View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE
BANK
©F MEW YORK

MONTHLY REVIEW
AUGUST

1 9 75

Contents
The Business Situation ..........................................171
The M oney and Bond Markets in J u ly ............ 177
Measuring the U nited States
Balance o f Payments ....................................... 183

Volume 57




No. 8

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

171

Th e Business Situation

Economic activity steadied in the second quarter of
1975, following five consecutive quarters of significant
decline. While the gross national product (GNP) in real
terms dropped again, the reported decline was negligible
and was more than completely accounted for by an inten­
sification in the rate of inventory liquidation. Indeed, the
latest GNP data suggest that the longest and steepest post­
war recession has finally bottomed out. Although the
inventory liquidation may well continue for sometime fur­
ther, it seems clear that businessmen have been successful
in bringing stocks into better alignment with sales.
Buoyed by consumption spending, final demand as a
whole rose in real terms in the second quarter for the first
time since mid-1973. As a result of lower income taxes
and increased transfer payments, consumers were able to
expand their purchases and at the same time to rebuild
liquidity. Elsewhere, outlays on housing stabilized in real
terms, but business fixed investment spending continued to
decline. Conditions in the labor market improved in July
as employment rose and the unemployment rate declined
to 8.4 percent of the civilian labor force.
On the inflation front, the latest evidence indicates
that the deceleration in inflation which began in the fourth
quarter of last year extended into the April-June period.
The rate of growth of the fixed-weight price index for
GNP— which, unlike other GNP deflators, is unaffected
by compositional shifts in output— was 6 percent in the
second quarter, 1.5 percentage points below the increase
in the previous quarter and the lowest recorded since the
fourth quarter of 1972. However, recent and prospective
developments cast some doubt on whether this favorable
trend will continue. While industrial commodity prices
have moderated in the face of mounting unused capacity
and inventory liquidation, prices of petroleum products
and fuel have recently been climbing at a somewhat accel­
erated pace. Another discouraging factor has been the
recent acceleration in food prices. Moreover, spot and




future prices of agricultural commodities have jumped in
response to reports of large foreign grain purchases. On
the wage front, the latest evidence suggests that the slack
in the labor market has begun to dampen the growth of
wages. The growth of compensation per hour worked de­
celerated in the second quarter and, coupled with in­
creased labor productivity, the rate of increase in unit
labor costs slowed considerably.
GNP AND R E LA TE D D EVELO P M EN TS

According to preliminary data released by the De­
partment of Commerce, the market value of the nation’s
output of goods and services rose by $16.8 billion in the
second quarter, a 4.8 percent seasonally adjusted annual
rate of gain. After adjusting for the effects of higher prices,
real GNP inched down at an annual rate of 0.3 percent,
in sharp contrast to the 11.4 percent plunge in real GNP
in the preceding three-month period (see Chart I). On
balance, real GNP in the April-June quarter stood 7.8
percent below the peak attained in the final three months
of 1973. This is the longest and steepest drop recorded
during any postwar recessionary period.
As in the first quarter, the rapid pace of inventory liqui­
dation was the most important depressant on economic
activity. Current-dollar final expenditure—i.e., GNP less
the change in inventories— rose $31.3 billion, or 9 percent,
at an annual rate. In real terms, the increment in final
sales amounted to 3.3 percent at an annual rate, the first
such gain in six quarters. The increase in real spending
resulted from advances in consumer, residential construc­
tion, and government outlays that more than offset the
drop in business fixed investment.
Preliminary estimates based on partial data indicate that
inventory liquidation accelerated to a record rate in the
second quarter. In current-dollar terms, businesses reduced
their inventories by $33.7 billion, outpacing the very large

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1975

172

C h a rt I

REAL G R O S S N A T IO N A L PR O D U C T A N D FIN A L SA LES
S e a s o n a lly a d ju s te d a n n u a l ra te s
Percent
14

12

10
8

6
4

2

0
-2
-4

-6
-8
-1 0

-12
1 1 I I I I I I 1 I I 1 1 I I 1 1 I I I 1 I I I 1 I I I 1 I I I IsM tsl I I I 1 I 1 1 1 II I 1 I I I 1 I I.J
1953
N o te :
S ource:

-1 4

54
S h a d e d a re a s re p re se n t re c e ssio n p e rio d s , in d ic a te d by the N a tio n a l B ureau o f E c o n o m ic R esearch c h ro n o lo g y .
U n ite d S ta te s D e p a rtm e n t o f C o m m e rce , Bureau o f E conom ic A n a ly s is .

$19.2 billion decline in the first quarter. Despite this
massive inventory liquidation, the $14.5 billion restraint
on GNP expansion was much smaller than the $37 billion
drag in the first quarter, when inventory investment swung
from accumulation to decumulation. Although the massive
inventory correction acts as an immediate depressant on
economic activity, in the long run the liquidation is essen­
tial for an eventual pickup in production.
In the first quarter, about half of the swing to liquida­
tion was accounted for by real retail auto inventories. In
contrast, inventory liquidation in the April-June interval
was much more broadly based, with all major categories
posting sizable declines (see Chart II). In retrospect, it
appears that the inventory correction commenced late in
1974 in the nondurables trade sector and has spread since
then to all major sectors of the economy. Thus, in the
second quarter of this year, inventory reductions occurred
in the durable and nondurable manufacturing, whole­




sale, and retail trade sectors. As a result of the massive
inventory liquidation and the recent pickup in final sales,
the ratio of constant-dollar inventories to final GNP sales
has now receded from the extraordinarily high level to
which it had risen at the end of 1974. While imbalances
probably still remain in certain sectors of the economy,
especially durable manufacturing, the overall inventory
situation is now vastly improved over what it was at the
beginning of the year.
There was in the second quarter a marked improvement
in final sales, spurred by a sharp rise in disposable income.
Consumers’ disposable income surged by $63.3 billion
in the second quarter, as tax rebates, cuts in taxwithholding rates, and special supplemental social security
transfers swelled spendable income. The jump in disposable
income stemmed from a $27.4 billion increase in personal
income, coupled with a $36 billion drop in personal tax
payments. Part of the gain in personal income was at­

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

tributable to onetime payments of $50 to social security
recipients, while tax rebates amounted to $31.7 billion at
an annual rate. Together with an easing in the rate of
inflation, real disposable income rose at a 22 percent season­
ally adjusted annual rate.
Personal consumer expenditures increased by $24.9
billion in current-dollar terms (see Chart III). In real
terms, the gain in personal consumption expenditures was
the largest since the first quarter of 1973. With disposable
income increasing sharply and consumption spending
increasing more moderately, the saving rate soared to 10.6
percent of disposable income, the highest rate of saving
since the first quarter of 1946 and well above the 7.5
percent averaged over the previous four quarters. While
this accumulated saving is likely to be used initially by

C h a rt II

REAL INVENTORY INVESTMENT AND REAL INVENTORY-SALES
RATIOS IN THE GNP ACCOUNTS

1
II.llli III...1■i.l
H
LI111111 ,_L_L.jJI
S e a so n a lly a d ju s te d a n n u a l rates

B illio n s o f 1958 d o lla rs

B illio n s o f 1958 d o lla rs

REAL INVEN1 rORY INVEST)WENT:
TRADE

■

M A N U F A ' CTURING

■■■1
■

r

.■ilnl i
-

.■ ii

I I 1. 11L 111 LI._L_ I 11 ]
Percen t

Source: United States D epartm ent o f Commerce.




P ercent

173

consumers to reduce instalment debt and rebuild liquidity,
it will at the same time provide a foundation for stronger
consumer spending in future months. Moreover, the im­
pact of lower withholding schedules and extended unem­
ployment benefits will continue to be felt in the future,
and an 8 percent cost-of-living increase in social security
benefits will also boost disposable income. The gain in
real consumer spending reflected higher outlays for du­
rable and nondurable goods as well as for services. Real
service expenditures increased at a 4.8 percent annual
rate. Real spending on consumer durables rose at a 10
percent annual rate in the June quarter, with auto expen­
ditures expanding at a 9 percent annual rate and nonauto
spending rising at a 10.5 percent annual rate. Sales of
domestically produced cars have edged up steadily in re­
cent months, running at 7.1 million units in June as com­
pared with the 6 million units sold in March. Nondurable
goods outlays rose at a 6.3 percent annual rate, the largest
increase since the fourth quarter of 1972.
After skidding for two years, real residential construc­
tion spending edged up in the second quarter. To be sure,
the increase was negligible, but it nonetheless suggests that
the collapse in housing has ended. Most other measures
of housing activity confirm the pickup in home building,
but the strength of the recovery is still uncertain. Permits
to build new homes rose each month of the quarter and,
over the quarter, averaged 892,000. While this remains a
depressed rate by historical standards, it is 30 percent
higher than the first-quarter average. Another encouraging
factor has been the improvement in sales of single-family
homes. Sales are now at their highest level since May
1974. No doubt the tax credit on purchases of new, pre­
viously unoccupied houses is a factor in the sales pickup.
On a newly built home of $40,000, which is close to the
median price of new one-family homes, the 5 percent tax
credit works out to be roughly equal to a 20 percent re­
duction on a 25 percent downpayment. The ratio of unsold
new homes to sales fell in May to its lowest level in nearly
two years. Despite the recent upturn of short-term interest
rates, rates on time and savings deposits have remained
relatively attractive and deposit growth at thrift institutions
has continued to accelerate. In June, deposits at savings
and loan associations and mutual savings banks rose at
close to a 20 percent annual rate. Thus, the outlook for
housing remains moderately encouraging, as the increased
inflow may lead to further easing in mortgage lending terms.
Business fixed investment declined $2.3 billion in the
second quarter, as the drop of $2.6 billion investment in
structures more than offset a $0.2 billion increase in
producers’ durable equipment. In real terms, plant and
equipment outlays fell for the fourth consecutive quarter.

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1975

174
C h a rt III

RECENT CH A N G ES IN G RO SS N A TIO N A L PRODUCT
AND ITS CO M PONENTS
S e a s o n a lly a d ju s te d
C h a n g e fro m fo u r th q u a r te r
1 974 to fir s t q u a r te r 1975

m h h

C h a n g e fro m firs t q u a r te r to
se co n d q u a r te r 1975

-4 0 -3 5 -3 0 -2 5 -2 0 -1 5 -1 0

-5

0

5

10

15 20 25 30

35

B illio n s o f d o lla rs

S o u rc e :

U n ite d S ta te s D e p a r tm e n t o f C o m m e rc e , B u re a u o f E c o n o m ic A n a ly s is .

