View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

IEbiB\Jilllk
August 1, 1980

Two Weeks Can Be a l on g Time
Lagged reserveaccounting is one of the most
arcane, yet frequently debated monetarypol icy issuesof the past decade.On its face,
this regulation-part of FederalReserveRegulation D -appears to be simple and innocuous. It statesthat, in any given week, Federal
Reservemember banksmusthold reserves(in
the form of depositsat a FederalReserveBank
or vault cash) in prescribed percentagesof
their various types of depositsoutstanding
two weeksearlier.This rule hasbeen in effect
since 1968, replacing the systemof contemporaneous reserveaccounting, which required banks to hold reservesbasedon their
currentweek'sdeposits.

times, depending on certain technical features of the Fed's efforts to control money.
Specifically, lagged accounting createsa
major problem onlywhen reservesborrowed
from the Federal Reserveare nearly at zero
levels, andwhen the Fedwishes to focus its
monetary-control procedureson bank reserves.The problem is that the Fed may find
it necessaryto control money by setting
Federal-funds rate targets-the method it
abandoned lastOctober in favor of a reserves
method.
Funds-rateoperating procedures
The Fed can influence money growth in
either of two basic ways-by targeting the
quantity of reservesit supplies to the banking
systemor by targeting the Federal-fundsrate,
the interest rate at which banks borrow reservesfrom each other and from other institutions. Prior to October 6, 1979, the Fed
used the latter method. When it wanted
slower monetary growth, the Fed raised the
funds rate, making reservesmore expensive
for banks to obtain.

Many observers,including Milton Friedman
in his Newsweek
column, are currently suggesting that the Fed should switch from the
lagged systemback to the contemporaneous
rule. They arguethatthis action would significantly improve Federal Reservecontrol over
the monetary aggregates.Thesearguments
took on new urgency this spring, when several key policy aggregatesdeclined at a time
when the economy was moving into a recession. (The narrow M-1 B measure-currency
plusbank demand depositsplus other checktype deposits-decl ined at a 7.7-percent rate
over April and May.) The rule thus has become an important policy issue,in view of
the argument that lagged accounting hampers efforts to push the monetary aggregates
back up into their target ranges.

Under lagged accounting, any increasesin
depositsthis week forced banksto obtain
more reservestwo weeks later. Furthermore,
an increasein this week's funds rate often
indicated that the funds rate two weeks later
would be similarly high. The higher expected
funds rate induced balance-sheetreactions of
individual banks that led to slower growth in
system-widedeposits, and thus in M-1 B.
Demand-depositgrowth was also reduced
as the funds-rate increasespreadto other
money-market yields, reducing the public's
demand for deposits. Sincethis process
would have been virtually identical under
contemporaneousaccounting, the choice of
reserveaccounting rules was of little consequenceunderthe former funds-rate
procedure.

Is the choice between laggedand contemporaneous accounting,really all that important? After all, a matter'of only two weeks is
involved. Indeed, some analystsmaintain
that a two-week lag can only insignificantly
influence the decisions of individual banks,
which are basedupon longer-run considerations. In this view, the choice between reserve accounting rules plays only a minor
role in how the money stock is determined.
Our analysis suggests,however, that both
sidesof this debate are correct at various

Reservesoperating procedures
On October 6, 1979, the Federal Reserve
1

§§

1F

@ill
]ED@iEldk
§@i1l'0.

1FJJ'@ill'l1(\;
li (\;CSJ)

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not
necessarily reflect the views of the management
of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco"
nor 01 the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System,
announCEidthat it wou Id place a greater
emphasis in the day-to-day control of the
monetary aggregates on the quantity of bank
reserves, and allow greater short-run fluctuations in the funds rate (see the October 19,
1979 Weekly Letter-"The Fed Crosses the
Rubicon"), The Fed took this action because
the funds-rate approach to monetary control
had not worked as well as was desirable or
possible, But these efforts to tighten monetary
control had another effect closer to the current discussion -the choice between lagged
and contemporaneous accounting became
an important monetary-policy issue,

