the service charge assumption
in Line
I.B1 in the table ignores the common
current practice in
some markets
of providing
free checking
services
for
relatively
modest
minimum
balances.
The net service
charge increases
shown in the table understate
the increases
that depositors
able to take advantage
of these
current programs
would experience.

19 The interest

gains shown in the table are on a beforetax basis.
The after-tax
benefit would be smaller.
Also,
most checking account customers
presently
earn “implicit
interest”
in the form of free services
or service charges
that are below the costs the bank incurs in providing
checking services.
Unlike explicit interest,
implicit interest is not taxed.
Therefore,
to the extent that automatic
transfers
substituted
explicit for implicit interest,
this tax
benefit would be lost.
Hence the tables probably
understate
the checking
balance
levels
at which
automatic
For a discussion
of
transfers
would be advantageous.
implicit interest,
see [9].

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

9

Federal Reserve System’s Functional
Cost Analysis
Report for 1977. This Report provides balance sheet
and income statement
data for “average”
banks in
three size classifications
based on information
provided by 846 member banks throughout
the nation.
It must be stressed that the analysis is not a prediction of the actual transitional
effects of automatic
transfers on the earnings of most member banks. No
such estimate
is possible in the face of the wide
variety of prices and price policies contemplated
by
individual banks.
The aim of the example is to provide a suggestive benchmark
estimate under specific
assumed conditions.
Individual
banks might then
alter the conditions and the estimate to fit their individual situations.
The specific conditions
assumed
include the pre- and post-automatic
transfer
price
and interest rate terms in Section I of the table along
with the additional assumptions
noted in Section III
of the table. Therefore, as in the preceding section of
the article, the focus is on zero-balance
automatic
transfer accounts offered without charge to depositors
with minimum
balances over $3500.
The analysis takes account of three of the major
factors likely to affect member bank earnings during
the transition
to automatic transfers.20
These are:
(1) the increased
interest expense due to shifts in
deposits from demand to savings accounts
(Lines
III.A to III.C) ; (2) the net gain or loss from service charges (Lines III.D to III.F) ; and (3) additional earnings that result from the lending or investment of required
reserves released as a result of
shifts from demand to savings deposits (Lines III.G
to III.L).
The principal factors omitted from the
analysis are the potential impacts of automatic transfers on (1) bank non-interest
costs (in this example
mainly accounting
and computer expenses)
and (2)
Information
that would have peroverdraft
fees.
mitted estimation
of these effects was not readily
available.
The estimate of additional
interest
expense
(an
increase
of $607,000 in this example)
essentially
follows from the assumption
(Line III.B)
that 20
percent of the bank’s dollar volume of household
demand deposits would be converted to savings balances during the first year automatic
transfers
are
available.
This estimate is based on a separate estimate of the joint
distribution
of demand and savings
deposits by account size using Federal Reserve Functional Cost Analysis
data on the individual
size

20 The

methodology
employed
here is straightforward
and follows
the procedures
used in several
recent estimates of the similar potential
effect of nationwide
NOW
accounts
on bank profits.
See [5, 10].

10

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

distributions
of demand and savings deposits, respectively.21
This separate analysis suggested that perhaps as much as 60 percent of the dollar volume of
the “average”
large bank’s household
demand deposits might be presently
lodged in accounts that
would benefit from being shifted to savings deposits
subject to transfer,
reflecting the surprisingly
high
percentage of household demand and savings balances
in high balance accounts.22
It was somewhat arbitrarily assumed that 40 percent would actually convert over a three-year
transition
period, with 20
percent converting
during the first year.
This estimate is close to the first year conversion factors estimated and publicly announced
by some large banks.
Lines III.D to III.F
estimate the net change in.
service charge revenues using the stated activity level
assumptions
in conjunction
with the before and after
charge schedule in Section I of the table. Underlying
these calculations
are data on the number of personal.
demand accounts
in various
size categories
at an
average large bank. These data were also developed
in the separate analysis mentioned
above.
As indicated, the bank in this example would experience a
moderate
net reduction
in service charge revenue.
This follows directly from (1) the assumption
that
the bank would offer automatic
transfers free for a
minimum balance of $3500 and (2) an estimate based
on the separate analysis that fully 80 percent of converted balances would be in accounts that qualify for
the free service.
Obviously,
this percentage
would
be sensitive to the minimum
balance level for free
service, if any, set by an individual
bank.
Lines III.G to III.L suggest that the return on the
investment
of released required reserves would provide a modest offset to the additional interest expense
shown on Line III.C.
The offset would be larger for
banks having a higher marginal
required
reserve
requirement
ratio on demand deposits and lower for
banks having a lower ratio.
The final line suggests that the bank in this example might experience
a reduction
of before-tax
earnings
on the order of 5½ percent during
the
initial year of the transition
to automatic
transfers.
It should be emphasized again that this estimate re-

21 See

[3, Tables
7.2 and 8.2].
Table
7.2 shows
the
distribution
of total demand balances
including
nonpersonal balances.
This distribution
served as a benchmark
for an estimate
of the distribution
of personal
demand
balances.

22 The

analysis
indicated
that the major portion
of the
funds would be shifted
from checking
accounts
with
average balances that currently
exceed $3000. Functional
cost data indicate
that between
60 and 65 percent
of
household
demand balances
are in such accounts.
NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1978

flects the assumptions
from which it was derived.
It
does not take account of differences
in competitive
conditions or differences in individual depositor characteristics faced by different banks.
Some banks will
experience little or no reduction.
Others will probably experience greater reductions.
The most striking result of the analysis is its suggestion
that due
to the existing size distribution
of personal account
balances, banks offering the service without charge
for minimum
balances in the $3500 range or less
will not receive an offset to their increased interest
expense from higher service charge revenue.
On the
contrary,
they might anticipate
some net decline in
these revenues.
Economic
Efficiency
The two preceding
sections described two of the more immediate potential
effects of automatic transfers.
This section and the
next section deal briefly with two of the possible
longer run ramifications.
It should be noted that the
points made below are not uniquely relevant to automatic transfers
but would be associated
with any
regulatory
or technological
change tending
to increase the extent to which depositors are able to use
interest-bearing
deposits for purposes previously
requiring non-interest-bearing
demand balances.
Economists
have argued that removal of the current prohibition
of explicit interest on demand deposits would increase the efficiency of the nation’s
payments mechanism in two ways.23 First, it would
reduce the wasteful shifting of funds between demand and savings deposits that results from the
efforts of depositors to maximize the return on their
transaction
balances.
Second, it would improve the
allocation
of economic resources
in the aggregate.
The logic of the second claim runs along the following lines. Most household depositors currently
earn
an “implicit” return on their demand balances in the
form of a remission of service charges.24 Obviously,
this implicit return can only be realized in the form
of checking services, thereby severely restricting
the
depositor’s
use of the return.
If the return were
paid in the form of explicit money interest, many
households would probably use it to consume other
goods or services.
Resource allocation would then
more nearly reflect consumer
preferences.
The first of these two arguments

is less relevant

to

23 The

term “efficiency”
is used here in its technical
economic sense: i.e., the efficiency
with which basic labor
and capital
resources
are allocated
among
competing
uses.

24 See footnote
there.

19 above

and

the

article

by

Klein

cited

automatic
transfers
than to the outright removal of
the ban on explicit interest on demand accounts or
to NOW accounts because automatic
transfers
require the continued maintenance
of distinct checking
and savings accounts.
Resources must still be used
to shift funds back and forth between the accounts,
although-depending
again on how banks price the
service--the
burden may be shifted to some extent
from depositors
to banks or to those who borrow
from banks.
The second argument
is relevant
to automatic
transfers,
but only under certain conditions.
The
essence of this argument
is that if explicit interest
were permitted,
efficiency would increase because
explicit, pecuniary
interest would be substituted
for
implicit interest.
Because implicit interest is simply
the provision of payments services to depositors free
or at fees below the value of the resources used in
producing
the services, the existence of implicit interest invites excessive use of these services and
therefore virtually
guarantees
a misallocation
of resources.
If banks used automatic transfers to reduce
implicit interest payments,
efficiency in the use of
resources to carry out payments transactions
would
probably increase, even though the precise magnitude
of this benefit might be difficult to measure.25
On
the other hand, if banks offer automatic
transfers
either without charge or at a low fee on a widespread basis, implicit interest payments would not be
Indeed, they might not even be signifieliminated.
cantly reduced.
In these circumstances
efficiency
gains would be small or nonexistent.
The charge schedules
announced
for automatic
transfers to date by individual banks suggest that the
substitution
of explicit for implicit interest will proceed slowly.
As time passes, however, the existence
of automatic transfers and the additional costs associated with providing
them may gradually
increase
the incentives
for banks to raise customer fees for
checking and other payments
services, thereby reducing implicit interest and the inefficiencies
arising
Increasingly
conservative
pricing policies
from it.
have characterized
the NOW account experience in
New England.26
Implications for the Conduct of Monetary Policy
In addition
to their potential
consequences
in the
areas already
discussed,
automatic
transfers
may
25 At the time this article

was prepared a few banks had
indicated
they planned
to review
all of their service
charges in conjunction
with the introduction
of automatic
transfers.

26 See Kimball

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

[8, pp. 34-38].

11

have some important
repercussions
on the implementation
of monetary policy. Economists
have long
recognized that the prohibition
of explicit interest on
demand deposits and, by extension,
the progressive
erosion of the force of that prohibition
due to technological developments
and other changes raises major
theoretical
and practical
questions
regarding
the
definition of the money supply and the stability of the
demand for money, however defined, with respect to
interest rates and income.27
If automatic
transfers
lead to substantial
shifts from demand to savings
deposits, their introduction
might produce the kinds
of effects contemplated
by those concerned with these
broader questions.
It was suggested above that any
such shifting might be small initially, in which case
the practical importance
of these effects may not be
very great in the immediate future.
Nonetheless,
the initiation
of automatic
transfers
is likely to create some problems of interpretation
at
an early date for both Federal Reserve policymakers
and others who monitor monetary policy.
The procedures currently
used in implementing
monetary
policy include setting both longer run targets and
short-run
tolerance
ranges for the growth rates of
various monetary
aggregates.
Automatic
transfers
may temporarily
complicate
the use of these procedures, particularly
the interpretation
of short-run
growth rates of the various aggregates.
Specifically,
shifts of funds from demand deposits to savings deposits to take advantage of the transfers will tend to
depress the growth rate of the narrowly
defined M1
aggregate
(which includes demand but not savings
deposits) while leaving the growth of the boarder M2
aggregate
(which
includes
both)
little changed.28
Because neither the magnitude
nor the timing of the
shifts induced by automatic
transfers
can be confidently predicted,
and since complete
data on the
shifts will not be available
on a current
basis,29 it
may be difficult during the transition
to determine
whether changes in one- or two-month
growth rates
are being caused by changes in underlying
economic
conditions
or by the spread of automatic transfers or

27 These

issues are well beyond the scope of this article,
but an extensive
literature
is available.
For a brief summary see [1, pp. 72-89].
For a comprehensive
survey of
these and related
current
issues in monetary
research,
see [2].

28 This statement
does not take account of possible
of deposits from thrift institutions
to banks.
Such
would tend to raise the growth
rate of M2.

shifts
shifts

29 The

Federal
Reserve
will, however,
conduct
a telephone survey of a sample of banks to estimate
the order
of magnitude
of shifts during the transition.
The survey
is described
in American Banker, October
26, 1978, p. 1.

12

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

both.
Since M2 should not be strongly affected by
automatic transfers,
it might be helpful during the
transition to evaluate M1 data in the light of what is
happening to M2. But this procedure is by no means
foolproof since M2 growth
rates are themselves continuously buffeted by a variety of adventitious
forces
in the short run.
The interpretative
difficulties
introduced
into the
monetary
policy process by the transition
to automatic transfers
will probably
be short-lived.
But
more than the usual degree of uncertainty
might
surround
short-run
policy actions during the early
weeks of the transition.
Experienced
Fed policy
watchers recognize the potential
confusion.
Their
awareness should limit any disruption.

IV.

CONCLUSION

This article began by considering
automatic transfers in an evolutionary
context.
It was suggested
that the amendment
to Regulation
Q allowing the
service was the latest in a lengthy series of events
over the last decade or so that have made it increasingly easy for the public to achieve with interestbearing balances certain ends that previously required
non-interest-bearing
demand
balances.
The latter
part of the article summarized
some of the potential
effects of the amendment
under given assumptions.
On the basis of the pricing
policies
announced
through mid-October
1978, it seems likely that the
service will appeal primarily to depositors with large
checking balances who will apparently
be offered
the service without charge or for a small fee by many
of the larger banks.
For this reason, the analysis in
the preceding section suggested that ( 1) the earnings
of a typical large bank offering the service might be
reduced somewhat during the transition
since service
charge income might not offset the increased interest
expense and (2) the potential
improvement
in the
efficiency of resource usage in the payments
system
might not be forthcoming
initially
because many
banks are not planning
to take advantage
of the
introduction
of the service to reduce implicit interest
payments
significantly.
It was also suggested that
the shifting of balances from demand to savings accounts might complicate
the conduct
of monetary
policy in a mechanical way during the transition.
Despite these reservations,
automatic transfers will
probably be useful both to banks and the general
public as a part of the longer run transformation
of
the nation’s payments mechanism
currently
in progress. Whatever the prospects for continuation
of the
legal prohibition
of explicit interest on demand de-

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1978

posits, the force of the prohibition
is bound to be
weakened and eventually reduced to insignificance
as
continued
development
and refinement
of electronic
payment facilities make it ever more convenient
and

less costly to transfer
funds from one account to
another.
Moving gradually in this direction through
such partial steps as automatic transfers is preferable
to an abrupt and possibly disruptive
transition
later.

References
1.

2.

Board of Governors
of the Federal
Reserve
System.
“The Impact
of the Payment
of Interest
on Demand Deposits.”
Staff
Study,
January
31, 1977.
Feige,
Edgar
Substitutability

L.,

and Pearce,
Douglas
K.
“The
of Money
and
Near
Monies.”
Economic Literature,
XV (June
1977),

Harry
G.
“Problems
of
Management.”
Journal
LXXVl
(September/October

Economy,

Efficiency

of

in

Political

1968),

971-990

8.

