View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY LETTER

September 14, 1990

Regional Effects of the Thrift Bailout
The billions of dollars of government debt being
raised to resolve the problems of hundreds of insolvent thrift institutions have drawn attention to
the possible regional effects of the so-called
"thrift bailout:' Regional effects are at issue because the insolvent institutions are concentrated
in a few states, such as Texas, while the government obligations incurred to protect depositors
fallon the nation as a whole.

thrifts. More importantly for the purposes of this
Letter, for a given set of losses, uninsured depositors in an affected state would have reduced their
spending (increased saving) in response to their
loss of wealth. In effect, deposit insurance has
insulated depositors from the thrifts' losses, and,
thus, has blunted the negative economic effects
of the thrift crisis in the states with high concentrations of insolvencies.

It has been argued that the states with large concentrations of ailing thrifts will experience
stronger economic growth at the expense of the
other states. This Letter takes a somewhat different view. While government deposit insurance
protection should have a salutary effect on the
economies of states experiencing thrift insolvencies, it is not necessarily at the expense of
current taxpayers in other regions.

However, the realization of this benefit in regions
with high concentrations of thrift failures does
not occur when the government actually pays out
its deposit insurance obligations. As pointed out
in a previous Letter (May 12, 1989), for all intents
and purposes, the wealth transferto the depositors of the troubled thrift institutions took place
long before the government's explicit decision to
finance the thrift bailout. Depositors of insolvent
thrifts, for the most part, have behaved all along
as if they were protected. Most, if not all, of the
positive effects of deposit insurance protection
already should be reflected in the economies of
the states plagued with thrift insolvencies. This
means that the government's outlay of billions of
dollars to acquire the assets or to accommodate
takeovers of insolvent thrifts should not provide a
further boost to the economies of these states.

Two issues
At least two interesting questions arise when
evaluating the regional consequences of government deposit insurance and the thrift bailout.
First, for a given set of losses, how are regional
economic growth rates affected when the federal
government protects depositors compared with a
situation in which the losses are borne regionally? Second, how does the financing of the
deposit insurance claims affect interregional
spending patterns, and hence regional economic
growth rates?

Regional effects
of deposit insurance guarantees
In a state plagued with thrift insolvencies, the
economy would be stronger with a federal government guarantee than if depositors (or others)
in the state had to absorb all of the losses. During the past several years, as conditions in the
thrift industry have deteriorated, insured depositors in the affected states have had no reason to
reduce spending. In contrast, if all deposits had
been uninsured, depositors would have been
more concerned about the risky activities that
thrifts were undertaking. This added concern
might have helped to limit the losses among

Nevertheless, the expenditures made to resolve
the status of the ailing thrifts may allow unfinished projects that had been lying idle to be
started up again as assets are sold off. To the
extent that such projects are geographically concentrated, the bailout might have some impact
on economic growth regionally. Also, to the extent that there is any friction in interregional
capital flows, the ongoing thrift bailout could
have some impact on the regional distribution of
funds. However, these effects are likely to be
small and do not stem from wealth transfers
per se.
Thus, the answer to the first question is that the
economies of regions with high concentrations of
thrift problems are better off with deposit insurance than they would have been in the absence

FABSF
of federal deposit insurance. However, this benefit derives from the government's deposit
insurance guarantees, and the actual payment of
bailout funds should have little additional stimulative effect on these regions' economies.

Paying the piper
Paying off actual deposit-insurance obligations
requires the federal government to raise funds,
whether through raising current taxes or issuing
debt. It is this need to raise funds to pay for the
bailout that has led some to argue that funding
the thrift bailout hurts the economies of states
with few thrift insolvencies.
Economies in regions with few thrift insolvencies
would be hurt if taxes were raised to cover thrift
losses as institutions became solvent. The payments from the insurance funds would be regionally concentrated, while the taxes to cover the
expenditures would be spread throughout the
country. Taxpayers as a group would reduce their
spending on private goods and services as their
tax obligations rose. If the bailout were financed
in this way, then the positive effects of deposit
insurance for depositors in some states would indeed come at the expense of current taxpayers in
other ·states.

Debt financing
In practice, however, most of the expenses incurredby the deposit insurance system are being
financed with government debt, rather than with
current taxes. Moreover, the debt being issued to
cover the cost of the thrift bailout merely makes
explicit what had been implicit obligations of the
government.
The impact of the debt-financed bailout on the
saving and spending decisions of current taxpayers depends on whether current taxpayers
view themselves as bearing the burden of the
debt, and whether the volume of the debt is significantly different from what current taxpayers
previously had expected. Only if current taxpayers assume they will bear the cost of the
bailout, and if the cost is appreciably higher than
expected, will they increase their rate of saving
further and cut back on consumption. Otherwise,
current spending will be little affected by the
bailout itself.

