View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THE PURCHASING POWER PARITY DOCTRINE
Thomas M. Humphrey

Prominent among the many competing explanations that have been advanced to account for foreign
exchange rate movements in the post-Bretton Woods
era of floating exchange rates is the so-called purchasing power parity (PPP)
theory.
One of the
most popular, simple, and durable explanations of
exchange rate behavior, the purchasing power parity
doctrine holds that currencies are valued for what
they will buy. Therefore the relative external value
of two currencies, i.e., the exchange rate between
them, is determined by their relative internal purchasing powers as measured by the ratio of the general
price levels in the two countries concerned.
From
this it follows that changes in relative national price
levels determine changes in the exchange rate. In
particular, the theory predicts that the percentage
rate of change of the exchange rate will tend to equal
the differential between the relative rates of price
inflation at home and abroad. Thus if the domestic
rate of inflation in the U. S. is, say, five percentage
points higher than the comparable rate of inflation in
Switzerland, the theory maintains that the dollar will
tend to depreciate on the foreign exchanges at a rate
of five percent relative to the Swiss franc. It follows
from the theory that the way to strengthen a currency’s external value is to strengthen its internal
value by reducing the domestic rate of inflation. In
terms of the preceding example, the way to arrest
the fall of the dollar relative to the Swiss franc is to
bring the U. S. rate of inflation down into equality
with the lower Swiss rate.
With both currencies
experiencing the same rate of inflation (or fall in
internal purchasing power), their relative purchasing
power will remain unchanged and the exchange rate
will stabilize.
The foregoing view is scarcely new. Rather it is
the product of at least 175 years of past theorizing
about the connection between money, prices, and
exchange rates. It is no exaggeration to say that
the PPP doctrine has attracted the attention of some
of the leading monetary theorists of all time, including Thornton, Wheatley, Ricardo, Marshall, Cassel,
von Mises, Keynes, and Viner.
As proponents or
critics, these economists helped formulate, develop,
modify, and refine the central analytical propositions
of the PPP doctrine. The purpose of this article is
to identify and explain these propositions, to trace

their development in the history of economic thought,
and to indicate the extent of their survival in modern
versions of the theory.
What is the PPP Doctrine?
In essence, the PPP
doctrine is a theory of the determination of the nominal exchange rate and its movements in long-run
equilibrium when the trade balance is zero and the
real barter terms of trade and its underlying real
determinants are presumed to be constant.
Given
these conditions and assuming that all goods are
exportables, the equilibrium exchange rate can be
expressed as the product of the terms of trade and
relative general price levels, respectively. In symbols,
(1) E=TP/P*
where E is the exchange rate (defined as the domestic currency price of a unit of foreign currency),
T the terms of trade (defined as the real export cost
per unit of imports, i.e., the quantity of exports
given up to obtain a unit of imports), P the home
country price level, and P* the foreign price level.1
Via an appropriate
choice of units, the terms-oftrade variable can be normalized and set equal to
unity. This step permits the PPP theory to be stated
conventionally in its so-called absolute and relative
versions.
The absolute version of the doctrine states that
the equilibrium exchange rate will equal the ratio of
domestic to foreign general price levels, i.e.,
(2)

E = P/P*.

1 The derivation of Equation 1 is particularly simple in
the case where each country produces only one good,
part of which it exports to the other.
Trade balance
Equilibrium requires that the total value of each country’s
exports must exactly equal the total value of its imports
measured in terms of the same money.
For the home
country, this condition can be expressed as QP =
Q*P*E,
where Q is the quantity of physical exports of
the home country, Q* the physical quantity of its imports
(i.e., the quantity of the foreign country’s exports), P
the home currency price of home country product, P*
the foreign currency price of foreign country product, and
E the exchange rate defined as the home currency price
of a unit of foreign currency.
This expression says that
the values (quantity times price) of exports and imports
are the same measured in terms of the home country’s
money.
Solving this expression for the exchange rate
yields E = (Q/Q*)(P/P*),
where the first term on the
right hand side is the real terms of trade, i.e., the quantity
of exports given up to obtain a unit of imports. Denoting
the terms of trade variable as T, the foregoing expression
reduces to E = T P/P*, which is Equation 1 of the text.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

3

Original formulators of the doctrine stated it this
way, arguing that since currencies are valued for
what they will buy, the exchange rate between them
must equal their relative internal purchasing powers
measured by relative general price levels.
The relative version of the doctrine states that
changes in the equilibrium exchange rate will equal
changes in the ratio of general price levels, or, more
generally, that the percentage rate of change of the
exchange rate will equal the differential between the
percentage
rates of price inflation at home and
abroad. In symbols, the relative version is
(3)

e = p-p*

where the lower-case letters denote percentage rates
of change of the variables in Equation 2.
The foregoing brief statement of the doctrine, however, is hardly sufficient.
More than just the bare
conclusion that the exchange rate and its movements
tend to equal relative national price levels and their
movements, the doctrine also consists of a number of
interrelated propositions that support that conclusion.
The most important of these propositions refer to
(1) the international
equalization of price levels
measured in terms of a common currency, (2) the
corresponding international equalization of the value
of money, (3) the stability of PPP equilibrium, (4)
the neutrality of equilibrium exchange rate changes,
and (5) the causal role of money. Taken together
these propositions constitute the central analytical
core of the PPP doctrine.
Price Level Equalization
The first proposition
states that the equilibrium floating exchange rate
must equalize foreign and home country general price
levels measured in terms of a common currency unit
General prices must be
at the rate of exchange.
equalized across countries because if they were not,
goods would be a bargain in one country compared
to the other. Everybody would want to buy in the
low-price country and sell in the high-price one. The
resulting excess demand for the currency of the
former and the corresponding
excess supply of the
currency of the latter would force the exchange rate
into PPP equilibrium thereby eliminating the price
disparity.
That the condition of price equalization is implied
by PPP can be seen by rearranging Equation 2 to
read P = EP*, which says that home and foreign
price levels are the same when expressed in terms of
home currency units at the equilibrium rate of exchange. Likewise, price levels are also the same when
expressed in foreign currency units as can be seen by
arranging the equation to read P/E = P*. In short,
4

the PPP doctrine implies that a representative bundle
of goods will cost the same everywhere measured in
terms of either money. Neither country will enjoy a
price advantage over the other at the PPP exchange
rate. Nor will residents of either country be able to
purchase goods more cheaply at home with local
currency than abroad after converting local into foreign currency. Neglecting transport costs, Londoners
will find goods to be as cheap in New York as in
London and vice versa for New Yorkers.
Equalization of the Value of Money A second
PPP proposition refers to the international equalization of the value (purchasing power) of money.
According to the PPP doctrine, the equilibrium
value of money must be everywhere the same. For
if it were not, people would demand more of the
high- and less of the low-purchasing power money
on the market for foreign exchange.
The resulting
excess demand for the former money and the corresponding excess supply of the latter would cause the
exchange rate between the two moneys to adjust
until purchasing power was equalized and both
money stocks were willingly held, Equalization of the
value of money across countries is therefore a necessary prerequisite of international monetary equilibrium. For only if such equalization prevails would
there be no inducement to switch from one currency
to the other. Only then will both money stocks be
willingly held and the markets for money balances in
both countries be cleared simultaneously.
Note that equalization of the value of money is the
exact counterpart
of price level equalization.
By
definition, the value of money is nothing other than
And since the
its purchasing power over goods.
purchasing power of money in terms of a representative market basket of goods is simply the inverse
of the general price level l/P, it follows that equalization of price levels automatically implies equalization of the value of money.
That is, when PPP
prevails, any currency tends to command roughly
the same amount of goods and services whether spent
at home or converted into foreign currency at the
equilibrium rate of exchange and then spent abroad.
Thus a dollar will purchase no more in the U. S.
than it will buy in the U. K. after conversion into
pounds sterling at the equilibrium rate of exchange
and vice versa for sterling.
A third proposition
Stability of Equilibrium
refers to the stability of PPP equilibrium.
Regarding stability, the PPP doctrine contends that when
the actual rate of exchange deviates from the PPP
equilibrium, automatic responses tend to eliminate

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MAY/JUNE

1979

the deviation and restore the exchange rate to parity.
With respect to disturbances to equilibrium, the PPP
theory readily admits a host of factors-real
shocks,
expectations, speculation, capital flows and the likethat may cause the exchange rate to deviate temporarily from PPP.
But it also describes strong stabilizing pressures that work to correct such deviations
and push the exchange rate back toward equilibrium.
More specifically, the doctrine postulates an automatic self-correcting mechanism that keeps the actual
exchange rate hovering close to its equilibrium level.
This mechanism relies on the corrective influence of
price-induced shifts in international trade and the
associated shifts in the demand for and supply of
foreign exchange.
For example, suppose the dollar
price of the pound falls below its PPP equilibrium.
On the market for foreign exchange, the pound is
now undervalued and the dollar overvalued relative
The
to their actual internal purchasing powers.
undervalued pound makes British goods seem underpriced to Americans whose eagerness to purchase
them deluges the foreign exchanges with dollars seeking to buy pounds.
Conversely, the overvalued
dollar makes American goods appear overpriced to
Britons whose reluctance to buy them dries up the
supply of pounds seeking to buy dollars. The resulting surplus of dollars and the corresponding shortage
of pounds would quickly bid the exchange rate back
to PPP where the external and internal values of the
currencies correspond.
Via this self-adjusting mechanism the actual exchange rate would tend toward its
equilibrium value, i.e., the exchange rate would tend
to hover about the PPP.
Neutrality of Exchange Rate Changes A fourth
tenet of the PPP doctrine is that equilibrium exchange rate movements that merely reflect differential inflation rates have no effect on real variables
such as exports, imports, the trade balance, or the
terms of trade. These real variables are determined
by real (exchange
rate-adjusted)
relative prices.
According to Equation 2, however, the real relative
price term P/EP* is a fixed constant equal to one.
This means that movements in the equilibrium exchange rate exactly offset changes in the nominal
price ratio P/P*, thereby preserving the real terms
of trade between foreign and domestic goods.
For example, Equation 2 says that a doubling of
domestic prices relative to foreign prices will be accompanied by a corresponding
doubling of the exchange rate leaving real (exchange rate-deflated)
relative prices unaltered.
Since the real relative
price of domestic goods compared with foreign goods
is the same after inflation as before, the general rise

