View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Call for Papers
Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago

2003 Conference on
Bank Structure and
Competition
Fourth Quarter 2003

Economic.

perspectives

2

Decimalization and market liquidity

13

Estimating U.S. metropolitan area export
and import competition

30

Family resources and college enrollment

42

An introduction to the WTO and GATT

58

Index for 2003

Economic .

perspectives

President
Michael H. Moskow

Senior Vice President and Director of Research
Charles Evans
Research Department
Financial Studies
Douglas Evanoff, Vice President

Macroeconomic Policy
David Marshall, Economic Advisor

Microeconomic Policy
Daniel Sullivan, Vice President
Regional Programs
William A. Testa, Vice President
Economics Editor
Craig Furfine, Economic Advisor
Editor
Helen O’D. Koshy

Associate Editor
Kathryn Moran
Graphics
Rita Molloy
Production
Julia Baker, Yvonne Peeples
Economic Perspectives is published by the Research
Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The
views expressed are the authors’ and do not necessarily
reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
or the Federal Reserve System.

Single-copy subscriptions are available free of charge. Please
send requests for single- and multiple-copy subscriptions,
back issues, and address changes to the Public Information
Center, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, P.O. Box 834,
Chicago, Illinois 60690-0834, telephone 312-322-5111
or fax 312-322-5515.
Economic Perspectives and other Bank
publications are available on the World Wide Web
at http:Zwww.chicagofed.org.

Articles may be reprinted provided the source is credited
and the Public Information Center is sent a copy of the
published material. Citations should include the following
information: author, year, title of article, Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago, Economic Perspectives, quarter, and
page numbers.

a chicagofed, org
ISSN 0164-0682

Contents

Fourth Quarter 2003, Volume XXVII, Issue 4

2

Decimalization and market liquidity
Craig H. Furfine
This study examines the stocks of 1,339 companies that began decimal trading on the NYSE on
January 29, 2001. Using the price impact of a trade as a measure of liquidity, the author finds
that decimalization typically led to an improvement in liquidity.

13

Estimating U.S. metropolitan area export and import competition
William Testa, Thomas Klier, and Alexei Zelenev
This article estimates the extent to which the manufacturing sectors of U.S. metropolitan
economies face competition from abroad and, in turn, how much they export overseas.

28

Call for papers

30

Family resources and college enrollment
Bhashkar Mazumder

This article reviews the literature on the effects of family income and tuition costs on college
enrollment and finds mixed evidence in support of tuition subsidies. The author also presents
new evidence showing that college enrollment is especially sensitive to income for families
with modest amounts of wealth, suggesting that borrowing constraints may be a factor in
limiting access to higher education.

42

An introduction to the WTO and GATT
Meredith A. Crowley
This article reviews the history of GATT and the WTO. It discusses the founding principles of the
post-WW II world trading system—reciprocity and nondiscrimination. Lastly, the article reviews
the economics literature on regional trade agreements and administered protection, two important
exceptions to GATT’s requirement for nondiscrimination in trade policy.

58

Index for 2003

Decimalization and market liquidity

Craig H. Furfine

On January 29, 2001, the New York Stock Exchange
(NYSE) implemented decimalization. Beginning on
that Monday, stocks began to be priced in dollars and
cents, and price changes were allowed to be as small
as 1 cent.1 Prior to this change, NYSE stocks were
quoted in fractions of a dollar and traded in increments
of 1/16, or 6.25 cents. Decimalization of stock markets
is relevant for policymakers because it has the poten­
tial to affect market liquidity, and therefore the over­
all functioning of financial markets.
Advocates of the adoption of decimalization argue
that the finer gradation of stock prices will benefit in­
vestors. This is because the pricing increment dictates
the smallest possible bid-ask spread for a given stock.
This spread represents the difference between the lowest
price an investor can pay for a stock and the highest
price an investor can receive for selling the same stock.
Prior to decimalization, actively traded stocks often
had a spread equal to the minimum price increment, or
tick, of 6.25 cents. For instance, an investor might have
faced a bid-ask spread of 50 1/2-50 9/16 for shares
of stock in XYZ company on Friday, January 26, 2001.
That is, abstracting from any transaction fees levied
by brokers, an investor wanting to sell a round lot of
100 shares of XYZ could expect to receive $5,050 and
an investor needing to buy 100 shares would have to
pay $5,056.25. Following decimalization, however,
the two investors might face a spread of 50.51-50.53.
Thus, the seller of XYZ would receive an extra penny
per share and the buyer of XYZ shares would save
3.25 cents per share.
However, decimalization may affect more than a
stock’s bid-ask spread. To understand this, consider the
set of firms and individuals that stand ready to buy and
sell the stock of XYZ company. For example, prior to
decimalization, a dealer might have been willing to
commit to buy 10,000 shares ofXYZ company at 50 1/2
and to sell 10,000 shares at 50 9/16. In practice, these
commitments may have been made by the dealer

2

placing a limit buy order for 10,000 at 50 1/2 and a
limit sell order for 10,000 shares at 50 9/16. If these are
the only outstanding orders for XYZ stock at these
prices, then the stock will have a bid-ask spread of
1/16 and a so-called depth of 10,000 (at the bid price)
by 10,000 (at the ask price) shares. With decimal pricing,
the same dealer may have decided not to post limit
orders of the same size at the new prices of 50.51-50.53.
This is because the profitability of committing to be
willing to both buy and sell a given stock, as measured
by the bid-ask spread, has declined. Thus, the dealer
might only be willing to offer depth of 1,000 by 1,000.
From the perspective of a small investor, for example
one wishing to trade only a few hundred shares, this
reduction in depth at the bid-ask spread is not a con­
cern. Depth at the best available prices will suffice.
However, for large traders, for example those wishing
to trade several thousand shares, quoted depth at the
best-quoted prices may be insufficient to fill the de­
sired order. For such trades, the effective transaction
price lies somewhere outside the posted bid and ask.
In this article, I examine how various measures
of stock market liquidity changed following decimal­
ization. A stock’s illiquidity measures the cost to a buyer
or seller of transacting in shares beyond the true un­
derlying value of the security. These costs arise from
a lack of an infinite supply of shares that can be pur­
chased and sold at the same price. That is, if investors
could buy or sell any number of shares of XYZ stock
at 50.52, then one would say that XYZ shares are per­
fectly liquid at that price. Bid-ask spreads and limited
depth represent two departures from this situation and,
thus, bid-ask spreads and depth are two measures of
Craig H. Furfine is an economic advisor at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago. The author would like to give
special thanks to Bob Chakravorti and Helen Koshy for
helpful comments.

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

liquidity. Lower spreads and higher depth represent
more liquidity. Higher spreads and lower depth signal
less liquidity.
I document that decimalization did lead to smaller
spreads and lower depth, and thus caused a theoretically
ambiguous change to market liquidity. Thus, to em­
pirically address whether and/or to what extent market
liquidity was affected by decimalization, one must focus
on a liquidity measure that is affected by both a finer
pricing grid and lower depth. In this article, I examine
the revision to a stock’s price that follows a trade as a
direct measure of a stock’s liquidity. This is known as
the price impact of a trade. By definition, perfect liquid­
ity implies that a given trade should not affect the price.2
With imperfect liquidity, the size of the price revision
following a trade is likely positively related to tick
size, since any adjustment to prices must be at least
as large as the minimum tick. Likewise, the price im­
pact should be negatively related to market depth, since
lower depth implies that a given (large) trade may
have to travel through more prices in order to be filled.
In this study, I examine the stocks of 1,339 com­
panies that began decimal trading on the NYSE on
January 29, 2001.1 document what previous studies
have found regarding the relationship between tick
size, bid-ask spreads, and depth. I then estimate the
price impact of a trade, distinguishing trades under­
taken before decimalization from those after and fur­
ther distinguishing large trades from small trades. I find
that for both large and small trades, decimalization
typically led to an improvement in liquidity as mea­
sured by a decline in the price impact of a trade for
actively traded stocks. For less actively traded stocks,
decimalization led to improved liquidity more often
than it led to reduced liquidity. However, the most com­
mon empirical finding for infrequently traded stocks
was that there was not a statistically significant change
in liquidity following decimalization.

Selective literature review
I mention only a few contributions to the extensive
literature on the effects of reducing tick sizes on vari­
ous measures of market performance, including liquidity.
In Seppi’s (1997) theoretical framework, reduction in
tick sizes leads to a reduction in the willingness of both
small and large traders to supply liquidity through limit
orders (depth). However, because retail investors re­
quire less depth to conduct trading, optimal tick size
depends positively on typical trade size. That is, institu­
tions that typically trade in large amounts prefer large
tick sizes, whereas small investors prefer small tick sizes.
Harris (1994), using data from a time when the min­
imum tick was 1/8, fits a regression model estimating

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

the frequency at which spreads are at the minimum.
Using this relationship, Harris estimates that the im­
pact of reducing the minimum tick size to 1/16 would
be accompanied by both lower bid-ask spreads and
lower quoted depth. His results are therefore also con­
sistent with the notion that optimal tick size is related
to the size of a trade. They indicate that small traders
would almost certainly benefit from smaller tick sizes,
but that large traders might be hurt if the depth of the
market were to fall sufficiently.
Goldstein and Kavajecz (2000) analyze the NYSE’s
reduction in tick size from 1/8 to 1/16 and address the
relationship between minimum tick size, bid-ask
spreads, and market liquidity. What is unique about this
study is that these authors not only look at the depth
reported at the best bid and ask prices, they also collect
data on liquidity available at some distance away from
the best bid and ask prices. This complete collection
of prices and available depth is called the limit order
book. They find that not only did depth at the best bid
and ask decline, but cumulative depth similarly de­
clined throughout the limit order book following the
NYSE’s previous reduction in minimum tick size. They
found such declines in depth as far as 50 cents from
the midpoint of the bid-ask spread. Using implied aver­
age price of a trade of a given size derived from the
limit order book, these authors find that large traders
were not made better off by the smaller tick sizes and
were made worse off for infrequently traded stocks.
More recent work has examined changes in mar­
ket liquidity for NYSE-listed stocks since decimaliza­
tion. Chakravarty et al. (2001) study a small set of
stocks that began trading in decimals as part of an
NYSE pilot program in 2000. These authors find that
decimalization has led to significantly lower spreads
and also lower quoted depth. Bacidore et al. (2001)
also study stocks in the decimalization pilot. These
authors focus on whether decimalization leads to sig­
nificant changes in order submission strategies. They
find that there is no noticeable change in the use of
limit versus market orders, but the size of limit orders
has fallen and the frequency of limit order cancellation
has increased since decimalization. Smaller limit orders
and higher cancellation rates explain how lower depth
materialized.
Bessembinder (2003) studies a larger sample of
NYSE and Nasdaq (National Association of Securities
Dealers Automated Quotation) stocks and documents
that following decimalization, bid-ask spreads fell
noticeably, with the largest declines seen for the most
actively traded stocks. Bessembinder also reports an
increase in the frequency of price improvement on the
NYSE following decimalization. Price improvement

3

occurs when a trade is conducted at a price
inside the bid-ask spread. Higher rates of
price improvement are consistent with the
fact that decimalization makes it easier for
traders to step in front of the current best
bid or ask to take the other side of a mar­
ket order.

Data, sample selection, and
summary statistics

TABLE 1

Average trading activity of sample stocks
Category

Average time between trades

1
2
3
4
5
6

5-10 minutes
1 minute-4 minutes, 59 seconds
30-59 seconds
15-29 seconds
5-14 seconds
Less than 5 seconds

Number
of stocks

191
722
237
108
70
11

For this study, I extracted stock mar­
Source: New York Stock Exchange, 2001, Trades and Quotes (TAQ) database,
ket trade and quote data from the NYSE
January 16-February 16.
TAQ (Trades and Quotes) database, cover­
ing the 24 trading days beginning Tuesday,
January 16,2001, and ending on February 16,
size, suggesting that nearly all of the 722 stocks in that
2001? Following Hasbrouck (1991), I also impose a
category experience minimum tick-sized spreads dur­
minimum price requirement on each company’s stock.
ing each day. Even for those stocks trading only every
I require each stock to be trading for at least $5, on
five to ten minutes, average minimum spreads hover
average, during the five-week sample period. I simi­
around 6.5 cents when the minimum tick size was
larly impose a maximum price of $200. Also follow­
6.25 and fall to around 2 cents after decimalization.
ing Hasbrouck (1991), I require a minimum level of
Figure 2 plots the mean spread within a day aver­
trading activity. I limit my sample to stocks that trad­
aged across stocks in a given trading category. As ex­
ed, on average, at least every ten minutes over these
pected, more frequently traded stocks have lower
five weeks. Finally, I eliminate those stocks that were
spreads. For stocks in all categories, decimalization
part of the NYSE pilot program and, therefore, trad­
has led to a decline in average bid-ask spreads. This
ed in decimals prior to January 29, 2001. My final
decline in mean spreads is most pronounced for the
sample consists of 1,339 stocks.
more actively traded stocks. For example, mean bidThe data are then adjusted according to procedures
ask spreads for stocks in Category 1 averaged 13.6
common in the microstructure literature. Following
cents, about a penny over two ticks, in the two weeks
Hasbrouck (1991), I keep only New York quotes and
prior to decimalization. Following decimalization, the
consider multiple trades on a regional exchange for the
average mean spread of these stocks fell to 10.5 cents.
same stock at the same price and time to be one trade.
For the most actively traded stocks, average mean
Then, I sort the trade data (for each company and day)
spreads were 11.3 cents before decimalization and
by time, with the prevailing quote at transaction t de­
fell to 7.0 cents after.
fined to be the last quote that was posted at least five
The narrowing of bid-ask spreads following deci­
seconds before the transaction (Lee and Ready, 1991).
malization illustrated in figures 1 and 2 has been ac­
I group the 1,339 stocks into six categories accord­
companied by a decline in average depth at the posted
ing to their average trade frequency, with Category 1
prices. Figure 3 reports the mean of the bid and ask
stocks being the least traded and Category 6 stocks
depth posted throughout a day, averaged across stocks
being the most frequently traded. The number of stocks
in each category. The post-decimalization decline in
in each category is shown in table 1.1 first calculate
posted depth was significant, especially for the most
the narrowest bid-ask spread witnessed by each stock
actively traded stocks that had previously had a very
and for each day. I then average these minimums across
large number of shares committed to trade at the post­
stocks within the same trading category. These average
ed spread. For the least actively traded stocks, posted
minimum values are plotted in figure 1. As is apparent
depth fell by half, from just under 6,600 shares to 3,300
from figure 1, minimum tick size strongly influences
shares on average. The most actively traded stocks
the extent to which bid-ask spreads can narrow with­
experienced depth declines of more than two-thirds,
in a day. Every stock in the four most actively traded
from an average of 18,700 shares to slightly more
categories experienced a bid-ask spread equal to the
than 6,000 shares.
minimum tick size at least once on every day of the
sample period. For stocks in Category 2, that is, those
Price impact of trading
trading every one to five minutes, minimum spreads
The statistics reported in the previous section
were always within 1/10 of a cent of the minimum tick
confirm that decimalization has led to both a decline

4

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

FIGURE 1

Average minimum daily spread

♦ Category 1 (least actively traded)

I Category 2

A
X

Category 3

X

Category 4

I Category 6 (most actively traded)

Category 5

Source: NYSE TAQ database from January 16-February 16, 2001.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

5

FIGURE 3

Average daily quoted depth (in number of round lots)
300 i-

200

100

—
rxxxx

vXX.

♦

0

1A z

L

1/15/01

1/22/01

♦ Category 1 (least actively traded)

**x*x

..

I

l

l

1/29/01

2/5/01

A

Category 2

Category 3

••••

.

1/12/01

X

Category 4

Category 5
Category 6 (most actively traded)

Source; NYSE TAQ database from January 16-February 16, 2001.

in spreads and a decline in depth. Thus, an investor
making a relatively small trade generally faces improved
liquidity, since the trade can be executed at a narrower
spread. For institutional investors making large trades,
however, the lower depth may imply that a large trade
must travel through several prices before being ful­
filled, and thus decimalization may not necessarily have
led to better execution prices. To try to combine the
effects of spread and depth in one framework, I examine
a liquidity measure called the price impact of a trade,
which was first motivated and estimated by Hasbrouck
(1991). This is a measure of how much the price of a
stock changes following a given trade as estimated in
an autoregression framework. While other measures of
liquidity are conceivable, price impact has the advantage
of being influenced by both smaller price increments
and lower depth. In particular, decimalization may
cause the price impact to decline since prices can ad­
just by smaller increments, but it may also cause the
price impact to rise since more prices must be exhaust­
ed because depth at any given price is lower.
In the price impact framework, the dependent vari­
able of interest is the trade-to-trade return on a given
stock. I denote this return r and define it formally as
the change in the natural logarithm of the midquote of
a given stock that follows the trade at time That is,

6

flnf bidM+ask,+CI 1npz'^+asMl
ll
2
1
I
2
}}

The use of midquotes eliminates price changes
caused by the bid-ask bounce, that is, the alternating
arrival of buys and sells transacting at the ask and bid
price, respectively. Following Hasbrouck (1991), I de­
fine the variable xt as an indicator of the direction of
the trade occurring at time t. If the trade is initiated by
the buyer, the variable xt = 1. If the trade is initiated
by the seller, then the variable y = -1.1 assume trades
at a transaction price greater than the midquote were
buyer-initiated and trades below the midquote were
seller-initiated. For trades at the midquote, xt is as­
signed to equal zero. Defining Dt as an indicator that
equals 1 if trade t occurs during the first 30 minutes
of the trading day and decf as an indicator that equals
1 if trade t occurs during the decimal period after
January 29, 2001,51 estimate the regression
5

2)

rt = oc£>,x, + £[0,. + 8,.

] rt_,

7=1

5

+IK +Mec,-,-Ki +ez
7 =0

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

for each stock in my sample.6 The price impact of a
trade in this framework is equal to the sum of the y.
coefficients during the pre-decimalization period and
equal to the sum of the y. + X. coefficients after deci­
malization. Because purchases should put upward pres­
sure on prices, I expect that y. should be positive for
some or all of the trade lags z. This prediction follows
from traditional microstructure theory. In Glosten and
Milgrom (1985), for example, market makers set a
positive bid-ask spread as compensation for trades
made with counterparties with superior information.
As a sequence of sell orders arrives, market makers
lower bid prices, incorporating the probability that
the order flow implies that better-informed investors
believe the previous price was too high. The reverse
occurs when a sequence of buy orders arrives. This
type of dynamic quote adjustment leads to the pre­
diction of a positive value of the y. coefficients. The
X. coefficients may be either positive or negative de­
pending on whether the stock has become less or
more liquid (higher or lower price impact of a trade)
since decimalization.
Table 2 summarizes the results from these 1,339
regressions. Each row of table 2 corresponds to stocks
in different trade activity categories. The numbers re­
ported in the first column represent the average value
of the sum of the y. coefficients across all stocks in
the given category. These coefficients measure the price
impact of a trade in the two weeks prior to decimal­
ization. For instance, the first entry in the first column
reports that the average price impact of a trade during
this time is 9.2 basis points for stocks in the least ac­
tively traded category. Put another way, 11 trades in
the same direction move an infrequently traded stock’s
price by 1 percent. As the numbers in the first col­
umn indicate, liquidity as measured by price impact

increases with trading activity, since trades of more
actively traded stocks move prices less. For example,
a trade of a stock of a very actively traded security moves
the stock’s price by just over 1 basis point. The num­
bers in the second and third columns summarize the
statistical significance of the price impact results. The
second and third columns report the fraction of stocks
in the given category whose price impact estimate was
positive and statistically significant (at the 5 percent
level) and negative and statistically significant, respec­
tively. As the numbers in columns two and three indi­
cate, none of the stocks in the sample had a negative
and significant price impact of a trade, whereas virtu­
ally all of the sample stocks had significantly positive
price impacts.
The last three columns summarize the results for
the decimalization period. A comparison of the fourth
column with the first indicates that for stocks in all
categories, the average price impact of a trade declined
following decimalization. That is, stocks became more
liquid on average. However, the numbers reported in
the final two columns suggest that this result is not as
uniform as the positive price impact result reported
for the pre-decimalization period. For stocks in the
least actively traded category, only one-quarter saw
a statistically significant decrease in price impact
following decimalization. Around two-thirds of the
stocks in category two had statistically significant
increases in liquidity. For the more actively traded
stocks, that is, those that on average trade at least
once per minute, more than 95 percent witnessed
an increase in liquidity (decrease in price impact)
following decimalization. The magnitude of the in­
creased liquidity is fairly large, with the typical de­
cline in price impact following decimalization being
close to 40 percent.

TABLE 2

Average price impact of a trade: Before and after decimalization
Before decimalization

Trade category

After decimalization

Average
price
impact
(sum of y,)

Share of
stocks with
positive
and sig. y.

Share of
stocks with
negative
and sig. y.

Average
price
impact
(sum of y; + A.)

Share of
stocks with
positive
and sig. A.

Share of
stocks with
negative
and sig. A.

1

0.092

0.974

0.000

0.074

0.016

0.251

2

0.070

0.999

0.000

0.045

0.007

0.652

3
4

0.043
0.032

1.000
1.000

0.000
0.000

0.025
0.019

0.008
0.000

0.945
0.954

5

0.023

1.000

0.000

0.014

0.014

0.957

6

0.011

1.000

0.000

0.006

0.000

1.000

5

5

Based on the regression equation rt = aDtxt + [0, +
Note: Sig. indicates significant.
1=1

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

rt_, + 22[y,- + Kdect-fct-i + ef.
i=0

7

The preceding results suggest that decimalization
led to increased liquidity for virtually all stocks that
trade at least once per minute. Among less frequently
traded stocks, the results were more mixed, with a sig­
nificant fraction of stocks experiencing no statistically
significant change in price impact following the move
to decimal pricing. My previous discussion of micro­
structure theory, however, suggests that decreases in
tick size and depth may have different implications
for trades of different sizes. In particular, small trades
may benefit from tighter spreads and correspondingly
smaller price increments because they can normally be
executed within posted depth. Large trades, however,
may have become less liquid following decimalization
due to the significant decline in depth. I extend my
empirical framework to test for this possibility. I de­
fine the variable Bigta& an indicator that equals 1 when
trade t is among the largest 10 percent of trades for
the given stock and then estimate an extended regres­
sion model described by equation 3.
5

3)

rt = aD,x, + £ [P# + 5,.rtec,_,. ] r,_y
7=1

5

+El'C + ^idec,_i +[iiBigl_i +Qidecl_iBig,_i]x,_i
7=0

+ £,.

