View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

April 24, 1981

PolicyDebate
A major debate within the economics profession has now been reflected in the financial press and in policy circles. The debate
concerns the appropriate role for monetary
policy and, to a lesser extent, fiscal policy in
the Reagan economic game plan. A March
23 Wall Street Journal editorial, entitled
"Money Doesn't Matter," sets forth one point
of view with the following propositions: 1)
the Federal Reserve, through its monetarypolicy tools, can control the money supply
and thus the inflation rate; 2) the Federal
government, through its fiscal-po!icy tools
(tax rates and government spending) can
affect productivity and employment; 3) monetary policy has little effect on employment
and growth; 4) fiscal pol icy has Iittle effect on
inflation.
If these four propositions correctly describe
the world, then the implementation of monetary and fiscal pol icy wou Id be rather easy
and straightforward. Monetary policy should
be directed towards lowering inflation, because of its lack of consequences for real
output. Fiscal policy should be directed towards loweri ng taxes and government spending to encourage productivity, because of its
lack of consequences for inflation.

Rebirthof classicalview
Some critics have labeled the Journal's argument as new, radical, and untested. That is
misleading. Indeed, the Journal's editorial
simply garbs in modern clothes the classicai
view of economics, which dominated the
economics profession from the time of Adam
Smith (The Wealth of Nations, 1776) to the
time of Lord Keynes (General Theory, 1936).
This classical economic theory focused
policy attention on the long run, where
money was a veil, so that changes in the
money supply only affected prices. Short-run
business-cycle problems, in this view, simply
reflected random economic events, which
policymakers could not anticipate and thus

cou Id not offset. But because private markets
were efficient and flexible, the economy
quickly returned to a new equilibrium value
following any external shock. Policymakers'
attempts to stabilize the economy in the
short-run thus would be both unnecessary
and undesirable. Rather, government policy
should be directed toward long-run considerations-monetary
policy to stabilize
prices and fiscal policy to encourage
economic growth.
The Great Depression of the 1 930's-a
worldwide traumatic event -seemed to
undermine one of the major assumptions of
the classical theory, however. With the unemployment rate over 10 percent for a decade, economists could no longer reasonably
assume that the business cycle was due to
random shocks which would be selfcorrecting by the efficient and flexible response of private markets.
The "Keynesian Revolution" in economic
thinking arose as a direct response to the
Great Depression. It shifted the focus of policy analysis to the short run from the long
run-"when
we are all dead," in Keynes'
words. It provided a theoretical rationale for
the failure of private markets to adjust effectively to an outside shock (such as a decl i ne in
aggregate demand) and for the need for government "stabilization" policy to offset these
influences. But although the Keynesian approach provided a theory for deal i ng with the
short-run business cycle, it did not incorporate a long-run theory of either inflation or
economic growth. (Keynes himself had
strong, even classical, views on these topics,
but they were not incorporated into his
General Theory.) This turned macroeconomic policy on its head. While the classical
theory focused on the long run and assumed
away the short run, the Keynesian theory did
just the reverse.
In recent years, the classical model has revived in response to the accelerating inflation

Inflation (Personal
consumption
deflator)

....... ...:....a...a.....&..!b..I!.....&..&....I.....II....L-I!...Il...dI-2I!-:&...b..IbdI..........,,"""'1952

1960

1968

1976

1980

1948

1956

19

For 1981, dots reprE

-_. _---_

....-._.......--.....

-_ __-.....----_.__._-_.__.._ __.....- - - - _ ...._-_..._---

_._._----_.. .._..

...

..

of the 1970s, which forced policymakers to
focus more on reducing inflation and less on
stabilizing income. Because of the Keynesian
model's failure to provide a theory of inflation, economists began to return to a classical
model-in its purest form, a "rational expectations" approach -which did provide such
a theory.

-- ..--_.

nf
rI",ht ::>nrl hro",t orr
................._ .............. .....··0 ...... 0· ....

_------_

high money growth was associated with a
high inflation rate in the post-1 965 period.
Specifically, the inflation rate averaged about
one percentage point below the moneygrowth rate before 1965, and about one
percentage point higher in later years.
Non-monetary factors-such as the upsurge
in OPEC oil prices-can also affect the inflation rate in the short run. The oil crisis pushed
the inflation rate above that related to underlying monetary factors in 1974 and again in
1 979-80. Weather-caused food shortages
have caused similar price shocks on several
other occasions.

