View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1972

186

Th e Business Situation
The economy continues to exhibit an impressive and
broadly based expansion. Real gross national product
(GNP) rose at a vigorous 8.9 percent seasonally adjusted
annual rate in the second quarter, as almost all major
components contributed to the advance. Moreover, this
gain followed sizable upward revised increases in real GNP
in the two preceding quarters. Industrial production posted
only a moderate increase in June, but over the first half of
the year output rose at a rapid 8.5 percent annual rate.
Both civilian employment and labor force changed little
in July, on a seasonally adjusted basis. Consequently, the
unemployment rate remained at 5.5 percent for the sec­
ond consecutive month, down markedly from its average
level of 5.9 percent that had prevailed since late 1970.
Recent data on wages and prices show some definitely
encouraging developments. The pace of wage increases has
slowed somewhat, and unit labor costs declined in the sec­
ond quarter for the first time in over six years. The im­
plicit GNP price deflator—the most comprehensive
available measure of price behavior—rose at a relatively
modest 2.1 percent annual rate in the second quarter, but
shifts in the composition of output caused some under­
statement of actual inflation. The rise in consumer prices
has been appreciably slower in the last four months. On
the other hand, throughout the period since the end of
the price freeze last November the wholesale price index
has continued to rise rapidly.
GROSS N ATIO N AL PRODUCT
AND R ELA TE D D EVELO PM EN TS

According to preliminary estimates by the Department
of Commerce, the market value of the nation’s output of
goods and services rose by $29.9 billion during the second
quarter to a seasonally adjusted annual rate of $1,139
billion. Measured in current dollars, the increase was a
bit smaller than the advance in the first quarter. However,
only about one fifth of the most recent gain was accounted
for by price increases, whereas in the first quarter price
rises constituted almost half of the expansion in nominal




GNP. Hence, the growth in real GNP— that is, GNP
adjusted for price changes— accelerated sharply in the
April-June period to a seasonally adjusted annual rate of
8.9 percent, the largest quarterly percentage increase in
real GNP since the fourth quarter of 1965. Along with the
preliminary data for the second quarter, the Department
of Commerce released its annual revisions of the GNP
data going back through 1969. Estimates of real GNP
were revised upward significantly for the final quarter of
1971 and the first quarter of this year. Over these two
quarters combined, real GNP growth is now estimated to
have averaged 6.6 percent per annum, nearly 1 percentage
point more than was previously reported. These latest
figures bring the increase in real GNP over the four quar­
ters ended in the second quarter of 1972 to a healthy 6.1
percent, significantly above the gain for any comparable
period in the past six years (see Chart I).
Inventory investment as well as final spending appar­
ently rose substantially in the second quarter. Tentative
and incomplete data indicate that the annual rate of
inventory accumulation in the GNP accounts accelerated
to $4.3 billion in the April-June period as compared with
only $0.4 billion in the preceding quarter. Thus, after a
prolonged period of sluggishness, inventory spending
provided a $3.9 billion stimulus to the overall advance of
GNP (see Chart II). Prospects appear to be good for
further gains in inventory investment in the months ahead
in line with increases in sales. Business inventory-sales
ratios, particularly in the manufacturing and retail sectors,
remain at relatively low levels. Moreover, the latest survey
conducted by the Department of Commerce found that
manufacturers expect to add substantially to their inven­
tories in the third quarter.
The second-quarter rise in current-dollar final expendi­
tures— i.e., GNP net of inventory accumulation—
amounted to $26.1 billion, down from $32.2 billion in
the first quarter. In real terms, however, final spending
rose at a rapid 7.2 percent annual rate, a shade higher
than the growth over the January-March period. Among
the components of final expenditures, consumer spending

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

and business fixed investment were particularly strong,
while residential construction rose modestly. Net exports
of goods and services was the only major component which
failed to contribute to the overall expansion of GNP, as
the gap between imports and exports of goods and services
widened slightly to an annual rate of $4.9 billion.
Personal consumption expenditures rose by $16.4
billion over the April-June period to a seasonally adjusted
annual rate of $712.5 billion. Outlays for nondurable
goods and services posted relatively strong gains, while
the increase in spending for durables moderated somewhat
from the pace of the previous quarter. The large secondquarter rise in overall consumer spending as recorded in
the GNP accounts had been presaged by developments in
retail sales during the quarter. Such sales were particularly
strong in May, but according to preliminary June data—
which could be revised substantially— retail sales declined
by $500 million in that month after increasing by an
average of $400 million per month over the January-May
period. Automotive sales as well as sales of other durables
and nondurables were all down substantially in June.




187

However, retail sales may have been held back significantly
in that month by the effects of flooding in the northeastern
part of the country. In any event, recent surveys of con­
sumer attitudes indicate that the consumer remains in a
relatively strong buying mood. In addition, the recently
enacted social security measures which provide a 20 per­
cent general benefit increase with payments beginning in
October should provide a boost in consumer spending in
the fourth quarter.
The severe flooding in the East seems also to have had
a significant effect on personal income in the final month
of the quarter. After registering sizable gains in April and
May, personal income was essentially flat in June when
sharp declines in proprietors’ income and rental income
offset the rise in wage and salary disbursements. Over the
quarter as a whole, personal income rose by $15.5 billion,
a considerably smaller increase than the $25.5 billion
advance of the first quarter. It should be noted, though,
that the first-quarter rise was boosted by several non­
recurring special factors. Disposable after-tax income grew
by $12.4 billion over the April-June period, about the

188

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1972

Chart II

RECENT CHANGES IN GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT
AND ITS COMPONENTS
Seasonally adjusted

Change from fourth quarter 1971 ^^^HChange from first quarter
to first quarter 1972

to second quarter 1972

GROSS NATIONAL PRODUCT

Inventory investment

Final expenditures

Consumer expenditures for
d urab le goods
Consumer expenditures for
nondurable goods
Consumer expenditures for
services
Residential construction

Business fixed investment

Federal Government
purchases
State and local government
purchases
Net exports of goods
and services

i
-5

0

5

10
15
20
B illions of dollars

25

30

35

Source: United States Department of Commerce.

same gain that was posted in the preceding quarter. At
the same time, the ratio of personal savings to disposable
income declined for the fourth consecutive quarter to
6.6 percent.
The latest reading for the savings rate is the lowest
since the fourth quarter of 1969 and is only slightly above
its average for the entire post-Korean war period. While
the overwithholding of personal income taxes has probably
artificially depressed the savings rate in the last two quar­
ters, it appears that even allowing for this effect there has
still been a significant decline. For example, it is estimated
that overwithholding increased Federal tax payments by
approximately $8 billion at an annual rate in each of
these two quarters. Even if all of this overwithholding were
fully intentional, the implied value of the true savings rate
in the April-June period would still be about 1 percentage
point below the record 8.6 percent posted in the second
quarter of 1971.




Business fixed investment grew by $4 billion in the
second quarter, with the gain concentrated almost exclu­
sively in producers’ durable equipment. This increase,
coupled with the extraordinary $6.3 billion rise in capital
expenditures during the January-March period, brought
the growth in the first half of this year to an annual rate
of 19.6 percent. Moreover, recent data suggest continued
strength in spending for new capital equipment in the
months ahead, as new orders for nondefense capital goods
rose sizably in both April and May and edged up further
in June. In light of this evidence, it appears quite possible
that the rise in plant and equipment expenditures for 1972
as a whole will surpass the 10.3 percent increase that was
expected in the May survey of spending plans conducted
by the Department of Commerce and may be closer to the
14 percent gain indicated in the McGraw-Hill spring
survey. By comparison, plant and equipment expenditures
rose by a small 1.9 percent in 1971.
Spending on residential construction increased by $0.8
billion over the April-June period. This was the smallest
quarterly gain in almost two years, suggesting that the
housing boom may be peaking out— albeit at a very high
level. Housing starts in the second quarter averaged 2.2
million units at an annual rate, down from the unprece­
dented 2.5 million unit pace set in the January-March
period. In addition, the second-quarter level of building
permits was slightly below its average of the previous
three-month period.
Government purchases of goods and services contributed
$5.2 billion to the second-quarter GNP advance. Federal
expenditures rose by $2.5 billion, about half the increase
of the January-March period which was swollen by civilian
and military pay raises. The bulk of the rise in Federal
expenditures in the second quarter reflected an increase
in defense spending. This increase brought Federal spend­
ing for defense to an annual rate of $78.6 billion, the
highest level in more than two years. At the state and
local levels, spending rose by $2.7 billion in the April-June
period, down $0.8 billion from the increase of the previ­
ous quarter.
PRICES, WAGES, PR O D U CTIVITY,
AND E M P LO Y M E N T

With the exception of movements in the wholesale price
index, recent price data confirm a definite easing of infla­
tionary pressures. The slow advance of the consumer price
index in the last four months is especially encouraging.
Taking a somewhat longer perspective, June marked the
first time since 1967 that the year-to-year change in this
index was less than 3 percent. Moreover, the GNP de­

