View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY LETTER

September 2, 1988

Specialists in the Stock Market
The stock market price "break" of October 1987
generated interest in the activities of certain
mernbers of stock exchanges called specialists.
Currently, the exchanges assign each stock to one
particular specialist firm, comprising one or more
individual specialists. Each specialist firm maintains a post at a particular location on the
exchange floor, which becomes the only location
on the floor where the stocks assigned to the specialist are traded. Specialist firms are both
brokers and dealers, and the exchanges compel
the specialists to maintain a "fair and orderly"
market in their assigned stocks.
This Letter examines the role of specialists, focusing on the question whether specialists' market
power in their stocks generates economic inefficiencies in the stock market. Although the specialist firm's monopoly in handling trading in its
stocks is likely to be consistent with economic
efficiency, its exclusive access to information
about orders is not.

The role of specialists
As brokers, specialists execute other investors'
orders, and are paid a commission. Specifically,
they execute limit orders and market orders on
behalf of other brokers. A limit order specifies
the minimum price at which a customer is willing to sell stock (the ask price) or the maximum
price at which the customer is Willing to buy
stock (the bid price). Specialists record all the
limit orders for their stocks in computerized
"books," executing each when the limit price is
reached. Each specialist publicizes the highest
bid and lowest ask prices for a particular stock.
Market orders are then executed at the highest
bid price in the case of a sell order, and at the
lowest ask price in the case of a buy order.
Over time, specialists' role as dealers in the
stocks they have been assigned has increased. As
dealers, specialists buy and sell their assigned
stocks for their own accounts, thereby making
markets in these stocks. In fact, the exchanges require specialists not only to execute orders
promptly, but also to maintain a "fair and orderly

market" in their stocks. Specifically, the New
York Stock Exchange (NYSE) rules stipulate that a
fair and orderly market is one in which there is
price continuity, reasonable depth, and minimum
temporary disparities between supply and demand. Price continuity means that the prices at
which consecutive transactions take place are
not too far apart. A market has reasonable depth
when large quantities of stock can be bought or
sold without significant changes in price.

Maintaining an orderly market
A specialist's dealings can contribute to price
continuity by narrowing the bid-ask spread that
is on the book of limit orders. For example, say
that a stock has just sold at 50 and now the highest bid price on the book is 49V4 and the lowest
ask price is 50V2. The specialist may believe the
stock is undervalued at 49% and choose to bid
49%, narrowing the bid-ask spread by V2 point. If
the specialist receives a market sell order, he will
buy the stock at 49%, which is % point away
from the last transaction price, instead of %
point. In this way, subsequent transactionsfrequently are closer in price to preceding
transactions than they would have been without
the specialist's intervention.
Specialists can obtain advance warning of temporary gaps in supply and demand at prices near
the last transactions price by observing the limit
orders. They can help reduce these gaps by entering the market on the buy side (by quoting a
higher bid price than is on the book) when there
are too many sellers and entering on the sell side
when there are too many buyers. In so doing,
specialists often deal for their own accounts
against the trend of the market, buying when the
market is falling, and selling when the market is
rising. Such dealing provides depth to the market
and has been referred to by exchange officials
and others as "stabilization:'

Specialists' market power
Apparently, the activities of specialists are highly
profitable. Occasional reports from the Securities
and Exchange Commission (SEC) and the NYSE

FRBSF
have indicated that specialists often enjoy unusually high rates of return. For example, the
excess of NYSE special ists' pre"tax return on
equity over that of other NYSE member firms
ranged from 4 percentage points to nearly 33
percentage points overthe past six years. (See
chart.)
NYSE Members' Pre-Tax
Return· on Equity

37 stocks with competing specialists. By the
1970s, specialist competition had disappeared,
although there was a short-lived episode of competition involving eight stocks in 1986.

Percent

50
Specialists

.... .....

".

.

.
.

"

.

'0

,"

.... ...

40

"'",

.
.
.
. ..
. ..

"

.....
..
.

30

...
...
....

.

.~

Other member firms

20

•

10

o
1982

1983
Source:

1984

1985

1986

1987

"Floor ~1l',ad_ers Had Big P!"oflt In Spite of Crash,"
New York Times, June 1, 1988.

Many observers complain that these high returns
result from th.e undue market power of specialists. Specifically, each· stock typically has only
one specialist firm. In addition, only the specialist has access to the book of limit orders for his
stocks. This information about the latent strength
of demand and supply gives the specialist an advantage in bidding, thereby reducing competition below what it would be were the limit orders
publicized. For example, knowingthat there are
buy limit orders on the book justbelow the current price limits the riskthespecialist runs in
buying for hisown account. These anticompetitive aspects of the specialist system concern
economists because they signal potential economic inefficiencies.
Although new stock issues are assigned to only
onefirm, there is Iloexchange rulethat prohibits
competing specialists from applying to. be registered in a stock thatalreagy has been assigned to
another firm. In the past, competing specialists
were quite common andwerepreyalent in the
most active stocks. Foy instance,in 1933 there
were 466 stocks withcompeting specialists and
in 1957, 228.· By 1963, however, there were only

