View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

December 15, 1978

Recession?-A
Market\/ie\Aj
Will there be a recession in 1979? The
money market appears to think so, because it is forecasting a drop in shortterm interest rates in mid-1979, of the
type that usually accompanies a decline in business activity. But this assumed recession would be relatively
brief and mild, and thus might have
little effect on the imbedded inflation
rate. For that matter, the market's belief doesn't mean that there will actually be a recession, because the actions
taken by private and public decision
makers in coming months could forestall that possibility - and because the
market in some cases (as in 1974) has
been a poor predictor of cyclical
changes.
How can the market make such a prediction? First, it should be remembered
that money-market professionals are
in the business of forecasting future interest rates. The interest rate on sixmonth bills, for instance, should just
equal the average of today's threemonth rate and the market consensus
on what the three-month rate will be
three months from now - plus, perhaps, a premium to compensate investors for holding the bill with the
higher maturity. By using a similar calculation for longer-dated securities, the
market consensus on the expected
level of the short-term rate at any point
in the future can be found. This process can also be reversed, and the market consensus as to the shape of the
yield curve at any point in the future
can be calculated. (The yield curve relates the yield on various securities with
the time they have left to maturity.)
The short-term end of the yield curve
generally moves up and down with

the level of business activity. Thus, by
matching what we know of these
cyclical swings with what the market
expects to happen - and by making
certain assumptions about the cyclical
movement of short-term interest
rates - we can arrive at the market's
consensus on the prospects for the
real economy. Further, by comparing
the currently expected swing in rates
with those of past cycles, we can arrive
at an estimate of the severity of the
currently expected cycle. And finally,
we may derive an estimate of the
longer-term inflation premium
imbedded in interest rates, and see
whether the market expects the coming cycle to have much effect on that
"'permanent'" rate of inflation. It should
be noted that there is no conflict between the cyclical aspect of interestrate movements, as described here,
and the general notion that interest
rates must fully reflect the expected rate of inflation. Rather, such short-period expectations follow the cycleand there is also a cycle in short-term
realized "'rear interest rates.
In making this analysis, we used yield
data, as of December 1, 1978, for a
number of Federal-agency securities issued by the Federal Home Loan Banks,
the Federal Land Banks, and the Federal National Mortgage Association.
Treasury bills normally would be a
more obvious choice, but these are
not normal times in the T-bill market,
because yields have been fluctuating
wildly in response to heavy foreign
buying and selling. The agency market
is somewhat isolated from such pressures, and in addition is the only
homogeneous market (other than the
Treasury market) offering a broad
(continued on page 2)

.:1=
u,.l.!.LCl.1,-"",,,-,,-,i1

ne=es:;anlv
the \/ie\/\/s of the management
ReS2r\le Bar1!( Sa.n;"""''''':-';4-'''''"

orthe

range of maturity choice. l\gency issues mature in at least eight months of
every year through 1985.
Cyclical behavil()ll' I()frates
Typically, the peak in short-term interest rates coincides with the peak in
real GNP. During a recession, short
rates fall sharply, and they continue to
fall on average for three or four quarters after the recession ends at the
trough in real GNP. This behavior reflects the fact that the period with the
lowest level of real GNP relative to its
trend continues until roughly five to six
quarters after the trough. Thus the
lowest short-term rates coincide with
the lowest relative levels of GNP,
though hardly with its lowest growth
rates.
As expansions proceed further, shortterm rates generally begin to rise.
Steady increases continue throughout
periods of mature recovery, when the
level of output is high and increasing
pressures develop on the supplies of
labor and capital. Indeed, interest
rates generally show a steady rise
throughout the mature-expansion
phase of the cycle, as does business'
demand for capital goods. This strong
positive association reflects the influence of the overall state of real aggregate demand on movements in both
interest rates and the capital stock.
Yseld-curve implications
Yield curves consist of averages of the
market consensus on expected future
short rates. For example, the twelvemonth bill rate is an average of the current three-month rate and the three
month rates expected to prevail three,
six, and nine months from now. Thus,

2

estimate the market consensus on expected future yield curves, and use
these as a basis for certain cyclical
comparisons.
1. The actual yield curve (marked
1978.4 in chart) is a rarity, a
humpbacked yield curve with its peak
at a short maturity. This implies a continuation of mature expansion for the
immediate future, and thus a further
run-up in short-term interest rates. Although milder humpbacks have occurred from time to time, this precise
shape occurred only in early 1973, prior to the advent of the sharp 1974-75
recession. Humpbacks occur when the._
market consensus expects short rates
to continue rising for a time, and then
to fall to a level below the yield-curve
peak for a prolonged period. Mild
humpbacks seem to occur during prolonged periods of mature expansion,
when the market expects an eventual
downturn but lacks a consensus about
the date. Sharp humpbacks, of the
early-1973 and late-1 978 variety, seem
to occur after sharp external shocks
which market participants expect
might trigger a downturn - such as
the worldwide price upsurge of early
1973 or the policy-tightening moves
adopted by U.s. policymakers in late
1978.
2. By mid-1979, the market expects
short-term rates to peak, with the
yield curve reaching the classic recessionary inverted shape (marked
1979.2 in chart). At this point, the market anticipates that all future expected
short-term rates will be below the current short-term rate. Thus, almost all
of the yield curve would have a negative slope. Short-term rates tend to

Yield %

CURVE EXPECTED I N:

