View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

November 2, 1 979

__ ._---_
..-_._--------_
..__ ._._---_._.
__
___--_._._----_.-.-_--__------------_ ..-

--_.__.

.__

.

..

.......

..

_-------_

.......

_

.. ..._.._..__
..._--,-_._"""" .."._---_
.._-.-......
_._._._""--,......... ---"" ..,,,

-.-..- ...._....,,-

The Mystery
Edward Denison's path-breaking work,
Accounting for United States Economic
Growth, 7929-69, will soon have a timely
sequel in Accounting for Slower Economic
Growth: The United States in the 7970's.
In an excerpt from his forthcoming book
in the August issue of the Survey of Current
Business, Denison tries to explain why the
nation has become so unproductive during
this frustrating decade, but confesses that the
causes of the downtrend remain largely
a mystery. In this situation, it might be useful
to examine some of the explanations Denison
puts forward, to see which (if any) might clear
up the mystery he describes.
Apparently, 1973 marks the watershed year,
although some slackening in productivity
was apparent even earlier. Over a quartercentury, 1 948-73, national income per
person employed in the private sector
increased by an average of 2.4 percent a year.
(This sector includes the entire economy
except government and housing.) Overall,
productivity increased 82 percent in that 25year period. But by mid-1 979, productivity
was actually below the 1973 level, reflecting
the ups and (mostly) downs of the past halfdozen years. In contrast, productivity today
would be roughly 1 6 percent above the 1973
level if the earlier trend had continued.
Whatever the reason for the slowdown,
it apparently has pervaded the entire
economy. Citing an alternative productivity
measure, real GN P per hours worked,
Denison finds that growth rates declined
substantially in the post-1 973 period for
1 0 of 11 major industries-including durable
manufacturing, nondurable manufacturing,
trade, services and the like. The only
exception was communications (mainly the
telephone industry). International comparisons provide similar evidence. The growth
rate of real output per worker declined for
seven major industrial countries in the post1 973 period, and not only forth is country.

Indeed, all other countries except Germany
showed even larger declines than the United
States.
Accounting for growth
Denison views economic growth asthe result
of changes in a large number of determinants
that govern the size of a nation's output.
He thus estimates the contributions, positive
or negative, made to the growth rate by all
quantifiable determinants. The combined
contribution of the remaining determinants
is obtained as a residual-which
is where
most of the present problem resides.
Growth of output may be obtained by using
more labor and property resources in production, or else by increasing the output
obtained from the same quantity of resources.
Contributions of the former type would result
from changes in employment, working hours,
and personal attributes of employed persons,
and also from changes in the amount
of capital or the amount of land employed.
Contributions of the latter type would result
from changes in the state of knowledge,
efficiency of resource allocation, size
of markets, and other conditions that alter the
amount of output obtainable from a given
amount of input.
A substantial rise in many of these factors
helped generate the 2.43-percent average
growth rate of output per worker over the
1 948-73 period (see chart). Increased'
education of employed persons, increased
capital per worker, improved resource
allocation, and economies of scale all contributed to the strong overall productivity
growth. The growth rate would have been
even larger but for reductions in average
hours of work and shifts in age-sex composition toward younger and less experienced
workers.
In contrast, many of these factors turned unfavorable in the post-1 973 period, so that

f8\'6' _.

L!::::V

l..1

((\\
1;
"-'0 $11
7
J1

(ell§CC(G)

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not
necessadlv reflect the views of the management
of the Feeleral
Bank of San Francisco,
flC)f

()f

(;f

(ff

Reserve

The residual showed a nearly constant
growth rate between 1 948 and 1973,
because those determinants whose effects
could be directly estimated accounted for
most of the irregularities in the productivitygrowth trend up to that
But the series
then departed abruptly from past experience,
much to Denison's puzzlement. He reviews a
number of possible reasons-1 7 in all-that
might account for the abrupt shifts in this
residual measure of productivity growth, but
he finds most of them unsatisfactory. The
basic problem is that nearly all the possible
reasons advanced for the slowdown wou Id
be much more likely to affect growth trends
gradually rather than suddenly, as actually
happened.

