View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Business insights
Em ploym ent and
unem ploym ent
CONTENTS

Banking insights
Banks n ow o ffe r savings
deposit service to businesses
Nonbanking activities of
bank holding companies

March/April 1977

ECONOM IC PERSPECTIVES
Single-copy subscriptions of Economic
Perspectives, a bimonthly review, are
available free of charge. Please send requests
for single- and multiple-copy subscriptions,
back issues, and address changes to Public
Information Center, Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, P. O. Box 834, Chicago, Illinois
60690, or telephone (312) 322-5112.
Articles may be reprinted provided
source is credited and Public Information
Center is provided with a copy of the
published material.
Application to mail at controlled
circulation rates is pending at Chicago P.O.




3

8

12

The growth o f bank holding
companies and their tendency to ac­
quire nonbanking business enter­
prises raise numerous economic
issues. These include permissible
nonbanking activities, diversification,
risk, soundness, concentration and
competition, operating efficiency,
and pricing and profitability—among
the issues examined in this article.

State and local government
deposits in the district
Laws and deposit allocation
State and local government
deposits are becoming increasingly
important on the balance sheets of
the Seventh District's—and the
nation's—commercial banks.

22

Business insights
Employment and unemployment
Early each month, usually the first Friday, the
United States Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS)
issues its report, "The Employment Situa­
tion.” This publication presents a dozen
statistical tables with estimates of total
employment and unemployment, nationally,
with appropriate breakdowns.
The news media typically give wide
publicity to current estimates of changes in
unemployment, but often omit mention of
estimates of changes in employment. This
practice distorts the overall intelligence
provided by the data. Not infrequently, un­
employment increases in months when
employment also increases, and vice versa.
The unemployed are not necessarily people
who have "lost their jobs,” but, rather, people
without jobs who are "seeking work” for
whatever reason. Rising job opportunities
sometimes encourage potential workers to
look for jobs. Until they find work or cease
looking, they are classified as unemployed.
Big gain in employment

High levels of unemployment un­
questionably reflect underutilized human
resources, and often personal tragedy. But
keeping the spotlight on unemployment has
tended to obscure the substantial growth in
output and employment that has occurred in
the past two years.
In December, before the severe weather
struck, 88.4 million Americans were em­
ployed in civilian jobs. (These figures allow for
normal seasonal influences.) This was 3
million more than a year earlier, 2.2 million
more than at the prerecession high in 1974,
and 4.2 million more than at the recession low
in the spring of 1975. Almost 41 percent of the
entire population held civilian jobs in late
Digitized Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
for FRASER


1976, a record proportion.
Despite the strong rise in employment in
the past two years, unemployment is es­
timated to have totaled 7.5 million in
December—7.8 percent of the civilian labor
force, which includes both those working and
those seeking work. Unemployment was
almost as high as the average for 1975. The
civilian labor force rose 3 percent last year,
twice as fast as in 1975, and substantially more
than most analysts had expected on the basis
of historical experience. Reasons for the rapid
rise in the labor force are not fully un­
derstood. Aside from the growth of job op­
portunities, other suggested reasons include
a desire for supplementary income to offset
inflation, and pressures on employers to hire
people who had been considered un­
employable in the past.

Sharp rise in employment
since early 1975
millions

1974

1975

1976

1977

3

Samples and surveys

scanning want ads. Some job seekers, es­
pecially "secondary" workers who are not
responsible for dependents, may have strict
reservations as to the pay, hours, and type of
work they will accept. No attempt is made to
evaluate the degree of determination in­
volved in seeking work. On the other hand,
the unemployed do not include "discour­
aged" people who have decided a job search
is fruitless.
Only about half of those counted as un­
employed each month are “ job losers." The
other half either (1) left their jobs voluntarily,
(2) are first-time job seekers, or (3) have
reentered the labor force after taking time
out for school, child rearing, or other reasons.
Clearly, the concept of unemployment is
less precise than the concept of employment.
Definitions of unemployment have changed
over time, thereby affecting historical com­
parisons. The social environment also has
changed as unemployment compensation
has been liberalized and extended, and
welfare programs have been expanded.
These benefits are supposed to be paid only if
people able to work represent themselves as
seeking suitable work. Increased home
ownership, larger accumulated savings, and

BLS estimates of total employment and
unemployment (the "household" series) are
derived from interviews by the Bureau of the
Census in its Current Population Survey.
About 47,000 households, representing
almost 150,000 individuals, are contacted each
month. Respondents are asked a series of
questions, relating to the week containing the
12th day of the month. Each individual is
classified as employed, unemployed, or "not
in the labor force." Estimates are for the
civilian noninstitutional population (inmates
are excluded) 16 years and over.
Employed persons counted by the
household series are those who worked fulltime or part-time for pay, either as employees
or proprietors or as unpaid workers in a family
enterprise. The household series considers
strikers to be employed.
The BLS also prepares a monthly estimate
of nonagricultural payroll employment based
on reports from employers (the "establish­
ment" series). Payroll employment, also for
the week including the 12th, excludes
proprietors, domestics, and farm workers, but
may count people twice if they hold two jobs.
The establishment series does
not include strikers. Also, it
Employment at new high relative
provides no information on
to population
unemployment. Employment
estimates for states and local
millions
areas are based on the es­
200
tablishment survey.
Both the household and
establishment series include
160
government as well as private
workers. Neither includes the
120
armed forces, which number
2.1 million currently.
The household series
80
counts people as unemployed
if (1) they did not work at all in
40
the survey week, and (2) they
had searched for work in any
of the preceding four weeks.
1929 1933 1940 1950 1960 1970 7 4 7 5 76
The job search may take any
Note: Before 1950 employment and unemployment
are for persons 14 and over.
form, e.g., asking relatives or
4




population, July 1

average
unemployment
average civilian
employment

Economic Perspectives

broader use of severance pay also permit peo­
ple to withhold their services from the job
market if attractive jobs are unavailable. Final­
ly, the rise in the proportion of the labor force
represented by women, teen-agers, and
minority groups in the past decade or so tends
to increase total unemployment because
these groups have higher unemployment
rates than adult men.

Women workers comprise
rising share of work force
millions
60

annual average

—
50 __

male employment
female employment

More women workers

In 1947, after many women had given up
war-related jobs, women workers averaged
16 million, 28 percent of the total 57 million
American workers. This proportion has in­
creased almost every year. Last year, female
employment averaged over 35 million, 40 per­
cent of total employment, which averaged a
record 87.5 million. As recently as 1965 the
proportion of women workers was under 35
percent.
The absolute number of women workers
has averaged higher each year since 1958. In
this period the number of male workers
averaged lower than in the previous year in
1961 and 1975. The contrast was particularly
striking in 1975, when the average number of
male workers declined 1.3 million, or 2.5 per­
cent, while women workers increased
130,000, or 0.4 percent.
Although work performed by women in
their own homes clearly has economic
significance, housewives have never been
counted in the labor force and their
'‘product" is not counted in the gross national
product. Increased use of household ap­
pliances and convenience foods has freed
many women for paid jobs. Other women
have sought work because of the rise in
divorces and broken homes. A very important
factor has been the decline in the birth rate
from 25 per 1,000 population in 1957 to under
15 in the past five years. This has meant that a
declining proportion of adult women have
small children to care for. Along with these
forces female employment has been in­
creased by changes in social attitudes. In­
creasingly, jobholding by women has been
viewed with esteem rather than opprobrium.
Digitized Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
for FRASER


1950

1960

1970

1974

1975 1976

The growth of female employment also
has been aided in recent years by court orders
and regulatory decrees. Job upgrading for
women has also been pushed. Nevertheless,
earnings for women in full-time jobs average
significantly less than for men, and a larger
proportion of women are voluntary part-time
workers. These factors tend to slow growth in
average earnings and average hours as
calculated for all workers.
Teen-agers

The problems young people encounter
in getting and finding jobs is a matter of con­
tinuing concern. However, it should be kept
in mind that relatively few teen-agers are the
"primary" workers in a household or family.
Although they may add significantly to total
family income, much of their earnings isspent
on their own education, automobiles, or
other wants.
Unemployment rates for the 16-19 year
age group have held close to 20 percent in re­
cent years, while rates for both males and
females aged 20 and over have been below
the average for all workers. Unemployment
among teen-agers tends to be high for a
number of reasons: (1) the high birth rates of
5

the late 1950s have increased the supply of
young workers relative to demand; (2) they
often lack experience, skills, and proper work
habits; (3) they have low seniority on full­
time jobs; (4) their attachment to the job
market is often sporadic; (5) personnel re­
quirements of the armed forces which draw
heavily on teen-agers are less than in earlier
years; and (6) minimum wages, whether en­
forced by government or unions, tend to
restrict opportunities for new workers.
In 1976 there were 17 million Americans
aged 16 through 19. This is virtually the same
as the number of births in the years 1957-60
when births were at an all-time high of 4.3
million per year. The number of births began
to decline in 1962 and in recent years has
averaged just over 3 million. In future years,
therefore, the number of teen-agers will be
declining while the total population con­
tinues to grow, partly through net immigra­
tion from abroad.
Only about 53 percent of the 16-19 age
group is in the labor force, either employed
or unemployed at a given time. Of 7.3 million
teen-agers employed last year, on average, 46
percent held part-time jobs, compared to 14
percent for all workers. Of these, the great
majority did not want full-time jobs, usually

Teen-age population and
employment growth slow
millions

because they were full-time students.
Teen-age workers have accounted for 8
percent of total employment in recent years.
This proportion has tended to fluctuate year
by year, but is well above the 6 percent ratio of
the late 1950s. The higher proportion of
young workers tends to reduce somewhat
average hours and average earnings for all
workers. This influence appears to have
reached its peak, but much depends on
trends in the average number of years spent in
school.
Part-time workers

The BLS defines full-time employment as
35 or more hours per week. Part-time workers
are those who work less than 35 hours per
week—with a range from one to 34 hours.
About 80 percent of all part-time workers
do not choose to work full time. They are
called "voluntary"' part-time workers in con­
trast to those who are on short weeks for
economic reasons. Last year the number of
voluntary part-time workers averaged 12.5
million, over 14 percent of all workers. This
ratio has increased gradually from under 11
percent in the early 1960s.
In the 16-19 year bracket voluntary parttime workers account for over 46 percent of
the total. For women over 20 the proportion is
22 percent; for men over 20 it is 5 percent.
Voluntary part-time employment has in­
creased each year since 1963 (earliest com­
parison available) when it averaged 7.3
million. It rose in 1975, when total employ­
ment declined substantially, although at a
slower pace. The uptrend accelerated again
last year.
Supplementary income

Part-time workers, both adult women
and teen-agers, are often members of families
in which the "head" and primary income
earner is an adult male. In 1975, latest year
available, over 58 percent of the husbandwife families with the husband working had
other family members employed. (Many of
these other members were full-time
workers.) This proportion has risen steadily
from 47 percent in 1965 and under 40 percent

6




Economic Perspectives

in 1955. For working wives alone the ratio was
38 percent in 1975, compared to 29 percent in
1965 and 24 percent in 1955. For families with
the head unemployed—2.3 million, on
average, in 1975—62 percent reported at least
one other member working. The ratio was 45
percent for wives alone.
In 1975 the number of heads of husbandwife families working declined from 38.3
million to 36.8 million. This decline of 1.5
million exceeds the decline of 1.2 million for
all workers in 1975. It appears that the heads of
households were affected more than propor­
tionately by the recession. Many were for­
tunate that wives and other members of the
family were able to contribute to family buy­
ing power.
The flexible work force