Kimball,
Account

Banks.

9.

Klein, Michael
A.
“The
Implicit
Deposit
Rate
Economic
Concept : Issues
and
Applications.”
Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond,
(September/October
1978),
pp. 3-12.

“The Early History
and Initial
Accounts.”
New England
Economic Review,
Federal
Reserve
Bank
of Boston,
(January/February
1975),
pp. 17-26.

10.

McConnell,
C. Edward.
NOW Account Implications.
Keefe
Special
Report.
New York:
Keefe,
Bruyette
and Woods, Inc., 1977.

11.

Report of the President’s
Commission on Financial
Structure
and Regulation.
Reed O. Hunt, Chair-

Journal of

439-469

3.

Functional

4.

Gibson,
Impact

5.

Gilbert,
Gary G., and McCall,
Alan S. “The Transitional
Impact
of Nationwide
NOW Accounts
on
Bank
Earnings.”
Issues in Bank Regulation,
I
(Winter,
1978), 20-31.

6.

7. Johnson,
Monetary

Cost

Report
published
1977

Analysis:
by the

1977 Average

Federal

Reserve

System,

Katharine.
of NOW

Jacobs,
Donald P., and Phillips,
Almarin.
“Overview of the Commission’s
Philosophy
and Recommendations.”
Policies
for a More Competitive
Financial
System, Conference
Series No. 8, Federal
Reserve
Bank of Boston,
1972.

Ralph
C.
“The
Maturing
of the NOW
in New England.”
New England
Economic Review,
Federal
Reserve
Bank
of Boston,
(July/August,
1978),
pp. 27-42.

man.
Office,

12.

Washington,
1971.

D.

C.:

Government

Printing

U. S. Congress.
Senate.
Committee
on Banking,
Housing
Urban
and
Affairs.
NOW Accounts,

Federal Reserve
Hearings
before
on Banking,
on S.1664,
and S.1873,

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

Membership

and Related

Issues.

a subcommittee
of the Committee
Housing,
and Urban Affairs,
Senate,
S.1665,
S.1666,
S.1667,
S.1668,
S.1669,
95th Cong., 1st sess., 1977.

13

REGULATION Q AND THE BEHAVIOR OF
SAVINGS AND SMALL TIME DEPOSITS
AT COMMERCIAL BANKS AND
THE THRIFT INSTITUTIONS
Timothy Q. Cook

The behavior of small time and savings deposits at
commercial banks, savings and loan associations,
and
mutual savings banks is a matter of widespread interest for a number of reasons.
Part or all of these
deposits are included in various monetary aggregates,
which are widely viewed as important
determinants
of economic activity and play an important
role in
the formulation
of monetary
policy under current
Federal Reserve operating procedures.
In addition,
many observers feel these deposits have a significant
impact on the performance
of the housing industry.
Finally, the behavior of these deposits directly affects
the financial health of savings and loan associations
and mutual savings banks.
This article examines the behavior of savings deposits and small time deposits of less than $100,000
at commercial banks and the thrift institutions
(savings and loan associations and mutual savings banks)
in recent years.
Savings deposits are time deposits
on which 30 days’ notice may be required prior to
withdrawal.
In practice, however,
such notice is
seldom enforced and these deposits can be withdrawn
on demand without penalty.
Other small time deposits have maturities
ranging
up to several years
and are subject
to substantial
interest
forfeiture
penalties if withdrawn
prior to maturity.
The Federal Reserve Board sets interest rate ceilings on these deposits at member banks under Regulation Q of the Federal Reserve Act.
The Federal
Deposit
Insurance
Corporation
and the Federal
Home Loan Bank Board-in
coordination
with the
Federal Reserve Board-set
Federal ceilings on deposits at federally insured nonmember
banks, savings and loan associations, and mutual savings banks.
As will be shown in detail later in the article, the
movement
of small time and savings
deposits
is
closely related to movements in market interest rates
around these ceilings.
In particular,
when market
interest rates rise above Regulation
Q ceilings, the
growth rate of small time and savings deposits falls
14

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

sharply as many investors
withdraw
funds out of
the deposit institutions
to invest in market instruments.
Such behavior is widely referred to as “disintermediation.”
A Brief

History of Regulation
Q Because
of the
importance of Regulation
Q as a determinant
of the
volume of small time and savings deposits, a short
review of the history of this regulation may be useful.
Deposit interest
rate ceilings under Regulation
Q
originated with the Banking Act of 1933 and initially
applied only to rates paid on commercial
bank time
and savings deposits.
The purpose of the ceilings
was to prevent “excessive”
rate competition
for deposits that might encourage
risky loan and investment policies and lead to bank failures.
Until the 1960’s Regulation
Q was of little significance in U. S. banking.
There were two main
reasons for this. First, between 1933 and 1960 commercial banks showed little or no interest in competing for time and savings deposits,
leaving the
so-called “thrift deposit” market to other types of
institutions.
In the second place, market interest
rates through most of this period were below the
legal ceilings and market instruments
posed no serious threat to the ability of banks or other institutions
Only in 1957, after a
to attract thrift deposits.
gradual but steady updrift in market rates, did market instruments
begin to compete with thrift instituIn
that year, the legal ceiling was
tion deposits.
The only
raised from 2½ percent to 3 percent.
previous adjustment
in the ceiling was a reduction
from 3 percent to 2½ percent in 1935.
For reasons associated mainly with a continuing
updrift in interest rates and its impact on the ability
of commercial
banks to raise funds, this situation
changed dramatically
in the 1960’s.
Early in that
decade commercial
banks began to compete, with
increasing aggressiveness,
for both thrift deposits and
money market funds. Through 1961 and 1962, when
NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1978

interest rates were low following a recession trough,
they were able to do so effectively.
But as the business recovery progressed
and market interest rates
rose, the Regulation
Q ceiling, at a maximum
of 3
percent,
hampered
banks in their efforts to raise
funds.
At the same time, the philosophy
of bank
regulation,
which between 1933 and the late 1950’s
focused on limiting competition,
was evolving in a
direction
that placed emphasis
on increasing
competition, not only among commercial
banks but also
between the various types of depository institutions.
In this new environment,
the maximum
Regulation
Q ceiling was raised to 4 percent. and then to 4½
percent in 1964 and 5½ percent in late 1965.
The rising interest rates in the early and middle
1960’s affected banks and thrift institutions
differently, mainly because of differences in the asset composition of the two types of institutions.
For thrift
institutions
a large imbalance
existed between the
long-term
maturity
of their assets (primarily
mortgages) and the short-term
maturity
of their liabilities. As a result, it was difficult for them to compete
for deposits at current market levels without experiencing poor or negative cash flows. In order to discourage rate competition
for deposits among savings
and loan associations
in these circumstances,
the
Federal Home Loan Bank Board (FHLBB)
in 1964
and 1965 refused to make advances to institutions
Due
that paid above a specified yield on deposits.
to the value of FHLBB advances to savings and loan
associations in this period, this action by the FHLBB
constituted
de facto rate control.1
The average maturity of commercial bank assets is
much shorter
than that of the thrift institutions.
Consequently,
banks were better able to compete for
deposits on a rate basis when market interest rates
rose in 1965 and 1966. As the rate paid on deposits
at banks rose relative to that paid at the thrift institutions, the growth rate of deposits at the thrift institutions in 1965 and much of 1966 fell relative to the
growth rate at commercial
banks.2
This experience
provoked strong protest from the thrift institutions.
There was also a widespread
belief at the time that
1 The
rates

actions
taken by the
are described
in [9].

FHLBB

to control

dividend

2 In 1963 and 1964 the growth rates of time and savings
deposits
at the thrift institutions
were 12.0 percent
and
11.1 percent respectively,
while the growth rates at banks
were a comparable
11.8 percent
and 10.0 percent.
In
the growth
rate of deposits at the thrift
1965, however,
institutions
was 8.3 percent
while the growth
rate of
deposits at banks was a much greater
14.7 percent.
Similarly, in the first three quarters
of 1966 the annualized
growth rate of deposits at the thrift institutions
was 3.8
percent, while the growth rate at banks was 10.7 percent.

the decline in the relative growth rate of thrift versus
bank deposits was having an adverse effect on mortgage markets and the housing industry.
Congress
reacted to these concerns in September
of 1966 by
passing the Interest
Adjustment
Act.
The Interest Adjustment
Act expanded the coverage of deposit interest rate ceilings to the thrift institutions.
The purpose of this expanded coverage was
to prevent
“excessive”
competition
between
banks
and the thrift institutions.
By setting rate ceilings on
both banks and the thrift institutions,
it was reasoned,
loss of funds from the latter to the former could be
prevented in periods of rising interest rates.
This,
of savings
however, would not prevent withdrawal
and time deposits from both institutions
for investment in market instruments
that carried yields above
the Regulation
Q ceilings.
A second feature of the Interest Adjustment
Act
was the establishment
of a “differential”
between the
ceiling rates that banks and thrifts could pay on
deposits, which allowed the thrifts to pay a higher
rate.
The rationale underlying
the differential
was
that banks had an inherent
competitive
advantage
over thrifts because of the wider array of services
they could offer customers.
In order to offset this
competitive advantage, it was argued, thrifts needed
to be able to pay higher deposit rates.
The ceiling
rates on savings deposits were initially
set at 4.00
percent for banks and 4.75 percent for the thrift
The
institutions,
a differential
of 75 basis points.
ceiling rate for time deposits at banks was rolled
back from 5½ to 5 percent while the ceiling rate
for the thrift institutions
was set at 5¼ percent, a
differential
of 25 basis points.
These rates were
below comparable
maturity
market interest rates at
the time.
Since the passage of the Interest Adjustment
Act,
there have been major revisions
of Regulation
Q
ceiling rates on savings and small time deposits in
1970, 1973, and 1978.3 Each revision was a reaction
resulting
from rising
to declining
deposit growth
market interest rates. The first revision occurred in
January
1970 following
the sharp rise in market
interest rates in 1969. The 1970 revision established
three separate maturity categories of small time de3 It should be emphasized
that this discussion
applies
only to small time deposits less than $100,000.
The Regulation Q ceilings
on large time deposits
greater
than
$100,000 were removed in June 1970 for maturities
from
30 to 90 days and removed in May 1973 for longer maturities.
Also,
this
discussion
ignores
some
minor
changes Revisions
of Regulation
Q ceiling rates are summarized in the Federal Home Loan Bank Board Journal
and the Federal Reserve Bulletin.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

15

posits. Ceiling rates for banks were set at 5 percent
for time deposits of maturity up to a year, 5½ percent for l- to 2-year maturities,
and 5¾ percent
for maturities
of 2 years and over.
The goal of
this graduated
rate structure
was to lengthen
the
average maturity of deposits- at banks and the thrift
institutions,
in order to reduce the potential for large
scale withdrawals
in periods of rising interest rates.
The

ceiling

rate

for bank

savings

deposits

was

raised to 4½ percent.

The ceiling for thrifts

was set

at 5 percent,

reducing

deposit

differential
time deposit
points.

thereby

to 50 basis points.
categories

the savings
The differential

was maintained

in all

at 25 basis

When
interest
rates rose sharply
and deposit
growth rates plummeted
in 1973, Regulation
Q was
again revised.
Although the design of the July 1973
revision followed the lines of the 1970 revision, the
changes were more substantial.
The 1973 revision
raised the commercial
bank interest ceiling on passbook savings from 4½ percent to 5 percent
and
raised the ceiling rate on time deposits with maturities of 90 days to 1 year from 5 to 5½ percent.
The
l- to 2-year category was changed to 1 to 2½ years
and its ceiling rate was raised from 5½ to 6 percent.
In addition, two new categories were established
to
replace the “greater-than-two”
year category.
These
new categories were 2½ to 4 years and 4 years or
more. The 2½- to 4-year category was allowed a 6½
percent ceiling rate while the 4-year category initially
carried no ceiling at all. Deposits in the latter category were widely dubbed “wildcard”
deposits.
Because the wildcard deposits had no ceiling rate,
banks and the thrift institutions
could compete for
them freely.
This fact, in conjunction
with the declining growth rate of deposits at the thrift institutions during this period, fostered the belief that the
wildcard
deposits were responsible
for a massive
shift in deposits from the thrift institutions
to the
As a result, in November
of 1973 ceiling
banks.4
rates of 7¼ percent at banks and 7½ percent at the
thrift institutions
were placed on these deposits.
The differential
on all time deposit categories was
left at 25 basis points in the 1973 revision of Regulation Q, with the exception of the l- to 2½-year
category,
whose differential
was set at 50 basis
points.
The savings deposit rate ceiling at the thrift
institutions
was raised only to 5.25 percent, thereby

further reducing the savings
from 50 to 25 basis points.

This brief history of Regulation
Q raises a number
of questions.
For example, how do Regulation
Q
ceiling rates affect the growth of small time and
savings deposits at banks and the thrift institutions?
How successful was the substantial
1973 revision of
Regulation
Q in diminishing
the threat of disintermediation?
How has the rate differential
affected
the relative growth of deposits at banks and the thrift
institutions?

