View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

M O N T H L Y REVIEW
O f Credit and Business Conditions

FEDERAL
V o lu m e

RESERVE BANK

39

NOVEMBER

OF N E W Y O R K

1 95 7

No. 11

MONEY MARKET IN OCTOBER
Member bank reserve positions remained under rela­
tively steady pressure during most of October, although
a sharp rise in float just after the middle of the month
eased the pressure temporarily at that time. The money
market continued tight throughout, however, with Federal
funds firmly bid at the 3 Vi per cent ceiling on every day.
Short-term interest rates advanced toward the middle of
the month, and longer regular Treasury bills traded at
slightly below 3^8 per cent over the latter half of the
month as compared with about 3 Vi per cent early in the
period. Most longer term yields showed mixed changes;
the Treasury 3W s of 1978-83 closed the month to yield
3.70 per cent, 5 basis-points above the yield at the end of
September, and the 3’s of 1995 closed at 3.60 per cent,
up 4 basis-points. However, yields on long-term corporate
bonds remained fairly stable and those on municipals
declined. These and other developments are described
more fully below.
M e m b e r B a n k R e s e r v e P o sit io n s

Except for the temporary easing in the week ended
October 23, member bank reserve positions remained
under fairly steady pressure during the five statement
weeks ended in October. Net borrowed reserves averaged
380 million dollars for the full five weeks, about 50
million lower than in September. In the statement week
ended October 23, the midmonth rise in float temporarily
supplied a large volume of funds to the banking system,
as the accompanying table shows. Most of these funds
were withdrawn in the final week, but net borrowed re­
serves did not return to the high level prevailing earlier
in October. Over the month as a whole, member bank
borrowings from the Reserve Banks amounted to 845
million, about 130 million lower than in September, while
average excess reserves declined to 465 million from
540 million.
Reserve positions tightened early in the period when
required reserves rose sharply, partly as the result of bank
payments through Tax and Loan Accounts for their
purchases of the new Treasury securities sold in mid-




September. Payment for the 4 per cent certificates and
notes was due on September 26, and at least one half of
the payment for the 4 per cent bonds sold at the same
time was due on October 1, with the remainder deferred
if desired until not later than October 21. (Most sub­
scribers elected to make full payment for the bonds on
October 1.) Although average float declined by some
300 million dollars during the first of the five statement
weeks, when required reserves were rising, the impact of
these pressures on reserves was offset by funds supplied
through a reduction in Treasury balances with the Reserve
Banks to normal working levels, by System purchases of
Government securities (including outright purchases and
those made under repurchase agreements), and by other
factors. Average member bank borrowing from the
Reserve Banks actually declined by 165 million dollars
during the week ended October 2, almost fully accounting
for the drop in excess reserves.
Day-to-day fluctuations in reserve positions remained
in a relatively narrow band until the middle of the month,
when float rose substantially and most other operating
factors also added to the reserve base. System securities
operations absorbed some of these reserves, but member
banks used the largest part of the funds briefly available
to them at that time to reduce their indebtedness to the
Reserve Banks. During the week ended October 23, aver­
age member bank borrowing from the Reserve Banks
declined by 387 million dollars to 598 million, the lowest
level since the last week in July.
In the final statement week of the period, net borrowed
reserves moved back to about 350 million dollars as float
averaged 466 million dollars lower than in the preceding
CONTENTS
Money Market in O ctober...............
International Monetary Developments
. . 148
The New York Foreign Exchange Market .. .. 150
Selected Economic Indicators...............
.. 156

146

MONTHLY REVIEW, NOVEMBER 1957

and then fluctuated irregularly upward over most of the
remainder of the period. Outright investment demand was
generally light, with trading confined for the most part
to tax-switching operations as dealers and investors at­
tempted to assess the implications of a wide variety of un­
certainties confronting the market. Prices moved upward
early in the month, as the firm tone in the corporate and
municipal bond markets reinforced a developing opinion
that interest rates were not likely to rise further in the near
future. On the other hand, views regarding the outlook
for interest rates were tempered by the realization that the
volume of new bond flotations scheduled for the forth­
coming months was still unusually large.
The announcement late on Friday, October 4, of the
successful launching of an earth satellite by the Soviet
Union gave rise to considerable speculation with respect
to the impact of this development on Government defense
spending, the debt ceiling, and the cash needs of the
Treasury in forthcoming months. Announcements by the
United States Defense Department of curtailment of prog­
ress payments to defense contractors clouded the picture
further, as did conflicting rumors in the market regarding
the future course of Federal Reserve policy. In addition,
the announcement on October 15 that the Federal National
G o v e r n m e n t S e c u r it ie s M a r k e t
Mortgage
(FNMA) would issue 750 million
Prices of Treasury notes and bonds generally moved dollars of Association
short-term
notes injected further uncertainty
moderately higher early in the month, turned around and into the outlook for interest
Concern over such in­
fell back rather rapidly between October 8 and October 17, fluences was reflected in a rates.
sharp drop in the prices of
Treasury bonds and notes between October 8 and
T able I
October
17.
C hanges in F acto rs T end in g to Increase or D ecrease M em ber
B ank R eserv es, O ctober 1957
By October 18, however, prices steadied, and over the
(In m illion s of d o llars; ( + ) d en otes in crease,
(— ) decrease in ex c e ss r eserv es)
balance of the month they tended to move irregularly
higher, in many cases regaining all of the losses of the
Daily averages—week ended
midmonth
period and recording small gains for the month
Net
Factor
Oct. changes
Oct.
Oct.
Oct.
Oct.
as
a
whole.
Market atmosphere seemed to be primarily
2
16
23
30
9
influenced
by
uneasiness regarding near-term business
Operating transactions
Treasury operations*....................... + 262 - 2 - 9 + 40 — 58 4- 233
prospects
and
by
sharp declines in stock market prices.
Federal Reserve float....................... - 318 - 9 + 80 + 446 - 466 - 267
Currency in circulation................... + 14 - 91 - 62 + 62 4- 121 4- 44
Over
the
month
as a whole, the prices of most Treasury
Gold and foreign account............... + 35 _ 4 + 52 + 23 + 5 + 111
bonds and notes maturing through 1962 showed mixed
Other deposits, etc............................ + 79 — 7 + 10 - 12 4- 66 4~ 136
changes, ranging from losses of about Vs of a point to
Total........................................... + 71 - 113 + 71 + 559 - 331 4- 257
gains of about % of a point. Issues due after 1962 and
Direct Federal Reserve credit
transactions
Government securities:
through 1972 generally rose by Vs to % of a point. The
Direct market purchases or sales. 4- 121 + 18 - 31 - 59 - 43 4- 6
Held under repurchase agree­
33/4?s of 1978-83 closed at 922%2 (bid), down 2%2 of
ments.......................................... + 47 + 181 - 143 - 45 - 29 4- 11
Loans, discounts, and advances:
a point over the month, and the 3’s of 1995 closed at
Member bank borrowings........... - 165 + 68 - 18 - 387 ~r 105 - 397
—
—
-Other............................................... --87 2 down % of a point. The new 4 per cent Treasury
Bankers’ acceptances:
_
_ - 1 _
- 3
notes
of 1962, issued last month, fluctuated close to par
Bought outright............................ - 2
Under repurchase agreements... —
—
—
+ 2 — 2
—
over
most
of the month and closed at 100%2 (bid), a rise
+ 268 - 192 - 490 + 31 — 383
Total........................................... of
V4
of
a
point
over the period. The new 4 per cent bonds
Total reserves.......................................... + 71 + 155 - 121 + 69 - 300 - 126
Effect of change in required reserves f .. - 259 + 5 + 47 + 4 4- 96 - 107
of 1969 fell as low as V\ of a point below par in midExcess reservesf ...................................... - 188 + 160 - 74 + 73 - 204 - 233
October, but then recovered, and closed the month at
Daily average level of member bank:
100% 2 ? a gain of %2 of a point over the month.
985
598
935 1,003
Borrowings from Reserve Banks..
703
845J
393
553
552
479
Excess reserves f ...............................
348
465 %
As mentioned above, the Treasury announced on
October
15 that the FNMA would offer 750 million dol­
Note: Because of rounding, figures do not necessarily add to totals.
lars
of
short-term
notes for cash subscription on October
* Includes changes in Treasury currency and cash,
t These figures are estimated.
21, the proceeds to be used to retire borrowings from the
X Average for five weeks ended October 30.

week. Part of this loss of funds was offset by a return flow
of currency from circulation, but member banks also
found it necessary to step up their average borrowing from
the Reserve Banks to 703 million.
System holdings of Government securities were in­
creased by 83 million between September 25 and October
30, as outright holdings of Treasury bills rose by 22 mil­
lion dollars and there was a net increase of 61 million
dollars in short-term Government securities held under
repurchase agreements. Repurchase agreements were writ­
ten in largest volume early in October to alleviate the
strains on the money market stemming from the reserve
pressures during the first two statement weeks of the
month. The outstanding balance rose from zero on Septem­
ber 25 to 148 million on October 2 and remained at that
level one week later. By October 16, however, the balance
had fallen to 53 million, all of which was retired before
the next statement date, October 23. In the final week
of the month, new acquisitions of securities under repur­
chase agreements w^ere arranged to relieve renewed pres­
sures on bank reserves; the outstanding balance totaled
61 million dollars on October 30.




—

—

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

Treasury. The 4V& per cent Series ML notes were dated
October 29 and are to mature on June 26, 1958. The
Treasury handled the offering for the FNMA, and,
although payment by Treasury Tax and Loan Account
credit was not permitted, arrangements were made between
the FNMA and the Treasury whereby the Treasury de­
posited with qualified banks, on request, amounts equal to
the notes allotted to such banks for themselves and their
customers. After some initial hesitancy immediately after
the announcement of the 4% per cent coupon (rather than
5 per cent as expected by some observers), the issue was
fairly well received by the market. However, commercial
banks were restrained in their subscriptions because of
uncertainty over their ability to liquidate allotments
quickly on a “when-issued” basis in the secondary market.
Total subscriptions aggregated 1.6 billion dollars; subscrip­
tions of $100,000 or less were allotted in full and others
received 44 per cent of their bids, with a minimum of
$100,000.
The market for Treasury bills was generally in balance
early in the period but weakened at midmonth, and the
average issuing rate in the regular weekly auction climbed
to a post-1933 high of 3.660 per cent for the bills dated
October 17. This represented an increase of 14 basispoints from the average issuing rate of 3.525 per cent
established in the first auction of the month, held on
October 7, with the advance primarily attributable to a
slackening of demand and a reluctance of dealers to in­
crease their inventories at prevailing high borrowing costs.
Investment demand picked up gradually after midmonth,
and the average issuing rate declined to 3.619 per cent
on October 21. In the final auction, held on October 28,
the rate held steady at 3.622 per cent, and three-month
bills were bid at 3.60 per cent by October 31.
O t h e r S e c u r it ie s M a r k e t s

147

11 basis-points since the end of September, but the long­
term Aaa-rated corporate bond index was unchanged at
4.12 per cent. (The recent highs in these indexes have
been 3.45 per cent for the municipals at the end of
August, and 4.15 per cent for the corporates near the
end of September.)
New municipal flotations were generally well received
despite a heavy volume of new public offerings totaling
an estimated 605 million dollars, 250 million more than
in the previous month and 80 million more than in Octo­
ber of 1956. Among the new municipal issues marketed
early in the month was a 31 million dollar Aa-rated State
bond flotation which carried a 3.32 per cent net interest
cost to the borrower. These bonds had first been offered
for competitive bidding early in September but the best
bid at that time, entailing an interest cost of 3.68 per cent,
was rejected by the borrower because of a technicality.
The unplanned delay in the sale of the bonds thus saved
the borrower a substantial sum in interest charges and
furnished a measure of the change in market atmosphere.
As a further example, in the middle of the month a 64
million dollar Aa-rated State bond issue was well received
at a net interest cost to the borrower of 3.49 per cent,
15 basis-points below the interest cost to the same bor­
rower on a smaller flotation in August.
Public offerings of corporate bonds for new capital pur­
poses are estimated to have totaled 535 million dollars
during the month, 55 million below the previous month
and 225 million more than in October of last year. The
month’s only Aaa-rated corporate flotation, a 100 million
dollar issue of 3 5-year utility debentures, was marketed
early in the period at a price to yield investors 4.70 per
cent—almost the same as the 4.71 per cent on the previous
similarly rated issue, which had been marketed late in
September. The October issue, which is callable at 110
for the first five years and at declining prices thereafter,
moved slowly at first, but sales picked up as the month
progressed. Toward the end of the month a 250 million
dollar flotation of Aa-rated 26-year telephone utility de­
bentures, noncallable for the first five years, moved slowly
when reoffered at 4.90 per cent. This was the largest
offering since a flotation of similar size by the same
borrower this past March, which had moved well when
reoffered to yield 4.30 per cent.
On October 8 most dealers in open market commercial
paper raised their rates by Vs of 1 per cent on all maturi­
ties, and the others followed suit on October 9. This rise,
the first since August 7, brought the dealer offered rate
on prime four-to-six months’ paper to 4Vs per cent; in
the two months since the previous rate increase most
other short-term rates had also been realigned upward.

Both the corporate and municipal bond markets re­
mained relatively firm during October, with trading par­
ticularly active in the tax-exempt area. For the most part,
new municipal issues were aggressively bid for by under­
writers and attracted a favorable investor response; the
corporate market was not quite so robust, and for a while
new issues moved rather slowly, but it was still marked
by generally stable yields. The impression seemed to be
circulating, as in the market for Governments, that long­
term yields had reached their peak for the present and were
unlikely to move higher in the coming months. However,
a continued heavy calendar of future offerings created a
considerable amount of uncertainty regarding the pros­
pects for significantly lower yields.
Prices of outstanding issues tended upward in both
markets over most of the first half of the month but sagged
M e m b e r B a n k C r e d it
slightly during the latter part of the period. Moody’s index
Total loans and investments of the weekly reporting
of yields on seasoned long-term Aaa-rated municipal
bonds closed the month at 3.30 per cent, a decline of banks decreased by 513 million dollars between September



MONTHLY REVIEW, NOVEMBER 1957

148

18 and October 23, as a 994 million dollar fall in total
loans more than offset a 481 million dollar expansion in
investment holdings.
The loan contraction was attributable to an 800 million
dollar fall in business loans, in large part the result of net
repayments by sales finance companies amounting to al­
most 500 million dollars over the five-week period. Metals
and metal products firms also reduced their bank borrow­
ings substantially, while seasonal increases were posted by
food, liquor, and tobacco firms and by commodity dealers.
In each of these latter cases, however, the rise was less
than that recorded during the corresponding weeks last
year. Retail and wholesale trade concerns also increased
their bank borrowings, in this case by about the same
amount as in the corresponding weeks last year.
The rise in investment holdings stemmed primarily from
bank acquisition of the 4 per cent certificates, notes, and
bonds sold by the Treasury in September and acquired by
the banks during the week ended October 2. This large
expansion in holdings was in part offset by securities sales
both before and after that week.
Thus far this year, business loans have risen by 515
million dollars at the weekly reporting banks, but total
loans adjusted have fallen by 174 million. In the corre­
sponding period last year, business loans rose by 3.1 billion
dollars, total loans by 3.4 billion. The bulk of the 3.6
billion dollar shortfall in the growth of total loans this year
as compared with last is thus attributable to the 2.6 billion
dollar relative decline in business loans. The reduced rate
of growth in business loans this year may be at least
partially attributable to high rates of corporate securities
flotations and smaller growth of business inventories.

T able II
C hanges in P rincipal A sse ts and L ia b ilities of th e
W eek ly R ep ortin g M em ber B an k s
(In m illion s of d ollars)
Statement week ended
Item

Sept.
26

Oct.
2

Assets
Loans and investments:
Loans:
Commercial and industrial
196 - 82
188
1 ~
6
Agricultural loans.....................
5 —
Securities loans......................... — 58 + 277 — 100
2
Beal estate loans...................... +
7 +
2 +
All other loans (largely con44
19 + 33
Total loans adjusted*.......... - 265 + 231 - 335
Investments:
U. S. Government securities:
152 - 109
136
Treasury bills........................
Other...................................... — 58 +1,226 — 194
_ 210 +1,117 _ 330
Other securities......................... — 19
8 + 34
Total investments................ - 229 +1,109 - 296
Total loans and investments
- 494 +1,340 - 631
Loans to banks................................. +
2
9 -r 2 _
Loans adjusted* and “other”
284 + 223 - 301
Liabilities
Demand deposits adjusted.............
306 - 773 + 329
Time deposits except Government. + 75 + 62 + 56
U. S. Government deposits............ + 130 +1,833 -1,25 4
Interbank demand deposits:
621 + 385 + 106
43 + 81 + 20

and

P o l ic ie s

remained focused on the
tightening of monetary policy that had taken place in
September. Amid early evidence of its effectiveness in
strengthening the pound, the authorities made further
statements concerning the background, nature, and objec­
tives of the restrictive measures they had taken. Address­
ing the annual bankers’ dinner at the Mansion House, the
Chancellor of the Exchequer declared that the govern­
ment’s policy, although harsh, was called for because
“the choice is not really between the strength of the
pound sterling or full employment, for in the long run
the first is a prerequisite to the second”. While stressing
that the wage-price spiral could not be halted overnight,
the Chancellor reaffirmed his confidence in the measures
taken and made clear once again the government’s deter­
mination to push them through to success.
Speaking on the same occasion, the Governor of the
Bank of England explained that the exceptional 2 per
cent increase in the discount rate had been decided
upon because a more positive use of the bank rate was



Oct.
16

Oct.
23

300 +
—34 +
4
1 — 338 —
30 + 10 —
26 +
+ 28
+ 25 - 650 —

59
37
22
22

+
+
-

+
—
_
—
-

8
84
76
27
103

—
_
+
-

515
21
716
83
318
174
808
576
1,384
172
1,212

+ 25 - 753 - 1,386
_ 139 + 95 _ 137
3
677 2
+
2,831
+ 430 + 609
3 -f- 1,886
+ 19 —
670
425
719
972
+ 540 _ 1,029
20 +
38
+ 29

* Exclusive of loans to banks and after deduction of valuation reserves; figures for the individual
loan classifications are shown gross and may not, therefore, add to the totals shown.

