View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Nonneutrality

of Money in

Classical Monetary

Thought

Thomas M. Humphrey

Introduction
The rise of the new classical macroeconomics, with
its key idea that systematic monetary policy cannot
influence real activity, has revived interest in the
so-called classical neutrality postulate. That postulate,
of course, holds that money-stock changes affect only
the price level and not real output and employment.
My concern in this paper is not with the neutrality
postulate per se but rather with some recent claims
made about the original classical economists’ adherence to it.
In particular, I am concerned with the contention
that the classicals-i.e.,
those predominantly British
economists who wrote during the period 1750-1870
dating roughly from the publication of David Hume’s
Essays to the emergence of the marginalist revolution in the writings of William Stanley Jevons, Carl
Menger, and Leon Walras-denied
that money-stock
changes had output and employment effects even in
the short run. Such contentions have been voiced
most recently by Lucas Papademos and Franc0
Modigliani in their essay “The Supply of Money and
the Control of Nominal Income” in volume 1 of the
prestigious Handbook of Monetary Economics. They
state:
The role of money in classical economics is a simple one,
and so is the effect of a change in the quantity of money
on aggregate nominal income. According to classical theory
all markets for goods, including the market for labour services, clear continuously, with relative prices adjusting
flexibly to ensure the attainment of equilibrium. Resources
are fully utilized and thus aggregate employment and output
are always at the “full-employment”
or “natural” levels
determined by tastes, productive technology and endowments, except for transitory deviations due to real
disturbances.
In such an economy, money . . . does not influence the
determination
of relative prices, real interest rates, the
equilibrium quantities of commodities, and thus aggregate
real income. Money is “neutral”, a “veil” with no consequences for real economic magnitudes . . . (pp. 4056).

Others arguing that the classicals believed that
money is always neutral with respect to output and
employment include David Glasner, Arjo Klamer,

Kevin Hoover, and Michael Artis. Glasner, in his
1989 book Free Banking and Monetary Refire,
asserts that “in the economy the classical theorists
envisioned, the monetary sector could not . . . be
a source of instability. A disturbance could only arise
in the nonmonetary or real sector . . .” (p. 59). Arjo
Klamer agrees. In the first chapter of his well-known
1984 Conversations with Economists, he characterizes
the classical view by means of a vertical aggregate
supply schedule drawn at the full-capacity level of
output in price-output space. The vertical supply
curve guarantees that any money-induced
shift in
aggregate demand affects only the price level but not
real output. Support for Klamer’s interpretation
comes from Kevin Hoover who, in his 1988 Th Nm
CLassicalMameconomics: A Skeptical Enquz’ry, writes:
The vertical aggregate supply curve provides an adequate
capsulization of the classical view. . . . Changes in the level
of the stock of money would change the general level of
prices, but, because money was thought to be neutral . . .
relative prices and the levels of employment and output
would not be affected (pp. 9-10).

Likewise, Michael Artis, in his 1984 Macrveconomics,
explains:
the classical model guarantees full employment equilibrium,
and the ‘neutrality of money’, i.e. the property that changes
in the nominal money supply do not affect the real outcomes, but only the price level (p. 193).

This article argues (1) that the foregoing interpretations are wrong, (2) that the classicals held that
money affects output and employment certainly in
the short run and perhaps to some extent in the long
run too, (3) that they identified at least nine reasons
for the occurrence of such effects, and (4) that their
concern with money’s impact on the level of real
activity strongly influenced their views of the
desirability or undesirability of monetary expansion
and contraction. In short, the following survey of
eleven leading classical monetary theorists-including
Thomas Attwood, Jeremy Bentham, David Hume,
Thomas Robert Malthus, John Ramsay McCulloch,
James Mill, John Stuart Mill, David Ricardo, Henry
Thornton, Robert Torrens, and John Wheatley-

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

3

from price inertia which caused money-stock changes
to influence output before fully affecting prices. They
found another source of nonneutrality in the lag of
nominal wages behind rising or falling prices. This
lag caused real wages and thus real profits to change,
thereby altering incentives for employment and
production. They also attributed money’s nonneutrality to the ftity of certain nominal contractual costs
whose real burden rose or fell with deflation or
inflation.

reveals that at least eight rejected the notion that
money is always neutral and that continuous marketclearing and perfect wage-price flexibility prevail. l
In holding that money’s short-run impact is predominantly on output while its long-run impact is chiefly
on prices, the classicals adhered to much the same
view expressed by Milton Friedman in his 1970
Wincott Memorial lecture on The Counter-Revohdon
in Monetav Thory. Wrote Friedman: “In the short
run, which may be as much as five or ten years,
monetary changes affect primarily output. Over
decades, on the other hand, the rate of monetary
growth affects primarily prices” (pp. 23-24).

Inflation-induced shifts of real income from workers
and rentiers to producers who invest in real capital
constituted an additional source of nonneutrality. So
did the lag in nominal interest rates behind inflation
which caused real rates to change thus affecting
business borrowing, capital investment, and real activity. Nonneutrality was also seen to stem from
desired fixed inventory-to-sales
ratios that transformed money-induced increases in sales into increased production for inventory. The classicals
likewise traced nonneutrality to a confusion between
changes in general and relative prices-this
confusion causing monetary shocks to be misperceived as
real ones requiring output .adjustments.

The article proceeds as follows: First it itemizes
the particular sources or causes .of nonneutrality
specified by the classicals. Next it describes what
individual classical writers had to say about each item.
Finally it shows how classical views of nonneutrality
continue to survive in twentieth-century
monetary
thought. The central message is that the notion of
at least some nonneutrality is part of an enduring
classical monetary tradition and that theories stressing neutrality-always
are a departure from that
tradition.

The classicals further argued that money affects
output by influencing business confidence. They also
cited the boost to productivity given by moneyinduced increases in aggregate demand which, by
extending the scope of the market for goods, encourages specialization and division of labor. Some
classicals even held that money’s output effects
emanate from the-need to work harder to maintain
one’s real income in the face of inflation.

Sources of Nonneutrali&
The table below lists the causes of nonneutrality
specified by the classicals. A glance at the table
shows how erroneous is the notion that those
economists denied that money affects real activity.
For example, they argued that real effects could stem
1 On these points see O’Brien (1975, pp. 162-6.5) and Niehans
(1987) both of whom stress the short-run nonneutrality of money
in classical thought. See also Viner (1937, pp. 185-200) for an
earlier treatment of that same subject.

Rightly or wrongly, the classicals appealed to
many explanations to account for money’s impact on

SOURCES OF NONNEUTRALITY
Cause(s) Money to affect
real activity through:

Source

Sticky
Sticky

prices
nominal

wages

Fixed nominal costs
Fixed nominal income of
certain groups (“forced
Sticky

nominal

interest

Fixed inventory-to-sales
General

price-relative

Hume

real wages

Thornton,

Torrens

real cost burdens

Attwood,

McCulloch

shares and capital

rates

real interest

ratios

inventory

price confusion

State of business confidence
Market-size
limitation to division
Efforts to maintain real income
4

real expenditure

distributive

saving”)

of labor

Described by:

misperceived

Bentham, Thornton, Malthus,
Ricardo, McCulloch
Torrens
Thornton

rates

investment

J. S. Mill

price signals

changes in confidence
labor productivity
labor-force participation

formation

rate

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MARCH/APRIL

1991

Attwood,

McCulloch,

Attwood,
Torrens

Malthus,

Torrens
Torrens

output and employment. One of the first to do so
was David Hume, who invoked the notion of price
inertia.
David Hume and the Lag of Prices
Behind Money

kinds, for the use of his family. . . . It is easy to trace the
money in its progress through the whole commonwealth;
where we shall find, that it must first quicken the diligence
of every individual, before it encrease the price of labour
(P. 3%

The classical theory of nonneutrality, though partly
rooted in the writings of Richard Cantillon, John Law,
and William Potter, owes its greatest debt to David
Hume. In his 1752 essays “Of Money” and “Of
Interest,” Hume argued that while a fixed absolute
quantity of money is of no consequence for the level
of output and employment, c/langes in the quantity
of money have a very real significance.
Accordingly we find, that, in every kingdom into which
money begins to flow in greater abundance than formerly,
every thing takes a new face: labour and industry gain life;
the merchant becomes more enterprising, the manufacturer
more diligent and skilful, and even the farmer follows his
plough with greater alacrity and attention (p. 37).

Hume attributes these nonneutralities to the lag
of prices behind money. This lag, he says, causes
money-induced changes in nominal spending to be
divided in favor of output before being fully absorbed by prices. In his words:
To account, then, for this phenomenon, we must consider,
that though the high price of commodities be a necessary
consequence of the encrease of gold and silver, yet it follows
not immediately upon that encrease; but some time is
required before the money circulates through the whole
state, and makes its effect be felt on all ranks of people.
At first, no alteration is perceived; by degrees the price
rises, first of one commodity, then of another; till the
whole at last reaches a just proportion with the new quantity of specie which is in the kingdom. In my opinion, it
is only in this interval or intermediate situation, between
the acquisition of money and rise of prices, that the encreasing quantity of gold and silver is favourable to industry
(pp. 37-38).

Hume ascribes the price lag to the availability of
idle labor willing to work at existing wages. Prices
and wages rise only after all hands become fully
employed.
When any quantity of money is imported into a nation, it is
not at first dispersed into many hands, but is confined to
the coffers of a few persons, who immediately seek to
employ it to advantage. . . . They are thereby enabled to
employ more workmen than formerly, who never dream of
demanding higher wages, but are glad of employment from
such good paymasters. If workmen become scarce, the
manufacturer gives higher wages, but at first requires an
encrease of labour; and this is willingly submitted to by the
artisan, who can now eat and drink better, to compensate
his additional toil and fatigue. He carries his money to
market, where he finds every thing at the same price as
formerly, but returns with greater quantity and of better

David Hume
(1711-1776)

Hume next distinguishes between temporary and
permanent nonneutrality. Temporary nonneutrality
stems from one-time changes in the money stock,
changes to which prices eventually adjust. By contrast, permanent nonneutrality stems from a continuous succession of such changes to which prices
never fully catch up.
As an example of temporary nonneutrality, Hume
considers the transitory stimulus to output exerted
by a one-time rise in the money stock. Noting that
the stimulus vanishes once prices adjust to the
augmented quantity of money, he concludes that
Money, however plentiful, has no other effect, iffixe, than
to raise the price of labour. . . . and . . . commodities.
. . . In the progress towards these changes, the augmentation may have some influence, by exciting industry; but after
the prices are settled, suitably to the new abundance of
gold and silver, it has no manner of influence (pp. 47-48).

Hume points out that this same process works in
reverse, a one-time contraction in the money stock
first depressing output and employment before it
lowers prices.
A nation, whose money decreases, is actually, at that time,
weaker and more miserable than another nation, which
possesses no more money, but is on the encreasing hand.
This will be easily accounted for, if we consider, that the
alterations in the quantity of money . . . are not immediately attended with proportionable alterations in the price of

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

5

commodities. There is always an interval before matters
be adjusted to their new situation; and this interval is as
pernicious to industry, when gold and silver are diminishing,
as it is advantageous when these metals are encreasing
(P. 40).

was equally adamant, holding that “an increase of
money has no other effect than to cause its own
depression” in value (1803, p. 17, as quoted in
Fetter 1942, p. 370).

To Hume, monetary contraction had devastating
real effects:

True, Ricardo and Wheatley sometimes expressed concern with the evils of monetary contraction. But the evils they had in mind consisted almost
solely of the arbitrary redistributive effects of deflation. Virtually no output or employment effects were
envisioned.3 Such views, however, were exceptions
and not at all representative of the dominant classical
position. Starting with Hume, most classicals accepted the view that money matters for real output
and employment, temporarily if not permanently.

The workman has not the same employment from the
manufacturer and merchant; though he pays the same price
for everything in the market. The farmer cannot dispose of
his corn and cattle; though he must pay the same rent to
his landlord. The poverty, and beggary, and sloth, which
must ensue, are easily foreseen (p. 40).

Here is the source of the classicals’ emphasis on the
evils of monetary contraction.
As for permanent nonneutrality associated with sustained rates of monetary change, Hume argued as
follows: Continuous money growth combines with
sluggish price adjustment to keep money forever
marching a step ahead of prices, perpetually
frustrating the latter’s attempts to catch up. The gap
between money and prices persists indefinitely, thus
producing a permanent change in the level of real
activity. Hume’s advice to the policymakers: exploit
such nonneutrality via gradual enduring monetary expansion. For while
it is of no manner of consequence, with regard to the
domestic happiness of a state, whether money be in a
greater or less quantity, [t]he good policy of the magistrate
consists only in keeping it, if possible, still encreasing;
because, by that means, he keeps alive a spirit of industry
in the nation, and encreases the stock of labour, in which
consists all real power and riches (pp. 39-40).

Lag of Wages Behind Prices
Hume blamed nonneutrality on sluggish price
adjustment. The next source of nonneutrality recognized by the classicals was the lag of nominal wages
behind prices. The classic& explained how monetary
expansion and the resulting rise of prices would,
because of the stickiness of wages relative to prices,
lower real wages, raise real profits, and thereby spur
J On this point see Fetter (1942, pp. 369-71) who effectively
refutes Viner’s contention that Wheatley was concerned with
the output effects of contraction. Also note that Ricardo’s belief
in money’s neutrality extended only to the leeeel, not the composition. of outout. He (W&z I, 208-9) thouaht that, because
ihe structure of excise taxes was fixed in’nomi&l terms, moneyand hence price-level changes could, via their effect on the real
tax structure, alter profit rates and thus incentives to produce
in different sectors of the economy. The result would be a change
in the composition, though not the aggregate level, of output.

Hume’s theory of the inflation mechanism was
inherited by the other classical economists. Of these,
only James Mill, David Ricardo, and John Wheatley
rejected it in its entirety. Ricardo, whose skepticism
of monetary policy’s ability to influence real activity
rivals that of modern new classicals, simply called
Hume’s theory “an erroneous view” (fi&
V, 524)
and remarked that “money cannot call forth goods”
(K&s, III, 301). Mill likewise dismissed Hume’s
mechanism with the assertion that money cannot
exert even the briefest stimulus to output since prices
instantly rise to absorb all the stimulus.z Wheatley
2 Mill wrote: ‘The man who goes first to market with the
augmented quantity of money, either raises the price of the commodities which he purchases, or he does not raise it.
If he does not raise it, he gives no additional encouragement
to production. The supposition, therefore, must be that he does
raise prices. But exactly in proportion as he raises prices, he sinks
the value of money. He therefore gives no additional encouragement to production” (1821, p. 123, as quoted in Cony, 1962,
p. 40).