In light of the current low levels of capacity utilization,
there is little reason to look for a turnaround in spending.
Indeed, the most recent Commerce Department survey of
capital spending plans, taken in late April and May, indi­
cates such a meager increase in nominal outlays in 1975
that a decline in real terms seems certain. Outlays on new
plant and equipment are expected to be only 1.6 percent
higher than in 1974.
PRICE DEVELOPM ENTS

By virtually every measure, inflation continued to de­
celerate over the April-June period. Prices of goods and
services, as covered by the implicit GNP price deflator,
advanced at a 5.1 percent annual rate in the second
quarter, down substantially from the 8.4 percent advance
recorded in the previous three-month period. In part,




however, it appears that the slowdown in the implicit GNP
deflator overstated the actual improvement because of the
changing composition of output, especially the sizable
pickup in the level of auto production between the first
and second quarters. The fixed-weight price index, which
holds constant the composition of output, improved more
modestly, with its annual rate of increase falling from 7.5
percent in the first quarter to a 6 percent rate in the
second quarter.
To the relief of consumers, the rate of inflation in retail
prices is now running well below the double-digit range.
Since peaking at an 11.9 percent annual rate in the third
quarter of 1974, the rate of advance of consumer prices
has eased considerably. In the second quarter, such prices
rose at a 5.8 percent annual rate, the slowest quarterly
rate of increase since the end of 1972. This deceleration
reflected a sharp slowdown of inflation in the prices of
nonfood commodities and services, as well as food. How­
ever, it appears that the volatile food component is headed
back up. Led by rapid increases in the price of meat, the
increase in food prices accelerated each month of the
quarter. Nonfood commodity prices rose at a 6.7 percent
annual rate over the quarter, less than half of the 13.6
percent rate of increase a year earlier. Service prices in
the second quarter rose at a 6.1 percent annual rate,
compared with a 9.3 percent annual-rate advance in the
previous quarter.
At the wholesale level, prices of industrial commodities
continued to decelerate, rising at a 2.6 percent annual
rate over the April-June period. This was in sharp contrast
to the year-earlier quarterly increase that exceeded 30
percent at an annual rate. The deceleration would have
been even more pronounced if power and fuel prices had
not begun to rise rapidly again. Unfortunately, the nearterm outlook for energy prices is not encouraging. The
full impact of import fees of $2 per barrel on crude oil
and 60 cents per barrel on refined petroleum products is
still to be felt and undoubtedly will add to pressures on
energy prices. In addition, energy prices could accelerate
even further in the event that either domestic crude oil
prices are decontrolled or the Organization of Petroleum
Exporting Countries (OPEC) cartel raises its price of oil.
Excluding power and fuel, industrial commodity prices
rose only at a 2.2 percent annual rate in June. After de­
clining in the first three months of 1975, wholesale agri­
cultural prices increased at a 16 percent annual rate in
the second quarter. As a consequence, wholesale prices
as a whole rose at a 7 percent annual rate in the second
quarter after declining in the first quarter. To a large ex­
tent, the turnaround in agricultural prices reflected a jump
in the prices of livestock and meat, as prices of hogs and

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

beef cattle have soared recently.
In July the outlook for food prices was clouded by
reports of drought damage to USSR crops and by news
that the Soviets were seeking to purchase substantial
amounts of wheat and corn from the United States. De­
spite forecasts of record domestic production of corn and
wheat, prices of these commodities have jumped sharply.
As of the end of July, the USSR had contracted to pur­
chase 9.8 million metric tons of domestic wheat, corn,
and barley. Although it is clear that the increased Soviet
demand for United States grain exports will lead to higher
prices of corn and wheat, it does not appear that these
purchases will precipitate the skyrocketing prices of 197273. With the exception of the USSR, prospects for an
increase in worldwide production appear good, and pro­
duction estimates suggest that carry-over stocks in this
country at the end of the year will likely be larger than at
the beginning.
WAGES, P R O D U C TIVITY, AND EM P LO YM EN T

Recent data indicate that the pace of wage increases
has slowed in the past several months. Over the AprilJune interval, compensation per hour worked, which
includes wages and fringe benefits, rose in the private
nonfarm sector of the economy at a seasonally adjusted
annual rate of 7.2 percent, a slower pace than the 10
percent increase averaged in the previous four quarters.
The slowdown in wage gains has also been mirrored
in other wage series. Average hourly earnings increased
at a 5.1 percent annual rate in the second quarter, com­
pared with an 8.5 percent advance recorded in 1974.
However, because movements in this series reflect not
only wage changes but also changes in manufacturing
overtime and interindustry shifts in employment, a better
measure of wage-rate changes is the adjusted hourly
earnings index. After adjusting for changes in overtime
in manufacturing and interindustry shifts, the gain in
average hourly earnings slowed to 6.9 percent at a sea­
sonally adjusted annual rate in the second quarter, the
third consecutive quarter of slower wage gains and the
lowest rate of increase since the first quarter of 1974.
Over 1974 as a whole, adjusted average hourly earnings
climbed at a 9.1 percent rate.
Developments reported in the separate survey of major
collective bargaining agreements also reveal a modest
slowing in the rate of wage increases, although the gains
remain sizable. In collective bargaining agreements cover­
ing 5,000 or more workers, contracts settled in the sec­
ond quarter provided for a 9.3 percent annual rise in
wages and benefits over the first year of the contract and




175

7.7 percent annually over the contract life. In contrast, the
increases in contracts signed in 1974 averaged 10.7 and
7.8 percent, respectively. For wages alone, settlements
covering 1,000 or more workers in the second quarter
provided for first-year increases of 9.8 percent, compared
with 12.5 percent in the preceding three-month period.
Because union negotiators have concentrated on winning
large first-year wage increases, the relatively light cal­
endar of major contracts that expire in 1975 should tend
to help moderate wage pressures, since most union
workers will be receiving the relatively smaller secondand third-year increases provided by agreements signed
in earlier years. This tendency is reflected in the Bureau
of Labor Statistics’ effective wage series, which includes
gains arising from current settlements, deferred increases
negotiated in earlier years, and additional gains from
escalator clauses. In the second quarter, the effective
wage rate rose at a 7.8 percent annual rate after advancing
9.4 percent in 1974.
Productivity, as measured by output per hour of work
in the nonfarm private economy, rose at a 3.4 percent
seasonally adjusted annual rate over the April-June
period, the first increase in more than two years. This
advance, however, resulted from a decline in hours
worked which exceeded the decline in total production.
Typically, during the early stages of a cyclical recovery,
productivity tends to pick up sharply as producers are
able to utilize idle capacity more efficiently without large
additions to their labor force. However, some analysts
have argued recently that productivity increases in com­
ing months may be subnormal for this phase of the busi­
ness cycle since durable manufacturing industries may post
smaller productivity increases than in typical recoveries.
These analysts foresee only a modest recovery in the pro­
duction of durable goods which ordinarily have bounced
back sharply. In any event, the prospect of a moderate in­
crease in unit labor costs this year looks promising since
productivity growth, even if sluggish, is still likely to miti­
gate wage gains somewhat. In contrast, productivity
declined continuously in 1974. In the second quarter, be­
cause of the deceleration in compensation and gains in
productivity, unit labor costs in the private nonfarm sector
rose at a seasonally adjusted 3.9 percent, the slowest annual
rate of increase since late 1972 and far below the 14 percent
advance posted in 1974.
According to the household survey, labor market con­
ditions improved in July as the rate of joblessness fell to
8.4 percent. This was the second consecutive monthly
decline and left the unemployment rate at its lowest level
since February. Since the unemployment rate in June had
been artificially depressed by faulty seasonal adjustment

176

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1975

procedures, it was widely expected that the jobless rate
would post a substantial increase in July. Under these cir­
cumstances, it seems likely that the 0.2 percentage point
decline in July may understate the actual degree of labor
market strengthening. Despite this, the unemployment rate
remains high by historical standards and, moreover, it
remains to be seen if some of the improvement was an
aberration. Typically, the unemployment rate tends to lag
somewhat behind the pickup in economic activity, since
employers expand production initially by lengthening the
workweek of their work force without recalling laid-off
workers or hiring new ones. In addition, as job prospects
improve, this often encourages individuals who have
stopped looking for employment to seek jobs, thus tending
to swell the labor force and raise the rate of unemploy­
ment. Whatever the near-term behavior of the unemploy­
ment rate, employment has begun to expand. In July, total
employment registered its fourth consecutive increase, ad­
vancing by 634,000 workers to its highest level in seven
months. The number of unemployed persons fell in July to
the lowest level since February. Most labor force groups
shared in the improvement in employment; in addition,




the number of persons working part time because they
couldn’t find full-time employment declined sharply in
July, dropping by 175,000.
While the household survey points to an increased pace
of employment growth, the separate payroll survey indi­
cates a more modest advance in employment. Of course,
the household and payroll surveys may diverge because of
differences in definition, coverage, sources, and estimation
procedures. In July, the survey of nonfarm establishments
indicated that employment rose by 88,000 as employ­
ment in services, trade, and state and local government
expanded. Employment in construction declined slightly
but this may have reflected the effects of increased strike
activity. Manufacturing employment also dipped slightly,
but average weekly hours worked in manufacturing
jumped to the longest workweek since November 1974.
While the household survey points to a much faster em­
ployment growth than the payroll survey, the payroll sur­
vey nevertheless suggests that the employment gain was
broadly based. The percentage of nonfarm industries ex­
periencing increases in employment rose to 54.9 percent,
the highest level in more than a year.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

177

Th e M oney and Bond Markets in July

Both short- and long-term interest rates advanced dur­
ing July, partly in response to a substantial buildup in
the corporate and municipal bond calendars and the
belief of market participants that some firming of mone­
tary policy was under way. The sharp rise in yields on
the Municipal Assistance Corporation’s bonds when they
began trading without price restrictions was an additional
depressant in the municipal market since it rekindled con­
cern over the financial problems confronting New York
City and some other urban areas. During the month,
Treasury borrowing also continued heavy, through sizable
amounts of new cash raised at each weekly bill auction
and through the sale of $1.5 billion of new notes. At the
end of the month the Treasury auctioned $5.8 billion of
coupon issues to refund August maturities and raise $1
billion of new cash.
In the money market, most rates moved upward in
July for the second consecutive month. The rates at which
Federal funds traded increased over the month to an
average of 6.10 percent. Higher yields were also posted
on all maturities of commercial paper and on large certifi­
cates of deposit (CDs). In addition, major commer­
cial banks boosted their prime lending rate over the
period by V2 percentage point to IV 2 percent. This was
the first increase in the prime rate since July 1974, when
the rate reached a record 12 percent before falling
steadily to 7 percent in June of this year.
According to preliminary estimates, the growth in both
the narrow and broad money stock measures moderated
considerably in July from the very rapid expansion of
the previous two months. However, since consumer-type
time deposits at commercial banks continued rising
sharply, the slowdown in the growth of the broad money
stock was less pronounced. The bank credit proxy fell
somewhat in July, as declines in Government deposits
at member banks and in CDs offset demand and
consumer-type time deposit growth.




