View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

May 18,1979

__ .........

....._ ........
___

,_

_

,__ ...._, .......
·_ _ _ _ ... __

..,_ .............
.....- _____

___

--

..".- ..- ..--......----

....,....-------..-,.-.-

Th e M u l ti pl e- Cu rren cy Defense
Rememberthe gold clause
During the half-century ending in
1914,"greenbacks" and "free silver" were the favorite instruments
of American inflationism. William
Jennings Bryan became the mouthpiece of what we call today "reflation" and "economic stimulation"
thinking. As insurance against
greenbackery and "Bryanism," and
later against any revival of Ncheap
money," bondholders and other
long-term creditors accepted lower
nominal interest rates in exchange
for "gold clauses" in the securities
they held. (If you held a $1000
bond with a gold clause, you
could claim both interest and
eventually principal in gold. Were
the price of gold to double over
the life of the bonds, for example,
you could claim $2000 in U.S. currency when the bond matured.)
The gold clause is a simple
example of "choice in currency." It
harks back to the disinflation
which took place from the end of
the Civil War until the resumption
of specie payments in 1879 - "the
only period in which two kinds of
money exchanging ata fluctuating
rate - greenbacks and gold were used domestically side by
side to any considerable extent."
In 1933, the first New Deal
administration raised the U.S.
price of gold from $20.67 to
$35.00 per ounce. This was done
to reflate the price level to a predepression figure. (The price
theory which prompted this
action was simply wrong.)

An issue of Baltimore and Ohio
Railroad (8&0) bonds, with gold
clauses, matured in 1933, with the
price of gold $35 per ounce but
the general price level still close
to its depression lows. Some B&O
bondholders demanded $1693
(1000 x 35.00/20.67) for each $1000
bond as per the gold clause, although gold clauses had been
abrogated by Congress. B&O
refused to pay more than $1000.
The bondholders sued, calling the
Congressional abrogation of existing gold clauses unconstitutional.
The resulting lawsuit was decided
5-4 in B&O's favor by the U.S.
Supreme Court in 1935 ( B&O v
Francis). Query: Were the case to
come up today, would the learned
Justices decide the same way
despite altered "equities?"

Generalized currency choice
The "choice in currency" movement proposes, by legislation, to
reverse the gold-clause decision in
the U.S. and similar decisions in
other countries, and to re-establish on broader geographic and
other bases the situation prevailing in the U.S. between the Civil
War and the 1879 "resumption."
Currently, private parties can of
course specify in advance the currency - or other commodity - in
which interest and principal of
debts should be payable. Such
stipulations, however, are not
legally binding or enforceable
unless "legal tender" currency is
specified. "Choice in currency"
advocates propose to abolish this

(continued on page 2)

distinction by broadening the
. "legal tender" concept.
This change would permit U.S.
creditors who distrust U.S. economic policy to stipulate payment
in gold, German marks, or anything else they (and their debtors!) can agree upon. If a U.S.
contract were written in marks,
and the marks rose during the life
of the contract, the creditor under
a "mark clause" could demand
either marks or the current dollar
equivalent. The courts would
enforce his claim as though the
contract had been drawn up in
U.S. dollars. Before agreeing to a
mark clause, a gold clause, or a
yen clause in a long-term contract,
the rational American debtor in
1979 should insist upon a relatively low nominal interest··rate.
Debtors might go even further,
and persuade creditors to accept
payment in currencies depreciating faster than the U.S. dollar in
exchange for higher nominal interest rates. Once agreed up'on by
creditors, such stipulations would
also be binding.
With media of payment negotiable
between contracting parties, each
contract or security might conceivably specify its own idiosyncratic
legal tender. Absence of any contrary stipulation would surely be
interpreted in the U.S. to imply
mutual acceptability of the U.S.
dollar. The various U.S. governments (national, state, and local)
would also continue to require
payment of tax and similar Iiabili-

2

ties in U.S. dollars. In earlier days
some Southern states permitted
deer and coon skins to be used
for payment of taxes.
The revival of interest in currency
choice reflects desires by prospective creditors for a defense against
inflation, and by prospective debtors for a defense against high
nominal interest rates. The revival
is largely the work of one man,
Friedrich von Hayek of Austria, a
1974 Nobel laureate in economics.
Hayek would even permit private
parties (from David Rockefeller
to Robert Vesco, from General
Motors to Penn Central) to issue
certificates of indebtedness which
would compete freely for public
acceptance as money. The conventional reading of U.S. financial
history in the "wildcat banking"
generation which preceded the
Civil War renders most economists
skeptical about this extension of
the free market.
Impact problems
The availability of alternatives to
the dollar would doubtless have
kept American money managers
and legislators more sensitive to
inflationary dangers in the past
than they actually were. Market
participants would have deserted
the dollar in favor of gold and
foreign currencies in a more
massive and more rapid fashion,
bringing more and earlier pressure
on the. dollar exchange rate in international finance. A wider nominal interest spread between
contracts denominated in dollars
and in more stable media would
have provided early warning to
the government of developing
distrust of the American currency.

