View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

M in i-O P EC 's?
More than a thousand delegates
will meet next month in Nairobi,
Kenya, to discuss development
problems under the auspices of the
United Nations Conference on
Trade and Development (UNC­
TAD). At these negotiations, the oil­
importing less-developed countries
(LDCs) will make a strong attempt
to improve their economic position
relative to the industrialized world,
as they have been trying to do ever
since the success of the Arab oil
embargo.

and weather conditions. Second,
demand grows rather slowly, in
relation to both available capacity
and manufactured-goods demand,
so that increased sales often occur
only at declining prices. Following
the Korean war boom, export
prices received by non-oil produc­
ing LDCs dropped more than 8
percent over the 1951-72 period,
while their import prices rose by 15
percent. Consequently, this shift in
the terms of trade seriously eroded
their purchasing power.

Less-developed countries argue
that non-oil commodity prices have
fallen relative to manufacturedgoods prices for practically all of
the past quarter-century—the com­
modity boom of the 1972-74 period
being a brief exception—and thus
they propose that commodity
prices be set at higher levels and
then pegged to a manufacturedgoods price index to ensure future
parity. However, they may find
from the experience of other
would-be cartelists that boosting
prices is not always quite so simple.

For a brief span in the 1972-74 peri­
od, the LDCs thought that a new
era of prosperity had dawned. Non­
oil commodity prices nearly dou­
bled, as a synchronized boom
throughout the industrialized
world and a wave of speculative
buying fueled by the Arab oil em­
bargo pushed the demand for com­
modities beyond the limits of cur­
rently available capacity. But then
the bubble burst with the deepen­
ing of the world-wide recession and
the liquidation of excess specula­
tive inventories. Indeed, despite a
recent upturn, the spot-price index
of two-dozen internationallytraded commodities still stands
about 22 percent below its July 1974
peak. Moreover, with import prices
sharply rising and export prices
weakening, the combined balanceof-payments deficit of oil­
importing LDCs surged from $9
billion in 1973 to $38 billion in 1975.

Recurring weakness

Exports of primary products ac­
count for some 75 percent of the
total export earnings of the non-oil
producing LD Cs. Consequently,
fluctuations in commodity prices
and quantities can have a destabi­
lizing effect on their economies,
which generally have little margin
for error. Yet with few exceptions,
the market for their major products
is relatively unstable. First, prices of
these products fluctuate widely,
reflecting the vagaries of the busi­
ness cycle, speculative influences



Stabilization efforts

For decades developing countries
have sought to stabilize their export
earnings by entering into interna­
tional commodity agreements to
(continued on page 2)

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not
necessarily reflect the views of the management of the
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, nor of the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

regulate production, export
quantities and prices. Prior to the
Arab oil embargo, agreements were
in effect for wheat, coffee, sugar
and tin, utilizing such stabilization
techniques as buffer stocks, long­
term purchase contracts and export
quotas. Immediately after the oil
embargo, however, many of the
developing countries tried to apply
the OPEC tactics elsewhere. How­
ever, efforts of this type have suc­
ceeded only in periods of sharply
rising demand. Thus, when four
major copper exporters attempted
in late 1974 to halt slumping copper
prices with a 10-percent cut in ex­
ports, their efforts were singularly
unsuccessful. Instead, the foreign
producer price dropped from an
all-time high of $1.52 per pound in
April 1974 to only $0.53 per pound
in December 1975, and rose only to
$0.63 in the ensuing recovery.
Mini-OPEC's?

The ability of a group of restrictionist producers to raise prices above
competitive levels depends on the
size of their share of world output
and exports, the lack of easily avail­
able substitute materials, and the
cohesiveness of the group. In the
case of copper, the four cartel
members (Chile, Peru, Zaire and
Zambia) account for over 40 per­
cent of non-Communist world pro­
duction. But four developed
countries—the United States, Cana­
da, South Africa and Australia—
account for a slightly greater share,
while a large number of small pro­
ducers account for the remainder.




The cartel's control over the market
also has been diluted by an increase
in the supply of recycled scrap,
which accounts for over one-fifth
of total production. On the de­
mand side, copper is sensitive to
recession because its markets are
dependent upon the highly cyclical
durable-goods and construction in­
dustries. Given the sharp decline in
consumer demand and the produc­
ing countries' reluctance to reduce
employment in the industry, the
copper cartel's members have been
unable to reduce production suffi­
ciently to prevent an excessive
buildup of producer inventories.
In fact, most analysts question
whether any other producer groups
can duplicate the success of the
OPEC cartel in limiting production
and boosting prices. Petroleum is
influenced much less than other
commodities by cyclical move­
ments in business activity. With a
cushion of large foreign-exchange
reserves built up in past years, most
oil-producing nations have been
able to curtail production without
suffering short-run repercussions.
The industry is capital rather than
labor intensive, so that restrictions
on production have not had serious
employment effects. For most of
the members, enmity against a
common political adversary has
served as a unifying factor.
In contrast, most other basicmaterials industries lack the charac­
teristics required for the establish­
ment of workable cartels. For most
minerals, sources of supply are

