View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MONTHLY REVIEW
J U N E 1959
Contents
The Business Situation

......................... ..78

Money Market in M a y ........................ 80
International Financial Developments . . . . 84
Creeping Inflation .............................. ..86
Special Supplement:
The Future of the Dollar by Dr. Wilhelm Vocfee

Volume 41




No. 6

78

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1959

T h e B u s i n e s s S it u a t io n
The vigorous advance in business activity is continuing
on a broad front across the country. The industrial pro­
duction index rose by two more points in April to reach
a record level 18 per cent above the recession low of
April 1958, and output and sales apparently expanded
further during May. Personal income rose sharply in
April to yet another record and, while official figures will
not be available for some months, business profits prob­
ably are also running at an all-time high.
As during the first quarter of the year, some of the
recent gains probably reflect production increases for the
purpose of building up inventories, most notably of steel
and automobiles. The major part of the advance, however,
appears to rest on substantial further increases in the cur­
rent demand for consumer and capital goods. A morethan-seasonal expansion in sales of new cars and other
consumer durables pushed total retail sales higher in April,
and automobile and department store sales apparently
scored further gains in May. Housing starts have been
maintained near peak rates. And with sales and profits
booming, business firms have been adding to their invest­
ment programs and have stepped up their orders for capi­
tal equipment.
Perhaps most encouraging is the substantial improve­
ment in the employment situation over the last two months.
From mid-February to mid-April, the seasonally adjusted
rate of unemployment fell from 6.1 to 5.3 per cent, and
some further drop is suggested by the decline of unemploy­
ment insurance claims in subsequent weeks. Much of the
reduction, moreover, has occurred among men in the
“head-of-family” age brackets, and long-term unemploy­
ment also has declined (although it still remains consider­
ably larger than at any time in the postwar period prior to
1958). With the length of the workweek restored to pre­
recession levels, the further expansion of factory output
was achieved mainly by adding workers rather than by
lengthening hours. More jobs have also become available
in construction and other outdoor work now that the
winter is over. In recent months, moreover, hiring has
been stepped up by the trade, finance, and service indus­
tries and for “nonproduction” workers in manufacturing.
Most of the expansion in private employment over the
last few decades has occurred in these occupations, and
they are the ones in which employment gains during the
upswing have lagged most notably compared with pre­
vious business recoveries.




With increased demand for labor, there has also been
a more rapid rise in wage rates (partly reflecting an in­
crease in overtime). In the six months following the trough
in general business activity in April 1958, average hourly
earnings of factory workers increased by less than IV2 per
cent. Over the succeeding six months through April 1959,
however, these earnings have advanced by more than 4
per cent. Coinciding with the more rapid rise in average
pay rates, wage costs per unit of factory output also
appear to have turned upward (after tending to decline for
more than a year), contributing to the upward pressures
on prices. In April, industrial wholesale prices were more
than 2 per cent above the year-earlier level (and also the
pre-recession level), while retail prices for nonfood items
were higher by over IV2 per cent (and by 3Vi per cent as
compared with the pre-recession level).
During the past year, the rise in prices of nonfood items
has been offset by the decline of food prices following two
and a half years of uptrend. Now food prices are on
the threshold of a seasonal rise, which is likely to result
in some increase in the over-all price indexes. Of much
more far-reaching significance for the prospects of price
stability, however, will be the impact of the settlement
ultimately reached in the steel industry, which may deter­
mine whether the upward tendency in industrial prices will
remain of limited scope or whether it will broaden out
into an economy-wide advance.
DEVELOPM ENTS

IN

FO R E IG N

TRADE

A major exception to the broad upswing in business has
been the absence of any recovery in exports. Exports of
merchandise (exclusive of military-aid shipments), which
at the first-quarter 1957 peak had been running at a sea­
sonally adjusted annual rate of over $20 billion, fell
sharply to $16 billion by the first quarter of 1958, and to
only about $15 billion in the first four months of 1959
(see Chart I). Over the same two-year period, the exports
of the rest of the world also have declined but not nearly
so sharply.
It is worth emphasizing, however, that roughly three
fourths of the drop in the value of United States exports
between the first quarters of 1957 and 1959 has been con­
centrated in only five commodity groups: cotton, wheat,
coal, iron and steel, and petroleum (see Chart II). Even
in early 1957, when exports of these five products were
at or close to their peaks for recent years, they accounted

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

79

than the five noted above— particularly of machinery—
also have declined significantly, while there have been
UNITED STATES EXPORTS AN D IMPORTS
OF MERCHANDISE
few
important gains. The sluggish behavior of these other
Q u a r t e r ly v a lu e s at s e a s o n a lly a d ju ste d a n n u a l rates
B illio n s of d o lla r s
B illio n s of d o llars
exports may in part be traceable to the foreign exchange
difficulties recently experienced by many of the under­
developed countries (difficulties that in turn are due partly
to the fall in the prices of their raw material exports).
The fact remains, however, that the manufactured goods
exports of several other major industrial nations have
been faring better than those of the United States.
To some extent, the misgivings concerning the com­
petitiveness of our finished goods exports are confirmed by
the developments in our import trade. While the season­
ally adjusted rate of merchandise imports fell about 8 per
cent during the 1957-58 recession, most of the drop re­
flected the fall in world prices of raw materials; in terms
N o te : E x p o rts e x clu d e shipm ents u nde r m ilit a r y grants.
of physical volume, imports barely declined at all. Follow­
Source: U n ite d S ta te s D e p artm e n t of Com m erce th ro u g h 1958. D a ta for the
first quarter o f 1959 e stim a te d by the Federal Re serve B a n k of N e w York
ing
the upturn in business activity and the recovery of raw
from p re lim in ary m o n th ly fig u re s issued b y the D epartm ent of Com m erce.
material prices, imports increased once more, achieving a
new high in the last quarter of 1958 and again in the first
quarter of 1959. About a quarter of the increase in im­
for less than a third of total commercial exports. Further­ ports from their low point, however, reflected a rise in
more, the 1957 highs were achieved only through a co­ imports of petroleum and petroleum products, partly in
incidence of temporary influences, among them the Suez anticipation of the restrictions on such imports eventually
crisis and the pronounced business boom abroad which imposed in early March; since then, oil imports have
was then approaching its peak. Cotton and wheat exports, dropped sharply. The ratio of total imports to gross
for example, which are largely dependent on various Gov­
ernment subsidy programs, were unusually high in early
1957— more than two and one-half times the early 1956
value. The subsequent decline in shipments (about three
C h a rt II
CHANGES IN THE PATTERN OF
fourths for cotton and one fourth for wheat) has been
UNITED STATES EXPORTS
chiefly a consequence of Governmental policies, har­
B illio n s of d o lla rs
B illio n s of d o lla r s
vest fluctuations, and the world textile recession rather
than of market competition. In the case of petroleum and
petroleum products, our 1957 exports were inflated be­
cause of the temporary closing of the Suez Canal in late
1956, which cut off Europe from its normal sources
of petroleum supply. United States exports of petroleum
products nearly tripled between early 1956 and 1957, but
with the return to more normal conditions they have now
fallen even somewhat below the 1956 rate. Finally, as
regards coal and steel, foreign demand in 1956 and 1957
was buoyed by the boom in economic activity abroad. In
the case of steel, foreign capacity and inventories were
substantially expanded during the boom (as was the case
in the United States), to the point where supplies abroad
have become more nearly sufficient to cover currently
prevailing needs.
N ote: E x p o rts e x c lu d e shipm e nts under m ilitary g ra n ts.
But, even if much of the drop in United States exports
* R a w cotton, w heat, co a l, p e tro le u m a n d products, a n d iron a n d
can be explained by special factors, there are no grounds
steel m ill products.
Source: United States D e p a rtm e n t of Com m erce.
for complacency. Exports of a number of products other




C h a rt I

80

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1959

national product in the first quarter of 1959 was about the
same as before the recession.
Most significantly, imports of finished goods did not
decline during the recession and have expanded appre­
ciably since. This has reflected chiefly the remarkable
demand for foreign cars; imports of autos and parts more
than tripled between the first quarters of 1957 and 1959.
Demand for other imported consumer goods also has
been relatively strong. But the behavior of capital goods
imports is of particular interest. In the aggregate, these
imports are small; in the first quarter of this year, for
example, they amounted to perhaps 15 per cent of our
capital goods exports and to perhaps 3 per cent of the
total domestic market. It is noteworthy, however, that
these imports did not decline during the recession despite
the sharp drop in domestic outlays on producer goods;

indeed, they began to rise in 1958 while capital goods
purchases by American business were still falling, and
they were some 40 per cent higher in the first quarter
of 1959 than in the same periods of 1957 and 1958.
In summary, much of the decline in our exports is
attributable to special considerations not directly related
to the competitive position of individual products. A num­
ber of American products, however, notably capital goods,
do appear to have become less competitive in world mar­
kets. If this is so, the rapid rise in United States prices
for these products (on the domestic market, capital goods
prices have risen 20 per cent in the last four years) pre­
sumably must carry at least part of the responsibility,
although such factors as improved quality and better de­
livery terms offered by foreign producers have probably
also played important roles.

M o n e y M a r k e t In M a y
Member banks were under generally steady reserve
pressure during May, as bank loans continued to expand
throughout most of the country. On a few occasions the
money market developed a relatively easy tone, but for the
most part this occurred as a result of temporary accumula­
tions of reserves at the large New York City banks rather
than because of an increased supply of reserves in the
banking system. Effective May 29, the discount rates of
the Federal Reserve Banks of New York, Chicago, Min­
neapolis, St. Louis, and Dallas were increased to 3Vz per
cent from 3 per cent. Earlier in the month, on May 15,
major commercial banks throughout the country an­
nounced an increase to AV2 per cent from 4 per cent in the
“prime” loan rate, the borrowing rate for business bor­
rowers with the highest credit rating.
Activity in the Government securities market in May
centered in the short-term area, as the Treasury replaced
a certificate issue and a special bill issue due on May 15
and raised a small amount of new cash through the issu­
ance of three new securities, all of one year or shorter
maturity. The financing operation was unusual, involving
an exchange offering of one-year certificates for the
maturing certificates, cash redemption of the maturing
bills, and the sale of two new special bills for cash. The
latter issues were December 1959 tax anticipation bills
and April 1960 special bills— the second quarterly issue
in the Treasury’s new one-year cycle. In the face of pre­
vailing uncertainties regarding the effect of the recent
surge in business activity upon interest rates, the market




reception of the new offerings was generally restrained.
The same influences affected the intermediate and long­
term markets and, in limited trading, prices of Treasury
notes and bonds declined further over the month, although
less sharply than they had in April.

