View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

September 26,1975

O n e World?
The world's finance ministers and
central bankers dicussed a num­
ber of topics at the recent meetings
of the World Bank and the
International Monetary Fund, but
one of the strongest themes was
the call for the United States to
adopt stimulative policies to pull the
rest of the world out of recession.
This discussion aptly illustrates the
growing interdependence of the
world economy. It has long been
recognized that developments in
the U.S. can affect other countries,
but one of the most important
lessons of the past several years
has been the degree to which
developments in the rest of the
world can also affect the United
States.
The 10-percent-plus U.S. inflation
rate in 1973-74 was accentuated by a
25-percent rise in prices of worldtraded goods. Since the underlying
monetary expansion in the U.S.
probably would have supported no
more than about a 6-percent rate
of inflation, a significant share of
our actual inflation apparently was
“ imported". A rise in prices of
world-traded goods during this
period directly impacted on U.S.
agriculture, raw-materials produc­
tion and many industrial-goods
sectors.
Developments in the rest of the
world also added to the length
and severity of the U.S. recession.
First, world inflation reduced the
real purchasing power of U.S.
consumers more than would
otherwise have been the case.
Second, the slowing in world de1

Digitized for FRA SER


mand led to a slower growth of
U.S. exports in real terms (though
not in nominal terms). Both
elements, but especially the for­
mer, contributed to a large de­
cline in the real demand for goods
and services in the U.S.
The same factors also worked in
the other direction, helping to
account for the recessions in other
major industrial countries. Thus,
the level of industrial production
in Western Europe is far below a
year ago—9 percent lower in
West Germany and 7 percent
lower in France—while the num­
ber of unemployed has doubled in
a year's time.
Simultaneous world cycles
The simultaneous worldwide
boom and bust since 1971 has
added a new dimension to the
economic scene. Until recently,
each major industrial country
marched to its own business-cycle
drummer, thereby contributing to
world economic stability. When
one country was expanding anoth­
er country was contracting, and
as a result the demand on
internationally-traded goods re­
mained fairly stable, in line with
the growing capacity to produce
such goods. Prices of worldtraded goods thus increased at a
modest 1.3-percent average an­
nual rate between 1962 and 1969.
Relative stability in the interna­
tional sphere helped to soften
business-cycle fluctuations in any
one country. During the expansion
phase of the cycle, a country
(continued on page 2)

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not
necessarily reflect the views of the management of the
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, nor of the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

could acquire imports at stable
world prices, and therefore would
suffer only from the price conse­
quences of its own internal expan­
sion. In the declining phase, a
country's export demand typically
would hold up because of expan­
sion elsewhere, thus mitigating the
effects of a softening domestic
demand.
This relatively stable environment
was thrown out of equilibrium by
the shock associated with the
breakdown in the international
monetary system in the early 1970's.
The accelerating U.S. inflation had
already eroded private market
confidence in the dollar as an
international currency. This trig­
gered a flight from the dollar
which culminated in suspension
of dollar convertibility into gold in
August 1971. Then, by overstaying
fixed exchange rates, foreign cen­
tral banks purchased in excess of $68
billion in dollar-denominated
assets in the two years ending
March 1973.
The overall effect was equivalent
to a simultaneous easing of mone­
tary policy and acceleration of
domestic money growth in all
major industrial countries. The
resulting worldwide businesscycle boom led directly to accel­
erating world inflation. However,
the movement to flexible ex­
change rates in March 1973 permit­
ted a sharp slowing in money

2

Digitized for FRA SER


growth, which then contributed to
the current worldwide recession
and the easing of inflation.
Repeat of boom and bust?

Perhaps the overriding question for
the second half of the 1970's is
whether the major industrial coun­
tries will continue on a largely
synchronized and unstable path of
boom and bust, or return to the
less synchronized but far more
stable business-cycle patterns which
existed in the 1950's and 1960's.
The possibility of another interna­
tional monetary shock may be
fairly remote. As long as the major
industrial countries continue to
maintain reasonably flexible ex­
change rates, with moderate
exchange-market interventions,
foreign central banks should be
able to avoid massive flows of
capital and internationally-induced
expansions in domestic money.
However, the maintenance of flexi­
ble exchange rates is no guaran­
tee against the repetition of anoth­
er boom and bust. All foreign
central banks are now faced with
the same set of domestic econom­
ic problems: the worst recession in
the postwar period, with a high rate
of unemployment and a high but
decelerating rate of inflation. If the
major industrial countries re­
spond to this common economic
phenomenon with a common
desire to recover as quickly as

possible, we could see a common
set of stimulative policies, result­
ing among other things in a
simultaneous expansion in their
domestic money stocks. This could
lead to a repeat of the worldwide
business-cycle boom in 1976-77
followed by a recession in 1978-79.
Such a scenario is analogous to the
U.S. experience of the past
decade. Prior to 1966 the U.S.
enjoyed five years of growing
prosperity and price stability.
However, the shock of the Vietnam
war, which was marked by Gov­
ernment deficit financing in a
period of full employment and
an acceleration in the U.S. money
stock, disturbed this equilibrium
and led to an accelerated inflation.
The policy response from 1968
through early 1970 involved res­
trictive monetary and fiscal actions
to counter the inflation. This led
to a rise in unemployment and a
subsequent reversal of policy,
which in turn made the next round
of inflation even more severe.
Interdependence

The U.S. is still suffering the
consequences of the monetary and
fiscal shock of 10 years ago be­
cause of the tendency for subse­
quent policy actions to amplify and
reinforce that initial shock. If
policy makers in other industrial
countries were now to follow the
same destabilizing reaction func­

tion, then a worldwide boom-andbust scenario might well continue
through the second half of the decade.
Probably the major threat of
another worldwide boom and
bust comes from sharply expan­
sionary policies designed to gen­
erate an overly rapid recovery
from the current recession. The U.S.
plays the key role in this situation.
First, the U.S. economy by itself
represents almost 50 percent of
the income of the industrial coun­
tries of the world. Thus, a slow but
stable growth in this country
would contribute to a moderate
growth in the demand for inter­
nationally traded goods and would
thereby ease the pressure on
their prices. Second, a moderate
U.S. recovery policy would streng­
then the resolve of others not to
follow excessively expansionary
policies.
Nonetheless, our trading partners
may continue to press for strong­
ly expansionary policies on the part
of the U.S. Most major industrial
nations are looking towards an
export-led recovery in their econo­
mies. They wish to avoid further
deterioration in their own trade
balances, in view of the adverse
effects which higher oil prices have
already imposed. Thus, they
would like the U.S. to provide a
strong market for their exports,
through a more expansionary
policy on our part.
Michael Reran

3

Digitized for FRA SER


uoj8u!qsE/v\ • qetn • uo S o jo • epeA9|s| . ogepi
MEM EH

7!|B3

'o d s o u b jj

•

E J U J O P IE 3

•

EUOZUy

•

B )jS E |V

u i$

ON llWU3d
aivd
aovisod s n
nvw SSV1D 1SMIJ
ZSL

p asrap M aQ isping®®®^

BANKING DATA—TWELFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)
Amount
Outstanding
9/10/75

Change
from
9/03/75

Loans (gross, adjusted) and investments*
Loans (gross, adjusted)— total
Security loans
Commercial and industrial
Real estate
Consum er instalment
U.S. Treasury securities
O ther securities
Deposits (less cash items)—total*
Demand deposits (adjusted)
U.S. Government deposits
Time deposits—total*
States and political subdivisions
Savings deposits
Other time depositsi
Large negotiable C D ’s

86,066
65,278
2,287
22,536
19,560
9,998
8,138
12,650
86,258
24,245
358
59,877
5,832
20,709
29,548
15,714

+ 1,044
+ 1,217
+ 1,315
100
+
29
2
153
20
+ 915
+ 658
+
58
+ 115
33
+
9
+ 129
+ 118

Weekly Averages
of Daily Figures

W eek ended
9/10/75

+ 1,742
1,777
+ 1,000
1,671
279
+
350
+ 3,832
313
+ 5,769
+ 2,202
47
+ 3,742
98
+ 2,979
+
485
105
-

W eek ended
9/03/75

53
29
82

+

67
12
55

+

1,486

+

+

915

+

-

+

-

-

+
-

+
+
-

+
+
-

+
-

+
+
-

2.07
2.65
77.70
6.90
1.41
3.63
88.99
2.41
7.17
9.99
11.60
6.67
1.65
16.80
1.67
0.66

Comparable
year-ago period

-

6
249
255

1,236

u>
o
CO

Member Bank Reserve Position
Excess Reserves
Borrowings
Net free (+) / Net borrowed (-)
Federal Funds—Seven Large Banks
Interbank Federal fund transactions
Net purchases (+) / Net sales (-)
Transactions of U.S. security dealers
Net loans (+) / Net borrowings (-)

Change from
year ago
Dollar
Percent

+

Selected Assets and Liabilities
Large Commercial Banks

-

351

+

695

*lncludes items not shown separately. ^Individuals, partnerships and corporations.

Information
Information
Phone (415)
Digitized for FRA SER
http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/
Federal Reserve Bank of St.

on this and other publications can be obtained by calling or writing the Public
Section, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco 94120.
397-1137.

Louis