View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

September 7, 1973

While the economy floundered in
the doldrums several years ago,
economists tried to reassure their
readers that consumers sooner or
later would give the economy a
much-needed boost by spending
more and saving less of their after­
tax income. In the words of one
such observer (Gardner Ackley),
"Departures of the saving rate in
one direction from the average are
ultimately redressed by a regression
toward the mean". These predic­
tions have now come true with a
vengeance, since the saving rate has
dropped all the way from 8.1 per­
cent in the 1970-71 period to only
5.9 percent in the first half of 1973.
There may be disagreements about
the level of the "average" saving
rate, but the rates recorded around
the turn of the decade obviously
were quite high— in fact, the
highest of the past quarter-century.
In contrast, the recent 5.9-percent
rate fell about midway between the
relatively low average rate of the
1960-64-period and the relatively
high rate of the 1965-69 period.
The buy-now, pay-later atmosphere
of early 1973 helped pull down the
rate. So too did a crucial long-run
factor—the growing importance in
the population of large numbers of
young families who normally are
heavy spenders and poor savers.
On the other hand, some factors
worked to make at least some con­
sumers save more— in particular,
the recent fall in the level of con­
sumer confidence, as well as the
sharp increase this spring in inDigitiz<e9 f3 pFRAfeeRu n d s http://fjaser.stlouisfed.org/
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Take with caution
All estimates of personal saving, it
must be added, should be treated
with considerable caution. For ex­
ample, the initially reported rate of
6.7 percent for the first quarter of
this year has now been revised
sharply downward to 5.9 percent,
and some weighty discussions pub­
lished this spring of why consumers
were saving so much now appear
somewhat irrelevant. The problem
lies with the nature of the esti­
mating process.
The Commerce Department calcu­
lates personal saving as a residual
between disposable (after-tax) in­
come and consumer outlays for
goods and services. (Incidentally,
the saving figure includes not only
personal saving, but also the saving
of noncorporate businesses, both
farm and nonfarm.) Being a resid­
ual, the saving series is dependent
on the accuracy of the estimates of
the two underlying determinants.
Since these series are constantly
being revised, significant differ­
ences can develop between the
initial saving estimate that Com­
merce makes just after the end of
any given time period and the later
estimate based on more complete
and up-to-date information.
Buying for life
The present relatively low level of
saving, as indicated by the latest
revised figures, may be related to
certain demographic changes which
are best explained by the life-cycle
theory. According to this view,
households in their formative years
keep up their consumption stan(continued on page 2)

Resoaircfei O qpajrtaaim it

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not
necessarily reflect the views of the management of the
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, nor of the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

dards and maintain relatively low
levels of saving. In other words,
they devote a large share of their
income to assets high in consump­
tion services, such as housing and
durable goods, and devote a corre­
spondingly smaller share to assets
high in saving services, such as time
deposits, stocks and bonds. During
middle-age, households take advan­
tage of their higher income to build
up their stock of saving assets for
retirement. During retirement, the
final stage of the life cycle, house­
holds keep a large percentage of
their wealth in liquid form to meet
current expenditures not covered
by their sharply reduced income,
and they also dissave by selling or
consuming (through asset deprecia­
tion) certain assets such as housing
and durable goods.
Consequently, the demographic
shifts in recent years would con­
tribute to a lower saving rate, be­
cause the sharp increase in the
number of young people in the
working population would tend to
boost consumption rather than
saving. Moreover, the importance
of this factor should increase
sharply throughout the present
decade. The number of individuals
in the 25-34 age bracket should rise
by 9.1 million in the 1970's— a 57percent gain, or three times the
increase of the past decade.
This has meant a boom in house­
hold formations; in 1972, there
were 2.3 million marriages, as
against only 1.5 million in 1960.
Moreover, these young families
have been spending heavily—for

Digitized for F R A S E R


everything except baby clothes.
(The birth rate has dropped consist­
ently in recent decades, so that the
number of babies born in 1972
reached the lowest level of the
postwar period.) Also, the long­
term decline in the number of per­
sons per household has meant a
duplication of purchases for
housing and durable goods, espe­
cially in view of the large increase in
the number of young single (or
double) households. All of these
factors have tended to induce
higher consumption and thereby
reduce saving.
Caution and inflation
In the immediate future, however,
there may be a tendency toward a
higher saving rate, especially in
view of the “precipitous decline" in
consumer confidence reported by
the University of Michigan's spring
consumer survey. Consumers indi­
cated in this survey their intention
to reduce purchases of both new
cars and housing, partly because of
increased caution, and partly be­
cause of the reaction to recent
“borrowing" of sales from future
time-periods. One recent study
suggests that about one-fourth of
this year's purchases represented
hedge buying against future price
increases.
The inflation factor is hard to mea­
sure, because some observers claim
that inflation tends to make con­
sumers buy in advance of future
price increases, whereas others
claim that it tends to reduce their
buying because of an anticipated
reduction in real income. The ex­
planation may lie with the differ-

ence between anticipated and un­
anticipated price inflation.

such repayments statistically are
defined as saving.

