View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY lErrEA

February 1, 1991

Taiwan's Trade Surpluses
In the 1980s, Taiwan's trade surplus in goods
and services reached unprecedented levels,
peaking at nearly 21 percent of GNP in 1986.
By comparison, trade surpluses peaked at 1.1 to
1.2 percent of GNP in Japan and Germany and
7.7 percent in Korea in the 1980s.
Most explanations for Taiwan's trade surpluses

have focused on the country's competitive advantages, in particular, on the role of Taiwan's
nominal exchange rate policy in limiting the
appreciation of the New Taiwan (NT) dollar.
However, other factors that may be traced to
Taiwan's exchange rate policy have received less
attention, and may also have contributed to the
country's remarkable trade surpluses. As discussed below, low inflation appears to have been
an important contributor to Taiwan's competitiveness in the 1980s. Furthermore, Taiwan's trade
surpluses in the 1980s reflect an increase in
Taiwan's domestic saving and a sharp decline
in investment as a proportion of GNP.
This Letter attempts to clarify how exchange
rate and sterilization policies may have contributed to the persistence of trade surpluses in
Taiwan through their effects on inflation, saving,
and investment. The discussion will focus on
three factors that may have influenced adjustment: (1) government efforts to limit the rate of
appreciation of the New Taiwan (NT) dollar may
have stimulated the speculative demand for
money, thus attenuating inflationary pressures;
(2) government exchange rate policy contributed
to a boom in domestic asset prices, which may
have encouraged higher saving while dampening
investment spending; (3) by absorbing the saving
of Taiwan residents, government sterilization
policy may have "crowded out" domestic
investment spending to some degree.
Exchange rate policy
Although Taiwan's trade surpluses began
widening in 1981, strong upward pressure on
the NT dollar became most apparent late in
1985. At that time, the major industrial countries
voiced concerns about surpluses in Taiwan and
other Asian economies which reinforced the per-

ception that the NT dollar was undervalued and
would have to adjust upward. The perception
triggered a surge in speculative private capital
inflows, for example, through foreign lending to
Taiwan banks. The present discussion will focus
on the economic impact of the government's exchange rate policy in the face of capital inflows.
These occurred chiefly between 1985 and 1987,
after which the government effectively restricted
short-term capital inflows in Taiwan.

In an effort to offset the upward pressure on
the NT dollar resulting from capital inflows the
Central Bank of China (CBC) pursued a policy
of purchasing foreign currency. Since such purchases involved the sale of NT dollars, they
produced a substantial increase in the domestic
money supply which tended to limit the rate of
currency appreciation. (Specifically, the CBC's
purchases or sales of foreign currency were designed to ensure that the daily adjustment of the
spot exchange rate would not exceed 2.25 percent of the central rate on the previous business
day.) As a result of this policy, the CBC's foreign
asset holdings increased sharply, from NT$504
billion in 1983, to a peak of NT$2.26 trillion in
1987, about 30 times its level ten years earlier.
(In foreign currency terms, Taiwan's foreign
exchange reserves peaked at US$77 billion in
1987, third largest after Japan and Germany.)
In a second action, the government sought to
offset-or sterilize-the expansionary impact
of exchange market intervention on the domestic
money supply by sharply reducing domestic
credit. The CBC accomplished this by borrowing
in the form of interest-bearing short-term central
bank certificates of deposits and savings bonds.
As financial institutions surrendered money in
order to acquire interest-bearing CBC paper, the
issuance of such paper absorbed a significant
proportion of the liquidity that had been created
by the CBC's purchases of foreign currency assets. The amount of interest-bearing paper outstanding issued by the CBC increased from
NT$14 billion in 1983 to a peak of nearly NT$1.2
trillion in 1987, and was still NT$755 billion at
the end of 1988. At their 1987 peak, these inter-

FRBSF

Chart 1
Taiwan's Exchange Rates

Trade-Weighted
Index (1980=100)

01
I1

est-bearing liabilities of the CBC amounted to 52
percent of the foreign assets held by the esc,
and 180 percent of the supply of base money.

.....

These massive sterilization efforts, however, did
not prevent acceleration in annual base money
growth from around 12 percent in 1983-1985 to
close to 30 percent in 1986-1988. (Base money
corresponds to the monetary reserves held by the
domestic banking system with the central bank.)

140
130
120
110

...........'

100

1987

1989

90

Lagging adjustment
Taiwan's efforts to limit the rate of appreciation
of its currency are widely bel ieved to have enhanced its external competitiveness and contributed to its large trade surpluses in the 1980s.
However, theory suggests that efforts to maintain
the exchange rate below its equilibrium value
will lead to other adjustments that will reduce
trade surpluses. In the case of Taiwan, the rapid
expansion in liquidity should have created inflationary pressures, thus eroding Taiwan's external
competitiveness. At the same time, the expansionary stimulus should lead to reduced saving
and increased investment, which, by reducing
Taiwan's available saving, would lead to reductions in Taiwan's trade surpluses. (A trade surplus
means a country is selling more than it is purchasing abroad; or equivalently, that saving
exceeds investment). However, these expansionary effects appear to have been muted.
First, Taiwan's inflation rate remained below
inflation among its major trading partners,
even following the sharp acceleration in money
growth. This significantly enhanced Taiwan's external competitiveness. As illustrated in Chart 1,
Taiwan's trade-weighted nominal exchange rate,
on balance, appreciated in the 1980s. However,
because of Taiwan's low inflation rate, Taiwan's
real (inflation-adjusted) exchange rate appreciated by much less than the corresponding
nominal index.
Second, Taiwan's saving continued to rise and
investment continued to fall for some time after
1985 (Chart 2). In spite of a subsequent reversal
of these trends, Taiwan's trade surpluses were still
high in comparison to its own historical experience, or to that of other countries, by the end of
the 1980s.
While the reasons for lagging adjustment are
not enti rely clear, exchange rate pol icy may have

Chart 2
Taiwan's Trade Balance,
Saving, and Investment

Percentage
of GNP

.- .....

