View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY LETTER

March 30, 1990

Is Rising Leverage A Problem?
In recent years, firms in the United States
have been increasing their debt and buying back
equity. As a result, corporate leverage, or the
aggregate debt-to-assets ratio, increased at an
annual average rate of about three percent from
1982 to 1988, and firms' interest obligations
relative to their cash flows increased by about
four percent a year during that period.
For any given firm, this increase in interest
obligations relative to cash flow implies that a
higher threshold level of cash flow is needed to
keep the firm solvent, making it more vulnerable
to adverse economic conditions. Such an increase in the solvency risk of individual firms,
in turn, may translate into increased risk to the
economy as a whole, particularly if the highly
leveraged firms are also highly cyclical, in the
sense that their income and cash flow rise and
fall with economy-wide activity. During recessions, the high leverage of these firms could
exacerbate their cyclical difficulties, and could
cause a liquidity contraction for financial institutions and a decrease in wealth for bondholders,
resulting in a generalized credit squeeze in the
economy.
Th is Letter outl ines recent leverage patterns in
the United States, reviews some explanations for
the increasing reliance on debt, and examines
whether the increasing leverage by firms in the
United States presents a potential problem to the
economy. There is some evidence that in recent
years firms in cyclical industries have increased
their leverage more rapidly than firms in noncyclical industries. This trend raises some concern, particularly if it were to continue.

leverage patterns in the

u.s.

Firms in the United States have been increasing
their leverage over the past several years. In a
sample of 1,293 financial and non-financial firms
for which data are available, the debt-to-asset
ratio rose at an average annual rate of 2.6 percent, increasing from an average of 59 percent
in 1982 to 68 percent in 1988. This increase in

leverage also raised these firms' interest burden.
The ratio of their interest expenses to cash flows
increased by an average of 3.8 percent a year,
from 15 percent in 1983 to 19 percent in 1988.
This increase in interest burden is worth noting
since the level of interest rates declined about
two percentage points over the period.
Increasing leverage may be a response to recent
changes in tax laws and the economic environment. Many economists have pointed out that
our tax structure historically has favored the use
of debt over equity since it in effect taxes dividend income twice, while it makes corporate
interest payments tax deductible. Randaii
Pozdena at this Bank has shown that tax factors
account for much of the observed variation in
aggregate leverage in the manufacturing sector
over the last 50 years.
Pozdena also found that the changes in the U.S.
tax system effected by the 1986 Tax Act further
biased corporate financial structure towards the
use of debt because this Act raised the differential between the corporate tax rate and the
personal margi nal tax rate, increased the rate at
which income from capital is taxed relative to
ordinary income, and reduced the availability
of such nondebt shields as the investment tax
credit. In a previous issue of this Letter (November 24, 1989), Frederick Furlong confirms that
the net effect of changes in marginal income tax
rates, provided for by 1986 tax reform bills,
was to increase the incentives to use debt.
Other reasons that have been cited for the rise in
corporate leverage include recent developments
in financial markets. For example, by making
debt markets more complete, floating rate financing may have facilitated debt finance. Likewise,
enhancements in the marketing of junk bonds,
some have argued, facilitated debt finance particularly by corporations trying to avoid takeovers
as well as by those having to restructure as a result of takeovers. Securitization also may have
encouraged the growth of debt by lowering the

FABSF

squeeze on the rest of the economy, including
healthy corporations, and thus feed recessionary
tendencies in the economy.

cost of debt through improved technology of
debt issuance and, some argue, by obscuring
the credit risks involved.

Thus, it appears that the trend towards increased
leverage has the potential to increase bankruptcy
risk within the e<::onomy as a whole, particularly
if the increase in leverage is concentrated in
industries that are highly cyclical. i\ccordingly,
it is important to determine whether leverage has
in fact increased in cyclical sectors of the economy. To obtain a measure of cyclicality, sectoral
output is regressed on total private sector Gross
Domestic Product, and the resulting slope cOc
efficient is called the coefficient of cyclicality
(COC). A COC equal to or greater than one
means that product cycles in that sector are at
least as pronounced as business cycles in the
economy as a whole. These sectors are deemed
"cyclical:' On the other hand, a COC less than
one means that business cycles are dampened
in the sector, and such a sector is classified as
"non-cycl ical."

leverage and cyclicality

leverage and risk
The trend towards increased leverage in recent
years may have increased bankruptcy risk.
Because they face higher interest obligations
relative to their cash flow than do firms with low
leverage, highly leveraged firms are more vulnerable to the declines in cash flow that often occur
in recessions.
Economists Ben Bernanke and John Campbell
found that many highly leveraged firms would
have gone bankrupt in 1986 if these firms had
encountered conditions like those during the
recessions of 1973-74 and 1981-82. Faced with
shocks of the magnitude of the 1973-74 recession, for instance, ten percent of these firms
vvould have seen their debt-to-asset ratios rise
above unity, thereby forcing them into bankruptcy. When the effects of the 1981-82 recession were simulated, the deterioration in leverage
ratios was less dramatic, but still noticeable for
firms with high debt-to-asset ratios.
In contrast, however, economist Michael Jensen
has argued that highly leveraged firms are actually less vulnerable to bankruptcy than are lowdebt firms because at the point of insolvency,
when the total market value of assets is barely
equal to the value of debts, creditors are more
likely to restructure the debts of highly leveraged
firms than they are the debts of low-leverage
firms. He reasons that at the point of insolvency,
the assets of highly leveraged firms necessarily
are worth more than those of firms that previously had low leverage. Since the market value
of the assets of highly leveraged firms needs to
deteriorate only a little to make them insolvent,
while asset value must deteriorate a lot to make a
low-leverage firm insolvent, creditors are more
likely to liquidate an insolvent firm that started
out as a low-leverage firm.
Although Jensen's argument may have merit,
nonetheless, increased leverage poses potentially greater risks of an economy-wide liquidity
squeeze. Restructuring does not eliminate risk; it
merely transfers bankruptcy risk to creditors. In
an economic downturn in which a large number
of highly leveraged firms are forced into restructuring their debt, creditors may become at least
temporarily illiquid. This could lead to a credit