Table

PERCENTAGE
CEILING

REVIEW,

PAYING

ON NEW

DEPOSITS

180 Days
to
Savings
July

31,

2½ to 4

Years

4 to 6

6 Years

Years

or More

Years

63.9

47.3

80.3

86.3

31,

1973

76.1

81.2

92.3

95.4

January

31,

1974

79.0

87.1

95.8

96.4

56.6

80.8

89.5

96.6

97.6

62.1

82.7

89.5

97.1

97.7

69.8

April

30,

July

31,

1973

1 to 2½

1 Year

October

1974
1974

October

31,

1974

83.7

90.5

97.4

97.9

74.5

January

31,

1975

84.9

93.0

97.8

98.0

78.5

96.8

85.5

91.4

94.9

97.5

79.7

93.6

86.4

92.7

96.5

98.1

81.7

95.1

87.8

93.2

96.5

97.7

82.7

93.9

April

30,

July

31,

1975
1975

October

31,

1975

January

31,

1976

April

30,

1976

88.5

91.7

97.2

98.7

83.5

95.9

89.1

92.3

97.4

98.3

83.2

94.8

86.6

92.6

96.1

97.6

85.4

91.5

October

27,

1976

84.7

91.6

96.3

97.1

84.3

95.2

January

26,

1977

83.9

89.2

94.5

97.1

80.0

91.7

84.4

87.0

91.9

92.6

77.6

87.4

84.6

91.2

95.6

94.7

79.3

93.9

July

28,

April
July

27,
27,

1976

1977
1977

October

26,

1977

86.1

92.2

95.4

97.2

81.9

91.8

January

25,

1978

86.0

91.1

96.9

97.5

86.1

93.3

86.3

91.8

96.9

95.7

85.9

93.8

April

Notes:

26,

1978

(1)

Prior

to

the

paying

April

1975

highest

50

“percent

paying

ceiling

between

the

series

two

survey

basis

the

point

data

are

for

bracket”

rates.”

However,

is generally

less

“percent

rather
the

than

than

difference

2 percentage

points.
(2)

In

the

July

changed.

1976
These

1976

issue

Prior

to the

savings

4 In retrospect,

ECONOMIC

la

OF BANKS

RATES

of

partnerships

16

rate differential

In December
1974 yet another maturity
category
was established,
for deposits with a maturity
of 6
years or more.
The ceiling rate for such deposits
was set at 7½ percent at banks and 7¾ percent at
the thrift institutions.
A final revision, in 1978, will
be discussed later in this article.

(3)

there appears to be little evidence
that
the wildcard
deposits
resulted
in a significant
shift of
small time deposits
from the thrifts
to banks.
See
Kane [6].

deposit

organizations”
than
source:

Federal

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

the

July

domestic
Reserve

1978

the
ore

Federal
1976

and

category

survey
changes

sampling
described

Reserve

survey

all data

corporations

(IPC).”

shown
while

all

government
Bulletin.

is

the

was

December

Bulletin.
are

for

“individuals

other

categories

units.”

technique
in

for

“individuals,

Subsequently,
and
are

the

nonprofit
for

“other

Some

Survey

Results

Since the 1973 revision
of
Regulation
Q, the FHLBB
has conducted
semiannual surveys on the amounts outstanding
of and the
rates paid on the various categories of savings and
small time deposits at savings and loan associations.
Similar surveys, on a quarterly basis, of commercial
banks have been conducted by the Federal Reserve
since 1967. The information
provided in these surveys is useful in answering the questions posed above.
The survey data, collected from various issues of the
Federal Home Loan Bank Board Journal and the
Federal Reserve Bulletin, is presented below.
The Rates Paid The first set of survey information is the rates paid on the various categories
of
The percent of
small time and savings deposits.
banks paying the Regulation
Q maximum
rate is
shown in Table Ia and the percent of savings and
loan associations
is shown in Table Ib.5 Table Ia
shows that most banks have paid the ceiling rates on
all categories of small time and savings deposits since
the new ceilings were instituted
in 1973. For some
banks, however, there was a lag before the high
market rates of 1974 induced them to move to the
new ceiling rates.
In 1976 and 1977 some banks
moved away from the ceiling rates in reaction to
lower market interest rates, but most remained
at
When market interest
rates moved
the ceilings.
higher in the second half of 1977 and the beginning
of 1978, those banks that had lowered their rates
returned
to the ceiling rates.

The rate-setting
behavior
of savings
and loan
associations,
shown in Table Ib, has been similar to
that of banks.
Most savings and loan associations
have paid the ceiling rates in all maturity categories,
On average
except the 90-day to l-year category.
only 40 percent have paid the maximum rate on that
category.
As in the case of banks, some savings and
loan associations
moved away from the ceiling rates
on longer term maturities when market interest rates
declined in 1976 and 1977, and then returned to the
ceiling rates when market rates subsequently
rose.
Because the majority
of both thrifts and banks
paid the maximum rates on the various categories of
small time and savings deposits throughout the 19731978 period, these rates can be used as a measure of
the yields available
on such deposits during
that
period.
Chart 1 shows the differentials
between the
ceiling rates on small time deposits at banks and

5 Survey

data are also collected
on percent
of deposits
paying the maximum rate. The comments
in this section
would also apply ii the data were shown on that basis
rather than on the basis of percent
of banks.

Table lb

PERCENTAGE
SAVINGS

AND

CEILING

LOAN
RATES

OF

ASSOCIATIONS
ON MEW

90 Days
1 to 2½ 2½ to 4
to
Savings 1 Year Years Years
September

30,

Match

1974

31,

September

30,

March

1975

31,

September

30,

March

1976

31,

September

30,

March

1977

31,

September

30,

March

1978

Source:

31,

1973

1974

1975

1976

1977

Federal

PAYING

DEPOSITS
4 to 6 6 Years
Years or More

86.9
90.7

37.8

72.3

80.2

92.5

38.5

77.3

82.0

90.8

93.7

39.7

81.2

84.0

88.4

58.8

94.0

40.8

82.6

85.0

91.1

60.9

94.7

41.1

83.8

85.2

87.7

59.2

95.3

41.2

84.8

85.4

85.7

56.1

94.9

37.4

80.3

81.2

72.3 44.7

95.7

40.0

84.7

84.3

84.7

55.1

96.8

43.3

88.3

87.2

93.6

77.7

Home

Loon

Bank

Board

66.2

Journal.

rates on Treasury securities of comparable maturity.
The chart illustrates that the attractiveness
of a particular maturity
category can change greatly over
time.
In addition, the relative attractiveness
of the
various categories of small time and savings deposits
varies substantially
as the yield curve on market
Finally, the chart shows that
instruments
changes.
the yield on the 4-year or over category has been
the most attractive relative to market rates ever since
it was created in 1973.
Movement
in the Deposit Categories
Tables IIa
and IIb summarize
the information
from the surveys
on the amounts
of the various categories
of small
time and savings deposits outstanding
at banks and
savings and loan associations.
Table IIa
shows the
amounts outstanding
and percentage
of the total for
five categories of bank deposits, namely savings deposits and time deposits with original maturities
of
30 days to 1 year, 1 to 2½ years, 2½ to 4 years, and
4 years or more.
Charts 2 and 3 use the bank survey data from
Table IIa to plot the quarterly
movements
of (1)
savings deposits plus time deposits of less than 1year maturity and (2) time deposits of maturity of
(Together
these constituted
86
4 years or more.
percent of total bank small time and savings deposits
in the April 1978 survey.)
The movement
of the
differentials
between Regulation
Q ceiling rates and
market interest rates shown in Chart 1 is helpful in
understanding
the behavior of these deposits.
Chart 2 compares
the spread between the bank
ceiling rate on 90-day to l-year deposits and the
6-month
Treasury
bill rate to the movement
in

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

17

savings plus time deposits less than l-year at banks.
The chart
shows
that quarterly
movements
in
these deposits have varied over a wide range of -$l
billion to +$14
billion primarily
in response
to
wide swings
in short-term
market
interest
rates
around the Regulation
Q ceiling rate. A noteworthy
aspect of the behavior
of the short-term
deposits
shown in Chart 2 is the sharp drop in the growth
that accompanied
a relatively
small negative spread
in late 1977. This sharp drop can be attributed
to
the run-off of highly interest
sensitive
short-term
funds that had accumulated
over the previous yearand-a-half
when short-term
yields on money market
instruments
fell below Regulation
Q ceilings.
As shown in Chart 3, time deposits of maturity of
4 years or more have also varied with the attractiveness of that category’s yield spread, although the
variation
has been much narrower
than for shortterm deposits.
The sharp decline in inflows of the
18

4-year
maturity
during
the July-October
1977
period can be attributed to the run-off of the wildcard
deposits issued four years earlier.
A large amount
of these wildcard certificates
at banks were shifted
to the thrift institutions
in response to the 25 basis
point differential
available at those institutions.6
The survey data in Table IIa is also useful in
tracking
trends in the overall composition
of small
time and savings deposits.
The table shows that the
percentage
of total small time and savings deposits
with an original maturity
of 4 years or more rose
from 1.4 percent in July 1973 to 19.1 percent in
April 1978. The proportion
in 2½- to 4-year deposits changed little over the 1973-78 period while
the proportions
in 1 to 2½ years and 30 days to 1
year declined.
The proportion
of the total in savings
6 About
1973.

$27 billion of the wildcard deposits were sold in
Of these, about one-third
were issued by banks.

ECONOMIC REVIEW, NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1978

Table

ORIGINAL

MATURITY

OF SMALL

TIME

AND
($

Savings

Less Than

July

31,

1973

October

31,

January

31,

April

30,

July

1974

October
January

Total

Amount

124,086

54.4

42,963

124,217

54.1

38,944

126,175

53.4

129,928
131,701

AT COMMERCIAL

BANKS

Years

2½

to 4 Years

% of

Total

Amount

Total

18.8

48,170

16.9

45,543

38,638

16.4

53.6

37,592

53.6

36,107

4 Years

or Over

% of

% of

Amount

Total

21.1

9,841

4.3

3,203

1.4

19.8

11,576

5.0

9,506

4.1

229,786

45,037

19.1

13,262

5.6

12,954

5.5

236,066

15.5

42,670

17.6

14,391

5.9

17,592

7.3

242,173

14.7

41,006

16.7

15,326

6.2

21,364

8.7

245,504
246,574

Amount

Total

Total
228,263

1974

132,449

53.7

34,621

14.0

38,744

15.7

15,865

6.4

24,895

10.1

31,

1975

135,856

53.5

34,628

13.6

37,240

14.7

17,365

6.8

28,752

11.3

253,841

144,250

53.9

36,329

13.6

36,203

13.5

18,568

7.0

32,450

12.1

267,800
280,736

1975

31,

1 to 2½

% of

Amount

DEPOSITS

31,

30,

July

1974

1974

31,

April

1973

SAVINGS

millions)

1 Year

% of

IIa

151,965

54.1

37,443

13.3

35,872

12.8

19,500

6.9

35,956

12.8

October

31,

1975

154,282

54.0

37,262

13.0

35,397

12.4

20,318

7.1

38,603

13.5

285,862

January

31,

1976

165,470

54.7

38,424

12.7

36,006

11.9

20,453

6.8

42,070

13.9

302,423

178,190

55.7

40,019

12.5

36,093

11.3

19,357

6.0

46,399

14.5

320,058

180.698

56.2

39,773

12.3

33,008

10.3

18,690

5.8

49,281

15.3

321,450

187,506

55.8

41,761

12.4

34,002

10.1

18,402

5.5

54,098

16.1

335,769
352,363

April

1975

30,

July

1976

28,

1976

October

27,

1976

January

26,

1977

April

27,

July

1977

27,

1977

199,028

56.5

42,620

12.1

33,979

9.6

17,646

5.0

59,090

16.8

206,416

56.5

43,062

11.8

34,077

9.3

18,119

5.0

63,556

17.4

365,230

210,081

56.4

43,895

11.8

34,207

9.2

18,768

5.0

65,804

17.7

372,755

October

26,

1977

211,928

56.9

41,492

11.1

34,601

9.3

18,539

5.0

66,132

17.7

372,691

January

25,

1978

213,184

56.7

41,296

11.0

33,977

9.0

18,463

4.9

68,864

18.3

375,782

216,622

56.6

39,743

10.4

34,075

8.9

19,181

5.0

72,948

19.1

382,569

April

26,

Notes:

1978

(1)

Data

(2)

In

exclude

the

effect
Source:

July
on

Federal

domestic
1976

the

“percent

Reserve

government

survey

the
of

units.

sampling

total”

technique

calculations,

was

changed.

however,

appears

created

a

discontinuity

in

the

quantity

data.

The

Bulletin.

Table

ORIGINAL

This

negligible.

MATURITY

OF SMALL

TIME

AND

Ilb

SAVINGS

DEPOSITS

AT SAVINGS

AND

LOAN ASSOClATlONS

($ millions)

90 Days

Amount
-September

30,

March

1974

31,

1973

September

30,

March

1975

31,

1974

September

30,

March

1976

31,

1975

September

30,

March

1977

31,

1976

September

30,

March

1978

31,

Note:

The
this

1977

FHLBB

table

with

a rate

over

category.

2½-year
Source:

that

from

% of Total

Amount
--

2½

% of Total

to 4 Years

Amount
--

4 Years

% of Total

or Over

Amount
--

Total

% of Total

209,691

103,451

49.3

95,996

45.8

2,740

1.3

7,504

3.6

104,600

47.4

82,724

37.5

6,680

3.0

26,782

12.1

220,786

102,763

46.0

65,679

29.4

9,351

4.2

45,702

20.4

223,495

109,399

45.7

52,306

21.9

11,671

4.9

65,789

27.5

239,165

116,819

45.1

47,921

18.5

13,774

5.3

80,678

31.1

259,192

124,557

44.0

48,956

17.3

14,046

5.0

95,501

33.7

283,060

129,885

42.9

49,778

16.4

13,485

4.5

109,824

36.2

302,972

136,813

47.5

52,748

16.0

14,061

4.3

126,145

38.3

329,767

142,457

40.3

54,494

15.4

14,562

4.1

141,549

40.1

353,062

146,252

39.3

53,996

14.5

14,942

4.0

157,085

42.2

372,275

collects

are

to

2½ Years

Savings

the

deposit

certificates
6.51

Because

to

6.75
of

data

on

with a
the

are
way

rate
in

the
in

the

basis

equal

to

2½-

which

of
or

rote
less

to

4-year

the

data

paid

than a

category;
are

rather
6.50
and

collected,

than
percent

term-to-maturity.
rate

certificates

no attempt

ore
with

was

in the
a

mode

The
90-day

assumptions
to

2½-year

rate

greater

than

6.75

to

separate

the

90-day

used

to

category;
are
to

in

construct
certificates

the

1-year

4-year
and

or
1- to

categories.