189

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

flator posted a relatively modest increase in the second
quarter, although shifts in the composition of output caused
some understatement of actual inflation.
According to preliminary estimates, the implicit GNP
price deflator rose at a 2.1 percent seasonally adjusted
annual rate in the second quarter, down sharply from the
5.1 percent rate of the January-March period. This com­
parison overstates the deceleration in the underlying pace
of inflation since the first-quarter deflator was given a
temporary boost by the post-freeze clustering of price in­
creases and the Federal pay raises. Beyond this, the slow­
down partly reflected shifts in the composition of output
in the second quarter toward goods— such as producers’
durable equipment—whose prices have risen less rapidly
relative to the prices of others since the base year for the
index. These shifts had a depressing effect on the deflator
in the April-June period because this index is a weighted
average of component price indexes, with the weights de­
termined by the composition of output in each quarter.
Thus, the chain price index, a measure of prices which is
not affected by changes in the composition of output be­
tween adjacent quarters, rose at a 3.2 percent annual rate
in the second quarter, down from the 3.9 percent average
gain posted over the preceding four quarters.
Recent movements in the consumer price index are
encouraging. In June, consumer prices rose by only 0.7
percent on a seasonally adjusted annual basis. This small
increase followed a 4 percent rise in May but very modest
advances in the two preceding months. During the MarchJune period as a whole, increases in the consumer price
index had averaged less than 1.8 percent per annum, the
slowest advance in this index for any four-month period—
including the months covered by the price freeze—in al­
most seven years. Overall, in Phase Two thus far, con­
sumer prices have risen at an annual rate of 3.1 percent,
down 0.7 percentage point from the pace of the first eight
months of 1971 and substantially below the increases reg­
istered in each of the preceding three years when con­
sumer prices rose annually between 4.7 percent and 6.1
percent. To some extent, this comparison may understate
the recent deceleration in the advance of consumer prices,
since increases that might otherwise have occurred during
the price freeze tended to be bunched in the immediate
post-freeze period. Thus, when the price-freeze and Phase
Two periods are combined the slowdown is even more ap­
parent (see Chart III).
The small June increase in the consumer price index
resulted from virtually no change in prices of nonfood
commodities as a whole, coupled with a 3.7 percent an­
nual rise (not seasonally adjusted) in prices of services
and a 2 percent gain in food prices. In the nonfood com­




modity group, the prices of some individual products—
such as homes and used cars— moved up appreciably, but
these increases were balanced by declines in the prices of
apparel, gasoline, liquor, and fuel oil and coal. Within
the service sector, mortgage interest rates moved up for
the first time since October of last year and doctors’ fees
rose at a 6 percent annual rate. Not surprisingly, given
recent movements in food prices at the wholesale level,
retail prices of meats and poultry climbed sharply in June,
and vegetable and fresh fruit prices also rose. In the light
of the steep advance of wholesale food prices in July, the
rise in consumer food prices seems likely to accelerate in
coming months.
At the wholesale level, prices rose in July at a sea­
sonally adjusted annual rate of 8.6 percent, the sharpest
gain since August of last year. This huge July bulge mainly
reflected a large increase in prices of farm products and
processed foods and feeds which surged ahead at over a
24 percent annual rate. Livestock prices, particularly for
hogs, and prices of fresh fruits, eggs, and poultry posted
steep increases. At the same time, however, the rise in
industrial commodity prices moderated to an annual rate
of 2.8 percent.
July was the first month this year in which industrial
commodity prices rose by less than 4 percent. While the
rapid advance of such prices during the first few months
of the year was expected in view of the post-freeze cluster­

Chart III

RECENT CHANGES IN CONSUMER PRICES
Annual rates
Percent

Percent
10

8

0
;

Dec 1969-Dec 1970

[ .t 'j

Dec 1970-Aug 1971

Aug 1971-Jun 1972
Note: Data are seasonally adjusted with the exception of services.
Source: United States Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

190

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1972

ing of price increases, the sharp increase of 4.5 percent
posted in the second quarter remains somewhat disturbing
despite the more moderate July increase. Overall, in Phase
Two thus far, industrial commodity prices have climbed
at an annual rate of 4.1 percent, down 0.6 percentage
point from the rise in the first eight months of 1971 but
0.6 percentage point above the average gain registered in
the 1968-70 period.
The pace of wage increases has slowed somewhat in
recent months. Compensation per hour of work in the
private economy rose at a 5.6 percent seasonally ad­
justed annual rate in the April-June period, down from
an average increase of 6.5 percent over the previous
four quarters. Average hourly earnings— one of the
monthly sources for the series on compensation per hour
of work— rose very rapidly in April, posted very small
increases in both May and June, and then rose moderately
in July. Moreover, the latest Bureau of Labor Statistics
survey reveals some moderation in the rate of increase in
wages and benefits under major collective bargaining settle­
ments. For example, in the manufacturing sector the mean
life-of-contract wage and benefit gain for settlements,
covering 5,000 or more workers, negotiated from January
through June was 6 percent in contrast to 7.7 percent in
1971. The slowdown was even more pronounced in the
construction sector, where the increase in the average
life-of-contract settlements for wage and fringe benefits
was 7.6 percent in the first half of 1972, down sharply
from last year’s 12.1 percent gain. It should be noted,
however, that this survey covers contracts involving
only 616,000 workers for all industries and excludes wage
settlements, involving 750,000 workers, which had not
been acted upon by either the Pay Board or the Con­
struction Industry Stabilization Committee. In addition,
1972 is a relatively light collective-bargaining year and a
much heavier load of settlements is expected to be nego­
tiated in 1973. Thus, the extent to which this recent slow­
down in the pace of wage increases under collective bar­
gaining agreements proves to be of a permanent rather
than temporary nature depends in part on future decisions
of the Pay Board and perhaps more fundamentally on




whether price inflation is brought under control.
The growth of productivity, as measured by the index
of output per hour of work in the private nonfarm econ­
omy, accelerated to a 4.8 percent seasonally adjusted an­
nual rate in the second quarter. Including the farm sector,
where productivity changes tend to be quite volatile on a
quarterly basis, output per hour of work climbed at a 6.3
percent annual rate. This gain coming on the heels of the
sizable advance in output per hour of work over the pre­
vious nine-month period brought growth in the second
quarter from four quarters earlier to a rapid 4.4 percent,
about 1.2 percentage points above its long-run trend. As a
consequence of the substantial increase in productivity
coupled with the moderation in compensation per hour of
work, unit labor costs declined slightly in the second quar­
ter for the first time in over six years. In contrast, unit
labor costs climbed at an average annual rate of 6 percent
over the 1968-70 period and rose by 2.2 percent in 1971.
According to the monthly survey of households, both
civilian employment and the labor force were virtually
unchanged in July, after adjustments for seasonal varia­
tions. As a consequence, the unemployment rate remained
unchanged from June’s level of 5.5 percent. Prior to these
two months, the rate of unemployment had hovered near
5.9 percent since late 1970. Notably, the jobless rate for
men twenty-five years of age and older declined in July
by 0.3 percentage point to 3.0 percent, its lowest level in
nearly two years. Jobless rates for teen-agers and men and
women between twenty and twenty-four years of age rose
during the month after posting declines in June. Following
several months of sizable gains earlier in the year, the
most recent survey of establishments indicates that non­
farm payroll employment was essentially flat for the sec­
ond consecutive month. In July, employment in the
construction and manufacturing industries was particularly
weak. It should be noted, however, that the decline in
construction employment in this month partly reflected an
increase in strike activity. Also, according to the Bureau
of Labor Statistics, employment in both construction and
manufacturing seems to have been held back by the effects
of tropical storm Agnes.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

191

Financial Developments in the Second Quarter
During the second quarter of 1972, the narrow money
supply (MO grew at a seasonally adjusted annual rate
of 5.3 percent, 4 percentage points below its rate of
advance in the first three months of the year. At the same
time, the broad money supply (M2) and the volume of
reserves available to support private nonbank deposits
(RPD) expanded at far slower rates than had been
witnessed in the January-March interval. However,
aggressive bank marketing of large negotiable certificates
of deposit (CDs) allowed the more comprehensive mea­
sure of member bank liabilities— the adjusted bank credit
proxy— to expand at virtually the same rate as in the
first quarter. On the asset side of the commercial banking
system’s balance sheet, bank credit growth slowed over
the quarter, although the extent of the slowing may have
been exaggerated by the manner in which bank credit is
measured.
Despite the slowdown in the expansion of the monetary
and reserve aggregates, upward movements in interest
rates were quite moderate. To be sure, those money
market yields most closely tied to the availability of funds
to the banking system— the Federal funds rate, the rate
on large negotiable CDs, and the prime loan rate— ad­
vanced somewhat over the interval. However, Treasury
bill rates were virtually stable, as were commercial paper
rates following an initial upward surge in this latter rate in
April. At the longer end of the maturity spectrum as well,
there was only a slight upward drift in yields, reflecting in
part the easing of the demand for funds by the Federal
Government and private corporations.
The healthy tone of the capital markets manifested by
these interest rate developments was further reflected in
the performance of the nonbank depository institutions as
suppliers of funds to the residential mortgage market. The
inflow of deposits to these institutions continued strong,
though the rate of growth decelerated substantially from
that witnessed in the first quarter. However, the data avail­
able through May suggest that despite the slowdown of
deposit growth the combined rate of acquisition of
mortgages by these institutions accelerated.




M O NETAR Y AGGREGATES

Following its rapid first-quarter growth at a rate of 9.3
percent, Mx— defined as currency outside banks plus
private demand deposits— expanded at a more moderate
rate of 5.3 percent in the second quarter (see Chart I).
As a result, the growth rate of Mx for the entire six-month
period ended June 1972 was 7.4 percent. Moreover, from
November 1970—which the National Bureau of Economic
Research has tentatively dated as the trough of the cur­
rent business cycle— through June of this year, Mx grew
at a seasonally adjusted annual rate of 6.8 percent, a rate
only slightly above that regarded by many as commen­
surate with the goal of viable economic recovery.
The decline in Mx growth over the quarter was
accompanied by reductions in the rate of advance of RPD
and M2— which adds to Mx commercial bank savings
accounts and time deposits except negotiable CDs in
denominations of $100,000 or more. In the April-June
interval, the seasonally adjusted annual rate of growth of
RPD slowed to 7.4 percent, compared with 11 percent in
the first three months of the year. Growth of M2 took
place at a rate of 8.6 percent through the April-June pe­
riod, in contrast to its first-quarter rate of 13.3 percent.
This decline in M2 growth was attributable not only to the
slowing of Mx expansion, but also to a marked decline in
the rate of advance of consumer-type savings deposits from
17.1 percent in the first quarter of the year to 11.8 percent
in the second. As a result, the growth rate of M2 over the
six months ended June 1972 was 11.1 percent, the same
as its rate of growth over all of 1971.
Despite this deceleration in the growth of private
deposits, a broader measure of liabilities of banks that
are members of the Federal Reserve System— the adjusted
bank credit proxy—increased at a rate of 11.1 percent in
the second quarter, a rate of growth only 0.2 percentage
point below that realized in the first quarter. To a large
extent the continued strength of the bank credit proxy in
contrast to the slowdown in the growth of the deposit
aggregates reflected the ability of commercial banks to

192

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1972

Chart I

CHANGES IN THE RESERVE AND M ONETARY
AGG REG ATES
Seasonally adjusted annual rates

rate during both of the first two quarters of 1972, bank
earning assets— measured as loans and investments
adjusted for loan sales to affiliates— displayed a marked
slowing in their rate of growth during the second quarter
of the year. After having expanded at an annual rate of
15.1 percent over the January-March period, bank credit
increased at a rate of 7.3 percent during the second quar­
ter of 1972 (see Chart II). The slowing in bank credit
growth resulted in part from a lower rate of purchase of
securities, both United States Government and others. It
also reflected a June decline in business loans, which had
grown rapidly over the first two months of the second
quarter. In contrast, the growth of real estate and con­
sumer loans accelerated in the second quarter from their
already rapid growth in the first three months of the year.
To some extent, the disparate growth patterns of bank
credit and the proxy during the second quarter reflect the

ADJUSTED BANK CREDIT PROXY

1971

1972

RPD - Total member bank reserves less those required to support United States
Government and interbank deposits.
Ml = Currency plus adjusted demand deposits held by the public.
M2 = Ml plus commercial bank savings and time deposits held by the
public, less negotiable certificates of deposit issued in denominations
of $100,000 or more.

Chart II

CHANGES IN BANK CREDIT AND ITS COMPONENTS
Seasonally adjusted annual rates
TOTAL BANK CREDIT*

Adjusted bank credit proxy = Total member bank deposits subject to reserve
requirements plus nondeposit sources of funds, such as Euro-dollar
borrowings and the proceeds of commercial paper issued by bank holding
companies or other affiliates.
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

TOTAL L O A N S *

attract funds through the use of large-denomination CDs.
Over the quarter, the rate on three-month CDs in the
secondary market rose from 4.28 percent at the beginning
of the quarter to 4.67 percent by its end. The volume of
CDs outstanding expanded over the quarter by $3.7
billion seasonally adjusted, an annual rate of increase of
44 percent. At the outset of the period, this CD growth
was accompanied by large increases in the level of
Treasury deposits in Tax and Loan Accounts. However,
the accounts were drawn down sharply in June and showed
a small net decline over the quarter.

4 \\

BANK C R ED IT, IN TE R E S T R A TES ,
AND T H E BOND M AR K ET
* Adjusted for loans sold to affiliates.

Although the sources of bank funds, as indicated by
the adjusted bank credit proxy, grew at virtually the same




Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

different methods used in calculating these aggregates. To
place this matter in proper perspective, it should be re­
called that the bank credit proxy as well as the other
monetary aggregates, when calculated monthly or weekly,
are obtained on a daily average basis. In contrast, sea­
sonally adjusted bank credit is reported monthly at its
level on the last Wednesday of the month. Judging from
the data available on a nonseasonally adjusted basis for
weekly reporting banks, it appears that bank credit
dropped temporarily in the last statement week in June,
a week in which bank credit had been rising seasonally in
recent years.
There was moderate upward pressure on short-term
interest rates during the second quarter (see Chart III).
For example, the average effective rate on Federal funds
rose from 3.83 percent in March to 4.46 percent in June.
CD rates also rose over the quarter. As the cost of funds
to banks drifted upward, the prime business loan rate at
most major commercial banks was raised from 4% percent
at the end of March to 5V4 percent by the end of June.

193

Chart IV

LONG-TERM INTEREST RATES
Percent

Percent

Note: The Aa-rated utility yields are taken from Salomon Brothers indexes of yields
on newly issued Aa-rated utilities with deferred call. Beginning and end of month
quotes have been averaged to form monthly yields. Yields on three- to five-year
Government securities are monthly averages of daily figures. Yields on twentyyear municipal bonds are monthly averages of Thursday figures.
Sources: Salomon Brothers, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
and The Bond Buyer.

Chart III

SHORT-TERM INTEREST RATES
Percent
9

Note: Yields on three-month Treasury bills and four- to six-month commercial
paper are monthly averages of daily figures. The prime rate is the interest
rate posted by major commercial banks on short-term loans to their most
creditworthy business borrowers.
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.




Treasury bills were firmer than the rest of the market,
with rates on three-month bills rising only about 20 basis
points over the quarter.
Yields on intermediate- and long-term securities were
for the most part little changed during the second quarter,
with modest increases outnumbering slight declines. Inter­
est rates etched an irregular pattern over the quarter,
generally rising through most of April, declining in late
April and through May, and then rising again in June
(see Chart IV ). One particularly interesting development
during the quarter was the strengthening of the intermedi­
ate sector of the market for United States Government
coupon obligations. Although yields in this sector had
declined in general concert with the downward movement
of interest rates following President Nixon’s announcement
of the new economic program, the decline in rates on
three- to five-year Governments ended earlier than those
on instruments in other sectors of the market, as inves­
tors became concerned about the financing implications of
the prospective Federal deficit for the fiscal year 1973.
Consequently, the first-quarter average yield on three- to

194

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1972

five-year Government securities was higher than it had
been in the first quarter of last year at the same time that
most other securities were yielding less than they had dur­
ing the same period last year. With the announcement of
the Treasury’s May refunding plans on April 26, which
disclosed that a portion of the maturing securities would
be redeemed, market expectations for this sector of the
market brightened considerably and yields dropped sharply
throughout May. Although rates backed up slightly in
June, the average yield on three- to five-year Governments
over the entire quarter was below that witnessed in the
second quarter of last year.
The relative stability of intermediate- and long-term
interest rates during the second quarter reflected in part
the absence of heavy demands for funds in the capital
markets. The United States Government repaid a net of
$6 billion of debt, in contrast to the $1.6 billion raised
during the second quarter of 1971. The Federal budgetary
deficit for the fiscal year that ended June 30, 1972 was
$23 billion—large historically but far below the $38.8 bil­
lion projected in the Budget document submitted by the
Administration last January. Outlays were $5 billion be­
low the January estimates, while receipts exceeded the esti­
mates by $10.8 billion. The larger than expected tax rev­
enues reflected not only overwithholding of individual
income taxes but also the impressive strength of the recov­
ery in economic activity during the fiscal year. In addition,
the Treasury obtained during the second quarter $2.5
billion through the sale of special nonmarketable securities
to foreign central banks which had acquired dollars in
foreign exchange markets in an effort to prevent the ex­
change rates of their currencies against the dollar from
exceeding the limits specified in the Smithsonian Agreement
of December 18, 1971.
The corporate bond market was bolstered by a rela­
tively light calendar of securities offerings. In part, this
reflected the buildup of corporate liquidity that was
accomplished through the record volume of bond offerings
during 1970 and 1971 and the recent increases in cash
flow as a result of increasing profits and accelerated
depreciation allowances. Consequently, nonfinancial cor­
porations floated only $10 billion of securities in the
corporate bond market in the first six months of 1972,
after having raised $15 billion through bond flotations
over a comparable period last year. At the same time,
state and local governments raised $12 billion in the
bond market during the first half of this year. While it
was almost equal to the record $12.5 billion in funds dur­
ing the first half of 1971, a larger part of this year’s gross
proceeds have gone toward retirement of outstanding debt.




T H R IF T IN S TITU TIO N S

The slowdown in the growth of small-denomination
time deposits at commercial banks was paralleled at thrift
institutions. Savings and loan association shares grew at
an annual rate of 16 percent during the April-June inter­
val, compared with the near-record rate of growth of sav­
ings and loan association capital of 23Vi percent in the
first quarter, while mutual savings bank deposit growth
decelerated from its 14Vi percent rate in the first quarter
to 11 percent during the second (see Chart V ) . As a result
of the total buildup of savings and loan association capital
during the previous five quarters, however, the growth of
mortgage holdings by savings and loan associations ac­
celerated to a rate of 18 percent, compared with a growth
rate of 15 percent in the first quarter of the year. At
mutual savings banks, data available through May suggest

Chart V

THRIFT INSTITUTION DEPOSIT FLOWS
AND HOME M O RTG AG E LENDING
Seasonally adjusted annual rates
Percent

Percent

Note: Mutual savings bank mortgage statistics for the second quarter of 1972
are based on April and May data.
Sources: Federal Home Loan Bank Board and National Association of Mutual
Savings Banks.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

that the growth of mutual savings bank mortgage holdings
accelerated to an 8 percent annual rate in the second
quarter, after having been IV 2 percent in the first quarter.
With this continued strong participation of thrift institu­
tions in the mortgage market, yields on new home
conventional mortgages averaged 7.53 percent, 11 basis
points below their average in the first quarter.
The deceleration of thrift institution deposit growth in
the second quarter of this year notwithstanding, the over­
all performance of these deposits over the eighteen-month
interval ended June 1972 was unusually strong. Over that

195

period of a year and a half, savings and loan association
capital grew at a seasonally adjusted annual rate of 21
percent, while mutual savings bank deposits increased at
a rate of 14 percent. To be sure, much of this growth
occurred in a period when the ratio of personal savings to
disposable income was unusually high and when rates on
competing market instruments were relatively low. How­
ever, it was also attributable to the aggressiveness with
which thrift institutions have been offering higher yield­
ing certificate-type accounts as a means of attracting de­
posit liabilities.

Th e Money and Bond Markets in July
Interest rates generally drifted slightly lower in July.
At the beginning of the month, it had been widely expected
that the upward trend exhibited in June would continue.
However, increases in interest rates during the month
were generally small and were later reversed. In conse­
quence, most interest rates closed a bit lower on balance.
Late in July, rates were influenced by anticipations
concerning the Treasury’s refunding announcement. More
uncertainty than usual preceded the announcement. On the
one hand, the Treasury continues to enjoy an unusually
comfortable cash position. On the other hand, the Trea­
sury’s longer run cash needs are believed to be quite large
in view of the sizable Federal budgetary deficit expected
in fiscal 1973.
The Treasury announced the terms of a massive
refinancing operation after the close of business July 26.
Along with the $2.3 billion of publicly held notes and
bonds maturing August 15, an additional $17.4 billion of
coupon issues maturing at later dates this year and at
selected dates in 1974 and 1975 was eligible for the
refunding. One of the Treasury’s goals is to lengthen the
maturity structure of the debt. The average maturity of
marketable Federal debt outstanding had fallen from five
years four months in 1965 to less than three years three




months by mid-1972. The shortening of the debt occurred
partly because the AVa percent interest rate ceiling on
Treasury bonds had prevented the issue of new bonds
from 1965 until the 1971 suspension of this ceiling,
which permitted the Treasury to issue up to $10 billion of
bonds at rates in excess of AVx percent. The new offering
did not include a short-term note but instead consisted of
3 Vi-year and 7-year notes and 12-year bonds. The offering
was enthusiastically received, and an impressive $8.7 bil­
lion of new securities was subscribed. Because of the
Treasury’s currently strong cash position, no companion
issue was offered for cash. In part, the strong cash position
reflects the recent sale of special nonmarketable issues to
foreign official institutions.
About $3.1 billion of special certificates of indebted­
ness was issued in July to absorb the large volume of
dollars purchased by foreign central banks. This operation
was one of the repercussions that followed the British
decision in late June to allow the pound to float. Other
governments quickly reaffirmed their determination to
maintain the exchange rate structure established in the
Smithsonian Agreement, but even so widespread specula­
tion developed in favor of several continental European
currencies. With exchange rates driven hard against their

196

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1972

upper limits against the dollar, the foreign central banks
were required to absorb large quantities of dollars, with
which they in turn purchased both marketable and nonmarketable United States Treasury securities. On July 19, the
Federal Reserve initiated a new line of operations by of­
fering German marks in the New York exchange market.
Federal Reserve Board Chairman Arthur Burns explained
that the United States authorities “are now moving to play
our part to restore order in foreign exchange markets and
to do our part in upholding the Smithsonian Agreement”.
The Chairman said that such operations would continue
on whatever scale and whenever transactions were deemed
desirable, and he disclosed that the suspension on use of
the Federal Reserve swap lines that went into effect last

August 15 had been lifted. During the remainder of July, the
exchange markets were quieter and dollar rates improved.
BANK RESERVES AND T H E MONEY M AR KET

Short-term interest rates generally declined slightly over
the month of July. There were a number of minor upward
movements early in the month, which were reversed as the
month progressed. For example, rates on 90- to 119-day
dealer-placed commercial paper increased Vs percentage
point in the first week of July but fell back Vs point in
the third week to 4% percent (see Chart I). Rates on
most other maturities of commercial paper were also
lowered Vs to V4 percentage point during July. Secondary

SELECTED INTEREST RATES
M ay-July 1972
Percent

M ONEY MARKET RATES

BON D MARKET YIELDS

Percent

Note: Data are shown for business days only.
MONEY MARKET RATES QUOTED: Bid rates for three-month Euro-dollars in London; offering
rates (quoted in terms of rate of discount) on 90- to 119-day prime commercial paper
quoted by three of the four dealers that report their rates, or the midpoint of the range
quoted if no consensus is available; the effective rate on Federal funds tthe rate most
representative of the transactions executed); closing bid rates (quoted in terms of rate of
discount) on newest outstanding three-month Treasury bills.
BOND MARKET YIELDS QUOTED: Yields on new Aa-rated public utility bonds (arrows point from
underwriting syndicate reoffering yield on a given issue to market yield on the same issue




immediately after it has been released from syndicate restrictions); daily averages of yields
on seasoned Aaa-rated corporate bonds,- daily averages of yields on long-term Government
securities (bonds due or callable in ten years or more) and on Government securities due in
three to five years, computed on the basis of closing bid prices; Thursday averages of yields
on twenty seasoned twenty-yea/ tax -exempt bonds (carrying Moody's ratings of Aaa, Aa, A,
and Baa).
Sources: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
Moody's Investors Service, and The Bond Buyer.

197

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

In millions of dollars; (+) denotes increase
(—) decrease in excess reserves

Changes in daily averages—
week ended

Net
changes

Factors
July

July
12

July
19

July
26

+ 291
+ 336
+ 714

— 640
— 28
+ 164
+
—

439

— 230
+ 76
— 358

— 312

4+
—
—
—
+

192
199
215
143
72
633

—

2

5

“ Market” factors
Member bank required reserves ..................
Operating transactions (subtotal) ................ —
Federal Reserve float ................................... —
Treasury operations* ..................................... +
Gold and foreign account .......................... _
Currency outside banks ............................... —
Other Federal Reserve liab ilities
and capital ....................................................... —

638
176
444
998
98

66
23

OO




T able I
F A C T O R S T E N D I N G TO IN C R E A S E O R D E C R E A S E
M E M B E R B A N K R E S E R V E S , J U L Y 1972

—
+
4+
—
—

795
331
219
691
117
476

+

16

194

+ 134

+

market rates on large negotiable certificates of deposit
(CDs) climbed about 20 basis points at the start of July
but were reduced later in the month by as much as 30
basis points. Rates on bankers’ acceptances were reduced
by Vs percentage point late in July. Euro-dollar rates
continued to be sensitive to uncertainties in the foreign
exchange markets. The three-month Euro-dollar rate
generally advanced through July 18. After that, some de­
gree of calm was restored to the exchange markets partly
in response to Federal Reserve sales of German marks.
Euro-dollar rates subsequently declined and ended the
month at 5¥s percent, 3/s percentage point above the
opening rate. A few large banks raised their prime com­
mercial loan rate to 5V2 percent in response to previous
increases in market rates. Most banks did not feel,
however, that loan demand was sufficiently strong to
justify such an increase, and therefore they retained a
5Va percent prime rate. Effective July 31, in response to
a drop in commercial paper rates, two major banks with
floating prime rates reduced their prime rate from 5V2
percent to 5% percent.
The average effective rate on Federal funds in July was
4.55 percent, 9 basis points above the June level. For
the statement week ended July 5, excess and borrowed
reserves increased sharply (see Table I). However, in each
succeeding week, excess and borrowed reserve levels were
both reduced. Since excess reserves fell more rapidly, free
reserves declined, becoming negative after the first state­
ment week.
The growth in reserves available to support private
nonbank deposits (RPD) accelerated in July to an esti­
mated 9 Vi percent seasonally adjusted annual rate. By
excluding reserves backing Treasury and net interbank
deposits, which are not included in the money supply, the
RPD series is more closely related to the money supply
than is the total reserves series.
According to preliminary data for the period through
July 26, the growth of the narrowly defined money supply
(M O — adjusted demand deposits plus currency outside
banks— also accelerated in July, to an estimated 15 percent
seasonally adjusted annual rate from its more restrained
5.3 percent pace in the second quarter. The acceleration
took place during the first two weeks of July after which
the money supply fell back slightly. As was indicated by
Federal Reserve Board Chairman Burns in testimony
before the Joint Economic Committee of the United States
Congress, the System is still “in a favorable position to
continue pursuing a path of moderate monetary growth”.
Despite the bulge in July, longer term growth rates,
generally considered to be more meaningful in evaluating
the impact of money supply behavior, show somewhat

814

+ 627

— 668

+ 391

— 464

+

827

— 698

-j- 612

— 505

+ 236

-h
4-

804
2
21

— 732
—
2
— 11

+ 300
_
1
—

— 72
—
3
—
7

4 - 400
—
4
— 39

40
4
6
183
8

+

33

+

6

+ 247
4- 45

— 329
— 58
— 36
—
4

—
—

Total “ market” f a c t o r s ................................. -

Direct Federal Reserve credit
transactions
Open market operations (subtotal) ...........
Outright holdings:
Treasury securities ........................................
Bankers’ acceptances ...................................
Federal agency obligations ........................
Repurchase agreements:
Treasury securities ........................................
Bankers’ acceptances ...................................
Federal agency obligations ......................
Member bank borrowings ...............................
Other Federal Reserve assetsf ......................
Total

__

-h
—

+
+
+

.................................................................... + 1 ,0 1 8

Excess reserves ............................................................ +

204

9
11
1

51

+ 21
— 51
4 - 54

41

+ 42
4 - 154

— 732

4- 614

— 468

4 - 432

— 105

—

— 77

— 32

+
8
— 85
+

54

+

—

Monthly
averages

Daily average levels

Member bank:
Total reserves, including vault ca sh .............
Required reserves ..............................................
Excess reserves ...................................................
Free, or net borrowed ( — ), reserves...........
Non borrowed reserves ........................................
Net carry-over, excess or deficit ( — ) § . . . .

33,143
32,815
328
312
16
32,831
98

32,747
32,524
223
227
—
4
32,520
209

33,333
33,164
169
175
—
6
33,158
182

33,064
32,972
92
171
— 79
32,893
133

33,072$
32,869$
203t
221$
— 18*
32,851$
156$

N ote: Because of rounding, figures do not necessarily add to totals.
*Includes changes in Treasury currency and cash,
fln clu d es assets denom inated in foreign currencies.
lAverage for four weeks ended July 26.
§Not reflected in data above.

more moderate rates of advance. Over the three months
through July, M! increased at an annual rate of about
8 percent (see Chart II). In the past year, Ma grew by
about 5V2 percent.

198

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1972

The broad money supply (M 2) — defined as M t plus
time deposits other than large CDs— accelerated slightly
in July to a 12 percent annual rate of growth from a
IOV2 percent rate in June. The acceleration in this aggre­
gate resulted entirely from the speedup in M l Time
deposits other than large CDs advanced more slowly than
they had in June.
The adjusted bank credit proxy, consisting of member
bank deposits subject to reserve requirements and certain
nondeposit liabilities, advanced at an estimated 13
percent seasonally adjusted annual pace in July, quite close
to the rate of growth of M2. Treasury deposits and net
interbank deposits at member banks, both of which are
included in the proxy but not in the money supply, rose
only slightly in July. However, large CDs, the other major
element of the proxy excluded from the money supply,
increased at a significantly faster pace than did other types

Chart II

CHANGES IN MONETARY AND CREDIT AGGREGATES
Seasonally adjusted annual rates
Percent

Percent

Ml
>— ^ ^ 4

\

/

From l!2
months ear Her

1

~

/

\

/

i r
From 3
months earlier

1

_1_L J
1_ _1

.

1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

i

i

1 i

i

1

i

i

1 I

;

1

M2
From 12
months earlier

/

/

From 3
months earlier

\

V

—

\

/

—
1 1 1 1 1 1

I

1 1 1 I

1 I

1 1 i

I

ADJUSTED BANK!CREDIT PROXY

ss,.

From 3
months earlier

/
1 .1

From l2
months earlier

I 1 1 I
1970

-JLJ..1. I

JL..J

1971

1 1

1

1 J_ . 1 I

1.1 1,1...
1972

Note: Data for July 1972 are preliminary estimates.
Ml = Currency plus adjusted demand deposits held by the public.
M2 = Ml plus commercial bank savings and time deposits held by the
public, less negotiable certificates of deposit issued in denominations
of $100,000 or more.
Adjusted bank credit proxy = Total member bank deposits subject to reserve
requirements plus nondeposit sources of funds, such as Euro-dollar
borrowings and the proceeds of commercial paper issued by bank holding
companies or other affiliates.
Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York.




of deposits so that, on balance, proxy growth paralleled
that of the monetary aggregates.
TH E GOVERNM ENT SECURITIES M AR KET

The market for United States Government securities
was subject to conflicting sets of influences in July. Vari­
ous news items indicating that the economy was experi­
encing a vigorous expansion, along with the concern about
the impact of the large Federal budget deficit on the size
of future Treasury financing needs, worked toward push­
ing up interest rates on Government securities. However,
continuing turmoil in the foreign exchange markets tended
to depress yields, particularly in the shorter maturities, as
foreign central banks purchased Government securities
with the dollars they acquired in support operations. Add­
ing to the downward pressure in rates was the rather thin
floating supply of securities, especially in certain inter­
mediate maturity ranges. The Treasury had actually retired
debt on balance in the second quarter and raised only a
modest amount in July through weekly additions of $200
million to the maturing bills beginning July 13.
On July 26, the Treasury announced a major refunding
operation. In the refunding, holders of the remaining five
issues of notes and bonds maturing in 1972— on August 15,
September 15, November 15, and December 15—were
offered 5% percent 3Vi-year notes priced to yield 5.96
percent, 6 V4 percent 7-year notes priced at par, and 6 3/s
percent 12-year bonds priced to yield 6.45 percent. In ad­
dition, the holders of notes and bonds due in November
1974 and February 1975 were given the opportunity to
exchange those securities for either the 7-year notes or the
12-year bonds. The bonds were also offered for cash to
individuals in amounts not to exceed $10,000.
Preliminary results of the refunding indicate that it was
highly successful. Of the $2.3 billion of publicly held
securities maturing August 15, $1.67 billion was ex­
changed for an attrition rate of 27.6 percent, somewhat
lower than usually expected in refunding operations con­
taining no new short-term issue. In addition, $3.3 billion
of the $6.2 billion maturing between September and De­
cember 1972 and $3.1 billion of the securities due to ma­
ture in 1974 and 1975 were exchanged. The holders of
issues maturing in 1972 purchased primarily the 3Vi-year
notes, but the longer term issues sold well because of
orders from holders of the 1974 and 1975 securities. Pre­
liminary figures show subscriptions for $3.9 billion of the
new 3Vi-year notes, $3 billion of the 7-year notes, and $1.1
billion of the 12-year bonds, including $22 million sold to
individuals for cash.
Treasury bill rates were particularly sensitive to the

199

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

foreign situation. With large dollar-support operations
undertaken by foreign central banks, prices tended to be
bid up in the bill market in anticipation of probable for­
eign official demand for bills. Although there was some
upward pressure on bill prices from official foreign sources,
it was smaller than it might have been because much of
the foreign demand was channeled into special nonmarketable Treasury certificates of indebtedness. Over the month,
the Treasury issued about $3.1 billion of special certifi­
cates to foreigners while marketable United States Govern­
ment securities held by the Federal Reserve in custody for
foreign official accounts increased by $670 million.
Against this background, three-month Treasury bill
rates declined by about 15 basis points through July 19.
During this period, several other short-term rates increased.
Then, as speculative pressures eased in the foreign ex­
change markets, bill rates began to edge upward again. In
the final days of the month, bill rates fell once more as the
absence of a short-term issue in the refunding pointed to
limited supply conditions. On balance, secondary market
rates ended the month about 3 to 40 basis points below
their opening levels.
The weekly auction of three- and six-month Treasury
bills that would normally have been held in the first week
of July was pushed forward to June 30, since July 3 was
a holiday for many. At that auction, interest rates had
moved up somewhat—by 12 basis points on the threemonth bills. Beginning with the first auction actually held
in July, bill rates began to slide. At that auction, on July
10, three-month rates declined 4 basis points to an average
4.102 percent (see Table II). In the intervening week,
purchases by foreigners were heavy and, at the auction
held on July 17, three-month Treasury bill rates fell a
further 15 basis points to an average of 3.948 percent.
Bill rates climbed 10 basis points in the auction held on
July 24 after foreign exchange jitters began to ease. In
light of this turnaround, the monthly auction of nine- and
twelve-month Treasury bills, held on July 25, exhibited
mixed results. Yields on the nine-month bills averaged
2 basis points less than those on equivalent bills offered
in June. On the other hand, the yield on the one-year bill
climbed 6 basis points to 4.918 percent, the highest rate
posted since last September. In the final auction of threeand six-month bills, held July 31, yields dropped substan­
tially— to 3.794 percent on the three-month bills— in
response to previous declines in secondary market rates.
Yields on intermediate-term Treasury issues declined
early in July, but later these yields moved back up so that
they were little changed over the month as a whole. Long­
term Government bond yields edged lower through most
of the month. Treasury bond issues have benefited in the




T able II
A V E R A G E IS S U I N G R A T E S *
A T R E G U L A R T R E A S U R Y B IL L A U C T IO N S

In percent

Weekly auction dates— July 1972
Maturities
July
31

July
10

July
17

July
24

4 .102

3.948

4.047

3.794

4.605

4.455

4.585

4 .2 9 8

Monthly auction dates— May-July 1972

May
23

June
23

July
25

4.367

4.754

4.731

4 .465

4.854

4.918

* Interest rates on bills are Quoted in terms of a 360-flay year, with the discounts
from par as the return on the face amount of the bills payable at m aturity. Bond
yield equivalents, related to the amount actually invested, would be slightly higher.

last few months from the low level of new financing. Yields
have remained significantly below the highest levels for the
year established in April. On April 13, the average yield
on Treasury bonds maturing in more than ten years
reached 5.79 percent. By the end of July, however, the
average yield had fallen to 5.52 percent, the lowest level
of the year.
OTHER SECUR ITIES M ARKETS

Corporate bond prices stabilized early in July, braking
at least temporarily the decline of the previous month. Dur­
ing the remainder of July, the market was jostled by al­
ternately favorable and unfavorable news, but it still man­
aged to absorb an expanded volume of issues with little
difficulty.
A particularly light calendar during the holidayshortened Fourth of July week contributed to the early
stabilizing of rates. In the succeeding two weeks, how­
ever, the volume of new corporate bonds placed on sale
mushroomed to about $1.7 billion. On July 11, a utility
issue rated Aa sold well at a yield of 7.60 percent, the
same yield as another Aa bond which had been poorly
received in late June. The next day, a much larger Aarated utility bond was offered to yield 7.50 percent. A
surge of activity late in the day led to heavy sales. On the
following day, however, a relatively small utility issue rated
Aa by one rating service and A by another met with a poor
reception despite its 7.55 percent yield.

