View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

99

T h e D o lla r in th e W orld Today*
By A l f r e d H a y e s
President, Federal Reserve Bank of New York

As we move into the tenth year of sizable deficits in the
United States balance of payments, I am disturbed to find
a growing sense of impatience in the American business
and financial community, directed less toward our failure
to cope adequately with this problem than toward the
restraints which the problem itself imposes on the freedom
of American capital to move abroad in response to purely
private considerations. To oversimplify, there is a tendency
to regard all American investment abroad as good per se
and to look upon those who counsel restraint for balanceof-payments reasons as unrealistic adherents of outworn
economic theories.
It is my view that these attitudes, while understandable,
are quite wrong and, if given free rein, would result in a
breakdown of the whole international financial system
which has served world trade and world investment so
well since World War II.
Now there is no denying that the United States econ­
omy is the strongest in the world today, that the United
States offers almost unrivaled opportunities for the invest­
ment of short-term funds, and that the dollar is at present
used as a vehicle currency for perhaps half of all interna­
tional financial transactions, in addition to its unique role
as a reserve currency for most of the leading industrial na­
tions. All of these facts give the dollar a very large measure
of inherent strength; but not even they can guarantee the
preservation of that strength, unless we perform adequately
on two counts: (1) We must see that the dollar’s internal
purchasing power is reasonably stable; (2) we must come

* An address before the Graduate School o f Business Administra­
tion of New York University, June 8, 1967. On this occasion, Mr.
Hayes was presented with the School’s C. Walter Nichols Award.




reasonably close to equilibrium in our balance of payments,
on the average, over a period of years.
It has been argued that, to the extent that our pay­
ments deficits are offset by an increase in our long-term
assets abroad (and in recent years such assets have grown
even more rapidly than our cumulative payments deficit),
we need not worry “because the bank is decidedly solvent”.
The point is, however, that we cannot meet a short-term
liability, if it is presented for payment, by offering a share
in American-owned factories in foreign countries. Like any
bank, we must keep enough liquid assets available, in pro­
portion to our liquid liabilities, to inspire confidence in our
lasting ability to pay off those liabilities on demand.
Of course, aside from the use of our dwindling gold
stock, there are other ways of meeting the temporary pres­
sures that may arise from such liquid claims. A whole
spectrum of voluntary cooperative credit arrangements
has been built up since World War II, with the Interna­
tional Monetary Fund occupying the central position and
with strong support from the Federal Reserve swap lines
and other central bank credits, the sale by the United
States Treasury of foreign currency bonds, and related
measures. These credit facilities have proved their worth
in taking care of several massive speculative attacks on
major currencies, as well as serious potential pressures on
the dollar and a multitude of temporary payments swings;
and over the coming years I am sure they can be further
refined and enlarged. Incidentally, in the current Middle
East crisis, Federal Reserve swap lines and other forms of
central bank cooperation have again demonstrated their
solid worth. But no amount of credit can ever assure sta­
bility if a one-way disequilibrium proves too large and
too lasting.
The same comment applies to the current worthwhile
efforts to reach agreement on some form of supplemen­

100

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1967

tary reserve asset which would relieve some of the burden
on gold while preserving the usefulness of the dollar as
a reserve currency. After all these years of study and
debate, it would be very useful to find some agreement
on such a contingency plan before too much additional
time has elapsed. But no solution of this problem can
relieve in the slightest degree our obligation to reach
equilibrium in our international accounts.
Far from justifying a more casual and high-handed
approach to payments imbalances than in the case of other
currencies, the dollar’s special position entails special
responsibilities for prudent behavior. A country whose
currency is held by many other countries as a monetary
reserve may have available a considerable measure of auto­
matic credit. On occasion this can be very useful indeed,
and clearly there are a variety of benefits accruing to the
United States by reason of the dollar’s almost universal
use as a vehicle and reserve currency. It seems to me wholly
reasonable, however, to expect the United States to order
its financial affairs in a way to merit the world’s confidence
in our currency.
There is another aspect of this question which is worth
bearing in mind. The attitude of foreign countries toward
American investment in their markets varies widely from
country to country and, even within a single country, is
a composite of differing strands of thought, both favor­
able and unfavorable. Suppose, for example, that a large
United States firm is constructing a new industrial plant
that will provide greatly intensified competition for exist­
ing domestically owned concerns. The move may be very
popular with construction companies which will benefit
from the initial investment activity, or with bankers
who may handle a large volume of initial financing, or
with companies which believe they will be able to buy the
products of the new plant more cheaply than would have
been possible if the older plants had been the only source
of supply. And the officials responsible for development
and economic growth may be very well pleased. On the
other hand, the move may be anything but popular with
the competing companies whose path will be more diffi­
cult under the new conditions, and with the central bank­
ing authorities who may feel that the additional stimulus
is more than can be absorbed without undue inflationary
pressure. In addition, there may be those who fear that
worldwide United States enterprises may be becoming too
dominant in their national economy. On balance, the atti­
tude may be highly favorable. But, if it should become
obvious that the United States was deliberately following
a policy of fostering overseas investment without any regard
for a huge concurrent accumulation of dollar holdings
abroad, the balance of forces in the country in question




could swing sharply against us, even to the point where
severe restraints were initiated against further Ameri­
can investments.
In arguing that we must not and cannot ignore the
discipline of balance-of-payments pressures, I am cer­
tainly not contending that the burden of adjustment should
rest entirely with the deficit country. There are many steps
that can and should be taken by the surplus countries to
try to reduce their surpluses— steps involving a loosening
of restraints on capital exports, encouragement of merchan­
dise imports, the selection of an appropriate mix of mone­
tary and fiscal measures, etc. In the present setting, it seems
to me quite reasonable that we continue to call upon Europe
for more effective “cooperation” in carrying out its share
of the adjustment process.
In so doing, we should neither assume nor imply that we
ourselves have done everything that we can to achieve
equilibrium. While equilibrium may not prove attainable
as long as Vietnam expenditures are at anything like their
present level, this does not excuse us from continuing our
efforts in this direction. There may be additional possibili­
ties for savings in our public outlays abroad, although here
we must of course weigh the political and military factors
as well as the financial. But if, as I believe, our best hope
of coming closer to payments equilibrium lies in achieving
a larger trade surplus, then it is not good enough to feel
satisfied if, as in the past year or so, our costs and prices have
risen no more rapidly than those of most other industrial
nations. Obviously, we must do even better than they if
our relative competitive position is to be improved, with
consequent benefits to our trade surplus. I think that it is
in this area of costs and prices that there is still inadequate
awareness, on the part of many Americans, of the vital
importance of achieving greater stability. When union
leaders and business executives are ready to give this
international factor due weight in every wage negotiation
and price decision, then we may be well on the way to
building the larger trade surplus that we need. And of
course appropriate fiscal and monetary policies also play a
big role in influencing both the trade balance and other
important elements in our overall balance of payments.
Progress on these fronts, as well as more effective coopera­
tion by the surplus countries, would open the way to elim­
inating the kinds of emergency restraints on capital exports
which have proved so understandably irksome to our bank­
ers and businessmen. These restraints must certainly be
regarded as a necessary evil— desirable only in the sense
that they are preferable to the financial chaos that would
probably follow from our failure to keep our overall pay­
ments under some control.
I might add that, while the restraint on foreign bank

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

lending has been relatively severe, it seems to me that di­
rect investment has been subjected to only rather moder­
ate curbs. The major effort has been to prevent further
increases in an outflow which has been at record levels for
the past two years, well above the level of the early sixties.
In my judgment, it will not be necessary for us to attain
absolute equilibrium, year in and year out, in our so-called
liquidity balance. If the dollar continues to perform use­
fully its function as a vehicle currency to finance inter­
national trade and investment, there will undoubtedly be
a need for some gradual growth in private dollar holdings.
And I would not preclude a gradual growth over the years
in the dollar reserves of foreign countries which are pre­
pared to strengthen their financial positions in this way.
After all, there is no absolute rule as to the proper rela­
tion between our gold holdings and our current liabilities
to the rest of the world. In my own estimate, the present
relationship between these quantities would be accepted
by the world as quite “conservative” if only it could be
demonstrated that large continuing deficits are a thing of
the past. In the years ahead, of course, the world’s entire
reserve structure should be strengthened by the addition
of some new type of asset.
I hope that I have said enough to demonstrate why I
would emphatically disagree with the suggestion of some




101

private citizens that we should perhaps threaten other
countries with radical changes in the role of the dollar if
they failed to perform in ways that we deemed desirable.
Such a threat is only too likely to backfire and defeat our
purpose, besides being quite inappropriate to the dignity
and responsibility of the world’s most powerful nation.
It is heartening that our Government has made clear its
determination to preserve the dollar’s present role.
I regard the fixed relationship of gold to the dollar
at $35 per ounce, on both the buying and the selling side,
as the very keystone of the world’s financial structure.
Fortunately this fact is recognized by the world’s monetary
authorities, and our own Government’s unchanged policy
with respect to this relationship has been forcefully reiter­
ated on many occasions. Those private commentators who
are inclined to make light of this relationship, and even
to suggest some measures calculated to alter it, would
do well to reflect on the major contribution which this
keystone has made to the world’s unprecedented measure
of prosperity in the years that have passed since the far­
sighted Bretton Woods arrangements were first set up.
Our best assurance of further growth and prosperity lies
in leaving the keystone in place and reinforcing it with
appropriate domestic policies and appropriate measures
of international financial cooperation.

