View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

154

MONTHLY REVIEW, JULY 1972

Am endments to Regulations D and J
On June 22, 1972, the Board of G overnors o f the Federal Reserve System announced amendments to its
Regulations D and J which are designed to restructure on a more equitable basis the reserve requirements o f
member banks and to modernize the nation’s check collection system. The changes are basically the same as
proposals the Board published on M arch 28 for public com ment, but they have been modified in detail and
method o f application in the light o f com ments received.
The change in Regulation D , which governs member bank reserves, will restructure requirements against
net demand deposits so that the same requirement ratio will apply to all m em ber banks o f equal size regardless
of their location. M oreover, all banks with demand deposits o f more than $400 m illion will be considered “reserve
city banks”. This m ethod o f classification is in contrast to the current one in which the “reserve city” designation
is generally applied to larger banks in larger cities, with all others com m only called “country banks”. At the present
time, reserve city banks are required to hold reserves o f 17 percent against net dem and deposits under $5 m illion
and of 17 Vi percent on net demand deposits over that amount, while the corresponding required reserve per­
centages for country banks are H V2 percent and 13 percent, respectively. W hen the scheduled changes becom e
effective, a more graduated scale will apply and requirement ratios for m ost categories will be lowered. The re­
structuring will apply the follow ing ratios to member banks:
A m o u n t of net demand deposits

Reserve percentages applicable

First $2 m illion or less
Over $2 m illion-$10 m illion
Over $10 m illion-$100 m illion
Over $100 m illion-$400 m illion
Over $400 m illion

8 percent
10 percent
12 percent
13 percent
MVi percent

The new reserve requirements are to take effect in two steps. Beginning in the statement week o f September 21
to September 27, the first three ratios— 8 percent, 10 percent, and 12 percent— will apply to net demand
deposits of $100 m illion and less, based on the average level of deposits during the week ending September 13.
At the same time, the 17Vi percent ratio that now applies to demand deposits between $100 m illion and $400
m illion at present reserve city banks will be reduced to 16!/2 percent. During the statement week from September 28
to October 4, the latter ratio will be reduced to 13 percent based on the average level o f deposits during the week
ending September 20.
Beginning September 21 an amendment to Regulation J, covering collection of checks and other items by
Federal Reserve Banks, will becom e effective. From then on, all banks served by the System ’s check collection
m echanism will be required to pay for checks drawn on them with funds im m ediately available on the day that
the Federal Reserve presents the checks for payment. Currently, m ost banks outside cities with Federal Reserve
facilities or paym ent areas served by the newly created Regional Check Processing Centers pay for checks in
funds collectible one day or more after presentation. This change will result in a reduced volum e o f Federal
Reserve float to such banks, although this effect will be offset in part by more rapid payment o f funds to these
banks. The Board is giving high priority to accelerating the developm ent o f additional Regional Check Processing
Centers so that these banks can also have facilities for overnight check gathering, processing, and clearing.
The Board established conditions under which it will be appropriate for a Reserve Bank temporarily to
waive penalties for member bank reserve deficiencies resulting from the impending changes in Regulations D and
J. In this connection, the Board set the follow ing guidelines:
— A waiver will be granted initially only for penalties on reserve deficiencies equal to a reduction in avail­
able funds that exceeds 2 percent o f a member bank’s net demand deposits.
— The amount o f deficiency eligible for waiver o f penalties will decrease 1 percent o f net demand deposits
for each quarter beginning January 1, 1973.
— N o further waivers will be granted under this authority after June 30, 1974.
The net effect o f these regulatory changes is expected to amount to a release of about $1.5 billion o f reserves
to the banking system. There will be a total release o f about $3.5 billion from the restructuring of reserves and
the waiver o f penalties, offset in part by the $2 billion reduction in float resulting from the change in Regulation J.
It is intended that open market operations will be adapted as needed, when the amendments go into effect, to
neutralize the impact on monetary policy.




FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

155

Th e Business Situation
Recent data indicate that economic activity has con­
tinued to expand briskly. Retail sales rose markedly in
May but then dropped in June, according to preliminary
information. Sales were probably held down in June by
the storm which affected much of the East. Industrial
production posted a moderate, though broadly based in­
crease in May. Over the first five months of the year,
output has risen at a rapid 9 percent annual rate. In May,
personal income climbed at roughly the pace of the first
four months of the year and the volume of residential
housing starts increased after easing off in the two previous
months. Moreover, there are tentative signs of some
strengthening in inventory spending. The unemployment
rate fell to a seasonally adjusted 5.5 percent in June, as
employment increased and the civilian labor force de­
clined by nearly 100,000 workers.
The latest price information suggests that inflationary
pressures persist. Seasonally adjusted consumer prices,
boosted by a rapid rise in prices of some nonfood com­
modities, increased at an annual rate of 4 percent in May.
Retail food prices declined for the second consecutive
month, but this improvement is not expected to be main­
tained. Wholesale prices of farm products and processed
foods and feeds rose rapidly again in June, and industrial
wholesale prices advanced at a disappointing 5 percent an­
nual rate. June data reveal only a modest increase in wages
for the second consecutive month, although over the Phase
Two period as a whole wages have climbed considerably.
PRODUCTION, ORDERS, AND INVENTORIES

The Federal Reserve Board’s index of industrial pro­
duction rose in May by 0.5 percent on a seasonally ad­
justed basis, and the readings for the preceding three
months were revised upward slightly. Thus, in recent
months output has resumed rapid growth after the decline
and subsequent stagnation associated with the recession of
1969-70 (see Chart I). Since the beginning of the year,
industrial production has climbed at a fast 9 percent
seasonally adjusted annual rate, roughly the pace of ex­




pansion registered between early 1961 and mid-1969, to
reach a level only 0.3 percent below its peak of Sep­
tember 1969. The May increase in output was widespread,
including gains in the production of consumer goods, busi­
ness equipment, and intermediate products. On the other
hand, output of defense and space equipment and of
materials edged down a bit following sharp advances in
April.
The May rise in production of consumer goods was 10
percent at an annual rate. Output of most appliances, fur­
niture, and consumer nondurable goods increased, while
automobile assemblies declined somewhat from their April
pace despite the strength of automobile sales. Since De­
cember 1971, consumer goods output, seasonally adjusted,
has advanced at an annual rate of 6.7 percent, with the
increase concentrated largely in durable goods. Output of
business equipment climbed at an annual rate of 8.3 per­
cent in May, after an upward revised increase of nearly 17
percent in April. Over the first five months of 1972, pro­
duction of business equipment has risen rapidly at an
annual rate of 12 percent and, in May, stood at 7.5 per­
cent above its level of a year earlier.
Orders placed with manufacturers of durable goods
edged up by about $0.1 billion in May. Excluding the
volatile transportation equipment sector, bookings rose
by a healthy $0.7 billion, or 2.8 percent, to a seasonally
adjusted $26.6 billion (see Chart II). This series, along
with manufacturers’ shipments, unfilled orders, and inven­
tories, has recently been revised to reflect new bench
marks derived from the annual Survey of Manufacturers
and new seasonal adjustment factors. As a result, there
have been substantial downward revisions in the orders
and shipments series, while inventory levels, and therefore
inventory-sales ratios, were revised upward. In any event,
in May new orders for electrical machinery and primary
metals rose, while bookings for transportation equipment
fell more than $0.6 billion after posting a gain of similar
magnitude in the previous month. Bookings for nonde­
fense capital goods, a new category which replaces pro­
ducers’ capital equipment, were off slightly in May but

156

MONTHLY REVIEW, JULY 1972

C hart I

INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION
S easonally a d ju s te d ; 1967=100

Note: Shaded areas represent recession periods, according to the National Bureau of Economic Research chronology.
The dates of the 1969-70 recession are tentative.
Source-. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

were still about 21 percent above the level of May 1971.
Shipments of durable goods climbed modestly to a new
record, while the backlog of unfilled orders increased for
the eighth consecutive month.
There are tentative indications of some pickup in in­
ventory spending after a prolonged period of sluggishness.
During April, the book value of total business inventories
increased at an $8.3 billion annual rate following an up­
ward revised March gain of $6.2 billion. Trade stocks
rose substantially, particularly at the wholesale level, but
manufacturers’ holdings declined slightly. However, pre­
liminary May manufacturing data suggest a strength­
ening in inventory spending in this sector, as seasonally
adjusted holdings climbed $4.9 billion at an annual rate.
This gain occurred entirely in the durable goods sector. In
1972 thus far, manufacturers’ inventories have risen at a
$2.8 billion annual rate after remaining virtually flat




throughout 1971. For all manufacturers, the ratio of in­
ventories to sales was 1.69 in May, the same as April’s
upward revised level.
R ETAIL SALES, PERSONAL INCOME, AND
R ESID EN TIA L CONSTRUCTION

Recent data provide impressive evidence of continued
strengthening in consumer spending. In May, seasonally
adjusted retail sales climbed $0.6 billion above the up­
ward revised April level to a record $36.9 billion. Sales
of both durables and nondurables increased, with auto­
motive sales accounting for much of the strength in
durables. Among nondurables, sales of general merchan­
dise and food rose sizably. Preliminary June data indicate
a drop in retail sales from the May peak, but spending was
still a healthy $36.4 billion. Moreover, June sales were

157

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

undoubtedly held down somewhat by the tropical storm
which affected much of the East Coast. Nevertheless, over
the second quarter retail sales were a substantial 2.8 per­
cent above the first-quarter average. In June, sales of new
domestic-type automobiles moderated somewhat from
their very rapid May pace to a 9 million unit seasonally
adjusted annual rate, still a strong showing. Over the
April-June period, sales of new domestic-type autos
averaged 9.2 million units at an annual rate by com­
parison with an 8.7 million unit pace in the first quarter.
Meantime, sales of imported cars were at an annual rate
of 1.6 million units in June by comparison with 1.5 mil­
lion units in both April and May.
Personal income posted a $4.8 billion increase in May,
reaching a seasonally adjusted annual rate of $915.9 bil­
lion. It should be noted that month-to-month fluctuations
in this series have been affected recently by retroactive
payments of wage increases approved by the Pay Board,
as well as by other special factors. After adjustment for
these influences, the May gain in personal income was
$5.3 billion, roughly in line with the adjusted increases
of the past several months. Further, over the January-May
period, personal income averaged $905.4 billion, 8 per­
cent above the average of the first five months of 1971.
Wage and salary disbursements were up moderately in
May, with a rise in manufacturing payrolls providing
about half of the overall gain. The durable goods sector,
particularly primary and fabricated metals and machinery,
accounted for most of the rise in manufacturing payrolls.
After declining for two consecutive months, the pace
of private housing starts increased by 221,000 units in
May to a volume of 2.3 million units at a seasonally ad­
justed annual rate. While this was below the extra­
ordinarily strong performance of the first quarter, it never­
theless represented a healthy total by most other stan­
dards. The May advance was concentrated in starts of
single-family units, which climbed to their highest level in
four months. Newly issued building permits increased
slightly in May as well. Recent information suggests a
modest tightening in mortgage market conditions. The
average interest cost on conventional new home mort­
gages inched higher in May as did the effective rate on
loans for existing homes. Moreover, the secondary-market
yields of Federal Housing Administration-insured loans
edged up for the second consecutive month.
LABOR M A R K ET DEVELO PM EN TS

consequence, the unemployment rate fell to 5.5 percent
after holding steady at 5.9 percent over the previous three
months. In June, the rates of unemployment for most
major labor force groups declined, with a particularly pro­
nounced drop in joblessness among teen-agers. This de­
cline stemmed, in part, from a smaller than seasonal influx
of young people into the labor force. At the same time,
the unemployment rate for adult men dipped to 4 percent,
compared with 4.3 percent in both April and May, and
the rate of unemployment for adult women fell to 5.5 per­
cent in June from 5.9 percent in May. On balance, these
data suggest that the rather substantial increases in em­
ployment in recent months have begun to have an impact
on joblessness. Over the April-June period, civilian em­
ployment averaged a sizable 589,000 above the level of
the first quarter, an annual rate of increase of 2.9 percent.
Expansion of the labor force was also rapid' in the second
quarter, amounting to 2.5 percent at an annual rate.
After several months of sizable gains, the most recent
survey of establishments indicates only a small increase in
nonfarm payroll employment in June. With this advance,

Chart II

NEW ORDERS FOR DURABLE GOODS
Seasonally adjusted
Billions of dollars
34

r

32 -

30 -




32

-

K,

Total

28

i

30

28

/

26

26

/

i
/
24 —

Total excludii "9
transportation equipment

/V'AJ

22

/

18

M

/ 4
y

/

_

24

-

22

-

20

niiiiiiiii

18

|
V

1

1
20

V

V

/

niiiiiiiii Illllllllll
1968

According to the monthly survey of households, civilian
employment, seasonally adjusted, rose by 273,000 workers
in June, while the labor force decreased by 91,000. As a

Billions of dollars
34

1969

Illllllllll
1970

Illllllllll
1971

1972

Source: United States Departme nt of Commerce, Bureau of the Census.