Federal

Home

Loan

Bank

Board

Journal.

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK

OF

RICHMOND

19

deposits rose slightly
early 1978.

on net from mid-1973

through

Table IIb shows roughly the same breakdown
for
small time and savings deposits at savings and loan
Time deposits with an original maassociations.
turity of 90 days to 1 year and 1 to 2½ years
are combined in one category because of the way the
data are collected by the FHLBB.7
The table shows
that the trends in the composition
of small time and
savings deposits have been similar to those at banks,
although there are some significant
differences,
The
savings component
of total savings and loan association deposits fell from 49.3 percent in the September
1973 survey to 39.3 percent in the March 1978 survey. Another difference is that time deposits with an
original maturity
of 4 years or more had risen to
42 percent of total small time and savings deposits
by March 1978.

7 See note,

20

Table

IIb.

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

Table IIb also demonstrates
that the pattern
of
movement
of the categories
at S&L’s as market
interest rates have changed has been similar to the
pattern at banks.
The Maturity Profiles
The survey data in Tables
IIa and IIb are on the basis of original maturity.
The FHLBB
also collects data on current time-tomaturity of outstanding
deposits at savings and loan
associations.
These data, summarized
in Table III,,
provide the best information
on the impact of the
1973 Regulation
Q revision on the maturity
of outstanding deposits.
Table III shows that in the first
half of the five-year period there was a steady decline
in the proportion
of deposits highly vulnerable
to
disintermediation,
i.e., savings deposits plus time deposits maturing
in less than 1 year.
When shortterm rates fell below Regulation
Q ceiling rates in
1976 and 1977, however, the resulting huge inflow of
short-term
deposits had the effect of actually raising
the overall proportion
of deposits especially vulner-

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1978

able to disintermediation.
This shows up clearly in
Table III.
The ratio of savings and small time deposits maturing in less than a year to total small time
and savings deposits dropped steadily from 74.7 percent in the March 1973 survey to 63.2 percent in the
September 1975 survey.
Subsequently,
however, the
ratio rose to 66.7 percent in the September
1977
The March 1978 survey shows a drop back
survey.
to 63.6 percent in this ratio following the withdrawal
of interest sensitive short-term
deposits from S&L’s
in reaction to rising market interest rates.
The Federal Reserve surveys do not collect data
on the current
maturity
of outstanding
deposits.
However, it was shown earlier that the proportion of
total bank small time and savings deposits with an
original maturity
of at least 4 years had risen only
to 19.1 percent by April 1978.
Furthermore,
it
was shown that the proportion
in savings deposits
actually
rose slightly over the period covered in
Table IIa. Consequently,
it can safely be concluded
that the bank ratio of savings plus small time and
savings deposits maturing in less than a year to total
small time and savings deposits declined significantly
less over this period than did the S&L ratio.

Table

MATURITY

RESERVE

OF OUTSTANDING

AND
SAVINGS

SAVINGS
AND

SMALL

DEPOSITS

LOAN

TIME

AT

ASSOCIATIONS

(Percentages)

Maturing

Maturing

Within
Savings
March

31,

1973

September

30,

March

1974

31,

September

30,

March

1975

31,

September

30,

March

1976

31,

September

30.

March

1977

31,

September

30,

March

1978

31,

Source:

1973

1974

1975

1976

1977

Federal

Home

in 1 to

Maturing

Savings
+
Maturing

After

Within

1 Year

2 Years

2 Years

1 Year

50.4

24.5

21.4

3.7

74.7

48.8

27.8

16.2

7.2

76.6

46.5

27.8

9.8

15.8

74.3

46.0

23.5

7.9

22.6

69.5

45.7

18.7

6.8

28.8

64.4

45.1

18.1

7.6

29.3

63.2

44.0

17.5

13.3

25.2

61.5

42.9

19.0

15.7

22.4

61.9

41.5

24.3

13.6

20.6

65.8

40.3

26.4

10.6

22.6

66.7

39.2

24.4

7.9

28.5

63.6

Loan

Bank

Board

Journal.

ential has been insufficient
to offset the advantage
banks have in competing for savings deposits. On the
other hand, the survey data clearly do not support
the need for a 25 basis point differential
on the ceiling rate for small time deposits of 4 years or more,
which involve only one transaction
at the beginning
of a four- or six-year period.
The differential
has
apparently
induced most savers to place these deposits at the thrift institutions.

The Impact of the Ceiling Rate Differential The
survey data are also useful in assessing the impact of
the differential
between the ceiling rates at thrifts
versus banks.
From the September/October
1973
surveys to the March/April
1978 surveys, savings
deposits at banks rose $92.4 billion, while savings
deposits at S&L’s only rose $42.8 billion, despite the
25 basis point differential
favoring
S&L’s.
As a
result, the proportion of savings deposits at banks to
total savings deposits at banks and S&L’s rose from
54.6 to 59.7 percent. Over the same period, however,
small time deposits of original maturity
of 4 years
or more rose $63.4 billion at banks and $149.6 billion
at S&L’s.
Consequently,
the percentage
of small
time deposits of 4 years or more at banks to the
total of those deposits at banks and S&L’s combined
was only 31.7 percent at the end of the period. While
small time deposits of original maturity of less than
4 years declined at both banks and S&L’s over the
period, the proportion
of the total at banks rose from
49.3 to 57.4 percent.
As noted, the rationale for the differential favoring
S&L’s is that it is necessary to offset the inherent
competitive
advantage
that banks have in offering a
wide variety of financial services.
On the one hand,
the survey data appear to support this rationale with
respect to regular savings accounts, which typically
In fact, the
involve several transactions
over time.
survey data indicate that the 25 basis point differFEDERAL

III

The survey data is ambiguous
concerning
the impact of the differential on competition
for small time
deposits of original maturity
of less than 4 years.
As indicated, the banking sector’s share of these deposits has risen over the survey period.
A large
percentage
of S&L’s, however,
has not paid the
maximum
rate on small time deposits of less than
1 year.
(See Table Ib.)
Therefore,
the increased
bank share of these deposits can not necessarily
be
attributed
to an insufficient
ceiling rate differential.
Summary
the aggregate
to summarize
Reserve

of the Survey

Data

Before

turning

to

data, it may be useful, as a preliminary,
the major

and FHLBB

conclusions

surveys

of the Federal

:

(1) Most banks and S&L’s kept their rates at
the Regulation
Q ceiling rates throughout
the
However,
the proportions
of
1973-78 period.
banks and S&L’s paying the ceiling rates varied
somewhat
in response to movements
in market
interest rates.
BANK

OF

RICHMOND

21

(2) Since the 1973 revision of Regulation
Q,
the fastest growing
category of small time and
savings deposits at both banks and S&L’s has, on
average,
been deposits
of 4 years or more in
original maturity.
(3) When short-term
money market rates fall
to or below Regulation
Q ceiling rates, the depository institutions
experience large inflows of highly
interest sensitive short-term
funds, which are subsequently
withdrawn
when market
rates rise.
Consequently,
movements
of market interest rates
above and below the Regulation
Q ceilings (especially ceilings for short-term
maturities)
have continued to cause wide swings in inflows of small
time and savings deposits.

Rebate
Quarters
R

(4) Since the 1973 revision of Regulation
Q,
there has been a moderate decline in the proportion of small time and savings deposits at S&L’s
maturing
within 1 year.
While survey data on
current maturity
are not collected in the Federal
Reserve surveys, it appears that the proportion
of
small time and savings deposits at banks maturing
within 1 year has declined significantly
less than
at S&L’s.
(5) The 25 basis point differential
that the
thrift institutions
can pay on small time and savings deposits has not offset the advantage of banks
in the competition for savings deposits. The differential has, however, given the thrifts a competitive
advantage in the sale of long-term
certificates.
The Aggregate

Data
Chart 4 compares
the quarterly growth rates of total small time and savings
deposits at both banks and thrift institutions
to the
spread between the six-month bill rate and the ceiling
rate on 90-day to l-year deposits.8
The “X’s” show
the growth rates from 1968 II through 1973 II, while
the “O’s” show the growth rates from 1973 III
through 1978 II. Over the period shown in Chart 4,
there was a fairly stable linear relationship
between
the growth rate of small time and savings deposits
A demand equation based on
and the yield spread.
this relationship
is estimated in the Appendix
to this
8The aggregate commercial
bank small time and savings
deposit series used in this section was calculated
by subtracting
a series
on large time deposits
greater
than
$100,000
constructed
by the Board
of Governors
from
total time and savings
deposits.
The aggregate
small
time and savings deposits series for the thrift institutions
includes
all time and savings deposits,
because
data on
large time deposits
at S&L’s
are not available
prior to
1976. As of the end of 1977, however, large time deposits
constituted
only 2.4 percent of total S&L deposits.
Consequently,
the bias in comparing
the movement
in the
two series is quite small.

22

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

article.
A major exception
to the relationship
occurred in the second and third quarters
of 1975,
when the tax rebates boosted deposit growth rates to
higher levels than would have been expected given
the behavior
of market interest
rates at the time.
These quarters are indicated on the chart.
Chart 4 shows that yield spreads in favor of deposits have resulted in very large quarterly
growth
rates. Conversely,
large yield spreads (as high as 3
percentage points) in favor of money market instruments have resulted
in a negative growth rate of
small time and savings deposits only once during the
period.
To appreciate this aspect of the behavior of
the growth rate of total small time and savings deposits, it is useful conceptually
to divide depositors
into two groups, those who are sensitive to interest
There is
rate movements
and those who are not.
evidence that the two groups correspond
roughly to
large savers and small savers.”
Investors
in the
9Evidence
supporting
this view is provided in an article
by Goldman
[4] based on a survey of the behavior
of
savings
balances
by size at 25 S&L’s
during the I974
period of disintermediation.
NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1978

latter group have not been interest
sensitive
primarily because they have had limited access to money
market instruments.

reasons.
First, there were several other events in
recent years affecting the relative growth rates of
small time and savings deposits at banks and thrift
institutions.
Foremost
among these were the sale
of the wildcard deposits in 1973, two-thirds of which
were sold by the thrift institutions,
and the maturing
of these wildcard deposits in 1977. A large part of
the maturing wildcard deposits at banks were shifted
to the thrift institutions
and, perhaps, to other investments.
As a result, the growth of small time and
savings deposits at banks, compared to thrifts, declined in the second half of 1977.
The second problem
in comparing
the interest
sensitivity
of demand for small time and savings
deposits at the two sectors is that over the earlier
part of the period the large commercial
bank time
deposit data, used to construct the small time deposit
series, are probably not of very high quality.10
A
third relatively
minor problem is that while large
time deposits greater than $100,000 have been removed from the bank data, a small amount of large
time deposits remains in the thrift data.
Chart 5 compares the growth rates of small time
and savings deposits at commercial
banks and the
thrift institutions.
Clearly, the growth rates have
moved together over the past ten years.
There appears, however, to be some tendency for the thrift
growth rate to fluctuate less in response to changing
interest rates in the latter half of the period.
From
1973 through 1978 the growth rate of small time and
savings deposits at banks varied over a -0.9 to 24.2
percent range, while the comparable
range at the
thrift institutions
was only 3.7 to 17.4 percent.
Therefore, short of a firm conclusion,
the aggregate
data appear to support the view that the growth rate
of small time and savings deposits at the thrifts has
been slightly less interest sensitive over the last five
years than the growth rate at commercial banks.
In
any case, the similarity
in the behavior of the two
growth rates is much more striking than the difference.

When yield spreads are favorable to small time
and savings deposits, there is a large inflow of funds,
especially short-term,
from interest rate sensitive investors.
Hence, relatively
modest positive spreads
between Regulation
Q rates and Treasury
bill rates
have generally resulted in high growth rates of small
time and savings deposits.
On the other hand, when
the spreads turn negative,
interest sensitive
funds
return to the market.
However, investors who are
not interest
sensitive
continue
to put money into
deposits.
As a result, the growth rate of small time
and savings deposits has almost always been positive
despite the behavior of the interest sensitive group
of depositors.
Impact of the 1973 Regulation
Q Revision
Chart
4 provides no indication
of a decrease in the sensitivity of small time and savings deposits to movements in short-term
interest rates following the 1973
revision of Regulation
Q. That is, the relationship
between the growth rate of small time and savings
deposits and the spread between the bill rate and the
Regulation
Q ceiling rate appears very similar in the
1968 II - 1973 II and 1973 III - 1978 II
periods.
This is consistent with the survey data, which showed
only a small decline in the latter period in the proportion of small time and savings deposits maturing
within one year. Furthermore,
the regression equation reported
in the Appendix
provides additional
support for this observation.
Therefore, it is reasonable to conclude that at least through 1978 II, the
1973 revision of Regulation
Q did not reduce the
sensitivity of the growth rate of small time and savings deposits to movements
in short-term
market
rates relative to Regulation
Q ceiling rates.
Disintermediation:
Banks Versus Thrift Institutions
The FHLBB
and Federal
Reserve survey
data reviewed
earlier
showed that, compared
to
banks, thrift institutions
have a larger proportion
of
their total small time and savings deposits in longterm certificates and a smaller proportion
in savings
deposits.
Accordingly,
the percentage of small time
and savings deposits especially vulnerable to disintermediation was somewhat lower at the thrifts than at
banks. In view of the survey data, one might expect
total small time and savings deposits to hold up
better at the thrifts than at banks in periods of rising
Do the aggregate
data support this
interest rates.
expectation?
This

question

is difficult

to resolve

for

several

FEDERAL

RESERVE

The

1978

Emergence

Revision
of Money

of

Regulation

Market

Q

and

the

Funds

In 1977 and
early 1978 market interest rates rose to levels equaling or surpassing Regulation Q ceilings. At a result,
the growth rate of small time and savings deposits
10 The large time deposit data used in this study is based
on actual
survey data beginning
in 1973.
From
1968
through
1972, however, it is constructed
on the assumption that the ratio of large time deposits
to negotiable
CD’s at weekly reporting
banks was stable. The Board of
Governors
is in the process of constructing
a new large
time deposit series using some survey data in the earlier
period.
BANK

OF

RICHMOND

23

declined sharply.
The regulatory response was predictable:
Regulation
Q ceilings were again adjusted.
Two changes were made as of the beginning
of June
1978. The first change established a new category of
time deposits having a maturity of 8 years or longer.
The ceiling rates on this category were set at 7¾
percent for banks and 8 percent for the thrift institutions.
The second and more dramatic change in Regulation Q was the introduction
of 6-month
“money
market certificates”
with ceiling rates tied to the
average return
in the weekly auction
of 6-month
Treasury
bills. Banks are allowed to offer the average auction rate on these certificates.
The thrifts are
allowed to pay ¼
of a percentage point higher, the
usual differential.11
The minimum denomination
for
the new certificates is $10,000, the same as the minimum denomination
of bills at the weekly Treasury
auctions.
In the past, Treasury
securities
have been the
major
investment
alternative
for those depositors
whose demand for small time and savings deposits
has been sensitive to the movement in market interest
rates.
By providing
this group of savers with the
alternative
of receiving a yield competitive
with the
Treasury
bill rate, money market certificates
should
11 For a detailed description
of the actual yield calculation
for the money market
certificates
see Kasriel
[7].