Some studies suggest that in
periods of uncertainty— including
uncertainty about rising prices—
consumers become more cautious
about spending and try instead to
increase their saving. According to
this view, rising prices force con­
sumers to reassess their capability
for servicing fixed commitments. In
particular, when caught unaware by
inflation, consumers tend to re­
spond by increasing their saving
and sharply reducing most types of
consumption spending.

Overwithholding
Finally, there may be less impact
from the tax-overwithholding phe­
nomenon, which has heavily influ­
enced the saving-consumption pic­
ture during the 1972-73 period. This
factor during 1972 caused dispos­
able income (and presumably
saving) to be smaller than it other­
wise would have been— smaller
than it would have been if tax­
payers had acted to tailor their
withholding taxes to match their
liabilities.(Partly for that reason, the
saving rate dropped from 8.1 to 6.2
percent between 1971 and 1972.) In
1973, overwithholding apparently
has been continued on current pay­
checks, but it has been offset (at
least in the spring period) by a
larger-than-otherwise final settle­
ment between the Treasury and
taxpayers on their 1972 taxes.

This year, however, the inflation
apparently has been anticipated
because of the wide publicity given,
first, to the easing of price controls
under the Phase III program, and
secondly, to the price upsurge in
the agricultural sector. In other
words, consumers have hurried to
buy in the anticipation that prices
would only go up in the future.
Accordingly, their saving has fallen
off as they have increased their
consumption to ever-higher levels,
including a whopping 18-percent
annual rate of gain in durable-goods
spending in the first half of this
year.
This factor should be less important
as time goes on, assuming that
consumers actually are becoming
more uncertain about the future
course of the economy. In addition,
an increase in saving would auto­
matically develop because of the
speed-up in debt repayments re­
sulting from the past upsurge in
? '9lt!fM f?fiiW e ^ & e d it e x t e n s io n s , s in c e
http://fraser.stlouisfea.org/
Federll Reserve Bank of St. Louis

It had been expected that the saving
rate would rise in spring 1973 as
consumers received their Treasury
refund checks. This factor undoubt­
edly was present, but was offset by
several other factors. (For that mat­
ter, measuring this phenomenon is
difficult because of problems in
seasonally adjusting the underlying
data.) Disposable income and
saving were reduced by the sharp
increase (over 20 percent annually)
in the social-security tax bite—and
by the tendency of consumers to
use their tax refunds as downpay­
ments on big-ticket items, which in
combination with heavy borrowing
helped support the buying splurge.
William Burke

o c=3

uoj8umsE/W •Ljein •uoSaJO •epeA9N . oijEpi
M EM EH

•

E jU J O J ! | E 3

.

EU O ZU V

•jj|i3 'o a sp u e jj u bs
ZSL O N HV\M3d
a iv d
3 D V lS O d s n
n v w s s v id is a u

(Dollar amounts in m illions)

Loans adjusted and investments *
Loans adjusted— total*
Securities loans
Com m ercial and industrial
Real estate
Consum er instalment
U.S. Treasury securities
O ther securities
Deposits (less cash items)— total*
Demand deposits adjusted
U.S. Governm ent deposits
Time deposits— total*
Savings
Other time I.P.C.
State and political subdivisions
(Large negotiable CD 's)
Weekly Averages
of Daily Figures
Member Bank Reserve Position
Excess reserves
Borrowings
Net free (+ ) / Net borrowed ( - )
Federal Funds— Seven Large Banks
Interbank Federal funds transactions
Net purchases (+ ) / Net sales ( - )
Transactions: U.S. securities dealers
Net loans ( + )/ Net borrowings ( - )

E>|SE|V

npjng© 8®^[

BANKING DATA—TWELFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT
Selected Assets and Liabilities
Large Commercial Banks

•

Am ount
Outstanding
8 / 22 / 73
74,241
57,489
1,130
20,383
17,039
8,556
5,026
11,726
71,917
20,918
461
49,400
17,566
23,081
5,975
12,097

Change
from
8/15 / 73
1,320
- 1,175
1,158
+
26
+
72
+
29
127
18
51
- 498
4
+ 508
33
+ 507
+
56
+ 386
-

Change from
year ago
Dollar
Percent
+ 9,892
+ 10,104
923
+ 3,698
+ 2,905
+ 1,335
912
+
700
+ 9,338
+ 1,365
1
+
+ 7,921
651
+ 6,894
+
782
+ 6,357

+
+

15.37
21.32
44.96
21.16
20.55
18.49
15.36
6.35
14.92
6.78
0.22
19.10
3.57
42.59
15.06
110.75

-

+
+
+
-

+
+
+
+
+
-

+
+
+

W eek ended
8 / 22 / 73

W eek ended
8/15 / 73

Com parable
year-ago period

11
126
- 115

50
226
-1 7 6

+

34
2
32

0

+ 463

-

933

+ 142

+ 651

+

144

"Includes items not shown separately.
Information on this and other publications can be obtained by calling or writing the
Digitized for FRA ^ r i nistrative Services Department. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702,
http://fraser.stlOLiSjiiiPra.ii cisco, California 94120. Phone (415) 397-1137.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis