View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

19

M onetary Policy In A Com petitive W orld*
By A l f r e d H a y e s
President, Federal Reserve Bank of New York
The past year has been a complex and difficult one for
monetary policy. This in itself is nothing new, but perhaps
the set of conditions we faced demonstrated more force­
fully than ever that there is no simple set of rules for
monetary policy to be followed under all circumstances.
Ours is an ever-changing and ever-evolving field— and
while there are a few timeless principles, the fast-changing
circumstances of our economy mean that for practical
purposes we must develop our “art” as we go along. As
we start a new year, what can we say of monetary policy’s
achievements in 1961 and its prospects in 1962?
In regard to achievements, I hope we have learned not
to take too much credit for favorable economic develop­
ments, just as I hope we may not be asked to shoulder too
much of the blame, as has happened occasionally during
the past few years, for undesirable economic events. Most
of 1961 was a period of impressive recovery and expansion
after the business slump of late 1960 and early 1961. It
was quite apparent early in the year that not only the
vigorous effort of the private economy but also the ener­
getic collaboration of all branches of Government would
be required for the nation to achieve desirable long-term
economic growth and adequate use of our human and
material resources. While the recession had been mild in
terms of the decline from previous peaks, it was not so
mild from the standpoint of unused resources. Similarly,
while the expansion to date has been quite rapid in regain­
ing and passing previous peaks in output, unemployment
remains at an unsatisfactorily high level. Nevertheless,
encouraging progress has been made and a favorable
monetary environment has undoubtedly helped.
The Federal Reserve System made this contribution to
domestic recovery and growth while confronted at the
same time with a serious and persistent balance-ofpayments problem. This aspect of our total problem is of
relatively recent origin, as the growing productive capacity
and competitive strength of the Western European and
Japanese economies have exposed us for the first time

* An address before the thirty-fourth annual midwinter meeting
of the N ew York State Bankers Association, New York City,
January 22, 1962.




since World War II to the challenges of an economy
open to competition from efficient and vigorous trading
partners. And accompanying and magnifying the prob­
lem has been the greater ease with which capital funds
have flowed among the major countries whose currencies
have become convertible.
During 1961 the Federal Reserve System saw to it that
banks were amply supplied with reserves. With their total
reserves rising by somewhat over 4 per cent during the
year, the banks were able to expand credit by a near-record
$15 billion. Demand deposits rose by about 4 per cent and
time deposits by some 14 per cent. Besides being in a
position to meet all reasonable demands for bank loans,
the banks were able to add substantially to their short-term
investments. Thus they are now quite comfortably liquid,
although not excessively so.
As for interest rates, there has been a relatively moderate
increase during this year of vigorous recovery. Yields on
long-term Treasury, corporate, and municipal bonds have
increased by something on the order of V* per cent, while
short-term Treasury bill rates have risen about V2 per cent,
most of this latter increase having occurred in the past
couple of months. In all maturities, rates are well below the
peaks reached in late 1959.
As we have often pointed out in recent years, the Fed­
eral Reserve System has by no means set itself a fixed goal
with respect to rates. For the past year and a half or more
we have found it necessary, however, because of urgent
international considerations, to avoid putting undue down­
ward pressure on short-term rates while providing an easy
atmosphere in domestic credit markets. This was the most
pressing reason behind the broadening of the System’s
open market operations in Government securities to in­
clude transactions outside the short-term area. But these
broader operations had the added merit, on the domestic
side, of encouraging increased flows of long-term capital
into useful investment channels. By helping to absorb the
overhang of Government securities that typically dampens
the capital markets in recovery periods, these operations
aided in the placement of corporate and municipal debt
issues, as well as mortgages. The System’s purchases
seemed to be especially helpful to banks, enabling them
to move out of intermediate-term Governments without

20

MONTHLY REVIEW, FEBRUARY 1962

being deterred by significant capital losses and into either
loans or various shorter term investments while waiting
for expected loan demands to materialize. Incidentally,
these operations have left the System with a portfolio that
is still highly liquid; Federal Reserve holdings of underone-year maturities were greater at the end of 1961 than a
year earlier.
Federal Reserve efforts to encourage a short-term rate
structure that would tend to create some drag on the out­
ward flow of capital and increase the attractiveness of
dollar investments to foreigners have been strongly rein­
forced by the Board of Governors’ recent action to raise
the interest rate ceilings on time and savings deposits.
Over a period of time, the higher rates our banks can
offer to foreign depositors may be of significant help to
our international accounts.
In general, the ability of the System to hold steadily to
a policy of ease throughout 1961 was a stabilizing and
encouraging element in the improving business outlook.
If we look for reasons why we were able to hold to’such a
policy for such a long time, we find first that, since the
banks were not flooded with reserves during the preceding
recession, there was no vast amount of “slack” to be taken
up as soon as recovery commenced. The banks were
already on a firm enough rein so that we could leave
matters pretty much as they were without inviting danger­
ous excesses.
Secondly, unlike the situation in some earlier postwar
recoveries, commodity prices have been largely free from
appreciable upward pressure, and indeed the over-all
price picture in the current recovery has been quite grati­
fying. Wholesale price indexes are now slightly lower
than a year ago, while average consumer prices are only
slightly higher. Doubtless some of the credit for this happy
situation should go to the increasing force of public pres­
sure on wage and price policies— but even more important,
and partly responsible for the increased public pressure, is
the greatly increased vigor of foreign competition in an
open economy such as ours. The persuasive power of a
potential loss of sales is cogent indeed.
A third reason for our ability to maintain a policy of
monetary ease has been the highly effective cooperation
of other arms of Government, notably in the areas of fiscal
policy and debt management. Far from limiting the scope
of monetary policy, close cooperation of this kind enables
monetary policy to make full use of its characteristic
adaptability and flexibility. When that intimate coopera­
tion has been lacking, or impossible, the scale of the job
left to monetary policy has been just too big for it, and
the possibilities for quick modification, if the need arose,
were severely limited. Federal fiscal policy during the




