View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal
Reserve Bank of
NewYork

Quarterly Review




W in te r 1980-81

V o lu m e 5 No. 4

1

In M e m o ria m : J o h n H e n ry W illia m s
1887-1980

3

In fla tio n and S to c k V a lue s:
Is O u r T ax S tru c tu re th e V illa in ?

14

24
27

C u ttin g th e F ed era l B u d g e t:
A n a ly z in g H ow Fast E x p e n d itu re ,
G ro w th Can Be R ed uce d
C u rre n t d e v e lo p m e n ts
T h e b u s in e s s s itu a tio n
T he fin a n c ia l m a rk e ts

30

G lo b a l P a ym en ts P ro b le m s :
The O u tlo o k fo r 1981

36

O il P ric e D e c o n tro l and B e yon d

43

S o c ia l S e c u rity and S a ving s B e h a v io r

50

T re a s u ry and F ederal R eserve F o re ig n
E x ch a n g e O p e ra tio n s

The Quarterly Review is published by
the Research and Statistics Function
of the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York. An “ In M em oriam ” honoring
JOHN HENRY WILLIAMS (1887-1980)
begins on page 1. Among the mem­
bers of the function who contributed
to this issue are MARCELLE ARAK
(on inflation and stock values, page 3);
JAMES R. CAPRA (on analyzing how
fast Federal budgetary expenditures
can be reduced, page 14); WILLIAM J.
GASSER (on the outlook for global
payments problem s in 1981, page 30);
PAUL BENNETT, HAROLD COLE, and
STEVEN DYM (on o il price decontrol
and beyond, page 36); and PAUL
WACHTEL (on social security and
savings behavior, page 43).

An interim report of Treasury and
Federal Reserve foreign exchange
operations for the period August
through October 1980 starts on
page 50.




In Memoriam
John Henry Williams
1887-1980
John H. W illiam s was the rare com bination of
the scholar, outstanding in academic pursuits,
and the active practitioner of the art of central
banking. Fam iliar with the evolution of econom­
ics, the bulk of his career was concerned with
the application of that discipline to public policy.
Born in Ystrad-gynlais, Wales, his parents emi­
grated to the United States when he was an
infant. The fam ily settled in North Adams, Mas­
sachusetts, where John grew up. After earning
his bachelor’s degree in 1912 from Brown Uni­
versity, he taught English there until 1915. In
that year he married Jessie Isabelle Monroe, by
whom he was to have two daughters and, already
in his late twenties, began the study of economics
at Harvard. There he won a Ph.D. and the Wells
Prize fo r his classic study on Argentine trade.
After teaching at Princeton and Northwestern, he
returned in 1921 to the faculty of Harvard, where
he remained until his retirem ent in 1957.
A distinguished academ ic career soon brought
him national recognition. In 1932, at the nadir of
the Great Depression, he was appointed a mem­
ber of the United States delegation to the Prep­
aratory Committee for the World Monetary and
Economic Conference. In the spring of the fo l­
lowing year, when the conference was about to
open, he joined this Bank as Assistant Federal
Reserve Agent and immediately became involved
in the efforts to stabilize the exchanges. Deeply
concerned with this objective, he remained at the
Bank full time until October 1934. Thereafter, he
divided his time fo r more than twenty years be­
tween this institution and Harvard where he be­
came, in 1937, the first Dean of the Graduate
School of Public Adm inistration. At this Bank,
he was appointed in 1936 Vice President in charge




of the Research Function to which he attracted
many able economists. From 1947 until he
reached retirem ent age in 1952, he served as
Economic Adviser, continuing thereafter as con­
sultant to the Bank fo r another decade. Among
posts and honors too numerous to list was his
election as President of the Am erican Economic
Association in 1951. Two years after the death in
1960 of his first wife, he married Katherine R.
M cKinstry who survives him.
Although it was his m ajor professional con­
cern, advising on policy never came easily to
John Williams. He wrote that he always tried “ to
look all round a problem rather than to plunge
forthw ith for the bold solution” . His circum spection
reflected a deep understanding of the com plexity
of the problems confronting the authorities. In
dealing with these problems, theory was certainly
essential. He liked to quote Keynes’ view that
w ithout theory we are “ lost in the w oods” . But,
by its very nature, theory was a sim plification of
reality. Moreover, the most influential theories
were products of unique circum stances and, in­
deed, had their origins in views about policy
growing from those circum stances. In effect, the­
ory was often a rationalization for policy. Since
circum stances were constantly changing, he
warned that those who drew prescriptions glibly
from theory were dangerous as policymakers.
Understanding both the value and the lim ita­
tions of theory, John W illiam s was constantly
testing hypotheses against the realities of the
market. In doing so, he found much to justify his
skepticism. He particularly questioned conven­
tional views about the gold standard. The classi­
cal specie flow mechanism was a beautiful in­
tellectual construct which, however, failed to

FRBNY Quarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81

m irror the realities. The international monetary
system, which it purported to describe, was in
fact one in which Britain maintained a gold stan­
dard, w hile most other countries based their
currencies on sterling. He found related faults in
classical trade theory which neglected both the
dynamic relationship between the center and pe­
ripheral countries and also the adjustment diffi­
culties that the spread of m anufacturing in the
periphery caused for traditional industries in the
centers themselves.
His view about the key role played by the in­
dustrial and financial centers shaped Dr. W il­
liam s’ advice about the handling of international
monetary problems. In the thirties and forties,
much of the w o rld ’s econom ic activity was cen­
tered in the United States and Britain. Their cur­
rencies were the media in which trade and finance
were conducted. The problem of exchange insta­
bility, which bedeviled the discussions of those
years, boiled down to negotiating a m utually
acceptable relationship between the dollar and
sterling and then m aintaining that relation— stable
but not immutable— through appropriate domestic
policies in the two center countries. Such views
clearly influenced the United States Government
in the negotiation of the T ripartite Agreement of
September 1936. They also were the basis for
John W illiam s’ reservations about the Bretton
Woods agreements.
These reservations focused prim arily on the
International Monetary Fund. Dr. W illiam s c riti­
cized numerous aspects of its articles but his
m ajor concern was that the Fund, which was
designed to help correct relatively modest and
tem porary international imbalances, would be
incapable of perform ing this function in the very
d ifficult circum stances expected at the end of
hostilities. B ritain’s external difficulties would be
p articularly severe. Unless “ heroic measures” — a
continuation of Lend-Lease or a large low-cost
loan— were granted by the United States, Britain
would not be in a position to cooperate in the

FRBNY Q uarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81




reestablishm ent of a m ultilateral trade and pay­
ments system. Yet, such “ heroic measures” were
beyond the capacities of the Fund; in th eir ab­
sence, the trade and exchange restrictions that
had been erected during depression and w ar
would almost certainly be extended long into the
postwar period. Thus, establishm ent of the Fund
would create only a facade of cooperation w ith ­
out the substance. As events developed, mea­
sures even more heroic than Dr. W illiam s had
advocated were adopted in the troubled years
follow ing the war— the Anglo-Am erican loan, aid
to Greece and Turkey, and the Marshall Plan.
These, combined with the cooperative efforts of
Western Europe, eventually built an international
environment in w h ic h the Fund could effectively
function.
In fu lfilling its role throughout this disturbed
period, the Federal Reserve benefited greatly
from the broad experience and wisdom of John
W illiam s. In 1956, as he approached his seven­
tieth birthday and accepted the need to lighten
his professional reponsibilities, this Bank’s board
of directors expressed its appreciation, stating that
His w ide-ranging knowledge and ex­
perience in econom ic affairs, his sound
judgment, and his whole-hearted dedi­
cation to the public interest have marked
Dr. W illiam s’ contributions to the work of
the Federal Reserve System during years
of depression, war, and inflation. In addi­
tion to the wise counsel he has brought
to deliberations, he has been a constant
source of encouragement and inspiration
to others on the Bank’s staff, always
generous of his time and wisdom, thus
carrying some of his prim ary vocation
into his work at the Bank to its enduring
benefit.
If all this were not enough, he will
remain long in the memory of his asso­
ciates at the Bank who treasure him as
a true and steadfast friend.

Inflation and Stock Values
Is Our Tax Structure the Villain?

At one time, investors regarded common stocks as a
good inflation hedge. Because stocks represented the
ownership of real capital, people thought that their
value would rise roughly in proportion to the general
price level, at least over periods of several years.
For the last decade or so, however, stock prices
have not kept pace with inflation. The Standard and
Poor’s index of stock prices, for example, stood at
133 in the fourth quarter of 1980, up only 26 percent
from its 1968 fourth-quarter level. Yet, the price level
more than doubled in that same period. This meant
that the real value of equity fell almost 50 percent.
Why did this tremendous drop in real value of equity
occur? Some observers have suggested that inflation
itself may account for this phenomenon. One theory
is that the tax structure in the United States, particu­
larly that applicable to corporations, becomes more
burdensome when the price level rises. As a conse­
quence, a change in inflation can reduce a corpora­
tion’s real aftertax earnings. This could, in turn, lower
the value of owning equity.
This article explores the question of whether the
tax system— along with the acceleration in inflation—
could account for the poor performance of stock
prices. Overall, the analysis indicates that the tax
structure may well have played a sizable role in reThis is a revised version of an article that is part of a forthcoming
Federal Reserve System study of the Federal tax structure. I would
like to express my appreciation to Patrick Corcoran, Patric H.
Hendershott, Patrick Lawlor, Martha Scanlon, Thomas Simpson, and
Helmut Wendel for useful comments and suggestions, and to
Joseph Snailer for statistical assistance.




ducing real stock prices. At the same time, the analy­
sis indicates that the tax structure cannot account for
the whole decline.
A closer look at real stock prices
Stock price averages such as the Standard and Poor’s
index of 500 common stock prices moved up sharply
in the early 1960s and then more slowly from 1966 to
1973 (Chart 1). Then, in 1974, prices plunged. Although
they recovered somewhat thereafter, stock prices un­
til very recently remained below their 1973 peak.
In constant dollars, stock price performance was
much worse, falling dramatically since 1968 (Chart 2).
Real stock prices peaked in the 1965-68 period and
then declined through 1970. Although there was some
recovery from 1971 through 1973, real stock prices
did not regain their previous peak. Then, in late 1973
and 1974, real stock prices dropped precipitously back
to their 1954-55 level. They have not since recovered
substantially.
How can one explain this phenomenal drop in real
stock values? One simple hypothesis is that stock­
holders were paid dividends in excess of aftertax cor­
porate earnings. In this case, corporations would not
have had sufficient funds to replace equipment or
structures as they depreciated unless they borrowed.
Whether corporations ran down their stock of fixed
capital or borrowed to maintain it, the amount of fixed
capital owned free and clear by stockholders would
decline. The data, however, do not support this hypoth­
esis: in every year from 1967 to 1979, corporations
paid dividends smaller than their aftertax “true”

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81

3

Chart 1

Standard & Poor’s Stock Price Index of
5 0 0 Stocks

Chart 2

1941-43=10

Standard & Poor’s index deflated by
the GNP price deflator

Index
1 3 0 ----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

" R e a l” Stock Prices

Index
1 3 0 --------------------------------------------------------------

Sources: Standard & Poor’s index of 500 stocks:
Standard & Poor’s Corporation; gross national product
implicit price deflator: United States Department of
Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.
Source:

Standard & Poor’s Corporation.

profits (see glossary). Thus, the stock price per dollar
of equity investment, w hich includes retained earn­
ings, declined even more sharply than the real stock
prices shown in Chart 2.
A second hypothesis is that inflation was responsible
fo r the decline in equity values. Here the data do lend
support. For example, the acceleration of inflation in
the seventies (Chart 3) does coincide roughly with the
deterioration of real stock values. Moreover, statistical
analyses over long periods of tim e indicate that stock
prices were negatively correlated with the rate of
inflation.1 O ther statistical studies show that the re­
turns to equity— which may have been reflected in
equity values— were also negatively affected by in­
1 See Franco M odigliani and Richard A. Cohn, “ Inflation, Rational
Valuation and the M arket” , Financial Analysts Journal (M a rc h /A p ril
1979); Bruno Oudet, “ The Variation of the Return on Stocks in
Periods of Infla tion” , Journal o f Financial and Quantitative Analysis
(M arch 1973); and John Lintner, “ Inflation and Security Returns” ,
Journal of Finance (M ay 1975).

4 forFRBNY
Digitized
FRASERQ uarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81


flation.2 All this evidence suggests a negative correla­
tion between inflation and stock values. However, it
does not explain the linkage. One explanation of the
linkage is that the structure of the tax system reduces
equity returns when inflation accelerates.
Tax nonneutrality as an explanation of
stock prices
A tax is “ neutral” with respect to inflation if it collects
the same tax monies, in real terms, from a given
amount of real income regardless of the price level.
That is, the taxation ratio associated with a given real
income does not change w ith inflation. Both the per­
sonal income tax and the corporate income tax codes
in the United States contain features that are not neu­
tral. For example, the marginal tax rate brackets of
2 See Eugene F. Fama, “ Stock Returns, Real Activity, Inflation and
Money” , Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago
W orking Paper (1979).

the personal income tax are based upon dollar income
rather than real income. If tax rates are unchanged, a
proportional rise in prices and nominal incomes will
put taxpayers in higher marginal tax brackets and
their taxes w ill rise more than in proportion to prices.
As a result, a larger percentage of their income w ill
be paid in taxes even though their real income is no
higher. Also, the dollar value of realized capital gains
is taxed even if the asset did not appreciate in real
terms, i.e., no additional purchasing power was
achieved.
At the corporate level, the Federal tax code has two
main features that cause an increase in the tax bur­
den when prices accelerate: (1) “ nom inal” inventory
profits are taxable3 and (2) allowable depreciation is
based upon the original, rather than the replacement,
cost of equipment and structures.
Inventory profits
Corporations are taxed on total nom inal inventory
profits. Like capital gains, inventory profits are taxed
even if the goods do not appreciate in real terms. The
value of inventories is typically computed by using one
of two accounting methods: “ first in-first o u t” (FIFO)
or “ last in-first o ut” (LIFO). For a corporation using
FIFO, the oldest item in inventory is assumed to be
the first sold. The value of a fixed volume of raw ma­
terials, say, w ill rise as “ o ld ” items are taken from
inventory and new higher priced ones are added. In
contrast, fo r corporations using the LIFO procedure, the
item inventoried most recently is the one assumed to be
removed from inventory and replaced with a newly
produced item. The inventory profit calculated by this
method is typically small, unless a firm liquidates an
extensive portion of its inventory. As a consequence,
firms have an incentive to switch to LIFO and some of
them did switch, particularly in 1973-74. Many more,
however, were reluctant to do so, perhaps because of
costs entailed in making the switch or because they
feared that their stock price would decline if they imple­
mented an accounting change which reduced reported
profits even though increasing true aftertax profits.
On balance, only a small proportion of the inventory
profits are computed on a LIFO basis and, in aggregate,
inventory profits are therefore substantial in an infla­
tionary period. For example, inventory profits soared
in 1973-74 and again in 1979 when inflation acceler­
ated (Chart 4). As a consequence of this link between
inventory profits and inflation, the tax burden associ­
ated with inventories increases in real terms when
inflation accelerates.

Depreciation allowances
Corporations are perm itted to deduct allowances fo r
depreciation of th e ir fixed capital— structures and
equipment— in com puting th eir taxable income. These
allowances are based upon the “ service life ” of the
capital good, as specified by the Internal Revenue
Service (IRS), and the o rigin al cost of the capital
good. The service lives set out by the IRS are gen­
erally shorter than the useful service lives of capital
goods. Thus, capital goods can be depreciated faster
than they wear out. When prices are rising, however,
the depreciation allowances that are permitted, based
upon original cost, w ill understate the true cost of
replacing capital goods. And the more rapidly the
price level is projected to increase, the smaller is the
anticipated present value of the depreciation allow ­
ances on a new capital good. For example, when the
inflation rate is 8 percent, a corporation is permitted
to deduct only 53 percent of the “ true” depreciation
on a thirty-year structure (Table 1).
Debt
While the Federal code taxes nominal capital gains,
which may not represent an increase in the general
purchasing power of the asset, some im plicit real

Glossary
Cash flow

is de fin ed as profits b e fo re ta xes plus c a p ita l

co nsu m p tio n a llo w a n c e s plus net in terest paid.
A

neutral tax

(in

an

in flatio n a ry

sense)

co lle c ts the

sa m e m onies, in real te rm s, fro m a given am ou nt of
real in co m e re g a rd le s s o f th e p ric e level.

Reported profits

(a fte r ta x e s ) are c o rp o ra te ta x a b le in­
co m e less c o rp o ra te ta x lia b ility.

Adjusted profits

a re re p o rte d profits m inus (a) inventory

profits and (b) a co rre c tio n fa c to r to put d e p re c ia tio n
on a re p la c e m e n t-c o s t basis.

True profits

are ad ju s ted profits plus th e redu ctio n of

th e real v a lu e of net o u tstand ing fin a n c ia l d ebt du e to
inflation.

True profitability

is th e ratio of tru e profits to ca p ita l,

va lu ed at re p la c e m e n t cost, less th e m a rk e t va lu e of
net debt.
The
ratio

rate of return on total capital
of to tal

a d ju s te d

c a p ita l

is c a lc u la te d as the

in com e— in terest

plus

a fte rta x profits, a d ju s te d to e lim in a te in ven tory profits
and to re fle c t d e p re c ia tio n on a re p la c e m e n t-c o s t basis
— to th e re p la c e m e n t co st of ca p ita l.

3 There is no easy way to calculate true inventory profits.




FRBNY Q uarterly R eview/W inter 1980-81

5

capital gains are not taxed. Consider, fo r example,
the real value of a corporation’s financial debt. When­
ever the price level increases unexpectedly, the real
value of the corporation’s outstanding debt declines
and the shareholders’ real wealth increases. Yet there
is no tax on this real gain. (Unexpected inflation would
cause some wealth shift toward debtors even if part of
it were taxed.)
Second, a change in the anticipated rate of infla­
tion that affects nominal rates of interest may also
benefit shareholders in a firm which has net debt
outstanding.4 Suppose, fo r example, that the ex­
pected rate of inflation rose by 1 percentage point.
To earn (or pay) the same real rate of interest, the
aftertax nom inal yield would have to rise by 1 percent­
age point in order to offset the inflation increase. A
cred itor in a 25 percent marginal tax bracket would re­
quire an interest rate increase of 1 y3 percentage points
to net 1 percent more after taxes [(1 - .25) (1 1/3) = 1].
The corporation in a 46 percent tax bracket, in con­
trast, would require a 1.85 percentage point increase in
the nominal bond rate to pay 1 percentage point more
after taxes [(1 - .46) (1.85) = 1]. Any sm aller increase
in the nominal rate of interest would improve its real
income. Therefore, if the interest rate increased by
1 V3 percentage points, just enough to maintain the
real aftertax earnings of the recipient of interest, the
corporation’s real aftertax cost would decline.

Chart 3

Growth Rate of GNP Price D eflator
From four quarters earlier
Percent
1

1953 55

60

65

70

75

4 There are two parts to this argument. The first concerns the tax
treatm ent of interest and the second the difference between the
tax rates of the corporation that pays interest and the individual who
receives it.
In general, the real cost of borrowing after taxes and inflation is:
r — p — T, where r is the nominal interest rate, T is the reduction
of taxes permitted because of the interest payment, and p is the
expected annual percentage decline in the real value of the principal
that is owed. A tax w hich is neutral with respect to the rate of in­
flation would allow a deduction of the real interest cost (r — p) per
do lla r of debt. The aftertax cost would therefore be (I — tc) (r — p),
where tc is the corporate tax rate on marginal income. One way of
looking at this neutral tax system is that it allows all interest to be
deducted but counts the reduction of the real value of the debt as
taxable corporate income. (That is, the aftertax real cost could be
written as: r — rtc — p + tcp, w hich is identical to the neutral tax
form ula shown a few lines above.) In the United States tax system,
however, nominal interest payments, rather than real interest
payments are tax deductible. The aftertax real cost of a d o lla r of
debt to the corporation is therefore: (I — tc) r — p. From the
view point of the interest recipient, a neutral tax system would apply
the marginal tax rate to the real interest earnings. The recipient,
under a neutral tax, would therefore be left with (I — tp) (r — p)
after taxes and inflation, where tp is the personal tax rate on
marginal income. But, under the United States Federal tax code,
nominal interest is fully taxed, so that after taxes and inflation
the earnings per do lla r of principal are: (I — tp) r — p. If the
inflation rate w ent up by 1 percentage point, the interest recipient
would be at least as well off providing the nominal rate of interest
increased by more than I / ( I — tp) w hile the corporation would be
at least as well off providing the interest rate increased by less than

I / O — t c).

Digitized 6for FRASER
FRBNY Quarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81


Source: GNP price deflator from United States
Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

To summarize, inflation influences the aftertax real
income of stockholders, reducing it through the gener­
ation of taxable nominal capital gains and nominal
inventory profits, as well as through the reduction of
the real value of depreciation allowances, and increas­
ing it through the tax treatm ent of debt and debt ser­
vicing.
Can we say on balance how large an effect inflation
has had on the value of stockownership? First, let
us define precisely what we mean by “ infla tion ” . For
purposes of computing the impacts on real stock
values, three different cases must be distinguished:
• the occurrence of inflation that was expected,
• the occurrence of more inflation than was ex­
pected, and
• an increase in the rate of inflation expected to
prevail in the future.

Table 1

The Present Value of Statutory Depreciation
Allowances Relative to the Present Value of
Price-Level-Adjusted Depreciation Allowances
In percent

Ten-year equipment*
Sum-of- Straightyears d ig its
line

Inflation
rate

Thirty-year
structure*
S traightline

0

102

108

111

2

95

100

88

88

93

73

83

87

61

77

82

53

4
v *

r e >,

6
8

...

......................

Statutory lifetim es.
Statutory depreciation allowances are based on the sum -ofyears d ig its form ula for equipm ent and the 150 percent
de clining-balance form ula for structures. (For structures, a
switch is made to the straight-line form ula in the eleventh
year, so that the present value of statutory allowances is as
large as possible.) The statutory allow ances for both eq u ip ­
ment and structures use the stated lifetimes. The alternative
sum -of-years digits and stra ight-lin e allow ances for eq uip­
ment and the straight-line allowances for structures are based
on price-level-adjusted depreciation form ulas extending over
lifetim es 25 percent longer than the statutory lifetimes.
The entries in the table are ratios of the present value of the
statutory allowances and their price-level-adjusted alternatives.
The real aftertax discount rate is 3 percent.
Source: Taken from Richard Kopcke, "A re Stocks a B argain?” ,
New England Econom ic Review (M a y /J u n e 1979).