There might also have been an
earlier and faster migration of the
world financial community from
Wall Street to rival centers. The
U.S. government might then have
acted sooner, and more consistently, against inflation. This
change of public policy would
have been an added bonus of the
Hayek proposals, which Hayek
duly stresses.
Introduction of currency-choice in
mid-inflation, however, exerts
unhappy impact effects. With gold
clauses suddenly made legal and
enforceable, we can forecast a
shift in the demand for money Keynesian "liquidity preference"
- from dollars to gold. This
would raise the price of gold and
weaken the dollar internationally.
On the domestic scene people
would hold fewer dollars for
shorter periods, raising the velocity of dollar ci rculation; at the
same time, the volume of transactions carried on by exchange of
goods for dollars would fall. All
these reactions could accelerate
the American inflation, not only
until our money managers
"learned their lesson" but quite
possibly until short-term resumption of inflation became as
unlikely as it seemed 50 years ago.
Now consider the reactions of currency choice upon an economy in
a period of at least relative deflation. To make this scenario more
concrete, consider a two-country
world and neglect gold and other
commodities. Our two countries
are North America or N .A. (a dollar country in which we live) and
latin America or l. A. (a peso

3

country with more rapid inflation).
With currency choice in both
countries, total demand for N .A.
dollar-denominated assets would
rise as latin Americans shifted to
the dollar from the peso. This
would slow N .A. inflation (or accelerate N. A. deflation). It would
probably raise real N .A. interest
rates on balance. The deceleration
of inflation we should instinctively
consider stabilizing, while acceleration of deflation would be destabilizing. These changes would
also handicap N .A. export and
import-competing industries in
international competition.
This analysis ignores the effects of
cu rrency choice in N .A. itself, i.e.,
the preference of N .A. debtors to
borrow in pesos, paying higher
nominal interest rates as an offset.
Such borrowings would presumably be rare. But why, one wonders, would they be rare? My
personal belief is that most of us
develop early in life a certain.
_
stability preference with regard to
general price levels. This stability
preference would be an aspect of
the same risk aversion which
makes so many of us pay premiums for insurance and which
generates ulcers when circumstances force us to become largescale risk-bearers (gamblers). I
also believe that this stability
preference is overlooked in
theoretical-economic discourses
about the "welfare cost of i nflation" - but that is a subject for
another sermon.
Martin Bronfenbrenner

uOll3U!4SEM"4Eln .. uol3aJO.. EpEt\aN" 04EPI
!!EMEH .. E!UJOj!lE:)
EUOZpV" E>fsEIV

CD)

'llleJ 'O:lSpueJ::B
Ui! S
ZSi:'O N
alVei
:l9V l S Od '5'0

llVW SSV1:>

JJ

BANKING DATA-TWELFTH FEDERAL
RESERVE
DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)
SelectedAssetsand liabilities
large Commercial 8anks
Loans (gross, adjusted) and investments*
Loans (gross, adjusted) - total#
Commercial and industrial
Real estate
Loans to individuals
Securities loans
U.S. Treasury securities*
Other securities*
Demand deposits - total#
Demand deposits - adjusted
Savings deposits - total
Time deposits - total#
Individuals, part. & corp.
(Large negotiable CD's)
Weekly Averages
of Daily Figures
Member Bank ReservePosition
ExcessReserves (+ )/Deficiency (-)
Borrowings
Net free reserves(+ )/Net borrowed ( -)
Federal Funds- Sevenlarge Banks
Net interbank transactions
[ Purchases(+ )/Sales (-)]
Net, U.s. Securities dealer transactions
[Loans (+ )/Borrowings (-)]

Amount
Outstanding
5/2/79
124,975
102,205
30,172
36,466
21,247
1,644
7,707
15,063
42,597
30,534
29,632
49,680
40,387
17,061
Weekended
5/2/79

Change
Change from
from
year ago @
Dollar
Percent
4/25/79
549
+ 17,324
+ 16.09
798
+ 16,616
+ 19.41
192
+ 13.95
+ 3,693
+' 7,871
176
+ 27.53
114
NA
NA
154
NA
NA
- 4.39
217
354
32
+ 1,062
+ 7.59
26
+ 8.60
+ 3,373
857
+ 2,892
+ 10.46
_. 1.96
31
591
64
+ 15.48
+ 6,661
+ 21.47
5
+ 7,138
106
+ 1,458
+ 9.34
Weekended
Comparable
4/25/79
_year-agoperiod

10
224
214

67
122
55

25
66
41

+

967

+ 1,365

+ 1,695

+

220

+

84

63

* Excludestrading account securities.
# Includes items not shown separately.
@ Historical data are not strictly comparable due to changes in the reporting panel; however,

adjustments have been applied to 1978 data to remove as much as possible the effects of the
changesin coverage.In addition, for someitems, historical data are not availabledue to definitional
changes.
Editorial comments may be addressedto the editor (William Burke) or to the author .... Freecopiesof
this and other Federal Reservepublications can be obtained by calling or writing the Public Information Section, Federal ReserveBank of SanFrancisco,P.O. Box 7702, Sanfrancisco 94120.Phone(415)
544-2184.