In equation 3,1 have extended the previous regres­
sion equation by allowing the price impact of a trade,
both before and after decimalization, to differ depend­
ing on whether the trade is large. Since large trades have
been generally found to be less liquid (see Hasbrouck,
1991), one might expect the q. coefficients to be posi­
tive. That is, larger trades will move prices more than
smaller trades. The <|). coefficients allow a direct test of
the hypothesis that the liquidity of large trades has been
adversely affected by the move to decimal pricing.
Table 3 summarizes the results from estimating
equation 3 for all 1,339 stocks in the sample. Table 3
follows a similar format as table 2, only expanded to
account for the fact that I now distinguish between
large trades (those in the top 10 percent of size with­
in the given stock) and regular trades (all others). The
first three columns of panel A in table 3 report statis­
tics for regular trades prior to decimalization. These
results are qualitatively similar to those reported in
the first three columns in table 2. In particular, I find
positive and statistically significant price impacts for
virtually all stocks in the sample for regular sized trades.
The size of the price impact is lower than that report­
ed for all trades in table 2. This can be explained by

8

the larger impacts found for large trades reported in
columns four to six of table 3. For example, a regular
trade of a stock in category 6 (most actively traded)
moved the stock’s price by roughly 0.9 basis points.
Large trades of such a stock moved the price by 3.0
basis points. Since I define large trades to be the top
10 percent of the size distribution, one might expect
the average price impact of an actively traded stock
to be 90% x 0.9 + 10% x 3.0 = 1.11 basis points, which
is the result reported in table 2.
The results in columns four to six of table 3 also
indicate that large trades are not necessarily less liquid
for relatively infrequently traded stocks. In particular,
I find that larger trades have a larger price impact for
only 29 percent of stocks trading every five to ten min­
utes and for only 50 percent of stocks trading every
one to five minutes. Large trades of stocks trading at
least every 30 seconds, however, do typically move
prices more than other trades. For these more active­
ly traded stocks, large trades move prices between
two and three times more than regular trades.
Panel B in table 3 summarizes the regression re­
sults related to the period following decimalization.
Average price impacts of regular trades fell following
decimalization for virtually all stocks trading at least
once each minute. For example, the price impact of a
regular trade of a very actively traded stock (category 6)
fell from 0.9 basis points to 0.5 basis points after deci­
malization. For stocks trading every 30-60 seconds
(category 3), the average price impact of regular trades
fell from 3.9 basis points to 2.3 basis points. For stocks
trading only every five to ten minutes, decimalization
did not generally lead to lower price impacts of regu­
lar trades. I find a statistically significant decline in
price impact (increase in liquidity) for only 17.8 per­
cent of such stocks.
The final three columns of panel B report my find­
ings regarding the liquidity of large trades after decimal­
ization relative to before. On average, large trades are
more liquid in the post-decimalization period. For
example, a large trade of a stock in the most actively
traded category moved the stock’s price by an average
of 3.0 basis points before decimalization, but by only
1.9 basis points after decimalization. For all 11 of these
stocks, the decline in price impact (increase in liquid­
ity) of large trades was statistically significant. Across
stocks in the entire sample, the decline in price im­
pact for large trades was less common than that found
for regular trades. For example, I find that the price
impact of a regular trade declined post-decimalization
for 92.0 percent of stocks that were traded every 3060 seconds (Category 3). However, the price impact
of a large trade fell in only 37.1 percent of these stocks

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

TABLE 3

Average price impact of a trade: Before and after decimalization, by trade size
A. Before decimalization

Trades with size in top decile

Regular trades

Trade category

Average
price impact
(sum of y,)

Share of
stocks with
positive and
sig. y.

Share of
stocks with
negative and
sig- Y,

Average
price impact
(sum of y, + p,)

Share of
stocks with
positive
and sig. p.

Share of
stocks with
negative
and sig. p.

1

0.080

0.942

0.005

0.141

0.288

0.000

2
3

0.062
0.039

0.989
1.000

0.000
0.000

0.115
0.077

0.499
0.789

0.001
0.000

4

0.029

1.000

0.000

0.062

0.944

0.000

5

0.019

1.000

0.000

0.049

1.000

0.000

6

0.009

1.000

0.000

0.030

1.000

0.000

Share of
stocks with
negative and
sig. X.

Average
price impact
(sum of
Y, + X.+ p.+ 0.)

Share of
stocks with
positive
and sig. 0,

Share of
stocks with
negative
and sig. 0,

B. After decimalization

Trades with size in top decile

Regular trades

Trade category

Average
price impact
(sum of y, + X,)

Share of
stocks with
positive and
sig. X,

1

0.067

0.016

0.178

0.126

0.026

0.084

2

0.042

0.008

0.569

0.101

0.008

0.140

3

0.023

0.008

0.920

0.061

0.004

0.371

4

0.018

0.000

0.926

0.044

0.000

0.657

5

0.013

0.014

0.914

0.033

0.000

0.886

6

0.005

0.000

1.000

0.000

1.000

Based on the regression equation rt = aDtxt +

[3,. + ^deCt-i

0.019
f + ^Big^ +

+ E,.

Note: Sig. indicates significant.

following decimalization. Most stocks trading less
frequently did not witness an increase in liquidity for
large trades following decimalization. For example,
among stocks trading only every five to ten minutes,
only 8.4 percent of the stocks saw a decline in price
impact for large trades following decimalization. In
fact, 2.6 percent of such stocks actually saw an increase
in price impact. Higher price impacts following deci­
malization, however, were virtually nonexistent for
stocks trading at least once every five minutes.
As a robustness check, I reestimate equation 3
after changing the definition of a large trade. The pre­
vious definition of large was an absolute one, namely
any trade that was among the largest 10 percent of all
trades of a given stock during the sample period. To
consider more explicitly that the liquidity of a trade
is not only related to size, but also to depth, I repeat
the analysis defining the variable Big to be equal to
1 when the given trade is executed for more shares
than posted depth. That is, a buy transaction for more
shares than posted ask depth or a sell transaction for
more shares than posted bid depth would be defined
as a large trade. Whereas 10 percent of trades were
previously defined as large, this alternative definition

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

identifies roughly 19 percent of all trades. However,
only approximately 60 percent of trades previously
identified as large satisfy this new definition. This
implies that much of the time, large trades occur
when depth is also high.
Table 4 reports results analogous to those in
table 3 for this alternative definition of a large trade.
The most substantial difference from the earlier results
is that trades that satisfy the new definition of big
seem more highly correlated with lower levels of liquidi­
ty. Whereas less than half of stocks trading less than
once per minute (Categories 1 and 2) had higher price
impacts for trades in the top 10 percent of the size
distribution (table 3), well over half of these stocks
experience a greater price impact for trades greater
than posted depth (table 4). The magnitude of the price
impact for these large trades is now larger under this
definition. Whereas the largest 10 percent of trades
of the most frequently traded stocks moved price by
3.0 basis points, trades greater than posted depth moved
the price of these same stocks by 3.9 basis points be­
fore decimalization.
With this new definition of large trades, decimal­
ization is still generally correlated with increased

9

TABLE 4

Average price impact of a trade: Before and after decimalization, by trade size
(alternative definition of a large trade)
A. Before decimalization

Trades with size > posted depth

Regular trades

Trade category

Average
price impact
(sum of y,)

Share of
stocks with
positive and
sig- Y,

Share of
stocks with
negative and
sig- Y,

Average
price impact
(sum of y, + p,)

Share of
stocks with
positive
and sig. p.

Share of
stocks with
negative
and sig. p.

1

0.074

0.942

0.000

0.188

0.476

0.000

2

0.058

0.988

0.000

0.143

0.731

0.003

3
4

0.035
0.026

1.000
1.000

0.000
0.000

0.091
0.070

0.987
1.000

0.000
0.000

5

0.017

1.000

0.000

0.057

1.000

0.000

6

0.008

1.000

0.000

0.039

1.000

0.000

Share of
stocks with
negative and
sig. X.

Average
price impact
(sum of
Y, + X.+ p.+ 0.)

B. After decimalization

Trades with size > posted depth

Regular trades

Trade category

Average
price impact
(sum of y, + X)

Share of
stocks with
positive and
sig. X.

Share of
stocks with
negative
and sig. 0.

1

0.062

0.010

0.168

0.140

0.010

0.173

2

0.040

0.011

0.553

0.106

0.010

0.325

3
4

0.020
0.015

0.008
0.000

0.895
0.926

0.062
0.044

0.000
0.000

0.679
0.935

5

0.010

0.014

0.957

0.033

0.000

0.957

6

0.004

0.000

1.000

0.019

0.000

1.000

5

5

Based on the regression equation rt = aDtxt + ^[3, + ^/dec^+ ^[y,
Note: Sig. indicates significant.
/=1
/=0

liquidity (lower price impact) of actively traded stocks.
Further, more stocks have a statistically significant
decline in price impact for large trades under the new
definition. With large trades defined as those with size
greater than posted depth, virtually all stocks trading
at least every 30 seconds and two-thirds of those trad­
ing every 30-60 seconds witnessed an increase in li­
quidity of large trades following decimalization. Thus,
according to these two measures of large trade size,
decimalization seems to have led to increased liquid­
ity for most actively traded stocks, and in virtually
no cases did decimalization lead to less liquidity,
even for large trades.

Conclusion
This article has examined the impact of decimal­
ization on the liquidity of NYSE stocks. Analyzing
transaction data for a sample of 1,339 stocks listed
on the NYSE over a five-week period surrounding
the January 29, 2001, implementation of decimaliza­
tion, I presented evidence of the following: Minimum
price increments do seem to have an impact on bid-ask

io

Share of
stocks with
positive
and sig. 0.

+ \dect_i +

+ Qjdec^Big^^^ + er

spreads. In particular, for nearly all but the least-trad­
ed stocks, bid-ask spreads were equal to the mini­
mum price increment at least once each day during the
sample period. Decimalization also led to a narrowing
of average bid-ask spreads. The largest declines in
spreads were found for the most actively traded stocks,
where the average decline in spreads was over 35 per­
cent. I also documented that the observed compression
of bid-ask spreads was accompanied by a decline in
posted depth. The decline in depth was also most
pronounced for the most actively traded stocks.
Because these findings suggest that decimaliza­
tion had an ambiguous impact on market liquidity
using spreads and depth as proxies for liquidity, I then
estimated a different measure of liquidity that would
be affected by changes in both spreads and depth.
Specifically, I estimate the price impact of a trade for
each stock in my sample. The price impact measures
the percentage change in a stock’s price that follows
a trade. Larger price impacts, therefore, reflect lower
liquidity. Intuitively, one would expect lower price
increments to imply lower price impacts but lower depth

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

to imply higher price impacts. Thus, calculating price
impacts before and after decimalization is one measure
of stock market liquidity that encompasses changes
in both spreads and depth.
Estimating price impact regressions, I find that
actively traded stocks generally experienced an increase
in liquidity (decrease in price impact) following deci­
malization. For less frequently traded stocks, the re­
sults were mixed. In particular, most stocks in the sample
traded once every one to five minutes, and of these,
only two in three experienced a statistically significant
decline in average price impact following decimalization.
I then expanded my empirical framework to con­
sider explicitly the fact that declines in posted depth
may be more important for large trades, defined as those
among the largest 10 percent of trades for a given stock.
These large trades may be more likely to be executed
at prices other than the best bid and ask price. I con­
firm that price impacts of these larger trades are greater,
reflecting their lower liquidity. Even though these large
trades have higher price impacts than other trades, I still
find that decimalization generally improved the liquid­
ity of large trades for actively traded stocks. However,
I find no statistically significant improvement in liquidi­
ty of large trades for a wider set of stocks in my sample.
For my set of stocks trading every one to five minutes,
for example, only one in seven experienced a statisti­
cally significant increase in liquidity of large trades

following decimalization. The liquidity of large trades
of most stocks after decimalization was statistically
indistinguishable from their liquidity before. My find­
ings were similar when I defined large trades as those
whose size was greater than posted depth.
The findings in this study suggest that decimal­
ization on the NYSE was a positive step because
policymakers prefer more liquid markets. Virtually
all actively traded stocks had improved levels of liquid­
ity following decimalization using price impact as
the liquidity measure, even if this improved liquidity
was not realized by those making large trades. Thus,
with respect to market liquidity, the lower willing­
ness of market participants to post limit orders seems
to be more than offset by the availability of a wider
array of prices at which to trade.
In the two years since decimalization, spreads and
depth have continued to fall. Actively traded stocks
typically have average spreads of around 3 cents, where­
as relatively infrequently traded stocks have spreads
of around 6 cents. Thus, market developments suggest
that it may not be long before one may ask whether
minimum price increments of 1 cent should be aban­
doned. Even before decimalization, prices were not
always equal to multiples of a penny, and thus, in prin­
ciple, prices could be as finely divided as desired by
traders. Perhaps, therefore, the optimal tick size is
less than a penny.

NOTES
few months later, the National Association of Securities Dealers
did the same for stocks trading on Nasdaq.
2Trades can affect prices for reasons of asymmetric information.
This will be discussed later in the article.
3Monday, January 15, 2001, was a holiday.

5For the regressions, I do not include the middle week of my
sample (that is, the week of January 29, 2001) to control for the
possibility that market participants require a period of adjustment
to a new quoting system.
6I choose five lags following Hasbrouck (1991). The results are
robust to adjustments in lag length.

4I eliminate observations spanning more than one business day.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

11

REFERENCES

Bacidore, Jeffrey M., Robert H. Battalio, and
Robert H. Jennings, 2001, “Order submission strate­
gies, liquidity supply, and trading in pennies on the New
York Stock Exchange,” Indiana University, mimeo.
Bessembinder, Hendrik, 2003, “Trade execution costs
and market quality after decimalization,” Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis, forthcoming.
Chakravarty, Sugato, Stephen P. Harris, and
Robert A. Wood, 2001, “Decimal trading and mar­
ket impact,” Purdue University, working paper.
Glosten, Lawrence R., and Paul R. Milgrom, 1985,
“Bid, ask, and transaction prices in a specialist mar­
ket with heterogeneously informed traders,” Journal
of Financial Economics, Vol. 14, pp. 71-100.

Harris, Lawrence E., 1994, “Minimum price varia­
tions, discrete bid-ask spreads, and quotation sizes,”
Review’ ofFinancial Studies, Vol. 7, No. l,pp. 149-178.
Hasbrouck, Joel, 1991, “Measuring the information
content of stock trades,” Journal ofFinance, Vol. 46,
No. l,pp. 179-207.

Lee, Charles M. C., and Mark J. Ready, 1991,
“Inferring trade direction from intraday data,”
Journal ofFinance, Vol. 46, No. 2, pp. 733-746.

Seppi, Duane J., 1997, “Liquidity provision with
limit orders and a strategic specialist,” Review of
Financial Studies, Vol. 10, No. l,pp. 103-150.

Goldstein, Michael A., and Kenneth A. Kavajecz,
2000, “Eighths, sixteenths, and market depth: Changes
in tick size and liquidity provision on the NYSE,”
Journal ofFinancial Economics, Vol. 56, pp. 125-149.

12

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

Estimating U.S. metropolitan area export
and import competition

William Testa, Thomas Klier, and Alexei Zelenev

This article calculates estimates of the extent to which
U.S. cities’ manufacturers face competition from for­
eign producers. Foreign and U.S production can com­
pete in the U.S. domestic market, foreign markets, or
both. Accordingly, this article examines measures of
metropolitan-area (MSA) level import competition,
based on each city’s industrial composition and in­
dustry-level data on import competition, as well as
measures of metro-level export competition, based
on U.S. export data. With these measures, we evaluate
whether the growth experience of U.S. cities that face
high competition from foreign producers substantial­
ly differs from that of cities with low competition.
Measures of import and export competition at the MSA
level may be helpful to metropolitan area residents
and policymakers in evaluating their own actions in
various arenas such as household movements, invest­
ment, and local development.
The International Trade Administration (ITA)
tracks exports from U.S. metropolitan areas. However,
there are no comparable statistics of actual imports
into particular metropolitan areas. Nor, even if they
existed, would such figures be particularly useful in
measuring the degree to which metropolitan area econ­
omies (and their local industries) are impacted by im­
port competition. To the extent that the manufacturing
sector of a metropolitan area sells much of its output
to markets located outside of its own metropolitan area,
own-industry imports at the metropolitan area level
would not fully measure the degree of competition to
this metropolitan area’s producers. As an alternative
to such a hypothetical measure of local imports, we
construct measures of metropolitan areas’ exposure
to national or U.S. market import competition.
In examining trends in imports into the U.S. mar­
ket over time, we find robust growth in imports of man­
ufactured goods during the 1990s. As one measure,
we allocate such imports—good by good—to each
metropolitan area based on its own size and mix of

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

manufacturing industries. In constructing these esti­
mates, we find a wide variation across U.S. metropoli­
tan areas in import market share and in the growth of
such imports from 1989 to 1999. A rapidly growing
share of imports, however, does not necessarily accom­
pany local production decline or stagnation, because
rising imports may also be associated with a rising
domestic demand for these products. For example,
imagine the rapidly rising U.S. imports for pharma­
ceuticals not necessarily displacing domestic produc­
tion, but simply serving a growing market (perhaps
fueled by an aging U.S. population).
A separate and different accounting of import
behavior over time, the degree of “import penetration,”
measures the extent to which the domestic U.S. mar­
ket for goods is served by foreign sources rather than
domestic producers. Here again, we find a wide re­
gional variation, both for the current period and across
time. Such evidence of market penetration does not,
of course, measure changes in the economic well-be­
ing of workers and firms. Imports of capital goods
and technology also assist domestic industry to im­
prove and stay competitive in its production and ex­
port activity. Indeed, imports are often not final goods
but intermediate products used in the production of
other goods, which are ultimately sold both domesti­
cally and abroad.1 And importantly, imports of con­
sumer goods presumably improve well-being and quality
of life for U.S. individuals and households. Even on
its production side, displacement of manufacturing

William A. Testa is a vice president and the director of
regional programs, Thomas Klier is a senior economist,
and Alexei Zelenev is an associate economist at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The authors would like
to thank Jeff Campbell and seminar participants at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago and express their
appreciation to the late senior economist Jack L. Hervey
for inspiration and friendship.

13

by imports may result in reallocation of workers and
capital to higher-valued production, for example, in
exports, non-traded goods, or in the service sector. In
these ways, enhanced imports can lift domestic pro­
duction and income rather than retard them.
On the export side, we analyze data gathered by
the International Trade Administration for large met­
ropolitan areas. These data are reported with several
user cautions, the most important of which is that the
production locale of exported goods often remains
unknown or is misleading, with the reported geogra­
phy perhaps attributed to the place of final shipment
of goods by an intermediary or perhaps to an affiliate
of the manufacturer, rather than to its origin of produc­
tion. To offset the possible slant of these data toward
cities where exports are shipped abroad or otherwise
affiliated, we construct an alternative, hypothetical
measure of exports. This measure allocates U.S. ex­
ports by location of similar production activity; in
particular, it allocates exports associated with an in­
dividual industry in proportion to each MSA’s employ­
ment share of that same industry in the U.S. Such a
measure, imperfect in its own way, is slanted toward
production origin of the good rather than toward the
place of shipment. Both measures indicate a wide
range of openness across individual metropolitan areas.
In comparing the two measures of exports, we find
significant and systematic differences, suggesting that
each measure may reflect a different dimension of
metropolitan area exports—both point of production
and point of shipment overseas. As evidence, we find
that metropolitan areas with large transportation sec­
tors tend to have higher rankings in the ITA’s reported
MSA export series. The presence of large manufac­
turing company headquarters, however, does not ap­
pear to slant reported ITA export figures in any
systematic way.
Given that our import measures are constructs
rather than observed data, we would like to test whether
these measures lend themselves to a plausible inter­
pretation. We examine the cross-sectional growth
behavior of metropolitan areas’ net job creation in
manufacturing from 1989 to 1999. Using a single-equa­
tion ordinary least square (OLS) regression, we regress
the growth rate of manufacturing jobs on the growth
rates of exports, import market growth, and export
and import penetration specific to each U.S. metro­
politan area. In this exercise, we find statistically sig­
nificant regression coefficients that are plausible. That
is, trends toward import penetration of an area’s local
industries are associated with short-term manufactur­
ing job disruption (declines) in a metropolitan area;
export growth is associated with manufacturing gain.

14

Yet this simple modeling exercise does not allow firm
inferences about causality. For example, increased
metro area imports could be a response to a negative
technology shock affecting a specific industry in the
home country that faces import competition.
In the next section, we begin by looking at some
previous studies of imports into the U.S. and then de­
scribe our measures of import sensitivity. In the fol­
lowing section, we focus on exports.

Imports
Previous attempts at attributing U.S. imports to
regions have been made at broad geographic levels.
In their work on the potential impact of the North
American Trade Agreement (Nafta), Hayward and
Erickson (1995) allocate manufactured imports from
Canada and Mexico by individual industry in propor­
tion to each state’s share of domestic shipments by
that industry. They find much variation among states,
and highlight the fact that these trade flows are smaller
than most people believe. Hervey and Strauss (1998)
allocate manufactured imports for an industrial ag­
gregation at the even-broader “durable” and “nondu­
rable” industry categories, though in the process, they
are able to identify imports as coming from 44 indi­
vidual foreign countries. They attribute high overall
import shares to the manufacturing East South Cen­
tral and East North Central regions. These high im­
port shares are ambiguous in that they might represent
either imports into a region or that region’s competi­
tion for markets served in the remainder of the U.S.
In this section, we improve on these import allo­
cations in two respects. First, we use a much narrow­
er industry breakdown to allocate finely defined U.S.
imported goods to particular metropolitan areas. Us­
ing employment data for U.S. counties from the County
Business Patterns (CBP) data, we can identify four­
digit Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) based
industry definitions for manufactured products.2 This
use of narrow industry definition means, for exam­
ple, that automotive production (and attendant import
competition) need no longer be erroneously attribut­
ed to the state of Washington; domestic aircraft pro­
duction need not be erroneously attributed to Detroit.
A second refinement is that imports can be attrib­
uted to metropolitan areas rather than to states and
multi-state regions. Metropolitan area economies are
more cohesive than state or multi-state economies, in
that they share a common work force and transporta­
tion infrastructure. In addition, metropolitan areas
are not so arbitrarily defined by jurisdictional bound­
aries, as are state economies, for example.3

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

Import trends
Manufactured imports into the U.S. grew rapidly
for most of the 1990s. This is not surprising, given
that import growth is strongly influenced by the over­
all growth of the home country’s economy. From 1991,
the trough of the previous economic downturn, to 2000,
the peak of the expansion, total U.S. imports increased
by $722 billion in nominal dollars, and by $616 bil­
lion (or 109 percent) as deflated by the general price
index for U.S. gross domestic product (GDP) (figure
1). Indeed, import expansion outpaced the more gen­
eral and robust expansion of the 1990s. As measured
against the yardstick of (nominal) GDP, (nominal)
imports climbed from an 8.1 percent ratio to GDP in
1991 to over 12 percent in 2000 (figure 2).
Import competition
How did the run-up in imports play out across met­
ropolitan areas? In order to link national import growth
to the industries of a particular metropolitan area, we
examine the industry-by-industry growth of foreign
imports in the U.S. market. Therefore, we allocate
actual U.S. imports by industry category to individual
metropolitan areas according to the metropolitan
presence of that same industry. In particular, we use
employment data by industry at the county level of
geography to construct a local employment share of
each national industry for each of 269 metropolitan
areas in the United States for 1989 and 1999.4 Each
MSA’s employment share of the nation for a particular
industry then becomes the metro area’s share of nation­
al imports for that industry. For each metropolitan

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

area, the sum total of these imports across all industries
is taken as the measure of its total import competition.
Thus, import competition in MSA z = Sum over
j M'ls, where M^s = I? xMj andMSA z’s
share of U.S. employment for good j. M1 = U.S. im­
ports of good j.
In examining the 25 most populous metropolitan
areas in 1999, the allocated import pattern reveals an
approximate but imperfect correspondence with the
size of metropolitan population in 1999 (table l).5
Places with heavy manufacturing concentrations and
large economies—such as Southern California—have
an outsized measured share of estimated imports at­
tendant to the region’s industrial structure. However,
there is much variation in these import allocations
owing to varying industry (import) composition. As a
yardstick, we can compare allocated imports against
the size of each metropolitan economy. In order to do
this, we construct estimates of gross metropolitan
product (GMP) for each metropolitan area and report
imports as a share of GMP.6 For 1999, we find an es­
timated average ratio of imports to gross product of
9.48 percent for the 25 most populous metropolitan
areas. The Detroit-Ann Arbor area is a leader in this
measure with 19 percent. Heavy U.S. imports of au­
tomotive products—many of them from nearby
Canada—coupled with Detroit’s sharp concentration
in automotive industries, lie behind the reported im­
port competition. Manufacturing and technology-inten­
sive San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose and PortlandSalem follow behind at 14 percent and 17 percent,
respectively. At the other end of the spectrum, the

15

TABLE 1

Manufacturing imports as percent of GMP (1999)
Rank by
imports

MSA (by 1999 population)

Imports

% of
GMP

($ biIIio ns)

(Sbillions)

1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25

New York-Northern New Jersey-Long Island. NY-NJ-CT
Los Angeles-Riverside-Orange County. CA
Chicago-Gary-Kenosha. IL—IN—Wl
Washington-Baltimore. DC-MD-VA-WV
San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose. CA
Philadelphia-Wilmington-Atlantic City. PA-NJ-DE-MD
Boston-Worcester-Lawrence. MA-NH-ME-CT
Detroit-Ann Arbor-Flint. Ml
Dallas-Fort Worth. TX
Houston-Galveston-Brazoria. TX
Atlanta. GA
Miami-Fort Lauderdale. FL
Seattle-Tacoma-Bremerton. WA
Phoenix-Mesa. AZ
Cleveland-Akron. OH
Minneapolis-St. Paul. MN-WI
San Diego. CA
St. Louis. MO-IL
Denver-Boulder-Greeley. CO
Pittsburgh. PA
Tampa-St. Petersburg-Clearwater. FL
Portland-Salem. OR-WA
Cincinnati-Hamilton. OH-KY-IN
Kansas City. MO-KS
Sacramento-Yolo. CA

2
1
6
31
3
9
5
4
8
7
17
40
11
16
18
14
22
24
19
23
46
10
28
34
64

43.3
51.8
27.9
6.1
43.1
16.6
28.5
33.7
17.0
18.1
8.4
4.7
10.3
8.9
8.2
9.0
7.8
7.8
8.1
7.8
3.5
11.0
6.7
5.6
2.2

GMP

5.4
11.2
8.8
2.1
14.0
8.6
12.5
19.0
9.1
11.0
5.8
5.0
7.8
10.2
9.6
8.3
9.4
10.1
8.5
11.7
6.0
17.0
11.5
9.9
4.4

797
464
316
289
308
193
229
177
186
164
145
93
132
87
86
108
83
77
96
67
59
65
58
57
51

Notes: MSA is metropolitan statistical area. GMP is gross metropolitan product.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Commerce, International Trade Administration, Trade Development,
Office of Trade and Economic Analysis: Haver Analytics: and U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Baltimore-Washington, DC area registers only 2 per­
cent on this metric.
Looking more widely at all metropolitan areas
taken as a group, the largest metropolitan areas aver­
age less direct import competition in manufacturing
than smaller areas (figure 3).7 In 1999, metropolitan
areas greater in population than 610,000 approached
10 percent in import competition versus almost 17
percent for metro areas ranging in size from 275,000
to 610,000. The import competition for smaller metro
areas differed little from this.
From 1989 to 1999, import intensity for all metro
areas grew significantly, along with the general expan­
sion of imports into the national economy. However,
the average differences between large and small metro
areas widened significantly, with the third quartile of
metro area—with 275,000-610,000 in population—
growing the most, from a ratio of 12 percent imports
to GMP in 1989 up to almost 17 percent by 1999.
Are large metropolitan areas, then, not “open”
economies compared with small metropolitan areas?

16

Large metropolitan areas have increasingly become
service economies and less hospitable to many types
of manufacturing. Congested highways and high land
costs in many large urban areas are not conducive to
today’s production processes in manufacturing. Nor
have the tendencies toward global competition made
it any easier for manufacturers in higher cost urban
locales. In response, many domestic manufacturing
facilities have sought out lower cost locales in small
cities and rural areas, often adjacent or with close
access to divided highways and the interstate high­
way system. There are countervailing forces at play,
however. A counter-tendency has been the surge in
technology and information intensity of the U.S.
economy—both manufacturing and services alike.
In this regard, urban areas are thought to have an
advantage because key inputs to high-tech produc­
tion—namely information and technology—may
be acquired more easily in urban areas. At the same
time, high-tech manufacturing industries often fea­
ture young firms that require proximity to the wide

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

array of specialized business, legal, and financial
services that are to be found in large cities.8
The high service intensity that is attendant to
manufacturing may also mean that data based on
manufacturing location alone may belie the actual
openness of the largest urban area economies. Em­
bodied in the value of manufactured goods is an in­
creasing service component—be it advertising, design,
maintenance, management, marketing, or research
and development. The service economy of a large city
in America is in this way an unseen portion of inter­
national trade in goods. Such considerations are ca­
veats to the traded good measures that we construct,
and these caveats are inherent in almost all data on
traded goods and their location of value added. More
generally, globalization also means that the geography
of production is stretched and expanded across wider
and wider landscapes, making it more difficult to de­
termine any meaningful and specific location of value
added of exports.
Importpenetration
An alternative way to measure imports into the
U.S. domestic market more directly reflects “compe­
tition” to U.S. producers. Import penetration measures
the ratio of imports for a particular industry to the sum
of imports plus that portion of domestic production
that is not exported abroad. Varying between zero and
one, this measure of import penetration shows the share
of domestic sales of a good that is imported rather

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

than domestically produced. We measure an MSA’s
import penetration as a weighted average of national
import penetration for each industry. For each metro­
politan area, the weights are its own industry em­
ployment shares across all of manufacturing.
Import penetration in MSAi = Sum over all
industries j MP', where MP' = L'1 x MPj and L'] =
MSAi’s share of its own manufacturing employment
employed in industry j. MPj = U.S. import penetra­
tion of good.9
Import penetration at the national level is often
used to indicate the degree to which domestic sales
in an industry have been penetrated or accounted for
by imports.10 For a particular region, we assume that
an industry domiciled there tends to sell much of its
output across the national domestic market. This as­
sumption is somewhat realistic for U.S. metropolitan
area economies because the U.S. market remains the
primary market for domestic production plants. Ex­
ports as a share of U.S. gross domestic production re­
main below 8 percent overall. Meanwhile, domestic
manufacturing plants sold between 64 percent and 82
percent of production domestically in the year 2000.11
We report import penetration estimates for the
25 most populous MSAs for 1999 (table 2). We see
a wide range, from an import penetration of 11.7 per­
cent for the Kansas City MSA, to upwards of 24 per­
cent for San Diego. A pattern emerges that seems to
suggest that high import penetration alone may not
be indicative of local area industrial stagnation. For
example, many MSAs known for a concentration in
high technology also have high import penetration.
These include Boston, the San Francisco Bay area,
San Diego, Portland, and Phoenix. Translating metro
area import penetration rates to the more familiar
state level, we can map the geography of import com­
petition for the entire country (figure 4 on p. 19).12
One can see that in 1999 most of the states east of
the Mississippi River (bold line on map) experienced
import competition on par or above the U.S. average
(16 percent). Somewhat surprisingly, eight states west
of the Mississippi generally not associated with man­
ufacturing report above-average levels of import
competition as well.
Increases in import penetration over time may
be more reflective of industrial competition. Here,
the variation in growth of import penetration is again
very wide (see table 2). Metro areas such as Miami
and Kansas City registered under 30 percent growth
in penetration from 1989 to 1999; metro areas as di­
verse as Seattle and Pittsburgh more than doubled
their import penetration over the same period.

17

TABLE 2

Import penetration, 25 largest metro areas
Import penetration (percent)
MSA (by population)

1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25

New York-Northern New Jersey-Long Island. NY-NJ-CT
Los Angeles-Riverside-Orange County. CA
Chicago-Gary-Kenosha. IL—IN—Wl
Washington-Baltimore. DC-MD-VA-WV
San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose. CA
Philadelphia-Wilmington-Atlantic City. PA-NJ-DE-MD
Boston -Worcester-Lawrence. MA-N H -M E-CT
Detroit-Ann Arbor-Flint. Ml
Dallas-Fort Worth. TX
Houston-Galveston-Brazoria. TX
Atlanta. GA
Miami-Fort Lauderdale. FL
Seattle-Tacoma-Bremerton. WA
Phoenix-Mesa. AZ
Cleveland-Akron. OH
Minneapolis-St. Paul. MN-WI
San Diego. CA
St. Louis. MO-IL
Denver-Boulder-Greeley. CO*
Pittsburgh. PA
Tampa-St. Petersburg-Clearwater. FL
Portland-Salem. OR-WA
Cincinnati-Hamilton. OH-KY-IN
Kansas City. MO-KS
Sacramento-Yolo. CA

1989

1999

% change
1989-!

10.4
11.1
9.6
8.2
16.7
9.3
14.6
11.3
10.4
8.8
8.4
13.2
7.9
14.7
8.8
9.1
16.8
9.6
13.2
8.7
9.5
13.2
10.0
9.2
7.9

17.8
17.7
15.5
12.4
23.7
16.5
21.7
16.3
16.1
13.9
12.6
16.7
16.7
19.3
13.8
14.1
24.1
12.9
17.3
17.8
16.2
21.7
16.9
11.7
12.8

70
60
62
51
42
77
49
45
55
58
50
26
112
32
56
55
43
35
31
104
70
64
68
28
62

Notes: MSA is metropolitan statistical area. GMP is gross metropolitan product.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Commerce, International Trade Administration Trade Development,
Office of Trade and Economic Analysis; National Bureau of Economic Research: and U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census,
Center for Economic Studies, Annual Survey of Manufactures.

Exports
The flip side of import penetration has been the
rapid export expansion of U.S. manufacturing. Both
economic growth in overseas markets and lower tariff
barriers to trade have helped to expand U.S. exports.
Until the currency crises beginning in 1997, rapidly de­
veloping countries in Asia such as Thailand, Malaysia,
Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan led the world in rates
of economic growth. Though growth was export-led
there, imports of manufacturing goods from developed
countries—especially capital goods—grew as well,
largely to meet the development needs of manufac­
turing industries in these nations. The manufacturing
sectors of the industrial economies, including the U.S.,
grew rapidly to meet the demands of both the devel­
oping economies and a general worldwide expansion.
The nominal value of manufactured exports attrib­
uted to U.S. metropolitan areas was $567 billion for
the last reported year, 1999, up from $374 billion in
the first reported year, 1993 (see figure 5). Exports

is

began to level off in 1997, coincident with the Asian
economic crisis. As measured against the gross do­
mestic product of metropolitan areas, exports de­
clined from a peak of 8.8 percent in 1997 to 7.9
percent by 1999 (see figure 6).
For individual metropolitan areas, export data
are telling but not straightforward to interpret. The only
publicly reported export figures for MSAs are drawn
from information of the U.S. Census Bureau, compiled
and reported by the International Trade Administra­
tion. In particular, exports are reported by businesses
in “export declarations,” which identify location us­
ing five-digit zip codes. Yet the exporter of record is
not necessarily the entity that produced the merchan­
dise, so the data do not fully reflect the production
origin of manufactured goods. Instead, the exporter
of record is the party “principally responsible for ef­
fecting export from the United States.”13 This means
that if the exporter of record is a manufacturing com­
pany, the location may either be the production plant

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

FIGURE 4

Import penetration 1999: Metro areas by state

Average import penetration

□ 0.180 to 0.279 (16)
□ 0.146 to 0.180 (17)
□ 0.060 to 0.146 (18)

or an administrative establishment of the company,
such as a corporate headquarters. Similarly, exporters
of record can be service companies, typically whole­
salers, but also other intermediaries, such as retail­
ers.14 This means that the wholesaler, headquarters,
or marketing arm of manufacturing—to which the

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

export may be attributed by the data—actually tends
to be responsible for some significant value added.15
Yet, the location of export production often tends to
be coincident, with wholesalers of a manufacturing
product likely to locate in the same region as the pro­
ducer. The larger metropolitan areas are likely to

19

more accurately represent the location of value-added
exports because larger areas are more likely to con­
tain all parties in the transaction—all contributors to
value added of the exported good.
Accordingly, we aggregate to the largest possible
MSA geographic definition, the so-called consolidated
metropolitan statistical area or CMSA. In this way,
we minimize the errors inherent in geographical as­
signment versus site of production. In addition, in re­
porting on individual metropolitan areas, we focus
on the largest MSAs. Wherever possible, we exclude
commodities, such as coal and minerals, from our mea­
sures of manufacturing exports. Commodities are more
likely to be produced outside metropolitan areas, but
to be shipped abroad from them.16
Export levels tend to correlate with size of the met­
ropolitan area. As a result, a “mega-sized” NY-Long
Island-Northern New Jersey consolidated metropoli­
tan area yields very large reported manufactured ex­
ports, leading with $46.6 billion in 1999 (table 3).

As we might expect from their large size and manu­
facturing orientation, the greater Chicago and Los
Angeles areas round out the top three in value of ex­
ports. However, the correspondence between size of
economy and level of exports is highly variable across
the top 25 largest metropolitan areas. The ratio of ex­
ports to gross metropolitan product averaged 8.7 per­
cent in 1999, but the standard deviation was a sizable
5.2. At the low end, service industry and domestical­
ly oriented regional areas such as the WashingtonBaltimore-Northern VA area reported a low 3.2 percent
of regional product. At the top of the spectrum, shipping-oriented and aerospace-intensive Seattle reported
a ratio of 25 percent. High-tech San FranciscoOakland-San Jose (at 14.8 percent) aligns with our
high prior expectations for that economy. Auto-inten­
sive Detroit-Ann Arbor’s ratio (at 17.2 percent) may
be surprising to some, since the automotive sector is
not always known as a U.S. export industry. However,
the Detroit auto corridor to Ontario ranks among the

TABLE 3

Metro area export intensity, 1999

MSA (by population)

Exports

% of
GMP

($ biIIio ns)

1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25

New York-Northern New Jersey-Long Island. NY-NJ-CT
Los Angeles-Riverside-Orange County. CA
Chicago-Gary-Kenosha. IL-IN-WI
Washington-Baltimore. DC-MD-VA-WV
San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose. CA
Philadelphia-Wilmington-Atlantic City. PA-NJ-DE-MD
Boston-Worcester-Lawrence. MA-NH-ME-CT
Detroit-Ann Arbor-Flint. Ml
Dallas-Fort Worth. TX
Houston-Galveston-Brazoria. TX
Atlanta. GA
Miami-Fort Lauderdale. FL
Seattle-Tacoma-Bremerton. WA
Phoenix-Mesa. AZ
Cleveland-Akron. OH
Minneapolis-St. Paul. MN-WI
San Diego. CA
St. Louis. MO-IL
Denver-Boulder-Greeley. C0a
Pittsburgh. PA
Tampa-St. Petersburg-Clearwater. FLa
Portland-Salem. OR-WA
Cincinnati-Hamilton. OH-KY-IN
Kansas City. MO-KS
Sacramento-Yolo. CAa

46.6
34.7
21.5
9.4
45.6
14.2
15.5
30.5
11.8
19.3
7.2
13.9
33.0
7.3
7.4
8.4
8.7
4.4
2.6
3.6
2.4
7.9
6.6
1.6
2.6

GMP
($ biIIio ns)

5.8
7.5
6.8
3.2
14.8
7.4
6.8
17.2
6.4
11.8
4.9
15.0
25.0
8.5
8.6
7.8
10.4
5.7
2.7
5.4
4.1
12.1
11.4
2.9
5.1

797
464
316
289
308
193
229
177
186
164
145
93
132
87
86
108
83
77
96
67
59
65
58
57
51

aExports include nonmanufactured commodity shipments
Notes: MSA is metropolitan statistical area. GMP is gross metropolitan product.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Commerce, International Trade Administration, Office of Trade
and Economic Analysis; U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Exporter Location Series; and U.S. Department
of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

20

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

most integrated binational economic relationships in
the world.17
Exports appear to have added to metro area growth
in the 1990s, assuming no displacement. For the 25
most populous regions reported in table 4, estimated
export growth added an average of 3.4 percent to the
size of metropolitan economies from 1993 to 1999.
In comparison, import growth (also measured against
GMP) for the same period and sample averaged 8.4
percent. The Asian crisis falloff post-1997 in U.S. ex­
ports accounts for some of this difference; U.S. exports
flattened out, even while domestic demand (and im­
port purchases) continued to grow robustly.
Export-led growth contributed more to large met­
ropolitan area economies than to smaller ones. Over
the 1993-99 period, exports contributed an average
of over 3 percentage points to growth in metropolitan
areas with over 500,000 in population, versus just

over 1 percent in the smallest population size category,
250,000 and less.
Can we generalize about export orientation by size
of metro area economy? Figure 7 confirms that larger
metropolitan areas are more export oriented. The top
quartile, with population of 900,000 and above, report
a weighted average of over 8 percent exports in 1999.
In contrast, smaller metropolitan areas report smaller
average export intensities for 1999, with an average
of 6.95 percent for the second largest quartile, 6.36
for the third, and 6.74 for the fourth and smallest quar­
tile. Still, these data suggest that smaller metropolitan
areas do fully participate in export trade. In this re­
gard, it is noteworthy that export intensity increased
across all MSA size classes from 1993 to 1999.
A different explanation for the high degree of ex­
port intensity in the San Francisco Bay area is that re­
ported exports may overstate actual exports along

TABLE 4

Prospective export intensity

MSA (by population)

1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25

New York-Northern New Jersey-Long Island. NY-NJ-CT
Los Angeles-Riverside-Orange County. CA
Chicago-Gary-Kenosha. IL-IN-WI
Washington-Baltimore. DC-MD-VA-WV
San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose. CA
Philadelphia-Wilmington-Atlantic City. PA-NJ-DE-MD
Boston-Worcester-Lawrence. MA-NH-ME-CT
Detroit-Ann Arbor-Flint. Ml
Dallas-Fort Worth. TX
Houston-Galveston-Brazoria. TX
Atlanta. GA
Miami-Fort Lauderdale. FL
Seattle-Tacoma-Bremerton. WA
Phoenix-Mesa. AZ
Cleveland-Akron. OH
Minneapolis-St. Paul. MN-WI
San Diego. CA
St. Louis. MO-IL
Denver-Boulder-Greeley. CO
Pittsburgh. PA
Tampa-St. Petersburg-Clearwater. FL
Portland-Salem. OR-WA
Cincinnati-Hamilton. OH-KY-IN
Kansas City. MO-KS
Sacramento-Yolo. CA

GMP
1993

Exports
1993

Exports
1999

Growth8

($ biIIio ns)

($ billions)”

($ biIIions)”

(GMP 1993)

561
343
221
206
190
143
152
128
112
104
86
67
82
48
65
72
56
57
57
51
38
42
40
39
33

43.5
25.6
13.8
8.5
29.8
9.3
10.0
19.7
6.2
12.8
3.6
9.0
24.0
4.3
4.7
6.2
4.3
3.0
1.3
2.6
1.3
3.6
3.8
1.1
1.2

41.8
31.1
19.3
8.4
41.0
12.8
14.0
27.4
10.6
17.3
6.5
12.5
29.7
6.6
6.6
7.5
7.8
3.9
2.3
3.2
2.2
7.1
6.0
1.5
2.3

-0.3
1.6
2.5
0.0
5.9
2.4
2.6
6.0
4.0
4.4
3.3
5.1
7.0
4.8
2.9
1.9
6.4
1.6
1.7
1.2
2.3
8.2
5.4
0.9
3.3

"Real growth in 1993-99 exports as a percent of 1993 GMP.
bDeflated to 1993.
Notes: MSA is metropolitan statistical area. GMP is gross metropolitan product.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Commerce, International Trade Administration, Office of Trade and
Economic Analysis: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Exporter Location Series; and U.S. Department of Commerce,
Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

21

some dimensions. In particular, seaports such as
Portland and San Francisco may have more exports
attributed to them in the reported data than they would
under an alternative method that reflected the origin
of production. To explore the possible bias in the re­
ported export data further, we construct a second, hy­
pothetical set of export figures (see table 5). We allocate
(impute) to metropolitan areas national-level U.S. De­
partment of Commerce, ITA data on exports. Export
data at the national level are available for detailed indus­
try classifications. We apportion these exports to partic­
ular metropolitan areas according, again, to the area’s
national share of employment in the corresponding

industry. We then develop an overall measure of ex­
ports from each metropolitan area by summing across
all industries. In this measure, since we are apportion­
ing exports directly by the location of production, the
export total will tend to reflect “origin of movement.”
Thus, this measure will have the opposite bias to the
reported exports, which may reflect point of shipment
or arrangement to ship. Note that there will be errors
in assigning the exports in the new measure due to
the fact that not all industries in locales actually have
the same propensity to export. In addition, our mea­
sure assumes that labor intensity is uniform geographi­
cally within each industry.
Looking individually at the most populous metro­
politan areas, we see a general tendency for the reported

22

exports to exceed the estimated and hypothetical mea­
sures, though this is not the case for nine of the metro
regions. More startling is the extent to which the re­
ported metro area figures exceed the production-ori­
ented estimates that are imputed from ITA data in a
number of metro areas with significant international
ports or trans-shipment industries: In New York, the
reported data exceed the imputed estimate by $22.2
billion (91 percent); in the San Francisco Bay metro
area by $18.7 billion (69 percent); in Seattle-Tacoma
by $18.5 billion (128 percent); in Miami by $11.6
billion (207 percent); in Houston by $8.1 billion (72
percent); and in Detroit by $15.8 billion (108 percent).
On the other hand, interior cities such as Denver,
Dallas, and St. Louis display a hypothetical export
base, according to the production method of alloca­
tion, that is greater than the reported export figures
for these cities.
To explain the variance between these data series,
we ran an OLS regression with the metropolitan ex­
port estimates reported by the ITA as the dependent
variable (see table 6 on p. 24). We used the sample of
all 208 metropolitan areas for which data were report­
ed for 1998 and 1999. We included an independent
variable for each observed metropolitan area, “percent
of its employment in transportation industries,” to test
for the effect of shipment rather than production lo­
cation on manufacturing exports. Even after account­
ing for the estimated exports based on the location of
manufacturing, the transportation variable is positive
and significant at the 1 percent level.
Another source of bias in the reported metro ex­
port series is suspected to arise from the separate loca­
tion of a manufacturer’s corporate headquarters from
its production plants. In particular, exports may tend
to be attributed to the location of the headquarters rather
than to the location of the production plant. Large com­
panies in particular have a very high propensity to ex­
port, and they also tend to have separate headquarters
locations. Accordingly, the presence of a single or mul­
tiple large company headquarters in an MSA might
tend to inflate the reported export figures compared
with our estimated (imputed) export figure, the latter
being based on the production employment location
of industries. When we account for large headquarters
in our regression equation, we find no apparent system­
atic relationship between headquarters location and
the levels of reported exports. Of course, there may be
significant individual instances in which large-scale ex­
ports are attributed to company headquarters, and thereby
serve to inflate the reported exports of particular MSAs.