Each of these events should in principle have a differ­
ent effect on stock prices. When expected inflation
occurs, the real valuation of the firm should not be
affected; any effect on anticipated real earnings should
have altered equity valuation when the anticipation
was form ulated.5
Unexpected inflation, in contrast, can alter the real
value of the firm ’s equity when it occurs since its impact
on real tax liab ility was not anticipated. For example,

5 The real value of equity equals the present discounted value of
expected future real earnings. To the extent that actual dividends
are less than the perm anent level of dividends (where permanent
dividends are defined as that constant level w hich has the same
present value as the stream of aftertax corporate p ro fits), the real
value of the firm w ill rise over time. In the case where dividends are
equal to perm anent aftertax profits, the real value of the firm should
remain constant.




this inflation would give rise to a once-and-for-all
nominal inventory profit on which corporate tax must
be paid. In addition, it would cause a loss in the real
value of the depreciation allowance on capital pur­
chased prior to the unexpected price rise. Tending to
offset these negative effects is the unexpected reduc­
tion of the real value of the firm ’s outstanding debt.
A change in the expected rate of inflation affects
real tax liabilities in ways sim ilar to those from unex­
pected inflation— through the creation of inventory
gain and the understatement of depreciation. However,
in this case, both of these effects are ongoing. (Note
that, in the case of an unexpected price rise, there is
a one-time loss on existing fixed capital only. New
equipment, purchased at the higher price level, would
have a depreciation allowance that is the same per­
centage of replacement cost as was typical prior to the
unexpected price level rise.) In addition, stockholders
can anticipate that the accrued nominal capital gain
between any two future points of time w ill be larger if
the price level is expected to rise more rapidly. Should
they sell, the realized capital gain and th eir personal
tax liability would be larger in the higher inflation case.
It is possible to obtain a rough idea of the maximum
effect of a change in the expected rate of inflation
by examining the form ula for the rate of return and
figuring how much it would be affected by inflation
w orking through each tax feature.6 For example, the
present value of depreciation allowances can be ex­
pressed as a function of the rate of inflation. How
much a change in the rate of inflation impacts the
present value of depreciation allowances can therefore
be calculated. The effect on depreciation allowances
can then be translated into the effect on taxes and into
the effect on aftertax income.
The percentage im pact on stockholder returns is
an upper lim it of the possible percentage im pact on
real stock prices. If there are other assets whose real
returns are unaffected and these assets were available
in unlim ited supply, then stock prices would have to
fall enough to produce the same real return on equity
as prevailed before the inflation increase. That is,
stock prices would have to fall as much as the real
return. Suppose, on the other hand, there were few
alternative assets. At the same time, the public wanted
to maintain the same stock of accumulated wealth
despite the lower returns. In this case, there could be
no attempted shift out of equities and the public would
simply end up accepting a lower return on stocks. In
addition, my estimates overstate the impact because:

6 These calculations assume no change in the capital intensity of
production and no change in the firm ’s d e b t/e q u ity ratio.

FRBNY Quarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81

7

(1) The investment tax credit, which has been
greatly increased since its inception, is not
figured into my calculations. This would offset
part of the negative effects on stock values.
(2) Taxes have been reduced on average partly
in response to inflation-caused rises in reve­
nues. Therefore, figuring the impact while
holding the tax structure constant w ill over­
state the net effect.
(3) There has been a shift away from straightline depreciation to accelerated depreciation,
a reduction of perm issible service lives for
the calculation of depreciation deductions,
and a shift from FIFO and LIFO. All these
changes tend to reduce the impact of infla­
tion on stock values.
The results of the calculations for a change in the
expected rate of inflation are displayed in Table 2,
first column. My estimates show that the prescribed
rules for depreciation allowances are the tax element
with the largest impact. Indeed, a 4 percentage point
rise in the expected rate of inflation could lower stock
values by 11 percent through this one tax feature. The
taxation £of inventory profits and the taxation of capital
gains at the individual level each account for about a
5 percent fall. W orking in the opposite direction, the
real interest rate effect could raise the return by about
5 percent, offsetting about one quarter of the negative
effects of the other three tax features.
The effects of a once-and-for-all bout of unexpected
inflation are shown in Table 2, last column. Because

unexpected inflation is not reflected in the interest rate,
the gain to the firm from the reduction of the real
value of outstanding debt is not offset by higher interest
payments on that old debt. (In the case of a change in
inflationary expectations, the interest rates would be
higher, lim iting the gain to the firm.) This large posi­
tive benefit from inflation washes out almost all nega­
tive effects of inflation on inventory profits and the
understatement of depreciation allowances.
Altogether, a 4 percentage point increase in the
expected rate of inflation could lower real stock prices
by as much as 17 percent. The expected rate of infla­
tion has probably risen by 6 percent over the past
decade. According to my calculations, the increase in
the expected rate of inflation coupled with our tax
system could have caused a 25 percent decline in real
stock prices. Therefore, of the 50 percent decline in
real stock prices in the past decade or so, the tax
structure could account fo r as much as half. Although
this suggests that the tax structure may have had a
significant effect on stock values, clearly it is not a
full explanation. Indeed, at least half of the decline in
stock values remains to be explained by other factors.
Kopcke and Feldstein, Green, and Sheshinski (FGS)
also evaluated the impact of inflation on stockholders’
returns.7 Kopcke calculated the effect of the same
four tax elements that I examined, obtaining estimates

7 Richard Kopcke, “ Are Stocks a B argain?” , New England Econom ic
Review (M a y/Ju n e 1979); M artin Feldstein, Jerry Green, and Eytan
Sheshinski, “ Inflation and Taxes in a Growing Economy w ith Debt and
Equity Finance” , Journal of P olitical Economy (A pril 1978), Part 2.

Table 2

Inflation’s Effect via the Tax System

Com ponent of tax system

Percentage change in equity value
due to a 4 percentage point rise
in the expected inflation rate*

Percentage change in equity value
due to an unexpected once-andfor-all rise in the price level
of 4 percent

Tax on inventory profits ...........................................................

-

5.4

-0 .6

Tax on understated depreciation allowances ....................

-1 0 .9

-0 .9

Effect on nominal debt and debt s e r v ic in g ........................

4 .8 f
5.3

Capital gains tax (in personal incom e tax code) ...........

-

Total

— 16.8

..............................................................................................

* Upper lim its of the im pacts.
t Assumes that real rate of interest earned by bondholders remains constant, the corporation reaping the entire gain from the
tax treatm ent of interest payments. (R efer to discussion in the text.)
Source: M arcelle Arak, “ Can the Performance of the Stock Market Be Explained by Inflation C oupled with Our Tax System ?",
Federal Reserve Bank of New York Research Paper Number 7820.

Digitized8for FRBNY
FRASER Quarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81


1.1
0
-0 .4

about 50 percent larger than mine. In a different ap­
proach, FGS compared two situations with different
rates of inflation. According to their model, a 6 per­
cent inflation differential leads to a 21 percent differ­
ential in the rate of return on equity, a bit less than my
calculations indicate. All in all, the different method­
ologies indicate that the tax system could be an im­
portant factor in the perform ance of the stock market
but it cannot explain the entire decline in real stock
prices.
Criticism of the corporate taxation argument
Although taxes appear to be a plausible explanation
of at least part of the stock price decline, several re­
searchers have argued that the historical data are in­
consistent with this explanation.
One piece of evidence cited is the ratio of taxes to
before-tax cash flow (see glossary). This tax ratio
declined from the fifties to the sixties to the seventies,
whereas the tax structure hypothesis suggests an in­
crease in the ratio of taxes to capital income.8
Although the movement of the ratio of taxes to cash
flow is suggestive, it is not necessarily an accurate
measure of the tax burden on stockholders. First, it
uses all capital income rather than income earned by
stockholders. If a larger fraction of funds is raised
through debt, the relative tax burden w ill fall because
interest is deductible in com puting taxable corporate
income. Second, the ratio of taxes to corporate in­
come reflects current taxes. But a change in the ex­
pected inflation rate w ill affect anticipated future taxes
and their ratio to cash flow. The ratio of current taxes
to current cash flow could be affected very little.
Another piece of evidence cited is the rate of return
on total capital (see glossary). This rate of return
shows no trend in the postwar period as a whole,
although it was somewhat lower in the midseventies
than in the m idsixties, when it was particularly high.
In this case also, it is not accurate to interpret the
total return to capital as a measure of the return to
stockholders. From the sixties to the seventies, there
was a shift toward debt finance which has a more ad­
vantageous tax treatment. Because interest payments
create a tax deduction for the corporation while divi­
dend payments do not, the increased use of debt w ill
raise total capital income, other things being constant.
(Of course, it also raises leverage and riskiness.) For
example, a corporation which raised the proportion of
capital financed with debt by 10 percentage points
8 A ccording to Fama (1979), the decline in the tax ratio resulted from
improved depreciation allow ances— shorter service lives and acce l­
erated depreciation— and the de du c tib ility of interest payments. In
the seventies, the larger investment tax credit was important.




could raise its total return on capital by about V2
percentage point.9
Let us look more closely at the income of stock­
holders and th eir return on capital. To obtain the in­
come of stockholders, reported aftertax corporate
profits (see glossary) must be adjusted to eliminate
inventory profits and to reflect depreciation on a
replacem ent-cost basis; both of these adjustments
reduce aftertax profits. Then, to this adjusted profits
(see glossary) figure must be added the gain to stock­
holders from the reduction of the real value of their
net financial liabilities. Inflation lowers stockholders’
real debt to bondholders, banks, etc., so that the cor­
poration could issue more nominal debt w ithout raising
the future real burden of its debt; the funds from the
new bond issues could be used to increase stock­
holder dividends w ithout reducing the corporation’s

9 Let K be the capital stock, D the corpora tion’s debt, r the interest
rate, and G gross earnings after labor and depreciation costs. Total
capital incom e is aftertax corporate profits (I — t) (G — rD) plus
interest payments rD. If the fraction “ b” of capital is financed by
debt, incom e per d o lla r of capital is
(I - t) (G - rbK) + rbK
„
x G
--------------^ -------------------------- or (I - t) — + trb.
A change in “ b ” alters the return by t r ( A b ) . If " t ” is 0.46 and
r is 0.12, then A b of 0.1 produces a change in the rate of return of
0.55 percent.

FRBNY Q uarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81

9

Table 3

Views on Inflation and Stock Values
M ajor reason why
inflation harms
stock value

Author

Is the corporate tax
structure relevant?

Are other tax
elem ents im portant?

.....................................................

Taxation of equity a
partial explanation

Yes

Yes, capital gains

F a m a .....................................................

No true connection

No

No

Hendershott ........................................

Favored tax treatment
of housing

No
(E quity values
should be
helped by
inflatio n)

Yes, treatm ent of housing

Kopcke .................................................

Taxation of equity ex­
plains a large portion

Yes

Yes, capital gains

...............................

Use of a nom inal interest
rate to discount profit
streams, plus error in
calculating profits

No

No

Arak

M odigliani-Cohn

Sources: See text.

ability to maintain the same level of future real d ivi­
dends. Thus, according to standard econom ic defini­
tions of “ incom e” , such gains on outstanding liabilities
should be included in income.
Reported profits and true profits have been very
different in recent years (Chart 5). The divergence
between the measures in the fifties and early sixties
reflected prim arily the relatively long service lives
specified by the IRS. These kept depreciation allow ­
ances below true depreciation. As service lives were
liberalized, this situation changed. When inflation ac­
celerated in 1973, however, it became the predominant
influence on the relationship between profit measures.
True profits began to fall very far short of the standard
profits. For example, in the fourth quarter of 1979,
true profits were running at a $90 billion annual rate,
23 percent below reported profits.
The adjusted profits measure— used by many ana­
lysts— fell even more relative to standard profits. But
it is apparent that this measure substantially overstates
the effect of inflation on stockholder income. The
adjusted profits measure involves subtractions from
reported corporate profits fo r inventory profits and true
depreciation but does not add in the gain to stock­
holders from their reduced bond obligations.
The true profits figures can be used to calculate
the tax rate of, and rate of return to, stockholders. The
tax burden on stockholders (as measured by taxes

Digitized10
for FRASER
FRBNY Quarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81


relative to before-tax true profits) declined from the
fifties to the sixties (Chart 6). Since the 1960s, how­
ever, the tax burden on profits increased, in contrast
to the tax burden on total capital income cited above.
The rate of return to capital owned by stockholders
— the stockholder analogue to the rate of return to
total capital— was computed using true profits in the
numerator. The denom inator was the replacement cost
of capital minus the market value of (net) financial
debt, as calculated by George Von Furstenberg.10 The
decline in the stockholder returns from the high levels
of the sixties to the seventies was enormous (Chart 7),
whereas the total capital return did not decline much.
The data therefore support the view that the tax
burden on stockholders increased since the sixties.
The data also suggest that there was a very substan­
tial decline in the aftertax return to equity capital, a
decline only partly attributable to the higher effective
tax rate.
Alternative explanations of the fall in real stock prices
Economists have put forth several alternative explana­
tions of the decline in real stock prices (Table 3). One
cogent argum ent begins with the observation that our
10 George Von Furstenberg, “ Corporate Investment: Does Market
Valuation Matter in the A ggregate?” , Brookings Papers on Economic
A ctivity (1972:2).

tax system treats owner-occupied dwellings in a spe­
cial way. In an inflationary environment, homeowners
expect the value of th eir houses to appreciate; at the
same time, interest rates w ill be high, reflecting the
expectation of price rise. Homeowners can deduct
their interest payments in figuring their taxable income.
However, the services rendered by owner-occupied
dwellings, that is, the im p licit rental value, is not taxed,
and the capital gains are taxed only when a home is
sold and then only in some circum stances.11 In effect,
if an owner lives in his own house, the “ dividends” —
the current rental services— are not taxed as they
would be if provided by a third party. Also, the capi­
tal gains on owner-occupied housing are effectively
taxed less heavily than capital gains on other assets
because home-sale capital gains taxes often can be
postponed by reinvestment or com pletely avoided by
selling after age 55. When inflation accelerates, both
interest costs and expected capital gains increase and
the asymmetry in tax treatm ent becomes more valu­
able. This asymmetry in the tax treatm ent of owneroccupied housing has caused the user cost of housing
to decline substantially. For example, if a person is
in a 45 percent tax bracket, the decline has been
about 4 percentage points according to Hendershott
(1979).12
What effect would the reduction of the cost of hous­
ing have on stock prices? Lower housing costs w ill
influence people to buy rather than rent and to buy
larger a n d /o r higher quality houses. The shift of funds
toward housing and away from other investments
would tend to push down equity prices. Profits rela­
tive to stock prices would then be higher, comparable
to the attractive yield on homeownership. This argu­
ment is both logical and consistent with most of the
facts including the rapid increases in the prices of
homes. The one fact that does not quite fit is that
bond yields have increased about as much as the rate
of inflation, so that the real return on bonds has not
risen along with the return on houses and corporate
equity.
A different argument is that inflation causes people
to make mistakes in evaluating investment opportu­
nities. Modigliani and Cohn, for example, hypothe­
size that investors use a nominal interest rate in
calculations which should be done with a real interest

11 For those under age 55, gains from sale of a principal residence
w hich are reinvested in a new principal residence are not taxed at
the tim e of receipt. For those over 55, $100,000 of the capital
gain may be excluded from taxation, subject to certain conditions.
i 2 Patric H. Hendershott, “ The D ecline in Aggregate Share Values:
Inflation, Taxation, Risk and P rofita bility", Conference on the
Taxation of Capital (N ovem ber 16-18, 1979).




rate. During an inflationary period when the nominal
rate is substantially higher than the real rate, this error
means that they are discounting future earnings too
heavily and therefore undervaluating equity ownership.
Suppose, fo r example, that current dividends per share
of a particular corporation are $2, the real return on
risky investments is 7 percent, and the expected in­
flation rate is 8 percent. The nominal return to risky
investments is therefore 15 percent (= 7 + 8 ). With an
inflation rate of 8 percent, dividends w ill probably be
2(1.08) next year, 2(1.08)2 the follow ing year, etc. The
value of a share of stock is the present discounted
value of that flow of dividends. Discounting this stream
of nominal earnings by the nominal rate of interest,

Chart 5

Alternative M easures of Aftertax Corporate
Profits of Nonfinancial Corporations
Billions of dollars

Source:
Reported and adjusted profits: United States
Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.
True profits: calculated by the author as described
in the text.

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81

11

C h a rt 6

Taxation of A lternative Measures of
C orporate Profits of N onfinancial
Corporations

Chart 7

Aftertax Profitability of Corporate Capital
Rate of return

F o ur-quarter moving average
Ratio
.6 5 0 -------------------------------------------------------------------------------

S ource: Tax payments and reported profits:
United States D epartm ent of Comm erce, Bureau of
Econom ic A nalysis. True profits: calculated by the
author as described in the text.

the value of the share of stock is:
(a) 2 + 2(1.08)/1.15 + 2(1.08)7(1.15)2 +
or roughly
(b) 2 + 2/1.07 + 2 /(1 ,07)2 + .. . +
which amounts to about $30. Note that, according to
(b), the current dividend should be discounted at the
real rate of interest, not the nominal rate of interest.
(This is true for other returns and inflation rates as
well.) If the current dividends were discounted by the
nominal return of 15 percent, the stock would be
m istakenly valued at only $13!
In addition, Modigliani and Cohn hypothesize that
investors make a second mistake: they fail to include
the reduction of the real value of outstanding debt
caused by price increases as part of profits.
They test these hypotheses by analyzing the factors
that influenced share prices in the past. Specifically,
the authors estimate an equation for share prices
which includes among other items (a) the nominal
rate of interest and (b) a weighted average of past in­
flation rates that was assumed to represent expected
inflation. Since the real rate of interest can be repre­
sented as a nominal interest rate less the expected
Digitized12
for FRASER
FRBNY Q uarterly R eview/W inter 1980-81


Num erator is true p ro fits ; denom inator is capital valued
at re placem ent cost less the m arket value of net
financial debt. See te x t fo r a description o f the
ca lc u la tio n s and the data sources.

rate of inflation, (b) ought to get a coefficient of oppo­
site sign to (a). As it turns out, however, both the inter­
est rate and the inflation rate variable get negative
coefficients! The negative coefficient on the price vari­
able is not significantly different from zero in a statisti­
cal sense. However, even zero is much too low a
coefficient.13
The authors interpret this result as evidence that
investors are making two valuation errors— misusing a
nominal rate as a real rate and failing to include the
fall in the real value of outstanding debt as part of
equity earnings.
How strong is their argument? Hendershott pointed
out that it is difficult to reconcile such a misvaluation
with the fact that the nominal bond rates have risen
about one for one with the increase in inflation. By
his model, investor shifts from stocks into bonds cause
the real aftertax returns, adjusted for risk, to be equal.
Therefore, if investors did not properly account for
inflation, bond returns would have stayed low, in tan­
dem with real returns on stocks.
13 Expected inflation should have an equal and opposite sign from
the nominal rate of interest— to convert the nominal rate to a real
rate— plus a coefficient reflecting the anticipated future inflationproduced capital gains on the outstanding debt.

Moreover, there are other ways to explain the empiri­
cal results obtained by Modigliani and Cohn. For ex­
ample, a weighted average of past inflation rates could
be a poor estimate of the inflation rate expected to
prevail over the long term. On the other hand, because
nominal bond rates incorporate price expectations,
changes in bond rates could be a good proxy for
changes in expected inflation. Indeed, if variations in
the real rate of interest tend to be small, then most
of the changes in the bond yield will reflect changes
in price expectations. In this case, the bond rate would
be proxying for expected inflation and its coefficient
would represent the effect of expected inflation on
equity values rather than the effect of real interest
rates on equity values. By this interpretation, the co­
efficient of -0 .0 5 9 obtained in one of their regres­
sions indicates that each 1 percentage point increase
in the expected rate of inflation would reduce stock
values by 5.9 percent; a 6 percentage point increase
in the rate of inflation would therefore reduce real
stock prices by about 35 percent. Interestingly enough,
this is within the range of the Arak-Kopcke stock price
impact calculated from the tax structure.
While many explanations of stock price behavior
are related to inflation in some way, others are not.
For example, some economists argue that equity
prices have declined for the simple reason that cor­
porate profitability before taxes has dropped sharply.
Charts 6 and 7 lend support to this view; they show
that stockholders’ (aftertax) return dropped substan­
tially while the tax rate on stockholders increased only
moderately. Another factor may be that the growth
prospects during the 1960s were much brighter than
during the 1970s. Since stock values are based upon
expected dividend growth, the outlook could well be
an important element.
Conclusions and implications
There is no single factor that can plausibly explain
the substantial fall in real stock values over the past
ten to fifteen years. However, the tax system— the
corporate and capital gains tax as well as the tax treat­
ment of housing— probably has played a significant
role.
Besides lowering real stock values, the current tax
system may impair productivity by lowering desired
capital investment and encouraging shorter lived
capital than is optimal from an economy-wide vantage




point. Moreover, the tax system gives firms a large
incentive to leverage themselves. Taken together, there
would be important gains from reforming the corporate
tax system to get rid of the features which cause non­
neutrality with respect to inflation.
Of the features considered above, the depreciationallowance rules are the single most important in terms
of the impact on real stock values. Moreover, the de­
preciation allowances probably were important in in­
ducing business to build less durable capital than is
desirable from society’s viewpoint.14 The ideal solution
is to base allowances on replacement cost, rather
than on original cost, while using write-off schemes
that approximate the true depreciation of each piece of
capital. Ad hoc schemes to improve depreciation allow­
ances, such as shortening the permissible service lives
or widening the scope for use of accelerated deprecia­
tion, work imperfectly. Only at one particular inflation
rate and with one particular technological mix will they
exactly offset the shortfall in the true depreciation
generated by the use of original cost. If the inflation
rate were to fall, such schemes would lead to higher
profits and longer lived equipment than is economi­
cally efficient. According to the Bureau of Economic
Analysis, Department of Commerce, the understate­
ment of depreciation was about $17 billion in 1979.
If this were added to the depreciation write-offs cur­
rently allowed, it would have cost the United States
Treasury less than $8 billion in 1979, far less than some
of the other schemes that have been proposed to im­
prove depreciation write-offs.
Another issue is whether the United States wants
to retain tax provisions that allow the full deduc­
tion of nominal interest payments by both business
and homeowners, and the full taxability of interest
receipts. For the corporation, the deduction of nominal
interest payments about offsets the taxability of nominal
inventory profits. However, for the homeowner there
is no similar offset; the homeowner clearly benefits.
Although this country wants to encourage homeownership, inflation undoubtedly has widened the encour­
agement far beyond the original plan. Some tax change
that would alter this situation without greatly hurting
current homeowners would be desirable.

14 Patrick Corcoran, “ Inflation, Taxes, and the Composition of Business
Investment”, this Q u a rte rly R e v ie w (Autumn 1979), pages 13-24.

