View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

The European Monetary System
Securities losses—a liquidity trap?
Business loans at large commercial
banks: policies and practices
Index for 1979

The European Monetary
System
CONTENTS

3

The European Monetary System—a
new exPeriment in international monetary
cooperation—was launched by nine
members of the European Economic
Community in March 1979.

Securities losses— a liquidity
trap?

11

Although banks are facing increased
funding problems, there has been no
reduction in their holdings of securities.
November/December 1979, Volume III, Issue 6

ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVES
Single-copy subscriptions of Economic
Perspectives, a bimonthly review, are
available free of charge. Please send requests
for single- and multiple-copy subscriptions,
back issues, and address changes to Public
Information Center, Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, P. O. Box 834, Chicago, Illinois
60690, or telephone (312) 322-5112.
Articles may be reprinted provided
source is credited and Public Information
Center is provided with a copy of the
published material.
Controlled circulation postage
paid at Chicago, Illinois.




Business loans at large com­
mercial banks: policies and
practices

15

An examination of loans by large
banks to businesses other than financial
institutions reflects the recent directions in
bank lending policy.

Index for 1979

23

The European Monetary System
Neil ). Pinsky and Joseph G. Kvasnicka
In March 1979, nine major European coun­
tries, members of the European Economic
Community, launched a new experiment in
international monetary cooperation—the
European Monetary System. The system con­
sists of a number of special arrangements, in­
cluding a composite common currency unit
similar in structure to the Special Drawing
Rights of the International Monetary Fund,
detailed rules for the maintenance of relative­
ly fixed exchange rates between currencies
of the member countries, and an intricate
network of mutual credit facilities that will be
ultimately administered by an EC super­
national monetary authority. This article
traces the historical development of the new
system, looks at the details of the underlying
arrangements, and evaluates its significance.
Historical background

The launching of the European Monetary
System represents yet another step toward
close economic cooperation between Euro­
pean nations in the post-World War II period.
The first steps in that direction were taken in
1950 with the establishment of the European
Payments Union that was designed to
facilitate settlements of international trade
transactions between European countries. In
1951, efforts to promote trade relations
between the European nations through
removal of trade barriers led to the creation of
the European Coal and Steel Community. Un­
der the arrangement, Germany, France,
Belgium, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, and
Italy dismantled restrictions on the move­
ment of raw steel and coal. The European Coal
and Steel Community provided a nucleus for
the establishment of the European Economic

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago



Community in 1957. The Treaty of Rome sign­
ed by the six nations comprising the European
Coal and Steel Community established a
framework of cooperation toward the ul­
timate goal of unrestricted movements of
goods, services, capital—and people—
between the member nations as a means of
increasing the standard of living and political
stability of the area. The European Economic
Community or the EC, as it has come to be
known, made great strides over the years of its
existence toward the goals of economic and
political integration. The intra-EC tariffs were
gradually phased out and common tariffs
applicable to trade with non-EC countries
were established. A common agricultural
policy aimed at stabilization of prices and en­
couragement of trade in agricultural com­
modities within the EC was established. Un­
der the auspices of the European Parliament,
common budgetary policies are being
developed, and common standards in patents
and other legal matters are being established.
The goal of establishing a monetary
union within the European Community was
first approved at a conference of national
leaders in 1969. The plan called for the com­
pletion of the union by 1980, with a common
currency. This was to be achieved by gradual­
ly narrowing the extent of day-to-day fluc­
tuations in the exchange values of individual
EC countries' currencies in terms of each
other. Once the exchange values were
stabilized and maintained fixed, it would be a
mere technicality to “ convert" individual
national currencies into a common unit. It
was hoped that the stability of exchange rates
of the currencies of the member countries
would be an important stimulant for trade
among them, and (particularly after the goal

3

of the common currency has been achieved)
that it would cement the evolving close
economic, political, and social ties between
them.
The EC blueprint for progress toward the
goal of fixed and stable exchange rates
between the member countries was drawn
within an already existing framework of
relatively fixed exchange rates worldwide.
The Bretton Woods international monetary
system, which was still in existence at that
time, required all participating countries to
maintain exchange rates of their currencies
within 1 percent of the declared par value in
terms of the U.S. dollar. By this arrangement,
the exchange rates of the EC currencies were
held within 2 percent of each other. Progress
toward complete stability called for in the EC
blueprint appeared fairly easy from this van­
tage point. However, in 1971, the Bretton
Woods System collapsed, and the new inter­
national monetary arrangements that were
agreed upon by representatives of IMF
member nations after months of intensive
negotiations in December 1971 at the
Smithsonian Institution in Washington allow­
ed for a much wider range of fluctuation. All
currencies were permited to fluctuate within
a 41/2 percent band relative to the dollar. This
meant that the EC currencies would fluctuate
relative to each other within a total spread of 9
percent.
In order to return to the path toward
stability of their exchange rates, Belgium, Lux­
embourg, France, Italy, the Netherlands, and
West Germany entered into a European Joint
Float agreement in April 1972. The arrange­
ment became known as “ the snake." Shortly
after the launching of the snake arrangement
by the six, four at that time non-EC countries
(Denmark, Ireland, Norway, and the United
Kingdom) joined in. Under that arrangement,
the exchange rates of the snake-member
currencies were to be rrfaintained within a 21A
percent spread, and were allowed to move
jointly within the 41/2 percent limits establish­
ed by the international agreement. The 41
/2
percent limit for the joint “ twists of the
snake" became known as the “ tunnel." The
European monetary arrangement thus ac­

4




quired the name the “ snake in the tunnel."1
In the day-to-day functioning of the
snake, the exchange rates of the participating
members' currencies were maintained within
prescribed limits by official intervention in
the foreign exchange markets. For example,
as the value of one member's currency would
begin to rise on the world's exchange markets
due to a strong commercial or specu lative de­
mand for that currency, one or a combination
of the following measures had to be taken:
One, the member whose currency was rising
would meet the market demand for its
currency by purchasing dollars with its own
currency. The resulting increase in supply
would reduce the upward pressure on the ex­
change rate. Two, the central banks of the
other snake countries would meet the
market's demand for that one member's
currency by selling it against their own
currencies. The currency sold would be
typically acquired by them through borrow­
ing on a short-term basis from the central
bank of the member whose currency was ris­
ing. This, as well as the third alternative, which
involved selling dollars against their own
currencies from their reserves, would cause
their currencies to rise jointly against the U.S.
dollar and the rest of the world currencies.
However, the extent of the joint rise of the
snake currencies would be limited by the41
/2
percent limit set by the international
monetary arrangement. Thus, as the snake
currencies would jointly approach the ceiling
of the tunnel, members would be required to
moderate their joint rise relative to the dollar
by purchasing dollars with their own curren­
cies. A precisely opposite set of measures
would be called for when one member's
currency would begin to decline in value.
1
The Dutch and the Belgians entered into a special
supplementary arrangement with respect to the ex­
change rates of their currencies that reflected the par­
ticularly close relationship between the econom ies of
these two countries. They agreed to maintain the value of
the Belgian franc and the Dutch guilder within a 1 per­
cent band relative to each other and to move jointly
within the 2Vapercent band established by the snake rela­
tive to other participating EC currencies. The DutchBelgian arrangement became known as the "w orm ,” and
the European monetary arrangement was known as “ the
worm within the snake within the tunnel.”

