View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

159

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

Treasury and Federal Reserve Foreign Exchange Operations*
By

Charles

During the first four months of 1967, sterling staged a
strong recovery while international financial markets gen­
erally moved into better balance as inflationary pressures
receded and credit conditions eased. Toward the end of
May, unfortunately, the sudden eruption of the Middle
East crisis jolted confidence in both the gold and foreign
exchange markets. Money immediately flowed in heavy
volume to the traditional haven of Switzerland, thereby
imposing further strain on the Euro-dollar market from
which funds were already being withdrawn in anticipation
of midyear liquidity requirements. Sterling also came under
pressure, reflecting concern that Britain might prove par­
ticularly vulnerable to adverse developments in the Middle
East. In the gold market, fears that the Middle East hos­
tilities might develop into a broader conflict briefly, but
strongly, intensified speculative buying, already influenced
by public discussions of United States gold policy, the
Treasury’s suspension of silver sales, alternating reports
of imminent success or failure of negotiations to increase
international liquidity, and tensions in the Far East.
These severe pressures in the gold and exchange mar­
kets in early June brought an immediate central bank
response. To relieve the stringency in the Euro-dollar
market, the Bank for International Settlements (BIS)
drew $143 million on its swap line with the System and
placed these funds in the market. This BIS operation, which
was reversed in July, helped to settle the market and ease
the pressures on sterling resulting from the pull of higher

A.

C oom bs

Euro-dollar rates. At the same time, the United States
authorities, in cooperation with the Bank of England,
acted to absorb sterling from the market by purchasing
spot against forward resale a total of $112.8 million equiv­
alent of sterling. In addition, the Bank of England strength­
ened its own resources by reactivating its swap line
with the Federal Reserve through a drawing of $225 mil­
lion in June. The Federal Reserve made even heavier draw­
ings on its Swiss franc swap lines to absorb the flow of

Table I
FEDERAL RESERVE RECIPROCAL CURRENCY ARRANGEMENTS
August 31, 1967
Institution
Austrian National Bank .....................

100

National Bank of Belgium .................

150

Bank of Canada ...................................

500

National Bank of Denmark ...............

100

Bank of England ...................................

1,350

Bank of France ....................................

100

German Federal Bank .........................

400

Bank of Italy .........................................

600

Bank of Japan .......................................

450

Bank of Mexico .....................................

130

Netherlands Bank .................................

150

Bank of Norway ...................................

100

Bank of Sweden ...................................

100

Swiss National Bank ...........................

250

* This report, covering the period March to September 1967, Bank for International Settlements
is the eleventh in a series of reports by the Vice President in
Swiss francs/dollars .........................
charge of the Foreign function o f the Federal Reserve Bank of
Other European currencies/dollars
New York and Special Manager, System Open Market Account.
The Bank acts as agent for both the Treasury and the Federal Re­
Total .............................................
serve System in the conduct o f foreign exchange operations.




Amount of facility
(in millions of dollars)

250
300
5,030

MONTHLY REVIEW, SEPTEMBER 1967

160

Table

U

DRAWINGS AND REPAYMENTS BY FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
UNDER RECIPROCAL CURRENCY ARRANGEMENTS
M arch 1962-August 1967
In millions of dollars
1962
Institution

First
half

1963

Second
half

Austrian N ational Bank
Drawings ................................................
Repaym ents.............................................

50.0

National Bank of Belgium
Drawings ................................................
Repaym ents............................................

30.5
15.5

First
half

50.0

Bank of France
Drawings ................................................
Repaym ents.............................................

50.0

50.0

10.0
25.0

150.0

Bank of Italy
Drawings ................................................
R epaym ents............................................
Netherlands Bank
Drawings ................................................
Repaym ents.............................................

25.0
25.0

50.0

German Federal Bank
Drawings ................................................
R epaym ents............................................
50.0

10.0

50.0
50.0

Second
half

First
half

15.0

15.0

Second
half

First
half

Second
half

First
half

JulyAugust

Total

145.0
100.0

65.0
50.0

85.0
110.0

35.0

30.0
30.0

37.5
10.0

92.5

510.5
390.5
20.0
20.0

10.0
10.0

85.0
85.0

21.5
12.5

9.0

136.0
226.0

55.0
115.0

Drawings
outstanding
on
August 31,
1967

50.0

100.0

15.0
65.0

140.0

250.0
82.0

100.0
168.0

100.0

140.0

546.0
546.0

325.0
310.0

15.0

725.0
725.0

50.0
10.0

100.0
70.0

80.0

100.0

25.0
25.0

65.0
30.0

35.0

50.0

80.0
5.0

25.0
100.0

150.0
90.0

60.0

75.0
60.0

60.0

40.0

480.0
447.0

210.0
403.0

80.0
25.0

55.0

150.0
5.0

145.0

310.5
190.5

235.0
265.0

532.5
348.5

80.0
464.0

dollars to Switzerland, while the Gold Pool kept the Lon­
don gold market price under firm control.
Although the immediate disturbances in the gold and
exchange markets associated with the Middle East crisis
were thus quickly dealt with, international financial mar­
kets remained uneasy during succeeding months while
short-term funds continued to move across the exchanges
in response to differentials in interest rates and credit con­
ditions. Recurrent pressures on sterling, for example,
seemed to reflect interest rate differentials marginally un­
favorable to London, as well as hedging. At the close of
August, the successful conclusion of the Group of Ten
discussions on international liquidity brought about some
covering of short positions in sterling while also relieving
speculative buying pressure on the London gold market.
As in the past, dollar rates in the exchange markets

120.0

71.5
71.5

50.0

Bank for International Settlements
Drawings ................................................
Repaym ents.............................................




First
half

1967

20.0
20.0

50.0

110.0

Second
half

1966

50.0
50.0

Swiss National Bank
Drawings ................................................
Repaym ents.............................................

All banks
Drawings ................................................
Repaym ents............................................

1965

50.0

Bank of Canada
Drawings ................................................
R epaym ents............................................
Bank of England
Drawings ................................................
Repaym ents............................................

1964

100.0
395.0
100.0

135.0

20.0

420.0
400.0

20.0

185.0
43.0

33.0
17.0

598.0
425.0

173.0

75.0

185.0
75.0

15.0

605.0
405.0

200.0

710.0
430.0

407.5
318.0

160.5 3.631.0
17.0 3.118.0

513.0

were influenced both by the United States balance-ofpayments deficit and the backwash from large shifts of
funds among third countries. The Federal Reserve swap
lines, after having reverted fully to a standby basis last
February, were once again activated in May when the Sys­
tem began a series of drawings on its swap line with the
Belgian National Bank in order to absorb a continuing
influx of dollars into Belgium. Such drawings of Belgian
francs rose to $120 million equivalent by the end of
August, while drawings of $20 million equivalent of Dutch
guilders were also required to absorb dollar acquisitions by
the Netherlands Bank. By far the largest operation, how­
ever, was undertaken in Swiss francs in order to absorb
$390 million that poured into the Swiss National Bank
during May and June. There were only very limited op­
portunities to reverse these operations during the sum-

161

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

sues, partly offset by redemption at maturity of Belgian
franc-denominated bonds totaling $30.2 million, brought
to $1,015.5 million total outstanding issues of United
States Treasury foreign currency obligations (see Table III).

Table III
OUTSTANDING UNITED STATES TREASURY SECURITIES
FOREIG N CURRENCY SERIES
In millions of dollars equivalent

Issued to

Austrian National Bank....
National Bank of Belgium ...

1967
Amount
Issues or redemptions (—) Amount
outstand­
outstand­
Net
ing on
ing on changes
January 1, 1966
July- August 31,
1967
1966
August
II
1
50.3

100.7 — 50.3
30.2

-3 0 .2
477.0

German Federal Bank..........

602.1 -251.5

Bank of Italy..........................

124.8

124.8

257.3 — 46.2

210.8

Swiss National Bank.............
Bank for International
Settlements*...........................
Total...............................

92.6
1,207.8 —348.0

125.5

152.7

60.2
30.0

125.5

1,015.5

Note: Discrepancies in amounts are due to valuation adjustments, refundings,
and rounding.
* Denominated in Swiss francs.

mer months, and at the end of August System swap
drawings outstanding totaled $513 million (see Table II).
Subsequently, in early September the Federal Reserve drew
an additional $5 million under its arrangement with the
National Bank of Belgium and $10 million from the Neth­
erlands Bank.
During the period under review, the Federal Reserve
swap network was expanded and further strengthened. In
May, new swap facilities were negotiated with the cen­
tral banks of Denmark and Norway in the amount of
$100 million each and with the Bank of Mexico for
$130 million. Then in July, against the background
of the Middle East problem, the System negotiated in­
creases in: (1) its Swiss franc swap lines with the Swiss
National Bank and the BIS (each facility being increased
by $50 million to $250 million), and (2) its swap line
with the BIS providing for swaps of dollars against other
European currencies (this facility rising from $200 mil­
lion to $300 million). Thus, the Federal Reserve swap
network now comprises bilateral agreements with fourteen
central banks plus the BIS which provide mutual credit
facilities totaling $5,030 million.
In April and May, the United States Treasury issued
to the BIS certificates of indebtedness denominated in
Swiss francs, the proceeds of which ($60.2 million equiva­
lent) were used to reduce third-currency swaps negotiated
with the BIS last February to liquidate previous Swiss
franc drawings by the System. In July the Treasury issued
the first of four scheduled AVi-year $125 million notes,
denominated in German marks. These latest security is­




STERLING

During the first quarter of 1967, funds that had fled
from sterling during the summer of 1966 began moving
back at an accelerated pace. By early March, these in­
flows had enabled the Bank of England to liquidate com­
pletely the swap drawings from the Federal Reserve
and to repay fully other sizable special credits from the
Federal Reserve and the United States Treasury. (At their
peak in August of last year, credits from the United
States had reached $750 million. By the end of September
they had been reduced to $575 million through substitution
of other credit facilities.) Announcement of these repay­
ments confirmed to the market the degree of recovery that
had already taken place and triggered a spurt of buying that
gained momentum as the month progressed.
Other developments during March contributed to a
surge of covering of short positions. These included an­
nouncements of (1) renewal of the credit lines from nine
central banks and the BIS, (2) unexpectedly good fourthquarter balance-of-payments figures, (3) a cut in bank rate
from 6 V2 per cent to 6 per cent, which was taken as a sign
of confidence, and (4) the Government’s decision to con­
tinue strict control over price and wage increases through
July 1968. In addition to having repaid early in March its
swap with the Federal Reserve, the Bank of England later
in the month used most of its record reserve gains to repay
other short-term central bank debts. Thus, within a sixmonth period, the Bank of England had repaid $575 mil­
lion to the United States authorities and $720 million to
other parties. Remaining central bank credits linked spe­
cifically to changes in overseas sterling balances were
liquidated early in the second quarter.
The influx of short-term capital continued in April and
early May, though at a diminishing rate. The British
authorities were able to announce a reserve increase of
$145 million in April, as foreign short-term interest rates
continued to fall and the United Kingdom budget message
met with a generally favorable reception. As early as April,
however, some market concern was beginning to be ex­
pressed about the trend in the trade figures, and by early
May covered interest rate comparisons that had tended
to favor London earlier in the year started to turn ad­
verse. Shortly after the announcement on May 4 of the
third cut in bank rate this year, from 6 per cent to 5 V2
per cent, Euro-dollar rates began to firm, despite subse­