This approach in effect asserts that monetary
policy should be directed in the long run
towards lowering the inflation rate. It asserts
also that in the short run, the business cycle is
largely due to random fluctuations, which
policy authorities can neither anticipate nor
do anything systematic to offset. I f policy is
systematic, it can also be anticipated by the
public, who will actto offset its influence. For
example, if the Fed announces as-percent
faster growth in the money supply in response
to a rise in unemployment, the public will
revise its inflation expectations by 5 percent,
so that there wou Id be no favorable impact on
real growth or unemployment.

Fiscalpolicy andinflation
Does fiscal policy affect inflation? Apparently
not, at least in any significantly direct way.
For example, 'an increase in the government
deficit increases the demand for credit and
therefore tends to push up interest rates.
However, it does not necessarily increase the
demand for goods, and thus does not push up
the inflation rate. This is because the deficit's
pressure to raise interest rates tends to "crowd
out" a roughly equal amount of private
interest-sensitive spending, so that the total
demand for goods fails to rise significantly.
This suggeststhatthe deficit, even in the short
run, will not systematically affectthe inflation
rate.

Markets are rational in the sense that they use
all information available in a systematic way,
and they are efficient in the sense that they
respond to external shocks in the least-cost
way. Thus, there is no role for stabilization
policy in this rational-expectations worldthe world of the Wall Street Journal editorial.
Because of the current importance of that
approach, the major propositions stated in
the Journal editorial deserve further analysis.

However, fiscal policy and the government
deficit can affect the inflation rate indirectly,
through money-supply effects. The rate of
change in the government deficit is closely
related in most years to the rate of change in
the money supply (see Chart 2). This close
statistical association is not based on any
basic behavioral relationship; in fact, the
relationship is not nearly as close in other
countries as it is in the United States.

Monetarypolicy and inflation
Does monetary policy affect the inflation
rate? Apparently yes. Monetary policy, measured by the annual rate of change in the
money supply, is a good predictor of the
inflation rate, with approximately a two-year
lag (seeChart 1). For example, money-supply
growth in 1 978 was a majorfactor explaining
the inflation rate in 1 980.

The close historic relationship between deficits and money in this country reflects a
number of potential factors:
• Even-keel considerations. Until the mid1970's, the Federal Reserve tended to hold
interest rates steady during periods of large

The trends of money and prices over long
periods of time are closely related. Low
money growth was associated with a low
inflation rate in the pre-1 965 period, while
2

..

_----

Change(%)

8

,

6

;=1221Ci\lP/

4

\

r ';

2

I .;/. \.

'\(./':

-2
-4
changes
(annual averages)

1972

estimatedgrowth
of money,

-6
1962

__

1965

1970

1975

1980

Monetary policy and GN P
Does monetary pol icy affect real output
(GNP)? Economists generally recognize that
the growth in real output, in the long run,
depends on the growth of capital, labor and
technology, and that fiscal policy can affect
those variables importantly through government taxing and spending decisions. However, in the short run, the growth in real GN P
is largely a function of incentives to utilize the
existing stock of capital and labor. These
incentives depend upon the level of aggregate demand, which can be influenced by
monetary policy.

Treasury financing. The reserves and
money created during such "even-keel"
periods may not all have been offset in
periods.
" Federal Reserve operating procedures. Until October 1979, the Fed controlled the
money supply via an interest-rate targeting
procedure. A large deficit could put upward
pressures on interest rates, which would
tend to induce monetary accommodation.
CDPol icy coi ncidence. Government deficits
were usually associated with businesscycle recessions, when monetary policy
was typically eased and the money supply
increased.

As we have seen, monetary policy tends to
affect inflation with a lag. In the meantime, a
change in the nominal money stock affects
the real (or inflation adjusted) money stock,
which tends to change aggregate demand
with about a two-quarter lag (Chart 3). Many
other factors are involved, of course, but real
money and real GN P have maintained a systematic cyclical relationship over time.

The one major break in the link between large
deficits and rapid money growth occurred in
1 975-76, when money growth stabilized in
the face of a record increase in the deficit. But
Administration policymakers expect that experience to be repeated in the 1 981 -82
period. The Federal Reserve is targeting a
31/2-to-6 percent growth rate in the (M-1 B)
money supply in 1 981 -considerably below
the 1 980 rate-and presumably it will target
even less in subsequent years. On the other
hand, the Government deficit may remain
high this year and next, as tax revenue reductions are expected to outpace planned
spending cuts.

In summary, economists widely accept the
long-run relationships between monetary
policy and inflation, and between fiscal policy and real output. But it also seems true that
monetary policy can affect real income in the
short run. In addition, fiscal policy appears to
influence the inflation rate, at least indirectly,
through its impact on the growth of the
money supply.

We might encounter difficulty repeating the
1 975-76 experience in the 1 981 -82 period.
The 1 975-76 deficit was associated with the
1 974-75 recession -the most severe since
the 1 930's-which sharply reduced private
demands for credit. Therefore, financial markets were able to finance an unusually large
government deficit with relatively little strain,
with little pressure on the Fed to monetize
that deficit. But no one expects a recession of
1 974-75 magnitude over the next year or so,
which means that financial markets could
feel considerable strain under the conflicting
pressures of a high government deficit and a
slowdown in money-supply targets.

Policymakers cannot ignore the short-run
costs involved in the necessary attack of
monetary policy on inflation. These costs are
of two kinds. First, there are the costs in terms
of pressures on financial markets when tight
money is associated with large government
deficits. Second, there are the costs of tight
money associated with a decline in real output and a rise in unemployment. Recognizing
these costs shou Id not paralyze action to fight
inflation. But being forewarned about costs,
one can be forearmed to deal with them.

MichaelW.,Keran

3

SS\11:J .lSl::ii:J
U018U!4seM
• 4eln • uo8aJO• epeAaN• o4epi
!!eMPH 0 e!uJoj!lP:)
euoz! J\'. e>jselV

(\J)

<§y

J(
<r))

JJ,

WJJ,CU'Wd[

BANKINGDATA-TWELfTH FEDERAL
RESERVE
DISTRICT
(Dollaramountsin millions)
SelectedAssetsandliabilities
largeCommercialBanks
Loans(gross,adjusted)
andinvestments*
Loans(gross,adjusted)
- total#
Commercialandindustrial
Realestate
Loansto individuals
Securities
loans
U.s.Treasury
securities*
Othersecurities*
Demanddeposits- total#
Demanddeposits- adjusted
Savings
deposits- total
Timedeposits- total#
Individuals,part.& corp.
(Largenegotiable
CD's)
WeeklyAverages
of Daily Figures
MemberBankReserve
Position
Excess
Reserves
(+ )/Deficiency(- )
Borrowings
Netfreereserves
(+ )/Netborrowed(
-)

Amount
Outstanding

Change
from

4/8/81

4/1/81

146,216
123,851
36,486
51,552
22,695
1,497
6,617
15,748
42,931
30,677
31,588
75,411
66,677
28,995

-

-

-

456
504
122
44
57
66
36
12
487
329
572
488
422
83

Changefrom
yearago
Dollar
Percent
6,681
6,114
1,837
5,708
- 1,641
774
92
475
- 2,216
- 2,553
4,529
12,460
12,245
6,533

Weekended

Weekended

4/8/81

4/1/81

n.a.

n.a.

2

118

n.a.

n.a.

4.8
5.2
5.3
12.5
- 6.7
107.1
1.4
3.1
- 4.9
- 7.7
16.7
19.8
22.5
29.1

Comparable
year-ago
period
35
200
165

* Excludes
tradingaccountsecurities.
# Includesitemsnotshownseparately.
Editorialcommentsmaybeaddressro
to theeditor(WilliamBurke)or to theauthor.... Freecopiesof this
andotherFederalReserve
publications
canbeobtainedbycallingor writingthePublicInformationSection,
FederalReserve
Bankof SanFrancisco,
P.O.Box7702, SanFrancisco
94120. Phone(415) 544-2184.

<tdI