Economic Perspectives

After several weeks of relatively smooth
functioning, the snake came under severe
pressures as the basic economic forces that
typically underlie the movements in ex­
change rates began to assert themselves. In
early June 1972, the exchange rate of the
British pound came under heavy downward
pressure due to internal labor unrest that
threatened further deterioration of the coun­
try's already poor balance-of-payment posi­
tion. As the pound was pressed down by com­
mercial orders to sell, the Bank of England and
the other central banks of the snake countries
tried desperately to hold the pound's ex­
change rate within the snake's skin by official
intervention. However, the market pressures
proved stronger than the central banks'
resolve. After several days of turmoil in the
foreign exchange markets, the effort to main­
tain the pound sterling within the snake was
abandoned; the currency was officially
withdrawn and permitted to float freely.
Market pressures quickly shifted to the
Danish krone. After several days of vain ef­
forts to support it, the krone, too, was forced
out of the snake's skin. Italy was forced to
withdraw under similar circumstances in early
1973, shortly before market pressures on the
U.S. dollar caused a complete collapse of the
Smithsonian agreement. The remaining snake
members continued their effort to maintain
the arrangement, functioning in the environ­
ment of freely floating exchange rates that
followed the collapse of the Smithsonian
tunnel. However, divergent economic con­
ditions in the member countries made the
sought-after stability of exchange rates an ex­
ceedingly elusive goal. Currencies were
forced out of the snake by recurring market
p re s s u re s , and revaluations and/or
devaluations of individual members' curren­
cies had to be undertaken to keep the
battered snake alive.
Launching of the EMS

The brief history of the efforts of the EC
countries to provide for stability of the ex­
change rates of their currencies was a stormy

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago




one, as the achievement of the ideal of ECwide stability and unity came under repeated
attacks of centrifugal forces of economic
realities. But the ideal of exchange rate stabili­
ty as a means to closer political and economic
unification of the community persisted. This,
together with the growing frustration of
Europeans with the worldwide floating ex­
change rate regime in general and the volatili­
ty of the U.S. dollar in particular, kept the
search alive.
In July 1978, a plan for a new European
monetary system was presented to and was
approved by the heads of state of the nine EC
member countries. The launching date was
set for January 2,1979, but a last minute post­
ponement was made necessary by strife
within the EC over certain related aspects of
the EC's common agricultural policy.
The system was finally launched in March
1979. Seven of the nine EC members—
Belgium , D enm ark, France, Germany,
Ireland, Luxembourg, and the Netherlands—
became full participants. Italy decided to par­
ticipate under modified conditions, and the
United Kingdom, while becoming a member
of the EMS, elected not to participate in all the
arrangements.
The following are the main features of
the new system:
The European Currency Unit (ECU). A
newly created monetary unit, the ECU is the
linchpin of the new system. The ECU does not
exist in the physical sense that currencies of
individual countries do. It does serve,
however, as a monetary asset that par­
ticipating central banks can hold as reserves.
The central banks can also loan and borrow
the unit, and it can be used in settling debts
between them. Though use of the unitwill be
limited initially to countries participating in
the EMS, it is expected that the ECU could
serve eventually as an international reserve
asset similar to the Special Drawing Rights
issued by the International Monetary Fund
and held and used by central banks
worldwide.
In addition to its monetary function, the
ECU will serve an accounting function, its

5

value providing a benchmark against which
the central rates of individual currencies of
the EMS members will be established. Thus, at
the inception of the EMS, each of the par­
ticipating countries formally defined the
value of its currency in terms of the number of
units of that currency one ECU would “ buy."
Valuation of individual currencies in
terms of the ECU serves two purposes: (1) it
establishes a “ central rate" for every currency
in terms of other currencies, these relative
rates forming a “ bilateral grid" of exchange
rates linking all EMS currencies; (2) it provides
reference points for establishing a “ threshold
of divergence" that, once reached, will create
a presumption for members to take specific
economic measures.
In purely technical terms, the ECU is a
composite unit consisting of the EC member
currencies. It has been defined as the
equivalent of the sum of: 3.66 Belgian francs,

0.217 Danish kroner, 1.15 French francs,
0.00759 Irish pounds, 109 Italian lire, 0.14 Lux­
embourg francs, 0.286 Dutch guilders, 0.0885
British pounds, and 0.828 German marks.
The weights assigned to each currency in
the basket are derived from the relative GNP
of each member country and that country's
share in intra-European trade. The weights
will be reexamined every five years, or if the
relative value of any currency changes by 25
percent, the weights will be reexamined on
request.
In terms of the dollar, the unit is worth
about $1.40. The dollar value can be cal­
culated by multiplying the current dollar
“ price" (the exchange rate) of the individual
EC currencies by the weights of these curren­
cies in the ECU valuation basket. This dollar
value will, of course, vary from day to day with
fluctuations in the exchange rates of the Euro­
pean currencies relative to the dollar.

“ Bilateral grid" of the Central Rates of the EMS currencies
(Based on their par values in terms of the ECU as of March 13, 1979)
Value p e r/ ln terms
unit o f /
of

Bel./Lux.
franc

G erm an
mark

Dutch
guilder

Danish
krone

French
franc

Italian
lira

Irish
pound

0.0172

0.06506

G erm an mark

—

.07050

0.1836

0.1503

30.85

0.06363

.06895

0.17958

0.14695

29.1

0.0168

0.06220

Bel./Lux. franc

.06740

0.1755

0.1436

27.35

0.01642

1.1081

2.8859

2.3615

484.7

0.2698

1.0837

2.8224

2.3095

457.3

0.2639

7.0593

2.7589

2.2575

429.9

0.2580

2.6630

2.1790

447.3

0.2490

2.6044

2.1311

422.0

0.2435

2.5458

1.9832

396.7

0.2380

0.8367

171.7

0.09560

—

0.8183

162.0

0.0935

0.7999

152.3

0.0893

209.9

0.7769

16.0700

15.7164

—

15.3628

0.9020

5.6938

0.36228

0.3926

5.5685

0.35431

0.38397

5.4432
French franc

0.9435

0.92277

14.1763
Danish krone

14.8289

14.5026

Dutch guilder

0.34634

0.3753

6.9582

0.4427

0.4798

—

1.2496

198.0

0.1143

186.1

0.7777

6.8051

1.2221

0.4586

1.1946

0.0365

0.00232

0.00251

0.00654

0.00535

0.00219

0.00237

0.00617

0.00505

0.0323

0.00206

0.00223

0.00580

0.00475

60.8869

3.8742

4.1984

10.9341

8.9472

59.5471

3.7889

4.1060

10.6935

8.7503

1,732.7

58.2073

Irish pound

0.4692

0.4320

0.0344

Italian lira

0.4330

6.6520

3.7036

4.0136

10.4529

8.5534

1,628.7

—

0.000612
—

0.000577
0.000542

1,836.7
—

Note: The bold face numbers are the Central Rates of the currency in the left hand column in terms of the currency on the
top of each column. The italicized numbers are the maximum permitted deviations above and below the Central Rate.

6




Economic Perspectives

The Bilateral Grid is used in the day-today operations of the EMS and is the same as
in the snake. Each country must try to main­
tain the value of its currency relative to others
in the EMS by intervening in foreign ex­
change markets when the exchange rate of its
currency is pushed by the underlying market
forces toward the maximum permitted devia­
tion. In principle, the country with a currency
that appreciates 2Va percent (6 percent for Ita­
ly) above the central rate of another EMS
currency established by the bilateral grid will
be required to intervene in foreign exchange
markets to alter the supply and demand con­
ditions causing the appreciation.
The Threshold of Divergence. A new
p ro visio n , called the ''threshold of
divergence," is designed to guard against
conditions that recurred under the snake
arrangement and were a source of discord
among the members. These conditions arose
when the value of one member's currency
was pushed up on the world's foreign ex­
change market because of either internal
developments in that member's economy or
speculative pressures in the foreign exchange

deficits and to domestic unemployment.
The threshold of divergence feature built
into the new EMS is intended to prevent such
developments. As the currency of one EMS
member is pushed by internal or external
economic developments out of line with the
exchange rates of other member countries,
the threshold-of-divergence safeguard is
triggered. Once this happens, the other
countries are no longer required to “ follow
the leader" as far as their exchange rate
policies are concerned. Rather, it is entirely
up to the government of the member country
whose currency is out of line to bring the
exchange rate back in line through unilateral
corrective measures designed to eliminate
the market pressures causing the deviation.
Here is how the trigger mechanism is in­
tended to work. As explained above, the ex­
ternal value of the new common currency
unit, the ECU, is defined as a weighted
average of the external values of individual
member currencies. Under thisarrangement,
as EMS currencies rise (or fall), jointly in value
relative to the dollar, the external value of the
ECU in terms of the dollar rises (or falls). This
leaves the central rates of the EMS member

market. The other members had been re­

currencies undisturbed in terms of the ECU,

quired to follow the upward trend, at times to
the detriment of their own economies.
Because of a large surplus in Germany's
international trade accounts, for example, the
exchange rate of the mark would rise relative
to the dollar on world exchange markets. The
rise in the value of the mark was part of a nor­
mal adjustment that would eventually lead to
the elimination of Germany's trade surplus
through increases in the prices of German
goods in terms of foreign currencies. As the
mark rose, however, other member countries
were obliged to intervene in the foreign ex­
change markets to maintain the required
relationship of the exchange rates of their
currencies relative to the mark. In effect, their
currencies rose with the mark relative to the
dollar. The resulting appreciation of their
currencies relative to the dollar and other
non-snake member currencies was under­
mining their ability to export and, in many in­
stances, led to a worsening of their trade

and no action is necessary.
If, however, the value of only one
member's currency rises (or falls) the
weighted average is influenced only
marginally, depending on the weight of the
currency that is moving. As a result, the exter­
nal value of the ECU remains relatively stable,
as the ECU basket is anchored by the stability