T H E MONEY M ARKET AND
TH E M O N ETA R Y

AGGREGATES

Interest rates on money market instruments rose fur­
ther in July, following the sharp advances experienced
in the preceding month (see Chart I). As the Federal
Reserve absorbed reserves at progressively higher levels
of the Federal funds rate, participants became convinced
that a firming of monetary policy was under way. For
the month as a whole, the effective rate on Federal funds
averaged 6.10 percent, an increase of 55 basis points
from the comparable figure for June. Rates generally
increased Vi percentage point on directly placed commer­
cial paper in July, while most maturities of dealer-placed
paper registered a Vk percentage point gain. The average
yield in the secondary market on ninety-day CDs showed
considerable fluctuation during July and closed the month
at 6.55 percent, up 15 basis points from the end of June.
In line with these increases in money market yields, the
rate on prime business loans at most money-center banks
was boosted in July in two V<\ percentage point steps to
IV2 percent.
Business demand for short-term credit remained weak
during July, as corporations apparently continued to
lengthen the maturity of their liabilities. Over the first four
statement weeks of the month, business loans at large
commercial banks fell by $1 billion. This compares
with increases of $2.7 billion and $2.3 billion over the
comparable period in the two preceding years. In response
to this weakness, banks allowed a further large volume
of their CDs to run off in July. There was essentially no
change in the amount of nonfinancial commercial paper
outstanding during July when allowance is made for the
usual seasonal pattern.
Preliminary data indicate that there was a sharp de­
celeration during July in the growth of the narrow money
supply (MO—private demand deposits adjusted plus cur­

178

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1975

rency outside commercial banks. On an annual basis, the
average seasonally adjusted level of M1 in the four weeks
ended July 23 was 1.8 percent above the average for the
four weeks ended June 25. Both in May and particularly
in June, Mx had grown at extremely rapid rates, in part
due to the effects of tax rebates by the Treasury and
special social security payments. As a result, the expan­
sion in Mx in the four weeks ended July 23 from its
average level in the four weeks ended thirteen weeks
earlier was a substantial 10.6 percent at an annual rate.
Over the latest fifty-two-week span, however, Mx advanced
a moderate 5 percent (see Chart II).
Consumer-type time and savings accounts continued
to grow strongly in July, as rates on these deposits re­

mained attractive. The broad money stock (M2)— which
includes these deposits plus Mx—thus grew at an 8.4
percent seasonally adjusted annual rate in the four weeks
ended July 23, compared with the average four-week level
in the period ended June 25. Over this same period the
average levels at commercial banks of United States Gov­
ernment deposits and negotiable CDs declined substan­
tially on a seasonally adjusted basis. As a result, there was
a decrease in the adjusted bank credit proxy, a measure
which includes all deposits at member banks subject to
reserve requirements plus certain nondeposit sources of
funds. On an annual basis, the average seasonally adjusted
level of the proxy in the four weeks ended July 23 was 5.6
percent lower than its average level in the preceding four-

C h a rt I

SELECTED INTEREST RATES
M a y -J u ly 19 7 5
M O N E Y M A R K E T RATES

M ay

N o te :

June

B O N D M A R K E T RATES

Ju ly

May

June

Ju ly

D a ta a re show n fo r b u siness d a y s o n ly .

M O N E Y MARKET RATES Q UO TED: P rim e c o m m e rc ia l loan rate a t m ost m a jo r ba n ks;
o ffe r in g ra te s (q u o te d in term s o f ra te o f d is c o u n t) on 90- to 1 19-day p rim e c o m m e rc ia l
p a p e r q u o te d by th re e o f the fiv e d e a le rs th a t r e p o r t th e ir ra te s , o r th e m id p o in t o f
th e ra n g e q u o te d if no consensus is a v a ila b le ; the e ffe c tiv e ra te on F e d e ra l fu n d s
(the ra te m ost re p re s e n ta tiv e o f th e tra n s a c tio n s e x e c u te d ); c lo sin g b id ra te s (q u o te d
in te rm s o f ra te o f discount) on ne w e st o u ts ta n d in g th re e -m o n th T re a su ry b ills.
B O N D MARKET YIELDS Q UO TED: Y ie ld s on new A a a - r a te d p u b lic u tility b o n d s a re ba se d
on p ric e s a s k e d b y u n d e r w ritin g s y n d ic a te s , a d ju s te d to m ake th e m e q u iv a le n t to a




s ta n d a rd A a a - ra te d b o n d o f a t le a s t tw e n ty y e a rs ’ m a tu rity ; d a ily a v e ra g e s o f
y ie ld s on s e a so n e d A a a - ra te d c o rp o ra te b o n d s ; d a ily a v e ra g e s o f y ie ld s on
lo n g -term G o v e rn m e n t s e c u ritie s (bo n d s d u e o r c a lla b le in ten y e a rs o r m ore)
a n d on G o v e rn m e n t s e c u ritie s d u e in th re e to fiv e y e a rs , co m p u te d on th e b a s is
o f c lo s in g b id p ric e s ; T h u rsd a y a v e ra g e s o f y ie ld s on tw e n ty s e a s o n e d tw e n tyy e a r ta x -e x e m p t b o n d s (c a rry in g M o o d y ’s ra tin g s o f A a a , A a , A , a n d Baa).
S ources: F e d e ra l R eserve B a n k o f N e w Y ork, B o a rd o f G o v e rn o rs o f the F e d e ra l
Reserve S ystem , M o o d y 's In ve sto rs S e rv ic e , Inc., a n d The B ond B uyer.

179

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

week period. Member banks made somewhat heavier use
of the discount window during July, when borrowings
averaged $386 million (see Table I), compared with
$97 million in June.

C h a rt II

C H A N G ES IN M ONETARY AN D CREDIT AGG REGATES
S e a s o n a lly a d ju s te d a n n u a l rate s
P ercent

20
Ml

F rom 13
w e e k s e a r lie r

TH E GOVERNM ENT SECURITIES M ARKET

Yields on Treasury securities increased on balance
during July, initially in response to uncertainty about the
course of monetary policy and later in response to what
participants interpreted as a firming of this policy despite
the upcoming August refunding. A lack of significant
investor demand was also evident at various times. In
addition, the Treasury’s large financing needs engendered
a cautious tone, given the less than enthusiastic investor
interest exhibited from time to time during the month.
Rates on coupon issues generally edged higher during
the first week of the month in light, pre-Fourth of July
holiday trading. In the wake of the rise in rates at the end
of June, investors tended to wait on the sidelines in
uncertainty about the near-term course of interest rates,
and some unloading of holdings also took place. Then,
in the following week, the Federal funds rate receded from
its higher midyear level which had partly reflected seasonal
pressures. In addition, declines in Mi and in business
loans, coupled with better than expected demand in the
July 14 weekly bill auction, also contributed to an im­
proved tone in the Treasury coupon market at that time.
Market participants responded favorably, and yields on
notes and bonds moved down over the remainder of the
first half of July.
As the month progressed, growing concern developed
about investor acceptance of the $1.5 billion of Treasury
notes scheduled for auction on July 17 and the terms
and amount of the August refinancing which were to be
announced after the market’s close on July 23. Response
to the $1.5 billion of two-year notes auctioned at mid­
month turned out to be favorable, with tenders from the
public totaling $5.4 billion. The notes were sold at an
average yield of 7.52 percent. Following this auction,
rates increased in the wake of lackluster secondary market
interest in the new notes and in anticipation of the yields
which would be required to complete successfully the
Treasury’s August refinancing. The terms of the refinanc­
ing were announced as expected on July 23. To refund
$4.8 billion of publicly held notes maturing August 15
and to raise $1 billion in new cash, the Treasury auctioned
$3 billion of 2%-year notes, $2 billion of seven-year
notes, and $0.8 billion of twenty-five year bonds at the
end of July. Also, the Treasury sold $2.6 billion of
notes and bonds at the average price of accepted tenders




From ^52
,
w e e k s ec3r li e r

__ /

1 1 1 I 1 I III

J1

I I

/

/

i l l

i l l

i i

M2

From 52

^

^

/X

w e e k s e a r lie r
F rom

—

1

w e e k s e a r lie r

1 1

N o te :

1 1 1 1 1 1 III

1 L.

i l l

i l l

II

G r o w th ra te s a r e c o m p u te d on th e b a s is o f fo u r -w e e k a v e r a g e s o f d a ily

fig u r e s f o r p e r io d s e n d e d in th e s ta te m e n t w e e k p lo tt e d , 13 w e e k s e a r lie r a n d
52 w e e k s e a r lie r .

The la te s t s ta te m e n t w e e k p lo tt e d is J u ly 23 , 1975.

M l = C u rre n c y p lu s a d ju s te d d e m a n d d e p o s its h e ld b y th e p u b lic .
M 2 - M l p lu s c o m m e r c ia l b a n k s a v in g s a n d tim e d e p o s its h e ld b y th e p u b lic , less
n e g o tia b le c e r tific a te s o f d e p o s it is s u e d in d e n o m in a tio n s o f $ 1 0 0 ,0 0 0 o r m o re .
A d ju s te d b a n k c r e d it p r o x y - T o ta l m e m b e r b a n k d e p o s its s u b je c t to re s e rv e
r e q u ir e m e n ts p lu s n o n d e p o s it so u rc e s o f fu n d s , such as E u ro - d o lla r
b o r r o w in g s a n d th e p r o c e e d s o f c o m m e r c ia l p a p e r is s u e d b y b a n k h o ld in g
c o m p a n ie s o r o th e r a f filia te s .
S o u rc e :

B o a rd o f G o v e r n o rs o f th e F e d e ra l R e se rve S yste m .

to Government accounts and Federal Reserve Banks, which
held $2.9 billion of maturing notes. The public’s initial re­
sponse to the August refinancing was quite favorable. On
July 29, the Treasury received $5.6 billion in tenders for
its $3 billion of thirty-three-month notes and the average
issuing rate was set at 7.94 percent. The following day the
Treasury received tenders of more than $3.7 billion for its
$2 billion of seven-year notes. The average issuing rate for
the notes was 8.14 percent. Investors also tendered $2
billion for the final part of the sale, the $800 million of
twenty-five-year bonds which were auctioned on July 31
at an average yield of 8.44 percent.
At the time of the refunding announcement the Trea­
sury also disclosed its projected new cash borrowing for
the last half of 1975. It was estimated to be $41 billion,

180

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1975

Table I
$3 billion higher than the amount estimated in mid-June.
An additional $3.5 billion to $4 billion will be borrowed
FACTORS TENDING TO INCREASE OR DECREASE
MEMBER BANK RESERVES, JULY 1975
in late August and early September through issues of
In millions of dollars; (+ ) denotes increase
two-year and four-year notes, and there will also be addi­
and (—) decrease in excess reserves
tions to the regular bill auctions totaling $3 billion to $3.5
billion between mid-August and mid-September. From
Changes in daily averages week ended
then to the end of October, cash needs will be about $9
Factors
billion, but no details were given for raising that amount.
July
July
July
July
July
Over the month as a whole, the index of yields on
16
23
2
9
30
intermediate-term Government securities rose 32 basis
points to 7.88 percent. However, the index of long-term
bond yields rose only 7 basis points to 6.93 percent.
The Treasury bill market responded in similar fashion
to many of the factors which affected Government coupon
securities during July. Rates moved higher as the month
began, in response to the less than enthusiastic bidding in
+
the final weekly auction in June. Although investor interest
•—
3
emerged at the higher yield levels, participants remained
cautious because of their uncertainty about the future
111
+
—
+
trend in interest rates. Reflecting this atmosphere, the
+
average issuing rates on the three- and six-month bills
at the first weekly auction in July were 19 and 25 basis
points higher than a week earlier. Then, over the next
several days, rates on bills declined in response to the
lower level of Federal funds trading and expanded
investor and professional demand. As a result, the average
issuing rate on the three- and six-month bills declined by
1
some 15 basis points at the July 14 auction (see Table II),
and rates edged even lower following the sale.
After midmonth the tone in the bill market became
more cautious, as the rate on Federal funds began to rise
and the Federal Reserve absorbed reserves on several occa­
sions. Although some investor demand was evident for
selected maturities from time to time, bill rates increased
on balance and, over the month as a whole, yields on most
Treasury bills rose 29 to 59 basis points.
Daily average levels
Rates on Federal agency issues also rose during July,
and some new offerings encountered investor resistance.
On July 17, two farm credit agency offerings were marketed
!
at yields about 1lA percentage points higher than were pro­
vided on similar issues in June. At these yield levels, the
bonds were given a good reception. New securities offered
202
by the Federal Land Banks and the Government National
20
Mortgage Association (GNMA) encountered some initial
problems. Early in July the Federal Land Banks priced
20
$464 million of IV2 -year bonds to yield 8.20 percent and
$650 million of fifteen-month bonds to yield 7.20 percent.
Because of rounding, figures do not necessarily add to totals.
The longer bonds sold quickly, but the shorter ones did *Note:
Includes changes in Treasury currency and cash,
not because the yield was so close to that on comparable t Included in total member bank borrowings.
Includes assets denominated in foreign currencies.
Treasury issues. The GNMA offering on July 15 was also t§ Average
for five weeks ended July 30, 1975.
in two parts: $154 million of thirty-year securities yielding || Not reflected
in data above.




—

Net
changes

1

“ M a rk e t” factors

Member bank required reserves. . —

466

+

584

—

306

+ 106

+2,471

+1,851

— 667

+

—

100

— 294

415

—

— 160

449

+ 2,493

25

—

107

Operating transactions

...........................................

— 1,620

Federal Reserve float ..................

95

Treasury operations* ..................

— 1,538

+2,396

+2,244

G old and foreign account . . . .

—

+

10

—

32

—

604

—

220

(subtotal)

Currency outside banks

31

..........

362

19.2

+

+2,227
542

22

—

19

— 228 ,4-1.188

+

133

+

160

56

—

Other Federal Reserve

—

40

liab ilitie s and cap ital ................

47

307

41

Total “ m arket” f a c t o r s ..............

— 2,086

+3,055

+1,545

561

167

+ 2,120

+1,832

— 2,692

*— 1,600

+ 505

128

— 2,083

—

— 1,210

+ 587

240

—

823

+

—

1

+
—

4
2

D ire c t Fed era l R eserve c re d it
tra nsa c tion s

Open market operations
(subtotal)

...........................................

Outright holdings:

Treasury securities .......................

+

400

R ankers’ acceptances..................

+

8

Federal agency obligations . . . .

360

—

1

—

1

4

6

Repurchase agreements:

Treasury securities ....................... +1,184

— 2,008

_

298

—

90

Bankers’ acc ep tance s..................

+

124

—

152

—

81

+

11

Federal agency o b lig a tio n s ........

+

116

—

170

—

15

+

Member bank b o r r o w in g s ..............

+

683

—

648

—

21

................

+

5

—

2

+

3

+

Other Federal Reserve assets} . . .

—

156

—

3

+

43

+

Seasonal borrowings!

Total

...............................................

Excess reserves^ ................................

96

3

14

—

80

+ 180

129

+

65

1

4-

10

121

+

77

136

— 1,941

3 +
72 +

— 1,578

+ 757

+

■
—

_

+ 196

33

— 1,086
—

— 3,343

288

126

2

+2,359

273

+
+

+

31

+

179

Monthly
averages§

M em ber b a n k :

Total reserves, including

vault cashj .........................................

35,471

34,599

34,872

34,962

35,018

34,984

R equired reserves .............................

35,077

34,493

34,799

34,693

34,718

34,756

Excess reserves .................................

394

106

73

269

300

228

Total borrowings

.............................

871

223

382

253

386

Seasonal borrowingsf ................

15

13

16

19

Nonborrowed reserves .....................

34,600

34,376

34,670

34,580

34,765

34,598

71

226

97

79

99

17

Net carry-over, excess or
deficit

(— )||

...................................

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

8.42 percent and $70 million of twenty-five-year securities
priced to yield 8.44 percent. The larger issue in particular
sold quite poorly, and yields on both parts rose by 9 basis
points when the securities were released from syndicate
two days later.

181

Table II
AVERAGE ISSUING RATES
AT REGULAR TREASURY BILL AUCTIONS*
In percent
Weekly auction dates— July 1975
Maturity

TH E OTHER SECURITIES M ARKETS

Yields moved higher in both the corporate and munic­
ipal markets over the month of July in the face of heavy
calendars and some concern among participants as to the
near-term course of interest rates. Early in the month
there was a decline in both The Bond Buyer index of
twenty municipal bond yields and the Federal Reserve
Board’s index of yields on recently offered corporate
securities. However, in response to the pressure of addi­
tional new offerings and the increase in short-term rates,
the pattern was soon reversed and the indexes rose steadily
over most of July.
By far the dominant factor in the tax-exempt market
during the month was the $1 billion offering of New York
Municipal Assistance Corporation (MAC) bonds. The
two-day sale of this issue occurred on June 30 and July 1
and was generally considered successful at that time, al­
though there was reportedly little demand for the bonds
among out-of-state investors despite their very high yields.
As the month progressed and the bonds remained under
syndicate price restriction, speculation arose as to the
actual success of the sale. When the bonds were finally
freed to trade on July 21, their prices dropped sharply,
increasing the yields substantially. Since MAC was plan­
ning to raise an additional $2 billion by the end of Septem­
ber in order to aid New York City, its difficulties with the
initial sale generated concern about the fate of its future
offerings. With some $790 million of New York City notes
maturing in August, the municipal market was once again
confronted with the depressing possibility of a default by
the city.
In contrast to MAC’s and New York City’s problems,
the next largest tax-exempt issue, the New York State
Power Authority’s $200 million offering of top-rated
promissory notes, sold out immediately at midmonth.
These consisted of $150 million of IVa percent notes due
in three years and $50 million of IVi percent notes with
a five-year maturity. Priced at par, the issue provided gen­
erous yields when compared with another authority offering
a month earlier. Two issues totaling $275 million were
postponed during July, and some large new offerings in the
last half of the month sold somewhat slowly. However, an
improved tone developed as the month drew to a close, in
part because of renewed interest in the MAC bonds as




Three-month .........................................

July
7

July
14

July
21

July
28

6.203
6.510

6.045
6.344

6.247
6.626

6.318
6.719

Monthly auction dates— April-July 1975

Fifty-two weeks ...................................

April
30

May
28

June
24

July
24

6.400

5.803

6.292

6.782

* Interest rates on bills are quoted in terms of a 360-day year, with the discounts from
par as the return on the face amount of the bills payable at maturity. Bond yield
equivalents, related to the amount actually invested, would be slightly higher.

signs of some progress in New York City’s fiscal problems
emerged. The Bond Buyer index rose 22 basis points from
the end of June to a record 7.22 percent on July 24 and
then declined to 7.09 percent the following week. The
Blue List of dealers’ advertised inventories fell by $13
million and closed the month at $547 million.
The corporate bond market experienced a record vol­
ume of new issues during the first half of 1975, and
offerings continued heavy in July, a normally slow month.
Most of the large new issues were given a good reception
in July, albeit at higher yields. The largest taxable offering
during the month was $500 million of International Bank
for Reconstruction and Development Aaa-rated debt
which was sold on July 9. Almost all of the $200 million
of ten-year notes was sold the first day at a yield
of 8.6 percent, but the second part of the offering, $300
million of five-year notes paying 8.3 percent, moved
somewhat more slowly. The next day brought the market­
ing of two additional large offerings: $300 million of
Standard Oil Co. of California’s Aaa-rated debentures
and a $250 million Aa-rated package from Ford
Motor Credit Co. Both were well received. The thirtyyear oil company bonds were priced to yield 8.83
percent, 36 basis points more than a similarly rated oil
issue offered a month earlier. The two-part offering from
the credit company, $100 million in ten-year notes and
$150 million in twenty-five-year debentures, was also
attractively priced to yield 8.85 percent and 9.73 percent,
respectively. Reflecting the general rise in rates on corpo­
rate issues during July, the Bell Telephone Co. of

182

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1975

Pennsylvania’s Aaa-rated offering of forty-year deben­
tures was priced to yield 8.8 percent at midmonth, up
from 8.65 percent on a similar issue marketed in June.
These bonds sold quickly on their first day and were
followed by the successful sale of $250 million of eightyear Aa-rated utility company notes yielding 8.46 percent
the following day. Corporate bond issues marketed over
the remainder of the month were more modest in size
and were generally well received. The Board’s index of
yields on recently offered Aaa-rated corporate securities
rose 16 basis points from June 26 to July 17 but then de­
clined somewhat over the remaining two weeks. For the
month as a whole, the index showed a 4 basis point rise.
Some record-breaking and unusual developments




occurred in the taxable bond market during July. Citicorp
successfully marketed a record volume of publicly offered
convertible securities during the period, and the American
Telephone & Telegraph Company, which normally bor­
rows domestically, reported the placement of a $100
million note with the government of Saudi Arabia. In
addition, Standard Oil Co. (Ohio) and British Petro­
leum Co. Ltd., through a jointly owned subsidiary, pri­
vately placed a huge $1.75 billion debt issue to conclude
the financing of their 49 percent portion of the Alaskan
pipeline. Sohio/BP Trans Alaska Pipeline Finance, Inc.,
received commitipents from some seventy-five institutions
for purchase of this record-breaking amount of its 10%
percent notes.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

183

Measuring the United States Balance of Paym ents

By

P a tr ic ia H ag an K u w a y a m a *

The balance of payments is an important concept, one
which significantly influences our understanding of inter­
national developments in the United States economy. Each
time a new balance-of-payments statistic is released, it is
widely interpreted as an indication of how things have
become “better” or “worse” in the foreign sector of our
economy and as a measure of “strength” or “weakness”
of the dollar. Frequently, the figures are reported in more
popular media as “the” balance of payments, without rec­
ognition of the fact that at least seven different measures
are currently in standard use, each designed to illuminate
specific aspects of these broad qualitative issues. Indeed,
the number is larger than seven if all balance-ofpayments measures which are commonly used by profes­
sional economists for various types of analysis are included.
The existence of so many international payments “bal­
ances”, while in some ways inconvenient, should be wel­
comed as a reminder that there is no single answer to the
question whether our international transactions have
become better or worse in a given period—nor is there any
simple way of determining from any of these balances
the prospective strength or weakness of the dollar.
The meaning of several balance-of-payments measures
has also changed over the years, along with developments
in the international economy and institutions. In the postWorld War II period, the liberalization of international
trade and capital flows has led to an enormous growth in
the scale and sophistication of transactions engaged in by
both private and official parties and has blurred many of
the distinctions that were once useful. More recently, the
shift by industrial countries to a system of greatly increased
variability in exchange rates has provided new reasons for

* Mrs. Kuwayama is chief of the Foreign Research Division.




a revised approach to analyzing international flows. An­
other recent change that has added to the difficulty
of using the balances stems from the huge accumulations
of dollar reserves by the Organization of Petroleum Ex­
porting Countries (OPEC).
The United States Department of Commerce has re­
sponded to the changing needs over the years, carrying
out two major revisions (as well as many smaller ones)
of its official balance-of-payments presentation in the last
decade. One of these revisions followed an intensive
review of the statistics, commonly known as the “Bern­
stein Report” [10],1 in 1965. The second was introduced
with the June 1971 issue of the Survey of Current Busi­
ness [12], along with a detailed explanation which is still
a standard reference on official United States balance-ofpayments statistics and their interpretation. Currently,
another review committee of academic, Government, and
business economists is considering the questions of wheth­
er the official tables should be revised again and even
whether publication of traditional balance-of-payments
measures should be continued at all.
This article proposes to clarify the analytical differences
among major balance-of-payments measures and to explain
the usefulness of each in application to present-day
policy questions. No attempt is made to identify a
single statistic which can be regarded as “the” appropriate
balance-of-payments measure for the United States; nor is
there any consideration of what should, or should not, be
published as an “official” measure. Some recommenda­
tions are made to the users of balance-of-payments num­
bers as to how they can (or cannot) use the statistics in
answering specific questions, and major problems of con-