Marcelle Arak

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81

13

Cutting the Federal Budget
Analyzing How Fast Expenditure
Growth Can Be Reduced
Federal outlays in fiscal year 1981 threaten to exceed
$660 billion, well above the second budget resolution
ceiling of $632.4 billion and the goal of $635 billion
contained in the Stockman-Kemp memorandum to the
then President-elect Reagan on “Avoiding a GOP Eco­
nomic Dunkirk”.1 Federal spending as a percentage
of gross national product (GNP) could exceed the
postwar high of 23.1 percent, and the unified budget
deficit could be $60 billion or greater. When combined
with an off-budget deficit of about $23 billion, this
would result in new Treasury marketable financing of
over $80 billion. At this point, it is highly unlikely that
projected unified budget outlays for 1981 can be re­
duced. Various changes, some of which are cosmetic2
and do not affect the size of Government, may be
proposed. However, a major push during the next few
months to cut spending for 1981 could very well end
up a wasted effort and at the same time use up “po­
litical capital” necessary for meaningful cuts in 1982
and 1983. The outlook for Federal outlays in 1982 and
1983 under current policies is for continued high rates
James R. Capra, Senior Economist in charge of the Fiscal Analysis
Staff, Monetary Research Department, is the author of this article.
He was formerly the Chief of Budget Projections for the Congressional
Budget Office. The views expressed are those of the author and do
not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York
or the Congressional Budget Office.
1 This memorandum was written by David Stockman and Jack Kemp
in late November 1980. More recent policy statements indicate that the
administration may ultimately set a target of $645-650 billion for 1981
Federal outlays.
2 Among the cosmetic changes are asset sales from the Farmers
Home Administration to the Federal Financing Bank (F FB )— an
off-budget agency— and changes in the timing of offshore oil sales.

Digitized14
for FRASER
FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81


of spending. With the start of fiscal year 1982 only
eight months away, a legislative calendar devoted
primarily to the control of Federal spending could
reduce projected outlays for fiscal year 1982 by about
$10-15 billion. A significantly larger reduction would
take an extraordinary effort on the part of the new
administration and a degree of cooperation by the
Congress that is rarely seen. Realistically, however,
the earliest target date for a full offset (through spend­
ing cuts) to the $30-35 billion per year revenue loss
from a 1981 individual income tax cut probably would
be fiscal year 1983.
The 1981 problem
There appears to be a consensus that Federal spend­
ing programs ought to be cut, or at least the rate of
growth reduced. However, there is a misconception
that this can be done rapidly— in 1981, for example.
The two largest components of spending are national
defense and benefit payments for individuals (Table 1).
Defense clearly will not be reduced in the near future;
rather there appears to be widespread support for in­
creases. Almost all benefit payments programs are en­
titlements, which means that eligible beneficiaries have
a legal claim on the Federal Government. Changes
require substantive legislation that would take months
to formulate, negotiate, and implement. For example,
the recently enacted budget reconciliation bill— an
omnibus bill that changed current law for many pro­
grams— was formulated in the spring of 1980, negoti­
ated in part in the first budget resolution conference
in the early summer and in part by conferences bn
various components of the bill during the remainder

of the summer and in the fall. Some of the new pro­
visions of current law that are the result of this bill will
take months to implement, making the total time from

Estimated Federal Outlays for Fiscal Year 1981

■ .' ■

Benefit payments to in d iv id u a ls .....................................

331.4

Other grants to state and local go vernm ents! ..............

58.3

Net interest ...........................................................................

67.4

Other Federal operations ................................................

56.2

T o t a l........................................................................................

660.0

---- -------------------------------------------- ----- -----------* Includes Department of Defense m ilitary and defense-related
activities of the Department of'E nergy but not m ilitary retired
pay which is included under benefit payments.
t Includes those grants that are not for benefit payments

Table 2

Possible Proposals for 1981 Outlay Cuts and
Savings that Might be Claimed
In billions of dollars
Proposal

Amount

Type of cut

-----------------------------------------------------------Small Business Adm inistration
disaster lo a n s .....................................

1.2

(O n e tim e )

Medicare and m e d ic a id ....................

1.0

(P erm ane nt)*

Strategic petroleum re s e rv e .............

0.8

(C o s m e tic )t

Solvent refined coal dem onstration
plants I and I I .....................................

0.2

(Perm anent)

Public service e m p lo y m e n t.............

0.4

(P erm anent)

...............

0.8

(Perm anent)

Trade adjustm ent a s s is ta n c e ...........

0.7

(Perm anent)

Economic support fund ....................

0.4

(D elay)

Unem ploym ent insurance

social security in c re a s e .................... ...... 4.5

(O ne tim e)

Asset sales

................................................ 1.5

(C osm etic)

Outer continental shelf le a s e s ___ ___ 1.8

(C osm etic)

Travel, pay, and c o n s u ltin g ............. ...... 1.7

(C osm etic)

Tea,

.....................................................

m o ---------------------------------

.
* For the permanent items the savings to 1982 and 1983 outlays
would be different from the 1981 savings.
t This reduction is listed as cosm etic since the change probably
would not reduce the long-run costs to the Federal Government
and may ultim ately result in an increase.




proposal to implem entation almost a year.3
After defense and benefit programs, two sm aller
categories— grants and other Federal operations— re­
main for consideration. For grants, outlays during the
remainder of fiscal year 1981 largely represent pay­
ments fo r obligations that have already been incurred
or contracts already signed. M ajor programs in this
category include aid for elementary and secondary
education, grants for the construction of wastewater
treatm ent plants, and the Federal-aid highways pro­
gram. For the education programs, obligations for the
1981 school year were made in the summer of 1980.
For the construction programs, 1981 outlays prim arily
represent the execution of contracts signed in 1980
and prior years. Breaking these contracts would be
very difficult and very expensive. The final category—
other Federal operations— is comprised of many differ­
ent Federal programs, ranging from the strategic pe­
troleum reserve to farm price supports and pay fo r the
nondefense Federal work force. For the m ajor pro­
grams, the problems with reducing 1981 outlays are
sim ilar to those for national defense, benefit payments,
and grants. The strategic petroleum reserve is a high
p riority item. The new adm inistration and a clear Con­
gressional m ajority favor increases rather than a scalingdown of the program. The farm price supports program
is an entitlem ent and changes probably w ill not be
forthcom ing until a new farm bill is considered this
spring. Even m ajor changes in the bill w ill probably
not significantly affect 1981 outlays. Federal pay, on
the other hand, could be reduced by attrition or even
by layoffs. However, even a 10 percent reduction of
Federal civilian agency employment would save less
than $1 billion in fiscal year 1981.
The bleak prospects for changes that would reduce
1981 outlays need to be emphasized. If the prim ary
focus of the upcoming debate over control of spending
becomes fiscal year 1981, the prospects for meaningful
reductions in 1982 and 1983 may be jeopardized, with
near-term savings being achieved through delays or
even exchanged for subsequent program expansions.
The recently enacted reconciliation bill provides a
good example of the potential problems, with over­
emphasis on near-term savings. In the House-passed
bill, 1981 savings in medicare and m edicaid were ex­
changed for program expansions in 1982-85. Another
example is child nutrition where an immediate one­
tim e cut was finally agreed to in exchange for no re­
ductions in 1982-85. Some reductions of 1981 outlays
3 Another example of problem s with making cuts in benefit payments
quickly is the food stamp program. In each of the past two years
reforms have been enacted, but it now appears that in both cases
the changes will take more than one-year longer to im plem ent than
anticipated at the tim e of passage.

FRBNY Quarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81

15

are, of course, not impossible, but large cuts are highly
unlikely.
Nevertheless, the new administration is likely to pro­
pose budget cuts for 1981. The following list represents
some of the major components that have been dis­
cussed recently, together with the savings in the fiscal
year ending September 1981 which might be claimed
for them. The savings listed are highly dependent on
early enactment.
• Change the newly enacted Small Business Ad­
ministration (SBA) authorization to make farm­
ers who were victims of the 1980 springsummer drought ineligible for SBA disaster
loans. This change could be assumed to result
in a one-time saving of $1.2 billion in 1981.
(The new authorization made victims of future
droughts ineligible for SBA loans.)
• Make miscellaneous changes in the laws gov­
erning medicare and medicaid, including caps
on certain fees for services. By assuming al­
most immediate enactment, about $1 billion in
permanent savings could be claimed.
• Fund the strategic petroleum reserve by having
the Federal Government sell shares in the
stored oil or by issuing bonds to defray the
cost of oil purchases. If early enactment of
this complex proposal were assumed, an in­
crease of $0.8 billion in offsetting receipts and
a decrease in net Federal outlays would be
claimed. The future-year effects are unclear,
depending on whether the oil reserve is used
and on the assumed rate of return to share­
holders or bondholders. In all likelihood, the
proposal would increase the long-term costs
to the Federal Government.
• Delay, or possibly terminate, construction of
the two solvent refined coal demonstration
plants (SRC I and II) at a savings of $0.2 billion.
• Terminate all funding for countercyclical public
service employment, including a rescission of
funds already appropriated. Savings of $0.4-0.6
billion in fiscal year 1981 might be claimed, al­
though action would have to take place quickly.
A significant portion of 1981 funds have already
been obligated. As discussed later, this cut
would have a larger effect on projected out­
lays for 1982 and 1983.
• Make miscellaneous changes in the unemploy­
ment insurance laws, which if enacted quickly
would save $0.8 billion. Trade adjustment as­
sistance changes, saving about $0.7 billion,
also might be proposed.
• Change the method of disbursement of credits

Digitized for
16 FRASER
FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81


•

•

•

•

to Israel through the Economic Support Fund
back to the pre-1979 approach. By assuming
early enactment of this change, the new ad­
ministration could claim the delay of $0.4 bil­
lion in outlays until 1982.
Postpone the July 1, 1981 social security in­
crease until October 1, 1981. This proposal,
which would affect recipients of social security,
railroad retirement, supplemental security in­
come, and veterans’ pensions, would be for a
one-time postponement. Savings of $4.5 billion
in 1981 could be claimed, but there would be
no lasting effect on Government spending
levels.4
Increase asset sales of Federally held mort­
gages and insurance by the Farmers Home Ad­
ministration to the FFB. These sales would
shift about $1-2 billion in outlays off-budget.
The change would be cosmetic since the FFB
purchase would then become part of the offbudget deficit and would still be financed
through the issuance of Treasury debt.
Move a scheduled sale of outer continental
shelf leases from September to August 1981
so that all the receipts would offset outlays in
1981 rather than in 1982. This could reduce the
1981 budget totals by $1.5-2.0 billion but would
increase the 1982 totals unless the 1982 sched­
ule is revised.
Finally, the new administration may propose
miscellaneous rescissions of already enacted
appropriations for travel, pay, and consulting
services of about $1-2 billion. The size of the
cut may be somewhat dependent on how much
is needed to reach the announced goal for total
outlay reductions. Outlay savings in 1981 would
be difficult to achieve because, even if the
Congress enacted a rescission of budget au­
thority, agencies would probably absorb the
cut in slow spending programs rather than in
travel and pay where outlays flow quickly from
budget authority. Thus, the reduction would be
to 1982 outlays.

These possible proposals which total as much as $15
billion are summarized in Table 2.
Each of the proposals for 1981 reductions would
require a major effort on the part of the new adminis­
tration. Even proposed delays and one-time reductions
could encounter stiff resistance that might either ulti4 In theory, this proposal would lead to savings of about $400-600
million in interest on the public debt in 1982 and later years if the
temporary reduction of 1981 outlays were not used to fund a larger
tax cut or a larger defense program.

mately defeat the proposed changes or at least could
stall enactment until the savings would be significantly
reduced. In the long run, the Congress and the Pres­
ident can control virtually every dollar spent by the
Federal Government by making changes in the numer­
ous laws governing Federal expenditures. However,
forging a consensus on just which laws ought to be
changed— and how they ought to be changed— takes
time. Also, after that consensus is reached and laws
are changed, implementation is anything but im­
mediate.
Only eight months will remain in fiscal year 1981
after the new administration takes office and probably
only four months will remain by the time a third budget
resolution for 1981 is passed by the Congress. The
most realistic (and possibly the best) strategy may be
to forget about large budget cuts for fiscal year 1981
and to work out proposals carefully that will affect
1982 and more importantly 1983. Unfortunately, it is
already getting late to do as much as might be desired
about 1982. As will be shown later, more than a 2 per­
cent reduction of projected outlays for 1982 as a result
of Congressional action over the next eight months
is hard to visualize. A reduction of even that size
will not be possible if the 97th Congress and the ad­
ministration spend the next several months on quickfix options designed to reduce the 1981 budget totals.
Spending reductions for 1982 and 1983
At present, with no new program initiatives (except for
defense), Federal outlays for 1982 and 1983 may ba
projected at $760 billion and $850 billion, respectively.
The projection assumes 5 percent real growth of de­
fense, 2 percent real growth of benefit payments, pri­
marily due to demographic and case-load changes, and
no real growth of grants and other Federal operations.
The estimates in Table 3 provide a useful baseline
from which spending cuts can be considered.
In evaluating potential budget reductions, the follow­
ing factors are important. All cuts require joint action
by the administration and the Congress. With the pass­
age of the Congressional Budget Act, the President
can no longer impound funds. The proposals that
follow have been restricted to those that are con­
sidered to be politically and technically feasible in the
sense that they have a reasonable chance of being
proposed, adopted, and implemented in time to
achieve the savings listed for 1982 and 1983. Finally,
although outlay savings proposals for national defense
exist, they are not likely to result in a smaller spending
total. The entire national defense discussion is now
being framed in terms of real growth, with 5 percent
real growth being the minimum figure under active
consideration. Cuts in low priority or unnecessary de­




fense expenditures are likely to be offset by increases
in order to sustain the real growth target that emerges
from the debate over the next few months.
The remainder of this article will review in some
detail the ways in which projected Federal spend­
ing for fiscal years 1982 and 1983 could be cut.
The reductions of benefit payments, grants, and other
Federal operations that will be discussed and are sum­
marized in Table 4 cut across many different Federal
programs and represent an ambitious agenda for the
first session of the 97th Congress that would require
numerous changes in current law. The options do not
include all possible budget-cutting alternatives that have
been or will be proposed, but in general they are the
ones that have been most prominently discussed during
the past year. Some have been included in President
Carter’s budget proposal. Additional budget-reduction
alternatives may be put forward, and some that are
not considered in this article could ultimately be
enacted. However, since each change requires sepa­
rate consideration and negotiation, it is doubtful that
a program significantly larger than the one outlined
in this article could be formulated, negotiated, and
implemented within the next eight months.5
Benefit payments fo r individuals
The largest benefit payments program is social security
with projected outlays in fiscal year 1982 of over $160
billion. The upcoming July 1981 benefit-level increase,
estimated at over 12 percent, will raise the annualized
cost of social security by over $17 billion. Proposals
to make major changes in social security indexing
stand little chance of being enacted and probably
will not even be proposed since they affect over 35
million recipients, most of whom are eligible voters.
As a general rule, to stand any significant chance of
passage, proposed cuts in social security should be
designed to affect either subsets of existing recipients
or future recipients.6 For example, the following cuts
could be proposed (Table 5).
• Under current law, dependent benefits are paid
to unmarried students between the ages of 18
and 21. This benefit, which is not based upon
need and costs about $2 billion annually, could

5 A longer list of budget-reduction options can be found in R e d u c in g th e
F e d e ra l B u d g e t: S tra te g ie s a n d E x a m p le s (Congressional Budget
Office, February 1980). The Congressional Budget Office plans to
update this report in March 1981.
‘ This assumption may turn out to be wrong. However, the chances
of large near-term social security reductions that affect all current
beneficiaries appear to be so remote that it would be unproductive to
formulate a budget policy that depends to a significant degree on
their enactment.

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81

17

Table 3

Table 5

Projected Outlays Assuming 5 Percent Real
Growth for Defense and No New Nondefense
Initiatives*

Social Security Savings
By fiscal year; in m illions of dollars
Item

By fiscal year; in billions of dollars
Spending category

1982

1983
203

National defense ...............................
Benefit p a y m e n ts ................................. ...............

375

418

Other g r a n ts .......................................... ...............

64

69

.......................................... ...............

86

93

Other Federal operations .................. ...............

63

67

....................................................... ...............

760

850

Net interest

Total

1982

1983

Phase out student b e n e fits .............................

200

Elim inate minim um b e n e fit.............................

65

135

Elim inate lump sum death b e n e fit...............

165

190

Phase out survivor benefits for high
school children, age 16, 17, and 18 ...........

300

2,000

Total

730

3,125

....................................................................

800

* Also assumed is $16 billio n in off-budget spending
for 1982 and 1983.

Table 4

Reductions of Federal Spending for Fiscal Year 1982 and the Effects on 1983
By fiscal year
1982
Billions of dollars

Spending category

1982
Percent*

1983
Billions of dollars

1983
Percent
2.0

Benefit p a y m e n ts .................. .........................................................

— 5.9

1.6

— 8.5

Other g r a n t s ........................... .........................................................

-

3.0

4.6

-

4.4

6.3

Other Federal operations .. ........... .............................................

— 2.9

4.6

-

6.5

9.7

........................................ .........................................................

-1 1 ,8

1.6

— 19.4

2.3

Total

For each spending category, the percentage represents the cut as a fraction of projected spending for the category. For the total,
the percentage represents the sum of the reductions expressed as a fraction of projected total Federal outlays.

Table 6
Table 7

Unemployment Compensation Savings

Income Support Savings

By fiscal year; in m illions of dollars

By fiscal year; in m illions of dollars
Item

1982

1983
Item

Elim inate the national trigger for
extended benefits ............................................

1,000

1,000

Reduce trade adjustm ent assistance
b e n e fits ................................................................

1,400

300

Total

2,400

1,300

....................................................................

FRBNY Q uarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81
Digitized 18
for FRASER


1982

1983
500

Monthly incom e r e p o rtin g ...............................

400

Child nutrition ...................................................

200

200

Food stamps .......................... ..........................

700

1,000

1,300

1,700

Total

.......................................... ..........................

be phased out starting in 1982 by stipulating
that payments would not be made to students
who reach their eighteenth birthday after
October 1, 1981.
• A minimum social security benefit of $122 is
currently provided to insured workers who re­
tire at age 65, regardless of the level of their
past earnings. Many of those who receive the
benefit have earned pensions under other pro­
grams, typically civil service retirement. Elimi­
nation of this benefit and coverage of those
actually in need through supplemental security
income (SSI) would save about $100 million
per year.
• All surviving families receive a lump sum death
benefit of $255. The benefit is out of date, not
having increased significantly since 1954. Cov­
erage of those families in need could be pro­
vided through SSI.
• Currently, families with children under 18 are
entitled to survivor benefits for each child and
for the spouse under the assumption that the
parent cannot work away from home while a
child is in his or her care. A phasing-out of
benefits for high school children age 16, 17,
and 18— where the rationale for the benefit is
probably not applicable— would save up to $2
billion by 1983.
In the area of health, there are numerous proposals
to restrict the growth of medicare and medicaid. Pro­
jected costs in 1982 for hospital insurance, supple­
mentary medical insurance, and medicaid total more
than $67 billion. Like social security, however, medi­
care and medicaid benefits are paid to millions of
recipients (more than 45 million). Proposals with a
reasonable chance of enactment would save about
$1 billion in 1982 and $1.8 billion in 1983. Mandatory
hospital cost containment might save more. However,
the new administration and the Congress may wait
another year or two to evaluate whether hospitals have
voluntarily moderated their price increases. The earliest
consideration of a new cost containment proposal
probably will be in connection with the 1983 budget.
Unemployment compensation, with an estimated
fiscal year 1982 cost of over $20 billion, is another
area where reductions might be feasible. One of the
largest cuts would be achieved by eliminating the na­
tional trigger for extended benefits (Table 6). Currently,
an extra thirteen weeks of benefits are paid to all re­
cipients when the national insured unemployment rate
exceeds 4.5 percent even though a state’s rate may be
below 4.5 percent. This proposal was included in the
Senate’s version of the reconciliation bill but was re­




moved in the House-Senate conference agreement on
the bill. Other reductions of unemployment benefits
could be achieved by implementing the Government
Accounting Office recommendations that trade adjust­
ment assistance benefits be paid only to those who
have exhausted their unemployment insurance benefits
and be payable at the same level as unemployment in­
surance benefits. The rationale for this reduction is that
under current law it is possible for trade adjustment
assistance recipients to receive benefits (when com­
bined with other income transfer payments) which
exceed their take home pay prior to becoming unem­
ployed. Clearly, this is likely to create a disincsntive
for trade adjustment assistance recipients to start
looking for work.
Miscellaneous income support or welfare programs
such as aid to families with dependent children ($9
billion), food stamps ($12 billion), supplemental secu­
rity income ($8 billion), and child nutrition ($4 billion)
are potential targets for reductions (Table 7). A nation­
wide monthly income-reporting system, together with
one-month retrospective accounting (that is, basing
each month’s benefits on the previous month’s income),
would eliminate some of the current welfare abuses.
Other reductions include making permanent the change
from a semiannual to an annual cost-of-living adjust­
ment for child nutrition and certain miscellaneous food
stamp cuts.
Finally, veterans programs are a potential target for
reductions, although it has been extremely difficult to
obtain passage of legislation that would cut the $20 bil­
lion of benefits and administrative expenses. The larg­
est cut that has been discussed recently would require
private insurance companies to reimburse the Veter­
ans Administration for insured persons treated in vet­
erans hospitals, so-called “third party reimbursement”
(Table 8). The House and Senate Veterans Committees
have been very reluctant, however, to report this leg­
islation. Other changes for veterans, such as reducing
burial benefits by the amount of the other Federal
burial benefits received by veterans, would have a
smaller effect on outlays.
Grants to state and loca l governments
Over the last thirty years the largest growth of Federal
spending, on a percentage basis, has occurred in
grants to state and local governments for other than
benefit payments. The following are some possible cuts
(Table 9).
• Federal spending on highways is growing very
rapidly. It is not clear that this growth is desir­
able in light of the need to cut back on energy
consumption. Reimposition of a tight obligation

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81

19

Table 8

Veterans Savings
By fiscal year; in m illions of dollars
Item

1982

1983

Third party re im b u rs e m e n t......................

350

400

Veterans' com pensation, pensions,
and burial benefits ...................................

100

100

Gl b ill c h a n g e s ..........................................

60

80

510

580

Total

..............................................................

Table 9

Cuts in Grants to State and Local Governments
By fiscal year; in m illions of dollars
Grants
Highways

.....................................................

Environmental Protection Agency
low priority c o n s tru c tio n ...........................
Public service jobs

................................... . . .

1982

1983

700

1,500

50

350

1,000

1,100

Other Comprehensive Employment
and Training Act p ro g ra m s ......................

700

750

Im pact aid for school d is tr ic t s ................

250

350

D iscretionary health p ro g ra m s ...............

300

300

3,000

4,350

Item

1982

1983

Strategic petroleum reserve oil purchases . .

1,000

3,000

Term ination of solvent refined coal
dem onstration plants I and II construction .

Total

.............................................................. . . .

Table 10

Cuts in Other Federal Operations
By fiscal year; in m illions of dollars

500

1,000

C om m odity Credit C orporation
price support reductions ...............................

100

1,000

Railroad cuts in low priority ro u te s ................

300

350

Federal payment to postal s e r v ic e ...............

250

250

Wage board pay raises (nondefense) ___

60

60

R eduction of outm oded soil and water
conservation p r o je c ts ........................................

100

100

Reduction of civilian agency em ploym ent . .

440

480

Lim it nondefense travel and
tra n s p o rta tio n .....................................................

100

200

2,850

6,440

Total

....................................................................

FRBNY Q uarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81
Digitized20
for FRASER


ceiling on the Federal-aid highways program
could hold 1982 and 1983 outlays to about
$8 billion per year.
• The Environmental Protection Agency (EPA)
makes grants for the construction of waste­
water treatment plants. Because of various re­
quirements specified in the law that emphasize
“ ready to go” rather than high priority pro­
jects, approximately 25 percent of the funds
have been used fo r low priority projects. Un­
fortunately, the savings from a change to elim ­
inate these projects build slowly. Nevertheless,
the 1985 savings would be about $1 billion, out
of a projected cost of $4 billion.
• Expenditures for countercyclical public service
jobs w ill total about $1 billion in 1981. This
program has demonstrated a marked procy­
clical pattern. It probably should (and in all
likelihood will) be terminated in 1982.
• Many other Comprehensive Employment and
Training Act (CETA) programs do not appear to
be effective or duplicate private-sector pro­
grams. A 10 percent cut in the $7 billion in
projected outlays probably could be achieved
without impairing the effectiveness of the pro­
grams. The cuts could be across the board or
targeted toward specific programs like sum­
mer youth or the public service jobs program
for the structurally unemployed (Title II of
CETA).
• The impact aid program compensates school
districts for children whose parents live or work
on Federal property. Annual funding is about
$800 m illion. The purpose is to compensate
school districts partially for educating pupils
where the local tax base is reduced because
of Federal property ownership or where enroll­
ments are raised because of a Federal em­
ployer. Parts of this program clearly do not
meet the intended needs. Past adm inistrations
have unsuccessfully proposed cuts, but last year
the Congress came closer to approving re­
ductions.
• During the past year, several proposals were
made to reduce discretionary health grants
which overlap with other programs. These in­
clude drug and alcohol abuse, mental health,
family planning, and health planning. A pro­
posal submitted in 1980 by Republican mem­
bers of the House and Senate would save about
$300 m illion (or slightly over 10 percent of the
$2.5-3 billion spent on these programs).
The reductions to state and local government grants

summarized in Table 9 are for categorical grant pro­
grams, that is, grants where the Federal Government
specifies the precise purpose or use of the funding.
There appears to be little, if any, support in the Con­
gress or in the new administration for cuts in commu­
nity development block grants or in general revenue
sharing.7 In fact, most Republicans advocate the res­
toration of the $2.3 billion state share of general rev­
enue sharing in 1982. One way to offset such an in­
crease, however, might be to require states to forfeit
funds for categorical grants on a dollar-for-dollar
basis in exchange for revenue-sharing funds. This pro­
vision was written into the recently enacted general
revenue-sharing reauthorization; however, a plan for
implementing what could become a complex system of
credits and debits does not yet exist.
Other Federal operations
This category contains numerous Federal programs.
Some are not particularly effective, but few are large
when compared with defense and the major benefit
payments programs.
• Federal outlays for the purchase of oil for
the strategic petroleum reserve are projected
at about $3.5 for 1982 and $4.5 billion for
1983.8 All these outlays would not neces­
sarily be offset by the proposals for public
capitalization or debt financing of the reserve
discussed earlier. Various factors, ranging from
the marketability of the certificates of owner­
ship to the coupon rate (if any), would affect
the size of the offset. The savings for 1982
would also be affected by the timing of a
change in the law and lags associated with
implementation. For the purposes of this
analysis, savings (offsets) of $1 billion in 1982
and $3 billion in 1983 are assumed. The esti­
mates reflect gradual implementation of a
change enacted late in fiscal year 1981 or
early 1982 and a program that includes an
annual interest payment on the debt out­
standing.9

7 Over the next few months proposals may be made to cut Urban
Development Action Grants, a program to help cities revitalize their
economic bases and reclaim deteriorated neighborhoods. Reductions
of appropriations, however, will not significantly affect outlays until
after 1983.
8 This projection assumes a fill rate in excess of 100,000 barrels per
day and further increases of world oil prices.
9 It should be noted that, in the long run, this proposal may cost more
than current policies, depending on whether the oil purchases are
debt financed or equity financed and on the relationship between oil
price increases and interest rates.




• As discussed earlier, the termination of con­
struction at the two solvent refined coal demon­
stration plants (SRC I and II) might be a poten­
tial budget reduction option since the current
program has already shown the feasibility of
the technology.
• Several changes could be made in the farm
price support program administered by the
Commodity Credit Corporation (CCC). The
CCC spent about $3 billion in fiscal year 1980.
Although several aspects of the various CCC
programs could be changed so that outlays
would be reduced, the Congress will be under
considerable pressure for program expan­
sions. The disaster payments program prob­
ably can be eliminated since it largely dupli­
cates the newly enacted Federal crop insurance
program. Also, cuts in dairy price supports,
such as indexing support levels to annual
rather than semiannual changes in prices, ap­
pear to be justified.
• Federal support of railroads totals $1.9 billion,
including funds for construction and operating
subsidies. Subsidies for low priority routes
could be reduced, saving about $300 million
per year.
• The $1.2 billion annual Federal payment to the
Postal Service could be reduced. The cut need
not specify elimination of Saturday mail de­
livery, as was proposed in March 1980. The
Postal Service probably should be allowed to
decide how to absorb the cut— either by rais­
ing rates or by new efficiency initiatives.
• The current procedure for computing pay
raises for Federal blue-collar workers (wage
board employees) overstates the percentage
increase needed to maintain comparability with
the private sector. The savings from reform
would be over $500 million by 1983. However,
three fourths of the $10 billion in pay is an
expense of the Department of Defense. Most
of the cut probably would be offset by other
defense increases in order to maintain a 5 per­
cent (or greater) real growth target for defense
outlays.
• Miscellaneous soil and water conservation
projects that have outlived their usefulness and
actually are in direct opposition to wildlife con­
servation projects could be reduced. The bud­
get for the Soil and Water Conservation Service
is about $400 million.
• The Army Corps of Engineers currently spends
about $1 billion per year for construction and
operating costs on the nation’s network of

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81

21

inland waterways and to help maintain deepdraft ports. An increase in the per gallon fuel
tax paid by inland waterway users could de­
fray some of these expenses. (The receipts are
treated as offsets to Federal outlays.) An in­
crease of over 5 cents per gallon would be
required for each $100 million in offsets. It is
likely that such a proposal would encounter
stiff opposition. The most recent increase in
the tax was debated several years prior to
enactment.
• A reduction of Federal civilian agency employ­
ment through attrition (for example, a two for
one attrition-replacement policy) would reduce
employment by 2 percent. Assuming a 1982
payroll of $24 billion, savings would be
$400-500 million. However, it is not clear that
such a policy is desirable, compared with more
targeted cutbacks. The savings of $400-500
million could be achieved through attrition,
major cutbacks in certain departments like the
Department of Energy, or by a 10 percent cut­
back in the $5 billion spent by Federal agencies
to formulate and enforce Federal regulations.
• Federal travel and transportation cost about
$9 billion annually, with over 75 percent attrib­
utable to the Department of Defense. The
$1.7 billion for civilian agencies is embedded
within programs presented throughout the bud­
get. Although data are maintained on travel
and transportation expenses, budget and ap­
propriations review is generally done on a
programmatic basis rather than on an object
class or input basis. Pending detailed review
of travel and transportation policies, a general
provision limiting 1982 expenses to 1981 levels
could be attached to each nondefense appro­
priation bill, saving between $100-200 million.
(It is not clear that such a policy is appropri­
ate for the Department of Defense since most
funds are used to transfer military personnel
and move equipment.)
The reductions summarized in Table 10 do not
include some across-the-board cuts that are expected
to be proposed by the new administration. In particular,
reductions of expenditures for consulting services may
be proposed. However, unlike travel, little data is avail­
able on where or how money is spent or on how to make
the reductions. The new administration may include a
cut of about $700 million for such services in its bud­
get, but it would be extremely difficult to implement the
reductions.

Digitized22
for FRASER
FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81


Net interest
No reductions of interest on the public debt have
been included since it is unclear whether the spend­
ing cuts will lower the deficit or be used for larger
defense increases or for larger tax cuts. If spend­
ing cuts were used to lower the deficit, interest
costs in 1982 would drop by about $0.6 billion for
each $10 billion reduction of the deficit because of a
lower level of outstanding interest-bearing debt; by 1983
the savings would be $1.8 billion, if the $10 billion deficit
reduction were continued.
Summary
If all the reductions outlined in this article were en­
acted, the savings would be $12 billion in 1982 and
about $20 billion in 1983. These savings would repre­
sent about 2.0 percent of nondefense spending in
1982, 3.0 percent in 1983, and approximately 2 per­
cent of total Federal spending in each year. Between
80 and 90 percent of the reductions could be accom­
plished only by rewriting existing laws rather than
through regular appropriations action. The process of
changing laws generally requires extended and
drawn-out negotiations and is subject to greater delays
than appropriations. Because of the time required to
negotiate and implement the various changes in cur­
rent laws, the savings totals in this article are prob­
ably an upper limit on what can be achieved through
action during the remainder of this year. By com­
parison, the push for reductions in the fiscal year
1981 budget that started last March probably resulted
in nondefense legislated savings of only $4-6 billion,
despite the fact that the effort had administration and
bipartisan Congressional support for achieving a bal­
anced budget to resist inflationary pressures. However,
many of the reductions discussed in this article may
be opposed by the Democratic leadership in the
House. Also, the target date for a balanced budget
appears to be slipping further into the future. Conse­
quently, advocates of spending cuts cannot use the
balanced budget argument to defeat amendments that
exempt various programs from budget cuts.
An alternative to the goal of a balanced budget is
expenditure cuts that offset the revenue loss from a
tax cut similar to the first instalment of the Roth-Kemp
proposal and from a business tax cut. However, the
revenue loss in 1982 from a 10 percent across-theboard cut in individual income tax rates— about $30-35
billion10— is by itself in excess of what reasonably can
be expected in the way of outlay cuts. A package of

10 This estimate assumes enactment of a bill by about July 1,1981 and
changes in withholding tables by September 1, 1981. The cut would
not be retroactive to January 1, 1981.

cuts that yields significantly more than $10-15 billion
for 1982 may not be possible. In general, a larger reduc­
tion of total outlays probably would require making ad­
ditional separate program changes rather than making
each of the changes listed in this article more drastic.
The program of changes that has already been outlined
could occupy most of the time of the first session of
the 97th Congress with debate and decisions on Fed­
eral spending and consequently could leave little time
for consideration of major changes in taxes, Federal
regulatory policies, or energy policy. (The tax-writing
committees of the Congress are also the committees
responsible for social security, medicare, unemploy­
ment compensation, and welfare.) Active consideration
of more proposals in all likelihood would either be post­
poned or add to the overall confusion, making it more
difficult to achieve any reductions.
The Congress and the administration may have to
settle for a longer range goal of offsetting the revenue
losses from a tax cut by 1983. For 1983, the revenue
loss from a one-time 10 percent cut in rates enacted
in 1981 would be about $35 billion. The expenditure
savings of $20 billion for 1983 in Table 4 represent
estimates of the second-year effects of making per­
manent the program changes that reduce 1982 outlays.
Additional changes that either start in 1983 or begin
in 1982 but have no outlay effect in 1982 could
probably reduce 1983 outlays by another $10-15 billion,
yielding total reductions in 1983 of $30-35 billion. These
could include cuts in contributions to international
financial institutions, reductions of (or elimination of)




future funding for the space shuttle, additional cuts in
entitlements, and further reductions of Federal employ­
ment. These changes, together with those outlined in
this article, could come close to offsetting the income
tax cut by 1983 but would probably still fall short of off­
setting the $50-55 billion revenue loss from both a 1981
business tax cut and an individual income tax cut.
The possibilities for offsetting the revenue loss from
an individual income tax cut earlier than 1983 appear
to be limited. A reduction of the defense real growth
target might make a difference, but it would entail a
major shift in policy. Swift enactment of comprehensive
social security and medicare changes that affect all
beneficiaries could contribute to an earlier income tax
cut, but such changes do not appear likely because of
various political considerations and also would be at
variance with earlier policy pronouncements. A flood
of changes in existing laws well beyond that envisioned
in this article could possibly offset an income tax cut
by 1982, although both political and time constraints
make this extremely difficult. What seems to be clear,
however, is that the process of reconsidering basic
legislation would need to begin right away, regardless
of whether enough changes can be enacted to affect
total Federal outlays significantly in the immediate term.
Otherwise, unless the Congress begins immediately to
consider and to act on numerous changes in current
laws, the chances for any spending cuts for 1982 may
slip away and the opportunities for reducing spending
growth in 1983 and beyond could be severely cir­
cumscribed.

James R. Capra

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81

23

The
business
situation
Current
developments

Chart 1

The 1980 recession is unique by
postwar standards.*
The advance in economic activity
during the year before the downturn
was very weak . . .
Percent
Percentage increase in real GNP in the year
the cyclical peak

“before

—

I

I

I

IBBS IHi I

JE 3 I

1948-4 919 53-54 1957-58 1960-61 1969-70 1973-75

1980

. . . and the decline started
off sharply . . .
Percent
I Annual rates of decline in real GNP in the first
§~ quarters of rece s s io n s ---------------------------------------------

. . . but the economy seemed to turn
quickly around.
Percent
|| Annual rates o f change in real GNP two quarters
2 - a fte r the p e ak-------------------------------------------------------- ■

—4 --------------- --------— - .

I It

------------------------------------------------------

I
~ ~
I
I
J ______ I.........
1948-49 1953-54 1957-58 1960-61 1969-70 1973-75 1980

*D a ta for periods preceding 1969 do not reflect
latest revisions.
Source: United States Department of Commerce,
Bureau of Economic Analysis.

24

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81




Economic activity advanced in both the third and
fourth quarters follow ing the sharp second-quarter
decline. The recovery surprised many observers, be­
cause it was earlier and more vigorous than had been
expected. Industrial production rose more than 7 per­
cent from July to December, reversing about 80 per­
cent of the January-July decline. Construction activity
also picked up substantially, and sizable gains were
recorded in payroll employment. At the same tim e,
however, there were indications that further substan­
tial growth in early 1981 is unlikely. Retail sales, in
constant dollars, were essentially flat from July to
November and then tailed off. Domestic auto sales
were sluggish, and permits for housing construction
began to decline at the end of the year, as interest
rates reached the very high levels attained last spring.
While the business indicators were mixed, strong infla­
tionary pressures persisted.
The current business cycle has been very different
from earlier ones (Chart 1). The 1980 recession was
preceded by a year of weak econom ic growth, and
the ensuing downturn in econom ic activity was very
rapid. The 9.9 percent annual rate of decline of real
gross national product (GNP) during the second quar­
ter— led by rapid declines in the auto and housing
sectors— was the steepest on record in the postwar
era and by far the largest decline at the start of a reces­
sion. A fter this abrupt slowdown, the pace of business
activity picked up again in the third quarter. By most
conventional measures, the 1980 recession should be
one of the shortest on record. In terms of its over­
all magnitude, however, its peak-to-trough decline
would be close to the average for previous postwar
recessions.
The pattern of the current business cycle has been
reflected in the movements of both industrial produc-

Chart 2

Chart 3

Although there have been significant gains
in em ploym ent in recent months . . .

Consumers have m aintained a higher
savings rate . . .

Millions of persons

Percent

P ayroll err ploym ent

I I I I I
J FMAMJ

I

I I I I I
J A S O N D J

1-J 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 I I
F M A M J J

A S O N D

1

. . . and initial claim s for unemployment
benefits have declined . . .
Th ousands

. . . and have not increased purchases.
Index

. . . the unemployment rate has rem ained
well above 1979 levels.
Percent

Source:
United States Department of Commerce,
Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Source: United States Department of Labor,
Bureau of Labor Statistics.

tion and payroll employment. Industrial output rose
more than 7 percent from July to December, the larg­
est five-month gain since late 1975, when the economy
was recovering from the last recession. The recent
strength has been broadly based, stemming from ad­
vances in the production of consumer durables, inter­
mediate products, and basic materials. Reflecting the
pickup in econom ic activity, employm ent has been
rising in recent months, recovering about 95 percent
of the February-July decline. But, with the total labor
force expanding vigorously through November, the un­
employment rate has been in the 7.4 to 7.6 percent
range for eight consecutive months (Chart 2).




The domestic auto industry had a central role in
the first months of the upturn. Sales were sluggish
going into the recession, dropped further during the
second quarter, and rebounded— although to still fairly
low levels— in the third quarter. By and large, auto­
mobile sales fo r the new-model year have not met
producers’ expectations. Dom estically produced autos
sold at an annual rate of 6.5 m illion in the fourth quar­
ter, just m atching the third quarter’s sales pace. The
new fuel-efficient models were expected to be very
popular, but high prices and tight credit conditions
still cloud the sales outlook. Uncertain sales prospects
and high financing costs have encouraged dealers to
maintain low inventories, and this could tem porarily
delay sales even if demand strengthens.
By historical standards, the housing recovery also
has been less than vigorous. Nevertheless, the ad­
vance in housing starts— from a 900,000 unit annual
rate in May to more than 1.5 m illion in October, No­
vember, and December— contributed substantially to
econom ic growth in the fourth quarter. With interest

FRBNY Quarterly R eview/W inter 1980-81

25

rates markedly higher at the year-end, however, build­
ing activity showed signs of turning down once more.
Single-family housing starts and building permits reg­
istered modest declines, but the pace of multifamily
starts increased, sustained by work on new apartment
buildings to be occupied under Federal rent subsidies.
Nevertheless, the total issuance of single- and multi­
family permits in December was more than 300,000
below September’s rate, signaling a likely reduction
of housing activity in coming months.
Weakening demands for new homes and autos fit
into a broader picture of stagnant consumer spending.
In constant dollars, retail sales were essentially un­
changed from July to November after rising by almost
4 percent from May to July. A number of factors make
the outlook for consumer spending uncertain. The
savings rate remains high in comparison to its level
in late 1979 (Chart 3), suggesting that consumers have
remained cautious. (Recent data revisions have raised
the level of the savings rate but without changing its
pattern in the 1979-80 period.) On the other hand, there
is evidence that consumers are beginning to borrow
once again after the precipitous decline that occurred
during the credit restraint program. Outstanding con­
sumer credit grew by $3 billion from July to November,
offsetting 40 percent of the March-July decline.

26

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81




Despite the legacy of the sharp recession in the
first half of 1980, inflation continued at a rapid rate.
The consumer price index increased at a 12 percent
annual rate in the September-November period, boosted
by the volatile mortgage rate and food price compo­
nents. The latest statistics on wage increases also
suggest strong inflationary pressure. Average hourly
earnings in manufacturing, adjusted for interindustry
shifts, rose at a strong 9 percent annual rate in the
fourth quarter. However, this was considerably slower
than the previous three quarters, suggesting that in­
flationary pressure, while still strong, may be easing
somewhat.
With the uncertain outlook for auto sales, and high
interest rates causing housing to slow, it is unlikely
that the recent advance in business activity— if it lasts
— will have the vigor of the early stages of past expan­
sions. Given current economic conditions, it would
take remarkable strength in several sectors of the
economy to achieve a robust expansion, despite the
prospects for some additional stimulus in the coming
year from tax cuts and increased defense spending.
Moreover, these sources of strength are likely to be
offset, at least in part, by weakening export demand
as the economies of other major industrial nations
experience slowdowns.

The
financial
markets
Current
developments
Chart 1

After rising sharply for several months,
interest rates declined in the final weeks
of the year.
Percent

Percent
Long-term rates
F ive -ye a r
G ove rnm ent s e c u ritie s *

6

A aa-rated
c o rp o ra te bonds

G overnm ent s e c u r i t i e s * -----(T he Bond B uyer in d e x ) ----- 1

J u j u

J

11 1 1 1 i n 11 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 11 i i l n u l i 1 1 1 i . j l i l u u l j u l i - i . i i l
F
M A
M J
J
A
S
O
N
D
1980

* These yields are adjusted to five-year and twenty-year
maturities and exclude bonds with special estate tax
privileges.
Sources: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Moody’s
Investors Service, The Bond Buyer, and Donoghue’s
Money Fund Report of Holliston, Massachusetts.




Financial markets tightened throughout most of the
fourth quarter as interest rates approached and in
many cases exceeded the record highs of last spring.
But, in the final weeks of the year, interest rates de­
clined (Chart 1) as the m arket reacted to slow er money
supply growth and indications that the economy would
be weakening. For most of the fourth quarter, however,
the financial markets were responding to news of a
much stronger than expected economy and very rapid
money supply growth. As a result, the three-m onth bill
rate rose from about 11 percent at the end of September
to 16.7 percent in the week of December 17. To keep
the discount rate in line with other market rates and
to restrain the rapid growth of money and credit, the
Federal Reserve raised the discount rate tw ice during
the fourth quarter to a level of 13 percent and imposed
a surcharge on frequent borrowers from the discount
w indow .1
Partly as a result of the strengthening in econom ic
activity in the second half of the year, M-1B rose at
a 10.5 percent annual rate, compared with 2.3 percent
in the first half of the year. But the rapid growth of
M-1B did not stem only from the strengthening in
econom ic activity. A considerable volume of funds
were shifted from savings deposits, which are not part
of M-1B, into automatic transfer accounts (ATS) which
are a component of M-1B; ATS accounts, negotiable
order of withdrawal accounts (NOWs), and credit union
share drafts com prise the “ other checkable deposit”
component of M-1B. The inflow of funds from savings
1 The surcharge above the basic discount rate, which was set at
2 percentage points on November 17 and increased to 3 percentage
points on Decem ber 5, applies only to borrow ings fo r "ad justm e nt
purposes” by institutions with deposits of $500 m illion or more and
is charged when such borrowings occur in two or more successive
weeks in a calendar quarter or when borrow ings take place in more
than four weeks in a calendar quarter.

FRBNY Quarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81

27

accounts into ATS accounts during the latter half of
1980 was concentrated at comm ercial banks outside
the New York, New Jersey, and New England geo­
graphic area. Apparently, these banks were prom oting
ATS accounts aggressively in advance of the intro­
duction of nationwide NOW accounts fo r all financial
institutions as of December 31 to solidify in advance
market shares fo r interest-bearing checkable deposits.
Furthermore, to the extent that these ATS accounts
replace prospective NOW accounts, reserve require-

Chart 3

While the demand for short-term business
credit has increased sharply
since July . . .

Jan

Chart 2

With short-term interest rates rising,
the spread between m arket rates and
the return on money m arket funds
becam e positive after July . . .
Percent

2------------------------------------------------------

. . . leading to a decline in the
assets of money m arket funds . . .
Billions of dollars
90

Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec
1980

. . . the spread between the prime rate
and the com m ercial paper rate
has narrowed . . .
Percent

8 -----------

Jan Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul
1980

Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec

. . . and a larger share of short-term
financing has been provided by banks.
Percent
Percentage of short-term

1980

. . . and encouraging growth of
six-month certificates.
Billions of dollars

nonfinancial commercial paper

Sources:
Federal Reserve Bank of New York,
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
and Donoghue’s Money Fund Report of Holliston,
Massachusetts.

28for FRASER
FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81
Digitized


Jan Feb Mar Apr May Jun Jul Aug Sep Oct Nov Dec
1980
Sources:
Federal Reserve Bank of New York,
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

ments of these banks will be reduced for a while, since
requirements on ATS accounts will be phased in from
the previous ratio required against savings deposits
(3 percent) to the higher level required against trans­
action accounts (12 percent for deposits in excess of
$25 million). On the other hand, reserve requirements
on NOW accounts outside New York, New Jersey, and
New England will be at the level for transaction ac­
counts immediately.
The rapid growth of other checkable deposits dur­
ing the second half of 1980 makes it difficult to inter­
pret the growth of the narrow monetary aggregates
— M-1A and M-1B— relative to the annual targets for
1980 that were set by the Federal Open Market Com­
mittee (FOMC) last February. From the fourth quarter
of 1979 to the fourth quarter of 1980, M-1B increased
at an annual rate of 7.3 percent, about % percentage
point above the 6.5 percent upper limit set for 1980,
while M-1A advanced at a 5.0 percent rate, well within
the 6.0 percent upper limit of its annual range. The
upper limits of the M-1A and M-1B targets were set
with a 1/2 percentage point spread, assuming only
negligible effects from ATS and NOW accounts. As
it turned out, however, the spread between the annual
growth rates of M-1A and M-1B was 2.3 percentage
points as the public shifted a larger than expected
volume of funds from demand deposits and savings
deposits into other checkable deposits. After allowing
for these unexpected shifts, both M-1A and M-1B
increased at rates roughly equal to the upper limits
of their respective annual ranges. The broad aggre­
gates— M-2 and M-3— also showed strong growth
during the second half of the year and recorded
growth rates of 9.9 percent and 10.0 percent, respec­
tively, slightly above the 1980 targets.
The introduction of nationwide NOW accounts on
December 31, 1980 will continue to complicate the
interpretation of the narrow monetary aggregates dur­
ing 1981. As funds shift from demand deposits into
NOW accounts, the growth of M-1A will continue to be
reduced. This particular shift will not affect M-1B
growth because both components are included in the
definition of M-1B. However, other funds, primarily
savings deposits, will also be moved into NOW ac­
counts, which will add to M-1B growth in the same way
that shifts of savings deposits into ATS accounts
added to M-1B growth in 1980. As a result of funds
shifting from demand and savings deposits into NOW
accounts, M-1B growth is likely to be considerably
stronger than M-1A growth during 1981.
Reflecting the strong demand for money during the




fourth quarter, short-term interest rates increased
sharply. The rate on six-month Treasury bills rose from
about 11.5 percent at the end of September to 15.7
percent in mid-December. As a result of the higher
yields which were consequently available on six-month
money market certificates, the public invested a large
volume of funds in these certificates at banks and
thrift institutions during the latter part of the year
(Chart 2). At the same time, the average yield on the
assets of money market mutual funds increased from a
low of about 8 percent during the summer months to
16.6 percent at the year-end. However, since the yield
on money market mutual funds rises only gradually as
portions of the existing portfolio of money market in­
struments mature and are reinvested, the return tends to
lag behind other market rates. Consequently, the assets
of money market funds declined during the fourth
quarter. In contrast, during a period of declining inter­
est rates, money market mutual funds should be more
attractive than other market instruments because the
yield would not fall so quickly.
The rapid increase in interest rates occurred during
a period of strong demand for short-term business
credit. Commercial and industrial loans exclusive of
bankers’ acceptances plus commercial paper issued
by nonfinancial corporations expanded at an 18.7
percent annual rate between July and December
(Chart 3). In part, this overall strength stems from the
increased cost of borrowing in the long-term debt mar­
ket. During the fourth quarter, rates on long-term
corporate bonds were as much as 3 1A percentage
points above the trough level recorded last summer.
Many corporations became reluctant to incur such high
borrowing costs on a long-term basis and turned in­
stead to short-term sources of credit to meet their
financing needs. As a result, new corporate bond
offerings averaged only about $2.8 billion per month
during the fourth quarter, compared with $5.6 billion
during the spring and summer months.
As corporations turned to the short-term market, the
interest rate spread between commercial paper and
the prime rate was an important factor contributing to
the composition of their short-term borrowing. Even
though the prime rate rose to a record 2 1 1/2 percent by
the end of December, commercial paper rates rose by
a greater amount and, as a result, corporations raised
a larger proportion of their short-term credit needs at
banks rather than in the commercial paper market.
Another factor contributing to greater reliance on bank
loans was the downgrading of several large issuers of
commercial paper.

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81

29

Global Payments Problems
The Outlook for 1981

Since late in 1978, oil prices have risen sharply and
the major oil-exporting countries have again amassed
large financial surpluses. Correspondingly large deficits
have been contracted by oil-consuming nations. With
political tensions in the world’s major oil-producing
region at a new high, the questions of how large these
deficits and surpluses may become and how long
they can persist have taken on renewed urgency. This
article reviews recent developments and considers the
1981 outlook for international payments of the Organi­
zation of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) mem­
bers and the non-OPEC developing countries.1 The in­
dustrial country members of the Organization for Eco­
nomic Cooperation and Development (OECD) also face
serious problems. But, except for a couple of the least
developed OECD members, the central problem is to
reduce oil demand with minimum adverse effects on
employment and inflation rather than how to finance
the oil imports. Less developed countries (LDCs), too,
must adjust to higher oil prices, but these adjustments
at best take time. With their often limited capacity to
adjust and limited sources of external funds, many
LDCs find that their external financing constraint
quickly binds. The forced adjustment that then results
tends to be more costly than necessary.
The combined current account of members of OPEC
grew from near balance in 1978 to a surplus of over
$110 billion by 1980 (Chart 1). Most of this increase

i The definition of non-OPEC developing countries used here excludes
southern Europe, China, and South Africa. In discussions of gross
bank finance and gross oil trade, data for offshore financial centers
and offshore refining centers are excluded as well.

30 forFRBNY
Digitized
FRASERQuarterly Review/Winter 1980-81


was against the OECD member countries. The OECD
accounts for nearly 90 percent of the world’s oil im­
ports, and by 1980 its aggregate current account had
deteriorated to an estimated deficit of over $75
billion from a surplus of under $10 billion in 1978.
Meanwhile, the combined deficit of non-OPEC de­
veloping countries widened from about $25 billion
to over $50 billion.
The outlook for 1981 is critically dependent on very
uncertain oil prices, so that two different price sce­
narios are considered. If the recent Iran-lraq supply
interruptions are overcome early in 1981, an in­
crease in the oil price at least in line with inflation
in industrial countries is likely. A 12 percent OPEC oil
price increase on average from 1980, along with a
continued rapid rise in their imports would reduce the
OPEC current account surplus to about $80 billion.
The economic slowdown in major industrial countries
is expected to continue, and this would lower the com­
bined OECD deficit some $30 billion to around $45
billion. The deficit of the non-OPEC developing coun­
tries, on the other hand, would be expected to rise
nearly $10 billion to around $60 billion, as prices of
their primary commodity exports stagnate in the face
of weaker demand in the industrial world. Even this
scenario assumes that developing countries maintain
a tight check on real import growth as their deficits
are constrained by the availability of finance.
A higher price of oil in 1981 would result in a larger
OPEC surplus and a larger OECD deficit. For instance,
if the average oil price received by OPEC rises 25
percent to $40 per barrel for the year, their surplus
would again exceed $100 billion. Most of this increase

Chart 1

Global Current Account Balances
Billions of dollars

120

-20
-4 0

Non-OPEC developing countries t

40
60
80

1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1 9 80 1981a 1981b
Estimate Projections §
Members of the Organization of Petroleum Exporting
Countries (OPEC).
M em bers o f the O rg anizatio n fo r E conom ic C oop era tion
and D evelo pm e nt (OECD).
Excludes eastern and southern European countries, China,
and South Africa.
Projection 1981a assumes a $ 3 5 per barrel average OPEC
contract price for oil, while the 1981b projection assumes
a $ 4 0 per barrel average price.
Sources: OECD, International Monetary Fund (IMF);
Federal Reserve Bank of New York estim ates, projections,
and adjustments for consistent country coverage.

again would be reflected in the deficit of the OECD
area. As a group, these countries would not have a
serious financial constraint so long as they continue
to attract the bulk of OPEC investments. Non-OPEC
developing countries, a few of which would gain from
an oil price rise, would face a further $5 billion
erosion in their current account, bringing it to near
$65 billion. The oil-im porting countries in this group




would have to cover a $10 billion higher oil bill. Be­
cause oil imports are concentrated in a few countries,
the higher oil price could present serious financing
problems for individual countries even though it pro­
duces only a small increase in the combined deficit. In
this context, it has to be kept in mind that payments
interruptions by one or more of the m ajor debtor coun­
tries could raise the cost of borrowing for all and com ­
pound the adjustm ent problem fo r others.
OPEC
The combined OPEC current account surplus is now
estimated at about $110 billion in 1980, up from only
about $5 billion two years earlier (Chart 2). The group’s
annual export receipts more than doubled to over $300
billion during this period, as the 140 percent surge
in oil prices dominated a 10 percent decline in oil
production and export volume. But, by 1980, more
than a third of the $150 billion increase in export
revenue was being spent on current im port and trans­
fer payments abroad. These payments responded
slow ly at first to the rising oil receipts. Most OPEC
members entered 1979 with relatively austere plans
for econom ic developm ent and imports. Their emerg­
ing fiscal and balance-of-payments deficits between
1976 and 1978 led most OPEC countries to cut back
their import-intensive government spending plans. How­
ever, by early 1980, OPEC real im port growth
once again appears to have been in excess of 20 per­
cent per year. As a result, merchandise imports are
estimated to have risen to about $140 billion in 1980,
nearly $40 billion above their 1978 level. Moreover, the
OPEC deficit on net services and transfer payments
has risen about $10 billion since 1978 to more than
$50 billion despite growing earnings on OPEC invest­
ments abroad.
Real OPEC imports are likely to remain strong as
Iraq and Iran reconstruct war damage, or at least
rearm. Moreover, the heightened political tensions
w ill likely increase arms purchases elsewhere in the
region. If oil prices remain about constant in real
terms (a 12 percent nominal year-over-year growth),
this continued rise in imports would reduce the 1981
OPEC surplus to around $80 billion. On the other
hand, a 25 percent increase in oil prices to around $40
per barrel for the year average would again produce
a surplus in excess of $100 billion.
The conditions under which a higher oil price might
occur are not implausible. The Iraq-lran w ar has, as
of this w riting, driven spot prices to the $40 per bar­
rel range and led OPEC to announce increases in
th eir posted prices to an average of about $35 per
barrel. However, the OPEC price structure remains
split. Under announced plans, Saudi Arabian prices

FRBNY Q uarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81

31

still remain below those of equivalent grade oil from
other Middle Eastern producers w hile prices for higher
quality African crude oils remain well above their
traditional premia. These price differentials seem un­
likely to be sustained, but it is unclear whether market
forces w ill dictate cuts in the premium prices being
charged by Algeria, Libya, and Nigeria or induce
Saudi Arabia and other price moderates to recon­
sider their discounts. The lower price scenario is
consistent with an early return of Iran and Iraq pro­
duction and exports to near th eir prewar levels, and
no additional supply disruptions elsewhere. With slug­

gish activity in industrial countries, this would return
the world oil m arket to the oversupply situation that was
apparent in the third quarter of 1980. Then, inventories
had reached record levels and spot prices were falling,
even though OPEC production had declined more than
10 percent from its level a year earlier. This outcome
would allow a consolidation of OPEC prices around
the $35 per barrel level. Production cutbacks by the
high surplus Arabian Gulf producers in line with their
longer term plans would prevent a further price ero­
sion. On the other hand, a prolongation of hostilities,
a spread of the war, or new political disruptions in

Chart 3
Chart 2

Disposition of OPEC S u rp lu s*

OPEC Current Account

Billions of dollars

Billions of dollars
35 0
Merchandise exports
300

-5 0
— 1 00 - M e rc h a n d is e

im ports

-150 I

200

Trade balance

150
100
50
■ M

~50

-

n

* The total surplus available for disposition equals the
OPEC balance on goods, services, and private transfers
plus borrowings by OPEC members plus adjustments
for leads and lags of oil-export receipts.

Net services and transfers

-1 0 0 1
150

t Increase in liabilities of banks in industrial countries
as reported to the Bank for International
Settlements (BIS).

Current account

100
50

QI—
1973

f Includes direct investment, loans, portfolio investment,
and unrecorded items.

1974

1975

1976

1977

1978

1979

1980
Estimate

Sources:
IMF; Federal Reserve Bank of New York
estim ates and adjustments for country coverage.

32 forFRBNY
Digitized
FRASERQuarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81


§ Excludes purchases of World Bank bonds in
international capital markets.
Sources: IMF, OECD, BIS; Federal Reserve Bank of
New York estimates and adjustments for country
coverage.

other m ajor oil-producing countries could tighten the
oil market substantially and produce another run-up in
oil prices. While one can easily imagine even higher
oil price projections based on worsening political
scenarios fo r the M iddle East, the $40 per barrel oil
price assumption provides the flavor of th eir impact.
In investing its surplus, OPEC continues to favor
low -risk investments, particula rly government securi­
ties of m ajor countries and deposits in large inter­
national banks (Chart 3). The effect has been to shift
the job of lending to most oil-im porting countries—
including developing countries— over to banks and
other participants in the w orld capital markets. At
least three quarters of the available OPEC surplus in
1979 and 1980 was invested in industrial countries or
in Eurocurrency deposits of banks from these coun­
tries, and the banks alone have taken about half the
surplus. The remaining quarter includes direct credits
to developing countries, indirect funding through m ulti­
national organizations, and unrecorded items. Direct
and indirect assistance to other developing countries
has not grown in real terms since 1974 and has fallen
far short of the growth of the OPEC surplus in the last
two years.
Under the lower oil price scenario for 1981, the
level of OPEC lending to LDCs would increase little
from the $10-12 billion estimated for 1980. In the
past during periods of declining surplus, such lend­
ing has fallen back although with a lag. Also, as in the
past, much of this lending would be in the form of
concessional loans and would follow the political ties
of the high surplus OPEC members with Middle
Eastern and North African countries. Increased OPEC
investments at market-related terms may be a ntici­
pated. However, these investments probably would
compete with bank lending in those few more ad­
vanced developing countries that are adjusting well to
the oil shock, rather than complement bank lending
in countries where adjustm ent proves more difficult.
The main difference under the alternative higher
surplus scenario would be increased bank placements.
Some increase in direct LDC assistance and the fund­
ing of m ultilateral institutions might also be possible,
but the past growth and direction of these flows
suggest they would not compensate fo r the additional
oil cost to many LDCs w ithout a serious effort to
augment official recycling.
Non-OPEC developing countries
The non-OPEC developing country current account
d eficit mounted to over $50 billion in 1980, more than
double its level two years earlier. This deterioration
was nearly equal to the $35 billion growth of the annual
oil-im port bill of the group over the period (Chart 4).




Chart 4

Non-OPEC Developing Countries’
Trade Account
Billions of dollars
2 5 0 ------------------------------------------------------------------------Merchandise exports

200 -------------------------------------------------------------------Oil

150
100
50

H

0
-5 0
-100
-1 50 --------------------------------------

■200 ---- ---------------------------—25 0 - M erchandise imports
-3 0 0
50

Trade balance

0

m

I

-5 0
1973

I
1974

I
1975

I
1976

1977

"
1978

l

1979

1980
Estimate

Sources:
IMF, OECD; Federal Reserve Bank of
New York estimates and adjustments for
country coverage.

But the direct im pact of higher oil prices on
the developing countries is very uneven. Four coun­
tries— Brazil, India, Korea, and Taiwan— account for
nearly half of the group’s oil-im port bill. These
four also accounted for about half of the deterioration
of the deficit. Many sm aller countries with less export
or borrowing potential have been even more seriously
affected in proportion to their own income and output.
At the other extreme, those developing country oil
exporters that are not members of OPEC showed
about a $15 billion increase in net oil receipts over the
1978-80 period.2 These countries have expanded their
oil production nearly 25 percent since 1978, but their
dom estic oil consumption and nonoil imports have also
grown. As a result, they showed only a modest $2
b illion improvement in th eir current account deficit
by 1980.

2 The major non-OPEC developing country oil exporters are Mexico,
Oman, Trinidad and Tobago, Egypt, Malaysia, Angola, Bahrain, Peru,
Syria, and Tunisia.

FRBNY Quarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81

33

On top of their higher oil-im port bill, developing
country exports have suffered from weakening de­
mand in th e ir markets in industrial countries. The
slowdown in real gross national product (GNP) growth
of the industrial countries during 1979-80 cut 1980
developing country exports $10 billion to $15 billion
below what they would have been. Moreover, the full
im pact of this slowdown has not yet been felt. Pri­
mary comm odities prices were relatively strong for
LDC exporters until just recently and rose about 35
percent over the past two years. But the increases
were concentrated in a few products— sugar, copper,
tin, and rubber— and benefited only some countries.
Many developing countries also import prim ary com ­
modities, p articularly foods, and have been hurt by the
nearly 40 percent rise in grain prices.
For 1981, the non-OPEC developing country cur­
rent account d eficit is projected to widen to about
$60 billion, if oil prices remain constant in real
terms. The further slowing in industrial country growth
and the weaker com m odities prices w ill further re­
duce the growth of export receipts. Thus, most of the
deterioration w ill be reflected in the trade account,
even if real im port growth is again held to about
3 percent. The outlook for comm odities prices is
mixed. Most prices have been falling since the third
quarter of 1980, and only grains appear to have much
potential for a strong 1981 performance. As a result,
the terms of trade for developing countries is pro­
jected to deteriorate about 2 percent. Moreover, the
relatively strong grain prices w ill help only a few and
hurt the low income food-im porting countries who may
least be able to finance larger deficits.
A run-up in oil prices to $40 per barrel would add
another $5 billion to the combined developing country
deficit in 1981, widening it to around $65 billion. But the
$10 billion addition to the oil bill that this price brings
would again be concentrated in a few oil-dependent,
newly industrialized countries. Moreover, those least
developed countries where oil import payments al­
ready consume a heavy share of export receipts
would be forced to cut real imports and th eir eco­
nomic growth further. Some may not have the option of
running a larger deficit. Most of these countries w ill
not be helped by the $7 billion increase in receipts
that would accrue to the few LDC oil exporters that
are not OPEC members as the real oil price rises. The
indirect effects of the price hike could add perhaps
$1-2 billion to the 1981 deficit, after allowing for a
pickup in LDC exports to OPEC members. On the basis
of past experience, however, these indirect effects
work slowly. Thus, the further slowing of activity in
industrial countries brought by higher oil prices would
depress developing country exports well into 1982

Digitized
FRASER Quarterly R eview/W inter 1980-81
34for FRBNY


when even larger LDC deficits would be expected.
The above projections for developing country defi­
cits assume they can be financed. Past and emerging
financing trends provide a guide as to how this m ight

Chart 5

Financing Non-OPEC Developing Countries
Sources of Finance: Major Components *
Billions of dollars
50
Private sources
40
Bank lending^
Direct investment

30

20
10

■ LL

0
40 -

O fficial sources

30 —

Reserve related

20 -

Other bilateral and multilateral credits

10oL

lJLi
1973

1974

1975

1976

1977

1978

1979

1980
Estimate

Uses of Finance: Major C om ponents*
Billions of dollars
60Current account de ficit

20 -

Growth of official reserves

1979

1980
Estimate

Sources exclude suppliers’ credits and bonds which
are more than offset by growth of nonreserve assets
on the uses side and by errors and omissions.
t Growth of claims of banks in industrial countries as
reported to the BIS.
f Includes allocations of special drawing rights.
Sources: IMF, OECD, and BIS; Federal Reserve Bank
of New York estimates and adjustments for country
coverage.

be accomplished (Chart 5). In the past, bank lending3
has been the major source of finance as well as the
source most responsive to changes in LDC deficits. But
this bank lending has been concentrated in a few of the
more advanced non-OPEC developing countries. Just
ten countries4 account for nearly 75 percent of outstand­
ing international bank credits, and since 1978 four of
these countries— Brazil, Mexico, Argentina, and South
Korea— have received two thirds of the net new bank
lending to the group of more than 100 individual coun­
tries. The remaining developing countries have relied
heavily on official source credits to finance their defi­
cits. Except for reserve-related lending, mostly from
the International Monetary Fund (IMF), these credits
grew only slowly during the 1974-75 and 1978-79 peri­
ods of rising LDC deficits. Bilateral (government-togovernment) lending usually requires legislative ap­
proval in industrial democracies, and developing
country finance often takes low priority in times of
economic contraction at home. Multilateral loans and
credits (from the World Bank and regional develop­
ment banks) are linked mostly to project finance and
are disbursed only as these projects progress.
Financing the $60 billion 1981 deficit anticipated for
non-OPEC developing countries, if real oil prices re­
main constant, does not appear unsurmountable. Prob­
lems for individual countries doubtlessly would remain,
and there would be little room for reserve asset ac­
cumulation for the group as a whole. However, a rela­
tively modest growth of official finance and direct
investment, along with continued bank lending at its
recent rate, would cover the overall deficit. Official
source credits should continue to grow, principally

3 Bank lending is defined here to comprise the total increase in
claims on non-OPEC developing countries of banks in industrial
countries, as reported to the Bank for International Settlements. This
is a lending-net-of-repayments concept which includes short-term
credits and loans to the private sectors of developing countries which
may not carry government guarantees.
4 The ten major non-OPEC developing country debtors to commercial
banks are Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Korea, Mexico, Peru,
Philippines, Taiwan, and Thailand.




because of stepped-up IMF and World Bank lending.
Official financing is estimated to have grown from $14
billion in 1979 to near $20 billion in 1980. An increase
to around $25 billion in 1981 appears reasonable.
Recent increases in IMF quotas and guidelines on
maximum lending to individual countries, as well as
stepped-up disbursements on World Bank project and
structural adjustment loans, should make up a good
part of this increase. Private source credits would
still have to provide nearly $40 billion of the financing
under this scenario, mostly in the form of bank lend­
ing. The growth of bank claims could be somewhat
less than the $36 billion reported in 1979 and about
in line with the increase now estimated for 1980. This
would represent about a 20 percent growth of bank
claims on non-OPEC developing countries, somewhat
below the average growth rate since 1975.
The $40 per barrel oil price scenario calls for only a
$5 billion larger combined deficit, but little additional
official lending can confidently be expected. An addi­
tional $5 billion in bank loans might not be out of the
question, particularly if the lending spreads were to
widen. However, some of the countries that would be
hardest hit by the $10 billion rise in the LDC oil bill
may already have stretched their borrowing capacity
to the limit. Domestic political constraints may make it
impossible for them to reduce real imports enough to
avoid payments interruptions. Interruptions in trade
credit or debt service payments would not entail a broad
or permanent default on existing loans. Interruptions,
however, would lead to difficult and possibly prolonged
periods of negotiation to restructure the debt and re­
establish credit. During these periods, new credit to the
country concerned would be sharply curtailed. Forced
import cuts would then reduce the current account
deficit to meet available finance. If these interruptions
arise in a couple of the countries that account for most
bank credits, a drop in the overall rate of bank lending
and in the overall deficit is possible. In any event, the
increasing incidence of problems in individual de­
veloping countries could cause a retrenchment of
bank lending in general and aggravate the adjustment
problems in otherwise sound countries.

William J. Gasser

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81

35

Oil Price Decontrol and Beyond

Price controls on United States domestically produced
crude oil are currently being eliminated,* marking an
important step toward resolving our energy problem.
Oil price decontrol is one key part of a broader na­
tional initiative, which includes decontrol of natural
gas prices, encouragement of alternative energy
sources, and incentives for greater conservation and
efficiency. The main purpose of these efforts is to
reduce our dependence on increasingly costly and
uncertain supplies of foreign oil.
Decontrol of domestic oil will have several impor­
tant effects. First, by October 1981, when decontrol is
scheduled to be completed, United States refined
petroleum prices will be at least 20 to 30 cents per
gallon higher than they would be without decontrol.
Second, a price rise of this magnitude should lower
United States petroleum usage about 1 million bar­
rels per day. Third, since higher prices appear to have
stimulated United States crude oil production, the
total impact of decontrol on United States imports is
probably greater than 1 million barrels daily. Fourth,
by raising the responsiveness of our oil imports to
foreign prices, dropping the controls mechanism
raises United States resistance to future foreign price
increases. If the completion date for decontrol is
moved to earlier in 1981, its full effects would come
sooner and more abruptly but in other respects would
be basically the same as those outlined here.
There is, however, good reason to believe that the
mere decontrol of domestic crude oil prices does not
* This article was written prior to President Reagan’s recent announce­
ment immediately ending all price controls on crude oil and petroleum
products. As noted in the text, this does not substantially change
our conclusions.

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81
Digitized36for FRASER


go far enough. Because of the potentially devastating
effects of petroleum supply disruptions on the United
States economy, the cost of imported oil clearly ex­
ceeds its dollar price. Further steps beyond decontrol,
therefore, are called for to discourage imports. Tax
policies which effectively raise the relative price of
petroleum in the United States would be a logical ex­
tension of the decontrol strategy.
The price-control mechanism
Before examining the implications of decontrol, it is
helpful to review the basic elements of the pricecontrol system which is being phased out. United
States crude oil price ceilings originated in the gen­
eral wage-price restraints of the early 1970s, but the
basic form of the current controls evolved from the
Energy Policy and Conservation Act of 1975.1 Do­
mestically produced crude oil was divided into two
main categories, essentially based on the age and
productivity of wells. Oil from older wells, labeled
“lower tier” oil, was given a price ceiling below the
ceiling for "upper tier” oil, which was produced from
newer wells (or stepped-up output from older wells).
In 1976, production from small “stripper” wells— wells
producing under ten barrels daily— was decontrolled.2
The ceilings kept the average price of domestic oil
below the cost of imported oil. Without controls, re1 For a description of how Federal petroleum regulations evolved since
the 1930s, see Paul A. MacAvoy, ed„ F e d e ra l E n e rg y A d m in is tra tio n
R e g u la tio n , American Enterprise Institute for Policy Research
(Washington, D.C., 1977).
2 Oil from the Naval Petroleum Reserve, which has never accounted
for more than 1.6 percent of total domestic production, was also
exempt from price regulations.

finers would be willing to pay a similar price, including
transportation costs, for crude oil from both foreign
and domestic suppliers. For example, in the fourth
quarter of 1978 the average price of foreign oil de­
livered to United States refiners was $14.77 per barrel.
Stripper oil, which accounted for 15 percent of do­
mestic United States production, received an uncon­
trolled price of $14.54 per barrel, close to the import
price. Due to wellhead ceilings, however, the 35 per­
cent of United States output classified as lower tier
received only $6.14 per barrel. Upper tier oil (exclud­
ing Alaskan) was priced at $13.00 per barrel and ac­
counted for 35 percent of domestic oil. Alaskan North
Slope oil, which at the time made up 14 percent of
United States output, also was technically subject to
the upper tier wellhead ceiling but, due to high trans­
portation costs, actually received a wellhead price
less than the ceiling in order to stay competitive with
uncontrolled oil from other sources.3 For all domestic
oil, the combined average cost to refiners, including
transportation, was $10.88 per barrel, well below the
average import price.
The price ceilings were pegged to the implicit gross
national product (GNP) price deflator. Although this
has permitted the ceilings to keep pace with the infla­
tion rate, foreign oil prices since the end of 1978 have
risen much more than the general price level, causing
the gap between the domestic ceilings and the price
of imports to widen.
Merely holding down domestic crude oil prices,
however, would not guarantee that prices paid by
consumers of refined products would be lower. The
domestic price level for refined petroleum must be
high enough to make it profitable to refine and mar­
ket not only price-controlled oil but also oil from every
other source needed to satisfy total domestic demand,
including expensive foreign supplies. Thus, if left
alone, refined products prices would reflect the high
cost of foreign oil. Refiners of imported oil would
cover their costs, and refiners with access to pricecontrolled oil would be in a very profitable situation.
To make sure that United States refined petroleum
prices were indeed lower, and to remedy the poten­
tial inequities among refiners, an import subsidy was
enacted as part of a system of crude oil “entitle­
ments” to complement the crude oil price controls.4
3 At the wellhead, Alaskan North Slope oil received an average price
of $5.22 per barrel in 1978, compared with $12.15 per barrel for
other upper tier oil. At the refinery gate, Alaskan oil generally re­
ceived at least as much as other upper tier, and often more.
4 In addition, until mid-1976, prices of most refined products were
controlled directly. Currently, gasoline is the only major refined
product category subject to direct price controls, but these controls
apparently are not effectively binding much of the time.




Under the entitlements program, refiners of pricecontrolled crude oil pay a uniform per-barrel subsidy
to refiners of imported and uncontrolled domestic
crude oil. The subsidy lowers the effective cost of
refining foreign or uncontrolled domestic oil, thereby
lowering the price level of refined products. At the
same time, the required payment raises the average
effective cost of refining price-controlled oil, making
it approximately equal, on balance, to the average
effective cost of foreign and uncontrolled domestic
oil.5 The average effective cost of all oil to United
States refiners, therefore, is below the price of im­
ported crude.
Since the entitlements payments roughly equalize
the average effective cost of imported and pricecontrolled crude oil, the size of the subsidy auto­
matically rises when the import price increases rela­
tive to domestic price ceilings.6 For example, between
December 1978 and May 1980, the average delivered
price of imported crude oil to refiners rose from $14.94
per barrel to $34.33 per barrel. Over this period, the
lower tier wellhead price ceiling increased only from
$5.68 to $6.47, reflecting general price inflation. As a
result, the import subsidy, which was $1.27 in Decem­
ber 1978, jumped to $6.22 per barrel by May 1980.
Prices of United States refined products can rise
faster than average effective crude oil costs during a
tight world market. Since the import subsidy is paid on
a uniform per-barrel basis, it does not always fully
offset the higher crude oil costs paid by those refiners
who are forced to seek supplies from particularly ex­
pensive foreign sources. Even if most officially posted
foreign contract prices remain unchanged during a
world shortage, refiners without sufficient contractual
supplies may find it unprofitable to turn to more ex­
pensive sources unless United States refined product
prices rise. Under these circumstances, if the extra
supplies are needed to meet domestic demand, refined
product prices in the United States can rise consider­
ably, even though the average effective cost of all for­
eign oil increases much less. The spread between re­
fined products prices and average effective crude oil
costs therefore rises. Conversely, during a glut on the
world market, refiners can buy oil for less than the
5 The required payment per barrel of upper tier crude oil is less than
the payment per barrel of lower tier oil by just enough to equalize
the effective costs of these two categories of crude oil. For a more
detailed description of the system, see Kay Sherwood, “Crude Oil
Entitlements Program", M o n th ly E n e rg y R e v ie w (January 1977).
‘ More exactly, the entitlements system approximately equalizes the
average effective cost of price-controlled oil and the average com­
bined effective cost of imported and uncontrolled domestic crude
oil. Most of the time, however, market forces cause the price of
uncontrolled domestic oil to be about the same as the import price.

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81

37

long-term contract prices and, receiving the same perbarrel subsidy as other importers, can force down
United States refined products prices relative to the
average effective cost of all imported oil. Over the long
run, United States refined products prices would be
held below the level consistent with average imported
oil prices by an amount corresponding to the import
subsidy, but in the short run the spread between
United States refined products prices and average ef­
fective crude oil costs can fluctuate in response to
shortages or gluts on the world market.
For example, suppose the price charged for most
imported oil was $30 per barrel but, for domestic de­
mand to be satisfied, some oil would have to be im­
ported at $40 per barrel. Unless domestic refined
products prices were high enough to make importing
the more expensive oil profitable, refiners would not
buy it, and the resulting shortage would drive up the
price of refined petroleum in the United States until
it reflected the $40 per barrel cost less the uniform
subsidy. Since the bulk of crude oil was still being
bought at controlled domestic prices or at the $30 per
barrel import price, the spread between refined prod­
ucts prices and average effective crude oil costs would
widen as well. If, however, supplies of $30 oil subse­
quently became more abundant, the price of refined
products would drop to reflect an effective crude oil
cost of only $30 per barrel less the entitlements sub­
sidy, and the spread between refined products prices
and average effective crude oil costs would narrow
again.
The decontrol process
The current process of phasing out all crude oil price
ceilings began in June 1979 and is scheduled for com­
pletion in October 1981. In the month before decontrol
started, 83 percent of all domestic production was sub­
ject to price ceilings— 34 percent lower tier and 49
percent upper tier (including Alaskan). During the
phaseout period, lower tier is being gradually reclas­
sified as upper tier while, simultaneously, upper tier is
being gradually freed of price controls entirely. In
addition, oil with a high sulfur content, newly dis­
covered oil, and oil that is difficult and costly to re­
cover are now free of price ceilings.7 By the middle
of 1980, the proportion of domestic output subject to
price ceilings was down to 47 percent (15 percent lower
tier and 32 percent upper tier). During the first year
of decontrol, therefore, the proportion of total domestic

7 For definitions of these new categories of uncontrolled oil, see
United States Department of Energy, M o n th ly E n e rg y R e v ie w
(September 1980), pages 76, 96-97.

38for FRBNY
Digitized
FRASER Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81


output free of price controls rose from 17 percent to
53 percent.8
As crude oil price ceilings are eliminated, the re­
leased domestic oil receives a price comparable to
foreign oil prices. Consequently, the value of the en­
titlements payments, which equalize average effective
foreign and domestic crude oil costs, will fall automat­
ically to zero as decontrol approaches completion.
As the entitlements subsidy on imports disappears, the
effective cost of crude oil going into United States re­
fined products prices will rise to the price of imported
oil.9
How much lower would effective crude oil costs
and refined petroleum prices have been without de­
control? This depends on how large the import sub­
sidy would have been had controls been continued.
Suppose, for example, that the delivered price of
imported oil, which was $34.48 per barrel in June 1980,
reaches just $35 per barrel by October 1981. In this
case, under plausible assumptions regarding the path
of the continued controls mechanism, by October 1981
the import subsidy would have reached $8 per barrel,
or 19 cents per gallon.10 More plausibly perhaps, an
October 1981 import price of $39 per barrel would re­
sult in an import subsidy of $10 per barrel (24 cents
per gallon), while a $44 price would imply a $12 per
barrel (29 cents per gallon) subsidy. Depending on
foreign prices, therefore, by October 1981 the effective
cost of crude oil going into United States refined prod­
ucts would be around 20 to 30 cents per gallon higher
than without decontrol. Approximately the same figure

8 Due to high transportation costs, however, the upper tier ceiling
on Alaskan North Slope output (15 percent of the domestic total in
May 1979) became an effective constraint on wellhead prices only
after decontrol had already begun. This reflected the sharp rise in
the world market price.
’ The size of the entitlements subsidy can be expressed as the
product of (a ) an appropriately weighted sum of lower and upper
tier oil as a fraction of all oil refined and (b ) the difference between
the average price of all imported and uncontrolled domestic oil
eligible for the subsidy and the lower tier price ceiling. As price
ceiling coverage is phased out, term (a ) becomes zero, eliminating
the subsidy. As noted earlier in this article, however, the rise in
world prices during the first part of the decontrol process caused
an increase in term (b ) sufficient to produce a temporary rise in
the subsidy. Without the phaseout of coverage, of course, this
rise would have been larger (and not temporary).
10 Without decontrol, the October 1981 category shares were projected
as lower tier, 24 percent; upper tier (excluding Alaskan),
43.5 percent; Alaskan, 16 percent; and uncontrolled, 16.5 percent.
Price ceilings and transportation costs were projected to rise at a
10 percent annual rate, and imports were projected to account
for 45 percent of the crude oil used in the United States.

applies to refined petroleum prices.11 Over the 29month phaseout period (June 1979 through October
1981), therefore, decontrol will have added roughly a
penny per month to United States petroleum prices.
The actual path of refined products prices since the
start of decontrol has differed somewhat from the path
of average effective crude oil costs, but this has been
mainly due to the successive tightening and loosening
of the world market during this period. The Iranian
production cutoff at the beginning of 1979 sent spot
market prices soaring. Some exporting nations raised
prices considerably higher than others, and the price
of uncontrolled domestic oil in the United States was
bid above the average import price.12 Thus, as crude
oil prices from certain key sources rose considerably
more than the overall average, the price of United
States refined petroleum rose more than the average
effective cost of crude oil from all sources together.
The spread between refined products prices and aver­
age effective crude oil costs had already widened by
June 1979 when decontrol began, but it continued to
increase as the world market remained tight through
early 1980 (Chart 1). By summer 1980, spot prices had
fallen off and domestic uncontrolled oil had come back
into line with average import prices, reflecting a loos­
ening of the world market.13 As a result, the spread
between United States refined products prices and av­
erage effective crude oil costs narrowed again. During
all this period, however, decontrol was making the
import subsidy smaller than it otherwise would have
been. This in turn raised the effective cost of crude
oil from every source, thereby increasing United States
refined petroleum prices above what they would have
been without decontrol.

11 In the very short run, any reduced usage of petroleum in response
to higher prices may lower the profitability of refinery and dis­
tribution operations, reflecting competition fo ra smaller total amount
of business. In the longer run, however, refining and marketing
capacity will not be replaced unless the return on such investments
justifies the capital costs. Ultimately, therefore, the final products
prices will reflect the whole higher cost of crude oil plus the neces­
sary capital and operating expenses of refining and distributing it.
12 Late in 1978, Libyan and Algerian oils were priced about 10 percent
above Saudi Arabian light crude oil, but by the middle of 1979 the
price differential had widened to around 30 percent. See Department
of Energy, W e e k ly P e tro le u m S ta tu s R e p o rt (August 1, 1980),
page 39.
In December 1978 the average price, including transportation, of
United States stripper oil was $14.57 per barrel, close to the average
comparable import price of $14.92. By December 1979, however,
stripper oil was selling for $33.43 per barrel, while the average price
of imported oil was $28.91 per barrel.
13 By July 1980 the average price, including transportation, of stripper

oil
was $34.45 per barrel, just under the average import price
o f $34.51.




The effect on imports
Even casual observation confirms that higher prices
reduce United States petroleum use. After the first
major oil price hike in 1973-74, the rate of growth of
United States petroleum consumption slowed dramat­
ically to 1.7 percent annually during 1973-78, com­
pared with 4.7 percent over 1949-73. During 1978-80,
total consumption declined at a 5 percent annual rate.14
Moreover, the ratio of petroleum use to GNP was 17.2
percent lower in the first three quarters of 1980 than
its 1973 level.15
These observations are supported by a statistical
analysis of the relationship over time between United
States petroleum prices and consumption. The results
show that, holding GNP constant, a 10 percent rise in
the wholesale price of United States petroleum prod­
ucts is on average associated with roughly a 2 per­
cent fall in total usage.16 For example, in the scenario
described above with the price of imports reaching
$39 per barrel by October 1981, the impact of decon­
trol on United States products prices (assuming a
penny-for-penny pass-through of crude oil costs) is
calculated as 24 cents per gallon, which amounts to a
28 percent rise at the wholesale level. This, in turn,
should result in a fall of between 5.0 and 8.5 percent

14 Total United States consumption is measured as deliveries of
petroleum products from primary storage. The figure for 1978-80 is
based on a comparison of the first nine months of 1978 and 1980.
Sources: Department of Energy, Energy Information Administration,
A n n u a l R e p o rt to C o n g re s s 19 79, Volume Two, page 43, and M o n th ly
E n e rg y R e v ie w (June 1980 and December 1980).
15 The ratio of petroleum deliveries (thousands of barrels daily) to
real GNP (billions of 1972 dollars) was 13.79 in 1973 and 11.42
over the first three quarters of 1980.
14 Over the period 1975-1 to 1980-11, an ordinary least squares
regression was performed, with the following result:
C = 1.83 — 0.14P + 0.57Y + 0 .4 1 C (— 1)
_
(2.1)
(3.2)
(2.7)
(2.0)
R* = 0.86; D.W. = 1.63; SEE = 0.02
C is total petroleum consumption, P is a wholesale price index of
refined petroleum products, deflated by the GNP implicit price
deflator, and Y is real GNP, all in logarithmic form. The t statistics
are in parentheses. The coefficients of the price and income variables
are the respective short-run elasticities. The long-run price and
income elasticities are — 0.23 and 0.96, respectively, with 87 percent
of the effect o f movements in price and GNP on consumption
occurring within two quarters and 95 percent within three quarters.
The lag structure is admittedly crude. Experimentation with
alternatives failed to find a lag structure that was robust with respect
to its specification. However, the total effect of price on consumption
proved virtually unchanged under the alternative specifications.
An autocorrelation correction was performed to check for the
possible bias in the D.W. statistic imposed by the presence of the
lagged dependent variable, but this caused essentially no change
in the coefficients.
A statistical appendix, containing sectorally disaggregated
estimation results, as well as alternative estimation procedures, is
available from the authors. The various methods yield similar results.

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81

39

•
barrels daily, equal to 18 percent of the level of imports
in August 1980. This, moreover, understates the total
effect on imports because United States petroleum
output also depends on price. With newly discovered
oil now allowed to receive an uncontrolled price, d rill­
ing activity has stepped up considerably.18

C hart 1

United States Crude Oil Costs and
Refined Petroleum Prices
Cents per gallon
90
Actual and effectiv e cost of crude oil

/

S ubsidy

A verage im p o rt p ric e

X

xA verage e ffe c tiv e cost

S pread between average effective
cost of crude oil and retail
petroleum prices

C om posite retail price of refined
petroleum products

1 0 0 ------------------ ------------

1978
Source:

1979

I I I I I l I jJ
1980

United S ta te s D epartm ent o f Energy.

in total United States consumption, or between 800,000
and 1.35 m illion barrels per day.17
The im pact of decontrol on consumption, therefore,
is to reduce im ports of foreign oil by about 1 m illion

17 In August 1980, the approxim ate m idpoint of the decontrol period,
the com posite w holesale refined products price was 86 cents per
gallon and petroleum consum ption averaged 15.8 m illion barrels per
day. A 24 cents per gallon price increase im plies a rise of 28 percent
and, using the above elasticity estimate, results in a point estim ate
of about 1 m illion barrels per day. The range in the text allow s for
one standard deviation around the mean elasticity estimate.

40for FRBNY
Digitized
FRASER Q uarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81


Effect on the consumer price index
The 24 cents per gallon increase in retail prices over
the 29-month period of decontrol adds about 6 per­
centage points to the annualized rate of increase in
the consumer fuel and power com ponent of the con­
sumer price index, using August 1980 as a base level.
Since this component accounts fo r about one tenth
of the total index, the impact of decontrol on the
whole index is to add 0.6 percentage points to its
annualized rate of increase between June 1979 and
October 1981. Because this does not take into account
the pass-through of higher energy costs into the prices
of other consumer goods and services, the actual total
impact may be somewhat greater.
Resistance to future foreign price hikes
Under controls, the im port subsidy autom atically rose
along with foreign prices, offsetting roughly half of the
impact of higher im port prices on the effective cost
of crude oil to refiners.19 W ithout the subsidy, any fu­
ture foreign price hike w ill result in a larger increase
in United States refined petroleum prices and, therefore,
in a greater reduction of oil imports. This makes it more
difficult fo r exporters to raise prices unilaterally, since
a given price rise would then require a bigger produc­
tion cutback.
Suppose, for example, that the Organization of Pe­
troleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) is considering two
alternative strategies, one that increases prices by
10 percent and the other that raises prices 12 percent.
For the sake of argument, also assume that the sensi­
tivity of petroleum demand to price changes in the
noncom munist world is about the same as it is in
the United States. With total noncom munist w orld
consumption at about 50 m illion barrels daily, of which
16 m illion is United States consumption, a 10 percent

18 In the first eight months of 1980, 37 percent more oil w ells w e re '
drilled in the United States than in the first eight months of 1979.
See Department of Energy, M onthly Energy Review (O ctober 1980),
page 50.
19 Under controls, with im ported and uncontrolled dom estic oil
accounting for roughly half of refiners’ crude oil inputs, a $2 rise in
the im ported (and uncontrolled) price w ould raise the overall average
cost by $1. The im port subsidy w ould rise about $1, and the average
effective cost of im ported oil would, therefore, be up only $1 on
balance.

price increase would induce a 2 percent fall in con­
sumption outside the United States, or 680,000 barrels
daily. Due to price controls, however, United States
consum ption would fall only 1 percent, or 160,000
barrels daily. Thus, with United States price controls,
OPEC would have to cut production by a total of
840,000 barrels daily in order to sustain the 10 percent
price increase. Sim ilarly, a 12 percent price rise would
require an OPEC production cutback of 1 m illion bar­
rels daily with United States price controls.
Without United States price controls, however,
OPEC’s price-raising options would not be so great.
W ithout the im port subsidy to mitigate the im pact of
price increases on United States petroleum users,
cutting current production by 1 m illion barrels per day
would sustain only the 10 percent price increase
rather than the 12 percent rise possible before. More
generally, with world petroleum demand rising because
of econom ic growth, OPEC might even be able to sus­
tain price hikes w ithout cutting current output, but the
price rise possible under each alternative production
scenario w ill be sm aller w ithout United States controls.
Beyond decontrol
Crude oil price controls encouraged too high a level
of petroleum consumption, discouraged dom estic en­
ergy production, and increased oil imports. Although
the full price of each barrel of imported oil is paid to
the exporter, the subsidy makes the refined petroleum
appear cheaper to the user. The user may be aware
of econom ical ways to reduce consumption through
alternatives costing less than the foreign oil. The
controls program, however, reduces the incentives to
pursue these alternatives, and potential savings go
unexploited. If the true cost of foreign oil were no
greater than its price, merely removing controls would
rectify the problem, for then petroleum users would
be motivated to pursue all the alternatives costing
less than the unsubsidized price of oil.
It is clear, however, that the true cost of foreign
oil exceeds its dollar price. Most obviously, our de­
pendence on imported petroleum leaves the country
vulnerable to the threat of econom ic disruption.20 In
the 1970s, despite higher petroleum prices, United
States dependence on imports rose dram atically as
dom estic oil production fell and consum ption was

20 In addition, the more we reduce United States oil consum ption
(w hich accounts for nearly 30 percent of world oil output) the more
slack this allows in the world market, making it increasingly difficu lt
for exporters to maintain or raise their prices. Even if reducing
United States oil consum ption initia lly costs more than the dollar
price of the oil, the subsequent effect on import prices would make
it w orthw hile since the cost of the remaining oil im ports would then
be lower than otherwise.




Chart 2

United States Petroleum Production
and Consumption
Millions of barrels per day
2 0 ----------------------------------------

1949 50 52 54 56 58 60 62 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 8 0 *
* Preliminary for 1980.
^Domestic production includes crude oil, natural gas
plant liquids, processing gain, unaccounted-for crude
oil, and other hydrocarbons.
Source:

United States Department of Energy.

boosted by the growth of the economy (Chart 2). Do­
mestic oil price decontrol w ill augment the already
ongoing response to higher im ported oil prices in
making United States industry, homes, and automo­
biles more fuel efficient. Nevertheless, the United
States has become so dependent on foreign oil that
it w ill require a strong, sustained initiative to resolve
the long-run problem m eaningfully. Effective new pol­
icies w ill be needed to make possible both sustained
econom ic growth and substantial progress in reduc­
ing oil imports.
A logical and desirable extension of crude oil price
decontrol would be a tax to discourage imports. This
could take the form of an added tax on gasoline
consumption, an oil im port fee, or many other possi­
bilities. The basic idea is to raise the effective cost
(including the tax) of petroleum to a level that more
co rrectly reflects the true cost of im porting foreign
oil. This would further lower our im ports; the higher
the tax, the less foreign oil we would use. Such a tax
could then offset other government revenue sources
and thus would not require a net rise in overall taxes.
In Europe, gasoline is subject to much higher taxes

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81

41

than in the United States. As of July 1980, the tax on a
gallon of gasoline was $2.16 in Italy, $1.68 in France,
$1.23 in West Germany, and $1.19 in Great Britain,
in the United States the average tax in May 1980 was
only 14 cents per gallon. Suppose, for example, that
an additional one dollar per gallon tax on gasoline
in the United States were imposed at the expiration of
controls in October 1981. A rough estimate is that this
would induce a fall of 12 to 14 percent in United States
gasoline consumption.21 This would amount to a reduc­
tion of demand between 785,000 and 910,000 barrels
per day, which is 11 to 13 percent of current United
States petroleum imports.
An alternative would be to limit petroleum imports
directly with an import quota.22 With the petroleum
available to the domestic market restricted, the li­
cense to import petroleum would take on value. The
costs associated with securing the import license
then would be added to the imported oil price, raising
the total effective cost of petroleum on the domestic
market, just as a tax would. In this respect, direct
limits on imports would be similar to a tax on petro­
leum.
In another important respect, however, direct quotas
would be much worse since they would seriously
* Price and income elasticities for gasoline demand were estimated
as — 0.27 and 0.68, respectively (see the statistical appendix,
available from the authors), implying a level of gasoline consump­
tion in 1981-111 of 6.4 million barrels per day. The range reported
in the text allows one standard deviation from the mean in the
price elasticity.
22 This analysis of import quotas also generally applies to schemes
for directly rationing petroleum among final users, with the cost of
rationing coupons analogous to the cost of import licenses.

Digitized
FRASER Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81
42for FRBNY


undermine our resistance to future foreign price in­
creases. If exporters raised their price, a petroleum
tax would maintain the desired gap between the
import price and the effective cost of petroleum on
the domestic market, and imports would fall. Under
a quota system, however, imports are essentially pre­
determined. A foreign price increase would simply
reduce the value of the import licenses. Unless the
quota could be automatically adjusted downward
whenever oil prices were raised, the foreign price hike
would be, in a sense, completely subsidized, leaving
domestic petroleum prices unaffected.23 With United
States consumers’ responses eliminated, the sustain­
able price rise associated with each alternative pro­
duction scenario of exporting nations would be greater.
Conclusion
Decontrol is clearly a step in the right direction, but
once that is completed new initiatives to reduce oil
imports will be required. Replacing the current sub­
sidy on oil imports with higher taxes on petroleum
would help move the United States toward this goal.
Unlike quotas, higher petroleum taxes would retain
the United States increased resistance to future for­
eign price hikes. Furthermore, revenues from the pe­
troleum tax would stay in the country and could re­
place other sources of funding for government. Only by
continuing decontrol’s serious initiative against im­
ported oil can the United States realistically pursue
both economic growth and less dependence on foreign
oil.
® If foreign oil prices rose so much that the quotas became irrelevant,
then from that point on price increases would no longer be subsidized.

Paul Bennett, Harold Cole, Steven Dym

Social Security and Savings
Behavior

Among the most important issues facing the United
States economy today is whether existing public policy
discourages saving. A central aspect of the problem
of insufficient saving and capital formation is the role
of the social security system. Many people believe
that the United States social security system serves
to depress the level of saving in the economy. They
point out that a major motivation for saving by individu­
als is to provide income for retirement. If the need for
such saving is reduced because of the existence of
Government-sponsored transfers of income to the el­
derly, then the level of saving may be reduced as well.
The proposition is indeed disturbing because it
implies that growth of the social security system may
result in reduced levels of saving and capital formation
and, as a consequence, lower productivity growth and
real output growth. Clearly, if these trade-offs exist,
the social security system needs to be reexamined.
However, it is first necessary to evaluate the logic and
evidence underlying the proposition. As it turns out,
its veracity is not self-evident on either grounds. The
effect of social security on saving involves a diverse
and complex set of issues, of which retirement saving
is only one. Consequently, the popularity of the propo­
sition that the social security system depresses saving
is not justified.

The author is a professor of economics at New York University
Graduate School of Business Administration. This article was written
while he was a visiting economist at the Federal Reserve Bank
New York. The views expressed do not necessarily reflect those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York.




In addition to private retirement saving, the social
security system can affect a broad range of household
decisions. Thus, its effects on savings behavior remain
ambiguous. In particular, social security may affect
retirement decisions by inducing earlier retirement, in
which case saving during working years may be in­
creased. Additionally, social security interacts with a
whole variety of household investment decisions, such
as those involving human capital— schooling, job train­
ing, health, etc. In this context, social security, which
reduces the need for retirement saving, may lead to a
shift in the composition of saving toward human capi­
tal investments. Any apparent negative effect of social
security on saving, then, may be because broad areas
of capital formation are omitted from measured saving.
A related issue, which also implies that social security
has a potentially ambiguous effect on saving, is the
way in which social security affects the level of intergenerational transfer payments, such as gifts and
bequests to children by parents and support to elderly
parents by their adult children.
Finally, even if the hypothesis that social security
reduces savings incentives is true, it is important to
consider fully the effects on society of any changes
in the social security system. The usually suggested
remedy for the savings offset of the existing social
security system is to reduce benefits or to increase
social security taxes. Both of these could have pro­
found effects on the level of economic activity and the
distribution of income. In the light of these broad
consequences, it is not clear that the suggested
changes in the system are warranted.

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81

43

The social-security-depresses-saving proposition
The argument why social security substitutes for pri­
vate saving is deceptively simple. It is best explained
by examining the lifetime patterns of households’ con­
sumption and saving. Typically, individuals’ earnings
increase with work experience and then decline at
retirement. By saving during the most productive years
and dissaving during retirement, individuals can main­
tain a smooth pattern of consumption over their life­
time.1 If income increases with age until retirement,
while consumption is relatively constant, then there
are periods of dissaving early in life and after retire­
ment and a period of saving during mid-life.
With such a lifetime allocation, consumption de­
pends on total wealth or command over resources
rather than being constrained by income at any par­
ticular time. In this context, the concept of wealth is a
broad one. In addition to net financial assets and
physical assets, wealth includes the present values of
future earnings and of benefits to be received from
the social security system. These latter items are the
value today of earnings or benefits to be received in
the future. They are included in wealth because they
are part of the individual’s lifetime command over
economic resources. When social security benefits
are increased, every individual’s overall wealth or life­
time command over resources also increases. As a
result, the typical individual will raise the current level
of consumption. Thus, an increase in social security
benefits is an increase in wealth which can lead the
typical household to reduce the proportion of current
income that is saved.
The relationship is not, however, quite so simple. It
is complicated by the existence of social security
taxes, by the effect of social security on retirement de­
cisions, by the role of intergenerational transfer pay­
ments, and by the interaction of social security with
human capital investment decisions. An examination of
these issues reveals that an increase in social security
benefits can cause either an increase or a decrease
in personal saving. Ultimately, the question of whether
social security reduces saving must be settled by em­
pirical investigation. However, the existing empirical
evidence does not address all the issues raised.
Social security taxes
The role of social security taxes will be examined
first. If the social security system were fully funded,
which means that the present value liabilities of the

1 In the economics literature, this approach is known as the life-cycle
theory of consumption. For a more complete development see, for
example, Rudiger Dornbusch and Stanley Fischer, M a c ro e c o n o m ic s
(New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc., 1978), pages 146-54.


44 FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81


system are offset exactly by its assets, an increase in
future retirement benefits would be matched by an
equivalent increase in lifetime tax liabilities. The typi­
cal individual pays taxes that accumulate in a social
security fund. At retirement, this fund is just large
enough to pay out retirement benefits over the ex­
pected remaining lifetime. In the case of such a fully
funded system, the individual’s wealth and therefore
savings behavior would be unaffected by a benefit
change. This is because a benefit increase which
adds to wealth would be offset by wealth-reducing
increases in taxes.2
Although the social security system as originally
envisioned was a fully funded system, this is no longer
the case. Generally speaking, social security taxes are
set at a level sufficient to pay for current benefits.
Since both the size of the population and labor pro­
ductivity are growing, taxes levied to provide current
benefits are less than the present value of future bene­
fits. Thus, expansion in benefits has increased the
net social security wealth held by those currently
alive. The opposite effect can occur, if the retired
population is large relative to the working population
or if benefits accrue to nonearners. It is then possible
that an expansion in the benefit structure can require
tax increases for current workers, which are more
than equivalent to the increase in their expected bene­
fits. Changes in the age structure of the population
after the year 2000 are likely to bring such a situa­
tion about, since the number of retirees will be ap­
proaching the size of the working population.
Retirement decisions
Social security can also affect the decision to work.
The current system provides strong inducement to
retire at age 65 because retirement benefits are re­
duced by about 50 cents for every dollar earned over
a certain ceiling for those under age 72. Thus, the
social security system induces people to retire earlier.
To take advantage of the benefit structure, individuals
may accumulate additional assets during their working
years to provide more retirement income. With a
shorter working life, and the prospect of only partial
earnings replacement from social security, wage earn­
ers may increase their pre-retirement saving.
Thus, for the typical worker, an increase in the social
security benefit structure has a wealth effect which
reduces saving and a retirement effect which increases
2 This argument also relies upon some additional rather heroic assump­
tions, often favored by economists but hardly likely to be true. For
example, the rate at which individuals discount future benefits must
be equal to the rate of return on saving. In a complex world where
taxes and financial market imperfections intervene, individuals may
not be indifferent to present taxes as opposed to equivalent future
benefits.

saving. However, it is unlikely that the additional
saving due to induced earlier retirement would be as
large as the saving replaced by the social security
system. This is because social security benefits are
likely to be received for a number of years, while re­
tirement is likely to be only a few years earlier than
it would be in the absence of social security. Thus,
the value of benefits will be larger than the additional
saving needed for earlier retirement. This comparison
assumes that individuals have a clear perception of
the magnitude of the increase in wealth due to changes
in social security benefits. Such an assumption is un­
warranted as the benefits to be received by an in­
dividual are not known with certainty; they depend
on his or her earnings and length of life. Thus, the
effect of social security on the age of retirement can
have important implications for savings behavior.
The induced retirement effect of the social security
system has an ambiguous effect on aggregate saving
for an additional reason. The retirement effect would
change the savings behavior of workers and also in­
crease the relative size of the nonworking population.
The total effect on the income and saving of the en­
tire population has not been explored.
Intergenerational transfers
The discussion of lifetime planning of consumption
patterns did not refer to bequests or to private inter­
generational transfers of income. These phenomena
are widely observed in the real world, and the latter
one is of particular concern. Intergenerational transfers
of income may well be an important means of provid­
ing for retirement. Thus, Government provision of re­
tirement income through the social security system
may substitute for private intergenerational income
transfers rather than substituting for the intragenerational deferral of consumption (retirement saving).3 To
be specific, a situation can be envisioned where, in the
absence of social security, elderly persons are pro­
vided for by income transfers from their working chil­
dren. With a social security system, the working chil­
dren make tax payments instead of direct transfers
and retirement income for the parents Is provided by
the Government. It is conceivable that the two systems
are equivalent and the disposable income and saving
of both parents and children are the same in each
case.

3 This idea has been emphasized by Robert Barro, "Are Government
Bonds Net Wealth?”, J o u rn a l o f P o litic a l E c o n o m y (Novem ber/
December 1974), pages 1095-1118. However, aggregate social
security benefits are so large that it is difficult to imagine that, in
the absence of social security, private transfers would approach the
same magnitude.




This is an important possibility because it suggests
that social security has displaced private transfers
rather than private saving and capital formation. The
consequences for saving of such an income redistri­
bution have not been adequately explored but are
probably less severe than the wealth effects indicated
by the life-cycle approach.
Along these lines, it is interesting to note that the
social security system may have widespread influ­
ences on the living patterns of the elderly and the re­
lationship between the generations. For example, so­
cial security may encourage the elderly to live alone
rather than to share living arrangements with the
young. Alternatively, social security may be viewed as
a social response to these changes in mores.
Social security and human capital
The final complication to the basic life-cycle propo­
sition that social security offsets private saving involves
an important element of household savings decisions
and lifetime planning that is by and large overlooked
in discussions of the social security system. That is,
the interaction between social security and capital
formation in the form of human capital investments.4
Introducing human capital, particularly investments in
education, adds a degree of complexity that has not
been explored. This is a serious omission since it is
possible that the interaction of human capital invest­
ments with social security is strong.
The strength of the relationship is suggested by the
similarities between human capital wealth and social
security wealth. Both are nonfungible assets, unlike the
financial and physical assets which are viewed as
social security substitutes in existing empirical studies.
Thus, it is possible that the relationship between these
types of assets is as important as their relationship
to the standard forms of saving. Additional similarities
are that human capital investments, along with re­
tirement saving, are an important form of life-cycle
planning by the family unit and, also, that human capi­
tal investments are an important form of intergenera­
tional transfers.
It is not evident whether social security wealth
and human capital investments should be viewed as
substitute or complementary assets. In the first case,
social security which provides retirement income could
be viewed as an alternative to educating one’s chil­
dren so that they will have the income to provide re­
tirement support to their parents. This does not seem
to be the appropriate argument because the tendency

4 Sherwin Rosen suggests the possibility of a relationship in “Social
Security and the Economy'', T h e C ris is in S o c ia l S e c u rity (San
Francisco, California: Institution for Contemporary Studies, 1977).

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81

45

to invest in human capital has increased a great deal
since the inception of social security. It is more likely
that social security wealth and human capital are com­
plementary assets. In this case, the advent of the so­
cial security system, which reduced the burden of
saving for retirement, made it possible for the typical
individual to devote more resources to saving in the
form of human capital.5
Although these hypotheses have not been tested,
perhaps an effect of the social security system has
been to induce the household sector to channel its
resources into human capital investments. Thus, by
standard measures, saving did decline, although,
due to increases in human capital investments, overall
capital formation need not have declined. This argu­
ment does not obviate the entire issue, if policymakers
feel that the induced move from physical to human
capital formation has been excessive.
There is yet another interrelation between social
security and human capital investments. An individual
can provide for retirement by accumulating ordinary
assets over his working life or by investing in educa­
tion with the hope that the returns to human capital
investment will provide retirement income. As the
returns to human capital investments are highly vari­
able among individuals, there may well be a preference
for a less risky means of lifetime planning. Since so­
cial security reduces the risk of being without income
in one’s old age, it may encourage individuals to make
investments in human capital.
Because of the unavailability of data, there have not
been any empirical studies of the relationship of social
security to both private intergenerational transfers and
investments in human capital. Although there is some
evidence indicating that financial support from chil­
dren to parents is relatively small, it is not clear
whether this is a consequence of social security. Data
on intergenerational transfers of human capital and
the relationship between human capital and other
forms of wealth are almost totally lacking.
Social security policy
If the proposition that social security depresses saving
is in fact true, then some changes in social security
policy would be appropriate.6 Supporters of the propo­
sition have suggested changes in the way in which the

5 An elaboration of this argument is found in "Social Security and
Investment in Human Capital" by Thomas F. Pogue and L.G. Sgontz,
N a tio n a l T a x J o u rn a l (June 1977), pages 157-70. They also present
some empirical evidence that the advent of social security has
increased human capital investments.
4 For a complete review of all the policy issues, see Bruno Stein, S o c ia l
S e c u rity a n d P e n s io n s In T ra n s itio n (New York: Free Press, 1980).

Digitized
FRASER Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81
46 forFRBNY


system is financed. However, such modifications would
have additional undesirable effects on the economy. In
general terms, the overall issue is whether the system
should be one of intergenerational transfers, essen­
tially pay as you go, or whether it should be a fully
funded annuity system.
As the social security system grew, it evolved into a
pay-as-you-go system. The trust fund of Government
securities, which accumulated in the early years when
there were few beneficiaries relative to workers sub­
ject to the payroll tax, eroded as the Congress in­
creased benefits. An error made when the 1972 Social
Security Act was drafted, compounded the problem by
double-indexing the benefit structure.7 Without large
increases in payroll taxes, the trust fund was well on
its way to bankruptcy. This was rectified by the
amendments legislated in 1977 which put social se­
curity back on a sound pay-as-you-go system.8
Changes in the demographic structure of population
over the next fifty years will still put serious financing
strains on the system. After the year 2000, there will
be a substantial growth of the population above re­
tirement age relative to the working-age population.
The number of persons retired as a percentage of the
working population will increase from the present level
of about 19 percent to about 30 percent in 2030. The
increase will not start until after 2000 and will be even
larger if fertility continues at its present low level.
Thus, there is a long-term problem of an increasing
burden on financing social security pensions, even
though the amendments in 1977 reduced the immediate
crisis by stopping the growth of the so-called replace­
ment rate. The replacement rate— the ratio of the
median pension benefit at retirement to the median
wage prior to retirement— had increased from about
0.3 to over 0.4 in the 1970s because of the indexing
procedures. The current legislation will maintain the
rate at a constant level of about 0.42. If it had con­
tinued to increase, much larger increases in the pay­
roll tax would have been necessary.
Proponents of the social-security-retards-privatecapital-formation proposition argue that the system

7 The problem arose from linking both benefits paid and the wage base
used to determine initial benefits to changes in consumer prices.
8 The system is still not without its financial problems. There is con­
siderable pressure in the Congress to roll back the scheduled increases
in the payroll tax rate. In addition, continued high inflation could
create a cash flow problem for the trust funds by the mid-1980s. In
either case, short-run financing from general revenues may be neces­
sary. For a historical analysis of the social security system, see Martha
Dethrick, P o lic y M a k in g fo r S o c ia l S e c u rity (Washington, D.C.: The
Brookings Institution, 1979) and Rita Campbell, S o c ia l S e c u rity
P ro m is e a n d R e a lity (Stanford, California: Hoover Institution Press,
Stanford University, 1977).

should pay pensions from an actuarially appropriate
trust fund, rather than on a pay-as-you-go basis. In
this case, social security wealth would not be fictional
but instead would be backed by existing assets. Such
a proposal would require substantial tax increases for
the fund to accumulate sufficient assets. In essence,
there would have to be a larger Government surplus on
the consolidated budget as the trust fund accumulated
outstanding Government debt. The idea behind this is
that it would release funds to the private capital mar­
kets. However, the effect of such tax increases, in the
short run, on aggregate demand and output could be
devastating. A basic lesson of Keynesian macroeco­
nomics is that, although a surplus reduces government
demands on the capital market, it can induce a reces­
sion and lower the overall private-sector demand for
capital goods. These latter caveats are understood by
the proponents of the trust fund approach who argue
that social security should move toward a funded sys­
tem gradually, as short-term macroeconomic policy
permits.
The idea that social security should be funded can
be criticized on additional grounds best explained
by describing the development of the system.9 When
the social security system began, the initial generation
of beneficiaries received a considerable net transfer
since their benefits exceeded their payments. If the
argument is that this reduced their saving, then the
current generation is producing with a deficiency in
the capital stock. By increasing taxes and further de­
creasing the standard of living of the current genera­
tion, we may in the long run be able to accumulate a
fund and also make up the capital deficiency. This
transition may take several generations but, from then
on, the system will be funded in the sense that each
generation’s benefits are the taxes it accumulated plus
interest. Such a proposal imposes the burden of reduc­
ing consumption to accumulate a fund on the current
generation. This was not viewed as desirable forty
years ago when the system conferred benefits on the
initial generation and does not seem any more ap­
propriate now.
If the current capital stock is considered deficient,
there are many other policy approaches to influencing
the level of investment, including reduced taxation
o f capital income. If there is concern about making
the overall tax structure less progressive, it hardly
seems appropriate to use payroll tax increases to in­

♦The line of argument that follows draws upon the discussion by
Mordecai Kurz and Marcy Arvin in "Social Security and Capital
Formation: The Funding Controversy” , W o rk in g P a p e rs of the
President’s Commission on Pension Policy, 1979.




fluence capital formation. There is no specific reason
why a society has to make up any capital stock defi­
ciency that developed when intergenerational trans­
fers were introduced. It is instead a question of equity
and fairness in the design of an overall tax system.
Clearly, changes in the distribution of the tax burden
promote capital formation, but a society with a concept
of distributional equity might not make such choices.
Perhaps the most telling blow to the proposal of
funding is its impracticality. At current benefit levels
and interest rates, the fund would have to approach
$1,000 billion, more than the total privately held public
debt. Even a gradual fund accumulation would require
large changes in the tax structure, with distributional
consequences that are not likely to appeal to the
public or political decision-making bodies. The cur­
rent generation is not likely to volunteer to reduce
its living standard substantially in order to enlarge the
productive capital stock for its heirs. Rather than
dwelling upon the relative merits of a pay-as-you-go
or funded transfer system, perhaps society should
address the issues concerning taxation and capital
formation directly.
Review of the evidence
One of the most problematic aspects of the hypothesis
that social security curtails saving and capital forma­
tion is that casual observation of structural develop­
ments in the economy since the inception of the social
security system provides scant evidence of any such
effect. In a sense, the legislation created vast sums of
wealth in the economy while the physical assets in
’ the country were unchanged. Over time, one would
expect major adjustments in the structure of the econ­
omy in response to these changes. If there has been
an effect on saving, researchers should also be able to
detect the effect on capital intensity and on the rates
of return to capital. For example, the creation of social
security wealth makes physical assets relatively scarce
which should lead to larger returns on such assets.
Similarly, if social security displaces saving, some
downward secular trend in rates of saving and capital
formation should have emerged. However, economists
have not observed either phenomenon.10 It would be
difficult to argue that savings rates have been remark­
ably steady because increased real returns have offset
the depressing effects of social security. Most econo­
mists have argued that, if anything, real returns to

i# There is evidence that the rate of return to schooling, a major com­
ponent of human capital investments, increased for many years and
declined in recent years. This could support the interaction between
social security and human capital suggested earlier.

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81

47

capital have declined in the postwar period.11
More formal tests of the proposition that social
security depresses saving have been conducted,
largely in the context of the life-cycle approach, dis­
cussed earlier, which showed that wealth is a key de­
terminant of consumption. Econometricians attempt to
measure the impact of social security on saving and
consumption by specifying an equation that relates
consumption expenditure to social security wealth. So­
cial security is a savings depressant if the estimated
impact of social security wealth on consumption is
positive and can be statistically distinguished from a
zero effect. A brief description of the results follows.
A fuller, but still nontechnical, summary is presented
in the accompanying appendix.
Current interest in the effect of social security on
saving was sparked by Martin Feldstein’s 1974 econo­
metric study.12 His conclusion that there is a very
strong depressing effect has been the basis for all
discussion and argument since then. However, an at­
tempt by Dean R. Leimer and Selig D. Lesnoy of the
Social Security Administration to replicate his data
uncovered a data error.13 When the—social security
wealth variable is corrected, the results are strik­
ingly different. Feldstein’s conclusion that social secu­
rity has reduced personal saving by one half and the
stock of capital by one third is completely unsubstan­
tiated with the corrected data. This is important be­
cause the enormous depressing effect on saving has
been widely quoted and supported by many econo­
mists for six years.
Empirical studies have also attempted to measure
the effect on labor supply and retirement decisions.
Social security may affect saving because it provides an
incentive for retirement. The advent of social security
makes much of the working public plan for retirement
by increasing their saving during working years. Alicia
Munnell’s tests of this hypothesis found that the siz­
able decline in the labor force participation rate for
men aged 65 and over (from just under 50 percent
when social security was introduced to less than 25
percent by the mid-1970s) had a substantial positive

effect on saving. Even if this entire increase were at­
tributed to social security, the induced increase in
saving would offset only about one half of the reduc­
tion of saving due to social security wealth.14
Clearly, it is difficult to make definite judgments
based on aggregate savings data. Since economists
do not conduct controlled experiments, it may not be
possible to determine what the world would be like
without the social security system. The historical com­
parison of the present economy with the depression
era may be inadequate for isolating the effect of the
creation of the social security system from all the
other changes in the structure of the economy over
the past forty years.
There are two other types of data which also can
be used to investigate the effects of the social security
system on saving: data on the savings behavior of dif­
ferent individuals (cross-section data) and data on the
savings behavior in different countries.
Cross-section data have been used to investigate the
effect of differences among individuals in private pen­
sion plans and social security benefits and taxes on
savings behavior. The evidence concerning the wealth
effect of social security on saving is weak.15 Lawrence
Kotlikoff suggests that the savings offset predicted by
theory is not found in the data because individuals
are unable to forecast their social security benefits and
their age^of retirement. Others argue that reduced intergenerational transfers and induced retirement ef­
fects of social security are unlikely to offset the nega­
tive effect of social security on wealth accumulation.
However, even the cross-section results, indicating that
individuals with relatively higher social security save
less, do not necessarily imply that, after aggregation
over the entire population, an increase in the scale of
the social security program reduces total saving.
Another path of empirical investigation examines
differences in both savings behavior and social secu­
rity systems among countries. Virtually all industrial­
ized nations have some form of government-sponsored
program for transfers to the elderly. Since the cross­
national differences in savings behavior are large,
some analysts have asked whether these differences
in savings behavior are to any extent due to differ­
ences in social security benefits. Most recently, Robert

11 It should also be noted that social security is only one type of
fictional wealth. Social security wealth— the present value of future
benefits— is fictional because it is not matched either by future con­
tributions or by the expected earnings from existing assets. The vast
unfunded liabilities of private (for some large corporations such
liabilities exceed net worth) and government (civil service, military,
etc.) pension systems are also forms of fictional wealth. Even more
than social security, these wealth components have grown very rapidly
in recent years, without any obvious effect on aggregate saving.

14 In the Munnell study, “The Effect of Social Security on Personal
Savings" (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Ballinger Publishing Co.,
1974), the income coefficient in the consumption relation depended
on the labor force participation rate for men aged 65 and over.

12 "Social Security, Induced Retirement, and Aggregate Capital
Accumulation” , J o u rn a l o f P o litic a l E c o n o m y (September/October
1974), pages 905-26.
w Their results were presented to the annual meeting of the American
Economic Association in Denver, September 5-7, 1980. For a report,
see “ Economic Diary", B u s in e s s W e e k (September 22, 1980).

w For example, see the studies by Lawrence Kotlikoff, “Testing the
Theory of Social Security and Life Cycle Accumulation” , A m e ric a n
E c o n o m ic R e v ie w (June 1979), pages 396-410, and by Martin
Feldstein and Anthony Pellechio, “Social Security and Household
Wealth Accumulation, New Microeconomic Evidence", T h e R e v ie w
o f E c o n o m ic s a n d S ta tis tic s (August 1979), pages 361-68.

48for FRASER
FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81
Digitized


Barro and Glen McDonald examined the effect of inter­
national differences in the ratio of real social security
benefits per person over 65 to real income per capita
on savings rates.16 They conclude that available cross­
national data are not rich enough to allow any infer­
ences about the effect of social security on saving.
At this juncture, it is useful to draw some conclu­
sions concerning the em pirical evidence on the effect
of social security on savings behavior. One can only say
that there is some highly tentative em pirical support for
the hypothesis that social security substitutes for pri­
vate retirem ent saving. Since private retirem ent saving
represents wealth accum ulation which results in capi­
tal form ation, w hile unfunded social security programs
are backed only by the accum ulation of “ fictio n a l”
wealth, it is possible that overall capital form ation is
depressed. However, there is a complex set of other
effects of social security which makes it impossible to
give unqualified support to this hypothesis. These ef­
fects that the em pirical literature has been unable
to isolate adequately include retirem ent decisions,
the private provision of pensions, other form s of intergenerational transfers, and other types of capital for­
mation.
Conclusions
Although this discussion of social security involves a
com plex and diverse set of issues, two threads do
seem to emerge.
Social security should not, at this juncture, be
viewed as a substitute fo r private retirem ent saving.
The issue is an em pirical one, and the existing evi­
dence offers only some tentative statistical support for
the hypothesis. Furthermore, the evidence is deficient
because it omits any serious consideration of the
complex relationships between social security and
other forms of intergenerational transfers, such as hu­
man capital investments.
The unfunded, or pay-as-you-go, public transfer sys­
tem should not be viewed as the cu lp rit that has
caused a lower than desired capital stock and lag­
ging productivity growth. Social security is just one
part of an overall system of public expenditure and
income redistribution that interacts with private sav­
ings decisions in many ways. The desirability of in­
ducing more capital form ation is a broad policy issue
that should be dealt with in a larger fram ework, par­
ticu la rly since the extent of any capital form ation
effect of social security is, as yet, uncertain.
14 "S ocial Security and Consumer Spending in an International Cross
S ection” , J o u rn a l o f P u b lic E c o n o m ic s (A ugust 1979), pages 275-89.




Appendix: The Effect of Social Security on Saving
T h e re have been s e veral e m p iric a l studies of th e e ffect
of so cial s e cu rity on

saving w h ich fail to re a c h

any

consensus. A th o ro u g h te c h n ic a l survey of th e s e stu d ies
w as

m ade, one by Louis E spo sito,

S e cu rity

on S avin g:

R eview

S tates T im e S e rie s D a ta ” ,

“ E ffect o f S o cial

of S tu d ie s

U sing

U nited

Social Security Bulletin

(M a y

19 78), p a ges 9-17, and one by N. B u le n t G u ltek in and
D en nis Lo gu e, “ S o cial S e c u rity and P erso n al S avin g :
S urvey

and

N ew

Private Saving,

Social Security versus

E v id e n c e ” ,

G e o rg e M . von F u rs ten b erg , ed . (C a m ­

b rid g e, M a ssac h u setts: B a llin g e r P u b lishing C o., 19 80).
A brief, n o n tech n ica l su m m ary of th e m eth o d o lo g y, re ­
sults, and so u rces of th e d is a g re e m e n t is p res en ted here.
T h e re is b ro a d a g re e m e n t am o n g ec o n o m ists ab ou t
th e

g e n eral s p e c ific a tio n

of a life -c y c le

consu m p tio n

fu nction es tim a te d from tim e se rie s d a ta . T y p ic a lly , it
ta k e s the fo llow ing fo rm :
C t — ao - f on

Y D t + a s Y D t_i - f o i W t - f a * S S W t + n t

w h ere :
C =

real p e r c a p ita co n su m p tio n ex p e n d itu re s ,

YD =

real p e r c a p ita d isp o sab le p e rsonal in com e,

W =

real per c a p ita p e rsonal s e c to r net w orth,

SSW =

real per c a p ita so cial s e cu rity w e a lth , and

Mt =
The

resid ual o r e rro r te rm .

p a ra m e te r

es tim a te s

e n a b le

the

to p re d ic t th e e ffe c t on co nsu m p tio n

e c o n o m e tric ia n
(and

hence

on

saving) of th e v a ria b le s on th e rig h t-h an d sid e of the
eq u atio n . For th e qu estio n being c o n s id e re d — th e effect
of so cial

s e cu rity

on

sa vin g — th e

c o e ffic ie n t on

the

S S W v a ria b le d e fin e d in th e te x t is o f c ru c ia l in terest.
T h e e c o n o m e tric lite ra tu re in clud es m any va ria tio n s on
th is eq u atio n , and th e re is so m e co n tro v ersy co n ce rn in g
w h ich , if any, a d d itio n a l e x p la n a to ry va ria b le s should be
in clu d ed

in th e co n su m p tio n re latio n sh ip . T h is is im ­

p o rtan t b e c a u s e th e c o e ffic ie n t o f S S W is sensitive to
th e inclusion of o th e r v a ria b le s , such as th e u n em p lo y­
m ent rate, and to c h a n g e s in th e tim e p erio d of histo ric al
d a ta used fo r es tim atio n .
Im p o rta n t fo r e v alu a tin g th e m a g n itu d e of an y p a r­
tic u la r c o e ffic ie n t is th e c o n c e p t of statis tica l sig n ifi­
cance.

W ith o u t

providin g

a

te c h n ic a l

e x p la n a tio n ,

a

c o e ffic ie n t is s ta tis tic a lly s ig n ifican t if th e results p ro ­
vid e reaso n a b ly su b stan tial e v id e n c e th a t th e e s tim ated
co efficien t differs from ze ro . C h a n g e s in th e s p e c ific a ­
tion of an e q u atio n ca n a ffe c t both th e m a g n itu d e of
th e co efficien ts, as sta te d a b o ve , as w ell as th e ir statis­
tic a l sig n ifican ce. In o u r co ntext, social s e c u rity is a
saving s d e p re s s a n t if th e c o e ffic ie n t on S S W is po sitive

(i.e.,

in c re a s e s in S S W raise co n su m p tio n ) and sig n ifi­

ca n tly d iffe re n t from zero .

Paul Wachtel

FRBNY Q uarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81

49

August-October 1980 Interim Report
(This report was released to the Congress
and to the press on December 3, 1980.)

Treasury and Federal Reserve
Foreign Exchange Operations

Coming into the August-October period under review,
exchange market participants remained cautious about
the outlook for the dollar. Traders were encouraged
by the improving trend in the United States current ac­
count, which had swung from deep deficit to near
balance and was expected to move into surplus by late
1980. At the same time, however, they were concerned
about the outlook for inflation in the United States.
Even though our price indexes were no longer rising as
rapidly as before, inflation remained uncomfortably high
by historical standards and by comparison with infla­
tion rates in many other industrial countries. Moreover,
it was feared that the improvements in our current ac­
count and price performance might prove transitory to
the extent that they stemmed from the sharp recession
which had emerged in the United States earlier in
1980. Meanwhile, discussion of possible tax cuts or of
an easing of monetary policy had generated concern
in the market that heavy stimulus to the economy
might undercut the anti-inflation effort. For its part,
the Federal Reserve had phased out the special credit
restraints imposed in March, but Chairman Volcker
had made it clear that the Federal Reserve would con­
tinue to adhere to its efforts to slow the growth of money
and credit in the United States by placing primary em­
phasis on bank reserves rather than on interest rates.

A report by Scott E. Pardee. Mr. Pardee is Senior Vice President
in the Foreign Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York and Manager of Foreign Operations for the System Open
Market Account.

50

FRBNY Quarterly Review/Winter 1980-81




By August, United States interest rates were rebound­
ing from their latest lows, and a sudden surge in the
growth of the monetary aggregates gave rise to some
expectations that United States interest rates might
advance even further.
Meanwhile, the market’s uncertainties were not lim­
ited to the outlook for the dollar. Most other major in­
dustrial countries were afflicted with inflation rates
which were too high by their own standards and by
substantial current account deficits which had been
aggravated by the oil price increases of 1979 and early
1980. The authorities had pursued restrictive policies
to deal with these problems. By late summer, eco­
nomic growth was slackening generally, prompting the
authorities in several countries to move cautiously to­
ward a less restrictive policy stance. But they were
reluctant to move too quickly in the direction of ease
in view of the need to fight inflation and their efforts
to keep interest rates sufficiently high to attract funds
from abroad to finance large current account deficits.
As a result, interest rates remained high even as mar­
ket expectations built up that, in view of domestic
economic considerations, an easing of monetary pol­
icy was imminent in several countries.
Consequently, an uneasy atmosphere persisted in
the exchange markets through August and early Sep­
tember as traders sought to assess the implications
of these economic and financial developments here
and abroad. In addition, the sense of unease was
heightened from time to time by political events, such
as general strikes in Poland and continued tensions

in the M iddle East. In this environment, exchange rates
fluctuated widely day to day but few clear trends de­
veloped, with the exception that both sterling and the
Japanese yen were bid up by force of heavy capital
inflows. Among the currencies participating in the join t
float arrangement, the French franc remained near
the top of the band and the German mark near the
bottom.
In the absence of renewed selling pressures on the
dollar, the United States authorities took the oppor­
tunity to acquire currencies to repay debt arising from
earlier intervention and to rebuild balances. Operating
on days in which the dollar was firm or rising, the
United States authorities bought a total of $426.6 m il­
lion equivalent of German marks in the market, either
in New York or in Frankfurt through the agency of the
Bundesbank. Over the same period, the Trading Desk
purchased an additional $453.6 m illion of marks from
correspondents. The Federal Reserve used a portion of
these marks, along with previously acquired balances,
to repay swap debt to the Bundesbank, which was re­
duced from $879.7 m illion at end-July to $362.6 m illion
on September 15. The remaining acquisitions were
added to Treasury balances which increased by $338.1
m illion equivalent. The Federal Reserve also bought
small amounts of French francs and Swiss francs in
the market and from correspondents. On occasions
when the dollar came under selling pressure in Au­
gust, the United States authorities intervened on five
different days, selling a total of $69.6 m illion equiva­
lent of marks, including $53.9 m illion equivalent from
Federal Reserve balances and $15.7 m illion from
United States Treasury balances.
By mid-September, econom ic indications suggested
that the United States was moving out of recession.
Although the upturn was welcomed by the markets, it
dimmed the prospects for further inflation relief in the
near term. Indeed, partly because of rising food prices,
the United States inflation rate was expected to accel­
erate. Moreover, the money and credit aggregates
were growing rapidly. In response to this buildup in
the demand fo r money, the Federal Reserve was act­
ing to constrain the growth of bank reserves. Market
interest rates clim bed sharply, and on September 26
the Federal Reserve raised the discount rate by 1 per­
centage point to 11 percent. Strong demand for money
and credit persisted through October, putting addi­
tional upward pressure on money market rates.
This advance of United States interest rates was not
matched abroad, where, if anything, the authorities
were becoming increasingly concerned about slower
econom ic growth and the prospect of recession. Con­
sequently, interest differentials swung increasingly in
favor of the dollar against most m ajor currencies,




Table 1

Federal Reserve System Drawings and
Repayments under Reciprocal Currency
Arrangements
In m illions of dollars equivalent;
draw ings ( + ) or repayments ( — )
System
swap
com m it­
ments
July 31,
1980

Transactions with
Bank of France

.............

166.3
879.7

German Federal Bank ..

1,046.0

August
through
October 31,
1980

System
swap
com m it­
ments
O ctober 31,
1980

-

165.2*

-0-

-

873.0*

-0-

— 1,038.2*

-0-

Because of rounding, figures may not add to totals.
Data are on a transaction-date basis.
* Repayments include revaluation adjustm ents from swap
renewals, am ounting to $1.1 m illion for draw ings
on the Bank of France and $6.7 m illion for draw ings on the
German Federal Bank w hich were renewed during the period.
Table 2

United States Treasury Securities,
Foreign Currency Denominated
In m illions of dollars equivalent;
issues ( + ) or redem ptions ( — )
Am ount of
com m itments
July 31,
1980

Issues

August
through
O ctober 31,
1980

Amount of
com m it­
ments
October 31,
1980

Public Series
Germany .............................

5,233.6

-0-

5,233.6

Switzerland ........................

1,203.0

-0-

1,203.0

T o t a l.....................................

6,436.6

-0-

6,436.6

Data are on a value-date basis.
Tabie 3

Net Profits ( + ) and Losses ( —) on
United States Treasury and Federal Reserve
Current Foreign Exchange Operations
In m illions of dollars

Federal
Reserve

Period

United States Treasury
Exchange
S tabilization
General
Fund
account

August 1, through
O ctober 31, 1980 .............

+ 1 4 .0

+

0.1

-0-

Valuation profits and
losses on outstanding
assets and lia b ilitie s
as of O ctober 31,1980 . . .

+ 1 2 .7

— 372.8

+ 1 3 8 .8

Data are on a value-date basis.

FRBNY Q uarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81

51

prompting flows of funds into dollar-denom inated as­
sets. Much of this pressure fell on the German mark,
in view of Germany’s low nominal interest rates relative
to rates abroad and Germany’s sizable current account
deficit. Funds were shifted out of marks not only into
dollars but into sterling and French francs as well.
W ithin the European M onetary System (EMS), the Ger­
man mark and the French franc were pushed to their
respective intervention points, and the Bundesbank
and the Bank of France were obliged to absorb sub­
stantial amounts of marks against francs. At the same
time, the EMS currencies as a group declined against
the dollar.
As a result of the flow of funds into dollar assets, the
d o lla r rose in October to end the three-month period
up a net 7 percent against the German mark and other
currencies in the EMS, 31/2 percent against the Swiss
franc, and 1% percent against the Canadian dollar.
Over this same period, sterling rose a net 4% percent
against the dollar and the yen moved up by 7% per­
cent.
With the dollar in demand, the United States author­
ities stepped up th eir acquisitions of currencies to re­
pay debt and rebuild balances. Operations were con­
ducted in New York, Frankfurt, and on occasion in the
Far East. When strong one-way pressures emerged
late in October, the Desk intervened, sometimes force­
fully, in the m arket as a buyer of German marks. Pur­
chases of marks in the spot market totaled $1,770.7
m illion equivalent between mid-September and end-

October. Moreover, as part of the effort to repay debt
and rebuild balances, the United States authorities
purchased a total of $346.6 m illion of marks from cor­
respondents, divided about equally between the Fed­
eral Reserve System and the Treasury, and $132.9
m illion of outright forw ard marks on behalf of the Trea­
sury. As a result, the Federal Reserve was able to
complete liquidation of its swap debt w ith the Bundes­
bank by the end of the period.
In addition to its mark purchases, the United States
authorities bought over the three-m onth period $87.5
m illion equivalent of Swiss francs, including $25 m il­
lion equivalent in the m arket and $62.5 m illion equiva­
lent from correspondents. Of this amount, $62.6 m illion
equivalent was added to System balances and $24.9
m illion equivalent went into Treasury balances. The
Federal Reserve also took advantage of opportunities
to buy $158.6 m illion of French francs to com plete
repayment of its swap debt with the Bank of France.
During the August-O ctober period, the Federal Re­
serve realized $14 m illion in profits on its foreign
exchange operations and the Exchange Stabilization
Fund (ESF) realized $0.1 m illion. As of the end of the
period, the Federal Reserve showed valuation profits
of $12.7 m illion on its foreign exchange assets w hile
the ESF showed valuation losses of $372.8 m illion on
its foreign exchange assets. The Treasury’s general
account showed valuation profits, related to the out­
standing issues of securities denominated in foreign
currencies, of $138.8 m illion.

SELECTED PAPERS OF ALLAN SPROUL
The Federal Reserve Bank of New York has released a
representative selection of the published and unpublished
w ritings of its third chief executive officer in a 254-page
book entitled “ Selected Papers of Allan Sproul” . The book,
w hich includes a biographical essay, was edited by Lawrence
S. Ritter, Professor of Finance at New York University.
A copy is available on request from :
Public Information
33 Liberty Street
New York, N.Y. 10045

52

FRBNY Q uarterly R eview /W inter 1980-81




Subscriptions to the Quarterly Review are free. M ultiple copies in reasonable
quantities are available to selected organizations for educational purposes. Single
and m ultiple copies for United States and fo r other Western Hemisphere sub­
scribers are sent via th ird - and fourth-class mail, respectively. All copies for
Eastern Hemisphere subscribers are a irlifted to Amsterdam, from where they are
forw arded via surface mail. M ultiple-copy subscriptions are packaged in envelopes
containing no more than ten copies each.
Quarterly Review subscribers also receive the Bank’s Annual Report.




Library of Congress Catalog Card Number: 77-646559