View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

.'F\J

}fFl

0

November 4, 1977

Can SteelCompete?
u.s. steel consumption has risen
only 15 percent over the past decade because of intermittent recessions, the loss of markets to substitute materials, and the recent slack
in demand for capital goods. But to
add to the domestic industry's
problems, foreign imports in the
past decade have siphoned off a
major portion of this modest market growth.
.
The Administration acknowledges
the seriousness of the import problem, but tends to disapprove of the
use of mandatory quotas or formal
marketing agreements to restrict
the flow of low-cost steel into the
u. S. market. Administration
spokesmen argue that such restrictions would only raise the price of
foreign and domestic steel without
attacking the basic causes of the
import threat, namely, excess
worldwide production and relatively high domestic production costs.
Consequently, the Administration
is likely to put less emphasis on
import barriers than on tax benefits
and other measures to encourage
plant modernization and cost reduction.
Meanwhile, several producers have
petitioned the Treasury for relief
under laws which call for the imposition of duties on foreign products
found to be in violation of antidumping statutes-that is foreign
products sold in the u. S. market at
less than cost or home-market
prices. This raises the question as to
whether the domestic steel industry
is in fact a relatively high-cost pro-

ducer and, if so, whether these cost
differentials are sufficient to account for the wide disparity between foreign and domestic steel
prices in the u.S. market.

Import upsurge
Since the Second World War, the
U.S. steel industry has watched its
position in the world steel market
steadily decline. In 1950,the United
States was the largest steel producer
in the non-Communist world, accounting for 56 percent of total
production. In 1976, it was still the
largest single producer, but its
share of the total had dwindled to
25 percent, just slightly larger than
that of Japan and somewhat less
than the share of the European
Economic Community. Domestic
production moved irregulady upward over the 1950-65period from
97 to 132 million tons, remained at
approximately that level until the
1973 boom-but is presently running at an annual rate of only
around 125 million tons, approximately the 1964 level.
Steel imports gained their first real
foothold in the u.S. market in 1959,
when a prolonged strike turned the
United States into a net importer of
steel. The foreign share of the market continued to rise as
dollar
became increasingly overvalued
under the then-prevailing system of
fixed exchange rates, with imports
reaching 18 million tons by 1971,
equivalent to 18 percent of total
U.S. apparent consumption. Imports then receded after the 197173 dollar devaluations, but another
(continued on page 2)

JD)®JP>©llfltm:m<eml
It

IF®cdl®1
f@ll
§@ITil

IF

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not
necessarily reflect the views of the management of the
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, nor of the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

-_.
import upsurge began in the mid1970's, with foreign steel reaching
16 percent of total u.s. apparent
consumption in January-July 1 977and 20 percent of the total market
in August, when the flow reached
an annual rate of 22 million tons. As
a consequence of the increase in
imports over the 1964-76 period,
foreign producers captured nearly
all of the growth of the u.s. market.
In 1976, about 56 percent of u.s.
steel imports came from Japan and
another 22 percent from the European Economic Community.

Comparative costs
Comparative steel-production
costs, as developed recently by the
Council on Wage and Price Stability
(COWPSL help to explain how Japanese producers were able to increase their penetration of the u.S.
market in recent decades. Historical
cost data are scantier for European
producers, but the available data
suggest that U. S.-European cost differentials alone cannot explain
their inroads into the u.s. market.
I ndeed, the data show that total
production costs per ton of raw
steel are roughly comparable in
Europe and the U.S., and that the
costs of transporting steel from Europe to the u. S. raise their delivered costs far above those of domestic producers.
Raw-material cost data show that
the U.S. steel industry has gradually
lost its earlier comparative advantage over Japanese producers. Ac-

2

cording to COWPS estimates, the
costs of purchased raw materials
per ton of raw steel currently are
about $5 less in Japan than in the
u.S. The Japanese advantage is
somewhat less if both purchased
and company-produced materials
are included, since the largest u.S.
firms produce most of their own
raw materials.
Unit labor-cost data show that the
traditional labor-cost advantage
held byJapanese producers. has
narrowed over time, but remains
large nonetheless. Output per manhour more than doubled in the
Japanesesteel industry Qver the
1964-76 period, while the productivity gain in the u.s. industry
amounted to only about 18 percent
due to a much slower growth of
output. In contrast, hourly compensation rose nearly six-fold in the
Japanesesteel industry over that
same period, while it increased
about 142 percent in the u. S. industry. Yet despite the narrowing differential, unit labor costs are still
about $36 less in the Japanese steel
industry than in the u.S. industry,
per ton of raw steel. Th is advantage
is due mainly to the fact that wage
rates in Japan are still only about
one-half American rates. Output
per manhour is only slightly higher
in Japan than in the U.S., despite
the more rapid gains made in Japan
over the 1964-76 period.
Combining these raw-material and
labor-cost differentials-and converting them from a raw-steel to a

