View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

111

T he Business Situation

Economic activity continues to move higher but pos­
sibly at a somewhat slower pace than earlier in the year.
Growth in production and income was more moderate dur­
ing April, and total employment eased off slightly, resulting
in some relaxation of the extreme tightness that prevailed
in the labor markets during the winter months. And, for
the third consecutive month, new housing starts were be­
low the exceptionally high rate recorded earlier in the year.
On the other hand, new orders received by durables manu­
facturers surged to a record in April and auto sales in May
recovered a bit from the slow pace set during the winter
months. Thus, while the recent business statistics appear
to have been balanced on the softer side, it is too early to
conclude that the rate of economic growth is slowing suffi­
ciently to ease the upward thrust of prices. The April rise
in consumer prices was again huge, and preliminary data
for May indicate a further large overall gain in whole­
sale commodity prices even though the industrial com­
ponent rose only moderately.
O U T P U T , IN V E N T O R IE S, A N D
C O N S T R U C T IO N A C T IV IT Y

Industrial activity expanded further in April though by
a considerably smaller margin than in the previous two
months. The Federal Reserve Board’s index of industrial
production reached 171.5 percent of the 1957-59 average,
up 0.3 percent from the March level. Output grew at
about twice that rate in the two preceding months. How­
ever, the April slowing of overall output was chiefly due to
sharply curtailed activity in the automobile industry which
was hit by strikes during the month. Auto assemblies fell
by more than 9 percent to a seasonally adjusted annual
rate of 7.7 million units, substantially below the 8.4 mil­
lion production level originally scheduled for the month.
Output of business and defense equipment and of mate­
rials rose strongly in April, and there were sizable ad­
vances in the steel, coal, and petroleum industries. Produc­
tion of household furniture and consumer nondurables
also increased, but the sharp drop in auto assemblies re­
sulted in a modest decline— the first since last November
—in the aggregate output of goods for consumer markets.




Despite the continuation of strikes in the auto industry,
auto assemblies in May were at an annual rate of 7.6
million units, down only slightly from the April figure, and
the tentative June schedule points to a pace of 8.8 million
units. Dealer inventories of new cars have recently declined
from their record March levels, partly as a result of the
strikes and partly because the pace of new car sales has
become a bit livelier. In May, dealer sales of domesticmodel cars were at a seasonally adjusted annual rate of
8.5 million units, up 4.3 percent from April.
Another development pointing to near-term strength in
industrial production was a very sharp $1.3 billion April
increase in the volume of new orders placed with durable
goods manufacturers. This increase, which may have re­
flected some anticipation of the repeal of the 7 percent
investment tax credit requested by President Nixon on
April 21, brought the month’s new orders to a record
$31.0 billion. A large part of the gain was in orders placed
for transportation equipment, but an expanded orders
volume was also reported by the other major sectors of
durables manufacturing. Shipments rose very little in April,
and as a result the backlog of unfilled durables orders
also rose sharply to $86.4 billion, a $1.3 billion gain for
the month.
Durables manufacturers and wholesalers accumulated
inventories in March at a fairly substantial pace, while
stocks of nondurables manufacturers and retailers were
virtually unchanged. With the availability of full data for
March, the estimate of the inventory accumulation com­
ponent of first-quarter gross national product (GNP) was
revised to an annual rate of $6.9 billion, up by $0.5 billion
from the preliminary estimate but still well below the
fourth-quarter pace of $10.6 billion.1
Despite the continued fairly strong rise in the book

1 The Department of Commerce has revised its preliminary
estimate of GNP during the first quarter of 1969 from $903.4
billion, discussed in the May issue of this R eview , to $903.3
billion. Inventory investment and spending by state and local
governments were adjusted upward, while consumption outlays
were revised downward.

112

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1969

value of business inventories in recent months, there is
little evidence to suggest any significant imbalance cur­
rently between inventories and the levels of business
sales. The inventory-sales ratio for manufacturers moved
higher in March and rose slightly further in April, but
remained at about the 1968 average and well below the
level of last December. At the same time, the ratio for
wholesalers declined in March to tie lowest level since last
September, as strong increases in stocks were outweighed
by even sharper sales advances. The inventory-sales ratio
for retail trade firms moved up substantially in March
when retail sales declined, but the strong sales recovery
in April probably reversed that movement.
The rate of construction starts on new housing units
moved lower in April for the third consecutive month.
However, the decline— which may have been due in some
degree to scattered strike activity— was substantially milder
than in February or March. New private housing units
were begun in April at a seasonally adjusted annual rate of
1.54 million units, down about 2 percent from the March
pace and 18 percent from January’s unusually high rate.
On the other hand, there was a small gain in April in the
number of residential building permits issued. The costli­
ness and short supply of mortgage credit appear to have
had a significant impact on the single-family sector of the
housing market. The effective interest rate on conventional
mortgages to purchase new single-family homes again rose
sharply in April, reaching a nationwide average of 7.6
percent, nearly a percentage point higher than in the
same month of 1968. Probably as a reflection of this,
the starts rate for single-unit homes has fallen from an
annual rate of 1.1 million units in January to 0.8 million
units in April, a decline of 26 percent. Multi-unit building
has fared better, probably in good measure because rates
on such loans are generally unrestricted by state usury
laws and because of the ability of institutional lenders to
acquire an equity interest in apartment buildings on which
they extend mortgages. Multi-unit housing in April was
started at the rate of 0.8 million units, little changed from
January’s high level. A recent survey by the National As­
sociation of Home Builders found that builders expect
multi-unit starts to register a modest rise in 1969 over
1968, but also expect that increase to be more than offset
by a decline in single-unit starts.
P R O F IT S A N D P R O D U C T IO N C O S T S

Growth in corporate profits slowed markedly during
early 1969 (see Chart 1). Pretax profits in the first quarter
rose by only $0.3 billion to a seasonally adjusted annual
rate of $96.0 billion, according to the preliminary figures




Chart I

CORPORATE PROFITS BEFORE TAX
S eason ally ad ju sted a n n u a l rates
B illio n s of d o lla rs

So urce:

B illions of d o llc rs

United States D epartm ent of Com m erce.

of the Department of Commerce. The increase was the
smallest in two years, with most of the gain attributable
to nonmanufacturing corporations such as financial in­
stitutions and utilities. In the manufacturing sector, profits
declined, largely because of lower earnings in the auto­
mobile industry. Moreover, when aggregate first-quarter
book profits are adjusted for the effects of sharply rising
prices on the valuation of inventories, the resulting pretax
profits figure showed a drop of $1.7 billion, the first decline
since early 1967.
Pressure on profit margins during the first three months
of 1969 stemmed from steeply rising prices of materials
and labor and from a slowdown in productivity. Unit labor
costs in the private nonfarm economy rose in the first
quarter by almost 2 percent to 122.4 percent of the 195759 average. Compensation per man-hour continued tc
increase, while output per man-hour declined. The drop
in productivity, the first since 1967, reflected the fact that
man-hours increased strongly in the first quarter but growth
in real output was relatively modest. In the manufacturing
sector, the gain in unit labor costs was not so steep as in
the private economy as a whole. Productivity in manu-

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

factoring continued to grow, but the advance was less than
half as large as the gain in compensation.
P E R S O N A L IN CO M E A N D C O N S U M E R D E M A N D

Personal income rose $2.8 billion in April to a season­
ally adjusted annual rate of $730.5 billion. The gain was
considerably smaller than those in recent months and re­
flected the distinctly smaller increase in wage and salary
disbursements that accompanied the April slowdown in
employment. Sluggish growth in payrolls was widespread
among most of the major industry divisions, but was most
marked in the manufacturing sector where wages and
salaries rose by only $0.1 billion compared with an aver­
age gain of $1.2 billion during the first three months of
the year. In the distributive and service industries, payroll
growth was curtailed almost as sharply.
According to preliminary statistics, total retail sales in
April rose by IV2 percent to a new all-time high of $29.4
billion—in a month when taxpayers were faced with large
final payments on their 1968 income taxes. Nondurables
led the advance, but steadier automobile sales and in­
creases in other durable goods also contributed. Dealer

113

sales of domestic-model cars ran at a seasonally adjusted
annual rate of 8.1 million units in April, only fractionally
lower than the March pace which was down 6 percent
from that in February. The retail sales increase estimated
for April followed a 1 percent decline during March and
brought volume to an all-time high, but only $0.5 billion
above the pace in September 1968. Following a tempo­
rary surge immediately after imposition of the surtax in
mid-1968, retail sales have shown little change on balance
in the past seven months (see Chart II). Indeed, the 1%
percent gain in retail sales since September is smaller than
the rise in retail prices over the same period.
The preliminary first-quarter estimate of total consumer
expenditures on the GNP basis has been reduced by $1.0
billion because of a large downward revision in the ini­
tial estimate of March retail volume. The revision was
centered in nondurables outlays. At the same time, the
preliminary estimate for disposable income in the first
three months of 1969 was revised upward, with the re­
sult that the personal saving ratio is now estimated at 6.1
percent in the first quarter, down 0.7 percentage point in­
stead of the previously reported reduction of a full per­
centage point.
PR ICE D E V E L O P M E N T S

Chart II

RETAIL SALES
Billions of dollars; seasonally adjusted

Note: Latest d a ta plotted ere based on pre lim in a ry reports.
Source: United States D epartm ent of C om m erce, Bureau of the C ensus.




In April, consumer prices continued their rapid climb,
increasing at a 7.6 percent annual rate. The consumer price
index reached 126.4 percent of the 1957-59 average. The
April rise was primarily due to higher prices for food and
for services. However, mortgage interest and other house­
hold costs were sharply higher, and medical care also
continued to rise steeply. In addition, the prices for ap­
parel and recreation gained strongly.
Wholesale prices rose fairly modestly in April, but
apparently again increased sharply in May. The wholesale
price index rose at a 2.1 percent per annum rate in April
when there was some easing of lumber and plywood
prices and of farm products prices. In May, however, pre­
liminary statistics indicate that total wholesale prices rose
at a 7.5 percent annual rate, reaching 112.6 percent of the
1957-59 average. Farm products prices climbed in May
at a phenomenal 49 percent per annum rate, and processed
foods and feeds by 17 percent per annum. In contrast,
industrial commodities in May rose by a modest 1.1 per­
cent per annum, as increases in metals and machinery
were partly offset by further decreases in lumber prices.
Total wholesale prices thus far in 1969 have risen on
balance at a far faster rate than in 1968, and the latest
month’s increase in farm and food prices is the most
severe in eleven years.

114

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1969

T he M oney and Bond M ark ets in M ay
Pressures in the money and bond markets intensified
during May amid international financial uncertainties and
continued domestic monetary restraint. Following the res­
ignation of President de Gaulle of France on April 28,
new rumors of an impending revaluation of the German
mark, coupled with a possible devaluation of the French
franc, set in motion massive speculative movements of
international funds into Germany. Partly as a result, rates
on Euro-dollar borrowings by domestic banks rose quickly
to record levels and continued to climb during most of the
month. At the same time, the effective rate on Federal
funds moved upward, reaching a new high of 9% percent
on the final day of the period. Other money market in­
struments also responded to the increasing tautness in the
market; the costs of borrowing through commercial paper
and bankers’ acceptances rose in several steps during May.
Moreover, as commercial banks experienced higher costs
on funds raised in the Federal funds and Euro-dollar
markets, they in turn raised interest rates on call loans to
dealers in United States Government securities. After mid­
month the situation in the foreign exchange markets
quieted somewhat, but increasing discussion of the pos­
sibility of a rise in the commercial bank prime lending
rate contributed to continuing unsettlement in the domes­
tic financial markets.
Corporate bond prices moved higher during the early
part of May in response to renewed interest from some
major pension funds and favorable reaction on the part
of investors to recent new issues. The improved tone did
not, however, extend to the tax-exempt sector where both
inventories and the calendar of new issues remained heavy.
Attention in the Government securities market during the
first week was focused on the results of the Treasury’s
refunding operation for which subscription books were
open to holders of “rights” from May 5 through May 7.
Results of the refunding show that private holders of the
eligible issues subscribed for $2.1 billion of the new
6% percent fifteen-month note and $2.2 billion of the
6Vi percent seven-year note at an overall attrition rate
of 27.6 percent. In the weeks following the Treasury’s
refunding, all segments of the bond markets deteriorated
except for a brief rally prior to President Nixon’s May 14




nationwide address, which was based on market optimism
that the speech might contain news of some dramatic
improvement in the Vietnam situation.
BANK RESERVES A N D THE M O NEY M ARKET

Reflecting the heightened pressure on bank reserves
during May, member bank borrowings at the discount
window rose substantially from the preceding month, as
did the rate range in which most Federal funds trading
occurred. In the week ended on May 7, daily average
borrowings from the Federal Reserve Banks climbed to
$1.6 billion, the highest weekly level since the end of 1952,
and for the month as a whole averaged $1.4 billion, some
$300 million greater than in April. With excess reserves
little changed from the previous month, average net bor­
rowed reserves also increased by approximately $300
million in May, reaching record high levels in the final
two statement weeks of the month.
With the exception of one day, the effective rate on
Federal funds was in a 7% to 9¥s percent range through­
out May, in contrast to the 63A to 8 percent range that
prevailed in April following the increase in the Federal
Reserve discount rate to 6 percent. A consistent intra­
weekly pattern prevailed during the month as the major
money market banks bid aggressively for funds at the start
of each week to make certain of meeting their reserve re­
quirements early in the statement period, thus driving the
Federal funds rate up. Later in each week the rate fell
somewhat, as these banks reduced their demand and ex­
cess reserves reached the market (see Chart I ). In part
the behavior of these money center banks resulted from
a substantial deterioration in their basic reserve position
which was considerably more than seasonal (see Chart II).
The increased deficit was particularly striking at the eight
major New York City banks which increased their loans
and investments by a sizable amount over the first three
weeks of the period despite a runoff in all types of de­
posits. There was a progressive deterioration of the reserve
position of the New York City banks until the final week
in May.
As pressures on the reserve and liquidity positions of

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

the major money center banks mounted, their net inter­
bank purchases of Federal funds rose steadily although
their borrowings at the discount window moved irregularly.
Despite some easing at the end of each statement week,
the money market was quite firm throughout the month
of May, and the effective rate on Federal funds moved
steadily higher with the opening of each period. The
effective rate on May 1 was %Va percent; on May 8,
8% percent; on May 15, 8V2 percent; on May 22, 9
percent; and on May 29, 9% percent. During the last two
days of the month, some Federal funds traded at a rec­
ord rate of 93A percent.
Due to the tendency of market factors to absorb reserves
during the month as currency outside banks rose sharply
and a decline in float provided an additional drain, the

System injected $724 million of reserves on average in
May through open market operations (see Table I). Be­
cause of the intraweekly pattern, noted earlier, of tautness
in the money market at the beginning of statement weeks
followed by some easing toward the close, System oper­
ations consisted largely of repurchase agreements against
Treasury and Federal agency securities and bankers’ ac­
ceptances, which were arranged early in the week and
allowed to mature without replacement toward the close.
Daily average deposits subject to reserve requirements
(the bank credit proxy) declined in May at a seasonally
adjusted annual rate of about 1 percent, after a 5 percent
rise in April. Although there was some increase in net
demand deposits on a seasonally adjusted basis, this was
more than offset by a further decline in time deposits.

C h a rt I

SELECTED INTEREST RATES
M arch-M ay 1969

Note: Data are shown for business days only.
M ONEY MARKET RATES QUOTED: Daily range of rates posted by m ajor New York City banks
on call lo ans (in Federal funds) secured by United States Governm ent securities (a point
indicates the absence of any range); offering rates for directly placed finance com pany paper;
the effective rate on Federal fu n d stthe rate most representative of the transactions executed);
closing bid rates (quoted in terms of rate of discount) on newest outstanding three- and six-month
Treasury bills.
A, and Baa).

immediately after it has been released from syndicate restrictions); d aily averages of yields on
seasoned A aa-rated corporate bonds; d aily averages of yields on long-term Governm ent
securities (bonds due or ca lla b le in ten years or more) and on Governm ent securities due in
three to five ye ars, computed on the basis of closing bid prices; Thursday averages of yields
on twenty seasoned twenty-year tax-exempt bonds (carrying M oody’s ratings of A aa , A a,

BOND MARKET YIELDS QUOTED: Yields on new A a a - and A a-rated public utility bonds (arrows point Sources: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
from underwriting syndicate reoffering yield on a given issue to m arketyield on the same issue




115

M oody’s Investors Service, and The W eekly Bond Buyer.

116

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1969

C h a ri II

BASIC RESERVE POSITIONS OFM A JO R M O N EY MARKET BANKS
Billions of d o llars

Billions of d ollars

Note: A ll figures shown represent deficit positions. Calculation of the
basic reserve position is illustrated in Table II.

Liquidation of large certificates of deposit continued but
at a much slower pace than in the early months of the
year. Commercial bank liabilities to foreign branches rose
by some $300 million during the four statement weeks
ended in May, after a drop of $200 million during
April. Moreover, domestic banks also continued to raise
additional Euro-dollar funds by sales of assets to their
foreign branches. The seasonally adjusted money supply
registered no further gain in May, following a large in­
crease in April which partly reflected special factors of a
technical nature.
TH E G O V E R N M E N T SE C UR ITIES M A R K E T

Yields on Government securities rose on balance during
May although generally good demand, pressing on a lim­
ited market supply, restricted the increase in short-term
bill rates to a narrow range (see Chart I). Part of the de­
mand for bills arose from foreign sources in the wake of
the speculative activity surrounding the German mark.
Despite the increased demand for bills and their rela­




tively short market supply, upward pressures were exerted
on bill rates by the high costs of dealer financing and the
Treasury’s decision to roll over rather than retire the bills
that were added to six issues in the March “strip” auction.
Moreover, dealers were somewhat disappointed by the
volume of demand for bills arising from the Treasury’s
May refunding. At the final weekly auction on May 26,
average issuing rates for the new three- and six-month bills
were set at 6.124 and 6.218 percent, respectively, 7 and
18 basis points above the average rates established at the
last weekly auction in April. At the regular monthly auc­
tion on May 27, average issuing rates on the nine- and
twelve-month bills were set at 6.307 and 6.270 percent,
respectively, 33 and 34 basis points higher than compar­
able rates at the auction a month earlier (see Table III).
The auction rate on the twelve-month bill was the highest
since last December.
In the market for longer term Government securities,
attention was centered on the Treasury’s May refunding
during the early part of the month. The Treasury offered
holders of notes and bonds maturing in May and June
of this year the right to exchange their holdings into
either a fifteen-month 63/s percent note yielding 6.42 per­
cent or a seven-year 6V2 percent note priced at par. The
terms were considered generous by most market partici­
pants, and the overall attrition by private holders of only
27.6 percent was near the lower end of the range of
market expectations. By the end of the month the longer
note had fallen to a bid quotation of 19/32 below par while
the shorter note was bid about % 2 below its issue price.
Prices of outstanding intermediate-term Treasury notes
declined about half a point during the first week of May
in initial reaction to the terms of the Treasury refunding
and moved somewhat lower over the remainder of the
month. Prices of long-term bonds, in contrast, rose early
in the period in response to some indications of moderating
domestic economic activity and favorable press discussions
concerning the Paris peace talks. In the latter part of the
period, prices generally declined due to disappointment
over the President’s Vietnam speech, concern over the high
costs of financing dealer positions, and the worsening state
of the corporate and municipal bond markets. Over the
month as a whole, prices on most intermediate-term issues
were 1 to 11%2 points lower, while those on longer term
issues declined by 222/32 to 4 18/32 points.
O THER SE C U R IT IES M A R K E T S

Yields on new and seasoned corporate bonds declined
somewhat in the first week of May, largely in response to
favorable investor reception of the preceding week’s new

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

117

Table I

Table II

FACTORS TENDING TO INCREASE OR DECREASE
MEMBER BANK RESERVES, MAY 1969

RESERVE POSITIONS OF MAJOR RESERVE CO Y BANKS
MAY 1969

In millions of dollars; ( 4 ) denotes increase,
( —) decrease in excess reserves

In millions of dollars
Daily averages—week ended on
Factors affecting
basic reserve positions

Changes in daily averages—
week ended on
Net
changes

Factors
May
14

May
21

May
28

93
100

4- 170
— 94
— 108
— 42
- f 32
— 264
4- 288

— 94
— 195
4- 288
-4- 141
— 4
— 454
— 167

4- 37
— 305
— 351
4- 128
4- 8
4- 151
— 242

— 660
— 221

— 400

4- 76

— 289

— 268

— 881

May
7

“

Total “market” factors . . ....................

