View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

2022-21 | August 8, 2022

Will Workers Demand Cost-of-Living Adjustments?
Reuven Glick, Sylvain Leduc, and Mollie Pepper
Households are currently expecting inflation to run high in the short run but to remain muted over
the more distant future. Given this divergence, what role do short-run and long-run household
inflation expectations play in determining what workers expect for future wages? Data show that
wage inflation is sensitive to movements in household short-run inflation expectations but not to
those over longer horizons. This points to an upside risk for inflation, as workers negotiate higher
wages that businesses could pass on to consumers by raising prices.

The U.S. labor market has rebounded strongly from the deep pandemic-related recession and is now very
tight. Employment is back at pre-pandemic levels, job openings are surpassing the number of unemployed
workers, and people are quitting jobs at high rates. Reflecting the difficulties businesses face in finding
workers, wages have climbed substantially. Wages were growing about 3% annually before the pandemic,
when the labor market was also tight; now, average hourly earnings are growing at roughly twice that rate,
and even more in some sectors hit hardest during the pandemic, such as leisure and hospitality. Other
measures, such as employment wage costs that control for worker shifts between occupations and
industries, are up almost as much.
However, the substantial nominal wage gains have not been enough to compensate for the rise in inflation
over the past year. The 12-month change in consumer price inflation has risen from 1.4% at the start of
2021 to more than 9% in June 2022. As a result, real wages, which adjust for the rising cost of living, have
declined.
This increase in inflation was mostly unanticipated and expected by many to be temporary. Thus, it was
likely not a major factor in wage negotiations until recently. However, if inflation remains very high,
workers may expect it to persist and demand higher wages to match the rising cost of living (Lansing
2022). While the inflation rates that households expect over the longer run remain fairly stable, yearahead inflation expectations have risen substantially since early 2021. In April 2022, year-ahead expected
inflation was up to 5.4% before receding slightly to 5.2% in July. Therefore, future wage inflation depends
in part on its sensitivity to short- and long-run inflation expectations.
In this Economic Letter, we show that year-ahead inflation expectations have a large impact on wage
inflation, while long-term inflation expectations have essentially no influence. Given the large increase in
short-term inflation expectations in the past year, our results point to an important upside risk to inflation,
as workers demand higher wages that businesses could pass on to consumers by raising prices. By
reducing demand, ongoing monetary policy tightening will help reduce the probability that this risk

FRBSF Economic Letter 2022-21 | August 8, 2022
materializes. As such, the stability of long-run inflation expectations is a sign that households have
confidence that the Federal Reserve will achieve low inflation over time.

The recent evolution of inflation expectations
Every month the University of Michigan conducts a survey of consumers. As part of this survey, a
representative group of households are asked about their expectations for future inflation, either in the
short run over the next year, or over the longer run, the next five to ten years. Figure 1 shows that
household one-year-ahead inflation expectations have risen dramatically over the past year, in line with
higher actual inflation. Historically, household short-run inflation expectations are highly sensitive to
recent changes in inflation: the two series have a correlation of 0.91 between 1980 and June 2022. In
assessing what inflation is likely to be in the year ahead, households are particularly influenced by recent
changes in gas, food, and other commodity prices (Glick et al. 2021). Thus, it is not unusual to see spikes in
household inflation expectations following fluctuations in those prices, as in 2008 and 2011.
In contrast to the substantial rise in
household short-run inflation
expectations, Figure 1 shows that
households continue to expect only
moderate inflation over the longer
run, expecting prices to rise roughly
3% on average. This may reflect a
perception that the recent inflation
increase is driven by temporary
factors, for instance, the effects of
fiscal support or supply-chain
disruptions, which will wane over
time (Barnichon et al. 2021, Jordà et
al. 2022). Alternatively, they may
expect the Federal Reserve to raise
interest rates sufficiently to reduce
inflation over time, even if underlying
shocks prove persistent.

Figure 1
Price inflation and inflation expectations
Percent
16

CPI inflation

14
12

5-10 year
inflation expectations

10

1 year
inflation expectations

8
6
4
2
0
-2
1978

1983

1988

1993

1998

2003

2008

2013

2018

Note: Consumer price index (CPI) inflation measured as four-quarter percent change.
Source: BEA and University of Michigan; some missing 5-10 year expectations for the 1980s
use interpolations from adjacent quarters or FRB Philadelphia’s Livingston Survey.

The considerable rise in short-run inflation expectations may lead workers to demand higher wages to
compensate for the anticipated rise in the cost of living. However, businesses may be reluctant to give large
pay increases if price pressures are expected to be temporary, particularly if they are unable to pass higher
costs on to consumers. Thus, it is unclear how much wage growth responds to changes in short- or longrun inflation expectations.