102

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1967

T h e B u sin ess S itu a tion
Early spring saw little change in the pace of economic
activity. The readjustment in business inventories con­
tinued to have a dampening effect on production, employ­
ment, and incomes. In addition, labor disputes in the
trucking industry during April apparently played some role
in holding down the volume of economic activity. Taken
together, the most recent data seem to indicate that, early
in the second quarter, the economy remained on the high
plateau which had characterized it since the start of the
year. The general stability of the economy, in the face of
this year’s very sharp reduction in the rate of inventory
accumulation, attests to the continued strength of other
demand forces. Additional declines in inventory spending
seem probable, perhaps resulting in some actual liquidation
of aggregate stocks. However, the rate of adjustment is
unlikely to be so sharp as in recent months, and the result­
ing reduction in spending should thus have appreciably
less impact on overall production. At the same time, the
prospects are for substantial further growth in other de­
mand categories, including especially residential construc­
tion and government spending. The recent outbreak of war
in the Middle East has, of course, added a substantial ele­
ment of uncertainty to the outlook.

inventories and reduce the stock-sales ratio from the excep­
tionally high level reached early in the year. Responding
to the improved situation, automobile producers rescinded
some earlier cuts in second-quarter production schedules,
thus adding strength to the rise in the assembly rate. Auto
output in April, seasonally adjusted, rose by nearly 10 per
cent to an annual rate of about 7% million units, and a
further increase was recorded in May.
In contrast to the renewed strength of motor vehicle
output in recent months, production of other consumer
durable goods has continued to slacken. Retail sales of
furniture and home appliances have been weak, and sig­
nificant inventory problems have developed in some lines.
The market for television sets has experienced a par­
ticularly dramatic swing away from the surging growth
that characterized the 1964-66 period. In April, output of
television sets was fully 30 per cent below the peak
reached in December.
The easing of overall industrial production in 1967 has
reflected not only a sluggishness in consumer demand but
also a slowdown in the growth of capital spending. The
volume of business equipment output in April was almost
3 per cent under its December peak and about equal to
the level of late last summer. The restoration by Congress
of the tax incentives for investment that were suspended
P R O D U C T IO N , O R D E R S , A N D R E S ID E N T IA L
last
fall should give some boost to demands for capital
C O N S T R U C T IO N
equipment. Even with the restoration, however, the recent
Industrial output in April was slightly below the level of easing of capacity utilization rates and the decline in profits
the preceding two months. The Federal Reserve Board’s in the first quarter suggest that 1967 will see only a mod­
seasonally adjusted production index dropped to 155.9 per est further rise in spending on capital investment. According
cent of the 1957-59 average, 0.5 percentage point under to the latest survey of businessmen, taken in May by the
the reading in both February and March. The decrease Commerce Department and Securities and Exchange Com­
put the overall index at a level 2 per cent under the record mission, total capital outlays this year will be 3 per cent
high touched last December. Modest output declines in above the 1966 level. This represents a modest downward
April were widespread among manufacturing industries, the revision in anticipated 1967 spending from the figure re­
only significant exception being motor vehicle production ported in the Government’s February survey, with the
which rose strongly for the second month in a row. The bulk of the reduction being concentrated in the first half
spring brought an improvement in new car sales as well as of the year.
in producers’ expectations regarding the sales outlook. As a
The inflow of new orders for durable goods increased
result, the industry has been able to work down auto moderately in April and at $22.3 billion was somewhat




FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

Chart I

PRIVATE NONFARM RESIDENTIAL CONSTRUCTION
Season ally adjusted annual rates
Thousands of units

Thousands of units

Source: United States Bureau of theCensus.

larger than the first-quarter average. Most major industries
reported orders gains for the month, including the primary
metals producers whose orders had slumped quite sharply
in March. The machinery and equipment industries experi­
enced a second consecutive rise in new bookings; from
last October through February, such orders had dropped
month by month. Shipments of durable goods declined in
April— in part, perhaps, because of labor disputes in the
trucking industry. Since shipments and orders were virtu­
ally equal, the total backlog of unfilled orders showed no
significant change in contrast to the substantial declines in
the earlier months of the year. The backlog of primary
metals producers declined significantly further in April.
However, the aircraft industry’s backlog grew strongly,
while unfilled orders changed little in most other dura­
bles industries.
The volume of new orders for defense products rose in
April, returning to the February level. This series, which
tends to be heavily influenced by swings in orders for air­
craft, can give only a rough approximation of the actual




103

trend of defense buying of durable goods. The Commerce
Department’s figures on new orders for defense products
do not include all defense ordering of durables and, on the
other hand, they do record some nondefense ordering, espe­
cially of aircraft. While new orders for defense products
have been essentially stable for some months, there can
be little doubt that the impact of military demands on the
economy has continued to be very substantial. A revision
of first-quarter gross national product (GNP) figures shows
that the rise in Federal purchases of goods and services
for defense purposes was $4.2 billion at a seasonally ad­
justed annual rate, accounting for more than 25 per cent
of the total rise in final demand, that is, GNP excluding
inventory investment.
The recovery in residential construction is continuing.
On a seasonally adjusted basis, the number of private non­
farm housing starts rose only slightly in April after a small
March decline (see Chart I ) . Underlying these figures,
however, is the fact that the actual number of starts suc­
ceeded in scoring the very strong March-April advance
which is expected as a seasonal phenomenon and is thus
allowed for in the seasonal adjustment of the data. In un­
adjusted terms, housing starts rose by almost 50 per cent
in March and by more than 20 per cent in April. These
rises occurred despite the relatively short period of time
that had been available to the home-building industry to
adjust to a higher rate of operations, in the wake of last
year’s steep decline.
The resurgence of residential building can also be seen
in the trend of building permits issued by local authorities
(see Chart I). In areas requiring permits, there has been
a strong rise in authorizations of both single-family homes
and of units in multifamily structures. (While only about
80 to 85 per cent of total starts in recent years have been
covered by permits, nearly all multifamily structures are
built under permit authorizations.) The slump last year in
construction of multi-unit housing followed two previous
years of weakness which had resulted from earlier over­
building in some areas, especially in the West. There was
no tangible decline in the national rate of vacancies in rental
units until 1966, when the vacancy rate in the West, which
had previously stopped rising, finally turned downward.
Vacancy rates moved still lower in the first quarter of 1967,
and their substantial decline in the past year or two sug­
gests the existence of an appreciable volume of potential
demand for rental housing.
E M P L O Y M E N T , IN C O M E , A N D C O N S U M E R B U Y IN G

Manufacturers made further reductions in both April
and May in the number of production workers on their

104

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1967

payrolls. A large part of the May decline was attributable
to the effects of strikes in the rubber industry. Employ­
ment expanded in most other sectors of the nonfarm econ­
omy, with government continuing to show a particularly
strong uptrend, but the total number of persons on nonagricultural payrolls nevertheless declined in both months.
The May cutback in manufacturing employment was the
fourth in a row and, at the same time, the average length
of the workweek dropped back to the February figure fol­
lowing two small increases. Average weekly hours in dura­
bles manufacturing have been essentially unchanged since
February, but in nondurables the workweek lengthened
slightly in March and April and then fell back in May.
Having made a very sharp reduction in the workweek dur­
ing the winter months, manufacturers in the spring were
apparently making further adjustments to slower produc­
tion largely by way of cuts in employment.
The rate of unemployment in the civilian labor force

Chart II

UNEMPLOYMENT RATES
Unemployment as a percentage of the civilian la b o r force
Percent

Percent

1963

1964

1965

Source*. United States Bureau of Labor Statistics,




1966

1967

edged back up in April to the 3.7 per cent figure that had
prevailed from December through February, and moved
to 3.8 per cent in May (see Chart II). Thus, the unemploy­
ment rate has changed but little this year despite a definite
slowing in the economy. In part, the fact that the rate
has been so nearly stable is the result of a reduction in
average output per worker. This reduction, in turn, is at­
tributable to the combined effects of a cut in workers’
average weekly hours and a halt to the growth of produc­
tivity, that is, output per man-hour.
Moreover, in periods when there is a slowing in eco­
nomic activity and in the growth of job openings, it is
quite common for some women to withdraw from— or to
refrain from entering—the labor force. This is often true
of teen-agers as well. There has been some evidence of
such a development in recent months. In 1966, when the
economy was growing very rapidly and demands for labor
were very strong, there was a vigorous expansion in the
number of women in the labor force, with virtually all the
growth representing an advance in the number of women
employed. During the first five months of this year, in con­
trast, the average number of women in the labor force was
only very slightly larger than in the preceding five months,
and the average number of women employed declined.
Largely as a consequence, overall labor force growth has
slowed during the early months of 1967.
The April cutbacks in manufacturing employment and
overtime were accompanied by a drop in total wage and
salary payments in that sector, which in turn held down
the growth of personal income. Also working to hold
back the expansion of income in April was the fact that
accelerated payments of dividends on veterans’ life insur­
ance had temporarily swelled personal income in Febru­
ary and March; this buoying influence then disappeared
in April. Altogether, the rise in personal income for the
month was the smallest in well over a year.
Since the closing months of 1966, consumers have sharply
stepped up the proportion of their after-tax incomes allo­
cated to savings. Over the same period, aggregate retail
sales volume has been virtually stable and consumption
spending on goods and services has contributed only mod­
estly to overall GNP expansion. According to recent revi­
sions of GNP figures, personal consumption expenditures
grew by $5.8 billion in the first quarter, at a seasonally
adjusted annual rate,1 rather than the $8.1 billion indicated

1 With various other components also revised, the net effect of
the revisions was to reduce total first-quarter GNP by $0.6 billion to
$763.7 billion.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

by the preliminary estimate and reported last month in
this Review. The downward revision was largely in pur­
chases of nondurable goods, and was chiefly due to the fact
that preliminary estimates had overstated retail sales in
February and March. With consumption spending revised
downward, the ratio of savings to disposable income was
revised upward to 6.5 per cent, compared with 5.9 per cent
in the fourth quarter and a quite low 4.8 per cent in the
third quarter.
As a concomitant of the recent vigorous growth of sav­
ings, there has been a strong buildup in consumers’ hold­
ings of liquid assets, such as savings deposits. This trend
suggests that a favorable basis is being established for the
development of renewed vigor in the expansion of con­
sumer spending. Preliminary April data, however, pro­
vided little evidence of any appreciable strengthening in
the behavior of overall retail sales. Sales of nondurables
increased by about 1 per cent, and outlets dealing in motor
vehicles and related goods also registered a gain in dollar
volume. Sales declined at other durables stores, how­
ever. Total April sales were estimated as being up by
less than 1 per cent, following a slightly stronger rise in
March.
Sales of new automobiles made a relatively good show­
ing in both March and April. A rise of about SVi per cent
in the latter month brought sales to a seasonally adjusted
annual rate of 7.6 million units. May sales held very close
to the April pace. While the current selling rate is low,
relative to the experience of the last few years, the improve­
ment during the spring has buoyed manufacturers’ expecta­
tions regarding the sales outlook.




105

C O S T A N D P R IC E D E V E L O P M E N T S

The general stability of output in recent months has
been accompanied by a cessation of growth in overall out­
put per man-hour, with some sectors of the economy ap­
parently recording actual declines. Hourly compensation
has shown a strong rise, and labor costs per unit of output
have continued to increase at a significant rate. Nonfinancial corporations, whose activities generate well over
half of total GNP, experienced a first-quarter rise in unit
labor costs equal to almost 10 per cent at an annual rate.
The quarter’s increase for manufacturing firms alone was
of nearly the same magnitude. The pressure of rising unit
costs was clearly a factor behind the first-quarter drop in
corporate profits, and price increases aimed at protecting
profit margins could well become more common over the
months ahead.
According to preliminary figures, the wholesale price
index rose in May, following three months of decline.
There has been no change since February in the average
level of industrial commodity prices. Thus, the behavior
of the overall index has been dominated by agricultural
prices, which trended downward through April but then
rose rather sharply in May, largely as the result of an up­
turn for livestock and meats. This recent advance in
wholesale food prices may well be followed by a renewed
rise at the consumer level. In April, however, the con­
sumer food price index continued to decline, but increases
for other goods as well as for services pushed the total
consumer price index up by 0.3 percentage point—the
largest advance since last October.

106

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1967

T h e M o n e y and B on d M a rk e ts in M a y
The money and capital markets exhibited divergent the month with some issues falling to their lows of the year.
movements in May. Conditions in the money market There was good demand from investors and other sources.
remained generally comfortable and some short-term inter­ Demand particularly favored shorter maturities, in part
est rates declined further, but yields in the intermediate- and reflecting generally cautious investor attitudes, and thus
long-term sectors—which had begun to climb sharply in there was a progressive widening in the rate spread between
April— continued to advance until the last week of the short- and long-term bills.
Free reserves continued to fluctuate in the range of re­
month. At their late May highs, offering yields on new
corporate issues were very close to their 1966 peaks, and cent weekly variations during May, and the distribution of
yields on tax-exempt issues were within about V2 per­ reserves shifted in the second half of the month toward
centage point of last year’s peaks. Yields on long-term banks in the money centers, who apparently were making
Treasury issues reached 4.84 per cent in late May, before preparations for loan demands expected in connection with
falling somewhat over the final week of the month.
mid-June corporate tax payments. Banks had little diffi­
The upward pressure on bond yields during May largely culty in covering most of their residual needs in the Federal
reflected the same factors that pervaded the capital mar­ funds market at rates generally at or below 4 per cent, and
kets in April. In particular, congestion persisted in both borrowings from the Federal Reserve System were light.
the corporate and tax-exempt sectors under the weight of A heavy volume of negotiable certificates of deposit (C /D ’s)
the heavy flow of current and prospective flotations. Only matured during May, and to stem further attrition some
a few of the new issues in May were accorded good investor banks moved up their offering rates, especially on longer
receptions despite progressively higher yields. In addition, maturities. This contrasted with movements in other short­
there was growing apprehension over anticipated large term rates, which generally declined during May.
Treasury financing needs (including sales of participation
certificates) in the months ahead, especially in view of
T H E G O V E R N M E N T S E C U R IT IE S M A R K E T
possibly increased military spending for the Vietnam war.
While the statistics released during the month indicated lit­
Early in May, attention in the market for Treasury
tle change in the level of economic activity, and resulted notes and bonds was centered on the Treasury’s refunding
in some temporary improvement in market sentiment of up to $22.1 billion of notes and bonds maturing in May,
around mid-May, most market participants generally looked June, and August (of which $9.0 billion was held by the
for an early strengthening in the economy. The better mar­ public). Holders of May and June maturities were offered
ket tone that emerged late in the month was most pro­ the right to exchange them for either a AVa per cent fifteennounced in the Treasury sector. The technical position of month note or a 43A per cent five-year note; holders
that market had improved considerably, reflecting the of August maturities were given the opportunity to ex­
cumulative effects of sizable official purchases during the change them for the latter note only.1 Market reaction to
month. There were also expectations— stimulated by dis­ the terms of the refunding, announced on April 26, was
cussion in the press—that the Federal Reserve might con­ somewhat hesitant for a while but gradually became more
tinue to purchase some Treasury coupon issues over positive. By the time the subscription books were closed
succeeding weeks in the course of meeting the midyear on May 3, the public had exchanged 81 Vi per cent of its
reserve needs of the banking system. In addition, investors
began to find the prevailing high yields on corporate and
municipal securities attractive, and underwriters were able
to clear out some of their inventories of unsold new issues.
1 For further details of the offering, see this Review (May 1967),
In the Treasury bill market, rates declined throughout page 90.




FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

holdings of May and June maturities and about 26V2
per cent of its holdings of August maturities, taking a total
of $2.0 billion of the new fifteen-month note and $2.7
billion of the five-year note.
The improved tone of the market extended through May
4, when a reduction in the British bank rate from 6 per cent
to 5V2 per cent was announced. Investor activity subse­
quently contracted, however, and as a weaker overall tone
reemerged, dealers became increasingly restive with their
newly enlarged positions of refunding issues. In this atmo­
sphere, professional offerings expanded and prices of Trea­
sury coupon issues declined throughout the list.
The downward movement in prices of outstanding
coupon issues accelerated somewhat on May 8 and 9,
as professional offerings of intermediate-term issues—
where dealer positions were largest—weighed heavily on
the market and as prices of Government securities were
strongly affected by further deterioration in the corporate
and tax-exempt markets. In addition, there was wide­
spread apprehension that the size of the Treasury cash
financing needs might be larger than previously anticipated
in the last half of this calendar year and in fiscal 1968
generally, particularly in view of newspaper reports of the
possibility of further escalation of the Vietnam conflict.
However, sizable investment orders from official accounts
as well as other buying at the lower price levels on these
two days removed some of the heavy overhanging supply
of securities on dealers’ shelves, and prices of intermediateterm issues subsequently moved back up somewhat, with
some of the gains also carrying over into the longer term
sector. Reports of lower retail sales in March than had pre­
viously been estimated, a large drop in bank loans to
businesses in the statement week ended on May 10, and
the absence of any significant selling prior to the refunding
settlement date helped reinforce this improved atmosphere.
A heavier tone returned to the market again on May
15—the settlement date for the Treasury’s refunding. Sen­
timent was initially dampened by Secretary Fowler’s re­
quest for two revisions affecting the 4V\ per cent interest
rate ceiling on long-term Treasury issues. Specifically, the
requests were to extend from five to ten years the maximum
maturity on Treasury notes, to which the ceiling does not
apply, and for authority to sell up to $2 billion of bonds
annually without regard to the interest ceiling.2 Treasury re­

2 Later in the month, the House Ways and Means Committee
voted approval of an extension of the maximum maturity of Trea­
sury notes to seven years but did not approve the sale of bonds out­
side the interest ceiling.




107

quests for an increase in the debt ceiling and its estimates
of budgetary deficits had largely been anticipated and had
only a limited initial effect on quotations, but over suc­
ceeding days more and more attention was focused on the
prospects of very large Treasury cash needs in the second
half of this calendar year. Of immediate concern, more­
over, was the likelihood of another sizable sale of participa­
tion certificates before the end of the current fiscal year.
Pressure on long-term rates eased somewhat during the
last week of the month, and the heavy atmosphere that had
been in the market earlier gradually lifted. Market partici­
pants took heart from indications of concern within the
Administration over the recent steady rise in interest rates
and from increased discussion of the possibility of a tax
rise later this year. System purchases of coupon issues
around this time contributed to a further improvement in
the technical position of the market, and overall senti­
ment was buoyed by discussion of the likelihood of addi­
tional System buying in the course of meeting reserve
needs over the weeks ahead.
Treasury bills were in strong demand during May. Over
the month as a whole, market rates declined generally by
15 to 30 basis points on outstanding bills maturing within
five months and by 4 to 20 basis points on longer maturi­
ties. Demand as a rule favored the shorter maturities, and
consequently the rate spread between three- and six-month
bills widened to 28 basis points at the end of the month,
the largest differential since November 1966. The broadbased demand for bills reflected in part expectations by
some investors of continued upward pressure on long-term
rates. Additional demand for bills came from commercial
banks and from other financial institutions rebuilding their
liquidity, while corporations were active buyers of the
June tax anticipation bills. In addition, some of the
proceeds of recent corporate and tax-exempt bond flota­
tions apparently have been invested temporarily in Trea­
sury bills. Bidding in the five weekly bill auctions held in
May was aggressive, as dealers sought to rebuild their gen­
erally depleted positions. At the final weekly auction, aver­
age issuing rates on the new three- and six-month issues
were set at 3.477 per cent and 3.733 per cent, respectively,
down about 24 and 4 basis points from the rates established
in the last auction in April. Demand was not so insistent
for the longer maturities, however. In the auction of ninemonth and one-year Treasury bills in late May, average
issuing rates were set at levels about 10 basis points above
the rates set a month earlier, though they remained below
the levels of March. (For information on average issuing
rates of other Treasury bill auctions in May, see Table III.)
Movements in the market for Government agency secur­
ities during May closely paralleled those in the market for

108

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1967
Table I

Table II

FACTORS T E N D IN G TO INCREASE OR DECREASE
M EM BER B A N K RESERVES, M AY 1967

RESERVE POSITIONS OF MAJOR RESERVE CITY BA NK S
M A Y 1967

In millions o f dollars; (-f-) denotes increase,
(—) decrease in excess reserves

In millions o f dollars
Daily averages—week ended on

May

10

May
17

May
24

May
31

4- 159
—
_
—
—
—

291
52
109
7
139

+

16

— 451
— 57
4- 146
— 16
— 485

4- 89
44444-

304
128
102
21
109

— 59
— 292 | 4 - 393

Total “market” factors...

4- 226

4- 40

4 - 133

—
—
4—
—

219
382
230
37
19

_

—

10

— 184
4- 20
— 114

+

1

222

4- 425
—
—
4—
—

841
343
255
38
401

Total..........
Excess reserves*

4- 287

+ 253
+ 43

+ 5
-f

36

4- 163 | — 157
— 8 1 — 42
— 5 !— 3
— 71 ! 4- 60

4- 533 | 4- 255 j
4-153 j

— 300
— 18

105

■369

37 j 4- 24 I

63

May
24

May
31*

32
19
705
1,287
582
— 693
665

Thirty-eight banks outside N ew York City

Direct Federal Reserve

4- 197
— 1

May
17

Reserve excess or
deficiency (—-) t .......................
29
62
13
16
38
Less borrowings from
_
_
Reserve Banks .......................
39
21
36
Less net interbank Federal
funds purchases or sales(—) .
960
681
864
691
329
G ross purchases ................
1,292
1,446 1,326
1,332
1,038
Gross s a le s ...........................
611
486
462
641
709
Equals net basic reserve
surplus or deficit(—) ............ - 692 — 920 — 887 - 676 - 291
N et loans to Government
securities dealers ..................
684
865
607
577
591

4 - 42

credit transactions

Open market instruments
Outright holdings:
Government secu rities----Bankers’ acceptances ----Repurchase agreements:
Government securities . . . .
Bankers’ acceptances ---Federal agency obligations.
Member bank borrowings........
Other loans, discounts, and
advances ......................................

May
10

Eight banks in N ew York City

“ Market” factors

Member bank required
reserves* ..................................
Operating transactions
(subtotal) ..............................
Federal Reserve flo a t........
Treasury operations! ........
Gold and foreign account.
Currency outside banks*..
Other Federal Reserve
accounts (n et)t ................

May
3

Net
changes

Factors
May
3

Average of
five weeks
ended on
May 31*

Factors affecting
basic reserve positions

Changes in daily averages—
week ended on

4- 127

4- 559

+

4-

1

l

4- 69
— 28

4 - 28
— 53
— 3

4- 52

+ 4

4- 222 i

4- 536

4 - 43

4 - 120

Reserve excess or
deficiency ( —) f .......................
4
127
4
10 46
Less borrowings from
2
Reserve Banks .......................
60
22
56
46
Less net interbank Federal
917
funds purchases or sales(—).
1,432
1,035
1,267 1,137
1,768
1,832 2,176
Gross purchases ................
1,991 2,022
852
744
886
797
Gross s a le s ...........................
723
Equals net basic reserve
surplus or deficit(—) ............ -1 ,0 9 2 -1 ,3 0 7 -1 ,3 0 3 -1 ,2 0 5 — 969
N et loans to Government
677
640
577
476
731
securities dealers ..................

20
37
1,158
1,958
800
-1 ,1 7 5
620

N ote: Because of rounding, figures do not necessarily add to totals.
* Estimated reserve figures have not been adjusted for so-called “ as o f” debits
and credits. These items are taken into account in final data,
t Reserves held after all adjustments applicable to the reporting period less re­
quired reserves and carry-over reserve deficiencies.
Table m
A V ER A G E ISSU IN G RATES*
AT R EG U LA R TR EA SU R Y BILL AU C TIO N S

Daily average levels

In per cent
Member bank:
Total reserves, including
vault cash* ..................................
Required reserves* ......................
Excess reserves* ..........................
Borrowings ....................................
Free reserves* ..............................
Nonborrowed reserves*
..............

