View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY LETTER

January 13, 1989

Time To Give Credit Its Due?
The last ten years have seen significant innovations in the financial sector of our economy that
have altered the environment in which the Federal Reserve conducts monetary policy. This
Letter reviews some of these developments and
argues that now may be a good time to examine
whether credit-based measures of financial intermediation might be useful policy indicators
instead of, or in addition to, the traditional monetary aggregate measures.

Money-based policies
Over most of the period since 1975, the Federal
Reserve has expressed its pol icy stance by setti ng
targets for the growth of the monetary aggregates,
M1, M2, and M3. Until qUite recently, M1, which
comprises the outstanding stocks of currency and
fully-checkable deposits, was found to be a particularly useful target for policy purposes,
because it was a reasonably reliable leading indicator of real GNP and inflation. Rapid growth
in M1 tended to signal an impending uptick in
economic activity and hence a need to restrict
the supply of bank reserves in order to push up
interest rates, slow the growth of the economy,
and head off inflation.
This observed behavior of M1 as a leading indicator rested on solid theoretical ground. Both
Keynesian and monetarist economists argue that
the supply of money has an important bearing on
the rate of price iriflation in the economy. They
agree that, at least in the short run, the supply of
and demand for money, relative to other, less liquid, financial assets, influence the level of
interest rates, which in turn affect the level of
economic activity and the rate of inflation. Monetary policy works by affecting the ability of the
banking system to create money. When it undertakes open market operations that decrease bank
reserves, the Federal Reserve indirectly reduces
the supply of money relative to the demand for it,
causing interest rates to rise and economic activity to slow. Since M1 comprises the highly
liquid assets that serve as the medium of exchange in the economy, it 'corresponds closely to

the concept of money in this theoretical framework.
Thus, on theoretical as well as purely empirical
grounds, M1 was a logical target for monetary
policy. In addition, because currency and checkable deposits did not pay interest, members of
the public had a strong incentive to limit their
holdings of M1 to the minimum level needed for
transactions purposes. As a result, the public's
demand for M1 was more directly related to developments in the macroeconomy than were the
broader aggregates.

Financial innovation
In the last ten years, virtually all the restrictions
on the interest yields payable by depository institutions on their deposit liabilities have been
swept away. This process of deregulation has reduced the distinctions both among the monetary
aggregates and between monetary and nonmonetary assets.
The introduction of interest-bearing checking accounts, for example, has reduced depositors'
incentives to monitor carefully the distribution of
their liquid assets between transactions and nontransactions accounts. As a result, checkable
deposits now contain both transactions funds
and saving balances. This commingling of transactions and saving balances has lessened the
uniqueness of M1 and weakened the link between aggregate economic activity and the
demand for the narrow aggregate. As a result, M1
no longer is a reliable leading indicator, and the
Federal Reserve ceased setting formal targets for
the growth of this aggregate in 1987.
However, this change in the nature of M1 is just
one manifestation of a more fundamental concern that the institutional and regulatory changes
of the last decade have made the line between
instruments that serve as "money" and those that
do not more difficult to draw. This weakens the
usefulness of the traditional theoretical paradigm
in which interest rates are viewed as being deter-

FRBSF
mined by the interaction between the supply of
and the demand for money, since the definition of
what we mean by "money" has become a lot
more "fuzzy:'

A problem for the Federal Reserve
From the point of view of the Federal Reserve, a
more immediate implication of this "fuzziness"
is that there is no longer a single,well-under~
stood, leading indicator that will serve as a
reliable guide in the formulation of monetary policy. The Federal Reserve continues to set targets
for the broad monetary aggregates, M2 and M3,
but recognizes that at times neither one may be a
particularly reliable indicator in the short run. In
1987, for example, M2 increased only four percent, which was below the lower bound of the
targeted 5V2 to 8V2 percent range, while the
economy expanded strongly and inflation picked
up a bit. Hence, the growth of M2 and M3 relative to target receives less attention than the
growth of M1 did in the early 1980s.
In view of the theoretical paradigm that has
guided monetary policy for some time now,
economists understandably would like to find
some alternative monetary indicator that could
replace M1 as a policy target. However, deregulation may have so muddied the distinction
between money and other assets that this distinction and the paradigm that considers it important
may no longer be useful for policy purposes. A
new paradigm and a new indicator may be
necessary.

The role of intermediaries
One potentially promising avenue of research is
the impact of financial intermediation on the
economy. For the economy to grow, we must
continually invest resources in plant and equipment, education, homes, cars, and other durable
goods. The funds needed to finance these investments ultimately come from the nation's savings.
Financial intermediaries assist in the process of
channelling funds from those who save to those
who are in a position to undertake productive investments. By simultaneously providing savers
with instruments that meet their individual maturity, denomination, and risk requirements, and
borrowers with financing suited to their specific
needs, intermediaries reduce the cost of moving
funds from savers to investors. This lowers the
general level of interest rates facing investors,
thus making some investment projects profitable

that otherwise would not be. More investment
occurs and we accumulate larger stocks of
capital.
The traditional money-interest rate paradigm
does not dispute this role of financial intermediaries in reducing the cost of capital in the long
run, but does suggest that changes in the degree
of intermediation are not significant factors affecting interest rates in the short run. In recent years,
however, a number of economists have begun to
examine the shorter-run impact of changes in the
level of intermediation, or at least certain types of
intermediation, on interest rates, economic activity, and prices. The emphasis of this research is
on why these financial intermediaries come into
existence and on how shocks to their ability to
intermediate affect the overall economy. These
economists argue that banks, in particular, have
an impact on the economy not only because, as
the traditional paradigm suggests, they create
money, but also because they provide a particularly important form of financial intermediation
for which there are few good substitutes.
Unlike most other intermediaries, banks maintain
continuing business relationships with their
customers, through the deposit and transactions
services they supply. These continuing relationships make it easier for banks to obtain up-todate information about the credit-worthiness of
their customers and to monitor their activities.
Having access to this information enables banks
to provide credit to many smaller or more risky
businesses and to individuals, who would find it
difficult or impossible to borrow in anonymous
financial markets. As part of their continuing
customer relationships, banks specialize in
providing short-term "repeat borrowing" to their
customers rather than long-term loans of the type
provided, for example, by insurance companies
or pension funds. According to this view, then,
the activities of banks are important because they
alone provide a particularly important form of
credit.
Thus, unlike the traditional paradigm, which
claims that a tight monetary policy raises interest
rates by reducing the supply of money relative to
the demand for it, this view suggests that a decrease in bank reserves restricts the ability of
banks to supply credit and it is this that drives up
interest rates, with the decrease in the money
stock being viewed as a by-product.

An early example of this research was the finding
by economist Ben Bernanke that the collapse of
the banking system in the 1930s worsened the
Depression not so much because it reduced the
money supply as because it interrupted the flow
of bank credit. If this financial disruption had not
occurred, Bernanke claims, nonfinancial businesses might have been better able to weather
the downturn.

as non-bank institutions like money market mutual funds have begun to issue liabilities that are
close substitutes for transactions accounts.
Checkable deposits at banks now fund only onethird of all outstanding bank loans. Conversely,
the volume of bank loans represents only onehalf of total M3. As a result, changes in neither
the broad nor the narrow concept of money are
good indicators of changes in the flow of bank
credit.

Is a new indicator needed?
In the not-too-distant past, a monetary aggregate
like M1 could serve equally well as an indicator
of changes either in the money supply/money
demand relationship or in the degree of bank intermediation. This was because banks raised the
bulk of their funds by issuing checkable deposits.
In the 1950s, demand deposits represented about
two-thirds of total bank liabilities. This meant
that changes in the outstanding stock of transactions deposits were closely related to changes in
the amount of financial intermediation through
the banking system.
When the Federal Reserve reduced the stock of
reserves and interest rates rose, this rise could be
attributed equally well either to the slowing in
monetary growth or to the simultaneous decline
in the degree of financial intermediation provided by banks. Nonetheless, most economists
found the money supply/money demand paradigm a more useful way of analyzing interest rate
movements, and largely ignored the macroeconomic effects of changes in financial
markets that did not involve changes in the demand for or supply of money.
Over the last three decades, however, the link
between the stock of transactions money and the
supply of bank credit has weakened, as banks
have issued more non-transactions liabilities and

Consequently, if bank intermediation is an important determinant of interest rates, output, and
prices, as some of the recent research suggests, a
monetary aggregate no longer will provide the
proper signals to policy-makers. Rather than look
for a monetary indicator for policy, we may find it
more useful to turn our attention to credit-based
measures. Although broad measures of total debt
outstanding already are monitored by the Federal
Reserve, these do not appear to be good shortrun indicators. The theoretical approach that
focuses on the special role of banks or bank-like
intermediaries, suggests that narrower credit aggregates thatreflect the share of total credit flows
provided by these institutions may turn out to be
more useful for policy purposes.
It must be recognized however, that although
these credit flows might provide useful information for policy purposes, it is unlikely that policymakers would be able to control them with any
precision. Since banks issue many liabilities with
either zero or low reserve requirements and have
large holdings of marketable securities, the ability of the Federal Reserve to alter the stock of
bank loans by changing the supply of bank reserves is probably quite limited.

Brian Motley
Senior Economist

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be ad&essed to the editor (Barbara Bennett) or to the author.... Free copies of Federal Reserve
publications can be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702,
San Francisco 94120. Phone (415) 974-2246.

¥

Research Department

Federal Reserve
Bank of
San Francisco
Alaska
nevada

Arizona
Oregon

California Hawaii
Utah

Idaho

Washington

BULK RATE MAIL
U.s. POST AGE
PAID
PERMIT NO. 752
San Francisco, Calif.