162

MONTHLY REVIEW, SEPTEMBER 1967

quent steps toward further monetary ease by several Con­
tinental countries. Moreover, announcement on May 11
that the British trade deficit had jumped from $36 million in
March to $115 million in April was followed a few days
later by President deGaulle’s sharply negative comments
at a press conference on Britain’s application to join the
Common Market. By mid-May the combination of these
adverse factors had led to the first net selling of sterling this
year. Nevertheless, the British authorities proceeded with
their plans to prepay $405 million on May 25 to the Inter­
national Monetary Fund (IM F )— more than half of the
amount due this December under the 1964 drawing—
together with the whole amount ($80 million) borrowed
in 1964 from Switzerland, thus further reestablishing avail­
able credit facilities.
On June 1, market expectations of an imminent out­
break of hostilities in the Middle East sparked a burst
of selling of sterling. Such apprehension of war affected
sterling not only directly but also indirectly through the
Euro-dollar market, where precautionary withdrawals of
funds combined with the usual pressures associated with
midyear window dressing to create a sudden squeeze and a
sharp hike in rates. These dual pressures were immediately
met by a coordinated central bank response in both the
exchange and Euro-currency markets. On June 1 the
United States authorities, in consultation with the Bank of
England, purchased a total of $92.9 million of sterling in
the New York market on a swap basis, buying spot against
forward sales. That same day the BIS began placing in
the Euro-dollar market new dollar funds drawn under its
swap arrangement with the Federal Reserve. By June 7,
when a cease-fire resolution by the United Nations served
to reduce tensions somewhat, the BIS had drawn a total of
$143 million from the System and had placed these dollars,
together with funds received from other central banks, in
the Euro-dollar market. Meanwhile, the United States
authorities had temporarily taken another $20 million of
sterling out of private hands through additional swap pur­
chases in New York. With the cessation of actual hostili­
ties, covering by the market of short positions in sterling
boosted the spot rate from a low of $2.7900 on June 6 to
$2.7932 on June 7 while permitting the Bank of England
to recoup much of the exchange that had been used during
the preceding few days.
As the month progressed, however, rumors that Arab
countries might withdraw sterling balances revived market
anxieties while the announcement at midmonth of disap­
pointing trade figures for May had a further disturbing
effect. Finally, the pull of foreign interest rates, particu­
larly during a brief squeeze in the Euro-dollar market
at the end of June, exerted further pressure. To cushion




the reserve impact of these adverse developments, the
Bank of England drew $225 million during June under its
$1,350 million swap arrangement with the Federal Re­
serve.
SWISS FRANC

During the first half of 1967, Swiss interest rates de­
clined less rapidly than rates outside Switzerland. Indeed,
during much of this period, the Swiss credit market re­
mained relatively tight, and there was on the whole more
incentive for foreigners to pay off previous Swiss franc
borrowings than there was for Swiss residents to place new
funds abroad. Even in the early months of the year, the
reflux to foreign markets of funds repatriated by Swiss
residents at the year-end was less than might have been
expected on the usual seasonal pattern. As a result, the
Federal Reserve was unable to acquire through the market
sufficient francs to pay down completely earlier drawings
under its swap lines with the Swiss National Bank and the
BIS. To liquidate the residual balance of $75 million in
Swiss francs due to the BIS, the United States authorities
in February used $75 million equivalent of sterling bal­
ances to acquire Swiss francs from the BIS on a temporary
swap basis. Subsequently, when the Swiss National Bank
released to the Swiss commercial banks part of their de­
posits that had been blocked since 1961 the banks bought
BIS Swiss franc promissory notes in the amount of $60.2
million equivalent. The BIS placed these francs at the dis­
posal of the United States Treasury, which in exchange
issued certificates of indebtedness denominated in Swiss
francs. The Swiss franc proceeds of these issues were used
to reduce the commitment under the sterling/Swiss franc
swap to $14.3 million equivalent.
In order to forestall a rapid rise in the Swiss franc rate
during March when Swiss banks repatriated funds for
liquidity requirements, the Swiss National Bank announced
early in the month that it would provide Swiss francs
against dollars for end-of-quarter needs through short­
term swaps with the Swiss commercial banks. This was the
first time that the Swiss authorities had offered this facility
other than at midyear and at the year-end. During the
final weeks of March, the central bank took in $221 mil­
lion on this basis and immediately reinvested the money
in the Euro-dollar market to assist in moderating pres­
sures in that market.
Following the end of the quarter, interest rates on ster­
ling and dollar investments continued to decline, while the
unwinding of the Swiss National Bank swaps with its com­
mercial banks tended to tighten the Swiss market once
again. Foreigners, particularly Italians, began to bid for

163

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK
Table IV
DRAW INGS AND REPAYMENTS BY FOREIG N CENTRAL BANKS
U NDER RECIPROCAL CURRENCY ARRANGEMENTS
March 1962-June 1967
In millions of dollars

1962
Institution

First
half

Second
half

National Bank of Belgium

Bank of Canada
Drawings ..............................................................
Repaym ents.................................................... .....

250.0

1964

1963
First
half

Second
half

35.0
25.0

10.0
20.0

First
half

1965

Second
half

First
half

Second
half

First
half

25.0

Bank of Italy
Drawings ..............................................................
R epaym ents....................................................... ...

25.0
50.0

Bank of Japan
D raw in g s..............................................................
R epaym ents..........................................................

15.0 1.355.0 1.215.0
1.170.0 1.055.0

550.0
435.0

175.0
475.0

50.0

250.0

250.0

60.0
25.0

60.0
45.0

First
half

17.6
17.6

267.6
267.6

450.0
275.0

225.0 4.010.0
350.0 3.785.0

Drawings
outstanding
on June 30,
1967

225.0

150.0
150.0

100.0
150.0

80.0
80.0

30.0
80.0

Bank for International Settlements*
D raw in g s................................................ .............
R epaym ents.........................................................
All banks
D raw in g s..............................................................
R epaym ents..........................................................

Second
half

Total

45.0
45.0

250.0

Bank of England
Drawings ..............................................................
Repaym ents..........................................................

1967

1966

165.0 1.385.0 1.215.0
150.0 1.250.0 1.055.0

550.0
435.0

175.0
475.0

285.0
85.0

225.0
282.0

510.0
367.0

143.0

752.6
377.6

450.0 5.062.6
632.0 4.694.6

368.0

* Includes, in addition to drawings in connection with Euro-dollar operations, BIS drawings of dollars against European currencies other than Swiss francs to
meet temporary cash requirements. During the first six months of 1967, such drawings totaled $82 million.

Swiss francs to repay indebtedness previously incurred and
started shifting their borrowings to currencies that were
being lent more cheaply, notably German marks, while
in addition there may have been some net repatriation of
funds by Swiss banks. As a result, the spot rate moved up
from $0.2307Vi at the beginning of April to the effective
ceiling of $0.23 VJV2 by April 26, at which point the Swiss
National Bank became a buyer of dollars for the first time
in 1967. With credit conditions remaining tight and some
nervousness developing about sterling and the prospects
of a Middle East clash, the rate held at or close to the ef­
fective ceiling through most of May, and the Swiss Na­
tional Bank added some $180 million to its reserves. The
prepayment by the Bank of England in May of the $80
million credit extended to it in December 1964 resulted
in equivalent dollar acquisitions by the Swiss National
Bank.
During the first days of June the rumor, and then actual
outbreak, of hostilities in the Middle East precipitated a
heavy flow of funds to Switzerland. The dollar holdings
of the Swiss National Bank, already swollen by the in­
flows in May, jumped by $212 million in the first week of
June. In order to absorb these dollar flows, the Federal




Reserve on June 2 and June 8 drew a total of $370
million equivalent of Swiss francs in equal amounts
under its swap arrangements with the Swiss National Bank
and the BIS; in addition, the Swiss National Bank pur­
chased $30 million of gold from the United States Trea­
sury. Although only a part of the shift of funds to Switzer­
land during this period represented transfers directly out
of sterling, the Swiss authorities were prepared to cooper­
ate with the Bank of England in countering the effects of
such shifts. One by-product of this cooperation was the
acquisition by the Federal Reserve of $28 million equiva­
lent of Swiss francs which were used on June 16 to repay
an equivalent amount of its drawings on the Swiss Na­
tional Bank.
Following the cease fire in the Middle East, the demand
for francs abated, only to pick up again on a moderate
scale just before midyear. Once again, the Federal Reserve
drew on its swap arrangements to absorb these inflows; it
added $33 million to its drawings on the Swiss central
bank and $15 million to its drawings on the BIS, bringing
the total of Swiss franc drawings outstanding on July 3 to
the equivalent of $390 million, out of credit lines then to­
taling $400 million. The drawing on the Swiss National

164

MONTHLY REVIEW, SEPTEMBER 1967

Bank was reduced on July 28 to $180 million, when the
Swiss National Bank purchased $10 million from the Sys­
tem against Swiss francs to meet Swiss official require­
ments. In view of continuing uncertainties in financial
markets and unsettled conditions in the Middle East during
the summer, it was agreed in mid-July that the Federal Re­
serve swap lines in Swiss francs with the Swiss National
Bank and the BIS should be expanded by $50 million each
to a new combined total of $500 million. (At the same
time, the $200 million swap facility with the BIS in Eu­
ropean currencies other than Swiss francs was increased
by $100 million equivalent to $300 million.)
The capital inflows in May and especially in June led to
increased liquidity in Switzerland and eliminated the need
for any special measures, such as short-term swaps, to
meet midyear needs. Indeed, there was some easing in
Swiss interest rates. In order to reinforce this trend, the
Swiss central bank on July 10 reduced its discount rate
from 3V2 per cent to 3 per cent, explaining that the move
was “likely to facilitate the reestablishment of interest rate
differences existing normally between Switzerland and
foreign countries and thus also the reflux abroad of the
excess liquidity registered in the past two months”. Follow­
ing this move, and as Euro-dollar rates became relatively
more attractive, some movement of funds out of Switzer­
land began to develop, and by late August the franc had
eased considerably. When the rate reached $0.2304V&,
the Swiss National Bank began selling dollars to the mar­
ket. The Bank subsequently purchased $7 million from the
System which used the Swiss franc counterpart to reduce
its outstanding drawings in Swiss francs. Such Federal Re­
serve drawings thus amounted to $373 million as of the
end of August.