24

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

work to raise the growth rate of total small time and
savings deposits consistent
with any given market
rate.
Money Market Mutual Funds
While the introduction of money market certificates is a development
that should decrease disintermediation,
another recent development
should work to increase disintermediation.
This development
is the emergence
of
the money market mutual fund as a major financial
market
institution.
Money market
mutual
funds
were established in reaction to the high interest rates
of 1973-74.
Many small investors
were prevented
from obtaining high market yields during that period
because they lacked sufficient funds to meet the minimum purchase
requirement
for Treasury
bills, let
alone the much larger minimum requirements
typical
of other money market investments.12
As of mid-1978 there were over 50 money market
mutual funds offering shares in portfolios of various
types and combinations
of money market
instruBecause the assets of these funds are shortments.
term, the yield on shares in them tends to follow
the yield on current money market instruments
with
a fairly short lag. Minimum purchase requirements
12 According to two recent studies, Pyle [8] and Hendershott
[5], the loss in interest to the small saver as a
result of binding Regulation
Q ceilings
in the three-year
period 1973-7.5 was $6 to $9 billion.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1978

are frequently
only $2500 and sometimes as low as
$1000.
Consequently,
money market mutual funds
offer the opportunity
to obtain money market yields
to those small investors who previously
were unable
to purchase money market instruments.
As market
interest rates in the latter part of 1977 and in 1978
rose relative to Regulation
Q ceilings, the purchase
of money
market
mutual
fund shares
expanded
sharply.
About $1 billion were purchased every two
months during the first eight months of 1978. The
level outstanding
as of August was $7.9 billion.
Implications
for Deposit Growth
The net effect
on disintermediation
of money market certificates
and money market mutual funds cannot be assessed
with certainty.
However, in view of the huge amount
of funds that have shifted from the deposit institutions into the Treasury
market in past periods of
high interest rates, it seems likely that the positive
effect of money market certificates will dominate the
negative effect of money market funds.
If so, the
growth rate of total small time and savings deposits
will be less variable than in the past. One conclusion
that can be made with a fair amount of certainty is
that without the 1978 revision of Regulation
Q, the
rapid growth of money market mutual funds would
have caused the growth of small time and savings
deposits to fall even more in periods of rising market
rates than it had in the past.
What is likely to be the relative impact of the
money market certificates
on the behavior of small
time and savings deposits at banks versus the thrift
institutions?
On the basis of the survey data examined earlier, it can be expected that, due to the 25
basis point differential,
these certificates will have a
greater impact on deposits at thrifts than at banks.
The very limited amount of data available as of this
writing supports this expectation.
Federal Reserve
data indicate that in the three months following the
introduction
of the certificates,
commercial
banks
sold $7.8 billion, while savings and loan associations
and mutual savings banks sold $14 billion and $5
billion, respectively.
The net impact on the growth
rate of small time and savings deposits was also
clearly greater at the thrift institutions.
The average
annual
rate of growth of small time and savings
deposits at the thrift institutions
was 7.4 percent in
the six months ending May 1978. In the following
three months the annualized
growth rate at these
institutions
rose to 11.4 percent.
The growth rate at
banks, however, only rose from 5.1 to 5.3 percent in
the same period.
The expectation that thrifts will benefit more than
banks from the money market certificates
assumes

that the thrifts will offer them at the maximum rate.
It is possible that at certain market interest
rate
levels many thrifts, because of the long-term maturity
of their assets, would no longer be willing to offer
the ceiling rate. In such a case, the relative impact
of the certificates
on banks versus thrifts may well
shift toward banks.
Large Time Deposits as a Response to Disintermediation
Total time deposits include large time
deposits, defined as those greater than $100,000, as
well as the smaller time and savings deposits that
have been discussed
to this point.
Regulation
Q
ceilings on these large deposits were suspended
in
June 1970 for maturities of 30 to 90 days and in May
1973 for all other maturities.
The surveys discussed
earlier showed S&L’s with only $10.8 billion of these
large time deposits in March 1978, while commercial
banks had $164.9 billion in April of that year.
Since the early 1970’s, sales of large time deposits
by banks in periods of high interest rates have more
than offset declines in inflows of small time and
In fact, while there is a strong
savings deposits.13
negative correlation
from 1972 through early 1978
between the growth rate of small time and savings
deposits and spreads between market rates and Regulation Q ceilings, there is actually a positive correlation between the growth rate of total time and savings deposits and market rates and those spreads.
Until recently the thrift institutions
had not raised
a significant
amount of funds through
large time
deposits.
Recent FHLBB
surveys, however, show
that from September
1977 through
March
1978,
S&L’s raised $2.2 billion dollars, or 10.5 percent of
their net increase of total deposits, through large time
deposits.
This was the highest percentage on record
and indicates
that some thrift institutions
are increasing the use of large time deposits not subject
to Regulation
Q ceilings as a response to disintermediation.
Regulation Q and the Monetary Aggregates
To
the extent that the 1978 revision of Regulation
Q
decreases the interest sensitivity
of small time and
savings deposits at banks and thrift institutions,
the
13 The inverse relationship
between the growth of small
time and savings deposits and the growth of large time
deposits is shown in Cook [3].
14 The correlation
coefficient
between the growth rate of
small time and savings deposits
and the spread between
the 6-month
bill rate and the ceiling rate on 6-month
certificates
was -.69
from 1972 I through
1978 I. The
correlation
coefficient
between
the growth
rate of total
time and savings deposits and the spread was +.26 over
the same period.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

25

relative

growth

rates

periods

of high

market

of the monetary
interest

rates

aggregates

stable over the 1968-78 period.
In particular,
there
appears to have been no decrease in the sensitivity of
the demand for small time and savings deposits to
movements
in short-term
interest rates following the
1973 change in Regulation
Q.

in

will be affected.

In particular,
the growth rates of the broader aggregates will be higher relative to the growth rate of M1.
Consequently,
a given M1 policy rule will result in a
more rapid growth rate of the broader aggregates in
expansionary
periods.
This has become a cause of
concern among those who believe the broader aggregates are more appropriate
intermediate
targets for
monetary
policy than M1.
Even
among
the broader
aggregates,
relative
growth rates are likely to be affected by the money
market certificates.
In particular,
in periods of high
market rates, the certificates probably will raise the
growth rate of M5 relative to the growth rate of M4
and also the growth rate of M3 relative to M2.15
This will occur because M5 and M3 include small
time and savings deposits at both banks and the
thrift institutions,
while M2
and M4 only include
Hence, small time and
those deposits at banks.
savings deposits are a larger component
of M3 than
of M2 and a larger component of M5 than of M4.16

The 1978 revision
of Regulation
Q introducing
money market certificates
should work to decrease
the sensitivity of total small time and savings deposits
to market interest rates.
However, other recent developments,
especially the emergence of money market mutual funds, should have the opposite effect.
While the net impact of these developments
is uncertain, the evidence to date suggests that the growth of
small time and savings deposits following the introduction of the money market certificates
has been
greater than in past periods of comparable
spreads
between money market rates and Regulation
Q ceilings. To the extent that the money market certificates
affect the interest sensitivity
of total small time and
savings deposits,
the relative growth‘ rates of the
monetary
aggregates
in periods of rising interest
rates will be different than in the past.

Summary

This article has examined
the impact
of Regulation
Q ceiling interest rates on the behavior
of small time and savings deposits at banks and the
thrift institutions.
It has attempted to show the close
relationship
that exists between movements in market
interest rates around these ceilings and movements
in small time and savings deposits.
This relationship
shows up clearly in the Federal Reserve and Federal
Home Loan Bank Board survey data as well as in
the aggregate deposit data. The relationship
between
the aggregate growth rate of small time and savings
deposits and movements
in short-term
interest rates
relative to Regulation
Q ceiling rates appears quite
15 M2 equals M1 plus small time and savings deposits at
banks plus large time deposits at banks other than negotiable CD’s at
weekly reporting
banks; M4 equals M2
plus
those large time deposits not included in M2, about half
of the total;
and M3 equals M2
plus time and savings
M5
deposits
at the thrifts
plus credit
union shares.
equals
M3 plus negotiable
CD’s
at weekly
reporting
banks.

References
1.

“Changes
in Time and Savings
Deposits
at Commercial
Banks.”
Federal
Reserve
Bulletin,
various
issues.

2.

“Changes
eral Home

3.

Cook, Timothy
Q.
“The
Impact
Deposits
on the Growth
Rate
of
Review,
Federal
Reserve
Bank
(March/April
1978),
pp. 17-20.

26

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

Fedissues.

of Large
Time
M2.”
Economic
of
Richmond,

Goldman,
Thomas
A. “Disintermediation
Microscope.”
Federal
Home
Loan
Journal,
(December
1975),
pp. 13-15.

Bank

under the
Board

Hendershott,
Patric
H.
“Deregulation
and
the
Capital
Markets:
The Impact
of Deposit
Rate Ceilings and Restrictions
against
VRMs.”
Paper
presented at “Deregulation
of the Banking
and Securities Industries
: Impacts,
Interactions,
and Implications,” a conference
sponsored
by the Center for the
Study
of Financial
Institutions
at the New York
University
Graduate
School
of Business
Administration,
May 18, 1978.
6.

“Getting
Along
Without
ReguKane,
Edward
J.
lation
Q: Testing
the Standard
View of DepositRate
Competition
During
the ‘Wildcard
Experience’.”
The Journal
of Finance,
(June
1978),
pp.
921-932.

7.

“New Six-Month
Money
Kasriel,
Paul
L.
Certificates---Explanations
and Implications.”
nomic
Perspectives,
Federal
Reserve
Bank
cago,
(July/August
1978),
pp. 3-8.

8.

“Interest
Pyle,
David
H.
Worth
Losses by Savers.”
rency Research
Workpaper

9.

United
States
and Loan
Fact

16 Specifically,

the interest
elasticity
(a measure
of the
responsiveness
to a change in interest
rates)
of any of
the monetary
aggregates
equals a weighted
average
of
the elasticity
of its components,
where the weight
assigned
each component
is its proportion
of the total
aggregate.
If the impact of the money market certificates
on the interest
elasticity
of small time and savings
deposits at banks and the thrift institutions
is the same,
then the interest
elasticity
of M3 would decrease relative
to that of M2 simply because the share of small time and
savings
deposits
in M2 is less than that is M3.
If the
time and savings
deposits
interest
elasticity
of small
drops more at thrifts
than at banks as a result of the
certificates,
then the interest
elasticity
of M3 would decrease even more relative
to M2.

in S&L Savings
Account
Structure.”
Loan Bank
Board
Journal,
various

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1978

Market
Ecoof Chi-

Rate
Ceilings
and Net
Comptroller
of the Cur77-3.

Savings
and Loan League.
Book,
1966 and 1967.

Savings

APPENDIX
THE

DEMAND

FOR

SMALL

TIME

AND

This Appendix
first estimates a demand equation
for total small time and savings deposits.
The equation is subsequently
used to test the hypothesis that
the introduction
of longer maturity
time deposits in
1973-74 succeeded
in reducing
the interest
sensitivity of the demand for small time and savings deposits.
The following stock adjustment
model was
specified in logarithmic
form :
(1)

log STSD

-

log STSD-1

=
-

The regression
results are reported in the Table.
Equation
(A) is the basic equation (3) above, Equation (B) adds dummy variables for the temporary
impact of the tax rebates, REB, in mid-1975 on the
holdings of small time and savings deposits.
The
equations are estimated using ordinary least squares.
The coefficients all have the expected signs and are
significant
at the 5 percent level.
In particular,
the interest rate spread variable exerts the expected
negative influence on the demand for small time and
savings deposits and has a very high t-statistic.
The
speed of adjustment
and income elasticity estimates
will be discussed below.