1 The numbers in brackets refer to the references cited at the
end of this article.

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1975

184

cept and measurement are explored with reference to these
applications. Particular attention is devoted to changes in
the use of the balances that have been dictated by recent
developments in the international economy, including the
shift to more flexible exchange rates. In this latter respect,
the most important conclusion to be drawn is that the
problems of measuring the United States balance of pay­
ments in a contemporary setting do not stem mainly from
the new exchange rate regime. Most of the problems have
existed for some time and reflect the complexity of inter­
national capital movements at least as much as the flexi­
bility of exchange rates.
Finally, the discussion which follows emphasizes that,
while a proper use of balance-of-payments concepts is a
helpful starting point for understanding developments in
the international sector of the economy, these measures
can never provide answers to important questions by them­
selves. Even if balance-of-payments statistics were gathered
in much more detail than they are now, and even if they
are interpreted with a maximum of sophistication, they still
only summarize the net flow of transactions between
domestic residents and residents of foreign countries. For
the United States particularly, this is but part of the story.
The widespread use of United States dollars by foreigners
in transactions which do not directly involve the United
States at all means that American businessmen and policy
makers must consider the potential impact on the United
States not only of this country’s balance-of-payments
flows, but also of a variety of other factors affecting the
supply of and demand for dollars in international use.
Thus, while this article is intended to promote the
best possible use of the balance-of-payments statistics, it
is not necessarily intended to advocate more attention to
these measures; if anything, balance-of-payments measures
are probably overused as an approach to international
policy analysis and should be supplemented as much as
possible by other kinds of information.
DEFINITIONS OF TH E BALANCE OF PAYM EN TS

The balance-of-payments statistical statement is de­
signed to summarize all economic transactions between
residents of the United States and those of foreign
countries. It is based on the principle of double-entry book­
keeping: every payment creates a claim or extinguishes
a liability, and the corresponding receipt provides an off­
setting entry somewhere else within the accounting state­
ment. Thus, the broadest balance— involving all trans­
actions by both private and official parties— should always
equal zero by definition.
However, not all transactions between Americans and




foreigners are captured in the statistics. Furthermore,
because in some cases one side of a transaction fails to be
reported, or the two sides may be reported with incon­
sistent values, the sum of all recorded transactions is
never zero. Therefore, there is always one item called
“errors and omissions”, which is derived as the statistical
discrepancy that is found when all recorded transactions
are added together. This residual item is usually thought
to be composed largely of unrecorded capital items. A
review of past statistics will show that it has been large
and negative (i.e., representing unrecorded outflows) in
periods when the United States dollar was under specula­
tive attack. However, there can be large errors in the
reporting of transactions other than capital as well.
The payments balances which are used for analytic
purposes all result from separating out one or another sub­
set of international transactions which are thought to have
a particular type of significance. A line is drawn below these
items, and they are then summed up to obtain a balance of
payments which may or may not equal zero. Each defini­
tion involves its own division into “above-the-line” and
“below-the-line” flows, and the latter of course exactly
offset (in some contexts we would say “finance” or “set­
tle”) the former. Where the line is drawn depends on the
purpose of the analysis. Some balances are intended to
measure stable as opposed to ephemeral elements in the
current payments picture. Others result from an attempt
to separate autonomous flows from the accommodating
transactions which authorities undertake in order to defend
a given exchange rate. Alternatively, a balance may be
drawn to show the net absorption by foreigners of United
States domestic product, or the net balance of United
States residents’ lending to (or borrowing from) residents
of other countries. Table I shows some— though by no
means all— of the balances that are frequently used to
analyze United States international payments: seven dif­
ferent partial balances are encountered as one reads down
the table, each one including a broader set of items above
the line than the balances preceding it. The following
reviews the definitions and measurement of all of these
standard balances, starting with merchandise trade and
ending with official reserve transactions. Some less stan­
dard balances with particular relevance to current cir­
cumstances are also mentioned in the course of this article,
and statistical illustration of these is provided in Table II.
m e r c h a n d is e t r a d e b a l a n c e . The balance of merchan­
dise trade is probably the most familiar and well-defined
of all payments concepts. The data in Table I give an
idea of the shift which the United States trade balance has
undergone in the last several years as the result of dollar

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK
Table I
UNITED STATES BALANCE OF PAYMENTS, 1971-74
In millions of dollars; + denotes increase in claims on, or
reduction in liabilities to, foreigners
Type of balance

Exports of goods .....................................
Imports of goods ....................................
Merchandise trade balance ...................
Services, net ................................................
Balance of goods and services ..............
Unilateral transfers, net .......................
Balance on current account ...................
United States Government capital
flows, net (excluding reserve
transactions) ...............................................
United States direct investment
abroad ...........................................................
Foreign direct investment in the
United States .............................................
United States purchases of foreign
securities, net .............................................
Foreign purchases of United States
securities (excluding Treasury
issues), net ..................................................
Net change in long-term claims
on foreigners .............................................
Net change in long-term liabilities
to foreigners .............................................
Balance on current account and
long-term capital (basic balance) ..........
Net change in nonliquid short-term
claims on foreigners ..............................
N et change in nonliquid short-term
liabilities to foreigners .........................
Errors and omissions ..............................
Net liquidity balance (excluding
allocations of SDRs)* ................................
Net change in liquid claims on
foreigners ....................................................
Gross liquidity balance (excluding
allocations of SDRs)* ................................
Net change in liquid liabilities to
private foreign accounts .......................
Allocation of SDRs* ..............................
Official reserve transactions balance ....
Net change in primary reserve assetsf

+43,311
-45,579
— 2,268
+ 2,031
— 237
— 3,642
— 3,879

1974

4-49,388 +71,379 + 98,268
*-55,797 —70,424 -103,796
— 6,409 + 955 — 5,528
3,222 + 9,102
4- 479
4,177 + 3,574
- 5,930
3,842 — 7,182
— 3,780
335 - 3,608
— 9,710

- 2,376 — 1,335 — 1,490 + 1,118
- 4,738 — 3,530 — 4,968
-

175 +

7,268

380 + 2,656 + 2,224

- 1,113 — 618

759 — 1,990

+ 2,289 4- 4,507 + 4,055 +

672

-

780 - 1,550 — 1,366 -

1,560

-f

134 4- 743 +

559 -

515

—10,637 —11,113 — 977 — 10,927
— 2,332 — 1,763 — 5,069 — 14,789
— 15 4- 221 + 831 + 1,840
— 9,698 — 1,884 — 2,436 + 4,834
*—22,682 — 14,539 — 7,651 — 19,043
— 1,097 — 1,247 — 1,951

6,113

—23,779 —15,786 — 9,602

25,156

— 6,691 4- 4,722 + 4,294 + 16,782
0
0
4- 717 4- 710
—29,753 -10 ,35 4 - 5.308 - 8,374
169
+ 998 — 121 + 242

Net change in reserve position in the
IMF (secondary reserve assets)f 4- 1,350 4Net change in liabilities to official
foreign accounts.....................................
Balance on all accounts ........................

1973

1972

1971

153 -

33 -

1,265

4-27,405 4-10,322 + 5,099 + 9,808

0

0

Note: Because of rounding, figures do not necessarily add to totals.
* SDRs = Special drawing rights.
t Excludes revaluations of assets to reflect changes in the par value of the
dollar or in market exchange rates.
Source: United States Department of Commerce, Survey of Current Business
(June 1975).




185

depreciation and other factors (most notably, worldwide
agricultural shortages and the quadrupling of crude oil
prices in late 1973 and early 1974). The deficit in trade
was largest in 1972, the year following the Smithsonian
exchange rate realignment, reflecting what has become
known as the “J-curve” effect, in which the initial, adverse
impact of devaluation in raising dollar import prices for
a time outweighs the slower, desired responses of higher
export and lower import volumes. The volume effects, of
course, eventually dominated, resulting in a net improve­
ment of the trade balance, at least until the enormous
boost in the oil import bill supervened in 1974.
Some analysts have used a special computation of the
balance of United States trade, which includes all mer­
chandise except petroleum, to summarize trade develop­
ments over this recent period. When this is done, as in
Table II, the improvement in “nonoil trade” is seen to
continue through 1974. This case provides a convenient
example of how a special balance-of-payments definition
sometimes comes into temporary use, because events in a
particular period make it an analytically useful comple­
ment to the standard measure. Another ad hoc measure
that has been widely used lately, also shown in Table II,
is the balance of United States trade excluding not only
petroleum imports but also agricultural exports. Adjust­
ments of this kind represent an attempt to abstract two
major disturbances of recent years, both of which have
affected the United States balance of trade in ways that
are largely unrelated to the other adjustments that it has
been undergoing.
One reason for the attention that is paid to the trade
balance is that it is available more promptly than any other
balance-of-payments data: it is published monthly, within
about a month of the end of the covered period.2 Analysis

2 The trade figures which are published monthly are on a “cen­
sus basis”, which means that they reflect only clearances through
Customs. These are not quite the same as the trade statistics
which eventually appear in the United States balance-of-payments
accounts, as the latter reflect a number of adjustments to the
Customs data. The most important differences are: the exclusion
from the balance-of-payments data of exports under United States
military agency sales contracts (which are included elsewhere in
the international accounts), the inclusion in them of imports into
the Virgin Islands from foreign countries, and adjustments for vari­
ous items that are not captured in Customs statistics (e.g., the
export or import of ships, of nonmonetary gold, and of gift parcels
sent through the mails) or which are considered to be inaccurately
valued in Customs statistics. For details of these adjustments for
recent years, see the June 1975 Survey of Current Business, page
22, Table B l, “U.S. Merchandise Trade, by Principal End-Use
Categories— Reconciled to Balance of Payments Basis5’.

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1975

186

of the trade balance in a short-term framework, how­
ever, involves some problems different from long-term
analysis. Trade flows are measured by clearances
through Customs and therefore reflect the timing of ship­
ments rather than of actual payments. To assess the
impact of short-run changes in the trade balance on
exchange markets, it is necessary to know how the pur­
chases are financed. Some countries collect trade informa­
tion on a “cash”, or “payments”, basis as well as on the
basis of shipments, thus providing a useful insight into the
trade financing pattern and the changes it undergoes when
there is relative interest rate movement and/or currency
speculation. In the United States, however, this information
is buried within the data on other capital flows.

Table II
SELECTED NONSTANDARD UNITED STATES PAYMENTS BALANCES

The goods and ser­
vices balance includes net payments for services— such
as investment earnings,3 shipping receipts, fees and royal­
ties related to technological transfers, and so on— as well
as trade. This balance corresponds to the “net exports”
item in the gross national product (GNP) accounts, thus
representing the foreign component of total expenditure
for goods and services produced in the United States.4 The
measurement of this balance is fairly straightforward,
although some of the items (such as interest payments
and receipts) must be estimated by indirect methods, and
others are subject to large errors. An important example
is the overreporting of United States petroleum com­
panies’ overseas earnings in the 1966-73 balance-ofpayments statistics; these were later revised on the basis
of a special survey conducted in January 1974, with re­
visions coming to as much as $1.7 billion for 1973.5 It
may be worth noting that many goods and services that
are sent overseas are excluded from net exports in both
sets of accounts. For instance, shipments under military
b a l a n c e o f g o o d s a n d s e r v ic e s .

3 Reinvested earnings of foreign affiliates other than branches
of United States firms (and similarly for foreign investors in the
United States) are excluded from the measurement, although in
principle they should be included as service receipts. This omis­
sion also affects the capital accounts of the balance of payments
in that the reinvested earnings are omitted from measured direct
investment.
4 There frequently have been large discrepancies between net
exports data appearing in the published United States GNP and
balance-of-payments statistics for recent quarters. These reflect
the procedures used for approximating items on which information
is still missing or preliminary, and differences in the timing of
revisions of the two sets of data.
5 See the June 1974 Survey of Current Business [12] for a com­
plete explanation of the changes.




In millions of dollars; + denotes increase in claims on, or
reduction in liabilities to, foreigners
Payments balances

Balance of trade, excluding
petroleum imports .....................
Balance of trade, excluding
petroleum imports and
agricultural exports ...................
Balance on current account,
excluding net United States
Government transfers ............
Balance on current account, plus
net United States Government
capital ...........................................
Balance of monetary
movements* ................................
Official reserve transactions
balance, excluding United
States liabilities to OPECt

1971

1972

1973

1974

+ 1,348

— 1,783

+9,096

+20,534

— 6,438

-11,288 I

-8 ,7 6 6

— 1,723

— 1,294

— 6,965

+2,966

+ 2,545

- 6,255

11,045

—1,155

- 2,490

—20,683

—12,442

—4,715

— 6,837

—29,300

— 9,500

—4,800

+

100

* The balance of monetary movements equals the official reserve transactions
balance minus changes in United States banks’ net short-term interna­
tional position.
f The liabilities to the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC)
include all recorded short-term liabilities to banks and official institutions
in OPEC, plus long-term liabilities to those OPEC countries for which such
data are available. These figures represent rough estimates of the required
adjustments since they may include some liabilities to nonofficial OPEC
residents and may exclude some long-term liabilities to official accounts.
Sources: United States Department of Commerce, Survey of Current Business
(June 1975 ). United States Treasury Department, Treasury Bulletin (Feb­
ruary 1971 to June 1975).

grants are included within Government expenditures in
the GNP statistics and are treated as a special transfer
item in the balance-of-payments accounts. This is because
these goods and services are regarded as an economic
demand by the United States Government rather than as
one coming from the foreign sector.
b a l a n c e o n c u r r e n t a c c o u n t . The current-account bal­
ance includes unilateral transfers to and from foreigners
along with the trade in goods and services. These transfers
are composed of payments under grants by the United
States Government and also pensions and remittances by
private citizens to relatives or other persons residing in
foreign countries. The balance thus includes all transac­
tions which are “current”, in the sense that they are not
acquisitions of claims or liabilities vis-a-vis foreign resi­
dents. The current-account balance has as its below-theline counterpart the overall “capital account” of the
whole economy, and thus one of the contributions of
the current-account balance is that it measures the net
lending or borrowing position of the entire United States

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

economy, i.e., of all private citizens and corporations
together with the Government.
In 1974, the United States current-account balance was
seriously distorted by some very large, nonrepetitive spe­
cial transactions between the United States and India,
Israel, and Vietnam. These enlarged the size of the re­
corded outflows of United States Government transfers
overseas by $3.1 billion for that year. Because of this, many
economists have at least temporarily preferred to use a
nonstandard current-account measure which excludes all
Government transfers. As Table II shows, this provides a
more realistic (and smaller) assessment of current-account
deterioration in 1974.
In more normal years, one of the most criticized faults
of the current-account concept in the United States case
is the artificiality of the distinction between Government
grants and loans. Insofar as some of the latter are more
like unilateral transfers than like private loans— in moti­
vation as well as in implication for United States total
wealth— current-account surpluses are overstated (or
deficits understated) by the conventional measure. For
this reason, some analysts prefer to utilize a broadened
current-account measure that includes all current trans­
actions plus flows of United States Government capital
(see Table II). This balance, it may be noted, is also
unaffected by the exceptional Government transfers to
India, Israel, and Vietnam in 1974, since all of these
transfers were offset by corresponding inflows in the
United States Government capital account. Other econo­
mists consider this same measure as the narrowest— and
most “basic”— definition of the basic balance, one that
avoids some of the complicated measurement problems,
discussed below, which arise in the attempt to separate
basic from other private capital flows in the statistics.
, BALANCE ON CURRENT ACCOUNT AND LONG-TERM CAPITAL
(b a s ic b a l a n c e ). The idea of the “basic balance” is to

separate the underlying structural developments in inter­
national payments from distorting short-term movements.
Included above the line are all current transactions, plus
those capital flows which are thought to be mainly respon­
sive to long-term changes in fundamental economic condi­
tions rather than to short-run influences like changes in
interest rates or exchange rate expectations. Specifically,
the basic capital items are (1) United States Govern­
ment capital, (2) direct investments by United States
corporations abroad and by foreign corporations in the
United States, (3) private portfolio investments, and
(4) all long-term private loans, defined as those whose
original maturity from time of issuance to maturity
exceeds one year.




187

Great difficulties arise in this attempt to identify private
capital flows which are motivated by long-term, as op­
posed to short-term, considerations. More than one moti­
vation may sometimes be involved in a single transaction,
and borrowers and lenders may not even know themselves
which ones are dominant. This makes the attempt at
statistical separation extremely difficult, if not impossible.
As an example, one of the most important long-term
trends in the United States balance of payments has been
the growth of direct investment overseas. However, in any
given quarter this trend may be swamped by unrelated
short-term movements in the direct investment flows
measured by our statistics. If the measurement of direct
foreign investment included only permanent additions to
capital in overseas affiliates, regardless of sources of
financing, this might not be true. But direct investment is
measured in part by the flow of funds between parent
and overseas affiliates within a multinational firm, and it
therefore reflects all kinds of short-run changes in financ­
ing patterns. These intracorporate transactions are as
interest sensitive as any liquid capital flows, and they may
also be distorted by tax considerations and various ac­
counting practices of the multinational firms. An exami­
nation of the behavior of the United States direct invest­
ment account during periods of exchange market specula­
tion easily reveals how important this distortion of the
basic balance can be.
In addition to these problems in the direct investment
account, international portfolio flows can also be seriously
distorted by short-term fluctuations. In fact, investment
in foreign securities has sometimes been an important
vehicle for currency speculation. And, finally, the for­
mal maturity of loans cannot be identified with the actual
motivation of transactions. For instance, a long-term bond
purchased one day before maturity may serve as a short­
term asset for the buyer, while long-term financing can
sometimes be secured by negotiating short-term loans with
an advance understanding that they will be renewed at
maturity. Because of this, statistically recorded portfolio
flows and so-called long-term private loans are demon­
strably sensitive, in aggregate, to short-run changes in
interest rates and changes in expectations about relative
inflation rates, monetary policies, and ultimately exchange
rate relationships.
n e t l iq u id it y b a l a n c e . The net liquidity balance in­
cludes what are termed nonliquid short-term capital flows,
along with long-term capital transactions, as above-theline items. It also includes errors and omissions, as if
this item represented only nonliquid capital flows. Tables
III and IV summarize the distinction between nonliquid

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1975

188

and liquid private capital transactions as they are
currently embodied in reporting practice. As can be
seen, the net liquidity balance contains many arbitrary
elements. All loans by United States banks, except those
to their own branches, are treated as nonliquid, even
overdrafts, which must by definition be quickly reversed.
On the other hand, all transactions between United States
banks and their branches (but not subsidiaries) and be­
tween United States agencies, branches, or subsidiaries of
foreign banks and their head offices or parent organiza­
tions and/or branches overseas are considered liquid,
although they may be directly connected to nonliquid
(and even long-term) lending by the foreign affiliate. All
deposits are liquid, even those that are held as compen­
sating balances against nonliquid borrowings.
g r o ss l iq u id it y b a l a n c e . Changes in liquid claims on
foreigners are included in the gross liquidity balance with
above-the-line items, leaving changes in liquid liabilities
to private foreigners as the only settlement items aside
from official reserve transactions. As Table IV shows,
liquid liabilities to private foreigners means, simply,
short-term bank-reported liabilities to private foreigners
and all private long-term foreign holdings of United States
Treasury securities. The asymmetry in treatment of liquid
claims as opposed to liabilities has been justified on the
ground that the balance measures additions to the poten­
tial drain on the United States monetary reserves. United
States residents’ liquid claims on foreigners, it has been
argued, could not necessarily be mobilized for this pur­
pose, while the liabilities did represent a potential “call”
on our official reserves. In recent years, however, the total
stock of liquid liabilities to foreigners has so much ex­
ceeded the stock of our reserves that this idea has lost all

possible relevance. Therefore, the.symmetric treatment of
the net liquidity balance has generally been preferred by
users of the liquidity concept.
The liquidity balance definitions above have been de­
signed specifically for analyzing United States payments
and are not used in other countries. A somewhat similar
measure which does have wide international usage is the
balance of monetary movements. In this balance, all bankreported short-term capital movements6 are treated as
financing items along with official reserve transactions, and
all other flows are placed above the line. The assumption
underlying this treatment is that, in some countries at least,
central banks through various regulations exert a major
influence on the net short-term international position of
commercial banks. Table II includes a computation of this
balance for the United States in the last four years.
OFFICIAL RESERVE TRANSACTIONS BALANCE. The m O St
comprehensive of the standard balances is the balance of
official settlements. Here, all international transactions
except for changes in the net official reserve position of
the United States are above the line. This measure is in­
tended to reflect the amounts of foreign exchange which
monetary authorities have supplied to the markets to bal­
ance private supply and demand at current exchange rates.
All private and nonreserve Government transactions are

6 Bank-reported capital, it should be noted, includes some assets
and liabilities which are not part of the banks’ own balance sheets:
for example, items held for the account of the banks’ customers
and securities issued by the United States Treasury or United
States Government agencies.