200

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1972

In the week beginning July 17, market sentiment vac­
illated. Observers were generally glum at the beginning
of the week, as several older issues were released from
syndicate price restrictions on Monday and quickly
climbed as much as 10 basis points in the secondary mar­
ket. The next day the market regained some stability when
a heavy demand greeted a finance company bond and two
new industrial issues. But the succeeding day, optimism
was dissipated as a two-part $250 million Aaa-rated offer­
ing by a Bell Telephone subsidiary met with a disappoint­
ing reception in spite of a 7.45 percent yield on the 38-year
debenture, the same rate that was offered on a similar Bell
System obligation in June which had sold well. This bond
was released from syndicate price restrictions on the fol­
lowing Tuesday, and the yield quickly climbed 4 basis
points in the secondary market.
In the final July week, the volume of corporate financing
slackened. In that week, two utility issues rated Aa and
priced to yield 7.55 percent and 7.52 percent, respectively,
attracted only lukewarm interest initially but sold well on
Friday following the announcement of prime rate reduc­
tions by two banks.
Prices on most tax-exempt securities were relatively
stable over the month of July. The Bond Buyer index of
twenty municipal bond yields remained unchanged at 5.43
percent for three weeks through July 6. During the next
two weeks the index fluctuated slightly, then declined at
the end of the month to 5.35 percent. The volume of taxexempt securities was light in the first and third weeks, but
heavy in the second and fourth weeks. Dealers were able
to reduce their inventories somewhat, with the Blue List




of dealers’ advertised inventories declining by $80 mil­
lion to $674 million during the month. New York City
offered $267.2 million of securities on July 12. These
bonds, rated Baa-1, were priced to yield from 4.25 per­
cent in 1974 to 6.80 percent in 2013. By comparison, a
similar New York City offering in April was priced to yield
6.90 percent on the longest maturity. Most of the new is­
sue was reported sold the first day. Other tax-exempt se­
curities marketed the same week did not fare quite so well,
but in the maturity ranges considered to be generously
priced the securities stimulated substantial interest. The
final week’s sizable volume of offerings met with generally
favorable receptions despite instances of aggressive pricing.

KEY TO T H E GOLD V A U LT

Key to the Gold Vault, a new, sixteen-page pam­
phlet, unlocks some of the mysteries of gold,
exposes some of its often glamorous past, and
reveals the work-a-day operations of the New York
Fed’s gold vault— the depository for the world’s
largest gold treasure.
Key to the Gold Vault is available without charge
from the Public Information Department, Federal
Reserve Bank of New York, 33 Liberty Street, New
York, N.Y. 10045.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

201

Reform of Reserve Requirements
By G e o r g e G a r vy
Economic Adviser, Federal Reserve Bank of New York

The Board of Governors has concluded that the
ORIGINS
prospect of eliminating a considerable amount of float as
a result of extending same-day payment of collection
Formalization of the traditional cash reserves of com­
items offers an opportunity for making simultaneously the mercial banks into a set of legally required reserve ratios
first significant change in the structure of reserve require­ was an American invention. Not until the Great Depres­
ments since the creation of the Federal Reserve System.1 sion of the 1930’s did reserve requirements begin to be
The purpose of this article is to place these changes in re­ widely used abroad as a policy instrument. Legal reserve
serve requirements in perspective by reviewing, first, the requirements became part of much of the banking legisla­
shortcomings of the system of reserve requirements which tion that was enacted or modified in foreign countries dur­
the new changes in Regulation D are designed to remedy ing World War II and the early postwar years. Some of the
and, then, past efforts directed at improvements.
leading countries, such as the United Kingdom and France,
Banks must hold a certain amount of cash as a matter introduced reserve requirements only a few years ago. So
of sound banking practice to meet possible deposit losses. far, the Bank of England continues to rely on voluntary
In addition, most countries, including the United States, compliance with ratios set by it. In several other countries
have legal provisions stipulating a minimum amount of of Western Europe, central banks have obtained powers to
reserves that must be held in prescribed form. These “legal impose reserve requirements but have made use of them
reserves” provide a fulcrum against which Federal Re­ only intermittently or not at all. In Germany, however,
serve System control over reserve availability becomes reserve requirements have become a main tool of monetary
effective in influencing bank credit and the monetary ag­ control.
The present structure of member bank reserve require­
gregates. Achieving the objectives of monetary policy de­
pends primarily on the System’s ability to control the ments based on a geographical classification of banks was
availability of member bank reserves, rather than on a inherited from the National Banking Act which specified
particular average level of prescribed reserve ratios.
reserve ratios, in increasing amounts, for three classes of
The average (weighted) reserve ratio for demand and banks: country, reserve city, and central reserve city
time deposits sets an upper limit on the deposit multiplier. banks. Prior to the enactment of the Federal Reserve Act,
However, attempts to define an optimal average reserve a specified portion of reserves could be held on deposit
ratio, or even to agree on criteria for determining it, have with banks in designated cities. Indeed, the rationale for
not been successful. Required reserves can perform their higher reserve requirements in reserve and central reserve
fulcrum function even when set at a relatively low level. cities was undermined by the provision in the Federal Re­
Arguments have been put forward in academic literature serve Act which required that reserves be deposited (after
in favor of large as well as small deposit multipliers.
a transition period) with the Federal Reserve and not with
other banks. The system of reserve requirements embodied
in the Federal Reserve Act linked reserve requirements to
assumed liquidity needs. The liquidity function of reserves,
in
turn, was related to location, because of the presumed
1 A summary of the amendments to Regulations D and J
greater exposure of banks in cities which served as clearing
appeared in this Review (July 1972), page 154.




202

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1972

centers to sudden and/or sizable deposit withdrawals.2
For all banks in cities designated as reserve cities the Act
imposed requirements that were higher than those for
country banks, and still higher ones for those in the
central reserve cities.3 After the transfer in 1917 of re­
serves of member banks to the Federal Reserve Banks,
the three-tier structure of ratios was justified on different
grounds, such as the smaller velocity or volatility of de­
mand deposits at country banks.
While the geographic principle had become outmoded
a long time ago, the existing system became more and
more anachronistic with the succeeding changes in banking
practices and advances in transportation and communica­
tions that have taken place over the years.4 It failed to ac­
cord equal treatment to banks that were similar in most
significant aspects of their activities but different in terms
of location, or to provide differential treatment reflecting a
bank’s place in the banking system as it affects the con­
duct of monetary policy. As a result, banks with virtually
identical net demand deposits and similar business have
been often subject to different reserve ratios. Specifically,
a number of large banks participating in the money mar­
ket and/or having extensive foreign operations through
branches or affiliated Edge Act corporations have con­
tinued to be classified as country banks because of their
location.
PAST CHANGES

While no comprehensive reform has been undertaken
since the passage of the original Federal Reserve Act,

2 On the history of minimum reserve requirements, see Phillip
Cagan, “The First Fifty Years of the National Banking System—
An Historical Appraisal” in Banking and Monetary Studies, Deane
Carson, ed. (Homewood, Illinois: 1963), notably the Figure 2
showing required, excess, and total reserve ratios of national
banks, 1865-1913.
Reserve requirements stipulated in some state banking laws
antedated those of the National Banking Act.
3 The Federal Reserve Act originally designated three central
reserve cities: New York, Chicago, and St. Louis. In 1922 St.
Louis was reclassified as a reserve city.
4 Irving M. Auerbach pointed out in “Reserve Requirements
of Commercial Banks”, this Review (July 1948), reprinted in an
updated and expanded version in this Bank’s publication Bank
Reserves (1953), that a proposal to base reserve requirements
on the class of deposits was advanced even before the Federal
Reserve Act was enacted. For a review of the earlier history of
reserve requirements, in addition to Auerbach’s article, see “The
History of Reserve Requirements for Banks in the United States”,
Federal Reserve Bulletin (November 1938), pages 953-72. See
also “Member Bank Reserve Requirements— Heritage from His­
tory,” Business Conditions (Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
June 1972.




there have been several changes in the definitions of de­
mand deposits subject to reserves as well as assets qualify­
ing as reserves, in reserve accounting, and in the struc­
ture of reserve requirements. The following may be con­
sidered the most significant:
(1) In 1935, reserve requirements were made
variable within specified ranges by giving the Board
of Governors the authority to increase the reserve
ratios up to double the ratios then in force.
(2) The next important change was in 1959,
when the Board of Governors was given broad dis­
cretionary powers to reclassify individual banks in
reserve cities as country banks, thus exempting
these banks from the higher reserve ratios attached
to the reserve city bank status; previously, only
banks in “outlying areas” could be so reclassified.
This change recognized the fact that banks located
in a reserve (or central reserve) city could differ
greatly in significant features, and these differences
were not necessarily systematically related either to
a bank’s size or its location within a city.
(3) Banks were permitted to count a portion of
their vault cash as a reserve asset in 1959; all vault
cash was permitted to be counted in 1962.
(4) The central reserve city classification was
abolished in 1962, thereby reducing the reserve
requirements to which twenty-two large banks
in New York City and Chicago were subject at that
time.
(5) The principle of graduation was introduced
in 1966, by establishing a higher reserve ratio for
time deposits other than savings deposits of over $5
million at any bank. In 1968, it was expanded by
raising requirements for net demand deposits above
$5 million, for country as well as reserve city banks.
(6) Lagged reserve accounting was introduced in
1968. Since then, reserve requirements against de­
mand and time deposits in any statement week have
been based on average deposit liabilities two weeks
earlier.
(7) Reserve requirements on borrowings from
foreign branches (or foreign banks) were introduced
in 1969, in the form of marginal requirements on
amounts above an exempt base figure. Reserve re­
quirements on commercial paper issued by bank affil­
iates, another nondeposit source of funds, became
effective in 1970.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

The introduction in 1935 of variable reserve require­
ments was widely hailed as a significant innovation in
techniques of monetary control; subsequently they were
adopted by many other countries. The actual use of reserve
requirements has varied with monetary conditions and
with the prevailing views within the System but, on the
whole, changes have been quite infrequent. Some of the
most notable episodes include the sharp (and contro­
versial) increase in requirements in 1936-37 to mop up
excess liquidity, the successive reductions in 1942 at
central reserve city banks from maximum levels to
facilitate bank absorption of war loans, the modest
increases in 1951 to cushion the initial impact of the
Korean war on bank credit,5 followed by gradual reduc­
tions from 1953 to 1966 to meet a widespread criticism
that requirements were at excessively high levels. The very
modest increases in 1968 and 1969 were related to over­
heated conditions in the economy, though no similar in­
creases had been made when the economy approached
cyclical peaks in the previous fifteen years. Yet, for both
classes of member banks, reserve ratios for demand de­
posits at the beginning of 1972 were not far from the
late-1930’s levels, a period when bank reserves were
considerably enlarged by gold inflows.
In the ten years (1949-58) following the immediate
postwar adjustment period, the lowering of reserve ratios
supported most of the deposit growth at member banks,
but in the following years the further growth of deposits
was supported mostly through open market operations.
The possibility of reducing reliance on open market
operations by making frequent changes of small percentage
amounts in reserve requirements has been explored, but
no experimentation along these lines has been undertaken
as open market operations have provided an effective
tool for implementing policy objectives. Indeed, monetary
policy was revived in the early fifties under conditions
which offered a unique opportunity to control reserves
through open market operations. The public debt was large
and widely distributed and was comprised largely of mar­
ketable securities with a wide range of maturities.
Thus, in recent years, there has been a clear tendency
to use the reserve tool sparingly. To be sure, reductions in
requirements were usually timed so as to be coordinated

203

with other moves to ease credit conditions and/or to meet
seasonal demands. On several occasions the possibility of
changing reserve requirements was considered, but no
action was taken. On the whole, the System seemed to
agree with Allan Sproul who, when president of the Fed­
eral Reserve Bank of New York, remarked that reserve
requirements were a “blunt instrument”. When reserve
ratios were changed, in most instances cushioning open
market operations were undertaken.
The respective advantages of the two means of supply­
ing and absorbing reserves have been the subject of study
and discussion within the System and also of lively debate
in academic journals.6 There was less interest among aca­
demic economists in devising a better system of reserve
requirements.7
REFORM PROPOSALS

Over the years the Board of Governors and several
committees of the Conference of Federal Reserve Bank
Presidents and of the System’s research function have con­
sidered and tested numerous ways of placing member
bank reserve requirements on a more logical footing and
of making them more flexible on either an automatic or a
discretionary basis. Numerous attempts were made to de­
velop an alternative system which, even though not ideal
or even wholly logical, would constitute a sufficiently de­
sirable improvement (without posing significant adminis­
trative problems) to warrant a request for appropriate
Congressional legislation.
Because of uniformity of reserve requirements on time
deposits for all classes of banks and because ratios have
consistently been considerably lower than those on de­
mand deposits (which resulted in about 80 percent of
aggregate reserve assets being held against demand
deposits), the System’s efforts to find an alternative sys­
tem have been focused on demand deposits alone. While

6 See, for instance, J. Ascheim, “Open-Market Operations versus
Reserve Requirement Variations”, Economic Journal, (December
1959); C. A. Thanos, “Open-Market Operations and the Portfolio
Policies of the Commercial Banks”, ibid. (September 1961); H. N.
Goldstein, “The Relative Security Market Impact of Open-Market
Sales and ‘Equivalent’ Reserve-Requirement Increases”, ibid. (Sep­
tember 1962); John H. Kareken, “On the Relative Merits of
Reserve-Ratio Changes and Open-Market Operations”, Journal of
Finance (March 1961).

5
The Board of Governors also exercised its power, granted
for a limited period by the Anti-Inflation Act of 1948, to raise
7 See, however, Frank E. Norton and Neil Jacoby, Bank D e­
reserve requirements above the statutory limit. It did not make
posits and Legal Reserve Requirements, UCLA (Los Angeles,
full use of these powers, which lapsed less than a year after they
1959) and Neil Jacoby, “The Structure and Use of Variable Bank
were enacted.
Reserve Requirements”, in Banking and Monetary Studies.




204

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1972

the need for legal reserve requirements on time deposits
was occasionally questioned both within and outside the
System, the various schemes considered focused on
demand deposits. Studies of alternative structures of
reserve requirements were, of course, limited by the prac­
tical considerations of public acceptance and the problems
of transition. It was clear that any alternative system should
permit effective control of bank deposit expansion. Further­
more, it was recognized that, in order to facilitate transi­
tion, a new plan should result in aggregate reserve liabili­
ties not much different from those held at the time by all
member banks combined. Various sets of ratios were
suggested and tested with this constraint in mind.
The history of endeavors to achieve a more equitable
and more defensible system of reserve requirements and
to reassess its role in relation to other instruments of
monetary control is a good example of the difficulty of
finding practical solutions to complex problems, of achiev­
ing a sufficiently broad agreement within the System when
the problem at hand has considerably different regional
aspects, and of the interplay between academic discussion
and internal System efforts.
Proposals for a more rational system of reserve ratios
proceeded along two lines. Earlier efforts had concentrated
on finding a substitute for the reserve city bank classifica­
tion by relating reserve requirements either to the rate of
activity (turnover velocity) of deposits or to the relative
importance of interbank deposits at a given bank. Differ­
ent reserve ratios on various classes of deposits were
proposed primarily on the presumption that different rates
of use of such deposits reflected significant differences in
the function of each class of deposits in our monetary
system. Higher reserve requirements on interbank de­
posits were proposed not so much on the basis of a theory
which justified them, but rather as a means of abandon­
ing the outmoded geographic classification without chang­
ing considerably the existing pattern of reserve liabilities
among individual banks and without lowering or raising
the aggregate volume of reserves by a significant amount.
Later endeavors concentrated on devising a system of
graduated reserve requirements that would apply to all
banks irrespective of location.
Attempts to devise a more rational system for distribut­
ing the burden of member bank reserve requirements go
back at least to 1931, when an elaborate study (by a Fed­
eral Reserve System committee chaired by W. Riefler)
resulted in a published report which served as the basis
for recommendations to the Congress, on which, however,
no action was taken. Since that time, the issue has come to
life intermittently. The Board of Governors discussed
many, but endorsed none, of the various proposals de­




veloped over the years by its own staff, by various System
committees, or outside the System.
When, after World War II, the banking situation reemerged little changed and with the war-generated liquid­
ity replacing the prewar influx of reserves from abroad,
consideration of the problem of reserve structure was
placed on the agenda again. In 1948 the Board presented
to the Joint Economic Committee, without endorsement,
a version of the “uniform reserve plan” .8 This plan, de­
veloped by Karl Bopp, then director of research of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, would have sup­
planted the geographic classification, in that different
ratios would apply to interbank and to other demand de­
posits. Under this plan, reserve requirements for demand
deposits could ultimately have been made completely
uniform merely by lowering the initially higher ratio on
interbank deposits.
A closely related plan would have related reserve re­
quirements directly to deposit velocity. It is likely that the
System did not formally endorse the velocity version of
the uniform reserve plan because no workable solution
could be foand to deal with the special situation of “stock­
yard banks”, which, although few in number, had some
importance and an association to defend their interests.
These banks, servicing primarily accounts maintained by
sellers and buyers at major cattle markets, held an excep­
tionally high amount of interbank deposits in relation to
demand deposits (up to 50 percent), and their deposits
had an exceedingly high velocity. There were other small
groups of banks which had similar characteristics, such as
banks in tobacco-auction centers. More importantly, the
association of velocity with certain relevant characteristics,
such as bank location, type of business, or structure of
deposit liabilities, was too erratic and too complex (some
of these characteristics being interrelated) to permit gen­
eralizations that could be used as a basis for an alternative
system of reserve requirements. There were, furthermore,
considerable doubts with regard to the theoretical under­
pinnings of the proposal.
Interest in a reform of reserve requirements was revived
in the early fifties as a result of continuing post-World
War II inflationary pressures, which were reinforced by
the outbreak of the Korean war. Also, System officials
recognized that over the longer run the System would have
to provide support for continuous deposit growth either
through an ever-growing scale of open market operations

8 See Credit Policies, Joint Economic Committee, 79th Congress,
Second Session (1948).

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

205

or, in part at least, by lowering average reserve require­ (even though a partially offsetting increase in reserve re­
ments.
quirements for country banks was made at the time), and
A variant of the velocity proposal was recommended establishing a lower reserve ratio on the first $5 million of
for consideration by the “Douglas Subcommittee” in demand (and also for “other time” ) deposits— all con­
1950,9 and was again discussed in 1952 in System replies tributed to improving the structure of reserve require­
to a questionnaire and in oral testimony in connection with ments. Liberal use of the discretionary authority to de­
the “Patman Subcommittee” inquiry.10 A committee of classify reserve city banks (as well as mergers) resulted
System economists studied the problem again in 1953-54 in a reduction of this group to only 179 by the time the
but, after producing numerous analyses and conducting new Regulation D was promulgated. While the Board had
discussions which revealed considerable differences of the power to designate new reserve cities (as well as to
views on several important issues, failed to agree on recom­ terminate such designation), no such actions were taken
mendations. Two proposals, which, in fact, represented after December 1965. Some quite large banks have re­
variants of the velocity plan, were circulated within the mained in the country bank category, including, for in­
stance in this District, several banks in Albany, the state
System in the following years.
In 1957, a committee of Federal Reserve Bank officers capital, and in Newark, New Jersey. On the other hand,
studied a report by an American Bankers Association three large and rapidly expanding suburban country banks,
committee which recommended moving toward a single by acquiring New York City banks through merger,
reserve ratio on all demand deposits. It rejected the velocity became subject to reserve city requirements.
Interest in a reform of reserve requirements acquired
approach and differential ratios for interbank deposits.
While endorsing a uniform reserve plan as the ultimate new urgency in recent years as withdrawals from member­
goal, it recommended that further studies be made to de­ ship became widespread in some Federal Reserve Dis­
termine the range within which the Board should have tricts. The System, of course, always has been aware of the
effect of reserve requirements on profits and on member­
the power to vary reserve ratios.
Subsequently, discussions within the System centered ship. Requirements imposed by state authorities are typi­
on a system of graduated reserve requirements put forward cally lower than those in force for member banks, and can
in April 1963 by the President’s Committee on Financial be satisfied in a less onerous manner. In particular, inter­
Institutions (known as the Heller Committee) but, even bank deposits held for business purposes can usually be
though a good deal of testing with a variety of sets of counted among eligible reserve assets. In some states, a
ratios and size brackets was undertaken, no urgency was proportion of reserves can be held in specified (usually
felt to find an immediate solution to the problem of re­ United States Treasury) securities. In the recent past,
some states have taken various steps to liberalize further
serve structure.
Every plan considered in the past would have resulted the reserve requirements for nonmember banks.
in increasing total reserve liabilities for some significant
group of banks; it was obvious that only a general lowering
T H E NEW SYSTEM
of average reserve ratios could avoid it.
The change which is to take effect for the reserve period
Nearly all proposals considered in the past required
changes in the Federal Reserve Act. For a variety of rea­ September 21 to September 27 is thus the result of a
sons, the System has been reluctant to recommend for­ forty-year search to find a workable solution for a situa­
mally new legislation to reform reserve requirements, tion which, in fact, antedated the creation of the Federal
or else concluded that chances for passage were too Reserve System. By redefining reserve city banks on the
slim to try. In the meantime, liberal interpretation of basis of net deposit size, it abolishes the geographic prin­
the authority to reclassify banks in reserve cities as coun­ ciple through administrative action within the framework
try banks, permitting use of vault cash as a reserve asset of existing legislation.
The uniform treatment of all member banks, irrespec­
tive of location, will be achieved under the revised Regula­
tion D by applying a uniform set of graduated reserve
ratios to all member banks and by defining reserve cities
9 M onetary, Credit and Fiscal Policies, Joint Economic Com­
other than those with Federal Reserve offices as a func­
mittee, 81st Congress, Second Session (1950).
tion of the net demand deposit size of the largest mem­
10 Monetary Policy and the Management of the Public Debt,
ber
bank located in a given city. Every city with a bank
Joint Economic Committee, 82nd Congress, Second Session
having net demand deposits of over $400 million will
(1952).




206

MONTHLY REVIEW, AUGUST 1972

automatically become a reserve city. However, country
bank status will be granted to all banks located in such a
city having net demand deposits of $400 million or less.
A number of centers (none in this District) will lose the
reserve city designation because even their largest banks
will be reclassified as country banks, and a few centers
(probably Albany in this District) will become reserve cities.
With the passage of time, more banks now in the country
bank category will reach the demand deposit size that
will shift them automatically into the reserve city bank
category. In fact, however, the reserve city-country bank
distinction will lose much of its meaning. A borderline
bank would be considered a reserve city bank only for the
reserve periods when its demand deposits subject to re­
serves exceed $400 million. The provisions in the Federal
Reserve Act relating to these two classifications will merely
continue to set an upper and lower limit for graduated
reserve ratios that can be imposed within the range stipu­
lated in the Federal Reserve Act as amended in 1935.
The revised Regulation D establishes five net demand
deposit-size brackets, with reserve ratios ranging from 8
to H V 2 percent and which apply cumulatively. More than
4,200 member banks will henceforth be subject to the firstand second-bracket ratios only, which will reduce signifi­
cantly reserve liabilities for each of them.
The lowest reserve ratio (8 percent) applies to the first
$2 million of net demand deposits, instead of the 12V^
percent ratio now in force for country banks. For the fol­
lowing tranche, between $2 million and $10 million, the
reserve ratio is 10 percent, still substantially below the
average ratios formerly in force for this deposit size (12V^
percent applying to deposits of $5 million and under, and
13 percent for amounts exceeding $5 million). A bank with
net demand deposits of $10 million will be subject to an
average reserve ratio of only 9.6 percent, and the ratio is
smaller for banks below this size. Given the average rela­
tionship between net demand deposits, time deposits, cash
items in process of collection, and capital funds, a bank
with $10 million in net demand deposits would typically
have a balance sheet of about $25 million.
The reserve ratio for net demand deposits in excess of
$10 million, but less than $100 million, will be 12 per­
cent. A reserve ratio of 13 percent (formerly applicable
to net demand deposits in excess of $5 million at country
banks) will apply to deposits in excess of $100 million and
up to $400 million (with a \6Vi percent ratio applicable
in the transitional week on deposits at existing reserve city
banks which now are subject to a 11V2 percent reserve
requirement).
Institutions formerly classified as country banks with
net demand deposits of $400 million or less benefit from




the new system to the extent that the first $100 million of
such deposits are now subject to an average ratio of 11.76
percent instead of 12.98 percent, as formerly. This reduc­
tion is quite significant for banks with net demand deposits
in excess of $10 million, but for a country bank with de­
posits at the upper limit the reduction of reserve liabilities
(by $1,215,000) is fairly small, only about two cents for
each dollar of reserves now required.
The reduction under the new regulation is also signifi­
cant for the fewer than sixty institutions which will continue
to be classified as reserve city banks, even though their net
demand deposits in excess of $400 million will continue
to be subject to a HV 2 percent reserve ratio— the same
ratio as now applicable to net demand deposits at such
banks in excess of $5 million. Banks in this category are
benefiting from a reduction in their reserve liabilities
against the first $400 million; the reduction amounts to
$19,215,000 for each bank, irrespective of size. Again, the
relative value of this reduction for members continuing in
the reserve city bank classification is the greatest (about
27 percent of the liabilities prior to the revision) at the
lower limit of the bracket, that is, for banks with total
assets of about $1 billion, but diminishes rapidly for the
giant money market banks. The only institutions that are
experiencing an increase in their reserve liabilities are four
or five banks being shifted from the country to the reserve
city bank classification.
It is estimated that the revised Regulation D will reduce
reserve requirements by about $3.4 billion, or approxi­
mately $1.4 billion more than the estimated loss resulting
from the change in Regulation J. The prospective shrinkage
of float as a result of same-day payment occasioned by the
revision of Regulation J which will also become effective
September 21 is expected to reduce member bank reserves
by approximately $2 billion on average.
There is no sure way of knowing to what extent the
reduced reserve liability will offset, or more than offset,
the loss of Federal Reserve float (and thus of reserves)
experienced by each given member bank, although the
various Federal Reserve Banks have endeavored to obtain
as complete an analysis of their situation as possible from
the individual member banks. Some banks may reap a con­
siderable advantage from changes in Regulation D, while
losing little from the change in Regulation J; but the oppo­
site case is likely to occur quite frequently. Also, the re­
duction of reserve liabilities will become effective on a
single date, while additional losses of float may result from
a number of changes in the collection mechanism beyond
the establishment of additional county or regional clearing
arrangements, not all of which are directly related to the
current change in Regulation J. Even the effects of changes

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK

resulting from the revision of Regulation J may take some
time to work themselves out.
The new version of Regulation D removes, in effect, the
anachronistic basis for the structure of reserve require­
ments, but the much-delayed reform is becoming effective
at a time when the banking system is undergoing what
might well be the most profound changes in its history.
Indeed, the most conspicuous developments— liabilities
management and formation of multibank holding com­
panies— are only two of a wide range of changes that
are profoundly affecting the environment in which banks
operate. The relationship of deposits to other categories
of short-term assets and liabilities and of commercial
banks to other categories of financial institutions are
also undergoing important changes, as are banking prac­
tices and policies. The geographic area of operations open
to individual banks is widening in many states, and the
diversification of services which individual banks or holding
companies are able or willing to offer is growing. On the
other hand, a variety of influences, including the generally
less onerous burden of reserve requirements in almost all
states, has resulted in a decline in membership and a result­
ing shrinkage of the percentage of total demand deposits
held by member banks.
Clearly, revisions in Regulations D and J, taken to­
gether, represent a significant change in operating condi­
tions for member banks. It remains to be seen what their
effect will be on the collection mechanism and on banking
structure. For instance, the graduated structure of reserve
requirements might favor the holding company route over

mergers as a means of banking growth.
The new Regulation D leaves room for subsequent
moves toward more complete uniformity in reserve ratios.
Under existing legislation a single ratio could be set
within the range of 10 and 14 percent. The desirability
of making identical reserve requirements applicable to all
commercial banks, irrespective of membership,11 continues
to be debated. A good case can be made for extending
reserve requirements to all short-term liabilities at all
depository institutions or at least at all commercial banks
—particularly if some of the developments that are taking
place or are being widely discussed further blur the distinc­
tion of demand accounts of commercial banks from other
short-term liabilities, or reduce considerably the unique
role of banks in the payments mechanism.12 Questions also
have been raised as to whether, by substituting (with
proper adjustment in reserve ratios) gross for net demand
deposits as the basis for assessing bank liabilities, addi­
tional simplification and uniformity could be achieved.

11 The Board o f Governors of the Federal Reserve System has
requested legislation along these lines in several of its Annual
Reports since 1964.
12 The President’s Commission on Financial Structure and
Regulation has recommended in its Report of December 22, 1971
that membership in the Federal Reserve System be made manda­
tory not only for all state-chartered commercial banks but also
for all savings and loan associations and mutual savings banks that
offer third-party payment services (with identical reserve ratios
becoming applicable after a transitional period).

Subscriptions to the m o n t h l y r e v i e w are available to the public without charge. Additional
copies of recent issues may be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve
Bank of New York, 33 Liberty Street, New York, N.Y. 10045.
Persons in foreign countries may request that copies of the m o n t h l y r e v i e w be sent to
them by “air mail-other articles”. The postage charge amounts to approximately half the price of
regular air mail and is payable in advance. Requests for this service and inquiries about rates should
be directed to the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 33 Liberty
Street, New York, N.Y. 10045.




207