in domestic prices will not affect imports or exports.
The physical quantities of those variables will be the
same as originally and only the monetary units in
which they are measured will have changed.
In
short, the PPP doctrine holds that exchange rate
movements serve the purpose of offsetting differential
rates of inflation and thus leave real relative prices
and all real variables undisturbed.
Provided the exchange rate corresponds to PPP, its changes will not
affect real economic magnitudes.
Being perfectly
synchronized with price movements, such exchange
rate changes are entirely neutral in their impact on
the real economy.
Causal Role of Money
The fifth proposition
refers to the direction of causality between price
levels and the equilibrium exchange rate. Although
strictly
speaking the PPP
price-exchange
rate
an
equilibrium
condition
between
two
equality is
endogenous variables, it is often interpreted as a
cause and effect relationship.
Causation is typically
viewed as running from price levels to the exchange
rate rather than vice versa. In particular, many PPP
theorists argue that, in the long run when the determinants of the demand for money have stabilized at
their steady-state equilibrium values, national money
stacks determine national price levels which in turn
determine the equilibrium exchange rate.
If true,
this means that the ultimate determinant of the equilibrium exchange rate is relative national money
stacks and that the exchange rate moves over time
as the differential in the growth rates of the money
stocks. It also means that depreciation of the equilibrium exchange rate is a consequence rather than a
cause of domestic inflation.
Henry Thornton and the Origin of the PPP Doctrine The foregoing propositions
are hardly new.
They were enunciated early in the 19th century to
explain the behavior of the floating paper pound
following Britain’s suspension of the gold convertibility of its currency in 1797.
Henry Thornton
(1760-1515) was the first economist to clearly explain the operation of the self-adjusting mechanism
that keeps the exchange rate close to its purchasing
power par. In his classic The Paper Credit of Great
Britain (1802) he argued that a rise in the price
level in a country with an excess stack of paper
money would automatically
produce
a roughly
equivalent rise in the exchange rate. He explained
how a rise in British prices relative to foreign prices
would, at the preexisting exchange rate, make foreign
goods seem relatively cheap to the British whose
desire to acquire them would increase the supply of

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

5

pounds seeking to buy foreign exchange.
At the
same time, British goods would become relatively
expensive to foreigners whose unwillingness to purchase them would reduce the supply of foreign currency seeking to buy pounds. The resulting excess
supply of pounds and the corresponding excess demand for foreign money would immediately bid the
exchange rate up to the new PPP equilibrium consistent with the higher level of British prices. [11,
pp. 198-9]
Thornton was also the first to advance the notion
of the neutrality
of equilibrium
exchange
rate
changes.
He noted that the rise in British prices
would not act as an obstacle to British exports because the corresponding
change in the equilibrium
exchange rate would “obviate the dearness of our
articles” and “serve as a compensation to the foreigner” for the higher price of British goods. In this
manner, he said, the offsetting rise in the exchange
rate would “prevent the high price of goods in Great
Britain from producing that unfavourable balance of
trade, which, for the sake of illustrating the subject
[11, p. 199] Here is the
was supposed to exist.”
origin of the proposition that PPP exchange rate
changes cannot affect real variables like the balance
of trade since they merely offset divergent nominal
inflation rates and thus leave real (exchange rateadjusted) relative prices unaltered.
John Wheatley
Thornton’s
discussion
of PPP
took the foreign money stock and price level as given
constants. On this basis he concluded that the equilibrium exchange rate moves with the domestic price
level alone. His contemporary John Wheatley (1772
1830), however, extended his analysis by considering
variations in money and prices abroad as well as
domestically.
Wheatley concluded that the relative
quantity of money operating through genera1 prices
is the sole determinant of the exchange rate so that
the latter varies in strict proportion to relative money
stocks. He reached this conclusion via the following
route.
First, he asserted that “the course of exchange is
exclusively governed by the relative state of prices,
or the relative value of money, in the different countries between whom it is negotiated.”
[13, p. 85]
This, of course, is the absolute version of the PPP
theory stating that the equilibrium exchange rate
equals the ratio of domestic to foreign price levels
according to the relationship
(4)

E = P/P*.

Second, he argued that under purely paper monetary standards the level of prices in each country
6

varies in strict proportion to the quantity of money.
This, of course, is the rigid version of the quantity
theory of money which may be expressed as
(5)

P = kM and P* = k*M*

where M is the money stock, k is a constant coefficient equal to the ratio of the circulation velocity of
money to real output (both variables treated as fixed
constants by Wheatley),
and the asterisks denote
foreign country variables.
Third, he substituted Equation 5 into Equation 4.
This gave him the result that the exchange rate varies
in strict proportion with relative money supplies, i.e.,
(6)

E = kM/k*M*

= K(M/M*)

where K is the ratio of the constants k and k*. He
stated this result when he declared that “the course
of exchange is the exclusive criterion of how far the
currency of one country is increased beyond the cur
[14, p. 207]
rency of another.”
Wheatley commented at length on the key propositions of the PPP doctrine. Regarding the directic
of causation between price levels and exchange rate
he asserts that “variation in the state of the exchange
. . . is the effect, not the cause” of variation in price
levels. [13, p. 88] With respect to equalization of
price levels and the value of money he asserted that
“prices are everywhere the same” and that money
serves “as a uniform measure of value over the
whole world.”
[13, p. 59] Two things, he said,
operate to ensure price equalization across countries.
The first is exchange rate adjustment, which equalizes the common currency value of any given local
currency price levels. The second is commodity arbitrage, which equalizes the common currency prices of
internationally traded goods at any given exchange
rate. Regarding the equalization of prices by commodity arbitrage, he contended that the openness of
modern national economies rendered the law of one
price applicable to general price levels as well as to
the specific prices of internationally
traded goods.
As he put it,
The facility with which the reciprocal communications of nations is carried on has a necessary
influence on the markets of all, and approximates
the price of their produce to a general level. [13,
p. 45]

Nevertheless, he insisted that the essence of the PPP
concept consists of more than just the law of one
price. Specifically, he interpreted PPP as a condition
of international monetary equilibrium in which the
value of money is equalized across countries and exchange rate variations are the means by which this
result is achieved.
That this is indeed his view is

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MAY/JUNE

1979

evident from his statement that “the course of exchange constitutes the practical means, by which
money is enabled to discharge its functions over the
whole world as a uniform measure of value.”
[13,
p. 25] To Wheatley the central role of the exchange
rate is to clear all markets for money balances by
equalizing the internal purchasing power of various
currencies. It therefore follows that
fluctuations in the exchange exclusively arise from
the efforts of the different individuals of different
countries to reduce their respective currencies to
the same relative amount for the purpose of maintaining the general equivalency [of purchasing
power]. [13, p. 25]

Wheatley also discussed the stability of PPP equilibrium and the neutrality of equilibrium exchange
rate changes. His treatment of these issues is among
the more rigid and uncompromising in the literature.
Regarding temporary deviations from PPP, he flatly
denied they could occur. In his view, the exchange
rate is always at its equilibrium level and thus it is
impossible for currencies to be temporarily over- or
undervalued on the market for foreign exchange. In
other words, the self-equilibrating mechanism works
perfectly and instantaneously
to maintain the exchange rate at its PPP equilibrium.
Here is a supreme example of Wheatley’s tendency to apply the
PPP theory of long-run equilibrium to the short run
as well. This tendency is also manifest in his treatment of the neutrality issue. Regarding neutrality,
he argues that, because the exchange rate is always
in equilibrium, its fluctuations will not affect trade
in the slightest.
To summarize, Wheatley’s version of the PPP
doctrine is among the more extreme in the history of
monetary analysis. Not only did he argue that the
exchange rate is determined solely by relative money
supplies operating through relative price levels, he
also emphatically denied that real shocks could ever
affect the exchange rate. His position was that such
shocks, by affecting real national incomes, would
immediately alter each country’s demand for the
other’s product sufficient to maintain equilibrium in
the trade balance and the exchange rate. For example, he argued that a domestic crop failure requiring increased food imports would, by reducing British
real income and capacity to purchase, tend to force a
compensating contraction of nonfood imports leaving
the trade balance undisturbed.
Conversely, if imports
were not curtailed the resulting rise in British purchases from abroad would itself increase the income
of foreign exporters and so their demand for British
goods. Exports would rise to match imports thus
leaving the trade balance and the exchange rate unEither way, adjustment
would occur
disturbed.

frictionlessly through income changes without affecting the exchange rate.2 By ruling out real disturbances, Wheatley was able to assert that the exchange
rate never deviates even momentarily from PPP and
that causation runs in a strict unidirectional channel
from money to prices to the exchange rate. In his
view, exchange rate movements are always and everywhere solely a monetary phenomenon.
Others adhering to this extreme monetarist version
of the PPP doctrine were David Ricardo (17721823) and Walter Boyd (17641837).
They too
denied that real shocks could affect the exchange
Such shocks they regarded
rate even temporarily.
as automatically and instantaneously
self-correcting
having no impact on the exchange rate.
That is,
they simply assumed that the slightest real pressure
on the exchange rate would, by making British goods
cheaper to foreigners, result in an immediate expansion of exports sufficient to eliminate the pressure.3
In their view the exchange rate is always at the PPP
equilibrium determined by relative money stocks, and
rises in the exchange rate are solely and completely
the result of an overissue of currency.
Consequently they regarded exchange rate depreciation,
together with the premium on gold bullion, as constituting both proof and measure of excessive money
creation.
In other words, if the exchange rate
is 5 percent above its old gold standard par, then
this is prima facie evidence that the money stock is
also 5 percent in excess of its nonflationary level and
should be contracted.
The PPP doctrine also appears in the famous
Bullion Report (1810) where it is expressed in the
following words.
In the event of the prices of commodities being
raised in one country by an augmentation of its
circulating medium, while no similar augmentation
in the circulating medium of a neighboring country
has led to a similar rise in prices, the currencies
of the two countries will no longer continue to bear
the same relative value to each other as before.
The exchange will be computed between these two
countries to the disadvantage of the former.
[6,
quoted in 1, p. 91]

Like Ricardo and Boyd, the Bullion Report concludes
that exchange rate movements, together with the
premium on gold bullion, “form the best general
criterion from which any inference can be drawn as
to the sufficiency or excess of paper currency in circulation.”
[6, quoted in 1, p. 91]
2 Regarding Wheatley’s notion of the frictionless income
adjustment mechanism see Fetter [4, p. 47], Metzler [8,
p. 217], O’Brien [10, p. 149], and Viner [12, pp. 138-9,
295-7].
3 On this point see Fetter [4, p. 47], Metzler [8, p. 217],
and O’Brien [10, p. 149].

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

7

Gustav Cassel The preceding has specified the
key propositions of the PPP theory and has traced
their origin to Thornton and Wheatley in the early
1800’s. For the classic statement of these propositions, however, it is necessary to turn to the writings
of the Swedish economist Gustav Cassel during and
immediately following World War I. It was Cassel
who introduced the phrase “purchasing power parity”
into the literature.
He did so when he resurrected
the theory to explain the behavior of the dislocated
European exchanges during the war and afterward
in the hyperinflation
episodes in the early 1920’s.
His forceful and systematic exposition of the theory
was largely responsible for the popularity it enjoyed
in the 1920’s. His contributions to the doctrine include the following.
First, as previously mentioned, he christened the
theory with the name it bears today.
Second, he
clarified the concept of the PPP exchange rate, defining it in its absolute version as “the quotient
between the general levels of prices in the two countries” and in its relative version as “the old rate
multiplied by the quotient of the degree of inflation”
in both countries.
[2, p. 62; 3, p. 140] Third, he
redefined the somewhat vague notion of equalization
of the value of money to mean that “a certain representative quantity of commodities must cost the same
in both countries, if the exchange rate . . . stands at
its equilibrium.”
[3, p. 175] He points out, however, that this statement is strictly true only if the
representative market basket of commodities is identical for both countries.
Fourth, he reformulated and refined the neutrality
proposition in the following words.
the purchasing
power parity represents an
indifferent
equilibrium
of the exchanges in the
sense that it does not affect international
trade
either way. Thus a country’s export is not checked
by low rates of exchange? provided only these rates
correspond to a high price level abroad, or a low
level at home; nor . . . is export particularly
stimulated by high foreign exchange rates, so long
as they only correspond to the relative purchasing
power of the different currencies.
Similarly, low
prices of foreign currencies do not mean the encouragement
of import from abroad or keener
competition
for the home producers, so long as
these rates are merely a true expression for the
purchasing power parity of the foreign currencies.
On the same hypothesis high prices of foreign currencies do not in any way act as a check on import.
[3, p. 157]

Here is the classic statement of the proposition that
PPP exchange rate changes leave the real (inflationadjusted)
exchange rate unaltered and so do not
affect real exports and imports.
From this Cassel
drew the practical policy conclusion that no country
could increase its competitiveness in foreign markets
simply by deflating its price level. The deflation, he
8

said, will be matched by an identical fall in the
equilibrium exchange rate, leaving the real exchange
rate and hence real exports unchanged.
[3, p. 143]
Cassel’s fifth contribution was his identification of
the sources of temporary deviations from PPP and
his description of the self-correcting mechanism that
operates to eliminate such deviations.
Regarding
causes of temporary deviations from PPP, he specified (1) expectations of future depreciation of the
currency owing to anticipations of future inflationary
money growth, (2) speculation against the currency,
(3) forced sales of a country’s currency abroad at
arbitrarily low prices, (4) failure of export prices
to move equiproportionally
with general prices in
response to monetary shocks, and (5) random real
disturbances to the balance of payments.
For all
these reasons, he notes, a country’s currency may be
temporarily undervalued on the foreign exchanges.
Regarding the operation of the self-correcting mechanism in such cases, he writes that
as soon as a country’s currency is undervalued
compared with its purchasing power parity, it will
be of peculiar advantage to buy this currency, and
to employ the money thus obtained in procuring
commodities from that country. This stimulus thus
applied to demand will necessarily very soon raise
the price of the currency to the level of the purchasing power parity.
[3, p. 149]

Conversely, the corresponding overvaluation of the
currency of the other country will, by making its
goods seem overpriced on international markets, reduce the demand for its exports and thus for its currency.
If country A’s currency is overvalued and
B’s currency undervalued, then the
export from A to B must be largely checked . . . .
At the same time the import from B to A would be
artificially stimulated by such a valuation.
Indeed,
both these influences would tend to raise the value
of B’s currency in A, and to restore it to the purchasing power parity, which shows that this parity
is the true equilibrium of the exchanges.
[3, p.
158]

In short, deviations from PPP affect trade flows in a
direction that counteracts the deviation and represents a corrective to it.
Finally, Cassel elaborated on the issue of priceLike
exchange rate causality and its implications.
Wheatley, he repeatedly states that causation runs
from price levels to the equilibrium exchange rate,
i.e., that the latter variable is “determined by” or
[3,
“dependent upon” the ratio of the price levels.
pp. 141, 185, 186] More precisely, he invokes the
quantity theory of money to assert that money determines prices which in turn determine the exchange
rate. In short, he argues that the exchange rate is
determined by relative national money stocks operating through relative price levels. This means that

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MAY/JUNE

1979

relative national money stocks are the ultimate determinant of exchange rates. In his words, the exchange
rate between two countries “must vary as the quotient between the quantities of their respective circulating media.” [2, p. 62]
From the foregoing he drew two implications. The
first is that in a regime of floating exchange rates,
inflation is entirely homemade and cannot be imported from abroad. “An important consequence of
the . . . dependence of the exchange on the purchasing power parity,” he said, “is . . . that a rise in
prices in a foreign country can never cause a rise in
prices at home.”
[3, p. 145] For, assuming the
exchange rate is at PPP,
a rise in prices in a foreign country should have
no other effect than that of the country’s currency
being quoted so much lower that the prices on
goods imported therefrom remain unaltered.
If
the influence of the rise in foreign prices is carried
further, it is a sign that it has found support in an
independent domestic inflation.
[3, p. 167]

In sum, a rise in foreign prices will be offset by a
corresponding drop in the equilibrium exchange rate
leaving the price of imports, and so the domestic price
level, unchanged.
If the domestic price level does
indeed rise, it is because of domestic monetary expansion and not the rise of foreign prices.
The second implication is that exchange rate depreciation itself cannot cause domestic inflation.
A
rise in the equilibrium exchange rate, he said, is the
result, not the cause, of domestic inflation. He did
acknowledge that a rise in the exchange rate above
the PPP could produce import price increases. But
he denied that these import price increases could be
transmitted to general prices provided the money
stock and total spending were held constant.
He
maintained that, given a fixed money stock, the rise
in the particular prices of imported commodities
would be offset by compensating reductions in other
prices leaving the general price level unchanged. As
he put it
Only if the B currency were quoted above the PPP
could the high price of this currency have any
influence to raise the prices in country A.
But
even this influence would not be able to raise the
general price level unless it had the support of a
more plentiful supply of means of payment . . . .
[3, p. 168]

Ludwig van Mises Rivaling Cassel as the principal proponent of the PPP doctrine in the 1920’s
was the famous Austrian economist Ludwig von
Mises. It is not necessary to give a lengthy summary
of his writings on the subject. Three quotations will
suffice. The first refers to equalization of the value
of money, the second to the stability of equilibrium,
and the third to the causal role of money- all key

propositions of the PPP doctrine. Regarding
zation of the value of money, he states that

equali-

exchange rates must eventually be established at a
height at which it makes no difference
whether
one uses a piece of money directly to buy a commodity, or whether one first exchanges this money
for units of a foreign currency and then spends
that foreign currency for the desired commodity.
[9 p.
30]

The operation of the self-equilibrating mechanism
is described by von Mises in the following words.
Should the rate deviate from that determined by
the purchasing power parity . . . an opportunity
would emerge for undertaking profit-making
ventures. It would then be profitable to buy commodities with the money which is legally undervalued
on the exchange, as compared with its purchasing
power parity, and to sell those commodities for
that money which is legally overvalued on the
exchange, as compared with its actual purchasing
Whenever such opportunities
for profit
power.
exist, buyers would appear on the foreign exchange
market with a demand for the undervalued money.
This demand drives the exchange
up until it
reaches its “final rate” [i.e., the PPP].
[9, pp.
30-1]

Finally, with respect to the causal role of money
in the determination of the equilibrium exchange rate,
he states the “exchange rates rise because the quantity of the domestic money has increased and commodity prices have risen.” [9, p. 31]
Criticisms of the PPP Doctrine
Even at the
height of its popularity in the 1920’s the PPP doctrine was the target of severe criticism. Critics such
as Frank Taussig, J. M. Keynes, A. C. Pigou, and
Jacob Viner contended that the theory suffered from
certain crippling defects. For one thing, it overlooks
factors other than relative price levels that determine
exchange rates.
Consisting of the terms of trade,
obstacles to trade (tariffs, transport costs and the
like), and the structure of prices in both countries,
these factors may produce a permanent disparity between the equilibrium exchange rate and the calcuMoreover, their movements
lated absolute PPP.
over time tend to generate a persistent discrepancy
between exchange rate movements and those of the
PPP thus invalidating the relative version of the
doctrine. For example, changes in the terms of trade
caused by shifts in international demand would produce permanent changes in the equilibrium exchange
rate even if PPP remained unchanged.
Likewise
changes in tariffs and transport costs as well as alterations in the relationship between export prices and
general prices in either country would prevent the
equilibrium exchange rate from adhering to the path
dictated by PPP. Discrepancies may also stem from
the existence of nontraded (purely domestic) goods
whose prices have no close connection with the ex-

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

9

change rate although they do enter the general price
levels used to compute the PPP.
For these reasons
the critics argued that the doctrine is incorrect when
applied to general price levels. They held that it was
valid only when restricted to the prices of internationally traded goods in which case, to use Keynes’s
expression, it becomes a “truism, and as nearly as
possible jejune.”
[7, p. 75]
Bresciani-Turroni’s
Critique The foregoing criticisms were themselves evaluated in a famous 1934
paper by the Italian economist Costantino BrescianiTurroni.
In what is perhaps the most rigorous and
systematic analysis of the PPP doctrine to be found
in the economic literature, Bresciani-Turroni
concluded (1) that the absolute version of the doctrine
is indeed generally incorrect, (2) that the relative
version, however, is theoretically correct in the case
of monetary but not real shocks, and (3) that, as an
empirical matter, the relative version may be approximately correct even in the latter case. In so doing
he provided a masterful defense of the relative version of the theory.
The foregoing conclusions were derived by Bresciani-Turroni
on the basis of a simple analytical
model which he constructed via the following steps.
First, he assumed that tariffs, transport costs, and
other obstacles to trade tend to raise the supply price
of each country’s exports by a certain fraction. Thus
if Px and
are the domestic prices of a unit of
home and foreign country exportables, respectively,
and t and t* represent the fraction by which those
prices are raised by obstacles to trade, then the total
supply prices to buyers of the countries’ exports will
be Px(l+t)
and
(1+t*),
respectively.
These
expressions state that the price of goods in the buying
market must exceed the price in the selling market
by the cost of transport and tariffs.
Second, he argued that long-run equilibrium requires that the total value of each country’s exports
be exactly equal to the total value of its imports
measured in terms of a common currency.
For the
home country, this zero trade balance equilibrium
condition can be expressed as
(7) QPx(l+t)

=

Q*Px*(l+t*)E

where Q is the quantity of physical exports of the
home country, Q* the physical quantity of its imports (i.e., the quantity of the foreign country’s
exports), PX(l+t)
the home currency supply price
(including transport costs) of home country exports,
(1+t*)
the foreign currency supply price of
foreign country exports, and E the exchange rate
10

defined as the home currency price of a unit of foreign currency.
Third, he assumed that the domestic price of each
country’s exportables can be linked to general price
levels P and P* via the following relationships
(8)

Px =

RP and

= R*P*

where R and R* denote the equilibrium ratio of
export prices to general prices in each country, as
can be seen by expressing the equations in the form
R = Px/P and R* = /P*.
Representing the
equilibrium relative prices of exportables in terms of
general price levels at home and abroad, these equations summarize the equilibrium structure of prices
in the two countries concerned.
Finally, he substituted Equation 8 into Equation 7
and solved for the equilibrium exchange rate thereby
obtaining the expression

which says that the equilibrium exchange rate is the
product of four determinants,
namely the unobstructed barter terms of trade, relative transport and
tariff costs, relative price structures, and the PPP,
respectively.
Regarding these determinants,
note
that the terms of trade variable shows the quantity
of exports the home country must give up in the
absence of tariff and transport costs to obtain a unit
of imports (the other country’s exports) and thus
represents the real cost of obtaining the latter in
terms of the amount of the export good sacrificed.
Determined by real factors such as tastes, technology,
and resource endowments, the terms of trade variable
captures nonmonetary
influences affecting the exchange rate.
The relative tariff and transport
cost variable
shows the impact on the exchange rate of natural and
artificial obstacles to trade.
Note that when these
obstacles are identical both for exports and imports
such that t=t*, the ratio reduces to one and thus
cannot distort the exchange rate from the PPP. Only
if trade barriers are more severe in one direction
than another, i.e., exports and imports are hampered
unequally, would such distortion exist.
The remaining determinants can be summarized
briefly.
The price structure variable compares the
relationship between export prices and general price
levels at home and abroad.
Unless both countries
possess identical price structures, this determinant
will cause a persistent discrepancy between the equilibrium exchange rate and the PPP. Note also that
the price structure variable is determined not by
monetary but by real factors (e.g., tastes, technology,

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MAY/JUNE

1979

resource supplies), which means that it is largely
invariant to monetary changes. By contrast, the PPP
variable is, in Bresciani-Turroni’s
own words, determined by “the monetary conditions particular to each
country” and thus varies with changes in relative
money stocks. [1, p. 93]
On the basis of Equation 9, Bresciani-Turroni
reached the following conclusions regarding
the
validity of the PPP theory. First, the absolute version of the theory is generally incorrect.
Evidently
the equilibrium condition is not “exchange rate equals
PPP” but rather “exchange rate equals PPP multiplied by the terms of trade, relative obstacles to
trade, and relative internal price structures.”
These
other things may cause the equilibrium exchange rate
to deviate permanently from the PPP.
Second, the relative version of the doctrine remains valid if these other factors are constant. That
is, other things remaining the same, the exchange
rate varies equiproportionally
with relative price
levels as predicted by the theory. This can be demonstrated by holding the other factors constant in Equation 9 and letting the PPP double or quadruple. The
changes in the PPP will be matched by a corresponding doubling or quadrupling of the exchange rate.
Third, whether other things remain the same depends upon whether disturbances emanate from the
Purely
monetary or real sectors of the economy.
monetary disturbances will not affect the long-run
equilibrium values of the non-PPP determinants of
the exchange rate.
These determinants
are real
variables.
As such they are largely invariant to
monetary shocks. In long-run equilibrium the latter
affect only price levels and the PPP.
It therefore
follows that the relative version of the theory holds
in the case of monetary changes.
Fourth, in sharp contrast to purely monetary disturbances, real disturbances will indeed alter the
non-PPP
determinants of the exchange rate, thus
producing systematic divergences between exchange
rate variations and those of the PPP.
This means
that the relative version will not hold exactly in the
case of real changes. Nevertheless, it may hold at
least approximately if the real effects are small. And,
according to Bresciani-Turroni,
that is exactly what
one would expect to find. He maintained that there
are limits to how far away from the PPP real disturbances can distort the exchange rate. These limits
are set by the price sensitivity (elasticity) of international demands.
If this sensitivity is high, then
even slight deviations from PPP will invoke large
price-induced shifts in trade sufficient to check further deviations. It follows, he said, that “when international demands are very elastic, which happens in

the case of modern industrial countries with a considerable resourcefulness
of supply,” the influence
of real changes on exchange rates is “likely to be
confined within narrow limits.” If so, “there will be
for exchange rate indexes a tendency to settle at a
level approximately
equal to the ratio of . . . price
indexes.”
[1, p. 122] In short, provided international demand elasticities are high, the relative version of the doctrine remains approximately valid even
in the case of real economic changes.
Finally, mention should be made of BrescianiTurroni’s rejection of the so-called commodity arbitrage interpretation of PPP. This interpretation sees
PPP as an extension of the law of one price, according to which the operation of goods arbitrage equalizes the common currency price of internationallytraded goods across countries.
Since this reasoning
only applies to internationally traded goods, its proponents advocate restricting the PPP concept solely
to the prices of traded goods.
Bresciani-Turroni,
however, emphatically rejected
this interpretation as a trivial truism devoid of economic content. He argued that because internationally-traded goods have a single world price, their
common currency prices by definition must everywhere be the same (transport costs aside). In other
words, the ratio of their prices in domestic currencies
must, shipping costs aside, move with exchange rates
purely as a matter of arithmetic.
Moreover, since
arbitrage by definition equalizes prices of traded
goods at any given exchange rate, it fails to explain
how a unique equilibrium exchange rate is determined. He, of course, took it for granted that arbitrage would occur, but he insisted that the essence of
the PPP doctrine was not the law of one price but
rather the notion that exchange rates accurately reflect the monetary conditions in the countries concerned.
And if the purpose of PPP is to indicate
relative monetary conditions, then one should compare not the prices of traded goods alone but rather
general price levels that measure the value of money.
Friedman and Schwartz
The principal contribution to the PPP doctrine since Bresciani-Turroni’s
analysis has been Milton Friedman’s and Anna
Schwartz’s 1963 generalization of the price-induced
PPP self-equilibratin
g mechanism to apply to all
items in the balance of payments.
This was a new
development.
Prior to Friedman and Schwartz,
stabilizing price pressures were viewed as operating
solely or primarily through the trade accounts alone.
Cassel, for example, argued that the exchange rate
would be brought into conformity with PPP via
price-induced changes in commodity trade.
In his

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

11

account, a doubling of U. S. prices relative to foreign
prices at the existing exchange rate would, by making
U. S. goods twice as expensive to foreigners and
foreign goods half as expensive to Americans, discourage U. S. exports and encourage U. S. imports
thereby resulting in an increased supply of dollars
seeking to buy a reduced supply of foreign currency
on the market for foreign exchange.
The resulting
excess demand for foreign currency and the corresponding excess supply of dollars would bid the
exchange rate to double its original level. In this
way changes in exports and imports and the corresponding shifts in the supply and demand for foreign
exchange would raise the exchange rate to the level
Thus, in the traditional view,
dictated by PPP.
price-induced changes in commodity trade constitute
the primary means by which the exchange rate is
restored to the PPP equilibrium.4

excess supply of dollars would help bid the exchange
rate up toward its PPP equilibrium. In this manner
the self-equilibrating mechanism operates through the
capital account as well as the current account of the
balance of payments. More generally, since all items
in the balance of payments are critically dependent
on relative national price levels, all contribute to the
stability of PPP equilibrium.

On the market for foreign exchange, this reluctance
to invest in the U. S. would be reflected in a reduced
supply of pounds seeking to buy dollars. Likewise,
the corresponding increased desire of Americans to
invest in Britain would be manifested in an increased
supply of dollars seeking to buy pounds. The resulting excess demand for pounds and the corresponding

Concluding Comments
This article has traced
the evolution of the PPP theory of exchange rates
from its initial formulation by Thornton and Wheatley in the early 1800’s to its definitive critique and
restatement by Bresciani-Turroni
in the mid-1930’s.
It is now time to summarize the views of current
proponents of the doctrine.
With the exception of Friedman and Schwartz,
modern proponents have added little beyond Bresciani-Turroni’s analysis. Like him they hold that the
long-run behavior of the equilibrium exchange rate
is chiefly, but not solely, determined by the behavior
of relative money stocks operating through relative
price levels.” Like him they readily acknowledge
that a variety of factors-tariff
changes, output disturbances, shifts in demand, capital movements and
the like-impinge
on the equilibrium rate and force it
to deviate from the path dictated by the PPP.
And
like him they argue that price parities operate to
limit these deviations and hold them in check. In
particular, they contend that divergences from PPP
will trigger the restraining force of price-induced
trade and capital flows that arrest further deviations.
For example, they argue that real factors that push
the external value of a currency below its PPP will
inevitably generate price incentives tending to spur
exports and check imports. The resulting trade balance improvement and the associated strengthening
of demand for the currency on the foreign exchanges
will halt further deviations from price parity.
In
this manner, the PPP mechanism tends to constrain
systematic distortions between the equilibrium rate
and price parity.
The same mechanism, proponents note, also works
to correct random rate variations and to keep the
actual rate tending toward the equilibrium
rate
whether or not the latter differs from PPP. That is,
suppose the equilibrium rate is permanently distorted
from price parity as indicated by the expression
E = K (P/P*)
where K is the divergence between
the two variables.
Notwithstanding
this distortion,
the self-corrective mechanism will eliminate all devi-

4 Recall, however, that in Wheatley’s
ments also play a role.

5 What follows
214-23].

Friedman and Schwartz, however, argued that
such adjustment is not restricted to the trade accounts alone. In particular, price-induced changes in
unilateral transfers and capital movements also play a
role. Regarding unilateral transfers, they contended
that a doubling of wages and prices in the U. S.
relative to those abroad
would mean that a given number of dollars transferred by immigrants, for example, to their families abroad would constitute only half as large a
fraction of the immigrants’
wages and so would
tend to increase the amount sent. [5, p. 61]

On the market for foreign exchange, this increased
desire to make unilateral transfers would translate
into an increased supply of dollars seeking to buy
foreign currencies, thereby putting upward pressure
on the exchange rate.
The same holds true for capital flows. Regarding
such flows, Friedman and Schwartz state that, given
the U. K. price level and the dollar/pound exchange
rate, a doubling of U. S. prices
would mean that a given number of pounds sterling
intended for capital
investment
in the United
States would buy only half as much physical capital
while still commanding
an unchanged amount at
home and so would discourage capital investment
in the U. S. [5, p. 61]

12

view income adjust-

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MAY/JUNE

1979

draws heavily from Yeager

[15, pp. 210,

ations from PPP up to the factor K and the. equilibrium exchange rate will remain powerfully related to
the PPP.
Finally, proponents
note that the PPP theory
completely explains equilibrium exchange rate movements stemming from purely monetary
changes.
Moreover, they contend that it applies, albeit approximately, when monetary changes dominate real
changes. They point out that a money-induced rise
in the PPP tends to be reflected to its full extent,
without modification, in the exchange rate. By contrast, a real shock operating through the balance of
payments
provokes compensations
that limit its
effect on the exchange rate. In the long run, therefore, exchange rate movements will largely reflect
changes in relative money stocks as predicted by the
theory. For these reasons proponents hold that the
PPP theory remains a valid and useful concept.

References
1. Bresciani-Turroni,
C.
“The ‘Purchasing
Power
Parity' Doctrine.”
L’Egypte
Contemporaine,
25
(May 1934), 433-64.
Reprinted in his Saggi di
Economia.
Milan: Giuffre, 1961.

Friedman, M., and Schwartz, A. J. A Monetary
History of the United States, 1867-1960. Princeton,
New Jersey: Princeton University
Press for the
NBER, 1963.
Papers, (Commons),
6. Great Britain, Parlimentary
“Report from the Select Committee on the High
Price of Gold Bullion” (no. 349) III, 1810.
A Tract on Monetary
Reform
7. Keynes, J. M.
Reprinted in the Collected Writings of
(1923).
John Maynard Keynes.
London : Macmillan for
the Royal Economic Society, 1971.
8.

Metzler, L. A.
“The Theory
of International
Trade.”
A Survey of Contemporary
Economics.
Edited by Howard S. Ellis.
Philadelphia:
Blakiston, 1948.

9.

Mises, L. V. Stabilization of the Monetary Unit
from the Viewpoint of Theory (1923).
In On the
Manipulation of Money and Credit. Translated by
Bettina Bien Greaves and edited by Percy L.
Greaves, Jr.
Dobbs Ferry,
New York:
Free
Market Books, 1978.

10. O’Brien, D. P. The Classical Economists.
Oxford University Press, 1975.

London:

11. Thornton, H.
An Enquiry into the Nature and
Effects
of the Paper Credit of Great Britain
(1802).
Edited with an introduction by F. A. v.
Hayek. New York: Rinehart, 1939.
12.

Viner, J. Studies in the Theory of International
Trade. New York: Augustus Kelley, 1965.

2. Cassel, G. “The Present Situation of the Foreign
Exchanges.”
Economic Journal, 26 (March 1916),
62-65.

13.

Wheatley, J. An Essay on the Theory of Money
and Principles of Commerce. Vol 1. London:
Cadell and Davies, 1807.

3.

After

14.

Remarks on Currency
London : Burton, 1803.

4. Fetter, F. W.
Development
of British Monetary
Orthodoxy 1797-1875.
Cambridge, Mass. : Harvard
University Press, 1965.

15.

Yeager,
L.
International
Monetary
Theory, History, and Policy.
2nd ed.
Harper and Row, 1976.

1914.

Money and Foreign Exchange
New York: Macmillan, 1922.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

and Commerce.
Relations:
New York:

13

WAGE-PRICE RESTRAINT AND
MACROECONOMIC DISEQUILIBRIUM
Roy H. Webb

During the past forty years the United States
government has made numerous attempts to restrain
wage and price increases. Initially these were associated with comprehensive wartime economic controls, as in World War II and, to a lesser extent, the
Korean War.
Several varieties of wage-price restraint were even attempted during the Viet Nam era.
President Kennedy introduced “guideposts” in 1962
which were to “provide standards . . . not replace the
normal processes of free private decisions.” [3]
Throughout President Johnson’s tenure, wage-price
restraint escalated as more detailed rules were estabAlthough the Nixon Administration
first
lished.
eschewed any type of wage-price restraint, it imposed
a comprehensive wage-price freeze in August 1971.
Controls of varying severity were maintained through
April 1974.
Recently, even without the excuse of war, attempts
to restrain individual wages and prices have remained
remarkably durable.
President Ford announced a
“Whip Inflation Now” program in October 1974
which included a token mention of wage-price restraint. President Carter has announced several versions of wage-price restraint, the last of which was
put forward in October 1978.l Other modern industrial nations with market economies have also made
numerous attempts at wage-price restraint.
And
throughout history wage-price restraint has been repeatedly attempted in preindustrial societies.
Based on its frequency of use, one might conclude
that wage-price restraint is a panacea. Yet on eco-

1 The latest program involves quasi-voluntary wage and
price standards. Violators are explicitly threatened with
bad publicity and loss of government contracts.
Implicitly, possible violators must be aware of potential
retaliation by regulatory agencies not formally incorporated in the wage-price control program. For example,
the Carter Administration has recently hinted [11] that
the amount of future trucking industry deregulation (by
the Interstate Commerce Commission or by act of Congress) will depend on the outcome of Teamster wage
negotiations.
Due to the magnitude of discretionary authority
possessed
by the Internal
Revenue
Service,
Environmental
Protection Agency, Federal Trade Commission, Occupational Safety and Health Administration,
etc., a large potential for retaliation confronts any business.

14

nomic and other grounds, such restraint has been
charged with creating many severe difficulties while
This article delineates the
failing to curb inflation.
persistent puzzle, continued advocacy of wage-price
restraint by those who are well aware of its many
drawbacks.
Accordingly, some of the more obvious
shortcomings of wage-price restraint are first reviewed. Second, a theoretical case for such restraint,
shortcomings
notwithstanding,
is explained.
In
short, this article will present both the modern theory
behind wage-price restraint as well as some severe,
predictable pitfalls common to all control programs.
PRELIMINARY

TOPICS

Effectiveness
In subsequent
parts of the article
it will be assumed, for purposes of discussion, that
wage-price
restraint
programs
can be effective.
However, this assumption may not be valid, since
wage-price restraint conflicts with a basic human
characteristic, the desire of individuals to improve
their own welfare through trade. If each party involved in a transaction agrees to the price, or terms
of trade, then clearly they believe the transaction to
be mutually beneficial.
Thus controllers seeking to
prohibit such transactions, on the grounds that the
terms of trade conflict with policy objectives, should
not be surprised that the traders are willing to circumvent price regulations.
For example, although the sticker price of a new
car might be frozen by law, a dealer can always vary
the trade-in allowance, warranty terms, credit terms,
predelivery preparation, etc. Similarly, automobile
manufacturers can vary the options included or excluded on the same model, or introduce a new model
that is only superficially different from the old.
Since prices of new products, or new models of old
products, are difficult to regulate, exchange may actually occur at the same quality adjusted price that
would prevail in the absence of a price freeze.
Wage controls can also be circumvented.
For
one thing, employers may upgrade workers’ jobs in
name only, a difficult practice to detect.
As an

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MAY/JUNE

1979

illustration, consider the opening of a new factory.
While it would probably first attempt to hire skilled
workers at prevailing wages, it might not receive a
sufficient response, in which case it might choose to
raise its wage offers. If confronted with wage controls, the newcomer might label its machinists “assistant mechanical engineers” and offer a higher wage.
Price controllers may not realize that the jobs are
the same, albeit with different titles. If not, existing
firms, who continue to pay the controlled wage rate,
must find some way of making their jobs more rewarding if they are to retain their employees.
In principle, given enough information, vigorous
enforcement, and a legal staff large enough to either
write clear regulations or litigate ambiguous ones,
evasions could be controlled.
In practice, however,
the quantity of information required to evaluate product quality and to classify employee functions is
enormous.
Moreover, much of the data is rapidly
changing. But if this information is not timely and
acquired in useful form, evasion is both possible and
profitable. At the very least, therefore, any discussion
of wage-price restraint should consider the high cost
of obtaining and evaluating information, as well as
the cost of specifying clear regulations.

particularly
dramatic example was the televised
drowning of baby chickens when the Nixon program
of wage-price restraint froze the price of chickens
while simultaneously exempting the price of grain
included in chicken feed.
Consequently it became
less costly to kill a baby chicken than to pay high feed
prices and sell the grown animal at the low controlled
price.
Distortions created by price controls are exacerbated in an open economy.
When a commodity is
freely traded on the world market, the domestic price
can diverge from the world price only by the cost of
transportation.
If the domestic price is kept artificially below the world price, there is no incentive for
foreign producers to sell in the country with the
controlled price. Moreover, it is more profitable for
domestic producers to export rather than sell at the
controlled price. However, if prices of traded goods
are not controlled, a price control program would be
limited to non-traded commodities such as haircuts
and local telephone calls.

It should not be assumed that an ineffective attempt to control wages and prices indicates lack of
will by controllers, since even the most draconian
control measures have not always been successful.
For example, the Roman emperor Diocletian initiated
a program of wage-price restraint under which violators received the death penalty.
One account reports that the law effected “much blood shed upon
very slight and trifling accounts; and the people
brought provisions no more to market.”
[6] The
program “in shambles” was abandoned after thirteen
years.
These difficulties notwithstanding,
the remainder
of this article will assume, for purposes of discussion,
that wage-price restraint is able to hold wages, and
prices received by sellers, below market levels. This
assumption facilitates the discussion of some predictable consequences of effective wage and price restraint.
Single Market Effects
A basic proposition
of
economics is that if a price is set below the marketclearing level, then actions by both buyers and sellers
will be distorted. At an artificially low price, buyers
wish to buy more than sellers wish to supply, and a
shortage results in that market, as illustrated in
Figure 1. Effective price control programs provide
ample illustrations of such distorted behavior.
A
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

15

Another perverse effect is that even if the price a
seller receives is below the market-clearing
level, it
does not follow that the buyer pays a below market
price.
If shortages occur and buyers as a whole
cannot obtain all they wish at the controlled price,
individual buyers may well spend valuable time and
money attempting to buy the scarce good. The expense of waiting in lengthened queues, as well as
additional search for a scarce item, are both included
in the total cost of an item to a buyer.
A recent example occurred in early 1974, when
the ceiling price of gasoline was set at an artificially
low level. When predictable shortages occurred in
several metropolitan
areas, long lines appeared at
open gas stations. Waits of well over an hour were
common. Some dealers made it possible for buyers
to avoid the lines by selling gasoline only to buyers
of overpriced repair services.
Additionally, middlemen may be able to buy at the
low, controlled price and sell at the higher price
buyers are willing to pay. “FEA millionaires” were
recently enriched by such reselling of domestic crude
oil.
In short, when a price is restrained below the
market-clearing
level, the low price received by producers discourages production.
And final buyers
confront reduced supply, even though the item’s total
cost to an individual buyer may well be no lower
than in an uncontrolled market.
GENERAL

EFFECTS

OF WAGE-PRICE

RESTRAINT

Wage-Price Restraint as a Substitute for Monetary and Fiscal Restraint While economists generally agree that monetary and fiscal restraint will
eventually lower inflation, such restraint will also
temporarily
lower real economic growth, possibly
causing a severe recession.
As the director of the
Council on Wage and Price Stability, Barry Bosworth, put it, “In the last three recessions, on average you had to throw 1 million people out of work
in order to get 1 percentage point off the rate of
inflation. You have to do it for at least 2 years and
each year you lose about $75 billion worth of GNP.”
[12]
In light of this high cost, policymakers often refuse
to lower inflation by lowering aggregate demand
through monetary or fiscal restraint.
Rather, wageprice restraint is advocated in place of lowered aggreThe view that wage-price restraint
gate demand.
and monetary-fiscal
restraint are substitutes is exemplified by Sherman J. Maisel, a former governor
16

of the Federal Reserve Board, “Stable prices result
primarily from either severe depressions or pricewage controls.”
Moreover, the record of American policymakers
also indicates that wage-price restraint is used as a
substitute for monetary and fiscal restraint.
During
Phases I and II of the Nixon wage and price controls, the money supply (Ml) grew at an annual rate
of 7.5 percent and the high employment deficit averaged 1.2 percent of GNP ; during the tenure of the
Nixon administration
before Phase I, the money
supply grew at an annual rate of 5.2 percent and the
high employment surplus averaged 0.2 percent of
GNP. Thus, both monetary and fiscal policies were
less restrictive after controls were imposed.2 Other
American experiences with wage-price restraint were
generally accompanied by expansionary monetary and
fiscal policies.
When wage-price restraint is imposed as a substitute for monetary and fiscal restraint, it unfortunately
shifts attention from monetary and fiscal policy to
individual prices or wages.
For example, shortly
after President Carter announced the October 1978
wage-price restraint program, the mass media directed considerable attention to a relatively trivial
matter, the rising price of Hershey chocolate bars.
The monthly report on policy action released by the
Federal Open Market Committee received almost no
coverage.
However, had the President, in his televised address, substituted a discussion of monetary
policy for his lengthy discussion of single prices and
wages, reporters might have paid more attention to
the FOMC.
At worst, this distracted attention can
degenerate into a search for scapegoats while monetary and fiscal expansion remain unchecked.
A General Output Effect There is another, often
overlooked effect of wage-price restraint when used
as a substitute for monetary and fiscal restraint.
Whenever a price level which cannot freely adjust
is inconsistent with the existing level of aggregate
demand and high output, the economy can encounter
macroeconomic disequilibrium.
Robert Barro and Herschel Grossman have provided an incisive analysis of such disequilibrium.
Both the informal discussion of this section and an
2 A myopic

measure of monetary
policy, looking no
earlier than May 1971. nor later than June 1972, would
show the opposite.
However, most economists believe
that a few months is too short to establish a policy, since
unrelated influences can cause abnormal figures in short
period data. Thus. May-August 1971 would not be taken
as indicative of precontrol policy.

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MAY/JUNE

1979

Appendix giving a more elaborate disequilibrium
analysis rely heavily on the Barro-Grossman
presentation.3 While this method of analysis generally confirms conclusions of orthodox macroeconomics,
its
use helps divert attention from minor issues which
have often obscured more important topics.
One
very important topic highlighted by Barro-Grossman
is the macroeconomic importance of wage and price
levels. A conclusion of this analysis is that when
inflexible price and wage levels are too low (as
would happen when wage-price restraint is effective)
the result is macroeconomic disequilibrium, in this
case labeled general excess demand. Consequences of
general excess demand include involuntary unemployment and reduced production, exactly as would
be expected from a recession.
When general excess
demand exists, economic recovery can occur only if
(1) prices and wages rise, or (2) aggregate demand
is lowered by monetary-fiscal restraint.
To understand these results, consider the essentials of a very simple disequilibrium model, containing
(1) a household sector, whose members supply labor
and purchase commodities, (2) firms which purchase
labor and supply commodities, (3) a government
which can create or destroy money, levy taxes, and
buy commodities, and (4) price and wage levels
which are realized as the outcome of all private and
governmental decisions.
When the economy functions normally, price and wage levels adjust so that
output and employment are at high levels. For example, if the money supply4 were to rise in an economy with full employment, thereby raising aggregate
demand, prices and wages normally would increase.
However, if aggregate demand is greater than the
economy can supply at current price and wage levels,
but prices and wages are legally frozen, then something else has to give. And an output-employment
fall is the only “give” left in the system.
Moreover, the fall is more severe than might be
expected from looking only at single markets. Dislocations in one market can aggravate problems in
another market and vice versa.
If prices are too low
3 But any shortcomings
in this article
responsibility
of the author.

naturally

are the

4 An increase in the money supply is used as an example
of a change which affects aggregate demand. This category also includes changes in government
spending,
taxes, household preferences for current relative to future
consumption,
and in more complex models, changes in
investment decisions of firms and net exports. Since the
origin of an aggregate demand change is of secondary
importance in discussing its qualitative effects, for ease of
exposition the example of a money supply change will
continue to be used as an example of a change affecting
aggregate demand.

to equilibrate demand with available supply, households will not be able to buy all the commodities they
wish, and they will thus tend to substitute current
leisure for unavailable current consumption.
Since
more current leisure means less current work, firms
will be unable to obtain the amount of labor they
seek. However, a reduced amount of labor employed
limits the amount of commodities firms can produce.
In this manner an initial disturbance can cause selfreinforcing output-employment
declines throughout
the economy.
In short, output and employment fall when there is
inconsistency among (1) high output and employment levels, (2) fixed price and wage levels, and
(3) the prevailing level of aggregate demand.
If
either of the latter two elements were able to change,
Starting
then output and employment could rise.
from an economy experiencing general excess demand, recovery could thus involve allowing prices
and wages to rise. Alternatively, lowering aggregate
demand, possibly by cutting the money supply, could
also initiate recovery.
Fortunately, general excess demand has not been a
problem in industrialized, market economies.
Especially in the U. S. experience with wage-price restraint, it is hard to see any sign of general excess
demand, which suggests that controls may have been
more symbolic than real. An alternative explanation
might be that single market distortions were promptly
ameliorated by relaxing controls at the first sign of
trouble. Consequently, the price level could rise and
there would not be enough time for spillovers among
markets to generate disequilibrium and a general
output effects.5
Additionally, a real economy has, for a short time,
more flexibility than the simple economy described
above.
Lower inventories, higher unfilled orders,
and more employee overtime could be immediate responses to an aggregate demand increase. But there
is a limit to the flexibility such measures can provide.
Inventories cannot fall lower than zero, and employees will not accept whatever amount of overtime
firms propose.
Therefore, while an economy has
many responses which can delay the onset of general
excess demand, the delay is only temporary.
Events in post-World War II Germany can be
interpreted as indicating general excess demand, al5 Eastern
European
economies
might be studied for
general excess demand effects, due to their rigid prices
and expansive aggregate
demand policies.
However,
necessary data on output, prices, and government policies
are difficult to obtain in a form suitable for analysis.
However, see Howard.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

17

though there are other plausible explanations.6
In
1936 the Nazi government imposed a comprehensive
price freeze, which combined with wages frozen at
1932 levels to yield a wage-price restraint policy
which outlasted the Nazi government.
In 1945 the
Allied Control Authority maintained German price
laws as well as local price control agencies. While
it may not be surprising that a totalitarian police
state was able to implement effective restraint, even
under the Allies “price control during the first three
years of occupation was surprisingly effective . . .
the bulk of the goods changed hand at legal or
nearly legal prices . . . legal wages prevailed
throughout the economy.”
[9] On June 20, 1948,
actions were taken which ultimately cut the money
Simultaneously much wagesupply by 93 percent.
price restraint was abandoned.
As the economy
recovered industrial production rose at an annual
rate of 97 percent between June and November 1948.
The German recovery is thus similar to recovery
from general excess demand as modeled in this
article. In both, cutting the money supply and relaxing wage-price restraint result in higher output
and employment.
To summarize, users of the disequilibrium model
are in the position of predicting the danger of general
excess demand on the basis of theory unconfirmed by
strong empirical evidence.7 If the analysis presented
above is relevant, then to ignore the possibility of
general excess demand would seem to imply that
necessary conditions to create it are not met. That is,
either wage-price restraint is believed to be ineffective or, as discussed below, it is expected to be used
6 Any discussion of the postwar German experience
should mention what many economists would refer to
The identification
as a severe identification problem.
problem arises because any economic result at the time
can be plausibly attributed at first glance to numerous
exceptional causes. One explanation of low output might
note Allied bombing lowering the stock of business fixed
capital. High output growth-rates could be a catch-up to
more normal levels or a result of Allied aid, notably the
Surprisingly,
Germany had substantial
Marshall Plan.
industrial capacity at the end of the war. Wallich noted
that after all allowingfor in-slant repairs, more capacity was
added during the war than was destroyed. He also noted
that while Germany received $4.5 billion in Allied aid,
the Allies simultaneously imposed burdens on Germany
including reparations, occupation costs, etc. that could
offset some, or all, of the stimulating
effects of aid
payments.
Also, the data available are distorted by the pervasive
black markets.
hoarding. and bilateral barter of the
period. For example, it is hard to interpret early industrial production figures due to hoarding by manufacturers
(anticipating the relaxation of price controls) and sales
in the black markets.
7 But the same approach applied to another problem, the
business cycle characterized by periods of general excess
supply, has better empirical support.

18

as a complement to, rather
monetary and fiscal restraint.

than a substitute

for,

Wage-Price
Restraint as a Complement
to Monetary-Fiscal
Restraint
As discussed above, general excess demand can develop if prices are too low.
But general excess demand is not the only possible
form of disequilibrium. If rigid prices and wages are
too high, then general excess supply is possible. For
example, suppose that the economy is initially producing high levels of output and employment.
Then
suppose that the money supply is suddenly reduced,
with prices and wages not immediately changing.8
The fall in real money holdings would result in a fall
in the household sector’s desired level of consumption, and an increase in their desired amount of
employment
(to restore some of their lost money
holdings).
Firms, however, would offer less employment, since their sales are down. But if firms
cut the amount of employment, households would buy
even less, leading to further drops in sales, jobs,
income, and consumption.
The final outcome of the resulting general excess
supply is lower output and employment. The reasoning behind this conclusion is analogous to the reasoning that general excess demand causes lower
Both general excess supply
output and employment.
and general excess demand occur when inflexible
wages and prices are inconsistent with government’s
monetary and fiscal policies, households’ consumption and labor supply choices, firms’ production and
employment choices, and high output and employTo restore equilibrium, one of two
ment levels.
things must happen: either prices and wages must
adjust to appropriate
levels, or the government’s
monetary and fiscal policies must adjust aggregate
demand appropriately.
The contention that monetary-fiscal restraint is a
costly way to lower inflation has a firm foundation,
namely the premise that such restraint would entail
a period of genera1 excess supply.
That is, for
some time after restraint is imposed on an inflationary economy, prices and wages would be too high
and disequilibrium would develop. Were the government able to establish equilibrium levels of prices
and wages at the initiation of monetary and fiscal
restraint, disequilibrium could be avoided. This is a
major reason why some economists continue to advo8 The Achilles Heel of this section is the failure to show
why prices and wages would not adjust immediately and
completely.
An earlier discussion relied on the assumpOne approach,
tion of effective wage-price restraint.
taken by Okun, notes that in an uncertain world buyers
and sellers can benefit from formal and informal long
term contracts which limit price and wage flexibility.

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MAY/JUNE

1979

cate wage-price restraint despite its past performance.9
An observant reader might question the implicit
contention that the government will have better information on appropriate price and wage levels than
do households and firms. After all, the only information possessed exclusively by the government is the
course of monetary and fiscal policy. Thus, it would
appear that simply announcing policy changes before
they went into effect would allow the private sector
to adjust smoothly to the policy change. Unfortunately, this simple solution is probably too good to be
true.
Government policy has historically been so
erratic that current announcements have little credibility.
Moreover, formal and informal contracts
would limit immediate price or wage adjustment in
response to even a credible announcement.
Consequently, if one believes the government to
possess better knowledge than the private sector on
appropriate levels of wages and prices, and if one
believes the government to be capable of promptly
employing this knowledge in wage-price control, then
one could logically support temporary wage-price
restraint, concurrent with monetary-fiscal
restraint.
9 Another economic argument for wage-price restraint
rests on the concept of administered prices. While often
stated as a simplistic conspiracy theory with little economic content, it can also be given a more sophisticated
form. Imagine an economy with most prices determined
by firms that can arbitrarily move price within a zone of
control, and most wages set by unions with similar economic power. Now imagine one or both of these groups
attempting to grab a larger portion of national income by
using its economic power to push up prices or wages.
That group could be successful, at least temporarily, if
the government concurrently expanded aggregate demand
enough so that sales and employment were not reduced.
The result of this expanded aggregate demand,. however,
is inflation. Wage-price restraint, it is argued, is the best
way to curb this “administrative inflation.”
Means has
given a classic statement of this doctrine.
Even in its most sophisticated form, however, many
economists do not find the argument persuasive. First,
there may be better ways to limit price increases in concentrated industries.
For example, proponents of the
administrative inflation doctrine often point to the steel
industry.
But the steel industry has been able to raise
prices only because the government has limited imports
of low cost foreign steel.
Thus, removal of import
tariffs and quotas would allow American manufacturers
to purchase low cost steel without wage-price restraint.
Also, if big business and big labor have enough political clout to induce the government to expand aggregate
demand in the first place, they probably have enough
clout to influence a wage-price restraint program in their
favor. Moreover, it is not clear what fraction of prices
and wages are administered, how large are the zones of
price control, and to what extent members of a group
like big business would cooperate rather than compete.
Yet these are all crucial elements of the theory.
For
example, an oligopolist might not be able to raise its
price since that would create sufficient profit opportunities to attract new competitors.
And not being-able to
raise price makes the theory inapplicable.
Therefore,
unless these questions can be satisfactorily answered, it
is possible to accept the abstract theory without seeing
any relevance to the American economy.

Present rhetoric acknowledges the latter part of this
conclusion.
For example, President Carter’s chief
inflation fighter Alfred Kahn has stated “it has been
recognized that wage and price controls would be
futile if they were not accompanied by really quite
stringent
budgetary
restraint
and monetary
restraint.”
It should be noted, however, that political
rhetoric has often endorsed demand restraint while
simultaneous actions produced monetary-fiscal
expansion.
CONCLUSION

Economic activity consists of the production and
exchange of goods and services. A person may exchange productive labor for money wages, and at a
different time trade the money for any of numerous
commodities. Trades are made whenever each party
concerned believes the transaction will improve his
own well-being. Wage-price controls, however, seek
to prohibit certain of these mutually beneficial transactions. In so doing, controls conflict with a very
powerful human motivation, the desire to improve
one’s own well-being. Therefore it is not clear that
controls will actually succeed in prohibiting transactions.
Even if the central authority does successfully
limit the transactions people can make, it does not
follow that the effects will be desirable. Since governments are limited in the amount of information
they can acquire and process, and make decisions
slowly, if at all, single market distortions are inevitable when controls are effective. Dogged controllers,
undeterred by such distortions, could cause general
excess demand unless they were to follow the unusual
procedure of concurrently restricting aggregate demand by monetary or fiscal policy.
And even if aggregate demand restraint is concurrently employed, and if single market effects are
not severe, wage-price controls still may not have a
desirable impact on the economy.
The theoretical
argument that controls will allow the economy to
avoid general excess supply requires not only that
the government be better able to identify appropriate
price and wage levels than the market process, but
also to be able to act expeditiously upon that knowledge. Both requirements are stringent, and demand
a higher level of governmental competence than is
actually observed.
Therefore, employing wage-price restraint to battle
inflation might well prove to be the Viet Nam of
economic policy. That is, the battle is likely to be
protracted, with no light at the end of the tunnel, and
with burdens on the population mounting as the battle

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

19

continues. Perhaps a paraphrase of Senator Aiken’s
Viet Nam strategy is appropriate for wage and price
controls.
That is, declare victory over inflation if
necessary, but end the controls program immediately.

APPENDIX

This appendix uses a simplified model economy to
examine macroeconomic
disequilibrium.
After the
basic features of the economy are presented, suppressed inflation is studied in Part I. A more traditional recession is analyzed in Part II, as a first step
towards explaining a rationale sometimes given for
wage-price restraint.
The disequilibrium model presented is quite flexible, and can be applied to a wide
range of macroeconomic problems.
I.

GENERAL

EXCESS

DEMAND

The Basic Model
Imagine
an economy
with
three markets: output (Y), labor (L), and money
(M); three types of decision makers : firms, households, and a government; and two prices : the price of
commodity output (P) and the price of labor (W).
Households and firms engage in economic activity in
their own self-interest, and no attempt is made to
explain why the government
engages in economic
activity.
Households make two economic decisions: how
much output to buy and how much labor to sell. It is
assumed that the higher the real wage (W/P)
or the
higher their real money balances (M/P),
the more
output households wish to consume (Cd). While a
higher real wage is assumed to induce households to
supply more labor (Ls), it is assumed that households who are wealthier because of higher real money
balances enjoy their additional wealth by consuming
both additional output and additional leisure. Since
more leisure means less work, increasing real money
balances will lower the labor supply schedule (that is,
the amounts of labor potentially offered at each possible wage rate).
Firms decide how much output they produce (Ys);
their labor demand (Ld) is the quantity of labor
needed to produce Ys.10 An increase in the real wage
rate lowers the demand for labor and thus, with less
labor employed, a smaller amount of output is produced. Government
obtains funds to purchase output
(G) by taxing households or printing money. Ag10 More precisely,

there is an aggregate

production

func-

tion F such that Y = F(L);
moveover, it is also assumed that the quantity produced is equal to the quantity
sold.

20

gregate commodity demand (Yd) is the sum of demands by households and the government.
For the commodity market to be in equilibrium, it
is necessary that Ys = Cd + G; for labor market
equilibrium, Ls = Ld. If these two markets are in
equilibrium, so must the money market11 and the
model economy consequently exhibits general equilibrium. If Ld > Ls and Cd + G > Ys, the situation
will. be labeled general excess demand (although
general here refers to only the “real” sectors as
opposed to the monetary sector).
Persistent Excess Demand
Assume that there
is initially a general equilibrium, with LO hours of
labor and YO units of output exchanged at wage WO
and price PO. Now imagine that the government
prints additional money (M rises from MO to M1)
and distributes it to households.
A first analysis
might simply note (as described above) that the increase in real money holdings would increase household demand for output but decrease household labor
supply (by increasing the demand for leisure).
If
the wage and price levels did not change, there would
be excess demand in each market, as shown in Figure
2. However, a sufficient increase in the price 1evel
could lower Ml/P to MO/PO; along with the same
percentage increase in the wage level, commodity
demand and labor supply of households would return
to their original values.
Now suppose that wage-price restraint is imposed
at the same time the money supply is increased.
If
wages and prices do not adjust then there are new
questions to answer. First, what quantities are exchanged in each market?
When quantity demanded
is equal to quantity supplied, the answer is easy.
But now quantity demanded is greater than quantity
The answer uses the assumption that
supplied.
households and firms engage in economic activity in
their own self-interest, and are not forced to make
any transactions; accordingly, the quantity supplied
is the quantity exchanged.
Suppliers do not wish to
supply more and are not forced to.
While a naive analysis might stop here, there is
another problem. Firms cannot buy as much labor
by paying WO as they could before; is it reasonable
to assume an unchanged supply of output?
In this
simple world, cutting back labor input directly lowers
the level of commodity output. As shown in Figure
3, Ys’ is the effective commodity supply given the
labor market constraint on the amount of labor firms
11 This follows from direct application of Walras' Law.
Crouch presents an unusually clear exposition of Walras’
Law.

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MAY/JUNE

1979

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

can purchase. Moreover, there is another spillover:
households supply labor in order to receive wages
with which they buy output; if they cannot buy all
the output they wish, then they can at least reduce
their labor supply and have more leisure time to
enjoy. Thus the labor supply can be represented as
in Figure 3 by Ls’, the effective supply of labor
given the commodity
market constraint
on the
amount of output households can purchase.
The analysis presented above can be summarized
with the aid of a graph, such as the one in Figure 4,
which includes effective supply curves for labor and
real output, Ls’ and Ys’. Demand curves are omitted
since when there is excess demand, exchange is
limited to the amount supplied.
At point A both
markets are in equilibrium.
While the wage and
price levels are restrained at WO and PO the quantity
of money is increased from MO to M1. As a result
there are excess demands in the labor and output
markets.
Households thus face a supply constraint
on consumption and firms face a supply constraint
In response, households reduce
on labor purchases.
effective labor supply and firms reduce effective out-

put supply. The final outcome yields levels of employment and output, point B, significantly below
initial levels.
Recovery
The economy can recover and move
back to point A in one of two ways. If restraints
are removed and the price level rises enough so that
M/P returns to its old level, and there is an equal
percentage increase in the wage level, then the economy can move from B to A. If wages and prices
continue to be restrained, a cut in the money supply12
can still result in movement from B to A. In either
case, after adjustment W/P = WO/PO and M/P =
MO/PO; therefore Yd = YS = YO and Ld = Ls = LO.
This analysis can give meaning to the phrases “too
high” or “too low” a price and/or wage level. At
point B both the price level and the wage level are
too low, since increasing both would increase employment and output. One of the hardest tasks in learning economics is unlearning oft-repeated fallacies;
one such fallacy is that high prices are bad but low
prices are good. As has been seen, if low prices and
wages result in general excess demand, then the
whole economy suffers.
It is interesting to contrast this general approach
with the partial analysis of viewing equilibrium in
only one market, as in Figure 2. Imagine, as before,
that the money supply increases and, consequently,
households’ planned purchases rise. In the market
for output it would appear that lowering the real
wage, by lowering W
with P unchanged, would
effect a new equilibrium at an output level higher
than YO. A general analysis, as summarized in
Figure 3, would show the error of ignoring the labor
market.
The initial shock causes a movement from
A to B. If W were forced down with P unchanged,
then Ls’ would shift to the left, resulting in even
lower output and employment than at B.
II.

GENERAL

EXCESS

SUPPLY

Without Continuing Inflation The basic model
of Part I will be used to examine a typical recession,
in which the problem is general excess supply rather
than general excess demand.
Assume that initially
there is a general equilibrium, with LO hours of labor
and YO units of output exchanged at wage WO and
price PO. Now suppose that the money supply is
suddenly reduced from MO to M2. A first analysis
might simply note that the decrease in real money
holdings would decrease household demand for outThus if wages and prices did not
put and leisure.
12 More generally, any action which decreases aggregate
demand can be substituted for a cut in the money supply.

22

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MAY/JUNE

1979

change there would be excess supply in both the
commodity and labor markets. However, a sufficient
decrease in the price level could raise M2/P to
MO/PO; along with the same percentage decrease in
the wage level, Cd and Ls would return to their
original values.
Now suppose that wages and prices cannot fall as
much as described above. Consequently there is still
excess supply in each market. As before, when quantities supplied and demanded are not equal, the lesser
of the two is the quantity traded. Thus, the quantity
demanded is the quantity exchanged. Also, there are
spillovers between the two markets.
Firms cannot
sell as many commodities as in equilibrium; therefore
they have a smaller labor requirement.
Households
cannot sell all the labor they wish; this fall in income
lowers their planned commodity purchases.
Thus
the initial shock is exacerbated by these reinforcing
spillovers. In other words, the initial aggregate demand shock has a multiplier effect.
The resulting situation is illustrated in Figure 5
with effective demand curves for labor and commodities. Note that disequilibrium does not result from
too high or too low a real wage ; on the labor market
side, the real wage rate can vary substantially without
affecting the quantity of labor employed.
Effective
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

23

demand curves are also drawn in Figure 6. Supply
curves are omitted, since under excess supply, exchange is limited to quantity demanded.
The initial
demand shock is a reduction in the quantity of money
from MO to M2 with the wage and price levels stuck
at WO and PO. Consequently there is general excess
supply. The final outcome entails levels of output
and employment, point D, significantly below initial
levels. Recovery occurs in an analogous manner to
the case of general excess demand. Either the wage
and price levels must fall, or the money supply must
rise, so that W/P = WO/PO and M/P = MO/PO.
The symmetry of general excess supply and general excess demand is illustrated in Figure 7. It is
assumed that the real wage is WO/PO and that wage
and price levels are frozen. Then there is one quantity of money at which output is at its maximum
level, YO. A lower money supply results in general
excess supply while a higher money supply results in
general excess demand.
One can also observe the
potential importance of a flexible price level, which
could change M/P and thus raise output from low
disequilibrium levels. Similar diagrams can be used
to illustrate effects of other variables, such as government spending or taxes.

Recession ‘with Inflation
The preceding section
presents a disequilibrium model of a recession in an
economy without continuing inflation.
In this section an ad hoc addition is made to the basic model
so that continuing inflation is included. The purpose
is to show how monetary-fiscal restraint can trigger
general excess supply, and how this might be avoided
by perfectly administered wage-price restraint.
Suppose that in every month for the past 10 years,
the money supply has increased by 1 percent, although the monetary authority announced at various
times its intention of slowing money growth. In. the
simple economy described above, general equilibrium
could be maintained by price and wage levels rising
1 percent per month.
Furthermore,
imagine the
monetary authority again announcing its intention
of slowing money growth and actually stopping
growth completely. Using anticipations (which with
perfect hindsight can be seen to be incorrect) based
on the previous 10 years, firms and households might
well ignore the monetary authority’s announcement
and agree to wages and prices 1 percent higher. If
the higher wage and price levels stuck, there would
be general excess supply, as described above. Real
money holdings would fall as the price level rose
and the money supply did not change ; consequently,
households would cut purchase plans. As a result,
firms would demand less labor. But if households
could not sell their desired amount of labor at the
going wage, they would lower planned purchases.
Thus monetary restraint would cause an initial
fall in output and employment. If monetary restraint
were maintained, then for recovery to occur it would
be necessary for households and firms to correctly
comprehend the monetary action, and for prices and
wages to adjust accordingly.
However, an effective
freeze of prices and wages at the same time the
money supply was first held constant would avoid
the general excess supply scenario.
Quantities exchanged in the commodity and labor markets would
not fall when the money supply is lower than expected. This happy result is due to artificially low
price and wage levels being consistent with the unexpectedly low money supply and general equilibrium.
Even in this simple world, there are quite strong
restraint
to
necessary
conditions for wage-price
achieve the potential output-employment
gains mentioned above. First, prices and wages must not automatically fall when monetary restraint is imposed
(otherwise, monetary restraint would not cause general excess supply). Next, the wage-price controllers
must have better knowledge of the extent of monetary restraint than the public (otherwise, the public

21

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MAY/JUNE

1979

could adjust prices and wages to appropriate levels
without intervention).
Finally, wage-price restraint
must be effective.

“Suppressed Infla1. Barro, R., and H. Grossman.
tion and the Supply Multiplier.”
Review of Economic Studies, 41 (January 1974), 87-104.

3.

York:

Money, Employment and Inflation.
New
Cambridge University Press, 1976, ch. 2.

Council of Economic Advisors.
1963 Annual ReWashington : Government Printing Office,
port.
1964.

New York:
4. Crouch, R. Macroeconomics.
Brace Jovanovich, pp. 144-147.
5. Kahn, A. Interview
December 18, 1978.

the

Dollar.

8. Means, G. The Corporate Revolution
Crowell Collier Press, 1962.

New

York:

in America.

9. Mendershausen, H. “Prices, Money, and the Distribution of Goods in Postwar Germany.”
American Economic Review, 39 (June 1949), 651-672.

References

2.

Managing
7. Maisel, S.
Norton, 1973, p. 282.

reprinted in American

Harcourt
Banker,

6. Lactantius, quoted in J. Collins, “Price Controls:
40 Centuries of Failure.”
Business Week, December 18, 1978, p. 13.

10. Okun, A.-

“Inflation:
Its Mechanics and Welfare
Costs" Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity,
(2: 1975).
11. Slevin, J. “Inside the Economy.”
American Banker, February 26, 1979.
12. U. S. Congress.
House.
Committee on Banking,
Finance and Urban Affairs.
The Administration’s
Anti-Inflation
Program.
Statement by Barry P.
Bosworth at the Hearings before the Subcommittee
on Economic Stabilization,
House of Representatives, 95th Cong., 2nd sess., June 21, 1978, p. 28.
13. Wallich, H. Mainsprings
Binghampton, New York:

of the German Revival.
Vail-Ballou Press, 1955.

Model in a Con14. Howard, D. “The Disequilibrium
trolled Economy.”
American
Economic Review,
66 (December 1976), 871-79.

The ECONOMIC
REVIEWis produced by the Research Department
of the Federal
Reserve
Bank of
Richmond.
Subscriptions
are available to the public without charge.
Address inquiries to Bank and
Public Relations,
Federal
Reserve
Bank of Richmond,
P. O. Box 27622, Richmond,
Virginia
23261. Articles may be reproduced
if source is given. Please provide the Bank’s Research
Department with a copy of any publication in which an article is used. Also note that microfilm
copies of
the ECONOMICREVIEWare available
for purchase from University Microfilms,
Ann Arbor, Michigan 48106.
The identification
number is 5080.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

25