View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

... '.
-,,;.'

ra

1 (G)IT
k

W
rr

cc: cc DJ
II C

November 6, 1981

Penalty Discount Rate: II
A number of economic policymakers and
analysts have urged the Federal Reserve to
maintain its discount rate (the rate it charges
banks to borrow reserves) at a penalty level
above the Federal funds rate (the cost of
borrowing reserves in the private financial
market). These analysts expect this approach
to improve Federal Reserve monetary control, since borrowed reserves would be kept
at low levels. This step consequently would
prevent borrowed reserves, and therefore the
money supply, from exacerbating inflation
and business-cycle fluctuations. Our last
Weekly Letterdiscussed these arguments as
well as evidence of monetary-control errors
occurring since October 1 979, when the Fed
began placing greater emphasis on bank reserves in the monetary-control process. This
week we explain some of the disadvantages
of a penalty discount rate for monetary control under present institutional arrangements.

lagged reserve accounting
One institutional change required for a
penalty rate is a switch from the Federal
Reserve's lagged reserve-requirement rule to
a system of contemporaneous reserve requirements. The lagged rule statesthat, in any
given week, institutions with reservable deposits must hold reserves (as deposits at a
Federal Reserve Bank or vault cash) in prescribed percentages of their various types of
deposits outstanding two weeksearlier. This
rule has been in effect since 1 968, replacing
the earlier system of contemporaneous reserve accounting, which required banks to
hold reserves based on the current week's
deposits.
To understand how reserve-requirement
rules affect the choice of a discount-rate
policy, we must understand how the Fed
exercises control over the monetary aggregates. Through its rules, the Fed setsthedollar
volume of reserve requirements equal to
fixed percentages of the various types of
deposits issued by depository institutions.

Thus if the Fed fixes the quantity of total
reserves available to the banking system,
bank deposits can expand only to some fixed
level. (By "bank," we mean all depository
institutions with transaction accounts.) If deposits expanded beyond that fixed level, total
reserve requirements would exceed the total
quantity of reserves available to meet those
requirements. Thus some individual banks
would find themselves without enough reserves to meet their requirements. These
banks would respond by bidding for reserves
from other banks in the Federal-funds market,
causing the funds rate to rise. That rate increase would induce banks to supply-and
the public to demand -fewer deposits. At the
appropriate funds rate, System-wide deposits
and reserve requirements would fall enough
to eliminate the System-wide reserve
deficiency.
Under lagged accounting, the link between
current deposits and required reserves is
broken. Banks enter any given week with an
unchangeable quantity of required reserves.
Unless the Fed wanted to force some individual banks into a deficiency, it must provide the quantity of reserves needed by the
banking system. Thus the Fed's supply of
reserves must adjust to the banking system's
demand.
Can the Fed use reserves to control the monetary aggregates under this system of accounting? The answer is yes under certain
circumstances, which depend on the level of
reserves which banks borrow from the Fed,
and thus on discount-rate policy. The Fed has
two basic methods of supplying reserves. The
System supplies nonborrowed reserves when
it purchases a Treasury bill or other security
directly or indirectly from a bank, paying for
the security with reserves (in the form of a
deposit at the Fed). The Fed supplies borrowed reserves when it makes a loan to a
depository institution at the discount rate.
Banks are reluctant to borrow from the dis-

..-"....",.,
.

....""

IP1\ ll\\CG)
S
Opinions expressed in
newsleHer do not
necessarily rdlect the views of the rnanageIT1ent
of thp Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco,
or ot the Board of Covernors of the Federal
Reserve Systern.
against various types of time and savings
deposits not included in M1 -B.) As noted
below, a new structure of reserve requirements is being phased in over the 1 980-87
period, in line with the stipulations of the
Monetary Control Act of 1 980.

count window, however. The Fed generally
discourages such loans except in emergencies, and moreover, it imposes restrictions on
the size and frequency of borrowing.
With banks reluctant to borrow, the Fed thus
can restrict money growth by providing a
larger proportion of banks' predetermined
requirements through the discount window
and a lower proportion through open-market
operations. The Fed achieves a more expansionary policy by shifting the split more in
favor of non borrowed reserves. This approach to monetary control would obviously
break down under a penalty discount rate,
since borrowed reserves would always be
nearly zero. As a consequence, the spl it between borrowed and non borrowed reserves
would always be set around 1 00-percent
nonborrowed/zero-percent borrowed, and
therefore could not be manipulated for .
monetary-control purposes.

To achieve its M 1-B targets, the Fed must
provide a level of total reserves which satisfies the demand for required reserves to support the target level of M 1-B, plus any excess
reserves; plus any reserves needed to support
deposits not included in M 1-B. Choosing the
appropriate reserves level for any monetarycontrol period requires forecasting the "multipl ier" relationship between M 1-B and total
bank reserves. This in turn requires forecasting (1) the composition of M1 -B with respect
to N OW versus checking accounts, and
checking accounts by size of bank, and (2)
the levels of the various reservable deposits
not included in M 1-B.

Uniform reserve requirements
If lagged reserve requ i rements represent such
a problem, why not switch simultaneously to
both contemporaneous accounting and a
penalty rate? For one reason, the switch in
accounting rules would impose added costs
on commercial banks. In addition, there
would be technical monetary-control problems resulting from differences in reserverequirement ratios on the various categories
of bank deposits. Ideally, reserve requirements would be applied uniformly to all
deposits included in the money-supply measure the Fed is most interested in controlling,
and wou Id be held at zero on the types
of deposits the Fed is less interested in
controlling.

Assume for example that the public decides to transfer funds from six-month
money-market certificates (M MC) to passbook-savings accounts, neither of which are
included in M 1-B. Since the M M C has a
lower reserve requ i rement than the passbook
account, total reserves absorbed by nonM 1-B deposits would rise-or the multiplier
between M 1-B and total reserves would fall.
If the Fed did not anticipate the shift in deposit
composition and did not provide the extra
reserves, fewer reserves would be available
to support M 1-B. Some individual banks
would find themselves with reserve deficiencies. They might try first to borrow reserves
from other banks in the Federal-funds market.
This would drive the funds rate up, causing
M 1-B to fall below target because of a decline
. in the money multiplier.

Unfortunately, this is currently not the case.
The Fed now pays most attention to M 1 -Bcurrency plus bank checking-account balances plus N OW and other interest-bearing
checkable deposits. It imposes certain reserve-requirement ratios on checking accounts, graduated upward according to the
volume of deposits, but imposes lower requirements on interest-bearing checkable
deposits. (Furthermore, reserves are required

Discount-rate policy strongly affects the extent to which the funds rate would rise and
M 1-B would fall short of its target. First assume that the discount rate is held constant
and at a below-market level. As the funds rate
begins to rise relative to the discount rate,
more and more banks will be induced to
borrow extra reserves at the now relatively
2

less expensive discount rate. The increase in
reserves will be used to satisfy the increased
need for reserves caused by the shift in deposit composition and by the lower money mu 1tiplier. This increase in total reserves relative
to their originally targeted path means a smaller decl i ne in M 1-B below its target level than
wou Id otherwise be the case. Thus the decline in the money multiplier caused by the
deposit-composition shift is offset to some
extent by an increase in total reserves relative
to their original path-an amount provided
through the disco,unt window. Our last
Weekly Letter showed that such offsets between multiplier errors and total reserve errors are quite important in practice.

Fed needs to offset (income and price movements), in order to achieve the desired
amou nt of monetary control. A recent Federal
Reserve study of the "New Monetary Control
Procedures" indicates that a penalty discount
rate would have a net disadvantage for monetary control under the current nonuniform
structure of reserve requirements. Onemonth-ahead forecasts of the monetary aggregates from two widely different money
market models (one developed at the Federal
Reserve Bank of San Francisco and the other
at the Federal Reserve Board) suggest that
failure to use the discount window as a
source of automatic changes in total reserves
would have impaired monetary control over
the October 1 979-0ctober 1 980 period.
Both sets of results included forecasts of
composition shifts, which the Fed should
accommodate, as well as income movements, which it shou Id not -and thus both
addressed the issue of relative predictability.

If a penalty discount rate were maintained,
the automatic stabilizer of M 1-B around its
target could not operate. With the discount
rate always above the funds rate, borrowings
from the discount window would be pegged
at nearly zero levels. Thus the extra reserves
necessary to stabilize M1 -B would not be
provided through the window.

Monetary Control Act
The effectiveness of a penalty discount rate
will be increased with the full implementation of the Monetary Control Act of 1 980.
This Act will make reserve requirements significantly more uniform. Bank and thriftinstitution transaction accounts (checking
plus interest-bearing checkable) over $25
million ultimately will have a uniform reserve
requ i rement of 12 percent, wh i Ie those under
$25 million will have a 3-percent requirement. No reserve requirements will be imposed on time and savings deposits, except
fornonpersonal time and Eurocurrency
deposits.

Double-edged
sword
The Fed's monetary control can be improved
when shifts in deposit composition are automatically accommodated by borrowed reserves. This can be a double-edged sword,
however. Borrowing also accommodates
other factors which the Fed does not want to
accommodate, such as a larger than desired
change in GNP. For example, higher GN P
causesthe publ ic' s demand for money to rise.
Banks' attempts to borrow the associated
extra reserves in the Federal-funds market
cause the funds rate to rise, inducing banks to
borrow reserves instead at the discount window. The extra reserves support the increased
deposits, and M 1-B thus overshoots its target.
Through this process, the Fed can inadvertently intensify business-cycle fluctuations by
providing a higher money supply when income is rising.

Choosing the level of reserves necessary to
hit a given M 1-B target thus will rely less
heavily on estimates of deposit-composition
shifts than is required under current reserverequirement rules. The new rules will not be
completely phased-in until 1 987, although
mostofthe phase-in will be accomplished by
1983. Thus for the next few years, problems
of predicting deposit composition will pose a
serious obstacle to the implementation of a
penalty discount rate.

The advisability of using a penalty discount
rate under contemporaneous accounting
thus depends on the relative predictability of
factors the Fed needs to accommodate (i.e.,
deposit-composition shifts) versus those the

JohnP. Juddand Adrian W. Throop
3

SS'o'1:>.LSl:
JI:I

!!eMeH •

• 4eln •
e!uJoj!/e:) •

CD) 4I

'lUe::>
10:lSpueJ:I
ues
(;SL 'ON II WHld
OIVd
I SOd 's'n
11V", SSV1::>
ISHI:I

BANKIN G DATA-TWELFTH FEDERAL
RESERVE
DISTRICT
(Dollaramounts millions)
in
Selected Assetsand liabilities
Large Commercial Banks

Loans
(gross,
adjusted) investments*
and
Loans
(gross,
adjusted) total#
Commercial industrial
and
Real
estate
Loans individuals
to
Securities
loans
U.s.Treasury
securities*
Othersecurities*
Demand
deposits total#
Demand
deposits adjusted
Savings
deposits total
Timedeposits total#
Individuals, & corp.
part.
(Large
negotiable
CD's)
Weeki'y Averages
of Daily Figures
Member Bank ReservePosition
Excess
Reserves }/Deficiency (- )
(+

Borrowings
Netfreereserves }/Netborrowed )
(+
(-

• epei\aN • o4epi
euozpy • e>/selY

Amount
Outstanding
10/21/81
153,036
132,143
39,766
54,929
23,162
1,661
5,585
15,308
39,391
27,728
29,387
85,751
77,917
33,409

Weekended
10/21/81
47
9
39

Change
from
10/14/8 i

Change
from
yearago
Dollar
Percent

-

87
95
469
140
2
151
13
5
-2,685
-1,974
145
- 327
- .295
456

-

-

Weekended
10/14/81
81
13
68

10,641
11,807
4,534
5,858
691
476
1,093
69
4,947
5,575
566
20,433
21,324
8,985

-

-

7.5
9.8
12.9
11.9
2.9
40.2
16.4
0.4
11.2
16.7
1.9
31.3
37.7
36.8

Com arable
P
year-ago
period
44
146
101

* Excludes
trading
account
securities.
# Includes
itemsnotshownseparately.
Editorial comments may beaddressedto the editor (William Burke) or to the author .... Freecopiesof this
and other FederalReserve
publications can beobtained by calling or writing the Public Infonnation Section;
Federal ReserveBank of SanFrancisco,P.O. Box 7702, SanFrancisco94120. Phone
(415) 544-2184.