Wage growth determinants
To examine the effects of short- and long-run inflation expectations on wage inflation, we estimate a wage
Phillips curve, an empirical relationship between overall wage inflation and its determinants. One
2

FRBSF Economic Letter 2022-21 | August 8, 2022
important factor driving fluctuations
Figure 2
in wage inflation is the business cycle
Unemployment gap and wage inflation
and the strength of the labor market,
Percent
as captured by the unemployment
10
gap. The unemployment gap
Wage inflation
measures the difference between the
8
unemployment rate and a measure of
6
maximum employment from the
Congressional Budget Office. A
4
negative unemployment gap thus
reflects a tight labor market. Figure 2
2
shows that, historically, wage
inflation has moved inversely with the
0
unemployment gap. When the labor
Unemployment gap
market is strong and the
-2
unemployment gap is negative,
1978
1998
2003
2008
2013
2018
1983
1988
1993
Note: Wage inflation measured as four-quarter percent change in employment cost index.
nominal wages tend to rise. In
contrast, when the labor market is
weak and the unemployment gap is positive, nominal wages tend to fall.
In addition to the unemployment gap, our wage Phillips curve includes household short-run and long-run
inflation expectations from the University of Michigan, and lagged core price inflation, which abstracts
from volatile food and energy price inflation, to capture the possibility that workers and firms are directly
influenced by previous price inflation when agreeing on wages. We use core inflation because it is more
persistent than headline inflation and thus more likely to influence wages. Other work suggests that
household inflation expectations may also capture the effects of lagged oil and other noncore inflation
components (Coibion et al. 2018 and Glick et al. 2021). We also include the trend growth in labor
productivity from the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). Over time, higher labor productivity growth
should boost wage growth, with the strength of the relationship depending on such factors as workers’ and
firms’ bargaining power. To rule out the possibility that inflation leads to ever-rising, “explosive” increases
in wage growth over time, we assume the total effects of lagged and expected inflation equal wage inflation
over the long run (see, for instance, Hooper, Mishkin, and Sufi 2020).
To estimate this wage Phillips curve, we use quarterly data from the second quarter of 1980 to the first
quarter of 2022. We measure wages using the wages and salaries component of the employment cost index
compiled by the BEA, with data beginning in the first quarter of 1980. This measure accounts for changes
in the composition of the workforce, which could impact wage growth separately from the wage Phillips
curve. Inflation rates in wages and core prices are measured as (log) changes over each quarter at an
annual rate.
Figure 3 reports the estimated coefficients for the wage Phillips curve components, where the height of the
bars indicates the estimated percent change of wage inflation in response to a 1 percentage point change in
each component. The figure also reports the 95% confidence bands around each estimate. The figure
3

FRBSF Economic Letter 2022-21 | August 8, 2022
shows that wage inflation is
significantly related to labor market
tightness, as Figure 2 implies. A
tighter labor market, represented by a
negative unemployment gap, is
associated with higher wage inflation.
The results also confirm that greater
productivity growth is accompanied
by higher wages.

Figure 3
Effects on wage inflation of 1% change in variables
Percent
1
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2

Most importantly, Figure 3 also
0
shows that short-run household
-0.2
inflation expectations are a key
determinant of wage inflation, along
-0.4
5-10 year
Unemployment
1-year
Lagged core
Productivity
with the unemployment gap, lagged
gap
inflation
inflation
inflation
growth
core price inflation, and trend
expectations expectations
productivity growth. In contrast,
Note: Dark blue bands indicate 95% confidence intervals.
long-run household inflation
expectations have no statistically
significant effects on wage inflation, as reflected by the fact that the confidence bands encompass the
possibility that these estimated effects are zero. The influence of short-term inflation expectations on wage
inflation is similar to their role for price inflation, as documented in Coibion, Gorodnichenko, and Kamdar
(2018).
Our general results are unaffected if we use alternative measures of variables in our analysis, such as
measuring wages with average hourly earnings or measuring slack with the vacancy-to-employment ratio,
or if we add other possible explanatory variables such as oil or noncore price inflation. Removing the
assumption that wage inflation is tied to past and expected inflation over the long run also does not affect
our main conclusion, that wages are sensitive to short-run but not to long-run inflation expectations.

