View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

2
2018
https://doi.org/10.21033/ep-2018-2

A monetarist view of the Fed’s
balance sheet normalization period
Marcelo Veracierto
Introduction and summary

1

The Federal Reserve currently holds over $4 trillion in fixed-income assets. However, since the fall of 2017
the Fed has been in a “balance sheet normalization period,” during which the size of its balance sheet is
gradually shrinking over time. In particular, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) has been instructing
the Federal Reserve trading desk to reduce its security holdings by reinvesting principal payments only to
the extent that these payments exceed gradually raising caps. These caps on redemptions will be maintained
until the Fed considers that its balance sheet has reached a desirable size.
At the same time, the Fed is implementing its target short-term interest rate by paying interest rates on reserves
to depository institutions. It supplements this tool by offering overnight reverse repurchase agreement
operations (ON RRP) to eligible financial institutions. By “encouraging competition, these instruments
support interest rate control by setting a floor on rates, beneath which financial institutions with access to
these facilities should be unwilling to lend funds” (Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 2018).
Given this monetary policy framework of administered interest rates, the Fed’s income statement may
receive some pressure as interest rates increase during the normalization period. Moreover, as the size of
the balance sheet decreases, the Fed’s interest income will shrink over time. A counterbalancing effect is
that during the balance sheet normalization period, the stock of reserves will decrease as well, reducing
the base over which interest is paid to depository institutions.
The Federal Reserve Bank of New York, which conducts open market operations on behalf of the FOMC,
regularly provides projections for the System Open Market Account (SOMA) portfolio and net income. In
all of its most recent reports (for example, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 2016, 2017, 2018), the New
York Fed has concluded that, under a variety of scenarios, the Fed’s remittances to the U.S. Department of
the Treasury will remain positive during the balance sheet normalization period, avoiding the need to enter a
deferred asset in its accounts.1 However, these calculations depend on how quickly reserves decrease over

Economic Perspectives

2 / 2018

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

time, which is closely tied to the rate of growth of currency in circulation. A key assumption that the New
York Fed has regularly made in its previous projections is that currency will grow at the same rate as nominal
gross domestic product (GDP).2 However, as interest rates increase, the demand for real cash balances will
decrease over time. As a consequence, currency may grow at a slower pace than nominal GDP and reserves
may decrease during the normalization period at a slower pace than previously estimated by the New York
Fed. If reserves remain at higher levels than estimated, interest payments on reserves will be higher and
the Fed’s net income will be lower than expected. In this article, I use estimates of money demand to redo
the SOMA projections and evaluate whether remittances to the Treasury could be severely affected by a
shrinking demand for real cash balances.
The first part of the article sketches the methodology previously used by the New York Fed and reviews the
SOMA calculations. The second part of the article expands those projections by incorporating empirical
evidence on the demand for money. However, the same basic result is still obtained: No red flags are raised in
terms of Treasury remittances.
The last part of the article is concerned with the money multiplier, which is given by the ratio of some
broad definition of money (such as M1, that is, the sum of currency in circulation, checking accounts,
demand deposits, and negotiable order of withdrawal [NOW] accounts) to the monetary base (that is, the
sum of currency in circulation and reserves).3 A potentially troubling result with the benchmark projections reported in this article is that they involve a striking doubling of the money multiplier over a period
of three years. However, I argue that this should pose no difficulties since, as a first approximation, when
the Fed pays interest on reserves, the size of its balance sheet becomes irrelevant for economic outcomes
while the Fed gains full control of the money multiplier.