Following the usual seasonal pattern, there was a sub­
stantial reflow of funds from Germany just after the yearend, and the Federal Reserve was able to acquire in the
market and through special transactions sufficient marks
to liquidate by mid-February the $140 million drawn on
the swap line with the German Federal Bank in December
1966. During March and April, the spot rate generally
held close to its upper limit but the central bank did not
add significantly to its reserves. By mid-May, however,
the mark began to ease as the cumulative influence of
easy money policy induced heavy outflows of commercial
bank funds. At the same time, German firms that had
taken up sizable amounts of funds abroad began making
repayments as credit became more readily available in
Germany.
The easing trend in spot marks became more pro­
nounced toward the end of June, when the German Fed­
eral Bank announced the fourth reduction in reserve
requirements this year. To encourage retention in Ger­
many of this newly released bank liquidity, the German
Federal Bank at the same time altered its pattern of ex­
change market activity. For several months, the central
bank had been concerned that its policy of active ease
had been more successful in stimulating outflows of funds
than in reducing domestic interest rates. By widening its
announced buying and selling rates and permitting a rapid
fall in the spot rate, the central bank sought to increase
the degree of uncertainty about future rate movements,
particularly for those who were investing abroad at very
short term on an uncovered basis. As the spot rate
dropped sharply in early July to just below par, investors
immediately began to purchase forward cover to avoid the
risk of a future rise in the rate and the cost of such cover
back into marks jumped from about 3A per cent for threemonth maturity, for example, to over 1% per cent and
GERMAN MARK
remained close to IV2 per cent through August.
The German economy has been operating at less than
During the period under review, there were discussions
capacity this year, and the slack in domestic activity has between Germany and the United States, together with
been reflected in a substantial drop in imports and buoy­ the United Kingdom, concerning military forces in NATO
ant exports. As a result, the German trade surplus nearly and the balance-of-payments consequences of United
quadrupled from $555 million in the first half of 1966 States and United Kingdom troop deployments in Ger­
to $2.2 billion in the first half of this year. Had it not been many. In early May, the United States authorities released
for the very large outflows of short-term funds stimulated an exchange of letters growing out of these discussions
by the significant easing in German monetary policy, this between the President of the German Federal Bank, Karl
trade surplus could have created severe strains in interna­ Blessing, and the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board,
tional credit markets and the foreign exchange market. William McChesney Martin, Jr., in which the former indi­
Thus, the series of reductions in the discount rate and in cated that the Federal Bank intended to continue its prac­
reserve requirements during the first eight months of this tice of not converting dollars into gold as part of a policy
year, while designed primarily to stimulate the flagging of international monetary cooperation. This statement
domestic economy, were very helpful from an international was made with the agreement of the German Federal
standpoint as well.
Government, which at the same time took note of the




FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

Federal Bank’s intention to purchase $500 million of
United States Government medium-term securities in four
equal quarterly instalments beginning in July. The first
$125 million equivalent German mark security was issued
on July 3.
DUTCH GUILDER

During the early part of 1967, the guilder came on
offer as the Dutch trade balance moved into deficit, pri­
marily due to slackening demand by some of its major
trading partners. At the same time, the recovery of sterling
attracted additional outflows of guilder funds. Under the
circumstances, the Netherlands Bank released dollars to
the market and further reduced its dollar reserves by con­
verting into dollars the guilder tranche of a multicurrency
drawing from the IMF by Spain. The Netherlands Bank
then replenished its dollar reserves by buying $35 million
from the Federal Reserve against guilders. The Federal
Reserve used the guilders to repay by the end of January
the remaining commitment under a $65 million swap draw­
ing made during the summer of 1966.
The Dutch economy continued to ease, and in midMarch the Netherlands Bank reduced its discount rate
from 5 per cent to 4 Vz per cent. (The rate had been
raised to 5 per cent in May 1966 in order to damp down
the then overheated economy.) The move also brought in­
terest rates in the Netherlands more nearly into line with
those in other centers. At the same time, the Netherlands
Bank removed the penalty deposit requirement for banks
exceeding credit ceilings. Despite these moves, money
market conditions in the Netherlands remained tighter
than abroad and Dutch banks withdrew funds from other
markets. Under the circumstances, the Dutch authorities
began to rely increasingly on swap transactions in the ex­
change market—that is the purchase of dollars spot
against forward delivery— as a regular method of relieving
money market pressures. Dollars taken in by the central
bank on a swap basis reached fairly substantial levels be­
ginning in May and rose to a peak of $150 million in
early June.
In the early summer, the backwash of the hostilities in
the Middle East and renewed pressures on sterling domi­
nated the foreign exchange markets. As additional funds
moved into Amsterdam, the guilder rose sharply and the
Netherlands Bank took in dollars both outright and on a
swap basis. Accordingly, at the end of July the Federal
Reserve drew $20 million of guilders under its $150 mil­
lion swap line with the Netherlands Bank and used the
proceeds to absorb an equivalent amount of dollars on the
books of the Dutch central bank. Following a further flow




165

of funds into the Netherlands, in early September the
Federal Reserve made an additional drawing of $10 mil­
lion equivalent.
CANADIAN DOLLAR

During the early part of 1967, movements in the Cana­
dian dollar rate were influenced by fluctuations in the
volume of new Canadian bond flotations in the New York
market and by short-term capital flows. A flurry of new
issues in January, together with the take-down of proceeds
of previous issues and the repatriation of funds from the
United States, more than offset adverse seasonal factors
and the Canadian dollar moved above par ($0.9250)
where it held through mid-February. At the end of Feb­
ruary, as the rate of new external issues abated and ad­
verse seasonal factors asserted themselves, the rate moved
below par and remained there during the rest of winter
and early spring.
The Canadian dollar began moving into a period of sea­
sonal strength late in the spring as grain shipments started
up again. Then in June an increase in the level of bond
issues lent further strength to the Canadian dollar, push­
ing it above par. An additional— although quite temporary
—boost was given to the spot rate when unfounded
rumors of an increase in the Canadian-Russian wheat
agreement were prompted by the arrival in Canada of a
Russian trade delegation. During the summer, tourist re­
ceipts were unusually large as the success of EXPO 67
drew an exceptional number of visitors to Canada. Con­
sequently, the Canadian dollar remained quite strong dur­
ing July and August, fluctuating in a narrow range around
$0.9300. Official gold and foreign exchange reserves
nevertheless declined moderately during the first seven
months of the year (by $53.3 million), with the decline in
large part ($31.8 million) the result of purchases by the
Canadian authorities of Canadian Government debt held
by United States residents.
BELGIAN FRANC

The Belgian franc moved above par in January as
lightly slackening activity in the Belgian economy con­
tributed to a more than seasonal drop in imports, and the
current account shifted from deficit to surplus during the
winter. There was no real pressure in the exchange mar­
ket, however, and official holdings of gold and foreign ex­
change were little changed through the first quarter.
In April the franc began to strengthen further as the
current account continued in surplus and from May on­
ward the franc held at or near its upper intervention point.

166

MONTHLY REVIEW, SEPTEMBER 1967

In part, this strength reflected an inflow of short-term
capital despite steps by the central bank to ease monetary
policy somewhat, including three discount rate cuts dur­
ing the first half of the year. During the rest of the period,
the National Bank of Belgium was compelled to take in
substantial amounts of dollars. Inflows in late April and
early May led the Federal Reserve to absorb $30 million
that had been acquired by the National Bank by utilizing
its $150 million swap line with that Bank. In an unrelated
transaction, the United States Treasury during May re­
paid two maturing Belgian franc denominated bonds to­
taling $30.2 million originally issued in 1963 using francs
it had acquired in late 1966 when the dollar was in de­
mand in Belgium.
The Federal Reserve used an additional $7.5 million
of the swap line in June but shortly thereafter repaid $10
million by selling dollars to the National Bank to meet
Belgian Government needs. In July and August demand
for francs was intensified as commercial banks increased
their inflow of short-term capital. (The scope for the banks
to employ in Belgium the proceeds of foreign borrowings
increased with the removal in late June of the credit ceil­
ings that had been previously applied on a voluntary basis.)
The renewed pressures on sterling also contributed to the
substantial inflow as commercial interests and banks re­
duced their holdings of sterling. In order to absorb dollars
purchased by the National Bank during this period, the
Federal Reserve used a further $92.5 million under the swap
arrangement plus $3 million of Belgian franc balances.
Thus at the end of August, total swap drawings by the
Federal Reserve stood at $120 million. Following a fur­
ther flow of funds into Belgium, in early September the
Federal Reserve made an additional drawing of $5 mil­
lion equivalent.
ITALIAN LIRA

The deficit that had emerged in late 1966 in Italy’s bal­
ance of payments continued during the first two months
of 1967, reflecting seasonal factors and intensified im­
port demand associated with an expanding economy. In
addition, there were sizable exports of capital, partly in
anticipation of changes in the Italian tax laws. Under
the circumstances, United States monetary authorities
were able to acquire sufficient lire to repay short-term
lira commitments totaling $114 million, of which the
final $15 million portion was liquidated at the begin­
ning of 1967.
In March, Italy’s balance of payments began to
strengthen, although the reemerging surplus was consid­
erably less than during the comparable period a year




earlier as import demand expanded further and capital ex­
ports continued. As economic expansion generated mount­
ing financial requirements on the part of Italian residents
for both foreign exchange and local currency, Italian banks
reduced their net claims on foreigners by nearly $275 mil­
lion during the first six months of the year. During the
same period, Italian official reserves, including Italy’s
position in the IMF, increased by $55 million.
About midyear the Italian payments position moved into
the period of seasonal strength and the demand for lire
intensified. The Italian authorities began to acquire sub­
stantial amounts of dollars, though on a lesser scale than
the previous year. The Federal Reserve did not draw upon
its $600 million swap line with the Bank of Italy during
the period, but outstanding Federal Reserve and Treasury
technical commitments in forward lire were rolled over
periodically during 1967.
OTHER CURRENCIES

During the period under review, there were no Sys­
tem transactions in Austrian schillings, French francs,
Japanese yen, Danish kroner, Norwegian kroner, Swedish
kronor or Mexican pesos. Nor were there any drawings
by the United States Treasury on the IMF. As of the end
of August, net United States indebtedness to the Fund
was $922.2 million.
EURO-DOLLAR MARKET

The Euro-dollar market eased considerably during the
first four months of 1967, after having been subjected to
considerable strain last year. Excessive reliance on mone­
tary policy in a number of countries had pushed domestic
interest rates to historically high levels which affected the
international money market as well. United States banks
in particular turned to the Euro-dollar market in an effort
to recoup deposits being lost as certificate of deposit rates
reached ceiling levels under Regulation Q and became
uncompetitive with commercial paper. Thus, between
late June and the peak in mid-December, United States
banks added some $2.4 billion to their borrowings
through foreign branches. Later, year-end liquidity re­
quirements placed additional demands on the market.
In the final weeks of 1966, concerted action was taken by
the BIS and a number of central banks to counter these
year-end pressures, and the constellation of Euro-dollar
rates began to ease. (For a description of these operations,
see this Review, March 1967, pages 43-51.)
The decline in rates was even more pronounced after
the turn of the year. By late April, three-month deposits

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

YIELD COMPARISONS BETWEEN THREE-MONTH EURO-DOUARS
UNITED KINGDOM IOCAL AUTHORITY DEPOSITS AND
CERTIFICATES OF DEPOSIT OF UNITED STATES BANKS
Per c«nt

Per cent

1964

1967

were quoted at 41% 6 per cent, lower than at any time in
1966 and 2 Vi percentage points below their peak of late
November (see chart). This sharp decline in rates re­
flected, in addition to the usual seasonal pattern, decidedly
easier monetary conditions in the United States and Ger­
many and to a lesser extent in other countries as well.
By the end of the first quarter, United States banks had
reduced their liabilities to foreign branches mainly in
London by some $1.25 billion from the mid-December
peak, while German and Swiss institutions added sub­
stantially to their net foreign currency assets abroad.
A large part of the foreign funds shifted to London dur­
ing the early months of the year were converted into




167

sterling, reflecting both the relative attractiveness of
sterling-denominated short-term assets and the return of
confidence in that currency. As indicated on the accom­
panying chart, British local authority deposits commanded
a modest edge over Euro-dollars early in the year and again
in April, even allowing for exchange cover. On an un­
covered basis, of course, there had been a substantial
interest margin in favor of sterling assets right along, but
this incentive became of practical significance in terms
of shifts of funds only with the return of confidence.
The trend in interest rate relationships shifted during
the second quarter as conditions in the Euro-dollar mar­
ket began to tighten, partly reflecting a similar movement
in United States short-term rates. Banks in some countries
began to withdraw funds from the Euro-dollar market
while those in other countries accelerated the pace of their
previous borrowing. At the same time, placement of Ger­
man funds tapered off and United States banks on balance
were no longer repaying previous borrowings. Rates in the
Euro-dollar market began to rise in May, and with the
outbreak of hostilities in the Middle East in June, precau­
tionary withdrawals of funds combined with preparations
for mid-year to cause a sharp jump in rates. The increased
interest incentive to shift funds from sterling to the Euro­
dollar market added a further element of pressure on
sterling. Accordingly, as indicated in the section on
sterling, the BIS immediately began to place sizable
amounts of dollars in the Euro-dollar market, financing
$143 million of such placements by drawing on the swap
line with the Federal Reserve. These operations quickly
calmed the market, and, with the cessation of fighting, the
rapid rise in rates came to a halt.
Apart from a brief period of stringency at midyear and
in early July, Euro-dollar rates have generally tended
downward in recent weeks despite renewed borrowings by
United States banks through their branches that have
brought these liabilities back to a level approaching last
December’s peak. Some new funds have come into the
market as a result of the United States payments deficit as
well as from short-term outflows from Germany and Swit­
zerland. In addition, there has been a shift of funds out of
sterling, partly because the covered incentive between
sterling and Euro-dollar investments has favored the latter
for several months now.

