View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

April 7, 1978

Power to the North west
Winter rains in the Pacific Northwest
have brought an end to that region's
serious drought-related shortage of
hydroelectric power. None too soon,
either, because the shortage had
forced Bonneville Power Administration - the wholesale marketing agency for power generated from Federal
dams along the Columbia River - to
curtail
power supplies
to aluminum companies and other industrial users throughout the past year.
(Interruptible supplies are those
which, under contract, can be discontinued in the event of a deficiency.)
But despite this short-term improvement, the Pacific Northwest may yet
be faced with a chronic long-term
shortage of electricity unless actions
are taken both to slow the growth of
consumption and to encourage the
development of new thermal-generating capacity.

Under this so-called Hydro-Thermal
Program, the Federal government
agreed to develop the remaining hydroelectric power pote'ntial of the Columbia River System and to construct
the necessary high-voltage transmission lines to accommodate the growth
in regional power deliveries. The utilities agreed to build and operate the
required new coal and nuclear generating plants. Bonneville was to acquire
some of this thermal power to add to
the supplies available from its existing
and planned hydro capacity. The idea
was that Bonneville would then have
enough energy to supply both its statutory preference customers - the publicly-owned power agencies- and
other customers such as the privatelyowned utilities and the several dozen
manufacturing firms that had originally
come to the Northwest in pursuit of
low-cost hydro power.

SUll'plil.ll§ shortage
to
Until a few years ago, the Pacific
Northwest was blessed with a surplus
of low-cost hydroelectric energy from
dams in the Columbia River Basin. But
most of the available dam sites were
developed by the late 1960's, and it
then became evident that higher-cost
thermal capacity would have to be
added to meet the region's future
needs. As a result, Bonneville Power
Administration and over one hundred
public and privately-owned utilities
agreed to develop the new generating and transmission facilities deemed
necessary to meet the growth of demand over the 1970-90 period.

But in the early 1970's, as rising costs
and environmental restrictions led to
delays in thermal-plant construction,
Bonneville began to cut back on its private customers in order to meet the future load growth of its preference
customers. Denied new contracts for
power - assured contract supplies - the private utilities were required to meet nearly all of their own
new power requirements, generally
from more expensive thermal
sources. This situation in turn led to a
wide disparity in retail rates to ultimate
consumers. Rates are now more than
twice as high in the state of Oregon,
where private utilities account for

(continued on page 2)

---.

_---_.

___----,
.

---

about 80 percent of all retail requirements, than in the state of Washington,
where the private-public mix is closer
to fifty-fifty.
The situation worsened in the mid
1970's, and in June 1976 Bonneville
notified its preference customersthe
- that it would be unable
to supply their requirements for additional power after July 1, 1983. And
since public utilities would have first
call on the limited energy available,
Bonneville might not be able to renew
the expiring contracts of its industrial
customers - forcing those customers
to turn to the privately-owned utilities,
which will have troubles of their own
developing new generating capacity.
Reduced power supplies for these
major industrial users could have serious regional and national consequences. The industries involved
employ about 15,000 persons with an
annual payroll of about $200 million,
and supply 30 percent of the nation's
primary aluminum, 100 percent of its
ferronickel, and substantial quantities
of other key materials.

Allocation plans
Most proposed solutions to the problem have focused on the use of ne\A/
institutional arrangements, rather than
on the use of the pricing mechanism
to balance supply and demand. The
most notable example is the plan proposed by the Pacific Northwest Utilities
Conference Committee, an organization composed of Bonneville's utility
and industrial customers. That plan, as
embodied in legislation submitted to
Congress last fall, would establish a
new planning organization to coordinate the development of the region's
2

thermal-power resources and to plan
procedures for Bonneville purchases
of power needs. It would also give
Bonneville expanded authority to purchase power from plants outside the
Federal system - thereby providing
for power pooling through the Bonneville transmission network. Also, it
would establish a region-wide energy
conservation program, as well as a
formal allocation and pricing scheme
for distributing available power at various rates to Bonneville's utility and industrial customers.
The problem with this and similar plans
is that they would perpetuate
Bonneville's current practice of average-cost pricing for determining power rates. Indeed, they ignore the
traditional economist view that marginal-cost pricing is required for the efficient allocation of resources. In other
words, they ignore the use of proper
price signalsas a rationing device for
allocating ayailable power supplies.
Role of price
There can be little doubt that low Federal power rates helped contribute to
the present situation. Bonneville power
rates remained virtually unchanged
through the first three decades of the
agency's history, thereby encouraging
a 7 1 -percent annual rate of increase
/2
in the Pacific Northwest's electrical
consumption over the 1950-70
period. But consumption growth then
slowed to a 3 V2
-percent rate between
1970 and 1975, as a result of the recession and supply shortages - as well
as Bonneville price increases, from
2.40 to 3.27 mills per kilowatt hour between 1973 and 1976. Nonetheless,
the region's per capita electrical energy
consumption continues to be almost

Billions

120

Cents/KWH

KWH

Pacific

Northwest

0.5

100

80

60

0.4

Electric power
consumption ""

/
/

-

-.

40

-

--.

---

--,

. ( -----

Average Federal power rate

/

0.3

/

0.2
0.1

20
1950

1960

double the national average, because
of Bonneville's policy of "'encouraging
the widest possible diversified use of
energy* through low-cost Federal
power.
In setting wholesale power rates,
Bonneville is required by law to
produce sufficient revenues to recover the government's costs of producing, purchasing, and transmitting
electricity. Bonneville has consistently
interpreted this budgetary requirement to mean that rates should be determined on the basis of average
cost - that is, by dividing total cost by
the number of units sold in a given period to obtain the unit cost and therefore the average price of electricity.
But critics question whether Bonneville
has actually recovered its average
costs, because its average power rates
remained stable during the 1960's
when less advantageous - and therefore more costly - hydro sites were
being developed.
More importantly, economists generally contend. that Bonneville should
have based its power rates, not on
average costs, but rather on marginal
costs - that is, the cost of providing
for the last increment of supply. They
argue that when new blocks of capacity are required to meet demand, electricity rates should be set on the basis
of long-run incremental cost pricing.
(Long-run incremental cost is defined
as the cost of producing additional
electricity, taking into account that additional fixed factors, i.e., plants, must
be added.) In essence, it approximates
the cost of electricity produced from a
new plant. This approach thus should
result in the most efficient allocation of
resources, because rates would re3

1970

flect the true cost of the resources expended to provide consumers with
each additional block of power.
However, long-run incremental cost
pricing could conflict with Bonneville's
statutory budgetary requirement of
covering costs. When incremental
costs are below average costs - when
economies of scale or superior technology make new blocks of power
less costly to develop than previous
blocks of power - incremental-cost
pricing would create losses and therefore would require subsidies to cover
the agency's costs. On the other hand,
when long-run incremental costs are
clearly above average costs - the current situation, as the Pacific Northwest
moves from a nearly pure hydro to a
mixed hydro-thermal power baseincremental cost pricing would result in
a surplus of revenue over costs.
Most economists would argue' that·
power pooled through the Bonneville
system should be priced to reflect the
cost of adding this more expensive
thermal generating capacity, so that
Bonneville's wholesale customers
could make the choices that would
help lead to an optimal allocation of
resources. This shift would encourage
Bonneville's utility customers to make
a similar switchover to iricrementalcost pricing, thereby providing ultimate electricity customers with the
price signals required to allocate available supplies more efficiently. Otherwise, unless the price system is utilized
to restrain consumption and to finance
necessary additions to capacity, the
supply-demand situation for Northwest electric power is likely to become increasingly unbalanced.

Yvonne levy

uOl8u!4SEM • 4Eln • uo8aJO G EpEAaN • o4EPI
!!EMEH
E! U J0:l!I E).
EUOZPV.
E)ISEIV

Jr
'J!lU!:)'OJSPUl?J:I Ul?S
(;SL'ON lUWlBd
OI Vd

: J9¥lS Od

's'n

llVW SS",:) lS}l1::B

JJ,

BANKING TA- TWElfTH fEDERAL
DA
RESERVE
DISTRICT
(Dollaramountsin millions)
Selected Assets and liabilities
large Commercial Banks

Amount
Outstanding
3122/78

Change
from
3/15/78

-

Loans
(gross,adjusted)and investments*
Loans
(gross,adjusted) total
Securityloans
Commercial
and industrial
Realestate
Consumer
instalment
US. Treasury
securities
Other securities
Deposits(lesscashitems) total*
Demanddeposits(adjusted)
US. Governmentdeposits
Time deposits total*
States
and politicalsubdivisions
Savings
deposits
Other time depositst
Largenegotiable.
CD's

107,938
84,772
1,831
26,139
28,720
15,081
8,718
14,448
105,423
28,529
375
74,869
6,444
31,735
33,892
15,657

Weekly Averages
of Daily Figures

Week ended
3122/78

-

+
+
+
-

-

+
+
+
+
+

421
92
306
65
132
48
69
260
750
497
486
516
49
125
353
310

Changefrom
year ago
Dollar
Percent

+ 13,845
+ 12,965
+ 403
+ 2,588
+ 6,473
+ 2,656
- 653
+ 1,533
+ 12,110
+ 2,332
+ 151
+ 9,668
+ 1,093
42
+
+ 7,835
+ 6,204

Week ended
3/15178

+
+
+
+
+
+
-

+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+

14.71
18.06
28.22
10.99
29.10
21.38
6.97
11.87
12.98
8.90
67.41
14.83
20.43
0.13
30.07
65.63

Comparable
year-agoperiod

Member Bank Reserve Position

Excess
Reserves(+)/Deficiency
(-)
Borrowings
Net free(+)/Net borrowed (-)
Federal Funds-Seven large Banks

InterbankFederalfund transactions
Net purchases )/Net sales(
(+
-)
Transactions
with US. securitydealers
Net loans(+)/Net borrowings(-)

+
+

432

42
16
58

72
13
59

+

+

1,059

110
+
+ 529
*Includesitems not shownseparately.
tlndividuals,partnerships
and corporations.

3
50
53

+

117

+

147

Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (William Burke) or to the author ... .
Information on this and other publications can be obtained by calling or writing the Public Information
Section, Federal ReserveBank of SanFrancisco,P.O. Box 7702,San
Phone (415) 544-2184.