158

MONTHLY REVIEW, JULY 1972

Chart III

CHANGES IN EMPLOYMENT
Seasonally adjusted
M illions of persons

June - December
1971
S o u rc e :

M illions of persons

December 1971June 1972

U n ite d S ta te s D e p a r tm e n t o f L a b o r, B u re a u o f L a b o r S t a tis tic s ;

s u r v e y o f e s ta b lis h m e n ts .

nonfarm employment reached a level 2.7 percent above
that of a year earlier. Growth has been more rapid since the
end of 1971, proceeding at a 3.9 percent seasonally ad­
justed annual rate over the first half of this year. Manu­
facturing employment declined in June, but over the
January-June period manufacturing payrolls have risen
by a healthy 342,000 workers, or 3.7 percent at an an­
nual rate. In contrast, during the last half of 1971, factory
employment dropped by more than 40,000 workers (see
Chart III). About 75 percent of the gain in manufacturing
jobs over the last six months has occurred in durable goods
industries. The rise has been widespread within the du­
rables sector, as there have been sizable employment
increases in primary and fabricated metals, machinery,
electrical equipment, and transportation equipment. The
average factory workweek and hours of overtime both
were essentially unchanged in June.
Most other areas of the economy have experienced
gains in employment in recent months, which surpassed
the increases in the last half of 1971. For example, over
the first six months of this year, employment in trade
and services rose by 336,000 and 270,000 workers, re­




spectively, whereas the corresponding advances between
June and December 1971 were less than 200,000 workers
in each case. Total government employment, including
Federal, state, and local but excluding the armed forces,
rose slightly in June to a level 3.7 percent above that of a
year earlier. Thus far in 1972, government employment
has increased at an annual rate of 4.3 percent. All of this
increase has been at the state and local government levels,
as such employment rose by 317,000 workers over the six
months ended in June. In contrast, reductions were or­
dered in Federal employment as part of the package of
new economic policies instituted in August 1971 and, over
the past ten months, Federal civilian employment declined
in addition to the sizable reduction in the armed forces.
This pattern of growth in government employment has
prevailed for some time. Between June 1969 and June
1971, Federal civilian employment dropped by about
140,000 workers while employment at the state and local
levels climbed by nearly 760,000. As a result, state and
local governments have accounted for an increasing por­
tion of overall government employment. In June 1972,
state and local employment constituted more than 80
percent of civilian government employment, whereas in
June 1969 it made up about 77 percent of the total. The
recent declines in Federal civilian employment have cen­
tered on the Department of Defense, as jobs in most other
areas have held relatively steady.
Seasonally adjusted average hourly earnings of produc­
tion and nonsupervisory workers in the private nonfarm
economy, adjusted for overtime hours in manufacturing
and for shifts in the composition of employment among
industries, increased at a 1.8 percent annual rate in June.
This marked the second consecutive month of modest
growth in earnings. Over the seven months since the end
of the wage freeze last November, the index has climbed
at a considerably more rapid 7 percent rate, about the
pace of 1970 and the first eight months of 1971. However,
excluding the sharp advances of December and January
which may have resulted from a post-freeze bunching of
increases, earnings have advanced at an annual rate of
only about 4.5 percent over the five months ended in June.
RECENT PRICE

D EVELO PM EN TS

The latest price statistics suggest that serious inflation­
ary pressures still persist. The consumer price index rose
at a 4 percent seasonally adjusted annual rate in May,
despite the second consecutive monthly decline in retail
food prices. Moreover, food prices advanced sharply at
the wholesale level in May and June, and it is likely
that consumer food prices will soon reflect these increases.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

Reportedly, retail prices of meats and some other products
increased considerably in the last half of June. Because
of the timing of the survey, these rises probably will not
affect the consumer price index until July. To help slow
the advance of food prices, the President recently removed
quota restrictions on imported meats and, shortly there­
after, controls were extended to cover prices of some
unprocessed foods at the wholesale and retail levels. In
any event, over the past three months, consumer prices
have advanced moderately at an annual rate of 2.1 per­
cent, while over the Phase Two period as a whole they
have moved up at a 3.5 percent rate, modestly below the
pace of the first eight months of 1971. Food prices have
climbed at a 4.4 percent pace over the six months ended
in May, somewhat slower than the 5 percent annual rate
of gain registered in 1971 before the price freeze.
The May rise in the consumer price index stemmed
from a rapid advance in prices of some nonfood com­
modities; in contrast, service charges increased moder­
ately. Nonfood commodity prices rose at a 6.2 percent
seasonally adjusted annual rate in May, the fastest pace
in a year. Prices for used cars and gasoline climbed par­




159

ticularly sharply. With the large May increase, the index
for all commodities less food has now risen at an almost
3 percent annual rate since the termination of the price
freeze, the same pace as during the first eight months of
1971. Nevertheless, this still represents considerable im­
provement relative to the increases experienced in non­
food commodity prices in 1970 and 1969.
At the wholesale level the advance of prices has con­
tinued to be disappointingly rapid. In June, such prices,
seasonally adjusted, climbed at a 5.7 percent annual rate.
With this increase, wholesale prices have risen at a 5.2
percent rate following the termination of the price freeze,
the same pace experienced over the first eight months of
1971. Wholesale prices of farm products and processed
foods and feeds increased at nearly a 6 percent annual
rate in June while, at the same time, industrial wholesale
prices advanced at a 5 percent rate. Prices of hides, skins,
leather, and related products and prices of lumber and
wood products rose very sharply again in June. In Phase
Two thus far, industrial wholesale prices have increased
at a 4.3 percent annual rate by comparison with the 4.7
percent pace of the first eight months of 1971.

MONTHLY REVIEW, JULY 1972

160

Th e M oney and Bond Markets in June
Interest rates rose in the money and bond markets dur­
ing June. Short-term rates began to rise early in the month,
and the general consensus seemed to be that these rates
might increase somewhat further, along with expanding
economic activity. There were, in fact, several upward
adjustments as the month progressed and, by the close,
yields on most money market instruments were from XA to
V2 percentage point higher than when the month opened.
Substantial investor resistance emerged to the lower rate
levels established in the bond market during May but,
even after prices were marked down on several issues in
June, only modest and sporadic interest was displayed
much of the time. There were several news developments
during the month which apparently contributed to a fairly
pervasive feeling that pressures in the long-term markets
were also increasing, and investors tended to remain on
the sidelines in anticipation of yet higher rates. These de­
velopments included announcements of accelerated rises
in wholesale and consumer prices during May and dis­
cussions in the press that the Treasury’s need for new cash
during the fiscal year 1973 might be higher than previ­
ously estimated. The turmoil in the foreign currency mar­
kets during the latter part of the month was an additional
factor depressing securities prices.
Indicative of the trend in the long-term markets during
the month, The Bond Buyer index of yields on twenty
municipal bonds climbed by 28 basis points to a level of
5.43 percent at the end of the month. In addition, the
backlog of unsold tax exempts measured by inventories
advertised in the Blue List mounted to the highest levels
since mid-January before declining toward the end of
June. Rates on new Aa-rated utility bonds rose to 7.60
percent from 7.25 percent at the start of the month. Yields
on long-term Treasury bonds, on the other hand, were
relatively steady, ranging for the most part from 4 to 13
basis points higher over the period.
BANK RESERVES AND T H E MONEY M AR K ET

The increases in interest rates on most short-term in­
struments occurred in several steps during June. Yields
on most maturities of dealer-placed prime commercial




paper rose by 3/s to V2 percentage point, while those on
paper placed directly ranged from XA to V2 percentage
point higher. A rise in rate of V2 percentage point was
also posted on bankers’ acceptances. Anticipating runoffs
of negotiable certificates of deposit (CDs) around the
mid-June corporate dividend and tax payment dates,
major banks began raising CD rates early in June and
continued to post increases throughout the month. Simi­
larly, rates on CDs trading in the secondary market rose
about 3/s to V2 percentage point during June. Largely in
response to the rise in money market rates, most major
banks raised their prime rate to 5lA percent from 5 per­
cent effective the final week in June. Two large banks with
“floating” prime rates increased these even further to 5%
percent on June 30. Rates on Euro-dollars shot upward
after midmonth, as tensions mounted in the foreign ex­
change markets leading up to the floating of the British
pound. Euro-dollar rates subsequently fell back but re­
mained above their levels at the beginning of the month
(see Chart I).
The effective rate on Federal funds in June averaged
4.46 percent, 19 basis points above the May level. Mem­
ber bank borrowings at the Federal Reserve discount
window declined slightly to $86 million on average, how­
ever (see Table I), as excess reserves increased. The
forty-six major money center banks were particularly
restrained in their use of the discount window. Prelim­
inary data indicate that total reserves of member banks
grew at a seasonally adjusted annual rate of about 8 V2
percent in June, while “reserves available to support
private nonbank deposits” (RPD) grew at about a 9
percent rate, a slightly more rapid pace for RPD than in
May (see Chart II).
According to preliminary estimates based on data for
the four weeks ended June 28, the narrow money
supply (M O— adjusted demand deposits and currency
held by the public— rose at about a 5 percent seasonally
adjusted annual rate in June, up somewhat from its in­
crease of 3.6 percent in May. Over the second quarter as a
whole, the annual rate of growth of M 1 also amounted to
some 5 percent. For the first six months of the year, Mx
grew at an annual rate of slightly over 7 percent.

161

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

The broader money supply (M2) also advanced some­
what more rapidly in June at a rate of about 9 V2 percent,
compared with 8.4 percent in May. The recent acceleration
resulted from a faster rise in both components of M2,
consumer-type time and savings deposits as well as Mx.
For the three months ended in June, however, the growth
in this measure was at a seasonally adjusted annual rate
of 8 V2 percent. Over the January-June period, M2 has
grown at an 11 percent annual rate.
In contrast to Mx and M2, the growth of the adjusted
bank credit proxy decelerated in June to an annual rate
of 5 percent, down from 14.4 percent a month earlier.
Both time and private demand deposits expanded sub­

stantially during June, but United States Government de­
posits at commercial banks declined by $2 billion on
average from the May level, in spite of a buildup in these
balances in the second half of June. It is estimated that
the proxy expanded at an 11 percent annual rate in the
latest quarter and at about the same rate over the first six
months of 1972.
On June 22 the Board of Governors of the Federal Re­
serve System announced its unanimous approval of two
regulatory changes designed to restructure the reserve
requirements of member banks on a more equitable basis
and to modernize the nation’s check collection system. The
changes, which will begin to go into effect on September 21,

C hart I

SELECTED INTEREST RATES
Percent

M O N E Y MARKET RATES

A p r il

M ay

A p n l-J u n e 1972

June

B O N D MARKET YIELDS

A p r il

M ay

Percent

June

Note-. Data are shown for business days only.
MONEY MARKET RATES QUOTED: Bid rates for three-month Euro.dollars in London; offering
rates (quoted in terms of rate of discount) on 90- to 119-day prime commercial paper
quoted by three of the four dealers that report their rates, or the midpoint of the range
quoted if no consensus is available; the effective rate on Federal funds Ithe rate most
representative of the transactions executed); closing bid rates (quoted in terms of rate of
discount) on newest outstanding three-month Treasury bills.
BOND MARKET YIELDS QUOTED: Yields on new Aa-rated public utility bonds (arrows point from
underwriting syndicate reoffering yield on a given issue to marketyield on the same issue




immediately after it has been released from syndicate restrictions); daily averages of yields
on seasoned Aaa-rated corporate bonds; daily averages of yields on long-term Government
securities (bonds due or callable in ten years or more) and on Government securities due in
three to five years, computed on the basis of closing bid prices; Thursday averages of yields
on twenty seasoned twenty-year tax-exempt bonds (carrying Moody's ratings of Aaa, Aa, A,
and Baa).
Sources: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
Moody’s Investors Service, and The Bond Buyer.

162

MONTHLY REVIEW, JULY 1972
Table I
FACTORS TENDING TO INCREASE OR DECREASE
MEMBER BANK RESERVES, JUNE 1972
In millions of dollars; (+ ) denotes increase
(—) decrease in excess reserves
Changes in daily averages—
week ended

Net
changes

Factors
June
7

June
14

June

June
28

Member bank required, reserves . . .
Operating transactions (subtotal)
Federal Reserve float ..................
Treasury operations* ....................
Gold and foreign a c c o u n t ...........
Currency outside b a n k s ..................
Other Federal Reserve liabilities

+ 380
— 123
+ 346

—
+
+
+

+ 217
— 784

— 355
+ 189
— 195

+
—
—
—
—

and capital ........................................

— 109

Total “ market” factors ................

+ 257

21

“ Market” factors
37
360
316
27
4

— 248

82
555
728
189
—
12
— 313

—
4
+ 251

+ 235

— 37

—

—

2'22

— 735

+
—
+
—
+
—

552
712
536
928
169
505

73

+ 473

Direct Federal Reserve credit
transactions
Open market operations (subtotal)
Outright holdings:
Treasury s e c u r itie s .............................
Bankers’ a ccep ta n ces........................
Federal agency o b lig a tio n s .............
Repurchase agreements:
Treasury s e c u r itie s .............................
Bankers’ a c c ep ta n c e s........................
Federal agency o b lig a tio n s .............
Member bank b o rro w in g s..................
Other Federal Reserve assetsf . . .
Total

...................................................