MEMBER

BANK

RESERVE

PO SIT IO N S

Net borrowed reserves averaged $278 million for the
four statement weeks ended in May, somewhat larger
than the $258 million average for April. Average excess
reserves increased from $418 million to $446 million,
while average member bank borrowings from the Reserve
Banks rose from $676 million to $724 million.
Fluctuations in the weekly average level of net borrowed
reserves were quite narrow until the last week. System
securities operations, for the most part, replaced bank
reserves lost largely through currency drains and gold
outflows, which together absorbed nearly $400 million in
the four weeks. Total System holdings of Government
securities increased by $282 million between April 29
and May 27.
The public’s demand for currency remained stronger
than might have been expected on the basis of seasonal
patterns, reflecting the quickening pace of the business
expansion. Outflows of gold continued in May at a faster
pace than in April. Float movements were sharp in the
last two weeks of the month, but they left reserve positions
unaffected over the month as a whole. In the third state-

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK
Table I
Changes in Factors Tending to Increase or Decrease
Member Bank Reserves, May 1959
(In millions of dollars; ( - f ) denotes increase,
(—) decrease in excess reserves)
Daily averages—week ended
Factor

Net
changes

May
6

May
13

May
20

May
27

Treasury operations*...............................
Federal Reserve float...............................
Currency in circulation............................
Gold and foreign account.........................
Other deposits, etc...................................

+ 15
7
- 125
- 53
- 27

+ 24
- 98
- 136
- 24
- 26

+ 19
+ 360
- 10
- 65
- 90

- 33
- 215
+ 42
- 10
+ 5

+ 25
+ 40
- 229
- 152
- 138

Total.....................................

- 199

- 258

+ 213

- 210

- 454

+ 98
+ 102

+ 234
- 32

-

-

+ 297
—

+

+

34
—

+ 144
—

- 195
1

+
-

_

-

1
1

-

-

Operating transactions

Direct Federal Reserve credit transactions

Government securities:
Direct market purchases or sales..........
Held under repurchase agreements.......
Loans, discounts, and advances:
Member bank borrowings.....................
Other...................................................
Bankers’ acceptances:
Bought outright...................................
Under repurchase agreements..............

-

—

19

—

1

+

l

14
61

21
9

—

1

2
1
—

3

+ 237

+

66

- 226

+ 296

Total Reserves.............................................
Effect of change in required reserves f ........

+
-

20
25

+

21
66

+ 279
- 118

- 436
+ 167

- 158
+ 90

Excess reserves f ..........................................

-

5

+

45

+ 161

- 269

-

709
444
- 265

853
605
- 248

658
336
- 322

724 %
446 X
- 278 X

Total...................................... + 219

Daily average level of member bank:
Borrowings from Reserve Banks..............
Net borrowed reserves.............................

675
399
- 276

68

Note: Because of rounding, figures do not necessarily add to totals.
* Includes changes in Treasury currency and cash,
t These figures are estimated.
X Average for four weeks ended May 27, 1959.

ment week, the midmonth expansion of float provided the
banks with $360 million additional reserves, but this was
largely absorbed by the increase in required reserves asso­
ciated with commercial-bank underwriting purchases of
the new Treasury bills, by the expiration of repurchase
agreements entered into earlier by this Bank with Govern­
ment securities dealers, and by other factors.
G O V E R N M E N T SE C U R IT IE S

MARKET

Interest rates moved moderately higher during May in
virtually all sectors of the Government securities market,
extending the sharp April increase. The rate trend reflected
continued concern over the implications for credit de­
mands of the recent acceleration in business activity. The
midmonth increase in the prime loan rate and the end-ofmonth increase in the discount rate seem to have been
largely discounted by the time they occurred. During the
last half of the month, yields on Treasury securities moved
lower, offsetting part of their earlier increases. Treasury
bill rates, however, rose moderately following the May 29
discount rate increase.
In the uncertain market climate, the Treasury debt
operations undertaken in early May to refund some $4.5




81

billion of securities due on the fifteenth met with a gener­
ally unenthusiastic response. Following an over-all financ­
ing program announced on April 30 and described in the
Monthly Review for May, the Treasury redeemed the $2.7
billion of special bills due on May 15 and held two special
bill auctions on May 6 and 7, the first for $2.0 billion of
340-day bills dated May 11 and maturing April 15, 1960
and the second for $1.5 billion of 221-day tax anticipation
bills dated May 15 and maturing December 22, 1959.
Commercial banks, attracted by the privilege of paying
for the new April bills by credits to Treasury Tax and
Loan Accounts, exhibited a fairly strong interest in this
issue. Tenders received by the Treasury for the $2 billion
offering totaled $3.5 billion and resulted in an average
issuing rate of 3.835 per cent. In contrast, the December
tax anticipation bills auctioned the next day attracted a
relatively small bid from investors (payment for this issue
by credit to Tax and Loan Accounts was not permitted).
The $1.7 billion of tenders barely covered the $1.5 billion
offering. The bills were awarded at an average issuing
rate of 3.565 per cent, but tenders were accepted at rates
as high as 3.655 per cent. At the close of the month, the
market rates on the April 15 and December 22 bills were
3.97 per cent and 3.57 per cent, respectively.
The Treasury had included in its April 30 announce­
ment an offering of one-year certificates of indebtedness
to mature May 15, 1960 in exchange for the $1.8 billion
of VA per cent certificates maturing May 15, but it did
not announce terms for the offering until after the results
of the bill auctions had become known. Late on May 7
the Treasury announced that the certificates would carry
a 4 per cent coupon rate and would be priced at 99.95
per cent of face value to yield 4.05 per cent. The return
on the new security was apparently not considered par­
ticularly attractive, and the new issue failed to de­
velop a premium above issue price while the books were
open. Subscription books were open on May 11 and
12, and the results were made known on May 14. Of
the $1,817 million IV4 per cent certificates of indebted­
ness outstanding, $1,270 million were exchanged into
the new 4 per cent certificates, leaving $547 million (or 30
per cent) to be turned in for cash on May 15.
Market yields on Treasury bills fluctuated irregularly
during the month, tending to decline among the short
issues and to rise, until late in the period, among the longer
issues. The temporary heaviness in the longer end of the
list reflected the additional supply of these maturities that
had to be digested following the Treasury financing opera­
tion. Around midmonth, dealers were called upon to
underwrite a sizable portion of the new tax anticipation
issue and to take up a residual supply of the new April 15

82

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1959

special bills being offered in the market by commercial
bank subscribers. Meanwhile, the demand which had been
anticipated from the reinvestment of the proceeds of the
May 15 cash redemptions of the matured special bills and
the unexchanged certificates was slow to develop. Eventu­
ally this demand gave support to longer bills, as well as
to short issues, and a part of the earlier rate increase was
reversed. The discount rate change at the end of May
touched off further increases in Treasury bill rates, par­
ticularly among shorter issues.
Illustrating the divergent trends in the two broad areas
of Treasury bill maturities, rates on the three- and sixmonth bills moved in opposite directions in the regular
weekly auctions of May 11 and 18. The three-month bills
were awarded at average issuing rates of 2.935 per cent
on May 4, of 2.722 per cent on May 11, of 2.869 per cent
on May 18, and of 2.878 per cent on May 25, compared
with 2.831 per cent on April 27. The six-month bills
were awarded at rates of 3.316 per cent, 3.408 per cent,
3.376 per cent, and 3.373 per cent in the respective May
auctions, compared with 3.189 per cent on the last April
auction date. Market yields on the maturities nearest
three months and six months rose by 22 and 27 basis
points over the month to 3.08 per cent and 3.45 per cent,
respectively.
Trading in Treasury notes and bonds was light through­
out the month. Prices of most intermediate and long-term
issues moved steadily lower in the first part of the month,
reaching new all-time lows immediately following the in­
crease in the prime loan rate, but recovered a part of
their losses later in the period. The average yield on
long-term Treasury bonds rose from 4.07 per cent on
April 30 to 4.08 per cent at the close of May.

ing. The volume of municipal issues amounted to $500
million in the current month, against $830 million in April
and $775 million in the same month last year. Estimated
corporate bond offerings for new capital purposes, how­
ever, amounted to $345 million in May, compared with
$300 million in April and $340 million in May 1958.
Investors were generally slow to take up new offerings
until the latter part of the period, when a sharply higher
pattern of reoffering yields resulted in rapid distribution
of new bonds, particularly corporates. For instance, two
Aa-quality 30-year utility mortgage bond issues, reoffered
to yield 5 per cent or better, were very well received and
moved quickly to slight premiums over the reoffering
price. On the other hand, a Aa-rated industrial issue of
like maturity, reoffered to yield only 4.69 per cent, moved
rather slowly. In addition, several large United States
Government agency issues were very well received during
the month, including $200 million of Federal Home Loan
Bank 4¥s per cent nine-month consolidated notes, $170
million of Federal Intermediate Credit Bank AVz per cent
consolidated collateral trust debentures of approximately
the same maturity, and $130 million of Bank for Coopera­
tives 4V4 per cent six-month debentures, all offered at par.
In the market for short-term debt instruments, several
upward rate revisions were made during the month. On
May 18, commercial paper dealers raised their rates by
Vs of 1 per cent, bringing the rate on prime four- to sixmonth paper to 3% per cent. On May 20 dealers in
bankers’ acceptances announced a rate increase of the
same magnitude, bringing the bid and offered rates on
90-day unindorsed acceptances to 3% per cent and 3V4
per cent, respectively.
C O M M E R C IA L

O TH ER SE C U R IT IE S

MARKETS

Yields on corporate and municipal bonds moved gradu­
ally upward in May in response to the same factors influ­
encing Government securities and to the build-up in the
calendar of expected new offerings. On several new issues
in which syndicate terminations were reported during the
month, yield concessions of as much as 50 basis points
were made. Even so, the market remained sluggish, and
dealers had difficulty in reducing their large holdings. The
average yields on Aaa-rated seasoned corporate bonds
rose from 4.30 per cent at the end of April to 4.43 per
cent on May 29, while the average yield on similarly rated
municipals advanced from 3.18 per cent to 3.31 per cent.
The total volume of new bond financing undertaken in
the calendar month fell off from the April total and from
that of May 1958 because of a decline in municipal financ­




BANK

C R E D IT

Total loans at the weekly reporting member banks dur­
ing the early weeks of May continued to show the vigor
which had first become clearly evident in April. In con­
trast to the relatively sluggish behavior of loans in the
first quarter, the $1.6 billion increase during April and
the first three weeks of May was well in excess of gains
during comparable periods of any recent year. In the
corresponding weeks of 1955, for example, when a strong
business expansion was under way, loans increased by
only about $0.8 billion (see Table II).
Since much of the recent expansion has taken place at
nonreporting banks, however, the statistics on weekly re­
porting banks are not fully indicative of the breadth and
strength of the recent loan upsurge. Preliminary data sug­
gest that loans of banks which do not report on a weekly
basis increased by about $0.8 billion in April. For all