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

TABLE 5

Export sensitivity test: ITA export data versus estimates
MSA (by population)

1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25

New York-Northern New Jersey-Long Island. NY-NJ-CT
Los Angeles-Riverside-Orange County. CA
Chicago-Gary-Kenosha. IL-IN-WI
Washington-Baltimore. DC-MD-VA-WV
San Francisco-Oakland-San Jose. CA
Philadelphia-Wilmington-Atlantic City. PA-NJ-DE-MD
Boston-Worcester-Lawrence. MA-NH-ME-CT
Detroit-Ann Arbor-Flint. Ml
Dallas-Fort Worth. TX
Houston-Galveston-Brazoria. TX
Atlanta. GA
Miami-Fort Lauderdale. FL
Seattle-Tacoma-Bremerton. WA
Phoenix-Mesa. AZ
Cleveland-Akron. OH
Minneapolis-St. Paul. MN-WI
San Diego. CA
St. Louis. MO-IL
Denver-Boulder-Greeley. CO
Pittsburgh. PA
Tampa-St. Petersburg-Clearwater. FL
Portland-Salem. OR-WA
Cincinnati-Hamilton. OH-KY-IN
Kansas City. MO-KS
Sacramento-Yolo. CA

1999
ITA exports

1999
estimates

1999

1993

x,„
- X est.,
ITA

x,„
- X est.,
ITA

(Sbillions)

(Sbillions)

(billions)

(billions)

46.6
34.7
21.5
9.4
45.6
14.2
15.5
30.5
11.8
19.3
7.2
13.9
33.0
7.3
7.4
8.4
8.7
4.4
2.6
3.6
2.4
7.9
6.6
1.6
2.6

24.4
32.4
17.5
4.5
27.0
10.2
18.5
14.7
14.6
11.2
5.6
2.3
14.5
7.9
6.4
6.5
6.5
8.4
3.5
4.5
2.0
7.5
4.9
2.6
1.9

22.2
2.3
4.0
4.9
18.7
4.0
-3.0
15.8
-2.8
8.1
1.6
11.6
18.5
-0.6
1.0
1.9
2.2
-4.1
-0.9
-0.9
0.4
0.4
1.8
-1.0
0.7

23.6
4.2
2.2
5.2
15.6
1.7
-0.9
6.6
-1.7
4.0
-0.2
7.3
15.5
0.4
0.1
1.4
0.0
-3.0
-1.4
-0.3
-0.1
-0.3
0.7
-1.3
0.4

Notes: The two datasets overlap between 1993 and 1999. In the data reported by the International Trade Administration (ITA),
the non-manufactured commodity shipments have been subtracted in 43 metropolitan statistical areas (MSA).
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Commerce, International Trade Administration, Office of Trade
and Economic Analysis; U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Exporter Location Series; and U.S. Department of
Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Examining trade and growth
Are the measures of trade—exports, export com­
petition, import growth, and import penetration—mean­
ingful measures that affect the growth and composition
of metropolitan areas? One way to explore this ques­
tion is to examine the relationship between MSA eco­
nomic growth and these trade-related measurements
over time. To do that, we can relate the growth or de­
cline in MSA total manufacturing employment to chang­
es in these variables using multiple regression. We use
manufacturing employment as the growth indicator—
the dependent variable to be explained—owing to
general data availability of these figures at the MSA
level of geography over the 1989-99 period. In par­
ticular, because MSAs vary in size, we use the per­
cent change in total manufacturing employment as
the dependent variable for the 269 U.S. MSAs.
The general estimation strategy is to examine a
cross-sectional panel of the percentage change in

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

manufacturing employment—a variable of growth
relative to the size of each particular MSA over a tenyear period. The estimation is in “changes” or first
difference form. This functional form has the advan­
tage of differencing out variables which presumably
remain constant for individual MSAs over the period,
but which vary significantly in level across MSAs—
the so-called omitted variable problem. A possible
downside is that, in first differencing, any measure­
ment errors in the regression variables tend to be
magnified—leading to inefficient estimators or large
standard errors in the coefficients.
The explanatory variables are also measured in
percent changes, so that the coefficients can be read
as elasticities. In this, there are two exceptions. One is
that the MSA’s predominant broad geographic region
is entered as a fixed effect. This is intended to pick up
the broad inter-regional shifts of economic activity,
which have been taking place from Frost Belt regions
to Sun Belt and from the Northeast-Midwest to the

23

TABLE 6

OLS regression: ITA annual manufacturing exports by metro area (natural log)

Constant

1

2

3

-6.36**
(-40)

-3.41**
(-35)

-4.72**
(-46)

.075
(-072)

.067
(-07)

.071
(.069)

.66**
(-05)

46**
(-071)

49**

Year (1998=1. 0 otherwise)

Estimated exports (log)

Gross metro product (log)

1.21**
(.041)

(-06)

.73**
(.083)

Employment share, transportation (log)

11.40**
(2.00)

14.0**
(2.00)

14.14**
(1-95)

Employment share, manufacturing (log)

5.27**
(.049)

Number of large manufacturing HQs

-.002
(.005)

.003
(.005)

.001
(.005)

.80
N=416

.81
N=416

.82
N=416

Adjusted R-squared

2.64**
(-62)

** Denotes statistical significance at the 1 percent level. Standard error in parentheses.
Notes: OLS is ordinary least squares. HQs is headquarters. Regressions were also estimated substituting “all manufacturing headquarters”
for “large” with different results. The signs on independent variables, including transportation, remained the same. However, statistical
significance dropped. “Large headquarters” is defined as worldwide employment of 2,000 or more. The calculations in this table are based
upon Exports MSA = ^(estExports USA) + P2(GMP„J + V3(ShTrMSA) + PA(ShMfgMSA) + P5(HQ„M) + Pe(Year Dummy) +
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Commerce, International Trade Administration, Office of Trade and
Economic Analysis: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Exporter Location Series', U.S. Department of Commerce,
Bureau of Economic Analysis: and Compustat.

South and West. Population in particular has been
shifting in these directions, which would be especial­
ly reflective of regional shifts in nontraded manufac­
tured goods. A second exception is the “size of MSA
economy” variable. This measure reflects the fact that
production activity in general has been tending to de­
concentrate from large metropolitan areas. This trend
has been ongoing for 50 years or more as production
technology has been shifting from multi-story, railroaddependent, labor-intensive modes to low-slung, truck­
intensive, capital-intensive operations. We measure
each of the remaining variables as percent change and
define them identically to those discussed in the pre­
ceding sections.
In estimating this simple OLS regression, we find
statistically significant results that are plausible (ta­
ble 7). That is, both export and import growth are as­
sociated with manufacturing gains. That is consistent
with imports having grown faster in industries with a
strong expansion in domestic demand.18 In addition,
we find that import penetration is negatively related

24

to manufacturing employment (column 3). Thus, an
increase in the level of imports as a share of domestic
demand is associated with lower labor usage over time
across metro areas. Similarly, we find a negative relation­
ship between a change in export intensity and manufac­
turing employment. A possible interpretation is that U.S.
industries may need to become more efficient in order
to compete in and capture foreign markets. Yet, caution
is urged as this simple modeling exercise does not allow
for confident inferences about causality. For example,
increased metro area imports could be a response to a
negative technology shock affecting a specific indus­
try in the U.S. that faces import competition.

Conclusion
The process of globalization has moved ahead over
the past ten to 15 years, albeit in fits and starts. Some
have speculated that metropolitan economies are sure
to undergo restructuring and upheaval attendant to
globalization. Their industry structure and performance,
along with local wages and prices, are thought to be

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

TABLE 7

OLS regression: Dependent variable as percent change in manufacturing employment
by MSA, 1989-99
1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

Constant

-0.0562
(0.030)

-0.0504
(0.033)

-0.0003
(0.030)

-0.0154
(0.029)

-0.019
(0.027)

-0.014
(0.027)

-0.017
(0.029)

-0.062
(0.017)*

% Change exports

0.0873
(0.0144)*

0.0881
(0.0145)*

0.1311
(0.014)*

0.1131
(0.01382)*

0.186
(0.017)*

0.178
(0.018)*

0.179
(0.018)*

0.196
(0.018)*

% Change imports

0.0202
0.0212
(0.00948)* (0.00950)*

0.0492
(0.0097)*

0.021
(0.008)*

0.027
(0.01)*

0.028
(0.010)*

0.035
(0.010)*

-0.039
(0.034)

-0.038
(0.035)

-0.036
(0.035)

-0.218
(0.039)*

-0.217
(0.040)*

-0.266
(0.039)*

-0.015
(0.011)

-0.011
(0.012)

-0.0006
(0.00002)*

-0.0007
(0.00002)'

-0.1208
(0.0241)*

% Change import
penetration

-0.1773
(0.0256)*

% Change export
penetration

-0.250
(0.027)*
-0.0287
(0.0130)*

% Change productivity.
1987-97

Size of MSA
by GMP 1989

Regional fixed effect
Sample size
R-bar squared

-0.0009
(0.0003)*
Yes

269
0.350

-0.0007
(0.0003)*

Yes

269
0.367

-0.0009
(0.0003)*

-0.0009
(0.0003)*

-0.0006
(0.0003)*

-0.0006
(0.0002)*

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

No

269
0.397

269
0.451

269
0.510

269
0.510

269
0.517

269
0.473

* T-stat significant at 5 percent level.
Notes: Standard errors in parentheses. OLS is ordinary least squares. MSA is metropolitan statistical area. GMP is gross metropolitan product
The calculations in this table are based upon PchMfgErnpmsa = fi^pChExports msa) + $2(pChlmports msa) + $3(pChlmPenetration msa) +
$4(pChExportPenetration msa) + $5(pChProductivity) + $6(regional dummies) + v>MSA.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from U.S. Department of Commerce, International Trade Administration, Office of Trade and
Economic Analysis: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Exporter Location Series, Center for Economic Studies, and
Annual Survey of Manufactures; and U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis: National Bureau of Economic Research.

under pressure as global integration gives rise to greater
trade opportunities and challenges. Many such changes
will take place, regardless of direct outflows and in­
flows of tradable goods. Still, measures of exports
and import competition may be important indicators
to policymakers and others of the sources and direc­
tion of upheaval and change. Both exports and im­
ports of manufactured goods have generally expanded
for U.S. metropolitan areas over the past decade or
more—imports more than exports—with wide varia­
tion across metropolitan areas.
Heretofore, direct insights into trade-related re­
structuring for U.S. MSAs were sparse, because there
is little data reporting directly on international trade
at the metropolitan area level of geography. In con­
structing new estimates, and exploring the properties
of existing data, we have suggested that there is a
wide variation in the openness to trade in manufac­
tured goods among U.S. metropolitan areas, both in
direct exports from these areas and in measures of
import competition and penetration for their specific
industrial sectors.
Large metropolitan areas do not appear to be ex­
periencing as high a level of import competition for man­
ufactured goods as medium and smaller metropolitan

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

areas. However, this may reflect the more general ten­
dency of production activity to eschew large urban areas
in favor of less densely populated areas. In reality,
the increasing service intensity of large urban areas
may belie their actual trade intensity in the global trade
of manufactured goods. Services, many of them orig­
inating in large urban areas, are implicitly and increas­
ingly embodied in manufactured goods—imports,
exports, and domestically produced goods alike.
When it comes to exports, large metropolitan areas
tend to report high export intensity for manufactured
goods. Many large urban areas tend to ship or facilitate
shipment of exported goods, and they are according­
ly cited as the domicile of exports abroad. In one sense,
this is misleading in that the origin of production for
many of these exports is likely to be in smaller metro
areas or rural areas. However, in another sense, it is
appropriate to attribute value added to large metropolitan
areas because, as mentioned above, services embedded
in manufactured goods often originate in these areas.
These first explorations of trade-related data at
the metropolitan level remain suggestive and rudimen­
tary. There is much more that we don’t know. Trade
remains a single but important element contributing to
shifting roles and structure of metropolitan areas.

25

NOTES
•See Campa and Goldberg (1997), who identify changes in the use
of imported inputs for a set of manufacturing industries from the
U.S., Canada, the UK, and Japan. They find manufacturing indus­
tries in the U.S. to have experienced a very strong increase in the use
of imported inputs. The role of trade in imported inputs in the con­
text of our article will be left for future research. See also Hummels
et al. (2001), who show that the internationalization of the supply
chain, a phenomenon they refer to as vertical specialization, has ac­
counted for a large and increasing share of international trade over
the last several decades. They find that this increase in vertical spe­
cialization accounts for a sizable piece of the growth in world trade.

2County Business Patterns is published by the U.S. Department of
Commerce, Bureau of the Census, and contains information on em­
ployment, payroll, and number of establishments by industry for
every county in the U.S. For 1998 and 1999, the North American
Industrial Classification System (NAICS) replaced the Standard In­
dustrial Classification (SIC) system. This new classification maps
fairly well into the former SIC system for manufacturing indus­
tries. One exception is the auxiliary establishment employment of
manufacturing companies (for example, corporate headquarters),
which has been shifted to a separate NAICS category in “services.”
3For example, the Chicago Consolidated Metropolitan Statistical
area encompasses the primary metropolitan statistical areas of
Chicago, IL, Gary, IN, Kankakee, IL, and Kenosha, WI. Yet, it is
possible that the use of subregional entities, such as metropolitan
areas, does not sufficiently account for regional economic linkages.
Multi-state regions are often highly integrated in their trade be­
tween and among industries (see Hewings et al., 1998).
4The CBP industry data are available at a four-digit level based
on SIC for 1977-97 and a six-digit industry level based on
NAICS for 1998 and 1999. Undisclosed or “suppressed” CPB
data were estimated by the Center for Public Policy at Northern
Illinois University (see Gardocki and Baj, 1985).

The data on U.S. exports and imports by industry contain infor­
mation on the value of physical goods that have cleared through
customs. These were provided to us by the International Trade
Administration of the U.S. Department of Commerce. Exports are
limited to domestic exports and are valued “free alongside ship,”
while imports are restricted to goods imported for consumption
(not for re-export) and are on a customs value basis.
The ITA data, which we use in our analysis, are classified accord­
ing to four-digit SIC and six-digit NAICS codes, yet, in their
original form, they do not strictly conform to the SIC and NAICS
industry definitions. The trade and economic analysts at the ITA
mapped original trade data categories from the Bureau of the
Census’ Foreign Trade (exports and imports) into industry classi­
fication codes (NAICS and SIC). They did so based on their
knowledge of and familiarity with industry products in interna­
tional trade into and out of the U.S. Between 2 percent and 3 per­
cent of imports could not be reliably assigned, or were assigned
to miscellaneous categories. These are dropped from our analysis.
5We construct these measures for 269 metropolitan areas of the
U.S. The employment data at the fine level of industry detail are
thought to be much more accurate for large metropolitan areas.
In such places, the county-level employment by industry is likely
to be less subject to errors of imputation. There, employment data
will be reported directly rather than imputed due to “disclosure”
problems of a thin presence in the number of establishments in
any particular industry.

26

6We construct our own estimates of gross regional product. To do so,
we allocate nonagricultural gross product for the U.S. to each metro­
politan area in proportion to its share of nonfarm personal income.
’Metropolitan area figures here are constructed as if the regions were
a single region, rather than taking an arithmetic mean with each metro­
politan area as an observation. (Either way, the results differ little.)

8See Ono (2001).

9Import penetration is defined for an industry by the ratio of im­
ports to domestic market sales.
10Yet this is not a wholly accurate accounting of the local impact of
overseas activity. An unmeasured change in competition or displace­
ment may take place in foreign markets that are now contested be­
tween U.S.-domiciled production plants and overseas producers.

11 The estimated range is derived by taking the value of exports of
manufactured goods to total production in the manufactured sec­
tor. The larger estimate measures production by “value added in
manufacturing.” The lower figure uses “value of shipments” in
manufacturing as the base. Since “export” value includes value
added from nonmanufacturing industries, value of shipments may
be an appropriate basis of comparison. However, shipments also
include re-shipments, some of which may be exported. Hence,
there may be a double counting in the U.S. of shipments data,
making value added another, perhaps preferable candidate.

12A state’s value on the map represents the average of its MSAs’
import penetration rates. The MSAs encompassing multiple states
and component primary MSAs (PMSAs) are allocated to the state
that includes the PMSA.
13See U.S. Department of Commerce (1999).

14As with other data, there are also flaws in reporting. In this
case, the principle problems are that approximately 7 percent of
exports do not report a location; and another 3 percent are not al­
locable to particular metropolitan areas using a zip code basis
(the “crossover” or overlap problem). The data are f.a.s. (free
alongside ship) basis and include re-exports.
15See Dow Jones and Company (2003), which reports that, of the
17 million manufacturing jobs in the U.S., 52 percent are produc­
tion workers versus 68 percent ten years earlier. For regional per­
spectives, see Testa (1989). These articles document that the value
of manufacturing shipments, exports or domestic shipments, is in­
creasingly composed of both services produced by manufacturing
companies and services purchased by manufacturing companies
and “embedded” into the value of the final manufacturing shipment.

16In particular, for many of the largest MSAs, the reported data
break out “commodity” exports, such as agriculture and mining,
for metropolitan areas. In our tables listing exports by metropolitan
area, we have extracted commodity exports whenever possible.
17See Klier and Testa (2002).
18See Hine and Wright (1997), who also point out that import and
export growth rates tend to be strongly positively correlated.

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

REFERENCES
Campa, Jose, and Linda S. Goldberg, 1997, “The
evolving external orientation of manufacturing in­
dustries: Evidence from four countries” Economic
Policy Review, Vol. 3, July, pp. 53-81.

Hummels, David, Jun Ishii, and Kei-Mu Yi, 2001,
“The nature and growth of vertical specialization in
world trade,” Journal ofInternational Economics,
Vol. 54, pp. 75-96.

Dow Jones and Company, 2003, “Manufacturers
find themselves increasingly in the service sector,”
Wall Street Journal, February 10, p. A2.

Katies, Michelle M., and Bruce C. Petersen, 1994,
“The effect of rising import competition on market
power: A panel data study of U.S. manufacturing,”
Journal ofIndustrial Economics, Vol. 42, September,
pp. 277-286.

Gardocki, Jr., Bernard C., and John Baj, 1985,
“Methodology for estimating nondisclosure in coun­
ty business patterns,” Northern Illinois University,
Center for Governmental Studies, April, mimeo.
Hayward D. J., and R. A. Erickson, 1995, “The North
American trade of U.S. states: A comparative analy­
sis ofindustrial shipments, 1983-91”/niernnZ/onnZ
Regional Science Review, Vol. 18, No. l,pp. 1-31.

Hervey, Jack L., 1999, “A regional approach to mea­
sures of import activity” Chicago Fed Letter, Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, No. 147, November.

Klier, Thomas, and William Testa, 2002, “The Great
Lakes border and economy,” Chicago Fed Letter,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, No. 179a, July.

Ono, Yukako, 2001, “Outsourcing business services
and the role of central administrative offices,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, working paper, No. 2002-01.
Testa, William, 1989, “Manufacturing’s changeover
to services in the Great Lakes economy,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, Regional Economic Issues,
working paper, No. WP 21.

Hervey, J. L., and W. A. Strauss, 1998, “Foreign
growth, the dollar, and regional economies 1970-97,”
Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, Fourth Quarter, pp. 35-55.

U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the
Census, 1999, County Business Patterns, 1989-99,
Washington, DC.

Hewings, Geoffrey J. D., Graham R. Schindler,
and Philip R. Israilevich, 1998, “Interstate trade
among Midwest economies,” Chicago Fed Letter,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, No. 129, May.

U.S. Department of Commerce, International
Trade Administration, Trade Development, Office
of Trade and Economic Analysis, 2003, U.S.
Exports and Imports, Washington, DC, January.

Hine, Robert C., and Peter Wright, 1997, “Trade
and manufacturing employment in the United
Kingdom,” in International Trade and Labour
Markets, Jitendralal Borkakoti and Chris Milner
(eds.), New York: St. Martin’s Press, pp. 118-139.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

27

CALL FOR PAPERS

May 5-7, 2004
40th ANNUAL CONFERENCE ON BANK STRUCTURE AND COMPETITION
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO

How Do Banks Compete?
Strategy, Regulation, and Technology
The Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago invites the submission of research and policy-

oriented papers for the 40th annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition

to be held May 5-7, 2004, at the Fairmont Hotel in Chicago. Since its inception, the

conference has fostered an ongoing dialogue on current public policy issues affecting

the financial services industry. In addition to papers related to the conference theme,
we are interested in any high-quality research addressing public policy issues affect­

ing financial services and will have a number of sessions on topics unrelated to the
conference theme. We welcome submissions on all topics related to financial services
and regulation.

he theme of the 2004 conference will address

compete. The manner in which commercial banks currently

issues related to how banks compete. Over the

underwrite their loans, finance their activities, grow their

past two decades, commercial banks have aggres­

franchises, distribute their services, and market their images

sively repositioned themselves to compete under new

would be barely recognizable to a banker from the 1970s.

economic, technological, and regulatory conditions. No

longer protected by regulatory entry barriers, and con­

Banks still do not compete in a completely unregulated

fronted with sea change advances in telecommunications

environment, however, and regulations continue to shape

and computer technology, banks are no longer able to rely

banking strategies. For example, federally insured deposits

on traditional banking models. Instead, banks and other

are a cornerstone of the community bank business strategy.

financial institutions have invested huge amounts of

Community Reinvestment Act (CRA) loans are a require­

resources in the search for new competitive strategies.

ment for any bank that wishes to grow by acquisition.

While many of these attempts have been dead ends, the

Investment decisions—at least at the margin—are

most successful strategic innovations have set new standards

influenced by capital regulations. Our system of multiple

for the industry and have changed the way that banks

regulators and bank chartering agencies can affect the

organizational form that banking companies choose.

The 2004 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago's Conference

Terrorist threats and governance scandals have led regulators

on Bank Structure and Competition will explore these

to make increased informational demands on banks. As

issues. Additional financial topics that we are interested

banking markets grow more concentrated, anti-trust laws

in evaluating include:

may increasingly limit the scale and scope of bank mergers.
At a minimum, regulation is simply a fixed cost that must

be borne by banks but does not influence bank behavior.
At the other extreme, and perhaps more realistically,

regulation can significantly affect banks' strategic choices
and

influence

competition

in

financial

markets.

Innovations introduced in the marketplace are often driven
by—and in some cases succeed exclusively because of—

the existing regulatory environment.

■ The regulation and riskiness of government
sponsored enterprises (GSEs),

■ The Basel II Capital Accord,
■ Financial industry consolidation,

■ Payments innovations,
■ Credit access: fair lending, CRA, and
predatory lending issues,

■ Deposit insurance and safety-net reform,

■ Measuring, monitoring, and managing bank risk,
■ The viability and future role of community banks, and

Similarly, commercial banks' competitive strategies are

■ Restructuring of financial regulatory agencies.

shaped not only by new technologies, but also by the
limitations of technology. Retail banking franchises have

traditionally been built around paper-based payments,
but information and communications technologies have

created new strategic possibilities for retail banking.
Electronic delivery of financial services can reduce
banks' overhead costs, but abandoning bank branch

If you would like to present a paper at the conference,
please submit four copies of the completed paper or a
detailed abstract (the more complete the paper, the better)

with your name, address, affiliation, telephone number,
and e-mail address, and those of any co-authors, by

December 22, 2003. Correspondence should be addressed to:

offices can also give rise to disastrous strategic costs.
New financial technologies have transformed risk-

Conference on Bank Structure and Competition

management at commercial banks, but application of

Research Department

leading-edge techniques may create unforeseen new

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

risks. After generations of technological stasis in the

230 South LaSalle Street

banking industry, the rapid pace of technological change

Chicago, Illinois 60604-1413

has made "strategic innovation" a viable competitive

For additional information contact:

strategy for some banking companies. In this environment,

Douglas Evanoff at 312-322-5814 (devanoff@frbchi.org),

must all banks become strategic innovators in order to

Robert DeYoung at 312-322-5396 (robert.deyoung@frbchi.org),

survive, or can some banks remain competitive as

or Regina Langston at 312-322-5641 (rlangston@frbchi.org).

strategic followers?

Family resources and college enrollment

Bhashkar Mazumder

Introduction and summary
During the 1980s and early 1990s, the U.S. ex­
perienced a pronounced increase in income inequality.
Associated with the rise in inequality has been a wid­
ening gap in earnings between those who have a college
degree and those whose schooling ends in high school.
According to census data, in 1975 men who completed
four or more years of college earned 51 percent more
than men who had completed four years of high school.
The comparable figure in 2001 was 122 percent.1 So,
on average, college graduates now earn more than
double what high school graduates earn.
Why has attending college become so much more
important? Many economists argue that as the economy
has become more technologically sophisticated, em­
ployers simply require a more educated and skilled
work force. The rising demand for skilled workers has
outpaced the increase in supply, resulting in a sizable
premium for college-educated workers.
College attendance is an important issue for other
reasons in addition to the growth in income inequality.
Clearly, a more educated work force should enhance
the productive capacity of the economy and promote
faster economic growth (Aaronson and Sullivan, 2001).
There are also likely to be important social externali­
ties to promoting greater college attendance, such as
greater involvement in the duties and responsibilities of
citizenship (for example, higher voting rates). Finally,
greater access to college might help foster greater intergenerationcil income mobility, namely a child’s abili­
ty to achieve economic success irrespective of their
parents’ economic circumstances. Recent studies have
shown that on average, at least 40 percent, and perhaps
as much as 60 percent of the earnings differences be­
tween families persist from one generation to another
(Bowles and Gintis, 2002). Clearly, any policies that
might be successful at bridging the divide in educational
attainment and, thereby, reduce earnings differences

30

might also help reduce the persistence in income ine­
quality over generations.
For these reasons, policymakers are interested in
what determines college enrollment and completion
and how best to promote higher education. This is a
particularly salient issue now, given the current fiscal
problems facing the federal and state governments,
which have already led to cutbacks in financial sup­
port for higher education.
An analysis of national trends in college enroll­
ment shows that overall college enrollment among
young adults has risen steadily over the last 30 years.
However, only about 35 percent of 18-24 year olds
currently attend college. There is currently a major
divide in college attainment by race and ethnic group.
In fact, these gaps are higher today than they were 25
years ago. The sharp differences in college enrollment
rates suggests that perhaps the key factors underlying
these trends are economic variables such as family
income and college costs. Indeed, an examination
of enrollment levels by income level appears to bear
this out. Adolescents from families in the lowest in­
come strata are far less likely to attend college than
their better-off peers.
However, the idea that family income and tuition
costs largely explain enrollment patterns is not as clear
cut as it might appear at first glance. There are many
different types of colleges with a wide range of costs,
and there are many potential sources of financial aid
and loan programs. Indeed, it is not unreasonable to
speculate that anyone who truly wants to attend some
Bhashkar Mazumder is an economist in the Economic
Research Department and the executive director of the
Chicago Census Research Data Center at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago. The author thanks Siopo Pat,
Kate Anderson, and David Oppedahl for their research
assistance. He also thanks Dan Aaronson and Dan
Sullivan for helpful discussions and comments.

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

type of college can find a way to finance it. Traditional
economic theory suggests that in the absence of mar­
ket imperfections such as borrowing constraints, those
who find it optimal to invest in their human capital
through postsecondary schooling will in fact do so, ir­
respective of their family’s current income level. The
key determinants in this model are the expected finan­
cial returns to attending college, the interest rate, and
the costs of attending college.
The fact that existing government financial aid
and loan programs do not cover the full costs of going
to college suggests that the existence of borrowing
constraints is certainly plausible (Keane and Wolpin,
2001). Whether individuals actually do not enroll in
college because of the inability to borrow is a point
of contention in the economics literature. While many
studies have found that there is a strong association
between family income and college enrollment, Cameron
and Heckman (2001) argue that this is because family
income captures the long-run factors that determine
whether an individual has the prerequisite skills to be
successful in college. They argue that there is very
little role for policies such as college subsidies that
influence the short-term financing considerations of
attending college.
Various other studies (for example, Kane, 1994;
Dynarski, 2003) find either that college costs are an
important factor or that college subsidies have an im­
portant effect on enrollment. While a sensitivity to price
is not what economists would call “borrowing con­
straints,” it does imply a potential role for public pol­
icy in subsidizing college costs for those on the margin
of attending, particularly if there are important social
benefits to increasing college enrollments. In fact, there
is some common ground in this literature, in that all
of these studies find that an increase in college costs
of $1,000 in 2001 dollars is typically found to trans­
late into a decline in enrollment of about 4 percentage
points. On the other hand, it is not at all clear whether
lowering college costs would reduce the disparities
in enrollment across income or racial groups.
Interestingly, none of the studies in the literature
investigate the empirical importance of family wealth
as opposed to income to college attendance. The omis­
sion of wealth in the literature is no doubt due to the
fact that the survey data used by previous researchers
do not contain very good information, if any, on fam­
ilies’ assets and liabilities. This is an important omis­
sion since for many families, a sizable fraction of college
expenses are covered by longer-term savings reflected
in financial assets. Families with high levels of wealth
are much less likely to be borrowing constrained. One
might expect that families with more wealth are better

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

able to borrow against their assets. Therefore, data on
wealth would seem to be particularly useful for testing
the borrowing constraints hypothesis implied by the­
oretical models. In addition, financial assets are an im­
portant part of most financial aid formulas, so higher
wealth can potentially lead to higher college costs net
of this aid and possibly lower enrollment levels, all
else equal.
This article begins to address this gap in the lit­
erature by using a data source that has highly detailed
information on family assets and liabilities, as well
as information on the enrollment decisions of adoles­
cents. A preliminary empirical investigation of this
data offers some suggestive evidence that income
might be an especially important factor for families
who have modest amounts of wealth. This may be
due to some combination of borrowing constraints
and higher actual costs due to lower financial aid. Cer­
tainly, this evidence suggests that further investigation
of the role of wealth in college enrollment is in order.

Trends in college enrollment
In recent decades there has been a clear upward
trend in the percentage of high school graduates be­
tween the ages of 16 and 24 who enroll in college
within a year of finishing high school, according to
data assembled by the National Center for Educational
Statistics.2 As figure 1 demonstrates, from 1960 until
the 1980s, the percentage enrolled in college fluctu­
ated around 50 percent. Since 1980, however, the rate
has risen sharply from 49 percent to 62 percent in
2001, reaching a peak of 67 percent in 1997. The rise
has been slightly more pronounced among women,

31

FIGURE 2

FIGURE 3

College enrollment rates
by race

College enrollment, bottom quintile
vs. top four quintiles

Source: U.S. Department of Education, National Center for
Education Statistics (2003), Digest of Economic Statistics.

whose enrollment rate briefly eclipsed 70 percent in
the late 1990s.
These figures, however, paint an overly positive
picture of college attendance because they only show
the rates among those 16-24, who finished high school
within the last year. In contrast, the college enrollment
rate among all 18-24 year olds in 2001 was just 36
percent. While this is still a significant improvement
over the 25 percent rate recorded in 1979, despite re­
cent positive trends, college enrollment remains more
the exception than the rule.
The gap in enrollment rates between whites and
minorities has been a focal point of some recent studies
on college enrollment (for example, Kane, 1994;
Cameron and Heckman, 2001). Figure 2 shows the
enrollment rates among recent high school completers
aged 16 to 24 across racial/ethnic groups. (Three-year
moving averages are shown so as to reduce the large
sampling variance in the survey data.) The difference
in the enrollment rates between blacks and whites was
only a few percentage points in the late 1970s but
surged in the 1980s, reaching a peak of 19 percentage
points in the mid-1980s. This sharp rise spurred the
debate over the impact of economic factors, such as
rising college costs, declining financial aid, and slow
real income growth on college enrollments. This was
also a motivating factor for studies that used econometric
models to understand more broadly the determinants
of the propensity to attend college.
In the late 1980s and through most of the 1990s,
the black-white gap progressively narrowed, falling
back into the single digits. However, since 1998, black
enrollment rates have fallen in each year, and the racial

32

Source: U.S. Department of Education, National Center for
Education Statistics (2003), Digest of Economic Statistics.

gap has begun to widen once more. The enrollment
gap between whites and non-white Hispanics is actually
larger and has widened considerably since the 1970s.
An important question is to what extent these minor­
ity enrollment gaps are merely reflecting disparities
in enrollment by income level that can be addressed
by tuition subsidies targeted to low-income families.
Figure 3 compares the enrollment rate of the bottom
income quintile versus the top four quintiles using data
from the October Current Population Surveys (CPS)
conducted by the Census Bureau. This chart illustrates
that enrollment rates have risen even among families
at the bottom of the distribution, but that the gap in
enrollment with other families has narrowed only
slightly over the last 30 years. This evidence certain­
ly fits a story that emphasizes income differences as
a critical factor in college enrollments.
While the CPS surveys typically used by research­
ers to investigate enrollment patterns do not collect
information on wealth, they do collect information
on homeowner status. Since housing equity is often
the largest share of a family’s wealth, tracking enroll­
ment rates by family homeownership might offer a
glimpse as to the importance of wealth considerations.
Figure 4 shows that historically there has been a large
gap in enrollment rates by homeownership status but
that this gap has narrowed quite a bit in recent years.
These figures suggest that while progress has been
made in achieving higher rates of college enrollment
among young adults, the disparities by race and income
are wider today than they were 25 years ago. Looking
forward, the current fiscal problems facing many
state governments are expected to lead to large cuts

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

in college subsidies and tuition increases at public
colleges, which raises the prospect of a further widen­
ing of these gaps in higher education. However, these
predictions depend critically on the extent to which
short-term financial considerations actually influence
the propensity to attend college.

Evidence from a sample of econometric
studies
The literature on college financing is large and
cannot be given a thorough treatment here. I discuss
a small sample of recent studies to provide a general
sense of how economists have approached this ques­
tion and their results.
As with many research questions in economics,
it is risky to rely exclusively on data that are based on
changes over time in aggregate statistics in order to
identify behavioral patterns such as those shown in
the last section. Economies are constantly in flux, with
many variables changing simultaneously. For example,
the causal relationship between college costs and enroll­
ment rates may be difficult to discern from “time-se­
ries” data. In the 1980s, both variables were increasing,
but it is unlikely that an increase in tuition could lead
to an increase in enrollment. Aggregate enrollment was
probably also influenced by other economic incentives,
such as the rising payoff to attending college.
Therefore, economists have estimated econometric
models using micro-level data on individuals and their
enrollment decisions at a point in time to infer the
underlying behavioral relationships that are typically
obscured in the national data. These “cross-sectional”
studies have generally found that college costs and

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

family income have a statistically significant and
economically important effect on enrollment decisions.
In a review of a number of studies predating 1990,
Leslie and Brinkman (1989) argue that a consensus
view is that a $1,000 (2001 dollars) increase in net
college costs results in about a 4 percentage point
decline in the probability of enrollment.
A more recent study by Kane (1994), which ex­
amines the decline and subsequent rise in the black
college enrollment rate during the 1980s, uses data
from the October CPS and includes a wide range of
variables such as parental educational attainment, family
income, homeownership, and local labor market con­
ditions. Kane studies the effects of these variables sep­
arately for blacks and whites and by income quartiles.
He also controls for state “fixed effects,” thereby cor­
recting for the potential problem that states with low
tuition levels might support enrollment in other ways.
Kane concludes that college costs exerted downward
pressure on the enrollment rate for blacks in all income
groups. Kane speculates that the sensitivity of even highincome black families to college costs might be ex­
plained by the fact that despite their high income, these
families have little wealth and, therefore, might also be
constrained from borrowing. Given the lack of data on
wealth in Kane’s sample, he cannot pursue this further.
Overall, Kane finds that a $1,000 (2001 dollars)
change in tuition costs lowers the probability of en­
rollment by around 4 percentage points. However, he
finds that these costs explain only about one-third of
the drop in enrollment for blacks during the first half
of the 1980s and that most of the rest of the decline can­
not be explained by his model. One somewhat puzzling
finding is that Pell Grant eligibility appears to have a
negligible effect on college enrollment. Pell Grants
are a federal means-tested program that provides grants
to qualified students for postsecondary education. An
earlier study based on aggregate time-series data by
Hansen (1983) also showed little effect of the program
on enrollment levels. Kane speculates that his finding
may be due in part to measurement error, since Pell
Grant eligibility is estimated based on available survey
data. He also suggests that perhaps low-income students
are less aware of their eligibility for the program. None­
theless, the lack of any strong effect of Pell Grants on
enrollments is a reason to remain somewhat skeptical
about the effectiveness of tuition subsidies.
While cross-sectional studies such as Kane’s avoid
some of the pitfalls of time-series analysis, they are also
subject to other potential deficiencies such as omitted
variables and measurement error. The lack of a good
measure of scholastic preparedness for college is a
particular issue of concern. If the ability to succeed in

33

college is the key determinant of college enrollment
but there is no good measure of this “ability” in the
data (for example, test scores) and if family income
is highly correlated with ability, then a cross-section­
al analysis might mistakenly overemphasize the im­
portance of family income.
This problem and other similar issues have led
researchers to pursue alternative approaches to study­
ing the issue. Cameron and Heckman (2001) exploit
longitudinal data—repeated observations on the same
individuals—to estimate a dynamic model of educa­
tional attainment. Through this approach they not only
examine college enrollment but also analyze grade
transitions prior to college enrollment, where financial
considerations ought not to be as important. As part
of their statistical model, they also directly incorporate
heterogeneous ability. Perhaps most importantly, they
use the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY),
a comprehensive dataset that contains not only all of
the relevant variables typically used by researchers,
but also a measure of scholastic ability, the Armed
Forces Qualifying Test (AFQT).
The AFQT is part of the Armed Services Vocation­
al Aptitude Battery (ASVAB) given to applicants to
the U.S. military. The ASVAB consists of ten tests.
The AFQT score is based on four of the tests that fo­
cus on reading skills and numeracy. The AFQT is a
general measure of trainability in the military and is a
primary criterion for enlistment eligibility. The test was
administered to nearly all respondents in the NLSY
in 1980 in order to provide new norms for the test based
on a nationally representative sample. The AFQT is not
viewed by the military or by most researchers as a measure
of general intelligence or IQ. Indeed, it is well known
that scores rise with additional years of schooling, so
researchers typically use scores that are age-adjusted.
Cameron and Heckman’s sample does not include
anyone who took the test after entering college.
Cameron and Heckman estimate their dynamic
educational attainment model separately for whites,
blacks, and Hispanics and estimate the probabilities of
completing ninth grade by age 15; completing high
school by age 24; and enrolling in college. The model
is run both including and excluding AFQT scores. They
use the results of the models to perform the following
thought experiment: How much of the white-minority
gaps would be eliminated if for each explanatory vari­
able, blacks and Hispanics were assigned the same aver­
age values as whites. Using the model results without
AFQT scores, they find that equating family income
would reduce the expected gap in college enrollments
by roughly half. However, they also find that simply
equating other family background variables, such as

34

parent education and family size, has an even larger ef­
fect on reducing these gaps. When they include AFQT
scores, equating this variable alone more than eliminates
the entire enrollment gap for both blacks and Hispanics,
while income has virtually no independent effect.
Based on this result, they argue that college pre­
paredness is the critical determinant of college en­
rollment and not any kind of short-term borrowing
constraint. This conclusion is also bolstered by their
finding that family income has an important effect on
grade advancement only at earlier stages in a student’s
educational career (for example, reaching ninth grade
by age 15), when short-term financing issues are pre­
sumed to be irrelevant.
While these results appear to be very strong and
make a compelling case against the existence of bor­
rowing constraints, they are still not fully satisfying.
How is it that white and minority enrollment trends
could diverge so rapidly in the early 1980s only to be
followed by a period of rapid convergence later in the
decade as figure 2 shows? It is possible that there were
rapid and sudden shifts in minority college prepared­
ness. But there is no evidence of this in test scores.
So while the results appear to present repudiation of
the idea that family income during the college-going
years matters, the study does not provide a fully per­
suasive story to explain the trends in the data that
motivated the model.
With regard to the broader question of whether
public policy ought to subsidize college education,
these results actually could be considered to provide
some evidence in favor of such a policy. A common
criticism of broad-based college subsidies is that they
simply subsidize the costs of middle-class families,
whose children would have enrolled in college anyway.
Cameron and Heckman’s results show that college
enrollment is sensitive to tuition costs, so that lower­
ing the costs for targeted families might turn out to
be an effective policy. This is particularly true for twoyear colleges. The authors estimate that a $1,000 (2001
dollars) increase in tuition at two-year colleges lowers
black enrollments in two-year and four-year colleges
combined, by 4 percentage points. For Hispanics, the de­
cline is even larger, at 8 percentage points. Although
college enrollments are less sensitive to changes in
tuition at four-year colleges, the effect of a $1,000
(2001 dollars) increase in costs at both two- and
four-year colleges would lower white enrollment by
5 percent—a figure right in line with the results of
the previous studies. Finally, the study does not ad­
dress the possibility that wealth may be a critical
factor in determining the likelihood of enrollment,
which is the question I turn to in the next section.

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

Each of the studies so far described exploits the ob­
served variation in a number of variables (for example,
enrollment or family income) across a sample of the
population to infer the basic statistical relationships
under certain simplifying assumptions. This approach
can lead to misleading inferences about causality if
there are other factors that are not captured by the
statistical model. In an ideal setting researchers would
prefer to design an experiment where individuals could
be randomly assigned different levels of family income
or tuition costs. Differences in enrollment rates be­
tween the treatment and control groups would reveal
the behavioral responses. Randomization would elimi­
nate the need to have a full set of control variables.
Of course, in the real world, such experiments are close
to impossible. In recent years, however, economists
have increasingly employed research strategies that
take advantage of real world situations that mimic ran­
dom assignment. These “quasi-experiments” allow
researchers to infer behavioral relationships that might
otherwise be difficult to identify through standard
statistical models.
Dynarski (2003) provides one such example in a
study of the effects of a particular tuition subsidy on
college enrollment. In 1982, Congress eliminated the
Social Security student benefit program that offered
monthly financial support to full-time students whose
parents were deceased, disabled, or retired. Dynarski
uses the NLSY to implement a quasi-experimental
design that compares the college enrollments of those
who were eligible for the aid due to the death of a
parent before the program was eliminated with a later
cohort who would have been eligible for the program
had it not been eliminated. The enrollment probability
of those with a deceased parent fell by more than 20
percentage points compared with a drop of just 2 per­
centage points for the rest of the sample. Incorporat­
ing figures on the size of the program’s benefit and
the costs of tuition, Dynarski calculates that a $1,000
(2001 dollars) increase in aid increases enrollment by
nearly 4 percentage points.
While Dynarski’s results are in line with much of
the previous literature, the quasi-experimental design
of the study makes it more credible than those of stan­
dard cross-sectional studies. The quasi-experimental
design, however, still has some drawbacks. It is diffi­
cult to know if the behavioral response that is estimated
from the subgroup of the population affected by the leg­
islative change, generalizes to the broader population.
The findings of Cameron and Heckman and other
research not discussed here3 makes many economists
skeptical that borrowing constraints are a critical factor
in limiting college enrollments. Indeed in a more recent

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

paper, Carneiro and Heckman (2003) estimate that
only about 8 percent of the population faces borrowing
constraints to attending college. Still, there appears to
be reasonably strong evidence that public policy can
influence enrollment levels.
In any case, there are several issues that deserve
more attention in future research. The first, which I
address below, is examining the role of wealth. It might
be the case that, for example, the sharply lower wealth
levels of blacks has been a major impediment to col­
lege attendance. In fact, the economic literature on
consumption has often used levels of wealth to detect
the presence of borrowing constraints among lowwealth families (for example, Zeldes, 1989).
A second question, which has not been examined
thoroughly, is the extent to which financial resources
and costs affect college completion? Perhaps the access
to college financing is available, but over time finan­
cial difficulties overwhelm some families and prevent
college completion. Finally, to what extent do financial
resources affect the kind of school or quality of school
one attends? There is growing evidence that fewer lowincome students are attending private universities and
four-year colleges (McPherson and Schapiro, 1998).
Therefore, there is reason to believe that there is not
only a college enrollment gap but there are also likely
to be disparities in educational quality.

Wealth and college enrollment
This article begins to address one of the short­
comings in the literature by using a data source that
has been neglected in the existing literature. The Census
Bureau’s Survey ofIncome and Program Participation
(SIPP) contains extremely detailed data on assets and
liabilities in addition to the full set of variables that have
typically been used to study the determinants of college
enrollment. The SIPP surveys began in 1984 and are
two- to three-year panels that allow for multiple measure­
ments of all the variables of interest. The SIPP surveys
approximately 20,000 households every four months
on income, labor market activity, and participation in
a wide range of federal government programs, such
as food stamps and Social Security.
The surveys also ask about school enrollment and
sources of financial assistance. Special topical modules
once a year collect information on housing equity, vehi­
cle equity, business equity, a range of financial assets,
unsecured debt, real estate property, individual retire­
ment accounts (IRA), and other retirement plans. The
panel aspect of the data enables one to construct a sample
of 11th and 12th graders and determine college enroll­
ment over the next two years.

35

I estimate a linear probability model (ordinary
least squares—OLS) of the likelihood of enrollment.5
The dependent variable is equal to 1 if a 12th grader
begins college by the following school year and 0 other­
wise. Similarly the variable is set to 1 if an 11th grader
starts college two years later and 0 otherwise. I pool
the 1984, 1985, 1986, 1987, and 1990 SIPP panels and
use both men and women. The sample for which all
the key information, including log wealth, is available
is 4,123. Of these, about 37 percent enrolled in college.
The description of the sample is given in table 1.
The key explanatory variables that are the focus of this
study are family income, tuition costs, and wealth.
Family income is averaged over the two calendar years
that are available in each of the SIPPs and includes
earnings from up to two jobs, two businesses, and any
income from other sources. Since ideally I want to
measure tuition for those at the margin of attending
college, I opt for two-year colleges. Tuition costs are
measured by using the average tuition at two-year
colleges in the individual's state of residence.6 Unlike
Cameron and Heckman (2001), I cannot measure this
at the county level so there is likely to be considerable
measurement error. In this analysis, I have not adjust­
ed tuition for Pell Grant eligibility as some previous
studies have done.
I use three different wealth variables, since it is
not clear a priori what the appropriate measure ought
to be. First, I consider housing equity, since this is the
largest share of wealth for many families. Second, I
construct a measure of liquid assets (for example, bank
accounts, stocks, bonds) that might better capture the
financial resources readily available to the family. The

third measure I consider is net worth, which is a sum­
mary measure that incorporates a large array of assets
and liabilities. A problem with wealth data is that the
non-reporting for some variables can be sizable, so
many values are imputed by the Census Bureau. As
an additional check, I limit analysis to data that is not
imputed, though this reduces the sample size.
Figure 5 shows how college enrollment differs by
quartiles of family income and the three measures of
wealth. It is immediately striking that the wealth mea­
sures do not appear to be appreciably different from
each other in terms of how they affect enrollment at
least unconditionally. Housing equity appears to show
the smallest differences across the quartiles. Liquid
assets shows the most striking difference between the
first and second quartiles, while net worth looks closest
to family income. I chose to use net worth, since it is
the broadest measure and since the results are not much
affected by the alternatives.
To the extent possible, I follow Kane (1994) and
Cameron and Heckman (2001) in the choice of other
covariates. These include family size, father’s years
of education, mother’s years of education, black indi­
cator, female indicator, indicator for whether a parent
has a long spell of unemployment, state, and year ef­
fects. For measures of the local labor market, I use the
unemployment rate and the average wage for those with
a high school degree. Wherever possible these are both
measured at the metropolitan statistical area level, other­
wise they are measured at the state level. Again, com­
pared with the county level measures used by Cameron
and Heckman, my measures are likely to suffer from
measurement error.