23,627
23,228
399
134
4- 265
23,493

23,431
23,069
362
63
+ 299
23,368

23,366
22,980
386
123
4- 263
23,243

23,077
22.754
323
50
4- 273
23,027

23,080
22,714
366
102
4- 264
22,978

Weekly auction dates— May 1967

23,316§
22,949§
367§
94§
4- 273§
23.222§

May
1
Three-month.....................................

May
8

May
15

May
22

May
29

3.770

3.671

3.628

3.493

3.477

3.907

3.831

3.802

3.692

3.733

Changes in Wednesday levels
Monthly auction dates— March-May 1967
System Account holdings
of Government securities
maturing in:
4 - 763
Less than on© year ....................
More
....................
than one y e a r

— 352

—3,161 — 83
4-2,878 4 - 102

4-427
4- 109

— 2,406
4- 3,089

4 - 763

— 352

— 283

4-536

4-

Total........................................

+

M

N ote: Because of rounding, figures do not necessarily add to totals.
* These figures are estimated,

t Includes changes in Treasury currency and cash.
t Includes assets denominated in foreign currencies.
§ Average for five weeks ended on May 31.




March
28

April
25

Nine-month..

4.078

3.842

3.944

One-year.......

4.074

3.832

3.933

May
24

683

* Interest rates on bills are quoted in terms of a 360-day year, with the dis­
counts from par as the return on the face amount o f the bills payable at
maturity. Bond yield equivalents, related to the amount actually invested,
would be slightly higher.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

direct Treasury coupon securities. Prices generally moved
lower over the month, with the largest changes in the
longer maturity area, which was especially affected by
concern over expected further sales of participation cer­
tificates in the next several weeks. These expectations
were confirmed on May 31, when the Federal National
Mortgage Association announced that it would sell $900
million of participation certificates on June 15, $250 mil­
lion of which would be sold directly to Government trust
accounts. Only two issues due beyond a year were offered
during the month. One was a $341 million offering of
twenty-month Federal Land Bank bonds priced to yield
4% per cent. This offering, which was made on May 10,
raised $161 million of new money; it was well received.
On May 16, the Tennessee Valley Authority sold $70 mil­

109

lion of twenty-five year bonds on a competitive basis to
an underwriting syndicate. The issue afforded five-year
call protection and was reoffered to investors at a 5.70 per
cent yield. The offering was well received. A total of
approximately $1.1 billion of shorter term agency issues
was marketed during the period and most were generally
accorded good initial receptions by investors.
O T H ER S E C U R IT IE S M A R K E T S

Prices continued to decline in other sectors of the capi­
tal market during May, as the volume of current and
prospective new corporate and tax-exempt offerings re­
mained at near-record levels. An improved tone in the
market for corporate securities developed temporarily early

SELECTED INTEREST R A T E S *
M arch -M ay 1967

M O N E Y M A RK ET RATES

Per cent

M arch

A p ril

M ay

BO N D M ARKET YIELDS

M arch

A p ril

M ay

Note: Data are shown for business days only.
* MONEY MARKET RATES QUOTED: Daily range of rates posted by major New York City banks

point from underwriting syndicate reoffering yield on a given issue to market yield on the

on new call loans (in Federal funds) secured by United States Government securities (a point

same issue immediately after it has been released from syndicate restrictions); daily

indicates the absence of any range); offering rates for directly placed finance company paper;

averages of yields on long-term Government securities (bonds due or callable in ten years

the effective rate on Federal funds (the rate most representative of the transactions executed);

or more) and of Government securities due in three to five years, computed on the basis of

closing bid rates (quoted in terms of rate of discount) on newest outstanding three- and six-month

closing bid prices; Thursday averages of yields on twenty seasoned twenty-year tax-exempt

Treasury bills.
BONDMARKET YIELDS QUOTED: Yields on new Aaa- and Aa-rated public utility bonds are plotted
around a line showing daily average yields on seasoned Aaa-rated corporate bonds (arrows




bonds (carrying Moody’s ratings of A aa, Aa, A, and Baa).
Sources: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
Moody's Investors Service, and The Weekly Bond Buyer.

110

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1967

in the month, when investor interest expanded at the higher
yield levels that were reached following a spate of syndi­
cate terminations. News of the reduction in the British
bank rate also encouraged market participants briefly.
With indications of heavy future demands for capital funds
continuing to mount, however, the pessimistic climate re­
appeared and persisted through the remainder of the
month despite announcements around mid-May of post­
ponements of a total of $328 million of corporate securi­
ties. The respite was generally expected to be short-lived,
and indeed $100 million of the postponed bonds was
offered the following week. The $935 million of new cor­
porate bonds that came to market during the month was
typically offered at progressively higher yields but, even
so, only a few issues were completely sold at the original
reoffering yields. Near the end of the month, two A-rated
industrial issues were offered at about 5.70 per cent with
ten years of call protection, near the highest yield on any
comparable issue marketed last year. Significant additions
to the forward calendar of corporate debt offerings were
made during the month, including one issue of $250 mil­
lion of telephone company debentures scheduled for August
1. Corporate bonds on the calendar for June totaled $1.4
billion, and heavy offerings loom in later months as well.
The market for tax-exempt bonds was also generally
weak throughout May, and dealers were able to move
bonds only at rather substantial price reductions; after
several syndicate terminations, price adjustments resulted
in yields 20 to 45 basis points higher than original re­
offering yields. These price cuts enabled dealers to re­
duce the volume of tax-exempt offerings advertised in the
Blue List to $576 at the end of May, compared with
the recent peak of $847 million reached on April 26. The
largest tax-exempt offering of the month was the $100
million issue of State of California bonds (Aa-rated) at
reoffering yields of 25 to 45 basis points above those on
comparable maturities in the state’s previous issue mar­
keted March 21. The bonds met a fairly good reception.
Several tax-exempt bond issues scheduled for offering dur­
ing May were canceled or postponed because of market
conditions. The largest such postponement, announced on
May 23, was that of a $96.3 million issue of New York
City bonds.
The average yield on Moody’s Aaa-rated seasoned cor­
porate bonds rose substantially during May, closing the
month at 5.35 per cent. The Weekly Bond Buyer's series for
twenty seasoned tax-exempt issues, carrying ratings rang­




ing from Aaa to Baa, rose by 27 basis points to 3.96 per
cent (see the right hand panel of the chart). These in­
dexes, however, are based on only a limited number of
seasoned issues and do not necessarily reflect market
movements fully, particularly in the case of new and re­
cent issues.
B A N K R E S E R V E S A N D TH E M O N E Y M A R K E T

Conditions in the money market were generally comfort­
able during May. The Federal Reserve System supplied a
large volume of reserves through open market operations,
and a decline in member banks’ required reserves tended
to increase excess reserves as bank credit showed only
moderate growth. Free reserves averaged $273 million dur­
ing the five weeks ended on May 31, in the upper part of
the range of variation in April. Federal funds, trading in a
narrow range around 4 per cent, accommodated most
short-term needs of banks in reserve deficit, and borrow­
ings from the System averaged a relatively light $94 million
over the period. (See Table I .)
The major money market banks remained in a basic
reserve deficit during May, but moved into a considerably
more comfortable reserve position toward the end of the
month, as they apparently began to prepare for loan de­
mands expected around the June tax date. In the final
week of the month, the forty-six major money market
banks had a basic reserve deficit aggregating only $1.3 bil­
lion, the smallest deficit since November 30, 1966. Several
of the major money market banks moved to stem attrition
in their outstanding C /D ’s during the month by bidding
somewhat more aggressively for large deposits. Some banks
in New York City raised posted rates by V4 to Vt. percent­
age point during May, and some were reportedly paying as
much as 5 per cent on a negotiated basis for six- or sevenmonth maturities. In contrast, the highest rate available in
New York City at the end of April was reportedly W 2
per cent. New York City banks recorded a $224 million
rise in their outstanding C /D ’s in the five weeks ended on
May 31, following a drop of $257 million in April.
Most other short-term rates declined during May. In
addition to the easing in rates on the three- and six-month
maturities of Treasury bills noted above, rates on prime
commercial paper declined by Vs per cent in May, while
yields on call loans to Government securities dealers and
bankers’ acceptances showed no overall change despite
a large volume of acceptances being offered on the market.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

111

R e ce n t E co n o m ic P o lic y M e a su re s in Industrial C o u n trie s A b roa d
Since the beginning of 1967, there has been a progres­
sive relaxation of policies of monetary restraint in a num­
ber of industrial countries abroad. During 1966, monetary
policy had been tightened in many countries to contain
acute inflationary pressures or to resist a deterioration in
the balance of payments.1 In the absence of sufficiently
restrictive fiscal action, interest rates had soared to their
highest levels in the postwar period. Later in the year,
however, conditions in the financial markets eased slightly,
as demand pressures subsided in several previously over­
heated economies. By early 1967, policy formulation in
virtually all countries took place in a context of better
balance between demands and resource availabilities. At
the same time, considerable progress had been made in
some countries toward the correction of payments imbal­
ances. In view of the slower growth in some countries,
credit conditions were allowed to ease slightly toward the
end of 1966. Since the start of the year, there has been a
further and more rapid reversal of last year’s upward spiral
of interest rates— a reversal marked by repeated reduc­
tions in central bank discount rates. In Germany, the dis­
count rate was lowered early in January in the first of a
series of overt moves toward monetary ease. This change
was quickly followed by reductions in discount rates in
Canada, Belgium, and Sweden. In subsequent months, dis­
count rates were cut further in these countries and credit
conditions eased in other industrial countries as well. Fol­
lowing the relaxation of monetary restraint abroad and
with the recovery of confidence in sterling, the Bank of
England has lowered the bank rate in several steps.

1 For a detailed discussion of developments in 1966, see “Recent
Economic Policy Measures in Industrial Countries Abroad”, this
Review (June 1966), pages 144-49, and (December 1966), pages
268-73.




U N IT E D K IN G D O M

Since the adoption of a sweeping stabilization program
in July 1966, inflationary pressures in the United King­
dom have eased considerably and during the fourth quar­
ter there was a dramatic improvement in the balance of
payments. The introduction in July of more stringent re­
strictions on instalment purchases, in combination with the
effects of an earlier policy of credit restraint, led almost
immediately to a reduction in sales of consumer durables.
At the same time there was a pronounced change in busi­
ness expectations, which led to some downward revision
of investment plans. New housing starts also dropped as
a consequence of an emerging squeeze on consumers’ dis­
posable income and the jolt to business confidence. More­
over, the rate of inventory accumulation, which had been
fairly rapid earlier in the year, fell sharply in the fourth
quarter—partly because of the decline in final sales and
partly because imports were postponed in anticipation of
the removal at the end of November of the remaining part
(10 per cent) of the import surcharge that had been in­
troduced in October 1964. Despite a recovery in exports,
industrial production turned down in the autumn months
(see Chart I ) . As employers reappraised their labor re­
quirements, employment began to fall and the seasonally
adjusted unemployment rate rose from 1.2 per cent in
June to almost 2 per cent by the year-end. In conjunc­
tion with the decline in overall demand, the standstill on
wages and prices, adopted as part of the July program,
proved very effective. Hourly wage rates, which rose at an
annual rate of almost 7 per cent during the first half of
1966, remained virtually unchanged during the second
half. Although retail prices rose by IV2 per cent from
July to December, this change largely reflected an increase
in indirect taxes imposed in July rather than an erosion
of the price freeze.
In the closing months of the year, the authorities took a

112

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1967

number of steps to bolster business confidence and cushion signs that the domestic economy had begun to stabilize
the readjustment. In November, the Bank of England after the sharp adjustment in the autumn. Consumer ex­
pointed out that outstanding credit extended by the clear­ penditures began to pick up in the early months of 1967,
ing banks was below the ceiling on loans to the private industrial production appeared to have bottomed out, the
sector, which had been renewed as part of the July stabiliza­ seasonally adjusted unemployment rate was only slightly
tion program, and made it clear that banks had the re­ higher than at the year-end, and the fall in demand for
sources to meet all justified demands from priority bor­ bank credit was beginning to moderate.
rowers. Then, on December 1, the government increased
Externally, the austerity program began to exert a cor­
the amount of direct grants for certain investment projects rective effect on the balance of payments in the closing
—from 40 per cent to 45 per cent of expenditures in the months of 1966. After allowance for seasonal factors,
so-called development areas and from 20 per cent to 25 exports were significantly higher in the fourth quarter
per cent elsewhere. By the turn of the year, there were while imports fell sharply, partly in anticipation of the
removal of the import surcharge at the end of November.
Despite a rebound in import deliveries in December, the
average level of imports in the fourth quarter was 7 per
cent lower than in the first nine months of the year,
clearly suggesting that the July measures had begun to
take hold. With the turnabout in the trade balance, the
current account moved into substantial surplus and, after
allowing for the repayments on the United States and Cana­
dian government loans, resumed in full in the fourth quarter,
there was an underlying improvement in the long-term capi­
tal account as well. Thus, after having run a very large
balance-of-payments deficit during the first three quarters
of 1966, the United Kingdom developed a $380 million
current-account surplus (seasonally adjusted) in the last
quarter alone, and the balance of payments moved into sub­
stantial surplus. The trade balance moved back into slight
deficit during the first quarter of 1967, but the overall bal­
ance on current and long-term capital account appears to
have remained in surplus thus far this year. Moreover, with
the further recovery of confidence in sterling and the re­
versal of “leads and lags”, foreigners continued to rebuild
their sterling balances. During the first four months of the
year, the Bank of England was able to increase its reserves
by substantial amounts, even after repaying all its drawings
under the Federal Reserve swap facility and fully liquidating
the short-term credits provided by other central banks last
summer. In addition, the Bank of England in January paid
off in their entirety the special credits obtained earlier from
the Federal Reserve and the United States Treasury.2 This
pattern of gradual improvement was interrupted in April,
when the trade balance worsened, with imports rising much
faster than exports. However, in May the United Kingdom
was able to repay, six months ahead of schedule, $405 mil­
lion owed to the International Monetary Fund under a 1964




2 See Charles A. Coombs, “Treasury and Federal Reserve For­
eign Exchange Operations”, this Review (March 1967), pages
43-51.

113

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

C hart II

CENTRAL BAN K DISCOUNT RATES AND SHORT-TERM INTEREST RATES
IN SELECTED COUNTRIES
Pe rce n t

Pe rce n t

drawing and an $80 million loan obtained from Switzerland
in 1964. With the repayment, the United Kingdom’s re­
maining indebtedness to the IMF due this year was reduced
to $393 million. Sterling drawings by other IMF members
are expected to reduce this indebtedness further.
Against this background of considerable progress to­
ward restoration of external and internal balance, the
Bank of England on January 26 lowered the bank rate
from its crisis level of 7 per cent to 6 Vi per cent (see Chart
II). This was followed by another Vi percentage point cut
in mid-March after a slight easing in money market
rates. However, clearing bank loans (seasonally adjusted)
declined in January but leveled out in February. As a result,
the margin between outstanding advances and the ceiling
on bank loans continued to widen. In April the ceiling was
removed from the clearing banks and the Scottish banks,
but at the same time it was announced that special deposits
by these banks would be used more flexibly to control the




P ercent

P e rc e n t

volume of bank credit, and the qualitative guidance cover­
ing the direction of bank lending was reaffirmed. So far
as all other banks were concerned, the ceiling was to remain
in force until suitable alternative methods of credit control
could be arranged. Moreover, the few tax changes an­
nounced in the budget in April were designed to be essen­
tially neutral in their impact on the economy, reflecting the
government’s view that it “should not take any substantial
action to influence demand just now”. The budget was well
received abroad and, following further reductions in interest
rates at home and abroad, the bank rate was cut to 5Vi
per cent in early May.
R E L A X A T IO N O F M O N E T A R Y R E S T R A IN T
IN O T H ER IN D U S T R IA L C O U N T R IE S

The slowdown in economic activity in Germany, which
first became apparent in the spring of 1966, developed

114

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1967

at an unexpectedly rapid rate in the second half of the
year. Fixed private investment weakened steadily, while
spending by state and local authorities was particularly
hard hit by the stringency in the money and capital markets. The slack in domestic demand was reflected in a
marked slowdown of imports and a sharp rise in exports.
The resultant improvement on trade account was the ma­
jor force behind the reemergence of a payments surplus
in the latter half of 1966. These trends continued into the
new year. By March, the level of industrial production,
seasonally adjusted, had fallen 7 per cent below its earlier
peak and the unemployment rate had reached an unusually
high 2.2 per cent. However, in April there were some
signs that the economy was beginning to respond to a
number of expansionary policy measures.
Conditions in the financial markets had already begun
to ease slightly toward the end of 1966, as the emerging
balance-of-payments surplus resulted in a large inflow of
liquid funds. Then, early in January, the German Federal
Bank lowered its discount rate from 5 per cent to AV2 per
cent in the first of a succession of overt steps designed to
lower interest rates and to expand bank liquidity. On
February 1, reserve requirements against nonresident de­
posits were reduced to the levels applied to the banks’
domestic liabilities. This move was followed by another V2
percentage point cut in the discount rate in mid-February
and by an across-the-board 10 per cent reduction in re­
serve requirements, effective on March 1. However, the
pull of relatively high money rates abroad, particularly in
the Euro-currency markets, resulted in a substantial out­
flow of liquid funds, which tended to brake the decline in
domestic interest rates during the first two months of the
year. The authorities cut the discount rate to 3 Vi per cent
on April 14 and, after a further reduction in reserve re­
quirements, the discount rate was reduced by another Vi
percentage point on May 11. With interest rates abroad
also declining, these moves were more fully reflected in
lower domestic interest rates.
The shift toward monetary ease in Germany has been
accompanied by a more flexible use of fiscal policy. Thus,
in an effort to stimulate investment, the authorities have
introduced liberalized depreciation allowances for ex­
penditures on fixed assets incurred before the end of
October 1967. The regular budget is expected to be
in deficit, as the slowdown in activity is likely to lead
to a shortfall of revenues below the budget estimates.
In addition to the regular budget, the new coalition govern­
ment also adopted in January a strongly expansionary
“contingency budget”, which provides for a substantial in­
crease in public investment. In order to alleviate any
strains in the financial markets resulting from the govern­




ment’s increased borrowing requirements, the German
Federal Bank has indicated its readiness to help finance
the Federal deficit.
The Canadian economic situation and the policies
adopted to meet it have also altered in recent months.
The pace of the business expansion lost some of its up­
ward momentum during the latter part of 1966, reflecting
in part the effects of monetary and fiscal actions taken
earlier in the year to moderate demand pressures.3 Despite
the slower growth in final demand, the average increase in
wages continued to be far in excess of productivity gains,
and upward pressures on prices were still very strong. Fiscal
policy remained oriented toward the need to contain infla­
tionary pressures through September, when the government
reduced certain planned expenditures. Moreover, the gov­
ernment announced that additional taxes would soon be
proposed in a supplementary autumn budget to cover higher
social security payments which were scheduled to begin in
January. However, the posture of policy shifted in subse­
quent months, as evidence accumulated that the investment
boom was running out of steam and that industrial pro­
duction had leveled off. Credit conditions were allowed to
ease considerably late in the year. Commercial bank liquid­
ity continued to increase after the turn of the year, and
bond yields declined substantially over a wide range of
maturities. On January 30, the Bank of Canada lowered
its discount rate from SVa per cent to 5 per cent. The dis­
count rate was again reduced on April 7, to AV2 per cent,
partly reflecting the change in credit conditions that had
already occurred and partly in response to a concurrent Vi
percentage point cut in the Federal Reserve discount rate.
This shift in monetary policy has been supported by
the removal of earlier fiscal restraints on business invest­
ment. To be sure, the supplementary budget, which had
been postponed until mid-December, called for a modest
increase in sales taxes, but this increase was calculated
to do no more than offset higher social security benefits.
Early in March, it was announced that the refundable tax
on corporate profits, which had been introduced in May
1966, would be terminated on April 1, 1967— a full seven
months before it was originally scheduled to expire. At the
same time, depreciation allowances, which had been cut
last year in an effort to restrain an exceptionally large
increase in planned business investment, were restored to
their earlier levels. The budget for fiscal 1968, presented
to Parliament on June 2, was designed to provide a mod­

3 For a discussion of these measures, see “Monetary and Fiscal
Policy in Canada”, this Review (August 1966), pages 182-87.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

erate offset to the continuing softness of private demand.
With expenditures expected to rise more rapidly than rev­
enues, the budgetary deficit is estimated at Can.$740 mil­
lion, compared with the actual outturn of Can.$428 mil­
lion for the fiscal year ended on March 31. In view of the
large increase in expenditures and continuing upward
pressures on costs and prices, the government was not pre­
pared to reduce taxes on personal or corporate income.
However, it announced that the 6 per cent sales tax on
machinery and equipment, which was originally scheduled
to expire next April, would be removed immediately to
encourage a recovery of private investment.
In the Netherlands, demand pressures abated in the lat­
ter part of 1966, as a restrictive monetary policy and cer­
tain anti-inflationary fiscal measures began to take effect.
Although fixed private investment continued to rise, there
was some slowdown in public investment, particularly by
local authorities, and the growth in exports subsided as
the year-end approached. The rate of increase in prices
leveled off around the turn of the year, and at the same
time there was an unexpectedly rapid rise in unemploy­
ment. Accordingly, the government announced in January
that cash grants would be made available to attract more
industry to those areas of the country where structural
unemployment is a particularly serious problem. With
manufacturers’ order backlogs dwindling, the Netherlands
Bank reduced its discount rate from 5 per cent to AVi per
cent on March 15, and also took steps which, in effect,
raised the quantitative limit on credit expansion imposed
on Dutch commercial banks. In a fiscal move designed to
alleviate the strains in Dutch capital markets and achieve
a better balance between monetary and fiscal measures, a
planned increase in turnover taxes originally scheduled to
take effect next year was advanced by six months to July
1, 1967, while a planned reduction in income taxes origi­
nally scheduled for January 1, 1967 was postponed until
midyear.
The pace of the Swedish expansion slowed down in the
latter part of 1966 in response to generally weaker de­
mand conditions both domestically and abroad. The growth
of investment moderated, labor shortages became less
marked, and Sweden’s external position improved as im­
ports stabilized. When signs of a slowdown in economic
activity became apparent in the summer months, the Bank
of Sweden engaged in sizable open market purchases and
bank liquidity eased considerably in the second half of the
year. This shift in monetary policy has continued thus far
this year. The Bank of Sweden cut the discount rate from
6 per cent to 5Vi per cent on February 3 and then to 5
per cent on March 10, in line with declining domestic and
foreign interest rates. Despite the slowdown in industrial




115

activity, upward pressures on costs and prices continued to
increase through the early months of 1967, partly as a re­
sult of a large retroactive increase in wages that was paid
at the end of 1966. In order to moderate consumption and
restrain continuing cost increases, the budget, presented to
Parliament last January, called for a substantial increase
in sales and excise taxes, some of which have already gone
into effect.
In Belgium, monetary policy remained generally restric­
tive through the end of 1966 in an effort to contain con­
tinuing inflationary pressures. Conditions in the financial
markets tightened from the spring through the end of
1966, as domestic credit demands accelerated and the
emergence of a balance-of-payments deficit strained the
liquidity of the banking system. Industrial production,
after having remained generally stable through most of
1966, picked up around the turn of the year. In sub­
sequent months, however, the pace of economic activity
slackened again and, as earlier tightness in the labor mar­
ket abated, there was some relaxation of monetary policy.
The National Bank of Belgium reduced its discount rate
from 5X
A per cent to 5 per cent on February 2. As market
rates of interest, both domestic and foreign, continued to
move downward, the discount rate was lowered on March
23 and again on May 11—by Va percentage point each
time. In a complementary fiscal move, the government ob­
tained special powers from Parliament early in April to
enable it to institute by decree a number of measures de­
signed to stimulate investment and to speed up regional de­
velopment programs. Under these powers, certain indirect
taxes were quickly raised, but the higher revenues are to
be used primarily to increase public investment. Decrees
were also issued to provide tax relief for new investment,
particularly in newly defined development areas.
IT A L Y , J A P A N , F R A N C E , A N D S W IT Z E R L A N D

Italian economic policy remained expansionary through­
out 1966. The recovery in economic activity, which had
been hesitant and unevenly distributed throughout most of
1965, accelerated and became more broadly based during
1966. A rise in exports was reinforced by resurgence of
domestic consumption, and in the latter part of the year
there was a recovery of fixed private investment. For 1966
as a whole, industrial production was almost 12 per cent
higher than in 1965 while the overall advance in real gross
national product (GNP) was 5.5 per cent. Fragmentary
information for the early months of 1967 suggests that the
advance has remained brisk in most industrial sectors and
that upward pressures on wage rates and prices are still
fairly moderate despite a continued decline in the un­

116

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1967

employment rate. Within this context of noninflationary
growth, monetary policy has remained relatively easy. De­
spite a substantial increase in credit demands, particularly
by the public sector, and a sharp rise in interest rates abroad,
Italian interest rates held steady in 1966, as the Bank of
Italy expanded its advances and rediscounts to the banking
system. The banks continued to make large short-term
investments abroad, particularly in Euro-dollars, and there­
by helped to ease the strain in that market resulting from
the strong demand from United States banks and German
borrowers. In the closing months of 1966, the growth in
exports tapered off and there was a substantial increase in
long-term capital outflows, reflecting higher interest rates
abroad. Nevertheless, the overall balance of payments re­
mained in substantial surplus. Since the start of the year,
however, there has been some reversal of earlier outflows
of bank funds, as the rise in domestic loan demands has out­
stripped the increase in deposits.
The Japanese recovery from the 1965 recession gathered
momentum in 1966, as a strong surge in fixed private in­
vestment was reinforced by a sharp increase in exports.
For the year as a whole, GNP advanced by about 9 per
cent in real terms and the level of industrial production
increased by 14 per cent. There was a substantial outflow
of long-term capital last year, but the normal cyclical
deterioration on trade account was partially offset by in­
creased United States military expenditures in connection
with the Vietnam conflict, and the balance of payments
moved into surplus. Thus far this year, new and unfilled
orders for machinery have continued to rise, import demand
has accelerated, and there have been some signs of emerging
labor shortages. Since the turn of the year the trade bal­
ance, seasonally adjusted, has moved into substantial def­
icit, but the deterioration of trade account has been partly
offset by renewed inflows of short-term funds, as Japanese
importers and other borrowers have taken advantage of
rapidly declining interest rates abroad to meet part of their
financing requirements. Despite the strong demand for
bank credit, the average interest rate on bank loans con­
tinued its downward trend through February. Credit condi­
tions tightened somewhat early in March, but then eased
again, when the Bank of Japan increased its limit on loans
to large city banks and supplied increased funds to the
private sector through purchases of securities. However,
in view of the unexpectedly rapid recovery in investment
and the resultant deterioration in the trade balance, the
government, in a special session of the Diet in mid-March,
warned businessmen to exercise caution in new plant and
equipment expenditures. Moreover, the budget estimates
for the fiscal year that began on April 1 provide for a
smaller overall deficit, and the government explained that




this was designed to prevent overheating.
In France, real GNP rose by almost 5 per cent for 1966
as a whole but the pace of the expansion slowed down in
the latter half of the year. Fixed private investment,
stimulated in part by a 10 per cent tax credit granted in
May 1966, continued to rise but consumer demand was
somewhat sluggish as the year-end approached and the
growth in exports leveled off. Consumer prices advanced
by less than 3 per cent during the year, and the labor mar­
ket has remained free of the strains that were present
before the 1963 stabilization program. However, the over­
all balance of payments moved into deficit in the fourth
quarter of 1966, when the slowdown in Germany and
some other countries resulted in a substantial deteriora­
tion in the trade balance. Against this background of some­
what slower growth, French economic policy has remained
cautiously expansionary. Interest rates moved upward dur­
ing the fourth quarter of 1966 in response to higher interest
rates in other financial centers, but this trend has been
partially reversed this year. Fiscal operations provided a
mild stimulus for the economy last year, and the 1967
budget, which was presented to Parliament last December,
is also expected to be moderately expansionary.
While there has been little change in the general stance
of monetary and fiscal policy, the authorities implemented
a number of broad-gauged structural reforms. In January,
they began to replace the existing required liquidity ratio
with a new system of cash reserve requirements for the
banking system. The former compulsory assets ratio, under
which a portfolio of Treasury bills, medium-term commer­
cial paper, and certain other assets had to be held as a
proportion of sight and time deposits, was in principle
abolished, but as an interim measure minimum holdings
of medium-term paper by banks were prescribed in order
to facilitate the transition to the new reserve system. The
controls on financial relations with other countries were
also relaxed toward the end of January. As a rule, all
exchange transactions and payments are now freely per­
mitted except those which specifically remain subject to
control, such as direct investments. Furthermore, non­
residents are now allowed to issue securities in the French
capital market on the same terms as domestic borrowers,
subject to prior authorization. Such clearance also is re­
quired for borrowing abroad by French residents. How­
ever, French banks are exempt from this control and can
freely lend and borrow abroad.
In Switzerland, there has been little change in the pos­
ture of monetary policy, which is still oriented toward
the need to contain inflationary pressures. During the fourth
quarter of 1966, interest rates moved upward in response
to relatively high interest rates in neighboring countries.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

As conditions in the domestic money market tightened, the
commercial banks raised the rate for savings deposits by
Vat per cent to 3% per cent early in January. Moreover,
interest rates on long-term maturities also moved up fur­
ther, despite strict controls on new bond issues. The 1964
emergency legislation, which provided for the introduction
of quantitative ceilings on bank credit, expired in March.
In view of the persistence of inflationary pressures, how­
ever, the Swiss National Bank asked the commercial banks
to limit the overall growth of their short- and long-term
advances during 1967 to 7 per cent of the amount outstand­
ing at the end of 1966— an increase slightly less than the
actual expansion last year.
C O N C L U D IN G R E M A R K S

The acute tensions that developed in financial markets
last year dramatized the need for more flexible use of
other policy instruments. The need for monetary restraint
would have been less compelling and the rise in interest
rates might have been less pronounced, if fiscal measures




117

had been used more vigorously to cope with inflationary
strains. But in most of the countries discussed here, fiscal
action was delayed or insufficiently restrictive and the
burden of restraint was largely carried by monetary policy.
At this particular juncture, the need for credit restraint
has become less acute in most European countries, and
indeed several countries have already moved in the di­
rection of monetary ease. This shift has been most
pronounced in Germany, where domestic economic con­
ditions called for active stimulus. However, in view of the
high sensitivity of capital movements to international inter­
est rate differentials, the shift toward monetary ease in
Germany was partly diluted by short-term capital out­
flows. Movements of short-term funds have often placed
limits on the ability of monetary policy to adapt to chang­
ing domestic requirements, but the continued develop­
ment of the Euro-currency markets, which have become
the focal points for international capital movements, has
narrowed these limits. Thus, the need for flexibility in
fiscal policy may be equally urgent, when domestic eco­
nomic conditions call for stimulus.

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1967

P u b lica tio n s of the Fe d e ra l R e se rv e B a n k of New Y o rk

The following is a selected list of publications available from the Public Information Department,
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 33 Liberty Street, New York, N. Y. 10045. Copies of charge pub­
lications are available at half price to educational institutions, unless otherwise noted.
1. t h e s t o r y o f c h e c k s (1966). A 20-page booklet which describes the origin and development
of checks, the growth and automation of check-clearing operations, and the checkless society envisioned for
the future. No charge in limited quantities.
2. c e n t r a l b a n k c o o p e r a t i o n : 1924-31 (1967) by Stephen V. O. Clarke. A 234-page book
which deals with efforts by American, British, French, and German central bankers to reestablish and main­
tain financial stability in 1924-31 and the frustration of those efforts during the financial crisis at the end
of that period. $2.00 per copy.
3. m o n e y : m a s t e r o r s e r v a n t ? (1966) by Thomas O. Waage. Revised edition. A 48-page
booklet explaining the role of money and banking in our economy. Includes a description of our mone­
tary system, tells how money is created, and relates how the Federal Reserve System influences the cost
and availability of credit. No charge in limited quantities.
4. m o n e y , b a n k i n g * a n d c r e o i t i n e a s t e r n e u r o p e (1966) by George Garvy. A 167-page
booklet which examines the role of banking and credit policy in seven communist countries and focuses
on developments arising from the recent changes in economic policy. $1.25 per copy (65 cents per copy to
educational institutions).
5. k e e p i n g o c r m o n e y h e a l t h y (1966). Revised edition. A 16-page illustrated primer on how
the Federal Reserve System works to promote price stability, full employment, and economic growth.
6. t h e n e w t o r k f o r e i g n e x c h a n g e m a r k e t (1965) by Alan R. Holmes and Francis H.
Schott. A 64-page booklet about the New York market for foreign exchange, and the large exchange opera­
tions in that market. 50 cents per copy.
7. e s s a y s i n m o n e y a n d c r e d i t (1964). A 76-page booklet containing eleven essays on tech­
nical problems of monetary policy, Treasury debt and cash operations, and the Federal Reserve’s daily
work. It also contains several analyses of money and securities market instruments and of banking prob­
lems and policies. 40 cents per copy.
8. o p e n m a r k e t o p e r a t i o n s (1963) by Paul Meek. A 43-page booklet describing for the inter­
ested layman how open market operations in United States Government securities are used to cope with
monetary stresses and promote a healthy economy. No charge in limited quantities.
Subscriptions to the m o n t h l y r e v i e w are available to the public without charge. Additional
copies of any issue may be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank
of New York, 33 Liberty Street, New York, N. Y. 10045.