widespread among both industrial­
ized and developing countries, sub­
stitutes and stockpile metal are
readily available—while industry
employment is too labor intensive,
and foreign-exchange reserves too
small, to make production cutbacks
feasible. Moreover, even if a pro­
ducer association tried to establish
a minimum price, individual
producers might try to undercut
the fixed price to expand produc­
tion and to increase their share of
the market.
For many primary commodities,
industrialized nations account for a
substantial share of world produc­
tion. The United States and Canada
are prominent producers of cop­
per, lead and zinc, for example,
while Canada, Australia and South
Africa are important producers of
nickel and iron ore. It is unlikely
that these countries would be will­
ing to join formal producer cartels,
although they might follow price­
raising actions by others during
periods of market strength. In fact,
less-developed countries account
for only one-quarter of the world's
total non-oil primary exports, and
their share has been drifting down­
ward during the past two decades.
Strong U.S. position

Overall, the United States is in a
relatively favorable position with
regard to the two-dozen or so non­
fuel industrial materials deemed
critical to national security. Imports
of these materials, mostly ores and
metals, comprise only about 15 per­
cent of total U.S. consumption, in
3




marked contrast to the dependency
of Western Europe (75 percent) and
Japan (90 percent).
U.S. reliance on foreign imports
varies greatly with respect to indi­
vidual materials. For example, this
country is nearly self-sufficient in
copper but totally dependent on
foreign tin. Canada, Australia and
South Africa supply over two thirds
of total U.S. industrial raw-material
imports, but developing countries
are significant sources for such
materials as bauxite, manganese, tin
and natural rubber. The United
States also relies on the U.S.S.R. for
significant amounts of two items—
platinum and chromium—
necessary for steel production.
None of these materials approaches
petroleum in terms of significance
to the U.S. economy, however. In
1975, U.S. petroleum imports
amounted to $24.8 billion, or about
one-fourth of total imports, but
purchases of iron ore, the second
ranking import, amounted to only
$0.8 billion. The 1973-75 quadru­
pling of oil import prices increased
the U.S. oil-import bill by about $17
billion, causing nearly a 25-percent
hike in overall import costs. A simi­
lar price increase for iron ore would
raise total import costs by only 2
percent. Nevertheless, despite its
strong position as one of the
world’s largest diversified rawmaterial producers, the United
States has an important stake in
ensuring an adequate supply of
non-fuel materials.
Yvonne Levy

uoiSinqsEM • i)Etn • uoSa-io • epeAaN • ogepi
M EM EH

.

E jU J O p iE ^

.

E U O Z JJV

•

• |j|E 3 ' o a s p u e j j u e §

ZSL ON llWH3d
aivd
39ViSOd s n
1IVW SSV1D 1SMIJ

BANKING DATA—TWELFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)

Selected Assets and Liabilities
Large Commercial Banks

Amount
Outstanding
3/24/76

Loans (gross, adjusted) and investments*
Loans (gross, adjusted)—total
Security loans
Commercial and industrial
Real estate
Consumer instalment
U.S. Treasury securities
Other securities
Deposits (less cash items)—total*
Demand deposits (adjusted)
U.S. Government deposits
Time deposits—total*
States and political subdivisions
Savings deposits
Other time deposits:):
Large negotiable CD's

87,045
64,645
875
23,102
19,526
10,633
9,707
12,693
87,133
23,989
242
61,666
6,144
25,217
27,833
12,695

Weekly Averages
of Daily Figures

Week ended
3/24/76

Change
from
3/17/76

Change from
year ago
Dollar
Percent

-

+ 1,652
791
564
983
262
+ 780
+ 2,237
+ 206
+ 2,583
+ 1,153
- 129
+ 1,446
544
+ 5,818
2,570
- 4,322

-

+
+
+
+
+
+
-

+
+
+
+

100
76
134
6
15
23
20
44
33
292
195
184
33
146
122
75

Week ended
3/17/76

+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
-

1.93
1.21
39.19
4.08
1.32
7.92
29.95
1.65
3.05
5.05
34.77
2.40
8.13
29.99
8.45
25.40

Comparable
year-ago period

Member Bank Reserve Position
Excess Reserves
Borrowings
Net free(+)/Net borrowed (-)

+

89
2
87

-

13
1
14

+

35
15
20

Federal Funds—Seven Large Banks
Interbank Federal fund transactions
Net purchases (+)/Net sales (-)
Transactions of U.S. security dealers
Net loans (+)/Net borrowings (-)

+ 1,287

+ 1,543

+ 1,740

+

+

+

25

310

715

*lncludes items not shown separately. ^Individuals, partnerships and corporations.

Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (William Burke) or to the author. . . .Information
on this and other publications can be obtained by calling or writing the Public Information Section,
Digitized for Fr ASER*^ ^ eserve
$an Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco 94120. Phone (415) 544-2184.


E>|S E|V