View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

October 3,1975

Tumbling Gold
September was a calamitous
month for gold bugs. Within a
month, the price of gold nose-dived
from $160 to $129 per ounce.
Although prices later recovered,
the steep decline left a hollow
feeling that the market might be a
bottomless pit. Financial analysts
correctly attributed the decline to
decisions on gold reached at the
August meeting of the Interim
Committee of the Governors of
the International Monetary Fund.
IMF decisions

The Interim Committee's decisions
were indeed momentous. First, the
Committee recommended the
abolition of the official price of
gold, which had been set at
$42.22 per ounce since the second
devaluation of the U.S. dollar in
February, 1973. Second, it recom­
mended removal of all the obliga­
tions under the IMF Articles of
Agreement requiring the use of
gold in transactions between
members and the Fund. Third, the
group agreed that the IMF should
return one-sixth of its 153 million
ounces of gold to members and
should sell off another one-sixth
at the market price, with the profit
from the sale to be used to
benefit the developing nations.
In a parallel action, the Group of
Ten (Belgium, Canada, France, West
Germany, Italy, Japan, Nether­
lands, Sweden, U.K., and U.S.)
agreed for a period of two years,
(a) not to peg the price of gold, (b)
not to increase the total official
stock of gold now in the hands of
the IMF and the Group 10 countries,
1
Digitized for FRA SER


and (c) to abide by any further
conditions governing gold arising
from future meetings of their
central-bank representatives.
In a formal sense, the Interim
Committee's decisions were merely
recommendations to amend the
IMF Articles of Agreement. Before
becoming effective, the entire
amendment process would take at
least eighteen months.
In fact, however, the impact of the
Interim Committee's decisions
will be felt much sooner. Because
of the Committee's wide national
representation—eleven major in­
dustrial nations and ten develop­
ing nations—as well as the Gover­
nors' favorable response, ultimate
ratification of the proposed
amendments is a foregone conclu­
sion. Ways may be found to
short-cut the amendment process
by arrangements which would
permit the IMF to carry out the
proposed measures. Moreover,
events of the past four years have
outstripped the IMF Articles of
Agreement. Few members will
feel constrained to conduct gold
transactions any longer at the
official price of $42.22 per ounce.
Since mid-1972 the market price
of gold has stayed well above the
unrealistic official price. As a
result, official gold holdings, in­
cluding those of the IMF and
national monetary authorities,
have been effectively frozen. The
abolition of the official gold price
thus frees the reserves for interna­
tional transfers.
(continued on page 2)

o

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not
necessarily reflect the views of the management of the
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, nor of the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Some have hailed the decision as a
move towards reactivation of gold
reserves for payment purposes. The
IMF Governor for South Africa,
for instance, predicted that “ gold
will be as sought-after as ever as
an element of strength in an
unstable world.” Others, how­
ever, were not as sanguine, argu­
ing that the freeing of gold reserves
could bring about an avalanche
of gold onto the market. The
critical question is thus what this
development portends for the
future of the gold market.
Gold as a store of value
Advocates of gold stress its histor­
ical role as a universally accepted
store of value. Especially during
times of war, uncertainty, and
inflation, gold provides a haven
for the savings of both rich and
poor. For national governments, the
fear of foreign-exchange assets
being frozen or expropriated by
hostile foreign authorities rein­
forces the argument for keeping
national reserves partly in gold.
Gold bugs predict that the trend of
gold prices will depend primarily on
the expected rate of world infla­
tion and the expected degree of
political disturbances. To the
extent that the future is clouded
with uncertainty and threatened
with instability, individuals and
governments will not only hang on
to their gold but will even de­
mand more.
The gold bugs' basic premise is that
gold will continue to be a safe
haven for personal and national

Digitized for FRA SER


savings. It is that very premise which
needs to be re-examined in view
of the recent IMF and Group-10
decisions.
Gold's universal popularity extends
far back into history. For centuries
and in many lands, gold was used
either directly as money or indirect­
ly as a backing of national monies.
Even in the present century, when
one after another national cur­
rency lost its gold backing, gold
continued to serve as an interna­
tional means of payments at a fixed
price in terms of some key interna­
tional currency. For most of the
period from 1717 to 1934, gold
could be converted into the
British pound at the equivalent rate
of $20 per ounce; from 1934 to
1971, it could be converted into the
U.S. dollar at the rate of $35 per
ounce. Thus, for centuries, gold
was considered a safe store of
value because of its assured
convertibility into a key interna­
tional currency at a fix ed rate.
Gold's universal value stemmed
primarily from its backing by a
key international currency, which
had relatively stable purchasing
power over goods and services
everywhere—not merely in the
country of its origin. It is a common
misconception—a sort of cartbefore-horse thinking—to hold
that a key international currency is

made so because it is backed by
gold, which in turn possesses an
“ intrinsic” value because of its
general acceptability.
Gold cut adrift