—
—
—
+
__
—
—

152
248
31
16

40

—
—
—
4_

39
842
202
243

4

Federal agency obligations .......... ..
Other loans, discounts, and ad vances....

Excess reserves .........................................

May
28

Reserve excess or deficiency
104
49
69 Less borrowings from
Reserve Banks ...................................
164
146
121
Less net interbank Federal funds
purchases or sales(—) .....................
1,660
695 1,292
1,872 2,118 2,593
Gross purchases .............................
933
Gross sales ......................................
1,177
826
Equals net basic reserve surplus
or deficit(—) ...................................... — 738 —1,345 -1,873
Net loans to Government
securities dealers ..............................
352
737
611
48
Net carry-over, excess or deficit(—)t~ 22
57

3

30

59

123

706
1,940
1,235

1,088
2,131
1,043

-7 6 8

-1,181

317
— 2

504
20

—

Thirty-eight banks outside New York City

Direct Federal Reserve credit
transactions
Open market operations (subtotal)
Outright holdings:
Government securities ............................
Bankers’ acceptances ......................
Repurchase agreements:
Government securities ....................

May
21

May
14

Eight banks in New York City

Market*' factors

Member bank required reserves..................
Operating transactions (subtotal) ----Federal Reserve float ................................
Treasury operations* ................ ...............
Gold and foreign account..........................
Currency outside banks ............................
Other Federal Reserve accounts (n et)t--

May
7

Averages of
four weeks
ended on
May 28

+ 309
- f 41

4- 139

— 38

4 -314

4 -7 2 4

4- M
— 1

4- 217
— 1

- f 339
_
4

4 - 663
— 5

+ 304
— 12
— 25
- f 486
__

4- 52
4
4- 18
— 433

— 256
— 7

—
—
4—

32
10
21
55

+ 68
— 25
4- 23
4-188

+ 794

— 293

4- 151

4- 257

4 - 909

+ 394

— 217

— 138

— li

4

4-

i

4-

4-

9

4- 188

—

Reserve excess or deficiency(—)*...
106
1 — 31 27
Less borrowings from
378
Reserve Banks ..................................
260
251
462
Less net interbank Federal funds
1,623
purchases or sales(—) .....................
1,819
1,810 1,996
Gross purchases ............................. 3,335 3,616 3,564 3,697
1,941
Gross sales ......................................
1,525 1,620
1,878
Equals net basic reserve surplus
or deficit(—) ....................................... -2,166 -2,255 -2,032 -2,098
Net loans to Government
securities dealers ..............................
99 — 38 36
59
39
62
Net carry-over, excess or deficit(—)t- 2
24

12
338
1,812
3,553
1,741
-2,138
10
30

—

28

Note: Because of rounding, figures do not necessarily add to totals.
* Reserves held after all adjustments applicable to the reporting period less
required reserves and carry-over reserve deficiencies,
t Not reflected in data above.

Table III

Daily average levels

AVERAGE ISSUING RATES*
AT REGULAR TREASURY BILL AUCTIONS
In percent

Member bank:
Total reserves, including vault cash.........

28,175
27,731
444
1,603
Free, or net borrowed (—), reserves.......... —1,159
Nonborrowed reserves .................................... 26,572
6
Net carry-over, excess or deficit (— )§ -----

27,788 27,744
27,696
27,561
27,655 27,618
227
78
89
1,170
1,358
1,303
— 943 —1,269 —1,225
26,618
26,386 26,393
217
160
80

27,851$
27,641$
210$
1,359*
—1.149*
26,492$
116

Weekly auction dates—May 1969
Maturities
May
5

May
12

May
19

May
26

Three-month.................................

5.978

6.084

6.148

6.124

Six-month.......................................

6.063

6.191

6.231

6.218

Changes in Wednesday levels
Monthly auction dates—March-May 1969
System account holdings of Government
securities maturing in:
Less than one year .......................................
More than one y e a r ........................................
Total .........................................................

— 410 —1,110 4-12,785
—10,804
—
—

— 227
4- 83

411.038
— 10,721

—1,110 4- 1,981

— 144

+

— 410

Note: Because of rounding, figures do not necessarily add to totals.
* Includes changes in Treasury currency and cash,
t Includes assets denominated in foreign currencies.
t Average for four weeks ended on May 28.
§ Not reflected in data above.




317

March
26

April
24

Nine-month...................................

6.058

5.977

6.307

One-year........................................

6.132

5.931

6.270

May
27

* Interest rates on bills are quoted in terms of a 360-day year, with the dis­
counts from par as the return on the face amount of the bills payable at
maturity. Bond yield equivalents, related to the amount actually invested,
would be slightly higher.

118

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1969

issues and to renewed demand from major pension funds.
Reflecting underwriters’ optimism, the first long-term
Aaa-rated issue marketed since early March, a $40 mil­
lion telephone issue, was priced on May 6 to yield 7.20
percent. This yield was 18 basis points lower than the
similarly rated telephone issue of March 11. Investor
response was not very enthusiastic, however, due in part
to the fact that a closely competitive utility issue, mar­
keted the previous day, was offered at 7.25 percent.
The trend of corporate bond prices was steadily down­
ward during succeeding weeks in May except for a brief
improvement prior to President Nixon’s speech on May
14. Despite the fact that White House press sources had
stated in advance that nothing basically new would be
presented, market participants were apparently hopeful
that some word concerning a quick end to the Vietnam
fighting would be included. When these hopes did not
materialize, the corporate bond market resumed its decline,
as participants continued to respond to the heavy demand
for funds, the lack of substantial progress at the Paris
peace talks, and the fact that inflation in the economy had
not shown any abatement according to the latest price
statistics. Several corporate syndicates were terminated
during the final three weeks of May, and some scheduled
new issues were either reduced in size or postponed be­
cause of market conditions. Indicative of the deterioration
which occurred, on May 27 a telephone company sold a
$65 million issue of debentures at a cost of 7.7 percent,
the highest cost for a Bel1 System unit since 1921. In ad­




dition, scheduled new issues for the month ahead are
estimated at some $100 million more than at the end of
April.
Prices on tax-exempt securities moved lower throughout
the entire month, though the decline accelerated after the
first week of the period as measured by The Weekly Bond
Buyer's index of twenty municipal bond yields. At the end
of May this index was at a 36-year high of 5.60 percent,
an increase of 50 basis points over the month. The cal­
endar of new municipal securities was sizable throughout
the period. Moreover, commercial bank demand for new
securities remained at reduced levels and some further
bank sales of outstanding tax exempts were reported.
Highlighting the activity in this market was the sale
of $182 million of housing authority bonds on May 21
at a record net interest cost of 5.517 percent. Yields to
investors ranged as high as 5.55 percent but, despite this
record return for tax-exempt securities guaranteed by the
Federal Government, the reception was less than en­
thusiastic. In this environment, syndicate terminations and
price cutting began to recur during the month and an
$88 million issue scheduled for marketing was withdrawn
by the state of New York because of the probability that
it could not be sold at or below the 5 percent interest
ceiling set on it. The calendar of scheduled new issues at
the close of May had declined by some $200 million over
the month, possibly reflecting an unwillingness on the part
of potential borrowers to announce firm dates given the
unsettled market conditions.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

119

How M uch D oes M oney M atter?
A Look at Som e Recent Evidence
By R ic h a r d G. D a v is
Adviser, Research and Statistics Function
Federal Reserve Bank of New York

Editor’s Note: The following is a paper presented at a Money and Banking
Workshop held on May 9, 1969 at the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. It
is being reprinted in this Review for the benefit of our readers who are interested
in the current controversy surrounding the role of the money supply. The views
expressed are the author’s and do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of New York or of the Federal Reserve System.

