View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY LETTER

March 6, 1987

The Trade Balance and the Economic Outlook
Since the value of the u.s. dollar peaked in February 1985, economic commentators have been
waiting anxiously for the u.s. trade balance to
improve. The failure of the trade balance to turn
around has been held responsible for dampening GNP growth, while continued expectations
of its eventual improvement form the basis of
optimistic forecasts of future GNP growth.
Unfortunately, the discussion of the relationship
between the trade balance and domestic economic growth has generally failed to specify
clearly the driving forces behind the expected
trade improvement. This Letter attempts to clarify the relationship between the trade balance
and the level of domestic economic activity by
focusing on three possible factors that have figured prominently in recent discussions: U.S. fiscal policy, U.S. monetary policy, and policy
actions by our major trading partners - Japan
and West Germany in particular.
Depending on which of these fundamental
forces is causing the economy to adjust, an
improved trade balance and more rapid growth
may develop. But an improved trade balance
and less rapid growth is a combination that can
also easily arise. Moreover, this latter outcome is
particularly likely to be produced byexpenditure cuts designed to reduce the federal budget
deficit.
In general, no systematic relationship between
net exports and economic growth should be
expected. The chart shows the annual growth
rate of u.s. real GNP since 1970 together with
the real value of the current account. The current account is equal to the net trade balance of
goods and services plus net remittances, pensions, and other unilateral transfer payments.
Strong output growth has been associated with
both an improving current account, asin 1978,
and a worsening current account, as in 1984.

Reasons
If we wish to draw the correct implications

about a current account improvement for GNP
growth, it is necessary to understand the forces
bringing about the current account
improvement.
First, though, a word about the most frequently
mentioned reason to expect a rise in our net
exports - the fall in the value of the dollar. As
the dollar declines in value against other currencies, U.s.-produced goods become cheaper relative to foreign-produced goods. This will tend to
increase U.s. exports as foreigners increase their
demand for cheaper u.s. goods; and it will tend
to decrease U.s. imports as U.s. consumers substitute U.s. products for the more expensive foreign goods. Net exports should eventually rise in
response to the fall in the value of the dollar.
The problem with this explanation is that it fails
to specify the reason for the fall in the dollar's
value! As will be seen from the examples discussed below, a falling dollar and rising net
exports can be associated w,ith stronger real economic growth, or with weaker growth. It all
depends on what causes the exchange rate, the
trade balance, and real growth to adjust.

U.S. fiscal policy
Changes in the stance of fiscal policy in the u.s.
will affect the value of the dollar, u.s. net
exports, and the level of domestic economic
activity. To understand the effects of fiscal policy, it is useful to distinguish between current
policy changes and expected future policy
changes.
A contractionary fiscal policy designed to
reduce the current federal budget deficit is one
example of a policy that is likely to improve the
trade balance, yet lead to slower real growth.
For example, a reduction in government purchases of goods and services will directly lower
the demand for domestic output and reduce the
borrowing needs of the government. A decline
in the government's borrowing needs will tend
to put downward pressure on market interest

FRBSF
rates. As U.s. interest rates decline relative to
rates of return available in other countries, so
will the value of the u.s. dollar.
The resulting decline in the dollar will tend to
stimulate U.S. exports, but not to the extent of
offsetting the contractionary effect of the fiscal
policy. Slower growth will result in the shortrun.
This scenario is the reverse of what many analysts claim occurred during the first half of the
1980s. At that time, expansionary fiscal policy,
consisting of tax cuts in 1981 and the rapid
increase in defense spending, generated high
real interest rates, a strong dollar, and a trade
deficit at the same time that it helped move the
economy out of the 1982 recession. Thus, faster
growth was accompanied by a deterioration in
the trade balance.
Perhaps more pertinent to our understanding of
the effect of fiscal policy in the current environment are the effects, not of current fiscal actions
to reduce the budget deficit, but of expectations
of future actions to reduce the budget deficit.
Over the last year, forecasters have generally
lowered their deficit projections for the rest of
the 1980s and into the 1990s. Instead of projections of $200 billion deficits for many years to
come, projections show the federal deficit
declining gradually over the next several years.
If actual fiscal policy changes affect current
short-term interest rates, then the expectation of
a change in future deficits should affect expectations of future short-term interest rates. Interest
rates on long-term assets reflect both current
short-term interest rates and the market's expectations of future short rates over the life of the
long-term asset. Consequently, changes in
expected future short-term rates will influence
the current level of long-term rates.
Through this "expectational" channel, expectations offuture contractionary fiscal policy are
likely to reduce the current level of interest rates
in the U.S. Since investing in U.s. financial
assets would become less attractive, the fall in
interest rates would also lead to a depreciation
of the dollar against other currencies. This fall in
the dollar would eventually produce a rise in net
exports.
Because the dollar would not be declining as the
result of a reduction in any other component of

the demand for u.s. goods and services, the rise
in net exports would represent a net increase in
the demand for our output. The rise in net
exports also would stimulate U.s. production
and lead to stronger growth. This case differs
from the effects induced by a current fiscal contractionsince the actual decline in government
spending occurs in the future, that is, there is no
simultaneous decline in government purchases
to offset the rise in net exports.

U.S. monetary policy
U.s. monetary policy can also affect the trade
balance. For example, an expansionary monetary policy that temporarily lowers U.s. interest
rates will also tend to produce a fall in the value
of the dollar. The dollar's fall, in turn, will stimulate U.S. exports and reduce our imports by
making foreign goods relatively more expensive.
The improved trade balance that would result
from an expansionary U.s. monetary policy
represents a net increase in the demand for u.s.
output. Domestic production will rise in
response. This exchange rate-induced improvement in the trade balance is one of the channels
through which a monetary expansion leads to
increased economic growth.
Foreign economic expansion

Recent press accounts on the trade deficit have
stressed the attempts by the Reagan Administration to pressure japan and West Germany into
adopting more expansionary policies. Increased
growth in these two major economies would
presumably increase the demand for U.S. goods
and services and thereby cut our trade deficit
and stimulate growth in the u.s. "For U.S.
exports to grow, the economies of our trading
partners must grow", according to President
Reagan in this year's Economic Report of the
President. However, this rosy outcome may
depend crucially on the economic policies those
countries use to generate increased growth.
A japanese fiscal expansion, for example, would
lead to the desired result of a reduced trade deficit and increased economic growth for the U.S.
The japanese expansion would tend to raise
interest rates in japan and drive up the value of
the yen. By making japanese-produced goods
more expensive, the stronger yen would reduce
u.s. imports of japanese goods, while simultaneously increasing the demand by japan for
u.s. goods. This increase in our net exports,
since it would not be offset by a decline in any

No Systematic Relationship Between
the Current Account and Economic Growth
Billions$
Annual Rate

Annualized Growth
Rate (Percent)

40

10
8

0

6

-40

4
2

-80

01-N---+--+------++-+---+----T-.-------I
-120
-2

1970

1972

1974

1976

1976

1960

1982

1984

1986

other component of demand, would stimulate
growth in the u.s.
The outcome could be quite different if japan
decided to stimulate its economy through the
use of expansionary monetary policy. In recent
months, some u.s. officials have suggested that
the Bank of Japan should cut its discount rate.
On February 23, the Bank of japan announced a
reduction in its discount rate from 3 percent to
2V2 percent. Such a cut will tend to reduce the
general level of interest rates in japan and produce a drop in the value of the yen. But a fall in
the yen makes japanese goods less expensive
and tends to reduce u.s. exports to japan while
increasing our imports from Japan. The results
are a worsening of our trade balance and a
slowing of u.s. growth.
The adverse effect on our growth and our trade
balance of aforeign expansion fueled by monetary growth would be offset somewhat by the
effects of the expanding income abroad. The
above-mentioned expansion in japan generated
by monetary policy would tend to produce a rise
in U.s. exports as income in japan rises. This
rise in U.s. exports may dominate the impact of
the falling yen, and lead to an improvement in
U.s. net exports. Clearly, the expansionary effect
on the u.s. of greater growth abroad will
depend crucially on the particular policies our
trading partners adopt to expand their
economies.

Lessons
A fall in the value of the dollar should improve
our trade balance, but whether that improvement is associated with faster GNP growth will
depend on the cause of the dollar decl ine. Fiscal
action to reduce the current federal budget deficit will contribute to a rise in net exports, but
such a policy will also tend to slow real growth.
Expected fiscal deficit reduction in the future or
current expansionary monetary policy will both
work to lower the trade deficit and to stimulate
real growth.
The effects of an economic expansion among
our trading partners on u.S. growth will depend
on the particular policies used by those countries. More expansionary fiscal policy in japan
and/or Germany should improve our trade balance and stimulate growth in the u.s. An expansion induced by monetary growth, however,
may lead to a much smaller improvement in net
exports and could even worsen our trade deficit.
These separate policies can be combined in
ways that may contribute to an improved trade
balance while strengthening real growth. For
example, a tighter domestic fiscal policy accompanied by easier domestic monetary policy
would work towards reducing the trade deficit
without producing the slower growth that would
result from a fiscal contraction alone.
Understanding the connection between movements in the trade balance and the outlook for
growth requires a consideration of the forces
causing the current fall in the value of the dollar.
These forces may include expectations of tighter
u.s. fiscal policy in the future and current market perceptions of some monetary stimulus. In
principle, such a policy combination implies
that the induced fall in the dollar and rise in net
exports should result in a net gain for u.s.
growth.
However, because the future eventually
becomes the present, policymakers must eventually take the contractionary fiscal steps necessary to reduce the budget deficit. To avoid
producing slower growth and to improve the
trade balance further, such steps may require the
simultaneous implementation of an easier monetary policy.

Carl Walsh
Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve BanI< of San
Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (Gregory Tong) or to the author •... Free copies of Federal Reserve publications
can be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco
94120. Phone (415) 974-2246.

uo~6U!4S0m

040PI

4o~n

!!omoH O!UJoJ!l0)

U060JO
ouoz!J~

OpOA0U
0>tsol~

O)SI)UOJ:J UOS

JO

~U08

aAJaSa~ IOJapa:J

~uaw~Jodaa LpJOaSa~
BANKING DATA-TWELFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)

Selected Assets and liabilities
Large Commercial Banks
Loans, Leases and Investments 1 2
Loans and Leases 1 6
Commercial and Industrial
Real estate
Loans to Individuals
Leases
U.S. Treasury and Agency Securities 2
Other Secu rities 2
Total Deposits
Demand Deposits
Demand Deposits Adjusted 3
Other Transaction Balances 4
Total Non-Transaction Balances 6
Money Market Deposit
Accounts-Total
Time Deposits in Amounts of
$100,000 or more
Other Liabilities for Borrowed MoneyS

Two Week Averages
of Daily Figures

Amount
Outstanding

2/11/87
205,365
184,344
54,339
67,845
38,059
5,459
13,943
7,078
206,749
51,611
35,741
19,269
135,869

Change from 2/12/86
Dollar
Percent!

Change
from

2/4/87
-

-

-

-

-

824
790
461
100
19
29
10
45
2,333
2,116
504
361
145

46,909

91
141

-

13

32,431
24,824

-

-

1.6
1.0
2.5
2.6
5.7
4.0
24.3
- 15.2
3.2
11.3
10.2
28.9
2.2

1,336

-

3,292
1,838
1,362
1,768
2,325
229
2,729
1,276
6,502
5,270
3,310
4,331
3,099

2.9

6,661
751

Period ended

Period ended

2/9/87

1/26/87

Reserve Position, All Reporting Banks
Excess Reserves (+ J/Deficiency (-)
Borrowings
Net free reserves (+ J/Net borrowed( - J
1

111
6
106

67
15
52

Includes loss reserves, unearned income, excludes interbank loans

2 Excludes trading account securities
3 Excludes
government and depository institution deposits and cash items
4 ATS, NOW, Super NOW and savings accounts with telephone transfers

u.s.

S Includes borrowing via FRB, TT&L notes, Fed Funds, RPs and other sources
6 Includes items not shown separately
7

Annual ized percent change

-

-

17.0
2.9