So long as the dollar possessed
relatively stable purchasing pow­
er, gold tied to the dollar provided
a relatively safe store of value.
However, as inflation accelerated
in the U.S. in the late 1960's, gold was
no longer such a safe asset. The
U.S. monetary authorities had then
two possible options—(a) raise
the official price of gold, so as to
preserve the purchasing power of
gold, and (b) cut the link between
the dollar and gold, permitting gold
to find its own price in the
market. In fact, the U.S. Treasury
did both. It suspended gold
convertibility of the dollar in Au­
gust 1971, and subsequently raised
the official price of gold first to $38
per ounce and then to $42.22 per
ounce. However, since the dollar
was no longer convertible into
gold, the official price of gold
had little meaning in relation to its
real purchasing power.
Cut loose from its moorings, the
market price of gold shot skyhigh, reaching $195 per ounce at
year-end 1974. Most of the
driving force came from specula­
tive demand, as industrial use
accounted for merely 40 percent of

the 1,180 metric tons supplied to the
market in 1974. But gold prices
then dropped precipitously in
1975. Without official price peg­
ging, gold has become a highly
risky asset.
Because of the recent IMF and
Group-10 decisions, gold has lost
its monetary support for the fore­
seeable future. Unless repegged
to an international currency, it will
float entirely on its own, with its
price continually buffeted by cur­
rent market sentiment. The precari­
ousness of this market is en­
hanced by the existence of a huge
gold stock in private and official
hands, relative to the volume of
current production and consump­
tion. In such a market, stability is
constantly threatened by what
might happen to that overhang­
ing stock. Indeed, under the
present circumstances, it is diffi­
cult to conceive of a less safe store
of value than gold.
The advocates of gold may be
mistaken in their indiscriminate
trust in the “ intrinsic” value of
gold, but they are correct in their
belief in the social function of gold
amid conditions of uncertainty.
Individuals and governments alike
need a safe store of savings in this
imperfect world. Even with the
SDR, one may question if the
world's finance ministers and
central-bank governors have devel­
oped an international financial
asset capable of fulfilling all the
functions which gold performed in
the past.
Hang-Sheng Cheng

Digitized for FRA SER


ucnSujqseM • i|ein •
MBMBH

•

uo S o jo

E |U J O p |E 3

.

• epEAON . oqepi

E U O Z J jy

•

• J j|B 3 'O D S p U B J J U E S
ZSL

ON UWlHd
aivd

a o v is o d s t i
n v w s s v i d is a id

BANKING DATA—TWELFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)
Selected Assets and Liabilities
Large Commercial Banks

Amount
Outstanding
9/17/75

Loans (gross, adjusted) and investments*
Loans (gross, adjusted)—total
Security loans
Commercial and industrial
Real estate
Consumer instalment
U.S. Treasury securities
Other securities
Deposits (less cash items)—total*
Demand deposits (adjusted)
U.S. Government deposits
Time deposits—total*
States and political subdivisions
Savings deposits
Other time deposits!
Large negotiable C D ’s

86,003
64,769
1,713
22,611
19,561
10,023
8,660
12,574
86,144
24,245
615
59,931
5,790
20,754
29,645
15,730

Weekly Averages
of Daily Figures

W eek ended
9/17/75

Member Bank Reserve Position
Excess Reserves
Borrowings
Net free (+) / Net borrowed (-)
Federal Funds—Seven Large Banks
Interbank Federal fund transactions
Net purchases (+) / Net sales (-)
Transactions of U.S. security dealers
Net loans (+) / Net borrowings (-)

Change
from
9/10/75
-

+
+
+
+
-

+
+
+
-

+
+
+

-

20
119
99

+
+

63
509
574
75
1
25
522
76
114
0
257
54
42
45
97
16

Change from
year ago
Dollar
Percent
+ 1,348
3,267
598
1,639
318
+
341
+ 4,620
5
+ 4,873
+ 1,516
229
+ 4,261
172
+ 3,035
+
954
+
481

W eek ended
9/10/75

+
-

+
+
-

+
+
-

+
-

+
+
+

1.59
4.80
25.88
6.76
1.60
3.52
114.36
0.04
6.00
6.67
27.13
7.65
2.88
17.13
3.33
3.15

Comparable
year-ago period

-

8
29
21

-

98
147
49

1,678

+

1,486

+

1,308

964

+

915

+

695

in c lu d e s items not shown separately. ^Individuals, partnerships and corporations.

Information on this and other publications can be obtained by calling or writing the Public
Information Section, Federal Reserve Bank o f San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco 94120.
Phone (415) 397-1137.
Digitized for FRA SER


B>(SE|V