168

MONTHLY REVIEW, SEPTEMBER 1967

Some Current Banking and Economic Problems*
By

W i l l ia m

F. T r e ib e r

First Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of New York

It is a great pleasure to be with you today. You, as state
bank supervisors, and we in the Federal Reserve System
have many common interests. Both are interested in pro­
moting a sound banking system that will continue to de­
velop and to serve effectively the nation and its people.
You have the responsibility of chartering and supervising
banks organized under state law. We in the Federal Re­
serve have a secondary responsibility of supervising some
of those banks. We are also concerned with the preserva­
tion of the value of our nation’s money, for we have been
delegated responsibilities in this respect by the Congress
which under the United States Constitution has the power
to coin money and regulate the value thereof. Today I
propose to discuss with you, as we see them, some recent
developments and current problems in promoting an effi­
cient and sound banking system, in preserving the value of
the dollar, and in promoting our other national economic
goals. Most of these problems involve Federal legislation
in one way or another.
REGULATION OF INTEREST RATES PAID BY
FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS

Public Law 89-597, which was enacted September 21,
1966, broadened and placed on a discretionary basis
the authority of the Federal Reserve Board and the Fed­
eral Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) to limit in­
terest rates paid by banks on time and savings deposits.
It granted similar authority to the Federal Home Loan
Bank Board to limit interest rates paid by savings and

loan associations, and required prior consultation among
all three agencies before any one agency could prescribe
new rate limits.1 The law is temporary. On September 21,
1967, the prior provisions of law will be restored unless
the Congress enacts new legislation. On July 17, 1967,
the Senate voted to extend for two years the provisions
of Public Law 89-597. The Senate bill is now before
the Committee on Banking and Currency of the House
of Representatives.
I would like to comment on two aspects of this tempo­
rary legislation: (1) the discretionary nature of the au­
thority to limit the rate of interest paid by commercial
banks, and (2) the authority to limit interest rates paid
by mutual savings banks and savings and loan associa­
tions. I think that these provisions, as well as other pro­
visions upon which I will not take the time to comment,
should be made permanent.
c o m m e r c i a l b a n k s . Prior to the enactment of the tem­
porary legislation last year, the Federal Reserve Board
was required by law to establish maximum rates on time
and savings deposits in member banks, and the FDIC
was required to establish maximum rates on similar de­
posits in insured nonmember banks.2 The objective of the
requirement, enacted more than three decades ago, was to
help assure sound banking. Improved bank examination
and supervision in recent decades make continuous regula­

1 The law also expanded the range within which the Federal
Reserve Board may vary reserve requirements on time and sav­
ings deposits, and it authorized the Federal Reserve Banks to
conduct open market operations in United States Government
agency obligations.
* An address at the sixty-sixth annual convention of the N a­ 2 Since 1938, insured nonmember mutual savings banks had been
tional Association of Supervisors of State Banks, Louisville, expressly exempted by the FDIC from the maximum rates estab­
Kentucky, August 16, 1967.
lished by it for insured nonmember banks.




FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

tion of interest rates unnecessary as a means of preventing
destructive competition and the resultant acquisition of
unsound assets.
In general, the public interest is best served when the
forces of supply and demand are permitted to reflect them­
selves in prices, including interest rates. The relationship
between buyers and sellers, or borrowers and lenders, is
likely to be more equitable, and the allocation of resources
is likely to be more satisfactory, when prices and interest
rates are free to reflect market forces. Yet there may be
times, and 1966 was such a time, when the establishment
of maximum interest rates is necessary either to prevent in­
stitutional practices in the payment of interest that would
be inconsistent with the safety and liquidity of a significant
number of institutions or to supplement other govern­
mental policies to promote our national economic goals.
These factors counsel continuation of the authority on a
discretionary basis. The exercise of such discretionary
authority, it seems to me, should be limited to such special
situations.
MUTUAL SAVINGS BANKS AND SAVINGS AND LOAN ASSOCIA­

Although prior to 1966 the Federal Reserve and the
FDIC were required to establish maximum interest rates
for banks, no Federal supervisory authority was directed
or even authorized to fix maximum rates of interest pay­
able by savings and loan associations.
The absence of a maximum interest rate for thrift in­
stitutions gave them, at times in the past, a competitive
edge over commercial banks in attracting funds. However,
as interest rates rose rapidly in 1966, the thrift institutions
were faced with very strong competition on the part of not
only banks but also marketable securities including those
of the United States Government. Because most of the
investments of thrift institutions had been made for long
terms when interest rates were lower, their earnings did
not rise as rapidly as did current interest rates.
The temporary legislation specifically authorized the
FDIC to limit the rate of interest paid by insured mutual
savings banks, and it authorized the Federal Home Loan
Bank Board to limit the rate paid by insured savings and
loan associations. The authority was granted to restrain
some thrift institutions from trying to match or to better
competitive rates available to savers. Although the rates
paid by insured commercial banks were already subject to
Federal Reserve or FDIC control, it was not feasible to
restrict further the rates paid by commercial banks while
the rates paid by competing thrift institutions were subject
to no supervisory control. The experience of 1966 dem­
onstrated the desirability of vesting in the FDIC and the
Federal Home Loan Bank Board, on a permanent basis,
TIONS.




169

discretionary authority to limit the rates of interest paid
by insured thrift institutions.
DISCOUNT WINDOW ADMINISTRATION

Another problem on which I would like to comment is
the administration of the Federal Reserve “discount win­
dow”. In recent years the Federal Reserve has sponsored
legislation that would eliminate the outmoded technical
requirements regarding the “eligibility” of customers’
paper presented at the discount window to secure advances
by the Reserve Banks to member banks. The System has
also been engaged in a basic reappraisal of the functioning
of the discount window in the light of the changes in the
banking system and the financial markets over the past
decade.
e l ig ib il it y
l e g i s l a t i o n . In April
1967, the Senate
passed S.966, streamlining discount window operations.
The bill is now before the House Committee on Banking
and Currency. Enactment of the bill would not cause a
dramatic or abrupt change in the type of collateral offered
by member banks to secure their borrowings at the Federal
Reserve Banks. It would still be more convenient most of
the time for member banks to pledge U.S. Government
obligations and simple notes of customers as collateral for
their borrowings. But this is important legislation for mem­
ber banks that have limited holdings of unpledged Govern­
ment obligations or that have small amounts of “eligible
paper” in their loan portfolios. For these banks, access to
the discount window under the circumstances specified in
the Reserve Board’s Regulation A would be facilitated.
The legislation should also prove helpful to any member
bank encountering an emergency or any other situation
requiring substantial assistance from a Federal Reserve
Bank.
The Federal Reserve System is already engaged in
forward planning to process the wide variety of collateral
that may be tendered at the discount window to support
borrowings. The System has organized and has commenced
to operate a school to train Federal Reserve discount per­
sonnel in collateral appraisal. As we in the Federal Re­
serve prepare for enactment of this legislation, member
banks, too, would be well advised to consider how they
may take advantage of the new possibilities when they
materialize.

s t u d y o f d i s c o u n t m e c h a n i s m . It is too early to report
the conclusions of the fundamental study of the discount
mechanism. It is not unlikely, however, that there will be
recommendations leading to a greater use of the discount

170

MONTHLY REVIEW, SEPTEMBER 1967

window to the advantage of both member banks and the
Federal Reserve.

a bank and for determining appropriate ways to meet such
needs. We expect to share the results of the study with
you, and we trust that they will be helpful.

STUDY OF BANK LIQUIDITY AND CAPITAL

The Federal Reserve System is also engaged in another
study which is even more closely associated with your in­
terests and responsibilities as bank supervisors. The events
of 1966 highlighted the importance of reexamining our
approach to member bank liquidity and capital.
b a n k l i q u i d i t y . Traditionally, a bank’s need for liquid­
ity has been thought of in terms of a possible drop in de­
posits. The events of last year brought into sharp focus
the necessity of considering also a bank’s ability to meet
potential credit demands, especially unexpected demands
representing legitimate needs in the community. Many
banks found it difficult to shift assets to meet such needs
in a period of rapidly rising interest rates. Liquidity analy­
sis should take into account not only potential deposit
losses but also potential credit demands.
Changing banking practices have highlighted the im­
portance of liability management. Banks have found that
sometimes an increase in liabilities may be a more feasible
way to obtain loanable funds than a sale or other disposi­
tion of assets. Banks and bank supervisors need to know
more about the potential impact on a bank of an increase
in various types of liabilities.

b a n k c a p i t a l . During the past decade, bank assets and
deposits have grown more rapidly than retained earnings.
The growth in time and savings deposits, coupled with the
steady rise in interest rates paid on such deposits, has
brought a sharp increase in total bank expenses in relation
to total assets. In addition, the shift in the composition of
bank assets from securities to loans, while yielding greater
income to offset higher costs, has increased the relative
amount of risk assets. Consequently, for most banks the
ratio of capital funds to total resources has declined, while
the ratio of risk assets to total resources has risen.
A number of banks have increased their capital by sell­
ing securities. Many more need to do so. All bank super­
visors are interested in the continued soundness of the
banks they supervise, including the maintenance of a capi­
tal position adequate to enable the banks to serve their
communities and remain strong and competitive.

s t u d y o b j e c t i v e s . The study being undertaken by the
Federal Reserve has two objectives: (1) developing im­
proved standards for measuring a bank’s liquidity, and
(2) formulating a guide for measuring the capital needs of