Total investments have fallen by 1.2 billion, while in the
first forty-three weeks of 1956 they contracted by 4.5
billion. Total loans and investments thus far in 1957 are
therefore down by 1.4 billion; in the similar period last
year they fell by 1.1 billion.

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY DEVELOPMENTS
M onetary T rends
U nited Kingdom. Attention

Oct.
9

Change
26, 1956
to Oct.
23, 1957

needed to protect the pound and because the parallel
action taken by the government in other fields suggested
that the increase would have “decisive effects on the
economy”. However, the Governor stated that the authori­
ties must also feel free to move the rate downward when
necessary, warning that “unless we can all accustom our­
selves to adjustments of Bank Rate to the requirements
of the moment, without heralding minor reductions from
crisis levels as a signal for new excesses of spending, Bank
Rate will gradually lose its utility”. The Governor wrent
on to emphasize that it was necessary for monetary re­
straint to be supported by complementary fiscal policy and
debt management measures if the money supply was to
be held stable, stating that “sterling will need to be but­
tressed under present circumstances, not only by an in­
creasing surplus on balance-of-payments account, but also
an over-all surplus on budget account”.
In the first half of the British financial year, which
began April 1, the deficit in the ordinary budget was
nearly 100 million pounds less than a year ago, but this
was largely offset by a substantial increase in “below-the-

149

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

line” (mainly capital) expenditures, so that the over-all
deficit was only slightly lower than in 1956-57. These
trends in the budget point up the importance to the gov­
ernment’s fiscal policy of the decision announced in
September to hold investment in the public sector in 1958
and 1959 to this year’s level. In the sphere of debt man­
agement, the Treasury announced on October 11 that no
conversion offer would be made to replace the 503 million
pounds of 2V4 per cent Funding Stock maturing in midNovember, since over four fifths of the issue had already
been brought into official hands. By mid-November the
Treasury will have made a net repayment of about 800
million pounds of maturing debt, mainly, as has been
officially stated, through the sale to the public of longer
dated securities from official portfolios against this year’s
maturities. While it has thus been possible to avoid add­
ing to the heavy maturities over the next few years, the
Treasury’s debt management operations have involved
some increase in the floating debt. However, the Treasury
announcement made it clear that the authorities would
continue to follow a policy of “reducing the floating debt
at all suitable opportunities by the most appropriate
methods”.
The recent upward trend of British interest rates ceased
in October. Prices of gilt-edged securities, which had been
declining sharply and reached a 36-year low in September
following the discount rate increase, recovered somewhat
last month; the yield of IVi per cent Consols declined
from the September high of 5.56 per cent to 5.43 per cent
on October 31. The average Treasury bill tender rate,
which had risen for six successive weeks prior to the dis­
count rate increase and had reached 6.60 per cent at
the following tender, remained virtually unchanged at this
level throughout October. The fall in bank loans that
began after the middle of the year continued during the
eight weeks to mid-October when the London clearing
banks’ advances declined a further 42 million pounds.
Although this was a smaller reduction than had taken
place a year ago and advances on October 16 were still
well above the 1956 level, they were about 20 million
pounds beneath the ceiling that the authorities had re­
quested the banks to observe in September. The banks’
net deposits rose substantially in the two months to midOctober as the decline in advances was more than offset
by an 87 million pound increase in the banks’ Treasury
bill holdings and a further rise in their investments; the
banks’ liquidity ratio rose 1 percentage point to 36.2
per cent.
Canada. The steady upward trend of long-term inter­
est rates was interrupted last month, as the yields of long­
term government bonds, which had been rising for six
months, receded from the record September levels; yields
on medium-term issues declined more sharply, with some
issues falling by as much as 0.45 percentage point. In the
short end of the bond market, where in mid-September the




government had floated a new 700 million dollar issue
of one and two-year bonds priced to yield 4.81 and 4.97
per cent, interest rates declined further in October, but
the fall was less sharp than in the preceding month. The
average Treasury bill tender rate, after having declined
for five successive weeks to more than Vk per cent beneath
the August peak, rose slightly during the first three weeks
in October but fell back somewhat at the fourth tender
and stood at 3.83 per cent on October 25. Thus, while
the rate on three months’ bills stood at about 3% per cent
toward the end of October, the longest dated bonds had
declined to nearly 4Vs per cent and medium-term bonds
to about 4 % per cent.
Bank lending declined only slightly last month from
the record September level, after correcting for the change
made at the beginning of October in the statistical basis
on which bank loans are reported. The banks’ Treas­
ury bill holdings fell by more than 100 million dollars in
October, more than offsetting the exceptional Septem­
ber rise of nearly 15 per cent in their bill portfolios. The
banks have continued to maintain their cash and liquid
assets ratio well above the required minima, and there
has been no borrowing at the Bank of Canada for more
than ten weeks.
Philippines. The Philippine central bank has adopted
new measures to restrict credit and curb imports in view
of the continuing decline in Philippine foreign exchange
reserves. Announcement was made early in September
of an increase in the rediscount rate to AV2 per cent from
2 . At the same time, a cash margin requirement of 100
per cent was imposed on letters of credit for imports of
nonessential consumer goods. The central bank’s gold
and dollar holdings declined by 24 per cent, or 38 million
dollars, during the first eight months of this year because
of the rapid growth in the trade deficit as imports rose
sharply while exports fell. The central bank had pre­
viously increased its discount rate to 2 per cent from 1V2
at the end of March, after having suspended rediscounting
completely at the end of January.
E xchange R ates

American-account sterling was in good demand during
most of the first half of October. With the exception of
October 10 and 11 when the market evidenced some
easiness as a result of demand for dollars in London, the
quotation steadily appreciated on commercial demand,
short covering, and offerings of dollars in London and
by midmonth reached $ 2 .80^ , the highest level since
June 1956. On October 17, however, as tension in the
Middle East increased, the rate fell rather sharply and,
at the opening on October 18, was $ 2 .791% 6 after hav­
ing been as low as $ 2 .7 9 % 6 in London before the New
York market opened. Subsequently, on October 21, fol­
lowing a recovery in London on October 19 (Saturday),

150

MONTHLY REVIEW, NOVEMBER 1957

the New York market quoted sterling as high as $2.801%2j
as a better feeling concerning the Middle East situation
developed and commercial interest in sterling was renewed.
Thereafter the quotation generally held above $2.80 except
for a temporary weakening to $2.792%2 on October 24.
At the month end American-account sterling was quoted
at $2.79%. Discounts on three and six months’ ster­
ling were narrowed by short covering, in a rather erratic
forward market, from 3 5/16 and 5 Vs cents on October 3
and 4, respectively, to 2 and 3% on October 9. Subse­
quently the discounts widened, and on October 31 stood
at 2Va and 32%2 cents.
Buying by sugar interests, and to some extent by cen­
tral banks, firmed the transferable-sterling quotation from
$2.7735 on October 1 to $2.7815 on October 9. After
easing somewhat, the rate again turned upward as Euro­
pean interests sought to cover short positions and by mid­
month reached $2.7845, the highest quotation since May
1956. On October 18, as Middle East tension rose, trans­
ferable sterling weakened to $2.7780 but recovered to
$2.7830 by the month end. The securities-sterling mar­
ket was relatively quiet during the month; the quotations,

THE NEW YORK FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET

The need for a foreign exchange market in the United
States arises from the simple fact that some American
firms and individuals receive foreign exchange in payment
for goods, services, and assets sold abroad, while others
make payments to foreigners in foreign money rather than
in dollars. Converting foreign exchange into dollars, or
dollars into foreign exchange, is essentially a banking
function. Most transactions in foreign exchange through­
out the United States are consequently handled by com­
mercial banks, and most commercial banks are equipped
to service customer requirements in foreign exchange,
either directly or through their large correspondents. But
like most other nation-wide financial markets, the market
in foreign exchange needs one center, where the net bal­
ance of supply or demand can ultimately be reflected and
where, by the action of what appears to be a centripetal
force in the natural law of financial markets, the bulk of
the large transactions will actually occur. In foreign ex­
change, as in all money market instruments, in Govern­
ment securities of all maturities, in listed equity securities,
and in over-the-counter trading of debt or equity instru­
ments, that center is located in New York City.
The foreign exchange market, like these other principal
financial markets, is continually changing. It has not
grown in volume or diversity of activity, however, in pro­
portion to the growing importance of the dollar as a world
currency, particularly as an international reserve cur­
rency. This is at least partly because the very impor­
tance of the dollar throughout the world has resulted in a
much greater expansion of activity abroad, in other foreign
exchange centers, where the dollar is sought as one of the




after fluctuating between $2.71Vi and $2.731/4, moved to
$2.74V^ on October 31.
During the first week of October, commercial demand
for United States dollars in Canada and European sales
of Canadian dollars weakened the Canadian dollar quota­
tion approximately % cent to the $1.03 level for the first
time since early November 1956. Thereafter, London
buying of Canadian dollars reappeared in the market
which, together with buying on grain account and short
covering, moved the rate upward. Additional strength
came from the demand for Canadian dollars associated
with the auction of oil leases and the commercial offerings
of United States dollars in Canada. During the closing
days of the month the Canadian dollar reached $1.04Vs.
The French franc continues to be quoted at about
$0.00232 (approximately 420 francs = U.S. $1) in
the New York market. On October 28 the French foreign
exchange arrangements introduced on August 10 were
revised to provide that the 20 per cent surtax on foreign
exchange purchases and the 20 per cent premium on for­
eign exchange sales be made applicable to those transac­
tions not hitherto subject to them.
world’s “hardest” currencies. Nonetheless, the world posi­
tion of the New York foreign exchange market is a central
and critical one. In a broad sense, this market is a mirror
reflecting the complex of economic, political, and psycho­
logical forces that lie behind the United States balance of
payments with the rest of the world, as well as the interre­
lations among foreign countries that hold and use dollars
in making international settlements.
This article will not be primarily concerned, however,
with the underlying forces that are constantly being re­
flected in this market. It will instead attempt to describe
the market itself, as it is now functioning. Attention here
centers on the organization of the market and the principal
instruments in which it deals. A second article for publi­
cation in this Review will carry the description further
into the mechanics and techniques of trading and the
day-by-day determination of foreign exchange rates in the
New York market.
T h e B a sis

of the

F o r e ig n E x c h a n g e M a r k e t

If all United States trade and payments abroad were
carried out in terms of dollars, there would be no need
for a foreign exchange market in New York since there
would be neither an American demand for foreign ex­
change nor any supplies of foreign exchange in American
hands. There would, of course, be a lively supply of and
demand for dollars in foreign exchange markets abroad.
This would be reflected on the books of New York banks
by the many transfers of dollars among foreign accounts.
Dollars earned by foreign exporters, for example, would
flow to the accounts of their banks, and dollars paid by
foreign importers of dollar products would flow out of the

A T esting P eriod

for

M onetary P olicy

Remarks of Alfred Hayes, President, Federal Reserve Bank of New York
at a Luncheon of the Bond Club of New York, October 16, 1957

The Bond Club of New York is an audience which I
feel especially privileged to address. I can think of few
groups who are as well qualified as you to take an under­
standing interest in the activities and policies of the
Federal Reserve System. For while our operations neces­
sarily affect the country’s whole economy, their impact is
especially prompt and direct in the New York financial
community. For our own part, we rely heavily on the
efficiency of this community to carry out our open market
operations, and we depend to a great extent on our con­
tacts with this community for an appraisal of money and
capital market conditions, which is of course a crucial
part of the considerations affecting the System’s policy
decisions. It seems to me fitting that I should express to
you on this occasion the System’s gratitude for your in­
valuable cooperation in these activities, as well as for the
strong moral support you have given us in our efforts to
pursue effective monetary policies.
I suppose that the subject you would most like me to
talk about is how we in the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York appraise current conditions, and how our policies
are influenced by this appraisal. I cannot, of course, go
all the way in responding, nor can I presume to speak
for all my colleagues throughout the Federal Reserve
System, but I do want to use this opportunity to talk with
you about some of the problems—here and abroad—that
make this an interesting testing period for the usefulness
of monetary policy.
Since so much has been written and spoken recently
about current business, perhaps you will forgive me if I
try merely to touch a few of the highlights. It seems clear
that the boom of the past two-and-a-half years has lost
much of its strong upward momentum, with private capi­
tal outlays and Federal Government expenditures leveling
out and perhaps commencing a decline—yet the decline
in capital expenditures should be modest, and we are all
hearing many public expressions of doubt, enhanced by
recent developments in outer space, as to whether the
proposed cut in defense spending can or should actually
be attained. Exports, which contributed much more than
was generally recognized to aggregate demand in 1956
and early 1957, are beginning to show the adverse effects




of payments difficulties in many foreign countries. Inven­
tory accumulation is no longer adding force to the boom
in any significant degree.
Although industrial production as a whole has been
stationary, for all practical purposes, for about a year,
the total national product continues to rise slowly, even
in physical terms. There is no doubt that business over all
is still extremely good, as evidenced by such measures as
high employment and personal incomes, and record figures
for retail sales. And there appears to be some further
upward thrust in State and local government expenditures,
to mention one of the expanding sectors.
But there are enough “soft spots” and doubts as to
future demand to have caused a good deal of uneasiness
among businessmen and economists as to where the econ­
omy is going next. It would seem that the greatest change
in the last two or three months has been not in business
statistics, which on the whole have changed very little,
but in business sentiment, which has deteriorated appre­
ciably and has been reflected in the declining trend of
stock prices since early summer. This change of senti­
ment may not last, but to my mind it is a healthy develop­
ment, if held within reasonable limits, after the rampant
optimism of a few months ago.
Meanwhile, what has been happening to commodity
prices? The wholesale index has stopped rising, and basic
commodities as a group have dropped rather sharply. The
index of consumer prices, on the other hand, continues
its slow and seemingly inexorable rise, primarily because
of increasing prices for services and for food products,
and perhaps also reflecting with the usual lag the upward
movement of wholesale prices that occurred some months
ago. Important wage negotiations are due next year, and
if the past gives any indication of the future, industry will
again be under pressure to grant wage increases in excess
of productivity gains. While we may derive some satisfac­
tion and hope from the slowing-down of the price rise, it
is certainly far too early to say that the danger of inflation
is past.
Another area we might consider for a moment is that
of the demand for and supply of funds. Corporate and
municipal bond offerings have been at record levels this

year, and the calendar for such issues, as you gentlemen
are well aware, is still heavy. To some extent these offer­
ings have enabled borrowers to repay old bank loans or
to avoid new ones. At any rate, total bank loans have
risen much less sharply than a year ago. On the other
hand, the Treasury’s difficulties in the way of attrition and
Savings bond redemptions, while helping to provide funds
for the corporate and municipal markets, have also put
heavy pressure on the banks as underwriters for the
Treasury. A new factor is the prospective shift in the
financing of defense procurement contracts from the
Treasury to the banks, which will reduce the need for
Treasury borrowing but increase the demand for loans.
This demand, however, will develop gradually over a
period of months, at least insofar as actual drawings are
concerned.
The banks, especially those in the chief money centers,
are a good deal less liquid than they were a year ago.
Consequently, in spite of the slowing-down in the growth
of bank loans, the banks in general feel that money is
about as tight as it has been at any time in recent years.
In contrast, the bond market, which is so sensitive to
expectations, as well as to current money conditions, has
shown some signs of stabilizing, or even strengthening, in
recent weeks. And there have also been encouraging
signs suggesting that personal savings may have grown
appreciably over the last few months.
The policy of the Federal Reserve System has been to
respond to the conditions outlined above with continued
steady restraint on bank reserves. I think that in some
quarters there have been misconceptions as to this policy.
Contrary to some impressions, we have made no attempt
to force liquidation of outstanding credit or to interfere
with the normal flow of savings into industrial plant and
equipment, new homes, or public projects. We have been
accused in recent months of intensifying our policy of
restricting the availability of credit, and for evidence the
finger is pointed at the summer rise in interest rates, in­
cluding the Vi per cent increase in the discount rate of
all the Reserve Banks. Basically it was not so much
Federal Reserve policy as the continuing excess of record
money demands over available savings, which caused in­
terest rates to go on rising. By refusing to provide the
reserves required for a sizable increase in the quantity
of money, we of course contributed to the pressure—but
when the demand for money continues to increase, inter­
est rates tend to continue to rise, even if our action con­
sists only in limiting the increases in the supply. We have
not intended and do not now intend to intensify pressures
in the money market, and the way in which during August
the discount rates of the various Reserve Banks followed
the increases in market rates, rather than leading them,
should have demonstrated this pretty clearly.




Incidentally, I should like to stress that no single statis­
tical series can give an adequate measure of the degree of
real tightness in the money and capital markets. There is
always grave danger of reading too much significance into
changes in the week-to-week level of net borrowed reserves
without giving enough attention to other factors such as
the various market rates of interest themselves, the geo­
graphical distribution of reserves, the concentration of
money market pressures evidenced by the financing prob­
lems of the Government securities dealers, and, more
generally, the “feel” of the market—including your own
evaluation of the supply-demand factors in the capital
market.
I hope you agree that it would be a great mistake to
relax credit restraint just as we see some hope of achieving
the price stability that we have all sought so ardently. The
moderate excess capacities that have appeared in several
industries, no doubt at least partly as a result of the recent
vast capital expenditures, are the best ally we could have
in seeking this goal. They should permit the normal forces
of competition to become increasingly effective and to put
a check to further price increases. Profits may be squeezed
somewhat in the process, but ultimately such a sequence
of events should not be without a restraining effect on fur­
ther wage boosts that cannot be absorbed through in­
creases in productivity.
While there have been many complaints of the uneven
impact of our policies on specific segments of the economy,
the fact remains that the country has continued to enjoy
high levels of prosperity. So long as the economy could
not do everything that all of us were trying to make it do,
all at once, there had to be some restraint somewhere.
There should have been no serious concern when the
effects of such restraint actually became visible. The only
serious question would have been whether the impact was
distributed in a manner that was arbitrary and out of
keeping with the market processes of a free economy. On
that score, I suggest that the record is about as good as
frail human beings could hope for. Moreover, while we
may not have succeeded fully in checking inflation, we
seem to be achieving at least partial success. There are
growing signs of public awareness of the inflation threat
and encouraging signs of disbelief on the part of the public
in the theory that creeping inflation is either desirable or
inevitable. Monetary policy cannot take all the credit,
but it deserves some of the credit.
It has often been said in the last year or two that mone­
tary policy has been going through a difficult testing
period. It is true that it has, and I am not sure that the
most difficult test is over. Perhaps too much of the re­
sponsibility for combating inflation has been placed on
monetary policy. It has had some help from fiscal policy,