(even if that quantity is less than current requirements), and in effect, force the banking
system to adjust its current deposits (and thus
required reserves) accordingly,
Under lagged accounting, the link between
current deposits and required reserves is
broken, Banks enter any given week with a
predetermined or unchangeable quantity of
required reserves, Unless the Fed wanted to
force some individual banks into a deficiency, it must provide the quantity of
reserves demanded by the banking system,
Under lagged accounting, the Fed's supply of
reserves must adjust to the banking system's
demand, This is just the opposite to contemporaneous accounting, where banks adjust
their demand for reserves (through deposit
changes) to the Fed's fixed supply,

To see this point, we must understand the
basic elements of controlling money through
reserves, As noted earlier, the Fed sets the
dollar volume of reserve'requirements equal
to fixed percentages of the various types of
deposits issued by banks, Thus if the Fed fixes
the quantity of total reserves available to the
banking system, bank deposits can expand
only by some fixed amount. Otherwise, total
reserve requirements for the banking system
would exceed the total quantity of reserves
available to meetthose requirements, As a
consequence, some individual banks would
find themselves without enough reserves to
meet their requirements,

Discount window
Does the Fed have any control over the monetary aggregates under a system of lagged
accounting, where it must accommodate any
quantity of reservesdemanded by banks?The
answer is yes under certain circumstances,
which depend on the level of reserves which
banks borrow from the Fed, The Fed has two
basic methods of supplying reserVes,Nonborrowed reserves are supplied when the Fed
purchases a Treasury bill or other security
directly or indirectly from a bank, paying for
the security with reserves (in the form of a
deposit at the Fed), The Fed supplies borrowed reserves when it makes a loan to a
bank at the discount rate, Banks are reluctant
to borrow from the discount window, however, partly because the Fed has historically
discouraged such loans except in emergencies, and partly because it imposes explicit
restrictions on the quantity of reserves it will
lend to anyone bank overtime, Thus, in view
of banks' reluctance to borrow, the Fed can
restrict money growth byproviding a larger
proportion of banks' predetermined requirements through the discount window,

These banks might respond by bidding for
reserves in the funds market, causing the
funds rate to rise, In fact, the funds rate would
have to rise to the level at which system-wide
deposits and reserve requirements fell
enough to eliminate the aggregate reserve
deficiency, Thus, the use of reserves to control money growth does not reduce the role of
the funds rate in the control process, This
approach instead makes the necessary fundsrate changes an automatic result of the Fed's
reserves targets,

Laggedreserve accounting
With contemporaneous reserve accounting,
banks as a whole influence their current
week's required reserves through changes in
current deposits, As a consequence, the Fed
can provide a fixed quantity of total reserves

For example, when the Fed wants to slow
money growth, it reduces its provision of
nonborrowed relative to borrowed reserves,
2

Funds
Rate

Demand

Supply

A - - - -

Total Reserves
Note: Below point A, borrowed reservesequal zero, and the funds rate is
below the discount rate.
Under laggedaccounting, this would not
change banks' requirementsfor total reserves,which are basedon the level of depositstwo weeks earlier-but it would force
some banks ultimately to borrow more of
thosereserves·fromthe discount window. But
since banksare reluctant to go to the window,
they may first try to meetdeficiencies through
the funds market, driving this rate up relative
to the discount rate. With the increase in the
relative cost of borrowing in the funds market, some bankswill be induced to make up
their deficienciesat the discount window. But
becauseof the rising funds rate, deposits will
expand lessrapidly.

funds rate could not be determined by nonFedparticipants in the reservesmarket becauseneither the demand for reservesnor the
supply of reservesrespondto the funds ratesupply is unresponsivebecauseborrowed
reservesare nearly zero, while lagged accounting makesreservesdemand unresponsive (seechart).
Crux of problem
To avoid such extreme funds-ratefluctuations, the Fed could buy the excessreserves
from banks through open-market operations
designedto set the funds rate at some desired
level. But in that event, the Fedwould be
following a funds-rateapproach to money
control-the approach it abandoned last fall.
Alternatively, the Fedcould maintain the discount ratelj"low thefunds'rilte,inducing a
positive level of borrowed reservesat all
times. But for a variety of reasons,the Fed
historically hasnot changedthe discount rate
actively enough to pursue such a policy.