)

An SEC report in 1963 attributed the dramatic decline in the incidence of multiple specialists for a
stock to an increase in the importance of the
specialist's role as a dealer. In the late 1930s the
NYSE began to compel specialists to act as dealers, imposing minimum capital requirements to
assure that specialists had adequate financial resources for maintaining a fair and orderly market.
Prior to that time, specialists primarily were
brokers. In 1933, for example, the NYSE president defined a specialist as one who executes
orders for other brokers in a particular stock. In
contrast, the NYSE president in 1961 stated that
" ...the essence of being a specialist is dealing
for his own account."
Natural monopoly?
Due to the specialist's more important dealer activities and responsibilities today than in the past,
multiple specialists for a given stock may no
longer be efficient for two reasons. First, as stated
above, specialists are subject to capital requirements for each stock in wh ich they are registered. For example, current NYSE rules state that
a specialist firm must hold capital equal to
$100,000 or the value of 1,250 shares of each
stock the firm is assigned, whichever is greater.
In practice, the specialist may need far more capital in order to maintain a fair and orderly
market. This is the opinion of the SEC, which already has approved the NYSE's proposed trial
increase in specialist capital requirements to the
greater of $1 million or the value of 3,750 shares
of each assigned stock.
In addition to substantial financial resources,
specialists also must acquire a large store of
knowledge about the market for each of their
stocks today in order to deal in those stocks and
. thereby maintain a fair and orderly market. A
single firm can spread the fixed costs of obtaining this information over a large number of trades
more efficiently than can multiple firms.
Technological progress, including the introduction of computers, probably also played a role in
the disappearance of multiple specialists. By increasing the number and size of orders that a

given specialist firm can execute efficiently, technological progress has made multiple specialists
in even the most active stocks unnecessary.
For these reasons, a single firm usually can produce the specialist's services for a particular
stock at a lower cost per unit of service than can
two or more firms. This naturally leads to monopolistic specialist firms. There is a concern that
such monopoly power will lead to commissions
that are higher and levels of output that are lower
than would be desired for economic efficiency.
However, economic theory tells us that monopolists will make the most profits by "price
discriminating"-constructing a price schedule
rather than setting a single price. Such pricing,
which is common in securities markets, can result in a quantity of service that is consistent
with economic efficiency. It is likely, therefore,
that the monopoly enjoyed by specialist firms is
benign in the sense that the level of service they
provide may still be optimal.

A proposal to promote competition
If specialists were required to publicize their limit order books, competition would increase,
thereby narrowing the bid-ask spread and increasing price continuity and the efficiency of
financial markets. Some economists, however,
see a problem with this proposal. They argue that
specialists may become less willing to deal
against the market and so provide stabilization if
the rewards for doing so are not large. This is
consistent with the view of the NYSE, which rewards its specialists by giving them exclusive
knowledge of the book of limit orders, while
maintaining a close watch on their activities.
However, other economists have suggested that
stabilization is a natural by-product of dealers'
profit-maximizing behavior, and therefore special
rewards for stabilization are not needed. Economist Hans Stoll has found that dealers in the
over-the-counter market, who are not closely
monitored and to some extent share knowledge
of all dealers' bid and ask prices, deal against

market trends just as much as specialists on organized exchanges.
Critics of the proposal to expand access to the
limit order book might also argue that such a
change could reduce depth in the stock market.
Any dealer attempting to buy or sell a large number of shares wants to conceal his intentions in
order to prevent other dealers from trading on the
information and diminishing the expected profits
from his transaction. If the specialist's book were
made public, dealers could hide their intentions
to buy or sell a large block of shares only by
dribbling out the transaction in small pieces,
thereby decreasing depth. Some argue that limited access to the specialist's book and the
specialist's duty to deal against the market currently minimizes the need for this type of behavior on the part of investors placing limit orders.
On the other hand, orders from institutions, involving the largest blocks of stock, are negotiated
off the floor, without the specialist's intervention.
Publicizing the specialist's book would not affect
the size of these orders, so the overall effect on
market depth of expanding access to the specialist's book may be quite small.

Conclusion
Specialists usually have a monopoly franchise in
their stocks that allows them to earn significant
profits. However, the specialist firm has an incentive to set a schedule of commissions that results
in a level of service that is economically efficient.
Currently, the NYSE is considering eliminating
the specialist's exclusive access to the information contained in the book of limit orders. If limit
orders were publicized, investors would benefit.
Bid-ask spreads would narrow, thereby increasing the economic efficiency of the stock market.
Price continuity also would increase, while stabilization, or dealing against the market trend,
probably would not be affected significantly.
Depth possibly would be reduced, but, overall,
the stock market likely would remain "fair and
orderly."

Elizabeth laderman
Economist

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (Barbara Bennett) or to the author.•.. Free copies of Federal Reserve
publications can be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702,
San Francisco 94120. Phone (415) 974-2246.

Research Department

Federal Reserve
Bank of
San Francisco
Alaska
nevada

Arizona

California Hawaii

Oregon Utah

Idaho

Washington