83

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

CHANGES IN LOANS AT MEMBER BANKS
1955 AN D 1959
C u m u la te d fro m b e g in n in g of ye a r
M illio n s of d o lla rs

M il li o n s o f d o lla r s

quarter during which the decline in bank credit, amount­
ing to almost $4 billion, was appreciably greater than sea­
sonal. Government securities were liquidated in substan­
tial volume during this period as bank reserve positions
came under persistent, although moderate, pressures.
Viewing the year 1959 to date, the change in bank credit
thus appears to be broadly in line with a strong and
healthy business upswing. But developments in April and
early May suggest that the expansion may be approaching
a stage where credit demands will press with sharply
mounting force against the available supply of loanable
funds.
Table II
Changes in Principal A ssets of the W eekly Reporting Member Banks
(In millions of dollars)
Period
First Quarter

Assets
Jan

Feb

Mar

Apr

J an

F eb

Mar

Apr

April—May

1955(a)

1959(b)

1955(c)

+ 174J

-

+

1959(d)

Loans and investments:
Loans:

commercial banks combined, the loan expansion in April
was $1.7 billion, or more than twice the increase of
any April during the last decade. This advance, more­
over, was widely distributed among various types of loans,
with borrowing by business, consumer, real estate, and
miscellaneous groups all exceptionally strong relative to
previous years.
Both in the first quarter and in the more recent period,
the loan expansion has almost entirely reflected a growth
in the portfolios of reserve city and country banks (see
chart). Central reserve city banks in New York City and
Chicago have not thus far participated in the expansion to
any appreciable extent, partly because these banks hold
a relatively small proportion of total consumer and real
estate loans which have accounted for a good part of the
recent loan increase. In addition, heavy repayments this
year by public utilities and petroleum firms, which borrow
mainly from the larger banks in New York City, have
largely offset the expansion of other business loans in
which these banks have shared.
Total commercial bank credit increased by an esti­
mated $2.4 billion during April as a result of the $1.7
billion increase in loans and of a $0.7 billion rise in
investments. This expansion in bank credit fell short of
last year’s record increase for April, when credit policy
was directed actively toward combating the recession;
nevertheless, it still was unusually large by the standard
of prior years. However, the April bulge followed a first




Commercial and industrial loans...
Agricultural loans.........................
Securities loans.............................
Real estate loans..........................
All other loans (largely consumer).

203
45
611

+

467
37
382
253
471

+ 521

+
-

385
778

86

+ 411
- 326

+

-

393

-3,594

-2,443

+ 85

-3,126

-2,943

+ 900

- 205
+ 298
4- 248

+ 212

+ 468

500

U. S. Government securities:
Treasury bills.....................
Other.................................

-1,257
-2,760

- 198
-2,331

Total. . . . . .
Other securities.

-4,017
+ 423

+

-2,529

Total investments........................
Total loans, adjusted,* and investments.

Total loans, adjusted*,

+ 160

+

+
-f

441
221
212

353

+

Investments:

-

110

10

* Exclusive of loans to banks and after deduction of valuation reserves;figures for the individual
loan classifications are shown gross and may not, therefore, add to the totals shown.
December 29, 1954 to March 30, 1955.
January 1, 1959 to March 25, 1959.
March 30, 1955 to May 25, 1955.
March 25, 1959 to May 20, 1959.

(a)
(b)
(c)
(d)

D E B IT S A N D

C L E A R IN G S

ST A T IST IC S

The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System has recently published a 156-page booklet
entitled Debits and Clearings Statistics and Their
Use, written by George Garvy, Adviser, Federal Re­
serve Bank of New York. This booklet is a revised,
up-to-date edition of the study originally published
in January 1952. Copies are available from the Divi­
sion of Administrative Services, Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System, Washington 25, D.C.,
at $1.00 each.

84

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1959

I n t e r n a t io n a l F in a n c ia l D e v e lo p m e n t s

The upturn in economic activity in the major industrial
countries abroad appears to be accelerating. The improve­
ment now extends to a large number of countries, and is
broadly distributed among the various economic sectors.
Prices have so far remained relatively stable, and unutilized
resources at this time are generally larger than in previous
recovery periods. In addition, most foreign industrial
countries at present hold a fairly comfortable cushion
of gold and foreign exchange reserves.
Given this environment, the authorities in these coun­
tries (except Canada, as noted below) have generally con­
tinued in the past two months to pursue a policy of mone­
tary ease, and in a number of instances have adopted
additional measures of credit relaxation.1 On April 23,
the National Bank of Austria reduced its discount rate to
AVi per cent from 5, the first change in the rate since
November 1955. On the same day, the Bank of France
lowered its discount rate to 4 per cent from AVa and also
reduced the penalty rates applicable to commercial bank
borrowing in excess of an individual institution’s discount
ceiling. These moves by the Bank of France followed two
earlier discount rate reductions in the past eight months
and the relaxation of other credit restrictions. The bank’s
latest measures appear to indicate that a rise in lending
activity is regarded as warranted in order to support eco­
nomic recovery. Meanwhile, the Bank of Greece reduced
its rates on most loans to private nonbank borrowers, and
in Belgium consumer credit controls were relaxed through
an extension of the maximum repayment period.
During the same month the German Federal Bank
twice reduced the interest rates at which it sells money
market paper, bringing these rates to postwar lows. The
bank thus continued its policy of reducing the interest rate
differential between German and other financial centers.
Other recent measures taken by the German Federal Bank
reflect the belief that, at present interest rate levels, fur­
ther large inflows of foreign funds are unlikely and that
the restrictions which had been imposed in May 1957 to
discourage speculation in favor of the mark are no longer
needed. Thus, the bank abolished, as of April 1, all
special reserve requirements against foreign-owned de­
posits, which had exceeded reserve requirements against

domestic deposits and had recently ranged from 10 per
cent for savings deposits to 30 per cent for sight deposits;
henceforth, the prevailing reserve requirements against do­
mestic deposits are to apply to foreign ones as well. The
bank also permitted credit institutions to resume interest
payments on foreign deposits and, as of May 1, removed
the remaining restrictions on the extension of loans and
credits by nonresidents to residents, whether in marks or
foreign currencies. Previously, such transactions—which
now may also include the acquisition of German money
market paper by nonresidents— had been subject to special
licensing, and had to have a minimum maturity of five
years.
In contrast to the Western European central banks, the
Bank of Canada in recent months has once more applied
some restraint, reflecting the fact that the current upturn
has been somewhat more vigorous in Canada than in
Europe. The chartered banks have sold substantial amounts
of government securities of all maturities in order to meet
the heavy demand for business loans, and interest rates
have risen sharply. Following a rise in general business
loans of over 10 per cent in the six months through April
(see chart), the chartered banks last month agreed among
themselves to exercise the utmost care in the granting
of credit in order to avoid any significant increase in the
over-all credit total.
In most other industrial countries abroad, the expan­
sion of economic activity in recent months has likewise
been accompanied (and indeed supported) by an expansion
of commercial bank lending. Such lending has, of course,
been encouraged by the gradual relaxation of credit re­
strictions. A particularly sharp rise in bank lending
has taken place in the United Kingdom, where the banks
during the first ten months following the ending of the
“credit squeeze” in July 1958 expanded their loans by
24 per cent to an all-time high. A substantial part of
this rise was attributable to an increase in personal loans
and in loans to finance the purchase of consumer goods.
These categories of credit had been most severely re­
stricted during the period of the “squeeze”; moreover, the
buying into finance companies and the introduction of
personal loan arrangements by British banks during the
second half of last year has tended to give greater scope
to loans for consumption purposes.2

1 For developments during January-March, see "International Monetary Developments”, M onthly Review, February and A p ril 19 59.

2 See "Commercial Banks and Consumer Credit Abroad”, Monthly
Review, January 1959.

M ONETARY




TRENDS AND

P O L IC IE S

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

8,5

firming, tended to decline, while the Canadian dollar, fol­
lowing some hesitancy, rose to new 1959 highs toward
the month end. Continental currencies maintained a firm
Mill ions
C A N A D A (C A N .$)
UNITED K IN G D O M ^ }
5000------------------------------------------- — ----- ,2500
undertone, with the Swiss franc recovering its April losses.
The Argentine peso continued under pressure, with the
quotation reaching new low levels.
Spot sterling, following the announcement of an increase
4500
2000
in April of £ 4 0 million ($1 1 2 million) in British gold and
convertible-currency reserves, advanced to $2.8170 in
J958
early May. Thereafter, the quotation fluctuated somewhat
1 I I I I J 1500
40001_!__I_I_!_L
erratically toward lower levels, reaching $2.8110 in the
G ER M A N Y (DM)
AU ST R IA (SCH)
14000
20000
morning of May 29. This movement largely reflected
demand for dollars in London shortly after midmonth, to
1959
cover short positions, and offerings of sterling from Con­
tinental sources at that time and again at the month end.
19000
13000
These factors more than offset good commercial demand
1953^
1958
for sterling in New York and occasional demand from
the Continent. At the market close, on May 29, spot
1
1
I
I
I
.
L_
.
1
J...
1
.1
18000!_1_L J—
I— I -1... 1-1.. J 120 00
L
sterling had recovered slightly to $2.8115.
SW EDEN (KR)
DEN M A R K (KR)
8000
12000
In the forward-sterling market, the discounts on three
j
L1959
and six months’ deliveries generally narrowed during the
1958
month, owing in part to some commercial demand and
1959
occasional demand from the Far East. From discounts of
7000
11000
K ^j/}958
47 and 86 points at the beginning of May, the spreads
1957
on three and six months’ forward sterling narrowed to
13 and 28, respectively, at the month end.
1 1 ! I 1
t i l l !
6000
10000
J A S O N D J F M A M J
Securities-sterling quotations, reflecting reduced investor
N ote: D a ta exclude in te rb an k lo a n s a n d lo an s to central an d m u n ic ip a l
interest in British securities, gradually eased from $ 2 .8 IV2
go v e rn m e n ts. D a ta are as of end of m onth, ex cep t for U nite d K in gdom ,
w h ich u se s third W e d n e sd a y of m onths other than June an d December.
at the beginning of the month to $2.80% on May 29.
Source: N a t io n a l statistics.
The Canadian dollar, quoted at $ 1 .0 3 5% 4 on May 1,
declined appreciably when Canadian commercial interests
entered the market to fill United States dollar require­
The growth of instalment and consumer credit facilities ments. The quotation touched $1.0316 on May 6, but later
in other industrial countries also has undoubtedly con­ recovered substantially, and then settled at about the
tributed to the expansion in commercial bank lending $1.0 3 2%2 level until shortly after midmonth. Following
in recent months. Following the introduction of personal the placement in the New York market of a new Canadian
loan facilities by commercial banks in Denmark, Ireland, provincial bond issue and the proposal of an American
the Netherlands, and Sweden late last year, the “big three” motor company to acquire outstanding stock of its Cana­
West German banks last month also entered this field— dian subsidiary, the rate for the Canadian dollar moved
an innovation in German banking. The credits to be upward to $ 1.0 4 1/4 on May 26. On May 29 the rate
granted under the new scheme range from DM 300 ($71) declined to $ 1 .0 3 5% 4, in response to general demand for
to DM 2,000 ($4 7 6), are repayable in six to twenty-four United States dollars by Canadian commercial interests,
monthly instalments, and are subject to an interest charge but closed at $ 1.0 4% 4.
of 4.8 per cent on the face amount of the loan. Initial
The Swiss franc, which had eased to $0.23 l l 1/^ at the
demand for these credits reportedly has been brisk.
end of April, gradually improved during most of May,
reaching $ 0 .2 3 1 6 ^ on May 29, the level that had pre­
vailed in early April.
EXCHANGE RATES
The Argentine peso declined steadily from 79.20 pesos
The New York foreign exchange market developed to the dollar (1 peso = $0.01262) at the beginning of
a mixed pattern during May. Spot sterling, after an initial May to 89.70 ($0.0114) at the month end.
COMMERCIAL BANK LOANS AN D ADVANCES
IN SELECTED COUNTRIES




---------------—

86

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1959

C r e e p in g In fla tio n
Throughout history, wherever people have used money
to express the values of goods and services, some
form of “inflation” has been a recurring theme. Even
though the actual inflations of past generations have, as
a rule, either had to be stopped by drastic action or ulti­
mately have destroyed themselves, often with intense
human suffering and severe economic loss, there seems to
be a tantalizing fascination in the illusion of greater wealth
created by rising prices. That lure has led time and again
to a search for a new and more promising form of infla­
tionary solution to pressing economic problems. Today,
in the United States, the alchemists are at work once more.
The new version is called “creeping inflation”.
This is not, of course, a single, coherent doctrine. Much
of its support comes, in fact, from people who know well
the dangers of a cumulative upward price spiral and would
oppose anything which they considered to be outright
inflation. There are a few, to be sure, who seem to regard
sustained price increases as genuinely desirable in order
to evoke what they believe will be the maximum of growth
in output and employment. But most are simply inclined
reluctantly to accept a regular and moderate edging-up
of prices year after year, at a rate of no more than 2 or 3
per cent, as merely the least costly way to resolve many
of the conflicting claims now being placed upon the
American economy.
In the various ways that this general thesis is developed,
a paradoxical quirk often appears in the treatment ac­
corded the Federal Reserve System. Both among those
who urge and those who reluctantly accept “creeping in­
flation”, there are many who assert their despair of mone­
tary and credit controls, condemning them for such varied
shortcomings as being too weak, or harshly punitive, or
inequitably discriminatory. And yet those who have con­
fronted the question of how to hold the “creep” of rising
prices within the bounds of the 2 or 3 per cent figure
invariably mention monetary and credit controls, along
with fiscal measures, as the principal means of performing
that job. Faced with this ambivalence between mistrust
and trust, the Federal Reserve itself might perhaps under­
standably be puzzled.
This article is an effort to seek clarification, first, by re­
stating briefly some of the various approaches that have
been taken by supporters of creeping inflation, and then ap­
praising these in the context of a similarly abbreviated
description of the pricing process, savings and investment,
“administered” prices and wages, international economic
relations, and economic fluctuations and growth.




The appraisal shows that creeping inflation is not
merely an innocent vice, a relatively costless or harm­
less way of relieving tensions. It will lead to much higher
rates of interest and a confusing network of “price
escalator” arrangements, a distortion and eventual impair­
ment of saving and investment, wider cyclical fluctuations,
and a stunting of growth. Moreover, there would be no
gains to offset these grave consequences. Over time, creep­
ing inflation would not lessen but would aggravate any
threat of unemployment; it would not cushion but would
stimulate any abuses that may be associated with “admin­
istered” prices or labor’s “cost push”; and it would not
relieve the kinds of political pressures that may at times
interfere with the functioning of a market economy. These
serious consequences would not only mean a failure to
fulfill the economic potential of the United States, but
would also gravely weaken this country’s ability to fulfill
its responsibilities of leadership in the international
economic community and in world affairs.
This single article can only provide a sketch of the
analysis underlying these conclusions. In later months,
various subjects opened here will be pursued further
in separate articles. A supplement to this issue of
the Monthly Review contains a condensation of one of the
most authoritative statements on the subject of creeping
inflation— some remarks made recently by Dr. Wilhelm
Vocke, former President of the Bank deutscher Lander.
That statement and this article, while recognizing that
there can never be ideal and final solutions to all of the
problems of a changing and growing economy, both con­
clude that a public policy aimed at reasonable price sta­
bility is essential in a modern economy if there is to be
sustained expansion of employment and income, for the
benefit of everyone.
THE CASE

FOR C R E EPIN G

IN FL A T IO N

Much of the appeal of creeping inflation lies in the
ready reconciliation it seems to provide among many of
the pressing issues of current concern in the American
economy. Is not the acceptance of some form of inflation
the only way out, for example, for an economy determined
to combat depressions and pursuing sustained maximum
employment as a national goal because it will no longer
tolerate the conditions under which most of the significant
and general price reductions of earlier times occurred? In
any event, the argument runs, with so many business con­
cerns able to “administer” prices, and thereby able to
reduce output instead of cutting prices when the demand

FEDERAL.

RESERVE

SUPPLEM ENT

THE

TO

BANK

MONTHLY

FUTURE

OF

NEW

YORK

R E V IE W , J U N E

OF T H E

1959

DOLLAR

By D r . W i l h e l m V o c k e *
Former President of the Bank deutscher Lander, now the
Deutsche Bundesbank, the central bank of the Federal Republic of Germany
You have invited me to discuss with you the problem of
the dollar, which is a task that I approach with some
hesitation since it concerns, after all, your country. Yet
the issues that are involved clearly reach beyond national
frontiers and indeed affect the world as a whole. There
would be little value in my joining this debate on monetary
problems if I thought the world were headed toward an­
other war. But I firmly believe in peace—many years of
peace; and I am convinced that the United States can
promote peace most effectively not only through the power
of its armaments, but through the strength of its financial
system as well.
The current debate over the future of the dollar and
economic growth has advanced to the stage where the
issues are now clearly drawn. The choice is between the
path of creeping inflation and that of a strong and stable
dollar. A clear decision as to which path is to be taken
must be made now in the interest of the business com­
munity and the nation, which must know the direction in
which the economy is moving and how much trust can
be placed in the currency. Things cannot be permitted
to drift, creating uncertainty and confusion among long­
term investors who must plan ahead and on whose ap­
praisal of the future the economic growth of the country
depends.

sons can be drawn. When I assumed office as President
of the Bank deutscher Lander ten years ago, monetary
conditions in Germany were in a desperate state. Several
experts, both German and foreign, with world-wide
reputation and extensive experience declared frankly that
the Deutsche mark had virtually no prospects of ever be­
coming a hard currency. That these well-meant opinions
proved wrong, as time has shown, is no doubt in part due
to a good deal of luck and favorable circumstances. But
I, for one, never wavered in my conviction that a monetary
policy, consistently and energetically pursued in order to
establish and maintain a stable currency, must succeed.
There are perhaps two principal lessons to be learned
from the German experience. The first is that currency
stability can be achieved and preserved even under the
most adverse circumstances. The second, and even more
significant, is that a monetary policy, firmly committed
to currency stability, not only does not conflict with a
high rate of economic growth but indeed is essential to its
achievement. Germany’s remarkable economic recovery
and expansion over the past decade was closely linked to
the restoration and preservation of a strong and stable
monetary unit.
Obviously, these policies did not escape the test of
public opinion. In 1955 the German economy was unmis­
takably headed toward a dangerous boom. All economic
indicators—production, employment, income, exports, and
TH E L E S S O N S OF TH E G ER M A N E X PER IEN C E
above all wages and prices— were surging upward at a
Let me first make a few observations on the German high pitch. Under these conditions prompt and energetic
monetary experience, from which some fundamental les­ measures by the central bank were called for, in order
to keep the economy from losing balance. The steps taken
to bridle the inflationary forces proved highly unpopular
* Condensation of remarks made in this country by Dr. Vocke on
April 13, 1959.
and were severely criticized by industrialists, government




officials, and the public on the grounds that they would
undermine economic growth. As matters turned out, none
of the somber predictions came true. On the contrary, as
a result of the early effort to defend the Deutsche mark,
the economy quickly regained both its equilibrium and the
basis for continued expansion in an orderly manner. This
experience proves that a central bank must be persistent
and unruffled in its pursuit of a determined course of
action, and must not shrink from occasionally taking un­
popular measures if its obligations and responsibilities to
the nation are to be properly fulfilled. In Germany, such
monetary measures had to be taken on several occasions
in the face of widespread criticism. But now that the econ­
omy is vigorously moving forward at a high level of pros­
perity and on the basis of a stable currency, what were once
unpopular policies have now become the object of rather
general praise.
The experience in the rest of Western Europe has been
much the same. Comprehensive monetary and fiscal meas­
ures have helped restore financial stability and have re­
vitalized the economies. The United States may regard
the accumulation of gold by these countries with mixed
feelings, but the fact remains that the gold had to be
earned by productive effort. After years of bitter experi­
ence with inflation, Western Europe has now turned to
monetary stability. The rejection of policies leading to
continual depreciation of the currency was dramatized
last December when thirteen European countries took
steps to make their currencies fully convertible.
T H E “ C R E E P IN G IN F L A T IO N ” T H E S IS