Table m
NONLIQUID VERSUS LIQUID UNITED STATES SHORT-TERM CLAIMS ON PRIVATE FOREIGNERS
Claims

Nonliquid

Reported by United States banks:
Payable in dollars ................................................................. Loans (including overdrafts); collections;
acceptances

Payable in foreign currencies ........................................... “Other” foreign currency claims
Reported by United States nonbanking concerns




Credits to finance exports or other transactions;
claims of United States brokers on foreigners,
mainly to finance securities transactions

Liquid
“Other” dollar claims, including deposits, money
market paper, and all claims (except acceptances)
of United States banks on their own foreign branches
and of United States agencies and branches of for­
eign banks on their own head offices and/or foreign
branches
Deposits; foreign government obligations; commer­
cial and finance paper.
Deposits held abroad; negotiable and transferable
foreign obligations; loans repayable on demand

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

189

Table IV
NONLIQUID VERSUS LIQUID UNITED STATES SHORT-TERM LIABILITIES TO PRIVATE FOREIGNERS*
Liabilities

Liquid

Nonliquid

Reported by United States banks ......................................... None
Reported by United States nonbanking concerns .......... All short-term liabilities

All short-term bank-reported liabilities
None

* In addition to these short-term liabilities, liquid liabilities to private foreigners also include net purchases
by the latter of long-term United States Treasury securities reported by both banks and nonbanking concerns.

thus interpreted in this balance as autonomous phenomena,
which are accommodated by official reserve transactions.
Most foreign countries measure their official settlements
balances simply as the net change in external assets and
liabilities of the monetary authorities. In the United States,
the matter is more complicated because foreign countries
hold United States dollars as an international reserve asset.
Recognizing this international reserve currency role of the
dollar, the United States includes, in its official reserves
measurement, information which it collects from private
United States residents about their liabilities to official
foreigners. In recent years, changes in these liabilities—
primarily foreign official holdings with United States com­
mercial banks and bank-reported official holdings of
United States Treasury securities— have accounted for
most of the movements in the official settlements balance,
since reserve assets (primarily gold) held by the United
States monetary authorities have been relatively stable.
In the last year and a half, United States liabilities to
the monetary authorities of OPEC have undergone a very
large increase, as OPEC countries have invested part of
their huge reserve accumulations in various types of assets
in the United States. All of these are counted as deficit
items in the United States official reserve transactions bal­
ance, which has deteriorated as a result. Some analysts
believe that these investments should be regarded as
largely autonomous rather than as accommodating flows,
and the reasons for this are discussed in some detail in
the next main section. It has therefore been suggested that
official reserve transactions vis-a-vis OPEC and those
vis-a-vis non-OPEC countries should be looked at sepa­
rately, with only the latter being taken as a measure of
exchange market disequilibrium in the traditional sense.
Published balance-of-payments statistics do not allow a
precise separation of OPEC reserve transactions from the
others; however, the last item in Table II roughly approxi­
mates this adjustment by using published data on liabilities
to residents of these countries. As the reader can see, con­




structing the balance in this way transforms into approxi­
mate balance what appears by the usual definition as a
very large official deficit for 1974. In contrast to the
impression that might be created by casual interpretation
of the 1974 official settlements deficit, this adjustment
shows that the dollar was not artificially supported by
massive net official intervention over the year as a whole.
Some foreign countries, for which changes in official
(i.e., monetary authorities’) liabilities are relatively insig­
nificant, use gross changes in reserve assets alone as their
measure of official settlements. Because of the fact that
foreign monetary authorities accept dollar liabilities of the
United States as a means of settlement, this has not usu­
ally been considered a useful balance-of-payments mea­
sure for the United States. However, in the United States
as in all countries, these assets do comprise a source of
the domestic monetary base. As a result, their changes
play an important role in monetary theories of balanceof-payments adjustment, which is discussed in the next
section.
PROBLEMS IN IN TER PR ETIN G
TH E B ALAN C E-O F-PAYM EN TS MEASURES

One of the principal uses of balance-of-payments mea­
sures is to evaluate changes in underlying conditions which
may alter the equilibrium value of a country’s exchange
rate. In the Bretton Woods system of fixed but adjustable
par values, this meant an attempt to identify cases of
“fundamenal disequilibrium”. Under International Mone­
tary Fund (IMF) rules, the existence of such a disequilib­
rium, depending on its source and other circumstances,
could lead to the changing of the value of the national
currency relative to gold or foreign currencies, or to
other adjustment measures. In the present exchange rate
regime of managed floating, balance-of-payments measures
are still used to identify disequilibria which may occur
when official intervention is large enough to influence

190

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1975

market exchange rates. However, a more important cur­
rent concern is to anticipate sources of future exchange rate
change and the potential impact of international develop­
ments on domestic economies. Some of the balance-ofpayments concepts that were previously used to identify
fundamental disequilibria are now applied in assessing un­
derlying trends that may help in making such predictions.
When analyzing trends evidenced by the balance of
payments over a fairly lengthy period— i.e., a few years
or more— economists have generally focused on compre­
hensive measures such as the official reserve transactions
balance. Its treatment of all transactions by persons other
than official reserve agencies as autonomous phenomena,
while regarding all official reserve transactions as accom­
modating,7 means that developments in all types of pri­
vate financial relationships are considered to play a role in
determining the equilibrium value of national currencies.
This recognition of all private financial flows as ultimately
market determined is particularly important in the case
of the United States, which as a world financial center
provides such a wide variety of banking services to for­
eign residents. It would be a mistake to exclude any of
these services when considering trends that affect the
value of the dollar over the long run.
The treatment of all official reserve transactions as
below-the-line, or accommodating, items is subject to
important exceptions. The assumption behind the official
settlements concept is that central banks gain or
lose reserves only through direct exchange market
intervention undertaken to defend established parities.
However, even under the fixed exchange rate system the
decision of monetary authorities to intervene in exchange
markets (as opposed to changing the national parity) could
be influenced by an official desire to accumulate or decumulate reserves, rather than being only a passive accom­
modation of market conditions. This qualification is all the
more important now, when the major countries are no
longer committed to defending specific, established parities.
Hence, the differentiation between private and official for­
eign holders of dollars is not always an adequate basis for
measuring disequilibrium, because central banks are
motivated by some of the same considerations as, and
handle their exchange portfolios similarly to, private partic­
ipants in the market.

Part of the problem with the official settlements concept
is that official reserve positions are also affected by other
transactions besides intervention. For instance, monetary
authorities may borrow foreign exchange from private
holders or lend it to them, and this will add to or reduce
their reserve holdings. Another important measurement
problem arises from the fact that foreign central banks
place some of their dollar exchange holdings with com­
mercial banks outside the United States— usually with
banks in their own countries (Japan being a well-known
instance of this) or in Euro-dollar centers elsewhere. In
such cases, a part of the dollar balances that are owned by
foreign monetary authorities is reported as liquid liabilities
to private foreigners in the United States balance-ofpayments statistics. As a result, while in principle the
official settlements of each country with all other
countries should be symmetric and the official settle­
ments of all countries when added together should
total zero,8 there are in fact very large discrepancies be­
tween the official balance that is recorded for the United
States in any recent period and the total reported official
settlements of all other countries.
The acquisition of large amounts of new reserves by
oil-exporting countries is currently providing a spectacu­
lar example of all of these problems. On the one hand,
OPEC governments have placed many of their dollar re­
serves with Euro-banks, and the principal reflection in
the United States balance-of-payments statistics of this
part of the OPEC reserve accumulations is likely to be
increased liquid liabilities to private foreigners, primarily
to foreign banks or the foreign branches of United States
banks that are located in Euro-dollar centers. At the same
time, it may be incorrect to regard all of OPEC’s direct
claims on the United States as deficit items, since many
such placements are investments motivated in part by
ordinary economic considerations rather than being simply
a passive accommodation to outflows from the United
States. In other words, these increased United States
liabilities to official foreigners reflect a conscious port­
folio choice by those officials to hold a certain portion
of their large reserve gains in a variety of dollardenominated instruments. This is the reason why some
analysts currently prefer to look at a narrower official
settlements measure, like the one in Table II which excludes
changes in liabilities to OPEC, for an indication of the

7 For the history of these concepts of autonomous and accom­
modating transactions, and their use in identifying fundamental
8 More precisely, they should total zero aside from any net
disequilibrium, see particularly Meade [9], Gardner [2], and changes in total world reserves, such as increases in monetary
Machlup, “Three Concepts of the Balance of Payments” in [8].
gold, in SDR allocations, or in other liabilities of the IMF.




FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

191

ment items all bank-reported short-term capital transac­
tions, but not liquid nonbank flows. Drawing the line at
short-term bank capital has the advantage of being con­
ceptually simpler than the liquidity distinction, but for
analytic purposes it is almost as arbitrary, at least for a
country with highly developed financial markets like the
United States. Because the monetary movements balance
is used by other countries, it is sometimes useful to compute
it for the United States also. However, this is a concept
that is asymmetric in definition. Consequently, it cannot
be added up for different countries to total zero. For exam­
ple, a transaction which is short-term bank capital on the
United States side frequently involves a nonbank resident
on the foreign side, and vice versa.
Under fixed exchange rates, and so long as United
States dollars held by foreign monetary authorities were
effectively convertible into gold, changes in United States
official reserve assets alone provided one type of measure
of overall balance-of-payments disequilibrium for the
United States, as foreign official dollar acquisitions could
then reasonably be viewed as voluntary. Without con­
vertibility there is no sense in which the disequilibrium
measures for the United States can be realistically con­
fined to reserve assets, and most official intervention to
support the dollar’s value in exchange markets has in fact
reflected itself in increased United States liabilities to
foreign monetary authorities rather than in reduced assets.
In all countries, primary international reserve assets
constitute part of the domestic monetary base, and there­
fore changes in these assets have an influence on money
supply. As a source of change in the domestic monetary
base, changes in primary reserve assets play a central role
in monetary models of the balance of payments. These
models treat the international balance as part of the mech­
anism that equilibrates portfolio choices of both residents
and nonresidents— including, in particular, their choices
to hold money denominated in various currencies. When
a balance-of-payments surplus results in an increase in
international reserve assets of a country, this adds to the
domestic monetary base. So long as this increase is not
offset by actions of the domestic monetary authorities, it
will affect the domestic money supply, and thereby na­
tional income and the price level. In the case of a
balance-of-payments deficit resulting in a reserve loss, the
opposite sequence occurs. So long as payments imbal­
ances are in fact reflected in changes in reserve assets, this
9 This brief discussion does not pretend to do justice to the constitutes an adjustment mechanism by which external
questions raised, since they have been extensively argued over the disequilibria tend to be eliminated automatically. This
years in many other places. The reader is referred particularly to
Lederer [7] and to the Bernstein Report [10]. Some additional ref­ monetary mechanism of balance-of-payments adjustment
erences are given following this paper, and more can be found in
Kindleberger [5] and in Stem [ 11 ], particularly Chapter I, “Balance was first outlined by David Hume in the eighteenth
century, arid the theory is now being further developed in
of Payments Concepts and Measures”.

amount of official intervention that has been affecting the
dollar’s value in any given period.
The liquidity balance is an alternative overall balanceof-payments measure which has been used for a long time
in the United States. This balance recognizes that official
reserve movements are sometimes motivated by market
considerations and thus are similar to private capital flows.
Moreover, it separates out changes in private holdings
of liquid claims on the United States as a potentially disequilibrating phenomenon that may eventually be trans­
lated into market pressure on currency rates and reserve
movements. Proponents of the liquidity measures argue
that the latter show the ability of the United States to de­
fend the dollar, and the possibility of needing to do so in
the future, whereas the official settlements balance concen­
trates on the amount of intervention required in the past.
The artificialities in the official-private distinction have
been recognized by most users of the official settlements
measure, which admittedly can be seriously distorted, par­
ticularly in the short run. However, very few economists
have been able to accept the alternative distinction be­
tween liquid and nonliquid capital as a useful basis for
balance-of-payments analysis. First, the notion that liquid
claims portray a “potentially disequilibrating” situation
cannot be applied indiscriminately to all such claims by
residents of one country on those of another, but only to
those amounts over and above the monetary balances
needed for transactions purposes. No theoretically sound
method has been advanced for making this separation in
the balance-of-payments statistics. Second, many assets
which are classified as nonliquid are in fact readily convert­
ible into liquid form. Thus, the exchange market implica­
tions of growth in these other claims are not necessarily
different, in any clear and simple way, from those of a
growth in foreign-held bank deposits. These are the prin­
cipal reasons why the liquidity balance has fallen increas­
ingly into disuse by economists in the United States.9
As described above, monetary movements is commonly
used in other countries as an overall measure much like
the liquidity balance of the United States. The difference
is that balance of monetary movements includes as settle­