PROTECTION OF PUBLIC DEPOSITS

The laws of many states require that banks receiving
deposits of the state or its political subdivisions secure
those deposits by the pledge of U.S. Government obliga­
tions or other specified types of securities. Similarly, banks
must pledge collateral to secure United States Treasury
Tax and Loan Accounts and other U.S. Government de­
posits. A decade or more ago, when most banks held large
quantities of eligible securities, there was not much of a
problem in making the pledge; but in recent years as loan
demands have been heavy and banks have reduced their
securities holdings, many banks have experienced some
difficulty in meeting the pledge requirements and at the
same time maintaining desirable flexibility with respect to
their investment portfolios. It has been estimated that over
$45 billion of collateral are tied up in such pledges.
Most state laws that require the pledge of assets to se­
cure public deposits exempt the FDIC-insured portion of
such deposits from the pledging requirements. There is a
similar exemption with respect to U.S. Government depos­
its. Last year an advisory committee of banking experts
appointed by the New York Superintendent of Banks to
assist him in a comprehensive reappraisal of banking laws
and regulations recommended to the Superintendent that
appropriate statutes be amended to provide for full FDIC
insurance of public deposits as a substitute for the pledging
of assets.3 Presumably upon the enactment of Federal leg­

3 1Second R eport of the A dvisory Com m ittee on Commercial
Bank Supervision submitted to the Superintendent of Banks of
the State of N ew York, September 19, 1966. In summarizing its
recommendations, the Committee said on page 9:
Security for Public D eposits. In order to provide security for the
repayment of public deposits and at the same time to eliminate
the onerous restrictions on the management of bank assets and
the costs associated with the pledging of assets as security for
such deposits, this Committee recommends that appropriate
statutes be amended to provide for full FDIC insurance of
public deposits as a substitute for the pledging of assets.
In a study prepared in 1967 for the Trustees of the Banking
Research Fund of the Association of Reserve City Bankers, en­
titled The Pledging of Bank Assets, A Study of the Problem of
Security for Public Deposits, Charles F. Haywood, Dean and Pro­
fessor of Economics of the College of Business and Economics,
University of Kentucky, said (page 8 ):
The final conclusion of this study is that the answer to the
pledged-assets problem should be sought within the context of
Federal deposit insurance and that an early effort in this direc­
tion would be most timely.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

islation providing for such FDIC insurance, the legislatures
of those states that do not exempt insured deposits from
pledging requirements would adopt legislation eliminating
the pledge requirements. I think the proposal provides a
constructive solution of the problem.
The proposal would protect public funds and simplify
the operations of public officers responsible for the funds.
The proposal would benefit practically every bank. It
would give the bank greater flexibility in the management
of its investment portfolio; it would increase the bank’s
effective liquidity because securities now immobilized as
collateral for public deposits would become available for
sale or for pledge as collateral for borrowing at the Re­
serve Bank; it would simplify a bank’s internal operations
in handling public deposits; and it would simplify operat­
ing relationships between the bank and the Federal Re­
serve Bank in its custodial, discount, and fiscal agency
functions.
RESERVE REQUIREMENTS AND
DISCOUNTING PRIVILEGES

Another important problem involves the role of com­
mercial bank reserves. On March 15, 1967, Senator
Sparkman, Chairman of the Senate Committee on Bank­
ing and Currency, introduced S. 1298 at the request of
the Federal Reserve Board. The bill has three principal
provisions:
(1) it would make reserve requirements applicable to
all insured commercial banks;
(2) it would eliminate the present classification of all
member banks as reserve city banks or as “coun­
try” banks, and establish a system of graduated
reserve requirements under which the reserves
required on a bank’s demand deposits would de­
pend primarily upon the amount of its deposits
rather than its location; and
(3) it would afford all insured commercial banks ac­
cess to Federal Reserve discount facilities.
u n i v e r s a l r e s e r v e r e q u i r e m e n t s . Historically, bank
reserves were that part of the assets of a bank specially
kept in cash, or in assets readily convertible into cash, as
a reasonable provision for meeting demands upon the
bank. The basic purpose of bank reserves is now quite
different from what it used to be. Today the primary pur­
pose of bank reserves is to serve as a fulcrum for the
implementation of monetary policy. The monetary policy
of the Federal Reserve is directed to the promotion of our
national economic goals of maximum sustainable economic




171

growth, reasonable price stability, maximum practicable
employment, and equilibrium in international payments.
The Federal Reserve promotes these goals by influencing
the availability and cost of credit. Additions to bank credit
generally bring additions to bank deposits, and the banks
then need additional reserves to support the additional
deposits.
Under the Federal Reserve Act, the deposits of a mem­
ber bank may not exceed a given multiple of its reserves,
and its reserves must consist of currency and coin or
deposits in the Reserve Banks. The basic source of such
reserves is the Federal Reserve Banks which, through
open market and discount operations, create reserves. By
making reserves readily available, or by making them
less readily available, the Federal Reserve System influ­
ences the ability and willingness of member banks to make
loans and investments. This activity of the Federal Re­
serve involves the performance of a national function
delegated to the Federal Reserve by the Congress. It is a
function similar to that performed by central banks in
other countries throughout the world.
Deposits in nonmember banks are no less a part of the
money supply of the country than those in member banks.
Yet reserve requirements applicable to nonmember banks
do not play a direct role in the implementation of mone­
tary policy, and in general they are less onerous than
those applicable to members of the Federal Reserve Sys­
tem. In one state there are no reserve requirements for
nonmember banks. In many states, the form in which
reserves may be held is more favorable to nonmember
banks. For instance, in a number of states, reserves may
be held partly in the form of securities. Furthermore,
correspondent balances, which nonmembers would main­
tain in some amount even in the absence of reserve re­
quirements, and from which they derive benefits, serve
to satisfy part or all of state reserve requirements. The
difference in reserve treatment of member banks and
nonmember banks tends to confer a competitive advantage
on nonmember banks.
It is generally recognized that an effective national
monetary policy is essential to a sound banking system
and the economic well-being of the country. Nonmember
banks enjoy the general benefits of such policy as well as
the specific benefit of Federal deposit insurance, but they
avoid the cost of the reserve requirements established to
effectuate national monetary policy. Monetary policy can­
not have its maximum impact when it fails to have a
direct effect upon a substantial number of banks.
In my view, the proposal for universal reserve require­
ments would contribute to the more effective implementa­
tion of national monetary policy, and would not adversely

172

MONTHLY REVIEW, SEPTEMBER 1967

affect the dual banking system. There would be no
impairment of the right of a state to charter a bank, to
determine the extent to which it should be permitted to
have branches, to determine its lending and investment
powers, and to regulate, examine, and supervise it. But
in an area of national concern, in promoting our nation’s
economic goals, the proposal would put all banks on an
equal footing.

any other basic change in reserve requirements will require
substantial adjustments. Federal Reserve open market
operations are customarily used to facilitate the adjust­
ment of the banking system to any change in reserve
requirements. No doubt, every banker would prefer that
there be no increase in the required reserves of his bank.
It is obvious that, if there were no increase in the required
reserves of any bank, and if the requirements of thousands
of banks were reduced in varying amounts, there would
be a large reduction in the general level of required re­
serves in the banking system; large excess reserves would
be created overnight. Whether such a result would be
justified and whether open market operations could ade­
quately provide the necessary adjustment would depend
on economic and credit conditions at the time of the
adoption of the new reserve requirements, and such condi­
tions cannot be predicted now. If, at such time, economic
conditions called for monetary ease, the creation of the
additional bank reserves would not create as great a prob­
lem as if economic conditions then called for restraint.
Today, it seems to me that it would be fruitless to discuss
further the details of any possible change and the problem
of adjustment in the light of future economic conditions
about which we know nothing.

With graduated re­
serve requirements, the reserves required of a bank in
respect of its demand deposits would depend on the size
of its deposits rather than its location. A smoothly gradu­
ated system would permit each bank to maintain a rela­
tively low reserve against the first few million dollars of
its demand deposits, a higher reserve against its demand
deposits above this minimum and up to a substantial fig­
ure, and a still higher reserve against its demand deposits,
if any, above the latter amount.
As you know, smaller banks find it necessary, in order
to obtain certain services from their city correspondents,
to hold a substantial portion of their assets in the form
of noninterest-bearing balances at other banks. In addi­
tion, the smaller banks are less able than the larger banks
to take advantage of the economies of scale. Thus, many
bankers and students of banking have concluded that, as a
ACCESS TO FEDERAL RESERVE DISCOUNT W INDOW . At the
matter of equity, the smaller banks should have a lower same time that S.1298 would establish universal reserve
level of reserve requirements in order to offset to some requirements, it would grant all nonmember insured com­
extent the disadvantages of smallness.
mercial banks access to Federal Reserve advances.
With graduated reserve requirements, all banks of the Through its power to create reserves, the Federal Reserve
same size in terms of demand deposits would carry equal is the ultimate source of funds to the banking system as a
reserves. As a bank grew in size and passed into a higher whole. Any insured commercial bank would have the same
reserve bracket, its overall reserve requirement percentage privilege that member banks now have of borrowing from
would rise smoothly and gradually, because the higher the Reserve Bank. Every insured commercial bank would
requirement would apply only to its additional deposits. know it could go directly to the Federal Reserve in case
There would, no doubt, be less change in total required of need.
reserves resulting from shifts in deposits among banks in
different cities, and there would be no need to struggle
ECONOMIC OUTLOOK AND FISCAL MEASURES
with the elusive problem of determining whether or not a
particular city is to be classified as a reserve city.
A few minutes ago I referred to our national economic
Many people consider it desirable to work toward a goals and the responsibility of the Federal Reserve to pro­
goal of uniform reserve requirements under which, for mote these goals. What is the present economic situation?
example, the same percentage requirement would apply What is the economic outlook?
to all demand deposits in large and small banks wherever
Business activity has continued to gain momentum. As
located. The proposal in S. 1298 would provide flexibility. the President reported in his message to the Congress on
Graduated reserve requirements would be facilitated but ^ August 3, Federal Government expenditures, particularly
would not be required. By permitting the Federal Reserve for defense, have continued to rise at a fast rate— much
to move first to graduated reserve requirements, the pro­ faster than indicated in the January budgetary estimates.
posal would make possible a transition to greater uniform­ At the same time, private spending is once more rising
ity, or to full uniformity, should that prove desirable.
across a broad range. The rise in consumer prices has ac­
The inauguration of graduated reserve requirements or celerated. Many wage settlements this year have provided
graduated

r e s e r v e r e q u ir e m e n t s .




173

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

increases much greater than the increase in general pro­
ductivity, and wage demands in current bargaining ses­
sions are large. Thus, pressures of increased demand on
an economy with little slack, coupled with upward cost
pressures, threaten an even more rapid increase in prices.
Corporations and state and local governments have bor­
rowed record amounts in the capital markets so far this
year, and in recent weeks yields on some types of long­
term obligations have exceeded last summer’s peaks. The
prospect of large United States Treasury borrowing in
the second half of 1967 and a growing belief that the rate
of economic advance will accelerate sharply have weighed
more and more heavily on the markets.
The United States continues to be plagued by a critical
international balance-of-payments problem. Inflation at
home would reduce our ability to compete in international
markets; it would be detrimental to our exports and would,
no doubt, increase our imports. At the same time, inflation
would diminish the faith of foreign holders of dollars in
the value of our currency. It would weaken the position
of the dollar internationally at the very time our world­
wide efforts require that confidence be sustained and
strengthened.
These developments make imperative prompt action to
reduce the Federal budget deficit significantly. Expendi­




tures should be rigidly controlled and reduced as much
as possible, but it is not realistic to expect large cutbacks
in spending. The President has recommended a compre­
hensive program to increase Government revenues; the
key recommendation is a temporary surcharge of 10 per
cent on individual and corporate income taxes. Prompt
and decisive fiscal action by the Congress would go far to
help assure that the renewed growth in the economy is
held to a sustainable pace with a reduction in the pressure
on prices and in the tensions in the money and capital
markets. It would, of course, lessen the need for monetary
policy to carry an excessive share of the overall antiinflationary effort, as was the case in 1966.
*

*

*

In closing, I am sure that all of us—not only bank
supervisors but also all our fellow citizens— want a sound
banking system and a sound dollar. The studies and pro­
posals I have discussed today are aimed at strengthening
our financial institutions and the procedures through which
our economic goals are promoted. Monetary policy and
fiscal policy have a coordinated responsibility in promot­
ing those goals. To assure a sound dollar, we need a more
effective monetary machine and wise monetary and fis­
cal policies.

174

MONTHLY REVIEW, SEPTEMBER 1967

The Business Situation
The business expansion gained increasing strength dur­
ing the summer months. Housing starts rose strongly in
July, industrial production advanced for the first time this
year, and the backlog of unfilled orders in durables manu­
facturing reached a new record high. At the same time,
personal income increased substantially, and preliminary
data indicate that retail sales turned in another strong ad­
vance. In August the unemployment rate dropped for the
second month in a row as employment—notably in manu­
facturing—recorded a large rise. Along with the quick­
ening pace of business activity, price increases on both
the wholesale and retail levels are accelerating and again
pose a threat to the orderly growth of the economy. Al­
though it is difficult to assess at this time the impact on
the economy of the automobile strike, which began as this
Review went to press, it seems likely that the strike will
only temporarily moderate the business expansion.
PRODUCTION, INVENTORIES, AND ORDERS

Industrial activity increased in July, following six months
of virtually uninterrupted declines. The Federal Reserve
Board’s seasonally adjusted production index rose by a
full percentage point—to 156.3 per cent of the 1957-59
average—recouping one fourth of the overall decline in
the index from its December peak of 159.0 per cent.
While the July upturn reflected improvement in the gen­
eral pace of industrial activity, a good part of the in­
crease was due to the settlement of strikes in the rubber
and electrical machinery industries and the surge in domes­
tic crude oil output following the curtailment of supplies
from the Middle East. In terms of broad market groupings,
production of materials, equipment, and consumer goods
all rose from the June levels.
In the consumer sector, output of automotive products
increased once again in July, continuing the advance from
the low mark reached in February. On a seasonally ad­
justed basis, the production of new cars rose by about W i
per cent to an annual rate of just over 8 million units.
While output slipped a bit in August, preliminary sched­




ules for September had indicated an unusually large rise
in automobile assemblies. However, the strike against the
Ford Motor Company— which manufactures about 25 per
cent of the nation’s cars—-will hold production below
scheduled levels.
Output of consumer goods other than automobiles was
about unchanged in July from the May-June pace. De­
clines in the apparel and furniture indexes were offset by
gains stemming from the settlement of a strike against a
major television set producer, as well as by increases in
output of other appliances. As a result of the JanuaryMay sluggishness in retail demand and of the sizable
inventories that existed earlier in the year, production of
nonautomotive consumer goods has shown little buoyancy
in the past few months. However, the recent pickup in
retail sales, coupled with an improved inventory situation,
points to a likely strengthening of activity in industries
producing for the consumer market.
In the equipment category, defense-related production
increased once again in a continuation of the rapid growth
that began two years ago. The rise in the output of
defense equipment over the first seven months of 1967
was at an annual rate of 18 Vi per cent, only moderately
below the 22 Vi per cent increase registered over the full
course of last year. At the same time, July saw this year’s
first increase in the production of business equipment. The
slowdown in capital spending in the first half of 1967 had
been reflected in a steady decline, dating from last Decem­
ber, in the pace of activity in the business equipment
industries. The July rise in output of business equipment
was not unexpected. Surveys of capital spending plans
taken throughout this year, including the most recent one
taken in August, have all pointed to increased outlays for
plant and equipment in the second half.
The July rise in industrial production, while due in part
to special factors, also provided some evidence that the
inventory adjustment is nearing an end (see Chart I).
This adjustment has, of course, been the major factor
dampening industrial activity this year. Following the
fourth quarter of 1966, when inventory additions averaged

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

Chart!

MANUFACTURERS’ INVENTORY ACCUMULATION
Seasonally adjusted
M illio n s of d o llars

M illio n s of d o llars

600

600

M a te ria ls a n d su p p lie s

400

200

TTf
- 200 ___I___I__ I___1___1__ I___1___I___I__ I___I
J

F M A M J

J

A

S

O

N

1966

D

I
J

I

l

I

I

I

I

F M A M J

1

I

1— 200

J A S

1967

Source: United States Department of Commerce:

about $lVi billion a month, the rate of business inventory
accumulation declined sharply.1 In June, manufacturers
actually reduced their inventories, the first decumulation
in three years. In the following month, however, such
stocks rose once again. The July accumulation was cen­
tered in inventories of work in process, and finished goods.
Inventories of raw materials and supplies were cut back
further.
Although the overhang of excessive inventories at
the beginning of the year was most noticeable in the manu­
facturing sector, trade inventories early in 1967 were also

1 Revised figures for second-quarter gross national product
(G N P ) show a cutback in inventory accumulation larger than that
previously estimated. However, upward revisions in other com­
ponents— notably consumer spending— offset the reduced figure
for inventory accumulation, and total GNP was therefore virtually
unchanged from the preliminary estimate discussed in this Review,
August 1967, pages 139-41.




175

high relative to sales. As a result of rising sales and of in­
ventory reductions during the first half, however, inventorysales ratios in the trade sector by midyear had moved back
down to levels prevailing before the inventory surge in the
later months of 1966. Indeed, the trade sector accounted
for almost half the December-June cutback in total inven­
tory accumulation. The June inventory-sales ratio for re­
tail trade was the lowest in many years.
The continued rise in the backlog of orders on the
books of durables manufacturers is another element of
strength in the outlook for production and employment.
Though new orders for durables declined in July from
the high June level, largely as a result of a sharp drop
in the volatile defense component, the backlog of unfilled
orders expanded once again. The July increase put the
backlog at a new record, surpassing the previous high set
last December. At the same time, shipments by durables
manufacturers rose for the third month in a row.
Residential construction activity is apparently continu­
ing its vigorous recovery from the depressed 1966 pace.
In July, housing starts rose strongly to an annual rate of
1.35 million units, closely approaching the average level
that prevailed before last year’s slump. Although the num­
ber of units authorized by building permits eased off
slightly in July, prospects for further improvement in
residential construction continue to be favorable. Statistics
on vacancy rates and sales of new homes indicate strong
demand. At the same time, mortgage credit availability
currently appears adequate for additional expansion in
new home and apartment construction.
EMPLOYMENT, INCOME, AND
CONSUMER DEMAND

Payroll employment rose sharply further in August.
Most significant among the widespread gains was the
upturn in manufacturing employment which resulted pri­
marily from a large rise in the number of production
workers employed. At the same time, the average week
worked by manufacturing production workers increased
again.
The civilian labor force expanded further in August for
the third consecutive rise. In most of the earlier months
of this year the labor force had declined on a seasonally
adjusted basis, and the recent turnaround suggests that
the quickening pace of economic activity has encouraged
more individuals to enter the labor force. Reflecting the
strength of demand in the labor markets, the growth of
employment in both July and August exceeded the rise
in the labor force, with the result that unemployment
edged off to 3.9 per cent in July and 3.8 per cent in August.

MONTHLY REVIEW, SEPTEMBER 1967

176

Increases in personal income through most of the first
half of 1967, though quite sizable, were nevertheless damp­
ened by the sluggish behavior of employment during the
period, and particularly by the reduction in the number
of workers and the length of the workweek in manufac­
turing. In June and July, however, the expansion of per­
sonal income showed renewed strength as employment
gains gave rise to rapid growth in wage and salary pay­
ments.
The stepped-up rate of income growth has undoubtedly
been a factor in the recent strengthening of consumer
demand. But, at the same time, consumers also seem to be
showing a willingness to spend a larger share of their
incomes. Indeed, recent revisions in the GNP accounts
for the second quarter indicate that the advance in con­
sumer spending was stronger than had been shown in the
preliminary estimates. The revised figures put the secondquarter savings ratio at an estimated 6.7 per cent, down
appreciably from the unusually high rate of 7.3 per cent
in the first quarter. The second-quarter savings figure was
nevertheless relatively high by historical standards, and
it is altogether possible that future consumer spending may
benefit from still further decreases in the savings ratio as
well as from income gains.
In any case, the available data do indicate rising con­
sumer demand. According to preliminary estimates, retail
sales volume recorded a sizable increase in July, follow­
ing a strong rise in the preceding month. During the first
five months of the year, sales at retail stores had followed
a generally upward course but at a very modest pace. Thus,
in the five-month period ended with May, retail sales rose
only 2 per cent; the June-July expansion, in contrast,
amounted to fully 3 per cent. In July, the increase was
centered entirely at durables outlets, where gains were
reported both for the automotive group and for other hard
goods lines. Sales of new automobiles in July were at a
seasonally adjusted annual rate of almost 8 V2 million units,
well above the low point of 7 million reached last Febru­
ary. In August, however, automobile sales dropped off,
reportedly because of a short supply of cars in the popular
lines. At the month end, the inventory of 1967 models was
more than 25 per cent below carry-over in 1966 of prioryear models (the timing of the changeover to the new
models was the same in both years).

totaling 4.6 per cent a year, compared with increases of 4.1
per cent for all of 1966 and 3.3 per cent for 1965. The
rapid advance in labor compensation this year has been ac­
companied by a leveling off in productivity growth. The
combination of rising labor costs and virtual stability in
output per man-hour resulted in a sharp increase in labor
costs per unit of output. To be sure, the index of unit labor
costs in manufacturing fell a bit in July, as the result of a
jump in productivity associated with the upturn in output.
Nevertheless, the July level of the index represented an ad­
vance over the first seven months of this year at a seasonally
adjusted annual rate of about 5 V2 per cent, compared with
a rate of 3 Vi per cent for all of 1966. While productivity
can reasonably be expected to move upward once again as
the economy expands more vigorously, it is unlikely that
the growth in output per man-hour will be adequate to
offset mounting labor costs.
In conjunction with the strengthening of demand,
the rising trend in unit labor costs has been a major

Chart II

CONSUMER AND WHOLESALE PRICES

WAGES, PRODUCTIVITY* AND PRICES

Wage costs continue to mount and the rate of increase
has accelerated. According to the Bureau of Labor Statis­
tics, collective bargaining settlements concluded in the first
half of 1967 involved wage and fringe benefit increases




Note: Consumer prices are plotted through Ju ly; w holesale prices are plotted
through August(prelim inary).
Source: United States Bureau of Labor Statistics.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

source of upward pressure on prices. The midsummer was
marked by a rash of announced price increases for a broad
range of commodities, including trucks, rubber goods,
household appliances, textiles, construction materials,
aluminum and steel for can-making, a variety of other
steels, and goods containing silver. Moreover, railroad
freight rates— which affect costs throughout the economy
—were also raised.
Some of these increases have already had an effect on
the broad index of industrial wholesale prices. Preliminary
figures indicate that this index rose sharply in August after
five months of stability (see Chart II). Wholesale prices of

177

agricultural commodities, however, dropped in August
after a steep three-month run-up, and this decline more
than outweighed the increase in industrial commodities.
As a result, the total wholesale index moved lower. In the
consumer area, prices rose by a sharp 0.4 per cent in July
as costs of food and services increased again. Prices of
nonfood commodities also rose substantially. The overall
advance was the largest in nine months and followed four
months of sizable gains. From February to July, the total
consumer price index advanced at an annual rate of 3.6
per cent, compared with 1.5 per cent in the preceding
five-month period.

The Money and Bond Markets in August
Money market conditions remained comfortable during
August. Federal funds generally traded in a narrow band
around the 4 per cent discount rate, while nationwide net
reserve availability continued to fluctuate within the range
of recent variation. As the month progressed, there was a
significant improvement in the basic reserve positions of
major banks in the money centers, reflecting in part a sub­
stantial contraction in business loans and increased acquisi­
tions of Euro-dollars. Major banks also acquired a large
volume of funds through sales of negotiable certificates of
deposit (C /D ’s) during the month.
As was the case in July, even with the comfortable tone
in the money market, yields on short-term and capital
market instruments rose further in August. The Presi­
dent’s request on August 3 for a 10 per cent surcharge on
individual and corporate income taxes was welcomed by
market participants, but the optimistic reaction was soon
dampened by consideration of the accompanying projec­
tions of a large budget deficit and Treasury financing needs
in fiscal 1968. Two Treasury cash offerings during the
month— one to refund the August maturities and the other
to raise new money— attracted only routine interest on the
part of investors and trading activity in the Treasury market
was generally light. Meanwhile, large current and antici­
pated corporate borrowing and the fair to poor receptions
accorded several new corporate issues— in spite of mount­
ing yields— contributed to a hesitant atmosphere through­




out the capital markets. By the end of the month, yields on
intermediate-term Treasury issues had risen by about 24
basis points, while long-term yields were up about 6 basis
points. The yield on a new Aa-rated utility bond issue with
five years’ special call protection reached 6.20 per cent at
the end of the month, 15 basis points more than the highest
yielding comparable offering in July. The tax-exempt mar­
ket was under somewhat less pressure than the corporate
market, against a background of a comparatively light cal­
endar and talk of an added relative yield advantage for
tax-exempt securities in the event of a tax increase.
The cautious mood of the capital markets during August
also pervaded the market for Treasury bills. Although
there was a significant investment demand for bills at times
during the month, rates on outstanding issues rose almost
steadily until late in the month, when they receded slightly.
The market yields on three- and six-month maturities rose
by 26 and 23 basis points, respectively, to 4.38 per cent and
4.83 per cent at the close of the month.
BANK RESERVES AND THE MONEY MARKET

The money market remained comfortable throughout
August. The effective rate for Federal funds generally was
close to the 4 per cent discount rate, with some trading at
4Vs per cent in the first half of the month and generally in
a 3 to 4 per cent range later on. Free reserves averaged

MONTHLY REVIEW, SEPTEMBER 1967

178
Table I

Table n

FACTORS TENDING TO INCREASE OR DECREASE
MEMBER BANK RESERVES, AUGUST 1967

RESERVE POSITIONS OF MAJOR RESERVE CITY BANKS
AUGUST 1967

In millions of dollars; (+ ) denotes increase,
(—) decrease in excess reserves

In millions of dollars
Daily averages—week ended on
Factors affecting
basic reserve positions

Changes in daily averages—
week ended on
Factors
Aug.
2

Aug.
9

Aug.
16

Aug.
23

Aug.
30

Member bank required

4- 82

-|-214

- f 63

-j- 94

4-371

Operating transactions
Federal Reserve flo a t.............
Gold and foreign account---Currency outside banks*........
Other Federal Reserve
Total “ market” factors----

— 68
— 342
4-179
— 70
— 43

— 235
— 193
— 178
— 14
- f 29

— 107
— 54
+ 477
— 50
— 510

— 8
— 18
— 79
4- 2
+ 71

+ 330
+ 247
— 7
— 6
4- 125

-f- 122

+ 31
— 25

+

14

— 30

+

73

4-210

-j-206

4-393

4- 46

4-' 303

— 317

— 48
— 324
— 34
— 2
4- 242

Direct Federal Reserve
credit transactions
Open market instruments
Outright holdings:
Government securities........

— 29
—

— 200
—

— 100
— 6

— 255
— 7

— 466
— 12

—
—
—
- f 62

- f 127
+ 49

— 17
— 49
+
2
+ 38

— 110
—
— 2
— 82

—
—
—
— 1

—
—
—
— 8

+
3
+ 184

—

—

—

—

—

+ 120

— 226

— 301

— 263

— 486

— 133

4- 95

— 20

4- 92

— 217

— 183

4- 118
+

Repurchase agreements:
Government securities........
Bankers* acceptances ........
Federal agency obligations.
Member bank borrowings..........
Other loans, discounts, and

1

— 25
3

Aug.
23

Aug.
16

Aug.
30*

Eight banks in New York City

“ Market” factors
— 82

Aug.
9

Aug.
2

Net
changes

Averages of
five weeks
ended on
August 30*

Reserve excess or
deficiency(—)t .......................
Less borrowings from
Reserve B a n k s.......................
Less net interbank Federal
funds purchases or sales(—).
Gross purchases ...............
Gross sales .........................
Equals net basic reserve
surplus or deficit(—) .............
Net loans to Government
securities d ealers...................

19

12

10

14

25

26

___

6

___

« _

392
1,255
862

486
1,186
700

508
1,198
690

— 399
963

474 — 505

—

1,048

943

16
6

169 - 19
1,120
991
951 1,010

307
1,150
843

— 155

44

— 298

928

907

958

Thirty-eight banks outside New York City
Reserve excess or
deficiency(—)t .......................
28
30
24
6
18
Less borrowings from
—
—
Reserve B a n k s.......................
13
17
28
Less net interbank Federal
835
633
funds purchases or sales(—)..
370
813 1,038
Gross purchases ...............
1,845 1,936 1,901 1,698 1,666
Gross sales ......................... 1,032
898 1,066 1,065 1,296
Equals net basic reserve
surplus or deficit(—) ............. — 823 -1,029 - 8 1 8 - 6 0 9 — 364
Net loans to Government
securities d ealers...................
571
560
337
505
669

21
12
738
1,809
1,071
-7 2 9
568

Note: Because of rounding, figures do not necessarily add to totals.
* Estimated reserve figures have not been adjusted for so-called “ as of” debits
and credits. These items are taken into account in final data,
t Reserves held after all adjustments applicable to the reporting period less re­
quired reserves and carry-over reserve deficiencies.
T a b le

in

AVERAGE ISSUING RATES*
AT REGULAR TREASURY BILL AUCTIONS

Daily average levels

In per cent
Member bank:
Total reserves, including
Required reserves* .....................
Excess reserves* ........................

Nonborrowed reserves* .............

23,967
23,676
291
116
175
23,851

23,980
23,594
386
91
295
23,889

23,746
23,380
366
129
237
23,617

23,775
23,317
458
47
411
23,728

23,464
23,223
241
46
195
23,418

23,786 §
23,438§
3485
86§
262§
23,700§

Weekly auction dates—August 1967
maturities

August
7

August
14

August
21

August
28

Three-month..................................

4.174

4.193

4.336

4.490

Six-month.......................................

4.757

4.791

4.922

4.995

Changes in Wednesday levels
Monthly auction dates—June-August 1967
System Account holdings
of Government securities
maturing in:
Less than one year ...................

— 50
—

—

—1,424
- f 1,224

— 100
—

—335

—1,909
4-1,224

Total ....................................

— 50

—

— 200

— 100

—335

— 685

Note: Because of rounding, figures do not necessarily add to totals.
* These figures are estimated,
t Includes changes in Treasury currency and cash.
t Includes assets denominated in foreign currencies.
8 Average for five weeks ended on August 30.




One-year.........................................

June
27

July
25

4.723

5.164

5.098

4.732

5.150

5.100

August
24

* Interest rates on bills are quoted in terms of a 360-day year, with the discounts
from par as the return on the face amount of the bills payable at maturity.
Bond yield equivalents, related to the amount actually invested, would be
slightly higher.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

about the same as in July, with continued fairly wide fluctu­
ations from week to week in line with varying demands for
excess reserves (see Table I). Nationwide borrowings from
the Federal Reserve Banks also averaged about the same
as in July but declined sharply in the last two statement
weeks of August. In the week ended on August 23, the
banking system benefited substantially from large declines
in required reserves and currency outside banks. In that
week, the major reserve city banks were entirely free of
Reserve Bank indebtedness, and borrowings of other re­
serve city and “country” banks fell to negligible levels (see
Table II). In the final week, only country banks borrowed
at the Reserve Banks. Throughout the month, banks in
New York City having branches abroad continued to bor­
row substantial amounts of Euro-dollars, as they had in
July. The sharply increased use of Euro-dollars since June
has resulted from a considerable narrowing of the differen­
tial between Euro-dollar rates and domestic C /D rates.
The attractiveness of Euro-dollars as a source of funds for
banks is enhanced by the fact that such borrowings are not
subject to reserve requirements or deposit insurance assess­
ments.
The financing needs of Government securities dealers
increased during August but were satisfied without dif­
ficulty by borrowing from either the New York City
banks or out-of-town institutions or through repur­
chase agreements with corporations. Borrowing was par­
ticularly heavy at the start of the period when the dealers
made payment for their awards of the new nine- and
twelve-month Treasury bills sold in the regular monthly
auction. Rates posted by the large New York City banks
on new call loans to Government securities dealers were
generally quoted within a 4Vs to 4% per cent range dur­
ing most of August, but declined rather sharply toward
the month end. Most other short-term money rates were
little changed on balance during August.
The New York City money market banks continued to
attract time deposits in volume during August through
the issuance of negotiable C /D ’s; over the five statement
weeks ended on August 30, the net increase in C /D liabili­
ties amounted to $298 million. Large commercial banks
outside New York City also benefited from a rapid inflow
of funds from this source, and their aggregate C /D liabili­
ties expanded by $643 million over the same five weeks.
The most often posted offering rate on new C /D ’s of the
large New York City banks at the end of August was
4.125 per cent for the shortest maturities, down from
4.50 per cent earlier in the month. On the other hand,
the city banks seemed to be having difficulty in selling
longer term C /D ’s, though the generally posted rate re­
mained at 5 lA per cent.