The air has been filled of late with signs of upheaval
in long-established patterns of thinking regarding mone­
tary and fiscal policy and, more generally, regarding the
role of money in the economy. The basic framework
used for years by most of us in analyzing these matters
has come under serious challenge. Signs of intellectual
disarray are evident all over, among public officials, in
the business press, and among academics. Indeed, the
current sense of confusion may well exceed anything
witnessed since the early 1930’s. Obviously the questions
of “how much does money matter?” and “in what way
does money matter?” are central issues underlying many
specific problems of policy making, forecasting, and
business-cycle analysis that are currently up for reexami­
nation.
The change in atmosphere has been a very recent
phenomenon. Only two or three years ago, there was
rather general agreement that a wide variety of factors
could produce fluctuations in business activity. Monetary
developments were but one item in the list and, in the
minds of many, by no means the most important. Money
was assumed to operate through its effects on financial
interest rates and through changes in the degree of credit
rationing impinging on certain types of borrowers oper­
ating in imperfect capital markets.
The view that “only money matters” or, perhaps more
accurately, that “mainly money matters” was the province
of an obscure sect with headquarters in Chicago. For the
most part, economists regarded this group—when they




regarded it at all—as a mildly amusing, not quite respect­
able collection of eccentrics. The number of serious
attempts to grapple with the Friedman view on the role
of money until recently has been remarkably small. A
1960 paper by John Culbertson,1 some work by Kareken
and Solow on Friedman’s approach to measuring lags,2
and the papers surrounding the controversy over the
Friedman-Meiselman work3 comprise a nearly exhaustive
list of the pre-1968 literature. The fact is that the view
held by Friedman and a few others on the predominant

1 See his “Friedman on the Lag Effect of Monetary Policy”,
Journal of Political Economy (December 1960), pages 617-21.
See also Friedman’s reply, “The Lag Effect of Monetary Policy”
in the October 1961 issue of the same Journal (pages 447-66)
as well as Culbertson’s rejoinder in the same issue (pages 467-77).
2 John Kareken and Robert Solow, “Lags in Monetary Policy”,
in Stabilization Policies (Commission on Money and Credit, 1963),
pages 14-96.
3 Milton Friedman and David Meiselman, ‘T h e Relative Sta­
bility of Monetary Velocity and the Investment Multiplier in the
United States”, in Stabilization Policies (Commission on Money
and Credit, 1963), pages 165-268. See also Donald Hester,
“Keynes and the Quantity Theory: A Comment on the FriedmanMeiselman CMC Paper”, and the Friedman-Meiselman reply
in the Review of Economics and Statistics (November 1964). In
addition, see Albert Ando and Franco Modigliani, “Velocity and
the Investment Multiplier”; Michael dePrano and Thomas Mayer,
“Autonomous Expenditures and Money”; and replies by Friedman
and Meiselman plus rejoinders by Ando-Modigliani and dePranoMayer, all in the American Economic R eview (September 1965),
pages 693-792.

120

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1969

perfect that it seemed scarcely possible that it could be
due to chance alone. The existence of these timing leads
was interpreted by Friedman and Schwartz to mean a
dominant causal role for money, while their length and
variability was taken as meaning a corresponding length
and variability in the lags with which the money supply
exerts its influence on business activity.
It is probably fair to say that relatively few not already
in the fold were converted by these arguments. The main
problem is that the evidential value of the monetary leads
in trying to demonstrate a dominant causal role for
money, as well as a long and variable lag in its timing,
is gravely compromised by the possibility of a reverse in­
fluence of business on money. This point was made back
in 1960 by Culbertson in the article mentioned earlier.
At the time he wrote, little work had been done on the
supply side of the money problem. Hence the existence of
important reverse effects of business on money could really
only be put forward as a plausible hypothesis. This situa­
tion was changed in 1965 with the publication of Phillip
Cagan’s book, The Determinants and Effects of Changes
in the Stock of Money. While Cagan’s book appears to be
very much in the Friedman tradition, it seems to me that
its results in fact tend to undercut that tradition. Cagan’s
work suggests rather clearly that the characteristic cyclical
timing relationships between monetary rates of change
and the business cycle are very importantly determined by
the influence of business on money. The case is made
even stronger if one takes explicit account— as Cagan
does not— of the impact of the Federal Reserve’s attempts
at countercyclical policy. Federal Reserve behavior alone
may be sufficient to explain the characteristic lead of
cycles in the monetary growth rate ahead of business-cycle
turning points during the postwar period without the need
to posit any influence of money on business whatever.
If Cagan’s work is correct, then the massive evidence
gathered by Friedman and Schwartz for leads in the turn­
ing points of monetary cycles seems distinctly question­
able
as evidence for a dominant causal role for money.
E V ID E N C E FOR TH E M O N E T A R Y P O S IT IO N
The second sort of evidence in behalf of the “mainly
By far the largest mass of evidence consisted of the money matters” position, as of last June, was the soFriedman-Schwartz measurement and comparison of spe­ called “reduced-form” equations turned up in the famous
cific cycles in the monetary growth rate with reference Friedman-Meiselman paper. As will be recalled, Fried­
cycles using the standard National Bureau techniques.4 man and Meiselman regressed first the money supply
The consistency with which cycles in the monetary growth against consumption and then what they called “autono­
rate were found to lead reference cycles was so nearly mous” spending against consumption. They regarded their
results as “strikingly one-sided”5 in support of the money

importance of money was just not given serious attention
by most economists.
This whole situation has been changing of late with a
rather startling abruptness. Indeed as far as the general
public is concerned, much of the change in atmosphere
has occurred within the last six to nine months. There
can be no doubt that the principal explanation for this
development has been the surprisingly exuberant behavior
of the economy since the tax surcharge was enacted last
June. Most forecasters who, like myself, have used the
usual techniques of short-term projecting, hopefully with
at least average skill, have consistently and fairly sub­
stantially underestimated the strength of the economy in
the past nine months. Now of course these forecasting
mistakes may not have been due to any overestimate of
the potency of fiscal policy or an underestimate of the
importance of the monetary growth rate. Many other
explanations are possible. Nevertheless, it has been dis­
tinctly unsettling to see the projected slowdown recede
further and further into the future, month after month and
quarter after quarter. It is the sort of experience to make
one reexamine one’s “maintained hypotheses”— and per­
haps such a reexamination is really in order.
The failure of conventional forecasting techniques in
the wake of fiscal restraint wrould not, of course, neces­
sarily send one running to the money supply for an
explanation were there not a large body of research on
the importance of money already waiting in the wings.
This research needed only the right historical moment to
bring it forth into the limelight. The post-surcharge ex­
perience has provided such a moment. Looking at the
evidence in behalf of a dominant role for money presented
in most of this research, however, it is not too difficult
to understand why it achieved relatively little acceptance
for the monetary view— on its own merits, so to speak,
and without the psychological benefit of the post-surcharge
trauma.

4 Their major results are summarized in Milton Friedman and
----------------Anna Schwartz, “Money and Business Cycles”, Review of Economics and, Statistics (February 1963 Supplement), pages 32-64.
5 Friedman and Meiselman, op. c i t page 166.




121

FEDERAL RESERVE RANK OF NEW YORK

multiplier over their version of the Keynesian multiplier.
Again, however, it seems unlikely that many outside
the fold were converted by the Friedman-Meiselman evi­
dence. As the mass of correlation coefficients computed
by the various combatants began to pile up, it became in­
creasingly obvious that the controversy would never be
able to produce a clear and decisive verdict. Results
turned out to depend very much on the definition of
“autonomous” spending and on the years for which the
computations were made. Using definitions of autono­
mous spending much more akin to those of the usual
textbook versions of Keynes than the one adopted by
Friedman and Meiselman, little difference between the
money multiplier and the autonomous spending multiplier
could be discerned. Moreover, interpretation of all the
results was complicated by the extreme simplicity of the
“models” chosen to be tested, as well as by the inability
of correlation techniques to distinguish an influence of
money on business from an influence of business on money.
To me, at least, the whole thing was a washout, proving
nothing and making the Friedman position seem not one
jot more plausible than it had seemed before.
Thus those economists, journalists, and public officials
who began to take a hard look at the evidence for the
monetarist position in the wake of the apparent failure
of the tax surcharge found a rather mixed bag. On the
one hand, Friedman and his colleagues had established
beyond question a very substantial gross association be­
tween the money supply and business activity. On the
other hand, the monetarists had failed to convince the
majority of their professional colleagues that their claims
for the importance of money had been adequately demon­
strated. The reasons for their failure lay mainly in rela­
tively esoteric matters of statistical methodology and
economic theory. Such problems have obviously made
much less impression on the lay public than has the simple
fact of the gross association between money and business
itself.
T H E ST. LO U IS E Q U A T IO N

Under these circumstances, a new study of the im­
portance of the money supply, and its importance rela­
tive to fiscal policy, was certain to be welcome. The
paper by Leonall Andersen and Jerry Jordan published
last November6 in the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank’s

6 “Monetary and Fiscal Actions: A Test of Their Relative
Importance in Economic Stabilization”, Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis Review (November 1968), pages 11-24.




Table I
THE FISCAL MULTIPLIERS IN
THE BOARD-MIT AND ST. LOUIS MODELS

St. Louis

Board-MIT
Elapsed time
Spending

Taxes

Spending

Taxes
0.2

After 1 quarter..............................

2.0

1.1

0.4

After 2 quarters.............................

2.5

2.2

0.9

0.2

After 4 quarters.............................

3.4

3.2

0.1

0.2

After 12 quarters..........................

3.2

4.7

0.1

0.2

Note: Figures for the Board-MIT model are estimates made from the simu­
lation presented in Charts 8 and 9 on pages 28 and 29 of the January 1968
Federal Reserve Bulletin. The tax simulations in the Board-MIT model are
actually in terms of percentage point changes in tax rates, but it is noted
on page 23 of the Bulletin that the .02 percentage point change used for
the simulations was equivalent to about $4 billion during the period for
which the simulations were conducted.

Review has understandably created a good deal of inter­
est. Their approach consists of regressing current changes
in gross national product (GNP) on current and lagged
changes in the money supply and in fiscal variables. Cer­
tainly their procedure is very simple but not, for that
reason, necessarily invalid. My own feeling is that, right
or wrong, the St. Louis article is a distinctly worthwhile
contribution to the literature on the importance of money.
It deserves to be taken seriously and, by the same token,
it deserves careful scrutiny. I propose to use the remain­
der of this paper to examine the claims made by Andersen
and Jordan.
The first thing I want to note about the St. Louis
equation is that it portrays a world in several respects
sharply at variance with the expectations of most of us.
1. The fiscal multipliers in the St. Louis world are
virtually zero. The fiscal multipliers for spending and
taxes taken directly from the St. Louis equation are shown
in Table I. At no point do these multipliers rise above
unity, and after four quarters they have returned essen­
tially to zero. Multipliers taken from the recent Federal
Reserve Board staff-Massachusetts Institute of Technology
structural econometric model are shown in the same Table
I. These multipliers, by contrast, correspond roughly to
expectations, rising to over 3 after a year.
2. Current and lagged changes in Mx (private holdings
of demand deposits and currency) explain a remark­
ably high proportion of the variance of quarterly changes
in GNP. For the 1952-68 period used by St. Louis, about
50 percent of the variance of changes in GNP is
“explained” by changes in money. This leaves the
remaining 50 percent to be accounted for by every other
possible determinant of the course of business activity!

