View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

The economy and the
banking system
CONTENTS

The longer-term success o f the
economy and of banking in the free
world depends on a revitalization o f the
free marketplace.

Fuel crisis hits business
The economy reeled this summer
from the impact o f a series of adversities
that ended the four-year upswing.
July/August 1979, Volume III, Issue 4
E C O N O M IC PERSPECTIVES
Single-copy subscriptions of Economic
Perspectives, a bimonthly review, are
available free of charge. Please send requests
for single- and multiple-copy subscriptions,
back issues, and address changes to Public
Information Center, Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, P. O. Box 834, Chicago, Illinois
60690, or telephone (312) 322-5112.
Articles may be reprinted provided
source is credited and Public Information
Center is provided with a copy of the
published material.
Controlled circulation postage
paid at Chicago, Illinois.




3

Municipal bonds in the
housing market
Large municipal bond issues to raise
money for residential mortgages have
gained wide private and public support,
along with government efforts at
prohibition.

9

The economy and the
banking system*
Banking, as we all know, is inextricably
linked with conditions in the economy. How
can the strength of banking be maintained
in the face of the tremendous economic
problems that appear to confront us?
The answer, I think, is becoming in­
creasingly clear. I am convinced that the
longer-term success of the economy and of
banking in our free world is dependent upon
a revitalization of the free marketplace.
S o lu tio n s to general econom ic
problems—whether energy, inflation, or
recession—cannot be based on short-term
myopia or short-circuiting of the free market.
Time and time again we have seen short­
sighted, stop-gap measures fail, only to
witness the reemergence of the same
problems with greater intensity a short time
later. We are in danger of being drugged.
Whether the current economic problems
create major and lasting disturbances to our
economy, or simply require modest ad­
justments, depends on the nature of our
response. If, for example, we react to our
current inflation problem by adopting drastic
policies designed to cure inflation within the
next year, we will surely compound our dif­
ficulties in the long run. The problem is best
attacked by policies of moderation, pursued
with unremitting determination, over a
period of years.
Similarly, in thecaseof our oil problem, if
we attempt through the construction of a vast
set of rules and regulations to ensure equity in
distributing the burden of the reduced supply
of oil and soften its impact on favored
sectors—as the United States is trying so hard
•Excerpt from a speech made by M r. Robert P.M ayo,
President, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, to the
Thirty-Sixth Assembly for Bank Directors, Harbour C a s­
tle, Toronto, Canda, June 7,1979.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago




to do—we will inevitably suffer far more in
the final analysis than if we simply let the
market do what it does best—allocate
resources where and to whom they yield the
greatest return. As an economic consultant
was recently quoted in the Wall Street Jour­
nal, “ There aren't any lines of people waiting
to buy lobsters."
I believe that the very essence of our
economy and our society are in the balance
today as we stand poised before the two alter­
native paths of further government regula­
tion and deregulation. As directors for highly
regulated institutions, you must share that
sense of concern.
I obviously cannot cover the whole
regulatory maze in our society this evening.
But let me touch on a few aspects of banking
regulation that illustrate the nature of the
regulatory problem confronting us.
At the outset, I should make it clear that I
do not oppose all regulation. That would be a
misguided position. Indeed, where the costs
arising from any activity are borne by a third
party rather than by those engaged in that
activity and are very large, and the costs,
measured by the administrative difficulty and
effectiveness of a regulatory solution are very
small, regulation is clearly in order. I would
only argue that such situations are not clearly
as common as is generally believed.
The contrast between my position on
regulation and that of many others may be il­
lustrated by an example taken from a recent
conference on regulation jointly sponsored
by the National Journal and the American
Enterprise Institute. A consumer advocate at­
tacked cost-benefit analysis as a fraud, shot
through with technical and methodological
errors. An honest person must agree that
current approaches to measuring costs and

3

benefits of public policies are deficient. They
are, however, usually the best that are
available and are constantly being improved.
Be that as it may, my objection to such a
remark is not with its appraisal of cost-benefit
analysis, but with its conclusions for
regulatory policy—which would put the
burden of proof on those who oppose a par­
ticular extension of federal regulation. This,
to my mind, is an example of the conquest of
reason by ideology; I would not even con­
sider accepting the nuisance of regulation ab­
sent a clear showing that its benefits out­
weighed its costs by a considerable margin. I
think you will be easily convinced that some
regulations in banking would not meet this
test. Moreover, it seems to me that many of
the regulations currently in place in banking
are inappropriate for the purposes they are
designed to achieve. Many are, in fact, in
direct conflict with one another.
There is a fundamental question as to
whether or not the banking industry is one in
which regulation is likely to offer great public
benefits. The answer is by no means as clearcut as has often been assumed. To be sure, if
one looks at the experience of the 19th cen­
tury, with its recurring business depressions,
liquidity crises, and waves of bank failures—
which not only wiped out the savings of many
depositors but temporarily crippled the
payments system—one might conclude that
strict regulation of banks was absolutely es­
sential. For many, the ultimate proof of the
need for detailed regulation of banking was
given by the Depression of the 1930s, when
some 9,000 banks closed their doors.
Yet, a more critical appraisal calls into
question the usual interpretation of the
evidence available about American banking
history. For one thing, it has never been
satisfactorily answered how much of the dis­
tress of the banking system in the 1930s was
due to bad banking practice and excessive
competition, and how much was due to
preventable errors in macroeconomic policy,
including the monetary policy pursued by the
Federal Reserve. More recent studies of those
years have tended to place much more weight
on the latter, and correspondingly less on the
4



former, than did students of banking in 1933.
Much more important, the primary external
cost related to bankingthat might be cured by
regulation—the fact that even well-managed
banks often used to fail when a general dis­
trust of banking led depositors to try to
withdraw their funds—was, for all practical
purposes, eliminated by the introduction of
federal deposit insurance. Indeed, it might be
argued that the primary justification for
regulation of banks today isthattheFDIC's in­
surance assessments are a flat percentage of
total deposits rather than assessments
based on the relative riskiness of bank port­
folios. This subsidizes risk-taking. It makes
it necessary to impose constraints on bank
behavior.
Perhaps more than anything else, the
conventional wisdom has held that it was ex­
cessive competition for deposits and the con­
sequent “ reaching for yield" in the form of
riskier loans and investments that brought
about the debacle of the 1930s. As a conse­
quence, the most important restrictions
placed on bank activity by the Banking Actsof
1933 and 1935 involve restrictions on entry
into banking and on the payment of interest
on deposits. During the subsequent 30 years,
the effect of new entry restrictions was to
reduce new capital investment in banking by
an estimated 50 percent below what it would
have otherwise been. Meanwhile, the interest
ceiling restrictions, becoming inoperative
when market rates fell far below the ceilings
in the mid-1930s, had little effect. Beginning
in the early 1960s, however, interest rate con­
straints pinched banks more and more as the
economy and loan demand expanded and
bankers' memories of the Depression faded.
Unfortunately, just as more and more
bankers and regulators were becoming con­
vinced that deposit rate ceilings were not
necessary for the maintenance of bank
solvency, the credit stringency of 1966
brought a new rationale for their existence—
the protection of thrift institutions and the
residential mortgage market from the ravages
of disintermediation. That the use of interest
rate ceilings for such a purpose must even­
tually prove futile has only recently come to

Economic Perspectives

be widely recognized.
Concern for maintaining competition in
banking, rather than simply solvency, was
reawakened in the early 1950s by a wave of
bank mergers that threatened increased con­
centration in local banking markets. This con­
cern, after several attempts to adopt new
legislation in the early 1950s, produced the
Bank Holding Company Act of 1956 and the
Bank Merger Act of 1960. It also resulted in
several antitrust suits attacking collusive price
fixing by local bank clearing houses. The same
concern over the lack of aggressive competi­
tion in banking led the Comptroller of the
Currency in the early 1960s to ease restrictions
on entry and authorize banks to enter a
number of new activities.
Thus it was that, by the early 1960s, a dis­
tinct inconsistency had developed in bank
regulations. On one side, regulation had the
expressed purpose of restricting bank com­
petition and risk-taking. Yet other laws and
administrative rulings had the clear purpose
of enhancing competition in banking. For ex­
ample, freer entry and legal sanctions against
merger or collusion to hold down interest
rates on depositors' funds was intended to en­
courage banks to compete for funds. At the
same time, Regulation Q ceilings on deposit
rates either prevent such competition from
occurring or force it to take other, nonprice
forms. This inconsistency of purpose is what I
would characterize as the schizophrenia of
current bank regulation.
Of course, inconsistency is one thing;
simple wrongheadedness is something else.
And it is under the heading of the latter that I
would like to discuss the phenomenon of in­
terest rate ceilings. Let us accept for the mo­
ment the conventional wisdom that banks
need to be protected from excessive com­
petition. It is, nonetheless, true that deposit
interest rate ceilings, including the zero ceil­
ing on demand deposits, have been the most
costly and ineffectual interferences with the
free marketplace in the financial arena ever
devised by man. They are costly because com­
petition has forced banks to resort to ever
more circuitous and ingenious, but highly
inefficient, means of circumventing the

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago



regulations in order to stay in business. They
are ineffectual both because the banks have
kept a few steps ahead of the regulators most
of the time and because other, less heavily
regulated institutions have found ways to in­
vade markets that formerly had been the ex­
clusive preserve of commercial banks.
The net consequence of deposit interest
rate ceilings through the years has been that
the high costs the ceilings were designed to
protect the banks from are still paid, but in a
different form. Depositors have been de­
prived of the option of taking their interest in
cash but are in effect forced, instead, to
accept stuffed lions or kangaroos or a clock or
a rose bush. Banks have lost position in the
competitive financial markets. One of the few
areas where the ceilings have been relatively
effective is on small passbook deposits whose
owners have few investment alternatives.
There we witness the spectacle of the federal
government enforcing a negative real rate of
return on the savings to maintain the profits of
banks and thrift institutions. This is not a
radical's perception of how the system works;
it is a simply factual description of the effects
of deposit rate regulation. It is this aspect of
the ceilings that led the late Professor Ross
Robertson of Indiana University to char­
acterize Regulation Q as “ wicked."
It would take more time than I have at my
disposal to catalog the many and varied direct
and indirect social costs of deposit interest
rate ceilings through the years. Many of the
most renowned financial “ innovations" dur­
ing the past two decades—the development
of the negotiable CD market, Eurodollar
borrowing by U.S. banks, the sale of loan par­
ticipation notes, the sale of commercial paper
by bank holding companies, the nonbank
repurchase agreement market, the advent of
NOW accounts, money market mutual funds,
telephone transfers from savings accounts,
and, most recently, automatic transfer
accounts—are all costly and cumbersome
means of getting around the law's proscrip­
tion of the payment of market interest rates
on deposits. What any first-year economics
student is taught to recognize as an economic
absurdity has been codified for more than

5

four decades as the law of the land.
The ramifications of the regulation of in­
terest rates on deposits extend well beyond
their costs to banks and bank depositors. One
of these, which has come into the limelight
recently, is what the ceiling has done to the
informational content of the traditional
monetary aggregates the Federal Reserve
must rely on in formulating monetary policy.
The ceilings encourage the long-term growth
of money substitutes. This, in turn, tends to
produce a long-term upward trend of income
velocity based on any narrow definition of
money (with pronounced discontinuities
marking the advent of major innovations in
the financial system). The ceilings also result
in a confusing cyclical pattern in the relative
growth rates of narrow and broad definitions
of money. At the present time, for example,
we are seeing a rapid growth of nonbank
repurchase agreements, some portion of
which functions as demand deposits during
most of the day before being taken off the
bank's books at the close of business, thus
making it more difficult to interpret even the
basic thrust of monetary policy.
One may argue with some cogency that
the most recent trends in regulation are in a
generally sensible direction, toward the
elimination of arbitrary price controls in
banking. Certainly, the advent of NOW ac­
counts and ATS accounts has moved us a long
way toward the simple payment of interest on
demand deposits. And the authorization a
year ago of the issue of money market cer­
tificates tied to the Treasury bill rate has
cushioned financial institutions against
ceiling-induced disintermediation on the
scale that occurred in 1965 and 1969.
Moreover, the recent testimony of Governor
Partee before a House Banking Subcom­
mittee makes it clear that the Federal Reserve
now endorses in principle the payment of in­
terest on demand deposits, desiring only that
any such move be tied to a resolution of our
Federal Reserve membership problem.
However, at the very time that sanity
appears to be emerging on one regulatory
front, a disturbing new trend is making its
appearance on another front. I am referring

6




to the increasing tendency to regard the
regulation of financial institutions as an ap­
propriate means for effectuating broad social
goals and the increased willingness to sub­
stitute official views of what is desirable for
the judgments of the free marketplace.
This trend has it roots in the consumer
movement of the late 1960s and 1970s. It has,
however, moved far beyond Senator Paul
Douglas' Truth in Lending law and its
reasonable demand that bankers state, in as
uniform, simple, and accurate a fashion as
possible, what rate of interest they are
charging for various forms of credit. We might
speculate that if Senator Douglas were alive
today, he would be appalled at how complex
and difficult to understand the regulations
designed to implement this seemingly simple
goal have become. Examples of what I have in
mind here are the Fair Credit Reporting Act of
1970, the Fair Credit Billing Act of 1971, and
the Equal Credit Opportunity Act of 1974, the
Consumer Leasing Act of 1976, the Real Estate
Settlement Procedures Act of 1974, the Home
Mortgage Disclosure Act of 1976, the Com­
munity Reinvestment Act of 1977, and the
Financial Institutions Regulatory and Interest
Rate Control Act of 1978. These pieces of
legislation have laudable purposes. They
hopefully ensure that people's credit records
are properly reported, that they are billed ac­
curately on their revolving charge accounts
and have adequate opportunity to make their
complaints heard, that lessees have the terms
of leasing contracts fully and accurately dis­
closed, that homebuyers are advised well in
advance of the closing date of all charges
related to the extension of credit on home
mortgages, and that financial institutions
actively serve the credit needs of the
communities in which they are located.
On paper, these laws remedy many of the
complaints consumers have made about the
credit granting process over the past decade
or so. In practice, however, it is often difficult
to determine whether a particular financial
institution is in compliance. It is even more
difficult to ensure that the laws will be ob­
served in the future. The process of trying to
do so involves enormous costs in terms of

Economic Perspectives

reporting, disclosure, surveillance, and litiga­
tion. What has not been established with any
degree of certainty is whether the benefits ac­
tually realized from the laws justify the costs
of the regulatory apparatus designed to en­
sure compliance with the laws. Some recent
research suggests that the costs of compliance
with the Equal Credit Opportunity Act—
estimated at $293 million—exceed any plausi­
ble estimate of benefits. Indeed, some of the
more careful research done in recent years
fails to find evidence of either systematic dis­
crimination in lending on the basis of sex or of
the commonly charged offense of redlining,
the systematic denial of credit to borrowers in
certain areas of cities without regard to the
actual lending risks involved.
This is not to deny that these types of dis­
crimination may, in fact, occur in isolated in­
stances. Of course, there is evidence of
systematic discrimination in lending in some
cases. But it suggests to me that consumers
may be better served, in the overwhelming
majority of cases, by relying on freer entry and
more intense competition to ensure fair
treatment—not on forced compliance with
an extensive regulatory apparatus. It is es­
pecially distressing that these laws were
adopted in the absence of any credible es­
timates of the magnitude of the alleged
problems they were designed to deal with or
even the most remote notion of the costs of
implementing them.
But, let us assume for purposes of argu­
ment that there have been some pervasive
and well-documented abuses in the granting
of credit that need to be remedied and that
this can only be done by regulation.
Nevertheless, there are serious grounds for
objecting to several provisions of the laws
enacted in recent years. For they go beyond
ensuring that the consumer is fairly treated
and knows what he is paying. They go beyond
what his obligations are. They arbitrarily dic­
tate the substantive provisions of credit
contracts and direct the allocation of credit
toward areas or purposes deemed worthy by
one or another special interest group or
federal agency. Many examples can be cited:
High on the list are limitations on the amounts

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago



a lender can require for tax and insurance es­
crow payments under the Real Estate Settle­
ment Procedures Act, the current prohibi­
tion of variable rate mortgages to federally
chartered savings and loan associations, the
federal limitation of cardholder losses from
unauthorized use of lost or stolen credit cards
to $50, and the requirement under the Com­
munity Reinvestment Act that the geographic
distribution of a bank's loans be considered in
judging its application for a new branch. And
it is not ony Uncle Sam who is so zealous. State
usury ceilings, and the increasingly restrictive
state limitations on such creditors' remedies
as wage garnishment, wage assignments,
deficiency judgments, and “ holder-in-duecourse" clauses, all inhibit sound financial
dealings.
The least of the undesirable conse­
quences of the restrictions on creditor
remedies is to raise the cost of credit to all
borrowers and require good credit risks to
subsidize the credit extended to poor credit
risks. And in conjunction with the liberaliza­
tion of the personal bankruptcy laws, these
restrictions have had the very damaging social
effect of undermining the belief, to which
most of us have subscribed all our lives, that
the repayment of freely contracted debt is a
serious moral obligation. The extent to which
the recent swing of the pendulum away from
the rights of creditors in favor of debtors has
altered traditional views of borrowers'
responsibilities was documented in a recent
article in the Chicago Tribune's Sunday
magazine entitled “ Bankruptcy and the new
state of grace." In it, a Chicago lawyer—who
obviously asked to remain anonymous—is
quoted as saying:
People have been brainwashed that
it's wrong not to pay their debts no
matter what. I want everybody to know
that you don't have to. That it's right not
to pay when they can't. I want
everybody to know they have a legal and
moral right not to pay. And the U.S.
Supreme Court in 1973 backed that up.
It would be hard to imagine a more clearcut
indication of decline in the moral fiber of our

7

society, or one with more ominous under­
tones for the continued efficient functioning
of a credit-based economy.
Other new laws and regulations attempt
to achieve by indirection, goals whose costs
the electorate apparently refuses to bear
through direct taxation. For example, the
Community Reinvestment Act's emphasis on
local lending essentially requires the banks'
depositors and shareholders to subsidize
what is deemed a worthy social goal—i.e.,
lending in declining areas of cities that pose
above-average lending risks. Generally, one
would think that the pursuit of such goals, if
deemed worthy by the electorate, should be
funded by a broadly based tax such as the
federal income tax. But the indirect tax ap­
proach of forcing financial institutions to in­
vest in ways that are not in their stockholders'
interest may be favored simply because the
proponents of such measures do not feel that
they could get a straightforward, visible sub­
sidy enacted into law. In any case, I think this
whole approach of subsidization through
what amounts to credit allocation—an ap­
proach long confined to policies designed to
stimulate residential construction—should
come under closer scrutiny.
In the long run, of course, most of the
laws and regulations that I have described
become superfluous anyway, as ways are
found to circumvent them and new in­
stitutions are developed to carry on the ac­
tivities prohibited to existing ones. In the
meantime, we suffer higher costs, an inef­
ficient allocation of resources, and all the
frustrations and limitations on freedom that
accompany any arbitrary and rigid constraints
on the market mechanism.

Why thesametired measures continueto
be tried, year after year and decade after
decade, is something of a mystery. But it is not
totally inexplicable. The fact is that many peo­
ple distrust the free marketplace because they
do not understand it. Their basic economic
education has been totally neglected. They
fail to recognize that our system reflects the
interactions of total wants of the entire pop­
ulace (weighted, to be sure, by purchasing
power), as embodied in total demands, with
the inescapable fact of limited means, as em­
bodied in supply conditions. They naively
believe that the marketplace is likely to yield
results that contradict what the populace ac­
tually desires. They are led to believe that
profits are bad and that anything big is bad.
The propensity to regulate also stems from a
myopic view of its effects—a view that fails to
take into account its side effects and longerterm ramifications. This accounts for the
"patchwork quilt" natureof the existing body
of regulations, most of which wereadopted as
short-term, ad hoc responses to immediately
perceived needs.
What I would like to leave you with is a
considerably greater skepticism toward the
frequently made promise of great benefits
and minimal costs for someone's pet
regulatory scheme. I believe that few such
claims can stand up under the glaring light of
close analysis. Even fewer can stand up under
the longer-term pressures of the free
marketplace—and our economic freedoms
are at the very heart of our democratic in­
stitutions and our personal freedoms. Let us
never forget this simple and fundamental
truth.

■■■■■■■■■

8




Economic Perspectives

Fuel crisis hits business
George W. Cloos
The economy reeled this summer from the
impact of a series of adversities. The most im­
portant was the shortage of motor fuel
resulting from the disruption of oil supplies
from Iran. Others included truck strikes, the
airline strike, labor pacts that exceeded Ad­
ministration guides, soaring interest rates,
further price inflation, and still lingering
effects of the severe winter. Together, these
blows brought an end to a four-year upswing,
an expansion already creaky with age by
historical standards. Belated recognition of
the fact that oil shortages are likely to recur is
having a profound effect on patterns of con­
sumer spending, business investment, and
real estate development. Rethinking of broad
strategies means delays in decision-making
and a more sluggish economy.
Real activity declined in the second
quarter after a miniscule gain inthe first. Infla­
tion was running at an annual rate of 10 per­
cent. Many analysts expect the decline in out­
put and the rapid rise in prices to continue
through the year. Surveys of both consumer
and executive opinion indicated a pessimism
perhaps unmatched since the Great De­
pression. Cautious spending policies could
accelerate the downturn.
Despite the gloom, total activity remain­
ed well above the year-ago level, with impor­
tant sectors remaining vigorous—some ex­
cessively so. Motor vehicle sales were hard hit
in total, but demand continued strong for
popular small cars and heavy trucks. Housing
was weak, but nonresidential construction
boomed. Tourism was down in many areas,
but airline traffic continued to set records.
Sales and output of producer goods con­
tinued to rise, especially machine tools and
transportation equipment. Agriculture was
prosperous with higher grain pricesand good
crops boosting income.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago



Consumer spending falters

Consumers led the expansion in 1975 and
1976. With brief letdowns or plateaus, they
continued spending at high rates through
1978. Even the first quarter of 1979 showed a
13 percent rise in retail sales from the depres­
sed first quarter of 1978. Savings rates were
lower than in past years and instalment credit
was used freely.
Consumer spending in current dollars
was slightly lower in the second quarter than
in the first quarter—an extremely rare
development. Adjusted for inflation, con­
sumer spendingwas down significantly. Retail
sales were only 8.5 percent higher than a year
earlier, while after-tax income was up over 11
percent.
The cutback in consumer purchases has
been heavily concentrated in vehicles that get
low gasoline mileage. Sales of motor homes
mounted on truck chasses have been poor all
year. Light trucks favored by consumers, es-

The rise in consumer prices
has accelerated
index, 1967=100, middle of month of quarter

9

pecially four-wheel drive models, were in
short supply early in the year, but sales began
fading in March and in June had dropped 35
percent below a year ago. The industry had a
135-day inventory of light trucks at midyear—
far more than any previous period. Sales of
full-sized cars, also very strong last winter,
were down over 40 percent in June, with in­
ventories equaling 150 days' sales for some
models—two to three times the preferred
level. With the model changeovers coming
up, manufacturers were offering historically
large rebates to dealers to move surplus
vehicles, especially full-size cars.
While sales of “ gas guzzlers” languished,
consumers paid premium prices for small
cars. Some signed up on waiting lists that
stretched out as much as four months. Sales of
U.S.-built subcompacts were up almost 50
percent over June a year before. Sales of im­
ported cars, almost all small, were up 9 per­
cent in June and would have been up more if
supplies had been larger.
There had been near-panic buying of
small cars in early 1974, following imposition
of the Arab oil embargo. Once gasoline
supplies improved that spring, however, de­
mand for small cars fell quickly, and full-size
models again asserted their supremacy. This
summer showed no signs of a revival of big
cars similar to that of 1974.

Consumer instalment
credit use soars
billion dollars

Car and truck inventories
backed up at midyear
days supply

120 r
100

-

80
60
40

1977

1978

1979

Customer traffic, and therefore sales, was
reduced at many outlying shopping centers in
May, June, and July as consumers tried to hold
down gasoline consumption. Part of this loss
was captured by higher catalog sales and
increased sales at neighborhood stores.
Another development was a pickup in home
freezer sales.
The rapid rise in consumer prices (at a 13
percent rate in the first half) led by fuel and
food encouraged some households to hold
back on less essential spending. Increases in
spendable incomes have trailed inflation
significantly. Many consumers apparently in­
creased their spending on big-ticket items
late last year to beat price increases, but such
anticipatory spending is usually followed by a
letdown.
Another sector of consumer outlays that
has suffered from the gas shortage is tourism
in areas usually reached by private vehicles.
With more people staying closer to home
because of the high cost of fuel—and its possi­
ble unavailability—volume at less accessible
resort areas was reported to be off 30 to 50
percent from year a earlier.
Capital goods retain vigor

Business expects to boost expenditures
on new plant and equipment 13 percent in

10



Economic Perspectives

1979, according to the most recent govern­
ment survey. That will be about the same rise
as last year. Adjusted for inflation, spending
will be up 5 percent, again about the same as
last year. The rise in capital spending will,
almost certainly, outpace the general
economy, through 1979 and into 1980.
All major industry groups plan to in­
crease capital spending substantially in 1979.
The leading categories in manufacturing are
machinery, paper, and chemicals. In non­
manufacturing, they are transportation (air,
highway, and rail), electric utilities, and
telephone companies.
In contrast to the weakness in residential
construction, nonresidential building will be
substantially higher than lastyear. In the three
months ended in May, outlays on new home
construction were down 8 percent from a
year earlier, after adjustment for inflation.
Nonresidential construction was up 11 per­
cent, with industrial construction up 33 per­
cent and office buildings up 20 percent. New
construction contracts awarded and bookings
for fabricated structural steel indicate the
nonresidential construction boom could ex­
tend into 1980. Recently, however, there has
been a weakening in new contracts for in­
dustrial buildings, compared at least with the
high level of last year.

Equipment output continues
upward, as vehicles slump
index, 1967=100

New orders for nondefense capital goods
leveled off in the spring, but they were still
above shipments and backlogs in orders con­
tinued to build. The backlog of over $125
billion at the end of June was a third higher
than a year before. Backlogs had been rising
fairly steadily since December 1976, partly
because of inflation.
Order lead times are particularly long for
machine tools, commercial aircraft,and some
types of freight cars and locomotives. Sales of
heavy trucks have been at record highs. They
may exceed 200,000 units this year—a new
high. Sales are also strong in equipment for
construction, agriculture, materials han­
dling, data processing, and electronic control
systems.
Production of business equipment,
measured in real terms by the Federal
Reserve's industrial production index, con­
tinued to rise through June, although total
manufacturing output apparently peaked in
March. In June, output of business equip­
ment was up 7.3 percent from a year earlier.
Total manufacturing output was up 4.8
percent.
If a general recession develops, some
orders for equipment now on the books
could be canceled without penalty. This
happened in late 1974 and early 1975—and to
a surprising extent. The 1974-75 experience is
not likely to be equaled in degree, however.
Orders are believed to have been booked
more carefully this time. Also, more of the
equipment on order now is badly needed to
cut labor costs, improve energy efficiency,
and comply with pollution controlsand other
regulatory mandates.
Housing starts decline

Monthly estimates of housing starts have
been erratic this year, partly because of the
hard winter and the catchup that followed.
Most analysts expect 1979 starts in the range of
1.6 to 1.7 million units, down 15 to 20 percent
from the 2 million levels of 1977 and 1978.
Prospects are that starts will not improve next
year. The decline in housing starts has been
much greater in the Chicago area than in the

Federal

R eserve

Bank of Chicago




11

Housing starts declined sharply
in the first half
million units
2.5

single family

1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977

1978 1979

‘ Severe w eather lim its activity.

nation as a whole. In the first half of the year,
new permits were down 40 percent in the
Chicago area from the same period a year
earlier.
Nationwide, decline in housing starts has
been fairly mild this cycle. After a peak of
almost 2.4 million units in 1972, a three-year
decline brought a drop of over 50 percent to
less than 1.2 million in 1975.
Multifamily startsare holding up better in
most areas than starts on single-family homes.
Many of these apartments, however, will be
for sale as condominiums. Of the rental units
started, about three-fourths are built under
government subsidized housing programs.
The decline in residential construction
would have been greater but for the con­
tinued general availability of mortgage credit.
In past cycles, high market interest rates
caused large outflows of funds from thrift in­
stitutions and reduced the supply of
mortgage funds. Also, usury ceilings in many
states prevented loans at competitive rates.
Since last summer, savings flows at thrifts have
been aided by these institutions being allow­
ed to offer money market certificates at com­
petitive rates. Many states, moreover, have
relaxed usury ceilings, allowing more move­
ment in interest rates.

12



Despite more flexible markets, increases
in interest rates to a level of about 11
percent—at least 2 points higher than last
year—has priced many buyers out of the
market. Rising home prices also have been
important as a deterrent to home purchases.
Prices of existing homes have doubled since
1972, for an annual compound rate of rise of
10 percent. Increases were even larger in the
past three years.
Sales of existing homes have slowed
down this year, especially in the Midwest,
with substantial price cuts needed to move
some homes. The softer market for existing
homes in outlying areas has been exacerbated
by fuel stringencies. Homebuyers show signs
of being more inclined to reject outlying
areas in favor of older locations with ready
access to public transportation, stores, and
other establishments. Slower sales of existing
houses hurt sales of new houses because most
buyers make downpayments with the equities
realized from the sale of their previous
homes.
The decline in residential construction
raises serious questions about the adequacy
of living space in theyears ahead. Households
are being formed at an annual rate of about
1.5 million, and perhaps 500,000 housing units
a year are demolished or abandoned as unfit.
Vacancy rates for both apartments and houses
are low. The spectre of a serious housing
shortage could bring demands for rent con­
trols and additional federal subsidies, despite
unfortunate experience with such programs.
Employment and labor costs

One of the most impressive devel­
opments of the four-year business expan­
sion has been the rapid rise in employment.
Nonfarm wage and salary employment reach­
ed a record 88.8 million in July. That was 2.8
mllion more than a year earlier and 10 million
more than in October 1974, the peak before
the recession. From March to July, the in­
crease in new jobs slowed to 500,000, down
from 1 million in the period from December
to March.

Economic Perspectives

The long uptrend in payroll
employment has slowed

Demand for trained (or trainable)
workers has intensified in recent years, serv­
ing to push up wage rates. Strong job markets
have also encouraged job hopping and
absenteeism, which hamper improvements in
productivity (output per worker hour).
About three-fourths of the increase in
employment since 1974 has been in the trade
and service industries and in state and local
governments. Changes in productivity in
these sectors are hard to measure, but gains
are probably well below average— certainly
much less than in manufacturing. In some
cases, productivity has actually declined.
The combination of rapidly rising com­
pensation and poor performance in produc­
tivity has meant a surge in unit labor costs
which translates, in turn, into higher product
prices. Total hourly compensation for non­
farm private jobs rose more than 9 percent last
year. With practically no gain in productivity,
unit labor costs rose almost 9 percent.
The change in productivity could be
negative this year, particularly if a recession
cuts operating rates relative to capacity. With
compensation rising at least as fast as in 1978,
the rise in unit labor costs could exceed 10
percent, supporting continued inflation at a
similar rate.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago



Labor pacts provide large gains

It was known before the turn of the year
that 1979 would be marked by heavy bargain­
ing in labor negotiations. Contracts covering
almost 4 million workers were due to expire,
compared with contracts for 2 million in 1978.
Some of the most powerful labor or­
ganizations, moreover—those in the truck­
ing, rubber, electrical equipment, auto, and
farm and construction machinery indus­
tries—would participate in the bargaining.
In an effort to restrain inflation, the Presi­
dent announced voluntary guidelines for
wage and price increases in October 1978.
The wage guide, which was to cover total
compensation (wagesand benefits),called for
maximum increases of 7 percent a year. That
was compared with an 8 percent rise for all
nonfarm workers in the 12 months ended in
September 1978.
After an 11-day strike and lockout, the
Teamsters and the trucking industry con­
cluded a new three-year pact on April 11,
providing for an 8 percent increase in thefirst
year—assuming a 6 percent rise in consumer
prices—plus substantial increases in the
welfare and pension package. Although some
analysts concluded that the increase in total
compensation would amounttoatleast9per-

Rising labor costs
push up prices
percent change year-to-year

13

cent, for each of the three years, the Council
on Wage and Price Stability interpreted the
agreement as being within the guidelines.
United Airlines and theMachinists Union
ratified a pact on May 24 ending a 55-day
strike. The agreement was said to boost total
compensation about 40 percent over three
years. Goodrich and the rubber workers
agreed on a three-year pact on June15 said to
be worth 40 percent, assuming a 9-percent
annual rise in consumer prices. The Council
on Wage and Price Stability said the airline
and rubber contracts were probably not in
compliance with the guidelines.
Much of the confusion over the value of
new labor contracts stems, first, from the
assumption of future cost-of-living ad­
justments (COLA), and, second, from the
valuation of changes in welfare and pension
benefits.
Through September—and maybe be­
yond if a strike is called—attention will be
directed to auto workers' negotiations with
the Big Three. About 700,000 auto workers are

covered by contracts that expire September
14. That is more workers than were involved
in all the other big labor agreements reached
so far this year. The farm and construction
equipment workers, whose contracts expire
September 30, usually take their lead from the
auto workers, as do the steel workers, who
will be negotiating again next year.
Auto workers, following the example of
the rubber and electrical workers, want a full
cost-of-living adjustment (up from about 80
percent now), plus "substantial” increases in
wages and benefits. They also want COLA for
pensioners. Total compensation of auto
workers, many unskilled, has increased from
an average of $5.76 an hour in 1970 to $15.10
(about $30,000 a year) today. That is an in­
crease of 162 percent in nine years, or 11.3
percent compounded annually.
The oil constraint

Gasoline lines and shortages of diesel
fuel have convinced most Americans that the

Dependence on foreign oil perils output growth
billion barrels

billion barrels

•Sales to users from refineries and prim ary term inals.
••C re d it oil and natural gas liquids,
t Estimated.

74




Economic Perspectives

energy problem is real and immediate.
Petroleum analysts concluded in July that a
temporary increase in Saudi Arabian produc­
tion of crude oil would be enough to prevent
"serious” supply disruptions through the rest
of the year—assuming continued conserva­
tion and barring any new interruption of
deliveries from major exporting countries. As
long as the United States depends on imports
for almost half its oil, much of it from the
troubled Middle East, a fragile balance
between supply and demand is inevitable.
Another complication is the cost of im­
ports. Soon to exceed $60 billion annually, im­
ports put pressure on the dollar in foreign ex­
change markets. On the domestic scene,
sharply higher prices for gasoline, diesel fuel,
and heating oil have only begun to find
reflection in costs of production and distribu­
tion. No sector is isolated from this influence.
In the 20 years that preceded the Arab oil
embargo in late 1973, the United States in­
creased oil consumption 4 percent a year.
During the same period, real GNP rose at a
compound rate of 3.5 percent.
If oil imports are held near the current
level, as the president has pledged, total U.S.
supplies will decline year-by-year. Domestic
production has been declining, with no signs
of reversal in sight. New domestic discoveries
are only about a fourth as large as current
output.
If total oil supplies decline, past standards
for estimating future growth will have to be
discarded. With population still rising, total
per capita consumption—and not just con­
sumption of oil products—will have to
decline. Those able to maintain their real in­
come through COLA adjustments or other
means will do so at the expense of those less
fortunate. A shift from oil and natural gas to
other fuels, including synthetics from coal or
oil-shale, will take years, requiring enormous
investments that, in turn, will reduce

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago




resources available for consumption. Nuclear
power is under a cloud. A substantial con­
tribution from solar energy is not on the
horizon.
What to do?

The growing apparition of recession—or
feeble growth at best—coupled with un­
abated inflation presents policymakers with a
dilemma. The problem is compounded by
constraints on supplies of fuel, transportation,
metals, and vital capital goods, and by limited
availability of employable workers, especially
professional and skilled people. A large por­
tion of the resources released by declining
sectors, vehicles and housing, is not readily
transferred elsewhere.
Some people are calling for substantial
tax reductions or a dramatic easing in
monetary policy. But the federal government
already is running a large deficit. Interest rates
are near record levels, but money and credit
continue to expand. Commercial bank loans
and investments were 12 percent higher at
midyear than a year earlier. Bank investments
were up 4 percent; both total loans and
business loans were up 15 percent. In addi­
tion, businesses had increased their outstand­
ing commercial paper 40 percent. Capital
markets absorbed more than $13 billion in
corporate bonds in the second quarter. That
was as much as in either of the second
quarters of the two previous years. Although
less than last year, mortgage loans closed have
exceeded the pace of earlier years.
The accepted formula of using more
expansive monetary and fiscal measures to
counteract lagging demand can be applied
only with caution under these conditions.
Given pervasive supply constraints, injection
of additional purchasing power would serve
more to stimulate inflation than to revive
production and employment.

15

Municipal bonds in the
housing market
D a v i d R. A l l a r d i c e

The first large municipal bond issue to raise
money for residential mortgages was offered
in Chicago in July 1978. The program, a $100
million issue to finance low and moderateincome families in the purchase of single­
family homes, was successful from its incep­
tion. Under this first offering, 2,100 Chicago
families received home mortgage loans at an
interest rate of 7.99 percent—about 2 per­
centage points less than the going rate on
conventional mortgages. The next March, the
city issued another $150 million of these taxexempt obligations.
By then, 50 municipalities across the
country had issued mortgage revenue bonds,
pushing the total outstanding to $1.6 billion.
But as this innovation in municipal bond
financing spread, objections were also raised.
• The President stipulated in his fiscal
1980 budget that the Administration would
propose legislation limiting single-family
housing bonds to programs intended either
to finance housing for low and moderateincome families or achieve “ other narrowly
targeted public policy objectives."
• The Congressional Budget Office es­
timated in April 1979 that state and local
single-family housing bonds might reach an
annual volume of $20 billion to $35 billion by
1984, resulting in a tax loss to the Treasury of
between $1.6 billion and $2.1 billion a year.1
• A bill (H.R. 3712) was introduced in
Congress that would remove the federal in­
come tax exemption for all Chicago-type
housing bonds issued after April 24,1979.
It now seems likely that further issuance
of this type bond may be greatly constrained,
if not prohibited altogether. A program with
Co ngressional Budget O ffice, Tax-Exempt Bonds for
Single-fam ily Housing (Washington, G overnm ent
Printing Office, April 1979).

76




wide support, private and public, has in less
than a year become the object of government
efforts at prohibition.
Why municipal bonds?

Municipal spending has traditionally
gone for either operating expenses or capital
improvements. Operating expenses of carry­
ing on local government are financed
primarily through current taxes or other in­
come. Expenditures too large for the current
budget and whose benefits will accrue to
future as well as current taxpayers, are fi­
nanced mostly through the sale of bonds.
There are generally four types of municipal
bonds:
• General obligation—bonds secured by
the full faith, credit, and taxing power of the
issuing authority.
• Special tax—bonds paid from the
revenue of a special tax imposed specifically
for that indebtedness.
• Housing authority—bonds secured by
a pledge of net revenues to a state or local
housing authority.2
• Revenue—bonds paid from revenues
generated by facilities built with proceeds
from the sale of the bonds.
From the standpoint of investors, one of
the attractive features of municipal bonds is
that the interest paid on them is usually ex­
empt from federal income taxation. Because
reciprocal tax immunity keeps one govern­
ment from burdening another with its taxes,
interest on most municipal obligations is not
taxed by the federal government, just as ind e sig n e d originally for financing multifamily hous­
ing, these obligations have been used in recent years to
finance programs to lower the cost of hom eownership
for low and m oderate-incom e families.

Economic Perspectives

terest on federal obligations is not taxed by
state and local governments.
The tax-exempt status of municipal
obligations is also explained partly on
grounds that the funds are used for public
purposes. There have been abuses, however,
as it is not always clear what constitutes a
public purpose.
Until 1968, interest on municipal bonds
was exempt from federal income taxes,
regardless of the application of the proceeds.
State and local governments issued industrial
development bonds, for example, to finance
construction of private industrial or commer­
cial facilities used by private interests. These
bonds were popular in the 1960s. But Con­
gress curbed their use by passing the Reve­
nue and Expenditure Control Act of 1968,
which substantially restricted the use of these
obligations.
It is this very act, in fact, that gives
municipalities authority to issue tax-exempt
bonds under home-mortgage programs. As
amended, the act gives tax-free status to
municipal bonds if substantially all the
proceeds are used for certain quasi-public
projects. Included among the allowed pro­
jects are sports facilities, convention and
trade show facilities, airports, sewage
facilities, industrial parks, and r e s i d e n t i a l r e a l
p r o p e r t y f o r f a m i l y u n i t s . According to the
Congressional Budget Office study, the
"residential real property. . . " phrase, added
to the bill in conference, did not specifically
exclude single-family homes. But since state
housing finance agencies began to finance
single-family housing with tax-exempt bonds
only in 1970, it may not have occurred to the
conferees that tax-exempt bonds could be
used for this purpose. Nor is it certain, if they
had known, what position they might have
taken.

How programs work

All single-family housing bond programs
have features of their own, but all work
basically the same. Before issuing mortgage
revenue bonds, municipalities determine
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago



whether they have authority under state law.
Only about a fourth of the states have laws
that allow municipalities to issue this kind of
obligation. Several, however, are considering
changing their laws to allow municipalities to
issue these bonds.
Of states in the Seventh Federal Reserve
District, only Illinois has a legal framework
that allows residential mortgage revenue
bonds to be issued.3 The Illinois constitution
designates municipalities with populations of
more than 25,000 as home-rule units. These
units can perform any function pertaining to
their affairs. This includes the power to tax
and incur debt. The law requires that
municipal financing serve a valid public pur­
pose, and various types of home financing
have been considered valid in Illinois.
Once a municipality decides its program
is permitted under state law, it must decide on
the features it wants the program to have,
such as income and mortgage limits, whether
loans can be made on both new and existing
houses, if funds can be used for rehabilitation,
and if there are to beany geographic limitson
loan extensions.
In evaluating the risks of these
obligations, Standard and Poor’s has in­
dicated that the highest quality mortgage
portfolio will be "restricted to a large pool of
geographically diversified, seasoned, highequity mortgages on single-family detached,
owner-occupied dwellings." Lower risks tend
to translate into lower borrowing costs for
muncipalities. And the costs of municipal
borrowing must remain low relative to con­
ventional mortgage rates if the programs are
to be attractive.
When provisions of the program have
been established and the bonds marketed,
the proceeds are placed in the custody of a
financial institution, usually a bank. Other
financial institutions designated as part of the
program then originate residential mortgages
in compliance with the terms and provisions
the muncipality has established.
3W isconsin issues substantial amounts of tax-exempt
general obligation bonds to finance purchases of single­
family houses for veterans.

17

Originating institutions allocate funds to
creditworthy homebuyers, primarily on a
first-come, first-served basis—which rewards
the well informed. Loans are made in accor­
dance with the usual lending standards of the
institution and constraints of the program.
Depending on the program, homebuyers
may be required to pay an origination feeand
a program participation fee. Mortgage in­
surance may also be passed on to the bor­
rowers. Monthly principal and interest pay­
ments are madetotheoriginatinginstitution.
Originating institutions usually sell the
mortgages to the custodial institution, but
they continue servicing the mortgages,
receiving payments, and remitting principal
and interest payments to the custodial institu­
tion on prescribed dates. For this service, the
originating institutions collect a service fee
based on the outstanding balance.
The custodial institution, in turn, makes
principal and interest payments to the

bondholders. The main risk of default lies
with the bondholders. The risk to them is
reduced, however, by insurance, reserve ac­
counts, and the structuring of programs to
include substantial numbers of loans to
moderate or high-incom e borrowers.
Municipalities have only limited risk ex­
posure. They would be exposed only if a large
number of mortgages were foreclosed or if
the bonds were more than the community
could absorb. The institutions originating the
mortgages bear no risk.
Programs in Illinois . . .

By mid-1979, 15 municipalities in Illinois
had issued $524.8 million in single-family
mortgage revenue bonds. Close to half of
that, $250 million, had been issued by the city
of Chicago.
Bonds outstanding, excluding the

Single-family mortgage revenue bonds
outstanding June 1, 1979—Illinois
_________________________________Features________________________________
Municipality

Population

Issue bond

Date

Income
limit

Mortgage Institutions
participating
limit

(million dollars)

(thousands) (million dollars)
Village of Addison
Belleville
Chicago (1st issue)
Chicago (2nd issue)
Chicago Heights
Danville
Decatur
Evanston
Highland Park
Joliet
Pekin
Quincy
Rock Island
Springfield
Waukegan
Wheeling

27
44
3099
3099
40
42
90
77
32
74
32
44
49
87
65
19

25.0
25.0
100.0
150.0
12.0
15.42
15.0
25.0
8.0
27.8&
15.0
16.76
20.0
31.0
23.73
15.0

Amount1
loanable

Apr
Nov
Jul
Mar
May
Dec
Jan
Jan
Feb
May
Dec
Nov
Nov
May
May
Jan

79
78
78
79
79
78
79
79
79
79
78
78
78
79
79
79

$40,000
40,000
40,000
40,000**
40,000
30,000
40,000
50,000
40,000
40,000
40,000
40,000
40,000
35,000
25,000*
40,000

$80,000
80,000
none
none
80,000
none
80,000
100,000
85,000
80,000
50,000
none
80,000
60,000
75,000
80,000

5
8
1
53
4
10
1
8
3
7
1
3
5
12
6
2

$21.0
20.8
83.0
132.8
9.9
12.9
12.5
21.0
6.7
22.0
12.6
13.9
16.0
26.2
19.8
12.5

Mortgage
interest rate

(percent)
8.45
8.52
7.99
8.125
8.95
8.55
8.675
8.25
8.45
8.45
8.55
8.35
8.35
8.375
8.50
8.95

*Loans made in designated redevelopment area are exempt from income limitations.
**A portion of funds are earmarked for families with incomes lower than tabled.
’Amount loanable is gross bond issue net of mortgage reserve fund, capital reserve fund, cost of issurance account, and
underwriter discount.

18



Economic Perspectives

Chicago programs, ranged from $8 million in
Highland Park to $31 million in Springfield.
Eight of the 15 municipalities were in the
Chicago SMSA. Funds were loaned at an
average rate of 8.47 percent, varying from 7.99
percent for Chicago's first program to 8.95
percent for the Chicago Heights and Wheel­
ing programs.
Loanable funds (gross bond issues net of
mortgage reserve funds, capital reserve
funds, costs of insurance, and underwriting
discounts) generated from these issues
amounted to $443.6 million. That was about
84.5 percent of the face value of the bonds.
The ratio varied from 78.9 percent in the Joliet
issue to 88.5 percent in Chicago's second
offering.
The higher the ratio, the more of the
funds that can be loaned back into the com­
munity and the lower the underwriting and
other costs. Although some consider these
ratios excessive, they compare favorably with
average ratios at savings and loan associations.
Loans outstanding at S&Ls at the end of 1978
amounted to 82.7 percent of total assets.4
Illinois programs, and those in other
states, have often been criticized for using
only a few lending institutions. Five programs
used no more than three institutions for
originating mortgage loans. Three of these
five used only one institution.
This shortcoming was probably at­
tributed, however, to the newness of the
programs. The first Chicago program, for ex­
ample, used only one mortgage originator.
The second program used 53.
Although billed in most instances as in­
tended for low or moderate-income families,
the programs have income and mortgage
limitations aimed more at middle-income
groups. Four of the programs in place in Il­
linois put no limit on the size mortgage that
can be acquired. The other 12 set limits
between $50,000 and $100,000.
All put limits on the annual income
allowed for participation. Twelve allow ad­
justed gross incomes of $40,000. Only one
4Savings and Loan Fact Book, 1979, United States
League of Savings Associations, Chicago, page 80.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago



limits income to $25,000. One program allows
$50,000.
Some of the programs, however, have set
aside funds for families with lower incomes.
The second Chicago program reserved 85
percent of the principal amount of the
mortgage loans for borrowers with incomes
of no more than $29,500.
. . . and the outlook for them

Before the introduction of legislation to
restrict the issuance of residential mortgage
revenue bonds, 67 municipalities in Illinois,
including all with populations of more than
25,000, were surveyed concerning their in­
terest and intentions of issuing these
obligations. Of the 15 that had already issued
bonds, only one indicated it might issue ad­
ditional bonds in 1979. Indications were that
this obligation would amount to about $20
million.
Ten municipalities indicated they were
taking steps to issue residential mortgage
revenue bonds. Together, their plans called
for about $170 million in mortgage revenue
bonds. If all these obligations were marketed,
the total outstanding in Illinois at year-end
would be about $715 million.5
Of the 67 municipalities surveyed, 37 in­
dicated they had considered issuing these
bonds and turned the idea down. The reasons
varied. Some believed they could attract peo­
ple to their communities even with conven­
tional mortgage rates high, so they saw no
need to subsidize mortgages. Some thought
benefits of the programs accrued to new
residents instead of current residents. Some
thought existing neighborhood renewal
programs preempted the need for such
mortgages. Only a few showed any concern
that the bonds would raise the municipality's
cost of borrowing or that providing
mortgages was not a proper function of local
government.
5The dollar amount of bonds issued will decline by
maturity, assuming no new issues. This is due partly to
loan repayments and to mandatory and optional bond
redemptions.

19

Results indicate most of thecommunities
surveyed (55 percent) had rejected the im­
plementation of a residential mortgage
revenue bond program before legislation was
introduced to prohibit these bonds.
Disadvantages of the programs
There are advantages and disadvantages
to a community issuing residential mortgage
revenue bonds. Some of the disadvantages
are the result of poorly structured or hastily
developed plans. As such they are transitory
and can be corrected by restructuring the
form of the programs. Others, however,
reflect the very nature of the programs and
cannot be corrected.
One of the most frequently cited disad­
vantages of residential mortgage revenue
bond programs is their cost to the Treasury in
terms of lost revenue. This cost is sometimes
called a tax expenditure.6
The Congressional Budget Office es­
timates that without restrictive legislation,
new issues of state and local mortgage
revenue bonds could increase to an annual
rate of $20 billion to $35 billion by 1984. And
for every billion dollars of obligations issued,
the tax loss to the Treasury amounts to
approximately $22.5 million per year for
the life of the bonds. (See box.) If these
programs are not curbed, the annual tax loss
could reach $1.6 billion to $2.1 billion by
1984.7 With the federal government trying to
balance the budget, a tax expenditure of this
magnitude could require offsetting cuts in
federal aid to state and local governments or
tax increases to offset the loss in revenue.
A somewhat related argument contends
that the loss of tax revenue to the federal
government is greater than the interest
6See R. A. Musgrave and P. B. Musgrave, Public
Finance in Theory and Practice, M cG raw -H ill, 1973, page
247.
7lt is worth noting that the estimated tax expenditure
for this program in 1984 is about a tenth of the taxexpenditure expected from tax deductions for interest
on owner-occupied homes for the same year. See Joint
Committee Print, Background and Issues Regarding H.R.

3712 Relating to

Tax-exempt

Bonds

for Housing

(Washington, Governm ent Printing O ffice, 1979), page
49.

20




savings to state and local governments. Under
these circumstances, direct subsidies would
be more efficient, and more equitable. It has
also been contended that the primary
beneficiaries of the programs are investors in
high income tax brackets, underwriters, and
mortgage originating institutions. Investors

Estimating the mortgage revenue
bond tax loss
The following example, taken from the
Congressional Budget Office study, Taxexempt Bonds for Single-family Housing, il­
lustrates the calculation of the tax expen­
diture (potential revenue loss) resulting from
the use of tax-exempt residential mortgage
revenue bonds.
Revenue loss is partly a function of the
marginal tax rate of investors. If it is assumed
that investors' marginal tax rates average 30
percent and taxable investments yield 10
percent, $1 billion transferred from a taxable
to a nontaxable status results in a gross taxloss of $30 million a year ($1 billion x .30 x .10
equals $30 million).
Adjustments can be made to reduce the
gross tax loss. It can be assumed, for example,
that 15 percent of the proceeds from the
bonds are placed in various reserve ac­
counts. It can be further assumed that
program participants pay 2 percentage
points less than conventional mortgage
rates, allowing them less interest deduction
from taxable income. Again, with an average
30 percent marginal tax bracket, the result is
a $5 million offset reduction in potential tax
loss ($1 billion x .85 x .02 x .30 equals $5
million).
It can be assumed further that invest­
ment bankers, insurance companies, and
participating lenders generate income equal
to 1 percent of the mortgage pool. With a 30
percent marginal tax rate, another $2.5
million in tax expenditures can be offset for
every billion dollars of bonds issued ($1
billion x .85 x .01 x .30 equals $2.5 million).
The net effect is a tax loss of about $22.5
million a year for every $1 billion of bonds
issued ($30 million less $7.5 million in offset
equals $22.5 million).

Economic Perspectives

able to use the tax-exempt features of the
obligations interfere with the equity of the tax
system (i.e., promote a less progressive
federal income tax system), and underwriters
and banks earn substantial fees from the sale
and servicing of the obligations.
The programs have also been seen as
having the potential for raising future costs of
borrowing for state and local governments.
Though not easily verified, one study shows a
billion-dollar increase in new mortgage
revenue bonds will raise interest rates on all
tax-exempt bonds by between 4 and 7 basis
points.8 Another study shows residential
mortgage revenue bond programs may have
already boosted the cost of borrowing for
state multiple-family housing bonds by as
much as 50 basis points.9
Although these programs would be ex­
pected to put upward pressure on local home
prices, no studies seem to have been made of
the actual effects of programs on local
markets. Programs already in effect have been
large enough to finance a significant propor­
tion of the single-family mortgages made in
the communities every year. As a result, there
should have been a tendency for them to
boost housing prices.
In Chicago last year, one to four-family
residential sales and mortgage originations
totaled about $3.1 billion. The city’s two
mortgage revenue bond programs accounted
for a significant 8 percent of the mortgage
originations and transfers. Nationwide, state
and local single-family housing bonds issued
before April 24,1979, amounted to about 2.6
percent of gross new mortgages on single­
family homes. Without constraints, it is
reasonable to expect these programs to make
up an even larger proportion of new home
mortgages.
There are signs in the Chicago area,
however, that competing programs are not
developing to any great extent between the
suburbs and central city. To the contrary,

more than half the Illinois communities sur­
veyed had rejected the idea of a residential
mortgage revenue bond program before
legislation was introduced to control their
use.
Another fundamental issue concerns
municipalities making use of tax-exempt
bonds to support homeownership. But it can
be argued that use of public funds for housing
is as justifiable as use of these funds to support
such quasi-public ventures as sports facilities,
industrial pollution control projects, and
trade show facilities.
Advantages of the programs

One advantage of the current mortgage
revenue bond programs is the additional
mortgage funds they provide— especially at
rates 1 to 2 percentage points below conven­
tional mortgage interest rates.10
Demand for home mortgages has strain­
ed conventional sources of funds, partly
because of the sharp rise in prices of houses
and increases in the cost of living generally.
Nationwide, prices of a new single-family
house averaged $62,500 last year, compared
with $35,500 as recently as 1973. And estimates
are that mortgage markets will have to sup­
port another $130 billion in debt this year.
Housing, often viewed as a social good,
has an unusual position in this country. The
nation's housing goal, adopted in 1949 and
reaffirmed in 1968, is aimed at providing a
“ decent home and a suitable living envi­
ronment for every American family." The
government has operated subsidy programs
for more than 40 years to increase the flow of
real and financial resources into housing.The
appropriateness of the housing goal has been
questioned, as has the appropriateness of the
programs used to reach it. It seems, however,
that the goal will remain. Under these cir-

Agencies, W ashington, forthcoming.

10The Congressional Budget O ffice report indicates
(page 43) that every $1 billion in mortgage revenue bonds
would add about $200 million in new money to the
mortgage market. The rest would be displaced money
that entered the mortgage market through other forms of
investment.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

21

8See Background and Issues, page 25.
9Ronald Forbes, A. Frankel, and P. Fisher, Taxexempt Mortgage Bonds, Co uncil of State Housing




cumstances, home mortgage revenue bond
programs can best be considered just another
means (though an inadvertant one) of enhan­
cing the flow of funds into home purchases.
These programs could be beneficial to
the recipients of the funds if they could not
otherwise have obtained mortgages. With
home prices rising and interest rates up, many
people are clearly priced out of markets for
houses they want. Some of the benefits to
recipients are offset, however, by increased
costs to others. Costs of issuing corporate
bonds may be higher, for example, as a re­
sult of having to compete with other long­
term offerings in capital markets.
The programs offer considerable flex­
ibility. Barring legislation to prevent further
use of mortgage revenue bonds, every com­
munity (state law permitting) can decide for
itself whether to adopt such a program, taking
into account its own needs and financial
circumstances.
If the local government is not in a finan­
cial condition to borrow at rates below the
conventional mortgage rates, a program is not
feasible. But once a community decides to
undertake a mortgage revenue program, it
has broad leeway. It can choose the size offer­
ing it wants to make and it can pick the
features it wants for its program. It can decide,
for example, to use part of the proceeds to
subsidize loans to low-income families—or
even all of the funds. Or it can direct the funds
into economically depressed areas or
geographic areas particularly short of
mortgage funds.
Once a community establishes the
parameters of its program and the municipali­
ty issues the bonds, practically no govern­
ment resources are needed to operate the
program. This is in contrast to the more
traditional federal and state housing subsidy
programs that have required constant ad­
ministrative supervision and control.
Other government programs are often
criticized as being of questionable value and,
although some states have adopted sunset
rules requiring the elimination of agencies
that have served their purposes, once in place
these agencies are hard to dismantle or even

22




reduce in size or scope.11 Mortgage revenue
bond programs, on the other hand, can be
undertaken incrementally, expanding or con­
tracting as needs dictate, and they can be dis­
continued without displacing government
workers.
Programs can be structured to stem the
flow of migration from inner cities and
p ro v id e fo r the redevelopm ent of
deteriorating neighborhoods. The Con­
gressional Budget Office found, on the basis
of early results, that mortgage bond programs
have been successful so far in inducing peo­
ple back into the inner cities. Whether such
an alteration in migration trends will be
enough to correct other problems besetting
metropolitan areas is another question.
The enabling ordinance for Chicago’s
first program noted that
. . . the availability of decent, safe and
sanitary housing that most people can
afford is essential to the promotion of
increased productivity of the residents
of the municipality, to retaining existing
industry and commercial activities near
or within the municipality.
The ordinance also noted that the hous­
ing problems of inner cities are neither tran­
sitory nor self-curing and that existing in­
stitutions had not been able to cope with
many of the housing problems. It was con­
ceded that the objectives of state and local
programs might not be in harmony with
national policies. For that reason, programs
needed to be tailored more to local needs.
Conclusion

Growth in the number and volume of
mortgage revenue bonds since mid-1978 has
provided an additional source of mortgage
money at rates below conventional mortgage
interest rates. And although the usefulness of
mortgage revenue bond programs has*
"F o r a discussion of federal housing subsidy
programs, see “ Subsidized housing— costs and benefits/'
William R. Sayre, Economic Perspectives ,Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago, M ay/June 1979, pages 3-9.

Economic Perspectives

depended on features of the particular bonds
and the communities issuing them, local
governments have incurred no direct liability
from the bonds, which are neither general
nor moral obligations of the issuing
municipalities. Investor safety is based on a
pool of mortgages, reserve funds, and
insurance.
There will continue to be a loss of
revenue to the Treasury, and interest rates
paid by other types of borrowers will be
affected. But the bond programs have made
low-cost mortgages available for some
families that might not otherwise have been
able to buy housing. As thesefundsarefungi­
ble, there is no guarantee that, once bor­
rowed, they have not been used for other
purposes, such as to the purchase of a new car
or the financing of a college education. They
could have gone for any number of expen­
ditures besides housing.

No recommendation can be made either
for adoption or rejection of a residential
mortgage revenue bond program without
knowledge of the particular bond and the
issuing municipality. Past experience with
legislative prohibition indicates that these
changes do not always resolve the basic
problem. For example, legislation passed to
curtail industrial revenue bonds planted the
seeds that brought forth residential mortgage
revenue bond programs. Left unanswered is
the basic issue concerning the economic
merits of tax-exempt status for municipal
bonds. Assuming that the tax-exempt status
will prevail, then it would seem better to allow
markets (to the extent feasible) to regulate the
development or curtailment of programs
similar to the residential mortgage bond
program. Market regulation should tend to
maximize the extent of program flexibility at
the state and local level.

■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■■

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago



23