To a foreigner it seems almost absurd that there should
be certain quarters in the United States where inflation
is tolerated or even recommended. Surely any price to be
paid for inflation must be excessive, considering not only
the adverse economic and social effects, but the irretriev­
able losses in national prestige it may entail. The path
of inflation in the United States would not only mean the
depreciation and ultimate devaluation of the dollar, but
also an acute decline in the moral authority, power, and
international stature of the United States. That there are
close links binding a nation’s prestige to its financial
posture is evident from the manner in which the emergence
of the Deutsche mark as a sound and stable monetary unit
has enhanced the stature of the new western Germany in
the family of nations.
The arguments advanced by the advocates of inflation
must be earnestly and thoroughly considered. To begin
with, the arguments set forth are, above all, political in




character. The inflationists purport to show that inflation
is an inevitable tide that can be stemmed only at the cost
of economic progress. Consequently, they say, the attitude
toward inflation must be rendered more flexible, and eco­
nomic doctrine and policy must be adapted to a new insti­
tutional setting instead of plodding along the old rut of
a stable currency.
Certainly, the proponents of this thesis by no means
favor galloping inflation, but only the mild, creeping kind.
In fact, they would for the most part readily admit that
even a moderate inflation entails certain evils. Neverthe­
less, they would argue also that, whatever these evils may
be, they are far less serious or significant than the grave
political repercussions bound to result from a policy that
tolerates an impairment of full employment, however tem­
porary. To the advocates of creeping inflation full employ­
ment and monetary stability are incompatible. And, if
there exists a choice, the decision would have to be in
favor of full employment, for political reasons. Super­
ficially, at least, these arguments may appear more or less
plausible, particularly since they rest on political con­
siderations. Yet on closer examination their contradictory
nature becomes self-evident.
Let us turn first to full employment. What does it mean
and to what degree can it benefit the nation and the
economy? If full employment should mean that the labor
force is occupied 100 per cent, the law of supply and
demand cannot function normally in the labor market, and
there exists, in effect, a state of overemployment. Under
such conditions, employers can expand output only by
outbidding each other for the available work force and
by drawing workers away from one another. Labor, in
turn, is enabled virtually to dictate its own wages. Such
a state of affairs clearly cannot be regarded as the desirable
optimum for the nation or the economy, either in its
domestic or international aspects.
It is also evident that in a free economy the level of
employment cannot be maintained constant to any greater
degree than the level of production, consumption, invest­
ment, or trade. But, while it may not be possible to elimi­
nate economic fluctuations entirely, the magnitude and
duration of the cycles can be at least minimized. In this
connection, one ought to bear in mind that, even at fairly
high levels of prosperity, it is easier to influence or control
the oscillations in employment and business activity than
to bridle a cumulative inflation which must eventually
lead to the proverbial bust. Nonetheless, the proponents
of creeping inflation recommend yielding to overemploy­
ment, continually rising wages, and the price-wage spiral,
w7hile declaring at the same time that what they envisage

is merely an inflation that crawls along at the leisurely rate
of, say, 2 per cent per annum. Let us examine how this
invention will work.
T H E C U M U L A TIV E

PROCESS

OF

IN FL A T IO N

The initial phase of inflation has a certain appeal.
Rising money income activates the economy like a breath
of spring that brings out the blossoms everywhere. Indus­
try invests and production expands; credit volume rises,
with borrowers planning to repay loans in depreciated
money as inflation progresses. Employment climbs, and
for a considerable part of the population the standard of
living actually increases as consumption moves up, while
the incentives to save wane. All economic indexes surge
upward, mutually reinforcing each other, and setting the
inflationary spiral in motion. At this stage, and at this
stage only, inflation finds many adherents. But this happy
state is usually short-lived and lasts only as long as some
faith in the currency is still maintained. Even while this
phase continues, an increasing segment of the population,
dependent on fixed incomes, begins to feel the ruthless
grip of the inflationary pressures.
The inflationists have a remedy at hand for the sectors
that are squeezed between rising prices and lagging in­
comes: the escalator clause. This clause, which auto­
matically links wages, salaries, and even some business
transactions to the cost-of-living index or gold, was widely
used in France, but with results that proved far from
encouraging. In fact, the escalator clause is merely an
illusion. As long as the depreciation of the currency is
minor, the clause is not invoked. And when inflation
progresses, it is satisfactory neither to income receivers nor
to income payers; meanwhile the government is forced to
inflate to an ever greater extent, in order to compensate
those groups that remain unsheltered by the index clause.
More importantly, however, the escalator clause, in itself,
officially discredits the currency and therefore intensifies
inflation. Moreover, what it clearly reveals is that, once
the currency no longer serves as a stable standard of value,
a substitute must be found. Since stability is, after all,
essential, the absurdity of abandoning a stable standard of
value in the first place becomes patently obvious.
All the various adaptations, compensations, and adjust­
ments to a rising price level may well be bearable as long
as inflation remains within narrow limits. But the fact is
that inflation is progressive and eventually becomes full­
blown. That point is reached when the public begins to
lose faith in the currency and the material-value psychosis
spreads. The scramble for goods is matched only by the




rush into equity investments, while the bond market sags.
The damage that inflation inflicts on the market for fixedinterest securities eventually makes it virtually impossible
for the government to consolidate its short-term debt. For
no one will acquire bonds when the money invested con­
tinually shrinks. The inevitable consequence is that the
central bank will be asked to absorb the unmarketable pub­
lic debt, which adds further fuel to the inflationary surge.
The reluctance to hold money or fixed-interest securities
finds expression also in the rapid decline in savings. Waste­
ful consumption and misdirected investments suddenly
become rational economic actions, compared with the fool­
ishness of saving money that is rapidly becoming worthless.
At this point the reckless spendthrifts and speculators are
proved right and amass fortunes, while the honest, con­
scientious, and weak lose the little they have. As the
process continues, customary standards of behavior are
swept away and accepted moral attitudes are shattered.
Soon everyone flees from the currency and joins in the
furious dance of inflation, while the nation is rapidly
moving to the brink of disaster.
The succession of events that I have just outlined would
probably be considered a gross exaggeration by the pro­
ponents of creeping inflation. They would assert that the
idea is not to let the inflation get out of hand, but to con­
fine it to a delightful 2 per cent per annum. How is this
feat to be accomplished? Obviously, inflation cannot be
kept automatically within prescribed limits. There is no
stable coefficient of inflation. Once begun, inflation spreads
like fire and feeds on itself. Moreover, even if a limited
depreciation of the dollar is envisaged, the public will try
to protect itself, and by doing so will inevitably accelerate
the pace of the price rise. Stability of the rate of inflation
is an illusion, for if the public knows there will be a creep­
ing inflation of 2 per cent per annum, then the 2 per cent
will be reached not at the end of the year, but at the
beginning, and the pressure for inflation will mount.
Since inflation is not self-regulating, by what method
would the advocates of creeping inflation confine it to the
predetermined limits? One answer is by credit policy,
including restrictions on the volume of borrowing and
increases in the rediscount rate. But the applications of
such measures would be precisely those which the inflation­
ists had sought to avoid in the first place. This means in
effect that, while the inflationist would not be prepared to
sacrifice full employment to monetary stability, he would
nevertheless be disposed to sacrifice it for the sake of
keeping the rate of inflation within arbitrary limits. The
contradictory nature of the creeping inflation thesis now
becomes self-evident.

We may even go one step further. What is really meant
by a 2 per cent rate of inflation? If it refers to the average
price level, and not to the prices of individual commodities,
say, straw hats or the wages of particular workmen on the
bench, then the statisticians may well find that, after they
have assembled and averaged the prices of all the separate
commodities, the actual rate of inflation has surpassed the
stipulated maximum. The consequence might then be the
application of an elaborate network of physical controls
over individual prices and wages. Adoption of a policy
that is defined in terms of hitting a rigid target for average
prices greatly increases the chances of detailed regulation
to assure its fulfilment. Such economic regimentation
would severely shatter the foundations upon which this
nation was built and radically alter its way of life. Inflation
inevitably breeds economic controls, regimentation, and
moral corruption.

For all the reasons stated, nothing must be permitted
to give the world the impression that the stability of the
dollar is in doubt. For any action that might signify yield­
ing to the inflation thesis would involve irretrievable losses
to the United States and would inflict immeasurable dam­
age to the international monetary mechanism.
C O N C L U D IN G C O M M E N T S

As a final word I may ask what there is to be gained
by setting free the forces of inflation, except a postpone­
ment of the unavoidable adjustments that every economy
must make sooner or later. It is certainly easier and less
painful to curb incipient inflation or moderate the magni­
tude and duration of economic fluctuations than to tame
an inflation that has reached the stage where only drastic
deflationary remedies can be administered to restore bal­
ance. The measures taken in the United States last year
illustrate that recession need not turn into depression and
T H E IN T E R N A T IO N A L A S P E C T O F IN F L A T IO N
can be short-lived even without turning on the engines of
Let me now touch briefly on the international aspect of inflation. Inflation essentially means weakness and thus
the creeping inflation thesis. During my years as President cannot furnish a sound or lasting basis for economic
of the Bank deutscher Lander, that institution accumulated progress. It is the line of least resistance, and not the
and kept a considerable amount of dollar assets in this road to an effective solution of economic problems or to
country as backing for the Deutsche mark. Other central the realization of economic aspirations.
banks did likewise. And today, foreign central banks
We are living in a critical period in which courageous
alone hold almost $10 billion here as part of their decisions must be made in order to win the struggle for
international reserves. These substantial holdings reflect freedom. This struggle, however, cannot be successfully
the confidence of the world in the strength and stability of waged by yielding to the disease of inflation, whether
the United States dollar. One should hasten to note, how­ creeping, crawling, or any other kind.
ever, that this faith in the dollar is by no means unshakable,
The United States need not fall victim to the grip of
and developments affecting its future are closely watched inflation if that be the nation’s firm will. But any wavering
abroad.
in the determination to preserve the strength and stability
There can be little doubt that a green light for creeping of the dollar may lose the battle before it is even begun.
inflation would entail grave international repercussions. I am confident that the underlying beliefs and traditions
Acceptance of the doctrine— which to me is virtually of this country are strong enough to give unhesitating ex­
unthinkable— would severely undermine the position of pression to the will to preserve monetary stability on which
the United States dollar and would set in motion forces much of the power and moral authority of the nation rest.
leading to its rapid replacement by gold as an international
The words of President Eisenhower and the firm attitude
standard and store of value. The inevitable result would of the Federal Reserve System leave no doubt that the
be a massive withdrawal of foreign dollar balances and right choice is being made. This should be recognized
heavy gold losses for the United States. Under these cir­ throughout the world. And, as the spectre of inflation is
cumstances the question of raising the price of gold and dispelled, the future of the dollar as the world’s best mone­
hence the devaluation of the dollar would again arise. I tary unit continues to be assured. One of the qualities that
have not discussed this issue here; suffice it to say, how­ has rendered this country strong and powerful has been
ever, that there are few things that I would regard as more common sense. If common sense is to continue to guide
detrimental to the United States and to the world than an American policies, the stability of the dollar cannot be
in doubt.
increase in the dollar price of gold.




FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

for their products declines, what hope can there ever be
again for the kind of old-fashioned price competition that
formerly resulted in prices moving freely downward as well
as up? Not only are a number of business concerns able to
“administer” prices in such a way as virtually to exclude
price reductions in periods of slow business, but they are
said to be readily able to “administer” prices upward when
the demand for their product strengthens. Thus able to
pass on cost increases in higher prices, they offer only
weak resistance to another inflationary pressure supposed
to characterize our modern economy. This is the influence
of “cost push”, most frequently attributed to the ability
of labor to obtain increased wages and fringe benefits that
exceed productivity gains.
For all of these supposedly new factors in economic
life— the quest for full employment, the banishment of
depressions, the spread of “administered” prices, and the
emergence of “cost push”— creeping inflation seems to
offer an accommodating cushion. Moreover, this simple
adjustment to the “facts” of modern economic life can be
achieved, the creeping inflationists believe, within the
framework of the kind of economy which this country
wants to maintain, and with which it is identified in the
eyes of the world, that is, a market economy. The argu­
ment has been made, in fact, that it is only by accepting
some inflation that the freedoms essential for a market
economy—the freedom of individual choice and free con­
tract— can be assured. For in the face of the strong up­
ward price pressures now present in the economy, the
argument runs, a determined effort to prevent average
prices from rising would almost necessarily require direct
Government intervention in the setting of prices and wages.
The only alternative, many seem to feel, would be mone­
tary and fiscal policies so restrictive in their impact on
aggregate demand as to generate unemployment and re­
duce the nation’s rate of economic growth below its poten­
tial. Yet both domestic needs and the present international
position of the United States make this alternative
unacceptable.
The various kinds of creeping inflationists all readily
concede that they are accepting a steady erosion in the
value of the monetary unit, and hence of the savings put
aside by a majority of the people in the form of such fixeddenomination assets as savings accounts, life insurance,
pension funds, and United States Savings bonds. Some
assert, however, that for the “average” person there is a
more-than-compen sating gain from the greatly increased
rise in the real income of the country as a whole to be
brought about by the faster growth that is to be expected,
and from the reduction of the real burden of mortgage
and other debt implied by rising prices. And for those




87

unable to share directly in these offsets, as well as for
many who do, there will be the possibility of “indexing”
annuities or other kinds of income or assets by inserting
“escalator” arrangements in the various contracts, linking
them to some index of prices.
On occasion, writers who state a case for creeping in­
flation as a conscious policy also present an impressive
array of statistics. These are used to show that rising
prices and rapid growth have occurred together in most
of the developed countries much of the time. The inference
is then drawn that inflation stimulates growth, and a
further conclusion is suggested: that satisfactory sustained
growth cannot be attained without sustained inflation.
Whether these “demonstrations” are representative, or
relevant, or perhaps a form of statistical sleight of hand,
may become clearer after the following cross-section
analysis of the possible impact of creeping inflation upon
the kind of economy that exists today in the United States.
P R IC E C H A N G E S A N D

EX PEC T A TIO N S

There is, of course, nothing inherently wrong with in­
dividual price increases. As long as such price changes
reflect the balance of prevailing conditions of supply and
demand for a particular product or service, they serve as
part of the essential signaling system that directs the alloca­
tion of productive resources in a market economy, just as
do individual price declines. The great sweeping move­
ments of the entire price structure in the United States,
however, have grown out of extraordinary events. The
major increases have come with the convulsions of war,
and the major declines have usually come with deep de­
pressions. But in between, when the market economy is
doing its normal job of allocating resources, with relative
changes in different prices stimulating and guiding growth,
it should be expected that there will be intervals of several
months, or even a year or more, when the net effect of
all individual price changes will emerge as a minor in­
crease, or a decrease, in the average of all prices. There
will also, as has been true for most of the past year, be
periods of continuing sideways movement.
So long as any general and moderate rise in prices just
happens, and no one can count with any degree of cer­
tainty at any particular time on a continuing rise, busi­
nesses and consumers can form their economic judgments
in the orderly way that assures the nearest practicable ap­
proach, in an imperfect world, to optimum performance of
the economy. When there is a roughly even chance, over
any short period ahead, that as many individual prices may
rise as fall, and that many will not move at all, there is no
reason to look outside the zone of one’s own competence
for possibilities of maximizing earnings or economizing

88

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1959

on purchases. But if there is definite assurance or a strong
presumption that the average of prices will continue to rise
indefinitely, even at a rate that seems quite small, everyone
sooner or later is tempted— even compelled— to become a
gambler. More and more businesses and individuals find it
necessary to protect themselves against expected price in­
creases on the products they buy and find it tempting to
speculate on expected price increases for the products they
sell. In that setting, more and more prices become the
objects, in effect, of a betting pool, and perform much less
effectively their economic role in a market economy.
The cumulative effect of even a small rate of inflation, if
it becomes continuous, would indeed be to impair seri­
ously the usefulness of money as a store of value, one of
the prime requirements for an acceptable monetary unit—
both for domestic commerce and in international trade.
Much of what has been said in support of creeping
inflation seems to neglect the critical role of expectations in
the spending, saving, and investment processes. All but the
most rudimentary decisions as to spending and saving,
and all investment, in housing, for example, or plant, or
inventory, result from judgments based partly upon ex­
pectations of the needs and opportunities that lie ahead.
If those expectations include a certainty that the value of
the dollar—its purchasing power—will be allowed to drop
steadily, then every considered judgment must include an
inflation hedge. Judgments may not be made in terms of
the values of things as they are, but must be made in the
light of what they will be a year or several years ahead.
That is, a home purchased today for $10,000 will, if home
prices move up only in line with average prices at, say,
3 per cent each year, cost $300 more a year from now,
in five years (compounding at the same rate) $1,600 more,
in ten (again compounding) $3,400 more, and so on.
Even with public policy aiming at broad price stability
there have been some peacetime years since World
War II when average prices have risen by several percent­
age points. But in each such case the price inflation
occurred in spite of public policy intentions and there was
no firm reason for projecting price inflation of similar mag­
nitude into the future. Yet each time there has been a
tendency for a wave of inflationary apprehension to spread
through the expectations of savers and investors. The re­
sults, while relatively mild because the episodes were rather
short, gave a foretaste of the force that changes in expec­
tations might exert if inflation, even of small annual pro­
portions, were to become a virtual certainty. Wage earners,
businessmen, retired persons, consumers, savers, and in­
vestors have only to consult their own experience during
one or another of those episodes to recall evidence, more
persuasive than any statistical demonstration, that, when




inflationary expectations infect the ordinary day-to-day
spending decisions, more and more attention is given to
subterfuges and hedges of various kinds, including the
hoarding of readily storable goods, in order to find some
protection from the probable loss in the value of the dollar.
That kind of behavior does not wait for the extremes of
recurring inflation and a frantic flight from the currency.
It occurs whenever expectations of generally rising prices
become widespread.
SA V IN G S A N D

IN V E ST M E N T

THE IMPACT ON SAVINGS

The creeping inflationists generally seem to believe that
there need be no decline in the rate of savings from cur­
rent income with their kind of inflation. Though this view
is perhaps subject to question, there will indeed be many
individuals who must still continue to save. Upon them—
along with all pensioners and others on fixed incomes—
the burden of a steady depreciation in the value of each
dollar saved will fall heavily and harshly. To the extent
they can, however, savers will certainly want to make a de­
cisive shift in the composition of their savings— preferring
those forms which offer a prospect of appreciation in value
or accretion in yield corresponding to the rate of “creep”
intended for the average of all prices. And it is scarcely
realistic to expect that the great network of institutional
arrangements now mobilizing savings in fixed dollar forms
could be completely converted, without loss of effective­
ness, to a different form of savings. To the extent that
these facilities could not be transformed, some decline in
total financial savings over time might well occur.
To minimize such shifts, and their consequences, some
of the creeping inflationists have argued for the issuance of
bonds with a price escalator attached. Also, they propose
that the saver should be offered either upward adjustments
of interest rates for conventional savings accounts, or
accounts at lower interest rates which would be adjusted in
principal amount as the relevant price index rose. There is
in all of this, to be sure, a rather frightening prospect of
conversions and exchanges for the hundreds of billions of
fixed-interest-bearing obligations that are already outstand­
ing. But, even if that combination of problems could be
surmounted in some way, the banks and insurance com­
panies and businesses and individuals undertaking new
liabilities, variably adjusted to one index or another, would
be confronted by other virtually impossible complications.
These complications are not, moreover, mere theoreti­
cal conjecture; they have occurred in Finland, for example,
where an extensive network of escalators was introduced
a few years ago, when a general acquiescence in creeping

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

inflation became part of public economic policy. The ex­
periment has already run its course, the Finnish public has
been disillusioned, and the apparatus is being gradually
dismantled. What happens, as escalator arrangements
crisscross the savings mechanism, is that accountants find
themselves unable to balance their books unless manage­
ments find a way to write up virtually all of their assets
(and realized gross income) at least as fast as the relevant
price index is increasing. Banks have to require borrowers
to escalate upward their liability on loans, or pay interest
that includes a surcharge sufficient (after taxes) to com­
pensate for a rate of “creep” of, say, 2 or 3 per cent. No
one— borrower, lender, or depositor— can know how
much he owes or is owed, nor whether his realizable
current assets can meet his rising current liabilities, nor
whether he is indeed solvent, from one month to the next
under full escalation, even if there were enough electronic
computers to go around.
At best, such schemes impose on the economy an enor­
mously complex superstructure of escalator connections,
with opportunities for inequity, incongruity, and ineffi­
ciency greatly enlarged. And, even if a fully comprehen­
sive, and all-inclusive, mechanism could be contrived,
would not the results be only a peculiarly circuitous ap­
proach to the same market allocation that would work
itself out under conditions of relatively stable prices? The
exercise, if fully successful, would only be similar to
that of canceling out equal values on both sides of an
algebraic equation. At the worst, instead of mere futility,
the result might instead be a kind of chaos, leading either
to a slow strangulation of the financial mechanism or an
acceleration of price increases as lender and borrower
attempt to match strides— each trying to offset the gains
of the other.
The apparent conclusion is that voluntary saving through
the institutional facilities now used by most savers would
be discouraged in some degree by a permanent condition
of creeping inflation, unless interest rates should rise so
high, and other escalator arrangements should be contrived
so effectively, that some approximation of the present
volume of saving could be achieved. In any event, regard­
less of whether, or by how much, total saving would be
reduced, there would be so many new frictions injected into
the system that much of the voluntary saving would prob­
ably still seek shelter in the stock market and in the direct
purchase of such durable assets as houses and land. A
considerable part of total saving would probably, in addi­
tion, be “forced” or “involuntary”— a euphemism for the
loss of real income suffered by those persons, or those
kinds of institutions, which would simply not be able to in­
crease their money incomes as rapidly as prices rise.