122

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1969

Just how well money does is illustrated in the chart. The implicit in the Board-MIT model. The money supply is of
equation used here differs from the St. Louis equation course an endogenous variable in this model, and so really
only in omitting the fiscal variables and in having an has no “multiplier” as such. However, the arithmetic
unconstrained lag structure. When it is kept in mind that multiplier can be computed by dividing the GNP multi­
the chart shows changes in GNP, I think the closeness is plier of nonborrowed reserves by the money multiplier of
visually reasonably impressive. The only prolonged period nonborrowed reserves. (This procedure includes reverse
of really serious errors is from the beginning of 1952 to effects of business on money, to be sure, but so does the
about mid-1954. On the other hand, the equation’s accu­ St. Louis equation. More later on this.) After four quarters,
racy since mid-1967 has been extremely high.
the money multiplier in the Board-MIT model is only
3.
The size of the money multiplier is much higher about 0.4. Even after twelve quarters, it is still only about
than might have been expected. As Table II shows, a 2.2, or only one third the size of the multiplier implicit
once-and-for-all increase in the money supply of $1 billion in the St. Louis equation.
in quarter 1 will have raised the level of GNP by $6.6
4.
To me, the most surprising thing about the world of
billion by quarter 4, according to the St. Louis equation. the St. Louis equation is not so much the force, but rather
This result can be compared with the money multiplier the speed with which money begins to act on the economy.

QUARTERLY C H A N G E S SN G R O S S N A T IO N A L PRO DUCT
Billions of d o lla rs




B illio n s of d o lla rs

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

This can also be seen in the results presented in Table II.
If the level of the money supply undergoes a $1 billion
once-and-for-all increase in a given quarter, it will already
raise GNP by $1.6 billion in that very same quarter. In
the next quarter, the level of GNP will have risen to $3.5
billion above what it would otherwise have been. And, as
noted, it will have risen to $6.6 billion higher in the fourth
quarter. In the Board-MIT model, by contrast, a onceand-for-all increase in M2 of $1 billion in a given quarter
would have almost no effect whatever on GNP in that
quarter, and only very little effect by one quarter later.
Even after four quarters, the level of GNP is only about
$400 million higher than it would otherwise have been.
I think it is clear from this summary that what is at
stake in the case of the St. Louis equation is not merely a
“shade of difference”, but a strikingly contrasting view of
the world—at least relative to what is normally taken as
the orthodox view roughly replicated and confirmed both
in methods and in result by the Board-MIT model. The
validity and meaningfulness of the St. Louis equation is
thus a question of some importance. There seem to be
two basic issues that need to be examined: First, how
good are the purely statistical properties of the sort of
relationship presented by Andersen and Jordan? Second,
how much of the relationship they find is due to a reverse
influence of business on money, the problem that has
plagued all previous attempts to buttress the so-called
“strong monetarist position”?
Before turning to these questions, I should note that I

Table H
THE MONEY MULTIPLIER IN
THE BOARD-MIT AND ST. LOUIS MODELS

Board-MIT
Elapsed time
A Mi

A GNP
(2)

(1)
After 1 quarter............................

+ 2.5

+

0.5

Multiplier

St. Louis
multiplier

(3)

(4)

0.2

1.6
3.5

After 2 quarters...........................

+ 3.5

+

1.3

0.4

After 4 quarters...........................

+ 4.3

+

2.0

0.4

6.6

After 12 quarters.........................

+ 5.0

+ 11.0

2.2

6.6

Note: Changes in Mi and GNP were estimated from charts presented on page
27 of the January 1968 Federal Reserve Bulletin. These charts show re­
sults for the Board-MIT model in which the effects of a $1.0 billion in­
crease in nonborrowed reserves are simulated. The implied “money
multiplier” shown in column 3 is computed by dividing the change in
GNP (column 2) by the change in money (column 1). Actually only
effects for demand deposits are shown—currency effects are thus assumed
to be comparatively small.
The money multiplier shows the change in the level of GNP after the time
period specified associated with a once-and-for-all increase in the level
of the money supply of $1.0 billion. Estimates of the money multiplier for
the St. Louis equation are obtained simply by summing coefficients over
the appropriate number of quarters.




123

have concentrated all my attention in what follows on the
question of the importance of money. I will have virtually
nothing to say on the seeming unimportance of the fiscal
variables. This latter problem is of course also of great
interest, but there has simply not been time to give
adequate attention to both issues.
O TH E R ST. L O U IS -T Y P E E Q U A T IO N S

Table III presents a number of St. Louis-type equations
covering different time periods and using different tech­
niques for estimating the lag structure. The first line of
figures contains the original St. Louis results for their
1952 to 1968-11 period. The second line reproduces these
results with two differences: (1) the fiscal variables were
not included and (2) a second degree polynomial was
used for the Almon lag rather than St. Louis’ fourth
degree. (This latter adjustment was made solely to accom­
modate programming limitations.) A comparison of these
two equations reveals that neither omission of the fiscal
variables nor reduction of the degree of the polynomial has
any substantial effect on the results for the monetary
variables.
Concentrating on this second set of equations in Table
III using the second degree polynomial, the following
observations seem pertinent. First, the coefficients for the
two subperiods are quite clearly different, but they are not
drastically different. The overall money multiplier after
four quarters is 3.6 for the earlier period and 5.3 for the
later period. Both are strikingly larger than the 0.4 oneyear multiplier of the Board-MIT model. The St. Louis
equation does pass the Chow test for the two subperiods
at the 5 percent level.
Second, the explanatory power of the monetary
variables is quite low in the first half of the period
(R 2 — .1 8 )7 and quite high (R 2 == .62) in the second half
of the period. What is the reason for this difference? One
possible answer is a strong common time trend in changes
in Mi and in GNP present in the 1960’s but not in the
earlier period. Such a trend beginning around the early
1960’s is readily visible in the chart referred to earlier.
(The R 2 of time alone on changes in GNP is .38 in the
later period, virtually zero for the earlier period and .36
for the entire 1952 to 1968-11 period.)
Now of course the mere existence of a common time
trend in the 1960’s does not necessarily mean that the
close relationship between money and GNP is spurious.

7 R2 is the square of the multiple correlation coefficient.

124

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1969
Table

in

is interesting to note that the one-period lag coefficient for
the entire 1952-68 period, which is the largest for the
Almon lags, actually becomes the lowest in the uncon­
strained equation.

CHANGES IN GNP REGRESSED ON CURRENT
AND LAGGED CHANGES IN Mi
Quarterly changes

Period

R2
SE of est

Sum of
coefficients

1
t

t-1

,,

-

P R O B L E M O F T W O -W A Y C A U SA T IO N

The St. Louis equationf
Almon lag with fourth degree polynomial
1. 1952-68*.....

.56
4.2

6.6

1.6
(2.2)

1.9
(3.6)

1.3
(1.9)

1.8
(3.4)

Equations using Almon lag with second degree polynomial^
2. 1952-68*

.48
4.6

5.6

1.6
(3.0)

1.7
(7.6)

1.4
(4.3)

0.9
(3.0)

3. 1952-60

.18
5.1

3.6

1.7
(1.7)

1.1
(2.6)

0.6
(1.1)

0.2
(0.5)

4. 1961-68*

.62
3.2

5.3

0.8
(1.6)

1.6
(6.4)

1.7
(5.4)

1.2
(4.5)

I

Equations using unconstrained lag coefficients^
5. 1952-68*

.50
4.6

5.9

2.7
(3.3)

—0.1
( -0 .1 )

2.2
(2.0)

6. 1952-60

.18
5.3

3.7

1.9
(1.1)

0.6
(0.3)

1.2
(0.5)

7. 1961-68*

.68
3.0

5.7

2.0
(2.8)

- 0 .3
(-0 .3 )

2.6
(2.8)

1.1
(1.3)
-

.05
(—)
1.4
(2.0)

Note: Values of “t” statistics are indicated in parentheses.
* Through the second quarter of 1968.
t Fiscal variables included but not shown.
} No fiscal variables included.

One could argue that we have had relatively steady rises in
quarterly GNP increments because we have had relatively
steady rises in quarterly money increments. Some equa­
tions including time as an explicit variable suggest that
there may have been a reasonably strong association
between GNP and current and lagged changes in Mi
during the 1960’s even after time is allowed for. Never­
theless, the fact remains that the degree of association
between GNP and current and lagged money supply would
have looked very different to Andersen and Jordan had
they done their work in 1961 instead of 1968. Given an
R 2 as low as prevailed in the 1952-60 period, it may be
doubted that they would have felt it worthwhile to pursue
the matter further.
Finally, I would like to point out the bottom three
equations shown on Table III. These are simply uncon­
strained multiple regressions of changes in GNP on
current and lagged changes in Mi. Comparison with the
other lines in the table shows the extent to which
imposition of Almon lags changes the results. The lag
pattern present in the unconstrained equations is, of
course, infected with multi-collinearity. Nevertheless, it




I now want to turn to the problem of two-way causa­
tion. That there is a high “gross” association between
money and business, however measured, has long been
apparent from the work of Friedman-Schwartz and
Friedman-Meiselman, as noted earlier. The St. Louis
results generally confirm this finding— at least for the
1960’s. As I noted, however, the possibility of important
influences running from business to money seem to
weaken substantially the evidential value of the work
done by Friedman and his collaborators in trying to estab­
lish a dominant causal role for money. The question now
is, does the St. Louis study suffer from the same fatal
defect?
In a critique of the St. Louis work published in the
April issue of the St. Louis Bank’s Review, Frank
deLeeuw, one of the principal architects of the BoardMIT model, and John Kalchbrenner take note of the twoway causation problem.8 They note that the “reducedform” approach used by St. Louis requires that the vari­
ables on the right-hand side be truly exogenous. If they are
not, biased coefficient estimates may result. Conceivably,
such bias could account for the surprisingly powerful and
quick-acting effects of money seemingly indicated by the
coefficients of the St. Louis equation. DeLeeuw and Kalch­
brenner believe that Andersen and Jordan recognized the
vulnerability of the money supply as an exogenous vari­
able and that it was for this reason that they constructed
an alternative version of their equation. In this alterna­
tive version, current and lagged changes in Mx are re­
placed with current and lagged changes in the monetary
base (adjusted for changes in reserve requirements).9 This
alternative version of the St. Louis equation is repro­
duced on the top line of Table IV. The explanatory
power is similar to that of the money supply equation.
The size of the multiplier, however, is naturally much
larger since it represents the combined effect of the baseto-money multiplier and the money-to-GNP multiplier.

8 Frank deLeeuw and John Kalchbrenner, “Comment”, St.
Louis Reserve Bank Review (April 1969), pages 6-11.
9 The monetary base consists of total member bank reserves plus
currency in circulation outside banks.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

The second line of figures on Table IV contains a reestimate of the parameters of line 1, this time with no
fiscal variables included and with the second degree poly­
nomial rather than the St. Louis fourth degree poly­
nomial.
The problem with the St. Louis equations using the
monetary base is that, while the latter may be more
exogenous than the money supply, its own “exogeneity”
is still far from beyond question. In other words, a good
case can be made for the view that the two-way causation
problem is still present in the monetary base. First, the
monetary base includes borrowed reserves. While the
Federal Reserve sets the conditions for borrowing and the
discount rate, actual borrowings take place at the initia-

Table TV
CHANGES IN GNP REGRESSED ON VARIOUS MEASURES
OF CURRENT AND LAGGED CHANGES IN THE
MONETARY BASE OR NONBORROWED RESERVES
Quarterly changes

R2
Period

Sum of
coefficients

SE of est

t

t-1

t-2

t-3

The St. Louis equation—total monetary base
Almon lag with fourth degree polynomialf
1. 1952-68*

.53
4.4

16.0

5.5
(3.4)

1.0
(0.5)

6.5
(4.1)

3.1
(1.5)

Total monetary base
Almon lag with second degree polynomial^
2. 1952-68* ...

.45
4.8

14.8

4.4
(7.1)

3.5
(1.8)

4.1
(3.5)

10 St. Louis Reserve Bank Review (April 1969), pages 12-16.

3. 1952-68*

.32
5.3

10.8

- 0 .1
( -0 .1 )

3.2
(5.2)

4.4
(4.7)

3.3
(4.0)

4. 1952-60

.07
5.5

— 3.4

-4 .1
(-1 .6 )

- 1 .0
( -0 .6 )

0.7
(0.4)

1.1
(0,8)

5. 1960-68*

.33
4.2

9.2

—1.0
( -0 .5 )

2.8
(3.0)

4.2
(3.5)

3.2
(3.3)

DeLeeuw-Kalchbrenner—nonborrowed monetary base
Almon lag with fourth degree polynomialf
.45
4.5

10.4

n.a.

n.a.

n.a.

n.a.

1
DeLeeuw-Kalchbrenner—nonborrowed reserves
Almon lag with fourth degree polynomialf

7. 1952-68*

.42
4.7

2.4

n.a.

|
|

n.a.

Note: Values of “t” statistics are indicated in parentheses.
* Through the second quarter of 1968.
t Fiscal variables included but not shown.
$ No fiscal variables included.




n.a.

tive of the member banks themselves. Certainly current
business conditions, interest rates, and the state of loan
demand influence the demand for borrowed reserves.
Second, the base includes currency. The volume of cur­
rency the public wishes to hold is an endogenous variable.
The banks supply the public with currency on demand,
and, during the period of the 1950’s and 1960’s, the Fed­
eral Reserve has more or less automatically replenished
the reserves lost by the banking system through currency
drains. Hence a strong case can also be made that the
currency component of the base is endogenous too. In a
rejoinder to deLeeuw and Kalchbrenner, Andersen and
Jordan dispute the contention that borrowed reserves
and currency should be subtracted from the base to obtain
a more “exogenous” variable.10 While I remain uncon­
vinced by their rejoinder, I will not say anything more
about this “exogeneity” issue since I want to pursue a
somewhat different tack.11
The remaining equations in Table IV show the results
of stripping away, successively, borrowed reserves and
currency from the total monetary base. As can be seen
from the table, R 2 falls and the standard error rises
noticeably when the sole independent variables are the
current and lagged nonborrowed monetary base. (Com­
pare lines 2 and 3.) Furthermore, breaking the entire
period into the two subperiods used earlier, we find no
significant relationship whatever between the nonbor­
rowed monetary base and GNP in the earlier period
ended in 1960. Indeed, the overall multiplier is actually
negative.

2.7
(2.5)

Nonborrowed monetary base
Almon lag with second degree polynomial^

6. 1952-68*

125

n.a.

11 Andersen and Jordan find a negative correlation between
changes in borrowed reserves and changes in nonborrowed re­
serves (op. cit., page 15). From this they conclude that the
Federal Reserve System automatically offsets the effects on total
reserves of endogenous changes in borrowed reserves and that
total reserves, rather than the nonborrowed component, should
therefore be treated as exogenous. However, a negative correlation
would also be found if the System used either nonborrowed
reserves or borrowed reserves (or some other related money
market variable such as free reserves or the Federal funds rate)
as an operational target. Thus a deliberate increase in non­
borrowed reserves would tend to make banks pay off borrowings.
Similarly, a deliberate increase in the level of borrowed reserves
would have to be engineered by a subtraction of nonborrowed
reserves. In neither of these cases would total reserves or the
total monetary base be the appropriate exogenous variable.
Similarly, Andersen and Jordan conclude that automatic System
accommodation of currency drains implies a nonborrowed reserves
target; that the System has not in fact followed a nonborrowed
reserves target; and, therefore, that currency cannot be endogenous
(op. cit., page 13). This chain o f reasoning is invalid, if only
because many targets other than a nonborrowed reserve target
involve automatic System accommodation of currency drains,
including free reserve and other money market targets.

126

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1969

The first deLeeuw and Kalchbrenner equation shown
in Table IV also uses the nonborrowed monetary base,
but differs from mine in that it includes fiscal variables.
The inclusion of the latter accounts for an R 2 higher
than the one in my equation. Otherwise, the results are
similar to mine. (Compare lines 3 and 6.)
The second deLeeuw-Kalchbrenner equation reported
in Table IV eliminates both borrowed reserves and cur­
rency from the monetary base, thus leaving nonborrowed
member bank reserves. As these authors note, the effect
of leaving out currency is to reduce the multiplier dras­
tically. Indeed, the multiplier of 2.4 obtained for this
equation is not very different from the 2.0 multiplier of
nonborrowed reserves onto GNP obtained from the
Board-MIT model (see Table II). As a result, deLeeuw
and Kalchbrenner conclude that the coefficients of the
St. Louis equation are in fact heavily distorted by simul­
taneous equations bias. Once this is removed, they argue,
the results closely resemble the sort of world most of us
have always believed in.
I certainly agree with deLeeuw and Kalchbrenner that,
while the total monetary base is statistically superior to
the money supply as an exogenous variable, it probably
is not exogenous enough. Moreover, I agree that the simi­
larity of the results for nonborrowed reserves to the
Board-MIT structural model is interesting. Nevertheless,
I can’t help feeling that this is not quite the end of the
story. Even if one were wholly satisfied that nonborrowed
member bank reserves are the proper exogenous monetary
variable, it must nevertheless be kept in mind that what is
at stake is not a member-bank-nonborrowed-reserves
theory of the economy, but rather a money supply theory
of the economy. There is a substantial gap between mem­
ber bank nonborrowed reserves and the money supply.
The problem with the computations presented in Table
IV is that they short-circuit a two-stage chain of relation­
ships consisting of the relationship between the nonbor­
rowed base or nonborrowed reserves and money, on the
one hand, and the relationship between money and GNP,
on the other. Let us suppose that the money supply does
exert a powerful and quick-acting influence on GNP. Let
us suppose also that the influence of GNP on the money
supply is minimal. One might nevertheless get a rather
weak and slow-acting influence of the nonborrowed base
or of nonborrowed reserves on GNP simply because the
relationship between the base, or reserves, and money
was relatively weak. Moreover, the lag between the base,
or reserves, and GNP would represent the sum of the lags
in the two links of the chain. In other words, it is possible
that, even though the regressions proposed by deLeeuw
and Kalchbrenner and myself may be more statistically




“pure” in terms of the “reduced-form” rationale of the
St. Louis equations, these regressions may nevertheless
fail to do justice to the real power, stability, and prompt­
ness of the causal influence of money on business.
This possibility puts us in a new dilemma. On the one
hand, we can’t accept the St. Louis equations at face
value because neither money nor the total reserve base
may be sufficiently exogenous. On the other hand, the
equations using the nonborrowed base or reserves may
understate the causal influence of money for the reasons
just given. To separate out the influence of money on
business from the influence of business on money, one
would seem to need a complete structural model. But
this is precisely what the “reduced-form” approach, origi­
nated by Friedman and Meiselman and carried on by
Andersen and Jordan, seeks to avoid!
R EDU CED-FORIW I E Q U A T I O N S F O R M O N E Y

One possible way out of this mess is to examine
reduced-form equations for money itself. If the relation­
ship between the nonborrowed monetary base and money
is not very tight, this will explain some of the relative
looseness of the relationship between the nonborrowed
base and GNP. Moreover, by adding current and lagged
GNP to the instrument variables of policy, it may be pos-

Table V
CHANGES IN Mi REGRESSED ON CURRENT
AND LAGGED CHANGES IN THE NONBORROWED
MONETARY BASE (A B)
Quarterly changes
Period

R2

AB

A B -i

A B-a

A B-«

Unconstrained lag structure
1952-68*..................................

.54

.67
(2.6)

.80
(2.8)

.55
(1.9)

.27
(1.0)

1952-60....................................

.37

.23
(0.6)

.85
(2.3)

.56
(1.5)

.90
(2.6)

1961-68*

.58

1.37
(3.4)

.64
(1.4)

.83
(1.8)

— .43
( -1 .0 )

...............................

Aim on lag—second degree polynomial
1952-68*...................................

.53

.73
(3.6)

.67
(8.4)

.56
(4.6)

.33
(3.1)

1952-60...................................

.34

.29
(0.9)

.74
(3.8)

.84
(4.1)

.59
(3.7)

1961-68*...................................

.54

1.31
(4.4)

.76
(5.1)

.36
(1.9)

.11
(0.7)

Note: Values of “t” statistics are indicated in parentheses.
* Through the second quarter of 1968.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

sible to get some qualitative idea of how much of the
gross relationship between money and GNP reflects a
direct causal influence of money on GNP and how much
of it reflects a reverse influence of GNP on money.
Some reduced-form equations for quarterly changes
in Mj using current and lagged values of the nonborrowed
monetary base are presented in Table V. Current and
lagged changes in the nonborrowed monetary base (which,
it should be recalled, has been adjusted for changes in
reserve requirements) explain about 54 percent of the
variance of quarterly changes in Mx. What is more to
the point for present purposes is that the nonborrowed
base fails to explain fully 46 percent of the variance. Hence
there is considerable looseness in the relationship between
the nonborrowed base and Mi. Again, such a looseness is
especially evident in the first half of the period. More­
over, the coefficients in Table V suggest that the influence
of the base on Mx does operate with a distributed lag
that would contribute to the total lag of the influence
of the base on GNP. Thus the results of Table V lend
some support to the contention that the regressions of
GNP on the nonborrowed monetary base understate
(implicitly) the closeness of the association between
money and GNP and the size of the money multiplier
operating on GNP within any given period of elapsed
time.12
If something in the neighborhood of one half the vari­
ance of quarterly changes in Mi is left unexplained by
the nonborrowed base, what accounts for the remainder
of this variance? One factor would be the other instru­
ment variables of policy, i.e., changes in the discount rate
and in the Regulation Q ceiling. In addition, there could
be various factors operating from within the banking sec­
tor of the economy, such as shifts in bank demand sched­
ules for excess and borrowed reserves. Finally, there
would be all the remaining factors summed up in the
expression “the influence of business on money”. Only
part of the influence of business on money would be rep­
resented as an influence of, specifically, GNP on money.
Other parts would perhaps be represented by movements
in the composition of GNP, interest rates, and the various
categories of credit demands.

127

How large a part of the unexplained variance does
reflect an influence of GNP, as such, on money is the
question that Table VI attempts to answer. The first equa­
tion presented for each time period covered in the table
attempts to show the influence of the nonborrowed base
and other policy instrument variables on changes in Mx.
Actually, the only difference between these equations and
those in Table V is the addition of changes in the dis­
count rate— which does not, in fact, make much differ­
ence. As noted earlier, changes in reserve requirements
are accounted for in the measure of the base. The remain­
ing instrument variable of policy, changes in the Q ceil­
ing, is simply not included. Some experiments on time
periods when no change in the Q ceiling occurred showed
essentially the same results. Hence it seemed better to
omit it and save the degrees of freedom.
On balance, the results presented in Table VI do not
seem to show any very strong feedback from GNP to
money—which, it should be emphasized again is not the
same thing as a feedback from “business” to money. To
be sure, current and lagged changes in GNP “explain” about
32 percent of the variance of changes in Mi over the
whole 1952 to 1968-11 period and a bit over 20 percent
in each of the two subperiods. However, most of this
impact appears to occur in the current quarter, when the
direction of causation is of course ambiguous. The lagged
changes in GNP contribute almost nothing.
Similarly, the addition of current and lagged GNP
variables contributes almost nothing to explaining changes
in M1? once current and lagged monetary “policy” vari­
ables have already been included. For the period as a
whole, the adjusted R 2 of .53 for the policy variables rises
only .05 to .58 when current and lagged changes in GNP
are added. In contrast, the addition of the policy variables
to the GNP variables raises R 2 substantially, from .27 to
.58. As to the subperiods, GNP does make a noticeable
contribution in the earlier period. In the 1960’s, however,
current and lagged GNP variables give an adjusted R 2 of
only .08 by themselves. When the policy variables are
added, this rises to fully .67. This is an interesting result
in view of the especially close relationship between changes
in GNP and current and lagged changes in Mi during the
1960’s, as noted earlier.
The impression that the influence of “policy” variables
on the money supply dominates any feedback from GNP
12 Essentially the same conclusions apply if member bank non­ to the money supply has to be modified, but only some­
borrowed reserves are used instead of the nonborrowed reserve
what, if nonborrowed member bank reserves are used in
base. However, R 2’s are of course lower since nonborrowed re­
place
of the nonborrowed monetary base. The reason is,
serves make no attempt to explain, or to allow for, changes in
the currency component of ML,. Using an unconstrained lag
of course, that nonborrowed reserves make no allowance
structure, nonborrowed reserves gives an R2 of .34 for the full
for the currency component of the money supply and
period with a total multiplier of 3.2. For the 1952-60 subperiod,
the R2 is .30, while it is .39 for the 1961 to 1968-11 subperiod.
therefore explain less of the variance of changes in Mi




128

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1969
Table VI
CHANGES IN Mi REGRESSED ON CURRENT AND LAGGED CHANGES
IN GNP, THE NONBORROWED MONETARY BASE, AND THE DISCOUNT RATE
Quarterly changes

Period

A GNP

A GNP-1

A GNP-2

1952-68*
.08
(3.9)

.01
(0.3)

_

_

<—)

(-)

.03
(1.7)

.01
(0.3)

(—)

_

AB

A B_i

A B_s

A B—
3

A R<i

.78
(3.0)

.85
(3.0)

.47
(1.6)

.17
(0.6)

.73
(2.1)

A GNP-3

- .04
( -2 .3 )

.95
(3.7)

1952-60

.46
(1.1)
.05
(1.9)

— .01
(-0 .4 )

.01
(0.2)

- .04
( -1 .7 )

.05
(2.2)

.01
(0.5)

.03
(1.1)

— .02
( -0 .9 )

1961-68*
.09
(2.0)

.01
(0,3)

- .03
( -0 .6 )

.02
(0.4)

.06
(1.7)

.03
(0.9)

- .05
(-1 .4 )

- .03
( -1 .1 )

R55

R2f

.57

.53

.32

.27

.79
(2.8)

.38
(1.4)

.02
(0.1)

.56
(1.4)

.64

.58

.93
(2.5)

.61
(1.6)

.88
(2.6)

.49
(1.1)

.39

.29

.23

.13

!
.70
(1.7)

.91
(2.5)

.64
(1.7)

.73
(2.3)

- .12
( - 0 .2 )

.55

.39

1.39
(3.8)

.86
(2.0)

.46
(1.0)

- .59
( -1 .5 )

1.54
(2.5)

.66

.59

.21

.08

.77

.67

1.61
(4.3)

.90
(1.8)

.21
(0.5)

- .64
( -1 .6 )

.86
(1.3)

Note: Values of “t” statistics are indicated in parentheses.
* Through the second quarter of 1968.
f Adjusted R2.

than does the nonborrowed base. For the entire 1952 to
1968-11 period, changes in nonborrowed member bank
reserves (adjusted for reserve requirements) and in the
discount rate have an adjusted R 2 with respect to changes
in Mi of .39. Addition of current and lagged changes in
GNP raises this to .50. For the 1952-60 subperiod, the
“policy” variables, so defined, give an adjusted R 2 of .20
alone, with R 2 rising to .21 when the GNP variables are
added. For the 1961 to 1968-11 subperiod, the “policy”
variables give an adjusted R 2 of .38, which rises to .50
when GNP is included. While these results using non­
borrowed reserves are less clearly one-sided than those
using the nonborrowed monetary base, the conclusion
that the feedback from changes in GNP to changes in Mi
may be relatively modest still seems warranted.
S U M M A R Y O F M AJO R S T A T IS T ICA L . IS S U E S

At this point a brief general summary of the major sta­
tistical issues for and against the St. Louis equation may
be useful. (1) The equation shows very little explanatory
power when fitted to the 1952-60 data. It seems to fit the
data well only in the 1960’s. Coincidentally or not, there
was a significant trend in the first differences of money
and GNP in the 1960’s that was not present in the 1950’s.




In rejoinder, St. Louis might note that the period 1952-60
happens to be about the worst possible subperiod from
the entire 1952 to 1968-11 period. The R 2 for this sub­
period, as noted earlier, is .18. For the still shorter sub­
periods, 1952-57 and 1955-60, it is about .32 in each
case. Personally, this rejoinder does not seem very impres­
sive to me. Consequently, I would regard the poor per­
formance of the St. Louis equation in the 1952-60 sub­
period as a distinct embarrassment.
(2) In the St. Louis equation’s favor is the fact that
the coefficients are reasonably stable over time, even
though the two halves of the 1952-68 period show such
different R 2’s.
(3) If the nonborrowed monetary base or nonbor­
rowed member bank reserves are used as the exogenous
variable, rather than the money supply or the total mone­
tary base, explanatory power drops rather substantially.
So do the sizes of the multipliers. Indeed, there is no
significant relationship at all between the nonborrowed
base, current and lagged, and GNP in the 1952-60 sub­
period. In defense of the St. Louis equation, however, one
may argue that the total base is in fact a more appropri­
ate “exogenous” variable than the nonborrowed base.
Again, I myself am not at all satisfied with the St. Louis
rejoinder on this point cited earlier. Nevertheless, I freely

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

confess that the problem of identifying a suitable exoge­
nous monetary variable does not seem to have an entirely
obvious solution.
(4) I would prefer a somewhat different defense of the
St. Louis equation. This would be along the lines that
the relatively poor relationship between the nonborrowed
base (or reserves) and GNP does not deal directly with
the question of the relationship between money itself and
GNP. To deal with this question, it is worthwhile to
attempt to determine how much of the relationship be­
tween changes in money and changes in GNP is a feed­
back relationship from GNP to money.
(5) The available evidence suggests that current and
lagged changes in the nonborrowed base (or nonbor­
rowed reserves) and other monetary policy variables
leave a substantial amount of the variance in monetary
changes unexplained. This therefore leaves a large po­
tential role for all the influences wrapped up under the
general rubric of “business conditions”.
(6) The specific variable GNP, however, seems to
contribute rather little extra to explaining the variance in
monetary changes beyond what is explained by the policy
variables. Hence, only a relatively modest part of the
gross relationship between money and GNP exhibited in
the St. Louis equation may reflect a feedback effect
from GNP to money. Much of the powerful influence of
“business” on money found by Cagan must be reflected
by variables other than GNP (such as interest rates)—
or perhaps the cyclical behavior of the monetary growth
rate is simply a very different sort of variable than quar­
terly dollar changes in Ma.
On balance it would seem fair to say that the St. Louis
equation has not been devastated by the critical scrutiny
to which it has been subjected. On the other hand, I think
it is equally obvious that some distinctly troublesome
questions exist regarding the equation. The equation’s
merits do not seem to me sufficient to compel by themselves
our acceptance of the world it portrays. This being the
case, it seems appropriate in closing to put aside regres­
sion results and consider briefly some of the underlying
economic issues.
T R A N SM ISSIO N M E C H A N IS M

The St. Louis equation says that a $1 billion increase in
the money supply this quarter will raise GNP in this same
quarter by $1.6 billion and that, by the next quarter,
money will have raised GNP by $3.5 billion. This is some­
what over half its ultimate influence. If the money supply
were increased by means of Government handouts of
newly printed dollar bills, this sort of quick, sharp reac­




129

tion would certainly seem reasonable. The actual process
of money creation is of course quite different, however. It
works primarily through central bank open market opera­
tions and through asset purchases by commercial banks. It
involves no direct effects on private income or wealth of
any great magnitude.
Most people now seem to agree that monetary impulses
must work their effects on GNP primarily through a chain
of substitution relationships. This chain most often begins
when the Trading Desk at the New York Reserve Bank
makes a bid over the phone to a group of Government
securities dealers who are persuaded by the terms of the
offer to exchange part of their portfolio of Governments
for demand deposits. Relative interest rates change and
portfolio balance is disturbed. Thus further substitutions
are made. Deposits are exchanged for private securities,
and the rates on these securities are bid down. Ultimately,
wealth holders must be persuaded that they should sub­
stitute into physical assets (whether producers’ goods or
consumers’ durables). It is at this stage that GNP begins
to be affected.
The crucial point is that, if there are no important in­
come or wealth effects stemming from the process of
money creation, then this final substitution into goods can
only take place as a result of the shifts in relative interest
rates that are set in motion by the monetary process. If
wealth holders’ net worth is unchanged, and if their income
is unchanged, they will be induced to try to shift into more
extensive holdings of real assets only if their demand
for such assets is sensitive to the changes in relative yields.
If there are no income and wealth effects whatever, the
impact of monetary changes on the real economy can be
no swifter or more powerful than is permitted by the
interest-rate responsiveness of the demand for real capital.
As far as I can tell, incidentally, these conclusions de­
pend in no way on the length of the chain of transactions
between the original money-creating transaction and the
first transaction involving nonfinancial assets. Some argue
that the initial money-creating transaction may lead im­
mediately to an increased demand for goods and that, in
such cases, the interest rate elasticity of the demand for
goods is irrelevant. This seems quite wrong to me. Suppose
an individual is induced to exchange with the Federal
Reserve some of his Government securities for deposits
because the Fed’s bid in the market makes such an ex­
change attractive to him. At this point in time, his income
and wealth are unchanged, but the rate on Governments
is lower. If his equilibrium portfolio composition now
involves, say, fewer Governments and more of both cash
and goods, it can only be because his desired holdings of
both cash and of goods are sensitive to the changed yield

130

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1969

on Governments. Given an unchanged utility function,
there is simply no other possible explanation.
To the extent that the monetary process depends upon
portfolio composition effects induced by changes in relative
interest rates, the monetary impulses in the St. Louis equa­
tion seem to me to influence GNP with an implausible
rapidity. We are, after all, not wholly devoid of information
on the response of business fixed investment, inventories,
and consumer durables to changes in interest rates. Indeed,
we have a large body of econometric and interview-type
studies accumulated over the years on these matters. Cer­
tainly these studies are open to a variety of interpretations,
and they are by no means unanimous in their findings.
Nevertheless, I think there can be little question that their
tenor is overwhelmingly against the sort of large shortperiod multipliers found in the St. Louis equation. The
Board-MIT model incorporates a fairly representative
sample of such econometric research, and its multipliers
are much closer to what this research had in the past led
us to expect.
On the other hand, it is possible that the conventional
studies of the interest-elasticity of demand of the different
categories of capital goods, as well as the traditional in­
terview approach to this subject, are leaving out major
elements of the transmission mechanism. The omission of
these elements may explain the divergence of the St. Louis
world from the world seemingly implied by the more
traditional sort of research. I can think of at least three
possible factors that may not be adequately accounted for
in the more traditional studies.
First, the money creation process itself— and the subse­
quent shifting of financial portfolios— does involve bid­
ding up the prices of a variety of financial assets, Govern­
ment and private. Obviously a rise in the market price of
outstanding private financial instruments has no effect on
real private wealth. However, there may be a sort of
“pseudo-wealth”, or “distribution” effect stemming from
such price rises. This could occur if private financial assets
were valued by their holders at market value while the
issuers valued their liabilities at maturity value or at some
conventional par. How important such distributional effects
may be we do not know. Certainly I would not expect
that the effects of rising market prices for debt instruments
related to the monetary expansion process would be of
much significance. For one thing, holders of these instru­
ments often do not value their holdings at market prices.
To this extent, net worth positions as perceived by their
owners would not be changed by changing market prices.
When one considers rises in the price of equities, however,
the possibility of a significant secondary wealth effect on
the demand for goods and services seems much more real.




A second possible source of transmission from monetary
changes to the real sector that may not have been given
sufficient attention in the traditional empirical research is
availability effects. We know that the capital market is
structured so that some potential borrowers simply cannot
obtain all the funds they want by raising their bid in the
market. To the extent that a money supply increase is as­
sociated with a direct increase in the funds made available
to these borrowers, it could have a direct, swift-acting, and
powerful effect on real spending. That there exists avail­
ability effects of this kind (is beyond question; that they are
important enough to accotraHior the very high short-run
multipliers in the St. Louis equation is less clear.
A third possible deficiency of the conventional research
may be its treatment, or lack of treatment, of the implicit
rates of return on real capital. Friedman and others have
argued for years that existing research on the importance
of interest rates in the demand for capital goods was wholly
inadequate because it failed to include own-rates of return
on real capital, including rates of return on consumer
durable goods. It is of course possible that a more adequate
treatment of implicit real rates would turn up a much
sharper and more rapid response to interest rates than has
been found in past studies. At the moment, however, this
is totally unexplored territory.

C O N C LU D IN G C O M M E N T

In conclusion, I can summarize my overall reaction to
the St. Louis equation about as follows. Andersen and
Jordan have produced a monetarist equation that holds
up rather better than I would have thought likely. In
particular, it does not seem easy to dispose of the asso­
ciation between changes in money and changes in GNP
by showing that it is primarily or largely a matter of
“reverse causation”. On the other hand, the reduced-form
approach they use, which at first looks so seductively easy,
turns out on closer inspection to be itself fraught with
difficulties. In this particular case, it leads to an equation
that produces a much quicker monetary response than
seems consistent with a large part of existing research on
the nature of the monetary transmission mechanism. At
the moment, I find it very difficult to believe in the
St. Louis equation: I just don’t quite see how things could
work that way. On the other hand, I am ready to concede
at least the possibility that proper allowance for various
secondary wealth effects, credit availability effects, and a
broader treatment of interest rates might, in principle,
be able to make the St. Louis world seem plausible.
I think the onus is now clearly on the monetarists to

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

spell out in detail precisely how they think the transmis­
sion process works. Moreover, this description must be
translated into an econometric model with a reasonable
degree of structural detail. Certainly the rest of us would
like to see just exactly how such a model would differ
from the Board-MIT model, for example. We need to see

precisely how money is supposed to produce the results
it appears to produce in the Andersen-Jordan equation.
I suspect that only after such a project is carried out, and
carried out successfully, will most economists really be
prepared to believe that money matters as much and as
fast as it seems to in St. Louis.

Subscriptions to the m o n t h l y r e v i e w are available to the public without charge. Additional
copies of any issue may be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank
of New York, 33 Liberty Street, New York, N.Y. 10045.




131