TABLE 1

Summary statistics
Variable

Mean

Enrolled in college
0.37
Log family income
10.41
Family size
2.94
Father's years of education
10.47
No father identified
0.19
Mother's years of education
11.19
No mother identified
0.10
Female
0.51
Black
0.11
Parent unemployed > 3 months
0.25
Local area unemployment rate
0.07
Local wage for high-school grad (1984$)
7.94
Tuition (1984$)
741
Net worth (1984$)
92.463
Housing equity (1984$)
46.562
Liquid wealth (1984$)
15.853

Sample size

36

Standard deviation

0.48
0.82
0.57
5.84
0.39
4.52
0.30
0.50
0.31
0.43
0.02
0.70
376
117.158
45.483
48.232

Minimum

Maximum

0
0
2
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
5.73
30
38
-2.385
0

1
12.70
6
18
1
18
1
1
1
1
0.19
10.16
1.641
1.285.442
251.519
1.010.100

4.123

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

The major limitation of the data, however, is that
for most years they do not contain information on
scholastic ability such as test scores. Therefore, the
analysis is subject to Cameron and Heckman’s criti­
cism that other variables such as income and wealth
may pick up the effects of this omitted variable. On
the other hand, this dataset does contain information
on the wealth of the parents, which is a critical omis­
sion in the NLSY, so the reverse criticism could be
made of the existing studies.
There are several hypotheses one might make
about how wealth could influence enrollment. First,
one might simply imagine that wealth has a direct ef­
fect on the probability of attending college. Imagine
two families with similar income but one has substan­
tially larger assets to draw from. If we thought that an
extra dollar of wealth simply acts the same way as an
extra dollar of income, a reasonable first step would
be to model wealth the same way as income and assume
a linear relationship.
However, there are several reasons to think that
the effects of wealth are nonlinear. One reason is that
wealth might serve simply as an indicator of borrow­
ing constraints. If there are market imperfections that
prevent students from borrowing from their expected
future income, they may be forced to rely on parents’
wealth either directly or as a form of collateral. In this
simple case, we might expect that additional financial
resources, either income or wealth, might be impor­
tant, but only for families below a certain threshold
of wealth, for example, the bottom quartile of the
wealth distribution.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

However, if scholastic ability is a critical factor
in determining college enrollment as Cameron and
Heckman (2001) show, and if it is correlated with par­
ents’ wealth, then the story becomes more complicated.
At the low end of the wealth distribution there might
be very few families who would actually benefit from
greater financial resources due to low levels of aca­
demic preparedness. It might be that as we move up
the wealth distribution, there are more families for whom
additional financial resources might matter. At some
point along the wealth distribution, of course, families
have sufficient financial resources and the effect might
dissipate. In this case financial resources might matter
most for families in the middle of the distribution.
Corak and Heisz (1999) reported this kind of finding
in their study of nonlinearities in intergenerational
mobility using Canadian data.
A second reason that wealth might have a nonlin­
ear effect is that it is typically an important variable in
financial aid formulas used by colleges and universities,
as well as government aid programs. In this case, great­
er wealth might actually increase the costs of college
attendance over a particular range of the wealth distri­
bution. This might produce a more complicated pattern,
where income matters the most for families with modest
amounts of wealth.
I use two simple approaches to estimate these po­
tential nonlinear effects. First, I simply include indica­
tor variables for quartiles of the wealth distribution.
This tests whether the direct effects of wealth on en­
rollment have a nonlinear pattern. It allows us to see
whether wealth matters most going from say the bottom
quartile to the second quartile. Second, I stratify the
sample by levels of wealth to see whether the effects
of family income or college costs matter at a particu­
lar point of the wealth distribution as hypothesized
above. This might help identify whether there is a
particular point in the wealth distribution where
borrowing constraints might bind and make income
particularly important.
The first set of results is shown in table 2. In the
first column, the results are shown without including
any wealth measures and with no state effects. Here
nearly all the coefficients are of the expected sign.
The coefficient on log family income is .04 and is
highly significant. Parent education is positive and
significant. Women are slightly more likely to enroll
in college and blacks are about 6 percentage points
less likely to enroll even conditioning on these other
variables. The one unexpected result is tuition, which
has a positive sign. The lack of good geographic detail
on tuition is probably the explanation. Local labor mar­
ket conditions do not appear to be significant. The

37

addition of state effects appears to make no difference
to the results (not shown) and does not improve the
performance of the tuition measure.
In column 2,1 add log of net worth to the model.
This measure of wealth is significant with a coefficient
of .02. Adding net worth lowers the coefficient on fami­
ly income by about one-quarter to .032. Interestingly,
most of the difference between whites and blacks is
now eliminated.
In column 3,1 take a simple approach toward
estimating nonlinearities in wealth by using indicator
variables for being in a particular quartile of the net
worth distribution. I use the first quartile as a basis
for comparison. After controlling for other covariates,
being in the second quartile of net worth raises the
probability of enrollment by only 3 percentage points.
The larger jumps take place at the top 2 quartiles. I find

a similar pattern when using housing equity or liquid
assets instead of net worth (not shown). This provides
suggestive evidence of nonlinearities in wealth. It
appears from this evidence that having above median
wealth is the critical threshold to overcome.
Finally in table 3,1 test directly whether family
resources are sensitive at particular points in the wealth
distribution. Here the exercise is to stratify the sample
by quartiles of net worth and compare the coefficients
on family income. For quartile 1, the effects of family
income are relatively small and only marginally statis­
tically significant. Interestingly, the gap with blacks
is small and statistically insignificant while the female
enrollment advantage is quite a bit higher. In the sec­
ond quartile of net worth, there is a dramatic rise in
the importance of family income—the coefficient is
.07 and highly statistically significant. Income appears

TABLE 2

The effects of adding net worth
Regression results where dependent variable is college enrollment

Log family income

Family size

Dad's education
Mom's education

Female
Black
Parent unemployed
Local unemployment rate
Local wage for high-school grad

State tuition

1

2

3

0.041
(0.008)
-0.036
(0.015)
0.025
(0.003)
0.024
(0.003)
0.038
(0.013)
-0.058
(0.020)
-0.019
(0.020)
0.694
(0.378)
0.011
(0.010)
0.000
(0.000)

0.032
(0.011)

0.029
(0.008)
-0.034
(0.015)
0.023
(0.003)
0.022
(0.003)
0.038
(0.013)
-0.032
(0.021)
-0.014
(0.020)
0.753
(0.377)
0.004
(0.010)
0.000
(0.000)

Log net worth

-0.041
(0.017)
0.025
(0.003)
0.024
(0.003)
0.035
(0.014)
-0.026
(0.024)
-0.009
(0.022)
0.795
(0.408)
0.007
(0.010)
0.000
(0.000)
0.021
(0.005)

Net worth quartile 2

0.034
(0.019)
0.083
(0.020)
0.135
(0.021)

Net worth quartile 3
Net worth quartile 4
Sample size
R-squared

4676
0.125

4123
0.128

4676
0.133

Note: Standard errors in parentheses.

38

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

to be twice as important in this range of wealth com­
pared with the sample overall and three to four times as
important compared with the lowest wealth quartile.
In fact, for this group neither gender nor race appears
to have any effect on enrollment rates. For the third
quartile, the income effects are similar to what was
estimated for the full sample in table 2. For the fourth
quartile, as we might expect, income matters much
less. In the upper half of the wealth distribution the
black-white gap is only marginally significant.
What should we take away from this exercise?
The results in table 3 raise the tantalizing possibility
that there might, in fact, be a group of families for whom
income matters and for whom financial aid or subsidies
might promote college attendance. These are not the
poorest families, but actually have wealth between the
25th and 50th percentiles. One hypothesis for this find­
ing is that the children of families in the second wealth
quartile have sufficient capability to perform well in
college but that they do not enroll (at least not right
away) because of insufficient financial resources. Under
this view, income does not explain the enrollment rate
for the poorest group of families (bottom quartile),

because they are also the least likely to have children
with the capability to succeed, so they would not have
enrolled even with additional financial resources.
An alternative explanation for the importance of
income for families in the second quartile of the wealth
distribution is the extensive use of financial aid formulas
in determining college costs. This formula essentially
acts as a tax on wealth. Families with little or no wealth
are unaffected. However, families with some, but not
a lot, of wealth will face higher college costs. Since I
do not measure the true net costs faced by families, this
sensitivity is captured by family income. As we move
higher in the wealth distribution, however, the penalty
no longer matters since the wealthiest families are in­
eligible for aid. This makes additional income less
important for families in the top two quartiles.
Further analysis
Additional research with other datasets may be nec­
essary to validate these results. It would be useful to
know whether this pattern of higher income sensitivity
at the second quartile of wealth also affects earlier grade
transitions, where we would not expect wealth to matter.

TABLE 3

The effect of income by quartiles of wealth
Regression results where dependent variable is college enrollment

(Samples are stratified by quartiles of the net worth distribution)
Quartile 1

Family income
Family size

Dad's education
Mom's education
Female

Black
Parent unemployed
Local unemployment rate
Local wage for high-school grad
State tuition

Sample size
R-squared

Quartile 2

Quartile 3

Quartile 4

0.017
(0.019)
-0.012
(0.037)
0.021
(0.006)
0.034
(0.007)
0.037
(0.028)
-0.184
(0.105)
-0.072
(0.051)
1.598
(0.823)
0.018
(0.020)
0.000
(0.000)
1159
0.104

0.020
(0.011)
-0.042
(0.025)
0.011
(0.005)
0.017
(0.005)
0.072
(0.024)
-0.023
(0.028)
-0.017
(0.035)
0.974
(0.738)
0.018
(0.017)
0.000
(0.000)

-0.058
(0.029)
0.017
(0.005)
0.026
(0.007)
0.011
(0.026)
0.008
(0.037)
0.046
(0.038)
-0.253
(0.736)
-0.014
(0.020)
0.000
(0.000)

0.034
(0.024)
-0.031
(0.035)
0.037
(0.006)
0.014
(0.007)
0.024
(0.027)
-0.086
(0.055)
-0.028
(0.042)
0.978
(0.740)
-0.003
(0.021)
0.000
(0.000)

1153
0.064

1169
0.098

1169
0.130

0.074
(0.022)

Note: Standard errors in parentheses.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

39

It would also be interesting to see if these effects still
hold up in other datasets where it is possible to control
for ability by using test scores. Still, the findings here
ought to prompt researchers to consider the possibili­
ty that all family resources, including wealth, should
be analyzed.

Conclusion
The growing gap in earnings between college grad­
uates and non-graduates has become an important feature
of the economy. Promoting greater college enrollment
might not only address the current earnings gap but
also offer the potential to improve economic mobility
for future generations. Other potential societal benefits
include a more productive economy and a better-informed citizenry.
To date, economic research has produced only
mixed findings for policymakers who wish to promote
college enrollment for disadvantaged youth through

greater access to financial resources. While there is some
skepticism as to whether a large number of families
are actually “borrowing constrained,” there is more
agreement that lower tuition costs and greater financial
aid do appear to affect enrollment. Whether these poli­
cies will narrow the gaps in enrollment by race, ethnici­
ty or income level is less clear.
Most studies, however, have neglected the poten­
tial role of wealth. The preliminary analysis here sug­
gests that incorporating wealth might be a promising
avenue for better identifying borrowing constrained
families for whom additional financial resources might
matter. Income appears to have a very large effect for
families in the second quartile of the net worth distri­
bution. Arguably, it is in these families that children
are academically prepared for college but for whom
additional financial resources make a big difference.
This is an especially important area for further analy­
sis, given the vast and growing educational divide.

NOTES
’This is based on Census Historical Income Tables, P32 and P35
available at the Census website at www.census.gov/hhes/income/
histinc/incperdet.html. These figures are for men aged 35-44 who
worked full-time and year round. The figures do not adjust for
variables such as hours worked and work experience that are
typically used by economists to estimate the “return to education”
using a regression model.

2This is taken from U.S. Department of Education, National
Center for Educational Statistics (2003), table 183.

4Dynarski (2003) and Cameiro and Heckman (2003) are excep­
tions to this.

5Using probit models produce exactly the same qualitative results.
The coefficients from a regression produce results that are easily
interpreted at any point of the distribution of the covariates.
6Data was provided by the Washington State Higher Education
Group.

3These include Cameron and Taber (2004) and Keane and
Wolpin (2001).

40

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

REFERENCES
Aaronson, Daniel, and Daniel Sullivan, 2001,
“Growth in worker quality” Economic Perspectives,
Vol. 25, No. 4, pp. 53-74.

Bowles, Samuel, and Herbert Gintis, 2002, “The
inheritance of inequality,” Journal ofEconomic
Perspectives, Vol. 16, No. 3, pp. 3-30.
Cameron, Stephen V., and James J. Heckman, 2001,
“The dynamics of educational attainment for black,
Hispanic, and white males,” Journal ofPolitical
Economy, Vol. 109, No. 3, pp. 455-499.

Cameron, Stephen V., and Christopher Taber, 2004,
“Estimation of educational borrowing constraints
using returns to schooling,” Journal ofPolitical
Economy, forthcoming.
Carneiro, Pedro, and James J. Heckman, 2003,
“Human capital policy,” National Bureau of Economic
Research, Cambridge MA, working paper, No. 9495.
Corak, Miles, and Andrew Heisz, 1999, “The
intergenerational earnings and income mobility of
Canadian men: Evidence from longitudinal income
tax data,” Journal ofHuman Resources, Vol. 34,
No. 3, pp. 504-533.

Dynarski, Susan, 2003, “Does aid matter? Measuring
the effect of student aid on college attendance and
completion,” American Economic Review, Vol. 93,
No. l,pp. 279-288.

Heckman, James J., Lance Lochner, and Christopher
Taber, 1998, “General equilibrium treatment effects:
A study of tuition policy,” American Economic Review,
Vol. 88, No. 2, pp. 381-386.
Kane, Thomas J., 1994, “College entry by blacks
since 1970: The role of college costs, family back­
ground, and the returns to education,” Journal of
Political Economy, Vol. 102, No. 5, pp. 878-911.

Keane, Michael P., and Kenneth I. Wolpin, 2001,
“The effect of parental transfers and borrowing con­
straints on educational attainment,” International
Economic Review, Vol. 42, No. 4, pp. 1051-1103.

Leslie, Larry L., and Paul T. Brinkman, 1989,
The Economic Value ofHigher Education, New York:
Macmillan (for the American Council on Education).
McPherson, Michael S., and Morton Owen
Schapiro, 1998, The Student Aid Game: Meeting
Need and Rewarding Talent in Higher Education,
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

U.S. Department of Education, National Center
for Education Statistics, 2003, Digest ofEconomic
Statistics 2002, Washington, DC.
Zeldes, Stephen P., 1989, “Consumption and liquidity
constraints: An empirical investigation,” Journal of

Hansen, W. Lee, 1983, “Impact of student financial
aid on access,” in The Crisis in Higher Education,
Joseph Froomkin (ed.), New York: Academy of
Political Science.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

41

An introduction to the WTO and GATT

Meredith A. Crowley

Since its inception in 1995, the World Trade Organi­
zation (WTO) has regularly been in the news. There
have been optimistic stories of expanding WTO mem­
bership that emphasize that freer trade generates numer­
ous benefits for consumers. Newspapers report on the
details of WTO entry negotiations for important coun­
tries like China and remind us of the gains from trade.
At other times, media reports might lead us to believe
that disputes among WTO members are about to tear
the organization apart. Disagreements between the
U.S. and the European Union (EU) over everything
from U.S. corporate taxation, to genetically modified
organisms, to special steel tariffs make headlines world­
wide. Finally, some groups seem unconvinced by and
resentful of claims that free trade makes the entire
world better off. Huge numbers of people from envi­
ronmental and labor groups gather at various interna­
tional meetings of heads of state and government
ministers to protest globalization in general and the
WTO in particular. Some representatives of develop­
ing countries are concerned that they have liberalized
their trade and agreed to intellectual property protec­
tion for developed country products but have received
almost no additional access to agricultural markets in
the industrialized world.
What are we to make of all this? What is the WTO?
What is it trying to accomplish and why? How does
the world trading system function? Why are there so
many disputes among countries that belong to the WTO?
This article provides an overview of the General
Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, better known as GATT,
and the WTO system. In the first section, I present a
brief history of GATT and the WTO. In the following
section, I discuss the fundamental principles that under­
lie the post-WWII world trading system and explain
how these principles work to increase welfare. In the
third section, I describe the numerous exceptions to
GATT’s requirement of nondiscrimination, or equal
treatment, and review the economics literature that

42

seeks to explain the rationale for and consequences
of these exceptions. Then, I present a short summary
of dispute resolution within the WTO.

A brief history of the WTO and GATT
The World Trade Organization (WTO) and its pre­
decessor, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
(GATT) have been enormously successful over the
last 50 years at reducing tariff and other trade barriers
among an ever-increasing number of countries. The
predecessor to the WTO began in 1947 with only 23
members; today it has 146 members, comprising ap­
proximately 97 percent of world trade.1 See box 1 for
a timeline of GATT and the WTO.2
Although the WTO, established in 1995, is rela­
tively young for an international institution, it has its
origins in the Bretton Woods Conference at the end
of World War II. At this conference, finance ministers
from the Allied nations gathered to discuss the failings
of World War I’s Versailles Treaty and the creation of
a new international monetary system that would sup­
port postwar reconstruction, economic stability, and
peace. The Bretton Woods Conference produced two
of the most important international economic institu­
tions of the postwar period: the International Monetary
Fund (IMF) and the International Bank for Reconstruc­
tion and Development (the World Bank). Recognizing
that the beggcir-thy-neighbor tariff policies of the 1930s
had contributed to the environment that led to war, min­
isters discussed the need for a third postwar institu­
tion, the International Trade Organization (ITO), but
left the problem of designing it to their colleagues in
government ministries with responsibility for trade.3

Meredith Crowley is an economist at the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago. She thanks Chad Bown, Craig Furfine,
and Mike Kouparitsas for detailed comments. Avinash
Kaza provided helpful research assistance.

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

BOX 1

Timeline of GATT and the WTO
1944: At the Bretton Woods Conference, which created the World Bank and International Monetary Fund
(IMF), there is talk of a third organization, the International Trade Organization (ITO).
1947: As support for another international organization wanes in the U.S. Congress, the General Agreement
on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) is created. The GATT treaty creates a set of rules to govern trade among 23
member countries rather than a formal institution.
1950: Formal U.S. withdrawal from the ITO concept as the U.S. administration abandons efforts to seek
congressional ratification of the ITO.
1951-86: Periodic negotiating rounds occur, with occasional discussions of reforms of GATT. In the 1980s,
serious problems with dispute resolutions arise.
1986-94: The Uruguay Round, a new round of trade negotiations, is launched. This culminates in a 1994
treaty that establishes the World Trade Organization (WTO).

1995: The WTO is created at the end of the Uruguay Round, replacing GATT.

2003: The WTO consists of 146 members, accounting for approximately 97 percent of world trade.

By the late 1940s, representatives of the American
government had met several times with representatives
of other major nations to design a postwar internation­
al trading system that would parallel the international
monetary system. These meetings had two objectives:
1) to draft a charter for the ITO and 2) to negotiate the
substance of an ITO agreement, specifically, rules
governing international trade and reductions in tariffs.
Although a charter was drafted, the ITO never came
into being. By 1948, support for yet another interna­
tional organization had waned in the U.S. Congress.
Without American participation, the institution would
have been greatly weakened and, in the event, the ef­
fort to create an organization to manage problems re­
lating to international trade was abandoned.
However, although the U.S. Congress would not
support another international institution, in 1945 it had
given the U.S. president the authority to negotiate a
treaty governing international trade by extending the
1934 Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act. This led to
the establishment of the General Agreement on Tariffs
and Trade (GATT) in 1947—a treaty whereby 23
member countries agreed to a set of rules to govern
trade with one another and maintained reduced import
tariffs for other members.4 The GATT treaty did not
provide for a formal institution, but a small GATT
Secretariat, with a limited institutional apparatus, was
eventually headquartered in Geneva to administer
various problems and complaints that might arise
among members.
Over the next 40 years, GATT grew in member­
ship and in its success at reducing barriers to trade.
GATT members regularly met in what came to be

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

known as negotiating rounds. These rounds were pri­
marily focused on negotiating further reductions in
the maximum tariffs that countries could impose on
imports from other GATT members. The success of
these rounds is evident (see figure 1). Tariffs on man­
ufactured products fell from a trade-weighted average
of roughly 35 percent before the creation of GATT in
1947 to about 6.4 percent at the start of the Uruguay
Round in 1986.5 Over the same time period, the vol­
ume of trade among GATT members surged: In 2000
the volume of trade among WTO members stood at
25 times its 1950 volume. This growth in the volume
of trade is impressive and appears to have accelerat­
ed in recent decades (see figure 2). Comparing the
growth of world GDP, expressed as an index number,
to the growth of the volume of trade among GATT/
WTO members, also expressed as an index number,
figure 2 shows that while trade grew more slowly
than world GDP in the early years of the GATT/WTO,
in recent years it has outpaced GDP growth.
Despite this success, by the 1980s several problems
had surfaced with the GATT apparatus. Firstly, the
dispute resolution mechanism of GATT was not func­
tioning as effectively as had been hoped. Countries
with longstanding disagreements were unable to reach
any sort of resolution on a number of issues, ranging
from government subsidies for exports to regulations
regarding foreign direct investment. Secondly, a num­
ber of commodities, most importantly, agricultural
products and textiles, were widely exempt from GATT
disciplines. Thirdly, it was widely believed that certain
forms of administered trade protection—antidumping
duties, voluntary export restraints, and countervailing

43

duties—were restricting trade and dis­
torting trade patterns in many important
sectors. Fourthly, trade in services was
expanding rapidly and GATT had no
rules regarding trade in services. Fifthly,
countries that produced intellectual prop­
erty—movies, computer programs, patent­
ed pharmaceuticals—were becoming
increasingly frustrated by the lack of in­
tellectual property protection in many
developing nations. Lastly, the rules re­
garding trade-related investment mea­
sures—for example, domestic purchase
requirements for plants built from foreign
direct investment—were hotly disputed.
To address these problems, a new
round of trade negotiations—the
Uruguay Round—was launched in 1986.
The goals of the Uruguay Round were far
more ambitious than in previous rounds.
It sought to introduce major reforms into
how the world trading system would function.
The treaty negotiated during the Uruguay Round,
the GATT treaty of 1994, established the WTO—the
international institution to govern trade that was first
visualized by the attendees of the Bretton Woods
Conference 50 years earlier. The new GATT treaty pro­
vided for an entirely new and different dispute resolu­
tion mechanism to eliminate the gridlock of the old
system. Furthermore, the Uruguay Round expanded
GATT’s authority to new areas—agreements regarding
trade in textiles, agriculture, services, and intellectual
property were major achievements. Finally, new sets
of rules regarding administered protec­
tion came into effect with the creation of
the WTO in 1995.

Fundamental principles of the
GATT/WTO system
The success of GATT as a dynamic
institution that has fostered dramatic in­
creases in worldwide trade lies in its
founding principles of reciprocity and
nondiscrimination. Reciprocity refers
to the practice that occurs in GATT
negotiating rounds, whereby one country
offers to reduce a barrier to trade and a
second country “reciprocates” by offer­
ing to reduce one of its own trade barriers.
Reciprocity, the practice of swapping
tariff concessions, facilitates the reduc­
tion of trade barriers. Nondiscrimination,
or equal treatment, means that if one

44

GATT member offers a benefit or a tariff concession
to another GATT member, for example, a reduction
in its import tariff for bicycles, it must offer the same
tariff reduction to all GATT members. Thus, nondis­
crimination extends the benefits of a reciprocal tariff
reduction beyond the two parties that initially negoti­
ated it to all GATT members. Papers by Bagwell and
Staiger (1999, 2001) argue that, together, these prin­
ciples work toward increasing the efficiency of the
world trading system.
Why is reciprocity important in reducing barriers to
trade? Don’t countries benefit by unilaterally reducing
FIGURE 2

Growth in volume of trade and total GDP
among WTO members, 1950-2000

Source: World Trade Organization (2001).