179

THE GOVERNMENT SECURITIES MARKET

An atmosphere of renewed caution appeared in the
Treasury coupon market in August, following a temporary
improvement in the market tone during July. Prices
moved irregularly lower to register declines for the month
as a whole of as much as 1 point in the intermediate area
and almost IV 2 points in longer maturities. Exceptionally
large Treasury financing needs in the second half of this
calendar year, together with the prospect of a sustained
heavy corporate demand for funds, were again the major
market influence during August. The President’s request
for a 10 per cent surcharge on corporate and individual
income taxes buoyed the market briefly at the beginning
of the month, but participants quickly came to the realiza­
tion that the deficit would be very large even after allow­
ance for the additional revenues this tax measure would
produce. Moreover, it was felt in the market that the tim­
ing and magnitude of the tax surcharge or, indeed, its
very adoption by the Congress were far from certain.
Two Treasury financing operations executed in Au­
gust dominated trading during the month. After the
close of the market on August 2, the Treasury an­
nounced the results of its refunding of three issues matur­
ing on August 15, for which subscription books had been
open on July 3 1.1 Awards of the new fifteen-month 5Va
per cent notes offered for cash or in exchange for the ma­
turing securities amounted to $9.9 billion against total
subscriptions of $15.6 billion. Larger public subscriptions
were subject to a 35 per cent allotment. This allotment
percentage was somewhat higher than initially estimated
by most market participants.
After the close of the market on August 17, the Trea­
sury announced the terms of a $2.5 billion of new cash
borrowing. Investors were offered a new 5% per cent note
due February 15, 1971, priced at 99.92 to yield 5.40 per
cent. Subscription books were open on August 22, and
payment was made on August 30. Commercial banks were
permitted to make payment for the issue by credits to
Treasury Tax and Loan Accounts. Many market partici­
pants had hoped that the Treasury would offer a some­
what longer note, perhaps in the five- to seven-year area,
as a means of extending the average maturity of its out­
standing debt. The Treasury’s choice of a 3 V i -year matu­
rity was widely interpreted as an attempt to avoid a higher
coupon rate which might have had adverse effects on the
thrift institutions and on other securities markets. Sub-

1 For details, see this Review , August 1967, page 143.

MONTHLY REVIEW, SEPTEMBER 1967

180

SELECTED INTEREST RATES
June-August 1967

MONEY MARKET RATES

Per cent

june

July

August

BOND MARKET YIELDS

July

August

Note: D ata a re shown for busine ss d a y s only.
* M O N EY MARKET RATES Q UO TED: D a ily ra n ge of rates posted b y m ajor New York C ity banks

point from underw riting syn d icate reo fferin g yield on a given issue to m arket yield on the

on new call loans (in ^ d e r a l funds) secured by United States G overnm ent securities (a point

sam e issue im m ediately after it has been rele ased from syn d icate restrictions); d a ily

in d ica te s the ab sen ce of an y ran ge); offering rates for directly p la ce d finance co m p an y pap er;
the effective rate on Fed eral funds (the rate most representative of the transaction s executed);

a v e ra g e s of yield s on lon g -term G overnm ent securities (bonds due or c a lla b le in ten years
or more) and of G overnm en t securities due in three to five ye a rs, computed on the b asis of

clo sing bid rates (quoted in terms of rate of discount) on newest outstanding three- and six-month

clo sin g bid prices; T hursday a v e ra g e s of yields on twenty seaso n ed twenty-ye ar tax-exem pt

Trea sury b ills .

bonds (carrying M oody’s ratings of A a a , A a , A , and Baa).

BO N D MARKET YIELD S Q U O TED: Y ie ld s on new A a a - and A a-rated p ub lic utility bonds are plotted
around a line show ing d a ily a v e ra g e y ie ld s on seasoned A aa-ra ted co rp o rate bonds (arrows

scriptions totaled $6 billion and late on August 24, the
Treasury announced that larger ones would be subject to a
38 per cent allotment. This allotment percentage was
above initial estimates by most market participants, but
generally in line with the consensus that emerged after
the books had closed.
Price fluctuations on Treasury coupon issues were fairly
wide early in August, but considerably narrower over the
remainder of the month. In the first three days of the
period, prices of intermediate issues declined in reac­
tion to speculation that the response of investors to the
offering of the new 5V4 per cent note in the August re­
funding would prove less favorable than had originally
been thought. Prices rebounded immediately thereafter in
a highly favorable market reaction to the President’s re­




Sources: Fe d e ra l Reserve Bank of N ew Yo rk, Board of G o v ern o rs of the Federal Reserve System,
M o ody’s Investors Service, and The W eekly Bond Buyer.

quest for a tax surcharge, since the suggested 10 per cent
was higher than most market participants had expected.
Once the new Federal budget statistics were fully di­
gested, however, prices began an irregular downward
drift which continued through the month end. The pessi­
mism prevalent in the market was reinforced by the
rising yield trend in the corporate and tax-exempt bond
markets. The reports of a light volume of subscriptions for
the new 5% per cent notes had little effect on the market.
Market activity during the month was mainly confined to
professional liquidation of holdings of intermediate is­
sues, investment switching into the new 5lA per cent
notes, and outright sales of long-term issues by investors
moving into corporate securities.
The Treasury bill market was moderately firm over the

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

first part of August, and rates for short-term bills continued
to decline from the high levels attained in July after the
Treasury announced that it would increase the size of each
of the regular weekly and monthly bill auctions by $100
million. The early strength of the market resulted partly
from the favorable yield on longer term bills relative to that
offered on the closely competitive new 5X
A per cent Trea­
sury notes of November 1968. Moreover, a fairly good in­
vestment demand from public funds and commercial banks
was in evidence. After midmonth, the declining rate trend
was reversed as the bill market was affected by the caution
apparent in the coupon sector. With investor demand con­
tracting and the possibility of some selling of bills around
the mid-September dividend and tax dates, dealers were
cautious in bidding for bills in the final auctions held dur­
ing the month, and bill rates rose somewhat. In the monthly
auction of nine- and twelve-month bills held on August 24,
average issuing rates were set at 5.098 per cent and 5.100
per cent, respectively, slightly lower than in the July
monthly auction. Average issuing rates established on the
regular three- and six-month Treasury bills moved pro­
gressively higher over the month, and in the last weekly
auction these rates reached 4.490 per cent and 4.995 per
cent, respectively (see Table III), compared with 4.182
per cent and 4.638 per cent in the last July auction. In the
wake of the auction, an active demand for bills by investors
and dealers developed, and rates declined over the final
three days of the month.
OTHER SECURITIES MARKETS

Developments in the markets for corporate and taxexempt securities closely paralleled those in the Govern­
ment securities market during August. The President’s pro­
posal of an income tax surcharge injected some temporary
optimism into the market at the beginning of the month
and, in fact, aided underwriters in completing a lagging
distribution of the month’s largest single corporate bond
offering. Subsequently, however, market sentiment deterio­
rated with the growing concern over the huge demands
likely to be made on the capital markets by the Treasury
and corporate borrowers in coming months. The taxexempt sector was slower than the corporate area to
succumb to the general weakening tendencies, however,
because of the somewhat lighter calendar of new offerings
than in other recent weeks and perhaps also because of




181

the yield advantage tax-exempt securities will gain by any
income tax increase. Nevertheless, The Weekly Bond
Buyer's average yield series for twenty seasoned taxexempt bonds, carrying ratings ranging from Aaa to Baa,
rose to 4.06 per cent at the month end from 3.98 per cent
at the close of July (see chart). The average yield on
Moody’s Aaa-rated seasoned corporate bonds rose to 5.69
per cent from 5.60 per cent a month earlier.
In the corporate sector, a total of $1.8 billion of securi­
ties was publicly offered during August, the same amount
as in July. The largest single offering was a $250 million
Aaa-rated issue of 6 per cent 3 3-year debentures of the
American Telephone and Telegraph Company, reoffered
to yield 5.95 per cent and nonredeemable for five years.
The issue was awarded to underwriters at a net interest
cost of 6.006 per cent, a record for this borrower and
considerably higher than the net interest cost of 5.46
per cent on a similar flotation by the same company in
January of this year. The offering drew only a modest
investor response prior to the President’s tax message,
but subsequently sold out quickly. In the heavier market
atmosphere that developed later in the month, only negoti­
ated industrial issues sold well, while public utility offer­
ings awarded in competitive bidding were received un­
enthusiastically by investors. One $200 million offering
by an oil company of Aaa-rated 53A per cent sinking
fund debentures, carrying ten-year call protection, sold
well at a reoffering yield of 5.85 per cent, 10 basis points
higher than the yield on a comparable offering only three
weeks earlier. During the month there were a number of
syndicate terminations resulting in upward yield adjust­
ments of about 10 basis points.
Total new publicly-offered tax-exempt securities
amounted to $0.7 billion in August, down from $0.8 bil­
lion in July. In contrast to the corporate market, the
municipal market retained a firm tone through mid­
month, enabling dealers to reduce their inventories to
the lowest level in seven months. Encouraged by the
improved technical position of the market and rather
light volume of offerings, dealers bid aggressively for
new issues around midmonth. Investors showed consid­
erable resistance to the lower yield levels, however, and
reoffering yields tended to rise subsequently. Even at the
higher yields available over the latter part of the month,
there was a marked lack of enthusiasm for new issues
being marketed, and most offerings moved very slowly.

MONTHLY REVIEW, SEPTEMBER 1967

Publications of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York
The following is a selected list of publications available from the Public Information Department,
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 33 Liberty Street, New York, N. Y. 10045. Copies of charge pub­
lications are available at half price to educational institutions, unless otherwise noted.
1. c e n t r a l b a n k c o o p e r a t i o n : 1924-31 (1967) by Stephen V. O. Clarke. 234 pages. Dis­
cusses the efforts of American, British, French, and German central bankers to reestablish and maintain
international financial stability between 1924 and 1931. $2 per copy.
2. e s s a y s i n m o n e y a n d c r e d i t (1964) 76 pages. Contains articles on select subjects in bank­
ing and the money market. 40 cents per copy.
3. k e e p i n g o u r m o n e y h e a l t h y (1966) 16 pages. An illustrated primer on how the Federal Re­
serve works to promote price stability, full employment, and economic growth. Designed mainly for sec­
ondary schools, but useful as an elementary introduction to the Federal Reserve. ($7 per 100 for copies in
excess of 100.*)
4. m o n e y a n d e c o n o m i c b a l a n c e (1967) 27 pages. A teacher’s supplement to Keeping Our
Money Healthy. Written for secondary school teachers and students of economics and banking. ($8 per
100 for copies in excess of 100.*)
5. m o n e y , b a n k i n g , a n d c r e d i t i n e a s t e r n e u r o p e (1966) by George Garvy. 167 pages.
Reviews recent changes in the monetary systems of the seven communist countries in Eastern Europe and
the steps taken toward greater reliance on financial incentives. $1.25 per copy (65 cents per copy to edu­
cational institutions).
6. m o n e y : m a s t e r o r s e r v a n t ? (1966) by Thomas O. Waage. 48 pages. Explains the role of
money and the Federal Reserve in the economy. Intended for students of economics and banking. ($15
per 100 for copies in excess of 100.* )
7. o p e n m a r k e t o p e r a t i o n s (1963) by Paul Meek. 43 pages. Describes and explains the Sys­
tem’s use of open market purchases and sales of Government securities to influence the cost and avail­
ability of bank credit. ($17 per 100 for copies in excess of 100.*)
8. t h e n e w y o r k f o r e i g n e x c h a n g e m a r k e t (1965) by Alan R. Holmes and Francis H.
Schott. 64 pages. Describes the organization and instruments of the foreign exchange market, the techniques
of exchange trading, and the relationship between spot and forward rates. 50 cents per copy.
9. t h e s t o r y o f c h e c k s (1966) 20 pages. An illustrated description of the origin and develop­
ment of checks and the growth and automation of check collection. Primarily for secondary schools, but
useful as a primer on check collection. ($4 per 100 for copies in excess of 100.*)
* Unlimited number of copies available to educational institutions without charge.
Subscriptions to the m o n t h l y r e v i e w are available to the public without charge. Additional
copies of any issue may be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank
of New York, 33 Liberty Street, New York, N. Y. 10045.