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago



Par V alues and the “ Th resho ld s of D iv e rg e n ce ” of the EMS
c u rre n cie s in term s of the European C u rre n cy Unit

(as of March 13, 1979)
Lo w er
“ T h re sh o ld
o f D iv e rg e n c e ’’

Par
value

U p p er
“ Thre sh o ld
o f D ive rg e n c e ”

B e l.-L u x . franc

40.0619

39.4582

38.8545

G e rm a n mark

2.53907

2.51064

2.48221

D utch g uild e r

2.76179

2.72077

2.67975

D anish k ro n e

7.20177

7.08592

6.97007

Fren ch franc

5.87659

5.79831

5.72003

Italian lira

1194.91

1148.15

1101.39

Irish p ound

0.67367

0.66264

0.65160

7

of the other members' currencies. The ex­
change rate of the currency that is singularly
rising (or falling) against the other exchange
rates is now also deviating from its ECU
central value.
When the rate deviates by 1.69 percent
(4.5 percent for Italy) from its ECU value, the
threshold of divergence is reached. The
authorities must adopt domestic economic
policies to stop further drift. Alternatively,
they must officially revalue or devalue their
currency.
Supporting Credit Facilities. In carrying
out market intervention in support of their
currencies, EMS members can use their
foreign exchange reserves (primarily dollars)
or they can avail themselves of special credit
facilities. The special credit facilities have
been available to EC countries participating in
the predecessor to the EMS, the snake, but
they were expanded to meet the needs of the
EMS. These facilities include three types of
credits structured by the maturity of the
“ loans."
The first tier consists of almost unlimited
amounts of members' currencies that can be
borrowed from other participants in the EMS
to carry out market intervention. Such loans
are available to members for up to 45 days
following the end of the month they were
made. The loans can be extended, within
limits, up to three months.
The second tier consists of credits for
three to six months, which can be extended to
nine months. The amounts that can be
borrowed are limited by the size of the pool
of credit (about 14 billion ECUs) and by the
member's quota, which is determined, in
turn, by the relative size of the member's
economy. This quota also determines the
member's access to the medium-term finan­
cial assistance, which is for a term of two to
five years. The third-tier pool of funds totals
about 11 billion ECUs. However, borrowing
under this facility will be conditional on the
member's willingness to follow internal
economic policies that will reduce the
domestic problems that gave rise to the need
to borrow.

8



The European Monetary Cooperation
Fund (EMCF). This institution was set up to

adm inister
the various EMS credit
arrangements. When a country borrows a
currency for intervention, its debt is
denominated in ECUs. The debtor country
can repay the debt either in the currency it
borrowed or in ECUs. A creditor country,
however, does not have to accept more than
half the repayment in the form of ECUs. The
rest of the repayment can be made in the
currency borrowed or acceptable inter­
national reserves, such as dollars or gold.
Countries that hold more ECUs than their
quotas will be paid interest on their excess
holdings. Countries that hold fewer ECUs
than their quotas will be charged interest on
their deficiencies. The interest rate will be
equal to the weighted average of the discount
rates of the EMS countries. To create an initial
supply of ECUs, central banks deposited 20
percent of their gold and dollar reserves with
the EMCF and received an equivalent amount
of ECUs. Until establishment of the EMCF is
formally approved by the legislative bodies of
the individual countries participating in the
EMS, the deposits will be in the form of
revolving three-month swaps.
Functioning of the EMS

The EMS was launched in March 1979
amid hopes of greater monetary stability be­
tween the members. Only a few weeks later,
however, problems began to surface in the
form of upward pressure on the exchange
rate of the German mark relative to the U.S.
dollar. To counter the mark's rise, monetary
authorities in Germany sold marks against
dollars in the foreign exchange markets.
Despite the intervention, the value of the
mark kept rising. Other EMS members were
required by the rules of the EMS to intervene
in their foreign exchange markets to keep the
exchange rates of their currencies in step with
the mark.
The intervention by German monetary
authorities on behalf of the mark relative to
the dollar and the intervention of the other
EMS members on behalf of their currencies

Economic Perspectives

relative to the mark were adding to Ger­
many's domestic money supply, threatening
to fuel further the already rising inflation rate
in Germany. To counter this threat, German
authorities moved to tighten domestic credit
conditions by raising the central bank dis­
count rate. However, higher interest rates
began attracting additional foreign funds to
Germany from the Eurodollar market as well
as from other EMS countries. This further
aggravated the pressure on exchange rates
both in Germany and in the other EMS coun­
tries. To alleviate these pressures, the other
EMS countries were forced to boost their in­
terest rates repeatedly even though their
sluggish domestic economic conditions
called for an easier monetary policy.
The scenario was reminiscent of the one
that plagued the functioning of the snake—
yet was unfolding under the new EMS that
was presumably structured to be immune to
it. It was precisely this scenario that the
threshold of divergence mechanism of the
EMS was supported to protect the system
against. Where did the "fail-safe" system of
the EMS fail?
In part, the failure was due to technical
difficulties with the threshold of divergence
mechanism. Since early summer, the British
pound and the Italian lira were rising sharply
in value relative to the U.S. dollar and other
currencies. Although the United Kingdom
does not participate in the exchange rate
maintenance scheme of the EMS, and
although Italy is only loosely associated, they
are both full members of the EMS, and the ex­
ternal values of their currencies are used in
computing the value of the ECU. Thus, the
rise in the external value of their currencies
caused the external value of the ECU to rise.
This, in effect, moved the anchor point of the
system upward, and the rising German mark
remained technically within the stipulated
threshold of divergence relative to the ECU, a
threshold that once reached would have
automatically forced Germany to take uni­
lateral measures to bring the mark into line
with the other EMS currencies. The upward
drift in the ECU, resulting largely from
developments outside the exchange rate

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago



History of the Snake
1972
April 24 The snake arrangement launched.
May 1 United Kingdom and Denmark join.
May 23 Norway joins.
June 23 United Kingdom withdraws.
June 27 Denmark withdraws.
Oct. 10 Denmark rejoins.
1973
Feb. 13 Italy withdraws.
March 19 Mark revalued 3 percent; general
float begins, with snake no longer constrained
by the tunnel.
April 3 European Monetary Cooperation Fund
established to support snake.
June 29 Mark revalued 5.5 percent.
Sept. 17 Guilder revalued 5.5 percent.
Nov. 16 Norwegian krone revalued 5 percent.
1974
Jan. 19 France withdraws.
1975
July 10 France rejoins.
1976
March 15 France withdraws.
Oct. 18 D a n is h k r o n e d e v a lu e d 4 p e rc e n t,
Norwegian krone and Swedish krona devalued
1 percent, mark revalued 2 percent.
1977
Apr. 4 Swedish krona devalued 6 percent,
Danish and Norwegian kroner devalued 3 per­
cent.
Aug. 28 Sweden withdraws, and Norwegian
and Danish kroner devalued by 5 percent.
1978
Feb. 10 Norwegian krone devalued 8 percent.
Oct. 16 German mark revalued 2 percent,
Danish and Norwegian kroner devalued 2 per­
cent.
Dec. 12 Norway withdraws.

adjustm ent process, neutralized the
mechanism, leaving the burden of adjust­
ment with weaker currencies.
For three months, between June and
September, the participants in the EMS

9

wrestled with the problem of reconciling
their domestic economic objectives with the
conflicting dictates of the EMS. The impass
was finally broken in early September, when
the British pound weakened sharply in the
foreign exchange markets. The declining ex­
ternal value of the pound led to a reduction in
the external value of the ECU, since thatvalue
is a weighted average of the values of the EC
currencies. With the external value of the
ECU down by definition, the ECU valueof the
German mark rose. This finally triggered the
threshold of divergence feature of the EMS,
leading to a 2 percent revaluation of the Ger­
man mark and a 3 percent devaluation of the
Danish krone, the weakest member of the
EMS.
While the exchange rate adjustments
represented a departure from the hoped-for
stability of exchange rates within the EC, they
at least alleviated internal pressures within the
EMS—not for long, however. In a few weeks,
new pressures began to surface. Continued
concern in Germany over incipient inflation
led to further tightening of monetary policy in
that country. Interest rates in Germany rose,
and other EMS members were forced to
nudge their interest rates up as protective
measures.
The pressures of rising interest rates were
felt most keenly in Denmark, whose currency
continued close to the floor of the EMS
despite the September devaluation. The of­
ficial discount rate was increased 2 percent in
late October, but the pressure continued. The
central bank was forced to intervene heavily
to keep the exchange rate within the
prescribed limits. Finally, in late November,
the krone was devalued by 5 percent and a
package of economic measures was in­
troduced, designed to bring Denmark’s un­
derlying domestic conditions more in line
with its EC partners. At the same time, the
Netherlands further boosted its discount rate
as a protective measure against the pressures
on its currency that were expected as a conse­
quence of Denmark’s action. It is still not
clear how effective these measures will be in
preventing further exchange rate ad­
justments within the EMS.

10




Conclusion

It is generally believed that stable ex­
change rates between currencies of the EC
member countries will encourage their
economic interaction, paving the way for a
closer economic and political union. The
snake and the subsequently more elaborate
European Monetary System represent the
mechanism through which countries of the
European Community hope to achieve that
goal. Exchange rates, however, are only the
tip of the iceberg. Hidden underneath are
myriads of intricate economic relationships
that must be satisfied for a free market to
produce a stable relationship between the ex­
change rates. Divergent trends in economic
developments and divergent economic
policies that reflect divergent social values are
invariably reflected in divergent exchange
rates. The forces of the free market will not
bow to the will of kings and prime ministers—
nor to the confines of man-made
mechanisms!
The snake, the predecessor to the EMS,
was plagued with problems because the
member countries generally pursued in­
dependent policies that reflected their own
economic priorities. While the EMS incor­
porates features that force countries to make
adjustments intended to correct the
divergences, it remains to be seen whether
these innovations will be sufficient to achieve
that goal.
Other problems may also arise. For exam­
ple, to the extent that the countries with
higher inflation rates adjust their economic
policy to conform with those of low-inflation
countries, the EMS would result in a slowing
in economic growth in Europe. If the lowinflation countries make the adjustments,
inflation will increase in Europe.
The success or failure of the EMS will
ultimately depend on the willingness of
European countries to sacrifice their own
divergent economic objectives for the sake of
stable exchange rates. Whether that can be
achieved within the still rather heter­
ogeneous European Community remains
to be seen.

Economic Perspectives

Securities losses—a liquidity trap?
Elijah Brewer
As high market interest rates have eroded
savings inflows, banks have bid for funds at in­
creasingly high cost in an effort to meet the
continued strong demand for loans. But for all
the funding problems of banks, there has
been no reduction in their holdings of
securities. Commercial banks in the United
States held $282 billion in securities in
September ($95 billion in Treasury securities),
compared with $267 billion at the first of the
year.
One reason banks have not tapped this
source of funds in the face of liquidity
"pressures has been the erosion in the book
value of bank investments as interest rates
climbed. Banks are reluctant to take the
losses. When yields rise abruptly—as in O c­
tober, for example—prices of outstanding
issues decline sharply. The quotation on an 8
percent coupon Treasury note maturing in
February 1985 fell to $87.84 per $100 par value
on October 31, down from a bid price of
$94.25 on October 1.
The reaction of banks to declining prices
of the securities they hold is important both to
bank profits and the functioning of restrictive
monetary policy.
A decline in the market value of a bank's
investments (which serve partly as liquidity
reserves) tends to slow sales of government
securities to finance loan expansion. For that
reason, a decline in the value of investments is
integral to the operation of restrictive credit
policies.
Part of the concern of banks over losses
on the sale of securities is the effect the losses
have on the accumulation of undivided
profits and their transfer to capital and surplus
accounts. These locking-in effects—capital
loss constraints on bank liquidations of
securities to meet loan demand—are in­
creased as yields on outstanding government
securities rise.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago




A look at the operations of member
banks in the Seventh District in 1978 shows the
level and structure of interest rates had farreaching effects on earnings from bank in­
vestment portfolios. These effects were even
greater in 1979. Responses of banks to rising
yields on outstanding securities brought
losses to banks in all sizes. This evidence
shows significant difference in reactions of
large and small banks.
Bank reluctance to take losses

As banks carry securities at cost, a decline
in the market value of securities resulting
from an increase in yields does not show up
on bank books unless the securities are sold.
Not only do banks like to increase the ac­
cumulation in capital, surplus, and undivided
profits accounts as much as possible, but they
are also concerned about losses that de­
positors or others might see as signs of poor
management.
Accumulations of capital, surplus, and
undivided profits are important because
capital can be used both directly in extending
credit and indirectly in attracting additional
funds. A sound capital base is needed for a
bank to grow and expand its operations. For
that reason, banks may try to avoid book
losses from the sale of securities in depressed
markets. The losses would slow the accumula­
tion of undivided profits and their transfer to
capital and surplus accounts. When there are
losses on securities, banks absorb them out of
current income. Since income represents
nothing more than additions to capital, the
effect is a reduction in the growth of the
bank's capital accounts.
With current earnings playing such a
large role in the adjustment to losses on
securities, banks are presented with a
problem. Losses on the sale of securities

11

reduce the reported earnings of the bank,
directly and visibly. If, by taking the losses, a
bank can switch into higher yields or into
securities with more potential for apprecia­
tion, it can often recover its loss over time
while adding to total income over the life of
the new assets it buys. It is hard to explain to
shareholders that reduced earnings are
advantageous. A portfolio strategy that
sometimes results in losses in securities,
nevertheless, enables management to meet a
major portfolio objective: over the long
haul, to achieve the highest, most consistent
growth in earnings possible.

Need for portfolio flexibility

For purposes of portfolio management,
the prices paid for current holdings of, say,
government securities do not bear on
whether the portfolio represents the best use
of funds. If a bank can increase its earnings by
selling the securities it holds and putting the
proceeds to another use, there is a distinct
sacrifice in not making the switch. If, com­
puted on the basis of market prices, two
similar government securites have different
yields to maturity, a bank holding the loweryielding security might increase future in­
come on its portfolio by switching to the
higher yielding issue. This could be true,
regardless of the effect of the switch on the
book value of the investments.
A bank also need not be deterred from
expanding its loan portfolio simply because of
losses that have to be realized when securities
are sold to raise funds for loan expansion. The
losses have been suffered anyway, whether
the bank shows them on its books or not. A
decline in the market value of security
holdings cannot be avoided by refusing to sell
the security.
The question in determining whether a
bank should continue holding a security is not
the market value of the security itself but
whether it has funds equal to the market value
available for a more attractive use. If not, in­
come on the bank loans and investments can
be improved by selling the security and put­
ting the funds to better use.

12




A flexible portfolio policy that takes ad­
vantage of changes in interest rates results in
fairly wide variations in gains and losses on
securities from year to year. When loan de­
mand is strong, interest rates high, and
monetary policy restrictive, prices of
securities tend to be depressed, the market
value of many bonds falling below their
purchase price. During these times, some
banks take losses on their securities and ex­
tend the maturities of their investments in the
expectation of lower interest rates and higher
security prices. Other banks liquidate their
securities to expand their loan portfolios.
When interest rates are low, bonds tend
to sell at above-average prices. Holdings, es­
pecially if the securities were acquired at
comparatively low prices during a period of
high interest rates, will be selling above their
purchase price. That is the time banks often
take their gains on securities and concentrate
on short-term investments.
In taking a more flexible approach to the
management of its investment portfolio, a
bank also considers the tax consequences of
capital gains and losses on securities. Banks
that do not see losses on securities as terrible
might be expected to establish such losses
through, say, the sale of government
securities, even though they do not want to
reallocate their resources into loans. This is
because the advantage of established losses
traces to the immediate tax savings, regardless
of how the funds are used after the securities
are sold.
Tax considerations

Although the unwillingness of banks to
sell their government securities when the
price is depressed may stand in the way of
more flexible management of investment
portfolio, the tax treatment of bank losses on
securities may encourage banks to take the
losses. Unlike other business, banks have to
treat both short-term and long-term capital
gains as ordinary taxable income—which
means any capital losses can be used without
limit to reduce taxable income.
Losses can be profitable if they offset tax­

Economic Perspectives

able income. Take, for example, a bank that
owns 20-year bonds it bought at $1,000 par
when rates were lower several years earlier.
Because of the rise in interest rates, the bonds
now sell at $800. For every $1 million of the
bonds the bank sells, it takes a $200,000 loss.
But if the bank is in the 50 percent tax bracket,
its net loss is only $100,000. By reinvesting the
proceeds in bonds of comparable quality and
maturity, and the same price of $800, the bank
will have a built-in future appreciation of
$200,000 at maturity.
As the bank will also have realized a tax
saving of $100,000 for every million in bonds it
sold, it will have that amount to invest at the
higher yields. The return on this additional in­
vestment resulting from the tax saving will ap­
preciably increase the bank’s income over the
investment period.
Banks without current taxable income
that offsets losses on securities can carry unus­
ed losses forward five years. Losses can be
offset against taxable income not only this
year but the four years following. Losses on
securities are valuable only to the extent that
they reduce tax liabilities. Banks have limited
their trading in securities in recent years
because of their small taxable incomes.
Because of other factors, such as equipment
leasing and foreign tax credits, the tax
positions of some banks, especially large
ones, are fairly small, leaving them little
reason to make use of tax deductions.
The tax treatment of gains and losses on
securities has allowed banks, however, to
moderate fluctuations in operating income.
They can take losses on securities in years of
sharply rising income and realize gains on
securities in years of declines in operating
income.

banks in the district averaged 0.16 percent of
operating income. Averages varied widely,
however, from 0.11 percent for banks with
total assets of less than $10 million to 0.26
percent for banks with assets of more than
$300 million and foreign branches and
subsidiaries.
Reflected in the difference was the faster
growth in profitability at large banks.
Generally, the more profitable the bank, the
more losses it can take before its capital posi­
tion is threatened. As a percentage of equity
capital, income (after taxes and before adjust­
ment for transactions of securities) rose an
average of about 210 basis points for banks
with over $300 million in assets and foreign
branches and subsidiaries. Profitability of the
smallest banks, those with assets totaling less
than $10 million, declined in 1978.
Net losses on securities relative to the
average investment portfolio were also
greater at large banks with foreign offices. Net
losses on securities averaged 0.12 percent of
the value of the investmet portfolios shown in
condition reports of the largest banks for
March, June, and September. The smallest
banks had net losses on securities amounting
to 0.03 percent of their investments on the
three call dates.
Investments represent a residual use of
funds at some banks, especially large ones.

Losses at district banks

Less than $10 million
$10-25 million
$25-50 million
$50-100 million
$100-300 million
$300 million and over with
domestic offices only
$300 million and over
with foreign offices

It will be sometime yet before loss-taking
in 1979 can be measured. However, evidence
from 1978 income reports of member banks in
the Seventh District indicate that rising in­
terest rates and declining prices of the
securities sold brought losses on securities to
banks in all sizes. Net losses on securities at

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago




Net gains on securities (after taxes) at
Seventh District member banks relative
to operating income

(by size of bank)
Asset size

1976

1977

1978

.52
.66
.48
.39
.46

.29
.25
.28
.28
.29

-.11
-.14
-.11
-.22
-.26

.08

.20

-.13

.32

.17

-.26

13

When loan demands are weak, interest rates
low, and bond prices high, the usual lagged
response of large banks is to buy securities.
When loan demands strengthen, drawing
bank funds into loan markets, banks become
less willing to hold securities. But interest
rates have risen and bond prices fallen, offer­
ing banks fewer opportunities for capital
gains on securities bought when interest rates
were low.
At other banks, investment portfolios are
not only a primary source of liquidity but also
an important source of income. This does not
mean these banks are less willing to stand
losses on securities. It means more of their
losses on transactions in securities are the
result of switches in securities made in
response to changes in economic and credit
conditions. For that reason, small banks are
likely to operate with smaller losses relative to
their investment portfolios than large banks.
Interest rates govern transactions

Losses on sales of securities varied with
interest rates. Rising rates and increased de­
mand for bank loans brought on losses in

14




securities for banks of all sizes in 1978. With
interest rates rising all year, market values of
securities depreciated, affording less oppor­
tunity for capital gains on securities bought
when rates were lower. This was in contrast to
1976 and 1977, when gains probably reflected
the sale of securities bought near the peak in
interest rates in 1974.
Although gains relative to investment
portfolios were about the same for all banks,
net gains on securities were usually higher at
the small banks. Loan demands had been
strong at small banks in 1976 and 1977, when
rates on securities were well below the peak
of the previous interest rate cycle. Loan
demands at large banks were comparatively
weak. With interest rates rising in 1978 and
loan demands increasing, large banks were
willing to take losses on their securities. While
some large banks liquidated securities to
meet loan demands, others switched their
securities to higher yielding investments.
Small banks, facing tighter liquidity positions
and reductions in the value of their invest­
ment portfolios, were less willing to take a
loss.

Economic Perspectives

Business loans at large commercial
banks: policies and practices
Randall C. Merris
Commercial bank lending was once a fairly
simple business. Business loans were nearly all
short term and carried fixed interest rates.
Any other details, except possibly collateral
requirem ents, w ere left to informal
agreements between a bank and its
customers.
Business lending began getting more
complex in the 1930s as many banks started
making term loans—loans with maturities of
more than a year. Relations between banks
and business borrowers have been growing
more complex—and more formal—ever
since, the formality of term loans now being
applied to many short-term loans as well.
Part of the push for more complicated
loan arrangements—and, therefore, a greater
variety in the kinds of agreements—has been
the need for banks and borrowers to protect
themselves from movements in interest rates
over the credit cycle. Increases in market rates
boost bank costs of funding outstanding
loans. They also increase the opportunities for
more lucrative new credits elsewhere. Reduc­
tions in market rates lower the interest costs
of other debt financing available to bank loan
customers.
Floating rates have probably been the
most important innovation in bank lending
since the advent of the term loan. Provisions
for adjusting loan rates periodically give
banks and borrowers some protection against
market rate fluctuations. By combining some
of the advantages of term and short-term
loans, floating rates have allowed banks to
compete effectively for their share of the
business credit market—even in the face of
increased competition from the commercial
paper market and other nonbank credit
suppliers. At the same time, use of floating

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago




rates has encouraged changes in the other
terms and conditions of business lending.
This article examines business lending
practices at large banks, especially toward
commercial and industrial loans. These loans
to businesses other than financial institutions
most clearly reflect the recent directions in
bank lending policy. Pricing, maturities, and
other lending terms depend on the particular
bank and borrower negotiating the credit, as
well as the use of the loan proceeds—such as,
to provide working capital, cover accounts
receivable, or finance expenditures on plant
and equipment.
Term loans

Term loans range in maturity from just
over a year to more than ten years. Banks once
held loans with maximum maturities of five to
seven years. For customers that needed
longer terms, banks participated with other
lenders. A bank might, for example, take the
first five years of credit, with an insurance
company taking the rest to maturity, often un­
der different terms and conditions. Banks are
more inclined now to take all the term credits
themselves or to participate with other banks,
each taking part of the loan for the whole
maturity.
W ith the future always uncertain,
lengthening the maturity structure of bank
loan portfolios might seem to mean banks
were taking more risks. But at least half the
term lending at large banks calls for periodic
adjustment of loan rates.
Costs are nearly always higher for in­
itiating term loans than short-term loans.
Considerable negotiation is required, usually
at top levels of management and often with
legal staffs representing the bank and the

15

borrower. And voluminous documentation is
needed to cover both the terms and con­
ditions of the loan. Administrative costs are
also high, especially in the frequent situations
where the bank and borrower need to keep in
touch throughout the life of the loan.
Agreement has to be reached not only on
the amount of the loan and its price but also

any number of other points:
Loan commitment—an arrangement for
the borrower to draw down loans and
sometimes even a schedule for disbursing the
funds. As the funds are made available to the
borrower whether he uses them or not, a fee
is sometimes charged on the amount of the
commitment not used.

Fall of the Real Bills Doctrine . . .
Though term loans were sometimes
made for special purposes, most banks
offered only short-term credit until well into
this century. This was because bank policies
were based on the commercial loan theory
of credit, an American adaptation of the Real
Bills Doctrine in England.
According to this doctrine, the only
appropriate bank loans were short-term,
self-liquidating notes. By self-liquidating,
bankers meant loans that led to enough in­
crease in sales and near-term profits to cover
repayment. Loans for plant and equipment
did not usually qualify, the reasoning being
that several years might be needed before
returns on fixed capital were enough to
retire the debt.
Some business loans were renewed
routinely, even as early as the 1830s, with the
result that nominally short-term credit
arrangements were actually long term. Not
until the 1920s, however, was the commercial
loan theory seriously challenged. The idea
that loans needed to be self-liquidating
began losing credibility for several reasons:
• The realization that the commercial
loan theory did not provide the monetary
policy advantages its proponents claimed.
• The practice of financing long-term
projects by borrowing from one bank to pay
off another—sequential bank financing.
• The emergence of the view that banks
could gain liquidity better from their non­
loan assets and their liabilities.
Proponents of the Real Bills Doctrine
had long argued that the requirement that
bank loans be self-liquidating made the
money supply expand and contract with the
needs of business. However, bankers

16



became increasingly aware, especially in
looking back on the Panic of 1907, that the
policy did not prevent severe contractions,
bank deposit runs, or bank failures.
Many banks, meanwhile, had imposed
the rule that customers had to have all their
loans at the bank paid up sometime during
the year. This clean-up rule, meant to
strengthen the commercial loan theory, ac­
tually had the opposite effect. Annual clean­
ups tended to encourage short-term
borrowing first at one bank, then another,
and then back at the first bank—all to extend
effective credit periods for fixed-capital
purposes.
Renewals, sequential financing across
banks, and the clean-up rule together de­
based the short-term loan doctrine. It took a
new theory of bank management, however,
to utterly discredit the commercial loan
theory.
The new theory took the view that as
most business loans were not actually liquid,
they did not serve as a funding cushion
against unexpected deposit withdrawals. In
place of short-term loans, the theory turned
for liquidity to other assets—such as govern­
ment and corporate securities, bankers'
acceptances, and commercial paper—that
could be sold with little loss of their capital
value. A forerunner to modern liability
management, the new theory also noted that
banks could acquire liquidity through
Federal Reserve borrowings and interbank
sale of bonds under repurchase agreements.
Together, these changes both in attitude
and in the structure of banks’ short-term
investment portfolios helped foster some
growth of term lending in the 1920s.

Economic Perspectives

Instalment schedule—a timetable for
paying down the principal and interest.
Payments are most often due monthly,
quarterly, or semiannually.
Supporting balance requirement—the
borrower's obligation to maintain demand
deposits that help offset the cost of funding
the loan. A bank may require that even a loan
commitment be backed by demand deposits.
Collateral—property put up against a
loan. Banker and borrower must agree on the
physical nature of the collateral, its value, and
the care to be taken in its handling and
protection.
Protective covenants—a requirement
that the borrower do certain things, as for ex­
ample, keep working capital above some
minimum level during the credit term or
furnish the bank periodic financial reports.
Covenants can also require that the borrower
not do certain things without the bank's

approval—for example, expand its fixed
assets, undertake further external financing,
enter a merger, or acquire an affiliate.
Some of the costs of initiating and ad­
ministering term loans are charged directly to
borrowers as fees. But there is, of course, an
interest rate at which banks are willing to ab­
sorb the remaining costs of term lending.
Revolving credits

Revolving credits were once treated as
short-term loans, which followed the bank­
ing convention that all loans had to be paid up
sometime during the year—the annual clean­
up rule. They now fall somewhere between
term loans and short-term loans. Customers
with revolving credits can borrow and repay
repeatedly over the life of the agreement
(usually two or three years) as long as the debt
outstanding does not exceed the amount
originally agreed on.

. . . and rise of term lending
Although Real Bills persisted into the
1930s, events gave impetus to term lending.
• The slack demand for short-term
loans during the Depression—even at a
prime rate of V/i percent from 1933 on—gave
banks incentives and opportunities to shift
into some higher yielding term loans.
• The Banking Acts of 1933 and 1935
limited bank activities in corporate security
markets, leading banks to substitute term
lending.
• The establishment of deposit in­
surance in 1933 reduced the likelihood of
financial panics and deposit runs, en­
couraging some lengthening of the maturity
of bank loan portfolios.
• A change in Federal Reserve rules in
1933 allowing loans of all maturities to be
used as assets for discounts and advances at
Federal Reserve banks increased the liquidi­
ty of term loans.
• Under the revision of bank examina­
tion standards in 1934, term loans were no
longer routinely classified as "slow.”
• With modern amortization gaining

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago




general acceptance, term loans, which had
usually called for payment of principal and
interest at maturity, were made payable in
annual, semiannual, quarterly, or monthly
instalments. Instalment payments smoothed
the flow of interest and principal back to the
bank and, by demonstrating a borrower's
ability to repay, helped banks monitor term
loans and identify problem credits.
• Banks were encouraged to help
finance the recovery, and followed the ex­
amples set by the Federal Reserve and
Reconstruction Finance Corporation in mak­
ing direct term loans to business.
The change was marked. A Federal
Reserve survey in 1939 showed term loans ac­
counted for a fourth of the dollar volume of
business loans at the banks sampled—39 per­
cent at the banks sampled in New York.
More than a third of the banks, however,
showed no more than five term loans on
their books. A 1946 suryey of member banks
showed term lending accounting for more
than a third of the dollar volume of business
loans.

77

As many banks have relaxed the clean-up
rule, however, allowing continuous in­
debtedness, revolving credits often qualify
now as an intermediate form of term lending.
Some contracts, in fact, include conversion
clauses that allow credits to continue as term
loans when the revolving credit agreement
expires. Under such contracts, the period of
revolving credit is often viewed as the first
years of a term loan.
Short-term and term loans as substitutes

Distinctions between term and short­
term loans have sometimes been misleading.
The most detailed survey of continuous in­
debtedness through renewal of short-term
loans was conducted nearly 25 years ago in
the Cleveland Federal Reserve District. The
survey showed that half of the dollar holdings
of short-term business loans outstanding at
member banks in the district were obligations
of borrowers continuously in debt to the
same bank for at least two years. A fourth of
the short-term credit was owed by businesses
in debt to the same bank continuously for at
least five years. Only 8 percent of this credit
was to customers in debt to the same bank no
longer than three months.