89

REPERCUSSIONS UPON INVESTMENT

In an atmosphere of continually rising wholesale and
consumer prices, financial markets would probably take on
some of the aspects of a casino and tend to lose their
efficiency in directing capital into the most productive uses.
At the same time, business concerns or individuals would
find it necessary to take into account a new dimension—
the certainty of a depreciating dollar—in deciding upon the
kinds of physical investment to make, and whether to
borrow funds for use in physical investment. The stock
markets would probably reflect less and less a consensus
of investors’ judgments of the long-term growth potential
or the soundness of management of a particular corpora­
tion, and more and more a guess as to the likelihood that
the corporation would be able to hold its own in the price
race. In the bond markets, interest rates would tend to
rise toward the point at which they could equate, on one
side, the advantage to borrowers of financing current
investment outlays in a form that could be repaid over the
years in depreciated currency with, on the other side, the
disadvantage to lenders of placing their funds in invest­
ments whose real value would depreciate over time. Al­
though individual adjustments would occur in different
ways, and could include arrangements for escalation of the
principal amount as an alternative to pushing interest rates
up drastically, one over-all result might be a reduced vol­
ume of bond financing, which could nonetheless only be
carried through at very high cost.
Meanwhile, to the extent that higher interest rates and
general escalation of prices and costs fell short of their
more or less idealized objectives, there would be strong
inducements to businessmen and individuals alike to accel­
erate their purchases of durable, investment-type goods. If
a new machine will be needed six months from now, and
the current flow of income permits, buy it today to avoid
the price increase. If rents are rising, buy a new home and
plan to take a profit on its resale five or ten years in the
future. Moreover, to the extent that interest rates do not
rise to the point where they fully offset the prospect of
rising prices, investors will want to borrow the money to
make these purchases. Even an economically submarginal
investment becomes desirable if the service or the product
it produces will so increase in price as to assure a profit
on the investment, particularly if the purchase price of the
investment can be repaid in depreciated currency.
Of course, total saving would probably be quite insuffi­
cient to provide all of the additional financing sought by
all of the individuals and businessmen attempting to make
tomorrow’s investment outlay today. Potential investment
outlays would have to be deferred in those areas of the
economy where the return from the sale of the product

90

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1959

could not be expected to increase so rapidly as the over­
all price average. What are some of these areas? They
include schools, hospitals, and other public service insti­
tutions that do not turn out an economic product whose
price can readily be escalated. Among them, too, would
be many of the institutions and agencies engaged in basic
research. And in all likelihood most of the electric
utilities and other public utilities concerns, including trans­
portation, would find their prices too slow in adjusting
because of the usual lags encountered when prices and
rates are regulated by a public body.
In short, both because other prices would rise faster than
their own, and because all interest rates would be much
higher than they would have to be with prices generally
more nearly stable, some of the most important areas for
the expansion of this country’s basic capital stock of
knowledge and facilities would fall behind in the com­
petition for investment resources. The creeping infla­
tionists’ answer might then indeed have to be to increase
central government regulation of investment flows,
perhaps even through direct expansion of Federal invest­
ment activities. Even so, school districts, philanthropies,
and other public agencies with relatively fixed incomes,
or incomes that might lag in adjustment, would probably
still be driven to various penny-wise, pound-foolish
economies that reduce the efficiency of essential services,
undermine the morale of their employees, and justifiably
anger the public.
It would seem scarcely conceivable that such an invest­
ment mix could result in optimum growth for the economy.
The condition of creeping inflation might well stimulate,
at least temporarily, a larger numerical total of dollar
investment. But neither investment nor the broader
goals of economic growth are mere matters of numbers.
The composition of investment, and of the national pro­
duct, are always of crucial importance, both for the current
satisfaction of the entire community and for the develop­
ment of a strong base for continuing growth in the future.

probably, introduced new elements of rigidity in the price
structure. Most observers, including those who accept
creeping inflation, would no doubt be most gratified if ways
could be found to improve the flexibility of prices through
the injection, in one way or another, of more vigorous
price competition. But the creeping inflationists, many
with regretful resignation, consider such an alternative
unrealistic, and look instead for a way of making room,
within the entire price structure, for the persistent upward
bias in prices that they consider inevitable, so long as impor­
tant sectors of the economy are dominated by administered
pricing techniques. A real question is whether creeping
inflation can really be only a palliative, or whether it may
not simply provide a stimulant to a further spread of
administered pricing, making the fundamental problems
eventually much greater.
Along with the widening public concern over adminis­
tered prices, there is general recognition, too, that the
growing strength of labor unions, along with the natural
pressures of market demand for labor, have brought about
a regular, and at times somewhat arbitrary, pattern of con­
tinuing increases in money wages— often without relation­
ship to the change in average productivity that may have
occurred during the preceding year or two, or during the
current year. Some of the more active proponents of
creeping inflation consider continuing increases of money
wages quite necessary in order to provide increased sales
and profits, and thereby induce businessmen to expand
capacity—providing the underpinning for further growth.
Many others, however, are less impressed by any
need to stimulate purchasing power, and concentrate
their attention on the cost aspects of rising wages and
labor benefits. While often concerned that such increases
may disturb economic balance, they have come to regard
them as virtually inevitable, and turn to creeping inflation
as a way of accommodating this kind of persistent upward
influence upon the price structure. As they see it, the pres­
sure for wage increases from organized labor is so irre­
sistible that public policies which prevented these increases
THE PR O B L E M OF "A D M IN IST E R E D ”
from being reflected in higher average prices would result
P R IC E S A N D W A G ES
in unemployment.
Much of the argument for creeping inflation has been
Whether support for creeping inflation originates in a
stimulated by the fresh attention given in recent years to resigned acceptance of administered prices or of wage in­
what have been called the twin problems of “administered” creases which exceed productivity, or whether it rests upon
prices and “cost push” (usually “wage push”). Although genuine endorsement of high wages and high costs as a
it is difficult to define precisely what is meant by “admin­ deliberate means of inflating the economy to promote
istered” prices, they occur in circumstances in which a few maximum growth, the analysis would seem to have been
large firms can maintain prices for their products without left surprisingly incomplete. It has to be carried one step
being closely responsive to short-run changes in supply further. If a slow but steady rate of general inflation were
and demand conditions. The spread of domination by to be tolerated as a form of surrender to the inevitability of
giant firms in some segments of the pricing process has, price increases in the “administered” price and “organized




FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

labor” industries, the end result would be the transfer of
purchasing power to the workers and management in these
industries at the expense of those whose savings are being
depreciated or who are unable to increase income in pace
with price increases. The proponents of creeping inflation
would deny, however, that they intend this type of enforced
transfer and would suggest that escalator arrangements be
developed in sufficient complexity to prevent the inflation
from having an income redistributing effect. Assuming
perfect success in this endeavor, the industries and labor
groups whose practices make creeping inflation necessary
would get the same share in the total national income that
they would get at stable prices, if inflation had been
prevented.
That kind of amplification points up one of the basic
fallacies in the argument for creeping inflation. What rea­
son is there to believe that these industries and labor groups
would be more likely to accept a smaller share of the
national product in a setting of creeping inflation than they
would in a setting of broad price stability? Is it not fully as
likely that they would continue to press for even larger
amounts, in order to preserve at least the same relative
share in the total that their strength, then as now, would
lead them to expect. Could there ever be a rate of inflation
large enough to disguise and mislead these underlying
fundamental forces? If creeping inflation were to be ac­
cepted as public policy, therefore, the apparent result
would seem to be either social injustice, if escalation were
not complete, or a tendency toward a steadily more rapid
rate of inflation if attempts at widespread escalation were
thoroughly successful. It is also notable, though thus far
apparently unnoticed by the creeping inflationists them­
selves, that one by one the countries which pioneered in
escalation— in this case, a “cost-of-living” adjustment fac­
tor, beginning with Australia roughly half a century ago—
are now abandoning the approach. They find it impairs
needed flexibility, both in reflecting technological changes
among industries as the years go by and in meeting the
shifts of competition, at home and abroad. These les­
sons may not be conclusive; but they post a precautionary
warning against this aspect of creeping inflation, too, at
least until there has been much more study of this experi­
ence than has yet occurred in this country.
IN T E R N A T IO N A L C O M P L IC A T IO N S

From the evidence already appearing, as the other
developed countries of the world reach the positions of
strength toward which the United States has been assist­
ing them since World War II, international competition
is becoming significant in the domestic economy of the
United States. Deliberate adoption of steady inflation




91

would certainly impair the ability of this country’s pro­
ducers to compete, both in our own markets and abroad,
with those other countries who have learned in their own
way to combat inflation, and who are strongly committed
to maintaining price stability. They would certainly be
both shocked and chagrined if it appeared that the United
States, after having helped them to surmount the obstacles
and dislocation created by inflation, had failed to learn
from their own lessons. But they would be quick to take
advantage of the competitive advantages ensuing as a
steady upward movement of United States prices gradually
priced American products out of foreign markets.
One can hardly disregard, moreover, the very serious
repercussions that continued inflation would surely have on
the United States international financial position, and in­
deed on this country’s stature as a leader of the free world.
Apart from its effect on the United States trade balance, a
sustained inflation in the United States cannot fail in the
long run to undermine confidence in the dollar. Such in­
ternational repercussions, in combination with the increas­
ing competitive handicaps of American business, might
have the effect of strengthening tendencies toward a new
economic isolationism. These tendencies might lead to a
reduction or elimination of foreign aid and investment, in
spite of the compelling considerations of world politics
and our international responsibilities calling for a continua­
tion of an aid and investment program. They also would
reinforce the pressure that even now is in many instances
being mobilized to exclude, by means of tariffs and quotas,
imports that are competitive with domestic products. The
United States might thus be forced to retreat into a highcost, “island” economy, while other countries, by pursuing
growth in a more well-considered way, were reaping the
benefits of international specialization and a gradual re­
moval of internal controls.
E C O N O M IC F L U C T U A T IO N S
E C O N O M IC G R O W TH

AND

The certain knowledge of continuing inflation, even at
a relatively small percentage rate per year, would as already
mentioned discourage the holding of money, or of obliga­
tions payable in a fixed amount of money, as a store of
value. Anyone lending money would want to stipulate
either a very high rate of interest or repayment in “esca­
lated dollars”, or some combination of both. The impres­
sion has too often gone unchallenged that a creeping infla­
tion would also mean “cheap” money. Quite to the
contrary, of course, as expectations of rising prices are
assured, interest rates must rise to provide some compen­
sation for the decline in the value of the dollars that would
ultimately be repaid. The question is only as to whether