Inflation risk
According to these results, the recent rise in household year-ahead inflation expectations could lead to
substantially higher wage inflation in the short run. Focusing on this channel alone, our estimated wage
Phillips curve suggests current household one-year-ahead expectations could add nearly 2.3 percentage
points to wage inflation. To the extent that companies raise prices and pass on the higher labor cost to
consumers, our results point to an important upside risk to inflation. To mitigate this cost increase,
companies could decide to automate or offshore some jobs, although higher tariffs and supply-chain
challenges make offshoring more costly than in the past.
On the other hand, the decline in unionization over the past 50 years and the disappearance of automatic
cost-of-living adjustments in long-term wage contracts make it less likely that short-run inflation
expectations will persistently boost wage inflation. Similarly, many firms have relied on one-time bonuses
4

FRBSF Economic Letter 2022-21 | August 8, 2022
to attract and retain workers instead of permanently raising wages. More broadly, monetary policymakers
have the tools to reduce this inflation risk by raising interest rates to lean on overall demand. The fact that
changes in long-run inflation expectations have been muted over the past year suggests that households
have confidence that the Federal Reserve will restrict monetary policy sufficiently to bring about low
inflation over the medium run and avoid a price-wage inflationary spiral.

Conclusion
Inflation is running at a 40-year high, and year-ahead household inflation expectations have risen
substantially, although households continue to expect relatively muted inflation over the longer run. Given
this divergence in expectations, this Letter assessed the role of short-run and long-run household inflation
expectations as a determinant of wage inflation. We showed that movements in short-run household
inflation expectations have a significant impact on wage inflation. In contrast, wage inflation does not
react to changes in long-run household inflation expectations. Therefore, the increase in short-run
expectations since last spring point to an important upside risk to inflation, as workers negotiate higher
wages that businesses could pass on to consumers in the form of higher prices. By reducing overall
demand, the ongoing monetary policy tightening will help reduce the probability that this risk
materializes.
Reuven Glick
Group vice president, Economic Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
Sylvain Leduc
Executive vice president, Economic Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
Mollie Pepper
Research associate, Economic Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

References
Barnichon, Regis, Luiz E. Oliveira, and Adam H. Shapiro. 2021. “Is the American Rescue Plan Taking Us
Back to the ’60s?” FRBSF Economic Letter 2021-27 (October 18).
Coibion, Olivier, Yuriy Gorodnichenko, and Rupal Kamdar. 2018. “The Formation of Expectations,
Inflation, and the Phillips Curve.” Journal of Economic Literature 56(4), pp. 1,447–1,491.
Glick, Reuven, Noah Kouchekinia, Sylvain Leduc, and Zheng Liu. 2021 “Do Households Expect Inflation
When Commodities Surge?” FRBSF Economic Letter 2021-19 (July 12).
Hooper, Peter, Frederic Mishkin, and Amir Sufi. 2020. “Prospects for Inflation in a High Pressure
Economy: Is the Phillips Curve Dead or Is It Just Hibernating?” Research in Economics 74(1), pp. 26–
62.
Jordà, Òscar, Celeste Liu, Fernanda Nechio, and Fabián Rivera-Reyes. 2022. “Why Is U.S. Inflation Higher
than in Other Countries?” FRBSF Economic Letter 2022-07 (March 28).
Lansing, Kevin J. 2022. “Untangling Persistent versus Transitory Shocks to Inflation.” FRBSF Economic
Letter 2022-13 (May 23).
5

FRBSF Economic Letter 2022-21 | August 8, 2022

Opinions expressed in FRBSF Economic Letter do not necessarily reflect the views of the
management of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or of the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System. This publication is edited by Anita Todd and Karen Barnes. Permission to
reprint portions of articles or whole articles must be obtained in writing. Please send editorial
comments and requests for reprint permission to research.library@sf.frb.org

Recent issues of FRBSF Economic Letter are available at
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/
2022-20

Christensen
Spiegel

COVID-19 Fiscal Expansion and Inflation Expectations in Japan
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/august/covid-19-fiscal-expansion-and-inflation-expectations-in-japan/

2022-19

Puig

The Unequal Effect of Interest Rates by Race, Gender
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/august/unequal-effect-interest-rates-by-race-and-gender/

2022-18

Christensen

The Increase in Inflation Compensation: What’s Up?
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/july/increase-in-inflation-compensation-whats-up/

2022-17

Daly

Policy Nimbleness Through Forward Guidance
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/june/policy-nimbleness-through-forward-guidance-speech/

2022-16

Mondragon

Credit Conditions in the Pandemic Mortgage Market
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/june/credit-conditions-in-pandemic-mortgage-market/

2022-15

Shapiro

How Much Do Supply and Demand Drive Inflation
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/june/how-much-do-supply-and-demand-drive-inflation/

2022-14

Bok /
Petrosky-Nadeau

Estimating Natural Rates of Unemployment
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/may/estimating-natural-rates-of-unemployment/

2022-13

Lansing

Untangling Persistent versus Transitory Shocks to Inflation?
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/may/untangling-persistent-versus-transitory-shocks-to-inflation/

2022-12

Duzhak

Pandemic Unemployment Effects across Demographic Groups
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-

letter/2022/may/pandemic-unemployment-effects-across-demographic-groups/