Excess reserves

+ 111
+ 214
—
1
+ 39
— 138
—
1
2

—

+

78

+ 8
+ 1
+ 100
—

—

7

—

+ 131

+ 243

—

+

S
35
18

+ 323
—
3

+

9
11

+ 1

— 2
+
+

+ 120
+ 142

10

+ 139

21

—. 190
+ 71
14

— 403
—

+ 341

— 36
+ 45

+

+ 2
— 119
+ 195

+ 481

+ 197
+

72

37

Monthly
averages

Daily average levels

Member bank:
Total reserves, including vault c a s h ...........

32,677

Excess reserves .....................................................
Borrowings ...........................................................
Free, or net borrowed ( — ), reserves ----Nonborrowed reserves .....................................

331
58
273

N et carry-over, excess or deficit (— )§ . . . .

32,619
43

32,448
32,309
139
93
46
32,355

32,602
32,391
211
57
154

32,299
32,174
125
135
— 10

32,545

32,164

32,507 +
32,305 +
202 +
86 +
116 +
32,421 +

1S7

10<S

in s

111 +

N ote: Because of rounding, figures do not necessarily add to totals.
^Includes changes in Treasury currency and cash,
tIncludes assets denom inated in foreign currencies.
JAverage for four weeks ended June 28.
§Not reflected in data above.

were first proposed in late March when the Board
invited comments from interested parties during the next
month and a half. The major effects of the changes will be
that reserve requirements on demand deposits will be




TH E GOVERNM ENT SECUR ITIES M AR KET

— 150

78
61

+
+

based upon size of bank rather than location and that all
banks using the System’s check collection facilities must
make payment in immediately available funds (see box
on page 154 for details). The Board received comments
from less than 5 percent of the nation’s banks, and the
main modifications suggested had to do with minimizing
the effects of the new check collection procedures upon
funds available for loans and investments. Taking these
suggestions into account, the Board modified the regula­
tions somewhat further. Thus, it reduced the new reserve
requirement for one size category of banks which will
lose a large amount of reserves as a result of the
new check collection rules and set up conditions under
which it will be appropriate for a Reserve Bank to waive
penalties for certain member bank reserve deficiencies
resulting from these changes. The waiver of penalties will
be granted for a maximum of twenty-one months. More­
over, to equalize competitive conditions among banks
and ease adjustment to the new check collection proce­
dures, the Board is assigning high priority to extending
Regional Check Processing Centers for clearing services.

Yields on most Treasury securities advanced during
June, in response to slackened investor demand and an
expectation on the part of many participants that interest
rates will rise as the economy continues to expand and
as the Treasury’s demand for funds places additional pres­
sure on the credit markets in months to come. This expec­
tation was fueled somewhat further by May increases in
wholesale and consumer prices which surpassed those in
April. Rates on Treasury bills and short- and intermediateterm coupon issues rose substantially, while relatively
modest increases were posted in yields on long-term
Treasury bonds. The increases in rates occurred in spite
of the retirement by the Treasury of $3 billion of tax antic­
ipation bills (TABs) and $1.2 billion of maturing bonds.
There was some tightening in the Federal funds market
at the start of the month, and a cautious atmosphere hung
over the bill market resulting from concern among par­
ticipants that some firming of monetary policy might be
under way. Modest investor demand developed, however,
and bidding in the first weekly auction was relatively ag­
gressive though rates did rise somewhat from the levels
set during the final auction in May. Investor interest soon
waned, however, and despite some professional demand
rates trended higher over the next several days. Market
sentiment brightened at the beginning of the next week,
reflecting some modest investor demand prior to the
weekly auction and the expectation of sizable reinvestment

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

demand from persons holding Treasury bonds maturing
June 15 and TABs coming due six days later. As a result,
at the auction on June 12 the average issuing rates on
three- and six-month bills were down slightly from the
week earlier (see Table II). Buoyed by the potential re­
investment demand and additional moderate investor pur­
chases, the market steadied briefly but then began to falter
when demand proved less than expected. Substantial pay­
ments of corporate income taxes on June 15 were met
through the runoff of liquid assets including TABs, while
borrowing was relatively light, thereby reducing the cor­
porate reinvestment demand for Treasury bills.
Some modest investor demand once again appeared

C h a r t II

MONETARY AND RESERVE AGGREGATES
S e a s o n a lly a d ju s t e d
B illio n s o f d o lla r s

B illio n s o f d o lla r s

388.

304.

205.

28.

25.
1970

1971

1972

N o te : D a ta fo r Ju n e 1972 a re p r e lim in a r y e s tim a te s .
M l = C u r r e n c y p lu s a d ju s te d d e m a n d d e p o s its h e ld b y th e p u b l ic .
M 2 = M l p lu s c o m m e r c ia l b a n k s a v in g s a n d tim e d e p o s its h e ld b y th e
p u b lic , le ss n e g o tia b le c e r tific a te s o f d e p o s it is s u e d in d e n o m in a tio n s
o f $ 1 0 0 ,0 0 0 o r m o re .
A d ju s te d b a n k c r e d it p r o x y = T o ta l m e m b e r b a n k d e p o s its s u b je c t to re s e rv e
r e q u ir e m e n ts p lu s n o n d e p o s it s ou rc es o f fu n d s , s uch as E u r o - d o lla r
b o r r o w in g s a n d th e p ro c e e d s o f c o m m e r c ia l p a p e r is s u e d b y b a n k h o ld in g
c o m p a n ie s o r o th e r a f filia te s .
RPD = T o ta l m e m b e r b a n k re s e rv e s less th o s e r e q u ir e d to s u p p o r t U n ite d S ta te s
G o v e r n m e n t a n d in te r b a n k d e p o s its .
S o urce-.

B o a r d o f G o v e r n o r s o f th e F e d e ra l R e s e rv e S y s te m .




163

after several days of rising bill rates and improved the
market’s tone. Participants once again bid rather aggres­
sively in the regular auction on June 19, and a better
atmosphere prevailed in the market for the next several
sessions. An additional lift was provided by the possibility
that, in the international currency uncertainty surrounding
heavy selling of the British pound and the dollar, some
demand for bills might be forthcoming from foreign cen­
tral banks. Demand again proved disappointing following
the floating of the pound early on June 23, and in the
unenthusiastic monthly auction held that day, average
issuing rates on the new nine- and twelve-month bills
reached their highest levels since last September.
A better tone emerged over the next few days in re­
sponse to some investor demand for bills for quarterly
financial statement purposes. Dealers were concerned
about the reversal of this demand following the end of
the quarter, however, and bidding was restrained in the
final weekly auction which was advanced to Friday, June
30, because many participants were expected to take a
long Fourth of July holiday weekend. In this second
auction for the week, average issuing rates on the threeand six-month bills were set at 4.138 percent and 4.688
percent, respectively, their highest levels since late in
1971. Over the month as a whole, most bill rates rose
by some 20 to 60 basis points.
Treasury coupon issues came under many of the same
pressures affecting the bill market during June, and yields
on most issues maturing within five years were also about
20 to 60 basis points higher over the month. Modest
investor demand and some dealer short covering limited
price changes on longer term notes and bonds to a some­
what narrower range.
A cautious tone emerged in this market early in June
when buying interest was sluggish and participants pon­
dered the implications of a firming Federal funds rate
for near-term monetary policy. The possibility of renewed
inflation, given the
percent (annual rate) rise in the
wholesale price index during May, and the corporate bond
market’s inability to sustain lower yields despite a reduced
calendar were further depressants to the market, and
prices of most issues eased over the first week in June. The
lower price levels attracted some investor interest, as well
as the opportunity for dealer short covering, and the
market began to firm. Prices fluctuated narrowly over the
next several days and then drifted lower amid predictions
by some analysts that the Treasury’s cash needs in the
fiscal year 1973 would be somewhat greater than estimated
earlier. In the face of renewed buyer apathy, dealers
marked prices lower in an attempt to elicit some interest
but to no avail. There was no selling pressure on the mar-

MONTHLY REVIEW, JULY 1972

164
Table II

AVERAGE ISSUING RATES*
AT REGULAR TREASURY BILL AUCTIONS
In percent
Weekly auction dates— June 1972
Maturities
June
12

June

June

June

5

19

26

30

3.861
4.243

3.798
4.187

3.924
4.328

4.023
4.484

4.138
4.688

June

Three-month .
Six-m onth . ..

Monthly auction dates— April-June 1972

April

25
Nine month .
One-year . . .

4.234
4.362

May
23
4.367
4.465

June
23
4.754
4.854

^Interest rates on bills are quoted in terms of a 360-day year, w ith the discounts from
par as the return on the face amount of the bills payable at m aturity. Bond yield
equivalents, related to the amount actually invested, would be slightly higher.

ket, however, as investors seemed content with their cur­
rent holdings, and prices of coupon issues drifted steadily
lower over the remainder of the month.
OTHER SECURITIES M AR K ETS

Considerable investor resistance was evident in both the
corporate and municipal bond markets during much of
June after rates had fallen early in the month to their low­
est levels since January. The announcement of larger in­
creases in the wholesale and consumer price indexes dur­
ing May as compared with April contributed to an expec­
tation of higher interest rates, and investors remained on
the sidelines a good part of the time.
On May 31 underwriters were able to sell only about
10 percent of a $100 million issue of new Aa-rated utility
bonds which were aggressively priced to yield 7.29 percent,
the lowest return since mid-January. Despite this experi­
ence, on the following day, June 1, an additional $50 mil­
lion of similarly rated power company bonds was marketed
at an even lower yield of 7.25 percent, and by late Friday,
June 2, only about $30 million of these two issues had been
bought by investors. Although the calendar of scheduled
offerings was relatively light, substantial retail demand
failed to materialize at the beginning of the next week. As
a result, on Tuesday, syndicate restrictions were removed
from the unsold balances of these two issues together with
two others, and yields on these bonds adjusted as much as
12 basis points higher.




Recognizing the fact that rates had already been pushed
beyond their currently acceptable levels, underwriters be­
gan pricing new offerings at progressively higher yields
over the next several days but with only moderate success.
Then, faced with a somewhat heavier schedule than there
had been in recent weeks, several syndicates disbanded on
the following Monday in advance of the sale of $125 mil­
lion of New Jersey Bell Telephone securities the next day.
This two-part Aaa-rated offering of $75 million of fortyyear bonds and $50 million of six-year notes, yielding 7.45
percent and 6.53 percent, respectively, sold out quickly.
The return on the bonds matched that placed on a slowselling Aa-rated offering three days earlier. Immediately
following the successful sale of the New Jersey Bell issues,
however, underwriters priced two Aa-rated utility bond
offerings to yield little more than the Aaa-rated Bell bonds
and investors once again balked. Finally, early in the week
of June 19, returns on new Aa-rated utility bonds were
placed at l l/i percent. Investors responded favorably to
this higher rate structure and the corporate bond market
tended to stabilize over the next few days, albeit with
yields on Aa-rated utility bonds some 25 basis points
higher than at the start of the month. In reaction to the
uncertainties in the international money market, rates
moved higher as the month drew to a close, and a sub­
sequent issue sold slowly at a yield of 7.60 percent.
Confronted with an increased supply of scheduled new
issues, investors displayed little interest in the lower yields
available on tax-exempt bonds at the start of June. There
was a sizable buildup in the Blue List of inventories ad­
vertised for sale, as dealers made preparation for the
heavier calendar which included $209 million of Aaa-rated
local housing bonds guaranteed by the Department of
Housing and Urban Development (HUD). Providing
yields of 2.60 to 5.08 percent, the HUD bonds were
marketed on June 7 and, even though many analysts be­
lieved they were not aggressively priced, only about one
half were sold during the first three business days. Some
additional sales resulted from a markdown in the price of
these bonds on the fourth day, but a sizable balance re­
mained.
The tax-exempt market registered a short-lived improve­
ment just before midmonth, when investors bought heavily
of several new issues, but faltered again in response to the
somewhat restrained reception to a $90 million offering
of Aaa-rated Connecticut securities. Two business days
later, the unsold portion of the thirty-year term bonds
was released from syndicate with an upward yield adjust­
ment to 5.40 percent from an initial 5.25 percent. On the
following day, other recent issues were also released from
pricing restrictions with increases in yields of as much as

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

25 basis points. Despite such adjustments, buyers re­
mained quite hesitant and showed very little interest in
the new offerings which were marketed later in the month.
For example, the unsold HUD bonds were reduced in
price a second time on June 22 and, despite some sales,
an estimated $20 million remained in dealers’ hands;
at the same time a one-day-old issue was released from
syndicate after first-day sales of less than 50 percent.
While the corporate bond market was stabilizing tem­

porarily, tax-exempt securities had difficulty finding a
viable level of rates, and that market continued under
pressure until late in the month. Reflecting developments
in this area over the period, The Bond Buyer index
of yields on twenty municipal bonds rose steadily from
5.15 percent on June 1 to 5.43 percent on June 22. Fol­
lowing postponement of a $151 million issue scheduled
for June 27, however, pressures abated somewhat and
rates stabilized.