but the budget surplus would have been a good deal more
helpful if it had been larger. Similarly, debt management
problems might have involved less difficulty both for the
Treasury and for the Federal Reserve if the Treasury had
not had to make such frequent trips to the market. That
frequency, of course, was partly a by-product of the debt
limit, as well as of the size of the cash surplus.
The “capital investment boom” has been held partly
responsible for the inflationary pressures of the past year
or two, but we are now beginning to benefit from the
effects of the enormous investment in new plant facilities
over this period. Some degree of statesmanship on the
part of labor and management will still be a necessary
ingredient if the specter of creeping inflation is to be laid
completely. However, I see no reason to accept the de­
featist argument that the only alternative to creeping infla­
tion is serious recession and unemployment.
Naturally we are gratified by the degree of public
acceptance attained by Federal Reserve policies. But we
don’t know whether the tendency for wage settlements to
outrun productivity gains will persist in spite of our steady
credit restraint, or whether the cry for relaxation of tight
money will be overwhelming if unused resources tend to
increase. Premature easing of credit conditions might
well nullify such results as we have already achieved in
checking inflation. We may face difficult decisions in the
year that lies ahead, and I hope we shall continue to re­
ceive your moral support as long as you believe that we
are on the right track.
The Federal Reserve System has had to concentrate so
much attention on the insidious problem of inflation in the
last year or two that we may have given the impression
that we are unaware of any other problems, real or poten­
tial. Such an impression would be wrong. Our policies
must always be framed with a view to the dangers of
recession as well as those of inflation—but the emphasis
necessarily varies with the current environment. Our
directives from Congress are couched in pretty general
terms, and there is wide room for judgment in deciding
how best to gear our actions to the general objective of
sustained economic growth—how much weight to give to
price developments and how much to signs of greater
availability of unused resources. I think we are fully aware
that the time may come when it will be necessary and
appropriate to follow an entirely different policy from that
of the last two-and-a-half years. For example, if the up­
ward trend of prices is stopped, or if the pressure for funds
becomes substantially less than it is now in relation to
available savings, or if we should be faced with a substan­
tial increase in unused resources of labor and materials,
some change of policy would be logical either in intensity
or in direction. The occasion for any major move may be




some distance ahead of us, and I am making no attempt
at a prediction. But we must be as careful to avoid
“overstaying” our market as to avoid premature ease of
credit. There is always some doubt as to how quick and
effective an easing of credit may be in remedying a down­
ward turn in the economy, if the turn reflects a need for
fundamental economic readjustments. I merely want to
emphasize that we understand that at times a central bank
may have to work the other side of the street—and that we
also understand that we don’t know all the answers, that
each business cycle differs greatly from all that have gone
before, and that we must always approach our task in
all humility.
Up to this point my comments have dealt almost
exclusively with the domestic situation. Now a few words
on the international outlook. The American economy now
plays such a key role in the world economy that the level
of our activity affects people everywhere.
All of us who are interested in the achievement of stable
and durable trading and investment relationships among
the countries of the world must have felt satisfaction in the
results of the recent annual meetings in Washington of
the International Monetary Fund and the International
Bank. In addition to exceptionally able exposition of
guiding principles by the heads of the world organizations,
the meetings were notable for the unequivocal statements
by the British and German Governments of their deter­
mination to maintain the present par values of the pound
and the Deutsche mark. Already there are signs that this
determined attitude, which is further underlined by the
British program announced a few days before the meet­
ings, has borne fruit in the form of a cessation of the
heavy speculative flow of funds which had tended to cause
concern about various European currencies. The under­
lying trade and payments statistics, while pointing to some
imbalance, especially in the matter of a powerfully favor­
able German position, were never the chief difficulty. Now
that the speculative wave has receded, it would appear that
the margin of imbalance is relatively small and that
appropriate monetary and fiscal measures can restore a
balanced position for most of the chief trading countries.
The crucial factor will be their ability to cope with their
internal problems, which in most countries are mainly
problems of inflation induced by excessive spending, both
public and private. There are now encouraging signs of
success in the curbing of such spending. Some of the less
developed countries have the additional problem of foreign
exchange earnings diminishing with the declining prices
of the primary commodities which they export. These
price declines admittedly increase the difficulties of the
primary-producing countries, but we should bear in mind
that neither these countries nor the world as a whole would
benefit in the long run from a departure by any of the

leading trading nations from a general program aimed
at orderly and sustainable growth free of inflationary
excesses.
There have been a number of comments recently on the
potential danger to this country of our sizable outstanding
short-term liabilities to foreign banks, corporations, and
individuals, in the sense that their sudden liquidation could
cause a heavy drain on our monetary gold stock. It has
always seemed to me that these fears have been exagger­
ated. The growth of these foreign-held dollar balances is
really the most convincing evidence we could have of the
strength of the dollar and the confidence of foreigners in it.
The rest of the free world has, to a considerable degree,
willingly made us its banker. We assume this role with
assurance because we are ourselves confident of our
economic and financial strength, and are aware of the
advantages both to ourselves and to foreigners of the
development of our market as the world’s largest interna­
tional money market. A very large part of these claims on
us constitute official monetary reserves on which the
foreign country in question is glad to earn a return, in
contrast with unproductive holdings of gold. Also, a large
part consists of private working balances which are in­
dispensable to the conduct of business between the United
States and other important trading countries. But the main
safeguard against a sudden large withdrawal in gold lies
in the powerful attraction which American products have
for many foreign countries, and in our enormous capacity
to export those products.




As an exporter we are at a great advantage because
our exports, though large in absolute terms, are still rela­
tively small in proportion to our total capacity to produce,
and can be expanded without impinging too greatly on
domestic consumption. Also, the American economy is
self-sufficient to a high degree so that our exports can
expand without requiring a corresponding rise in imports.
These factors were pointedly demonstrated by last winter’s
Suez crisis, the effect of which was to cause foreign coun­
tries to draw down their balances not in gold but in
American industrial and agricultural products. We took
this sudden increase in the demand for our goods in our
stride. We can best ensure our continued capacity to
export by preventing inflationary forces in this country
from putting our goods at a competitive disadvantage.
They are not now at a disadvantage, nor do they seem
likely to be.
To my mind, the holding of large balances for foreign
account is a normal part of the functioning of our interna­
tional monetary system. It is not only to our great benefit,
but a part of our growing world responsibilities, to make
this system work smoothly and efficiently. Of course, there
are some risks, but there is no country better able to
assume them. Moreover, if we manage our affairs so as
to maintain a sound and stable dollar, the risks will be
small.
Thank you for your courtesy in giving me a welcome
chance to talk to you.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

accounts of foreign banks here and into the bank accounts
of our own exporters.
No strict rules can be laid down to account for the
varying proportion of United States payments to and from
individual countries that is made in foreign exchange,
but the factors involved include the relative economic
importance of different countries, the strength of their cur­
rencies, the custom of the trade in certain commodity
transactions, the existence of exchange controls in many
countries, and the relative stage of development of bank­
ing and financial institutions abroad.
With a large number of countries United States trade
is carried out almost entirely in dollars; with others, such
as the United Kingdom, parts of the sterling area, some
Continental countries, and Canada, a much higher percent­
age is conducted in foreign exchange. In addition to ex­
change transactions arising from trade, there is often a
need for foreign exchange to finance United States direct
investment abroad, and to make remittances to foreign
countries, while fairly large amounts of foreign exchange
are required by United States tourists traveling abroad.
A large number of American firms and individuals are
thus involved in one way or another with some form of
foreign exchange activity. An American exporter of
tobacco, for example, may sell in Britain for sterling, while
a wool importer may need sterling to make payment for
wool to be imported from Australia. An American firm
may need Canadian dollars to expand the operations
of its branch in Canada, while at the same time another
firm may be anxious to dispose of Canadian dollars earned
from a sale to a Canadian importer. Since it would be
extremely difficult for each importer who needed foreign
exchange to search out an individual exporter who had the
proper amount of exchange for sale, the foreign exchange
market provides a medium through which these needs can
be easily met. Of course, some large international firms
are able to use, in their operations abroad, foreign ex­
change that they may have earned in other transactions,
and they consequently may be partially independent of
the market.
O r g a n iz a t io n

of the

M arket

The New York foreign exchange market can be broadly
described as a three-tiered market. At the heart of the
market lies the trading between the banks and their com­
mercial customers who are the ultimate users and suppliers
of foreign exchange. In New York there are approximately
twenty-five banks that maintain deposits abroad to facili­
tate their dealings in foreign exchange, although the bulk
of the business is accounted for by less than half that
number. There are also about thirty-five agencies of for­
eign banks which sometimes add an international flavor
to the market through their handling of foreign-owned
dollar balances and their close ties to their countries of
origin. In addition, there are a substantial number of spe­
cialized foreign exchange dealers who trade principally in




151

foreign bank notes. The second tier of the market is
represented by the interbank market in foreign exchange
conducted through the foreign exchange brokers, and the
third by the active trading in foreign exchange by New
York banks with banks abroad. The three segments of the
market are so closely interwoven, however, that it is diffi­
cult, if not impossible, to separate them; taken together,
they make up the New York foreign exchange market.
The foreign exchange market, unlike the stock or
commodity exchanges, has no centralized meeting place,
no fixed opening or closing time, and no formal re­
quirements for participation except the informal accept­
ance of a code of financial and moral conduct that has
evolved out of the working of the market itself. It thus
may best be regarded, not as a place, but rather as the
mechanism whereby buyers and sellers of foreign exchange
are brought together. Buyers and sellers do not ordinarily
meet face to face but carry on their trading primarily by
telephone, and also by telegraph, cable, or mail.
The Banks and Their Customers

The commercial banks maintain foreign exchange inven­
tories in the form of working balances with foreign banks,
in order to be in a position to meet the needs of their
customers. These balances are replenished by the pur­
chases of balances owned by firms, individuals, or other
banks; by the sale of dollars to foreign banks that
may, for their own purposes, need additional funds in
New York; and by the purchase of foreign bills of ex­
change, travelers’ checks, dividend warrants, bond cou­
pons, and the like. In order to handle their foreign
exchange business, each of the banks has several traders
who do the actual buying and selling; the trading rooms of
the banks make up, in fact, the nerve center of the foreign
exchange market. In addition, a clerical staff must be
maintained to handle the details of the transactions. The
activities of the foreign exchange traders are closely linked
to the activities of other divisions of the banks’ foreign
departments where import and export letters of credit,
foreign dollar balances, bills drawn on foreigners, and
other transactions with foreigners are handled.
In the course of a day’s trading activities the banks
purchase foreign exchange from some of their commercial
customers and sell exchange to others. Purchases of course
can be used to offset sales, so that each bank is to some
extent a clearing house where liabilities to foreigners and
claims on foreigners are matched up. Some of the banks,
however, will find that their purchases from exporters are
exceeding their sales to importers, while other banks will
find themselves in the opposite position. Since the banks
do not ordinarily care to tie up their resources by main­
taining unnecessarily large foreign exchange balances, and
since they obviously cannot sell what they do not have,
there has grown up an active market in foreign exchange
among the banks in New York. This market has some­
times been referred to as the “wholesale” market in foreign

152

MONTHLY REVIEW, NOVEMBER 1957

exchange, since trades are ordinarily for fairly large
amounts and in round numbers. This picture of the
interbank market as a wholesale market should not be
taken to mean, however, that transactions with a commer­
cial customer may not on occasion be for a considerably
larger amount than can be covered in a single transaction
in the interbank market.
The Banks and the Brokers

The New York banks do not deal directly with one
another but use the services of foreign exchange brokers.
There are at present eight such brokers in New York,
compared with about forty-five in the 1930’s when the
leading currencies of the world were freely convertible and
the exchange market was, as a result, much more active.
Some of these brokers tend to specialize in certain ex­
changes, but all of them handle the leading currencies
such as the pound sterling, the Canadian dollar, and the
Swiss franc. The brokers are not required to meet any
formal or legal requirements in order to operate, nor do
they assume any financial responsibility for the transac­
tions which they carry out as agents for the banks. Com­
petition among the brokers is keen, and a broker’s chief
assets are the skill with which he can carry out operations
for the banks and the degree of confidence that the banks
feel they can place in him.
The brokers have direct telephone connections with the
foreign exchange trading rooms of the leading commercial
banks, and are in almost constant contact with the bank
traders. Their primary function is to bring together buyers
and sellers among the banks, thus enabling the latter to
even out their positions. For each transaction that they
arrange among the banks, they receive a commission from
the selling bank. Use of a broker saves the banks both
time and effort. When a bank wants to either buy or sell,
it need only inform the broker of the amount it is inter­
ested in and the exchange rate at which it is willing to do
business. The broker then undertakes the matching-up of
the bank’s bid or offer in the market, while the bank
traders are left free to concentrate on their commercial
business.
The interbank exchange market is thus the mechanism
whereby excessive purchases or sales of foreign exchange
made by individual banks are ironed out. On many occa­
sions, however, the amount of sterling, for example, offered
for sale by commercial or other interests in the New York
market will exceed the demand, while on other occasions
the opposite will be true. The first thing that results from
this normal sort of imbalance is that the exchange rate
begins to move, rising if the exchange is in good demand
and falling if supplies are heavy. These movements them­
selves may help to correct the imbalance by encouraging
or discouraging the entrance of additional buyers or sellers
into the market. The banks too may offset, but usually
only within narrow limits, such imbalances by adding to
or drawing down their own exchange balances.




Trading with Foreign Banks

A third, and very important, method of correcting
supply and demand imbalances in the New York market
is by the purchase of foreign exchange from, or sale to,
foreign banks by the New York banks. Foreign banks,
operating in their own exchange markets abroad, are of
course active dealers in United States dollars, which are,
for them, a very important form of foreign exchange. The
activities of foreign central banks and exchange authori­
ties are of particular importance in these markets. Enter­
ing the market as both buyers and sellers, ordinarily
to prevent excessive swings in the exchange rate, they are
an ever-present factor and at times may be the most
important single element in the market. If a foreign bank
needs dollars to meet the requirements of its customers,
and if the currency of its country is actively traded in New
York, it may in the normal course of its operations offer
its currency to a New York bank in exchange for dollars.
Similarly, excess purchases of dollars by a foreign bank
from its customers may lead it to offer dollars to New
York banks, i.e., to demand foreign exchange in the New
York market. The initiative for such bank trading between
international centers may originate from either the United
States or the foreign side, and there is an almost constant
exchange of telephone calls, cables, and teletype messages
among the banks in leading centers. Through the relations
of New York banks with their foreign branches and cor­
respondents the New York foreign exchange market is
thus closely linked with exchange markets abroad.
The Combined Market

It should not be thought, however, that trading in the
New York market follows a neat and orderly pattern
whereby New York banks first trade with their commercial
customers, then utilize the: interbank market to dispose
of any net accumulation of exchange, or to make up any
deficiency, and finally have recourse to their foreign
branches and correspondents if they are not successful in
meeting their needs in New York. In actual practice,
everything happens at once. Each bank trader is con­
fronted by a constant flow of offers of, and bids for, foreign
exchange not only from commercial interests, but also
from other banks through the interbank market and by
cable from foreign banks. As he sells exchange he must
buy in order to make delivery, and as he buys he must
sell in order not to accumulate balances. And through it
all the exchange rate (the price of the commodity in which
he deals) is being pushed first one way, then the other,
by the changing balance of all the forces that make up
supply and demand in the market. The manner in which
the foreign exchange traders try to steer a straight course
through these constantly changing tides provides a large
part of the fascination of the market for its participants
and much of its mystery for the layman.
In addition to servicing the foreign exchange needs of
the New York area, the New York market serves as the

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

foreign exchange center of the United States as a whole.
There is some exchange activity in other cities such as
Boston, Chicago, Philadelphia, and San Francisco, where
certain banks maintain balances of their own with foreign
banks. Trading is hampered in these centers, however, by
the absence of foreign exchange brokers and by a smaller
volume of commercial exchange turnover. These banks
must consequently come to New York to meet some of
their foreign exchange needs, either by dealing directly
with their New York correspondents or by using the facili­
ties of the New York exchange brokers. The much larger
number of inland banks that do not maintain foreign
exchange balances abroad or large foreign departments of
their own are also able to provide their local customers
with foreign exchange facilities through their correspond­
ent relations with the New York banks.
T he M arket

f o r I n d iv id u a l

C u r r e n c ie s

In order for an active market in a foreign currency
to exist there must be both adequate sources of supply
of that currency and active demand. The supply and
demand need not originate entirely in the country where
the market is located, however, since a demand for dollars
in London, for example, is quickly translated into a
supply of sterling in New York through the highly effi­
cient communications systems that link the leading finan­
cial centers of the world. For the major currencies
traded in the New York market, such as the pound
sterling and the Canadian dollar, the exchange market is
such a two-way street. Trading in sterling in the New
York market does not merely represent the supply of, and
demand for, sterling by Americans, but reflects the manysided relationships between the pound and the dollar
throughout the world.
For some of the less important currencies, however,
which are not used in world trade, there is little possibility
of an active market in New York. While New York
banks do not maintain balances in such currencies, they
can nevertheless offer almost any currency in the world
for sale to their customers. They can do this because banks
in nearly all countries abroad maintain dollar balances
with American banks, and the New York banks are able
to obtain any of these currencies by dollar credits to these
accounts at either fixed or negotiated rates of exchange.
The Pound Sterling

The pound sterling is by far the most actively traded
currency in the New York market. While there are no
published figures, the volume of business transacted annu­
ally amounts to several billion dollars, and undoubtedly
exceeds the turnover of all other currencies combined. It
is probably impossible to compare directly the volume of
dollar business in the London foreign exchange market
with the volume of sterling business in New York, partly
indeed because of the very close links between the two
markets. It appears, however, that at times the sterling
activity in New York exceeds the dollar activity in London,




153

although the total volume of trading in all types of foreign
exchange must be considerably greater in London because
of that center’s close links with the Continent and the
overseas sterling area.
There are several “types” of sterling traded in the New
York market. These different types arise out of the classi­
fication for British exchange control purposes of foreignowned bank deposits in the United Kingdom, and reflect
the fact that, despite the progress made since the war, the
pound is not yet formally a fully convertible currency.
The market in American-account sterling is by far the most
important, and it is to this market that general references
to the “sterling market” in New York apply.
American-account sterling is simply the name given to
sterling deposits held by residents of the dollar area.1
Credits and debits to these accounts can be freely made for
all current transactions with the sterling area— such as the
purchase or sale of goods and services, profits, and other
remittances—and transfers can also be freely made to
other nonresident sterling accounts. American-account
sterling has always been fully convertible, and can be
exchanged for dollars in either the London or New York
exchange market within the official support limits for
the pound of $2.78 and $2.82. Another type of sterling
fully convertible in the same markets may be held by
nonsterling-area residents outside the dollar area. This is
the so-called registered sterling, which arises out of the sale
of gold or dollars in the London market.
There is a wide assortment of activities that enters into
the New York market for American-account sterling, and
as mentioned earlier the market is equally affected by the
demand for, and supply of, dollars in London. The
American and international oil companies play a particu­
larly important role in the market. At times they are large
suppliers of sterling from their sterling earnings, and on
other occasions they are net buyers of sterling for direct
investment, for royalty or tax payments, or for operational
expenditures in the sterling area. Substantial amounts of
sterling are earned from American sales of tobacco, grain,
a wide variety of manufactured goods, and from profits
and dividends received on American investments in the
sterling area. There is a demand for sterling for purchases
of such sterling-area exports as wool, jute, diamonds, tin,
and copper, for purchases of a wide variety of British
manufactured goods, and for American investment in
Britain or the overseas sterling area. There is also a
lively two-way activity arising out of the exchange of
banking, shipping, insurance, and other services, and from
tourism.
Transferable-account sterling is sterling held by resi­
dents of countries (except Egypt) outside the sterling and
1 According to United Kingdom exchange control regulations,
American-account countries consist of the United States of America
and its dependencies, the Central American and Caribbean republics,
Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, Venezuela, Liberia, and the Philippines.
Canada is classified separately, but Canadian-account sterling is also
fully convertible and can be freely transferred to an American-account.

154

MONTHLY REVIEW, NOVEMBER 1957

dollar areas. It can be freely transferred within that area,
or used for payments to any sterling-area country; it
cannot, however, be transferred to an American account.
Because of the usefulness and acceptability of transferable
sterling throughout so large a portion of the world, there
has grown up an active dollar market for such sterling out­
side the United Kingdom. The central market for trans­
ferable sterling is in Switzerland, but there is active trading
in New York also.
To a considerable extent the New York market in
transferable sterling is an entrepot market where supplies
originating, say, in Latin America can be matched with
demand arising, for example, on the Continent. A few
American exporters have at times been willing to arrange
to receive transferable sterling in payment for exports to
countries outside the dollar area, and there is some
American demand for transferable sterling in order to pay
for shipping or other services. American banks cannot
hold transferable-sterling accounts directly and must carry
out any transactions through branches or correspondents
located in a transferable-account country. At times there
has been a lively demand for transferable sterling by
nonsterling-area residents for the purpose of purchasing
sterling-area raw materials for transshipment and resale in
the United States. Because of the additional cost of trans­
shipment such transactions were only profitable when
transferable sterling was selling at an appreciable discount
from American-account sterling. Since such transship­
ments tended to deprive the sterling area of dollar earnings,
the British have, since February 1955, maintained the
transferable-sterling rate at only a small discount, usually
less than 1 per cent, from the market rate for Americanaccount sterling, and this action appears to have largely
eliminated such transactions.
A third type of sterling traded in the New York market
is securities sterling. Securities sterling arises principally
from the sale of foreign-owned sterling securities in the
London market. The sterling proceeds of such sales cannot
be freely converted into dollars within the official support
limits, but they can be freely sold to other foreigners for
similar investment in securities. Because of the close
link of this kind of sterling to the international securities
markets, a large part of securities-sterling transactions is
in the hands of specialized securities houses in New York.
Since American-account sterling has always been con­
vertible, the dollar markets for transferable and securi­
ties sterling have made the pound sterling, for all practical
purposes, a de facto convertible currency for all foreign
holders, but not at a single rate of exchange. Since both
transferable and securities sterling are more restricted in
their use, they are traded at a discount from the rate for
American-account sterling. Should the United Kingdom
make a move to formal convertibility of all foreign-held
sterling balances, the transferable-sterling market would,
of course, be merged with the market for American


account sterling. This would tend to widen the scope for
trading by New York banks since, for example, a shortage
of sterling in New York could be met by offering dollars
in any of the exchange markets of the world. Should
convertibility be extended to capital as well as current
transactions, the securities-sterling market would likewise
disappear.
The Canadian Dollar and Other Currencies

Next to sterling, the Canadian dollar is the most actively
traded currency in the New York foreign exchange mar­
ket. This is not surprising in view of the large volume
of trade and the close financial and commercial ties be­
tween the two countries. The major feature of the Cana­
dian dollar market in recent years has been the large
demand for Canadian dollars resulting from American
and other foreign investment in Canada. Direct invest­
ment by American firms, purchases of Canadian oil leases,
and the intensive use of the New York money and capital
markets by Canadian corporations and municipalities have
all played an important role in the market. A good part
of the heavy investment in Canada by British and Con­
tinental investors has also passed through the New York
market. Since the market for the Canadian dollar in other
leading international exchange markets is not so broad as
in the New York market, the demand for Canadian dollars
has had to be met partially by offering United States
dollars either in New York or in Montreal or Toronto,
rather than by offering other foreign currencies for the
Canadian dollar directly. On the supply side, the major
source of Canadian dollars has come from Canadian im­
porters, reflecting Canada’s large trade deficit with the
United States.
The bulk of the trading between the United States and
the Canadian dollar takes place in Montreal and Toronto.
This is not surprising, since the greater part of the trade
between the two countries is invoiced in United States
dollars, and there are consequently a greater number of
Canadian firms earning and spending United States dollars
than there are American firms earning and spending
Canadian dollars. New York has established itself, how­
ever, as an integral part of the Canadian dollar market,
and there is a lively competition between the two markets
for the growing volume of business.
Other important currencies traded in the New York
market include the Swiss franc, the German “capital”
mark (the sole means for investment transactions with
Germany), the Dutch guilder, the French franc, the Belgian
franc, the free Brazilian cruzeiro, and the free Argentine
peso. From time to time there may be important transac­
tions in other currencies as well. Trading in none of these
currencies, however, approaches that in the pound or the
Canadian dollar. Should the need or the opportunity arise,
however, the New York foreign exchange market has the
facilities available to expand its trading activities in these
or other currencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK
T h e In st r u m e n t s

of the

M arket

Although the business of the foreign exchange market
is, naturally enough, that of buying and selling foreign
exchange, the latter is not a homogeneous commodity.
Under the term foreign exchange there may be several
different forms of short-term monetary claims on foreign­
ers or on foreign banks expressed in terms of foreign
currencies. What precisely, then, are the instruments that
the banks use when dealing in the market?
Most transactions in the foreign exchange market in­
volve the transfer of a deposit held in a bank abroad. The
major instrument for effecting these transfers in the New
York market, as in other leading exchange markets
throughout the world, is the cable (telegraphic) transfer.
A cable transfer is nothing more than an order sent by
cable to a foreign bank holding an account for the seller
of a particular currency, directing that bank to debit this
account and credit the account of the buyer, or the account
of the person designated by the buyer, with a specified
amount. Thus, a United States exporter or other holder of
a foreign exchange balance of, say, £100,000 might sell
a cable transfer to a bank in New York; i.e., he would
cable his bank in London to transfer £100,000 to the
account of the New York bank, and would receive the
dollar equivalent of £100,000 at the going market rate
from the bank in New York on the same day that the
sterling balance changes hands. If the exporter does not
maintain a sterling account of his own in a London bank,
he might merely cable the British importer from whom
payment is due to make payment to the account of the
New York bank purchasing the exchange. When a New
York bank sells a cable transfer to an importer, it directs
its correspondent in London to transfer the sterling
amount from its account to the account of the importer,
or to the person designated by the importer, and collects
the equivalent amount of dollars from the importer.
The chief advantage of the cable transfer lies in the
speed with which it can be effected. Normally these trans­
fers are completed on the day following their purchase or
sale, but same-day transfers may in some cases be ar­
ranged. This, of course, permits the payment of exchange
abroad to be delayed until very shortly before it is due,
if that is practicable, and also allows a holder of a foreign
exchange balance to sell it and receive dollars almost at
once. In either case, use of the cable transfer avoids the
necessity of tying up funds in foreign exchange, since the
dollar payment for cable transfers is made on the same day
that the foreign exchange is paid out abroad.
The mail transfer is in every respect similar to the cable
transfer, except that the order to the foreign bank to make
the transfer is sent by mail rather than by cable. Before
the almost universal use of air mail, mail transfers usually
commanded a somewhat lower price than cable transfers,
since the seller had the use of his funds abroad until the
mail order arrived. There is now often no difference in the




155

rates quoted by the banks for air mail and for cable
transfers.
In some cases a remitter of funds to someone abroad
may want to make his payment directly to the firm or
individual without going through a foreign bank. In such
cases New York banks sell the remitter a draft on the
banks’ balance abroad. This is, of course, nothing more
than a written order from the New York bank to the bank
holding its account abroad to make a specified payment to
a designated person or firm upon presentation of the draft.
The remitter himself then mails the draft to the beneficiary
abroad, who is able to cash it as he would any other check.
Bills of Exchange

In addition to the trading in bank balances through the
purchase and sale of cable and mail transfers and bank
drafts, there are sometimes available in the market various
types of foreign bills of exchange. A bill of exchange is
defined by the Uniform Negotiable Instruments Act as:
an unconditional order in writing addressed by one person
to another, signed by the person giving it, requiring the
person to whom it is addressed to pay on demand or at a
fixed or determinable future time a sum certain in money to
order or to bearer.

Although the check is a special type of bill of exchange,
the term “bill of exchange” almost always refers to commer­
cial and bankers’ bills and acceptances. In international
trade, commercial bills arise whenever an exporter draws
a draft directly on the foreign importer for the amount of
the export. Bankers’ bills and acceptances arise, for ex­
ample, when an importer arranges a letter of credit with
his bank, under which the exporter draws drafts on the
bank or on one of its correspondents rather than on the
importer, thereby giving the exporter a bank undertaking
that his draft will be honored on presentation. The bills
may be payable on sight or at so many days (30, 60, 90, or
180) after sight. Bills may be “clean”, if the exporter is
willing to turn over title to the goods prior to payment or
acceptance of the draft by the importer, but more usually
they are “documentary”. “Documentary” bills are bills
accompanied by documents (such as bills of lading, in­
voices, shipping and insurance papers, and the like) that
carry title to the merchandise covered by the draft. Sight
drafts must ordinarily be paid, or time drafts accepted, by
the importer (or by his bank if he has arranged a letter
of credit in favor of the exporter) before the documents
carrying title to the goods are released to him.
Bills of exchange may be drawn in terms of dollars or
in terms of foreign currencies, and it is of course the latter
in which the New York foreign exchange market is directly
interested. On the whole, however, there are very few
foreign bills of exchange available in the New York mar­
ket. Checks drawn by foreigners in their own currencies
are not widely used for payment to United States firms and
individuals, except for a fairly substantial volume of
Canadian dollar checks that are bought by the New York
banks for credit to their accounts in Canada. Only a very

156

MONTHLY REVIEW, NOVEMBER 1957

few commercial bills are drawn in terms of foreign ex­
change, and these are almost always in sterling. There are
from time to time a few sterling grain acceptances, but
even these are not always presented to the banks for sale,
since the exporters often prefer to keep them to maturity
(thereby earning the interest on the bills) and then sell the
sterling in the form of a cable transfer. There is a some­
what larger volume of letters of credit that provide for
drafts to be drawn in foreign currencies, and there are
consequently some sterling and other bills drawn on for­
eign banks that are from time to time offered to the New
York banks by American exporters, and some demand for
foreign exchange by importers to meet maturing bills.
Most bills of exchange drawn in connection with United
States imports and exports are denominated in dollars,
and affect the New York foreign exchange market only
indirectly. Checks drawn in United States dollars are also
used fairly frequently by United States firms and individu­
als to make payments abroad, particularly for small pur­

chases or remittances. There is little doubt, consequently,
that the dollar bill of exchange is of greater importance
as an instrument in foreign exchange markets abroad than
is the foreign bill of exchange in the New York market.
Foreign activity in the New York bankers’ acceptance
market is one indication of this importance. Not only do
foreign banks use the bankers’ acceptance market to
acquire dollars to meet temporary dollar needs from time
to time, but a very large proportion of outstanding dollar
acceptances is held for foreign account. The sizable
volume of dollar-denominated bills of exchange, some
payable by foreigners to Americans and some by Ameri­
cans to foreigners, makes up a part of the total supply
and demand for dollars in exchange markets abroad. In
those cases where the foreign exchange markets are closely
linked, however, changes in the volume and composition
of these dollar instruments may be reflected in changes in
the supply of, and demand for, foreign currencies in the
New York foreign exchange market as well.

SELECTED ECONOMIC INDICATORS
United States and Second Federal R eserve D istrict
1957
Item

September
U N IT E D STATES
Production and trade
Industrial production*................................................................................
Electric power output*...............................................................................
Ton-m iles of railway freight*..................................................................
M anufacturers’ sales*.................................................................................
Manufacturers’ inventories*....................................................................
M anufacturers’ new orders, to tal*.......................................................
Manufacturers’ new orders, durable goods*....................................
R esidential construction contracts*.....................................................
N onresidential construction contracts*..............................................
Prices, wages, and employment
Personal income (annual rate)*.............................................................
Composite index of wages and salaries*............................................
Nonagricultural em ploym ent*................................................................
M anufacturing em ploym ent*............................... .................................
Average hours worked per week, manufacturing f ........................
Banking and finance
Total investm ents of all commercial banks......................................
Total loans of all commercial banks....................................................
Total demand deposits adjusted............................................................
Currency outside the Treasury and Federal Reserve Banks*. .
V elocity of demand deposits (337 centers)*....................................
Consumer instalm ent credit outstanding t . .. • ........................
United States Government finance (other than borrowing)
N ational defense exp en d itu res..............................................................
SEC O ND F E D E R A L R ESER V E D IST R IC T
Electric power output (New York and N ew Jersey)*.....................
Consumer prices (New York C ity )t.........................................................
Bank debits (Second D istrict excluding N ew York C ity )* ...........
Velocity of demand deposits (New York C ity )*................................

1956

Unit

1947-49 = 100
1947-49 =>100
1947-49 = 100
billions of $
billions of $
billions of $
billions of $
billions of $
1947-49 = 100
1947-49 =* 100
1947-49 = 100
1947-49 = 100
1947-49 = 100
billions of $
1947-49 = 100
thousands
thousands
hours
thousands
thousands
millions of $
millions of $
millions of $
millions of $
millions of $
1947-49 = 100
millions of $
millions of $
millions of $
millions of $
1947-49 = 100
1947-49 = 100
1947-49 = 100
1947-49 = 100
thousands
thousands
millions of $
millions of $
1947-49 = 100
1947-49 = 100
1947-49 = 100

August

144p

July

Percentage change

Latest month Latest month
previous from year
September frommonth
earlier

145
231
104p
28.2 p
28.6
54.2
54. Ip
27 .3
2 6 .8p
13.2
12.7 p
16.7 p
17.0
—
n.a.
—
246
8 7 .3
89 .3
118.4
11 8.Op
121.1
121.0
3 4 6 .5p
346.8
—
157p
52,682p
52 ,870p
16,692p
16,844p
40. Op
40 .0
2,380
2,317
2,552
2,609
72,620p
72,760p
9 2 ,880p
9 3 ,400p
1 0 5,llO p
105,480p
3 1 ,112p
31,128
83,608
81,281
148.1
146.3
33,159
33,045
8,115
7,104
7,404
6,647
4,402
3,223

144
233
99
29 .0
54.1
27 .3
13.0
17.0
n.a.
252
90 .2
118.2
120.8
346.2
157
52,815
16,880
39 .7
2,687
3,007
7 2 ,740p
9 2 ,360p
106, 570p
31,147
86,073
149.4
32,699
3,615
7,092
4,194

144r
219
109
27.1
5 0 .8
2 6 .8
13 .0
15.9
250
251
91 .6
115.5
117.1
331.1
151r
52,148
16,874
40 .7
1,998
n.a.
73,550
88,480
106,700
30,772
73,717
135.8
30,707
6,877
5,649
3,265

- 1
- 1
+ 5
- 1
#
+ 2
- 4
- 2
n.a.
- 2
- 2
#
#
f
#4
— 1
#
- 3
- 2
#
+ 1
#
#
- 3
+ 1
#
+ 14
-1 0
-2 7

#
+ 7
+ 1
+ 4
+ 6
#
- 2
+ 5
n.a.
- 4
~ 5
+ 2
+ 3
+ 5
+ 5
+ 1
- 1
- 2
+ 16
n.a.
- 1
+ 6
- 1
+ 1
+ 10
+ 9
+ 8
+ 18
+ 18
- 1

163
n.a.
n.a.
118.7
7 ,8 1 0 .8
2 ,6 3 0 .9
75,175
5,272
197.3
128
134

159
n.a.
n.a.
118.4
7 ,8 3 0 .7
2 ,6 5 5 .3
77,614
5,507
193.9
120
136

152
186
244
115.1
7 ,8 2 8 .3
2 ,6 7 8 .9
63,774
4,722
166.8
120
121r

+ 3
n.a.
n.a.
#
#
- 1
_ 2
_ 2f
- 9
- 1

+ 7
n.a.
n.a.
+ 3
- 1
- 2
+ 16
+ 12
+ 16
- 4
+ 10

—

—

—
—
118.3
7 ,7 8 1 .4p
2,6 1 3 .6 p
73,909
5,274
194.3
115
133

Note: Latest data available as of noon, November 1, 1957.
t»
p Preliminary.
r Revised.
t N ew basis. Under a new Census Bureau definition, persons laid off temporarily and those
n.a. N ot available.
waiting to begin new jobs within thirty days are classified as unemployed; formerly these
* Adjusted for seasonal variation.
persons were considered as employed. Both series will be published during 1957.
t Seasonal variations believed to be minor; no adjustment made.
# Change of less than 0 .5 per cent.
Source: A description of these series and their sources is available from the Dom estic Research Division, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, on request.