productivity actually declined at a 0.54percent annual average rate in the 1973-76
period-and apparently continued to
decline in the subsequent period, for which
detailed data are not yet available. The overall negative swing in productivity amounted
to 2.9ipercentage points (annual average)
between the 1 948-73 period and the 1 97376 period. Several factors remained positive
during the 1 973-76 period, such as increased
education, increased capital per worker, and
economies of scale. But other factors were
strongly negative, such as a sharp reduction
in hours worked and a significant increase
in costs associated with anti-pollution and
health-and-safety legislation.
Accounting for no-growth
But the most important reason for the break
in the growth pattern was a major-and
largely unexplainable-shift
in a catch-all
collection of other factors. This residual
category accounted for most of the 1948-73
growth but also for most of the later decline
in growth; indeed, it accounted for more than
two-thirds of the entire decline in the growth
rate between the two periods. In Denison's
view, growth in this category relies mainly
on "advances in knowledge"-the gains
in measured output that result from the
incorporation into production of new
knowledge of any type, managerial and
organizational as well as technological.
Quality changes are left out of consideration,
because on Iy the advances in knowledge that
reduce the unit costs of already existing final
products contribute to measured growth.

Denison tends to dismiss the popular
explanation, especially favored by elderly
commentators-"People
don't want to work
any more." (After Denison first reported his
puzzlement about the productivity decline,
many long-distance phone callers reminded
him, "usually with the patronizing air used
in speaking to children and the simpleminded," of this "obvious" explanation.) But
that explanation may not be relevant to the
present situation. After all, that argument has
been heard for generations (nay, millenia)
and indeed, it is heard today in such unlikely
places as Japan and Germany as well as the
United States.
Because of the strong importance of "advances in knowledge" to past productivity
growth, Denison examines several possible
underlying factors-such as a decline
in research-and-development spending or
the aging of the capital stock-to see if they
could account for the recent decline. While
not denying the existence of these phenomena, Den ison argues that they have
exerted only a modest negative impact
to date on productivity growth. Similarly,
he notes the existence of regulatory impedi-

2

CONTRIBUTION TO GROWTH RATE
(Annual average)

-1.0;.:.0_-..:.=,.5;:-0

Education

.....
1.50
•

_

_

(1946-73)
(1973-76)

Other labor inputs
Capital and land
Resource allocation
Legal environment
Economies of scale
Advances in knowledge, etc.

----_.-.--_

__._--_

.._.

_

_

_-_._------_._--_._._
_-----._-----------_._--_

...

..

_

--------'

__
. _-------------.

..-.._--_.

_----------

how to produce it, or how to employ owned
resources. The relevant information is about
relativeprices-of one product relative
to another, of the services of one factor
of production relative to another, of products
relative to factor services, of prices now
relative to prices in the future. But the
information in practice is transmitted in the
form of absoluteprices-prices in dollars
or pounds or kronor.

ments to growth, but argues that much of this
impact is already measured by such disincentives as anti-pollution and health-andsafety regulations.
Post-1973 factors
Since the key mystery is why productivity
weakened so badly after 1973, it seems
logical to search for factors which became
apparent after that date. An obvious explanation wou Id seem to be the energy crisisexcept that that factor's measurable impact
has been less than commonly supposed. For
example, George Perry states in a Brookings
study, "It seems unlikely that higher energy
prices have caused more than a O.2-percent
loss of labor productivity and potential output
between 1 973 and 1976./1Other studies
have come up with higher figures, but few
suggest that the energy crisis is a major cause
of the sharp break in the productivity trend.

"I f the price level is on the average stable
or changing at a steady rate, it is relatively
easy to extract the signal about relative prices
from the observed absolute prices. The more
volatile the rate of general inflation, the
harder it becomes to extract the signal about
relative prices from the absolute prices: the
broadcast about relative prices is, as it were,
being jammed by the noise coming from the
inflation broadcast . . . At the extreme, the
system of absolute prices becomes nearly
useless, and economic agents resort either
to an alternative currency or to barter, with
disastrous effects on productivity."