past year has involved a much smaller deficit than in the
preceding recovery period of 1958-59, and policy has been
headed clearly in the direction of a balanced budget for the
coming fiscal year. By avoiding heavy Federal Govern­
ment borrowing, it has been possible to give greater en­
couragement to other borrowers without risking excessive
credit expansion. Moreover, skillful debt management has
helped to resist any downward pressure on short-term rates
through concentration of the past year’s new cash offerings
in the short-term area, while leaving the supply of longer
term savings available for corporate, municipal, and
mortgage borrowers. At the same time, vigorous use of
advance refundings, which did not directly tap new long­
term investment funds, has offset both the added cash
borrowing in the short area and the shortening of the
average maturity of the debt that occurs merely through
the passage of time. Debt management also reinforced
monetary policy through the placing of a larger propor­
tion of the various Government trust funds’ debt holdings
in longer term issues.
It is certainly not possible to have any precise idea now
what the coming year holds for monetary policy. The
business expansion seems to be moving ahead at a healthy
pace at the moment, strengthened by an apparently in­
creased willingness on the part of consumers to step up
their purchases. This increased willingness, it may be
noted, has developed in an environment of essentially
stable prices— and by the same token it could be ad­
versely affected by a change in this favorable climate. As
regards business spending, while plans for capital outlays in
1962 appear moderate, they may very well be revised
upward if retail sales improve further. Corporate profits,
another major influence on business spending, seem to be
improving rather more quickly than seemed likely a few
months ago. Spending by various levels of Government is
also pushing higher. The unemployment situation, on the
other hand, is still a long way from satisfactory.
Naturally, the Federal Reserve will have to provide
reserves for further expansion of bank credit and the
money supply, although I would not expect these reserves
to be provided as abundantly in a buoyant economy as
they were in 1961. Further, the extent to which the Sys­
tem makes reserves available would certainly be affected
by any re-emergence of inflattionary pressures reflecting
generally excessive demand, or other causes. Future
Federal budget policies will also have a distinct bearing
on the scope for continued monetary ease. In this con­
nection, the prospect of a balanced Federal budget in fiscal
year 1963 is certainly encouraging.
Above all, we shall have to be mindful of balance-ofpayments developments, and it is to this topic that I wish

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

to address most of my remaining comments. I must say,
first of all, that the latest statistics in this area are on
balance disappointing, even though they have some en­
couraging aspects. On the encouraging side, our inter­
national payments showed only a small deficit in the first
half of 1961, after excluding the effects of special debt
repayments. But this marked improvement over the sub­
stantial and persistent deficits of the previous three years
was partly a fortuitous result of different business-cycle
phasing here and abroad; our own imports were held down
by recession, while booming conditions abroad boosted the
demand for our exports. It is also encouraging that in the
most recent half year our exports have performed exceed­
ingly well despite some slowing-down of the European
boom, but our own imports naturally have risen as our
economy gained strength. I am informed, too, that pre­
liminary fourth-quarter data indicate an improvement in
our combined trade, Government, and long-term capital
accounts as against the third quarter. At the same time,
however, there has apparently been a substantially in­
creased outflow of short-term capital, with the result that
the over-all deficit widened again in the fourth quarter
following the substantial deficit that had emerged in the
third quarter. While part of the recent worsening—per­
haps much of it— appears to reflect temporary, reversible
factors, the situation certainly is one that requires the
most careful watching, with the Federal Reserve and, I
am sure, all other branches of the Government as well
prepared to take resolute action if there should be devel­
opments ahead that represent more than a temporary set­
back on the road to our goal of balance-of-payments
equilibrium.
Monetary policy clearly must pay increasingly close
attention to this problem, and it will be increasingly free
to do so as the domestic business situation strengthens.
Let me emphasize, however, that there is no simple solu­
tion to our international monetary problem. The causes
of our balance-of-payments deficits are complex, and
there are other vital objectives in the international area
that must not be neglected while the balance-of-payments
deficit is being corrected. Nor would I want to give the
impression that there is any basic or irreconcilable con­
flict between policies designed to achieve sturdy economic
growth at home and those aimed at maintaining a viable
international balance. In the short run there will certainly
have to be compromises among our objectives from time
to time, but over the long pull the same policies are needed
to achieve both our internal and external goals.
Indeed, the more competitive world in which we now
live, and which makes our day-to-day monetary problems
considerably more difficult, is in my judgment already




21

proving itself to be a greatly improved world from the
standpoint of our own national interest. We in the United
States are already benefiting, through broader export mar­
kets and greater domestic price stability, from increased
two-way trade with larger and stronger partners in the
Free World. We have much to gain from the building of
a still broader and freer trading area among the advanced
nations— one which should permit more effective mobili­
zation of aid to the less developed countries and, more
important, a better market for the raw materials produced
by those countries. Without question, to achieve the
superior growth rates needed to give the Free World its
full economic and military strength depends in good meas­
ure on a substantial further lowering of national barriers
to international trade and investment.
In the face of these considerations it would be inexcus­
able to seek a solution of our troublesome balance-ofpayments problem through such measures as import re­
strictions, higher tariffs, or exchange controls. Even if
balance in our international accounts could be achieved
in such a manner (and frankly I believe that retaliatory
measures would more than offset potential gains), this
would be small return for the inevitable loss in our real
income and world position— political and military as well
as economic. But if we firmly reject, as we must, solutions
of this kind, we must also accept the burdens and respon­
sibilities inherent in the new environment in which we live.
We must be willing not merely to recognize foreign com­
petition as an economic fact, but also to make an aggres­
sive effort to compete more effectively in all markets, both
with new and improved products and with lower costs.
And, regarding the latter, let me say that while the role of
monetary policy in helping to hold back inflationary pres­
sures is difficult and unpopular— particularly when those
pressures originate elsewhere than in excessive demand—
the responsibility is nonetheless one that cannot be
shrugged off. Of course, this is not the job of monetary
policy alone—nor even of monetary policy primarily;
wholehearted cooperation from Government, industry, and
labor is a necessity in this area.
Success along these lines, together with more skillful
and effective export promotion, will enable us to achieve
a trade surplus high enough to take care of our heavy net
military outlays abroad, our economic assistance payments,
and the outflow of private long-term investment. At the
same time, we must make sure that the drains from these
latter sources are no larger than necessary. In this con­
nection, I am much heartened by the progress which the
Government has already made in arranging for our allies
to purchase in this country more of the military equipment
for mutual defense. Progress has also been made in

22

MONTHLY REVIEW, FEBRUARY 1962

achieving a better sharing of the foreign aid burden. In
my opinion, more can surely be done along these lines.
It might also be worthwhile to give further study to the
question whether our existing tax laws now make it un­
necessarily attractive to invest in relatively well-developed
foreign countries.
Measures of this kind are of the utmost importance to
achieve the basic payments equilibrium that we must have.
Of course, even after such an equilibrium is achieved,
there will be swings from time to time in response to
different business developments in this country and abroad.
But to some extent we could expect to see such cyclical
swings in trade offset by opposite swings in capital move­
ments, largely short term, which would be influenced by
relative levels of interest rates and credit availability here
and abroad. In fact, the proper role of our monetary
reserves— including our drawing privileges at the Inter­
national Monetary Fund as well as our gold— is to cushion
the effects of such swings in payments.
It follows, too, that the closer we come to equilibrium
in our balance of payments, the greater scope we have for
adjusting our monetary policy more largely to our domes­
tic needs, relying on various measures of international
cooperation to absorb the disequilibrating force of capital
flows moving in the wrong direction. The difficulty today
is that we do not enjoy a sufficient margin of safety in our
balance of payments to give monetary policy the desirable
degree of freedom to act without inviting excessive risks.
Even a gold stock as large as ours cannot withstand an
indefinite stream of losses, nor can we depend on an un­
limited willingness of foreign countries to build dollar
balances. Hence there is a real need for monetary policy
to remain entirely uncommitted and flexible, ready to
move if necessary in ways that will help to remedy any
significant worsening in our balance-of-payments position.
I would like, finally, to comment on some of the steps
taken in the past year which have made 1961 a real mile­
stone in the history of international monetary cooperation.
Goaded by the urgent need to minimize the danger of
massive speculative forays against one currency or another
— a danger greatly increased by the major payments im­
balances of several leading industrial countries, including
the United States— we have made notable progress in a
number of areas. As has often been pointed out, the
gold exchange standard has brought great benefits to the
postwar world by making possible striking economies in
the use of a limited supply of monetary gold. But in build­
ing the “banker” role of the key currency countries, which
in effect means the United States and Britain, we have also
increased the vulnerability of these currencies and coun­
tries to wide swings in capital movements.




This vulnerability was strikingly demonstrated by the
speculative assault on sterling which followed the German
and Dutch revaluations last March. These changes in
parities left the foreign exchange markets in a state of
shock, so that they were easy prey to speculative rumors
of further changes in parities. Within a few days, many
hundreds of millions of dollars in various currencies moved
across the exchanges, with particularly heavy speculative
flows from London to Zurich and Frankfurt. At this
critical moment, the central banks meeting each month at
the Bank for International Settlements in Basle announced
that they were cooperating in the exchange markets. As
subsequently revealed, this cooperation took the form of
short-term loans, ultimately reaching a total of $910
million, to the Bank of England from other European cen­
tral banks. In this connection, I should like to pay tribute
to the decisive and statesmanlike approach taken by the
various European central banks involved— particularly
the National Bank of Switzerland and the German Bundes­
bank, which received the bulk of the hot money outflow
from London. This so-called “Basle Agreement” which
provided emergency credit facilities of a necessarily short­
term nature will stand, I hope, as a first big milestone on
the road toward creating a truly formidable first line of
defense for the world’s major currencies.
The lessons of the March revaluations were not lost
upon the United States Government. Since then much
time and effort has been spent in exploring and develop­
ing techniques, in cooperation with foreign monetary au­
thorities, to defend the dollar against similar speculative
flows of hot money. Those New York banks which are
active in the exchange markets will recall that shortly
after the German revaluation the Federal Reserve Bank
of New York, as agent for the United States Treasury,
began to provide forward marks. This action, which was
undertaken in cooperation with the Bundesbank, was de­
signed to deal with an abnormally high premium on the
forward mark and, more generally, to exert a stabilizing
effect on both the spot and forward markets. At the end
of June, more than one billion marks of such forward
sales were outstanding, but the speculative tide had already
begun to recede before the Berlin crisis and, by midDecember, the entire volume of forward contracts had
been liquidated at maturity and the market was again
operating smoothly with only token intervention. In
effect, the German forward mark operation helped to
bridge the gap between heavy speculative buying of marks
and the subsequent restoration of a more balanced pay­
ments position.
Sizable operations have also been carried out in the
forward Swiss franc market, where cooperative measures

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

undertaken with the Swiss National Bank have succeeded
in reducing the unduly high premium on the forward
Swiss franc which had been one of the factors impeding
outflows of capital from Switzerland. In connection with
these operations, the United States Treasury supplemented
its holdings of Swiss francs by issuing short-term Treasury
obligations denominated in that currency. This technique
has proved effective and may well be employed in other
situations, if this seems desirable.
At the moment, operations in other European curren­
cies are being given serious consideration and will serve,
I hope, to extend still further the perimeter of the first
line of central bank defenses against speculative capital
movements. Incidentally, I should also like to mention the
effective cooperation of various foreign central banks in
cushioning exchange market pressures generated by the
heavy repatriation of short-term funds to foreign markets
for year-end window-dressing purposes. In contrast with
the experience of earlier years, such foreign central bank
cooperation at the end of 1961 effectively minimized the
potentially disturbing effects of these operations upon both
market rates and actual reserves.
One important obstacle to a fuller use of such coopera­
tive exchange operations by the United States is that the
Treasury’s resources for such purposes are quite limited.
We may need to consider, therefore, whether the problems
in this area may not require that the Federal Reserve Sys­
tem also enter into foreign exchange operations. The last
few years have shown that monetary policy does not stop
at the water’s edge. Short-term capital now can, and does,
move across national frontiers in the hundreds of millions
of dollars within a span of a few weeks. And indeed, such
movements can have marked repercussions on our own
money and capital markets in addition to their impact on
our gold and exchange reserves.
Effective as they are, measures of immediate counter­
action to speculative pressures in the exchange markets
clearly have to be backed up by a “second line” of even
sturdier defenses since one cannot always count upon an
early reversal of such pressures. In this connection, the
already large lending facilities of the International Mone­
tary Fund are in the process of being augmented further.
Through a network of stand-by credit arrangements, the
Fund will be in a position to obtain an additional $6 bil­
lion of the world’s leading currencies if and when any
major crisis endangers the world payments system.
The successful completion of these negotiations by the




23

ten major industrial countries involved must be a great
source of satisfaction to all who are interested in seeing
our international monetary mechanism bolstered to with­
stand any foreseeable contingencies. One may reasonably
expect, therefore, that the required legislative approval
can be obtained promptly in all countries concerned, in­
cluding the United States. Of course it is also to be hoped
that the mere existence of these facilities will make it
unnecessary to use them.
The progress of the past year has involved, and indeed
has required, increasingly close personal contacts, in the
financial area, between representatives of this country and
those of the leading countries of Europe. I am thinking
of the regular attendance of Federal Reserve representa­
tives at the monthly meetings of the BIS in Basle, Federal
Reserve participation in United States delegations to vari­
ous working groups of the OECD in Paris, and ever more
frequent and cordial bilateral meetings with representatives
of the other principal trading nations to exchange informa­
tion and discuss mutual interests. These frank inter­
changes have brought us a much deeper understanding of
the domestic and international economic problems not
only of our trading partners, but also of ourselves, as we
have seen our own problems ranged alongside those of
other countries. If the momentum of all these moves can
be maintained, 1962 should produce further noteworthy
gains in this vital area of international cooperation. Yet,
I would be remiss if I did not remind you once more, at
the end of my remarks, of the continuing reality and
urgency of our balance-of-payments problem. While the
initial development of close international cooperation can
be and has been stimulated through the very strains it is
designed to combat, the ultimate responsibility of each
nation for its own finances is still recognized both here
and abroad.
I am aware that time has allowed me only to touch very
lightly some of the high spots of the very broad subject
I selected for this talk. But I hope you will agree that we
are pursuing goals which all Americans feel are worth
seeking, and that the seriousness of the problems we face
together in the monetary sphere calls for the patient
understanding and cooperation of all elements in our so­
ciety. If we can work together effectively, as I believe we
can, we can have confidence that our economy will meas­
ure up to its full potential and that the dollar will retain
its key position in the arch through which the trade and
investments of the Free World move.

24

MONTHLY REVIEW, FEBRUARY 1962

The B usiness Situation
As the new year got under way, the economy appeared
to be expanding at a good though not exuberant pace.
Preliminary estimates for the fourth quarter of 1961 indi­
cate a strong advance in gross national product that en­
tirely reflected gains in final demand. In December, to be
sure, the rate of increase in industrial production and in
various other monthly measures was somewhat less than
in the two preceding months, while automobile sales de­
clined from their November high. In January, moreover,
department store sales slipped back from the record
proportions reached in December, and new car sales
apparently continued at the December pace. But such
forward-looking indicators as orders received by manu­
facturers of durable goods, and commercial and industrial
construction contracts, made a strong showing during
November and December, giving support to the view that
over-all activity would continue to move ahead. Another
favorable sign was the decline of the unemployment rate
in January to 5.8 per cent of the labor force. Late in that
month, President Kennedy stated in his Economic Report
that GNP is expected to amount to $570 billion in 1962, a
rise of about 9 percent over 1961.
Whether such an advance can be achieved, and whether
it will be followed by still further expansion, will be
importantly influenced by the behavior of prices. A re­
newal of the upsurge in prices of the sort experienced in
the mid-1950’s could well hamper the growth in consumer
demand that is essential for a sustained economic expan­
sion. It would also seriously reduce our ability to meet
the rising challenge of foreign competition. Although
prices have been unusually stable since the business
upturn in early 1961, this stability will be put to its
real test as the economy reaches higher levels of capac­
ity utilization and as wage contracts in major industries
are renewed.
It is clearly desirable that wage contract negotiations in
the steel and other industries be completed not only on a
noninflationary basis, but also as soon as possible. This
will avoid the unsettling effects on the economy that would
arise from speculative stockpiling of inventories against
the possibility of strikes or price increases. The importance
of these considerations was pointed up by the President’s
announcement that he is urging labor and management in
the steel industry to work out an early settlement consist­




ent with continued price stability. It was further underlined
by the attention that the Annual Report of the President’s
Council of Economic Advisers paid to the problem of
developing guideposts for judging whether particular wage
decisions are inflationary. The Council suggested that, to
be noninflationary, wage increases should in general not
exceed the trend of average productivity gains for the
private economy as a whole,,
T H E A D V A N C E IN G R O S S N A T I O N A L P R O D U C T

Gross national product rose by $16.2 billion (seasonally
adjusted annual rate) during the final quarter of 1961,
according to estimates by the Council of Economic Ad­
visers. Significantly, all of the gain was in final demand,
with the pace of inventory accumulation remaining un­
changed. In each of the preceding two quarters, by con­
trast, the change in inventory investment had accounted
for a significant portion of the over-all GNP advance (see
Chart I). The fourth-quarter step-up in final demand was
about twice as large as that in either of the two preceding
quarters, with the most striking increases occurring in con­
sumer purchases of durable goods ($3.2 billion), Federal
defense outlays ($2.6 billion), investment in producers’
durables ($2.0 billion), and net exports of goods and
services ($1.4 billion). The only major component to de­
cline was nonresidential construction, which edged off
slightly for the second consecutive quarter. This was more
than offset, however, by the rise in business investment
in durable equipment.
A key feature of the October-December GNP change
was the upsurge in personal consumption expenditures.
Such outlays climbed by 2 ¥ 2 per cent in the OctoberDecember quarter, following a rise of IV 2 per cent during
each of the two previous quarters. While about half of the
fourth-quarter advance in consumer spending reflected a
very considerable step-up in purchases of durable goods,
spending on nondurables also rose more rapidly than in
the earlier quarters. Expenditures for services, which have
been increasing steadily for many years, continued to ad­
vance at about the same rate as before.
The sharp rise in durable goods purchases during the
quarter to a large extent reflected increased sales of new
automobiles. Such sales rose 9 per cent in November, to

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

Chart I

CHANGES IN GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT
AND ITS MAJOR COMPONENTS
Se asonally adjusted annual rates

Change in
final demand
Change in
inventory investment *

1961
First quarter

Second quarter

Third quarter

Fourth quarter

5

10

Billions of dollars
* Refers to increases or decreases in changes in business inventories. Thus,
businessmen reduced inventories at a rate of $4 billion in the first quarter
of 1961/Or by $2.1 billion more than in the preceding quarter. In the second
quarter, their inventories rose by $2.8 billion, m aking for a change in
inventory investment of $6.8 billion.
Sources: United States Department of Commerce; Council of Economic Advisers.

a seasonally adjusted rate of almost 7 million cars a year,
partly on the strength of sales that had been deferred in
September and October because of shortages stemming
from strikes in the auto industry. In December, sales
receded to a rate of 6 million cars, but this was still
well ahead of the rate for any month prior to the fourth
quarter. During the first three weeks of January, auto­
mobile sales continued at approximately the December
pace, after allowance is made for the usual seasonal
decline. Sales of appliances and most other durable goods,
as well as of nondurables, continued to rise in December,
while the ratio of total retail purchases to personal income,
although down from November, was higher than in any
other month since March.
Federal Government outlays on defense, as indicated
earlier, provided a substantial lift to GNP during the
fourth quarter. The $2.6 billion increase in such spending
contrasted with a third-quarter rise of $0.2 billion, and
was larger than any preceding quarterly increase during
the ten years since the Korean war. Moreover, since De­
fense Department contract awards and obligations had
risen sharply during the summer, and since it ordinarily




25

takes many months before the full impact of new contracts
on defense output is felt, this component of GNP is
likely to rise further during the current and subsequent
quarters. It is noteworthy, however, that according to
the estimates in the Budget and in the Annual Report of
the Council of Economic Advisers, Federal purchases of
goods and services in 1962—including those for defense
—will on average rise more slowly than in 1961.
A further advance in fixed capital investment by busi­
ness also seems likely. Seasonally adjusted outlays for
commercial and industrial construction turned up at the
end of the year, and the volume of contract awards for
such construction rose markedly in November-December.
Moreover, while new orders for machinery and equip­
ment declined in December, they had moved uninterrupt­
edly upward during the four preceding months, probably
indicating there will be a continuing rise in production
of such items for some months ahead.
The outlook for investment in housing is more uncer­
tain. Private nonfarm housing starts declined in Decem­
ber for the second month in a row, but new building
permits for such construction rose strongly. While the
permit series is less comprehensive than the starts series,
it is also less erratic. Requests for Government-backed
mortgage financing, moreover, showed a substantial ad­
vance in December. The divergent movements of these
various indicators leave it unclear whether or not housing
outlays, which gained markedly in January, will be mov­
ing up further.
Although inventory investment did not contribute to
the fourth-quarter rise in GNP, this does not mean that
inventories were not being accumulated. It rather signi­
fies that business firms were adding to their stocks at
the same rate as before. This rate could increase in the
current quarter if final demand advances at a good clip.
It is worth noting in this connection that a study by the
Department of Commerce shows that manufacturers’
stocks at the end of 1961 generally were at a compara­
tively low level relative to sales and new orders. Much
will depend, of course, on the extent to which accumula­
tion of steel inventories is spurred by anticipations of a
strike. The heavy volume of steel orders in recent weeks
suggests that such anticipations have already had some
influence on steel buying.
P R O D U C T IO N , E M P L O Y M E N T , A N D IN C O M E

The Federal Reserve’s seasonally adjusted index of in­
dustrial production advanced by 1 point in December, and
gains in production continued to be widespread. Schedules
for January auto production point to a slight decline from

26

MONTHLY REVIEW, FEBRUARY 1962

the high December level, after allowing for the usual
seasonal rise, but the adverse effect from this source on
the over-all rate of industrial output may be more than
offset by a continuing advance in the output of steel and
other products.
Despite the December rise in industrial output, total
employment declined slightly. In January, however, em­
ployment rose back to about the November level, and the
unemployment rate, seasonally adjusted, fell below 6.0 per
cent for the first time in sixteen months. Nonagricultural
employment in December, as measured by the payroll sur­
vey, remained at about the November level. While employ­
ment in manufacturing continued to rise modestly, it fell
in most other major industries. For the nonmanufacturing
sectors that had been the hardest hit by the recession—
construction, transportation, and mining— the December
declines meant continuation of a downward drift that the
business recovery has yet to reverse.
The lack of strength in employment held the rise of
personal income in December to $2 billion (at a season­
ally adjusted annual rate), the smallest advance in three
months. Close to half of the increment came from a large
increase in dividend payments, while the rise in wage and
salary disbursements was only about one quarter as large
as in November.

two recessions, including an easing of farm prices and
excess industrial capacity. Some other factors probably
have been more powerful In holding back price advances
in the current than in earlier expansion periods. One of
these is foreign competition— from actual imports and
the ever-present threat of larger imports if domestic prices
get out of line. Such competition has no doubt rein­
forced consumer resistance to higher prices on automo­
biles and other “big ticket” items. In addition, there
has apparently been a growing awareness by manufac­
turers of such items that price increases in recent years
have tended to limit sales. Finally, wage rates have not
been rising as fast in recent years as they had earlier,

Chart II

WHOLESALE AND CONSUMER PRICES
1947-49=100
Per cant

P R IC E M O V E M E N T S

After eleven months of economic expansion, prices
have continued to show marked stability. The wholesale
price index of all commodities, which has been generally
stable since early 1958, was in fact lower in December
1961 than it had been at the February 1961 business
cycle trough (Chart II). Wholesale industrial prices,
moreover, were at about the same level in December as
in February, after allowance is made for the seasonal de­
cline between these two months. This was in contrast to
earlier postwar expansions when such prices invariably
rose during the first ten months. In the 1958-59 expan­
sion, for example, industrial prices rose markedly, and
only an offsetting drop in prices of farm products and
processed foods kept the over-all index from rising.
Consumer prices of commodities other than food rose
moderately between February and December— slightly
less than in the comparable phase of the 1958-59 expan­
sion. The IVi per cent rise in the price of services over the
period also was slightly smaller than the advance in 195859 and compares with much larger increases in most
other postwar years.
Many of the factors restraining price increases during
1961 also existed in the periods following the previous




Note: Shaded areas represent business recessions according to the
N ational Bureau of Economic Research chronology.
* A I I commodities less farm and food products.
Source: United States Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Per cent

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

partly because of the greater difficulty of passing on higher
production costs to consumers.
Raw materials prices have also come under more in­
tense pressures- The growing overlap of uses for dif­
ferent raw materials, for example, has widened com­
petition between aluminum and steel, steel and reinforced
concrete, metals and plastics, and rubber and nonrubber
synthetics. During last autumn, moreover, prices of many
world-traded commodities sagged as manufacturers in a
number of countries abroad curtailed their purchases—
either because demand for their own products was weaken­
ing or because, as in Japan and the United Kingdom,
balance-of-payments difficulties forced the adoption of
fiscal and monetary measures that curbed imports.
The second year of business expansion is, of course, a
more severe testing period for price stability than the first
year. In the expansion following the 1954 recession, for
example, the price rise was moderate until about a year
after the trough. (The second year following the 1958
recession provides a poor reference because of the dis­
tortions introduced by the steel strike in the second half
of 1959.) In 1955-56, bottlenecks developed in certain
sectors and led to price rises that spread throughout the
economy. Industrial capacity now, however, appears to
be better balanced to meet an increase in demands, and

27

foreign competition is more vigorous. While these ele­
ments in the price picture are relatively favorable, the
course of prices over the coming year will in large measure
depend on the pace of productivity gains, on policies fol­
lowed on the fiscal and monetary fronts, and on the
degree of restraint exercised by management and labor.

P E R S P E C T IV E : O N 19®1

The Federal Reserve Bank of New York has
just published Perspective on 1961, a twelve-page
review of economic and financial developments.
Many businessmen and teachers find Perspective
useful as a layman’s summary of the economic
highlights treated more fully in the Bank’s Annual
Report. Copies of Perspective are available with­
out charge in quantity to teachers for classroom
distribution and in limited quantities to others as
long as the supply lasts. Requests should be ad­
dressed to the Publications Section, Federal Reserve
Bank of New York, 33 Liberty Street, New York 45,
N. Y.

The Money Market in January
The condition of the money market varied between
moderate firmness and ease during January. A relatively
firm tone prevailed in the early days of the month, in part
reflecting the lingering effect of year-end firmness in
the money market associated with strong credit demands
which had built up over December. However, as these
pressures receded, an easier trend was evident over
the rest of the month. The effective rate for Federal funds
thus remained close to the 3 per cent ceiling during the
first few days of the month but generally fluctuated be­
tween 2 and 2Vi per cent thereafter, save for two oc­
casions toward the end of the biweekly reserve-averaging
periods of country banks (January 10 and 23), when
inflows of funds from these banks to the money centers
and an unseasonally high level of float combined to push
the rate as low as X
A per cent. Similarly, dealer loan rates
posted by the major New York City banks generally held




in the neighborhood of 2V^-3 per cent, but fell to the 1lA
per cent area during these intervals. In the market for
Treasury bills, rates rose early in the month to 2.82 per
cent and 3.07 per cent on three- and six-month issues,
respectively, the highest levels reached in well over a
year, but adjusted gradually downward during the bal­
ance of the period. Rates on both directly placed and
open market commercial paper followed the same pattern.
In the market for Treasury notes and bonds, prices fluc­
tuated narrowly during the month, and interest centered
on the Treasury’s refunding and “new money” borrowing
operations. On January 9, the Treasury auctioned $2 bil­
lion of one-year bills, dated January 15, 1962, at an aver­
age issuing rate of 3.366 per cent. The proceeds of the
bill issue were used to repay $1.5 billion one-year bills
maturing January 15 and to raise $0.5 billion of new cash.
The Treasury raised another $1 billion of new cash later

28

MONTHLY REVIEW, FEBRUARY 1962

in the month by offering on January 15 additional amounts
of the outstanding 4 per cent bonds dated October 1, 1957
and maturing October 1, 1969. The bonds were reopened
at a price of 99% to yield 4.04 per cent, with commercial
banks permitted to make payment by crediting Treasury
Tax and Loan Accounts. Subscriptions to this offering
were moderate, a large share coming from smaller banks,
and the Treasury allotted 60 per cent of the amount sub­
scribed above $50,000. Federally sponsored agencies were
also borrowers of long-term funds during the month, with
the Federal National Mortgage Association (FNMA)
taking $200 million and the Tennessee Valley Authority
(TVA) $45 million. In addition, the International Bank
for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD) borrowed
$100 million in United States dollars.
After the close of business on February 1, the Treas­
ury announced that it will offer holders of four issues of
Treasury notes, totaling $11.7 billion and maturing on
February 15 and April 1, 1962, the right to exchange
them for either of the following securities: 3Vi per cent
Treasury certificates of indebtedness dated February 15,
1962 and maturing February 15, 1963, priced at par; or
4 per cent Treasury notes dated February 15, 1962 and
maturing August 15, 1966, priced at par. Subscription
books for the exchange will be open February 5 through
7. Cash subscriptions will not be received.

average borrowings from the Federal Reserve rose by $16
million to $116 million.
THE G O V E R N M E N T SE C U R ITIE S M A R K E T

Prices of Treasury notes and bonds during January
held fairly close to the levels of late December. Over the
month as a whole, prices were generally 2¥32 lower to
10/32 higher.
The relative price stability which characterized the mar­
ket for the Treasury’s coupon obligations was the outcome
of a rough balancing of expectations concerning the course
of interest rates in the near-term future. During the first
half of January, prices tended to drift fractionally lower
in response to widely publicized predictions that growing
credit demands would soon lead to rising interest rates,
including particularly an increase in the prime lending rate
at commercial banks. Moreover, the announcement of the
C hanges in F a cto rs Tending: Ito Increase or D ecrease M em ber
B ank R eserves, Janu ary 1962

In millions of dollars; (4~) denotes increase,
(—) decrease in excess reserves
Daily averages—week ended
Factor

Jan.

3

Jan.
10

Jan.
17

Jan.
24

Jan.
31

Net
ohanges

Treasury operations* ...........
Federal Reserve float ...........
Currency in circulation........
Gold and foreign account.. ..

-f- 60
— 171
4-255
— 83
— 6

4 - 61
— 296
4 . 255
4- 44
4 . 46

— 62
— 189
4 - 275
— 36
— 28

— 3
— 84
+ 316
4- 12
— 16

+
7
— 559
4- 278
—
+ 10

63
+
1,299
+ 1,379
— 63
6
+

Total......................

-f 53

4 . 108

— 37

4- 224

— 264

+

4- 31

Operating transactions

M E M B E R B A N K RESERVES

Market factors released reserves to member banks over
the five statement weeks ended January 31. The usual
post-holiday decline in currency in circulation was the
largest single source of reserves, providing about $1.4
billion over the entire period. In addition, a lower aver­
age level of required reserves, largely reflecting a some­
what more than seasonal decline in bank loans, released
about $551 million of reserves. These factors more than
offset the effect of a seasonal decline in float aggregating
$1.3 billion. The drop in float proceeded more slowly
than usual, in part because of bad weather conditions
that delayed the movement of checks.
System open market operations absorbed reserves dur­
ing most of January. Over the period December 27, 1961
to January 31, 1962, average System holdings of Govern­
ment securities fell by $583 million, as outright holdings
were reduced by $535 million and holdings under repur­
chase agreements dropped by $48 million.
Over the five statement weeks ended January 31, free
reserves averaged $509 million, compared with $462 mil­
lion in the preceding four-week period. Average excess
reserves increased by $64 million to $625 million, while




84

Direct Federal Reserve credit
transactions

Government securities:
Direct market purchases or

— 125
Held under repurchase
agreements .......................... 4-183
Loans, discounts, and
advances:
Member bank borrowings... 4- 125
4- 13
Bankers* acceptances:
Bought outright ................. +
1
Under repurchase
+
4
Total....................... 4- 181

3

— 216

— 222

— 144

— 48

— 19

— 277
—

44-

5
5

— 25
+
8

+

2

—

—

1

-

—

___

—

3

1

48
4 . 16
+
6
—

— 260

4 - 52

With Federal Reserve Banks. 4- 234
Cash allowed as reserves! . . . 4 - 220

— 319
— 191

— 291
4 . 54

— 36
— 49

— 212
— 37

+ 454

— 510

— 237

— 85

— 249

4-394

4-233

4 . 177

+

;
=;
... . =■ —.=...
Daily average level of member
bank:
Borrowings from Reserve Banks
Excess reserves! .....................
Free reserves! ........................

4- 166

341
726
385

35

4 4- 92 — 214
— 116 —
= = = = = ..... — ----- —-------- ....... —

64
(510
1)46

69
606
537

1
—

— 254

— 288

44

698
654

Note: Because of rounding, figures do not necessarily add to totals.
* Includes changes in Treasury currency and cash,
t These figures are estimated.
t Average for five weeks ended January 31. 1962.

156
32

3

— 427

Excess reserves!

+

-

Member bank reserves

Total reservesf .....................
Effect of change In required

535

60

484
424

-

708
624

3

—
_

627

+

551

_

76
net

6251
509*

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

Administration’s intention to request a rise of the “ceiling”
on the public debt also contributed to the slight decline
in prices. Immediately after midmonth, however, the mar­
ket firmed and prices recovered somewhat, apparently in
reaction to the weakness in stock prices and to the Ad­
ministration’s proposal of a balanced budget for the fiscal
year 1963. In addition, there was evidence of a growing
feeling in some quarters, perhaps because loan demands
were not so buoyant as had been anticipated, that the
business advance might proceed without engendering sharp
increases in interest rates, at least for the present. As the
close of the month approached, the market for Treasury
notes and bonds drifted slightly lower, mainly reflecting
uncertainties with respect to the terms of the Treasury’s
impending February refinancing operation.
The reopening of the 4 per cent bonds of 1969, an­
nounced on January 11, caused only a mild reaction in the
market, despite the fact that a security of shorter maturity
was expected. Immediately prior to the announcement of
the terms of the financing, these bonds were quoted at
10022/32 bid, to yield 3.90 per cent. On Friday, in ad­
justment to the announcement of the Treasury’s offering
price, the outstanding bonds declined by 2% 2 to 992% 2Subsequently, however, the outstanding 4 per cent bonds
of 1969 declined another % of a point to 992%2 bid,
while other issues maturing from 1966 to 1980 came
under moderate selling pressure as some investors appar­
ently desired to switch out of these issues to purchase the
reopened bonds. The Treasury’s announcement on Janu­
ary 17 of a 60 per cent allotment on subscriptions (some­
what larger than the market expected) evoked only a mild
and brief reaction. Toward the end of the month, the new
bonds declined somewhat in price, together with other
longer term issues.
With the money market still relatively firm from yearend credit and liquidity pressures, Treasury bill rates rose
over the first part of January. In the first two weekly
auctions the average issuing rate on the three-month issue
was set at 2.823 and 2.770 per cent, compared with 2.703
per cent in the pre-New Year auction, while the rate on
the six-month bill rose from 2.941 per cent to 3.073 and
2.970 per cent. The rates set in the first auction were the
highest since the fall of 1960. Although the demand for
biUs, particularly by nonbank investors, was well main­
tained through this period—in fact, throughout the month
— upward rate pressures arose from the $0.5 billion in­
crease in supply of one-year bills auctioned January 9, as
well as from expectations that the Treasury financing
scheduled for later in the month would fall in the rela­
tively short-term area.
Later in the period bill rates adjusted downward, partly




29

in response to the fact that the Treasury did not offer
short-term securities in its cash financing, and partly
in response to the strong bank and nonbank demand that
had developed. Thus, in the regular weekly auction on
January 22, average issuing rates were set at 2.688 per
cent and 2.875 per cent on three- and six-month bills,
respectively, down about 9 basis points in each case from
the previous week. The rate on the new one-year bills
also moved downward from their average issuing rate of
3.366 per cent to reach 3.27 per cent by the end of the
month.
On Wednesday, January 24, the Treasury announced
that it would raise $100 million in new cash by increasing
the amount of 91-day bills to be sold in its regular weekly
auction on January 29. Despite this additional quantity of
three-month bills, a good interest developed in the auction
and rates on outstanding bills rose only slightly. Average
issuing rates were set at 2.705 per cent and 2.939 per cent
for the 91-day and 182-day bills, respectively.
OTHER SEC U R ITIES M A R K E T S

The volume of new publicly offered corporate bonds
during January amounted to $270 million, compared with
$165 million in December and $170 million in January
1961. Long-term Federal agency issues amounted to an
additional $245 million. Early in the period, prices for
corporate issues moved fractionally higher as a conse­
quence of the limited number of new offerings. Prices
eased slightly toward midmonth, as the flow of new offer­
ings increased and as the new financing calendar (includ­
ing agency issues) built up. The calendar took a sharp
jump with the announcement on January 16 of a forth­
coming fifteen-year $200 million FNMA issue, which
reached the market on January 23. In addition, the fol­
lowing issues were also marketed toward the end of the
month: $45 million AVi per cent bonds of the TVA
maturing in twenty-five years; $100 million AV2 per cent
bonds of the IBRD due in 1982; and $30 million Com­
monwealth of Australia 5Vz per cent bonds due in 1982.
Although these large issues were competitive with cor­
porate offerings and made substantial demands upon in­
vestors, they were generally very well received.
Among the larger corporate offerings was a utility issue
of $60 million (Aaa-rated) 4% per cent refunding mort­
gage bonds, due in 2002 and reoffered on January 9 to
yield 4.50 per cent. The bonds, which have no protection
against immediate call or refunding, met with an unenthusiastic investor response. Subsequently the syndicate
distributing the issue was terminated and these bonds
were traded at somewhat lower prices. As the month
progressed, the market for seasoned corporate bonds

30

MONTHLY REVIEW, FEBRUARY 1962

was generally quiet and prices moved sideway, as in­
vestors seemed reluctant to commit themselves. Toward
the end of the period, however, the market strengthened,
encouraged somewhat by the favorable investor response
to Government agency and international financings. The
average yield on Moody’s seasoned Aaa-rated corporate
bonds declined to 4.42 per cent over the month, 2 basis
points below the end-of-December level.
The volume of new tax-exempt issues rose to $890 mil­
lion in January, compared with $545 million in December
and $650 million in January 1961. Prices of new and
outstanding issues nevertheless continued to display firm­
ness, partly in response to further buying by commercial
banks seeking to improve earning power in the light of
higher rates being paid on savings deposits. Reflecting
the generally good demand, the Blue List of advertised
dealer offerings was around the $300 million level during
most of the month, the lowest since early 1961. The most




sizable public offering in the tax-exempt sector was a $100
million (Aa-rated) State of California issue which was
reoffered to yield from 1.90 per cent in 1964 to 3.40 per
cent in 1987. This issue was accorded an excellent recep­
tion.
Rates on private short-term instruments moved up early
in the month in sympathy with Treasury bill rates. Major
finance companies raised their rates on 60- to 89-day
directly placed paper by Vs per cent effective January 2,
and again on January 9, bringing the new rate to 3 per
cent. Also on January 9 commercial paper dealers raised
their rates on prime 4- to 6-month paper by Vs of a per­
centage point, bringing the new rate to 3% per cent
(offered). Following the decline in Treasury bill yields
later in the month, rates on directly placed paper were
lowered by Vs per cent, and open market commercial
paper rates were reduced in two steps by a total of
per
cent. Rates on bankers’ acceptances were unchanged.