Millions of
Net Tons

120

U.S. APPARENT CONSUMPTION

100
80

60
40
20
1959

61

63

65

finished-product basis-results in
about a $73 per ton (25 percent)
comparative advantage for Japanese over domestic producers.
However, the Japaneseadvantage is
narrowed somewhat when capital
costsand other expenses are
added.
The overall cost advantage held by
Japaneseproducers is further reduced when their inbound rawmqterial transportation costs and
outbound finished-steel transportation costs are included. The Japanese import most of their raw materials, while U.S. firms obtain most of
their raw material inputs from domestic sources. Japaneseinbound
transportation costs a're therefore
about $2 per ton higher than for
U.S. producers, while freight, loading, insurance and duty charges
incurred by Japaneseproducers in
U.S. marketing activities range between $44 and $54 per ton. Indeed,
subtracting all these transportation
costs from the Japanese
production-cost advantage, suggeststhat Japaneseproducers can
sell steel in the u.s.at only a modest overall discount below U.S.
producer costs and still make a
profit.
Counterattack
Domestic producers argue, however, that foreign producers have
been selling steel in the United
Statesat prices that are much lower
than would be warranted on the
basisof their comparative
advantage-in fact, have been sell-

3

67

69

71

73

75

77

ing steel at a loss in order to raise
their operating rates and employment above levels that would otherwise prevail. They claim, furthermore, that foreign steelmakers are
able to do this because deficits
sustained during periods of weak
demand are offset by stiff premiums
during periods of strong U.S. demand, and also because Japanese
firms are subsidized by their nonsteel subsidiaries.
These charges are still being investigated, but the fact that the Treasury
recently ruled tentatively in favor of
a small Pacific Northwest producer,
suggeststhat domestic steel companies may have a good chance of
winning their legal case against foreign producers. Whatever the outcome, it is clear that domestic firms
will be operating in an intensely
competitive environment for several years to come. Consumption of
steel in the non-Communist world
is expected to grow at an annual
rate of around 4 percent over the
1976-80 period. World capacity is
expected to grow at an even slower
rate as financially-distressed European and other producers sharply modify their expansion plans.
Still, this slowdown in the growth of
capacity may not be sufficient to
raise overall operating rates substantially above current depressed
levels. Thus, given their comparative cost advantage, Japaneseproducers may well continue to focus
on the U.S. market as an important
outlet for increased exports.
Yvonne levy

• 4Eln .
• EpEAaN .o4 EPI
!!EMEH " E!uJOJ!IE:J .. EUOZPV 0 E)jsEIV

4ImIW1

·J!Ii!::>IO;)SpUa?.I:l1 Ui!S
(;S,", · ON lRWtEic:i
OUVeI

·s·n

lAVW 55Vl::> lSMI:I

BANKING DATA-TWELFTH fEDERAL RESERVE
DISTRICT
amounts in Il'llllll''''''
Selected Assets and liabilities
large Commercial lSanks

Amount
Outstanding
10/19/77

-

Loans (gross, adjusted) and investments*
Loans (gross, adjusted)-total
Security loans
Commercial and industrial
Real estate
Consumer instalment
U.S. Treasury securities
Other securities
Deposits (less cash items)-total*
Demand deposits (adjusted)
U.S. Government deposits
Time deposits-total*
States and political subdivisions
Savings deposits
Other time depositst
Large negotiable CD's

101,240
78,989
2,132
23,924
26,087
13,742
7,864
14,387
98,903
28,516
457
68,159
5,316
31,804
28,803
10,955

Weekly Averages
of Daily Figures

Week ended
10/19177

Member Banl<Reserve Position
ExcessReserves(+)/Deficiency H
Borrowings
Net free(+)/Net borrowed H
Federal Funds-Seven large Banks
Interbank Federal fund transactions
Net purchases (+)/Net sales H
Transactions with U.S. security dealers
Net loans (+)/Net borrowings H

Change from
year ago
Dollar
Percent

Change
from
10/12/77

+

+
+
+

+

+

-

442
307
161
246
140
48
218
353
1,556
1,039
152
285
64
33
251
418.

+
+
+
+
+
+

+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+

10,777
10,096
571
1,602
5,139
1,910
919
1,600
8,551
2,611
10
5,609
222
3,489
1,990
141

Week ended
10/12/77
+

+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+

11.91
14.65
36.58
7.18
24.53
16.14
10.46
12.51
9.46
10.08
2.24
8.97
4.36
12.32
7.42
1.30

.comparable
year-ago period
37
1
38

39
162
201

+

118
107
11

+

902

+

277

+

12

+

426

+

480

+

114

*Includes items not shown separately. tlndividuals, partnerships and corporations.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (William Burke) or to the author . . . •
Information on this and other publications can be obtained by calling or writing the Public
Information Section, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco 94120.
Phone (415) 544-2184.