With estimated unemployment holding
fairly steady at almost 7.5 million in the past
year, there is a tendency to view this total as a
stable group of people who bear the whole
burden. Actually, some of the people
classified as unemployed find jobs soon after
the survey. Only about one-fifth of the un­
employed have been in this category for six
months or more. Average duration of un­
employment in December was 16 weeks, im­
plying a very substantial turnover in three and
one-half months, while the total number of
unemployed may have changed only slightly.
The particular individuals who are
employed also change from month to month,
although not to the same degree as in the case
of the unemployed. Some people retire each
month; others are seasonal workers; others
leave the labor force voluntarily either
forever or for periods of time; and some are
unemployed part of the year.
In 1976, when employment averaged 87.5
million, about 103.5 million different people
had some work experience during the year.
For the past decade the number of people
with some work experience during the year
has exceeded total average employment by
almost 20 percent, a remarkably stable
proportion. However, this ratio has increased
slightly in the past decade for men, while it
has decreased for women.
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago



In 1974, the last year for which detailed
data are available, men with some work ex­
perience during the year exceeded average
employment by 12 percent. For women the
ratio was 28 percent. As in the case of parttime employment, these comparisons in­
dicate that men are more likely to be permanentaly attached to the labor force than
women.
Further growth ahead

The aggregate figures released each
month by the BLS on employment and un­
employment reflect the net results of many
individual actions. People are losing jobs and
finding jobs, changing jobs voluntarily or un­
der pressure, leaving, entering, or reentering
the labor force.
In the past 30 years the structure of the
labor force has changed significantly. Among
the most important developments are the in­
crease in the proportion of women workers,
the change in the proportion of young
workers, the rise in college enrollment, and
the trend toward earlier retirement. These
changes were reflected in the labor force par­
ticipation rate (percent of the noninstitutional population 16 years and older),
which has trended irregularly upward. In 1976
this ratio was 62.1 percent, a record for the
period since World War II. It was 58.9 percent
in 1947 and 61 percent as recently as 1972.
Changes of 1 percent or more in this ratio
reflect a complex of forces that may have
profound implications.
Employment is a measure of activity; un­
employment of inactivity. Since World War II
average employment has declined from one
year to another only five times, and never for
two consecutive years. The increase from
1975, when employment declined, to 1976
was 3.2 percent. This compares favorably with
earlier recoveries: 2.2 percent in 1950, 3.4
percent in 1955, 2.5 percent in 1959, and 1.4
percent in 1962. Employment is expected to
rise throughout 1977 and average higher than
in 1976, but probably by a smaller ratio than in
1976. Unemployment is expected to decline
but not to prerecession levels.
George W. Cloos
7

Banking insights
Banks now offer savings deposit
service to businesses
Effective November 10,1975, amendments to
Federal Reserve System and Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation regulations allowed all
insured commercial banks to accept savings
deposits from businesses for the first time
since 1933. The limit placed on the amount of
these deposits is $150,000 per depositor per
bank. Currently, banks can pay up to 5 per­
cent on business savings accounts—the max­
imum rate permitted on any commercial bank
savings accounts. Thus authorized, commer­
cial banks can now compete on more equal
grounds for business funds with savings and
loan associations (S&Ls), which have not been
prohibited from accepting commercial
savings deposits.
An investment alternative for businesses

Bank savings accounts provide an alter­
native investment outlet for businesses with
temporarily idle funds, especially small
businesses. Before the reintroduction of com­
mercial savings accounts at banks, the
business with cash in excess of current needs
could (1) hold the funds in currency and/or
demand deposits, (2) deposit the funds in
savings accounts at S&Ls, (3) purchase shares
in money market mutual funds, or (4) make
direct investments in money market in­
struments such as Treasury bills and
negotiable certificates of deposit (CDs). A
bank savings deposit possesses certain at­
tributes that in some instances offer advan­
tages either as a substitute for or a supplement
to these other investment alternatives.
Currency and demand deposits. These
rank lowest among the choices in terms of
nominal return on investment. But while they
bear no explicit rate of interest, they are the
most liquid of the investment alternatives—
8



that is, they can be mobilized for transactions
purposes in the shortest period of time
(immediately) with the least risk of capital loss
(none, abstracting from bank failures or
depreciation due to inflation). Moreover,
they yield implicit returns in the form of ser­
vices a bank provides to its depositors. Many
banks today, however, are willing to transfer
funds from a savings account to a checking ac­
count upon telephone notification by the
depositor. A business whose bank offers this
telephone transfer service may now find bank
savings deposits preferable to demand
deposits as a temporary repository for idle
funds because their higher explicit nominal
rate of return is available with little or no loss
of liquidity.
Savings deposits at S&Ls. This second
alternative may afford businesses higher
earnings than comparable deposits at com­
mercial banks to the extent that the S&Ls in
the relevant market actually offer the max­
imum legal rate, which is Va percent higher
than what commercial banks may pay.
However, the S&L deposits are not as readily
convertible into transactions balances as are
bank savings deposits unless the S&L has an
agreement with a commercial bank whereby
a depositor’s funds can be transferred from
his S&L account to his bank checking account
immediately upon notification by the
depositor. This service is offered by some
S&Ls, primarily in the larger metropolitan
areas. Where it is not offered, the higher li­
quidity of savings deposits at banks may more
than compensate for their lower interest
return vis-a-vis their counterparts at S&Ls.
M oney market mutual funds. When in­
terest rates on short-term market instruments
are above the offering rate on savings
deposits, money market mutual funds may be
Economic Perspectives

an attractive investment alternative for
businesses. Shares in many of these mutual
funds can be purchased in units as low as
$1,000, and some funds permit investors to
write checks on their shares. The main draw­
back of a money market mutual fund is uncer­
tainty of return due to daily fluctuations in
short-term interest rates. Certainty of return is
much greater in the case of savings deposits
since offering rates are changed infrequently,
if at all, and then usually with advance
notification only at the start of a calendar
quarter.
M oney market instruments. Businesses
can buy and sell money market instruments,
but such operations are feasible on an
economical basis only to larger businesses
and corporations due to the relatively large
minimum denominations in which these in­
struments are issued and the large units in
which they are traded in the secondary
market. For example, Treasury bills and CDs
are issued in minimum denominations of
$10,000 and $100,000, respectively, and are
normally traded in units of $1 million. Some
small businesses would be precluded from
purchasing these obligations due to their high
minimum denominations. Other small
businesses, though not deterred by minimum
denominations, find the effective return
reduced by transactions costs of purchases
and sales in the secondary market. Like
money market mutual funds, daily fluc­
tuations in short-term interest rates make
the return on direct investments in money
market instruments uncertain unless held to
maturity.
In summary, savings deposits at commer­
cial banks should prove to be an attractive
short-term investm ent alternative to
businesses because these balances are poten­
tially very liquid, have a certain return, and
deposits can be made in any amount up to a
$150,000 maximum balance. This last attribute
should make savings deposits especially
appealing to small businesses. In addition to
these features, in periods when short-term
market interest rates fall below the rates paid
on savings deposits, as has been the case in re­
cent months, such deposits may be preferred
DigitizedFederal Reserve Bank of Chicago
for FRASER


over other temporary investment vehicles
even by larger businesses. By opening ac­
counts in more than one bank, a business can
invest more than $150,000. However, few
banks offer such an opportunity to a non­
customer, especially when the funds appear
highly interest-sensitive.
Growth in the Seventh District

Latest data available for all U.S. commer­
cial banks show business savings slightly over
$6 billion in mid-1976. Half of this was ac­
counted for by the large banks in major U.S.
cities (weekly reporting banks), which hold 55
percent of all commercial banking assets. In
February 1977 business savings deposits at
the 55 Seventh District weekly reporting
banks averaged $625 million and accounted
for slightly more than 13 percent of the total at
weekly reporting banks nationwide.
Except for the large banks, data on
business savings are available only from
quarterly condition reports. Latest available
readings (September 30, 1976) show signifi­
cant differences in the importance of these
deposits among member banks in varioussize
classes in the five district states. (See table.)
These data indicate that, within this dis­
trict, business savings deposits are most
prevalent at banks in Iowa, Michigan, and
Wisconsin. In these three states business
savings deposits are higher as a percent of
total savings deposits in almost every bank
size group than in Illinois and Indiana.
Moreover, the average amount of business
savings deposits per bank is higher in Iowa,
Michigan, and Wisconsin in most deposit-size
classes. Notable exceptions to this pattern are
the smallest banks in Iowa, where business
savings deposits are relatively unimportant
and the largest banks in Illinois, where the
significance of these deposits is much greater
than at smaller banks in the state.
Although business savings deposits are
not yet as important at Illinois and Indiana
banks, their more rapid growth rates in these
states over the March-September period in­
dicate that they may be catching up. One
reason for the lagging importance of these
deposits at Indiana banks is that state banking

9

laws prohibited business savings accounts at
commercial banks until January 14,1976, two
months after the Federal Reserve Board lifted
its prohibition.
The greater popularity of business
savings deposits at Iowa, Michigan, and
Wisconsin banks may be related to the fact
that prior to the change in bank regulations
permitting these deposits, S&Ls in some areas

of these states had been actively soliciting
commercial savings accounts. This had two
effects—first, to familiarize businesses with
this kind of account and second, to attract
deposits away from commercial banks. Thus,,
when banks were authorized to accept
business savings deposits, those that had lost
deposits to S&L savings accounts may have
been more aggressive in promoting their own

Business savings deposits at Seventh District
member banks, September 30, 1976
___________________ Deposit size (million dollars)_________________
Less than
10

10-50

50-100

100-500

Over
500

All
banks

Illinois
Amount outstanding ($000s)
Percent of total savings
Average amount per bank ($000s)
Percent increase*
Number of banks

1,629
1.7
27
227.8
60

29,862
2.0
169
9.3
177

40,338
2.5
611
12.8
66

88,722
3.1
1,888
55.9
47

98,105
3.8
16,351
60.4
6

258,656
3.0
727
42.4
356

110
0.5
8
**
13

5,995
1.4
84
38.9
71

9,378
2.8
469
57.4
20

22,052
2.4
1,225
63.6
18

7,826
1.4
2,609
146.0
3

45,361
2.0
363
68.4
125

489
1.2
17
42.3
28

18,473
3.5
212
8.0
87

14,814
4.1
823
38.6
18

42,745
8.0
3,288
57.7
13

—
—
—
—
—

76,521
5.2
524
38.5
146

2,512
6.2
140
40.4
18

25,983
2.8
274
59.6
95

18,742
3.5
892
55.4
21

82,494
3.6
3,173
36.0
26

199,055
4.3
19,906
35.8
10

328,786
3.7
1,934
38.5
170

2,289
5.4
120
60.6
19

20,711
3.6
280
43.3
74

14,842
3.5
873
55.4
17

32,712
6.2
2,974
25.0
11

23,496
5.4
11,748
38.0
2

94,050
4.7
764
37.0
123

7,029
2.9
51
73.4
138

101,024
2.5
200
27.1
504

98,114
3.0
691
32.6
142

268,725
3.8
2,337
45.8
115

328,482
3.6
15,642
44.1
21

803,374
3.4
873
41.0
920

Indiana
Amount outstanding ($000s)
Percent of total savings
Average amount per bank ($000s)
Percent increase*
Number of banks
Iowa
Amount outstanding ($000s)
Percent of total savings
Average amount per bank ($000s)
Percent increase*
Number of banks
Michigan
Amount outstanding ($000s)
Percent of total savings
Average amount per bank ($000s)
Percent increase*
Number of banks
Wisconsin
Amount outstanding ($000s)
Percent of total savings
Average amount per bank ($000s)
Percent increase*
Number of banks
Seventh District

10



Amount outstanding ($000s)
Percent of total savings
Average amount per bank ($000s)
Percent increase*
Number of banks

‘ From six months earlier.
“ None outstanding as of March 31, 1976.