192

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1975

contemporary literature.10
This monetary adjustment mechanism does not neces­
sarily work the same way for a reserve-currency country
like the United States, because deficits in United States
external payments are not usually reflected in changes in
United States reserve assets but rather in liabilities.
Changes in United States liabilities to official foreigners
do not normally affect the monetary base of the United
States except when they lead to a change in the level of
foreign deposits with the Federal Reserve Banks. The
great bulk of foreign central banks’ dollar holdings is
invested in nonmonetary assets (such as United States
Treasury securities) which are purchased from private
domestic holders, and in this case there is no net impact
on the monetary base in this country.11 This causes an
asymmetry in the international adjustment mechanism
described by the monetary models because, when the
monetary authorities in a foreign surplus country acquire
dollars through exchange market intervention, these
dollars are included in the international reserve assets
of that country and thus add to its monetary base.
However, the increase in United States liabilities causes
no corresponding reduction in the monetary base here, so
that the inflationary impact in the foreign country is not
matched by any automatic deflationary tendency in the
United States. Even in foreign countries, the practical use­
fulness of this primary reserve assets measure of balanceof-payments disequilibrium can be exaggerated. The auto­
matic nature of the international adjustment is in any case
limited by the fact that domestic monetary impacts of
external disturbances are frequently swamped by actions
of the domestic monetary authorities. Monetary authori­
ties in all countries consider domestic as well as interna­
tional factors in making policy, and by open market
operations or other actions they may— whether intention­
ally or not— cancel the effect which official reserve
changes might otherwise have had on the monetary base,
at least for a time. Thus, so long as the monetary authori­
ties in each country exercise independent control over
their own money supplies, the price-specie-flow mechan­
ism described by Hume does not work.
The overall balances, such as those discussed above,
may be considered an accurate guide to payments trends

10 For a brief introduction to the monetary approach to the
balance of payments and references to the important literature,
see Kemp [3, 4].
11 For details, see Auerbach f 11.




that continue for a fairly long period. However, the
inclusion of some capital flows which can vary widely in
the short run, even though their movements tend to
cancel out over a long period, makes these balances
unreliable for analyzing changes over only a few months
or quarters. Additional balance-of-payments measures are
therefore needed for current analysis. This is the motiva­
tion for computing a basic balance, which attempts to
isolate stable, underlying patterns and separate them from
movements of volatile, short-term capital. The latter are
taken to respond much more quickly to changes in relative
interest rates and/or exchange rate expectations, which
means that they are also more amenable to the influence
of short-run changes in monetary policy. Another way of
regarding basic transactions, therefore, is that they are
those transactions which can, in principle, be considered
as exogenous influences in short-run models used to formu­
late monetary policy.12 In practical terms, this means that
an imbalance in overall payments over a short period— as
measured, for example, by official settlements— is more
likely to be taken as indicating fundamental disequilibrium
if the imbalance is due to basic transactions than if it is
due to short-term capital movements. Moreover, trends in
basic payments may sometimes signal an emerging dis­
equilibrium situation before it materializes in official re­
serve movements or exchange rate changes.
While the theoretical distinction underlying the basic
balance is one on which there is wide agreement, it is
perhaps the most difficult balance of all to translate into
measurement. The conceptual distinction outlined above
simply cannot be identified with the categories found in
the available statistics. For this reason as much as any
other, balance-of-payments analysts often focus particular
attention on changes in merchandise trade, and perhaps on
trade in services. These flows are seen as depending on
relatively stable and well-understood relationships among
those classified as basic transactions. As a result, econ­
omists feel somewhat more confident about trying to
predict trade developments in the short run than they
do about predicting capital flows, even so-called long-term
capital flows.
All of the international payments balances discussed
so far are intended to indicate fundamental patterns in
United States external payments, in part to evaluate ex-

12 This view of the problem is not new. In particular, the
analysis by Hal B. Lary in 1963 [6] employed essentially this
approach to the issue.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

change rate developments. Aside from this concern, how­
ever, economic policy makers, in the United States as well
as in other countries, sometimes display preferences as to
the current-versus-capital-account structure of the balance
of payments. For this, they look at the overall balance on
current account, which includes trade and service transac­
tions as well as unilateral transfers to foreigners by the
United States Government and private residents and which
appears in the national income accounts as “net foreign
investment”.13 Since the current-account balance mea­
sures the extent to which the United States is a net
borrower from, or net lender to, foreign countries, it
may sometimes be a target of national economic policy
even aside from the question of maintaining a specific
exchange rate. (Another way of looking at the same
number, of course, is as net saving or borrowing by
the foreign sector in the national flow-of-funds accounts.)
The slightly narrower balance of goods and services car­
ries significance also, within a Keynesian framework
of domestic employment analysis, as a component of
the GNP accounts which measures the contribution of
foreigners to aggregate demand for United States output.
The goods and services and current-account balances
are both internationally symmetrical in definition. These
balances for the United States can thus be usefully
compared with the corresponding statistics for foreign
countries, and the balances for all countries taken together
must in principle total zero.
The current regime of fluctuating exchange rates has
led to some changes in the way economists use the
balance-of-payments statistics. Rather than asking whether
and how existing parities can be defended, analysts are
now trying to interpret the movements that occur simul­
taneously in exchange rates and payments flows. Assess­
ing the permanence of short-run changes in exchange rates
and predicting changes that may be indicated beforehand
are activities in which balance-of-payments information
will always be used. Of course, one should remember
that the resident-versus-nonresident distinction made by
balance-of-payments statistics may not accurately reflect
all the exchange market pressures for an international
currency like the United States dollar. Therefore, any
such analysis, while it may begin with balance-of-payments
numbers, cannot stop there.

193

The official settlements balance would presumably be
insignificant in size if the monetary authorities did not
intervene in the exchange markets and did not take other
measures to influence national currency rates and reserve
positions, such as official Euro-currency borrowings or
deposits of foreign exchange with commercial banks.
In reality, however, we have a mixed situation, in which
national authorities undertake some intervention in
the exchange markets to influence currency values, even
though they may not be committed to defending a fixed
set of parities. Thus, the official settlements balance is still
very much a fact of life, and it still measures market
disequilibrium at current exchange rates. The main dif­
ference is that simultaneous changes occur both in the
official settlements balance and in the exchange rate, and
the two must be interpreted as mutually determined.
In attempting to assess the permanence of changes in
exchange rates (and/or official settlements balances), the
same characteristics— short-run sensitivity to interest rates
and exchange rate expectations— are as important in the
case of floating exchange rates as in the Bretton Woods
framework. It is still desirable to separate payments
according to how stable or volatile they are, and how
responsive to short-run changes in monetary policy, in
much the same way as the basic transactions concept was
used under fixed rates to analyze short-run fluctuations in
the overall payments balance alone. In theory, therefore,
the basic balance, as well as other variants of this con­
cept, is just as natural a basis for analysis in the world
of floating exchange rates as it was under fixed exchange
rates. At the same time, however, the shift to more flexible
exchange rates has done nothing to mitigate the problems
of measuring these balances.
SUM M ARY OF CONCLUSIONS

The United States balance-of-payments accounts contain
a great deal of useful information about transactions be­
tween residents of this country and foreigners. But it is
misleading to focus attention on any one balance of part of
these transactions and attempt to conclude from that bal­
ance whether the external sector of the economy has
become better or worse in a given period. A surplus or
deficit on any of the balances is not necessarily a sign of
what is good or bad for the United States economy. And
there is no single balance of payments that can always be
taken as a measure of the pressure on dollar exchange rates.
Therefore, the most important conclusion to be drawn is
13 For the years in which new SDR allocations have been made that we should not expect too much from payments bal­
(1970 through 1972) “net foreign investment” corresponds to
the current-account balance plus the United States portion of these ances as a guide to policy.
The official reserves transactions balance is still a useful
SDR allocations.




194

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1975

statistic, but only if used with great care. Its contribution is
to give some indication of the extent to which exchange
rate movements, in any period, are influenced by direct
central bank intervention. Without such a measure of
short-run market disequilibrium, it is almost impossible to
evaluate the significance of observed exchange rate
changes. Supplementary information which central banks
publish about their intervention and/or nonmarket foreign
exchange transactions will sometimes be helpful in this
evaluation. In using the official balance, we must also
consider factors that might lead to changes in foreign
official demand for dollar reserves and look at shifts
among official holders who are thought to have
sharply different preferences. For example, because the
potential distortion due to investment in the United States
of official oil earnings is now so large, it is useful to sup­
plement the overall official settlements balance with
bilateral information indicating how much of this balance
is with the OPEC members and how much is with others.
The goods and services and current-account balances
continue to be relevant to domestic and international policy
questions. The value of both these balances is enhanced
by the fact that they are internationally symmetrical in
definition and correspond to the usage followed by other
countries.
In applications whose object is to separate “stable”
from “volatile” payments, or to distinguish flows that are
exogenous to short-run policy decisions from those
that are not, the basic balance concept still represents
the ideal that is sought. The available statistics are so
flawed by measurement problems, however, that none of
the usual approximations of this balance can be recom­
mended with any enthusiasm. Perhaps all that should be
attempted is to add the current-account and United States
Government capital items together, since they are the only
measured flow categories that can be regarded as largely
interest insensitive. The information gained from examin­
ing this balance by itself will be slight, though. Some
estimate (or guess) about underlying trends in private
direct investment must certainly be added by the user in
order to interpret the basic payments situation. The




empirical basis for such an estimate must be a careful
examination of past and current trends in a number of the
gross private capital flows, and probably of other infor­
mation as well. The search in our present statistics for
a reliable net basic balance that will consistently illuminate
the underlying balance-of-payments situation of the United
States is doomed to disappointment.
REFERENCES

[ 1] Auerbach, Irving M., “No Effect on M i or Reserves in U.S.
if Dollars Flow Out; Opposites True Overseas”, The Money
Manager (March 26, 1973), pp. 3-4.
[ 2] Gardner, Walter R., “An Exchange Market Analysis of the
U.S. Balance pf Payments”, IMF Staff Papers, VIII (May
1961), pp. 195-211.
[ 3] Kemp, Donald S., “A Monetary View of the Balance of Pay­
ments”, Review (Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, April
1975), pp. 14-22.
[ 4] Kemp, Donald S., “Balance-of-Payments Concepts— What
Do They Really Mean?”, Review (Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis, July 1975), pp. 14-23.
[ 5] Kindleberger, Charles P., “Measuring Equilibrium in the
Balance of Payments”, Journal of Political Economy
(November-December, 1969), pp. 873-91.
[ 6] Lary, Hal B., Problems of the United States as World Banker
and Trader (New York: National Bureau of Economic Re­
search, 1963).
[ 7] Lederer, Walther, The Balance on Foreign Transactions:
Problems of Definition and Measurement, Special Paper in
International Economics, No. 5 (Princeton: International Fi­
nance Section, Princeton University, 1963).
[ 8] Machlup, Fritz, International Payments, Debts, and Gold
(New York: Charles Scribner’s Sons, 1964).
[ 9] Meade, J. E., The Balance of Payments (London: Oxford
University Press, 1951).
[10] Review Committee for Balance of Payments Statistics, The
Balance of Payments Statistics of the United States (Washing­
ton, D.C.: United States Government Printing Office, 1965).
[11] Stern, Robert M., The Balance of Payments (Chicago: Aldine
Publishing Co., 1973).
[12] United States Department of Commerce, Office of Business
Economics: Survey of Current Business (Washington, D.C.:
United States Government Printing Office), monthly.
Balance-of-payments reports appear regularly in the March,
June, September, and December issues, with detailed revisions
of historical data usually published in June.