"Same as raising taxes?"
If taxpayers explicitly recognize the future tax
liability that is necessary to finance the thriftrelated government debt, then as information
about the size of the required expenditures becomes available, they would adjust their saving
enough to cover the change in their expected future tax payments. Thus, if current taxpayers
assume they will bear the cost of the bailout, and
if the cost is appreciably higher than previously
anticipated, they will increase their rate of saving
further and cut back on consumption. However,
even in that case, the adjustment in spending
would hold for taxpayers in all states, including
those that have realized the benefits of deposit
insurance.
Under these circumstances, we would have what
economists call "Ricardian equivalence." That is,
when current taxpayers recognize how much of
the government's deposit insurance obligations
will be funded, they reduce their spending on
private goods and services to compensate for
their share of the funding. When the funding is
debt-financed, the adjustments are the same as if
the obligations were funded through current tax
revenues. This means that, if Ricardian equivalence strictly holds, deposit insurance would
hurt the economies of states with few insolvent
thrifts as much if the deposit insurance obligations are funded by debt issuance as it would if
funded by higher current tax revenues.

...or intergenerational transfers?
On the other hand, if current taxpayers do not
adjust their rate of saving to cover higher future
tax burdens, the deposit-insurance related obligation would not be taken into account in private
decision making. Neither insured depositors nor
current taxpayers would change their spending
patterns in response to the thrift losses. Thus,
current consumption would be higher and saving
would be less than they would be if tax revenues
were increased or if the Ricardian equivalence
were to hold. Moreover, as Herbert Stein points
out in a recent article (Wall Street Journal, June
25, 1990), a lower rate of saving would mean that
the capital stock would grow more slowly than it
would if the thrift losses did affect the spending
and saving decisions of current taxpayers or
depositors.

In this case, the burden of the debt incurred in
the thrift bailout would be shifted to future generations. Higher current consumption would be
made possible at the expense of future consumption, since future taxpayers would inherit more
debt, as well as a smaller capital stock with
which to service the debt.

nancing in their current spending and saving
decisions. If taxpayers do not incorporate the future debt servicing costs in their current
decisions, then the debt-financed bailout will
have little negative impact on current economic
conditions in states with few insolvent thrifts.

Conclusion
This implies that the net benefit of deposit insurance for some states would not represent a
burden on current taxpayers in states with few
thrift failures, but rather would represent a burden on future taxpayers in all states. Thus, in this
case, current economic growth in regions with
few thrift failures would not suffer due to the cost
of the bailout, but future growth throughout the
nation eventually would be slower than it would
have been in the absence of the thrift bailout.

Which scenario?
There are differences of opinion concerning the
extent to which current taxpayers adjust consumption and saving in response to higher government debt. This is part of a broader question
about the economic impact of government deficits. However, to the extent that individuals do
not fully incorporate higher future debt obligations into their current spending and saving
decisions, the importance of changes in spending by current taxpayers associated with the
deposit insurance expenses is reduced.
Thus, the burden of paying for debt-financed
deposit insurance will retard spending and economic growth in states with healthy thrifts only if
taxpayers incorporate the future costs of debt fi-

The rash of thrift insolvencies has been geographically concentrated, raising concerns that
the economies of states with high concentrations
of thrift failures may benefit at the expense of
states that have few thrift problems. Deposit insurance has helped the economies of the states
affected the most by thrift insolvencies by maintaining the wealth of thrift depositors. However,
this benefit was associated with government obligations to depositors, and does not occur as the
government writes the checks to fulfill its obligations. Therefore, the funding of the bailout should
have relatively little further effect on the economies of states with large concentrations of thrift
failures.
Moreover, since debt financing has been used to
cover the losses registered at thrifts, the costs of
the bailout maybe borne by future taxpayers
throughout the nation, rather than by current taxpayers in states that are relatively free of thrift
failures. Thus, the concerns about negative effects on the current economies of regions that
have few thrift problems may turn out to have
been overstated.

Frederick T. Furlong
Research Officer

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federa! Reserve Bank of
San Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (Barbara Bennett) or to the author.... Free copies of Federal Reserve
publications can be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702,
San Francisco 94120. Phone (415) 974-2246.

Research Department

Federal Reserve
Bank of
San Francisco
P.O. Box 7702
San Francisco, CA 94120