........ ..' .

45

Saving
'

.' .

".

35
25
15
5

1981

1983

1985

-5
1987

1989

played a role, through its effects on the speculative demand for money and on the portfolio
investment decisions of Taiwan residents. In
retrospect, it appears that by limiting currency
appreciation at a predictable rate (2.25 percent
a day), government exchange rate policy maintained the perception that the exchange rate
would continue to appreciate, and increased the
speculative demand for NT dollars. The speculative increase in the demand for money in Taiwan
appears to have significantly dampened any inflationary pressures from the rapid money growth
produced by intervention in exchange markets,
and slowed the adjustment in the trade account.
(The increase in money demand is reflected in a
sharp decline in the velocity of money (M1) in
Taiwan from 1985 to 1988.)

Portfolio investment decisions
The reduction in Taiwan's trade surpluses
may also have been slowed by two effects of
exchange rate policy on portfolio investment
decisions in Taiwan, which had possibly significant effects on saving and investment behavior.

First, Taiwan's exchange rate policy attracted
speculators whose efforts to diversify their NT
dollar asset holdings triggered a boom in asset
prices (although not in the prices of goods). In
some places, land prices reportedly rose as much
as 250 percent between 1987 and 1989. Due to
thinness in the stock market and a subsequent
speculative frenzy, stock price increases were
even steeper. The stock price index rose from
945 in 1986 to 8618 in 1989, raising priceearnings ratios of listed companies to over 55
by the end of 1989 (compared to 14 in the U.S.,
and 62 in Japan). However, the effect of the
boom in stock prices in channeling more funds
for investment purposes was limited by the reluctance of Taiwan enterprises to list in the stock
market. Between 1986 and 1989 listed companies increased from 130 to only 181, while in
comparison the number of brokers and dealers
rose from 67 to 278.
The unprecedented run-up in domestic asset
values may have encouraged domestic residents
to postpone consumption in order to engage in
speculation, thus increasing the rate of saving.
At the same time, the speculative boom may
have shifted the asset-demand of domestic residents to the stock and real estate markets, in
comparison to investment projects. To the extent
that the reluctance of firms to list in the stock
market made the stock market less efficient as
a channel for raising investment funds, the net
effect may have been to reduce the relative
resources available for domestic investment
spending.
Second, the availability of a huge volume of
central bank certificates of deposit or savings
bonds issued to sterilize the impact of intervention in exchange markets created lowcrisk portfolio investment opportunities not previously
available in Taiwan. These safe new investment
vehicles may have been particularly attractive to
domestic banks, because the lending environment in Taiwan is believed to be quite risky and
because banks previously had very little access
to safe assets. (Conservative fiscal policies in the
past had limited the supply of domestic government securities, while access to safe foreign
assets, such as
Treasury bills, was limited
by capital controls.)

u.s.

The interest-bearing liabilities of the CBC had
a significant impact on bank portfolios. Between

1980 and 1988, the annual growth of government
securities held by banks averaged 41 percent,
compared to the 17 percent annual growth in
loans and discounts over the same period. Partly
as a result, the share of government securities
(mostly claims on the CBC) in bank assets rose
from 1.2 percent in 1980 to 4.9 percent in 1988,
while the share of loans and discounts in total
assets declined from 70 percent to 60 percent
over the same period.
Government sterilization policies in Taiwan
in the 1980s may have "crowded out" domestic
investment spending by absorbing a large proportion of the domestic saving of Taiwan residents. The saving of Taiwan residents instead
financed deficits in foreign saving through net
foreign asset acquisition by the banking system
and the CBC. Given the magnitudes involved,
government sterilization efforts may have played
a large role in dampening growth in investment
spending.

Conclusions
Taiwan's experience in the 1980s suggests
how exchange rate policy may contribute to
the persistence of current account surpluses
when financial markets are underdeveloped and
capital is mobile. By increasing the speculative
demand for NT dollar assets, exchange rate policy limited inflationary pressures, the stimulus to
domestic demand, and the trade adjustment that
might otherwise have resulted from the rapid
expansion in liquidity. Exchange rate policy may
also have slowed external adjustment by affecting the portfolio investment decisions of Taiwan
residents, in a manner that encouraged higher
saving, while tending to channel domestic
saving away from domestic fixed investment.
Taiwan's experience also highlights the potential effects of trying to limit exchange rate movements when there is a high degree of capital
mobility. Government efforts to protect the competitiveness of the external sector by smoothing
the exchange rate increased capital flows and
domestic assets prices, because no effective
curbs on short-term capital inflows were in
place. These effects were exacerbated by thin
and underdeveloped domestic financial markets.

Ramon Moreno
Economist

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor or to the author.... Free copies of Federal Reserve publications can be
obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco 94120.
Phone (415) 974-2246.

OU176 VJ

'OJSpUl!J:I Ul!S

lOLL x08 ·O·d

O)SI)UOJ~

JO

UOS

~U08

aAJaSa~ IOJapa~

~uew~Jodea l.pJOeSe~