A more relevant explanation may be
inflation. Of course, the nation was beset
by inflationary pressures prior to 1973, but
the persistence of the problem -and the
public's anticipation of further inflation
may have been the catalyst behind the recent
shift. Denison lists inflation as only one of the
17 possible explanatory factors, but its
pervasive influence can be seen behind other
factors that he cites, such as major data
miscalculations. For example, output data
in the post-1 973 period were probably
subject to greater errors than usual because
of inflation, since major price swings
significantly affect data adjustments, such
as the inventory valuation adjustment.

There may be no all-encompassing
explanation of the post-1 973 productivity
downtrend, but persistent inflation ma'y help
explain away a significant share of the
mystery which Denison cites. Obviously
further research is needed. This suggests,
at least, that more job opportunities will
be created for economists as the search
widens into the mystery of growth and
no-growth.
William Burke

Still, inflation's major impact has been felt
more directly through its debilitating impact
on productivity. As described by Milton
Friedman in his Nobel lecture, " A fundamental function of a price system . . . is to
transmit compactly, efficiently, and at low
cost the information that economic agents
need in order to decide what to produce and

3

SS"1::> l.SI:U:J

HE'MPH

CD

• 4Pln •
• ppPi\aN• o4PPI
P!UJOJ!lP) .. puozP'v' .. P>lsPI'v'

(\5)

'J!Il!:) IO:>SpUl!J:I Ul!S

lSL 'ON 11W2Bd
GI Yd
:I!)Y 1 S0d 's'n

JJ

llYW SSY1:)1S2I1:1

BANKING DATA-TWELFTHfEDERALRESERVE
DISTRICT
(Dollaramountsin millions)
SelectedAssetsand Liabilities
large CommercialBanks

Amount
Outstanding
10/17/79
134,195
110,988
30,961
41,271
23,494
1,901
7,605
15,602
44,264
31,751
30,102
55,524
47,086
20,818
Weekended
0/17/79

Changefrom
Change
yearago@
from
Dollar
Percent
10/10/79
+ 18,059
+ 15.55
640
+ 17,231
638
+ 18.38
344
+ 3,314
+ 11.99
+ 25.82
+ 216
+ 8,469
NA
NA
89
+
NA
NA
308
688
8.30
3
1
+ 10.76
+
+ 1,516
1,508
+ 2,746
+ 6.61
772
838
+
+ 2.49
569
1.86
182
+ 19.32
+ 682
+ 8,989
+ 9,558
+ 25.47
+ 608
+ 16.48
+ 365
+ 2,945
Weekended
Comparable
year-agoperiod
10/10/79

Loans(gross,adjusted)and investments*
Loans(gross,adjusted)- total#
Commercialand industrial
Realestate
Loansto individuals
Securitiesloans
U.s. Treasurysecurities*
Othersecurities*
Demanddeposits- total#
Demanddeposits adjusted
Savingsdeposits- total
Timedeposits total#
Individuals,part.& corp.
(LargenegotiableCD's)
WeeklyAverages
of Daily Figures
MemberBankReservePosition
27
52
ExcessReserves
(+ )/Deficiency(- )
31
96
25
Borrowings
127
Net freereserves
(+ )/Netborrowed(- )
44
52
96
FederalFunds- Sevenlarge Banks
Net interbanktransactions
+1,263
+ 113
+ 511
[Purchases
(+ )/Sales(-)]
Net, U.s. Securities
dealertransactions
+ 111
+ 238
+ 57
[Loans(+ )/Borrowings(-)]
* Excludestradingaccountsecurities.
# Includesitemsnot shownseparately.
@ Historicaldata arenot strictly comparabledueto changesin the reportingpanel;however,adjustments
havebeenappliedto 1978datato removeasmuchaspossiblethe effectsof the changesin coverage.In
addition,for someitems,historicaldataarenot availabledueto definitionalchanges.
Editorialcommentsmay be addressed
to the editor (William Burke)or to the author.... Freecopiesof
this and other FederalReservepublicationscanbe obtainedby callingor writing the PublicInformation
Section,FederalReserveBank of San Francisco,P.O. Box 7702, SanFrancisco94120.Phone(415)
544-2184.