View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY LETTER

Number 95-22, June 9, 1995

Understanding Trends
in Foreign Exchange Rates
In 1983 Richard Meese and Kenneth Rogoff
published a startling paper. Briefly stated, their
paper provided convincing evidence that traditional exchange rate models had no ability
whatsoever to predict exchange rates; in fact,
they could not even explain exchange rate
changes ex post, i.e., even afterfuture explanatory variables, like money supplies and interest
rates, became known. These results took the
wind out of the sails of researchers in international finance. For more than ten years now, a
demoralized and shrinking corps of international
economists has been devising ever more esoteric
models, ranging from chaos and catastrophe theory to neural networks and Markov switching, in
a (thus far) fruitless effort to explain exchange
rate movements. As a result, if you asked a random sample of economists to name the three
most difficult questions confronting mankind,
the answers would probably be: (1) What is the
meaning of life? (2) What is the relationship
between quantum mechanics and general relativity? and (3) What's going on in the foreign
exchange market? (Not necessarily in that order.)
This is an unfortunate state of affairs, because
whenever turbulence erupts in the foreign exchange market, as it has in the past few months,
economists are naturally called on to explain it.
Since economists cannot explain short-term
movements in exchange rates, the door is left
open to thousands of armchair economists who
are happy to sell you their own pet theories (as
long as you don't ask them about their track
'record). The resulting morass of contradictory
stories then creates the impression that economists know nothing about foreign exchange
rates.
This Letter will try to change that impression. I
argue that the economics profession does have
something useful to say about exchange rates, if
only you are patient enough. In particular, this
Letter shows that long-term trends in foreign exchange rates are pretty well accounted for by just
two factors-inflation and productivity.

Exchange rates in the post-Bretton Woods era
In 1944, Western leaders began drafting plans for
the post-War world. Part of these plans included
a strategy.to restore order to the world's financial
system. Global financial markets had been chaotic during the inter-war years, as nations resorted to competitive currency devaluations in
an ultimately unsuccessful effort to shift unemployment to other countries. To avoid a repetition
of this experience, the world's financial leaders
met in Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, to devise a system of fixed exchange rates. The basic
idea of the plan was to set a fixed value of each
currency against the dollar, and then to set a
fixed price of the dollar in terms of gold. Effectively then, the world was on a gold standard,
but with the important difference that the dollar,
not gold, served as the international store of
value.
This system worked remarkably well for more than
20 years. However, its success depended on the
world's confidence in the value of the dollar. If
other countries began to suspect that the dollar
would lose its value relative to gold, they would
want to convert their dollar reserves to gold in
order to avoid a capital loss. As U.S. inflation accelerated in the late 1960s, such a lack of confidence did in fact occur, as a given, fixed stock
of gold was being asked to support a larger and
larger supply of circulating dollars.
The Bretton Woods system ultimately collapsed
in the early 1970s. At the time, most economists
endorsed the dem ise of the Bretton Woods system,
thinking that it would free the world's economies
from the straitjacket of coordinating monetary
policies. Although everyone knew that exchange
rates would now move around as economic conditions varied from country to country, no one
thought that they would fluctuate much more
than underlying macroeconomic conditions.
Of course, these expectations were wildly inaccurate. The past 25 years of floating exchange
rates have been characterized by two unexpected

FRBSF
features. First, exchange rates have been much
more volatile than macroeconomic variables. For
example, exchange rates are about as volatile as
stock prices, and as noted above, are extremely
difficult to predict. In fact, it is easier to predict
year-to-year changes in the stock market than it
is to predict year-to-year changes in exchange
rates. Second, many exchange rates have exhibited a persistent trend against the dollar. For
example, Figures 1 and 2 plot the value of the
dollar against the yen and the mark. (Ignore
the dotted lines for now.) Note that except for a
brief interlude between 1980 and 1985, the dollar
has depreciated steadily during the past 25 years.
In 1970, a dollar was worth 358 yen and 3.65
marks. By 1994, the dollar was worth only 102
yen and 1.62 marks. (During 1995, the dollar has
declined an additional 15 percent.) While exchange rate volatility remains a mystery, I will
argue that these trends can be mostly explained
by two simple theories-the Purchasing Power
Parity theory of nominal exchange rates, and the
Balassa-Samuelson theory of real exchange rates.

logic is based on commodity arbitrage. For example, if the current yen/dollar exchange rate is
100, and the price of U.S. cars is $10,000 while
the price of Japanese cars is 1.2 million yen, then
everyone will want to buy u.s. cars since they
are $2,000 cheaper. This creates an excess demand for dollars, which eventually causes the
dollar to appreciate to 120 yen. (Or, if the exchange rate is fixed, causes u.S. car prices to
rise to $12,000, or Japanese car prices to fall
to 1.0 million yen.)
Now, an operational problem with this theory
is determining exactly which goods have their
prices equalized. As a practical matter, economists use a price index, like the CPI, to summarize the level of prices in each country. With
this definition, PPP says that the exchange rate
should equal the ratio of national price indices.
(Actually, since base periods and the commodity
composition of price indices may differ across
countries, PPP only predicts a proportional relationship between exchange rates and the ratio of
price indices.)

Purchasing Power Parity is one of the oldest theories in economics. It was formally stated by the
philosopher David Hume in 1752, but has no
doubt been around as long as currencies have
been exchanged. The basic idea is simpleaccording to PPP the value of an exchange rate
should equalize the prices of goods when expressed in a common currency. The underlying

The pattern of relative prices-the dotted lines in
Figures 1 and 2-provideevidence on the validity of PPP. To deal with base period indeterminacy, I assume that in 1980 the exchange rate
equaled the ratio of CPls, in other words, that
exchange rates were "in equilibrium" in 1980.
Clearly, PPP provides a poor theory of year-toyear changes in the exchange rate. Still, there
is definitely some sort of long-run relationship
between exchange rates and relative price levels,
particularly for the U.S. and Germany. Specifically, on average the dollar has depreciated 4.9
percent per year against the yen, and 3.2 percent

Figure 1
Japan

Figure 2
Germany

Purchasing Power Parity

\.ExEX:
,a:~
.

.

~.. \ ,

- .... :

/'-1

~,. -...

ReI. price level

--.--..

400

4

350

3.5

300

3

250

2.5

200

2

150

Rei. price level

1.5

100

7072 7476 78 8082 84 86 88 90 92 94

50

0.5

o

o
70 72 74 76 78 8082 8486 88 90 92 94

per year against the mark. At the same time, U.s.
inflation has exceeded Japanese inflation by·0.9
percent on average, and exceeded German inflation by 1.9 percent on average. Thus, while PPP
only accounts for 20 percent of the trend of the
dollar/yen rate, it accounts for a more substantial
60 percent of the long-run trend in the dollar/
mark rate. What about the remaining 80 and 40
percent? Discrepancies between observed exchange rates and their PPP levels are referred to
as "real exchange rate" changes, and the leading
theory of real exchange rate determination was
first put forth in 1964 by Bela Balassa and Paul
Samuelson.

The Balassa-Samuelson theory
of real exchange rates
An important problem with the notion of PPP is
that, either because of natural or governmentimposed barriers, many goods are not traded
between countries. For nontraded goods there
is obviously no reason for the exchange rate
to adjust to equalize prices, and therefore, to
the extent that nontraded goods enter national
price indices, no reason to expect changes in exchange rates to mirror changes in relative price
levels. In fact, estimates suggest that more than
50 percent of most countries' output consists of
nontraded goods. Specifically, products with a
large service component,like housing and routine medical treatment, tend to be nontraded,
while manufactured products, like cars and
computers, tend to be traded.
Balassa and Samuelson examined the consequences of nontraded goods for the theory of
PPP and the determination of real exchange
rates. They were motivated by the empirical regularity that wealthy countries have higher price
levels than poor countries, i.e., wealthy countries
have "overvalued" exchange rates. Their explanation of this phenomenon was based on the
tendency for productivity growth to be higher in
the traded goods sector than in the nontraded
goods sector. Because the prices of traded goods
are determined in world markets, productivity
growth in the traded goods sector doesn't lower
prices; instead, it raises the returns to factors of
production. However, since capital is relatively
mobile across countries, its return is also fixed by
world market conditions. Therefore, the primary
effect of traded goods productivity growth is increased wages in the traded goods sector. Then,
since labor tends to be mobile across sectors,

wage increases in the traded goods sector bid up
wages in the nontraded goods sector. Finally, an
increase in wages in the nontraded goods sector
gets passed along into higher prices of nontraded
goods, and more generally, into a higher overall
price level.
Does this theory explain departures from PPP?
Note that the yen has experienced an annual trend
real appreciation of 4.0 percent against the dollar, while the trend real appreciation of the mark
has been a more modest 1.3 percent. At the same
time, Japanese labor productivity growth in manufacturing, (a proxy for the traded goods sector),
has been 2.1 percent higher on average than
in the U.S., while German labor productivity
growth has on average been 1.1 percent higher.
Adding up the contributions of both PPP and
productivity, the result is that about 60 percent
of the trend in the yen can be accounted for,
while nearly all of the trend in the mark can be
accounted for.

Conclusion
Economists cannot explain short-run changes in
exchange rates. Nor can they explain the volatility of exchange rates. However, jf we focus on
the long run-measured in decades, not months
or even years-then someth ing can be said about
exchange rate determination. In particular, we
can explain nearly all of the trend in the mark,
and about 60 percent of the trend in the yen. For
the mark, most of the explanation comes from inflation differentials (i.e, PPP), while for the yen
most of the explanation comes from differential
productivity growth (i.e., the Balassa-Samuelson
effect).

Kenneth Kasa
Economist
References
Balassa, Bela. 1964. "The Purchasing Power Parity
Doctrine: A Reappraisal:' Journal of Political
Economy 72, pp. 584-596.
Meese, Richard A., and Kenneth Rogoff. 1983. "Empirical Exchange Rate Models of the Seventies:
Do They FitOut of Sample?" Journal of International Economics 14, pp. 3-24.
Samuelson, Paul A. 1964. "Theoretical Notes on Trade
ProblerTls:' Review of Economics and Statistics 46,
pp.145-154.

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor
or to the author. Free copies of Federal Reserve publications can be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco 94120. Phone (415) 974-2246, Fax (415) 974-3341. Weekly Letter
texts and other FRBSF publications and data are available on FedWest Online, a public bulletin board service reached by setting
your modem to dial (415) 896-0272.

Research Department

Federal Reserve
Bank of
San Francisco
P.O. Box 7702
San Francisco, CA 94120

Printed on recycled paper Q
~
with soybean inks.
~ !i§!I

Index to Recent Issues of FRBSF Weekly Letter

DATE

NUMBER TITLE

12/23
12/30
1/6
1/13
1/20
1/27
2/3
2110
2117
2/24
3/3
3110
3117
3/24
3/31
4/7
4114
4/21
4/28
5/5
5/12
5119
5/26

94-43
94-44
95-01
95-02
95-03
95-04
95-05
95-06
95-07
95-08
95-09
95-10
95-11
95-12
95-13
95-14
95-15
95-16
95-17
95-18
95-19
95-20
95-21

Effects of California Migration
Gradualism and Chinese Financial Reforms
The Credibility of Inflation Targets
A Look Back at Monetary Policy in 1994
Why Banking Isn't Declining
Economy Boosts Western Banking in '94
WhatArethe Lags in Monetary Policy?
Central Bank Credibility and Disinflation in New Zealand
Western Update
Reduced Deposit Insurance Risk
Rules vs. Discretion in New Zealand Monetary Policy
Mexico and the Peso
Regional Effects of the Peso Devaluation
1995 District Agricultural Outlook
Has the Fed Gotten Tougher on Inflation?
Responses to Capital Inflows in Malaysia and Thailand
Financial Liberalization and Economic Development
Central Bank Independence and Inflation
Western Banks and Derivatives
Monetary Policy in a Changing Financial Environment
Inflation Goals and Credibility
The Economics of Merging Commercial and Investment Banking
Financial Fragility and the Lender of Last Resort

AUTHOR
Mattey
Spiegel
Trehan
Parry
Levonian
Furlong/Zimmerman
Rudebusch
Hutchison
Mattey/Dean
Levonian/Furlong
Spiegel
Moreno
Mattey
Dean
judd/Trehan
Glick/Moreno
Huh
Parry
Laderman
GlicklTrehan
judd
Kwan
Schaan/Cogley

The FRBSF Weekly Letter appears on an abbreviated schedule in june, july, August, and December.