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

their tariffs because lower tariffs lead to lower domestic
prices? They may, but economic theory teaches us
that it depends on the size of the country.
Trade theory teaches us that import tariffs are
another type of tax. As a tax, tariffs raise the price that
consumers must pay for a good, provide tax revenue
to the government, and have the potential to create
distortions, or inefficiencies, in consumption and
production decisions.
If a country is very small, it will benefit by uni­
laterally lowering its tariffs, and reciprocity is not an
important consideration (see figure 3). This is because
small countries are unable to affect the prices of goods
on the world market. If a small country suddenly de­
cided to impose a 25 percent tariff on imports of au­
tomobiles, this would not affect the worldwide price
at which automobiles trade. The tiny decrease in world­
wide demand caused by this country’s new tariff would
be miniscule compared with the demand for automo­
biles in large markets like the U.S., the EU, and Japan.
However, this tariff would make the small country
worse off. Although the country’s government may
now collect more tariff revenue (area A in figure 3),
consumers would have to pay a higher price, result­
ing in a loss of welfare to consumers, and there would
be an efficiency loss due to the “consumption distor­
tion” of the tariff (area B in figure 3)—fewer cars
would be purchased overall. Thus, the optimal trade
policy for small countries is to charge no import tar­
iff. Regardless of the trade policies of its trading
partners, a small country should engage in free trade.
The story is a bit more complicated for large
countries or customs unions like the U.S. and the EU.
Reciprocity is important when large countries are think­
ing about changing their trade policies (see figure 4).
Because import demand in a large country will com­
prise a large share of worldwide import demand (MD
in figure 4), any change in a large country’s demand
for a good will have an effect on that good’s price on
the world market. Specifically, when a large country’s
government imposes a tariff, this reduces the quanti­
ty of imports demanded and, consequently, causes the
world price to fall. In figure 4, this is reflected in the
decline in the world price from Pto P*. When the
price of a country’s import good falls on the world
market relative to the price of the goods it exports, this
is called a terms-of-trade improvement. A terms-oftrade improvement makes a country better off because
it can buy imports at a relatively cheaper price on the
world market. Although consumers pay a higher price
for the imported good than they would under free trade,
the importing country’s total welfare is higher because

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

the government earns tariff revenue and because
import-competing producers earn higher profits.
Another way to think about a large country’s use
of tariffs is to focus on the question of who bears the
cost of this tax. Although the consumers in a large
country must pay a higher final price for the imported
good (P rather than P ) when their government im­
poses a tariff, they don’t bear the full tax burden of
the tariff. A tariff that causes the world price of a good
to fall hurts the foreign exporters that produce that
good, because they only receive P* instead of Pw. As
a whole, the exporting country loses some of its pur­
chasing power on the world market in this worsening
of its terms of trade. In this way, some of the cost of
the tariff is pushed onto the foreign producers of the
good in the form of the lower price they receive for
their product than they would under free trade. Because
foreign producers lose out under this import tariff, it
is sometimes called a beggar-thy-neighbor policy.
The use of a beggar-thy-neighbor tariff by a large
country not only makes the importing country strictly
better off and the exporting country strictly worse
off, it introduces inefficiencies into the world trading

45

FIGURE 4

Impact of a tariff on a large country
Home market

P
Q
S
D
XS

=
=
=
=
=

Price
Quantity
Supply
Demand
Export supply

World market

MD
Pt
Pw
MT

=
=
=
=

Import demand
Price with tariff
World price
Imports under tariff

system that cause the net effect of the tariff to be nega­
tive. The import tariff induces inefficient production
distortions in both countries. The level of production
is too high in the importing country and too low in the
exporting country relative to what the levels would be
under free trade. However, although the tariff is bad for
the world as a whole, it remains a desirable and beneficial
policy for the importing country. At the end of WWII,
many of the large countries that became the original
members of GATT had high tariffs. They found them­
selves in what economists call a terms-of-trade-driven
prisoner’s dilemma. The prisoner’s dilemma is a famous
problem in the field of game theory that describes a
situation in which two parties can improve their situa­
tions by acting cooperatively, but the individual in­
centives they face lead them to act noncooperatively.
Figure 5 provides a highly stylized example of
the terms-of-trade-driven prisoner’s dilemma faced
by two large countries—America and a foreign coun­
try—at the end of WWII. We can read the figure as
follows. The horizontal rows depict the policy options
available to America—free trade with the foreign coun­
try or charging a beggar-thy-neighbor tariff. The ver­
tical columns represent the policy options available to
the foreign country—free trade or a beggar-thy-neighbor tariff. The numerical entries in the four boxes show
the payoffs that each country will receive if the differ­
ent policy options are taken. The first number represents
America’s payoff; the second, the foreign country’s.
For example, the box in the lower left-hand comer

46

Foreign market

IVF = Imports under free trade

QT = Imports under tariff
Q171 = Imports under free trade
* indicates foreign.

tells us that if the U.S. imposes a beggar-thy-neighbor
tariff and the foreign country practices free trade, the
U.S. will receive a payoff of 15 and the foreign coun­
try receives nothing. In the upper left comer, if both
countries practice free trade, then the worldwide pay­
off of 20 (the sum of America’s payoff and the foreign
country’s payoff) is higher than under any other set
of policy options. However, in this example, both
countries want to avoid being the dupe that practices
free trade and faces a beggar-thy-neighbor tariff. Thus,
in equilibrium, each country charges a beggar-thyneighbor tariff and receives the low payoff of 5.
As in the stylized example in figure 1, the prob­
lem facing countries at the end of WWII was that they
knew that they would collectively be better off under

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

free trade. Although each country benefited from its
own import tariff, it also suffered at the hands of its
trading partners’ import tariffs. What was needed was
a mechanism by which countries could jointly commit
to tariff reductions that would reduce the losses due
to production and consumption distortions and, through
gains in efficiency, make all countries better off.
GATT, through its practice of reciprocal tariff re­
ductions, provided the necessary mechanism for coun­
tries to commit to freer trade. Under GATT, large
countries that reduced their import tariffs would ex­
perience a net gain because their trading partners would
simultaneously reduce their import tariffs. In all coun­
tries, the reallocation of labor and capital away from
protected import-competing firms and toward export
sectors would generate real efficiency gains.
It is evident that reciprocity is necessary for two
large countries to engage in trade liberalization, but this
could have been achieved with a network of bilateral
treaties.6 Why did GATT adopt a multilateral approach
with a strict requirement for nondiscrimination?
Nondiscrimination is a convenient way to reduce
the complexity of international trading relations. On
a purely practical level, it may be easier to negotiate
one set of import tariffs than to engage in dozens of
bilateral agreements. In fact, Jackson (1997) speculates
that when nondiscrimination, or “most-favored-nation,”
clauses were originally introduced into trade treaties
in the sixteenth century, they had a practical benefit—
drafters did not have to copy large sections of treaties
again and again.
However, while convenience and practicality are
important, nondiscrimination would not have become
a central feature of GATT if it did not yield real eco­
nomic benefits. Nondiscrimination in tariff policy, that
is, setting the same tariff on imports from all countries,
ensures that resources are allocated to their most pro­
ductive use. On the import side, nondiscrimination
ensures that countries purchase imports from the low­
est-cost source country. Further, nondiscrimination
prevents trade re-routing, in which goods are moved
through third countries in order to circumvent high
tariffs. Lastly, Bagwell and Staiger (2003) show that, on
the export side, nondiscrimination protects exporting
countries from bilateral opportunism.
As an importer, a country can charge a single nondiscriminatory tariff on imports from all countries or
it can set different tariffs on imports from different
countries. Under a nondiscriminatory tariff, imports
will be sourced from the lowest-cost producer in the
world. Compare this to a system of discriminatory
tariffs in which, for example, the U.S. sets a lower,
preferential tariff on T-shirts from Mexico than on

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

T-shirts from China. If China can produce T-shirts
more cheaply than Mexico, but the tariff on Chinese
T-shirts is so much larger than the tariff on Mexican
T-shirts that it is cheaper for Americans to buy T-shirts
from Mexico, there is a real loss due to the production
distortions caused by the U.S.’s discriminatory tariffs.
Resources in Mexico that could have been better em­
ployed in some other sector are utilized in its rela­
tively high-cost T-shirt industry. Resources in China
that could have been efficiently used to make T-shirts
are allocated to another industry. When a country uses
a nondiscriminatory tariff, this facilitates the allocation
of resources worldwide to their most productive uses.
Trade re-routing is a costly practice whereby an
exporter ships its goods to a third country, repackag­
es it, and then ships it to a final destination where it
will qualify for the third country’s lower, preferential
tariff rate (see figure 6). In some cases, in order to quali­
fy for the preferential tariff, the product must under­
go a substantial transformation in the third country.
This sometimes leads firms to move a stage of the pro­
duction process to the third country. When an import­
ing country utilizes a single nondiscriminatory tariff
for all imports, there is no need for exporters to en­
gage in the costly process of re-routing.
When two countries bilaterally negotiate tariff
concessions, the principle of reciprocity implies that
the tariff reductions on various products are balanced
in such a way that the terms of trade between the two
countries remain unchanged (that is, neither country
is “beggaring” the other), while the volume of trade
increases to a more efficient level. However, in a world
in which both countries remain free to negotiate an ad­
ditional trade agreement with a third country, the prob­
lem of bilateral opportunism arises. For example, if one
country were later to offer a lower tariff rate to a third
country, this could erode the value of the original tariff
concession to the first trading partner. Bagwell and
Staiger (2003) have shown that when negotiations uti­
lize the practices of reciprocity and nondiscrimina­
tion, the problem of bilateral opportunism is eliminated.
In summary, GATT’s founding principles of rec­
iprocity and nondiscrimination facilitate increases in
well-being for the countries that belong to the WTO.
By coordinating tariff reductions among large countries,
GATT makes efficiency gains from trade a reality.
By requiring that countries set nondiscriminatory tar­
iffs, GATT facilitates the production of goods in the
most efficient location. However, a number of excep­
tions to GATT’s nondiscrimination rule exist. In the
next section, I explore these exceptions and why GATT
allows the use of discriminatory tariffs in special
circumstances.

47

Exceptions to GATT’s nondiscrimination
principle
Although nondiscrimination is an ideal in GATT,
in practice a number of exceptions to this general rule
exist. Regional trade agreements—both free trade ar­
eas and customs unions—are allowed. Governments
may also use administeredprotection—special tariffs
that can be used for particular purposes. Both types
of exceptions create both problems and benefits for
the world trading system.
Regional trade agreements
In 1947 when negotiators drafted the original GATT
treaty, they recognized that from time to time, some
countries might want to push ahead with greater trade
liberalizations. Although GATT preferred nondiscriminatory tariffs, it did not intend to impede the gains
from trade that could be had if only a few members
were willing to reduce their tariffs even further. There­
fore, it allowed the formation of two types of region­
al trade agreements—free trade areas and customs
unions. In a free trade area, the members maintain
their original external tariffs with the rest of the world,
but engage in free trade with one another. In a customs
union, all member countries set the same external tar­
iff for imports from non-members and eliminate the
tariffs on imports from members. When GATT mem­
bers form a customs union, the common external tariff
can be no higher than a weighted average of the tariffs
of the member countries before the customs union
was formed.
From the beginning, the decision to allow region­
al trade agreements within GATT was controversial.
Viner (1950) framed the question as an essentially
empirical one: Were regional trade agreements “trade
creating” or “trade diverting?” He coined the term
“trade creation and trade diversion” to describe what
happens when several countries join together to form
a regional trade agreement (RTA). The reduction in
tariffs among RTA members leads to trade creation
among members. The problem is that the trade that

48

develops between RTA members may not reflect an
overall expansion of a country’s imports, but rather a
diversion of trade away from a non-RTA country to a
RTA member. In this case, there may be no worldwide
efficiency gains from trade if the non-RTA country is
the lowest-cost producer of some good.
Today, the question of whether regional trade agree­
ments are trade creating or trade diverting remains
unresolved. In fact, it is almost impossible to answer
this question definitively because economists never
observe the appropriate benchmark for estimating the
amount of trade creation and trade diversion associ­
ated with a regional trade agreement. Because econo­
mies and trade are always growing, it is hard to construct
a counterfactual estimate of how much trade would
have grown among RTA members if these countries
had not formed a regional trade agreement.
Sampson (1996) argues that the question of trade
creation and trade diversion is much less important
today than it was 50 years ago because tariffs today
are much lower. For the U.S. and the EU, most prod­
ucts face import tariffs of less than 5 percent. There­
fore, Sampson argues, although RTA members with
these countries do benefit from a 0 percent tariff rate,
the size of this tariffpreference—the difference be­
tween the tariff for RTA members and other countries—
is so small that it cannot possibly induce much trade
diversion.
Sampson’s argument finds some support in a num­
ber of recent papers that have tackled this question
using highly disaggregated data on commodity trade.
Both Romalis (2002) and Clausing (2001) examine
trade creation and diversion in the context of the North
American Free Trade Agreement (Nafta). Both papers
find that Nafta created substantial amounts of trade,
but Romalis also finds evidence that Nafta may have
induced substantial trade diversion when tariff pref­
erences are very large. Prusa (2001) and Bown and
Crowley (2003 b) focus on deviations from GATT’s
nondiscrimination rule that arise when the U.S. im­
poses country-specific antidumping duties. The tariff
preference associated with antidumping duties is very
large and, thus, these papers find strong evidence of
trade diversion. Prusa finds that antidumping duties
lead the U.S. to source its imports from countries that
face a lower import tariff. Bown and Crowley (2003 b)
focus on what happens to the exports of a country that
faces a country-specific antidumping duty. They find
a substantial “trade deflection” effect—exports are
diverted to countries with lower import tariffs. Over­
all, the empirical literature finds evidence that trade
diversion occurs. However, the debate over the relative
magnitudes of trade creation and diversion continues.

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

A different but related body of research exam­
ines whether regional trade agreements are “building
blocks” or “stumbling blocks” (Bhagwati, 1992) on
the path to worldwide free trade. A theoretical paper
by Bagwell and Staiger (1997a) on free trade areas
and papers by Ethier (1998) and Freund (2000) argue
that regional trade agreements are building blocks
that can facilitate greater multilateral tariff reductions
or higher global welfare. However, research on cus­
toms unions by Bagwell and Staiger (1997b) and re­
search on regional trade agreements by McLaren
(2002), Levy (1997), and Bond and Syropoulos (1996)
supports the idea that regional trade agreements are
stumbling blocks.
All these papers explore how productive resources
are reallocated across countries and/or across sectors
within a country when multilateral and regional trade
agreements are formed. In the models of Bagwell and
Staiger (1997a), Ethier (1998), and Freund (2000),
the reallocation of resources that accompanies the
formation of an RTA creates a situation where further
reallocation under a multilateral agreement is feasi­
ble and welfare enhancing for everyone. In contrast,
in Bagwell and Staiger (1997b), Levy (1997), McLaren
(2002), and Bond and Syropoulos (1996), changes in
the economy that result from the formation of a re­
gional trade agreement inhibit further multilateral
trade liberalization.

Administered trade protection
While RTAs were permitted by GATT because at
least some believed that they could facilitate greater
worldwide trade, administered trade protection—tem­
porary tariffs that are usually discriminatory—was
allowed for a variety of reasons.
The term administered protection refers to trade
restrictions that provide protection from imports above
and beyond the protection afforded by the tariffs that
were negotiated as part of GATT. GATT permits the
use of antidumping duties, countervailing duties, safe­
guard measures, and tariffs to assist with balance of
payments problems.7 Voluntary export restraints are
an administered trade barrier that is technically no
longer allowed within the WTO but was popular in
the 1980s. The use of these trade policies represents
a deviation from GATT’s principle of nondiscrimina­
tion. Antidumping duties, which are imposed at the
country or firm level, are probably the most discrimi­
natory. GATT requires that safeguard measures be nondiscriminatory, but in practice many countries apply
them in a discriminatory manner.
Economics research that seeks to rationalize
the inclusion of the various forms of administered

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

protection in the WTO explores the argument that
administered protection either 1) improves world­
wide welfare or 2) improves the welfare of politically
powerful importing countries and, especially, their
import-competing sectors. The first argument is that
administered protection can create a net benefit for
the world as a whole. The protection may make some
countries better off and others worse off, but if we
add up the gains and losses to everyone in the world,
the sum total is positive. In other words, the gains of
temporary trade protection outweigh the losses. The
second argument is partly political and partly economic.
Some group profits from the use of administered pro­
tection. Even though protection may reduce worldwide
welfare, it is included in GATT because those who
benefit wield enough political power to see that it re­
mains within the agreement. Furthermore, recall from
the discussion of reciprocity and the terms-of-tradedriven prisoner’s dilemma above that large countries
benefit when they unilaterally impose beggar-thyneighbor tariffs. Although countries may use GATT to
arrive at a cooperative welfare-enhancing outcome, they
still may be tempted to cheat and reimpose beggarthy-neighbor tariffs. The different forms of administered
protection could provide an avenue for doing this.
Next, I provide some background information
on safeguards, antidumping duties, and countervail­
ing duties and review the economic research on these
different trade policy instruments.

Safeguards
A safeguard measure is a temporary tariff or quota
that is used to protect a domestic industry from “fair”
foreign competition.8 Whereas antidumping and coun­
tervailing duties are intended to “level the playing field”
when foreigner exporters have an “unfair” advantage
over domestic producers, safeguard measures may be
used against foreign exporters that have a fair compet­
itive advantage in a product.
The use of safeguards first began in the 1940s when
the U.S. began to pursue a liberal trade agenda. Fear­
ing that the lowering of a tariff on some particular good
as part of a trade agreement could result in a largerthan-expected import surge that would hurt domestic
firms, the U.S. government insisted that a safeguard
provision be part of every trade treaty that it signed.
Under GATT, when members negotiated reciprocal
tariff concessions, they committed themselves to max­
imum tariffs. These commitments restricted, to a con­
siderable extent, a domestic policymaker’s authority
to unilaterally raise tariffs at some later date.
To encourage countries to make greater concessions
during negotiations, GATT included two provisions

49

under which countries could reintroduce protective
trade policies. Countries remained free to temporarily
raise a tariff above the maximum level or introduce a
temporary quantitative restriction under the Article
XIX safeguard provision. Countries wishing to per­
manently raise their tariffs could do so under Article
XXVIII.
According to GATT’s Agreement on Safeguards,
safeguard measures should be nondiscriminatory, but
in fact countries often use discriminatory safeguards.
This practice is contentious and frequently challenged
before the WTO’s dispute settlement body. For exam­
ple, the recent U.S. Global Steel Safeguard raised the
import tariff on steel for many countries, but granted
exemptions for steel imports from many of our free
trade partners like Canada and Mexico. The WTO’s
dispute settlement body recently announced that these
exemptions are violations of GATT’s rules.9
Other GATT rules specify that safeguards should
only be used when imports increase unexpectedly or
as the result of unforeseen developments. This leads
to numerous debates over what developments can be
classified as “unforeseen.” Prior to the Uruguay Round’s
revisions to the safeguard rules in 1994, the use of a
safeguard measure was subject to measured retaliation.
If a country imposed a safeguard on a product, its
trading partners that were hurt by the safeguard could
retaliate with their own tariff increases on other prod­
ucts. As part of the Uruguay Round reforms, the safe­
guard rules changed so that safeguards are no longer
subject to retaliation for the first three years they are
in effect. This rule change was intended to make non­
discriminatory safeguards more attractive for protec­
tion-seeking governments relative to discriminatory
antidumping duties.
The economics literature provides several differ­
ent rationales for why the WTO allows the use of
safeguards. Perhaps the most widely cited argument for
safeguards is that their existence can facilitate greater
tariff liberalization by governments during trade ne­
gotiations. Because a government has an escape valve
if a tariff reduction causes pain to its own producers,
it has more freedom to make larger and potentially more
risky tariff reductions. Because there are large gains
from permanent tariff reductions and relatively small
costs from imposing temporary safeguards in a few
sectors, the world gains by having safeguards in a trade
agreement, even when they are not actually used.
A paper by Ethier (2002) formalizes this basic idea.
His central concern is to analyze a trading system like
the GATT/WTO, which is characterized by the general
practice of negotiating tariff reductions to benefit all
members and the occasional use of temporary unilateral

50

tariff increases through safeguards or antidumping
duties. He develops a model in which countries grow
at different rates. The key insight is that when coun­
tries negotiate tariff reductions, they do not know if
their growth will be fast or slow. In a trade agreement
that does not allow temporary tariff increases, coun­
tries fear their growth will be slow and will negotiate
only small tariff reductions. When safeguards are add­
ed to the trade agreement, countries negotiate large
tariff reductions because they know that if they turn
out to have slow growth, they can temporarily increase
their tariffs.
Klimenko, Ramey, and Watson (2002) arrive at a
similar result by examining the question of why the
WTO’s dispute settlement body (DSB) exists. In their
paper, they show that when countries regularly rene­
gotiate their tariffs, as in the WTO’s trade rounds, a
DSB is necessary for the trade agreement to survive.
A DSB makes it possible for countries to punish each
other for violations. Because countries want to avoid
punishment, they won’t violate the trade agreement
when it includes a DSB. As an extension to their
paper, they also show that if the DSB allows countries
to temporarily raise their tariffs (as is the case with
safeguard measures) in response to some unexpected
change in the economic environment, they will nego­
tiate larger tariff reductions initially.
Although some of the theoretical arguments sug­
gest safeguards help facilitate trade liberalization, other
economists arrive at the opposite conclusion. Staiger
and Tabellini (1987) show that allowing for safeguard
measures could reduce the credibility of a trade agree­
ment. From this perspective, the inclusion of a safe­
guard measure can weaken the overall agreement.
On the other hand, another economic argument
in favor of the inclusion of safeguards is that they act
as a form of insurance against fluctuations in the terms
of trade. Consider a country that imports a good whose
price fluctuates substantially. When prices change,
the economic environment can become so different
that countries want to pull out of a trade agreement
that constrains them to set low tariffs.
Bagwell and Staiger (1990) explore how price
fluctuations affect large players in a trade agreement—
countries or regions like the U.S., the EU, and Japan
with such large markets that their safeguard measures
can significantly alter world prices. They argue that
due to the self-enforcing nature of the trade agreement,
in periods of large import volumes, a safeguard mea­
sure acts as a pressure valve to enable countries to
sustain cooperation by temporarily raising tariffs.
In the absence of a safeguard clause, countries would
not be able to sustain cooperation, and the result

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

would be a costly trade war with high levels of tariff
retaliation. Fischer and Prusa (1999) show that even
small countries, which cannot affect world prices by
imposing a safeguard, can use safeguards to insure
themselves against international price shocks.
To date, empirical research in economics hasn’t
been able to prove or disprove the ideas put forth in
the papers mentioned above. In some ways this is an
impossible task—how can we prove that countries
negotiate lower tariffs when a safeguard is part of a
trade agreement when all the trade agreements in ex­
istence include safeguards?10
Another important area of research argues that
the WTO allows the use of safeguards because of
concern for the interests of importing countries and
their import-competing firms and industries. Safeguards
may exist because the agents that benefit from the
safeguards are politically powerful. Many of these
papers focus on analyzing how the politically power­
ful agent gains from the safeguard. If one country
pursues a policy that benefits itself but harms other
countries, economists want to understand how and
why the policy creates a benefit so that they can de­
velop alternative policies that create the same or a simi­
lar benefit but reduce or eliminate the harm to others.
I examine three arguments for why governments use
safeguards to assist import-competing industries: to
help them catch up to their foreign competitors, to
facilitate their exit from the industry, and to reap the
gains for a politically preferred sector.
Several theoretical papers (Matsuyama, 1990;
Miyagiwa and Ohno, 1995, 1999; and Crowley, 2002)
explore how safeguards benefit import-competing
firms that are technologically behind their foreign com­
petitors. These papers examine the consequences of
using a temporary safeguard to induce domestic firms
to adopt newer, more efficient production technologies.
Economists have long understood that a government
subsidy is better than a tariff for helping a firm adopt
a new technology.11A direct subsidy can achieve the
same result as a safeguard, but because it doesn’t in­
crease the price consumers will face, it is less costly
to society as a whole. Thus, using a safeguard to fa­
cilitate technological improvement is a “second-best”
policy at best.
Matsuyama (1990) and Miyagiwa and Ohno (1995)
provide theoretical support for the WTO’s practice of
setting a strict termination date for safeguard protec­
tion and allowing exporting countries to retaliate against
safeguard measures that extend beyond this limit.
Miyagiwa and Ohno (1995) find that safeguards pro­
vide an incentive for protected firms to innovate quick­
ly only if the cost of the new technology is falling

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

over time and the termination date for safeguard pro­
tection is credibly enforced by foreign retaliation.
Crowley (2002) finds a nondiscriminatory safeguard
tariff can accelerate technology adoption by a domes­
tic import-competing firm, but will slow down tech­
nology adoption by foreign exporting firms. Because
a nondiscriminatory safeguard tariff can delay a for­
eign firm’s adoption of new technology, its worldwide
welfare costs may exceed its benefits.
Unfortunately, the little empirical evidence on
the effect of safeguards on technology adoption is not
very encouraging. A 1982 study by the U.S. govern­
ment’s administrative body that reviews safeguard
petitions, the U.S. International Trade Commission
(USITC), found that most safeguards failed to promote
a positive adjustment to import competition. Rather
than assisting companies in upgrading their facilities,
in most cases safeguards merely slowed an industry’s
inevitable decline. There are some exceptions; HarleyDavidson, a motorcycle producer, received safeguard
protection in 1983 and successfully retooled its plants.
However, successful cases are the exception to the
rule. A review of U.S. safeguard cases since 1974 shows
that some industries seek and receive protection re­
peatedly—for example, stainless alloy tool steel was
granted safeguard protection in 1976 and again in 1983.
Another group of theoretical papers shows how
firms in declining industries can utilize political sup­
port to maintain protection. Hillman (1982), Brainard
and Verdier (1994, 1997), and Magee (2002) all ex­
amine the use of tariff protection to allow a dying in­
dustry to collapse slowly rather than quickly. Because
these papers all assume that there are high costs to
quickly scaling back production, they find that a tem­
porary tariff that can slow an industry’s decline can
improve an importing country’s welfare. However,
this type of policy also slows the reallocation of capi­
tal and labor into other industrial sectors in which they
would be more productive. This loss of productivity
is an indirect welfare cost on the country imposing
the safeguard measure.
In summary, there are a number of potential rea­
sons GATT allows the use of safeguard measures. Most
of these papers do not explore the issue of nondiscrim­
ination. The one paper that does, Crowley (2002),
finds that a safeguard can only benefit the importing
country if the measure is nondiscriminatory.
Antidumping duties
Antidumping duties are a controversial form of
temporary trade protection permitted by GATT. An
antidumping duty is a tariff that an importing country
imposes on imports of a product that have been dumped

51

into its domestic market by some exporting country’s
firm(s). An importing country may only impose an an­
tidumping duty on a product if there is evidence that
foreign firms have sold their products at less than nor­
mal value and this has injured the domestic industry.
Historically, antidumping duties have been dis­
tinguished from other forms of administered protection
by the trade problem they were used to remedy Anti­
dumping duties were a government’s remedy for “unfair”
trade and were intended to offset the price undercut­
ting of foreign exporters engaged in anticompetitive
practices. In the early twentieth century, the U.S. in­
stituted an antidumping law to protect its domestic
firms from German cartels that sold their excess out­
put at low prices in the U.S. market. Although low
prices for imported goods improve the well-being of
a country and should be welcomed by the government,
in some cases they could present a problem. If a for­
eign firm is engaging in predatory pricing—setting
prices low in order to drive competitors out of busi­
ness—this could lower the welfare of a country in
the long run. This can happen if the foreign firm be­
comes a monopolist and uses its monopoly power to
charge consumers extremely high prices. GATT’s Anti­
dumping Code allows countries to violate the nondis­
crimination rule and impose an additional tariff—an
antidumping duty—on imports from a firm that is
dumping. Thus, one could view GATT’s antidumping
rules as an effort to improve worldwide welfare by
preventing the harmful practice of predatory pricing.
However, although most economists would agree
that an anticompetitive practice like predatory pricing
is harmful, there is almost no evidence of this type of
practice in alleged incidences of dumping.
Rather, in almost all modern cases of dumping,
foreign firms are either engaging in international price
discrimination or temporarily pricing below their av­
erage cost of production. In fact, GATT now defines
dumping as either international price discrimination—
that is, charging different prices for a good in differ­
ent countries because demand for the good is different
in the different countries—or as pricing below the
average cost of production. Prior to the Uruguay Round
reforms, antidumping duties had no effective time
limit. Once an antidumping duty was put in place, it
could remain in place for years. Today, antidumping
duties are subject to “sunset reviews” every five years.
During a sunset review, a duty is removed unless
there is evidence that the targeted country continues
to dump and this dumping is hurting domestic firms
in the importing country.
One peculiarity of GATT’s Antidumping Code is
that it encourages the use ofprice undertakings in

52

place of an antidumping duty. Economists view price
undertakings with suspicion because they look a lot
like government-sanctioned collusive pricing. Because
collusive pricing—a practice in which several firms
agree to simultaneously raise prices and keep them
high—hurts consumers, it is surprising that GATT
would encourage this type of practice. It is hard to
justify on economic welfare grounds.
Although the rhetoric that surrounds the use of
antidumping duties focuses on whether foreign firms
are behaving “fairly,” the important question is not
whether dumping is fair but whether dumping is harm­
ful. Thus, to understand how antidumping policy af­
fects the world trading system, economists first ask
why firms engage in practices like pricing below the
average cost of production.
With antidumping investigations into goods as
varied as fresh-cut flowers, semiconductors, and count­
less varieties of steel, economists have tried to ex­
plain the phenomenon of dumping and the government’s
policy response in terms of the different modes of
competition in the markets for dumped goods.
Several papers explain dumping in the context of
competitive markets. These papers focus on explaining
why competitive firms dump. In Ethier (1982), com­
petitive firms with implicit labor contracts will dump
during periods of slack world demand. Essentially,
these firms have high fixed costs that lead them to
price below their average total cost when demand is
weak. Staiger and Wolak (1992) show that a foreign
monopolist that faces weak demand in its own market
will dump into a perfectly competitive domestic mar­
ket. In this model, a foreign firm with excess capaci­
ty will sell at a price below average total cost in its
export market in order to protect its monopoly profits
in its own market. Unfortunately, neither Ethier’s pa­
per nor Staiger and Wolak’s explains how antidump­
ing policy affects the welfare of the importing country.
However, another paper that examines dumping in
competitive markets, Clarida (1993), finds that anti­
dumping policy reduces an importing country’s wel­
fare. In this model, competitive firms dump, that is,
sell below average cost, as they learn about their own
production technologies during a period of high world
demand. The importing country benefits when import
prices are low, so the introduction of an antidumping
policy that raises prices leaves the country worse off.
In summary, the research on dumping in competitive
markets suggests that antidumping policy is harmful
and cannot provide an economic rationale for its
existence.
The literature on dumping in imperfectly competi­
tive markets is somewhat more successful in providing

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

a rationale for why GATT includes an antidumping
provision. Markets where there are a small number
of large producers—like automobiles—are said to be
imperfectly competitive.
Dixit’s (1988) seminal paper on dumping in an
imperfectly competitive market shows that, in general,
when dumping is defined as international price dis­
crimination, it actually benefits the importing country.
More specifically, the benefits to consumers of being
able to buy goods at low, dumped prices outweigh the
losses to domestic producers. Thus, as a general rule,
antidumping policy reduces the welfare of importing
countries when markets are imperfectly competitive.
However, two papers, Gruenspecht (1988) and
Crowley (2002) utilize an alternative definition of
dumping—pricing below the average cost of produc­
tion—and find that this kind of dumping can hurt an
importing country. Thus, antidumping duties can help.
These papers provide one explanation for why GATT
allows antidumping duties.
Gruenspecht (1988) focuses on dumping by firms
in industries with steep learning-by-doing curves in pro­
duction. That is, he models industries like semicon­
ductors where production costs fall as a firm’s experience
in making the product increases. He shows that an
importing country benefits from an antidumping law.
In his model, antidumping duties can improve the
welfare of a large importing country by increasing
the size of the market available to sales by the home
firm. Higher production yields greater productivity
gains that improve the home country’s welfare.
Crowley (2002) focuses on industries in which
firms must pay large sunk costs to install capacity, for
example, an industry like steel. She shows that when
demand for the good fluctuates, foreign firms will
dump their output when demand in their own market
is weak. In response to this, the importing country
can improve its welfare by imposing a temporary an­
tidumping duty until demand in the foreign country
returns to a normal level. In this case, the antidumping
duty shifts some of the foreign firm’s profits back to
the home country.
Finally, the paper by Fischer and Prusa (1999)
that I discussed earlier in the context of safeguards also
provides a rationale for antidumping law. A small coun­
try that faces international price fluctuations can use
an antidumping duty as a form of insurance against
harmful movements in its terms of trade.
In summary, regardless of the degree of competi­
tion in a market, it is hard to rationalize the inclusion
of antidumping rules in GATT on economic welfare
grounds.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Countervailing duties
Countervailing duties, tariffs used to offset the
effect of a foreign government’s subsidy, are similar
to antidumping duties. Because a foreign government’s
subsidy to an export good lowers its price in the im­
porting country, in most cases a foreign subsidy ben­
efits consumers in an importing country. Thus, in
most cases, there is no economic welfare rationale
for a countervailing duty policy within GATT.
However, in markets that are imperfectly com­
petitive, a foreign government’s subsidy can reduce the
welfare of an importing country. In this case, although
consumers in the importing country benefit from the
subsidy, the losses to firms in the importing country
outweigh the benefits to consumers. Dixit (1988),
Spencer (1988), and Collie (1991) all show that in
this case, a countervailing duty can prevent the for­
eign government’s subsidization of its export good
and improve the welfare of the importing country.
In summary, although countervailing duties are
likely to lower an importing country’s welfare when
markets are competitive, it is theoretically possible
for them to improve an importing country’s welfare
when markets are imperfectly competitive.

Dispute resolution in the WTO
Having reviewed the various exceptions to GATT’s
nondiscrimination rule, I now turn to the issue of dis­
putes. What happens when a dispute arises between
countries over a GATT rule? What power does GATT
have to settle disputes? How does GATT enforce its
own rules?
GATT is a multilateral trade agreement with the
authority to regulate the trade regulations of its mem­
ber governments. As an international treaty, it has no
authority over individuals, private firms, or public cor­
porations. Rather, it governs the interactions of coun­
tries that voluntarily agree to abide by its rules.
The WTO mediates and settles disputes among
its members. Disputes that cannot be resolved among
the members themselves are referred to a panel of three
persons who act as judges. When a country is found
to be in violation of its GATT obligations, it has three
choices. It can appeal and have the case retried before
an appellate body, it can amend its laws to bring them
in line with GATT, or it can keep its laws as they are
and face “measured retaliation” from its aggrieved trad­
ing partners. If a country loses an appeal, its options
revert to amending its laws or facing retaliation.
Measured retaliation is the WTO’s main enforcement
mechanism. In the simplest case, if one country were
to violate its GATT obligations by raising its tariff on
some good and this tariff increase caused the volume

53

of imports from a second country to fall, the WTO
could authorize the second country to punish the first
by raising its own tariff on something. This retaliation
by the second country is “measured,” in the sense that
it should reduce trade from the offending first country
by roughly the same value as the first country’s tariff
increase.
The practice of measured retaliation is extremely
useful in maintaining the smooth functioning of the
world trading system. Historically, when one party to
a treaty violated one of its terms, the other party could
either accept the violation or withdraw for the treaty
entirely. Measured retaliation essentially allows both
parties to jointly withdraw from some of their treaty
obligations while still enjoying the benefits of the rest
of the treaty.
In fact, while the recent increase in disputes among
WTO members may, on the surface, appear troubling,
it could also signal the effectiveness of the dispute
resolution system. It could be that countries that have
grievances against their trading partners find the dis­
pute settlement system sufficiently effective that they
present their disputes to this body rather than seeking
some type of resolution outside the WTO.

Conclusion
This article has provided a brief history of the
WTO and has suggested that the success of the GATT
and WTO system can be attributed to the founding
principles of reciprocity and nondiscrimination. I have
also reviewed the numerous exceptions to GATT’s
principle of nondiscrimination. Although the various

exceptions may yield benefits, theoretical and empir­
ical research in economics questions whether the ben­
efits of these exceptions are sufficiently large to outweigh
the costs.
The WTO is currently engaged in a new round
of trade negotiations—the Doha Round. This article’s
review of the economics literature suggests that it
may be time to rethink GATT’s rules for administered
protection. The proliferation of antidumping duties is
costly to both consumers and many exporters. Many
countries that belong to the WTO would like to make
it more difficult for countries to impose antidumping
duties. However, because antidumping protection is
popular among import-competing firms in both the
U.S. and the EU, it will be politically difficult to
achieve meaningful reform of GATT’s antidumping
rules. There may be more support for modest chang­
es to the Agreement on Safeguards. For example, the
discriminatory application of safeguards has been an
issue in many WTO disputes. Negotiators to the Doha
Round could potentially preempt future disputes over
safeguards by closing some loopholes and clarifying
the language in the safeguard agreement.
Perhaps the largest gains that could be achieved
in the current negotiating round might come from
liberalizing trade in agricultural commodities. Devel­
oping countries, many of which have a comparative
advantage in agricultural production, would like to
see developed countries’ agricultural markets open
up through both tariff and subsidy reductions. The
liberalization of trade in agriculture has the potential
to generate huge welfare gains for the entire world.

NOTES
’See the WTO webpage at www.wto.org.

8This section draws heavily upon Bown and Crowley (2003a).

2Jackson (1997) and Hoekman and Kostecki (1995) provide good
histories of the post-WWII world trading system.

9See WTO (2003).

3For definitions of all terms in italics, see the appendix on p. 55.

4Under the GATT treaty of 1947, GATT members were technically
known as “contracting parties.”
5Hoekman and Kostecki (1995), p. 20.
6This article has emphasized the importance of reciprocity in
trade negotiations. However, large countries could engage in
trade negotiations for reasons not considered here.

10A related paper is the recent empirical contribution by Staiger
and Tabellini (1999), who compare two different policy environ­
ments to investigate the question of whether GATT rules help
governments make trade policy commitments. They find evidence
to support the claim that GATT rules do give governments com­
mitment power. However, their work also provides support for the
theory that the inclusion of an escape clause can have damaging
effects that erode a government’s ability to commit to liberalization.
nDixit and Norman (1980), Caves, Frankel, and Jones (2002),
and Krugman and Obstfeld (2000) are a few standard textbooks
that make this point.

7GATT also permits the use of tariffs to assist with balance of
payments problems in developing countries with fixed exchange
rates. The balance of payments exception is relatively
uncontroversial and I do not discuss it here.

54

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

APPENDIX: GLOSSARY OF TRADE TERMS
Administered protection '. Special tariffs, quotas, or other restrictions on imports that are allowed under GATT. The
treaty allows the various forms of administered protection for a variety of reasons, including to enable a country to
address specific domestic concerns and to promote macroeconomic stability. Policymakers often refer to adminis­
tered protection as trade remedies.

Antidumping duty'. A tariff used to raise the price of a dumped product.

Beggar-thy-neighbor tariff'. A tariff, imposed by a large country, that causes the world price of a good to fall.
This fall in the world price benefits importing countries and hurts exporting countries.
Bilateral opportunism'. The practice by which one country, after negotiating a bilateral trade agreement with
a second country, goes on to negotiate a bilateral trade agreement with a third country that undercuts the benefits
that the second country expected to receive under its agreement.
Countervailing duties'. Tariffs used to offset the advantage foreign exporters have over domestic producers in
cases in which foreign exporters receive subsidies from their governments.
Dumping'. Selling a product in an export market at a price below its “normal value.” GATT defines normal value
as the price a good sells for in its home market or a third country’s market, or as the average cost of its production.

Measured retaliation '. A mechanism to enforce the WTO rules. If one country violates a WTO rule and the
violation reduces trade from a second WTO member country, the WTO may authorize the second country to
punish the first country by allowing the second country to violate a WTO rule (for example, by raising a tariff).
This punishment should reduce trade from the offending first country by roughly the same amount as the trade
reduction caused by the original violation.

Negotiating round'. A meeting of GATT/WTO members at which members negotiate reductions in tariffs
and/or changes to GATT/WTO trading rules.

Nondiscrimination'. The policy of treating all of one’s trading partners equally. A country is practicing nondiscrimi­
nation if it charges the same tariff on imports of a product (for example, 5 percent on shoes) without regard to where
the product is made.
Price undertaking'. An agreement whereby a foreign firm accused of dumping agrees to raise its price. If the price
increase is large enough, the importing country agrees not to impose an antidumping duty.

Regional trade agreement'. An agreement among two or more countries in which the tariffs they impose on one
another’s goods are lower than the tariffs they impose on goods from other countries. These agreements are also
known as preferential trade agreements.
Safeguards'. Temporary tariffs, quotas, or tariff-rate quotas that protect an industry from fair foreign
competition.

Tariffpreference'. The difference between a country’s nondiscriminatory tariff and the tariff applied to imports
from a particular country due to participation in a regional trade agreement or application of a special tariff like
an antidumping duty.

Terms of trade'. The price of a country’s exports divided by the price of its imports. An increase or improvement
in the terms of trade raises a country’s welfare.

Voluntary export restraint'. An agreement whereby an exporting country reduces its exports to some importing
country. VERs are also known as orderly marketing agreements (OMAs), voluntary restraint agreements (VRAs),
and export restraint agreements (ERAs), among other terms.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

55

REFERENCES
Bagwell, Kyle, and Robert W. Staiger, 2003, “Mul­
tilateral trade negotiations, bilateral opportunism, and
the rules of GATT/WTO,” Journal ofInternational
Economics.
__________ , 2001, “Reciprocity, non-discrimination,
and preferential agreements in the multilateral trad­
ing system,” European Journal ofPolitical Economy.
__________ , 1999, “An economic theory of GATT,”
American Economic Review, Vol. 89, pp. 215-248.
__________ , 1997a, “Multilateral tariff cooperation
during the formation of free trade areas,” International
Economic Review, Vol. 38, pp. 291-319.
__________ , 1997b, “Multilateral tariff cooperation
during the formation of customs unions,” Journal of
International Economics, Vol. 42, pp. 91-123.
__________ , 1990, “A theory of managed trade,”
American Economic Review, Noi. 80, pp. 779-795.

Baldwin, Robert E., 1985, The Political Economy
of U.S. Import Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Bhagwati, Jagdish, 1992, “Regionalism versus mul­
tilateralism,” The World Economy, Vol. 15, pp. 535-555.
Bond, Eric W., and Constantinos Syropolous,
1996, “The size of trading blocs: Market power and
world welfare effects,” Journal ofInternational
Economics, Vol. 40, pp. 411-437.

Bown, Chad P., and Meredith A. Crowley, 2003 a,
“Safeguards in the WTO,” in The Kluwer Compan­
ion to the World Trade Organization, A. Appleton,
P. Macrory, and M. Plummer (eds.), Dordrecht:
Kluwer Academic, forthcoming.
__________ , 2003 b, “Trade deflection and trade
depression,” manuscript, August.

Brainard, S. Lael, and Thierry Verdier, 1997, “The
political economy of declining industries: Senescent
industry collapse revisited,” Journal ofInternational
Economics, Vol. 42, pp. 221-237.
__________ , 1994, “Lobbying and adjustment in
declining industries,” European Economic Review,
Vol. 38, pp. 586-595.

56

Caves, Richard E., Jeffrey A. Frankel, and Ronald
W. Jones, 2002, World Trade and Payments: an In­
troduction, (ninth edition), Boston: Addison-Wesley.
Clarida, Richard H., 1993, “Entry, dumping, and
shakeout,” American Economic Review, Vol. 83,
pp. 180-202.

Clausing, Kimberly A., 2001, “Trade creation and
trade diversion in the Canada-United States Free
Trade Agreement,” Canadian Journal ofEconomics,
Vol. 34, pp. 677-696.
Collie, David, 1991, “Export subsidies and counter­
vailing duties,” Journal ofInternational Economics,
Vol. 31, pp. 309-324.
Crowley, Meredith A., 2002, “Do antidumping duties
and safeguard tariffs open or close technology gaps?,”
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, working paper,
No. WP-2002-13, July.
__________ , 2001, “Antidumping policy under im­
perfect competition: Theory and evidence,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago, working paper, No. WP2001-21, December.
Dixit, Avinash, 1988, “Anti-dumping and counter­
vailing duties under oligopoly,” European Economic
Review, Vol. 32, pp. 55-68.
Dixit, A. K., and V. Norman, 1980, Theory’ ofInter­
national Trade, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Univer­
sity Press.

Ethier, Wilfred J., 2002, “Unilateralism in a multilat­
eral world,” Economic Journal, Vol. 112, pp. 266-292.
__________ , 1998, “Regionalism in a multilateral
world,” Journal ofPolitical Economy, Vol. 106,
pp. 1214-1245.
__________ , 1982, “Dumping,” Journal ofPolitical
Economy, Vol. 90, pp. 487-506.
Fischer, Ronald D., and Thomas J. Prusa, 1999,
“Contingent protection as better insurance,” National
Bureau of Economic Research, working paper, No. 6933.

Freund, Caroline, 2000, “Different paths to free trade:
The gains from regionalism,” Quarterly Journal of
Economics, pp. 1317-1341.

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives

Gruenspecht, Howard K., 1988, “Dumping and dy­
namic competition,” Journal ofInternational Eco­
nomics, Vol. 25, pp. 225-248.

Prusa, Thomas J., 2001, “On the spread and impact
of anti-dumping,” Canadian Journal ofEconomics,
Vol. 34, pp. 591-611.

Hansen, Wendy L., 1990, “The international trade
commission and the politics of protection,” American
Political Science Review, Vol. 84, pp. 21-46.

Romalis, John, 2002, “NAFTA’s and CUSFTA’s im­
pact on North American trade,” University of Chica­
go, Graduate School of Business, mimeo, July.

Hillman, Arye, 1982, “Declining industries and po­
litical-support protectionist motives,” American Eco­
nomic Review, Vol. 72, pp. 1180-1187.

Sampson, Gary P., 1996, “Compatibility of regional
and multilateral trading agreements: Reforming the
WTO process,” American Economic Review, Vol. 86,
pp. 88-92.

Hoekman, Bernard, and Michel Kostecki, 1995,
The Political Economy of the World Trading System,
Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Jackson, John H., 1997, The World Trading System:
Law and Policy ofInternational Economic Relations,
(second edition), Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Klimenko, Mikhail, Garey Ramey, and Joel Wat­
son, 2002, “Recurrent trade agreements and the val­
ue of external enforcement,” University of
California, San Diego, mimeo.
Krugman, Paul R., and Maurice Obstfeld, 2000,
International Economics: Theory’ and Policy (fifth
edition), Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.

Levy, Philip, 1997, “Apolitical-economic analysis
of free-trade agreements,” American Economic Re­
view, Vol. 87, pp. 506-519.
Magee, Chris, 2002, “Declining industries and per­
sistent protection,” Review ofInternational Econom­
ics, Vol. 10.

Spencer, Barbara J., 1988, “Capital subsidies and
countervailing duties in oligopolistic industries,”
Journal ofInternational Economics, Vol. 25, pp. 45-69.

Staiger, Robert, and Guido Tabellini, 1999, “Do
GATT rules help governments make domestic com­
mitments?,” Economics and Politics, Vol. 11, pp.
109-144.

__________ , 1987, “Discretionary trade policy and
excessive protection,” American Economic Review,
Vol. 77, pp. 823-837.
Staiger, Robert, and Frank Wolak, 1992, “The ef­
fect of domestic antidumping law in the presence of
foreign monopoly,” Journal ofInternational Eco­
nomics, Vol. 32, pp. 265-287.

United States International Trade Commission,
1982, “The effectiveness of escape clause relief in
promoting adjustment to import competition,”
USITC publication, No. 1229, investigation, No.
332-115, March.

Matsuyama, Kiminori, 1990, “Perfect equilibria in
a trade liberalization game,” American Economic Re­
view, Vol. 80, pp. 480-492.

Viner, Jacob, 1950, The Customs Union Issue, New
York: Carnegie Endowment.

McLaren, John E., 2002, “A theory of insidious re­
gionalism,” Quarterly Journal ofEconomics, Vol.
117, pp. 571-608.

World Trade Organization (WTO), 2003, “United
States—Definitive safeguard measures on imports of
certain steel products: Final reports of the panel,”
Geneva, July 11.

Miyagiwa, Kaz, and Yuka Ohno, 1999, “Credibili­
ty of protection and incentives to innovate,” Interna­
tional Economic Review, Vol. 40, pp. 143-163.

__________ , 2001, International Trade Statistics,
Geneva: WTO.

__________ , 1995, “Closing the technology gap un­
der protection,” American Economic Review, Vol. 85,
pp. 755-770.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

__________ , 1995a, Analytical Index: Guide to
GATT Law and Practice, Vol. 2, Geneva: WTO.
__________ , 1995b, Uruguay Round Agreement Es­
tablishing the World Trade Organization, Geneva:
WTO.

57

Index for 2003
Title & author

Issue

Pages

BANKING, CREDIT, AND FINANCE
Bankruptcy law and large complex financial organizations: A primer
Robert R. Bliss

First Quarter

48-58

Early warning models for bank supervision:
Simpler could be better
Julapa Jagtiani, James Kolari, Catharine Lemieux, and Hwan Shin

Third Quarter

49-60

ECONOMIC CONDITIONS
Economic perspective on the political history of the Second Bank
of the United States
Edward J. Green

First Quarter

59-67

Temporary help services and the volatility of industry output
Yukako Ono and Alexei Zelenev

Second Quarter

15-28

Vacation laws and annual work hours
Joseph G. Altonji and Jennifer Oldham

Third Quarter

19-29

Economic perspectives on childhood obesity
Patricia M. Anderson, Kristin F. Butcher, and Phillip B. Levine

Third Quarter

30-48

Family resources and college enrollment
Bhashkar Mazumder

Fourth Quarter

30-41

INTERNATIONAL ISSUES
Banking relationships during financial distress:
The evidence from Japan
Elijah Brewer III, Hesna Genay, and George G. Kaufman

Third Quarter

2-18

An introduction to the WTO and GATT
Meredith A. Crowley

Fourth Quarter

42-57

REGIONAL ISSUES
Employment subcenters in Chicago: Past, present, and future
Daniel P. McMillen

Second Quarter

2-14

Estimating U.S. metropolitan area export and import competition
William Testa, Thomas Klier, and Alexei Zelenev

Fourth Quarter

13-27

MONEY AND MONETARY POLICY
An evaluation of real GDP forecasts: 1996-2001
Spencer Krane

First Quarter

2-21

Inflation and monetary policy in the twentieth century
Lawrence J. Christiano and Terry J. Fitzgerald

First Quarter

22-45

The optimal price of money
Pedro Teles

Second Quarter

29-39

Testing the Calvo model of sticky prices
Martin Eichenbaum and Jonas D. M. Fisher

Second Quarter

40-53

Decimalization and market liquidity
Craig H. Furfine

Fourth Quarter

2-12

To order copies of any of these issues, or to receive a list of other publications, please telephone (312)322-5111 or
write to: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Public Information Center, P.O. Box 834, Chicago, IL 60690-0834. The
articles are also available to download in PDF format from the Bank’s website at www.chicagofed.org/publications/
economicperspectives/index.cfm.

58

4Q/2003, Economic Perspectives