Subscriptions to the m o n t h l y r e v i e w are available to the public without charge. Additional
copies of recent issues may be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve
Bank of New York, 33 Liberty Street, New York, N.Y. 10045.
Persons in foreign countries may request that copies of the m o n t h l y r e v i e w be sent to
them by “air mail-other articles”. The postage charge amounts to approximately half the price of
regular air mail and is payable in advance. Requests for this service and inquiries about rates should
be directed to the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 33 Liberty
Street, New York, N.Y. 10045.




165

166

MONTHLY REVIEW, JULY 1972

Impact of Direct Investm ent Abroad by United States Multinational
Companies on the Balance of Payments
By

S usan

The persistent and distressingly large deficits in the
United States balance of payments during the past decade
have aroused considerable interest in the overall impact
on the payments balance of direct investment abroad by
United States multinational companies.1 This paper sum­
marizes the measurable balance-of-payments flows associ­
ated with American firms’ operations overseas and at­
tempts to place these flows in an appropriate theoretical
framework.
The principal balance-of-payments flows associated
with overseas investment can be separated into two major
blocks: (1) those affecting the capital and related ser­
vices accounts (principally investment income), referred to
in this article as financial flows, and (2) those relating to
the merchandise trade account. The preponderance of evi­
dence indicates that the balance-of-payments impact of
the financial flows has been favorable when viewed in a
long-run context. Over the decade of the 1960’s these
flows cumulated to a net positive item of $35 billion.
Analysis of the financial flows within a theoretical frame­
work which explicitly takes account of the relationship
between investment outflows in one period and income
inflows in subsequent periods suggests that their balanceof-payments contribution will remain favorable.
Conclusions about the impact of United States direct
investment on the merchandise trade balance, on the
other hand, must be considered tenuous for several rea­
sons. First, the data available on trade flows related to
direct investment activity are very limited. Second, to as­

*Econom ist, Balance of Payments D ivision.
1 The phrase “m ultinational com panies” has been defined in a
variety o f ways by different analysts o f this subject. The termi­
nology is used in its br:adest ssnse in this paper to refer to the
activities of all United States firms with direct investments abroad.




B. F o s t e r *

sess the impact of overseas investment on trade flows, one
ideally should compare the flows that took place given the
existence of the overseas affiliates with the flows that
would have occurred in their absence, and the data nat­
urally do not permit such a comparison. Only by making
explicit assumptions about the behavior of firms can any
inferences be drawn. The assumption considered most
reasonable is that multinational firms are operating in
fairly competitive environments, which implies that most
of the observed changes in exports and imports would
have occurred even in the absence of United States foreign
investment, at least in the long run. In other words, if
United States companies had not exploited the overseas
opportunities as they appeared, foreign companies eventu­
ally would have. Therefore, these export and import
changes should be viewed more as reflections of adjust­
ments to changes in international competitiveness rather
than as a direct result of United States investment abroad.
More data are required, however, before this conclusion
on trade effects can be demonstrated empirically.
FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYZING DIR ECT
IN V E S TM E N T IM P A C T

The balance-of-payments flows associated with the ac­
tivities of United States multinational companies arise in
the following manner. The value of United States direct
investment in foreign enterprises2 can be augmented either

2 In the official statistics on the U nited States foreign invest­
ment position published by the United States Departm ent o f Com ­
merce, the book value o f United States direct investment abroad
is defined to include, not only the parent com pany’s share o f the
capital stock and surplus o f the affiliate, but also the net indebted­
ness o f the affiliate to the parent plus any long-term debt o f the
affiliate held by nonaffiliated United States residents.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

through additional contributions of capital from the
United States— a long-term capital outflow in the balance
of payments— or through the reinvestment of a portion of
the direct investors’ share of the foreign affiliates’ earn­
ings. The latter does not appear in the balance-ofpayments statistics if the foreign affiliate is incorporated but,
if the affiliate is unincorporated, reinvested earnings are
included as inflows of direct investment income offset by
capital outflows. The stock of assets abroad generates a
stream of earnings into the future, some portion of which
is returned to the United States in the form of dividends,
branch profits, and interest payments and recorded as
balance-of-payments inflows of “income from direct invest­
ment”. In addition, United States parent firms receive pay­
ments from the affiliates of royalties and fees for the use
of patents, managerial services, etc., which are also balanceof-payments inflows.
Since the inception in 1968 of the mandatory capital
control program on American corporations’ overseas in­
vestments,3 United States firms have relied to a significant
extent on foreign sources of funds to finance their direct
investment, principally by borrowing either through bond
issues or directly from financial institutions overseas. These
foreign borrowings are recorded as positive balance-ofpayments inflows, offset by corresponding capital outflows
when utilized to increase United States direct investment
in foreign concerns. United States companies’ interest pay­
ments on these foreign borrowings, of course, are also
balance-of-payments entries and are included as a part of
the figure recorded for United States private payments of
income on foreign investments in the United States.
In addition, there are a variety of possible merchan­
dise trade flows associated with United States direct in­
vestment abroad. Exports of capital goods may be gener­
ated by the establishment or expansion of facilities abroad,
and there may be a continuing stream of such capital
equipment shipments to meet replacement demands. There
may be exports of intermediate goods for further pro­
cessing and assembly abroad, and some goods may be
shipped to affiliates for immediate resale, with the affiliate
acting principally in a distributing or warehousing capac­
ity. On the other hand, United States exports may be dis­
placed by production and sale by the foreign subsidiary of
goods which would otherwise have been shipped from this
country. United States imports may also be affected

167

by United States direct investment abroad, as intermediate
or final goods produced by the affiliate in a lower cost en­
vironment overseas are imported back to the United States.
Before proceeding to attempt to measure these flows, a
brief exposition of the theoretical context appropriate to
the analysis of the real balance-of-payments effects stem­
ming from direct investment is in order. The first impor­
tant point which clearly emerges from the mere listing
of possible effects is that there is a dynamic process in­
volved and time must explicitly be taken into account in
any attempt to establish a causal relationship between out­
flows of investment funds and resultant income and net
trade receipts. Any addition to the stock of productive
assets abroad yields a flow of income as well as exports
and imports in subsequent periods. The balance-ofpayments impacts of a direct investment outflow in period
t, then, are the increments in periods t+ 1 , t+ 2 , etc., of
income and net trade receipts associated with that addition
to productive capacity. Alternatively, one can say that the
income and trade flows in any given year are attributable,
not to the capital outflow in that year, but to the cumula­
tive outflow in all previous years, i.e., to the outstanding
stock of investment in that year. Thus, matching inflows
and outflows on a year-by-year basis or cumulated over
several years must be regarded as purely a descriptive
method and not as an analytical tool.
The number of years required for an initial capital out­
flow to generate a return stream of income and net trade
receipts equal to it is frequently referred to as the recoup­
ment period, which several studies have attempted to cal­
culate.4 For purposes of illustrating the time pattern of
balance-of-payments impacts, which is implicit in the re­
coupment estimate procedure, the relationship between
capital outflows and related income flows will be exam­
ined, ignoring the trade effects for simplicity. The basic
model employed in these studies assumes that the invest­
ment base which produces the earnings stream is aug­
mented either through capital outflows from the United
States or through retained earnings. Then, given a constant
rate of earnings, a constant ratio of repatriated to total

4 For exam ple, Philip Bell, “Private Capital M ovem ents and the
U.S. Balance-of-Paym ents P osition”, F actors Affecting the U.S.
Balance o f P aym en ts (W ashington, D .C .: U nited States G overn­
ment Printing Office, 1962); N . K. Bruck and F. A . Lees, Foreign
Investm ent, C apital C ontrols, and the Balance o f P aym en ts (N ew
York University Graduate School o f Business Administration, In­
stitute o f Finance, Bulletin N o . 4 8 -4 9 ), April 1968; G. Hufbauer
3 This program is administered by the Office o f Foreign Direct and F. Adler, O verseas M anufacturing In vestm en t and the Balance
o f P aym en ts (W ashington, D .C .: United States Departm ent of the
Investments o f the Departm ent o f Com m erce and is usually re­
Treasury, 1 9 6 8 ).
ferred to as the O FD I program.




168

MONTHLY REVIEW, JULY 1972

earnings, and a constant rate of growth of new direct in­
vestment outflows, the number of years necessary to
achieve a cumulative positive balance-of-payments effect
can be calculated. The inflows will ultimately match and
then exceed the outflows, both on an annual and on a
cumulative basis, so long as some earnings are repatriated
and the rate of return is larger than the rate of growth of
outflows.5
This approach may be used to analyze two relevant
problems. In the first instance one can calculate how long
it will take for a single once-and-for-all capital outflow to
have positive balance-of-payments consequences. Clearly,
in the year it occurs the outflow will be a negative balanceof-payments entry which will not be offset by any inflows,
assuming that the investment does not earn a return until
the next period. On the other hand, in every subsequent
year the annual balance-of-payments effect will be positive
and equal to the remitted earnings. This income stream
will not be constant, however, but will grow because the
investment base is being augmented in each period by the
amount of reinvested earnings. As an example, if the earn­
ings rate equals 20 percent and the repatriation rate is 60
percent, it can be calculated that a single outflow of $100
will be totally recovered in terms of cumulated income in­
flows in the seventh year after the initial outflow.
For the purposes of analyzing the impact of aggregate
direct investment flows on the balance of payments, how­
ever, it is more appropriate to examine the situation where
there is a continuous, and probably growing, stream of
new capital outflows. As noted above, as long as the rate
of return on investment exceeds the rate of growth of
capital outflows and as long as some earnings are repatri­
ated, the balance-of-payments effect will ultimately turn
positive although the recoupment period will be longer
than in the example of a single nonrecurrent outflow. Us­
ing the same earnings and repatriation rates as in the ear­
lier case but allowing capital outflows to grow at 10
percent per year, the annual balance-of-payments effect
(i.e., yearly income inflows minus annual outflows) does
not become positive until year 10 and the cumulated in­
flows exceed the cumulated outflows only beginning in year
16. The length of the recoupment period is quite sensitive
to the assumptions made regarding the rate of return and

the rate of growth of outflows; in general, the larger the
excess of rate of return over the rate of growth of outflows,
the shorter the recovery time. Thus, whether one judges the
balance-of-payments impact of direct investment as posi­
tive or negative depends critically on the time horizon one
chooses. In the short run, the impact is likely to be nega­
tive, while in the long run the reverse is the case.6 It
should be emphasized that, as illustrated by the numeri­
cal examples, the short run in this context covers a period
of several years.
The second fundamental question which must be con­
fronted in any attempt to assess the overall balance-ofpayments impact of direct investment is what would have
happened in the absence of United States direct invest­
ment abroad. This question is not relevant in estimating
income flows associated with direct investment since there
would obviously be none in the absence of the initial in­
vestment, but it is critical in estimating trade effects.7 There
are a variety of explicit motives leading to the investment
decision. While the explanations may appear different on
the surface, they generally share the notion that there are
competitive advantages in producing abroad—frequently
in the form of lower costs. These lower costs could arise in
the production process itself because of lower costs of labor
or materials. Alternatively, savings could arise in the dis­
tribution process where local production allows lower
transport costs, or lower costs of delivery to final market
because of tariff barriers. Other less tangible benefits might
also accrue from local production, such as establishing
brand consciousness in the market or being better able to
tailor products to specific national tastes.
In some instances, the decision to produce abroad could
be based primarily on a defensive motive— to protect an

6 The length of the overall recoupment period w ill also be af­
fected by the size and direction of the net trade receipts generated
by the investment base. The larger and more positive these flows,
the shorter w ill be the pay-back period, whereas the recoupment
period will be lengthened the larger and m ore negative the net
receipts. Indeed, if the net trade balance effects were sufficiently
large and adverse, they could swamp the positive incom e inflows
and the net balance-of-paym ents effect w ould be negative. This
outcom e does not seem likely, however, for a variety o f reasons
discussed later.

7 Under certain conditions, other kinds o f capital flows, e.g.,
portfolio investment or bank lending, could arise in the absence
5 These conditions are sufficient to ensure that the rate o f o f direct investment. The existence o f such substitution might
growth o f the stock o f assets abroad (which equals the rate at
m odify the conclusions of a study such as this. But for the pur­
which incom e inflows grow ) will be sufficiently larger than the
poses o f evaluating the balance-of-paym ents impact of direct in­
rate o f growth o f outflows— because o f the reinvestment o f earn­
vestment by itself, the most m eaningful approach was to leave
ings— so that the balance-of-paym ents inflows w ill ultimately ex­
aside the possibility of substitute capital flows in the absence of
ceed the outflows.
direct investment.




FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

existing market share against the emergence of potential
rivals. Underlying this explanation is still the presumption
that there are advantages in producing abroad rather than
in the United States, however. If such advantages did not
exist, then the United States exporter could continue to
maintain his market share through exports and would not
be induced to begin production abroad in an attempt to
forestall the emergence of potential rival firms.
Another hypothesis about the behavior pattern of United
States direct investors has been propounded by Vernon
and is known as the product or industry cycle theory.8 This
thesis suggests that new products are first developed and
tested in the large and relatively high-income United States
market. Production remains in the United States during a
trial period when a variety of production processes and
product characteristics are tested, and during this period
a market abroad may be initiated through export. As the
market reaction both here and abroad is assessed, some
standardization occurs and the emphasis in the productionlocation decision shifts to cost minimization. At some point
during the expansion of the foreign market, costminimizing criteria may dictate shifting the locus of pro­
duction abroad. Vernon carries the argument one step
further and suggests that, in some instances, the cost of
production may be sufficiently lower overseas to offset
transport costs and the product may ultimately be pro­
duced abroad entirely, with some of it imported back to
the United States.
All of the foregoing explanations—by no means a com­
prehensive listing—have in common the basic premise
that there are advantages in producing in the foreign
market, which would suggest that the foreign-produced
goods could outcompete the comparable United States
product. Given relatively free markets in which the basic
technology of production is known and in which there
are no significant barriers to entry, such as prohibi­
tive start-up costs, competitive forces would suggest that
in the absence of United States firms establishing produc­
tion facilities abroad, other non-United States firms would
seize this profitable opportunity. Consequently, to the ex­

169

tent that foreign-sourced goods displace United States
exports or lead to United States imports replacing domestic
production, these effects would be likely to occur anyway
even without the United States firms producing abroad,
and therefore it would be wrong to attribute any export
loss or import creation to United States direct investment.
Rather these changing trade patterns merely reflect world
production adjusting to relative cost advantages.
Once again, however, it should be emphasized that the
time frame becomes an important consideration in this
evaluation. There may be a considerable lag between the
emergence of profitable production possibilities and the
perception and seizing of these opportunities. It seems
quite possible that United States firms may accelerate this
rationalization of worldwide resource utilization, perhaps
because they become aware more rapidly of the market
opportunities in certain products as developed through
their export trade and perhaps because of an ability to
raise the necessary capital more quickly either through
internal funds or through access to the larger United States
capital market. Thus, in the short run—which may be a
matter of several years— the shift of United States produc­
tion may be conceived to result in actual export loss or
import creation for specific products, but as indicated
above, given a longer run outlook, many of these exports
would probably have been forfeited and the goods im­
ported anyway. In a long-run time frame, then, theoretical
considerations suggest that the relevant criterion for
assessing the balance-of-payments impact of United States
direct investment abroad is whether or not the income re­
turns outweigh the associated capital outflows, and on this
basis the evidence seems clearly to indicate that the bal­
ance of payments is favorably affected by direct invest­
ment activity.
EXPANSION OF FOREIGN IN V E S TM E N T
AND SALES IN T H E 1960’S

The book value of United States direct investment
abroad has expanded from less than $32 billion at the end
of 1960 to $78 billion by the end of 1970 (see chart),
growing at an average rate of 9.4 percent per year. Total
affiliate assets, which are larger than the book value of
United States direct investment reflecting foreign equity
8
R. Vernon, “International Investm ent and International Trade participation in the affiliates as well as the affiliates own
in the Product C ycle”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.
borrowing from foreigners, appear to have grown even
L X X X (1 9 6 6 ). A recent exposition o f this hypothesis supported
more rapidly at least in the latter part of the decade.
by evidence obtained through case studies may be found in a
study undertaken by the Harvard Business School under contract
Unfortunately,
recent data on these total affiliate assets
for the United States Departm ent of Comm erce: R. B. Stobaugh
are lacking, but a survey conducted by the Office of For­
and A ssociates, “U .S. M ultinational Enterprises and the U.S. E con­
om y”, The Multinational Corporation: Studies on U.S. Foreign
eign Direct Investments (OFDI) covering the balance
Investment, Vol. I (U nited States Departm ent o f Com m erce, Bu­
sheets of the majority-owned affiliates of 469 United
reau o f International Com m erce, March 1972).




170

MONTHLY REVIEW, JULY 1972

States direct investors9 reveals that total assets of these
affiliates rose at an approximately constant rate of 13 per­
cent per year between 1966 and 1969. During this same
period, however, the United States direct investors’ share
of these total affiliate assets declined from 60.1 percent to
57.2 percent, reflecting the impact of the control program
on United States direct investment that was designed to
shift the financing of affiliate expansion from United
States to foreign sources.
Additional supporting evidence pointing to the con­
tinued expansion of overseas affiliate assets can be derived
from actual and anticipated plant and equipment expendi­
tures of foreign affiliates, which dipped in 1967-68 but
rose sharply in 1969-70. These figures indicate clearly

9 Office of Foreign D irect Investments, Foreign Direct Invest­
ment: Selected Statistics (U nited States Department o f C om ­
merce, July 1971).




that there has been no sharp curtailment in expansion
plans since the OFDI program was established in 1968.
Rather the expenditure pattern seems more probably to
reflect cyclical conditions in foreign business and capital
markets.
GEOGRAPHICAL AND INDUSTRIAL DISTRIBUTION OF FOREIGN

In the ten years 1961-70 inclusive, the increase in
total book value of United States direct investment
abroad was concentrated in the manufacturing sector,
where United States-owned assets rose by 190 percent to
$32.2 billion (see chart). The bulk of these manufactur­
ing investments was in Canada and Europe, but the rate of
growth in Europe considerably outstripped that in Canada.
Undoubtedly the formation of the Common Market at the
end of the 1950’s acted as a considerable inducement to
American firms to establish production facilities behind
the common tariff barrier in order to serve the markets of
the member countries. The establishment of such local
facilities was encouraged, not only as a means of avoid­
assets.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

ing the external tariff wall, but also to take advantage of
the expanded internal market which opened up possibili­
ties of achieving economies of scale and generated more
rapid economic growth in the European Community
countries than might otherwise have been achieved.
In absolute amount, investment in petroleum affiliates
represented the second largest industrial group by the
end of 1970, although their proportion of total investment
abroad had fallen to 28 percent from 35 percent ten
years earlier. The $21 billion of petroleum industry assets,
which include refining, distribution, and crude production
facilities, was about evenly divided between Canada and
Europe on the one hand and Latin America and other
areas on the other. Mining and smelting operations,
largely representing investments to obtain raw materials,
grew at about the same rate as petroleum investments
over the ten-year period and amounted to $6.1 billion at
the end of 1970, or roughly 8 percent of total investments.
As expected, these assets were concentrated in Canada
and Latin America.
The other category of investments displaying a growth
of just over 200 percent during the 1960’s was comprised
of trade and other industries, largely financial and other
service industries. The most rapid growth in this group
of enterprises occurred in Europe, as ancillary service
industries moved abroad with the rapid development of
manufacturing concerns. Despite the rapid growth in these
investments, however, they represented only some 8 per­
cent of total direct investment assets by the beginning of
1970. Finally, transportation and public utilities invest­
ment exhibited virtually no growth over the period and
represented less than 4 percent of the total investment
figure in 1970.
p r o d u c t i o n o f f o r e i g n a f f i l i a t e s . Unfortunately for as­
sessing the importance of the role of American overseas
investment in world production, comprehensive statistics
on the total output of foreign subsidiaries of American
companies located outside the borders of the United States
are not available. However, by assuming a constant
relationship between affiliates’ assets and their sales, an
estimate which is at least indicative of the rough order
of magnitude of such output can be derived.10 This proce-

171

dure suggests affiliate sales in 1970 of about $74 billion
by manufacturing concerns, roughly $36 billion for
petroleum affiliates, $6 billion for mining and smelting
subsidiaries, and $16 billion for all other affiliates. Thus,
a very rough approximation of total sales by all foreign
affiliates in 1970 would be in the range of $130 billion$140 billion, which contrasts with a total sales figure
(estimated similarly) of some $50 billion in I960.11
Clearly, then, the operations of United States-affiliated
firms abroad—whether measured in terms of asset forma­
tion or of total sales— exhibited sharp growth in the
1960’s and, by the end of the decade, were a very
significant factor in global production.
CA P ITA L AND SERVICES ACCOUNT FLOWS

To recapitulate briefly the relevant entries in the capi­
tal and services accounts of the balance of payments as­
sociated with United States direct investment, the
expansion in the book value of United States foreign di­
rect investment can be achieved either through a capital
outflow from the United States or through the reinvestment
of a portion of the United States share in the affiliates’
earnings. The first method of financing entails a debit
entry in the balance of payments, “direct investment
abroad”, whereas, as noted above, the latter does not ap­
pear in the balance of payments at all if the affiliate is
incorporated or it appears as offsetting debit and credit en­
tries if the affiliate is unincorporated. Direct investment
capital outflows rose from $1.6 billion in 1961 to $4.4
billion in 1970 (see Table I), with the bulk of the out­
flows going to manufacturing and petroleum affiliates.
These additions to the stock of investments subse­
quently generate a return flow of payments in the form
of repatriated earnings and interest payments on credit
extended by United States residents, all recorded as
“income on United States direct investment abroad”.
These flows have been a major positive factor in the
balance of payments, rising from $2.8 billion in 1961
to $6.0 billion in 1970 and again coming mainly from

11 The 1970 total is probably a conservative estim ate since it is
based on an assumed constant relationship between sales and as­
sets. However, the relationship actually used in the estimation
procedure is that between affiliate sales and the United States
10 This estim ation procedure was derived from work done by direct investors’ share o f book value, not gross assets. To the
Judd Polk, econom ist for the United States Council o f the Inter­
extent that the gross investment base o f the foreign affiliates has
national Chamber o f Commerce. For the few years when data
been augmented by an increased proportion o f foreign capital
on both assets and sales are available, the relationship was fairly
contributions, either debt or equity, total sales expansion might
stable.
well have exceeded that suggested above.




172

MONTHLY REVIEW, JULY 1972
Table I
NET EFFECT OF CAPITAL AND SERVICES ACCOUNT FLOWS
ASSOCIATED WITH DIRECT INVESTMENT OF UNITED STATES MULTINATIONAL COMPANIES
In billions of dollars; — denotes outflow
Capital and services account flows

1961

1966

1967

1968

1969

1970

United States direct investment abroad .........................................

- 1.6
*

- 3.7

— 3.1

- 3.2

- 3 .3

- 4 .4

0.7

0.5

3.4

2.4

3.9

- 0 .1

- 0 .2

-0 .4

- 0 .6

Borrowing abroad by United States direct investors.....................

Cumulated

1961-70
- 2 8 .8
11.2

Interest payments to foreigners on borrowing abroadt ...............

X

X

Income from direct investment abroad ......................................

2.8

4.0

4.5

5.0

5.7

6.0

41.8

Receipts of royalties and fees ..........................................................

0.7

1.3

1.4

1.5

1.7

1.9

12.4

N e t financial flow st ....................................................................................

1.9

2.3

3.2

6.5

6.1

6.8

35.3

-

1.3

* Not available,
t Estimated.
t Less than $50 million.
Sources: United States Department of Commerce, Survey of Current Business (June 1971) and
Foreign Direct Investment Program: Selected Statistics (July 1971).

manufacturing and petroleum affiliates.12 Receipts from
affiliates of royalties and management fees for services
rendered by the parent companies comprise another
balance-of-payments inflow, and these rose from $0.7 bil­
lion in 1961 to $1.9 billion in 1970.
In response to the OFDI program, United States com­
panies have borrowed substantial amounts of funds abroad
in recent years. These borrowings appear as an inflow of
nonliquid foreign capital in the balance of payments and
are subsequently counterbalanced by an outflow of direct
investment as the proceeds are transferred to foreign sub­
sidiaries. A survey carried out by the OFDI reveals that
borrowing by United States direct investors from foreign­
ers both in the form of bond issues and directly from
banks has been a strongly positive item in the balance of
payments, particularly in the 1968-70 period following
the institution of the mandatory restraint program. In
fact, during this three-year period, the average net posi­
tive contribution of all financial flows to the balance of
payments was $6.5 billion, and foreign borrowings by

12 Since a large number o f petroleum affiliates are branch sub­
sidiaries, the incom e figures from these affiliates include earnings
which in fact are reinvested, and thus the gross incom e inflows
overstate the amount o f incom e which remains in the United
States. From the overall balance-of-payments point o f view, how ­
ever, this overstatement is canceled out as any branch profits
reinvested are counted as capital outflows in the direct investment
account.