The Fed’s budget constraint

2

For simplicity I assume that the type of asset that the Fed owns is a bond of stochastic maturity that pays a
coupon rate k every period while maturity has not been reached. The per-period probability that the bond
matures is 1 − λ. The Fed’s budget constraint is then the following:
1) τ t + itR Rt −1 + qt ( Dt − λDt −1 ) = ∆Rt + ∆ t Ct + k λDt −1 + (1 − λ ) Dt −1 ,
where τ t are remittances to the Treasury, Ct is currency in circulation, Rt are reserves, itR is the interest
rate on reserves, Dt is the stochastic maturity bond, qt is the price of the bond, and ∆xt = xt − xt −1 .
This stylized budget constraint is used to perform projections during the balance sheet normalization
period. My first task is to review published SOMA projections. It happens to be the case that the latest
New York Fed report that provides SOMA projections (Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 2018) does
not provide enough detailed data for evaluating the extensions explored in this article (in particular, it
does not report estimated SOMA interest expenses or interest income). An earlier report that provides
such detailed data is Ferris, Kim, and Schlusche (2017). An apparent limitation of their analysis is that it
considers a view of the balance sheet normalization period that is much simpler than the one that was later
implemented. However, I view this as an advantage. The reason is that the introduction of gradually rising
caps over which principal payments are reinvested complicates the analysis and is not central to the main
focus of this article, which is how sensitive the SOMA projections are to incorporating an explicit demand
for money. For this reason, I adopt the simpler scenario in Ferris, Kim, and Schlusche as my benchmark
and refer to it as the “FKS scenario” for the rest of the article. I describe this scenario next.

Economic Perspectives

2 / 2018

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

The FKS scenario assumes that during the normalization period, the Fed pays interest on reserves and
stops reinvesting in bonds when they mature. That is, it assumes that
2) itR > 0, and
3) Dt − λDt −1 = 0.
Thus, under the normalization period, the budget constraint of the Fed effectively becomes
4) τ t + itR Rt −1 = ∆Rt + ∆Ct + k λ t D0 + (1 − λ ) λ t −1 D0 .
Under current practice, the Fed remits to the Treasury all of its net income on a period-by-period basis.
That is,
5) τ t = k λDt −1 − itR Rt −1 .
From equation 4, it then follows that
6) ∆Rt + ∆Ct = Dt − Dt −1 = − (1 − λ ) Dt −1 ,
that is, current contractions in bond holdings determine current contractions in the monetary base.
Once reserves reach $100 billion, the FKS scenario assumes that the Fed resumes asset purchases to
support normal balance sheet growth. However, since the analysis that follows will focus on the period
before that threshold would be reached, I use equation 4 throughout the rest of the article. Also, consistent
with the FKS scenario, I assume the normalization period would have started in mid-2018.

3

FKS projections
Estimating the size of the balance sheet during the normalization period (as well as SOMA interest income)
is far from trivial since it depends on the expected path of interest rates, which affects the pace at which
agency holdings of mortgage-backed securities (MBS) pay down. Fortunately, FKS have already performed
that calculation. The path for interest rates that they use is based on the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s
September 2016 Survey of Primary Dealers and is reported in figure 1. We see that starting from 0.8 percent
in 2017, the fed funds rate is assumed to increase gradually, reaching 2.9 percent by 2021. The associated
path for SOMA holdings that FKS estimate is reported in figure 2. We see that SOMA holdings decline
slightly in 2018, when FKS assume that the balance sheet normalization period starts, and then quite abruptly
through 2022 (after which the Fed resumes asset purchases to support normal balance sheet growth).
Given data for currency in circulation in 2016 and expected paths for inflation and GDP growth, a path for
currency in circulation between 2017 and 2022 is then constructed assuming that
7)

∆Ct ∆ ( PY
t t)
=
,
Ct
PY
t t

that is, that currency in circulation grows at the same rate as nominal GDP. The paths used for expected
inflation and GDP growth rates are taken from the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s September 2016

Economic Perspectives

2 / 2018

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

FIGURE 1

FIGURE 2

Fed funds rate

SOMA holdings

percent

$ billions

3.50

4,500

3.00

4,000
3,500

2.50

3,000

2.00

2,500
2,000

1.50

1,500

1.00

1,000
0.50

500

0.00
2017

’
’18

’19

’20

’21

’22

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 2016,
Survey of Primary Dealers, September.

2017

’19

’20

’21

’22

Source: Ferris, Kim, and Schlusche (2017).
			

FIGURE 4

Nominal GDP growth rate

Currency in circulation

percent

$ billions

4.2

2,000

4.2

1,800

4.1

1,600

4.1

1,400
1,200
1,000

4.0

800

3.9

600

3.9

400

3.8
3.8

’18

FIGURE 3

4.0

4

0

200
2017

’18

’19

’20

’21

’22

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 2016,
Survey of Primary Dealers, September.

0
2017

’18

’19

’20

’21

’22

			
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 2016,
Survey of Primary Dealers, September.

Survey of Primary Dealers and are reported in figure 3. Given the resulting path for Ct (shown in figure 4)
and for SOMA holdings Dt (shown in figure 2), a path for reserves Rt can then be obtained from equation 6.
The path for reserve balances calculated by FKS is reported in figure 5. We see that reserves drop continuously
over time, hitting the $100 billion threshold by 2022 (which triggers the resumption of asset purchases).
Figure 6 shows the path for SOMA interest expenses reported by FKS. We see that these interest expenses
increase sharply, reaching a peak of $50 billion before falling to $15 billion by 2022. The basic reason why
interest expenses remain relatively low even as interest rates increase is that reserves decline sharply over
time (see figure 5). Given the SOMA interest income estimated by FKS and reported in figure 7, we obtain
SOMA net income from equation 5. The resulting path is shown in figure 8. We see that SOMA net income
decreases to $50.5 billion by 2020 but then bounces back. As a consequence, remittances to the Treasury
remain positive, and equation 5 remains valid (that is, the Fed is not forced to book a deferred asset).

Economic Perspectives

2 / 2018

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

FIGURE 5

FIGURE 6

Reserves

SOMA interest expenses
$ billions

$ billions

60
			

3,000
2,500

50

2,000

40

1,500

30
20

1,000

10

500

0

0
2017

’18

’19

’20

’21

2017

’22

’18

’19

’20

’21

’22

Source: Ferris, Kim, and Schlusche (2017).

Source: Ferris, Kim, and Schlusche (2017).

			
FIGURE 8

FIGURE 7

SOMA interest income

SOMA net income

$ billions

$ billions

140

90

120

80
70

100

5

60

80

50

60

40
30

40

20

20
0

10
0
2017

’18

’19

’20

’21

Source: Ferris, Kim, and Schlusche (2017).

’22

2017

’18

’19

’20

’21

’22

Source: Author’s calculations based on data from
Ferris, Kim, and Schlusche (2017).

Before proceeding to the next section, I need to obtain two important pieces of information from the FKS
projections. Since in my simplified Federal Reserve budget constraint (equation 4) I impute all SOMA
interest expenses to interest on reserves, I calculate the effective interest rate on reserves as follows:
8) itR =

SOMA interest expenses at date t
,
Rt −1

where both denominator and numerator are obtained from the SOMA projections reported in figures 5
and 6, respectively. The resulting path for itR , which is reported in figure 9, is only slightly higher than
the path for the federal funds rate in figure 1.

Economic Perspectives

2 / 2018

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

FIGURE 9

FIGURE 10

Implicit interest rate on reserves

Monetary base

percent

$ billions

4,500
			

3.50

4,000

3.00

3,500

2.50

3,000

2.00

2,500

1.50

2,000

1.00

1,500
1,000

0.50

500

0.00
2017

’18

’19

’20

’21

’22

Source: Author’s calculations based on data from
Ferris, Kim, and Schlusche (2017).

0

2017

’18

’19

’20

’21

’22

Sources: Author’s calculations based on data from
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 2016, Survey
of Primary Dealers, September; and Ferris, Kim,
and Schlusche (2017).

Another piece of information that will be extremely useful is the implied path for the monetary base,
which is constructed as
9) Bt = Ct + Rt ,
where Ct and Rt are the currency in circulation and reserve balances reported in figures 4 and 5, respectively.
The resulting path for the monetary base is reported in figure 10.

6

A monetarist approach
Given a fixed balance sheet path, any change in currency has to be offset by an equal and opposite signed
change in reserves. This change in reserves in turn affects the total amount of interest payments on reserves
and therefore the remittances to the Treasury. The previous section assumed that during the normalization
period, currency grows at the same rate as nominal GDP. However, standard demand for money theory
suggests that as interest rates increase, the demand for currency may grow at a much lower rate than nominal
GDP or even shrink. As a consequence, reserves would not be able to contract as fast as previously calculated,
and therefore interest expenses would be larger and remittances to the Treasury lower than the benchmark
FKS calculations indicate. In order to address these concerns, in this section I redo the above calculations
by imposing that currency growth must be consistent with a demand function for currency.
Lucas and Nicolini (2015) provide empirical evidence for the demand for currency during the 1915–2012
period. In particular, figure A1 in the appendix (which reproduces figure 2b from their paper) plots the inverse
of the velocity of circulation of currency versus the three-month Treasury bill at an annual frequency.
Given the stable demand function that this figure indicates, I postulate the following functional form for
the demand for currency:
10)

Ct
−α
= Ac (it + φc ) c .
PY
t t

Economic Perspectives

2 / 2018

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

I then choose the parameters Ac , φc , and α c to fit the following three representative points of figure A1:

i
0.0
0.05
0.135

C
PY
0.09
0.045
0.04.

The required values for Ac , φc , and α c are 0.0316, 0.0002, and 0.1186, respectively, which imply an
approximately constant interest rate elasticity of about –12 percent. Equipped with this demand function
for currency, I turn to redoing the calculations of the previous section. The conditioning assumptions remain
the same. In particular, the path for interest rates, SOMA holdings, SOMA interest income, and monetary
base are left unchanged. The rationale for leaving SOMA holdings and SOMA interest income the same is
that they are determined by the initial SOMA portfolio, the reinvestment decisions of the Fed during the
normalization period, and the path for interest rates, and these are all unchanged across experiments. In
turn, the path for the monetary base is left unchanged because, during the normalization period, it is strictly
determined by the path of SOMA holdings and this remains the same.
With the increase in interest rates depicted in figure 1, figure 11 shows that the inverse of the velocity of
circulation of currency given by equation 10 decreases quite significantly (instead of remaining constant
as in the FKS experiment). As a consequence, the stock of currency in circulation grows at a lower rate than
nominal GDP. In fact, figure 12 shows that when this effect is taken into account, currency in circulation
remains essentially flat (hitting a minimum point in 2019) instead of increasing steadily as in figure 4. Since
the path for the monetary base is still given by figure 10, from equation 9 we know that the lower path for
currency in circulation must deliver a higher path for reserves. This is what figure 13 shows: The new path
for reserves is higher than in figure 5. Given this path for reserves, SOMA interest expenses itR Rt −1 are then
obtained by multiplying them by the interest rates on reserves in figure 9 (which are assumed unchanged).

7

FIGURE 11

FIGURE 12

Inverse of velocity of circulation
of currency

Revised currency in circulation
$ billions
2,000

0.058

1,800
0.056

1,600
1,400

0.054

1,200
0.052

1,000
800

0.050

600

0.048

400
200

0.046

0

0.044
2017

’18

’19

’20

’21

’22

Sources: Author’s calculations based on data from
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 2016, Survey
of Primary Dealers, September; and Lucas and
Nicolini (2015).

Economic Perspectives

2 / 2018

2017

’18

’19

’20

’21

’22

Sources: Author’s calculations based on data from
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 2016, Survey
of Primary Dealers, September; and Lucas and
Nicolini (2015).

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

FIGURE 13

FIGURE 14

Revised reserves

Revised SOMA interest expenses

$ billions

$ billions

3,000
			

60

2,500

50

2,000

40

1,500

30

1,000

20

500

10

0
2017

’18

’19

’20

’21

’22

0
2017

8

Something that is worth noting is the behavior of
the money multiplier underlying these projections.
Observe that the money multiplier is given by the
ratio of money in circulation to the monetary base:
11) µ t =

’19

’20

’21

’22

Sources: Author’s calculations based on data from
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 2016, Survey
of Primary Dealers, September; Ferris, Kim, and
Schlusche (2017); and Lucas and Nicolini (2015).

Sources: Author’s calculations based on data from
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 2016, Survey
of Primary Dealers, September; Ferris, Kim, and
Schlusche (2017); and Lucas and Nicolini (2015).

The resulting path, which is depicted in figure 14,
is higher than in figure 6. However, the implications for remittances to the Treasury (constructed
from equation 5) are small: Figure 15 shows that
remittances are smaller than in figure 8, but the
difference amounts to an accumulated total of only
$23 billion between 2019 and 2022. Thus, redoing
the calculations under a monetarist view does not
raise any red flags in terms of remittances to the
Treasury. However, the level of reserves by 2022 is
about $360 billion in figure 13, compared with
$100 billion in figure 5. Since the reserves threshold
for resuming purchases of Treasury securities is $100
billion, the monetarist view indicates that the resumption point occurs later than in the benchmark
calculations.

’18

FIGURE 15

Revised SOMA net income
$ billions

			
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
2017

’18

’19

’20

’21

’22

Sources: Author’s calculations based on data from
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 2016, Survey
of Primary Dealers, September; Ferris, Kim, and
Schlusche (2017); and Lucas and Nicolini (2015).

Mt
.
Rt + Ct

Thus, in order to describe the behavior of the money multiplier during the projection period, I need to
estimate the demand for money M t . An apparent difficulty in doing this is that the demand for money is
usually considered to be highly unstable over time (for this reason, policy discussions are hardly ever
conducted using the framework of a money demand function). In fact, figure A2 in the appendix, which

Economic Perspectives

2 / 2018

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

FIGURE 16

FIGURE 17

Money supply

Money multiplier

$ billions

5.00

12,000

4.50
4.00

10,000

3.50
3.00

8,000

2.50
6,000

2.00
1.50

4,000

1.00
0.50

2,000

0.00
0

2017

’18

’19

’20

’21

’22

Sources: Author’s calculations based on data from
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 2016, Survey
of Primary Dealers, September; and Lucas and
Nicolini (2015).

2017

’18

’19

’20

’21

’22

Sources: Author’s calculations based on data from
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 2016, Survey
of Primary Dealers, September; Ferris, Kim, and
Schlusche (2017); and Lucas and Nicolini (2015).

reproduces Lucas and Nicolini’s (2015) figure 2a, plots the inverse of the velocity of circulation of M1 versus
the three-month Treasury bill at an annual frequency during 1915–2012 and shows that the demand for
money was fairly stable during the 1915–1980 period, but that the relation broke down during 1981–2012.
Since figure A1 shows that the demand for the currency component of M1 remained fairly stable, this means
that the demand for demand deposits is what actually broke down. Figure A3 confirms this. Lucas and
Nicolini (2015) argue that the reason for this breakdown is that since the appearance of money market funds
in the early 1980s, some of the transactions that were previously done using checking accounts started being
done with money market deposit accounts. In fact, appendix figure A4 shows that when money market
deposit accounts are added to M1, the demand for money remains stable throughout the whole century.4

9

Motivated by this empirical evidence, I postulate a stable demand for money function of the following form:
12)

Mt
−α
= Am (it + φ m ) m .
PY
t t

I then choose the parameters Am , φ m , and α m to fit figure A4 in the appendix at the following three points:

i
0.0
0.05
0.135

M
PY
0.039
0.023
0.14.

The resulting values for Am , φ m , and α m are 0.0341, 0.0592, and 0.8625, respectively. Figure 16 depicts
the path for the money supply M t implied by the demand for money function (equation 12). Dividing
these numbers by the monetary base in figure 10 gives a path for the money multiplier µ t that is depicted
in figure 17. This figure shows a striking result: After remaining fairly constant through 2019, the money
multiplier is expected to almost double within a three-year period. Is it realistic to expect such a sharp
increase over such a short period? The next section addresses this question.
Economic Perspectives

2 / 2018

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

On the money multiplier...
In the old days, short-term interest rates were positive but reserves did not earn interest. As a consequence,
banks held just enough reserves to satisfy their reserve requirements. Defining At to be deposit accounts,
the money multiplier was given by
Ct
+1
Ct + At
At
µt =
=
,
Ct + Rt Ct
+ ρt
At
where
Ct
Ct
1
=
=
,
M
At M t − Ct
t
−1
Ct
and where ρt was the reserve requirement ratio. Using a reserve requirement ratio of 0.10 and the demand
M
for money functions in equations 10 and 12 to evaluate the ratio t C , we get that the money multiplier
t
µ t would have gone from 3.3 to 3.9 as the interest rate increased from 0 percent to 3 percent (the value by
the end of our projection period). That is, in the old days, a doubling of the money multiplier under such
an interest rate increase would have been far-fetched.5

10

But we do not live in the old days, nor are we likely to go back to them. The current environment is characterized
by abundant reserves and administered interest rates. In particular, the Fed puts a floor on safe short-term
interest rates by paying interest on reserves and offering overnight reverse repos. In a context of abundant
reserves, this would be enough to control short-term interest rates. But for the sake of argument, it may be
useful to think that the Fed will also operate some type of lending facility that will put a ceiling on short-term
interest rates. Moreover, for simplicity, assume that the floor and ceiling are the same, and therefore that
the interest rate on reserves is equal to the interest rate on safe short-term assets. Observe that in this situation,
banks should be completely indifferent between holding reserves and safe short-term assets.
In what follows, I argue that as a first approximation under such a policy regime, the size of the Fed’s balance
sheet is completely irrelevant for equilibrium outcomes while the Fed gains full control of the money multiplier.
To show this, let’s assume that the economy is in some equilibrium path for the price level Pt , real GDP
Yt , the interest rate it , currency Ct , deposits At , and reserves Rt . As a counterpart to their deposits At , banks
would generally hold safe short-term assets and reserves (among other assets). However, consider a first case
in which banks hold no reserves at all (yes, I am abstracting from any reserve requirements) and only hold
short-term Treasury securities in their portfolio of short-term assets. Observe that in this case, the banks receive
interest payments from the U.S. Treasury and use these receipts to pay interest to their depositors (while
the Fed stands idle on the side). Now consider an alternative scenario in which the Fed purchases all the
holdings of short-term Treasury securities of the banks with reserves (increasing its balance sheet). In this
scenario, the Fed is the one now receiving payments from the Treasury. The Fed uses these receipts to pay
interest on reserves to the banks, which in turn use the receipts to pay interest to their depositors. But aside
from having one more intermediary in the flow of payments ultimately going from the Treasury to depositors
(and some differences on who is holding what), there is no substantial economic difference between the

Economic Perspectives

2 / 2018

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

two scenarios: Equilibrium outcomes should be exactly the same. Since the monetary base is higher in the
second scenario but the quantity of money in circulation is exactly the same in both scenarios, the money
multiplier is lower in the second scenario. However, this is completely irrelevant for equilibrium outcomes.
With respect to the question I asked at the end of the previous section, we can then say that a doubling of
the money multiplier while the Fed shrinks the monetary base is a perfectly realistic outcome.

Conclusion
This article evaluated how sensitive projections of the net income of the Fed during the balance sheet
normalization period could be to the incorporation of an explicit demand for money function. Previous
projections assume that cash balances will grow at the same rate as nominal GDP. However, as interest rates
increase, the demand for real cash balances will decrease, making cash grow at a lower rate than nominal
GDP. As a consequence, reserves will decrease at a lower rate than expected and, given that the Fed pays
interest on reserves, the net income of the Fed will be lower than expected. However, while all these effects
are true, I find that the quantitative implications for the path of net income of the Fed are small.
A striking implication of the analysis is that the money multiplier is expected to double within a three-year
period. However, I argue that this should pose no problem because under a system of administered interest
rates that includes interest payments on reserves, banks are indifferent between holding reserves and safe
short-term assets. Under such a monetary regime, the Fed directly controls the money multiplier by
determining the size of its balance sheet.

11

A caveat of the analysis is that it was performed under a very specific path for the fed funds rate: the path
obtained in the September 2016 Survey of Primary Dealers. It would be extremely interesting to perform
the analysis under alternative scenarios. For instance, an interesting scenario would be one in which (maybe
because of an inflation scare), interest rates rise quickly to much higher levels than in the benchmark case.
In this scenario, the Fed would be paying much higher interest payments on reserves while reserves remain
at higher levels because of a sharper drop in the demand for real cash balances, putting considerably more
strain on the net income of the Fed than in the benchmark calculations. Another interesting scenario would
consider alternative levels for the “normalized” size of the balance sheet, since this has not yet been decided
by the FOMC (the $100 billion normalized reserves amount considered in this article was merely illustrative).
However, analyzing such alternative scenarios would require taking a stance on what would be the associated
paths for nominal GDP and the SOMA portfolio (which is highly sensitive to interest rates and the normalized
size of the balance sheet). Determining such paths, while necessary for considering alternative scenarios,
is outside the scope of this article.

Economic Perspectives

2 / 2018

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

APPENDIX: MONEY DEMAND EVIDENCE
This appendix reproduces the figures in Lucas and Nicolini (2015) that contain the money demand
evidence used in this article.
Figure A1: Currency/GDP vs. Interest Rate (Three-MonthT-Bill),1915–2012

Figure A2: M1/GDP vs. Interest Rate (Three-Month T-Bill), 1915–2012
0.5

0.12

1915 −1980
1981 −2012

1915 −1980
1981 −2012

0.11

0.45

0.1

0.4

0.09

M1 / GDP

CURRENCY / GDP

0.35
0.08
0.07

0.3

0.25
0.06
0.2

0.05

0.15

0.04
0.03

0

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

INTEREST RATE

0.1

0.12

0.14

Figure A3: Demand Deposits/GDP vs. Interest Rate (Three-MonthT-Bill),1915–2012
0.4

0.1

0.16

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

INTEREST RATE

0.1

0.12

0.14

0.16

Figure A4: New M1 (M1+MMDAs) vs. Opportunity Cost, 1915–2012
0.5

1915 −1980
1981 −2012

1915 −1980
1981 −2012

0.45

0.35

0.4

0.3

0.35
0.25

NEW M1 / GDP

DEMAND DEPOSITS / GDP

0

0.2

0.3

0.25
0.15

12

0.2
0.1

0.05

0.15

0

Economic Perspectives

0.02

0.04

2 / 2018

0.06

0.08

INTEREST RATE

0.1

0.12

0.14

0.16

0.1

0

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

OPPORTUNITY COST (RATE)

0.1

0.12

0.14

0.16

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

NOTES
A deferred asset would reflect the amount of future earnings that would be needed to be withheld to cover the Fed’s current operating
losses. During the period of time that a deferred asset remains on its books, the Fed’s remittances to the Treasury would be equal
to zero.
1

An exception is the New York Fed’s most recent report (Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 2018). Instead of assuming that
currency will grow at the same rate as nominal GDP, this report’s benchmark scenario uses the median response to a question in
the December 2017 Survey of Primary Dealers (SPD) about the expected level of currency in 2025. Currency is then assumed to
grow at a constant growth rate during the projection period consistent with that 2025 level. The resulting annual growth rate of
currency of 5 percent is actually larger than the 4 percent median annualized growth rate in nominal GDP between 2017 and 2025
implied by the December 2017 SPD expected paths for GDP and the PCE (personal consumption expenditures) deflator. That is,
the most recent New York Fed report has moved even further away from the scenario explored in this article. For an argument
supporting the view that currency may actually grow faster than nominal GDP due to foreign demand for U.S. currency, see
Haasl, Paulson, and Schulhofer-Wohl (2018).
2

The money multiplier is regularly described in textbooks as the consequence of commercial banks being required to hold only a
fraction of their deposits as reserves, lending the rest and thus creating additional money in circulation.
3

This monetary aggregate is known as money of zero maturity (MZM).

4

Under such a stable money multiplier, implementing the huge contraction in monetary base that the Fed is planning to do during
the normalization period would have created extreme deflationary pressures.
5

REFERENCES
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 2018, “Monetary policy implementation,” webpage, available online,
https://www.newyorkfed.org/markets/domestic-market-operations/monetary-policy-implementation.
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Markets Group, 2018, “Open market operations during 2017,” report,
April, available online, https://www.newyorkfed.org/medialibrary/media/markets/omo/omo2017-pdf.pdf.

13

Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Markets Group, 2017, “Domestic open market operations during 2016,”
report, April, revised May, available online, https://www.newyorkfed.org/medialibrary/media/markets/
omo/omo2016-pdf.pdf.
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Markets Group, 2016, “Domestic open market operations during 2015,”
report, April, available online, https://www.newyorkfed.org/medialibrary/media/markets/omo/omo2015-pdf.pdf.
Ferris, Erin E. Syron, Soo Jeong Kim, and Bernd Schlusche, 2017, “Confidence interval projections of
the Federal Reserve balance sheet and income,” FEDS Notes, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, January 13. Crossref, https://doi.org/10.17016/2380-7172.1875
Haasl, Thomas, Anna Paulson, and Sam Schulhofer-Wohl, 2018, “Understanding the demand for
currency at home and abroad,” Chicago Fed Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, No. 396.
Crossref, https://doi.org/10.21033/cfl-2018-396
Lucas, Robert E., Jr., and Juan Pablo Nicolini, 2015, “On the stability of money demand,” Journal of
Monetary Economics, Vol. 73, July, pp. 48–65. Crossref, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2015.03.005

Economic Perspectives

2 / 2018

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Marcelo Veracierto is a senior economist and research
advisor in the Economic Research Department at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
© 2018 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Economic Perspectives is published by the Economic
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago. The views expressed are the authors’ and do not
necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago or the Federal Reserve System.
Charles L. Evans, President; Daniel G. Sullivan, Executive
Vice President and Director of Research; Anna L. Paulson,
Senior Vice President and Associate Director of Research;
Spencer Krane, Senior Vice President and Senior Research
Advisor; Daniel Aaronson, Vice President, microeconomic
policy research; Jonas D. M. Fisher, Vice President,
macroeconomic policy research; Robert Cox, Vice
President, markets team; Gene Amromin, Vice President,

finance team; Leslie McGranahan, Vice President and
Director, regional research; William A. Testa, Vice
President, regional programs; Marcelo Veracierto,
Senior Economist and Economics Editor; Helen Koshy
and Han Y. Choi, Editors; Julia Baker, Production Editor;
Sheila A. Mangler, Editorial Assistant.
Economic Perspectives articles may be reproduced in
whole or in part, provided the articles are not reproduced
or distributed for commercial gain and provided the
source is appropriately credited. Prior written permission
must be obtained for any other reproduction, distribution,
republication, or creation of derivative works of Economic
Perspectives articles. To request permission, please
contact Helen Koshy, senior editor, at 312-322-5830 or
email Helen.Koshy@chi.frb.org.
ISSN 0164-0682

14

Economic Perspectives

2 / 2018

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago