View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

2

MONTHLY REVIEW, JANUARY 1960

T he B u sin ess Situation
The economy was revitalized in December by a swell­
ing flow of urgently needed steel. Automobile producers
and many other users of ferrous products who had been
short of steel were able to recall furloughed employees
and start filling back orders. Christmas buying apparently
set a new peak, boosting employment in retail trade and
certain other fields. And some uncertainties in the eco­
nomic picture were removed by the settlement of wage
negotiations covering many employees of the struck copper
industry, the East Coast docks (which had been operating
under a Taft-Hartley injunction), the aluminum industry,
and the nation’s two largest can companies. The settlement
of the steel strike in early January, of course, removed
another major question mark overhanging the business
scene. However, there were still important factors con­
tributing to an uneasy hesitation as to the weeks just
ahead. The effects of the various wage settlements upon
prices could not as yet be appraised. Numerous firms in
need of steel were not yet receiving adequate supplies,
and output and employment in many metal-working and
machinery industries consequently remained much below
pre-strike levels.
THE RENEW ED U PTU R N

The struck steel mills, which achieved a surprisingly
rapid recovery of output following the November 7 re­
opening, were operating at more than 96 per cent of
capacity (rated as of the beginning of 1959) by the second
week of December. In actual volume, weekly output
reached a record 2.73 million tons of ingots. Output
slipped slightly during the final half of the month, but
this was a result of the usual holiday closings. Shipments
lagged behind the high level of ingot production, because
the processing of steel into the various products demanded
by the mills’ customers requires, in some cases, several
additional weeks. Trade sources estimated, moreover,
that about one fourth of the December shipments would
be absorbed by “in transit” operations and by the rebuild­
ing of the better balanced stocks needed for starting up
operations in steel-using enterprises. A survey taken
in late November by some 415 purchasing executives in
steel-using industries showed that one fourth of those
polled thought steel supplies for their companies would
be insufficient for normal production until March or later.
Unusually heavy demands by automobile and railroad
equipment producers in the first quarter of 1960 are
expected to aggravate the steel difficulties of other firms.




Total industrial production rose slightly in November
and advanced more sharply in. December. The October
level had been the lowest point in the strike period,
7 per cent below the June record of 110 per cent of
the 1957 base now used in the index. (The Federal
Reserve’s index has recently been extensively revised to
use more up-to-date weights and to include output of
electricity and gas; the new index is now available with
a new base year, 1957, and also with the old base of
1947-49.) The one-point increase to 103 in November
reflected primarily the sharp rise in steel production and
an expansion in output of the bituminous coal and iron
ore required by the reopened steel mills. Despite the
increase in steel, the gain in total production was small
because of offsetting declines in automobile production
and electrical machinery. In December, however, the
index is expected to reflect the steep climb that occurred
that month in auto output, as well as the further expansion
in steel production.
Employment also moved up again, as the wheels of
industry started to turn faster. Nonagricultural employ­
ment rose by 124,000 between mid-October and midNovember, to a total of 52.1 million, seasonally adjusted
(see Chart I). Although unemployment rose over the
same period, the increase was less than seasonal and the
seasonally adjusted ratio of unemployed to the total
civilian labor force receded to 5.6 per cent from the
October strike-time high of 6.0 per cent. Later in Novem­
ber, there were additional layoffs of automobile workers,
but these had all been recalled by mid-December.
Personal income increased in November to a new alltime high of $384.8 billion (seasonally adjusted annual
rate). The previous peak, $1 billion lower, had been
reached in June. The $2.5 billion increase in November
was the largest of the monthly rises that have occurred
since September. Wage and salary payments rose by $1
billion, as sharply higher payrolls in the steel industry
and in the dependent mining and transportation industries
more than offset declines in steel-using industries. Transfer
payments also increased substantially.
The rise in personal income helped push retail sales
of nondurables to new heights in November, 2 per cent
above the October level on a seasonally adjusted basis
(see Chart I). Total retail sales, it is true, declined in
November by 1 per cent after seasonal adjustment; but
this was primarily attributable to a drop in sales of auto­
mobiles, resulting from the depletion of dealers’ inventories

3

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

Chart i

IN V E S T M E N T A C T IV IT Y

THE RENEWED UPTURN
Seasonally adjusted

110

110

100
90

In d u stria l p ro d u ctio n

-1,. ..l ^ T

100
90

!..... 1,, I - 1

Billions of d o llars

Billions of dollars

1958

Business plans for expenditures on plant and equipment
indicate continuing strength in that area, although the
anticipated growth is slower than the rates of increase
achieved during the first three quarters of 1959. A survey
conducted by the Securities and Exchange Commission
and the Department of Commerce in late October and
early November showed that business firms expected to
make capital outlays during the fourth quarter of 1959
at a seasonally adjusted annual rate of $34.0 billion, up
$600 million from the third quarter’s actual outlays; in
the first quarter of 1960, they intend to spend at an annual
rate $450 million higher than in the last quarter of 1959
(see Chart II).
Shortages and uncertainties resulting from the steel
strike did, of course, depress actual expenditures in the
third quarter and presumably contributed to the downward
revision in estimates for the fourth quarter. These factors
may have held down the spending rate anticipated
for the quarter just begun. The principal increases from
the third to the fourth quarter of 1959 were expected
to occur in manufacturing industries, with an almost equal

1959

^ R eflects paym ent of retroactive s a la ry in creases to Fed eral Governm ent
em ployees.

Ch art II

PLANT AND EQUIPMENT OUTLAYS

^ United States Bureau of Labor Statistics series.
Sources: Board of G overn ors of the Federal R eserve System , United States
Bureau of Labor Statistics, and United States Departm ent of Comm erce.

Se a so n a lly adjusted, a n n u a l rates
B illions of d o lla rs

40

B illio n s of d ollars

40

A L L B U S IN E S S E S

38

due to steel shortages. Preliminary data on department
store sales suggest that consumer demand remained strong
in December, although the increase in sales may have
been less marked than in the previous month. Automobile
sales were still depressed in the early part of December,
but may have risen in the latter part as 1960 models began
to reach dealers in greater numbers.
In contrast to the foregoing gains, construction outlays
in November decreased—-the sixth consecutive monthly
decline. The biggest drop, $700 million out of the total of
$1 billion, was in spending for private residential construc­
tion, which was 11 per cent below the May peak. The
limited supply of mortgage funds, especially for FHA- and
VA-underwritten instruments, was apparently the principal
reason for this decline. The rest of the November decrease
was attributable to the government sector, and particularly
to State and local government outlays for road construc­
tion. On the other hand, outlays for private nonresidential
construction, which had fallen in September and October
partly because of steel shortages, rose slightly.




A n t ic ip a t io n s
a s of th ird q u a r te r

36

V

34
32 -

/

i -

34

7

1...... J......

__1

28

_ L J____1„ .. ....1

-

1

Billio ns of d o lla rs

1

Billions of dollars

......... ....... „

28

10

A n t ic ip a t io n s [
a s o f th ird q u a r t e r

1

V

_

1 “

— —
J ..... 1 ...1
II

III

1957

30

B illio ns of dollars

N O N D U R A B L E M A N U F A C T U R IN G

I

32

Billions of d o llars

10

10

36

A n tic ip a tio n s
a s o f fou rth q u a r t e r

30

38

_1..... 1 ...I...
IV

I

II

III

1958

IV

-

A n tic ip a tio n s
a s o f fo u rth q u a r te r

I

II

III

1959

IV

I

1960

Sources: United States Departm ent of Commerce, and Securities and
Exchange Comm ission.

4

MONTHLY REVIEW, JANUARY 1960

division between durables (mainly the iron and steel indus­
try) and nondurables. The further advance foreseen for the
first quarter of 1960 was limited entirely to manufacturing,
and largely to expenditures planned by iron and steel
companies and by manufacturers of motor vehicles and
other transportation equipment.
Further confirmation of increasing investment activity
is found in the 6 per cent increase in capital appropriations

(seasonally adjusted) of large manufacturing firms between
the second and third quarters of 1959, as reported by the
National Industrial Conference Board. Appropriations—
that is, formal approvals of capital spending plans—usually
precede expenditures by several months. Excluding the
strike-hit steel industry, the recent increase was the largest
registered in any third quarter since this survey began
in 1956.

M on ey M a rk e t in the Fourth Q u arter
During the final quarter of 1959, while other areas of
the economy slackened under the influence of the steel
strike, demand and expectations remained buoyant in the
money and capital markets. Interest rates, both long- and
short-term, reached record highs for the past quarter
century or more. Bank reserve positions, although no
tighter than during the two preceding quarters, reflected
the cumulative stress of seasonal credit demands and
shrinking liquidity. While the expansion in commercial
bank loans appeared to be less rapid than in previous
months, this seems to have been due principally to the
effects of the steel strike. With the resumption of steel
output, and as the effects of the strike work themselves
out, market observers generally were anticipating that the
demand for credit would be relatively strong after the
turn of the year.
The money market continued tight throughout the
quarter despite some statistical indications of slightly
reduced pressure on member bank reserve positions, as
average net borrowed reserves of all member banks de­
clined somewhat from their third-quarter level. The
reduction in net borrowed reserves, however, in part re­
flected the release of reserves through changes in regula­
tions permitting the use of certain amounts of vault cash
to meet reserve requirements, and through other technical
changes. These measures, which became effective in early
December, primarily benefited country banks and, there­
fore, had little immediate or pronounced effect on the
tone of the central money market.
Yields on Government securities declined in October
but moved irregularly upward thereafter to close the
quarter at a substantially higher level than at its start.
Rate movements were particularly pronounced in the
Treasury bill market, but also spread to notes and bonds.
Market psychology during this period was strongly con­




ditioned by expectations of bank and corporate liquidation
of bills to meet the increased demand for funds, related
not only to the resumption of steel production but also
to the mid-December tax and dividend payments. The
Government securities market was also affected by Treas­
ury financing operations during the quarter, and by antici­
pations of additional financing which the Treasury will
undertake early in the new year.
After the close of business on December 30, the
Treasury announced that it would seek to raise $2 billion
in cash through an additional issue of June 22 tax anticipa­
tion bills, to be sold at auction on January 5. In addition,
it will replace $1.5 billion of the $2 billion bill issue
maturing January 15 with a new issue of one-year bills,
to be sold at auction on January 12, and will redeem the
balance of the maturing bills for cash. Net Treasury cash
borrowing in January would thus amount to $1.5 billion,
or less than had been generally anticipated.
C O M M E R C IA L

BANK

C R E D IT

Commercial bank credit developments in the fourth
quarter of 1959 followed much the same over-all pattern
that was in evidence all year long: there was little change
in total loans and investments as a further, if somewhat
less rapid, increase in loans was roughly offset by a con­
tinued liquidation of the banks’ securities holdings.
In the first eleven months of 1959, responding to strong
demands for bank credit from an expanding economy,
loans of all commercial banks increased by $9.2 billion
(data are not yet available for December). This rise was
only slightly smaller than the $9.8 billion increase during
the comparable period of 1955, when the economy was
also in a strong expansion, and it was considerably greater
than in any of the intervening years. Data for weekly
reporting banks through December 23 point to a further

5

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

loan advance in that month. As in 1955, consumer and
real estate credit and loans to business all contributed to
the credit expansion in 1959. Consumer credit, in fact,
rose somewhat more rapidly than in 1955, while the
increase in real estate credit in the first eleven months of
1959 was roughly the same as in 1955. The $4 billion
advance in loans to business, however, did not match the
$5.4 billion expansion in 1955.
As noted earlier, preliminary data suggest that the over­
all expansion of bank loans abated somewhat during the
fourth quarter. Loans of all commercial banks rose only
$1.0 billion during October-November, compared with
increases of $2.1 billion in the comparable period of 1958
and $2.7 billion in 1955, with the decline in the rate of
advance having been particularly pronounced for business
loans. The slowdown is traceable largely to a lull in
growth in October when, under the impact of the steel
strike and the attendant liquidation of inventories, the in­
crease was the smallest in a decade. The rate of advance
appears to have increased again in November and Decem­
ber, although data for weekly reporting banks through
December 23 suggest a smaller increase for the quarter
than in either 1955 or 1958.
The commercial banks in the fourth quarter of 1959,
as earlier in the year, financed the expansion of their loans
through a further liquidation of their holdings of Govern-

Tabie I
Q uarterly C hanges in Principal A ss e ts and L ia b ilities of th e
W eek ly R eporting M em ber B anks
(In m illions of dollars)
1959

Fourth quarter*

Assets
II

III

1955

+ 2,303
+
50
142
+ 504
+ 262

+ 1,255
+
61
181
+ 258
+ 550

+1,967}
+ 580
99
+ 433

+
+
+
-++

+2,875

+2,290 + 2 ,1 3 0

I

1958

1959

Loans and investments:
Loans:

Commercial and industrial loans.
Agricultural loans........................
Securities loans............................
Real estate loans.........................
All other loans (largely consumer)

+
+

Total loans adjusted t .............. -

226
8
145
207
126

67 + 2 ,955 + 1,922

887
45
517
489
355

+ 1,423
—
28
+ 299
+ 196
+ 242

Investments:

U. S. Government securities:
929 + 243 +
Treasury bills........................... + 276 O ther......................................... - 1 ,7 8 0 -2 ,2 1 4 -2 ,1 0 2 -

540 +
627 -

889 +
374 —

147
778

T otal..................................... - 1 ,5 0 4 -3 ,1 4 3 -1 ,8 5 9 206 37 Other securities............................ + 157 -

87 +
435 -

515 —
230 —

631
286

-

522 +

285 —

917

Total investments................... -1 ,3 4 7
Total loans, adjusted,! and invest­
ments .......................................................... -1 ,4 1 4

-3 ,3 4 9
-

-1 .8 9 6

394 +

26 +2,353

+ 2,575

+1,213

Note: Data for 1958 and 1959 are reported on an expanded coverage basis and are not strictly
comparable with 1955. For comparability, commercial and industrial loans in the third and
fourth quarters of 1959 include the category “ loans to uonbank financial institutions” .
♦ The latest 1959 data available are for December 23; fourth-quarter changes for each year
cover approximately the same period.
f Exclusive of loans to banks and after deduction of valuation reserves; figures for the individual
loan classifications are shown gross and may not, therefore, add to the totals shown.




Chert I

CHANGES IN MONEY SUPPLY AND IN LOANS
AND INVESTMENTS AT ALL COMMERCIAL BANKS
1958 AND 1959
Cum ulated from end of 1957
Billions of d o llars

Billions of dollars

Note: D ata for 1959 are p a rtly estim ated and exclud e structural changes
resulting from the additio n of banks in A la sk a and H a w a ii.

ment securities. Indeed, the investment decline for all
commercial banks for the first eleven months of 1959 was
somewhat greater than the large net liquidation in 1955—
$8.4 billion as against $7.6 billion.
The relative stability in total commercial bank loans
and investments found its counterpart in the continued
stability of the money supply, shown in Chart I. While
the seasonally adjusted money supply (demand deposits
adjusted plus currency outside banks) rose by $0.2 billion
during November, this was the first increase since July.
Because of the continuous decline from August through
October, the $139.9 billion level reached in November
(seasonally adjusted) was still lower than in most months
since February and was $2.5 billion below the July peak.
For the twelve months ended in November the money
supply rose only 0.8 per cent, compared with 3.6 per cent
in the year ended November 1958 and an average of 1.8
per cent per year over the past five years. There were
indications, however, that the money supply increased
somewhat more rapidly in December, and that the total
increase for 1959 may be somewhat greater than sug­
gested by the data through November. The relative sta­

6

MONTHLY REVIEW, JANUARY 1960

bility of the money supply was accompanied by its more
intense use. Thus, the rate of turnover of demand deposits
in centers outside New York City and other large financial
centers rose 6 per cent during the year through November.
The continued rise in bank loans and the further de­
cline in their Government securities holdings meant, of
course, that bank liquidity decreased further and began to
exert a more active influence on bank portfolio policies.
By December, loan-deposit ratios—which are often used
as an inverse measure of bank liquidity even though they
include some highly liquid assets (loans to Government
securities dealers, for example)—reached 69 per cent for
the New York City weekly reporting banks and 58 per
cent for reporting banks outside New York, compared
with 59 per cent and 51 per cent a year earlier. Similarly,
ratios of short-term liquid assets (including Treasury bills
and certificates and loans to Government securities dealers)
to deposits stood at 14 per cent for the New York banks
and 9 per cent for banks outside New York, compared
with 17 per cent and 13 per cent in December 1958.
MEMBER

BANK

RESERVES

Country-wide reserve positions of member banks re­
mained under firm, if statistically somewhat reduced, pres­
sure throughout most of the fourth quarter; net borrowed
reserves averaged $436 million during the quarter, com­
pared with a $528 million average during the third quar­
ter. In December alone, net borrowed reserves averaged
$414 million, little changed from the $433 million level
for November. Borrowings from the Federal Reserve
averaged $904 million during the quarter as against $956
million in the third quarter.
Bank reserve positions were subjected to strong seasonal
influences during the quarter. Operating transactions, on
balance, absorbed some $370 million of reserves, as the
effects of a seasonal expansion of $ 1,082 million in currency
in circulation, which accelerated after mid-November,
more than offset an increase in average float and net gains
from the movement in other operating factors. In addi­
tion, required reserves rose $314 million over the period,
as a $350 million increase in December offset earlier
declines.
The money market banks, as usual, bore the brunt
of the seasonal pressures, and borrowings from the
Federal Reserve increased periodically until the necessary
adjustments could be made in bank portfolios. While
borrowings continued to be collateraled largely by Govern­
ment securities, rising loan-deposit ratios and an increasing
shortage of Government securities in bank portfolios indi­
cated that the time may be approaching when some banks




Table II
C hanges in F actors T en ding to Increase or D ecrease M em ber
B ank R eserv es, D ecem ber 1959

(In millions of dollars; (4-) denotes increase,
(—) decrease in excess reserves)
Daily averages—week ended
Net
changes

Factor
Dec.
2

Dec.
9

Dec.
16

Dec.
23

27
- 225
- 175
46
+ 70

- f 71
~ 83
- 157
78
-f 14

31
+ 166
— 197
_
6
+ 59

+ 15
+ 649
- 126
35
3

+
-

19
30
31
33
2

~h
+
+

9
477
624
198
138

-

-

236

-

8

+ 501

-

53

-

198

+ 287

+

Dec.
30

Operating transactions

Treasury operations*......................
Federal Reserve float......................
Currency in circulation..................
Gold and foreign account...............
Other deposits, etc...........................
T otal..................................

402

Direct Federal Reserve credit
transactions

Government securities:
Direct market purchases or sales. + 191
Held under repurchase agree­
ments ............................................. 2
Loans, discounts, and advances:
Member bank borrowings.......... + 48
— 2
Bankers' acceptances:
Bought outright..........................
Under repurchase agreem ents...
—

+

--

12

-

172

-

183

30

+

3

+

5

24

-

52

+ 106
2

1

--

- f 135
+

12

41

+

45

+

-f- 5
—

+
+

4
14

+
+

2
13

+
+

4

-f* 12
+ 31

+ 235

-1- 369

+

46

-

131

-

224

+ 295

-

167

44

+ 133
+ 188

+
+

38
10

+ 370
+ 92

277

+

+ 97
+ 334

Total reserv es..........................................
Effect of change in required reserves f

- 123
+ 74

+ 321
- 157

+

48
118

+ 462
- 247

- 277
- f 98

+ 431
- 350

Excess r e serv esf.....................................

-

49

- f 164

-

70

+ 215

-

+

870
376
494

911
540
371

956
470
486

295

_

T o tal..................................

+

36

—

M ember bank reserves

With Federal Reserve Banks
Cash allowed as reserves................

Daily average level of member bank:
Borrowings from Reserve Banks..
Excess reserves!..............................
Net borrowed reserves f ..................

980
685

179
928
506
422

81

9291
5151
4141

Note: Because of rounding, figures do not necessarily add to totals.
* Includes changes in Treasury currency and cash,
t These figures are estimated,
j Average for five weeks ended December 30, 1959.

will revert to the practice of using commercial paper as
collateral for their borrowings.
Partly meeting seasonal needs, reserves were released
during the period through changes in Federal Reserve
regulations, effective in early December, which permitted
banks to count part of their vault cash as reserves, and
which also permitted member banks to exclude remittance
drafts drawn on their reserve accounts when calculating
gross demand deposits (so that required reserves were
reduced). First estimates indicated that some $400 million
of bank reserves were released by these measures, but
since they primarily affected country banks, and since the
additional reserves thus acquired by individual banks were
quite small, the measures had little or no immediate direct
effect on the central money market.
For the most part, seasonal reserve needs during the
fourth quarter were met through System open market
operations. Large amounts of reserves were provided in
the first two statement weeks of both November and
December, but reserves were reabsorbed in the latter part
of each of these months as the expansion in float reached

FEDERAL RESERVE RANK OF NEW YORK

unusually large proportions. From September 30 through
December 30, System outright holdings rose $185 mil­
lion and holdings under repurchase agreements rose $30
million.
G O V E R N M E N T S E C U R IT IE S

MARKET

Yields on most Treasury securities moved to a substan­
tially higher level by the end of December than they had
been three months earlier (see Chart II), but with rather
sharp day-to-day fluctuations in prices and yields during
the quarter. Fundamentally, the continued rise in Treasury
securities yields— as well as in other market rates—
reflected the heavy demand for credit and capital which
has accompanied the strong economic upsurge of the past
year and which has pressed on a necessarily limited supply
of funds. The short-term fluctuations superimposed on
this general rise in yields were largely the outcome of
pronounced changes in expectations during the quarter,
which in turn were conditioned by developments in the
steel situation as well as by the Treasury’s actual and pros­
pective cash financing and refunding operations.
Prices of Treasury notes and bonds, after having de­
clined sharply in August and September, rose during most
of October in a rally which carried yields back to their
mid-July levels. The stronger tone of the market during
this period to a large extent seemed to reflect some temper­
ing of expectations regarding the prospective demand for
credit—and therefore regarding the yield level over the

Chart II

YIELDS ON UNITED STATES GOVERNMENT SECURITIES
Per cent

Per cent

N ote: Latest d a ta plotted: w eek ended D ecem ber 26 for long-term bonds
and 3-5 y ear issues; auction held on Decem ber 2 8 for Treasury bills.




7

coming months—as the adverse effects of the prolonged
steel strike became increasingly felt throughout the econ­
omy. The market also was strengthened during this period
by the Treasury’s highly successful $2 billion issue of 5
per cent notes in early October—the “Magic Fives”—
which had an excellent reception in the market generally
and from small individual investors in particular.
The news in early November that steel production would
be resumed under a Taft-Hartley injunction, however, was
quickly followed by renewed market expectations of
heightened credit demands and higher rate levels over the
coming months. While these expectations had a par­
ticularly marked effect in the Treasury bill market, they
were also reflected in lower prices for notes and bonds.
The market was also affected by the Treasury’s November
refunding operations which involved, in addition to $8.9
billion of maturing securities, a special offer to holders of
$2 billion of 4 per cent notes due August 15, 1962 (but
redeemable at the holders’ option—on three months’ prior
notice—on February 15, 1960) to exchange for new 4%
per cent four-year notes; holders of the 4 per cent notes
were not eligible to exchange into the other issue offered in
the refunding—a 43A per cent certificate maturing in
November 1960. Although the exchange operation was re­
garded as successful, it resulted in a greater increase in
the supply of three- to five-year maturities than had been
generally anticipated, tending to depress that area of the
market.
A similar, although considerably smaller, influence
in the same direction was exerted by a subsequent
Treasury offer to owners of $1.6 billion of nonmarketable
Savings bonds to exchange 4% per cent Treasury
notes maturing May 15, 1964, with holders of $740
million of these bonds indicating they would participate
in the exchange. Sales of long-term bonds by investors
to finance purchases of new corporate issues at attractive
yields and, in December, some tax selling and switching
were also depressing influences in the Government bond
market. Under these influences, note and bond prices
declined throughout most of November and December,
more than erasing the October gains. By the end of the
year, prices of notes and intermediate-term bonds were
generally %2 to 11%2 points lower for the quarter while
longer term bonds had declined 12%2 to 32%2 points.
The average yield on long-term bonds, which had declined
to 4.10 by the end of October from 4.22 at the end of
September, climbed toward the end of the year to 4.39
per cent.
Changes in short-term expectations had a particularly
pronounced effect on the Treasury bill market. Along
with note and bond yields, Treasury bill rates declined

8

MONTHLY REVIEW, JANUARY 1960

through most of October, by as much as 20 to 55 basis
points for most issues. By the closing days of October,
however, demand for bills had been much reduced, while
market psychology was adversely affected by expectations
of increased demand for credit, not only as a result of the
resumption of steel production, but also in connection
with the mid-December tax and dividend payments. The
Treasury’s cash financing operations, moreover, added $4
billion to the supply of outstanding bills during the quar­
ter, while estimates of the cash financing the Treasury
might have to undertake early in the new year introduced
additional uncertainties. The bill market was also adversely
affected by the year-end pressure for funds and the high
cost of borrowing, with New York bank loan rates to
Government securities dealers remaining at 5 per cent
throughout most of November and December. Market
rates moved upward in short but pronounced spurts
throughout most of November and December, with par­
ticularly sharp increases on most of the auction days.
The average discount in the regular weekly auctions
reached a record high of 4.670 for 91-day bills in the
December 21 auction, whereas a high of 4.969 per cent
had been established for the 182-day bills in the Decem­
ber 7 auction; while the rates declined to 4.516 and
4.942 in the December 28 auction, these compared with
rates of 4.194 and 4.895, respectively, in the September
28 auction. Market rates declined in the closing days of
the period, however, as a moderate nonbank demand re­
appeared and as market psychology was favorably affected
by the fact that the Treasury’s $1.5 billion (net) cash
borrowing scheduled for January, which (as noted above)
was announced on December 30, was smaller than most
market observers had anticipated.

the corporate and municipal market and played a role
in this market similar to that of the “Magic Fives” in
the Government securities market. In December, however,
prices of corporate and, to a lesser extent, of municipal
bonds moved irregularly lower. By the end of December,
the average yield on Moody’s index of Aaa seasoned cor­
porate bonds stood at 4.61 per cent as against 4.56 at the
end of September, but the yield on similarly rated munici­
pals had declined to 3.49 per cent from 3.64.
New corporate bond offerings during the period totaled
$943 million, compared with $809 million during the JulySeptember period and $773 million during OctoberDecember 1958, while new municipal issues totaled
$1,292 million, compared with $1,259 million in the third
quarter and $1,117 million in the fourth quarter of 1958.
Market receptions were mixed, proving favorable when
the new issues were attractively priced and unfavorable
on certain occasions when underwriters sought to lead the
market toward lower yield levels by pricing rather closely.
Several syndicate terminations were reported in the latter
part of the period, with prices on the undistributed bal­
ances subsequently being marked down, while a $100
million State issue that had been scheduled for early
December was postponed.
Attention in the market for Federal agency obligations
was largely centered on the new issues sector during the
fourth quarter. New offerings totaled $1,577 million, of
which $1,139 million represented refundings and $438
million new cash. While the total was somewhat smaller
than the $1,908 million offered during the third quarter,
it was substantially larger than the $925 million total in
the fourth quarter of 1958. The new offerings generally
met with good investor response, although at yields
(usually well over 5 per cent) that were somewhat higher
O T H E R S E C U R IT IE S M A R K E T S
than in the previous quarter.
Several rate changes were announced for short-term
The market for seasoned corporate and, especially,
municipal obligations was firmer in October, reflecting the marketable debt instruments during the quarter. Bid
same background factors that led to the improvement in rates on unendorsed bankers’ acceptances were increased
Government bond prices. Moreover, despite the reappear­ from 43/s per cent to 4Vi per cent on December 2 and to
ance of weakness in the Treasury list, corporate and 45/s per cent on December 7. Commercial paper dealers’
municipal yields generally held steady throughout Novem­ rates for prime four- to six-month maturities were reduced
ber. Perhaps the most important factor contributing from 43A per cent to 45/s per cent on October 28, but were
strength to the market during this period was the en­ increased to 4% per cent again on November 20, and
thusiastic investor response to the $250 million issue of reached 4% per cent on November 30. The rate on
American Telephone and Telegraph Company debentures directly placed 60- to 89-day paper of large sales finance
due in 1986, which was reoffered to investors on Novem­ companies also was cut during October, by V2 per cent to
ber 17 to yield 5.22 per cent. The quick distribution of 4 per cent, but was raised again in two steps to 45/s per
so large an issue stimulated activity and prices throughout cent by early December.




FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

9

International D evelopm ents

PROGRESS

IN

D O L L A R -IM P O R T

LIB E R A L IZA T IO N

The easing of discrimination against dollar imports,
which began to gather momentum in 1958, continued at
an accelerated pace in 1959. With the restoration of ex­
ternal convertibility of the major currencies at the close of
1958, and with rising international reserves, the principal
trading nations, as well as other countries around the
globe, speeded the process of dismantling quota restric­
tions on dollar imports. At the same time, the administra­
tion of import-licensing systems was relaxed and some of
the remaining controls over currency transfers were eased
further. Following upon a long series of measures adopted
in recent years to restore greater freedom to international
trade and payments, these moves marked a decisive
phase of the transition to multilateralism from the postwar
era of restrictions and discrimination.
The emergence of huge balance-of-payments disequilibria in most countries at the end of World War II
resulted in the imposition or intensification of strict quan­
titative limits on imports. Import quotas were applied in
varying degrees to different commodities, depending on
how essential they were and in what currency payment
would have to be made. Since most foreign countries had
large payments deficits with the United States and there
was a world-wide shortage of dollars, imports from the
dollar area as well as other dollar payments were widely
singled out for especially stringent quotas.
With postwar recovery well under way by 1950, an
increasing number of countries, particularly in Western
Europe, recognized the adverse effects for continued eco­
nomic growth of the maintenance of import and exchange
restrictions. Accordingly, the Organization for European
Economic Cooperation (OEEC) in 1950 adopted a “Code
for Liberalization” which set forth a program for the
systematic removal of quantitative restrictions on both
intra-European and dollar trade.1 The code called for
freeing 75 per cent of intra-OEEC trade by 1951 and for
gradual elimination of discriminatory quotas on imports
from the dollar area. By the end of 1955, quantitative re­
strictions on some 86 per cent of trade among Western

European countries had been removed, and a major start
had been made toward the freeing of dollar imports, 54
per cent of which by then had been liberalized.2 However,
with the resurgence of inflationary pressures in Western
Europe and the financial repercussions of the Suez crisis
in 1956 and 1957, liberalization slowed down. One
notable achievement of the period was the increasing
reliance on the International Monetary Fund and on the
revived use of international short-term currency stabiliza­
tion loans which, along with domestic measures, enabled
most countries to pass through the period without reverting
to less liberal trade policies.
The build-up of international reserves in Western
Europe in 1958 and 1959 encouraged the rapid extension
of dollar liberalization. The United Kingdom virtually
eliminated dollar discrimination between May 1957 and
December 1959, leaving only a few dollar imports (prin­
cipally fruits and tobacco, coal, airplanes, and some chemi­
cals) still subject to quotas. Substantial increases in dollar
liberalization also were achieved in Denmark, Sweden, and
Italy; a large number of previously restricted consumer
goods were freed, though quotas on imports of textiles
and agricultural products, especially tobacco, were re­
tained. The Benelux countries, long leaders in the removal
of discrimination, eliminated virtually all remaining re­
strictions. Germany, which had advanced particularly far
in dollar import liberalization by 1957, imposed quotas
on coal in 1958 but resumed liberalization on a wide
range of other commodities during 1959. Germany is
now planning further moves in this direction in early 1960.
Perhaps the most dramatic extension of dollar liberaliza­
tion occurred in France, where internal economic problems
had kept discrimination high through 1957. In conjunc­
tion with its stabilization program, and in view of the
rapid strengthening of its external reserve position, France
extended dollar liberalization in several successive steps
during 1958 and 1959 to a level of over 80 per cent of
imports in November by removing a wide range of indus­
trial and consumer goods from the restricted list. A further
move to lift import quotas went into effect on January 1,

2 Intra-European import liberalization is computed on the basis of
1948 nongovernment trade; dollar import liberalization is computed
1 The members of the OEEC are: Austria, Belgium, the Nether- on the basis of nongovernment imports in 1953 from the United
States and Canada. These figures, compiled by the OEEC, indicate
ands, Denmark, France, West Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland,
liberalization only roughly, mainly because they do not allow for
taly, Luxembourg, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland,
changes in the pattern of trade since the reference years.
"urkey, and the United Kingdom.




10

MONTHLY REVIEW, JANUARY 1960

1960. Dollar imports are now treated on virtually the same
basis as nondollar imports.3
In addition to trade liberalization as such, various fur­
ther steps to ease controls on dollar payments were adopted
during the year. For example, in several countries includ­
ing France and the United Kingdom, currency restrictions
on foreign travel were considerably relaxed or eliminated
altogether.
Outside Europe, Australia and New Zealand substan­
tially increased their foreign exchange budgets (which set
limits on the total value of imports), and in the former
country dollar discrimination has now been virtually elimi­
nated. Among the African countries, Nigeria and the
Federation of Rhodesia and Nyasaland freed a significant
volume of their dollar imports, while in the Far East,
Malaya, Singapore, and Ceylon substantially modified
their quantitative restrictions on dollar purchases. In 1959
Japan expanded its exchange budget for a wide list of
products, from both the dollar area and elsewhere, in­
cluding foodstuffs, raw materials, machinery, and chemical
products. Moreover, Japan has announced its intention of
ending dollar discrimination altogether over the next
fifteen months. Latin America, a large part of whose trade
is with the United States, last year saw the further relaxa­
tion of dollar discrimination in those few countries where
discrimination remained a factor. The establishment of ex­
ternal convertibility in Europe resulted in the termination
of special trading arrangements between various Latin
American and European countries, thus automatically re­
ducing discrimination against imports from the dollar area.
Apart from the improved international payments posi­
tions of the major countries abroad, a widespread shift
in attitudes and policies toward economic controls has
contributed to the easing of restrictions on dollar imports.
Beginning in the fifties a number of countries, particularly
in Western Europe, embarked upon measures to widen
the scope of free markets. This development, which is
now spreading to other regions as well, reflects partly the
general economic improvement in many countries in re­
cent years and partly an increasing awareness of the extent
to which quantitative import restrictions and discrimina­
tion tend to stifle growth and initiative. At the same time,
increasingly strenuous efforts have been made in most
countries to curb inflation, efforts that in turn have implied
policies to secure imports in the cheapest market and to
expose domestic industries gradually to the discipline of
foreign competition.
3 See "The French Stabilization Program”, beginning on page
of this Monthly Review.




While the degree of dollar-import liberalization achieved
by the end of 1959 has been substantial, discriminatory
quotas on imports from the dollar area have not yet been
entirely removed in all countries. With greatly strengthened
international reserves in the major industrial countries
abroad, however, and external convertibility restored, the
major reasons for maintaining any discriminatory import
restrictions no longer exist. As Per Jacobsson, managing
director of the International Monetary Fund, recently
pointed out: “Now that all major trading currencies have
become convertible, it seems to be generally agreed that
there is no longer any balance-of-payments justification
for the practice of discrimination.”
With the easing of quantitative restrictions both globally
and on dollar goods, attention has begun to focus on tariff
barriers. Little, of course, would be gained if discrimina­
tory quotas were replaced by preferential tariff arrange­
ments. In this connection, the steps now under way,
particularly within the framework of the General Agree­
ment on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), to reinforce the moves
toward multilateralism may be regarded as an auspicious
development.

EXCHANGE

RATES

Early in December spot sterling, under heavy pressure
from large sales of sterling in New York and Continental
demand for United States dollars in London, declined in
the New York market from $2.8011 to $2.7957, the low­
est level since November 1957. By midmonth, good com­
mercial demand had firmed the quotation again to the
higher level but, as the holiday season approached, activity
slackened and the quotation moved lower to about
$2.7975. On December 31 the quotation was $2.7998.
In the forward market the premiums on three and six
months’ deliveries fluctuated between 38 and 58 points
and 64 and 87 points, apparently reflecting market senti­
ment concerning a possible increase in the British bank
rate. At the month end, the premiums were 45 and 75
points.
The Canadian dollar declined
cents to $1.04%
during the first two days of December on commercial
demand for United States dollars in Canada and reported
switching by some Continental interests from Canadian
to United States Treasury bills. Subsequently, European
demand and the conversion of the proceeds of a Canadian
provincial issue marketed in New York firmed the rate to
$1.052%4 on December 21. The Canadian dollar there­
after turned lower in a quiet market, and on December 31
11
stood at $1.05.

11

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

The French Stabilization P ro g ra m
One year ago France embarked upon a comprehensive
economic reform program designed to break the pattern
of inflation and of recurrent balance-of-payments crises,
which have plagued the French economy throughout most
of the postwar period. The program, which went into
effect at the same time that the European Common Market
was inaugurated and nonresident convertibility was re­
stored, was more far-reaching and fundamental than
previous stabilization attempts. Attacking basic causes
rather than symptoms, the program combined financial
austerity with a gradual dismantling of protectionist bar­
riers and of the obstacles that had interfered with the
functioning of free market forces in the domestic economy.
The results so far have been impressive. Confidence in
the currency has been restored, official international re­
serves have been rebuilt to near-record levels, and the
upward movement of prices has been slowed. While the
world-wide easing of inflationary pressures, along with
earlier stabilization measures, facilitated the implementa­
tion of the reforms, a basic element in the success of the
program was the emergence of a government able to
muster broad public support for a stabilization effort that
necessarily called for sacrifices.
TH E IN F LA T IO N A R Y

FRENCH PRODUCTION AND PRICES
1953=100
Per cent

Sources:

Per cent

O rg a n iz a tio n for European Economic C o o p eratio n ; French N a tio n a l

Institute of Statistics and Econom ic Studies.

BACKGROUND

Since World War II, France has been subjected to
recurrent inflationary pressures which culminated toward
the close of the 1956-57 boom, when an acute inflationary
thrust pushed wholesale prices up by 19 per cent. During
the same period, official international reserves declined by
about $1.3 billion to barely $600 million and confidence
in the currency all but collapsed.
The French economy, it is true, recorded a remarkable
productive advance during the postwar period, and espe­
cially in recent years. Between 1954 and 1957, for ex­
ample, the gross national product (expressed in constant
prices) increased at an average annual rate of some 6
per cent and industrial production advanced at an annual
rate of 10 per cent (see Chart I). Contributing heavily
to these achievements was a rise in industrial output per
man-hour of nearly 8 per cent a year, an increase unsur­
passed in any other Western country during the same
period. However, this rate of expansion was clearly not
sustainable, since it was achieved only at the expense of
a massive drain on international reserves and the accumu­
lation of huge external debts.




Ch art I

The causes of the French inflation were deep-rooted,
basically reflecting the enormous demands made on the
economy since the end of World War II. Despite sizable
United States aid, the postwar reconstruction effort and
the tremendous task of re-equipping and modernizing
French industry resulted in persistent pressures on avail­
able productive capacity. The government bore a major
share of the reconstruction burden, in both the nationalized
and the private sectors of the economy, and also made
large outlays for social welfare, including a variety of sub­
sidies aimed at limiting increases in the cost of living.
Moreover, after the end of World War II, France became
deeply involved in overseas armed conflicts, first in Indo­
china and then in Algeria. These constituted heavy drains
both on the country’s resources and on the budget—
although, until the end of 1955, substantial military assist­
ance from the United States alleviated the burden of
France’s total defense spending. Throughout the period
chronic budget deficits, which were often financed to a
considerable extent by borrowing from the banking sys­
tem, were a major inflationary force.

12

MONTHLY REVIEW, JANUARY 1960

While budget deficits thus fed the inflation, attempts
to minimize the effects of currency depreciation led to
the establishment of a widespread network of so-called
“escalator” clauses which did much to reinforce the price
rises. Clauses tying wages to the cost-of-living index were
incorporated in labor contracts and led, as the cost of liv­
ing rose, to automatic wage adjustments which, in turn,
pushed up prices. The index-clause system also spread to
other contractual relationships, notably bonds. While pri­
vate industry was often in a position to finance its invest­
ments from retained earnings, the Treasury and the
nationalized industries found it repeatedly necessary to
issue obligations in which principal or interest, or both,
were tied to the output or price of specific products, to
gold, or even to stock exchange quotations. This system of
indexed obligations, along with attempts to hedge against
the depreciation of the currency by moving capital abroad,
hoarding gold, or channeling savings into speculative in­
vestments, severely disrupted the capital market.
Unavoidably, inflation had a direct impact on the bal­
ance of payments. During the two years 1956-57 the ex­
ternal payments disequilibrium resulted in the loss of
$1.3 billion of official international reserves, already noted,
and exhausted existing foreign credits. During 1958, more­
over, France used up almost all of an additional $655 million
package of credits extended at the beginning of the year by
the International Monetary Fund, the European Payments
Union, the Export-Import Bank, and the United States
Treasury. By the end of 1958, it was evident that France
could no longer rely on foreign assistance and the drawingdown of its international reserves. Vigorous measures had
to be taken to halt inflation and to balance the external
accounts in order to utilize the rich potential of French
resources for a well-balanced and sustained expansion.
Several attempts had been made to deal with these prob­
lems in the postwar period. In mid-1957 a program
was adopted which included a measure of fiscal austerity,
tightening of credit controls, reinforcement of import re­
strictions, and partial devaluation of the franc. Beginning
in February 1958 the Bank of France imposed ceilings
on most types of commercial bank credit for a year. At
the same time the Treasury succeeded in reducing its
budget deficit, mainly through the imposition of additional
taxes, and with the advent in midyear of a more stable
government it was able to float a sizable long-term bond
issue on terms that induced the dishoarding of some $170
million of gold—the first dramatic evidence of a decided
shift in public confidence. While helpful, however, these
various measures were not fully adequate to cope with an
advanced stage of inflation which required a determined
attack on all fronts at once.




THE RE FO R M

PROGRAM

This comprehensive attack was undertaken by the
de Gaulle government, operating under decree powers, in
December 1958 and January 1959. The program was
designed not only to eliminate the inflationary effects of
the budget deficit but also to eradicate distorting influences
and uneconomic practices that had largely grown out of
the inflation itself. For this reason, the reform measures
were aimed not only at keeping down the government’s
budget deficit but also at a gradual dismantling of esca­
lator clauses, subsidies, rent controls, import restrictions,
and the like—in short, at reversing the succession of
attempts to rely on ingenious contrivances as an escape
from the implications of basic market forces.
With respect to the budgetary reform proper, the key­
stone of the program was a determined bid to reconcile
increases in expenditures—including those incurred for
capital investment — with the necessity of keeping the
deficit low enough to avoid inflationary financing. The
object of the reform was, in fact, to tailor the excess of
public outlays over revenues to the financing capacity of
the domestic savings stream. In order to break the
pattern of rising budget deficits, the authorities attacked
both the expenditure and the revenue sides of the budget
and succeeded in keeping the projected 1959 budget deficit
about 100 billion francs below the 1958 deficit of 690
billion. On the expenditure side, the reforms all but
swept away the elaborate system of government subsidies
that had been paid on food, fuel, and public utilities in
vain attempts to limit cost-of-living increases. In addition,
social welfare services were curtailed to some extent, and
veterans’ pensions were eliminated for all but the lowest
income groups. However, projected outlays for defense,
public investment, and housing—all regarded as essential
—were allowed to rise. Nevertheless, as a result of the
reform measures, the estimated increase in total spending
between 1958 and 1959 was kept down to 5 per cent,
in contrast to increases of 10-15 per cent in each of the
three preceding years. On the revenue side, an increase
of about 8 per cent was projected, as a number of taxes
were raised, including those on wine and tobacco and on
individual and corporate income.
On the external front, the franc was devalued by 14.93
per cent. This measure, along with those taken internally,
enabled France to join the other Western European
countries in the move toward currency convertibility at
the end of December 1958 and, shortly thereafter, to
abolish restrictions on capital transfers by foreigners.
Import liberalization, which had been suspended in 1957,
was also resumed; by mid-January 1959 France had

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

eliminated quota restrictions on 90 per cent of her imports
from the other members of the Organization for European
Economic Cooperation (on the basis of 1948 trade) and
on 50 per cent of her dollar imports (on the basis of 1953
trade). Furthermore, with the inauguration of the Common
Market on January 1, 1959, France and the five other
participating countries began to dismantle restrictions on
trade among themselves and to extend part of their mutual
trade concessions to a number of other nations as well.
No less important than the above measures was the
enactment of legislation sharply curtailing the use of esca­
lator arrangements. The indexing of bonds was not
affected, but existing cost-of-living clauses in wage con­
tracts were ruled inoperative after December 31, 1958.
The virtual ending of escalation represented a major
achievement since many individual segments of the econ­
omy had come to regard escalator clauses as a primary
defense against price rises, while the general effect of these
interlacing index ties was an accelerated propagation
throughout the economy of any impluse toward rising
prices originating in one sector or another. To ease the
burden of the stabilization effort on the weakest sectors
of the economy, the minimum wage rate remained linked
to the cost-of-living index and was raised 4% per cent to
compensate for the initial price increases expected to result
from the reforms.
Finally, as a symbol of the definitive nature of the
stabilization to be achieved by the program, the govern­
ment introduced a new monetary unit, the “new franc”,
worth 100 old francs and scheduled to replace the
old franc on January 1, 1960. Undertaken primarily for
psychological reasons, this measure emphasized the gov­
ernment’s determination to defend the currency against
any further depreciation.
THE

1958 came to an end, and in the second quarter of 1959
expansion was resumed.
Perhaps the most spectacular of the program’s results
has been the complete reversal of France’s external posi­
tion, attested by the constant quotation of the franc in
foreign exchange markets at or near the upper limit of
the official margin and by the fact that the Paris “free
market” rate for the dollar has consistently been below
the official rate. Partly as a result of the devaluation, the
trade gap was first drastically narrowed, and was then
transformed into a surplus beginning in the second quarter
of 1959 (see Chart II). Official exchange receipts from
tourism rose considerably, as foreign tourists bought their
francs through official channels rather than through the
free market. Moreover, a large inflow of foreign exchange
resulted from a repatriation of French funds and an
increase in foreign investment in France.
As a consequence of these developments, France was
able to rebuild official international reserves from $1.1
billion at the end of 1958 to $1.8 billion at the end of
November 1959 (see Chart III). During the same period,
foreign exchange liabilities of some $850 million were
liquidated by the French authorities, including the repay­
ment of $340 million to French commercial banks, $200
million to the International Monetary Fund, and substan­
tial amounts to the members of the former European Pay­
ments Union, to the United States, and to other foreign
creditors. Moreover, France was able to cancel the unused
stand-by credits totaling $240 million that had been ex-

Chart II

FRENCH FO REIGN TRADE
Q u a rte rly totals
M illio n s of d o lla r e q u iv a le n t

M illio n s of d o lla r e q u iv a le n t

RESULTS

The results of the stabilization program so far have
been striking—although the danger of renewed strains
has by no means been completely dispelled. In the first
year of stabilization, the price rise was slowed consider­
ably and, in contrast to earlier periods, most of the
increases were transitional or transitory in character.
Moreover, the Treasury’s cash position was so improved
as to make recourse to the capital market for long-term
funds unnecessary, while the dramatic strengthening of
the country’s balance of payments allowed France to
rebuild her official international reserves. At the same
time, France was able to make large repayments on
her foreign debt and to liberalize substantially her eco­
nomic transactions with the rest of the world. Meanwhile,
the slackening of economic activity that had occurred in




13

Note:
Source:

Fourth-quarter 195 9 d a ta a re b ased on O ctober a n d N ovem ber figures.
French N atio n al Institute of Statistics a n d Econom ic Studies.

MONTHLY REVIEW, JANUARY 1960

14

Ch art III

FRENCH OFFICIAL G O LD AND
FOREIGN EXCH AN GE RESERVES
Millions of dollars
xv/v/vs

Millions of dollars
2UUU
1800 -

f

/

1600 1400 —

/

/

1200 -

/

1000

-

1600

-

1400

-

1200
1000

/

800

/

/

1800

-

600

600 -

400 200 —
0
Note:

800

i

i i
1954

!

i

i i
1955

1

Mi l
1956

1 1 I
1957

I

i

i i
1958

1

' ! ’
1959

400
200
0

End of y e a r through 1956; end of quarter from 1957.

^ N o v e m b e r 30, 1959.
Source:

International M onetary Fund.

tended by four European central banks and the Bank for
International Settlements in support of the convertibility
move, as well as a $200 million credit extended by a
group of New York City banks for the same purpose.
Finally, last month France for the first time in thirty years
was able to return to the United States capital market;
taking advantage of the new financial strength achieved,
the Credit Foncier, a semipublic financial institution, suc­
cessfully floated a $50 million bond issue here.
Meanwhile, France has continued to liberalize her eco­
nomic transactions with the rest of the world. The inflow
of foreign exchange enabled the authorities first to re­
instate, and then to triple, the foreign exchange allocation
granted to French tourists traveling abroad. At the same
time, France in successive steps considerably expanded the
scope of the initial import-liberalization measures taken in
December 1958 and January 1959. By November 1959
the liberalization percentages had been brought to more
than 95 per cent for imports from the members of the
Organization for European Economic Cooperation (1948
basis) and to substantially more than 80 per cent for
imports from the dollar area (1953 basis). Moreover,
additional liberalization measures went into effect on
January 1, 1960, and imports from the dollar area are now
admitted on virtually the same basis as those from all other
areas.1
1 See also page 9 of this Monthly Review.




Internally, the December 1958 devaluation—unlike pre­
vious ones—was not followed by a surge of speculative
pressures on prices. Instead, such price rises as occurred
were inevitable results of the measures adopted and were
smaller than had been anticipated. Indeed, prices stabilized
shortly after the devaluation. So far, restraint on the part
of labor has kept wage increases down as well. By mid­
year, consumer prices were only about 3 per cent above
their pre-devaluation level, and wages had increased only
3 Vi per cent. Since June, prices of manufactured products
have remained relatively stable, but food prices have risen,
primarily as a result of a severe summer drought. As a
consequence of the drought and of the earlier effects on
prices that naturally followed in the wake of a devaluation
and a major reconversion to free markets, consumer and
wholesale prices had by the end of November edged up
to levels 6 to 7 per cent above those of December 1958
(see Chart I).
In view of the generally favorable developments, the
government was able to step up its efforts to counteract
the slackening in economic activity that had developed in
1958. Monetary policy had already gradually become less
restrictive, beginning in the second half of 1958. By
February 1959 the commercial bank credit ceilings, im­
posed one year earlier, had been removed; by April the
Bank of France’s basic discount rate had been reduced
gradually to 4 per cent from 5, and by early July its two
penalty rates had been lowered to 5 and 6 per cent from
8 and 12. In addition, during 1959 the government accel­
erated its investment outlays and enacted a program of tax
incentives designed to stimulate private investment, which
was still lagging. Tax concessions were granted to compa­
nies entering economically depressed regions, and a sched­
ule for the gradual relaxation of rent controls was adopted
so as to spur the flow of private funds into housing. Con­
sumption was encouraged by an easing of consumer credit
restrictions and a 10 per cent increase in family allow­
ances. In the second quarter, economic expansion re­
sumed, and by October (as shown in Chart I) industrial
production was 10 per cent above its low of December
1958, and nearly 5 per cent above the peak it had reached
early in 1958.
The Treasury has benefited from the general improve­
ment of economic conditions. An upward revision of
expenditures in the course of the year was covered by
larger-than-anticipated tax receipts. As a result, the budget
deficit was maintained within the limits envisaged by the
stabilization program, despite the continuation of the
Algerian conflict. The budget for 1960, moreover, projects
a deficit no larger than that for 1959. Thus, if events fulfill
expectations, 1960 will be the third successive year in

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

which the government will have succeeded in keeping its
budget deficit down to what it considers a manageable
level.
To finance its deficit for 1959, the Treasury borrowed
short term by tapping the rising liquidity of both the
banks and the nonbank public that stemmed from the largescale inflow of foreign exchange and the temporary slack­
ening in economic activity. The authorities thus abandoned
earlier plans for a long-term bond issue, and left at the
disposal of private borrowers a greater share of the re­
sources available on the capital market. With the new
confidence in the currency and the inflow of funds from
abroad, the capital market began to show signs of revival,
as illustrated by the fact that, in the first six months
of 1959, corporate flotations of bonds were more than
double their year-earlier level. Long-term interest rates
remain relatively high—5 Vi to 6 per cent for corporate
bonds—but they are sharply below their 1957 peaks.

LO O K IN G A H E A D

Despite the impressive performance of the French econ­
omy under the stabilization program, serious problems re­
main. New upward pressures on prices have developed
which, while not yet alarming, have created some concern.
One of the factors on which the government had pinned its
hopes of keeping prices down in the fall of 1959 was the
prospect of bountiful harvests. Instead, an extremely dry
summer brought about shortages in a number of foodstuffs
and a persistent inching-up of the price level in recent
months. The price rise resulted, on November 1, in a
statutory 2Vi per cent increase in the minimum wage rate,
under the escalator arrangement. This wage hike is ex­
pected to lead to adjustments in other wage rates as well,
and may put some pressure on prices. In this connection,
the recent advances in the general liberalization of imports
are expected to assist in safeguarding price stability. How­
ever, continuation of the restraint that French labor has
shown—at least until recently—in wage demands, and re­
straint on the part of industry in its pricing policies, both
remain basic elements in France’s struggle to preserve
stability.
On the external front, France’s newly acquired inter­
national strength needs to be consolidated. Imports are
expected to increase as a result of the pickup in economic
activity now under way, although it is hoped that the
recent discovery and development of oil and gas in France




15

and in the Sahara will drastically reduce the country’s
dependence on foreign fuel. In the next few years, France’s
balance of payments will also be burdened with heavy
short-term debt repayments—principally to the Interna­
tional Monetary Fund and to members of the former
European Payments Union—as well as with the servicing
of $2 billion in long-term obligations.
Over the long run, France like other countries is con­
fronted with the problem of sustained and balanced
economic growth. Large-scale investments in housing,
education, and industry, both at home and in the asso­
ciated territories, will require a steady expansion in the
flow of voluntary savings, which will be forthcoming only
in a climate of price stability and of confidence in the cur­
rency. Such a climate would not only be likely to elicit a
favorable response from a traditionally thrifty people but
might well induce Frenchmen to sell to the government a
substantial part of their large holdings of gold and foreign
assets, which have been variously estimated at between
$4 billion and $10 billion. The progress so far in restoring
confidence and encouraging savings represents a beginning.
However, given the postwar experience of inflation and
currency depreciation in France, it may take some time
before complete confidence in the currency can be re­
stored and a flourishing capital market re-established.
France also faces a number of structural problems.
While many French industries are highly efficient, the
country’s productive and distributive system still includes
antiquated and inefficient sectors which seriously handicap
the economy’s over-all progress. France hopes to mod­
ernize these sectors as rapidly as possible, and to eliminate
the remaining institutional and psychological obstacles to
expansion which were an outgrowth of inflation and of
government controls that stifled free market forces.
While many problems thus remain to be solved, France
now seems to be in a position to deal with them effectively.
A major achievement of the stabilization program, apart
from those already noted, is that it has hastened the
restoration of self-confidence and has added vigor to the
economic life of one of the most richly endowed countries
in the world. France’s recent export performance, both
within and outside the Common Market, is one of the first
signs of this transformation. Provided that a resurgence of
inflationary pressures is avoided, and that reliance upon a
genuinely free market mechanism continues to broaden,
there can be high hope everywhere that France will regain
and maintain the economic strength that her role in the
Free World requires.