United States direct investors accounted for nearly one
half of this— or $3.2 billion, as can be seen in Table I.
Finally, this foreign borrowing also gives rise to a
balance-of-payments outflow in the form of interest pay­
ments to foreigners. Estimates of these figures are avail­
able only for 1967-70 but, since borrowing abroad was
relatively insignificant prior to 1965, the absence of earlier
figures does not seriously distort the overall picture.
On the simplest level of analysis, these debit and credit
entries can be matched on a year-by-year basis or cumu­
lated over a period of years to yield a net positive or
negative impact on the balance of payments, as illustrated
in Table I. Clearly, on either of these bases, the inflows of
income, royalty and fee payments, and foreign borrowing
have greatly exceeded the outflow of funds for expanding
direct investment assets or for interest payments on foreign
debt: the net positive balance-of-payments flows cumulated
to over $35 billion in the period 1961-70, nearly one
third of which may be attributed to borrowing from for­
eigners.
As stated earlier, this simple comparison of flows is use­
ful mainly as a descriptive tool, but reveals little about the
causal relationship between capital outflows and future in­
cremental income returns generated by the addition to
the investment base. For this, time must be allowed ex­
plicitly to enter the calculus. When the model described
earlier is employed using actual data for the period 196169, the rate of return is found to have exceeded the rate
of growth of capital outflows and, therefore, one can con­
clude that the balance-of-payments effects of new direct

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

investment will ultimately be positive on both an annual
and a cumulative basis. This is consistent with the pres­
ently observed pattern of positive balance-of-payments
contributions of income and capital outflows, and suggests
that this pattern will continue in the future if the param­
eters remain stable.13
To evaluate the overall balance-of-payttients effect of all
capital and financial flows, certain other flows must also
be considered. The annual stream of receipts of royalties
and fees associated with the outstanding stock of invest­
ment will also increase as the investment base grows. In
the base period, each $100 of book value was associated
with about $3 of such receipts. This additional stream of
inflows enlarges the ultimate net positive balance-ofpayments effect and shortens the length of the recoup­
ment period. Second, the increase in United States
corporate borrowing from foreigners to finance overseas
investment will affect the time pattern of net balance-ofpayments effects. The borrowing may be considered as an
offset to direct investment outflows in the immediate pe­
riod, thus reducing net capital outflows, but repayment of
the debt in the future will lead to larger net outflows than
would otherwise have occurred. In addition, interest pay­
ments to foreigners on the debt will constitute an annual
stream of outflows, partially offsetting some of the posi­
tive effects mentioned above, and will tend to lengthen
the recoupment period.
These conclusions must be further tempered by other
qualifications. The calculations assume constant param­
eters— that is, rates of return, repatriation, and growth of
outflows— and there are a variety of factors which might
lead to a shift in these parameters. For example, there is

173

some evidence of a negative relationship between capital
outflows and the age of foreign affiliates.14 As the affiliates
mature, they provide for a larger part of their investment
needs through internal funds and rely less on funds from
the parent organization. This would suggest that, as the
previously noted bulge of investments in the 1960’s
matures, the rate of growth of outflows may decline. The
stability of the rate of return on investment is also open
to question. In particular, it appears that the foreign af­
filiates have been induced by the OFDI program to in­
crease their own borrowing to finance investment.15 The
impact of this greater leveraging of their assets may be to
increase the rate of return in the future. However, in­
creased leverage can also sharply cut rates of return
in periods of slackened demand for their output as the
higher interest costs reduce earnings. It is not obvious
which type of effect is likely to prevail' Finally, United
States ownership of assets abroad and/or the proportion
of foreign earnings which may be repatriated are, in some
instances, subject to control by host governments, and the
possibility of expropriation introduces a further uncer­
tainty into the long-run outlook.
TR A D E ACCOUNT FLOWS

e x p o r t s . As outlined in the introduction, there are a vari­
ety of possible export effects attributable to United States
direct investment abroad but, unlike the capital and other
financial effects, these cannot readily be isolated from
available statistics. There are two types of export effects
which it would be desirable to measure. (1) Exports
of goods to and through foreign affiliates, which would
not have been shipped to other foreigners if the affiliates
did not exist, are referred to as associated exports.
This category could comprise a variety of goods, such as
capital equipment associated with plant expansion, parts
and components to be assembled abroad, or final goods
13
The values o f the parameters were estimated to be: rate of
destined for immediate resale. (2) Exports which do not
return, 12 percent; rate o f growth o f outflows, 9 percent; repatri­
ation rate, 70 percent. These values were estimated as averages
occur
because of the competition of goods manufactured
over the period and, therefore, must be viewed as only rough
and sold by the foreign affiliates are described as dis­
approximations of the marginal relationships the use o f which
would be preferable since we are interested in isolating the incre­
placed exports. Unfortunately, we cannot directly answer
m ental incom e inflows from an addition to the investment base.
the question—which is central to these two effects—of
These estimates may be used to calculate the recoupm ent period,
although the results must be viewed with caution. Such sim ulations
what
the pattern of United States exports would have
suggest that the balance-of-paym ents impact (annual incom e in­

flows minus annual new direct investment outflow s) associated
with these new direct investments w ill becom e positive in the
twenty-second year, although the negative annual balances dim in­
ish in m agnitude after the fourth year. O f course, it should be
em phasized that the balance-of-paym ents impact o f total in­
com e and capital flows in future years will be a com bination of
not only these marginal flows associated with the new direct in­
vestm ent but also the positive flows generated by past investments.
On this basis, the calculations show that the net incom e and
capital flows associated with both old and new investments will
continue to be positive and to expand.




14 F. Cutler, “Benchmark Survey o f U .S. D irect Investment
Abroad, 1966”, Survey of Current Business (A ugust 1 9 71).
15 P. Berlin, Foreign Affiliate Financial Survey, 1966-1969
(U nited States Departm ent o f Commerce, Office o f Foreign Direct
Investm ents, July 1971).

174

MONTHLY REVIEW, JULY 1972

been in the absence of foreign direct investment. Never­
theless, very rough estimates of the order of magnitude of
such effects are presented below based on the limited
amount of available data and, most importantly, on judg­
mental assumptions about firm behavior.
Turning first to the question of estimating associated
exports, the only comprehensive data available are
provided in a bench-mark survey of direct investors for
1966. In that year, United States companies’ exports to
overseas affiliates amounted to $7.8 billion, of which $6.3
billion represented shipments by United States manufac­
turing concerns, primarily to their manufacturing affiliates
with distribution outlets receiving most of the remainder.
Several interesting facts emerge from this survey. First,
exports to foreign affiliates accounted for roughly one
half of the total exports of the direct investors. Second,
the total export sales of direct investors accounted for 67
percent of the total United States exports of merchandise
goods.16 Thi; i, as noted earlier, one of the associated ex­
port effects to be expected from United States overseas
investment is a demand for capital equipment— both for
use in constructing and expanding facilities and to fill the
subsequent stream of replacement needs. It has been sug­
gested that United States affiliates might be more likely
than other foreigners to purchase such equipment in the
United States, and therefore such exports would be di­
rectly associated with United States overseas investments.
When exports to affiliates are examined in terms of their
end use, it is apparent that shipments of capital equip­
ment for the affiliates’ use are small, amounting to only
9 percent of total exports to affiliates. Of the other exports
to affiliates, shipments of parts and components for fur­
ther processing or assembly accounted for 40 percent of
the total, with 51 percent of the goods destined for im­
mediate resale or lease. The bulk of the shipments of final
goods was received by manufacturing affiliates, suggesting
that in many cases the manufacturing affiliates themselves
act as distributing agents for finished products from the
United States.
Using these 1966 data as a bench mark and assuming a
constant relationship between exports to affiliates and

16 For comparability with the direct investor export figures, this
total merchandise export figure as published by the Census Bu­
reau is adjusted to exclude goods classified by the Census Bureau
as special category goods— m ainly military-type goods transferred
by the Departm ent o f D efense. For further details, see U.S. DU
rect Investm ents A b r o a d , 1966, Part II, a supplement to the
Survey of Current Business (U nited States Departm ent o f Com ­
merce, Bureau o f Econom ic Analysis, April 1972).




outstanding investments, a comparable figure for associ­
ated exports in 1970 can be estimated to be about $12
billion. It should be noted that this is only a rough esti­
mate of the amount of exports which would not have been
shipped in the absence of the foreign affiliates because it
assumes that all exports of United States firms to their
foreign affiliates can be attributable directly to the owner­
ship of the affiliates. This must be viewed only as an ap­
proximation because, on the one hand, at least some of
the goods sold through affiliates probably would have
been exported anyway. On the other hand, the existence
of the foreign affiliates may have helped promote the sale
— either through the affiliates or directly to other for­
eigners— of goods produced by their United States par­
ents that otherwise would not have been exported.
This brings us to the key question of displaced ex­
ports. At the outset, the argument over possible displace­
ment may be limited to the manufacturing industries
since the output of other affiliates, principally petroleum
and mining and smelting enterprises, represents develop­
ment of raw material sources not available in sufficient
supply in the United States. The problems of evaluating
the magnitude of export displacement render sharply
defined estimates impossible. To obtain such estimates,
it would be necessary to know to what degree the expan­
sion of foreign-sourced output by United States firms
replaced, not United States exports, but other potential
foreign-owned production. In other words, in the absence
of United States-owned affiliates abroad, would the for­
eign demand for the products have been met by United
States exports or by production abroad in a foreign-owned
facility? Here then, subjective assumptions about behavior
become critical. The most reasonable assumptions, as in­
dicated above, seem to be that markets are relatively com­
petitive for most of the manufacturing affiliates’ products,
that a significant portion of United States investment in
overseas facilities is undertaken in response to lower pro­
duction and distribution costs (including the effect of
tariff barriers), and that these cost conditions as well as
needed technological knowledge are fairly readily avail­
able to foreign organizations. These assumptions imply
that, on the basis of relative cost considerations, produc­
tion in the foreign market would eventually replace
United States exports and that, in the absence of United
States firms abroad, foreign firms would in time come to
produce the goods. Thus, some, and probably a large pro­
portion, of affiliate production should be viewed as a sub­
stitute for output of indigenous foreign firms without
United States affiliation rather than as a substitute for
United States exports.
Since the process of substitution of foreign production

175

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

for United States exports is a dynamic one involving ad­
justments over time, some insight into the shift of pro­
duction may be gained by examining the change over time
in relative market shares provided by United States ex­
ports as opposed to foreign affiliate production. For five
major categories of manufactured products for which
comparable data on exports and affiliate sales are avail­
able,17 the share of the market provided by United States
exports fell from 35 percent in 1962 to 30 percent in
1968.18 (See Table II for detailed sales and export data.)
In other words, if the relative market shares had remained
constant over this period, United States exports would

17 Affiliate sales data are classified by type o f industry while
export figures are by type o f product, so that the two categories
are not necessarily com pletely consistent.
18 For this purpose, the total supply to the market is defined as
sales by foreign manufacturing affiliates outside the United States
plus exports from the United States summed across the five major
categories for which we have comparable data. Data for sales and
exports o f transport equipment for Canada are excluded from the
calculations because the figures are heavily influenced by the
m ovem ent across the United States-Canadian border o f autom o­
tive parts associated with the 1965 A utom otive Agreement.

have been about $2 billion higher in 1968 than they actu­
ally were. It must be emphasized that this is not to be
interpreted as a numerical estimate of export loss during
the interval attributable to the existence of the affiliates.
The “loss” might well have occurred anyway as nonaffili­
ated foreign producers assumed a larger market share, and
might more appropriately be viewed as illustrative of a
general loss of competitiveness of United States exports
in world markets.
In summary, the question of whether there has been
export displacement and, if so, of what magnitude essen­
tially cannot be answered on the basis of existing data.
However, when the problem is appropriately viewed as a
dynamic adjustment process over time, reasonable as­
sumptions about firms’ behavior suggest that the amount
of export displacement attributable to direct investment is
likely to be fairly small. This, of course, in no way contra­
dicts the possibility that, at any one point in time, there
may be substitution of foreign affiliate production for
United States exports as the adjustment process works
itself orut.
i m p o r t s . As with exports, the question of what effect
United States direct investment abroad has on United

Table n
SELECTED DATA ON UNITED STATES EXPORTS AND SALES BY FOREIGN MANUFACTURING
AFFILIATES OF UNITED STATES MULTINATIONAL COMPANIES
In billions of dollars
Commodities

1962

1963

1964

1965

1967

1968

Chemicals:
Affiliate sales ......................................................
United States exports ......................................

4.4
1.9

5.1
2.0

5.9
2.4

6.9
2.4

8.9
2.8

10.2
3.3

Rubber products:
Affiliate sales ............................................ .........
United States exports .......................................

1.3
0.1

1.3
0.1

1.6
0.2

1.7
0.2

2.0
0.2

2.1
0.2

Machinery excluding electrical:
Affiliate sales ......................................................
United States exports .......................................

3.4
4.1

3.7
4.2

4.6
4.8

5.4
5.2

7.4
6.2

8.2
6.5

Electrical machinery:
Affiliate sales .......................................................
United States exports ......................................

2.7
1.4

3.0
1.5

3.6
1.7

4.0
1.7

4.8
2.1

5.3
2.3

Transportation equipment:
Affiliate sales ......................................................
United States exports* ...................................

6.7
1.8

8.0
1.9

9.5
2.2

10.7
2.2

12.8
3.1

14.5
3.7

Total for selected goods:
Affiliate sales ......................................................
United States exports* ......................................

18.5
9.3

21.1
9.7

25.2
11.3

28.7
11.7

35.9
14.4

40.3
16.0

* Excludes civilian aircraft.
Sources: United States Department of Commerce, Survey of Current Business and Overseas Business Reports, selected issues.




