View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF Economic Letter
2022-28 | October 11, 2022

Research from
the Federal Reserve
Bank of San Francisco

What If? Monetary Policy in Hindsight
Regis Barnichon
If the Federal Reserve had expected the upcoming inflation surge back in March 2021, would it have
acted differently? A new method to tackle such “what if” questions suggests that it may have been
preferable to only moderately raise the federal funds rate during 2021, even with perfect foresight. In
that case, inflation would have been about 1 percentage point lower as of June 2022, while
unemployment would be about 2 percentage points higher. This result reflects the importance of the
Fed’s dual mandate of price stability and maximum employment.

A number of critics have argued that the Fed has been behind the curve in its fight against inflation. Given
the recent high inflation numbers, they argue that the Fed should have lifted the federal funds rate much
earlier than March 2022. In fact, in a May 2022 interview, Fed Chair Jerome Powell said, “If you had
perfect hindsight you’d go back, and it probably would have been better for us to have raised rates a little
sooner” (Marketplace 2022). But if the Fed had tightened earlier, how different would the economy be
now? Would inflation be lower? What would have happened to unemployment?
For policymakers, such “what if” questions arise constantly, both during the decisionmaking process and
afterward to assess whether a policy decision was appropriate. Answering “what if” questions is difficult
however, because it’s not possible to run controlled experiments at a country level or go back in time and
try different approaches. In fact, in his interview, Chair Powell was quick to add, “I’m not sure how much
difference [an earlier lift-off] would have made.”
This Economic Letter applies a recent approach designed by Barnichon and Mesters (2022) to answer
“what if” questions with minimal assumptions. Using only two concepts that are already well known to
policymakers—(1) what is the current economic outlook, and (2) how much a change in policy will affect
that outlook—it is possible to provide quantitative answers to “what if” questions, including an evaluation
of the response to the 2021 inflation surge. The findings suggest that the main effect of earlier action by the
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) would have been slightly lower inflation at the cost of a
substantially higher unemployment rate.

Answering “what if” questions with sufficient statistics
In the context of economic policy, a “what if” question takes the following form: what would happen if
policymakers did Y instead of X? These types of economic policy “counterfactual” scenarios are notoriously
difficult to study.

FRBSF Economic Letter 2022-28 | October 11, 2022
Studying counterfactuals first requires knowing what policymakers' goals are. In the case of the Federal
Reserve, the congressionally mandated goals are to achieve price stability, understood as 2% inflation, and
maximum employment. These goals are often referred to as the dual mandate. The Fed aims to achieve the
dual mandate over time by adjusting the path of the federal funds rate, an overnight interest rate.
In addition, examining counterfactuals typically requires using theoretical models, which are mathematical
representations of the economy. Within the constructed world of an economic model, one can experiment
with alternative policies to assess their economic effects. In the case of monetary policy, a counterfactual
might be different levels of the federal funds rate at different points in time.
Unfortunately, the economy is highly complex, and mathematical models can provide only a simplified
description of the underlying system. As such, models often miss important elements of reality, especially
in exceptional times when many unprecedented events occur simultaneously. For instance, standard
macroeconomic models are not well suited for analyzing the recent events associated with the COVID-19
pandemic and its effects. Models are unlikely to accurately capture such unprecedented events and, as
such, may provide a distorted description of the economy, leading to misguided policy counterfactuals.
In this context, how can we approach “what if” questions? In recent work, Barnichon and Mesters (2022)
propose a solution: they show that it is possible to study policy counterfactuals without having to rely on a
fully specified economic model. Specifically, two sets of statistics are sufficient: a baseline macroeconomic
forecast, known informally as the economic outlook, and how much adjusting the policy instrument will
affect the economy, known informally as the policy multiplier.
Intuitively, starting from a baseline macroeconomic forecast capturing how the economy is expected to
perform under the status quo baseline policy, it is possible to compute how the economy would perform
under a different policy by simply adding the predicted effect of the policy change to the baseline forecast.

Estimating the sufficient statistics
Studying counterfactuals requires estimates for these two “sufficient” statistics: a baseline economic
forecast and the marginal effect of policy. Fortunately, these statistics are often readily available. First,
policymakers routinely publish their baseline economic forecast as part of their decisionmaking process.
Second, a large academic literature has estimated the marginal effects of policy, notably using so-called
natural experiments. While economists cannot conduct controlled experiments, nature or history
sometimes provides such natural experiments that allow them to tease out cause and effect in
macroeconomics (Nakamura and Steinsson 2018). For instance, to estimate the effect of a monetary policy
change, such as an interest rate hike, on inflation and unemployment, a natural experiment would be a
policy decision made for a reason unrelated to the short-run evolution of inflation and unemployment.
This could be when the Fed may have reacted to exceptional developments in financial markets or may
have changed policy because of a change in FOMC members.
2

FRBSF Economic Letter 2022-28 | October 11, 2022
A rich body of prior economic research
Figure 1
has developed methodologies for
Effect of policy rate change on unemployment, inflation
identifying such natural experiments—
Percentage points
0.8
or monetary policy “shocks”—and using
0.7
them to compute the marginal effect of
0.6
a policy change. Barnichon and
0.5
Mesters (2022) estimate the effect of
Unemployment
0.4
raising the federal funds rate one0.3
quarter percentage point (25 basis
0.2
points) during one year using historical
0.1
data over 1990–2007. Although the
0
sample period is relatively short, it has
-0.1
the benefit of focusing on a fairly stable
Inflation
-0.2
period in the conduct of monetary
-0.3
policy, as well as avoiding the zero
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10 11 12 13
Quarters
lower bound period when there were
Note: For details, see Barnichon and Mesters (2022). Dashed lines denote the upper and
no federal funds policy changes.
lower ranges of the 95% confidence bands for the line of the same color.
However, one caveat is that the
empirical effects from this previous period may be different in an episode like the pandemic.

14

The results, illustrated in Figure 1, point to two key patterns. First, monetary policy takes at least a year to
substantially affect inflation. Second, a federal funds rate shock large enough to bring inflation down about
0.1 percentage point (pp) after two years would be expected to increase unemployment by about 0.3pp
over the same period. This second finding quantifies the unemployment-inflation tradeoff that monetary
policymakers must grapple with. That said, the shaded areas showing the 95% confidence bands indicate
that these effects are estimated with substantial uncertainty.

Back to March 2021
With estimates of the two sufficient statistics in hand, we can look back to March 2021 and start asking
“what if” questions. In March 2021, unemployment stood at 6.2% and inflation was low, with core personal
consumption expenditures (PCE) price inflation sitting at 1.7% for the first quarter of the year. After the
passage of the American Rescue Plan, a few economists worried that inflation tensions could develop due
to the interaction of supply bottlenecks created by the pandemic and the strong demand boost injected by
the fiscal package (see, for example, Blanchard 2021 and Summers 2021). Yet at the time, the FOMC
anticipated a modest rise in inflation, and unemployment was expected to return slowly to its long-run
level of around 4%.This outlook was generally shared by FOMC members and professional forecasters: for
instance, as of March 2021, the median forecast in the FOMC’s Summary of Economic Projections (SEP)
anticipated a modest 2.4% inflation rate for 2021, in line with the March 2021 Blue Chip inflation forecast
of 2.3%.

3

FRBSF Economic Letter 2022-28 | October 11, 2022
Indeed, the reality turned out very different
from the forecasts. Figures 2 and 3 plot the
paths of inflation and unemployment
through the first quarter of 2022. While
unemployment declined as anticipated, core
inflation reached historic highs.

What if the Fed had foreseen the
inflation surge?
In this context, an interesting question is
whether, and more importantly by how
much, the Fed might have raised the federal
funds rate, if FOMC members had
anticipated the inflation surge that was to
come.
To study this question, imagine that we
stand in March 2021 and the Fed foresees
that, if they make no policy changes, we will
experience the inflation outburst that in fact
occurred. That is, assume that the Fed’s
March 2021 forecast looks like the solid lines
of Figures 2 and 3: these lines depict the
actual paths until the first quarter of 2022
and the median forecasts from the FOMC’s
June 2022 SEP afterward.

Figure 2
Path of inflation: actual versus counterfactual
Percent
6
5

Actual

4
3
2
Counterfactual with early policy tightening
1
Forecast
0
2021

2022

2023

2024

Note: Solid line “actual” data after the first quarter of 2022 reflect June 2022 median
SEP forecasts.

Figure 3
Path of unemployment: actual versus counterfactual
Percent
7

Counterfactual with early policy tightening

6
5
4
3

Actual

Given the estimated effect of policy (Figure
2
1), we can compute the change in the policy
1
path that, as of March 2021, would have best
Forecast
stabilized inflation and unemployment.
0
2021
2022
2023
2024
Figure 4 plots the results: the federal funds
rate rises immediately by about 1pp in
Note: Solid line “actual” data after the first quarter of 2022 reflect June 2022 median
SEP forecasts.
March 2021 and then increases to close to
2% by early 2022. With that intervention,
the Fed would have dampened the rise in inflation at the cost of higher unemployment: the dotted lines
show that inflation would be 1pp lower (Figure 2) and unemployment would be about 2pp higher (Figure
3). That said, these estimates are highly uncertain: the range of possible results within a 95% confidence
level (not shown) indicate that inflation would be between 0.2pp and 2pp lower, while unemployment
would be between 1pp and 3pp higher.
4

FRBSF Economic Letter 2022-28 | October 11, 2022
An important lesson of this exercise is
that, even with perfect foresight, the Fed
may have weighed the possible outcomes
and may have chosen not to eliminate all
of the rise in inflation. The reason is that
higher rates to combat inflation also
generate higher unemployment, creating a
tension between the two goals in the dual
mandate. When such tensions arise, the
Fed takes into account the misses from its
dual objectives when setting policy. If the
Fed had no unemployment mandate and
only focused on inflation, it could have
kept inflation low, but at the cost of an
unemployment rate climbing above 10%
(not shown).

Conclusion

Figure 4
Path of federal funds rate: actual versus counterfactual
Percent
5

Counterfactual with early policy tightening

4
Actual

3

2

1
Forecast
0
2021

2022

2023

2024

Note: Solid line “actual” data after the first quarter of 2022 reflect June 2022 median
SEP forecasts.

If the Federal Reserve had known about the upcoming inflation surge in early 2021 and had acted
immediately to combat it, how different would the economy be today? Perhaps surprisingly, my analysis in
this Letter suggests that it may have been preferable to only moderately raise the federal funds rate during
2021, such that inflation would be only about 1 percentage point lower now, and unemployment would
stand around 6%, about 2 percentage points higher. The reason for this moderate policy reaction is rooted
in the Fed’s dual mandate, such that any monetary policy aimed at containing inflation typically will take
into account the response of unemployment. Naturally, these estimates are subject to substantial
uncertainty, given the wide statistical ranges for our estimates and unique conditions associated with the
pandemic economy.
Regis Barnichon
Senior Research Advisor, Economic Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

References
Barnichon, Regis, and Geert Mesters. 2022. “A Sufficient Statistics Approach for Macro Policy Evaluation.” FRB San
Francisco Working Paper 2022-15.
Blanchard, Olivier. 2021. “U.S. Inflation Is Running High. What Should We Worry About Now?” Realtime Economics
Issues Watch (November 11), Peterson Institute for International Economics.
Nakamura, Emi, and Jón Steinsson. 2018. “Identification in Macroeconomics.” Journal of Economic Perspectives
32(3), pp. 59–86.
Powell, Jerome. 2022. “Fed Chair Jerome Powell: “Whether We Can Execute a Soft Landing or Not, It May Actually
Depend on Factors That We Don’t Control.” Marketplace, May 12 interview with Kai Rysdall.
5

FRBSF Economic Letter 2022-28 | October 11, 2022

Summers, Lawrence H. 2021. “Opinion: The Biden Stimulus Is Admirably Ambitious. But It Brings Some Big Risks, Too.”
Washington Post, February 4.

Opinions expressed in FRBSF Economic Letter do not necessarily reflect the views of the
management of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or of the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System. This publication is edited by Anita Todd and Karen Barnes. Permission to
reprint portions of articles or whole articles must be obtained in writing. Please send editorial
comments and requests for reprint permission to research.library@sf.frb.org

Recent issues of FRBSF Economic Letter are available at
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/
2022-27 Daly

The Singularity of the Dual Mandate
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/october/singularity-of-dual-mandate/

2022-26 Kmetz/
Mondragon/
Wieland

Remote Work and Housing Demand
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/september/remote-work-and-housing-demand/

2022-25 Jordà / Liu /
Nechio /
Rivera-Reyes

Wage Growth When Inflation is High
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/september/wage-growth-when-inflation-is-high/

2022-24 Bok /
Finding a Soft Landing along the Beveridge Curve
Petrosky-Nadeau https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/august/finding-soft-landing-along-beveridge-curve/
2022-23 Roth Tran

The Impact of Weather on Retail Sales
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/august/impact-of-weather-on-retail-sales/

2022-22 Paul

Two Years into COVID, What’s the State of U.S. Businesses?
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/august/two-years-into-covid-what-is-state-of-us-businesses/

2022-21

Will Workers Demand Cost-of-Living Adjustments
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/august/will-workers-demand-cost-of-living-adjustments/

Glick
Leduc
Pepper

2022-20 Christensen
Spiegel

COVID-19 Fiscal Expansion and Inflation Expectations in Japan
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/august/covid-19-fiscal-expansion-and-inflation-expectations-in-japan/