Economic Perspectives

savings accounts in order to regain these
deposits. Furthermore, some businesses,
familiar with this type of deposit as a result of
prior “ education" by the S&Ls, may have
chosen to open a savings account with a com­
mercial bank because of the typically greater
liquidity of bank savings deposits and other
bank-customer relationships.
Implications for monetary policy

The emergence of business savings
deposits at commercial banks may complicate
monetary policy decisions depending on the
quantities involved and the type of monetary
policy pursued. Since the early 1970s the
Federal Reserve System has moved toward a
monetary aggregates approach to policy; that
is, it has attempted to use its policy in­
struments to maintain growth rates of M-1
and M-2 within specified ranges over a
reasonable time period.1The rationale for this
approach is that the monetary authorities are
seeking to provide money and credit to the
economy in volumes consistent with the
achievement of the optimum possible com­
bination of the nation’s economic goals. The
re la tio n s h ip between the monetary
aggregates and income, employment, and
price stability goals is learned through obser­
vation of the economy's behavior in the past.
However,the introduction of business savings
deposits at commercial banks can be ex­
pected to alter some of these past
relationships, and uncertainty about these
changes could cause errors in the choice of
the appropriate target growth rates for the
monetary aggregates.
Suppose that corporations convert what
would have otherwise been idle demand
deposits into savings deposits at commercial
banks. This conversion implies a reduction in
the amount of demand deposits and hence
M-1 (assuming no change in the demand for
currency) the public wants to hold at any
given level of interest rates. The same level of
'M - 1 is defined as currency and demand deposits
held by the public. M -2 equals M-1 plus commercial bank
time and savings deposits other than large negotiable
certificates of deposit.

Digitized forFederal Reserve Bank of Chicago
FRASER


economic activity can now be supported with
a smaller quantity of M-1. The substitution of
savings deposits at commercial banks for de­
mand deposits, in and of itself, will reduce the
quantity of demand deposits.2 If the Federal
Reserve were following an M-1 target and
attempted to restore M-1 to its original level,
some unintended stimulus to the economy
might result.
However, if an M-2 target were being
pursued under these same circumstances, this
problem would not be encountered. No shift
in the demand for M-2 would occur since the
fall in the demand for demand deposits is
offset by an equal and opposite change in the
demand for savings deposits, also a compo­
nent of M-2. While the demand for the
elements comprising M-2 has changed, there
is nothing inherent in this assumed substitu­
tion of savings deposits for demand deposits
that requires the Federal Reserve to adjust its
M-2 target to achieve desired economic
effects. Although the savings-demand
deposit substitution will not alter the M-2
target, it will create excess reserves, which,
unless absorbed by the central bank, can lead
to an expansion in M-2 above its targeted
level (see footnote 2).
Of course, there are myriad assets other
than demand deposits which bank savings
deposits can be substituted for. Depending
on what assets are involved in these sub­
stitutions, the relationship between growth in
the monetary aggregates as now defined and
economic performance is likely to change.
The dilemma for policy makers is that
different kinds of shifts in the composition of
asset p re fe re n ce s are taking place
simultaneously, and accurate information as
to kinds of shifts taking place and quantities
involved is not always ascertainable.
Paul L. Kasriel
2
The reduction in demand deposits is likely to be less
than the increase in savings deposits since this substitu­
tion will create excess reserves, assuming a lower re­
quired reserve ratio for savings deposits than for demand
deposits. Unless absorbed by the central bank, these ex­
cess reserves will provide a base for the expansion of total
bank deposits, part of which will probably include de­
mand deposits.

11

Nonbanking activities
of bank
holding companies
Although bank holding companies (BHCs)
have existed for over three-quarters of a cen­
tury, their impact on the banking and finan­
cial sectors has become significant only in the
past decade.1Prior to 1971 BHCs weredivided
into two basic types, multibank and one-bank
holding companies. Multibank holding com­
panies (MBHCs) were defined as corporate
entities controlling at least 25 percent of the
ownership of two or more banks and since
1956 have been required to register with the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System. Historically, MBHCs have been used
largely to circumvent intrastate and interstate
branch banking prohibitions, but in recent
years they have been expanding into non­
banking areas.
One-bank holding companies (OBHCs),
on the other hand, have had a more varied
history. Originally,OBHCs wereorganized by
families or individuals to control small banks
while at the same time gaining certain tax ad-*
^ h e historical and legal development of bank
holding companies has been traced in several articles in
B u s i n e s s C o n d i t i o n s [22, 29, 30]. The banking aspects of
multibank holding companies were surveyed in the
December 1976 issue [9].

72




vantages offered by incorporation. In other
instances large nonfinancial holding com­
panies would acquire a bank to facilitate the
availability of banking services for their
customers and employees. This latter type was
frequently referred to as a “ conglomerate”
bank holding company [22, 25, 29].
About a decade ago, however, a distinct
change occurred in the rationale behind the
formation of OBHCs. This marked phe­
nomenon was the bank-originated OBHC,
whereby the holding company was formed at
the initiative of the bank itself. By so doing,
the bank holding company could diversify
both the range of financial activities it could
perform and the geographic area it served.
Prior to the 1970 amendments to the Bank
Holding Company Act of 1956, OBHCs were
neither required to register with the Board
nor were they subject to the act's restrictions.
Many of the activities performed by OBHCs,
though financial in nature, were activities
prohibited both to banks per se and to
NOTE: Numbers in brackets [ ] refer to the numerically
listed bibliography on pages 20-21. Citations are either to
studies the results of which are described in this article or
to scholarly elaborations of topics discussed.

Economic Perspectives

registered (multibank) holding companies.
The term "congeneric” has frequently been
applied to this form of BHC [22, 25, 29].
The rapid growth of OBHCs and their
tendency to acquire nonbanking business
enterprises raised the spectre of theZaibatsu
(large multi-industry combinations common
in Japan) dominating the American economy
and threatening the traditional separation of
banking from commerce. The logic of allow­
ing banks to perform functions indirectly
which they could not perform directly was
questioned. In addition, the combination of
banking with related nonbanking activities
could produce anticompetitive effects. These
concerns precipitated the inclusion of
OBHCs into the act via the 1970amendments,
which restricted OBHCs to the same range of
activities permitted MBHCs and also liberal­
ized the criteria for determining the per­
missibility of new activities.
This article presents, in light of economic
analysis and empirical evidence, the issues
surrounding BHC entry into nonbanking ac­
tivities. These issues include the permissible
nonbanking activities, diversification, risk and
the soundness of BHCs and the banking
system, concentration and competition,
operating efficiency, and pricing and
profitability. Unfortunately, however, the
empirical evidence available to decide the
issues is scanty because (1) nearly all attention
heretofore has been focused on the banking
aspects of MBHCs; (2) the gathering and
analyzing of data from affiliated nonbanking
subsidiaries is extremely costly; and (3) data
from nonbanking, nonaffiliated firms op­
erating in nonbanking activities are very
limited, thus making meaningful comparisons
difficult.
Permissible activities

The list of permissible nonbanking ac­
tivities for BHCs (see table) has increased only
slightly during the last two years2
—one new
activity was approved, while five proposed ac2
The regulatory status of nonbank activities as of
February 1975 is given in [30, pt. 1, pp. 3-6].

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago



tivities were denied and two were placed
"under consideration.” There are apparently
three reasons for the slackening. To begin
with, the Board has adopted a "go slow”
policy toward all BHC expansion, including
both new activities and the acquiring of non­
banking firms engaged in activities already
permissible. For example, the Board has
denied applications to acquire mortgage
guarantee insurance companies and firms un­
derwriting and dealing in U.S. Government
and certain municipal securities. Although all
of these meet the criteria of being "closely
related to banking” (see below), the Board
apparently did not believe the time and cir­
cumstances were "right” for BHC entry.
In addition, it is conceivable that the list
of permissible activities is close to being ex­
hausted. To be exempt from prohibition,
nonbanking activities must meet a two-part
test. First, each activity must be "closely
related to banking or managing or controlling
banks.” To qualify for exemption, one of the
following connections must be made:
1) that banks generally have in fact
provided the proposed service;
2) that banks generally provide ser­
vices that are operationally or func­
tionally so similar to the proposed ser­
vices as to equip them particularly well
to provide the proposed services;
3) that banks generally provide ser­
vices that are so integrally related to the
proposed services as to require their
provision in a specialized form.3
Second, the activity must be "a proper in­
cident” to banking and must pass a "net
public benefits” test, requiring that the possi­
ble benefits to the public—greater con­
venience, increased competition, or efficien­
cy gains accruing from the acquisition—
outweigh possible adverse effects—increased
concentration, decreased competition, or
unsound banking practices. Since many of the
activities clearly meeting both these criteria
have already been approved by the Board, the
3F e d e r a l R e s e r v e B u l l e t i n ,

February, 1976, p. 149.

13

1

Status of bank holding company
nonbanking activities under
Section 4(c)(8)
fas

o f M a r c h 11, 1977)

Activities approved by the Board
1. Dealer in bankers’ acceptances2
2. Mortgage banking2
3. Finance companies2
a. consum er

4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.

13.
14.
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
20.
21.
22.

b. sales
c. commercial
Credit card issuance2
Factoring company2
Industrial banking
Servicing loans2
Trust company2
Investment advising2
General economic information2
Portfolio investment advice2
Full payout leasing2
a. personal property
b. real property
Community welfare investments2
Bookkeeping & data processing services2
Insurance agent or broker— credit
extensions2
Underwriting credit life & credit accident &
health insurance
Courier service2
Management consulting to nonaffiliate
banks2
Issuance of travelers checks2
Bullion broker2
Land escrow services1
-2
Issuing money orders and variable
denominated payment instruments1 -4
-2

Activities denied by the Board
1. Equity funding (combined sale of mutual
funds & insurance)
2. Underwriting general life insurance
3. Real estate brokerage2
4. Land development
5. Real estate syndication
6. General management consulting
7. Property management
8. Nonfull-payout leasing1
9. Commodity trading1
10. Issuance and sale of short-term debt
obligations (“ thrift notes”)1
11. Travel agency1
-2
12. Savings and loan associations1
Activities pending before the Board
1. Armored car services2
2. Underwriting mortgage guarantee
insurance3
3. Underwriting & dealing in U.S. Government
and certain municipal securities2
-3
4. Underwriting the deductible part of
bankers’ blanket bond insurance
(withdrawn)1
5. Management consulting to nonaffiliated,
depository type, financial institutions1
-2

'Added to list since January 1, 1975.
-Activities permissible to national banks.
3
These were found to be “closely related to banking” but the proposed acquisitions were denied by the
Board of Governors as part of its “go slow” policy.
4 be decided on a case-by-case basis.
To

14




Economic Perspectives

number of future additions to the list of per­
missible activities is likely to be small. In
February the Board determined that the
ownership of savings and loan associations by
BHCs is not a permissable activity. Although
considered “ closely related to banking/' in
the Board's view the potential adverse effects
of affiliation with banking outweigh the
potential benefits.
Lastly, the adverse economic conditions
during the 1973-75 period caused serious
financial problems for some BHCs resulting in
the fall of BHC stock prices and contributing
to the Board's “ go slow" policy. Many BHCs
have been reluctant to push for either new ac­
tivities or new acquisitions, which has been
reflected by a considerable reduction in BHC
applications of both types being submitted to
the Board in recent years. However, as
economic conditions improve, this trend is
likely to be reversed [26].
The Board has been criticized by some
for being too permissive with respect to the
activities BHCs are allowed to perform, while
it has been criticized by others for being
too restrictive. Clearly, both criticisms cannot
simultaneously be correct, and they serve to
highlight certain problems faced by the Board
in ruling on proposed activities.
First, the words “ closely related to bank­
ing" in Section 4(c)(8) of the act are extremely
vague. Essentially, the interpretation was left
up to the Board, subject to judicial review. To
some degree the Board may feel constrained
by what it believes the courts will accept.
Second, it appears that the Board, in mak­
ing its determinations on activities, considers
those activities which are permissible for
national banks. With a few exceptions the
permissible activities for bank holding com­
panies and national banks are nearly identical
(see table). Thus the range of activities BHCs
may perform is not very different from that of
many banks.
Two other facets of the controversy over
the nonbanking activities of BHCs should be
noted. While the list of permissible activities is
impressive, BHC entry by acquisition has
been predominantly limited to three areas:
consumer and commercial finance, mortgage
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago




banking, and insurance (underwriting and
broker or agency) [26]. De novo entry has, by
and large, been limited to these three plus
leasing and advisory services. Intuitively,
these activities seem to afford the greatest
opportunity for the application of banking
expertise.
Given the controversy surrounding the
importance and range of nonbanking ac­
tivities, one would expect that these activities
constitute a relatively significant proportion
of the BHC organization. Quite the contrary is
true, however. Currently, nonbanking sub­
sidiaries account for less than 5 percent of the
total consolidated assets of BHCs [8, 32] and
about 3 percent of the assets of the largest 50
BHCs [33].
Risk, soundness, and BHCs

Perhaps the most important and con­
troversial current issue regarding entry of
BHCs into nonbank activities has been the im­
pact of such expansion and diversification
upon the integrity and soundness of affiliate
banks, the holding company, and the banking
system. Although BHCs entered nonbanking
areas en masse following the 1970 amend­
ments, entry into these activities has subsided
while the controversy has continued.
Proponents of BHC expansion argue that
through acquisition of nonbank subsidiaries,
the overall level of risk for a given level of
return can be lowered, thereby strengthening
the BHC and, consequently, the banking
system. Performance of nonbank activities
allows a BHC to diversify both by activity and
by geographic market area, especially since
nonbank activities may be performed across
state lines. Ever since the advent of mul­
tiproduct and multimarket firms, the logic of
diversification has been employed by firms in
nonregulated industries to stabilize the
profitability of the total organization by in­
sulating it from seasonal or cyclical variations
affecting the organization's component
divisions.
Opponents of BHC expansion question
whether entry into nonbank activities has ac­
tually stabilized the banking industry by
15

reducing risk per dollar of investment. They
also raise issues regarding permissible types of
risks for BHCs.
The spectrum of alternatives ranges from
permitting BHCs to engage in no activity
riskier than traditional banking services to
allowing BHCs to undertake activities con­
sidered much riskier than the basic functions
of banking. The Board’s position on BHC ac­
tivities appears to be about midway between
these two extremes.
The assessment of risks differs among
depositors, managers, owners, and regula­
tors. The Board, however, must view the
riskiness of nonbank activities within thecontext of safety for the entire banking system, a
constraint not imposed by the other groups.
That is, the Board must consider the riskiness
of each activity with respect to the bank af­
filiate and ultimately upon the banking
system, whereas the other groups view the
bank affiliate as one of several activities to be
performed by the enterprise.
Economists and financial analysts dis­
agree over methods for quantifying risk, giv­
ing rise to many views regarding the iden­
tification and objective measurement of
various risks. Consequently, the relationship
between diversification and risk and the
resultant impacts on the soundness of in­
dividual BHCs and the entire banking system
is difficult to assess.
Risk is essentially the lack of perfect
knowledge in making decisions. A relevant
measure of BHC performance is the mean, or
average, rate of return either on assets or
equity capital. A frequently used, but not un­
iversally accepted, statistical measure of risk is
the standard deviation (or variance) of the
rate of return, which shows the dispersion
(variation) of the profit rate about its average
value.
Two principal views exist regarding the
relationship of risk, diversification, and per­
missible BHC activities. One view holds that
risk, measured by the standard deviation or
variance of the rate of return alone, is a suf­
ficient criterion for determining the
desirability of entering nonbank activities.
Any activity having a greater variance in its
16




rate of return than banking is defined as being
riskier than banking, and some analysts ex­
tend this to say these should not be permissi­
ble activities. A second view holds that
variance alone is not a sufficient criterion.
Rather, the proper criterion in evaluating ac­
tivities should be risk relative to the expected,
or average, return, although some upper limit
to the amount of risk appropriate for BHCs to
assume is probably implicit.
In combining two activities, risk becomes
a function not only of the individual
variances, but also of the degree of correla­
tion between the profit rates of the activities.
If the profit rate of two activities exhibits
negative correlation, thevarianceof thecombined profit rate, and thus the risk, will be
lower than each activity taken alone. If the ac­
tivities are positively correlated, the advan­
tages of diversification may still exist. Com­
bining activities having positive correlation
between the rates of return may possibly in­
crease the total risk but reduce the risk
relative to the total level of production. The
return to the BHC, as with any investment
portfolio, is likely to be more stable the wider
the range of activities (industry securities)
held. In general, firms in the same industry are
more likely to do poorly at the same time than
are firms in unrelated industries.
An interesting situation arises regarding
those activities that pass the "closely related
to banking” test of Section 4(c)(8) of the act.
The more closely related the nonbank activity
is to banking, the more likely there will be a
positive correlation between the profits of
that activity and banking, and the smaller the
advantages arising from the diversification
principles. BHCs can, therefore, reduce their
relative risk exposure most by expanding into
the nonbank areas most remotefrom banking
(unless earnings variances are a great deal
higher than in banking). From 1956-70 only
one activity—banking—was explicitly per­
mitted bank holding companies by the act,
and little exercise of the diversification
motive was open to BHCs.
The justification for diversification is not
solely restricted to the expected reduction in
the variation of profits. Diversification also
Economic Perspectives

helps mitigate uncertainty; in particular, by
lessening a BHC's dependence on one activi­
ty, it reduces the potential losses if that activity
were to become obsolete or unnecessary.
Before we can make any assessment of
the impact diversification has had upon the
soundness of the banking system, we must
know the risk levels associated with each of
the nonbanking activities BHCs are likely to
enter, as well as the degree of correlation
between their profits and profits in banking.4
Because nonbanking activities are re­
quired to be “ closely related to banking," one
might expect the correlation between the
profits of banking and several of the non­
banking activities to be positive since they
would be subject to common influences.
While limited empirical evidence exists on
this issue, one study indicates that the profits
of several permissible nonbank activities are
negatively correlated with bank profits,
suggesting that it is possible to significantly
reduce a BHC's level of overall risk by diver­
sifying into these activities [14]. For example,
the returns in insurance and real estate finan­
cing tend to be high when returns in banking
are low. On the other hand, the profitability
of other nonbank activities—such as business
credit, consumer credit, and loan servicing—
exhibits a positive correlation with bank
profits. The different leasing functions have
mixed correlations. These correlations are
based upon the profits of each industry and
are predicated on the activities being per­
formed independently. Once banking is
combined with another activity under the
same corporate umbrella, these correlations
may no longer hold.
With respect to measuring the degree of
risk in various activities, the evidence is
somewhat contradictory. One study, measur­
ing risk by the coefficient of variation of in­
dustry profit rates (the standard deviation of
the profit rate divided by the average profit
4lndustrial firms practicing diversification have not
enjoyed unequivocal success. Diversification p e r s e may
not have been the cause of this lack of success, however,
since too rapid growth and expansion, undercapitaliza­
tion, and adverse economic conditions may also have
contributed to their lackluster performance.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago



rate), found banking to be one of the most
risky activities that BHCs are allowed to per­
form [14]. Another study, measuring risk by
the standard deviation in the monthly rate of
return on the common stock of firms in
various industries over the 1961-68 period,
found banking to be the least risky of the ac­
tivities considered [11]. While both studies
have shortcomings, the latter was character­
ized by a very small sample size (e.g., only 19
banks, two mortgage banking firms, one in­
surance company). Moreover, the return
(and standard deviation) was computed on a
monthly basis, which would seem to be
meaningful only from the viewpoint of the
small investor. The actual annual profits of the
firm—an item of major interest to managers,
controlling owners, and regulators in assess­
ing risk—were ignored in the study.
Thus, empirical evidence currently is not
sufficient to judge which nonbanking ac­
tivities, taken in isolation, are more risky than
banking and which are less risky; nor is it ade­
quate to identify those activities having the
greatest stabilizing effect on holding com­
pany profits.
While the variation in and correlation of
profits are important concerns in dealing with
soundness, they are not the only concerns.
Another is the problem of capitalization, both
of the BHC and of the nonbank affiliate. The
question has been raised whether parent
holding
companies tend to be under­
capitalized [5, 21, 34], and there is some
evidence to indicate that they are [21]. Also,
some evidence suggests that BHC nonbank
affiliates in consumer finance and mortgage
banking have lower equity capital-to-total
asset ratios than the respective industry stan­
dards [35] (referred to as leverage, but this is
only one of several possible definitions in
use). Whether BHC nonbank subsidiaries in
other activities are more highly leveraged
than their nonaffiliated competitors is not
known. Furthermore, the statistical method­
ology is somewhat faulty in that no effort was
made to measure each firm's leverage ratio
prior to acquisition. It is conceivable that the
preacquisition leverage was also higher than
the industry standards.

17

In the final analysis, however, a more
preferable method of evaluating the
soundness of the banking system might be to
simultaneously examine the mean and
variance of earnings and the capital structure
[36]. While this approach seems intuitively
appealing, most studies have focused on one
or the other.
Other factors play important roles in
determining the soundness of the banking
and financial sectors. For example, the
soundness of any business entity depends
upon the degree to which it is legally in­
sulated from the other bank or nonbank com­
panies with which it is affiliated. Soundness
also depends upon the degree to which BHCs
provide their affiliates with financial and
managerial resources, thereby strengthening
the affiliates. By instituting more aggres­
siveness and risk into the operating policies of
affiliates or introducing intersubsidiary trans­
actions having the eventual effect of
weakening the bank or other affiliates, BHCs
could significantly weaken themselves and
the banking and financial sectors. These con­
siderations are important, but at the present
time we have little knowledge of their extent
and impact.
In sum, it appears at this time that we are a
long way from having any definite knowledge
of the impact of the nonbank activities of
BHCs upon the soundness of the banking and
financial sectors. The partial evidence which
is available provides tenuous answers at best.
As a final thought, it should be noted that
even if entry into the nonbank activities were
to reduce the risk of failure for the BHC, the
external social cost of failure will very likely
rise because as the organization becomes
larger, the absolute cost of failure both to the
organization and to the financial system also
becomes greater [5]. Therefore, the net effect
depends on what happens to the “ expected
cost" of failure, obtained by multiplying the
increased cost of failure by the reduced
probability of occurrence.
But, to the extent that nonbank expan­
sion is a substitute, rather than a complement,
to bank expansion, the overall size of BHCs
need not increase.
18




Concentration and competition

After the 1970 amendments were passed,
BHCs moved rapidly into many of the per­
missible nonbanking areas, creating concern
about the impact this expansion would have
upon the concentration of economic re­
sources.5 One of the primary factors the
Board is required to consider under Section
4(c)(8) of the act is the prevention of “ an un­
due concentration of resources." Typically,
concentration is discussed at three levels:
aggregate or nationwide concentration,
statewide concentration, and local or market
concentration. Unfortunately, comment on
the effects of nonbanking activities upon
statewide concentration is not possible at this
time because no work has been done in the
area.
Aggregate concentration. Since BHCs
participate in banking as well as nonbanking
(but closely related to banking) activities, the
phrase “ concentration of resources" must
refer to financial resources. Between 1966 and
1973 the share of total financial assets held by
the largest 100 BHCs increased from 16 per­
cent to 29 percent [33].6While this increase is
substantial, it is questionable whether a 29
percent share accounted for by the largest 100
firms constitutes undue concentration by the
standards of most U.S. “ industries." It should
be kept in mind, however, that BHC entry into
the nonbanking areas has not been uniform
across activities.
On the other hand, it does not appear
that BHC entry into nonbankingactivities,per
se, has been a major contributor to this in­
crease in aggregate concentration. The Board
has limited entry into these activities largely to
either de novo or foothold entry; as a result,
nonbank assets account for less than 5 per­
cent of consolidated holding company assets
for all U.S. BHCs and only 3 percent for the
largest 50 BHCs. While the amount of assets
5
For a fuller conceptual discussion of concentration
and competition, see [9].
Excluding foreign branch assets, however, the
figures are 15 percent and 24 percent, respectively. The
largest relative increase has thus been in this category.

Economic Perspectives

held in nonbank activities has been growing,
it does not explain the 13 percentage point in­
crease in the share of financial assets held by
the 100 largest BHCs. Rather, this change
appears to be more likely a result of the in­
creased use by large banks of nondeposit
sources of funds to finance asset growth.
Local (market) concentration. Market
concentration is, by far, the most important
measure of concentration because it is most
closely associated with the degree of com­
petition in a local area [9]. While there is no
direct evidence on this issue with respect to
nonbank activities, it may be possible to get
some insight into the future by looking at the
Board’s policies related to permissible forms
of entry into nonbank activities.
The Board seems to be following a twopart policy regarding BHC entry into the non­
banking areas. First, the acquisition of large
firms (i.e., firms having a large share of the
market) is discouraged [17]. Second, entry
into new markets by either de novo or
foothold means is encouraged. In particular,
the Board has made de novo entry ad­
ministratively much simpler than the acquisi­
tion of a going concern. De novo entry has
been emphasized because it adds a new deci­
sion maker to the market and increases the
number of competing firms, thereby raising
the likelihood that BHC entry will have a
procompetitive effect. De novo entry would
probably be less prevalent in the absence of
the act and the Board’s enforcement policies.
With regard to credit services it is possi­
ble that BHC activity has improved the alloca­
tion of financial resources. Being able to ex­
pand geographically, especially interstate, has
allowed BHCs to compete over a wider area,
and thereby offer credit in locations where
the demand is greatest.
At the same time, however, the magni­
tude of mortgage lending has apparently not
been affected by BHC affiliation. Preliminary
evidence indicates affiliated mortgage banks
grow no faster than nonaffiliated mortgage
banks, while commercial banks neither in­
crease nor decrease their mortgage lending
activity upon affiliation with a mortgage bank
[27]. '
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago




Operating efficiency

Improved operating efficiency for non­
bank firms is a commonly cited benefit of af­
filiation with a bank holding company. That is,
through affiliation, the nonbank firm can
potentially achieve some cost reductions
through the parent holding company’sability
to generate new business for the nonbank af­
filiate, thus increasing the affiliate's level of
output. If the affiliate is operating on the
downward sloping portion of its average cost
curve, this increase in ouput could then be
translated into lower unit cost. The public
would benefit if and when this lower unit cost
is passed on in the form of lower charges.
Even if they are not passed on, lower
operating costs would increase the
profitability of the bank holding company,
thus enhancing the strength of the banking
and financial systems.
A second source of potential cost savings
arises from economies of affiliation, which
could result if some of the functions previous­
ly performed by the independent firm were
centralized at the BHC level or if the purchase
of some inputs was centralized. For example,
since the parent company may have greater
access to the capital market, it may be able to
acquire capital funds for the affiliate at a lower
rate than an independent firm of equal size
could obtain.
While these arguments have intuitive
appeal, at the present time there is no
evidence to support them. No systematic ef­
fort has been made to study empirically the
impact of BHC affiliation upon the operating
costs of nonbanking firms. On the other
hand, studies examining the impact of affilia­
tion upon banking firms indicate that af­
filiated banks, for some reasons, have higher
costs than independent banks [9]. While the
exact causes of this phenomenon have not
been determined, one possible reason is that
affiliate banks are subject to higher charges
from the nonbank subsidiaries or the parent
holding company [9]. A definitive judgment
cannot be made at this time as to the impact of
affiliation upon the operating efficiency of

19

firms engaged in nonbanking activities; more
work needs to be done in this area.
Pricing and profitability

Pricing. In the eyes of the Board public
benefits arise from BHC performance of non­
bank activities when affiliates charge lower
prices for any given service than their nonaffiliated competitors. Empirical evidence on
this issue is sparse and provides little insight.
The only nonbanking activity about which
there is any evidence is insurance un­
derwriting. Regulation Y stipulates that BHCs
cannot underwrite credit life, accident, or
health insurance unless the premiums char­
ged are less than the ceiling rates established
by the state. According to a recent study
analyzing the results of this policy, rates
charged by BHC affiliates in 1974 resulted in
approximately a 13 percent savings in
premiums [28].
Profitability. Because of the lack of infor­
mation concerning either the operating ef­
ficiency or pricing of nonbank affiliates, the
impact of affiliation on the profitability of
nonbank companies cannot be predicted.
However, a recent study covering 1973 and
1974 indicates that the rates of return on in­
vested capital in two of the more popular
nonbank activities—mortgage banking and
consumer finance—are considerably lower
for BHC affiliates than for each respective in­
dustry as a whole [35]. There are at least three

reasons for this occurrence. First, because of
their comparatively recent entry into these
activities, BHC affiliates could be charging
lower prices in an effort to attract customers
from their longer-established competitors;
second, affiliates could be incurring higher
costs; or third, affiliates could be carrying
higher levels of invested capital than the
average firm in the industry (which con­
tradicts Talley's study). Some combination of
the three is also possible. At the present time,
however, which influences may predominate
is not ascertainable. Additionally, because the
profitability of these firms priortoaffiliation is
not known, their lower rates of return may
not be due to affiliation.
Summary

Nonbanking activities of BHCsarea hotly
contested issue which will become even more
heated in the future. To draw any definitive
conclusions, based on evidence available at
this time, about the efficacy of BHC entry into
the nonbanking areas and the resultant im­
pact on the financial system would be
overstepping the bounds of credibility.
Evidence to support any conclusions is lack­
ing both in quantity and quality, and unfor­
tunately, if historical experience is a guide,
probably half a decadewill pass before we are
in a position to make a more definitive
declaration.
Dale S. Drum

Bibliography
1. Baker, Donald. “An Antitrust Look at the One-Bank
Holding Company.” In Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago. P r o c e e d i n g s o f a C o n f e r e n c e o n B a n k
S t r u c t u r e a n d C o m p e t i t i o n . . .7969, pp. 125-31.
Chicago, 1969.
2. Bunting, John R. “One-Bank Holding Companies: A
Banker’s View.” H a r v a r d B u s i n e s s R e v i e w , XXXXVIII (May/June, 1969), 99-106.
3. Chase, Samuel B., Jr. “Bank Holding Companies, the
Profit Motive and the Public Interest.” In Federal
R e se rve Bank of M in n e ap o lis. B a n k i n g
Organizations a n d Their R egu lation : P rocee d in g s
o f a C o n f e r e n c e . . .1973,

1974.

20



pp. 15-21. Minneapolis,

4. Chase, Samuel B., Jr. “The Bank Holding Company as
a Device for Sheltering Banks from Risk.” In
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. P r o c e e d i n g s o f a
C onference
petition. .

on

Bank

Structure

and

Com ­

.7977, pp. 38-54. Chicago, 1971.

5. Chase, Samuel B., Jr. and M ingo, John J “The
.
Regulation of Bank Holding Companies.” J o u r n a l
o f F i n a n c e , XXX (May, 1975), 281-92.
6. Childs, Bradley D. “Bank Holding Company Ac­
quisitions: The Role of Non-Banking Financial Ac­
tivities.” B a n k A d m i n i s t r a t i o n , LI (August, 1975),
30-33.

Economic Perspectives

7. Coldwell, Phillip E. “Ten C's of Holding Company
Regulation.” Remarks before the Fall meeting of
the Association of Bank Holding Companies,
Phoenix, Arizona, November 1976.

22. Mote, Larry R. “The One-Bank Holding Company—
History, Issues, and Pending Legislation.” B u s in e s s
C o n d i t i o n s , Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, July
1970, 2-16.

8. Coldwell, Phillip E. "Statement before the Subcom­
mittee on Financial Institutions Supervision,
Regulation, and Insurance of the Committee on
Banking, Currency, and Housing, U.S. House of
Representatives.” F e d e r a l R e s e r v e B u ll e t in , LXII
(February, 1976), 113-19.

23. Nader, Ralph, and Brown, Jonathan. “Disclosure and
Bank Soundness: Non Bank Activities of Bank
Holding Companies.” Washington, Public Interest
Research Group, June 30, 1976.

9. Drum, Dale S. “M BH Cs: Evidence After Two
Decades.” B u s i n e s s C o n d i t i o n s , Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago, December 1976, 3-15.
10. Edwards, Franklin R. “Tie-In Sales in Banking and
O n e -B an k H o ld in g C om panies.” A n t i t r u s t
B u l l e t i n , XIV (Fall, 1969), 587-605.
11. Eisemann, Peter C. “Diversification and the C o n ­
generic Bank Holding Company.” J o u r n a l o f B a n k
R e s e a r c h , VII (Spring, 1976), 68-77.
12. Fischer, Gerald. “Market Extension by Bank Holding
Companies: History, Economic Implications, and
Current Issues.” In Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago. P r o c e e d i n g s o f a C o n f e r e n c e o n B an k
S t r u c t u r e a n d C o m p e t i t i o n . . .7969, pp. 43-72.
Chicago, 1969.
13. Hall, George. “Some Impacts of One-Bank Holding
Companies.” In Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
P ro ce e d in g s o f a C o n f e r e n c e o n Bank Stru cture
and C om petition. .

.7969, pp. 73-94. Chicago, 1969.

14. Heggestad, Arnold A. “Riskiness of Investments in
Nonbank Activities by Bank Holding Companies.”
J o u r n a l o f E c o n o m i c s a n d B u s i n e s s , XXXXVII (Spr­
ing, 1975), 219-23.
15. Holland, Robert C. “Bank Holding Companies and
Financial Stability.” J o u r n a l o f F in a n c ia l & Q u a n ­
titative A n a ly s is , X (November, 1975), 577-87.
16. Jessee, Michael A. "A n Analysis of Risk-Taking
Behavior in Bank Holding Companies.” Ph.D. Dis­
sertation, University of Pennsylvania, 1976.
17. Jessee, Michael A., and Seelig, Steven A. "A n
Analysis of the Public Benefits Test of the Bank
Holding Company Act.” M o n t h l y R e v i e w , Federal
Reserve Bank of New York, June 1974, 151-62.