176

MONTHLY REVIEW, JULY 1972

States imports revolves around attempting to differentiate
between those imports which would have occurred even
in the absence of United States overseas affiliates and
those which may be directly ascribable to the existence
of these subsidiaries. Once again, the discussion may be
limited to imports from manufacturing affiliates since
purchases from petroleum and mining affiliates reflect
primarily raw materials needed in the United States,
which presumably would have been imported even if
the United States investors did not own the overseas
facilities.
Conceptually, the same considerations of exploiting
relative cost conditions as enunciated above in the export
discussion could lead United States firms, not only to
establish production units outside the borders of the
United States, but also to import the output of these
affiliates for direct sale or further assembly in the United
States. The manufacture of electronic components in the
Far East, such as Hong Kong, Taiwan, Korea, and the
Philippines, by United States producers is a frequently
cited example. Other specific examples can surely be
found. To the extent that lower production costs arise
out of differing relative factor endowments or other mar­
ket forces, such overseas production can be seen once
again as merely a more rational utilization of resources.
In other instances, the cost advantages of producing
abroad may arise not from market factors but from
specific incentives provided by host governments. For
example, special concessions are given to United States
firms by Mexico to induce them to set up assembly plants
on the Mexican side of the border and export the final
goods back to the United States. In situations of this
sort there are, of course, benefits to the host country in
terms, for example, of employment and foreign exchange
earnings, but there are also disadvantages to the United
States in terms of displacement of United States workers
with the attendant loss of income. When the cost ad­
vantages arise from artificial incentives, it is questionable
whether a more efficient pattern of resource use results.
The most striking conclusion which can be drawn
from data on sales of foreign manufacturing affiliates to
the United States is that such shipments represent a fairly
small proportion of total affiliate output and a much
smaller percentage of total United States imports than the
comparable relationship between exports to affiliates and
total United States exports. Imports from all foreign
manufacturing affiliates increased approximately fourfold
between 1962 and 1968 and reached a level of $4.7
billion in the latter year, or approximately 15 percent of
total nonmilitary merchandise imports. While the increase
over the period is fairly sizable, it is largely a result of the




1965 Canadian-United States automobile agreement. If
imports of transportation equipment from Canada are ex­
cluded, the remaining imports rose by about two and
one-half times to only $2.5 billion. These sales to the
United States accounted for only some 4 percent of total
affiliate sales in both 1962 and 1968. Thus, by far the
largest part of affiliate output is designed for sale in for­
eign markets, not in the United States.
Furthermore, the available statistics do not support
the claim that there are very significant imports from
affiliates in the areas frequently cited as the “low wage”
countries, such as Mexico, Taiwan, and Korea, where
United States firms are establishing assembly plants and
production facilities for parts and components.19 In fact,
the bulk of the increase in nonautomotive imports has
been from Canada and was principally centered in three
categories: paper and allied products, primary and fabri­
cated metals, and nonelectrical machinery.
Thus, on the basis of the available data, it seems rea­
sonable to conclude that the impact of foreign direct
investment on imports is small. Using the relationship be­
tween imports from affiliates to outstanding investment in
1968, it can be estimated that such imports (excluding
Canadian autos) were about $3 billion in 1970. Not only
is this absolute magnitude of imports from foreign affili­
ates fairly small, but additionally it is likely that a signi­
ficant portion of the goods currently purchased from these
overseas subsidiaries would have been imported from
other foreign sources if the United States affiliates did
not exist.
CONCLUSIONS

In summation, the empirical evidence available to esti­
mate the total impact on the trade balance of direct invest­
ment by United States multinational companies is inade­
quate to the task. As indicated above, rough estimates
can be made from existing statistics of two types of trade
effects associated with direct investment. Combining the
$12 billion of associated exports with the $3 billion import
figure suggests a net positive trade effect in 1970. But
even these are only partial estimates of the total trade bal­
ance effect and must be interpreted with great caution
for several reasons. First, they depend very heavily on

19 H owever, it should be noted that there m ay have been some
increase in this type o f activity recently which would not be cap­
tured in these statistics for 1968.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

the underlying behavioral assumptions. In particular, both
estimates assume that none of these exports to, or imports
from, affiliates would have occurred if the affiliates did
not exist, while in reality it is likely that some indetermi­
nate portion of both would have been traded with foreignowned firms in the absence of United States affiliates.
Second, these trade balance estimates for 1970 do not
take into account any possible export displacement which,
as noted above, may be significant in any particular year.
Third, and perhaps most importantly, all of these trade
effects are more appropriately viewed as part of a dynamic
process over time rather than as a specific impact in any
given period. On this basis, while there may be some
net export gain or loss or import creation in the short run,
over a longer time horizon the portions of the observed
changes in export and import patterns which can reason­
ably be ascribed to the direct investment process itself
probably tend approximately to balance out or perhaps
be a net positive item. Rather, most of the observed
alterations in trade patterns should more appropriately be




177

viewed as market responses to shifts in worldwide relative
competitive conditions, and would have occurred whether
or not the foreign facilities were owned by United States
investors.
The real balance-of-payments impact of United States
direct investment activities, then, hinges on the relation­
ship between capital account items and related financial
flows and, on this basis, the evidence seems clear that
United States direct investment is a long-run positive fac­
tor in the balance of payments. It must be recognized,
however, that there are still many unanswered questions
about the underlying motivations and the dynamic pro­
cesses involved in foreign direct investment. There are
most likely significant differences among industries and
countries which temper the investment decision, and the
future outlook could well be affected by changes in inter­
national economic and political relations.' There is a
great need for more and better statistics on the interna­
tional operations of multinational firms and wide scope
for further research on this important topic.

178

MONTHLY REVIEW, JULY 1972

Th e Program for the Automation of the Governm ent Securities M arket
By R i c h a r d A . D e b s
Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of New York

Editor’s Note: The following is based on a memorandum which was completed on
March 21,1972 and which was subsequently submitted by the Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System to the Subcommittee on Securities of the Committee on
Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs of the United States Senate in connection with
hearings relating to the clearance and settlement of securities transactions. The author
has responsibility for the Government Bond and Safekeeping operations of the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York. He is also chairman of a Federal Reserve
System Subcommittee on Fiscal Agency Operations, which acts as liaison between
the Federal Reserve Banks and the Treasury Department with respect to Reserve
Bank operations conducted as agent for the United States Government.

This paper outlines the development and current status
of the Federal Reserve-Treasury program for the automa­
tion of the Government securities market, including the
book-entry procedure for Government securities.
O BJECTIVES AND SCOPE

The ultimate objective of the program is a fully auto­
mated Government securities market, in which the pieces
of paper representing Government obligations—including
both Treasury and Federal agency obligations— have been
eliminated and replaced by computerized book-entries,
and in which transactions in such book-entry securities are
effected by means of wire messages—including computerto-computer communications— through high-speed lines
directly linking computer terminals on the premises of
each major market participant throughout the country.
In general, the program was designed to improve the
efficiency of operations in Government securities. It is in­
tended to reduce the time, money, personnel, and space
required to handle the increasing volume and velocity of
transactions in Government securities and, at the same
time, to ensure adequate controls and reduce to a mini­
mum the risk of loss or theft of such securities.




The benefits of the program will be available to all
owners of Government securities—whether they be pri­
mary dealers or private individuals— through the member
banks, which will be qualified to open book-entry accounts
at their Federal Reserve Banks and to deposit any or all
of their customers’ securities in such accounts. Thus, all
owners of Government securities may, if they so desire,
arrange to have their securities converted into book-entry
form by depositing them with a member bank, which in
turn will deposit the securities in its book-entry account
with its Reserve Bank. In this respect, the program pro­
vides a substitute for the physical custody of Government
securities.
In addition, and just as important, for those banks and
bank customers which are active participants in the Gov­
ernment securities market— such as the primary bank
dealers and the primary nonbank dealers, through their
clearing banks—facilities will be available for effecting
central market transactions in such securities through
Federal Reserve wire systems. In this respect, the program
provides a means for moving the book-entry securities
throughout all segments of the Government securities
market, with the speed and in the volume necessary to en­
sure the effective functioning of the market.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

Historically, the automation program has comprised
two separate, but parallel, lines of development. The first
was the development of facilities for transferring and
clearing securities transactions among the major partici­
pants in the market, beginning with the New York money
center banks and the establishment of the Government
Securities Clearing Arrangement. The second was the de­
velopment of the book-entry procedure itself, which began
with the conversion into book-entry form of Treasury
securities owned by country member banks and held in
safekeeping at their Reserve Banks. More recently, there
has been a third related development of significance for
the Federal Reserve System—the creation of the Reserve
Bank “checklist procedure”, developed as a transitional
measure to deal with the immediate problem of Govern­
ment securities thefts, pending the longer-term solution
offered by the automation program.
WIRE F A C ILITIE S AND CLEARING ARRANGEM ENTS

The basic concept of transferring Government securities
by means of wire messages has existed for many years in
the “CPD” wire facilities maintained by the Treasury and
the Federal Reserve Banks, which permit wire transfers
between most Federal Reserve offices. Under this system,
the commercial bank sender of a security delivers it to the
local Federal Reserve office, which then retires the secu­
rity and sends an appropriate wire message to another
Federal Reserve office, which in turn issues a new security,
which is then picked up by the ultimate recipient of the
transfer message.
The clearing arrangement carries this basic concept
further in three important respects: (1) instead of requir­
ing the delivery and pickup of a physical security for each
transfer, the transfers are debited or credited to a bank’s
“securities clearing account”—with appropriate cash en­
tries to its reserve account— and only one delivery of
securities is necessary at the end of the day, and only in
the net amount due to or due from the bank; (2) the
major commercial banks having a large volume of such
transactions are linked by wire directly with their Reserve
Bank, permitting them to transmit transfer messages from
terminals on their premises; and (3) as the final step in
a money market center, the major commercial banks are
linked with each other, through a Reserve Bank computer
switch, permitting them— and their customers, including
the nonbank primary dealers— to effect transactions
among themselves, thereby providing each of them access
to the other major participants in the Government secu­
rities market through their own terminals.
The first experiments with clearing procedures were




179

initiated in New York City in 1965, and resulted in the
establishment of the Government Securities Clearing Ar­
rangement, which now includes twelve participating mem­
ber banks. Over the years— and particularly since the in­
stallation of the Federal Reserve System’s Culpeper switch
and the Sigma 5 computer switch at the New York Re­
serve Bank— the arrangement has been expanded to the
point where it now handles virtually all types of transac­
tions in the Government securities market, in any volume
that may be required. As an example, during 1971, a year
of transition to the use of the new computer equipment,
there were about 470,000 transactions effected through
the Clearing Arrangement, totaling $710 billion. Last
month alone, there were more than 50,000 transactions,
totaling $99 billion.
Studies are now in progress for developing clearing
procedures at other Reserve Banks. The San Francisco
Reserve Bank has been operating a net settlement proce­
dure for CPD transfers with one of its member banks, and
the Chicago Reserve Bank has been exploring the possi­
bility of a similar procedure with its larger member banks.
Other Reserve Banks have been considering the possible
use of such procedures at some future date, as increasing
volume may warrant it. The importance of such proce­
dures lies not only in their immediate benefits, but even
more important, in the potential for integrating a clearing
arrangement with the basic book-entry procedure.
BO O K -EN TR Y PROCEDURE

In essence, the book-entry procedure is a new legal sys­
tem, created by Federal regulations having the force of
Federal law (e.g., Subpart O of Treasury Circular No.
300), under which the piece of paper representing a Gov­
ernment obligation may be eliminated, and the obligation
recorded on the books of a Federal Reserve Bank. The
first phase in the development of the procedure began in
1968, when it was established as a substitute for the physi­
cal custody of Treasury securities in the safekeeping ac­
counts maintained by the Reserve Banks for country mem­
ber banks. Although the procedure was made available to
all member banks at that time, until last year most of the
largest money center banks did not utilize the procedure,
primarily because of burdensome tax-reporting require­
ments.
Since 1968, there has been a gradual extension of the
procedure to additional types of securities accounts. The
process has been gradual because the conversion of each
class of security account has presented new and different
legal problems, tax questions, and operational complica­
tions. These are reflections of the fact that for centuries

180

MONTHLY REVIEW, JULY 1972

the law, commercial practices, and traditions governing
transactions in securities have been based on the posses­
sion of a piece of paper having intrinsic value. Under the
book-entry procedure, that piece of paper no longer exists.
By the end of 1970, most of the different types of safe­
keeping accounts maintained at the Reserve Banks had
been converted to book-entry form. The next phase of the
program contemplated an extension to Government securi­
ties held outside the Reserve Banks, including in particular
the securities of the primary dealers in Government securi­
ties— both bank dealers, which involved certain tax ques­
tions, and nonbank dealers, which involved in addition the
question of their legal status as customers of clearing
banks. Beyond that phase, the program aimed at covering
all securities held by member banks for any third party.
The overall plan for the conversion of these types of
securities accounts envisaged a program of several years’
duration. However, the timetable was greatly accelerated
by the “insurance crisis” in the Government securities mar­
ket early last year, which resulted from the abrupt emer­
gence of the problem of securities thefts.
SEC UR ITIES T H E F T S AND C H ECK LIST PROCEDURE

The problem of securities thefts is in large part rooted in
the difficulties of the financial community in coping with
the vast amounts of paper required by traditional methods
of operation. During the past year, the matter has been the
subject of close study by Congressional committees, the
Securities and Exchange Commission, and the financial
community itself. The studies continue, and will no doubt
result in basic changes in existing procedures in the bank­
ing system and in the securities markets, some of which
will come about as a result of Federal legislation. The
Federal Reserve has an interest in many aspects of this
problem and its proposed solutions, but for present pur­
poses it should suffice to note only those relating directly
to the Government securities market.
The problem of securities thefts first came to public at­
tention in connection with Government securities. Within
a matter of weeks at the end of 1969, $17 million in Gov­
ernment securities were reported stolen from three New
York City banks. By the end of that year, a national total
of approximately $30 million in losses had been reported
to the Treasury, and the losses continued at the same high
level in 1970.
In view of the magnitude of the problem, it was clear
that the Federal Reserve System had a direct interest in
the matter. Apart from the responsibilities of the Reserve
Banks as fiscal agents of the United States, the System had
an immediate concern in the problem as it affected the




banking system, and also as it affected the performance of
the Government securities market. It was also clear that,
while the book-entry program offered a long-term solution
as a means of preventing thefts, there was an immediate
need to assist in recovering securities already stolen.
It was against this background that the “checklist pro­
cedure” was developed. Under the procedure, which was
adopted on a uniform basis by all Federal Reserve Banks
through the Conference of First Vice Presidents of the
Federal Reserve Banks, a current list of stolen securities
is maintained at each Federal Reserve office, based on
reports received from banks and other financial institu­
tions throughout the country, and more recently, from the
Treasury. Up-to-date information is promptly circulated
to all Federal Reserve offices, by wire, through the New
York Reserve Bank, which acts as the coordinating bank
under the procedure. With the list, each Federal Reserve
office checks the securities received at that office, and also
serves as a clearing house for information on stolen securi­
ties within its own territory.
Experience with the checklist procedure since 1970 in­
dicates that it has been fairly successful in achieving its
primary objective— to assist in discovering stolen securi­
ties. It does not, of course, prevent securities thefts, a
longer-term objective that the book-entry program seeks
to achieve.
INSURANCE CRISIS AND AC CE LE R A TE D
BO O K -E N TR Y PROGRAM

The problem of thefts led directly to the “insurance
crisis” of early 1971, which endangered the continued
functioning of the Government securities market. At that
time, the Continental Insurance Company had announced
plans to terminate its coverage of bearer Government
securities held by money center banks, dealers, and brok­
ers. Since Continental was the predominant carrier in the
field, there was a risk ihat if such plans were implemented,
the major participants in the market would terminate op­
erations, and the market would cease to function.
The ultimate avoidance of such a result required sev­
eral months of intensive negotiations involving the Fed­
eral Reserve, the Treasury, the insurance companies, and
the leaders of the banking and securities industries. It also
involved the adoption of a contingency plan to attempt to
handle essential market operations through the New York
Reserve Bank; it required the enactment of Federal legis­
lation to permit the Treasury to settle claims on stolen
securities; and— most important in the long run— it re­
sulted in the formulation of a greatly accelerated program
for the further extension of the book-entry procedure.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

The new program was designed to accelerate existing
long-term plans for automation as rapidly as possible. The
program required action by the Treasury, in amending the
governing Treasury regulation; by the Internal Revenue
Service, in amending its tax rulings on dealer securities
and tax-reporting requirements; and by the Federal Re­
serve Banks, through the Committee on Fiscal Agency
Operations of the Conference of First Vice Presidents of
the Federal Reserve Banks, in revising Reserve Bank oper­
ating rules and procedures. To be successful in averting
the complete termination of insurance coverage, the pro­
gram also required action by the New York City banks
affected by the crisis, who were expected to begin promptly
the process of converting their securities accounts to the
book-entry procedure.
By April 1971, all of the necessary legal actions had
been completed. In brief, the program contemplated that
the book-entry procedure would be extended to cover (a)
securities owned by primary dealers—both bank dealers,
and nonbank dealers acting through their clearing banks;
(b) securities held by member banks in customer ac­
counts, including the establishment of special book-entry
accounts to accommodate collateral loans, repurchase
agreements, pledges, and similar arrangements; and (c)
eventually, securities held by member banks in trust ac­
counts, which required the resolution of certain legal
questions under state laws. The plan also contemplated the
further development and utilization of the Government
Securities Clearing Arrangement and the System’s wire
network. In addition, plans were made for the extension
of the overall program to the securities of Federal
agencies.
When the program was formulated, it was understood
that it would be put into effect in stages; the first stage
was limited to the New York City banks participating in
the Clearing Arrangement, who were most vulnerable to
the problem of insurance coverage. In view of the pres­
sures under which the program was formulated, such an
approach was also deemed desirable as a means of ex­
perimenting with the new procedures and developing a
basic pattern of book-entry accounts that could accom­
modate the operations of all member banks.
During the first six months of the program, nine banks
opened new book-entry accounts, including several special
accounts in which a limited number of customer securities
were gradually deposited. Several banks— particularly the
clearing banks, acting as agents for the nonbank dealers—
encountered delays because of the need to develop ade­
quate computer systems to handle the volumes involved.
During the period, the capabilities of the Clearing Ar­
rangement were further enlarged as the computer switch




181

systems came into operation, and all of the new bookentry accounts were integrated into the Clearing Arrange­
ment. During the same period, New York State enacted
legislation, endorsed by the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York, to permit the application of the book-entry procedure
to Government securities held by banks as trustees.
At the end of the six-month period, there was a compre­
hensive review of operations in the light of experience to
date, which indicated the desirability and feasibility of cer­
tain changes in the basic legal concepts underlying the bookentry procedure— particularly with respect to transfers and
pledges of customer securities— that would obviate cer­
tain operating complexities and result in a much simpler
system. Since then, the System Subcommittee of Counsel
on Fiscal Agency Operations, working with counsel to
the commercial banks and Treasury counsel, have been
developing the necessary legal framework to implement
the changes. It is expected that the new rules will be pub­
lished in the Federal Register as amendments to the gov­
erning Treasury regulation within the next week or two.*
CURRENT S TA TU S

At this point in time, ten of the participating banks
have opened a variety of new book-entry accounts, in­
cluding separate accounts to hold investment portfolios,
dealer inventories, customer securities, and special col­
lateral accounts. The total amount in these accounts is
now about $4 billion, and is continuing to increase. The
securities already deposited in these accounts include some
or all of the dealer inventories of most of the dealer banks
(including dealer banks in the Chicago and San Francisco
Districts, through their New York clearing banks), and
most of the nonbank dealers. The process of conversion
has been gradual and is continuing.
All of these book-entry accounts have been integrated
into the Clearing Arrangement. This means, in effect, that
all transactions in these accounts— including purchases,
sales, repurchase agreements, free deliveries, denomina­
tional exchanges, original issues, redemptions at maturity,
and any associated debits or credits to Reserve accounts—
are effected through the terminals located on the premises
of the member bank depositors, without the need for the
existence of any physical security.
The overall volume handled through the Clearing Ar­

* Editor’s note: The am endments were published on April 29,
1972.

182

MONTHLY REVIEW, JULY 1972

rangement continues to increase. In the week of Febru­
ary 18, during a Treasury refunding operation, 17,285
transactions went through the arrangement, totaling about
$32 billion.
In terms of the book-entry program as a whole, there
are approximately $171 billion in Treasury securities in
book-entry form at all Reserve Banks. About $145 billion
of that amount is held at the New York Reserve Bank.
Of the total amount in book-entry form, approximately
$155 billion is in marketable public issues, out of a total
of about $262 billion in total marketable public debt out­
standing. Thus, approximately 60 percent of the out­
standing marketable public debt is in book-entry form. In
addition there are about $84 billion in “special issues” in
book-entry form. Including these issues, approximately 70
percent of the outstanding gross public debt, excluding
savings bonds, is in book-entry form. In terms of the goals
of the program, there remains roughly $95 billion in bearer
Treasury securities eligible for conversion into book-entry
form. The great bulk of these securities is held by parties
which are— or could be— customers of member banks,
including trust accounts.
FUTURE PLANS

At this point, the most immediate goal of the program
is to complete the process of conversion of all primary
dealers’ securities. Then, as soon as the new amendments
to the Treasury regulation are published, the way will be
open to continue with the further extension of the pro­
gram to all customer securities, not only at the participat­
ing New York banks, but also at the other member banks
throughout the country. The basic pattern of accounts
and procedures has been worked out in the light of the
New York banks’ experience, and the new amendments
should facilitate the expansion of the program for all
member banks. There are some particular questions that
have yet to be resolved— such as agreement on contingency
plans in the event of computer failures and other emer­
gencies, and approval of a form of lending agreement
among the major market participants—but these questions
will no doubt be resolved soon. As soon as they are settled,
and as soon as new uniform operating circulars are formu­
lated for all Reserve Banks through the Conference of




First Vice Presidents, each Reserve Bank should be in a
position to make the program available to member banks
in its District. All Reserve Bank fiscal agency officers have
been preparing for that step; there have been meetings of
such officers during the past year to review the operations
of the program, and another meeting will be held soon,
before the next phase is begun.
While the book-entry program will be available to all
member banks for their customer securities, the rate at
which those securities will be converted will depend upon
the capabilities of the member banks themselves. No doubt
the process of conversion will continue to be a gradual
one. In addition, the laws of many states present legal
problems that must be resolved, presumably by legisla­
tion, before member banks subject to such laws may con­
vert securities held in trust accounts, which, of course,
comprise a large proportion of commercial bank custody
accounts.
Once the revised Treasury regulation is published, simi­
lar book-entry regulations can be promulgated by the other
Federal agencies, and the next phase of the program will
focus on the inclusion of agency securities. In January of
this year, the Postal Service became the first Federal
agency to promulgate a book-entry regulation and to issue
securities in book-entry form, but that was a rather special
situation. The inclusion of all of the issues of all Federal
agencies will be a gradual process, but it presents no spe­
cial legal or operational problems that would be difficult
to resolve.
It is impossible to indicate a timetable for the comple­
tion of the automation program. Apart from the obvious
uncertainties involved, it would be difficult to measure
with any precision the point at which the basic objectives
of the program will have been achieved. While it may be
desirable to attempt to convert all outstanding Treasury
and agency securities to book-entry form, the purposes of
the automation program will have been fulfilled long be­
fore that stage is reached. The program will have achieved
its ends whenever all— or virtually all—transactions m
Treasury and agency securities in the Government securi­
ties market can be effected by means of wire messages
among the major participants in the market, without the
need for physical securities. In the light of the experience
to date, that time does not seem too far distant.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

Publications of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Distribution and charge policy: The following selected publications are available from the Public
Information Department. Except for periodicals, mailing lists are not maintained for these publications.
The first 100 copies of the Bank’s general publications and the first copy of its special publications
are free on reasonable requests. Additional copies of general and special publications are free on reasonable
requests for educational purposes to certain United States and foreign organizations. United States: schools
(including their bookstores), commercial banks, public and other nonprofit libraries, news media, and Fed­
eral Government departments and agencies; foreign: central government departments and agencies, central
banks, and news media. (Such additional free copies will be sent only to school, business, or government
addresses.) Other organizations are charged for copies exceeding normal limits on free quantities (prices are
listed with the publications).
Remittances must accompany requests if charges apply. Delivery is postpaid and takes two to four
weeks. Remittances must be payable on their faces to the Bank in United States dollars collectible at
par, that is, without a collection charge.
GENERAL PUBLICATIONS
m o n e y : m a s t e r o r s e r v a n t ? (1971) by Thomas O. Waage. 45 pages. A comprehensive discussion
of the roles of money, commercial banks, and the Federal Reserve in our economy. Explains what money
is and how it works in a dynamic economy. (15 cents each if charges apply)
p e r s p e c t i v e . Published each January. 9 pages. A nontechnical review of the major domestic and in­
ternational economic developments of the previous year. Sent to all Monthly Review subscribers. (6 cents
each if charges apply)

SPECIAL PUBLICATIONS
e s s a y s i n d o m e s t i c a n d i n t e r n a t i o n a l f i n a n c e (1969) 86 pages. A collection of nine articles
dealing with a few important past episodes in United States central banking, several facets of the relationship
between financial variables and business activity, and various aspects of domestic and international financial
markets. (70 cents each if charges apply)
t h e v e l o c it y o f m o n e y
(1970, second edition) by George Garvy and Martin R. Blyn. 116 pages.
A thorough discussion of the demand for money and the measurement of, influences on, and the implications
of changes in the velocity of money. ($1.50 each if charges apply)

c e n t r a l b a n k c o o p e r a t i o n : 1924-31 (1967) by Stephen V. O. Clarke. 234 pages. A documented
discussion of the efforts of American, British, French, and German central bankers to reestablish and main­
tain international financial stability between 1924 and 1931. ($2.00 each if charges apply)
m o n e y , b a n k i n g , a n d c r e d i t i n e a s t e r n e u r o p e (1966) by George Garvy. 167 pages. A re­
view of the characteristics, operations, and changes in the monetary systems of seven communist countries
of Eastern Europe and the steps taken toward greater reliance on financial incentives. ($1.25 each if charges
apply)