(log
STSD*
log STSD-1)

The hypothesis
demand

The desired level of small time and savings deposits is specified as a function of the spread between
the six-month
bill rate and the maximum
rate on
three- to, twelve-month
certificates at banks (SPR)
and GNP (Y) :
STSD*

Substituting
for
equation, we get

in the

the following

DUM

=

log

a + b SPR
+ (l-

+ clog
Y
)log STSD-1

REGRESSION

RESULTS:

THE

DEMAND

Dependent

(A)

log

STSD

Constant

SPR

-.4152

- .0089

(5.11)

(B)

log

STSD

-

.2866
(3.66)

(C)

log

STSD

-

.2659
(3.18)

Note:

The
Treasury

spread
bill

is
and

expressed
deposit

log

-

.0085

.0090

(10.59)

in
rates

percentage
ore

both

changed
by adding

to the equation:
SPR,

=

0

1968 II

to 1973 II

=

1

1973 III

to 1978 I

that the interest

sensitivity

time and savings

deposits

cient

FOR

log
STSD-1

of Q is positive

SMALL

TIME

REB

AND

REB-1

but very

for small
half of

small

and not

DEPOSITS

SE

Q

h

.9997

.0052

1.45

.9998

.0045

1.42

.9998

.0045

1.45

(21.07)

.8716

.0096

.0169

(23.66)

(1.99)

(3.48)

.1489

.8775

.0098

.0167

.0008

(3.34)

(23.15)

(2.02)

(3.42)

(.74)

FEDERAL

of the demand

SAVINGS

.1569

points

significantly
can be made

is less in the latter

of Q that is positive,

(3.65)

calculated

and

from zero, then the conclusion

.8144

(5.02)

(14.10)

-

Y

.2250

(12.81)

deposits

was tested

of the

the period.
Equation
(C) in the Table adds Q to
Equation
(B). The regression results show a coeffi-

This specification,
which was chosen on the basis of
the information
in Chart 4, constrains
the growth
rate of small time and savings deposits to be a linear

Variable

variable

If the coefficient

log STSD

sensitivity

adjustment
different

(3)

half of the period

Q = DUM •
where

stock

that the interest

for small time and savings

in the latter

= aebsprYc

STSD*

DEPOSITS

function of the yield spread.
The coefficient, c, is an
estimate of the income elasticity of the demand for
small time and savings deposits.

where STSD is the actual level of small time and
savings deposits at banks and the thrift institutions
and STSD* is the public’s desired level. The change
in STSD in any period is specified as a function of
the difference between the desired and actual levels
of STSD and the speed of adjustment
parameter

(2)

SAVINGS

and

the

on

an

RESERVE

variables
effective

BANK

are

measured

annual

OF

in

billions;

t-statistics

ore

in

parentheses.

The

basis.

RlCHMOND

27

significantly
different from zero. Hence, they offer no
support for the view that the 1973 changes in Regulation Q reduced the sensitivity
of the demand for
small time and savings deposits to movements
in
short-term
rates relative
to Regulation
Q ceiling
rates.
The speed of adjustment
implied by the coefficients
of STSD-l
are .l86 in Equation
(A), .128 in Equation (B), and .122 in Equation
(C).
The estimates
of the income elasticity (the coefficient of Y divided
by the estimate of ) are within a narrow range of
1.21 to 1.23. The estimates of the speed of adjustment and the income elasticity should be viewed with

28

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

caution since they are determined
by the coefficients
of log STSD-l
and log Y. These two variables are
highly correlated over the period.
The last column in the Table reports Durbin’s hstatistic, which is used to test for serial correlation
in
the presence of a lagged dependent
variable.
The
hypothesis of zero autocorrelation
can not be rejected
at the 5 percent significance
level. It can, however,
be rejected at the 10 percent level. The equations in
the Table were re-estimated
using the CochraneOrcutt procedure.
The coefficients
all were very
close to those reported in the Table.
In particular
the coefficient of Q was little changed.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1978

CORRESPONDENT SERVICES,
FEDERAL RESERVE SERVICES, AND
BANK CASH MANAGEMENT POLICY
Bruce I. Summers

An earlier article published
in this Review
[4]
discussed the operational and legal factors that determine bank holdings of cash assets.
It showed that
smaller sized nonmember
banks in the Fifth Federal
Reserve District have operating
cash requirements
that exceed by a substantial margin the legal reserve
requirements
to which they are subject.
Conversely,
smaller sized member banks are subject to legal reserve requirements
that cause them to hold more
cash assets than needed purely for operating
purposes.
Accordingly,
legal reserve requirements
for
nonmember
banks, which are established by the various states, are described as nonbinding.
On the other
hand, reserve requirements
for member banks, which
are set by the Federal Reserve within limits established by Congress, are described as binding.
The key difference between state and Federal reserve requirements
leading to differences in nonmember and member
bank cash asset ratios centers
around the definition of eligible reserve assets. State
requirements
allow banks to count several types of
cash balances, including
balances held with correspondent banks, as eligible reserves. Federal requirements allow vault cash and deposits with the Federal
Reserve, but not correspondent
balances, as eligible
reserve assets.
In general, correspondent
balances
are held by both nonmember
and member banks to
compensate
private correspondent
banks for services
received.
For nonmember
banks such balances serve
a double purpose since they also count toward satisfying the legal reserve requirement.
Many smaller
member
banks hold compensating
balances
with
correspondent
banks in addition to holding reservable assets as specified by Federal legal requirements.
The conclusion
that member bank, but not nonmember bank, reserve requirements
are binding is
an empirical finding based on comparisons of average
cash assets for the two groups.
Smaller member
banks on average hold more cash assets than their
But it cannot automatinonmember
counterparts.
cally be concluded from this that individual
member
banks must hold such excess balances.
The Federal

Reserve System makes available to member banks a
number of correspondent
type services free of explicit
charge.
To the extent that member banks substitute
Federal Reserve services for those of private correspondent
banks they may be able to operate with
smaller correspondent
balances and hence with lower
levels of total cash assets than otherwise.
Indeed, it
may be possible that, through intensive use of Federal Reserve services, smaller member banks may
reduce their total cash requirements
to levels comparable with, or even below, those of similarly situated nonmembers.
This article

examines

how use of Federal

Reserve

System services affects member bank cash management policy.
The first section reviews the types of
correspondent

services

The second section
able to member
indicates

banks

the extent

ized by member

that are important

describes

the services

by the Federal

to banks.
made avail-

Reserve

to which those services

banks

in the Fifth

District.

In the third section,

member

banks

using

System

Federal

are utilReserve

cash asset positions
services

and

heavily

of
are

compared with cash asset positions of other member
and nonmember
banks of similar size located in the
same state.
Conclusions
are summarized
in the
fourth section.
Importance

of Correspondent
Services
In mid1976 the American
Bankers Association
sponsored a
survey to determine the relative importance of different correspondent
services to respondent
banks [1].
Over 200 correspondent
banks participated
in the
survey.
They were asked to evaluate 39 specific
services in terms of how important
they were to
respondent
bank customers.
The survey participants
rated each of the ‘services on a scale of 5 to 1, where a
rating of 5 indicates “very important,”
a rating of 3
“slightly
important,”
and a rating of 1 “not at all
Table I ranks in descending
order of
important.”
importance
the 20 services receiving
the highest
average scores on the survey.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

29

Table

CORRESPONDENT

SERVICES

IN ORDER
AMERICAN

I

Correspondent
banks rate overline credit and liquidity loan participations
as the most important ser-,
vice they offer. The importance
to banks of a source
of liquidity
is indicated
by more than the number
one ranking given over-lines and loan participation
services, however.
Two other services, regular Fed-.
eral funds sales to respondent
banks (number four)
and participation
in term loans originated by respondent banks (number
seven), also receive high scores
and are directIy related to respondent
bank liquidity
needs.
These results suggest that immediate credit
availability to meet both temporary funds deficiencies
and longer term loan demands
is of foremost importance
to respondent
banks.
Liquidity
services
are widely available, with at least 90 percent of all
correspondent
banks
participating
in the survey
offering each of these services.

RANKED

OF IMPORTANCE

BANKERS

ASSOCIATION

SURVEY
Percent

of

Correspondent
Banks
Type

of

Service

Overline

and

liquidity

participation
Handling
for

EDP

sell

Federal

respondent

Purchase
than
Offer

own

fund

in

originated

term

Offer

to

of

bank

Actively

Offer

13.

Assist

to

14.

loans

sell

U.

capitol
adequacy

for

pools

17.

Provide

18.

Offer

19.

Assist

or

1 Average
importance
Source:

30

55

3.96

78

3.96

75

3.95

72

3.94

72

A third
significant

or

3.83

77

purposes

3.82

65

bank

3.74

98

3.71

19

3.65

83

3.46

63

to

customers
services

banks

by

improving

of

banks

in

a

international

transactions

220

correspondent

services

on

a scale

to

their

respondent

Clark

[1].

bank
of

5

bank

responses,

to

1 in

each

descending

of

which

order

customers.

ECONOMIC

general

category

of services

that

seems

is management

advice.

Portfolio

in importance

in Table

I, although only

of the

correspondent

banks

offer

advice
such

More commonly
offered is assistance
in
advice.
meeting capital needs (number
thirteen)
and advice
in improving
operating
procedures
(number
nineteen).

in

coin

tenth

55 percent

procedures

of
the

3.99

etc.,

transfer

range

93

respondent

and

respondent

full

ranked

to

respondent

banking

3.99

ranks

banks

point-of-sale

20.

RP’s,

investment

respondent

revising

93

acceptances,

currency

their

banks

banks

loans

for

4.00

municipal

participations

respondent

Assist

standards

CD’s,

of

92

in commercial

respondent

banks

4.03

meeting

sell

bankers’

loans

98

in

respondent

deal

negotiable

Sell

or

and
to

paper,

4.24

In addition to liquidity requirements,
certain service requirements
relating
to bank operations
also
receive high ranking.
Check collection is the most
important
of these operating
services, as indicated
by its number two ranking and by the fact that 100
percent of correspondent
banks offer it. Also highly
ranked are data processing services (number three),
fund transfers
(number
six), and security safekeeping services (number
eight).
Automated
clearinghouse services and currency and coin services are of
Correspondent
banks
somewhat lesser importance.
also act as agents for their respondents
in the purchase and sale of U. S. Government
and municipal
securities,
and money market instruments
such
as
commercial
paper, bankers’ acceptances,
and negotiable CD’s.

services

banks

raising

buy

94

S.

banks

capital

Actively

16.

ACH

respondent

securities
15.

to

respondent

Actively

4.25

to

and

access

90

portfolio

Govt.
and agency
securities
to respondent
banks
12.

4.26

and

banks

buy

80

banks,

stock

service

respondent
11.

banks

directors

a systematic

analysis

banks

respondent

including
Offer

4.42

safekeeping

respondent

loans

officers

100

loans

by respondent

to

4.55

other

needs

security

services

97

from

transfers

Participate

Provide

funds

banks

for

4.68

funds

banks

Federal

respondent

Service

to

banks

Regularly
to

banks

services

respondent

Score1

collection

respondent

Offer

Offering

loan

assistance

check

Average

REVIEW,

of

Respondent
banks reimburse
their correspondents
for the types of services listed in Table I primarily
by holding compensating
demand deposit balances.
Data processing
services are an exception
to this
general rule, however, with fees being more important than compensating
balances.
Among the banks
reporting
in the 1976 ABA survey, 63.5 percent
derived less than 5 percent of their total correspond.ent income from fees while 85 percent derived 20
percent or less from fees [1, p. 44]. Correspondent
banks expect to receive an increasing
proportion
of
their income in the form of fees in future years.
NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1978

Indications
are, however, that any movement towards
substitution
of direct charges for compensating
balances is quite gradual.
It seems clear, therefore, that
compensating
balances remain the dominant form of
reimbursement
for correspondent
services.
The Federal
Reserve
System offers services to
member banks that can be considered full or at least
partial substitutes
for five of the twenty services
listed in Table I. The discount window is a source
of temporary
liquidity
similar
to overline
credits
offered by correspondent
banks.
In periods of extreme credit stringency,
however, the discount window may be more reliable than credit lines with
private correspondent
banks.
Federal Reserve check
clearing,
wire transfer,
security
safekeeping,
and
currency
and coin services are available
to meet
respondent
bank operating requirements.
These five
services can be directly
compared
to the private
correspondent
services
ranked,
respectively,
first,
second, sixth, eighth, and seventeenth
in importance
in Table I. In addition to these five services, the
Federal Reserve also administers
a standardized
cost
accounting
system, called Functional
Cost Analysis,
that is available to member banks.
This is comparable to a private correspondent
budgeting service
ranked twenty-seventh
in importance
on the ABA
survey.
Clearly, the range of correspondent
type services
offered to member banks by the Federal Reserve is
not nearly as wide as that offered by private correspondent
banks.
Nonetheless,
System services are
among the most important
types demanded
by respondent banks.
Indeed, the Federal Reserve offers
four services that rank among the top ten in the
ABA survey.
Another
essential service, provision
of currency and coin, probably receives a relatively
low ranking from correspondent
banks participating
in the survey because of its wide availability through
Federal Reserve banks.
It would appear, therefore,
that member banks have the opportunity
to substitute
use of Federal
Reserve
System services for some
important
private correspondent
services.
Description

of Federal

Reserve

System

cedures of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.
A survey of System service use by all commercial
banks in the Fifth Federal Reserve District was conducted over the two month period December
1977January
1978. Survey results on the use of these
services by member banks with less than $100 million in deposits are summarized
below, with accompanying descriptions
of the major services.
Discount Window
Borrowings
by member banks
from the Federal Reserve are governed by Regulation A, “Extensions
of Credit by Federal Reserve
Banks.”
While the discounting
of eligible paper is a
valid method of making funds available to member
banks, in actual practice virtually all member banks’
borrowings
take the form of credit advances secured
by the pledging of collateral.
Acceptable
collateral
includes U. S. Government
or Federal agency obligations,
eligible paper, mortgages
on one-to-four
family residential property, and municipal
securities.
Extensions
of credit to member banks are of three
basic types: (1) short-term
adjustment
credit; (2)
seasonal credit ; and (3) emergency credit.
Short-term
adjustment
loans are made to assist
member banks in adjusting
their reserve positions
to unanticipated
deposit withdrawals
or unexpected
credit demands.
Such loans may technically be made
for periods of up to 90 days, but normally are made
for much shorter periods.
Banks that have filed a
borrowing
resolution
and lending
agreement
with
the Federal Reserve bank can execute borrowings
quickly and conveniently
by telephone.
Seasonal
credit is available for longer periods of time to assist
member banks that experience
distinctive
seasonal
patterns
in deposit flows and credit demands
that
give rise to expected needs for funds. The prevailing
discount rate is charged on all short-term
adjustment
and seasonal loans secured by U. S. Government
or
Federal agency obligations, eligible paper, or one-tofour family residential mortgages.
The rate charged
on loans secured by municipal obligations
and other
types of collateral, e.g., customer paper that does not
meet eligibility requirements,
must be at least onehalf of 1 percent higher than the discount rate.

Services

The availability
of correspondent
type services from
the Federal Reserve System is essentially the same
in all Federal Reserve districts.
Nevertheless,
some
regional differences
exist as a result of attempts by
Reserve banks to tailor their services to the operating patterns of commercial banks in the areas they
serve.
The descriptions
of System services that
follow can be taken as broadly representative
of such
services available on a nationwide
basis.
Some details, however, may be unique to the operating
proFEDERAL

RESERVE

Emergency credit is available to member banks encountering
financial difficulties that may involve an
extended need for funds. Emergency
loans to member banks may be made at a special rate established
by the Reserve banks subject to review and determination by the Board of Governors.
Currently,
the
emergency loan rate is set 1 percentage
point above
the discount rate. The special emergency rate is not
applied in those instances where the emergency arises
as a result of some natural disaster.
BANK

OF

RICHMOND

31

Use of the discount window by member banks is
tied closely to movements
in money market rates.
For much of 1977 the discount rate was above the
Federal funds rate, and this discouraged
borrowing.
Only 51 of all Fifth District member banks less than
$100 million in deposit size borrowed from the Federal Reserve in 1977. By contrast, this number increased to 74 through the first nine months of 1978.
Check Collection
Federal Reserve banks accept
for collection
as cash items from member
banks
checks drawn on other domestic banks that remit at
par. Checks are accepted from nonmembers
if these
checks are drawn on banks located within the nonmembers’ Regional
Check Processing
Center territory.
The Reserve banks also accept as cash items
U. S. Government
checks, postal money orders, and
food stamps.
The check clearing operations
of Reserve banks are governed by Regulation
J, “Collection of Checks and Other Items by Federal Reserve
Banks.”
The Federal Reserve check clearing system
is primarily
intended
to facilitate check collections
both regionally
and nationally.
Commercial
banks
using this system are encouraged
to exchange cash
items payable at other local banks on a direct basis.

clearings
of regular
items,
i.e., checks
payable
through other commercial banks, of 2,220 during the
December 1977-January
1978 sample period.
Member banks clearing with the Federal Reserve have the
option of charging debits and credits arising from
check clearings to their own reserve account or to a
member correspondent
bank’s reserve account.
Nonmember banks, however, are required to charge their
activity to a member correspondent
bank’s reserve
A survey of banks in the Eighth Federal
account.
Reserve District found that many smaller member.;
clearing checks through the Federal Reserve remit
for cash letters using a correspondent
bank’s reserve
account [2]. In the Fifth District, however, this is
an uncommon
practice.
Almost all member banks
clearing through the Federal Reserve charge clearing
activity to their own reserve accounts.
Wire Transfer
Member banks have access to the
Federal Reserve System communications
network for
the electronic transfer of funds between reserve acTransfers
in any amount over $1,000 are
counts.
made free of charge, while a service charge of $1.50
is levied on transfers
in amounts
less than $1,000.
Transfer
requests can be made by telephone and advice of the transactions
is made on the member bank’s
daily summary
reserve statement.
Member banks
receive detailed statements each morning for the preTransfers
of
ceding days reserve account activity.
funds are consummated
on the business
day requested when such requests are received before 3:OO
p.m. local time. Member banks with large electronic
funds transfer
requirements
can arrange
to access
the Federal
Reserve communications
network
directly with on-line computer equipment.

Credit for checks’ presented
for clearing is made
through
entries to member bank reserve accounts
according
to a schedule published
in the various
Federal Reserve bank operating circulars. Immediate
credit is given for all qualified regional items and
one-day or two-day deferred credit is given for items
payable at banks located in Federal Reserve districts
outside the Federal Reserve district where presentment is made. In many cases, delivery of cash letters
to Federal
Reserve offices can be made using the
Federal Reserve Transportation
System.
All checks
presented
to Reserve
banks for clearing
must be
Magnetic
Ink Character
Recognition
(MICR)
encoded
with
ABA
routing
symbols
and
dollar
amounts.
Moreover, banks with large check clearing
volume must sort checks by location category
in
order to receive the earliest possible availability
of
credit.
Any bank having a daily average number of
collection items not exceeding
5,000 items payable
outside the city in which it is located is, however,
exempted from this sorting requirement.
Such banks
may send one unsorted
cash letter to the Federal
However,
banks choosing this unsorted
Reserve.
option lose one day’s availability
on immediate credit
items.

Security Safekeeping
Federal Reserve banks will
hold for safekeeping both U. S. Government
and eligible Government
agency securities
in book-entry
form and other securities in paper form, called definitive securities, that are solely owned by member
banks.
In addition, Reserve banks will hold bookentry securities
for customers
of member
banks,
where the member banks act as agents for their
customers.

Approximately
one-third of Fifth District member
banks less than $100 million in deposit size deposit
checks for clearing directly with the Federal Reserve.
These banks had a daily average volume of check

Interest
payable on book-entry
securities
or the
proceeds of maturing book-entry securities is credited
to the reserve account of the bank for which the
securities
are held.
For definitive
securities,
the

32

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

About 72 percent of Fifth District member banks
less than $100 million in deposit size originated wire
transfers totaling three or more per month during the
survey period.
These banks initiated an average of
eighteen transfers per month.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1978

safekeeping
service includes cutting
and
coupons, receiving securities for deposit to
ing accounts, withdrawing
and delivering
held in safekeeping accounts, and collecting
securities.

collecting
safekeepsecurities
maturing

The security safekeeping service is widely used by
Fifth District
member banks.
During
the survey
period over 80 percent
of smaller Fifth District
member banks held either book-entry,
or definitive,
or both types of securities
in safekeeping
with the
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond and its branches.
Transportation
of Currency and Coin
The Federal Reserve banks have been responsible for meeting
the currency and coin requirements
of all commercial banks, member and nonmember
alike, since the
1920’s. Member banks have the choice of privately
contracting
for transportation
of cash or of using
transportation
services arranged and paid for by the
Nonmember
Reserve bank supplying
their needs.
banks must pay for their own transportation
requireMoreover,
nonmembers
must pay a fee to
ments.
the Federal Reserve for preparation
of currency and
coin shipments.1
Member banks in the Fifth District can receive
free currency and coin transportation
to their main
office and to one-third of their branch offices in each
town where branches are located.
Armored carrier
is the usual method used for transporting
currency
and coin, although mail delivery is also used to a
much lesser degree.
Transportation
service is provided once each week, although in areas where there
is unusual cash movement
more frequent service is
provided.
Over 80 percent of smaller Fifth District member
banks utilize this service, and all but a few have their
own reserve accounts charged for cash transactions.
System

Service

Use

and Bank

Cash

Asset

Posi-

tions

What
effect does utilization
of Federal
Reserve
System services have on bank cash asset
positions?
The benefits of these services to commercial banks can best be measured by examining
differences between cash asset ratios of banks using the
services and similar banks not using the services.
In
fact, smaller banks vary greatly in the intensity with
which they use System services
[2, 3].
If banks
using System services are shown to have significantly

1 This fee paid by nonmember
banks
to the Federal
Reserve
is a cost that does not appear in compensating
The compensating
balances
of nonmembers
balances.
receiving
cash service directly from the Federal
Reserve,
therefore,
somewhat
understate
their total payments
for
services
received.

lower cash asset ratios than banks not using the services, then there would appear to be a beneficial
effect. This effect can be approximated
by the potential earning power of the differential.
This potential
can be calculated roughly by multiplying
the corresponding dollar amount of the reduction in the ratio
of cash assets to total deposits by the average earnings rate on funds invested.
An analysis of this type has implications
for the
question of the cost or burden of Federal Reserve
Commercial
banks generally
System membership.
bear an opportunity
cost by virtue of being Federal
Reserve System members that is equal to the income
foregone on cash balances required under Regulation
D that are in excess of operating needs. Yet member
banks have direct access to System services at zero
variable cost, potentially
allowing them to substitute
free services for those obtained from private correspondents and paid for with compensating
balances.
It is likely, however, that some trade-off exists for
member banks between receiving services from the
Federal Reserve or from correspondent
banks.
This
trade-off arises in cases where System services are
not available in the quantity and/or quality demanded
by member banks but are available
from private
correspondents.
It is also possible that some member
banks view System services as being inaccessible,
due to, for example, geographic
distance
from a
Reserve bank.
Inasmuch as the question of the burden of Federal
Reserve membership
is purely one of relative costs,
it is important
to consider to what extent, if any,
nonmember
banks have access to System services.
If System services allow member banks to economize
on correspondent
balances, the same would hold for
nonmembers
to the extent that they are granted
access to these services. In fact, the Federal Reserve,
as part of its continuing
effort to improve the nation’s
payments mechanism,
has adopted a policy that extends limited payments services to nonmember banks:
nonmembers
are granted Regional Check Processing
Center (RCPC)
area clearing privileges on the same
terms as are member banks, except that they must
settle through a member correspondent’s
reserve acBasically,
each Fifth District
state is an
count.
RCPC area, an arrangement
that gives nonmembers
clearing privileges for most items drawn on banks in
their state.2 For small banks generally, intra-RCPC
clearings
probably
dominate
their total clearings.
2 There

is one exception
to this rule.
RCPC
includes
not only Maryland
and
Columbia,
but also seven northeastern
and four northern
Virginia
counties.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

The Baltimore
the District
of
West
Virginia

33

Therefore,
nonmember
bank access to RCPC’s is a
potentially
important
factor in offsetting the relative
advantage to member banks of using Federal Reserve
clearing services.

services

Method
of Analysis
Information
on the use of
five Federal
Reserve services over the two month
period December
1977-January
1978 has been collected for all Fifth District member and nonmember
banks operating
on June 30, 1977. Adjustment
for
mergers and conversions
out of the Federal Reserve
System leaves 681 banks with total deposits less than
$100 million.
Four possible combinations
of membership and System service utilization
are defined
using this survey information :

not interested

1. member

fully

using

Fed services

2.

member

not fully using

3.

nonmember

using

4.

nonmember

not using RCPC

RCPC

(MU)

Fed services
services

;

(MN)

(NU)

services

;

; and

(NN).

Member users are defined as those member banks
that clear checks in volume through the Federal Reserve and that use two additional
services from the
group including money transfer, security safekeeping,
Member nonusers
include all
and wire transfer.
other member banks.
Nonmember
users are nonmember banks depositing
directly with the Federal
Reserve for RCPC area clearing.
Nonmember
nonusers are all other nonmember
banks.
The number
of banks falling into the MU, MN, NU, and NN
categories are 107, 227, 56, and 291, respectively.
Mean values of adjusted cash assets to total deposits are computed for the banks in each of these
four categories
by state and within each of three
The size groupings
are: $0-25
deposit size groups.
million; $25-50
million; and
$50-100 million. Larger
banks are not considered in the analysis inasmuch as
there is a tendency for correspondent
banking activity
to increase with size.3 Differences in mean cash asset
ratios are examined
for three comparison
groups:
(1) member users versus member nonusers
(MUMN);
(2) member users versus nonmember
nonusers (MU - NN);
and (3) member users versus
nonmember
users (MU - NU).4
Analysis of these
differences will help determine whether use of System
3 Large
banks
maintain
cash

acting
as correspondents
are likely
to
balances
for different
reasons
than do
This could lead to
smaller,
noncorrespondent
banks.
variability
between
banks
alike in all respects
except
degree of correspondent
activity and thus invalidate comparisons
aimed at finding the influence
of System service
use on cash positions.

4 More

34

detailed

comparisons

are available

in [3].

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

is significant

economize
System

on cash

services

opportunity
concluding

in allowing
balances,

allows

member

and

member

whether

banks

costs of membership.
in the detailed
section

of the article

use

to offset

Readers

results

banks

to
of
the

who are

can skip to the

for a summary.

Empirical
analyses conducted by state and within
size groups test the hypothesis that there is no statistically significant difference between sample means.
If the difference between sample means is statistically
significant,
the hypothesis
is rejected.
It can then
be concluded that the membership-service
use combinations
being compared
have differing
influences
on bank cash asset positions.
Two different adjusted
cash asset to total deposit ratios are evaluated.
Differences in means and t-statistics”
for ratios having
demand balances due from U. S. banks, currency
and coin, and deposits with the Federal Reserve in
the numerator
are listed in Table II. This measure,
however, tends to overstate the cash asset ratios of
banks clearing through private correspondents
relative to banks clearing through Reserve banks to the
extent that private correspondents
grant immediate
book credit for cash items presented
for collection.
These items represent
uncollected
funds carried on
respondents’
books as correspondent
balances.
Such
an overstatement
would bias downward
the differences between the user and nonuser ratios.
A reliable measure of the proportion
of collected to
total correspondent
balances for Fifth District banks
is not available.
Nonetheless,
the possible downward
bias of the differences
shown in Table II can be
corrected by adding cash items in process of collection to the calculations.
Differences
in means and
t-statistics
for ratios having the same numerator
as
those in Table II, except for the addition
of cash
items in process of collection
(CIPC),
are listed in
Table III.
Table III is intended to adjust for possible overstatement
in the correspondent
balances of
banks that clear checks through correspondent
banks.
This adjustment
is not perfect since, for member and
nonmember
bank users of Federal Reserve clearing
services, it includes CIPC resulting from correspondent clearing activity [4]. To the extent that smaller
banks using System check clearing
services act as
correspondent
clearing
banks, the ratios including
CIPC bias upward the differences between the user
and nonuser banks.
Therefore,
careful joint inter5 The statistic

t = (D - H)/SD,
where D is the difference between
the two sample means;
H
is the hypothetical
difference
between
sample means,
or zero; and
SD is the estimated
standard
error of the difference
between the two means.
NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1978

pretation
of the results from Tables II and III is
necessary to gain insight into the differences between
cash asset ratios of user and nonuser banks.
Empirical Results
The results shown in Table II
support the idea that use of System services by member banks less than $50 million in deposit size leads
to economies in cash balances.
In all eight of the
comparisons
with member
nonusers,
the member
user category has a lower mean cash asset ratio.
The differences are statistically
significant at the .20
level or above in four of the cases.
In each of the
three cases tested for the $50-100 million deposit size
classification,
however, the member users have higher
cash asset ratios than the member nonusers.
Comparison
of the MU - MN and MU - NN
differences provides insight into the effects of System
service use on the costs of membership.
For example,
Table II shows that Maryland member users in the
$0-25 million deposit size group have a cash asset to
total deposit ratio .95 percentage
points less than
that of the member nonusers.
The member user ratio
is also 1.58 percentage
points greater than that for
the nonmember
nonusers.
These results suggest that
member users have higher opportunity
costs than
nonmember
nonusers,
but that this cost, expressed
in terms of cash asset to total deposit ratios, is .95
percentage points lower than that experienced by the
member nonuser group.
The lower opportunity
cost
in dollar terms for member users compared to member nonusers can be approximated
using the method
described earlier.
Assume a member user bank in
Maryland
has $25 million in deposits.
If this bank
maintains an average cash asset to total deposit ratio
that is .95 percentage
points lower than that of a
similar bank not using System services, then the MU
has available for investment
$237,500 more than the
comparison
MN bank ($25 million ×
.0095).
This
amount invested at 5.27 percent interest (the average
3-month
Treasury
bill rate for 1977) yields additional before tax revenue of $12,500.
Applying this type of analysis to the $0-25 million
size groups in other states shows for users of System
services an elimination
of the burden in two states
(South
Carolina
and Virginia),
reduction
of the
burden in one state (West Virginia),
and enhancement of an already advantageous
position in another
state (North
Carolina)
when comparison
is made
with nonmember
nonusers of the RCPC area clearing
service.
Comparison
with nonmember
users,
however,
gives a somewhat different picture.
In four states
(Maryland,
South Carolina, Virginia, and West Virginia)
there is some indication
of a moderation
in

the relative gains made by member users, as shown
by the greater differences in the MU - NU compared to the MU - NN category.
This suggests
that nonmember
users of the RCPC service in these
states are able to achieve cash economies.
For member banks in the $25-50 million deposit
classification,
there is a reduction of the membership
burden for users of System services in two states
(Virginia
and West Virginia)
when comparison
is
made with nonmember
nonusers.
This result is also
suggested in Maryland, although less strongly.
The
small number of member banks in the $25-50 million
group

prevents

Carolina

as complete

and South

Carolina.

ever, that the member
nonmember

nonuser

users

ratio

in three states
ginia).
nonusers
users.
lina

have
While

member

ratios

than

(Maryland,

In South

the evidence

the MU -

NN

Carolina,

nonusers
and Vir-

the nonmember

than

suggests

experience

and

that nonmember

however,
ratio

than the

Carolina

nonmember

North

Carolina,

a higher
users

in North
suggests

for North

II shows, how-

Comparing

NU differences

have higher

Table

user ratio is higher

lower in South Carolina.
and MU -

an analysis

the nonmember
that South Caro-

no burden

compared

to nonmember
nonusers, the relative burden is substantial and significant when the comparison is made
with

nonmember

users

of the RCPC

area clearing

service.
This evidence, which is based on comparisons
of
mean cash asset ratios that exclude CIPC, is not
completely
consistent
with evidence in Table III
based on cash asset ratios that include CIPC.
In the
eight cases tested in Table III for banks less than $50
million in deposit size, the member user group mean
cash asset ratio is less than the member nonuser
group mean in only five instances.
Of these five
negative differences,
only one is statistically
significant.
For member user banks $0-25 million in deposit
size, the results in Table III support those in Table
II suggesting a reduction of the membership
burden
in Maryland
and West Virginia and elimination
of
the burden in South Carolina.
In North Carolina
and Virginia, Table III shows larger mean cash asset
ratios for the member users than for the member
nonusers.
This is due to the large CIPC ratios maintained by these member user groups.
The small
North Carolina member user banks have a ratio of
CIPC to total deposits of .0413 compared to .0104
for the member nonuser banks.
The small Virginia
member user banks have a ratio of CIPC to total
deposits of .0320 compared to .0078 for the member

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

35

nonuser
banks.
If these high
high dollar volume of clearing
banks should not be considered
pared to the nonusers.

ratios result from a
activity, then these
disadvantaged
com-

users of System services maintain higher cash asset
ratios than do member nonusers.
When CIPC is
included, however, the member user ratios are even
higher.
This combined evidence from Tables II and
III suggests that member
user banks above $50
million in deposit size are acting as correspondents.

The results from comparison
of $25-50 million
deposit member user and nonuser mean cash asset
ratios that include CIPC are about the same as the
results based on ratios that exclude CIPC.
An exception, however, is Virginia:
no reduction
in the
membership
burden is apparent
when CIPC is included in the analysis of $25-50 million deposit size
banks.

This analysis offers some support for the idea that
member banks less than $50 million in deposit size
are able to economize in their cash balances by using
System services.
It is reasonable to expect, therefore, that these banks generate more revenue than
similar banks not using System services.
In order to
test this proposition,
the tax equivalent gross return
on loans and investments
as a percent of total assets,

The evidence from Tables II and III is consistent
for banks above $50 million in deposit size: member

Table II

DIFFERENCES

BETWEEN

MEAN

VALUES

OF CASH

(Excluding
THREE

MEMBERSHIP-SERVICE

USE
FIFTH

CALCULATED
Deposit

DISTRICT
JUNE

DEPOSIT

RATIOS

CIPC)1

COMBINATIONS

FROM

TO TOTAL

BY

STATE

AND

SIZE

GROUP

STATES
30,

1977

CALL

REPORT

Size

(millions
of

ASSET

Maryland

dollars)

North

South

Carolina

Carolina
Member

0-25

25-50

User

minus

West

Member

-0.0127

-0.0388

(-1.0039)

(-2.0936)**

-0.0195
(-1.4445)*

2

0.0185
(1.2026)

2

Member
0-25

25-50

0.0158

-0.0144

(0.8567)

(-1.2342)

(-2.4043)***

2

2

User

minus

Nonmember

Virginia

Nonuser
-0.0178

-0.0095
( -0.4879)

50-100

Virginia

- 0.0090
( -0.9242)

-0.0106

-0.0161

(-1.3834)”

(-1.2416)

0.0166

0.0031

(1.4321)*

(0.2485)

Nonuser

-0.0125
(-0.7912)

-0.0125

0.0066

(-1.3220)*

(0.6244)

-0.0002

0.0070

-0.0111

0.0091

0.0124

(-0.0132)

(0.4142)

(-0.6433)

(0.9759)

(1.4747)*

0.0186

50-100

2

2

2

2

(0.9308)
Member
0-25

0.0222

-0.0150
(-0.8693)

(0.7248)
25-50

-

0.0498

-0.0029

0.0228

minus

Nonmember

User

-0.0117

0.0090

0.0095

(-0.7821)

(0.4385)

(0.5740)

-0.0078

0.0381

(-0.2196)

(-4.3899)****
50-100

User

(2.6987)***

-0.0311

2

2

(-1.0802)

(1.0516)

1 Numerators
2 Number

of
of

**significant

36

exclude

observations

* significant

****

ratios

at

the

in
.20

at

CIPC.
least

t-statistics
one

group

are
less

in

parentheses.

than

two.

level

at

the

.10

level

***significant

at

the

.05

level

significant

at

the

.01

level

ECONOMIC

REVIEW,

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

2

(-0.3958)

1978

0.0431
(3.2370)****

is computed for the groups of member banks examined above.6 The calculations
are based on operating
income data from the December 1977 Report of Income and total asset data from the June 1977 Report
of Condition.
The average tax equivalent gross return on assets
of member user banks less than $25 million in deposit
size in the five states is 7.76 percent versus 7.70 per-

cent for member nonuser banks.’ This implies that a
member
user bank $25 million in asset size has
$15,000 more in tax equivalent revenue than a similar
nonuser bank ($25 million ×
.0006).
The average
tax equivalent gross return on assets of member user
banks $25-50 million in deposit size in the five states
is 8.09 percent, versus 7.89 percent for member nonuser banks.8 Again, this implies that a member user

6 The tax equivalent return is used in order to adjust for
possible
differences
in bank investments
in tax free
municipal
securities.
In computing
the adjustment,
interest
income
from municipal
securities
is multiplied
by factors
ranging
from 1 (for banks with zero before
tax income)
to 1.9231 (for banks with before tax income
of greater
than $400,000).

7 The t-value for a test of significance
for the difference
in mean returns is 0.5334, which is not statistically
significant.

DIFFERENCES

BETWEEN

MEAN

VALUES

8 The t-value

for a test of significance
for the difference
in mean returns is 1.7932, which is statistically
significant
at the .10 level.

OF CASH

(Including
THREE

MEMBERSHIP-SERVICE

USE
FIFTH

CALCULATED
Deposit

DEPOSIT

RATIOS

CIPC)1

COMBlNATlONS
DISTRICT
JUNE

TO TOTAL

BY

STATE

AND

SIZE

GROUP

STATES
30,

1977

CALL

REPORT

Size

(millions
of

FROM

ASSET

dollars)

Maryland

North

South

Carolina

Carolina
Member

0-25

User

minus

west
Virginia
Member

Nonuser

-0.0122

0.0181

-0.0301

0.0065

(-0.5949)

(0.8793)

(-1.6515)*

(0.9426)

-0.0097

2

25-50

2

(-0.6863)
50-100

0.0199

2

0-25

0.0146

0.0257
(1.8736)**

(0.8015)
25-50

50-100

0.0002

-0.0174
(-1.1363)

(3.5698)****
User

minus

Nonmember

0.0108
(0.8676)

Nonuser

-0.0061

0.0163

0.0113

(-0.3850)

(1.6456)*

(1.0252)

0.0005

0.0033

-0.0013

(0.0292)

(0.2167)

(-0.0741)

0.0282

-0.0031
(-0.3232)

(0.0187)
0.0306

2

(1.6166)*
Member

Virginia

2

0.0254
(2.5875)***

2

2

0.0140
(1.6749)’
2

(1.6037)*
Member
O-25

25-50

0.0004

0.0188

(0.0270)

(0.9555)

-0.0402
(-3.0725)***

50-100

minus

Nonmember

- 0.0055
(-0.3858)

- 0.0028
(-0.2470)

0.0153

User

0.0432
(2.9287)***

2

2

2 Number

of
of

ratios

include

observations

in

CIPC.
at

* significant

at

the

.20

level

** significant

at

the

.10

level

*** significant

at

the

.05

level

**** significant

at

the

.01

level

0.0303

0.0149

(0.9531)

(0.9952)

0.0107
(0.5062)
-0.0124
(-0.4958)

(0.8916)

1 Numerators

User

least

t-statistics
one

group

are
less

in
than

2
0.0459
(3.5699)****

parentheses.
two.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

37

bank $50 million
tax equivalent

in asset size has $100,000

revenue

($50 million ×

than a similar

more in

nonuser

bank

.0020).

Conclusions

Private
correspondent
banks supply
a large variety of services to other banks.
The most
important
such services satisfy commercial
bank liquidity requirements,
both temporary
(overline
services) and longer term (loan participation
services).
Services relating to bank operations,
however, are
also very important.
The Federal
several

Reserve

services

be close substitutes
services.

System

Reserve

banks.

These

temporary

credit through

collection,

wire transfer

securities.

There
banks

include
of funds,

be able to economize

are

of corre-

the availability
window,

of
check

and safekeeping

to believe,

using

services

survey

the discount

is reason

heavily

to

bank

types of correspondent

listed in a recent nationwide

spondent

banks

appear

correspondent

In fact, ‘four Federal

services

cost that

for private

among the ten most important

member

offers member

at zero variable

System

therefore,
services

on compensating

of
that

might

balances

held

with private

correspondent

banks.

If so, then mem-

bers heavily

using

services

might

System

reduce

the opportunity

costs

bership

in the Federal

Reserve.

associated

be able to
with

ECONOMIC

References
1.

Clark,
John S.
“New Study
Shows
spondent
Banking
Stands,
Where
Banking,
(November
1976),
pp. 42f.

2.

“Utilization
of Federal
Reserve
Gilbert,
R. Alton.
Bank Services
by Member
Banks:
Implications
for
the Costs and Benefits
of Membership.”
Review,
Federal
Reserve
Bank of St. Louis,
(August
1977),
pp. 2-15.

3.

Summers,
Bruce
J.
“Required
Reserves,
Correspondent
Balances
and Cash
Asset
Positions
of
Member and Nonmember
Banks:
Evidence
From the
Fifth
Federal
Reserve
District,”
in Proceedings
of
Conference
on Bank
Structure
and
Competition.
Chicago:
Federal
Reserve
Bank of Chicago,
1978.

4.

“Managing
Cash
Assets:
Operating
Balances
and Reserve
Requirements.”
Economic
Review,
Federal
Reserve
Bank of Richmond,
(September/October
1978), pp. 17-25.

mem-

Analysis
of Fifth District bank cash asset ratios
indicates that member bank users of Federal Reserve
System services less than $50 million in deposit size
generally
maintain
lower cash asset ratios than do
member nonusers.
Moreover,
these member bank
users also earn a higher tax equivalent
gross return
on assets than nonusers.
The higher return is especially strong for member user banks in the $25-50
million deposit size range, implying $100,000 more in
annual tax equivalent revenue for a $50 million member user than a nonuser bank.

35

The analysis also suggests that use of System services can lead to a reduction
or elimination
of the
membership
burden when comparison
is made to
nonmember
nonusers of the
RCPC area clearing
service.
There is some indication, however, that the
relative gains made by member users are moderated
when comparison is made to nonmember
users of the
RCPC area clearing
service.
Also, available evidence suggests that among member banks greater
than $50 million in deposit size, users of System services maintain higher cash asset ratios than do nonusers.
The empirical results presented in this article thus
support the conclusion
that use of Federal Reserve
System services can help reduce the opportunity
costs
of membership
for some small commercial
banks.
All member banks pay for these services by virtue
of holding required reserves, although relatively few
fully use System services.
Among the smaller member banks in the Fifth Federal Reserve District, it is
primarily the nonusers of System services that suffer
burdens of membership.

REVIEW,

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER

1978

Where
CorreIt’s
Headed.”