As long as loans are renewable, some
borrowers with long-term financing needs
might actually prefer short-term loans. Initia­
tion costs are lower. And as the contracts are
less detailed, they are less likely to put
operating constraints on the borrower.
Continuous indebtedness of this kind
may not be to the bank's advantage, however,
especially if it has to renew credit to prevent a
loan default or bolster future demand for
loans or other bank services. The prospects of
renewal requests increase uncertainties for
the bank. A borrower may feel that the loan
can be renewed. But the bank cannot be sure
renewal will be requested. Even if a bank has
done very well in predicting renewal requests
and sorting out the loans it feels obligated to
renew, this ability is a poor second for certain
knowledge of the length of indebtedness
agreed on when the credit was first made.
Short-term loan renewals can, of course,
be appropriate at times, as for example, when
the need for longer-term credit was not an­
ticipated. But the flexibility of term loans
nowadays reduces the need for renewals. The
term loan itself can be written to capture one
of the main advantages of short-term loan
renewal—periodic adjustment in the interest
rate. Floating rates substitute directly for the

Floating loan rates . . .
Banks have been devising alternatives to
fixed-rate pricing of business loans for
decades. Graduated rates on some term
loans appeared in the late 1930s. This
scheme, applying progressively higher rates
to later years of maturity, did not provide
floating rates, of course. Term premiums to
be added to the loan rate for later years were
set when the loan was originated. The loan
rate did not move with market rates, and the
bank had no influence on it over the life of
the loan.
Floating rates came into use in the late
1940s, with the introduction of formulas in­
volving the addition of a quarter of a per­
centage point or more to the Federal Reserve
discount rate. Floating rates were not widely

18



used, however, as long as the discount rate
and other rates remained fairly stable.
When the discount rate began changing
more often in the early 1950s—and lagging
hikes in the prime rate— banks switched the
floating-rate base to the prime, a rate more
closely reflecting market forces. Floating rate
provisions, limited almost entirely to term
loans, were not nearly as common as today.
The big change came in the mid-1960s,
with the advent of modern bank liability
management, growth of money-market
funds, and more changes in short-term rates.
Floating rates gave banks a way of making
sure returns on outstanding loans—both
long and short-term—moved with the costs
of funds.

Economic Perspectives

. . . and the form ulas for com puting them

Essentially two types of prime-based for­
mulas are used in calculating floating rates:
• Prime-plus. The more conventional of
the two, this method calls for an add-on fac­
tor to adjust for default risk and provide a
term premium for long-term credit. An ex­
ample is the prime rate plus 2 percentage
points—“ prime plus 2.”
• Times-prime. Becoming more com­
mon, this method calls for multiplication of
the prime by a factor to adjust for credit risk
and a term premium. An example is the
prime m ultiplied by 1.2—“ 1.2 times
prime.”
With either example, a prime rate set
initially at 10 percent results in a floating loan
rate of 12 percent.
Differences follow, however, if the
prime rate is any rate other than 10 percent.
With reductions in the prime rate, floating
rates based on times-prime pricing decline
faster than plus-prime rates. And increments
in the prime result in faster increases in
times-prime rates than in plus-prime rates.
Suppose, for instance, that an initial 10
percent prime is hiked to 12 percent. The
prime-plus-2 loan rate moves from 12 per­
cent to 14. The 1.2-times-prime rate moves
from 12 percent to 14.4. If the prime is
lowered from 10 percentto8,the plus-prime
rate falls from 12 percent to 10, but the timesprime rate drops to 9.6 percent.
Banks sometimes combine the two
methods. An example is 1.09 times thesum of
prime plus 1 percentage point—a floating
rate equal to 1.09 times the prime plus 1.09
percentage points. Again, if the prime rate is
set initially at 10 percent, the combination
method leads to about the same floating rate
as the basic methods—for example, 1.09
times 10 percent plus 1.09 percentage points,
or roughly 12 percent. Effects for the com­
bination method at any other prime,
however, are the same as times-prime
pricing, given the same multiplicative factors
in the formulas.
As times-prime rates vary more than
plus-prime rates over the interest-rate cycle,

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago




they have greater implications for changing
bank loan revenue and, therefore, total
profits.
One of the main reasons for times-prime
pricing is that when the prime rate is raised,
bank costs of funding outstanding loans in
interest-sensitive markets may go up faster
than the prim e. The greater-thanproportional increase in the loan rate from
times-prime pricing helps compensate banks
for lagged upward responses of the prime
rate.
The drift away from compensating
balances also helps explain the growing use
of times-prime pricing. The trend toward
higher loan rates and lower required
demand-deposit balances has, in fact, been a
major factor in the use of more complicated
floating-rate formulas.
The idea is to raise the loan rate enough
to offset the loss of loanable funds when
compensating balance requirements are eas­
ed. But the cost to a bank of foregoing these
balances varies over interest-rate and credit
cycles. When credit demand rises and banks
scramble for ever more costly money-market
funds, earlier reductions in compensating
balances become increasingly costly. If rates
are adjusted by the times-prime formula, ex­
plicit reimbursement to the bank increases as
the prime rate rises. That is, an escalating rate
premium replaces the supporting deposit
balances.
Against these advantages of floating
rates must be set the main disadvantage—the
greater variation in loan revenue over the
credit cycle. The disadvantage of floating
rates becomes most apparent when market
rates are falling. If formula loan rates are
geared to fall as fast as money market rates,
or even faster, bank profit margins on out­
standing loans can be squeezed. Banks can
immunize part of their business-loan port­
folios from movements in money-market
rates and the prime by continuing to make
fixed-rate loans to customers interested
primarily in loan-rate certainty.

19

privilege of banks to change the interest rate
when a short-term loan is renegotiated at
maturity.
Both bank and borrower find advantages
in negotiating the effective maturity at the
outset instead of a nominal maturity that can
be renewed. Sure of the maturity of a loan, a
bank can absorb some of the other risks
elsewhere in a loan agreement or lower the
average loan rate. Assured of credit for the
full term, a borrower is spared the real (albeit
sometimes small) risk that a renewal request
might be denied.
Loan commitments

Loan commitments, once informal credit
lines available to customers that kept ade­
quate balances at a bank, are now more apt to
be firm agreements laying out a bank's obliga­
tion to provide credit in the future (including
the amount of the credit and the rate to be
charged) and often the customer's obligation
to pay fees on the credit availability. The
change has come with the growth of both
term loans and revolving credits and the
greater use made of formal commitments for
short-term lending.
The Federal Reserve Survey of Loan
Commitments at Selected Large Banks for
April 1979 showed $68 billion outstanding in
unused formal agreements. Of these unused
formal commitments, 16 percent was for term
loans, 71 percent was for revolving credits,
and the remaining 13 percent was mostly for
short-term credits. Loans that had been made
under formal commitments totaled $76
billion.
Despite the trend toward formalization
of loan commitments, informal but con­
firmed lines of credit still accounted for much
of the unused commitments. A total of $95
billion in unused credit was available to
business borrowers under informal but con­
firmed lines, compared with the $68 billion in
formal commitments. Use of informal lines
was much less, however. Loans outstanding
under confirmed lines amounted to $29
billion, compared with the $76 billion in
loans that had been made under formal
commitments.

20




Compensating balances

Although many banks still require com­
pensating (or supporting) balances, with the
trend toward explicit pricing of bank services,
less emphasis is put on these balances than in
the past. As a result, required balances are be­
ing replaced in many cases by explicit fees and
increases in lending rates.
Where demand-deposit balances are still
used, the requirement is usually stated as an
average deposit balance equal to a percent­
age of the loan or commitment. A typical re­
quirement is an average balance of 15 percent
of the loan. Another is 10 percent of the loan,
plus 10 percent of the unused commitment—
10 percent of the total commitment.
Negotiations sometimes result in higher
requirements on the loan commitments than
on the loans themselves. In other cases,
balance requirements are set higher on loans
than on commitments.
Pressure from a credit customer to shift
the balance requirement one way or the
other gives a bank some indication of how the
commitment is to be used. If the borrower
wants the balance requirement on the com­
mitment reduced enough to have the loan re­
quirement raised an equal amount, he clearly
expects to make little use of the loan
commitment—less than half of it on average.
If he expected to use most of the commit­
ment, he would want the opposite, with more
of the balance requirement on the unused
commitment.
Loan prepayments

Prepayment provisions in loan contracts
spell out the penalty costs (premiums)
charged for paying a loan before it matures.
Until the 1960s, banks usually did not charge
premiums when loans were paid off (or paid
down) before maturity, provided the funds
came from operating earnings or other inter­
nal sources. Although substantial premiums
were often imposed on prepayments fi­
nanced from other borrowing, especially
from other banks, many banks in the 1950s ac­
tually encouraged prepayments from a firm's
retained earnings.

Economic Perspectives

Profile of commercial and industrial loans
Average interest rates
percent

percent

T ____i____ i_____ i____ I_____ i_____i____ i_____I_____ i____ i_____ i_____I

X ____ i_____i_____i____ I_____i_____i_____i_____I_____i____ i____ i_____ I

Secured loans*

Loans at floating rate*

Loans made under commitment

•Proportions of total dollar volumes.
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Survey of Terms of Bank Lending. The survey data are taken from about 340 banks selected to represent all sizes of banks.
The data are collected from one business week in the middle month of each calendar quarter. Short-term loans have original maturities of less than one
year, and term loans have maturities of one year or more.

Banks today often impose substantial
penalties on the prepayment of fixed-rate
loans, the intentions being to hold borrowers
to the full terms of their contracts in return for
the banks' having to risk a rise in interest rates.
If term borrowers could prepay their
loans at will, with no direct or implied costs,
they would in effect control maturities. As
banks could not be sure of the repayment
dates, prime-setting decisions would have to
be based on probable prepayments, with
banks undoubtedly charging more to com­
pensate for the uncertainty.
Prepayment of floating-rate loans is

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago




s e l d o m a p ro b le m .
Borrowers have little in­
centive to prepay loans
when the rates move with
the costs of credit general­
ly. Even if other interest
rates fall a little faster than
the floating rate, or rise a
little slower, the substan­
tial costs of originating
other credit are apt to lock
a customer into the ex­
isting loan.
Whether the rates are
fixed or floating, then,
most term loans run to
maturity. And as a result,
outstanding term loans are
essentially immune to
changes in the prime rate.
There are limits, of
course, to the changes that
can be made in prime
rates. If floating rates went
up too much or did not
respond to drastic reduc­
tions in market rates,
borrowers would stand the
prepayment penalties and
term loans outstanding
would fall.
Secured loans

Although large cor­
porations with top credit
ratings routinely receive unsecured bank
loans, many business borrowers have to post
collateral. The amount of collateral and the
type depend on the customer's credit rating,
the size and maturity of the loan, and the pur­
pose of the credit. Because of risk factors in­
volved in some types of term credit, term
loans are more apt to be secured than are
short-term loans.
The most recent trend in secured bank
lending is the kind of asset-based lending
long handled by commercial finance com­
panies. Large banks and their holding com­
panies have become active in this specialized

21

form of secured lending by acquiring exist­
ing finance companies, establishing new
commercial-finance affiliates, and restruc­
turing their own lending policies for closer
management and monitoring of the collateral
behind secured loans. The inroads large
banks have made into asset-based lending
represent a competitive response— especially
to attract small business borrowers—and
awareness of the need for adequate
collateralization as an adjunct to the risk­
bearing business of modern bank lending.
Recent pricing tactics

When loan demand eases and moneymarket rates fall, large money-center banks
come under pressure to lower their primerate quotations in an effort to attract more
new business loan customers. This was the
situation in 1976 and 1977. Because of
floating-rate provisions in outstanding
business loans, however, reductions in the
prime rate aimed at bolstering new loans call
for forfeitures of revenue on floating-rate
loans already on the books. Bank concern
over loss of this revenue can slow the lower­
ing of the prime.
When two large banks in a money-center
have significantly different proportions of
their loan portfolios in floating-rate loans—
especially if the loans are priced by different
formulas (see box)—the one with the larger
proportion may well be at a disadvantage in
lowering its prim e. These interbank
differences in floating-rate loans help to ex­
plain split-rate primes—different prime rates
at various money-center banks.
Large banks have tried several loan pric­
ing policies aimed at bolstering loan demand
and at the same time protecting profit
margins on outstanding loans. One policy,
dating from the 1950s, specifies ranges in
which floating rates can be revised, as for ex­
ample, an initial loan rate of 6 percent with
the rate floating from 4 percent to 8 percent.
Some banks redesigned the cap-rate
feature a few years ago by offering floating
rates that would not average more than an
agreed-on rate over the life of the loan.

22



Because these cap rates combined the
borrowing advantages of both fixed rates and
floating rates, they gained some customer
acceptance in 1971 and 1972.
When open-market rates rose, in 1973
and 1974, however, pushing up funding costs,
profit margins on outstanding cap-rate loans
dwindled. The upper limit on average interest
costs became a ceiling that made further rate
increases impossible. Banks have paid little
attention to this type loan since. They have
also shown few inclinations to adopt
minimum-rate features that would limit the
decline in loan rates when the prime was
lowered.
Another technique for bolstering loan
demand while protecting bank loan income
has been floating rates tied to base rates other
than the prime. This pricing feature is often
tailored to the needs (and competitive en­
vironment) of large multinational cor­
porations with access to credit markets
abroad.
One of the rates that moves somewhat
independently of the regular prime rate
quotations governing other floating rates is
the London Interbank Offering Rate (LIBOR),
a short-term European money-market rate.
Although this is the most common formula
rate for these loans, such U.S. money-market
rates as the commercial paper rate and secon­
dary certificate of deposit rate are also used.
In some cases, large banks have revised their
overseas lending policies to provide credit in
the European market at rates tied either to
their U.S. prime rate or to LIBOR, depending
on the expected changes in the prime-LIBOR
rate spread.
Business lending strategies refined at
large banks during a time of rising interest
rates will be tested when demand for loans
eases and interest rates fall. As pressures
build for banks to lower their prime rates
from the above-15 percent levels of recent
months, a large part of their current loan port­
folios will still be on the books.
Banks have been preparing for an even­
tual downturn by diversifying their business
loans, interspersing fixed-rate loans with
loans written to various formula rates based

Economic Perspectives

on prime and other rates. Their success in
pursuing this diversification strategy will be
reflected in how well their prime rates follow
declines in market rates.
Since revisions in prime rates usually lag
behind changes in market rates, the tendency

is for the spread to widen when rates fall
rapidly. If, after adjustment for the lag, the
prime rate still responds sluggishly to
easing market conditions, banks may have to
rethink some of their explicit pricing methods
for business lending.

EC O N O M IC PERSPECTIVES
Index for 1979
Agriculture
Cattle cycles in perspective.....................................................

Issue

Pages

May/June

18-23

March/April

14-20

March/April

21-22

September/October
November/December

15-23
11-14

November/December

15-23

Banking, credit, and finance
Banks and the securities markets:
the controversy..........................................................................
Holding company affiliation and
scale economies in banking................................................
Bank holding companies: competitive
issues and p o licy.......................................................................
Securities losses—a liquidity trap? .......................................
Business loans at large commercial banks:
policies and practices..............................................................
Economic conditions
Review and outlook: 1978-79 ................................................
Subsidized housing—costs and benefits............................
The economy and the banking system ..............................
Fuel crisis hits business..............................................................
The inflation-unemployment tradeoff................................

January/February
May/June
July/August
July/August
September/October

3-30
3-9
3-8
9-15
3-9

July/August
September/October

16-23
10-14

May/June
November/December

10-17
3-10

Government finance
Municipal bonds in the housing market............................
Urban mass transit—a major revival.....................................
International finance and trade
Midwest—leading export region............................................
The European Monetary System ............................................
Money and money supply
Currency and the subterranean econom y.......................
Proposed redefinition of money stock measures.........

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago




March/April
March/April

3-6
7-13

23