View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FABSF

WEEKLY LETTER

Number 94-09, March 4, 1994

Monetary Policy in the 19905
The following is adapted from a speech given by
Robert T. Parry, President and Chief Executive
Officer of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, on January 14, 1994, to the Los Angeles
chapter of the National Association of Business
Economists.

This Letter discusses challenges in conducting
monetary policy in the 1990s-now that the monetary aggregates have proved unreliable. The
source of these challenges is financial changethat is, the sweeping financial deregulation and
innovation that began 20 years ago. As these developments spread through the financial markets,
they undermined the reliability of the monetary
aggregates. As a result, the aggregates were no
longer reliable indicators of monetary policy.
Moreover, they have been confusing to the public who may watch them to figure out the stance
of monetary policy. M1, which used to be our
main indicator, has been soaring for three years.
But the growth of M2, which replaced M1 as our
prime indicator, has been feeble. And contrary to
either indicator, we've had moderate growth and
well-behaved inflation. My focus will be on how
the Fed has handled policy without reliable aggregates, and on a couple of options under discussion as indicators or targets-real interest
rates and nominal GOP.

fiscal restraint. In the U.S. defense cuts and other
deficit-reducing measures in the US. are important factors that have restrained aggregate demand and slowed economic growth. And for the
last few years, economic activity in our major
trading partners has been lackluster, or worse. In
the other G-7 countries-Canada, France, Germany, Italy, the UK., and Japan-output grew on
average by only 1% percent in 1991, not at all in
1992, and (based on incomplete data) probably
by less than 1 percent last year; Although there
are a variety of special factors operating in individual countries, one common reason behind
these developments is policies designed to cut
rates of inflation. All of these countries have
made significant progress in reducing inflation
in recent years.
The Fed's role in countering these forces was to
lower interest rates-down to about a third what
they were in 1989. But we lowered them gradually and cautiously because of our concerns
about inflation. Like many other central banks,
we want to bring inflation down and keep it
close to zero where it will not distort economic
decisionmaking. Thus, in February, we raised the
funds rate by 25 basis points against a background of a sharp acceleration in the pace of
economic activity and declines in the amount
of slack in labor and product markets.

The economic setting in the U.S. and abroad
Not surprisingly, a good deal of attention has
been focused on the rapid real GOP growth in
the latter half of last year, and especially on the
nearly 6 percent growth rate registered in the
fourth quarter. But a longer-term perspective
shows the current expansion so far has been
moderate by postwar standards. Over the 11
quarters since the business cycle trough in early
1991, real GOP has risen at an average annual
rate of 2% percent-well below the 5 percent
average growth rate in previous expansions that
have lasted at least this long.

Although a policy of lowering inflation has its
costs in the short run, I believe it is worth it, because, in the long run, inflation reduces economic well-being (see Motley 1993). For one
thing, inflation often is associated with uncertainty about future inflation, which fosters higher
long-term real interest rates. Uncertainty also
complicates the planning and contracting businesses do that are so essential to capital formation, and it drives people to wasteful hedging
activities. Finally, inflation heightens the distortionary effects of our tax system.

Why did the economy "creep" out of the recession, rather than "boom" back, as it usually
does? Basically because the US., as well as many
of our major trading partners, are in a stage of
transition-a stage marked by disinflation and

Monetary aggregates
Now comes the problem of implementing a lowinflation policy without relying on the monetary
aggregates. The beauty of the aggregates was that
they helped us solve the "lag problem"-that is,

FRBSF
the classic "long and variable lag" between policy actions and inflation-probably 1V2 to 2
years. The aggregates were easily measured, we
could control them reasonably well in the short
run, and they had a fairly stable relationship to
long-run inflation.
What happened to them? To summarize some 20
years in a single phrase, deregulation and innovation swept through financial markets. Interest rate
ceilings on deposits were eliminated, new substitutes for deposits in M1 and M2 cropped up,
and shifting funds from one instrument to another got a lot less expensive. Of course, this
innovation and deregulation has been great for
the overall economy: It has brought us more
choices than ever to manage our financial affairs,
and it has made financial markets far more dynamic and efficient.
But it has created problems for monetary policy.
Growth rates of Ml and M2 no longer give us dependable information about future inflationthey often just reflect portfolio substitutions. For
example, over the past two years, M2 growth has
slowed dramatically-to an average of only 1V2
percent; if M2 were a reliable indicator of future
inflation, it would imply outright deflation in
1994. With inflation currently a little below 3
percent, that's clearly wide of the mark. Why did
M2 growth slow so dramatically? One important
reason is the steep yield curve of the last few
years. Households switched out of short-term,
low-yielding M2 holdings and into long-term,
higher-yielding stock and bond mutua! funds.
Now, I do not mean to imply that because we
have lost the aggregates as reliable indicators,
we are helpless. We have always looked at a
number of real and financial variables and have
based our decisions on a good deal of judgment.
And I think we have done fairly well. Real GDP
growth has been respectable, and inflation has
come down. The core inflation rate is now only a
little above 3 percent-better than the 4 to 412
percent rates we saw around the turn of the decade. And i think we are in a good position to
make further gradual progress on inflation. But I
would certainly be more comfortable about it if
I could look at a reliable leading indicator of inflation. Several indicators or targets to replace the
aggregates have been suggested in recent years. I
will focus on two: real interest rates and nominal
income targeti ng.

Real interest rates
The real interest rate is appealing because it has
a direct effect on business and household spending decisions. But italso has problems. Real interest rates are hard to measure because they
depend on unobservable expectations of future
inflation. And the Fed cannot target real interest
rates beyond the short run because they are determined by market forces. Finally, real interest
rates are meaningful indicators only compared
with a benchmark-an equilibrium real ratethat would be consistent with full employment.
That equilibrium rate is not directly observable,
and it is difficult to estimate, because it is affected by factors like productivity, government
spending, and income tax rates. So the real interest rate does not appear to be a good candidate
for the Fed's main inflation indicator (Cogley
1993, and Trehan 1993).
But that is not to say that real interest rates are
never useful. If real rates stay very high or very
low, that can be a warning sign. Look atthe
1970s, for instance. Real rates were persistently
negative, and that meant significant inflationary
pressures were building up. More recentlY,in the
past year or so, short-term real rates have been
close to zero (Figure 1). The recent rise in the
funds rate has raised real short-term rates somewhat, but they still are at fairly low levels. Is this
an early warning? Well, I would say this situation
does bear watching.

Figure 1
Real 3-Month T~Bi!1 Rate*

Percent

8

4

l

::r....::

r:~

.:;:;:

"::;;.

~~~

::}
:::;::
::;:

60

-:.;.

)~

:;:;::

t::
.;.;,;

1111

::::::
::::;:

64

68

72

76

80

84

88

* 3-Month T-bill rate less CPI inflation over
prior 12 months.

92

Nominal GDP
The second approach uses targets for aggregate
demand, or nominal GOP. Nominal GOP is appealing as a monetary policy target because its
long-run relationship with inflation is relatively
stable. Furthermore, it will remain stable unless
there's a sudden dramatic change in the trend
growth of real GOP. So it is clearly immune to
the effects of financial change that have undermined the monetary aggregates.
The problem with nominal GDP is that it does
not respond to policy actions as quickly as
money did, though the lag is shorter than the inflation lag. Some recent research on so-called
"feedback rules" for nominal GOP suggests a
way around this lag problem (McCallum 1990,
Judd and Motley 1993, and Taylor 1993). Feedback rules provide "recommendations" for
policy in the short run that are designed to control nominal GOP-and therefore inflation-in
the long run. The policymaker sets a target for
nominal GOP that is consistent with the inflation
goal. Then, if the latest quarter's actual data are
outside the target, the formula indicates by how
much the funds rate should be raised or lowered.
Consider an example of an inflationary episode
using one version of the rule the staff at the San
Francisco Fed has explored. Suppose the inflation
target is 1 percent. To allow for trend growth in
real GOP of about 3 percent, a nominal GOP
growth target would be set at 3Y2 percent. Now
suppose actual nominal GOP growth in one
quarter comes in at 4Y2 percent. That feedback
rule would call for raising the funds rate by 20
basis points. If nominal GOP continued to exceed its target, the rule would likewise call for
further increases until nominal GOP hit its target.
So with this approach, policymakers would have
a guide for responding to actual recent data on
aggregate demand and have more confidence
that they would hit their inflation target in the
long run. Of course, this approach is still in
the research stage. And, I personally wouldn't be
comfortable with strictly following any formula.
But I think this approach merits consideration.
The policy recommendations it generates might

be a useful input that provides a benchmark in
making judgmental policy decisions.

Conclusion
This Letter addressed some of the issues involved
in conducting monetary policy in the 1990s-a
time of worldwide disinflation, fiscal restraint,
and continuing dynamism in financial markets.
Replaci ng the monetary aggregates as targets
for policy is not going to be easy. They not only
served as a guide for monetary policymakers, but
they also gave useful signals to everyone else
about the future effects of policy. Even without
useful guidance from the aggregates, though, we
have managed to lower inflation. So let me conclude by assuring you that the erosion of the aggregates as reliable inflation indicators has not
eroded our commitment to moving gradually toward zero inflation, which I believe is the best
way the Fed can help the U.S. economy achieve
its maximum growth potential.

Robert. T. Parry
President and Chief Executive Officer

References
Cogley, Timothy. 1993. "Monetary Policy and LongTerm Real Interest Rates!' FRBSF Weekly Letter
93-42 (December 3).
Judd, John P., and Brian Motley. 1993. "Using a Nominal GDP Rule to Guide a Discretionary Monetary
Policy!' Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Review (3) pp. 3-11.
McCallum, Bennett. 1990. "Targets, Indicators, and Instruments of Monetary Policy." NBER Reprint No.
1550.
Motley, Brian. 1993. "Inflation and Growth!' FRBSF
Weekly Letter 93-44 (December 31).
Taylor, John B. 1992. "Discretion Versus Policy Rules in
Practice:' CEPR Publication No. 327. Center for
Economic Policy Research, Stanford University.
Trehan, Bharat. 1992. "Real Interest Rates:' FRBSF
Weekly Letter 93-38 (November 5).

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor or to the author.... Free copies of Federal Reserve publications can be
obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco 94120.
Phone (415) 974-2246, Fax (415) 974-3341.

~

t.r\

·S~U1 ueaqAos 41lM

~ 'C!JI Jaded papAOaJ uo pajUlJd

OZL176 \I)

'O:lSPUPJJ

WLL

X09

upS
·O·d

OJSIJUOJ::I UOS

JO ~U08
aAJaSa~ IOJapa::l
~uaw~Jodaa 4)JOaSa~

Index to Recent Issues of FRBSF Weekly Letter

DATE NUMBER TITLE
9/10
9/17
9/24
10/1
1n/o

lUlU

10/15
10/22
10/29
11 /5
11/12
11/19
11/26
12/3
12/17
12/31
1/7
1/14
1/21
1/28
2/4
2/11
2/18
2/25

93-30
93-31
93-32
93-33
93-34
93-35
93-36
93-37
93-38
93-39
93-40
93-41
93-42
93-43
93-44
94-01
94-02
94-03
94-04
94-05
94-06
94-07
94-08

AUTHOR

Summer Special Edition: Touring the West
The Federal Budget Deficit, Saving and Investment, and Growth
Adequate's not Good Enough
Have Recessions Become Shorter?

Cromwell
Throop
Furlong
Huh

Cal ifornia's ~~eighbors

Cromwell

Inflation, Interest Rates and Seasonality
Difficult Times for japanese Agencies and Branches
Regional Comparative Advantage
Real Interest Rates
A Pacific Economic Bloc: Is There Such an Animal?
NAFTA and the Western Economy
Are World Incomes Converging?
Monetary Policy and Long-Term Real Interest Rates
Banks and Mutual Funds
Inflation and Growth
Market Risk and Bank Capital: Part 1
Market Risk and Bank Capital: Part 2
The Real Effects of Exchange Rates
Banking Market Structure in the West
Is There a Cost to Having an Independent Central Bank?
Stock Prices and Bank Lending Behavior in japan
Taiwan at the Crossroads
1994 District Agricultural Outlook

Biehl/judd
Zimmerman
Schmidt
Trehan
Frankel/Wei
Schm idtiSherwood-Call
Moreno
Cogley
Laderman
Motley
Levonian
Levonian
Throop
Laderman
Walsh
Kim/Moreno
Cheng
Dean

The FRBSF Weekly Letter appears on an abbreviated schedule in june, july, August, and December.