10

Quarters

peak at the same time as rea! GNP,so
in the market's view, the curve with
the highest earliest-maturity peak (here
1979.2) would mark the business-cycle peak. The curve for 1979.3 (not
shown) would be very similar, which
suggests that the market consensus is
for a recession to begin near mid-year.
3. As each recession proceeds, short
rates tend to fall very rapidly, giving
rise to a second rarity, the U-shaped
yield curve (marked 1980.2 in chart).
The market consensus in this case
looks beyond the post-recession
trough in short-term rates, towards the
rising short-term rates which characterize recovery. The preceding quarter
exhibits a similar shape to the U curve
shown here for 1980.2, so that the
market consensus tends to envision a
recession of several quarters' duration,
ending sometime in the first half of
1980.
4. Short-term interest rates generally
continue to fall in early recovery, so
that the yield curve assumes its normal
upward-sloping shape (marked 1981.2
in chart) some time after the cyclical
low in output. Hence, the market anticipates an expansion in business activity throughout 1980 and early 1981.
We use
to describe the yield
curve associated with this movement,
because recoveries tend to be much
longer than recessions, which means
that most actual yield curves will exhibit an upward slope.

Mild recession?
With a number of qualifications, the
market seems to be anticipating a recession to begin in mid-1979, along
the lines of the mild 1960 and 1970 recessions. As the chart indicates, short3

Left to Maturity

term agency yields are not expected to
fall below 8 percent at any pointwhich would suggest a drop of no
more than 2 percentage points from
the cyclical peak. This modest decline
would be in line with the 1-percent
decline in real GNPachieved in the mild
1 960 and 1 970 recessions,in contrast
to the steeper declines exhibited in
other post-war recessions.
Finally, the market seems to suggest
that a modest downturn would keep
inflation from accelerating, but would
make little progress against an
6-percent inflation rate.
(The Administration, with its inflationdampening program now in place, of
course anticipates better results over
time.) The chart displays a convergence of long-term yields to a level just
below 9 percent - one which would
be independent of the date of the expected yield curve, if it were carried
out to ten years. On the basis of traditional patterns, the market might expect roughly a 3-percent "real" yield on
highest-quality Treasury issues, which
translates to perhaps 3.1 percent on
agencies because of their usual premium over Treasuries. Actually, the market recently has been operating with
negative
short-term rates. Still in
line with more normal expectations,
we would arrive at an imbedded longterm inflation premium of perhaps 5.9
percent (5.9
9.0-3.1 percent). This
number may be regarded as the market's long-term forecast of the rate of
inflation. Indeed, the chart shows an
extremely flat yield curve for long-maturity issues, which might suggest a
nearly constant inflation premium over
any period from 5 to 20 years.

=

larry Butler

., uo8<3JO " EPEJ\<3N ., oljEPI
E!UJOJ!lE::) •
EUOZPV
<II
E>jSl?IV

e

!! EMEH

.,

(G):J)<§

ell
(G)

'l!BU?:) IOJlSpUU?J:I

(;SL'ON
GIVd
150<1 's'n

ul\fW SSY1J lS(lB:!

BANKINGDATA-TWElfTH FEDERAL
RESERVE
(Dollaramountsin millions)
SelectedAssetsand Liabilities
LargeCommercialBanks
Loans(gross,adjusted)andinvestments*
Loans(gross,adjusted)- total
Securityloans
Commercialandindustrial
Realestate
Consumerinstalment
U.s.Treasurysecurities
Other securities
Deposits(lesscashitems)- total*
Demanddeposits(adjusted)
U.s. Governmentdeposits
Timedeposits- total*
Statesand politicalsubdivisions
Savingsdeposits
Other time deposits:/:
LargenegotiableCD's
WeeklyAverages
of Daily Figures

Amount
Outstanding
11129178
122,040
98,993
1,680
28,960
34,593
18,447
8,407
14,640
115,485
31,167
259
82,171
6,826
31,507
41,262
19,763

Week ended
11/29178

Change
from
11/22/78

+

-

+
+
+

-

+
+

-

+

-

+
+

155
126
152
175
143
140
138
143
925
555
18
354
1
94
521
331

Changefrom
yearago
Dollar
Percent
+ 17,086 + 16.28
+ 17,610 + 21.64

-

1,054

-

38.55

+ 4,240· + -17.15
+ 7,764 + 28.94
+ 4,183 + 29.33

-

+
+

-

+
+
+
+

+

Week ended
11122178

474
50
13,767
1,779
302
12,309
1,379
9
10,996
6,956

-

+
+

-

5.34
0.34
13.53
6.05
53.83
17.62
25.32
0.03
36.33
54.31

+
+
+
+
+
. Comparable
year-agoperiod

MemberBankReservePosition
Excess
Reserves(
+ )/Deficiency(-)
8
30
+ 40
+
Borrowings
36
51
92
Net free(+)/Net borrowed(-)
59
51
6
Federalfunds-Seven large Banks
InterbankFederalfund transactions
- 265
Net purchases
(+ )/Net sales(
-)
+ 989
+ 1,582
Transactions
with U.s. securitydealers
Net loans(+)/Net borrowings(-)
33
+ 357
+ 681
+
*Includesitemsnot shownseparately.:/:Individuals,
partnershipsand corporations.
Editorialcommentsmay be addressedto the editor (William Burke)or to the author. ...
Freecopiesof thisandother FederalReservepublicationscanbe obtainedby callingor writing the Public
InformationSection,FederalReserveBankof SanFrancisco,P.O. Box 7702,SanFrancisco94120.Phone
(415) 544-2184.