92

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1959

interest rates or escalated adjustments would just be 2 or
3 percentage points greater than under conditions permit­
ting expectations of reasonable price stability, or whether
the rise would be much greater. A companion develop­
ment to rising interest rates or charges, perhaps particu­
larly by concerns or individuals able directly to invest
their own gross savings in this way, would be a tendency
toward acceleration in investment outlays on durable or
storable products. These probable characteristics of creep­
ing inflation are significant in appraising the likely con­
sequences of a creeping inflation policy for the growth
of the economy and for the economy’s vulnerability to
major economic fluctuations.
In the initial transition period, for perhaps a year
or more, it is entirely possible that a creeping inflation
would increase the flow of resources into all kinds
of investments, as an increasing number of businessmen
and individuals employed their available cash (and any
credit resources available to them on profitable terms) to
accelerate investments in equipment, residences, and other
assets that would be more costly if delayed. The income
generated by this initial acceleration of expenditures would
presumably add to the demands for goods of all sorts.
Further investment would thus be called for to supply these
demands, and the continuous accelerating tendency of the
price outlook, reinforced by expanding product demand,
would be most likely to have a further multiplying effect
upon investment. Economic activity would blossom in the
hothouse atmosphere of assured price inflation, fed by a
growing volume of investment expenditures intended to
create capacity and accumulate inventories to meet a firmly
anticipated demand for goods— sometime in the future.
What possible fault can be found with this picture?
It has already been noted that the mix of this investment
boom would probably include more and more speculative
buying of land, for example, and discriminate against
schools and the other kinds of investments that are
essential to provide the structure needed to support the
steadily advancing technology that is required for long­
term growth. In general, over time, basic capital would
be allowed to run down as price conditions led to in­
creasing speculation, at the expense of considered evalua­
tion of longer range productive potentialities. But that
is not all.
There is always a considerable time interval beween the
initial appearance of enlarged demand, which leads pro­
ducers to plan expanded capacity, and the final appearance
of this new capacity. Moreover, there is also a rather per­
sistent and quite understandable tendency in a free mar­
ket economy for businessmen initiating investment plans
to reach beyond presently visible demand to provide for




some further expansion. As a consequence, investment
projects sometimes bunch together, especially when opti­
mism is running high, and the new wave of productive
capacity comes into use before demand is fully ready for
it. There is an appearance for a while of “overcapacity”,
and this often leads to some reduction of further new ex­
pansion plans, a reversal in inventory accumulation, and,
if there is a spread of pessimistic concern, to some more
general business retrenchment. This pattern has been a
significant part of the cyclical swings that have occurred
since World War II, although each swing has fortunately
been kept within a fairly narrow range of fluctuation. With
the continuous insertion of another incentive to overreach
— the desire to anticipate price increases— there would
seem to be an impelling reason to expect that the forces
making for both economic booms and recessions would
become more pronounced.
The combination of this greater gyration in real invest­
ment with the likely speculative boom in the stock market,
and the related speculative excesses that result from losing
the discipline of a stable standard of value, might create
circumstances that would have to be described by a
stronger word than “recession”. Moreover, economic ad­
justments, when they occurred, would strike an economy
from which the inflation prospect had absorbed any reserve
of liquidity. Once a turnaround began, so long as financial
markets remained reasonably free, most needs for liquidity
would have to be met by selling mortgages, or equities.
The effects might well be reminiscent of those more hazard­
ous times before modern economies had developed great
markets for providing secondary liquidity in periods of
economic unsettlement. The tasks of limiting any thrust
toward depression from purely financial factors might then
become much more difficult than anything experienced
in this country since World War II, while public policy has
been aiming for reasonable price stability.
For the long run, therefore, it seems likely that a policy
of creeping inflation would widen economic fluctuations.
Certainly there is no basis for expecting any narrowing. To
be sure, reliance upon growth would probably be cited
again as the answer, even by those who might, on reflection,
concede the possibility of greater cyclical swings. But what
is left now of any stimulus to growth, in view of the pros­
pects already described for saving and investment during
creeping inflation?
In its early phases, creeping inflation might stimulate an
expansion of investment in tangible assets and other equi­
ties, partly in real terms but even more as measured in
shrinking dollars. Then, later on, perhaps in a year or two
or three, as reliance upon the certainty of rising prices
became widespread, a new phase would become clearer—

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

that of further and further shifts into the kinds of assets
offering the best possibilities for hedging against deprecia­
tion in the purchasing power of the dollar. The numerical
values of investment, and of income, might still go on
rising at impressive rates, although the underlying real
structure of balanced productive capacity would have be­
gun to erode. Then ultimately, perhaps after a cyclical
downswing, or in a still later phase, the aggregate physical
capacity of the economy to produce the goods and services
that consumers really want and need might no longer rise
at all. By this time, the burdens of maintaining a maze of
interrelated escalators, and of diverting effort and materials
into providing speculative hedges, would have become so
great a drain upon the economy’s resources, particularly
upon entrepreneurial ingenuity and skill, that it would be
difficult indeed even to maintain existing capacity in rea­
sonable balance. Having run its course, creeping inflation
would have brought the economy to a state of stagnation,
and then, perhaps, creeping paralysis.
C O N C L U SIO N S A N D

IM PL IC A T IO N S

In looking back over all that has been suggested so
briefly here, many who are already critical of creeping in­
flation might note the absence of several important con­
siderations. They could suggest that a serious deteriora­
tion occurs in the moral character of a nation when its
economic life is subjected continually to the strains of rising
prices and deterioration in the value of its monetary unit.
They could cite many instances in which countries have
drifted into an acceptance of some inflation, only to find
themselves eventually drawn into a labyrinth of restric­
tive governmental controls. And they could point, too,
to the experience of a number of economies over the
past half-century where, despite a multiplication of devious
governmental controls, the outcome ultimately was a run­
away inflation. They could then, too, elaborate convinc­
ingly upon the horrendous effects of that kind of inflation.
All of these criticisms are, of course, perfectly valid.
They have, however, been stated so often and so well that
they need no repetition. Any critique of creeping inflation
should recognize, nonetheless, that all of these greater
eventualities— the sapping of moral vitality, the stultifying
influence of rigidifying governmental controls, and the
collapse that ensues from runaway inflation— are indeed
grave prospects that cannot be ignored whenever a modern
economy acquiesces in a pattern of inflation.
The lesson of this analysis of creeping inflation, though,
does not come from a parade of frightening extremes. It
should be enough for a considered evaluation to recognize
that, at the least, a consistent acceptance of creeping in­




93

flation will end in futility. There is nothing in the nature
of the influence exerted by a steady edging upward in prices
that can provide a solution to the important problems that
are, indeed, quite rightly the center of attention in the
American economy. But creeping inflation would not only
end in futility. The logic of the analysis and the facts of
experience demonstrate that the alleged gains from accept­
ance of creeping inflation cannot actually materialize. At
best, the result is a drastic rise in interest rates as prices
mount steadily, while one escalator arrangement after
another is superimposed upon those segments of the
economy that can practicably make use of such devices.
And in the end, with the futility of the escape mechanism
fully demonstrated, and as it becomes clear that the hopedfor gains cannot materialize, positively harmful manifesta­
tions emerge. Those who can raise prices most readily, or
increase wages most effectively, or escalate themselves to a
position of neutrality, get more and more of total income,
while the unsheltered get less. And, in due course, total
real income rises only slowly, if at all. The functioning
of a market economy, upon which both the vitality and
the growth potential of this country depend, becomes im­
paired and eventually corrupted.
All along the way, as the panorama of creeping inflation
unfolds, the Federal Reserve would probably find itself
called upon to attempt a succession of holding actions.
Eventually, even greater reliance might actually be placed
upon monetary and credit controls than is done today, but
because other upward forces of price pressure would also
have been condoned and strengthened, the effectiveness
of the Federal Reserve would probably be weakened or
even nullified. With everyone given a stake in pushing up
prices, with credit relationships entangled in escalator
clauses, and with interest rates held continuously at very
high levels, the scope for flexible variation in monetary
and credit policy, and the potentialities for sensitive re­
sponse to such policy throughout the financial structure
and the economy, would soon become narrow and limited.
To be sure, no central bank can be expected to bring
about stability in prices and in the economy by its own
actions alone. But postwar experience both here and
abroad strongly suggests that an effective central bank is
one essential part of the governmental apparatus, particu­
larly under any system that aims to avoid direct govern­
mental control over prices and wages. Without attempting
to outline the positive contribution that central banking
should be able to make, and without touching at all upon
the potentialities of such companion instruments as fiscal
policy, it should nonetheless be evident that a crippling of
the central bank would have serious implications for the
implementation of public policy in any market economy.

94

MONTHLY REVIEW, JUNE 1959

The creeping inflationist might still, however, wave all
of these grave consequences aside, insisting that the princi­
pal problem still remains— that any monetary or fiscal
policies strong enough to halt creeping inflation will in­
evitably create a volume of unemployment so large as to
be wholly unacceptable, socially and politically, in a mod­
ern society. The persistence and grip of that idea, despite
dramatic evidence to the contrary in several European and
other countries since the war, is truly remarkable. As a
theoretical concept, its appeal must come from the logical
simplicity of an “either-or” proposition. There is no evi­
dence to support it in United States experience.
Certainly there is no demonstrated basis for viewing the
supposed conflict between price stability and employment,
on which the creeping inflationists have fastened so firmly,
as inexorable. Even the supposed new influences of ad­
ministered prices and “cost push” have scarcely been
visible long enough to have set in motion the corrective
forces which distortions of that kind often produce from
inside themselves within a generation, or even less, so long
as the force of competition remains at work. And, if com­
petition along old paths may seem for a time to slacken, it
will spring up again, so long as public policy gives its deter­
mined support, from the influence of new firms, new prod­
ucts or new processes displacing the old, or from the im­
pact of new sellers or buyers abroad.




The issues confronted by the creeping inflationists do
not appear to be any different in significance for the cur­
rent generation from the kinds of issues visualized by the
popular economics of “secular stagnation” in the 1930’s,
or perhaps of “bimetallism” and others even further back.
Each of those new theories left behind its grain of truth, as
emerging developments pushed aside the base upon which
the theory itself had been erected, and there is no doubt that
some gain will remain in the articulation of public policy
and in the understanding of economic processes, after the
creeping inflation thesis has moved on into the archives of
economics. But its futility in reaching any of the underly­
ing causes for concern, such as administered prices and
wages, and the clearly harmful further consequences that
it would also produce, make creeping inflation unaccept­
able as a basis for public policy.

A limited number of additional copies of Dr.
Vocke’s remarks on The Future of the Dollar and
of the article entitled Creeping Inflation are avail­
able. Requests should be directed to the Publications
Division, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, New
York 45, N. Y.

T he F ed eral F unds M arket
The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System has just published a 120-page booklet entitled The
Federal Funds Market, A Study by a Federal Reserve System Committee. This study was originally made by a
special committee at the request of the Conference of Presidents and the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System. Its primary purpose was to obtain information on the structure of the market for Federal funds,
the volume of operations, and the use of the market by banks and others— to give a cross-section view of the
structure and operation of the market rather than to determine its behavior over a period of time. The study is
principally based on data collected in November 1956, and information obtained from interviews with officials
of banks and other institutions active in the Federal funds market; it thus throws light on conditions in the
Federal funds market during a part of the period of credit restraint that prevailed until the latter part of 1957.
Information developed in the study shows that the Federal funds market has become an important segment
of the short-term money market. Since the focus of the study is on fact finding covering a limited period, no
attempt has been made to draw broad conclusions concerning the efficiency of the Federal funds market as a
means of redistributing the supply of bank reserve funds, the effect of the market on the loan and investment
policies of the institutions that use it most frequently, or the implication of Federal funds transactions for
credit regulation.
Copies can be obtained from the Division of Administrative Services, Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, Washington 25, D. C., at $1.00 each up to ten copies and 85 cents each for ten or more
copies in single shipment.