24. Nadler, Paul S. “One-Bank Holding Companies: The
Public Interest.” H a r v a r d B u s i n e s s R e v i e w , XXXX­
VII (May/June, 1969), 107-13.
25. “One-Bank Holding Companies Before the 1970
Amendments.” F e d e r a l R e s e r v e B u l l e t i n , LVII
(December, 1972), 999-1008.
26. Rhoades, Stephen A. “Changes in the Structure of
Bank Holding Companies Since 1970.” B a n k A d ­
m i n i s t r a t i o n , Lll (October, 1976), 64-69.
27. Rhoades, S. A. “The Effect of Bank-Holding Com ­
pany Acquisitions of Mortgage Bankers on
Mortgage Lending Activity.” J o u r n a l o f B u si n es s ,
XXXXVIII (July, 1975), 344-48.
28. Rosenblum, Harvey. “A Cost-Benefit Analysis of the
Bank HoldingCom pany Act of 1956.” Unpublished
paper presented at the Western Economic Associa­
tion Conference, San Francisco, California, June,
1976.
29. Rosenblum, Harvey. "Bank Holding Companies: An
Overview.” B u s i n e s s C o n d i t i o n s , Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago, August 1973, 3-13.
30. Rosenblum, Harvey. “ Bank Holding Company
Review, 1973/74.” B u s i n e s s C o n d i t i o n s , Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, Pt. I: February 1975,3-10;
Pt. II: April 1975, 13-15.
31. Salley, Charles D. “1970 Bank Holding Company
Amendments: What is ‘Closely Related to
Banking?’” M o n t h l y R e v i e w , Federal Reserve Bank
of Atlanta, June 1971, 98-106.
32. Schotland, Roy A. “Bank Holding Companies and
Public Policy Today.” In U.S. Congress. House.
Committee on Banking, Currency and Housing.
FINE, F in a n c ia l I n s t i t u t i o n s a n d t h e N a t i o n ’s
E c o n o m y : Book I, pp. 233-83. Committee Print.
94th Congress, 2d session, 1976.

18. Johnson, Richard B., ed. T h e B a n k H o l d i n g Com ­
pany, 1973. Dallas: Southern Methodist University
Press, 1973.

33. Seelig, Steven A. “Aggregate Concentration and
the Bank Holding Company Movement.” Un­
published paper, Fordham University, 1976.

19. Lawrence, Robert J., and Talley, Samuel H. “An
Assessment of Bank Holding Companies.” F e d e r a l
R e s e r v e B u l l e t i n , LXII (January, 1976), 15-21.

34. Silverberg, Stanley C . “BankHoldingCom paniesand
Capital Adequacy.” J o u r n a l o f B a n k R e s e a r c h , VI
(Autumn, 1975), 202-7.
35. Talley, Samuel H. “Bank Holding Company Perfor­
mance in Consumer Finance and Mortgage Bank­
ing.” B a n k A d m i n i s t r a t i o n , Lll (July, 1976), 42-44.
36. Wolkowitz, B e nj a m i n . “ M e a s u r i n g
Bank
Soundness.” In Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.

20. Lerner, E. M . “Three Financial Problems Facing Bank
Holding Companies.” J o u r n a l o f M o n e y C r e d i t &
B a n k i n g , IV (May, 1972), 445-55.
21. M ingo, John J., Rhoades, Steven A., and Wolkowitz,
Benjamin. “Risk and Its Implications for the Bank­
ing System.” B a n k A d m i n i s t r a t i o n , LI I, Pt. I:
February 1976, 52-58; Pt. II: March 1976, 47-51.

DigitizedFederal Reserve Bank of Chicago
for FRASER


P ro ce e d in g s o f a C o n f e r e n c e o n Bank S tru cture
a n d C o m p e t i t i o n . . .1975, p p . 73-84. C h i c a g o , 1975.

21

State and local government
deposits in the district
Laws and deposit allocation
Individuals and business firms in the United
States have a significant amount of latitude in
selecting financial institutions that will meet
their needs for depository services. The
choice may be made from any of the more
than 14,000 commercial banks located in the
50 states, although in practice, most small ac­
count owners limit themselves to locally
available alternatives. In addition, depository
services are provided by approximately 5,000
savings and loan associations, more than 475
mutual savings banks, and more than 22,000
credit unions. While certain economic
factors—such as transactions cost and travel
time needed to conduct business—and non­
economic considerations—such as con­
venience of location—tend to influence the
private sector's selection of alternative finan­
cial institutions, there are few legal barriers
that have a direct impact upon the depository
selection process. The one important legal
barrier that limits the choice is that nonbank
financial institutions are prohibited in most
states from offering demand deposit services.
On the other hand, state and local
governments, in selecting institutions that will
meet their needs for depository services, are
subject to specific statutory and constitutional
restrictions tending to limit their alternatives,
usually as to type and location of institution.
As such, laws that influence the allocation of
public funds between and among various
banks and other types of financial institutions
have a definite impact upon the structure of
banking. This article examines the legal
framework influencing the allocation of state
and local deposits and analyzes the impact of
these laws upon the banking structure of the
five Seventh District states— Illinois, Indiana,
Iowa, Michigan, and Wisconsin.

22



State and local deposit importance

In both absolute and relative terms
deposits of state and local governments are
becoming increasingly important items on
the balance sheets of the nation's commercial
banks.
In a 1961 study the Advisory Commission
on Intergovernmental Relations noted that as
of June 1959, “ Of the approximately $14.2
billion on deposit by state and local
governments $3.7 billion was on time deposit
and $10.4 billion on demand deposit."1 By
June 30, 1975 total deposits of state and local
governments in commercial banks had grown
to approximately $67.0 billion, of which $48.5
billion was in the form of time deposits and
$18.5 billion was in the form of demand
deposits.* The data reveal that during the
2
past 16 years (June 1959-June 1975) total state
and local deposits held by commercial banks
have grown at a compounded annual rate of
approximately 10.2 percent, while individual,
partnership, and corporate (IPC) deposits
(i.e., private sector deposits) grew at only a 7
percent compounded annual rate. Of equal
significance is the reversal of the composition
of those deposits. Whereas in 1959 demand
deposits constituted the major portion of
total state and local deposits (approximately
73.3 percent), as of June 30,1975 time deposits
accounted for the major portion of total state
and local deposits (approximately 72.4 per­
cent). During the 16-year period state and
local government demand deposits have
' I n v e s t m e n t o f Id le C a s h B a l a n c e s b y St a t e a n d L o c a l
G o v e r n m e n t s , Advisory Commission on Intergovern­

mental Relations, Washington, D.C., January 1961, p. 14.
2A s s e t s a n d Li abi lit ie s: C o m m e r c i a l a n d
Sa v in g s B an ks , FDIC, December 1975.

Mututal

Economic Perspectives

grown at a compounded annual rate of only
approximately 3.6 percent, whereas, time
deposits of state and local governments over
the same period have grown at a com­
pounded annual rate of approximately 17.5
percent, a 13-fold increase.
Figure 1 illustrates the growth and chang­
ing composition of state and local deposits
over the 16-year period 1959-75. The change
from demand to time deposits reflects the
growing concern on the part of state and local
governments to invest their idle cash balances
so as to maximize earnings on public funds, a
concern heightened by the increase in
average interest rate levels over this period.
Further insight into the growing impor­
tance of state and local government deposits
is revealed in the analysis of the overall com­
position of commercial bank deposits. In June
1959 state and local government deposits ac­
counted for 6.8 percent of total deposits in in­
sured commercial banks. By June 1975 state
and local deposits constituted 8.8 percent of
total deposits in all commercial banks.
Except for "small banks" (deposits less
than $1 million) state and local deposits have
become an increasingly important source of
funds for banks of all sizes. As shown in Table

1, state and local deposits as of June 1959
amounted to over 11 percent of the total
deposits in "small banks" but accounted for
only 4 percent of total deposits held in the
nation's largest banks, i.e., those with deposits
of $1 billion or more. Since 1959 state and
local deposits have become less important
deposit sources at "small banks” and in­
creasingly important sources of deposits for
"large banks." In 1959 only one bank group
(those with less than $1 million in deposits)
had state and local deposits that constituted
10 percent or more of their total deposits. In
1975 two groups of banks held state and local
deposits that represented about 10 percent of
their total deposits, and in one group state
and local deposits accounted for over 11 per­
cent of the total deposits. Thus, state and local
government deposits are becoming a more
significant item on the balance sheets of com­
mercial banks.
There are 16,092 local governments in the
Seventh Federal Reserve District, including
county, municipal, and township govern­
ments, and school and special districts.3This
represents about 20.6 percent of all local
3Census o f G o v e r n m e n t s , 1972, Bureau of the Cen­
sus, U.S. Department of Commerce.

Figure 1. State and local deposits held by all commercial
banks in the United States
billion dollars

Digitized forFederal Reserve Bank of Chicago
FRASER


billion dollars
70

23

Table 1
Deposits of state and local governments by
commercial bank size
June 10, 1959______________

__________________________ June 30, 1975

(2)^ 0)

Total
deposits

(5)4- (4)

(p e rc e n t)

(m illion s)

(m illion s)

(p e rc e n t)

(4)

Total
deposits
(m illio n s)

(m illio n s)

(1)
Deposit
size of banks

(6)

(5)
Total state
and local
deposits

(2)
Total state
and local
deposits

(3)

Relative change
1959-1975
(6) - (3)

- 4.5

997.5

117.7

11.8

86.6

6.3

7.3

33,997.3

3,312.8

9.7

31,954.5

3,199.7

10.0

+ 0.3

$10 to 100 m illion

53,425.6

4,283.4

8.0

215,518.8

22,169.4

10.3

+ 2.3

$100 to 1 billio n

63,650.9

4,297.9

6.8

212,500.5

23,747.5

11.2

+ 4.4

Less than $1 m illion
$1 to 10 m illion

$1 billio n or m ore

TOTAL

54,634.3

2,142.2

3.9

297,624.8

17,771.1

6.0

+ 2.1

$206,705.7

$14,154.1

6.8

$757,718.2

$66,894.1

8.8

+ 2.0

N ote: Data for 1959 is for insured banks, w h ere asd ata for 1975 is for all banks. N um bers may not add d ue to rounding .
S O U R C E : F D IC , A n n u a l R e p o rt, D e ce m b e r 31,1959 and F D IC , Assets an d Liabilities o f C o m m ercia l an d M u tu a l
Savings Banks. )u ne 30,1975.

governments in the United States. Illinois,
with 6,385, leads the Seventh District and the
nation in the number of local governments.
Indiana, Michigan, Wisconsin, and Iowa have,
respectively, 2,792, 2,649, 2,448, and 1,818
local governments. As of June 30, 1975 state
and local deposits held by all insured com­
mercial banks within the Seventh District
states aggregated approximately $12 billion.
As such, state and local deposits represent ap­
proximately 9.3 percent (see Table 2) of all
deposits held by insured commercial banks
within these states, slightly above the national
average of 8.8 percent.
Of the $12 billion of state and local
deposits held by commercial banks in thefive
states, 74.3 percent was held in time accounts
and 25.7 percent was held in demand ac­
counts. Relative to the nation as a whole,
these figures indicate that, in the aggregate,
state and local governments in the district
states tend to hold a slightly larger proportion
of their total deposits in the form of time or
savings accounts (the national average is 72.4
percent). Table 2 further reveals a con­

24



siderable degree of variance in the impor­
tance of state and local deposits as a source of
funds to commercial banks in the five states.
For example, state and local deposits con­
stitute only about 6.7 percent of total deposits
held by insured commercial banks in Iowa but
13.4 percent of total bank deposits held by In­
diana commercial banks. Also, Indiana,
relative to the four other states, holds the
lowest percentage of state and local deposits
in the form of time and savings deposits (60.3
percent). State and local governments in
Michigan, on the other hand, maintain about
79.4 percent of their total deposits in time and
savings accounts.
Major concerns

Governmental bodies, just like busi­
nesses and private individuals, are faced with
the problems of investing their idle funds. For
state and local governments “ idle funds” are
created by the lack of synchronization
between the receipt of revenues and the out­
flow of cash expenditures. Since state and

Economic Perspectives

Table 2
Deposit composition of insured district banks
as of |une 30, 1975
Illinois

Indiana

Iowa

Michigan

Wisconsin

Total

( b ill io n d o ll a r s )

20.218
37.502
57.720

5.924
10.972
16.8%

3.794
7.129
10.923

9.113
19.905
29.018

4.592
9.834
14.426

43.641
85.342
128.983

Demand deposits of
state and local
governments

1.022

.895

.241

.646

.264

3.068

Time deposits of
state and local
governments

3.555

1.361

.494

2.491

.992

8.893

4.577

2.256

.735

3.137

1.256

11.961

7.93

13.35

6.73

10.81

8.71

9.27

Total demand deposits
Total time deposits
Total deposits

Total state and
local deposits
State and local deposits
as a percent of
total deposits

local government revenues are not received
in sufficient amounts on the day they are re­
quired to meet an expenditure, funds must be
accumulated prior to actual expenditure or
the governmental unit must be able to
borrow needed funds. Most state and local
governments have little if any excess idle cash
at the start of their fiscal years. However, idle
cash may begin to accumulate later as
revenues begin to exceed expenses. At this
point the governmental body must decide
how to invest these funds. Traditionally,
public finance doctrine has specified that
consideration be given to four factors: legali­
ty, safety, liquidity, and yield.4 Some
governments have added a fifth factor to this
list: the promotion of particular social goals.
• Legality. State constitutions and statutes
frequently specify the types of institutions
and financial instruments in which public
funds may, or may not, be employed. For ex­
4
See for example: I n v e s t m e n t o f I d l e F u n d s b y L o c a l
G o v e r n m e n t s : A P r i m e r , John A. Jones and S. Kenneth
Howard. Municipal Finance
Chicago, Illinois, 1973.

Officers

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago



Association,

ample, the Michigan Constitution precludes
savings and loan associations from acting as
depositories for state funds. Thus, public of­
ficers must be aware of the legal limitations
involved when they invest public funds.
• Safety. Speculation with public funds is
prohibited by law, and state statutes frequent­
ly specify that only the safest and most secure
types of investments be permitted. For exam­
ple, the Indiana courts have noted that a
public depository law was adopted primarily
for the security and protection of public funds
against the "devious methods and rascality of
dishonest public officials.”
• Liquidity. Money must be available
when needed. If public funds are invested in
long-term obligations, which are not readily
marketable and which fluctuate greatly in
value, a public body faced with a decline in
revenue may be forced to borrow funds at an
unfavorable rate.
• Yield. After complying with legal re­
quirements, providing for safety and ensur­
ing liquidity, investments that will produce a
maximum yield may be considered. Obvious-

25

ly, after complying with
Table 3
the first three con­
Deposits held by the five largest commercial
straints, the scope of inbanks in each district state as of June 30, 1975
vestm ent options
available with regard to
Rank of bank
Bank’s state and
type of financial institu­
in state_______
Bank’s IPC deposits
________ local deposits________
tion and type of finan­
(b ill io n do ll a r s )
( p e r c e n t ) 1 (m il li o n d o l l a r s )
(p ercent)2
cial in str um e nt is
Illinois
somewhat limited. For
1
7.984
16.3
395
8.6
small governmental
2
6.616
11.6
13.5
529
bodies with small
3
2.016
4.1
118
2.6
amounts of funds to in­
4
1.591
3.3
153
3.3
vest, the alternatives
5
.906
0.4
1.9
20
f r e q u e n t l y na rro w
Indiana
down to time deposits
1
1.017
163
7.2
7.3
at commercial banks
2
.956
174
7.7
6.8
and short-term U.S.
4.7
3
.508
3.6
107
4
.324
2.3
39
1.7
Treasury obligations.
5
.270
1.9
62
2.8
• Social goals. Cer­
Iowa
tain state and local
governments may and
1
.283
37
2.9
5.0
2
.204
2.1
2.6
19
do invest their funds in
3
.152
1.6
08
1.1
order to achieve or
4
1.4
.136
22
3.0
promote certain social
1.4
5
.131
2.7
20
goals. For example,
Michigan
some governments may
1
3.781
15.6
437
13.9
desire (or be required
2
2.259
114
9.3
3.6
by law) to invest and
3
2.090
8.6
145
4.6
deposit idle funds only
4
1.014
4.2
236
7.5
.687
5
2.8
106
3.4
with banks located in­
Wisconsin
state, in-county, or in­
city with the intention
1
1.108
8.8
195
15.5
2
.421
3.3
91
7.2
of fostering local
3
.251
2.0
41
3.3
d e v e l o p m e n t and
4
1.4
.179
21
1.7
economic growth. The
5
97
.165
1.3
7.7
rationale is that state
and local government
’Bank's IPC deposits relative to total commercial bank IPC deposits in
funds will be used by
the state.
local banks to promote
2Bank’s state and local deposits relative to state and local deposits
local investment, which
held by all commercial banks in the state.
will generate more local
income and employ­
ment and thus tax
revenues. Whether this
developmental objective will be achieved
Primary factor influencing allocation
depends on the use banks make of these
funds (i.e., whether or not they are locally in­
Every state and local government has
vested) and the size of the income multiplier
differing investment objectives; some are fac­
associated with locally used funds.
ed with staffing restrictions and others have

26




Economic Perspectives

Illin o is d e p o s ito ry law s

Chapter 130 of the Illinois Statutes sets forth the
major legal parameters for the deposit of state
monies. The law requires that at least once a year the
state treasurer notify “regularly established” nationaland state-chartered banks doing business in Illinois
concerning sealed bids for the deposit of public
monies in his custody. Asworded,thelaw excludes all
but commercial banks located in Illinois from holding
state monies. Two classes of depositories— time and
demand— are required. Securities at least equal in
market value to funds deposited must be pledged by
banks holding state funds. However, no such
securities are required for funds insured by the
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation.
The law requires that at all times at least 20 banks
be approved depositories for time deposits. Only the
state's two largest commercial banks, out of the 1,187
in the state, hold demand deposits, which are com ­
pensating balances for clearing checks and other
necessary services. There is no legal restriction on the
total dollar amounts of Illinois state funds that can be
placed in any one financial depository. However, no
bank can hold state funds until it certifies that it does
not engage in discriminatory lending practices and
pledges within the limits of its legal restrictions and
prudent financial practices, to make loans available
on low- and moderate-income residential property.
The state treasurer’s investment program
currently employs three different means by which
state funds are allocated among commercial banks.
Under the first program, the Basic Deposit
Program, time deposits are awarded for one-year
periods to any Illinois bank, except for major Chicago
banks (the five largest banks in the state), that applies
and meets certain criteria. Factors considered include
the amount of loans outstanding, the rate bid, and the
size of the bank. The second and third investment
programs employ the “linked-deposit” concept. U n­
der these programs time deposits are allocated among
bidding banks on the condition that specific lending
functions are being or will be performed by each
bank.
The second program— the Specific Opportunity

differing management philosophies, all of
which have an impact upon the allocation of
state and local deposits. However, state and
local laws comprise the primary factor that in­
fluences the allocation of state and local
deposits. In every state a body of laws has
evolved that determines the types, location,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago




Program— allocates time deposits to those banks will­
ing to participate in the financing of one or more pro­
jects. For example, in the past, time deposits have
been allocated to banks that have granted loans for
pollution abatement projects or to rural banks to en­
courage them to make agricultural loans.
The third program— the Community Service
Program— utilizes the “linked-deposit” concept to
allocate state deposits on the basis of the bank’s past
history of involvement in making community service
oriented loans. Under this program funds are
allocated annually for a one-year period, and banks
must bid at or above a predetermined minimum rate
set by the state. Banks bidding above the minimum
rate receive larger deposits. In addition, the banks
must report their outstanding loans in 13 categories.
Am ong these categories are bank purchases of local
tax anticipation warrants, student loans, agricultural
loans, Small Business Administration loans, construc­
tion financing for public housing projects, and pollu­
tion abatement loans.
For Illinois counties the county boards, when re­
quested by the county treasurer, are required to
designate one or more banks or other depositories in
which county funds may be deposited. The law does
not require that institutions selected as depositories
bid for county funds. However, the law does stipulate
that county funds deposited in any one bank “shall
not exceed 75 percent of the capital stock and surplus
of such banks.” The county treasurer may require that
securities equal in market value to the amount of the
funds deposited be pledged by the depository.
Illinois law states that a municipal treasurer may
deposit public funds in places designated by local or­
dinance and that the corporate authorities shall
designate a bank or banks to act as public
depositories. Like county deposits, municipal funds,
except for deposits of the city of Chicago, cannot be
deposited in a designated bank in excess of 75 percent
of the bank's capital stock and surplus. Illinois law
places neither geographic restrictions on the location
of banks nor does it require the establishment of a
bidding system for muncipal funds.

and size of institutions as well as types of in­
struments in which public funds may be in­
vested. For the most part these laws
emphasize safety. Public officials charged
with handling public funds determine the
specific allocation based upon the legal
guidelines, of which their power, however, is

21

In d ia n a d e p o s ito ry law s

Section 5, Article 12 of the Indiana Statutes con­
tains the major provisions of the state's public
depository law. The Indiana Department of the
Treasury is required to publish, 20 days before its
biennial meeting, a notice inviting proposals from
banks and trust companies for the deposit of state
funds. Institutions desiring to act as state depositories
must be located within the state. There is no bidding
system per se for state funds in Indiana. Any bank
"suitably located with reference to the convenience
of the officers and state institutions using them” and
agreeing in its proposal to provide the necessary
security is designated as a depository for state funds.
Although the law is somewhat vague with respect to
the allocation of state funds among the designated
depositories, the treasurer maintains balances in each
depository, as nearly as practicable, in proportion to
the total resources that each depository bears to the
total resources of all designated depositories. The
state may deposit idle funds in certificates of deposit
in any national, state, or mutual savings bank with its
principle place of business in the state. With certain
exceptions, the treasurer cannot deposit funds in cer­
tificates of deposit in any one bank in an amount
aggregating more than 50 percent of the combined
capital, surplus, and undivided profits of the institu­
tion. As of June 1975 the state had timedeposits in 396
of the state’s 406 commercial banks and three of the
four mutual savings banks. Between January and June
1975 the state of Indiana maintained demand deposits
in 16 of the state’s commercial banks.
The Indiana Depositories Act does not require
the designated depositories to pledge assets as

a residual. For example, if the law specifies
that public funds may be deposited only in
commercial banks within the state, then
public officials may select one or a number of
banks to hold the deposits, based upon safety,
liquidity, and yield. Assuming that all
available choices offered equal safety and li­
quidity, the bank paying the highest yield
would be chosen as the depository. Clearly,
the more specific the legal guidelines, the
smaller will be the residual prerogatives and
discretion allowed public officials.
The laws that influence the allocation of
public funds vary greatly from state to state

28



collateral for state and local funds held on deposit
because the state has an established public
depositories insurance fund. Under this system the
board of depositories— consisting of the governor,
treasurer, auditor, chairman of the commission for
financial institutions, and chief examiner of the state
board of accounts— is charged with establishing an
assessment rate and base for the insurance fund. The
assessment base isdetermined monthly and isdefined
as the sum of all the minimum balances of public
funds on deposit in each and all accounts during the
month. Every depository of public funds is required to
pay the assessment rate established by the board of
depositories. The rate may not exceed 2 percent per
annum and the maximum reserve for losses may not
exceed 10 percent of the average monthly deposits of
public funds on deposit in depositories during any
one month.
The requirements for the designation and alloca­
tion of funds of Indiana counties, cities, townships,
etc., largely parallel the requirements for the state,
with a few exceptions. First, the designation of
depositories and the allocation of public funds for
these entities is in the hands of specific boards of
finance. Second, the law tends to limit the geographic
scope with respect to the selection of depositories by
the local governments. Specifically, the various
boards of finance are required by law to select
depositories willing to accept public funds located
within their respective counties, cities, towns, or
townships. As in the case of the state, the law calls for
the proportional allocation of public funds among the
designated depositories.

and within the states.5 (See Boxes for more
detail.) Illinois, for example, is the only
Seventh District state that employs a true bid­
ding system by which to allocate state funds.
Indiana, on the other hand, does not use a
bidding system to allocate state funds; rather,
the law calls for the proportional allocation of
state funds among those banks which apply to
be public depositories. In Michigan the Con­
n or a discussion of cash balance management in
other states see: State C a s h B a l a n c e M a n a g e m e n t P o li cy ,
Merlin M . Hackbart and R. S. Johnson. The Council of
State Governments, Lexington, Kentucky, November
1975.

Economic Perspectives

Io w a d e p o sito ry law s

Chapter 453 of the Iowa Statutes sets forth the
major provisions concerning the deposit of the state's
public funds. In Iowa there is no biddingsystem perse
that determines the allocation of state funds. In
general, all deposits made by the treasurer of state,
who may nominate banks to act as depositories, must
be in banks in Iowa. For both the state and its political
subdivisions funds not needed for current operating
expenses may be invested in U.S. Government or
agency guaranteed obligations, or time or savings
deposits in approved commercial banks and insured
savings and loan associations. When state funds are
deposited, they must be at the rate established on a
monthly basis by a committee composed of the state’s
superintendent of banking, commissioner of in­
surance, and treasurer of state. The law does not ex­
plicitly limit the amount of state funds that may be
placed in any one depository nor is there any require­
ment for public depositories to pledge assets against

stitution limits the deposit of state funds to
banks organized under state or national
banking laws. Savings and loan associations
may not act as depositories for state funds.
And in Wisconsin an investment board is
responsible for designating state public
depositories and allocating state funds.6
Clearly, there is little uniformity in the
Seventh District states relative to those laws
which influenceand determinetheallocation
of state and local deposits.
Impact on state banking structure

Legal restrictions on the investment of
state and local funds have had an important
impact on the banking structure in each of the
five states. Table 3 shows the percentage share
of total state IPC deposits and state and local
deposits held by each of the district states' five
largest commercial banks as of June 30,1975.
For example, the largest commercial bank in
6For detailed discussion of the Wisconsin investment
program see: I n v e s t i n g St a te F u n d s : T h e W i s c o n s i n I n ­
v e s t m e n t B o a r d , Dick Floward and James Jarrett. The
Council of State Governments, Lexington, Kentucky,
August 1976.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago




public deposits. Iowa, like Indiana, has an established
state sinking fund to insure against the loss of public
deposits in the event of a bank failure. As of June 30
1975, the fund’s balance was about $203,000.
As in the case of the state, banks must be ap­
proved by the appropriate governing authority
before they can act as depositories for Iowa’s political
subdivisions. The approving board is required to
specify the name of each bank approved and the max­
imum amount that may be kept on deposit in each
bank. County funds must be placed in banks located
in their respective or adjoining counties, city funds in
banks located in the city; but if no bank is in the city,
then any other bank located in the state may act as a
depository. The interest rate paid for deposits is deter­
mined by the public officer or body responsible for
the funds and bank; however, the rate cannot exceed
nor may it be more than 1 percent below the rate es­
tablished for state funds.

Illinois held total IPC deposits of ap­
proximately $8 billion, which represented
16.3 percent of the total IPC deposits held by
all commercial banks in Illinois, but its $395
million in state and local deposits represented
only 8.6 percent of such deposits held by all
commercial banks in Illinois. In two of thefive
states (Iowa and Wisconsin), the five largest
commercial banks hold a significantly larger
proportion of state and local deposits than
they do IPC deposits. In Wisconsin, for exam­
ple, the five largest commercial banks, which
control approximately 16.8 percent of total
IPC deposits, control 35.4 percent of total
state and local deposits. Clearly, this is the
result of the interaction between the law
allowing for the establishment of a working
bank and the Wisconsin Investment Board's
selection (after bidding) of the largest com­
mercial bank to act asthesoleworkingbank.
In Indiana the law calling for the propor­
tional allocation of state and county funds
among designated public depositories is
reflected in the relative shares of public and
private deposits held by the five largest com­
mercial banks. The largest commercial bank
in Indiana holds approximately 7.3 percent of

29

r ------------------------------------------------------------------Michigan depository laws
Michigan is unique, being the only state in the
Seventh Federal Reserve District that has a con­
stitutional provision concerning the deposit of public
funds. Article 9 of the Michigan Constitution specifies
that state funds may not be deposited in any banks
other than those established under national and state
banking laws. This precludes their deposit in savings
and loan associations. Further, the Constitution
specifies that deposits of state money cannot exceed
50 percent of the capital and surplus of the depository.
No bidding system for state funds has been es­
tablished in Michigan. The law merely indicates that
state depositories must pay a rate of interest which the
state treasurer "shall deem best for the interest of the
state.” Furthermore, the state treasurer is required to
obtain “good and ample security” before a bank can
become a depository of state surplus funds. No
collateral is required for public monies which are in­
sured by the FDIC. Under current FDIC regulations

total IPC deposits and 7.2 percent of total state
and local deposits. In the aggregate Indiana's
five largest commercial banks hold about 22
percent of total IPC deposits and about 24
percent of total state and local government
deposits, which tends to indicate that the goal
of proportional allocation is being achieved.
In Illinois and Michigan the five largest
banks in each state tend to hold less than a
proportional amount of state and local
deposits relative to their holdings of IPC
deposits. In Illinois the five largest commer­
cial banks hold approximately 39 percent of
total IPC deposits in the state and ap­
proximately 26.5 percent of state and local
government deposits. Two features in Illinois
law tend to explain this less-thanproportional relationship between private
and public deposits. First, the five largest
banks are precluded from competing for state
funds allocated under the Basic Deposit
Program. Secondly, the "linked-deposit"
allocation schemes used by the state tend to
favor small- or medium-sized banks, which
have or will make specific state-approved
loans. The larger banks tend to be “ money
30



time and savings deposits of state and local
governments, if deposited in the depositor’s own
state, are insured up to $100,000. Public funds in de­
mand accounts and in out-of-state time and savings
deposits are insured only to $40,000. The state prefers
to pool its active balances in one bank, which creates
certain economies (e.g., ease of record keeping, per­
mits maximum investment of free balances, etc.).
Michigan counties are required by law to solicit
sealed bids for the deposit of public funds held by the
county treasurer from all banks within their jurisdic­
tion. If no satisfactory bids are received from banks
within the county, then bids may be solicited from
banks outside the county but within the state.
Collateral at least equal to the maximum amount
deposited is required from banks holding county
funds. No collateral is required for public monies that
are insured by the FDIC. Each county may establish its
own system of allocating public funds.

center” banks which derive a significant share
of their deposits and make a significant share
of their loans on a national or regional basis.
With respect to Michigan, the reason for
the less-than-proportional allocation be­
tween private and public funds is less clear
than it is for Illinois. Part of the explanation
may lie in the state's ability and preference for
using commercial paper as a short-term in­
vestment vehicle relative to certificates of
deposit and time accounts. The state, on
average, tends to invest about 60 percent of its
short-term funds in commercial paper. The
requirement that counties keep their funds in
county banks might further prevent the flow
of public funds to the five largest banks,
which are located in but two counties.
Conclusion

The laws that affect the allocation of state
and local government deposits within the
Seventh District tend to limit the flexibility of
the state and local officials who are responsi­
ble for the management of public funds and
may necessitate a trade-off between various
Economic Perspectives

W is c o n s in d e p o sito ry law s

Relative to the other Seventh District states,
Wisconsin is unique in that it has a seven-member
board responsible for the allocation of state funds.
Known as the Investment Board, it is required to
"designate public depositories for the deposit of
public moneys . . . coming into the hands of the state
treasurer; allocate the deposits of all public moneys
coming into the hands of the state treasurer, and limit
the amount of such public moneys . . .which may be
deposited in any public depository so designated."
Local government idle funds may also be managed by
the Investment Board. Any national, state, or mutual
savings bank in the state can act as a public depository.
Recently, the law was amended to allow savings and
loan associations to act as depositories of public
funds. The Investment Board is responsible for fixing
the rates of interest paid on deposits of the state
treasurer. There is no statutory limit on theamountof
state funds which may be deposited with any one
bank. With respect to state funds the depositories
selected must be located in Wisconsin.
Under Wisconsin law the Investment Board has
the authority to establish “working banks” which
hold state deposits (“active deposits”) on which
checks are drawn to conduct the daily affairs of the
state. This system is similar to the active bank concept
used by Illinois counties. Theworkingbank is primari­
ly responsible for providing the state with its
necessary banking services. Although the law allows
the establishment of more than one working bank,

public goals, such as economic development
and maximizing the rate of return on idle
public funds.
The results of this study reveal that states
which tend to stress efficiency in managing
state and local funds to achieve maximum
returns on invested funds (e.g., Wisconsin)
may have to forego certain social goals which
may be achieved by allocating idle funds,
such as promoting in-state (or in-county)
development and statewide bank participa­
tion in the use of public funds. If the
governmental body decides to select the goal

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago




the Investment Board concluded that the efficiencies
and potential for higher earnings surrounding the use
of one bank outweigh using a number of banks. The
working bank is selected on the basis of bids sub­
mitted by Wisconsin banks. Due to the amount of
work involved in handling the state account and the
amount of deposit variability (which may vary from $2
million to $100 million on any given day) only a wellstaffed and highly computerized bank is able to han­
dle the account.
Chapter 34 of the Wisconsin Statutes states that
public depositories are not required to give collateral
for public deposits. As in the cases of Indiana and
Iowa, Wisconsin has an established state deposit
guarantee fund to insure public deposits, thus
eliminating the requirement that banks pledge
collateral for public deposits.
For the most part the requirements of designating
and allocating funds of political subdivisions are the
same as for the state. O ne difference is that the
designation of publicdepositories is the responsibility
of the governing board of each subdivision— the
governing board for counties being the county board,
for cities the city council, for villages the village board,
and for towns the town board. As in the case of the
state, no security is required for subdivision funds. No
geographic restrictions are placed on public
depositories for subdivision funds other than that
the banks designated must be located within the
state.

of maximizing its return on the investment of
public funds, then the costs and benefits will
be easily measurable in dollar terms.
However, if the selected goal involves the
achievement of social goals (e.g., promoting
development), then the costs and benefits
may be more nebulous and harder to define
given the fungible nature of money. Since
money is a free-flowing object of trade which
ignores political boundaries, attempts to use
state and local deposits to promote social
goals and objectives may be of little avail.
David R. AI lard ice

31

Public Information Center
Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago
P.O. Box 834
Chicago, Illinois 60690
Please attach address label to correspondence
regarding your subscription.