cae

In the 19805 four of ten sectors had a
greater than unity. They were mining, construction, primary metals (including transportation
equipment), and other durable manufactures.
These sectors account for a quarter of private
sector output and half of the non-service component of private sector output.
As Charts 'I and 2 show, leverage, or the ratio
of firms' debt to assets, increased in nine of the
ten private sectors of the
economy between
1982 and 1988. Excluding the financial sector,
the highest growth occurred in three of the four
cyclical sectors: construction, primary metals,
and other durable manufactures. The only sector
to register a fall in leverage over the period was
utilities, the sector with the lowest COe and
thus the least cyclical of all the sectors.

u.s.

Chart 1

Cycllcallty, Interest Burden, and
Growth In Leverage In Cyclical Industries

%

30

27
Interest Burden
" Leverage
G

24

21
18
15
12
9

6
3
Mining

[3.6J

Construction
[1.0J

NumbefllnbraeketslepresemthllcOlllflcientsolcycllcailty.

Metals
[2.2J

Durables
[2.0]

o

Chart 2

Cycllcallty, Interest Burden, and
Growth In Leverage in Non·Cyclicallndustries

%

29
26
23

" Interest Burden
o Leverage

20
17
14

cause for complacency since it is due to the fact
that both cyclical and non-cyclical sectors were
increasing their leverage equally rapidly. The
yearly correlation coefficients between the
and leverage indicators are a reliable measure of
potential vulnerability especially since leverage
in almost all of the ten sectors increased every
year between 1983 and 1988.

cac

11

8

5
2

Chart 3

Cycllcallty, Interest Burden, and
Growth In Leverage Over Time

Correlation with

,....---r---,....---r---,....--...,-----,,....-----; -1
Petrochem.
[.5]

Peper
[.6)

NonDur.
[.3]

Utilities
[.2J

Finance
[.5]

coc
0.60

Services
[.7]

0.40

Number8 In brecketa represent lhe coetliclentll oIcycilcallty.

0.20

The relationship between leverage and cyclicality can be tested statistically by calculating the
correlation between the
and various leverage indicators: the debt-to-assets ratio, the
growth in the debt-to assets ratio, and the ratio
of interest payments to cash flows. A strong positive correlation between
and any of these
indicators suggests that in recent years the economy has become more vulnerable to a credit
squeeze than would be suggested by the rise
in aggregate leverage alone.

cac

cac

The statistical analysis suggests that the level
of leverage in the ten sectors, averaged over the
years 1982 through 1988, is only very weakly related with the
This means that, on average
in the United States, highly leveraged firms have
not been particularly concentrated in cyclical
sectors. However, the strength of correlation increased over the period, suggesting that firms in
cyclical sectors are becoming more leveraged.

cae.

As Chart 3 shows, moreover, cyclical sectors
were increasing their leverage more rapidly than
were non-cycl ical sectors over most of the period: the correlation between the annual growth
in the debt-to-assets ratio and the
steadily
increased from - 0.5 in 1983 to 0.5 in 1986. The
correlation declined in 1987 but remained positive, indicating that cyclical sectors were still
increasing their leverage more rapidly than were
non-cycl ical sectors. In 1988 the correlation decreased to approximately zero, but this is not

cac

0.00

..........

.. ..

-0.20

••••• Growth In Leverage
'

-0.40

'

-0.60
1983

1984

1985

1986

1987

1988

Cyclical sectors also have seen a faster rise in
interest burden, or the ratio of firms' interest
obligations to cash flows, than have non-cyclical
sectors. The correlation between interest burden
and
has increased fairly steadily over the
period, as Chart 3 shows. This means that the
economy as a whole has tilted towards greater
vulnerability to recession shocks.

cac

A cause for concern
Concerns over the rise in leverage in recent
years are compounded by the fact that through
1987 firms in cyclical sectors have increased
their leverage more rapidly than have those in
non-cyclical sectors. As a result, the need for
corporate restructuring likely will be higher in
the event of an economic downturn, making an
economy-wide credit squeeze a more serious
threat.
Rama Seth
Visiting Scholar
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
and Economist
Federal Reserve Bank of New York

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (Barbara Bennett) or to the author.... Free copies of Federal Reserve
publications can be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702,
San Francisco 94120. Phone (415) 974-2246.

Ont6 v:> 'OJSPUI?J:l

UI?S

WLL xog 'O'd

O)SI)UOJ~

JO

UOS

~uo8

aAJaSa~ IOJapa~

~uaw~Jodaa 4)Joasa~