David Ricardo
(1772-1823)

\

,\I
6

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MARCH/APRIL

1991

\

output and employment. Conversely, the lag of
nominal wages behind prices would cause monetary
contraction and the ensuing price deflation to raise
real wages, lower real profits, and thereby discourage
production and employment.
Henry Thornton was among the first to expound
these points. He noted that declines in the stock of
money would have no employment effect if wages
fell as fast as prices. He then observed that wages
in fact were downwardly inflexible in response to
price falls, particularly temporary or unexpected ones.
For that reason he thought monetary contraction
would depress real activity. In his 180’2 Paper Cmdit
he wrote:
It is true, that if we could suppose the diminution of bank
paper to produce permanently a diminution in the value of
all articles whatsoever and a diminution . . . in the rate of
wages also, the encouragement to future manufactures would
be the same, though there would be a loss on the stock in
hand. The tendency, however, of a very great and sudden
reduction of the accustomed number of bank notes, is to
create an unusu& and remporary
distress, and a fall of price
arising from that distress. But a fall arising from temporary
distress, will be attended probably with no correspondent
fall in the rate of wages; for the fall of price, and the distress,
will be understood to be temporary, and the rate of wages,
we know, is not so variable as the price of goods. There is
reason, therefore, to fear that the unnatural and extraordinary
low price arising from the sort of distress of which we now
speak, would occasion much discouragement of the fabrication of manufactures (pp. 118-19).

Of Thornton’s analysis two points are especially
noteworthy.
First, he attributes
money-wage
stickiness to the fact that wages are established on
the basis of the expected long-run equilibrium price
level which is much less volatile than temporary
prices. In a long footnote attached to the preceding
passage he explains that the equilibrium price level
in an open economy operating under the gold standard is determined
on purchasing-power-parity
grounds by the given world gold price of goods.
Second, he blames economic distress on unexpected
contractions of the money stock. In so doing, he
anticipates today’s new classicals who argue that only
unanticipated money matters for real variables.
To avoid deflation and its adverse effects, Thornton recommended
preventing
gold drainsparticularly those arising from bank panics and/or real
shocks to the balance of payments-from
shrinking
the money supply. The Bank of England should
offset or sterilize such drains with compensating note
issues, thus forestalling monetary contraction and its
adverse consequences. He was even willing to risk
temporary suspension of the gold standard rather than

Henry Thornton
(1760-1815)

to let specie drains precipitate declines in the quantity of money. To him, suspension was preferable
to contraction and the depression it would bring.
He was equally opposed to inflation although he
admitted that it could stimulate activity through the
wage lag. Said he:
. . . additional industry will be one effect of an extraordinary
emission of paper, a rise in the cost [i.e., price] of articles
will be another.
Probably no small part of that industry which is excited
by new paper is produced through the very means of the
enhancement of the cost of commodities (p. 237).
Ricardo disagreed with Thornton. He did so on
the grounds that wage flexibility rendered the lag too
short for money to have more than a negligible
impact on output. But other classicals concurred with
Thornton. Among them was Robert Torrens who
stressed the stimulus to profit and production
emanating from sticky wages. When the Political
Economy Club met in December 1830 to discuss
Hume’s theory of beneficial inflation, Torrens was
in attendance to state his views. According to J. L.
Mallet’s account of the proceedings:
Torrens . . . looks chiefly to profits as the great means of
increasing general wealth, and as wages are fixed from time
to time . . . and do not rise, perhaps for a long time after
the value of money has fallen, the Capitalist pays in fact
for long periods, lower real wages, and is a great gainer.
All employers of Capital borrowed are likewise benefittedpaying less interest. There is a greater stimulus to production (Political Economy Club, 1921, p. 219, as quoted in
Cony, 1962, p. 58).

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

7

Fixed Charges
Closely associated with sticky wages was another
source of nonneutrality, namely the existence of contractually fixed costs, notably rents, taxes, and debtservice charges. Being fixed in nominal terms, these
costs, the classicals explained, did not rise with prices,
at least not in the short run. Consequently when
prices rose due to monetary expansion the real
burden of fixed costs fell. The corresponding rise in
profits would spur output and employment. Conversely, monetary contraction and price deflation
would, by raising the real burden of fixed nominal
charges, discourage real activity.

gap between prices and fixed costs constituted the
key to money’s stimulus. “Prosperity,” he wrote, has
occurred whenever the government has
filled the Country with what is called Money; and thisp/m@
of Money has necessarily produced a general elevation of
prices; and this general elevation of prices has necessarily
produced a general increase ofpru$t in all occupations; and
this general increase of pm@ has, as a matter of course,
given activity to every trade in the kingdom; and whilst the
workmen, in one branch of trade, areprvdubzg one set of
articles, they are inevitably consuming an equal amount of
all other articles. This is the pmptity of & Country, and
there is no other prosperity which ever has been enjoyed,
or ever can be enjoyed (1826, pp. 11-12, italics in original).

Again,
The. . . prosperity of the Country is indeed to be attributed
to one cause only, and that cause is the general increase of
the Circulating Medium (1826, p. 12).

By contrast, monetary contraction and deflation,
he held, had the opposite effect. For when “paper
money is withdrawn” and “the prices of commodities
are suffered to fall . . . within the level of thefied
charges and expences . . . the industry of the country
dies” (1826, p. 42, italics in original). It does so
because “all the monied incumbrances,” being fixed
in nominal terms, “become encreased in real burthen,
and operate in arresting all the means and the motives
which conduce to the employment of labour, and to
the production of national wealth” (1819, p. 42).
Attwood concludes:
\

(1789:1864)

Of the classical writers, J. R. McCulloch and
Thomas Attwood stressed this particular source of
nonneutrality. Thus O’Brien (1970), in his definitive
study of McCulloch, writes that the latter saw the
benefits of monetary inflation
as being in reducing the weight of fKed burdens-rents
and
taxes-as they remained constant in money terms while the
prices of final products increased, hence increasing profit
margins. Increased profit stimulated production, employment, and wages. Precisely the opposite effect arose from
reducing the quantity of money (pp. 160-61).

Thomas Attwood too held that rising prices spur
activity by reducing the real burden of fixed costs
or, what is the same thing, by increasing the gap
between prices and these costs. “There is,” he
claimed, “no difficulty in employing and maintaining labourers, so long as the prices of the products
. . . are kept above the range of the fixed charges and
moniedmpenses” (1826, p. 42, italics in original). To
him the extra profits arising from a widening of the
8

When a [price] fall . . . takes place . . . first upon one
article and then upon another, without any correspondent
fall taking place upon debts and obligations, it has the effect
of destroying all confidence in property, and all inducements
to its production, or to the employment of laborers in any
way (1817, pp. 78-79, as quoted in Viner, 1937, p. 186).

In short, owing to rigid cost elements, deflation
leads to depression that brings suffering to the
unemployed and distress to producers. It therefore
follows, said Attwood, that
it is the deficiency of money, and not its excess, which
ought most to be guarded against, which produces want of
employment, poverty, misery, and discontent in nations
(1843, p. 18).

To prevent such disastrous monetary shortage he
recommended that the Bank of England
be obligated or otherwise be induced, to encrease the circulation of their notes as far as the national interests may
require, that is to say, until all the labourers in the kingdom
are again in full employment at ample wages (18 19, p. 44).

To Attwood, full employment was the overriding
policy goal and price increases the essential means
of attaining it. Said he:

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MARCH/APRIL 1991

so long as any number of industrious honest workmen in
the Kingdom are out of employment, supposing such deficiency of employment not to be local but general, I should
think it the duty, and certainly the interest, of Government,
to continue the depreciation of the currency until full
employment is obtained and general prosperity (1832,
p. 467, quoted in Fetter, 1964, p. xxii).

Accordingly, “the great object of currency legislation
should therefore be to secure and promote this
gradual depreciation” (1817a, p. lOln, quoted in
Checkland, 1948, p. 8). To this end he urged the
government to
Restore the depreciated state of the currency, and you
restore the reward of industry, you restore confidence, you
restore consumption, you restore every thing that constitutes
the commercial prosperity of the nation (1816, p. 66).

Attwood’s inflationary policy views were too
extreme even for other classical believers in the nonneutrality of money. John Stuart Mill (1833), for one,
opposed Attwood’s inflationism on the ground that
it only works by tricking or deluding producers into
thinking that nominal price changes are real and thus
constitutes a deceitful and immoral way to stimulate
activity. Mill did not, however, dispute Attwood’s
contention that inflation could raise profits by reducing the real burden of fixed costs. This item had
become a standard element of the classicals’ list of
sources of nonneutrality.
Forced Saving
The classicals explained the fourth source of
money’s nonneutrality by means of their&rce&z&zg
doctrine.4 The doctrine holds that monetary inflation
stimulates capital formation and potential output
by shifting real income from wage earners and fixed
income recipients having high propensities to consume to capitalist entrepreneurs having high propensities to invest.
The doctrine originates with Jeremy Bentham who,
assuming as he did continuous full employment,
used it to argue that a monetary stimulus must
operate through capital formation rather than through
the activation of idle hands, as Hume had claimed.
In his 1804 manuscript “Institute of Political
Economy,” the relevant parts of which were completed as early as 1800 or 1801, Bentham wrote:
All hands being employed, and employed in the most
advantageous manner, . . . the effect of every increase of
money . . . is to impose an unprofitable income tax on the
income of all fixed incomists.
If. . . the additional money have come into hands by
which it has been employed in the shape of capital, the
4 On the classicals’ forced-saving doctrine see Hayek (1932) and
Hudson (1965).

\

Jeremy Bentham
(1748-1832)

suffering by the income tax is partly reduced and partly
compensated. It is reduced by the mass of things vendible
produced by means of it. . . . It is in a certain degree,
though in a very inadequate degree, compensated for by the
same means; viz. by the amount of the addition made to the
quantity of sensible wealth-of wealth possessing a value in
the way of use. Here . . . in the . . . case of forced frugality, national wealth is increased at the expense of national
comfort and national justice (as quoted in Hayek 1932,
p. 125).

Henry Thornton extended the doctrine when he
argued that, owing to the lag of wages behind prices,
forced saving could be extracted from wage-earners
as well as from Bentham’s fixed-income recipients.
As he put it in his Paper Crediit:
Provided we assume an excessive issue of paper to lift up,
as it may for a time, the cost [i.e., price] of goods though
not the price of labour, some augmentation of stock will be
the consequence; for the labourer . . . may be forced by his
necessity to consume fewer articles, though he may exercise
the same industry. But this saving, as well as any additional
one which may arise from a similar defalcation of the revenue
of the unproductive members of the society, will be attended with a proportionate hardship and injustice (p. 239).

Oding to these forced-saving effects, Thornton concludes that “paper possesses the faculty of enlarging
the quantity of commodities by giving life to some
new industry” (p. 239).
T. R. Malthus further elaborated the doctrine in
his 18 11 Edinbu& Review article on “Depreciation
of Paper Currency.” He held that forced saving was
so potentially powerful in its effects on production
that output could rise equiproportionally with the

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

9

money stock leaving prices unchanged. Constituting
the most complete description of the forced-saving
mechanism in the classical literature, Malthus’s statement warrants quotation in some detail. He starts
by linking the money stock and its distribution to
capital formation and real output.
If such a distribution of the circulating medium were to
take place, as to throw the command of the produce of the
country chiefly into the hands of the productive classes
. . . the proportion between capital and revenue would be
greatly altered to the advantage of capital; and in a short
time, the produce of the country would be greatly augmented
(P. 96).

On every fresh issue of notes, not only is the quantity of
the circulating medium increased, but the distribution of the
whole mass is altered. A larger proportion falls into the
hands of those who consume and produce, and a smaller
proportion into the hands of those who only consume. And
as we have always considered capital as that portion of the
national accumulations and annual produce, which is at the
command of those who mean to employ it with a view to
reproduction, we are bound to acknowledge, that an increased issue of notes tends to increase the national capital,
and by an almost, though not strictly necessary consequence,
to lower the rate of interest (pp. 96-97).

These effects, Malthus said, may explain why “a rise
of prices is generally found conjoined with public
prosperity; and a fall of prices with national decline”
(P. 97).
Finally, Malthus notes that while forced saving
necessarily operates through rising prices, the rise
may be temporary. For
it frequently happens, we conceive, that . . . the increased
command of the produce transferred to the industrious
classes by the increase of prices, gives such a stimulus to
the productive powers of the country, that, in a short time,
the balance between commodities and currency is restored,
by the great multiplication of the former,-and prices return
to their former level (pp. 97-98).

In terms of the equation of exchange MV = PQ, with
velocity V constant, output Q rises to match the increase in money M leaving the equilibrium level of
prices P unchanged.
/
Thomas Robert Malthus
(1766-1834)

The key points, Malthus declares, are (1) that
new money accrues to capitalists to raise the share
of national income devoted to investment,
and
(2) that the corresponding required decrease in consumption is forced upon wage earners and fixedincome groups by the price rise caused by the
monetary expansion. Thus
A fresh issue of notes comes. . . . into the market, as so
much additional capital, to purchase what is necessary for
the conduct of the concern. But before the produce of the
country has been increased, it is impossible for one person
to have more of it, without diminishing the shares of some
others. This diminution is effected by the rise of prices,
occasioned by the competition of the new notes, which puts
it out of the power of those who are only buyers, and not
sellers, to purchase as much of the annual produce as before
(P. 96).

From his analysis, Malthus concludes that
10

Ricardo did not share Malthus’s opinion of the
productive power of forced saving. Though giving
formal recognition to the doctrine, he denied its
empirical importance. Thus he denied that redistribution from fixed-income receivers to capitalists
could produce accumulation since both groups, he
believed, possessed identical propensities to save and
invest. In this case, he said, “there is a mere transfer
of property, but no creation” of capital (WbrRs, VI,
16). And while admitting the theoretical possibility
that monetary expansion might extract forced saving from wage-earners via the lag of wages behind
prices, he contended that wage flexibility in fact
renders the lag too short and the resulting capital
formation and output expansion too trivial to
matter. Said he:
There appears to me only one way in which any addition
would be made to the Capital of a country in consequence
of an addition of money; it would be this. Till the wages of
labour had found their new level, with the altered value of
money,-the
situation of the labourer would be relatively
worse; he would produce more relatively to that which he
consumed, or rather would be obliged to consume less.

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MARCH/APRIL

1991

The manufacturer would be enabled to employ more labourers as he would receive an additional price for his commodities; he might therefore add to his real capital till the rise
in the wages of labour placed him in his proper sphere. In
this interval some mjhg addition would have been made
to the Capital of the community (W?, VI, 16-17, emphasis
added).

Likewise:
There is but one way in which an increase of money . . .
can augment riches, viz at the expence of the wages of
labour; till the wages of labour have found their level with
the increased prices . . . there will be so much additional
revenue to the manufacturer . . . so that the real riches of
the country will be somewhat augmented. A productive
labourer will produce something more than before relatively to his consumption, but this can be only of momentary
duration (WorRs, III, 318-19, emphasis added).

In sum, Ricardo, unlike the other classicals, was
extremely skeptical of the forced-saving idea.
Although the above economists disputed the size
of forced saving’s effects, none disputed the
distributive injustice involved. All saw forced saving
as an immoral and deceitful means of stimulating
accumulation and on that ground condemned its use.
Not so J. R. McCulloch, however. He praised
forced saving and its inflationary effects and rejected
any considerations of injustice. He readily acknowledged that inflation shifts real purchasing power from
fixed-income consumers to capitalist investors. But
unlike the others, he lauded such redistribution on
the grounds that the gainers exceeded the losers.
Besides entrepreneurs, the gainers included the whole
community which benefited from increased output,
employment, and capital formation. The losers were
confined to a small group of rentiers and annuitants
but excluded wage-earners since wages, he felt,
tended to rise with prices. The losers’ suffering he
thought a small price to pay for the general benefits
of inflation.5 Thus, at the December 3, 1830 meeting
of the Political Economy Club, he callously dismissed Thomas Tooke’s solicitude for fixed-income
recipients. According to J. L. Mallet’s Diaries:
McCulloch in his sarcastic and cynical manner derided Mr.
Tooke’s concern for old gentlemen and ladies, dowagers,
spinsters and land holders. He cared not what became of
5 Torrens in his 18 12 Erray on Moneyand PaDer Chzn~ took
much the same position. Hk wrote that fiied:income receivers
constitute “so small a proportion to the whole community, that
any inconvenience they may suffer, from a fall in the value of
money, sinks into insignificance, nay entirely vanishes, when
comoared with the universal ooulence. the general diffusion of
happiness arising from augmented trade; and &e rise in the wages
of labour, which the increased quantity of money is instrumental in producing” (pp. 40-41, as quoted in Robbins, 1958,
p. 76).

them, and whether they were driven from the parlour to
the garret, provided the producers-the
productive and
industrious classes-were benefited, which he had no doubt
they were by a gradual depreciation in the value of money
(Political Economy Club, 1921, p. 219, as quoted in
O’Brien, 1970, p. 166).

Although he extolled inflation, McCulloch’s main
concern was with the evils of deflation. In this connection he argued that any ill effects of paper money
expansion came not from inflation per se but from
the eventual need to contract to protect the nation’s
gold reserve. He feared that the damage wreaked by
the resulting deflation would far exceed the gains from
the preceding inflation. As proof, he noted that the
prosperity associated with inflation during the
Napoleonic Wars was more than offset by the distress
that accompanied the deflation in the immediate postwar period. To him, avoiding monetary contraction
was far more important than promoting monetary expansion. His emphasis on the damage of deflation
was typical of classical believers in the short-run nonneutrality of money.
Confusion of Monetary for Real Shocks
The classicals traced a fifth source of nonneutrality to a confusion between general and relative prices.
They explained that money has real effects because
changes in its quantity cause general price movements which producers mistake for real relative price
changes requiring output adjustments. Fooled by
unexpected monetary growth and the resulting
economy-wide rise in prices, economic agents treat
the price increases as signifying demand shifts special
to themselves and so expand production.
Credit for identifying this particular nonneutrality
goes to John Stuart Mill. In his 1833 article “The
Currency Juggle,” he explained how unanticipated
money growth had
produced a rise of prices, which not being supposed to be
connected with a depreciation of the currency, each merchant or manufacturer considered to arise from an increase
of the effectual demand for his particular article, and fancied
there was a ready and permanent market for almost any
quantity of that article which he could produce (p. 191).

In other words, each producer had misinterpreted
the rise in general prices as a relative-price signal to
expand his operations. Here is how monetary expansion and the resulting general inflation may, in Mill’s
words, “create a fat& opinion of an increase of demand,
which false opinion leads, as the reality would do,
to an increase of production . . .” (p. 191).
Mill recognized that the confusion between general
and relative prices applies equally to workers who,

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

11

The first relied on Adam Smith’s doctrine that the
division of labor is limited by the extent of the
market. Attwood, Malthus, McCulloch, and Torrens
employed this idea. They argued that monetary exaggregate
spending which
pansion stimulates
enhances the scope of the market for goods and services. In Attwood’s words:
the issue of money wi//create markets, and . . . it is upon
the abundance or scarcity of money that the extent of all
markets principally depends (1817b, p. 5, as quoted in
Fetter, 1965, p. 75).

John Stuart Mill
(1806-1873)

failing to see that price rises are so extensive as to
reduce real wages, supply extra effort under the
misapprehension that nominal wage increases constitute real ones. He explains:
the inducement which . . . excited this unusual ardour in all
,persons engaged in production, must have been the expectation of getting more commodities generally, more real
wealth, in exchange for the produce of their labour, and not
merely more pieces of paper (1848, p. 550).

Mill was no believer in long-run nonneutrality. He
insisted (1) that inflation’s stimulus is temporary at
best, (2) that it lasts only “as long as the existence
of depreciation is not suspected” or anticipated (1844,
p. 275), (3) that it ends “when the delusion vanishes
and the truth is disclosed” (1844, p. 275), and
(4) that it is “followed . . . by a fatal revulsion as
soon as the delusion ceases” (1833, p. 19 1). In other
words, once agents correctly perceive wage and price
increases as nominal rather than real, economic
activity reverts to its steady-state level, but only after
undergoing a temporary recession to correct for the
excesses of the inflationary boom. Here is Mill’s conclusion that, when people mistake general for relative
price increases, nonneutrality arises both at the time
of the misperception and also when it is corrected.
Mill’s insistence that only unperceived or unanticipated inflation has real effects marks him as a forerunner of the modern new classical school.

Similarly Torrens claimed that extra money improves
business .confidence and that “an enlargement of confidence always produces that enlargement of the
market which it anticipates” (1816, as quoted in
Robbins, 1958, p. 82). Extension of the market then
prompts increased specialization and division of labor,
thus boosting labor’s productivity. Through this
channel monetary expansion, in Torrens’s words,
“facilitates exchanges, and, by occasioning more
accurate division of employment,
augments the
productiveness of industry” (18 12, p. 95, as quoted
in Robbins, 1958, p. 77). In so doing, money growth
induces a higher level of output from a given labor
force.6
6 Traces of the division-of-labor argument survive today in the
popular notion that scale economies enable firms to respond to
demand-expansion policy by producing higher levels of output
at lower unit costs.

Other Sources of Nonneutrality
The preceding by no means exhausts the list,of
nonneutralities considered by the classicals. Also
analyzed were at least four more.
12

ECONOMIC ‘REVIEW, MARCH/APRIL

Robert Torrens
(1780-1864)

1991

Nor is this all. For Torrens in particular recognized that the labor force itself might expand under
the impact of inflationary money growth. He thought
that rising prices, by eroding the real value of fixed
nominal incomes, could force annuitants, rentiers,
and the like to go to work in an effort to maintain
their real incomes. Such people, he said,
finding their places in society perpetually sinking, will be
prompted to some species of exertion, in order to avert the
evil; and thus the number of idle individuals, who add
nothing to the general stock of society, will be diminished,
and industry will receive a two-fold stimulus,

namely one arising from increased division of labor
and the other from augmentation of the labor force
(1812, pp. 40-41, as quoted in Robbins, 1958, p.
76).
Torrens also acknowledged that money growth
could stimulate industry if nominal interest rates
lagged behind inflation so that real rates fell. He said
that when this happens “all employers of Capital borrowed are likewise benefitted-paying
less [real]
interest. There is a greater stimulus to production”
(Political Economy Club, 1921, p. 219, as quoted
in Carry, 1962, p. 58).
Division of labor, expansion of the labor force, lag
in nominal interest rate-these
constituted three of
the four additional sources of nonneutrality identified
by the classicals. Henry Thornton located the fourth
in sellers’ efforts to maintain constant real inventoryto-sales ratios. These efforts, which ensured that any
money-induced rise in the real volume of sales would
be matched by a corresponding rise in production
for inventory, were described by him as follows:
It may be said . . that an encreased issue of paper tends
to produce a more brisk demand for the existing goods,
and a somewhat more prompt consumption of them; that
the more prompt consumption supposes a diminution of
the ordinary stock, and the application of that part of it,
which is consumed, to the purpose of giving life to fresh
industry; that the fresh industry thus excited will be the
means of gradually creating additional stock, which will serve
to replace the stock by which the industry had been supported; and that the new circulating medium will, in this
manner, create for itself much new employment (1802,
p. 237).

All-in-all the classicals left a fairly extensive list of
factors explaining money’s short-run output effects.

real variables. Thus quantity theorists from Irving
Fisher to Milton Friedman introduced Hume’s price
lag into the equation of exchange MV = PQ to show
that, with velocity V constant, a change in the money
stock M produces a temporary change in output Q
before fully changing prices P.7 Keynesians employed
the same notion to argue that, with unemployed
resources, prices fail to rise in proportion with a
rising nominal money stock. The resulting rise in the
real money stock, Keynesians claimed, lowers the
rate of interest and thereby boosts investment
spending and thus the level of national income.*
Other classical sources of nonneutrality were
quickly absorbed into mainstream monetary thought.
Alfred and Mary Marshall (1879, pp. 155-56), A. C.
Pigou (1913, pp. 75-84), Ralph Hawtrey (1913), and
Keynesians in the 194Os, ‘5Os, and ’60s used the
notion of sticky money wages to explain how fluctuations in prices caused or accommodated by fluctuations in money produce corresponding fluctuations
in real wages and thus output and employment.
Irving Fisher’ (1913, Ch. 4) employed the idea of
sticky nominal interest rates to explain how moneyinduced price changes affect investment and real
activity by changing real rates. This idea formed the
basis of his (1923) theory of the business cycle as
“a dance of the dollar.” Likewise his (1933) debtdeflation theory of the Great Depression embodied
the classical idea that falling prices emanating from
monetary contraction depress real activity by raising the real burden of debt-service charges.
Additional classical ideas were put to work.
Austrian economists Ludwig von Mises (19 12) and
Frederich von Hayek (1933) used the classical doctrine of forced saving to explain the upswing phase
of their monetary overinvestment
theory of the
cycle. And most recently, Robert Lucas (1972) has
developed John Stuart Mill’s idea that money has real
effects when general price changes are mistaken for
relative price ones. Also prominent in Lucas’s and
other new classicals’ analysis is the Thornton-Mill
argument that real effects stem from unanticzipated
money. Classical contributions are thus seen to
underlie much twentieth-century work on money’s
nonneutrality.
These contributions notwithstanding,
the myth
persists that the classicals adhered to the neutrality

The Classicals’ Legacy
The classicals bequeathed their theory of nonneutrality to later generations of economists who
used it to account for money’s temporary impact on

7 On the nonneutrality of money in the writings of Irving Fisher,
the Chicago school, and the Cambridge cash-balance school, see
Patinkin (1972).
8 See Patinkin (1987, p. 640).

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

13

proposition in the short run as well as the long.
Keynes created this myth in his General T/rory when
he sought to differentiate his approach from those
of his classical and neoclassical predecessors. Today
economists and textbook writers perpetuate the myth
by disseminating a caricature “classical” macromodel
in which, money is always neutral. Further contributing to the myth is the tendency of writers
such as Arjo Klamer (1984, p. 12) to interpret the
new classical macroeconomics
and its policy-

ineffectiveness idea as a return to an original classical
tradition of neutrality-always. All are wrong. The
classical tradition never held that money was always
neutral. On the contrary, except for Ricardo and one
or two others, the classicals believed that money had
powerful temporary real effects and perhaps some
residual permanent effects as well. In the view of the
classicals, nonneutrality typified the short run and
neutrality at best held approximately in the long run
only.

REFERENCES
Artis, Michael J. 1984. Mu~~~economics.
Oxford:
Press.

Clarendon

Attwood, Thomas. 1964. Sekcfed Economti Writings of Thomas
Amood, ed. F. W. Fetter, London: LSE Reprints of Scarce
Works on Political Economy, 1964.
. 1816. Th Remedy; or, Thoughtson the Present
L&rzs.res. London. As reprinted in his Seiected Economic
wrtings.
. 18 17a. Prv@er@ Restored; or, Ref/ectioions
on the
Cause of the Present D&nxws and on the On/y Means of
Relievihg Th.
London.
. 18 17b. A Letter to the Ri&t Honorable Nicholas
Vu&turf. Birmingham.
. 1819. ALetterto the,!h’ofLiwpool. Birmingham.
As reprinted in his selected Economic Writings.
. 18 2 6. Th L.ute Pnxperity, and the PresentAdversity of the Country, Explained. London. As reprinted in his
SelectedEconomic Writings.

Fisher, Irving. 1913. The Purchusing Power of Money. Revised
ed. New York: Macmillan. Reprinted, New York: Kelley,
1963.
. 1923. “The Business Cycle Largely a ‘Dance of
the Dollar.’ ”Joumaiof theAmenkan StatitialAwxiation 18,
December, 1024-28.
1933. “The Debt-Deflation
Theory of Great
Depressibns.” Economemica 1. October, 337-57.
Friedman, Milton. 1970. Th Counter-Rewo&ionin Monetary
T/rewy. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.
Glasner, David. 1989. Free Banking and Monetary Ref0fm.
New York: Cambridge University Press.
Hawtrey, Ralph. 1913. GwdandBud Trade. London: Constable.
Hayek, Frederich A. von. 1932. “A Note on the Development
of the Doctrine of ‘Forced Saving.’ ” Quur?&y Joumai of
Economics47, November, 123-33.
. 1933. Monetary Thev
London: Jonathan Cape.

and the Trade Cycle.

. 183 2. Reportj?vm the Committeeon Secrecyin the
Bank of England &tier,
Parliamentary Papers (Commons)
1831-32, vi, Q 5758.

Hoover, Kevin D. 1988. The Nm Closrial Macroeconomics:A
Skqticol Enquiry. New York: B. Blackwell.

. 1843. ThomasAmoods Letter to Sir Robert Peel
on theCurrency. As reprinted in his S&tedBonomic Wn’tings.

Hudson, M. A. 1965. “Ricardo on Forced Saving.” fionomic
Recwd 4 1, June, 240-47.

Bentham, Jeremy. 1801-4. “The Institute of Political Economy.”
In Vol. III of Jeremy Bent/lam’s Economic Writings, ed.
W. Stark, London: George Allen & Unwin, 1954.

Hume, David. 1752. “Of Money” and “Of Interest.” In D.
Hume, Whitingson Economics, ed. E. Rotwein, Madison:
University of Wisconsin Press, 1970.

Checkland, S. G. 1948. “The Birmingham Economists,”
1850. T/re Economic HistoryRe&w, I-19.

Klamer, Arjo. 1984. Conversations withEconomy&: NXQI
Closccal
Economti~ and OpponentsSpeak Out on the Current Contn+
weny in Macnxonomtis. Totowa, NJ: Rowman & Allanheld.

1815

Cony, B. A. 1962. Monq, Saving and Investment in Engltih
Economics: 1800-1850. London: Macmillan.
Fetter, Frank W. 1942. “The Life and Writings of John
Wheatley.” Journal of PoliticalEconomy 50, June, 357-76.
. 1964. “Introduction.”
of ThomasAttwood. London.

SelectedEconomic Whitings

. 1965. Developmentof Btitih Monetary Orthoodoxy
1797-1875. Cambridge, Harvard University Press.

14

Lucas, Robert E. 1972. “Expectations and the Neutrality of
Money.” JoumaC of Economic Thory 4, April, 103-24.
Malthus, T. R. 1811. “Depreciation of Paper Currency.” Edinburgh Review 17, February, 340-72. In OccasionalPapets of
T. R. M&thus, ed. B. Semmel, New York: Burt Franklin,
1963, 71-104.
Marshall, Alfred, and Mary P. Marshall.
Industry. London: Macmillan.

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MARCH/APRIL 1991

1879. Economics of

Mill, James. 1821. Elements of Political Economy. London:
Baldwin, Craddock, and Joy.
Mill, John Stuart. 1833. “The Currency Juggle.” TuitS &finburgh Mugazitze2, January, 461-67. As reprinted in Vol. IV
of Th CollectedWok OfJohn Stuart Mill, ed. J. M. Robson,
Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1967, 181-92.
1844. “Of the Influence of Consumption on
Production.” In hays on Some UnsettledQuestionsof Politica/
Economy. London. As reprinted in Vol. IV of The Collected
WorRr of John Stuart MU, ed. J. M. Robson, Toronto:
University of Toronto Press, 1967, 262-79.
. 1848. Princ$les of Po&icaZEconomywith Some of
Their &p/ications to So&l Phiiosophy. 7th ed. 1871. As
reprinted in the Ashley edition, ed. W. T. Ashley, London:
Longmans, Green, and Co., 1909.
Mises, Ludwig von. 1912. Th Theory of Money and Credit.
2d. ed. 1934. London: Jonathan Cape.
Niehans, Jtirg. 1987. “Classical Monetary Theory, New and
Old.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 19, November,
409-24.
O’Brien, D. P. 1970. J. R. McCu&ch: AStudy in ClassicalEconomics. New York: Barnes and Noble.
. 1975. Th CC&al&momirs.

Patinkin, Don. 1972. “On the Short-Run Non-Neutrality of
Money in the Quantity Theory.” Banca Nazional’e del
L.avorv Quatter/y Review 100, March, 3-22.
. 1987. “Neutrality of Money.” In Th Nm Palraw:
A Dictionaryof Economics, ed. J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, P.
Newman.
Pigou, Arthur C. 1913. Unemp&vment.London: Williams and
Norgate.
Political Economy Club. 1921. Proceedings,Vol. 6, Centenary
Volume. London.
Ricardo, David. 1951-73. The Works and Correspondenceof
David Ricardo, ed. P. Sraffa, 11 Vols. Cambridge.
Robbins, Lionel C. 1958. Robert Torrent and the Evolution of
ClassicalEconomics. London. Macmillan.
Thornton, Henry. 1802. An Enquiry into the Nature and Effects
of the Paper Credit of &at B&an, ed. F. A. v. Hayek.
London: Allen & Unwin, 1939.
Torrens,

Robert.

. 1816. Letter to the Sun Newspaper.

April 23.

Viner, Jacob. 1937. Studies in the T/rory of InternationalTrade.
New York: Harper.

Oxford: Clarendon
Wheatley, John.
London.

Press.

18 12. Essay on Money and Paper Currency.

1803. Remarks on Currency and Commerce.

Papademos,
Lucas, and Franc0 Modigliani. 1990. “The
Supply of Money and the Control of Nominal Income.”
Chapter 10 of Benjamin Friedman and Frank Hahn, eds.,
Handbook of Monetary Economics 1, New York: NorthHolland, 399-494b.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

15

Productivity

in Banking and

Effects from Deregulation

*,

David B. Hunphmy

I.

I~R~DuCI+I~N
There has been a marked decrease in the rate of
productivity growth in the United States and other
countries since the early 1970s. The likely reasons
for this slowdown have been surveyed recently in
Cullison (1989). The slowdown shows up in measures of single factor (labor) productivity as well as
in the more comprehensive
multifactor measure,
which includes the productive effects of labor and
capital together. For example, productivity in the
U.S. nonfarm business sector only rose at a 0.22
percent annual average rate over 1973-87. But for
the 2.5 years prior to 1973, productivity growth was
over seven times larger (at 1.68 percent a year). The
slowdown was even more striking for some U.S. service sectors. In particular, the Finance, Insurance,
and Real Estate (FIRE) service sector experienced
an average labor productivity growth rate that was
negative, at -0.41 percent a year over 1973-87. In
the 2.5 years before 1973, however, this growth
averaged 1.41 a year (Baily and Gordon, 1988, pp.
355, 395).
Banking makes up 20 percent of the FIRE service
sector (net of owner-occupied housing) and thus contributes importantly to this sector’s behavior. The
purpose of this paper is to provide estimates of total
factor productivity for the banking service sector
over the past decade (1977-87) and to investigate
the cause of the low productivity growth found.
Productivity results are reported from two growth
accounting models: one based on a production
function and another based on a cost function. Both
approaches indicate a similarly low rate of productivity advance for the banking industry, ranging between - 0.07 (production approach) to 0.6 percent
(cost approach) a year.
The opinions expressed are those of the author alone.
Comments by William Cullison, Tony Kuprianov, and David
Mengle are appreciated. Alex Wolman contributed outstanding
research assistance.
l

16

It is argued that low productivity growth in banking is largely due to the effects of bank deregulation
initiated in the early 1980s. Deregulation permitted
the establishment of new interest-bearing consumer
checking accounts and eliminated ceilings on time
and savings deposit interest rates. Deregulation
during the 198Os, preceded by the intensive use of
cash management techniques by corporations in
the 197Os, effectively
removed
banks’ virtual
monopoly control over zero-interest checking accounts and low-interest small consumer time and
savings deposits. Core deposit interest costs rose but
were not offset by either reduced costs elsewhere
or with an expansion in measured bank output.
Apparently, market share considerations limited the
desire by banks to reduce operating costs enough to
fully offset the rise in interest expenses.
While banks may have experienced very low (to
negative) productivity growth, users of banking services have benefited. But the benefits, which are
similar to an increase in the “quality” of banking
output, are not captured in any measure of banking
output. Thus, although measured bank productivity
growth is low or negative, it would be inappropriate
to conclude that society as a whole has not benefited.
Rather, there has been a redistribution of productivity benefits in which users of banking services have
gained at the expense of banks.

II.
PRODUCTIVITYIS”OUTPUT PERUNITOF
INPUT,” BUT WHAT Is BANK OUTPUT
ANDWHATARETHEINPUTS?
What Do Banks Produce?
In many industries, physical measures of output
and inputs are readily available and, importantly, a
consensus also exists on how best to measure them.
In the electric power industry, for example, the
obvious measure of output is kilowatt-hours of electricity produced. Inputs used to produce electric
power include the number of workers, the real value

ECONOMIC REVIEW. MARCH/APRIL 1991

of electric generators and transmission facilities, and
the tons of fuel inputs used. In contrast, in the banking sector physical measures of output are not readily
available (although they exist for some banks); indeed no strong consensus exists regarding what it
is that banks produce. As a result, measures of
banking productivity can use different definitions of
outputs and inputs.
Banks produce a variety of payment, safekeeping,
intermediation, and accounting services for deposit
and loan customers (Benston and Smith, 1976;
Mama&s,
1987). Some have argued, however, that
banks primarily produce loans. With this (asset)
approach, the production of deposit services is viewed
as merely payment in kind for the use of funds from
which to make loans (Sealey and Lindley, 1977). In
effect, this is a “reduced form” model of the banking firm: the production of deposit services is treated
as an intermediate output to depositors who provide
loanable funds, so deposit services are netted out.
But there is no reason to focus on only a single
banking output such as loans, especially because the
production of deposit services accounts for half of
all physical capital and labor input expenditures.
Because deposit services are such a large component
of bank value added, explicit modeling of their productive structure, along with that of loans, will yield
a more accurate description of this structure for the
bank as a whole. This objective can be achieved
using a structural model of a multiproduct banking
firm. In such a model, the production of deposit
services would not be netted out; instead, it would
be one of a set of bank outputs.
For purposes of analysis, banks are considered to
produce payment and safekeeping outputs (associated
with demand deposits and savings and small denomination time deposits) as well as intermediation
and loan outputs (associated with real estate loans,
consumer installment and credit card loans, and commercial, industrial, and agricultural loans). Over the
last decade, these five deposit and loan output categories accounted for 75 to 80 percent of value
added in banking (Berger and Humphrey, forthcoming, see table). Such a categorization of bank output, with one exception (time deposits), is consistent with that identified in the user cost approach
to determine bank inputs from outputs (Hancock,
1986; Fixler and Zieschang, forthcoming).

used in productivity analyses: (1) the number of
transactions processed in deposit and loan accounts
(a flow measure); (2) the real or constant dollar value
of funds in the deposit and loan accounts (a stock
measure): or (3) the numbers of deposit and loan accounts serviced by banks (a stock measure).’ Because
output is typically a flow, not a stock, the preferred
measure is seemingly an output flow. Stock measures
would only be used if a flow measure were unavailable
or because the stock measure might be proportional
(on average) to a flow measure.
A time-series transactions flow measure of aggregate banking output is compiled by the Bureau of
Labor Statistics (BLS, 1989). However, this measure
exists only for the aggregate of all banks and has a
limited number of observations. Thus for most purposes, researchers have been forced to rely on stock
measures of bank output and to assume that there
is a proportionality between stocks and flows, so use
of stocks succeeds in approximating flows. Because
one possible stock measure-number
of deposit and
loan accounts-is
essentially unavailable for timeseries analysis,z researchers have relied on the stock
r A fourth measure, concerning bank debits and deposit turnover
(published monthly in the Federa/ Reserve Buh’etin),should not
be used. These data are in value terms and include both check
and wire transfer debits. As a result, the virtually exponential
growth in the value of wire transfers will grossly dominate this
series, even though wire transfer expenses are a minute portion
of total bank costs. While it is possible to remove the value
of wire transfer debits, the end result would be a measure of
the value of check and ACH debits, which is inferior to the quantity measure of aggregate check and ACH transactions captured
in the transaction flow measure discussed immediately below.
* See the Appendix for more detail on data availability.

Summary of Bank Total Factor
Productivity Estimates
(annual

average

growth rates;

1977-87)
QT

QD

GrowthAccountingMethod:
Production

Function

-0.00%
0.60

Cost Function

-0.07%
0.50

EconometricEstimation Method:’
Cost Function:
Hunter

& Timme

Humphrey

(1991)

(1991)

-

1.05
- 1.01

Measures of Bank Output
Based on data availability, there are at least three
different measures of banking output that could be

1 Both of these studies used multiproduct indicators of bank output rather
than the single aggregate index QD. Transactions flow data (QTI are not
available to be used in pooled times-series, cross-section econometric
analyses.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

17

of the real value of deposits and loans. These data
are available over -time and for each bank in the
United States. As a result, cross-section information
can be pooled over time, allowing the estimation of
more sophisticated econometric models than is possible with any of the other measures of bank output.
It is assumed, but has never been tested, that the
transaction flow of bank output over time is proportional to the stock of real deposit and loan balances
(Box 1).3 That these two alternative measures of bank
output have had a somewhat similar variation over
the last decade is documented below. While this does
not strongly support the assumption of strict proportionality between bank output flow and stock, it does
3 The same assumption is made in cross-section studies in
banking where scale economies are the focus of modeling and
estimation.

Box 1
When Will Stock and Flow Measures of
Bank Output Be Proportional
to Each Other?
Stock and flow measures of banking output
will be proportional to one another when only
the two following influences determine the
growth in nominal deposit and loan balances
over time. First, nominal deposit and loan
balances grow because of population growth.
An expanding population leads to a larger demand for bank transaction services as more
deposit accounts are opened, more checks are
and more savings deposits and
written,
withdrawals occur. Thus, over time, increased
transaction flows will be associated with larger
stocks of deposit balances. Population growth
and economic expansion also leads to loan
growth. The nominal value of the stock of bank
loans will rise as new loan transactions occur
and expand at a greater rate than outstanding
loans are retired. The second influence is .inflation, which raises the average size of loans
made and the average idle deposit balances held
by users of bank services. If only these two
influences determine the variation in nominal
deposit and loan balances, then deflation by
some appropriate price index will give the
real value of deposit and loan balances and
also reflect the underlying flow of bank
transactions.

18

suggest that somewhat similar estimates of productivity may be obtained using either output measure
for this period. This point is demonstrated below.
Inputs Needed to Produce Output
There is less controversy on measuring bank
inputs. Labor (number of workers or total hours
worked) and the real or constant dollar value of
physical capital (usually the book value of premises,
furniture, and equipment deflated by some price
index) clearly represent inputs needed to produce
bank output.4 However, there is less agreement about
also treating the real or constant dollar value of
loanable funds-core deposits plus purchased fundsas an input.
If labor and capital were the only inputs, then
measured productivity would refer to bank operating
costs. Since operating costs are less than one-third
of total banking costs, however, an operating cost
productivity measure by itself would not indicate the
degree to which productivity improvements may
affect user costs or bank profits. More importantly,
since capital and labor operating expenses which support a branch network are substitutes for the interest
costs of purchased funds (federal funds, CDs,
Eurodollars, etc.), operating expenses are not a
stable proportion of total costs either over time or
(especially) across different-sized
banks.5 This
instability can bias productivity estimates derived
solely from operating expenses, just as it has been
shown to bias the determination
of bank scale
economies (Humphrey, 1990). Hence the appropriate cost concept from which to estimate bank
productivity is total costs, which includes operating
plus interest expenses. From this it follows that the
five appropriate inputs are labor, capital, demand
deposits, small time and savings deposits, and purchased funds. Thus a total factor measure of productivity is preferred1
Unlike other industries, total costs for an aggregate
bank cannot be determined by simply summing all
costs at all banks. Some costs, such as the cost of
funds purchased from other banks in the interbank
4 Researchers familiar with the many problems associated with
measuring real capita! stock will find the measurement method
employed in this paper to be overly simple and potentially
misleading. Fortunately, these capital measurement problems
will have only a relatively small effect on the banking productivity results because the share of capital expenditures in total
cost is itself small, around 15 percent.
5 Purchased funds permit a bank to grow faster and attain a larger
size than if it relied solely on a base of branch-generated deposits.

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MARCH/APRIL 1991

funds market (e.g., federal funds), are costs only to
individual banks but need to be excluded when
aggregate data are used. This exclusion is necessary
because if there were only one aggregate bank, which
is the implicit assumption in using aggregate data in
the type of models specified, interbank costs would
not exist and total costs need to be reduced by this
amount. The cost of funds purchased outside of the
U.S. banking system, such as virtually all large CDs,
Eurodollars, and other liabilities for borrowed money,
however, would remain.
To sum up, both input (cost) and output (service
flow or stock) characteristics of core deposits are
specified (following Wykoff, 1991), rather than
only one or the other as is usually done in the
literature. In contrast, purchased funds have only
input characteristics. Overall, five categories of bank
output and five areas of input costs are specified.

III.
GROWTHACCOLJNTINGESTIMATESOF
BANKINGPRODUCTIVITY
There are essentially two ways to measure bank
productivity. The growth accounting approach (Box
2) uses raw data on input and output growth rates
plus information on input cost shares while an
econometric approach specifies a cost or production
function relating outputs to inputs and estimates this
relationship statistically. While the focus in this paper
is on the growth accounting approach, results of
existing econometric studies of bank technical change
and productivity are also noted.
The data necessary to determine banking productivity from growth accounting models based first on
a production function and second on a cost function
(both shown in Box 2) are different with the exception of the measure of bank output. In what follows,
the time-series variation of two bank output measures
are compared, after which productivity results
based on these output measures in both production
and cost-growth
accounting
models are then
contrasted.
Transactions Flow and Real Balance
Stock Measures of Bank Output
The transaction measure of bank output used here
is the BLS index of deposit and loan transactions
(QT). In contrast, the stock measure is an index of
the real value of deposit and loan account balances

Figure 1

A Comparison of Flow and Stock
Measures of Banking Output
(1977-87

or 89; 1977=100)

QT =: Transactions flow
QD =: Real balance stock
: Real total assets

, 6O _

1’

QD
/‘\

A’
....

120-

I

I

1977

I

‘79

I

I

‘81

I

I

‘83

I

I

‘85

I

I

‘87

I

I

‘8!

(QD).6 Both are shown in Figure 1. For comparison
purposes, the real value of total bank assets (QTA)
is also shown.7 Over 1977437, the annual average
rate of growth of QT was 3.8 percent while that for
QD was almost identical at 3.7 percent. But the
average figures can be misleading since QD was very
flat in the early 1980s but grew more rapidly than
QT at the middle of the decade. Thus the assumed
proportionality between bank transactions flows (QT)
and the stock of real balances (QD) is only approximate over this period even though the RZ between
QT and QD is relatively high (X2). In comparison,
QTA grew by only 2.7 percent on an annual average
basis and, if used as a measure of banking output here
(as some have argued), would understate the exbansion of bank output compared with the other two
measures.8 Such understatement holds even though
the R2 between.QT and QTA is higher (.97) than
that between QT and QD.

A Production-Based Measure of
Banking Productivity

The Bureau of Labor Statistics computes annually an aggregate measure of labor productivity in
6 The construction of both of these indexes are described in the
Appendix. The BLS data are available only through 1987 (BLS,
1989).
’ Real total assets were obtained by deflating the nominal value
of total banking assets by the GNP deflator.
s Since interbank sales of funds (e.g., federal funds sold) have
grown over time and show up in total assets, the aggregate value
of these assets will be overstated by this amount compared to
a situation where there is only one aggregate bank and interbank sales no longer appear on the balance sheet. Thus the
understatement possible when using total assets as an indicator
of aggregate bank output is even greater than that shown in the
figure since these total asset values have not been corrected for
this double counting.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

19

Figure 2

Production A preach: Single-Factor
(Labor) and l%al Factor Productivity
(1977-87; 1977=100)

4100
E 90

cent, and purchased funds growing by 3.1 percent.iz
The net result is that the cumulative level of total
factor productivity (TFP), using the QT transactions
flow output measure, is below that for labor productivity. A similar result occurs when TFP is derived
using the QD real balance stock output measure.
Overall, neither measure of total factor productivity
in a production-based
growth accounting model
shows any growth13 while the BLS labor productivity measure grows by 1.4 percent a year.14

A Cost-Based Measure of
Banking Productivity

80
II

l

1977

l

‘79

l

l-

‘81

.I

l

‘83

l

l

‘85

l

II

‘87

TFP(QT) = Total factor productivity

with transactions
flow output
TFP(QD) = Total factor productivity with real balance
stock output
LP(QT) = Labor productivity with transactions
j-low output

banking
output.
Cyclical
in bank
in new
growth

using transactions (QT) as its measure of
This series, LP(QT), is shown in Figure 2.
behavior of labor productivity is due to cycles
output transactions flows, specifically cycles
loans being made as deposit transaction
was always positive.9

Over the 1977-87 period, the average annual increase in numbers of workers was 2.4 percenti while
banking output (QT) rose by an average 3.8 percent.
Because output grew faster than the labor input, labor
productivity is positive (at 1.4 percent a year). But
labor productivity is not representative of overall
banking productivity if other inputs grew more rapidly
or slowly than labor.”

In a cost-based growth accounting approach (see
Box Z), input prices are used in place of input quantities and costs are attached to producing bank output. The productivity results using both output
measures in a cost model are. shown in Figure 3.
While the time pattern of the productivity indexes
differ over 1977-87, they start and end at almost the
same points so their annual average growth rates are
again quite similar, only this time they are slightly
positive-a 0.6 percent growth rate for QT and 0.5
percent for QD.ls
The differences in productivity estimates between
the production and cost approaches can be seen
in Figure 4. Total factor productivity estimates
I2 The real value of these three funds categories is the nominal
value divided by the GNP deflator. The real value of bank capital
is described in the Appendix.
‘3 More specifically, TFP using QT (QD) in the productionbased growth accounting model has a growth rate of -0.0
(-0.07) percent. The difference in TFP using QD versus QT
is directly related to QD being flat in the late 1970s but experiencing more rapid growth than QT in the mid-1980s (see
Figure 1).

r” Real labor input is from the BLS series on number of workers
in banking. The number of full-time equivalent workers from
the Call Repwt grew by only 1.6 percent a year over the same
period.

I4 Two alternative deflators for the replacement price of bank
physical capital were used for illustration. These were the GNP
deflator and the ratio of current capital expenditures (historical
depreciation) to the book value of physical capital. For the QT
output measure, average annual TFP was -0.28 percent and
-0.58 percent, respectively (rather than -0.0 percent as
reported above). For the QD output measure, these rates were
-0.35 percent and -0.64 percent (rather than -0.07 percent
as reported). All of these results use the BLS series on the
number of banking workers rather than the (slower growing)
number of full-time equivalent workers from the CaLRepwt. Use
of the CaLReporr labor data would change the QT productivity
growth rate from -0.0 percent to 0.06 percent and the QD
measure from -0.07 percent to 0.13 percent.

rr The bank labor productivity series derived in Baily and
Gordon (1988), p. 395, cannot be used for comparison here.
This is because their measure of bank output growth, derived
from National Income and Product Account data, is itself based
on the growth of the labor input. Thus labor productivity growth
will be zero by definition as the growth in bank output equals
that of the labor input.

is As in Figure 2, the divergence between the two TFP estimates
in Figure x is due to QD being flat in the late 1970s but having
a hieher arowth rate than OT in the mid 1980s. Also. use of
alter\ativi deflators for the v&e of bank physical capital resulted
in slighdy lower productivity growth rates (a result similar to that
obtained for the production-based
measure of banking
productivity-see
previous footnote).

Our (rough) estimate of the growth of the real value
of bank physical capital is 1.8 percent annually with
the real value of demand deposits falling by 3.5 percent, time and savings deposits growing by 5.9 per9 This result is seen in unpublished data on the six separate
components of QT (described in the Appendix) from the BLS.

20

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MARCH/APRIL 1991

Figure 3

Cost Ap roach:
Total Factor b roductivity

Figure 4

Comparison of Productivity Estimates
Based on Production and Cost
Growth Accounting Models

(1977-87; 1977=100)
120

(Source: Figures 2 and 3)
1201w
100
80III

1977

III

‘79

TFP(QT) =

III1

‘81

Total factor

‘83

I

‘85

‘87

productivity

with transactions

productivity

with real balance

8
a 90
4
80

Production

Approach

flow output

TFP(QD) = Total

factor

1977

‘79

‘81

‘83

‘85

'8;

stock output

derived from output and input quantities in Figure
2 are contrasted with those based on output cost and
input prices in Figure 3. Results from. the production approach suggest that productivity was mostly
negative or zero over the period and therefore slightly
lower than the cost approach, which yielded results
showing zero to slightly positive productivity growth.
In either case, the results show very low productivity growth, much lower than the annual 1.4 percent advance suggested in the BLS labor productivity
series (Figure 2).

IV.
ECONOMETRICESTIMATESOF
BANKING PRODUCTIVITY

V.
WHY WAS MEASUREDBANKING
PRODUCTIVITYSo Low OVER
THE LAST DECADE?

No studies, to our knowledge, have attempted
to econometrically estimate TFP for U.S. banks.16
Those U.S. studies that do exist have, instead,
estimated only the effect of technical change. In a
standard (translog) cost function context, In C =
f(ln Q, In Pi, t), technical advance-indexed
by
time t-is
expressed as -&-iC/&
while scale
economies are &rC/alnQ. Total factor productivity
is the combined effect of these two measures, adjusted for the change in output (dlnQ), or:
(5)

TFP

= -&KY&

+ (1 -alnC/&Q)

dlnQ.

Estimates of technical change in banking have
ranged from 0.96 percent a year over 198086 for
a panel of 219 large banks (Hunter and Timme,
I6 Two studies do exist for other countries; one for Canada
(Parsons, Go&b, and Denny, 1990) and another for Israel (Kim
and Weiss, 1989).
FEDERAL

forthcoming) to -0.90 percent over 1977-88 for a
panel of 683 banks accounting for two-thirds of all
bank assets (Humphrey, forthcoming).i7 In both of
these studies, the scale economy estimate was so
close to 1.00 that the scale adjustment to TFP in
(5) has only a small effect (altering the annual values
above to 1.05 and - 1.Ol percent, respectively). As
seen in the table, the econometric estimates of banking TFP lie on either side of those from the growth
accounting approach. Even so, all the estimates are
relatively small, much less than one might have expected a primi.‘*

RESERVE

Cash Managementand Deregulation:
The Loss of Low-Cost Deposits
In the late 197Os, historically high interest rates
greatly increased the use of cash management techniques by corporations. This meant large reductions
I7 The -0.90 percent figure is from one of the preferred models
estimated where bank physical capital is treated as a quasi-fixed
input and a time-specific dummy variable is used (instead of a
simple time trend) to reflect technical change. Two other studies
of U.S. bank technical change exist (Hunter and Timme, 1986;
Evanoff, Israilevich, and Merris, 1989) but these were concerned with only operating costs-not
total costs-and
are
therefore not comparable with the analysis here.
i* Indeed, the positive productivity growth rate from the Hunter
and Timme (forthcoming) study can be turned into a small
negative value when two deposit interest rates are specified in
their model-one
for core deposits, the other for purchased
funds-rather
than using the purchased funds rate for both as
they did (see Humphrey, forthcoming, for details).
BANK OF RICHMOND

21

Box 2
Growth Accounting Measures of Banking Productivitya
Production Approach:
Total Factor Productivity
Bank output (Q) is produced by combining
the real value of capital (K), labor (L), demand
deposits (D), small time and savings deposits
(S), and purchased funds (F) inputs according
to some production relation that changes in
efficiency (A) over time: Q = A f(K, L, D, S,
F). Expressed in terms of growth rates, the
growth in total factor productivity (A/A) is
defined to be the difference between output
growth and the expenditure share (wi, i = K,
L, D, S, F) weighted average of the growth in
inputs:
Total Factor Productivity
(1)

klA = Q/Q - w&K
- w&)/D

- w&/L

- w&/S

- w&F

where for Xi = Q, K, L, D, S, F:
%/Xi

= an annual growth rate expressed
as the index Xit/Xit - 1, where
t is time.

The use of expenditure share weights (wi)
presumes that the observed input prices-the
rental price of capital, the wage rate, and the
a This discussion

is drawn from Hulten (1986).

in idle demand deposit balances which did not pay
explicit interest. The process is described and
documented in Porter, Simpson, and Mauskopf
(1979) and can be seen in Figure 5. Increased use
of cash management techniques has emerged as the
dominant explanation for the unexpectedly slow
growth in the monetary aggregates during the 1970s.
To compensate for the loss of demand deposits,
banks came to rely more heavily on higher-cost purchased funds. Such a shift would have raised the real
average cost per dollar of bank assets even if all
input prices had remained constant. Since real
22

ECONOMIC REVIEW,

user cost of demand deposits, time and savings
deposits, and purchased funds-equal the value
marginal product of each input to the bank.
When the wi sum to 1.00, there is constant
returns to scale.b The productivity measure
(1) reflects total factor productivity (TFP)
because the productivity effects of all inputs to
the bank are being accounted for, along with
returns to scale. While TFP is the most comprehensive measure of productivity, it is also
the most difficult to compute because of the
data required.
Multifactor and Single-Factor
(Labor) Productivity
When
more aggregative
productivity
measures are derived, such as for all manufacturing or all services, intermediate inputs are
assumed to net out so only capital and labor
inputs are used. The resulting measure is
called multifactor productivity:
b In the econometric approach to measuring productivitv. the wr are estimated statisticallv , and need not sum
to 1:oO. In the growth accounting approach used here,
the observed expenditure shares will sum to 1.00 by
definition, imposing constant returns to scale. This restriction should only have a small effect on the results since
numerous cross-section banking studies either support
constant costs at the mean of all banks or are within
5 percentage points of it (so the cost elasticity of output
ranges from slight economies of .95 to slight diseconomies
of 1.05). See the surveys of Mester (1987), Clark (1988),
and Humphrey (1990).

average cost (corrected for input price changes) is
the inverse of productivity, measured TFP would
have fallen for this reason alone.
The negative cost effects from corporate cash
management
were continued with the banking
deregulation of the early 1980s. Deregulation permitted noncorporate bank customers to switch from
demand deposits to interest-earning Negotiable Order
of Withdrawal (NOW) and Money Market Deposit
Accounts (MMDAs). These new instruments inhibited the growth of demand deposits, shifting the
MARCH/APRIL

1991

Multifactor Productivity
(2)

k’lA*

= G/Q

- w&K

represents shifts in the average cost curve after
controlling for changes in input prices:

- w&/L

Total Factor Productivity

where WK + WL = 1.00.
(4)
The least comprehensive measure of productivity involves only the productivity of labor
(LP) or output per unit of labor input: LP =
Q/L. The growth in labor productivity is expressed as a reduced version of (1) or (2):

tiP/LP

= o/Q

- w&PS

Clearly, the growth of labor productivity in (3)
will only equal the growth in TFP in (1) when
labor is the only input (i.e., WL = 1.OO)or when
the growth pf othe: inputs are equal to that for
labor (i.e., L/L = K/K = D/D = S/S = F/F).

All of the above equations showing productivity growth in terms of a production function
have a corresponding cost function representation. That is, productivity can alternatively
be expressed as the residual growth in average
cost not accounted for by the growth in input
prices over time. In simple terms, total factor
productivity in a cost function context (B/B)

deposit expansion which did occur into interestearning time and savings deposits (see Figure 5).19
Prior to deregulation, banks had substituted convenient branch offices, service personnel,
and
nonpriced services (e.g., free checking) for their
inability to pay something close to .a market rate
on demand, savings, and small time deposits
I9 While checks can be written on NOW and MMDA balances,
they are not (legally speaking) available on demand and so have
been classified with time and savings deposits in the data
collected by regulatory authorities.
FEDERAL

RESERVE

- WKPK/PK
- w&D/PD
- w&F/PF

where:
- d/Q

= the growth rate of average
cost, expressed as the
growth in total cost less the
growth in output; and

$X/PX

= the growth rates of factor
input prices and the user
cost of funds, X = K, L,
D, S, F.C

- w&/L.

Cost Approach:
Total Factor Productivity

- Q/Q)

- w,jL/PL

c/C

Labor Productivity
(3)

B/B = (e/C

Under constant returns to scale, productivity
growth using the production relationship in (1)
equals minus one times the productivity growth
from the cost relationship in (4) or klA =
- B/B.d
’The measurementof these variablesis discussed in the
Appendix.
d k/A is positive because. increases in productivity in
(1) increases output while B/B is negative as increases in
productivity in (4) reduces cost.

(Evanoff, 1988). Once deregulation removed interest
rate ceilings and permitted consumer interest checking, banks quickly paid higher rates for the same
funds. From a cost standpoint, banks subsequently
found themselves to be “overbranched.” The profitability of their deposit base fell from $61 billion
in 1980, in constant 1988 dollars, to $4 billion in
1988 (Berger and Humphrey, forthcoming).
In effect, corporate cash management and deregulation removed banks’ virtual monopoly control over
zero-interest checking accounts and low-interest small
BANK OF RICHMOND

23

Figure 5

(which experienced the largest rate increases following deregulation), it is clear that the great majority
of the negative effects for banks seen during this
period are due to deregulation, not inflation.

Percent Composition of
Aggregate Bank Liabilities
(1977-891

~~~-:~.
-\ ‘\
‘\ ..

B
3
420-

----I

\ s-w.-.

Federal Funds
cIc-------------4)

lo-

1977

Demand Deposits
-.---B.--d-*\

I

I

'79

I

I

'81

I

I

'83

I

I

'85

I

I

'87

I

II

'89

consumer time and savings deposits (as rate ceilings
on these deposits were also removed).aO Subsequent
competition induced banks to shift from low-to
higher-interest cost funds inputs without a fully offsetting reduction in factor inputs used to provide
branch convenience and other low-priced deposit
services. In addition, since the deposit services
provided were largely unchanged as corporations
conserved on idle balances and consumers shifted
from one type of checking account to another, either
measure of bank output used here would have been
stable. With costs rising but output stable, costs per
unit of measured output should rise, even when corrected for input price changes, lowering TFP.
In addition to cash management and deregulation,
the inflation of the late 1970s and early 1980s also
contributed to the rise in bank costs. During this
inflationary period, some idle demand balances and
low-cost time and savings deposits would have continued to shift to Money Market Mutual Funds
(MMMFs) and been replaced by higher cost CDs
sold by banks to the MMMFs. But in order to control operating costs, MMMFs restricted the number
of checks written per month and specified high
minimum amounts. Such limitations would likely
have prevented any substantial disintermediation of
demand deposits and thereby helped keep bank costs
relatively low. Since over 80 percent of the deregulated bank balances were NOW and MMDA deposits
2o Another aspect of deregulation was that thrift institutions
obtained the ability to offer checkable deposits. This increased
competition and contributed to the reduction in banks’ monopoly
power over this low-cost product.

24

This analysis, we believe, explains why researchers
have failed to observe much positive net technical
change or productivity growth in banking during the
last decade. Going beyond this explanation, part of
the problem is also related to our inability to accurately capture all potentially important aspects of bank
output. If branch convenience and the continued provision of underpriced deposit services are valued by
users, then certainly some of the (now extra) costs
incurred by banks in providing “unnecessarily” high
levels of these services after deregulation have
served to increase the quality of bank output. If one
adopts this view, then what appears to be a productivity decrease may instead be the result of understating output growth as benefits received by bank
depositors rose relative to their pre-deregulation
level.
An analogous situation occurred in the electric
utility industry during the 1970s. Expensive pollution control restrictions were mandated for electric
utilities and, although these costs were largely made
up by rate increases, measured output of this
industry-kilowatt-hours-did
not rise commensurately. As a result, measured total factor productivity was seen to fall (e.g., Gallop and Roberts,
1983). But if cleaner air resulted, then the quality
of this industry’s output actually rose but will not be
captured in the output measure used. It is argued here
that the same sort of thing occurred in banking.
Market-Share Reasons for Not Reducing
Branch Convenience as Interest Costs Rose
It is easy to argue that the cost effect of deregulation could have been minimized if all banks had
pared their branch operations more rapidly and to
a greater degree. As it was, the real deposit/branch
ratio was still falling until 1982, when it reached a
minimum of around $28 million in core deposits per
branch office. This meant that banks were still
effectively building branches more rapidly than its
customer base was expanding, increasing convenience (and operating costs) in the process. While the
employee/branch ratio was more or less falling continually over this period, only after 1982 did the real
deposit/branch ratio start to rise, reaching around $36
million in 1988.
Seemingly, market share considerations inhibited
a more rapid and comprehensive reduction in bank

ECONOMIC REVIEW. MARCH/APRIL

1991

operating costs as interest expenses from deregulation rose. Since choice of a bank by a depositor is
largely based on convenience (according to industry
surveys), a dramatic and profitable reduction in one
banks branching network would serve also to expand
market share and profits at competing banks that retained their branch networks. In the end, both sets
of banks would have experienced higher profit rates
in the short run, but market shares and profit lfrr~ls
would have been redistributed away from those banks
that cut their branch networks the most. Thus
most banks seemingly chose to sacrifice short-term
profits in order to maintain market share and hoped
that long-term profit would follow as deposit growth
continued to exceed the establishment
of new
branches.
Outlook for the Future
The outlook is not very bright. First, the wave
of interstate mergers that have occurred already,
along with those expected during the 1990s (when
many states will eliminate their existing out-of-state
merger barriers), bring with them costly “one-time”
expenditures to integrate back office operations and
standardize the banking products offered. While these
expenditures will permit some cost reductions to be
realized, they will also add considerable software and
equipment expenses.
Second, the problem of excess banking capacity,
as evidenced by too many branches, cannot easily
be solved as long as failed or failing banks and thrifts
continue to be purchased by institutions with the bulk
of their own branch network typically outside of the
purchased bank’s deposit market area. Rarely do
regulators simply close a failed bank’s branches, and
rarely do banks in the same market area purchase
branches simply to close them. Instead, a failed
banks branch network is typically sold to an institution outside the market area and the buyer typically
keeps most of the branches open, perpetuating the
oversupply problem.
If the antitrust market concentration restrictions
on bank mergers were considerably relaxed, then
costs associated with overlapping branch networks
would fall. Such cost reductions result when large
competitors in the same deposit market area are
encouraged to acquire each other and close excess
branch offices (e.g., as occurred with Cracker and
Wells Fargo in California). While market concentration would rise, it is not clear that increased concentration would or has led to much uncompetitive
behavior in the form of reduced price competition
and increased profits. Indeed, recent research indi-

cates that low costs are the dominant explanation for
higher bank profits in concentrated markets (Timme
and Yang, 1990), not concentration itself as has long
been asserted. Overall, given the two problems just
outlined, it is hard to be optimistic about the future
of productivity in banking. The most likely outcome
is continued slow growth until the industry is able
to shrink itself sufficiently through greater reductions
in operating costs per dollar of deposits or assets.
Thus future productivity growth will more likely stem
from reducing current excess costs than from further
technological progress.
VI.
SUMMARY

Measured productivity in banking over the last
decade has been growing at a very low rate. Using
aggregate data over 1977-87, it is estimated that total
factor productivity growth has only been between
-0.07 to 0.60 percent a year? These estimates
are based on a nonparametric growth accounting
approach using first a production function and second
a cost function. These results were robust to a
number of influences (three different deflators for
deriving the real value of bank physical capital and
two different labor employment series). Importantly, these results are also robust to using two
different indicators of banking output: one a flow
measure of deposit and loan transactions and the
other a stock measure of the real value of deposits
and loan balances.
The primary explanation for the low productivity
growth experienced has been the shift in zero-interest
cost corporate and some consumer demand deposits
to purchased funds in the 1970s (a result of improved corporate cash management techniques,
higher interest rates, and the rise of Money Market
Mutual Funds), plus a later shift of consumer demand
deposits to interest-earning and checkable time and
savings deposits in the 1980s (a result of banking
deregulation which removed interest rate ceilings on
time and savings and established new interest-earning
checking accounts at both banks and thrifts). These
developments significantly raised the cost of bank
loanable funds. However, banks did not fully offset
these higher costs by lowering operating expenses,
reducing branch and service convenience, to compensate for the higher interest being paid. It is argued
that market share considerations
limited this
response.
21 Similarly low positive to low negative annual rates of productivity growth have also been found over a longer period, 1967-87
(Humphrey, 1991).

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

25

The outlook for the future is not bright. What is
necessary is a substantial reduction in operating costs,
since banking no longer has a virtual monopoly over
zero-interest checking accounts and low-interest small
consumer time and savings deposits. Future bank
mergers, while reducing costs in some instances, will
also lead to expensive “one-time” expenditures to
integrate back office operations and standardize
banking products. And bank failures, rather than

26

removing excess branch office capacity as would
occur in other industries, have tended to perpetuate
the overcapacity conditions that have led to higher
costs. Increases in banking productivity, when they
come, are more likely to result from reductions in
current operating costs and a rationalization of
overlapping branch networks than. from further
technological progress.

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MARCH/APRIL 1991

APPENDIX
Availability of Data and Measurement of Banking Output and Price Indexes

Data Availability
Aggregate data on the number of deposit accounts
from the FDIC are only available for two years over
the past ten, while no aggregate data are available
on the number of (new plus outstanding) loan accounts. While numbers of deposit and loan accounts
are reported in the Federal Reserve’s annual Functional Cost Analysis survey, the data cannot be used
in a time-series analysis. First, the sampled banks
change by upwards to 15 to 20 percent each year
so that a consistent time series covering the same
set of banks is not available. Second, the very largest
banks, those that service the largest number of such
accounts and experience the greatest rate of growth,
are not included in the survey.
Indexes of Bank Output
The transactions flow index of banking output
(QT) was developed by the Bureau of Labor Statistics
(BLS, 1989). This index measures demand deposit
output by the number of checks and electronic funds
transfers processed, which reflects the debiting and
crediting of demand deposit accounts as well as the
payment
processing
and accounting
activities
associated with these activities. Similarly, savings and
small denomination time deposit output is captured
by measuring deposit and withdrawal activity in these
accounts. Loan output is represented by the number
of new real estate loans, consumer installment and
credit card loans, and commercial, industrial, and
agricultural loans made during the year. Lastly, trust
and fiduciary activities are assumed to be proportional
to the number of trust accounts serviced. Investment
activities are treated as an intermediate good and
netted out, since their variation has historically been
associated with secondary reserves (where securities
are sold to fund higher-than-expected
loan demand
or deposit withdrawal activity and vice versa). In any
event, investment activities, plus the provision of safe
deposit boxes, investment advice, and insurance, account for only a little more than 4 percent of bank
employment, and their omission is not believed (by
the BLS) to have a significant effect on the variation
in measured output. Employment shares were used
to weight these separate transaction flows into a. single
index of banking output.

The alternative index of the real value of deposit
and loan account balances (QD) was developed by
the author. It represents a cost-share weighted
average of the dollar value of five deposit (demand
deposits, small time and savings deposits) and loan
categories (real estate loans, consumer installment
and credit card loans, and commercial, industrial, and
agricultural loans) from aggregate Call Report data.
The cost-share weights are from the annual Functional
Cost ha/y.& surveys for banks with more than $200
million in deposits. Nominal values of these five output categories were deflated by the GNP deflator to
approximate real values.
Total Cost of Output and Input Prices
Total cost is from the Cab Report and excludes
double counting at the aggregate level by deleting
the cost of purchased federal funds (see text). The
price of capital is a bank-weighted average of the new
contract cost per square foot of bank and office
building space for nine regions of the United States
reported in F.W. Dodge, Constmction Potentiaf..
Bdetin (various years). Other capital price deflators
were also used and their effects are noted in the text
(footnote 14). The real value of bank physical capital
used is book value deflated by the capital price
index. The price of labor is total expenditure on labor
divided by the number of full-time equivalent workers
(both from the Cal.. Report). The prices per dollar of
each of the three funds categories are in terms of user
costs, composed of the interest rate paid (i), the per
dollar reserve requirement (RR), and the per dollar
service charge income (SC). Following Hancock
(1986), but neglecting FDIC deposit insurance costs,
user costs (UC) are in general UC = (i + rFF’RR
- SC)/(l + r&, where rm is the rate on federal
funds, a market rate. The denominator adjusts for
the fact that the numerator costs are only fully realized
at the end of a one-year period, rather than at the
beginning. RR and SC are small for time and savings deposits and are difficult to separate out from
those on demand deposits, for which i is zero. With
these considerations in mind, our user costs are: UCo
=

(rFF RR

-

sc)/(l

+

rFF); UCS

=

k/(1

+

rFF);

and UCF = iF/(I + rm). In implementation, total
costs and the two factor input prices were deflated
by the GNP deflator to reflect real values. User
costs are already in real terms (see Hancock, 1986).

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

27

REFERENCES
Baily, Martin N., and Robert J. Gordon, “The Productivity
Slowdown, Measurement Issues, and the Explosion of
Computer Power,” in William Brainard and George Perry
(Editors), BrookingsPapers on Economic Actiti~ 2 (1988),
The Brookings Institution, Washington, DC: 347-420.
Benston, George, and Clifford Smith, Jr., “A Transactions
Cost Approach to the Theory of Financial Intermediation,”
Joumai ofFinance 31 (May 1976): 21531.
Berger, Allen N., and David B. Humphrey, “Measurement and
Efficiency Issues in Commercial Banking,” in Zvi Griliches
(Editor), OutputMeasurementin the &mikes Sector, University of Chicago Press (forthcoming).
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, FunctionaL
GxtAna,$s, National Average Report, Commercial Banks,
Washington, DC (various years).
Consolidated Report of Condition and Income,
Washinion,
DC (various years).
Clark, Jeffery, “Economies of Scale and Scope at Depository
Financial Institutions: A Review of the Literature,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Reziew 73
(September/October
1988): 16-33.
Cullison, William E., “The U.S. Productivity Slowdown: What
the Experts Say,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Economic Review 75 (July/August 1989): 10-21.
Evanoff, Douglas D., “Branch Banking and Service Accessibility,” JoumaiofMonq, Creditand Banking 20 (May 1988):
191-202.
Evanoff, Douglas D., Philip R. Israilevich, and Randall C.
Merris, “Technical Change, Regulation, and Economies of
Scale for Large Commercial Banks: An Application of a
Modified Version of Shephard’s Lemma,” Working Paper,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Chicago, IL (June
1989).
F.W.

Dodge Division, Dodge ConstmctionPotentialsBulletin,
Summary of Construction Contracts for New Addition and
Major Alteration Projects, McGraw Hill, New York
(various years).

Filer, Dennis J., and Kimberly D. Zieschang, “User Costs,
Shadow Prices, and the Real Output of Banks,” in Zvi
Griliches (Editor), output Measummentin the &mikes Sector,
University of Chicago Press (forthcoming).
Gallop, Frank M., and Mark J. Roberts, “Environmental Regulations and Productivity Growth: The Case of FossilFueled Electric Power Generation,” Journal of Political
Economy 91 (August 1983): 654-74.
Hancock, Diana, “A Model of the Financial Firm with Imperfect Asset and Deposit Elasticities,” JoumaL of Banking
and Finance 10 (March 1986): 37-54.
H&en, Charles R., “Productivity Change, Capacity Utilization,
and the Sources of Efficiency Growth,” Journal of Econometics 33 (October/November
1986): 3 l-50.
28

Hunter, William C., and Stephen G. Timme, “Technical
Change, Organizational Form, and the Structure of Bank
Productivity,” Journal of Money, Cmdit and Banking 18
(May 1986): 152-66.
Hunter, William C., and Stephen G. Timme, “Technological
Change and Production Economies in Large U.S. Commercial Banking,” Journal of Bushes (forthcoming).
Humphrey, David B., “Cost and Technical Change: Effects
of Bank Deregulation,” Journal of Productivity Analysis
(forthcoming).
“Flow Versus Stock Indicators of Banking
Output: ‘Effects on Productivity and Scale Economy
Measurement,”
Working Paper, Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond, Richmond, VA (May 1991).
“Why Do Estimates of Bank Scale Economies
Differ?,“’ Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic
Reehw 76 (September/October
1990): 38-50.
Kim, Moshe, and Jacob Weiss, “Total Factor Productivity
Growth in Banking: The Israeli Banking Sector 19791982,” JoumaL of PmductivityAnalysis 1 (1989): 139-53.
Mamalakis, Markos J., “The Treatment of Interest and Financial Intermediaries in the National Account: The Old
‘Bundle’ Versus the New ‘Unbundle’ Approach,” Review of
Income and Wealth 33 (June 1987): 169-92.
Mester, Loretta, J., “Efficient Production of Financial Services:
Scale and Scope Economies,” Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia Economic Review 73 (January/February 1987):
15-25.
Parsons, Darrell, Calvin Gotlieb, and Michael Denny, “Productivity and Computers in Canadian Banking,” Working
Paper, Department of Economics, University of Toronto,
Canada (June 1990).
Porter, Richard, Thomas Simpson, and Eileen Mauskopf,
“Financial Innovation and the Monetary Aggregates,”
Bnwkings Papers on Economic Activiity 1 (1979), The
Brookings Institution, Washington, DC: 213-29.
Sealey, Calvin, and James Lindley, “Inputs, Outputs, and a
Theory of Production and Cost at Depository Financial
Institutions,” humal of Finance 32 (September
1977):
1251-66.
Timme, Stephen G., and Won K. Yang, “On the Use of a
Direct Measure of Efficiency in Testing StructurePerformance Relationships,” Working Paper, Department
of Finance, Georgia State University,
Atlanta,, GA
(September 1990).
U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Pmductkity Measuresfor SelectedIndhstkesand GovemmentServices.
Bulletin 2322 (February, 1989): 170.
Wykoff, Frank C., “Commercial Banking Productivity Growth:
Evidence from Large Bank Balance Sheets,” Working
Paper, Department
of Economics,
Pomona College,
Claremont, CA (January 1991).

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MARCH/APRIL

1991

Survey Evidence

of Tighter

Credit Conditions:

What Does It Mean?
Stacey L. Schrqt and Raymond E. Owens *

Since early 1990, the results of the Federal Reserve
Board’s Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank
Lending Practices have been cited frequently as an
indicator of general credit availability. Results from
the Board’s survey suggest that a considerable share
of respondent banks were tightening their lending
standards during 1990 and early 1991. How should
these results be interpreted? This article attempts
to answer this question by addressing the nature of
the survey, examining the recent responses more
closely and comparing recent results to past results.
A Brief History and Description of the
Senior Loan Officer Survey
The Federal Reserve Board (hereafter, Board) first
began conducting its Senior Loan Officer Opinion
Survey in late 1964.’ The survey was considered
experimental until 1967, when it was made official
and the Board began releasing its results to the public.
Neither the survey’s sample nor its format was
changed from 1967 through 1977. Over this period,
a sample of at least 12 1 banks from among those
already participating in the Board’s Survey of Terms
of Bank Lending completed a written questionnaire
each quarter. These respondents represented banks
operating in the national business loan market, which
accounted for 60 percent of business loans outstanding at all commercial banks.
The survey is qualitative rather than quantitative,
focusing on loan officers’ judgments about recent
changes in their banks’ non-price lending practices.
Multiple- or dichotomous-choice
questions are
asked; that is, respondents must select a response
from a list provided. From 1967 through 1977, the
We would like to thank Marc Morris for critical research
assistance. Dan Bechter, Thomas Brady, Tim Cook, Bill
Cullison, Tom Humphrey,
John Scott and John Walter
orovided valuable advice and information. The views expressed in this paper are the authors’ and do not necessarily
reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or
the Federal Reserve System.
l

i From 1964 through 1977 the survey was called the Quarterly
Survey of Changes in Bank Lending.

survey contained a consistent set of 22 questions,
some of which were designed to identify whether
banks’ non-price lending policies (e.g., their standards
of creditworthiness) were, on net, tighter, easier or
unchanged from three months earlier. The Board
reasoned that banks first responded to changes in
the cost and availability of loanable funds by changing non-price lending terms and conditions of lending; only later would they adjust their interest rates.
Therefore, information on changes in bank non-price
lending policies would help explain the banking
industry’s response to monetary policy actions.*
The Board has revised the survey’s format several
times since 1977.3 In February 1978, it changed
several questions to capture more information on
bank interest rate policies and on the willingness to
make loans of different maturities. In May 1981, the
sample was cut to 60 large U.S. commercial banks,
generally the largest banks in their Federal Reserve
districts.4 Also at that time, the Board stopped conducting the survey through written questionnaires;
instead, Federal Reserve Bank officers familiar with
bank lending practices began conducting the survey
through telephone interviews with senior loan officers
at sample banks. In addition, the Board reduced the
set of common questions from 22 to 6, dropping the
questions on willingness to make term business loans.
Allowance was made for the inclusion of questions
on timely issues. 5 Since 1984, the survey format
has been even more variable, with the number and
type of questions usually changing from one survey
to the next; even the number of surveys may vary
2 See “Quarterly Survey of Changes in Bank Lending” (April
1968), pp. 362-63, and Taylor (1990).
3 See Davis and Boltz (1978), Trepeta (1981) and Taylor (1990).
4 In August 1990, 18 U.S. branches and agencies of foreign banks
were added to the sample. See Brady (1990).
s Over the years, questions have appeared on subjects like the
pricing of loan commitments, the use of standby letters of credit,
the financial deterioration of business loan customers, the
effect of money market deposit accounts on bank lending
practices and home mortgage activity.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

29

Chart 1

from year to year. Questions on standards of creditworthiness for business loans were not included from
1984 through early 1990.

Changes in Bank, Standards
of Creditworthiness
(% Tightening

Standards

- % Easing)

Recent Survey Results
In May of 1990, the Board reintroduced questions
on business lending standards. Respondents were
asked the following multiple-choice question: “Since
late last year, how have your bank’s credit standards
for approving loan applications from C&I [commercial and industrial] loan customers changed for
middle market firms and for small businesses?”
Respondents could answer that their banks’ credit
standards had “tightened considerably,” “tightened
somewhat,” been “basically unchanged,” “eased
somewhat” or “eased considerably.” Changes in the
enforcement of standards were to be reported as a
change in standards.
The question remained in subsequent surveys,
but the wording varied. In August and October of
1990 and January and May of 1991 the survey
asked, “In the last three months, how have your
bank’s credit standards for approving applications for
C&I loans or credit lines-other than those to be used
to finance mergers and acquisitions-from
large corporate, middle market and small business customers
changed?”
Chart 1 shows the results from the May 1990
through May 1991 surveys, which have received considerable media attention.6 It depicts the difference
between the number of respondents
reporting
“tightened considerably” or “tightened somewhat” and
those reporting “eased considerably” or “eased
somewhat,” as a percentage of all respondents.
Hence, the larger the difference, the greater the net
tightening of credit standards according to the survey
results. On net, over 50 percent of respondents
tightened standards for firms of all sizes during the
first third of 1990, based on the May 1990 survey.
Only one lender reported easing. The August survey
showed over, 33 percent tightening further on loans
6 Results are shown only for the 60 U.S. banks in the survey
sample, not the branches and agencies of foreign banks. It is
worth noting that the responses used to calculate the net percentages of respondents tightening lending standards or less
willing to lend are not weighted by the asset size of the respondent banks. Thus, if the respondents reporting tighter
lending standards generally have lower asset levels than those
reporting easing, true or asset-weighted credit standards may have
eased even though the survey might show more respondents
tightening than easing. In practice, the fact that results are not
weighted by asset levels has only been a problem to date for
the period 1978-83. During that period, there were usually some
respondents reporting tightening and some easing.

30

I
May 90
Source:

Federal

I
A%
Reserve

I
Ott

Board Senior

I
Jan 91
Loan Officer

I
May
Opinion

Survey.

to firms of all sizes; by October, at least 40 percent
reported further tightening. At most 37 percent
reported having tightened again on the January 199 1
survey, while 17 percent did so on the May survey.
No banks reported easing on the August, October
or January surveys.
Survey Results from Earlier Periods
How should the recent survey results be evaluated?
Are the results more extreme than those found
typically? Do they resemble results from surveys
taken during past recessions or periods of comparatively slow credit growth? Answers to these
questions can be gleaned from responses to similar
questions asked in earlier surveys.
2967-77 Since the Senior Loan Officer Opinion
Survey was initiated, the 1967-77 period has been
the only extended period during which consistent
questions about standards for and willingness to make
business loans were asked. Chart 2 summarizes the
responses to these two questions, neither of which
is identical in wording to those asked recently. The
solid line represents the responses of loan officers
when asked how their banks had changed their “standards of creditworthiness for loans to nonfinancial
businesses.” Possible answers were “much firmer
policy, ” “moderately firmer policy,” “policy essentially unchanged, ” “moderately easier policy” and
“much easier policy.” As in Chart 1, the line depicts
the difference between the number of respondents
reporting “much firmer policy” or “moderately firmer
policy” and those reporting “moderately easier policy”
or “much easier policy,” as a percentage of all

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MARCH/APRIL

1991

Chart 2

Standards and Unwillingness
Measures of Tightening
Lending Practices: 1967-l

to lend
of
977

Il,,,l,,,l,.,ll~~!l,,,l,,,l,,!I,,,II,,,l,,,l,,,I

1967

‘68

‘69

‘70

‘71

‘72

‘73

‘74

‘75

‘76

‘77

Note: Swveys were conducted in February, May, August and November
of each year. The chalt begins with data from February 1967.
Source:

Federal Reserve

Board Senior

Loan Officer

Opinion

Survey.

respondents.
An average of 18 percent more
respondents reported firmer standards than reported
easier ones over the 1967-77 period.7
The dotted line in Chart 2 shows loan officers’
responses when asked how their banks’ “willingness
to make term loans to businesses” had changed.
Officers chose from five responses ranging from “considerably less willing” to “considerably more willing.”
The line shows the net unwillingness to lend: the
difference between the number.of respondents ier.r
willing and those rnufe willing, as a percentage of all
respondents. That is, the greater the difference, the
less willing banks are to lend. On average, 2 percent
more respondents reported being less willing than
reported being more willing to lend.
Three general observations can be made from
Chart 2. First, changes in willingness to lend and
changes in net credit standards generally move
together; in fact, the correlation between the two
series is 0.88. That is, when banks are less willing
to lend, they tighten credit standards.
Second, the chart indicates a more generalized
tightening of standards and decreased willingness to
lend before.and during recessions (the shaded time
periods). For example, consider the December 1969
to November 1970 recession. Both series peaked
in May 1969, with 43 percent of all respondents
7 Of banks not reporting a tightening of standards, the vast
majority reported lending standards essentially unchanged from
1967 to 1977 and from 1978 to 1983.

indicating firmer standards of creditworthiness and
65 percent reporting decreased willingness to lend.
In contrast, for the last three months of the recession banks firming credit standards outweighed those
easing by only 5 percent; likewise, those more willing to lend dominated those less willing by 28 percent. For 1969-a year during which there was much
speculation about whether a credit crunch was in
progress-an
average of 38 percent reported tighter
lending standards, while an excess of 47 percent
reported decreased willingness to lend.
The survey yielded similar results for the November 1973 through March 1975 recession. Both
series peaked in August 1973 with over 57 percent
of respondents on net reporting firmer standards and
decreased willingness to lend. In 1973, as in 1969,
on average the net percentage tightening was 38 while
the net percentage reporting decreased willingness
to lend was 30. Both series declined for November
1973 and February 1974 and then began rising again,
reaching new peaks in August 1974. Results for the
end of the downturn, as captured by the May 1975
survey, showed that a below-average percentage of
respondents had somewhat firmer standards and a
decreased willingness to lend.
A third observation from Chart 2 is that r~@ondents
ahost never reported a net easing of standards on
business loans.* During expansions,
standards
tightened less dramatically than during recessions
(i.e., relatively fewer banks reported further tightening), but the number of respondents tightening continued to outweigh the number easing. We discuss
this remarkable aspect of the survey results below.
1978-83 By 1978 the Board had evidence that the
role of the prime rate was changing.9 Consequently,
in revising the survey, the questions on business
lending standards were rewritten to reflect that
evidence. From 1978 through 1983, loan officers
surveyed were asked about changes, compared with
three months earlier, in their institutions’ “standards
of creditworthiness to qualify for the prime rate” and
their standards “to qualify for a spread above prime.”
Possible. responses were “much firmer,” “moderately firmer,” “essentially unchanged,” “moderately
easier” and “much easier.” For a shorter period- 1978
through February 198 1-respondents
were also
asked about changes in their willingness to make
* The February 1972 survey is an exception; one more respondent (0.80 percent) reportedly eased than tightened that quarter.
9 See Brady (November

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

1985).
31

fixed-rate short-term (with maturities of less than one
year) loans and fured-rate long-term (maturities of one
year or longer) loans. The five possible responses
ranged from “considerately greater” to “much less.”
Responses to the two questions on lending standards
were highly correlated, as were those on the two
questions on willingness to lend.
Chart 3 depicts reported changes in lending standards on prime rate loans and willingness to make
fixed-rate, short-term loans. The results from the
February 1978 through May 1980 surveys were
similar to those from the 1967 through 1977 period.
Specifically, a net tightening of standards was always
reported, and changes in the willingness to lend are
highly correlated with changes in lending standards.
Moreover, the net tightening of standards reached
a peak with the survey preceding the 1980 recession (the November 1979 survey). This peak of 29
percent is lower than the peaks preceding the two
earlier recessions.
In contrast, the results for the August 1980 through
November 1981 surveys deviated considerably from
those for 1967 through mid-1980. For this period,
respondents reported a net easing of lending standards. These results are particularly perplexing
because they are the only evidence of a net easing
over a 15year period. The July 198 1 through
November 1982 recession is preceded by an easing
of standards that “peaks” in May 198 1, with 20 percent more respondents saying that they were easing

Chat 3

Standards and Unwillingness

‘79

‘80

‘81

‘82

32

Federal

Reserve

Board Senior

Loan Officer

With the survey results for mid-1980 through
1981 accounted for, we conclude that the trends
observed for the 1967-77 period continued to hold
for 1978 through 1983. As stated above, no questions on the standards of creditworthiness for business
loans appeared on the survey from 1984 until May
1990.

10The question on willingness to make fixed-rate short-term
loans was not asked after February 1981, but its relationship
to the standards question probably would have remained unchanged, given the high correlation between the two questions
(a correlation of 0.76 from February 1978 through February
1981), had it been asked.

‘83

Note: Surveys were conducted in February, May, August and November
of each year. The chart begins with data from February 1978.
Source:

What explains these anomalous survey results? As
Brady (1985) has documented, a weakening of the
link between prime rates and market rates took place
during the 1970s. Banks began pricing loans to large
borrowers at market rates and, to a great extent,
reserving the prime rate and prime-based rates for
smaller and less creditworthy borrowers. l l From
mid-1980 through 1981, the prime rate was abow
the average loan rate (Chart 4). With the margin on
p&m rate loans comparatively high, lenders depended
more on interest rates and less on standards of creditworthiness as a means of allocating credit. It is not
surprising then that survey respondents reported an
even more pronounced easing of standards on aboveprime rate loans that had even higher rates relative
to the average loan rate.

to lend

Measures of Tightening of
Lending Practices: 1978-l 983

1978

policy, most of them doing so “moderately,” than
saying they were tightening. For the question (not
shown in the chart) about changes in standards to
qualify for a given spread abow prime, the results
are more extreme: 42 percent reported easing on net.
Throughout the recession, a tightening of standards
was reported on net by at most only 17 percent of
respondents,
approximately the average for the
1967-77 period.‘0

Opinion

Survey.

I’ Brady (November 1985, pp. 21-22) explains that interest rates
(both market rates and the prime rate) were relatively stable until
the mid-1960s. Thus, prime-based loan pricing, which was
common during this period, resulted in relatively stable loan rates.
The relationship between market rates and the prime rate began
to change throughout the 1970s as market rates became more
variable and U.S. branches of foreign banks, which priced loans
off market rates, competed more actively in the U.S. commercial loan market. By about 1982, the practice of linking loan rates
to market rates, which represented the marginal cost of funds,
rather than to the prime, apparently a measure of the average
cost of bank funds, was commonplace. As a measure of average
costs, the prime changed more slowly in a volatile rate environment than did market rates. Thus, borrowers could obtain
relatively stable interest rates with prime-based loans. Brady suggests that small borrowers may have preferred this stability.

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MARCH/APRIL

1991

Chart 4

Spread: Prime minus Weighted Average
Short-Term C&l Loan Rate
3.0.
2.52.0-

Note:
Source:

Quarterly

data are shown beginning with the first quarter of 1977.

Federal Reserve

Board Quarterly

Terms

It is also worth noting that from 1967 through 1983
respondents almost never reported a net easing of
standards on business loans; in fact, net tightening
was reported by an average of 17 percent of respondents.is This suggests that the survey responses
might be biased. Why might bias arise? One possible reason stems from the incentive that regulated
institutions have to report to their regulator a tightening of standards, especially when their reports are
not made anonymously. This incentive would exist
if respondent banks perceive a risk of closer
regulatory scrutiny if they admit to having eased
standards. During 1990, this risk might have been
perceived as especially great, given reports that many
bankers viewed regulators as being overzealous in
their examination of loan portfolios.i6

of Bank Lending.

Interpreting the Recent Results
Looking at survey results from an historical
perspective shows that recent responses resemble
those from the 1969 to 1970 and 1973 to 1974 recessions.iz Specifically, for the years 1969 and 1973,
38 percent of respondents on net reported a further
tightening of lending standards, more than double
the percentage on average from 1967 through 1983.
During 1990, at least 40 percent reported further
tightening on average. 13 The 1991 survey results
thus far (those for January through May) closely
match those from the middle of both the 1969 to
1970 and 1973 to 1975 recessions. The May 1991
survey indicated net tightening by at most 17 percent, the average for the 1967 to 1983 period.i4

The persistent reports of tighter credit conditions
over the history of the survey make the survey’s
absolzm numerical results (that is, the net percentage
of banks tightening) difficult to interpret. To some
extent, however, the pattern of the reports of
tightness across business cycles means that the
survey’s results are most meaningful when viewed
datiwe to those from previous periods. Noting this,
the recent results of a tightening of lending standards
by a considerable share of respondents appear to be
typical for an economy entering or in a recession.

12We cannot compare the recent results to those for the 1980
or 1981 to 1982 recessions because the survey during those
periods asked about standards on prime rate and above-prime
rate loans and thus are not comparable, as discussed above.
r3 Recall that the 1990 surveys asked about standards to large,
middle-market and small firms. The average over the surveys
conducted in 1990 is at least 40 percent for firms in each
category.
‘4 Each quarter since 1973, the National Federation of Independent Business has surveyed its membership about their borrowing experiences. Dunkelberg (199 1) analyzes the results and
finds That the net percent of members reporting credit being
harder to eet during 1990 and the first auarter of 1991 is low
relative to-that in r974 and 1980.
-

15Remember that the survey results are essentially first differences: they report the change in lending standards over a threemonth period, not how tight standards are at the survey date.
Thus, because the results show banks continuously tightening
their standards from 1967 through 1983, if we take the survey
results literally, lending standards would have been unbelievably
stringent by late 1983.

16Despite these reports, relatively few survey respondents cited
regulatory pressures as the cause of their tightening of lending
standards.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND

33

The Consumer Installment Loan Question
Only one item has appeared consistently on
the Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey: “Indicate your bank’s willingness to make consumer installment loans now as opposed to
three months ago” (as worded on the January
199 1 survey). Possible responses were “much
more, ” “somewhat more,” “about unchanged,”
“somewhat less” and “much less.” Chart 5
displays the difference between the number less
willing and the number more willing, as a
percentage of all respondents. Answers to this
question exhibit the same patterns around
recent business cycles as do the answers regarding willingness to make business loans.
However, the 1980 results are extreme. On the
May 1980 survey, those reporting being less
willing to make consumer installment loans
exceeded those indicating greater willingness
by 57 percent, a record number and well above
the -42 percent level recorded in the August
1980 survey. The May survey was conducted
while selective credit controls were in place, and
it asked lenders to compare their willingness
to lend in May with that in February, before
the control program began. One component of
the controls was a 15 percent reserve requirement on all extensions of consumer credit over

some base amount.= The controls were lifted
in early July, and by August the economy had
rebounded from its spring slump. Lenders were
once again willing (and encouraged by policymakers) to lend.
a Schreft (1990) examines the 1980 credit control program in depth.

Chart

5

Unwillingness to Make Consumer loans
A Measure

1967 ‘69

‘7l

‘73 ‘75

of Tighter Lending Practices
1967-1991

‘77

‘79

‘81 ‘83

‘85

‘87 ‘89

‘91

Note: Surwys were conducted in February, May, August and November
of each year. The chart begins with data from February 1967.
Source: Federal Reserve Board Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey.

References
Brady, Thomas F. Memo entitled “The August 1990 Senior
Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices,”
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve Board, August
1990.
“The Role of the Prime Rate in the Pricing of
Business’ Loans by Commercial Banks, 197784,” Staff
Study No. 146. Washington: Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, November 1985.
Davis, Patricia, and Paul Boltz. Memo to Mr. Lindsey on
Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending
Practices, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, March 23, 1978.
Dunkelberg,
William C. “The Credit Crunch-Myth
Or
Mistaken Monetary Policy?” National Federation of Independent Business, April 199 1.

34

“Quarterly Survey of Changes in Bank Lending,” Fe&a/ Reeve
Bulletin, April 1968, pp. 362-63.
Schreft, Stacey L. “Credit Controls: 1980,” Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond, Economic Rewh, Vol. 76, No. 6
(November/December
1990), pp. 25-55.
Taylor, Gail Ann. Memo to Board Committee on Research and
Statistics on Proposal for Extension, with Revision, to
the Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending
Practices (FR 2018), Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, March 26, 1990.
Trepeta, Warren T. Memo to Mr. Simpson on Senior Loan
Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices, Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, June 19,
1981.

ECONOMIC REVIEW, MARCH/APRIL 1991