This procedure can provide for monetary
control if banks' reluctance to borrow is predictable, andif the 'aggregatequantity of .
discount-window borrowing is not close to
zero. But what happenswhen borrowed reservesare close to zero (becausethe funds
rate isbelow the discount rate) and when the
Fed increasesnonborrowed reservesto stimulate money growth? Under these circumstances,bankswould find themselveswith
excessreserves,which they would then lend
to other banks in the funds market. This
would make the funds rate fall as excessreserveswere transferredbetween banks. If
borrowed reserveswere significantly positive, the funds rate would stop declining as
bankswere induced to borrow fewer reserves
from the Fed,thus absorbingthe excessreservesin the banking system.But with borrowed reservesalready nearly zero, banks
could not be induced to lower that borrowing
any further. Thus the excessreservesin the
systemwould not be absorbeduntil the funds
rate approachedzero. In technical terms, the

This then is an important problem with
lagged accounting: if the Fedneedsto reduce
borrowed reservesto nearly zero, it must effectively return to the funds-rateoperating
procedure. This can Occurwhenever the
funds rate is below the discount rate,as has
been the case in recent months. Thus, from a
purely monetary-control standpoint,a switch
to contemporaneous reserveaccounting appearsto be justified as a natural extensionof
the Fed's October 6 actions,which involved
a change to a reservesprocedure for controlling the monetary aggregates.

JohnP.Judd

3

J.Sl:lI::l
UOlSU!YSEM• 410'1(1
• uoSfUO ,. epeA.3N ,. OljEPI
!!l?MEH

•

E!UJOj!le:>

OIV<I

39V1S0<l 'S'O
llVW SSVlJ 1SHI1

:If

BANKINGDATA-TWELFTHFEDERAL
RESERVE
DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)

loans(gross,
adjusted)
andinvestments*
loans(gross,
adjusted)- total#
Commercial and industrial

Realestate
Loansto individuals
Securitiesloans

U.S.Treasury
securities"
Othersecurities"
Demanddeposits- total#
Demanddeposits-adjusted

Savingsdeposits- total
Time deposits - total#
Individuals, part. & corp.

(LargenegotiableCD's)
WeeklyAverages
of Daily Figures
MemberBankReserve
Position
ExcessReselVes(+ )/Oefidency (-)
Borrowings
Net free reserves(+ lI Net oorrowed(-)

E'UOZPV

C\J)

·J!le::>
IO:>SpUI!J:I UI! S
1:St 'ON 11WH3<1

SelectedAssetsandliabilities
LargeCommercialBanks

•

Amount
Outstanding
7/16/80

136,940
115,294
33,204
46,666
23,584
973
6,274
15,372
44,161
31,948
28,719
61,534
53,262
22,116
Weekended
7/16/80

-

65
47
111

Changefrom
year ago
Dollar
Percent

Change
from
7/9/80

-

-

300
190
106
111
19
28
2
112
403
191
143
81
15
113

-

-

Weekended
7/9/80
10
2
8

7,696
8,610
1,819
7,624
1,129
615
1,349
435
558
369
1,969
11,492
11,687
4,966

6.0
8.1
5.8
19.5
5.0
- 38.7
- 17.7
2.9
1.3
1.2
- 6.4
23.0
28.1
29.0

Comparable
period

15
84
69

* Excludestradmg account securities.
# Includes items not shown separately.
Editorialcommentsmaybeaddressed
to theeditor(WilliamBurke)or to theauthor••.. Freecopiesof this
andotherFederalReserve
publications
canbeobtainedbycallingor writingthePublicInformationSection,
FederalReserve
Bankof SanFrandsco,P.O.Box7702,SanFrancisco
94120.Phone(415)

•

l?>jSl?I'v'